PHN Technical Notes GEN 3 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC APPRAISAL IN THE HEALTH SECTOR January 4, 1982 Population, Health and Nutrition Department * This paper is one of a series issued by 'the Population, * * Health and Nutrition Department for the information and * * guidance of Bank staff working in these sectors. The * * views and opinions expressed in this paper do not neces- * * sarily reflect those of the Bank. * sassasswww www.w......AA.................*..*...***.**** GEN 3 ABSTRACT This paper discusses the role of economic appraisal in the formulation of health sector policy in less developed countries. Specifically, it focuses on the application of economic analysis to public investment decisions in the health, sector, that is to the design, selection and financing of projects which constitute the health component of a development plan. Topics covered include financial analysis of health projects with particular reference to the problem of.recurrent cost financing, the techniques of cost-effectiveness and cost-benefit analysis, the treatment of uncertainty and shadow pricing in health project analysis, and alternative approaches to resource mobilization in the health sector. The underlying theme of the paper is the desirability of integrating the health sector more closely with the overall framework of development planning through a systematic process of project appraisal based on clearly specified objectives and resource constraints. Prepared by: Nicholas Prescott and Jeremy Warford Population, Health and Nutrition Department January 1982 ECONO'IC APPRAISAL IN THE HEALTH SECTOR by - Nicholas Prescott and Jeremy Warford 1. Introduction This paper discusses the role of economic appraisal in the formulation of health sector policy in less developed countries (LDCs). Specifically, it focuses on the application of economic analysis to public investment deci- sions in the health sector, that is to the design, selection and financing of projects which constitute the health component of a development plan. The underlying theme is the desirability of integrating the health sector more closely with the overall framework of development planning through a syste- matic process of project appraisal based on clearly specified objectives and resource constraints. Generalizations about LDCs as a group are inevitably heroic when - as described by the World Bank - they comprise countries as diverse as India, Lesotho, Fiji, Korea, Brazil and Chad. However, by definition, all of these countries share the characteristic of a relatively low level of per capita income (World Bank, 1981), typically associated with a limited tax base due to weak tax administration and low ratios of taxable surplus to GNP (Tait et al, 1979; Meerman, 1980). The combination of these factors produces an acute shortage of resources to finance public expenditure, thus emphasizing the im- portance of achieving efficient investment planning in the public sector. This is particularly true today when the prospects for per capita income growth in LDCs have deteriorated markedly (World. Bank, 1981) and the adoption of structural adjustment policies is enforcing a more rigorous review of public investment programs (Balassa, 1982). Other characteristics commonly observed in LDCs include overvalued exchange rates, substantial unemployment -2- or underemployment and a skewed income distribution, together with a variety of constraints which limit the ability of their governments to increase pri- vate savings and redistribute income with the conventional instruments of fiscal and monetary policy. These factors have important implications for project selection in the health sector. Resource allocation decisions have in the past been notori- ously inefficient and inequitable, and are now reflected in an emphasis on expensive urban and hospital-based curative care which is not directed at the major causes of ill-health in the majority of LDC populations. bbreover, health has tended to claim a low and often declining share of public expendi- ture (IMF, 1981), and the prospects for a substantial increase in real budge- tary allocations to the sector are poor. At the same tirde, recent interest in basic needs and the efforts by WHO and UNICEF to promote 'Health for All by the Year 2000' have created ambitious objectives for health improvement in LDCs. The Director-General of WHO has suggested that an infant mortality rate of less than 50 per thousand live births, and a life expectancy at birth greater than 60 years, should be minimum objectives for health improvement by the year 2000 (Mahler, 1977). These contrast with infant mortality rates higher,than 200 per thousand, and life expectancies lower than 40 years, ob- served in some low-income LDCs. The financial implications of these objec- tives are enormous. A recent WHO estimate implies that their achievement would require up to an eight-fold increase over the present level of public expenditure on health in low-income LDCs of approximately $2.5 per capita (WHO, 1981). However, the health sector continues to operate, to an extent that is unmatched in any other sector, without the guidance of systematic project appraisal criteria which could help to reconcile these health objec- tives with other development objectives in the face of increasingly severe resorce constraints. It is, therefore, essential to develop ways of improving the efficiency of public expenditure on health in LDCs, and also of mobilizing additional revenue to finance increased levels of expenditure. This paper examines these issues in the following framework. Section two discusses the basic elements of financial analysis which provide the starting point for analysis of efficiency and resource mobilization. Sections three and four review al- ternative forms of efficiency criteria, namely cost-effectiveness and cost- benefit analysis, with special attention to the treatment of uncertainty and shadow pricing in health projects (section five). Section six concludes with a consideration of cost recovery options to mobilize additional resorces from outside the public sector. 2. Financial Analysis Health ministries, using conventional public accounting procedures in LDCs, are generally unaware in detail of the allocation of public resources between different interventions and its relationship to stated health objec- tives, or of the unit costs of different interventions, or of the full poten- tial of available sources of finance. The situation is complicated by the activities of numerous other agencies, both public aid private, that affect health, major examples being those agencies concerned with water supply, nutrition and pharmaceutical production and distribution. This lack of basic financial data severely limits the ability of health ministries to make sys- tematic judgements about the merits of existing and proposed expenditure patterns and financing policies in the public sector, and reform of their financial accounting systems is clearly indicated. The starting point for economic analysis of investment decisions should be a detailed analysis of total public and private health-related expenditures in terms of expenditure patterns and sources of finance. Another paper is devoted to this set of issues, but it is appropriate here to highlight a few of the main features. -4- Expenditure patterns. Analysis of the allocation of public expenditure between different interventions indicates the extent to which the current ex- penditure pattern responds to a country's major health problems and pro- claimed objectives. Thus, it helps to signal the desirability of reallocat- ing existing expenditures or undertaking new investments. If, as rhetoric suggests, distributional objectives are also important, analysis of the dis- tribution of expenditure by beneficiaries in different income classes (Meerman, 1979; Selowsky, 1979, Tan, 1975), or simply by region (Ofosu-Amaaih, 1975), will be similarly revealing. Estimates of the unit costs of different interventions, making an appro- priate - if not scientific - allocation of joint costs, provide additional signals. Ideally, these should be estimated in terms of long-run marginal costs, which relate capital expansion and recurrent (i.e. operating and re- placement) costs to the volume of additional services provided (Saunders et al, 1977). Differences in the unit cost of interventions suggest the possi- bility of efficiency gains by switching expenditure to lower cost interven- tions if these are equally effective. The same applies to unit cost differ- ences for similar interventions delivered by different facilities. For example, a study in Malaysia found that the unit cost of outpatient services in rural clinics exceeded those provided by hospitals, suggesting the exist- ence of significant excess capacity in the rural clinic system (Meerman, 1979). Similar comparisons can be made between the public and private sec- tors. Data collected in Lesotho (Smith, 1980) indicate that the public sec- tor is a relatively inefficient producer of health services. The average cost per inpatient was almost three times higher in public than private hos- pitals, and similar differentials existed for hospital and clinic outpa- tients. Although unadjusted for case-mix and labor cost differences, it is improbable that these factors fully accounted for such high unit cost differ -5- entials. Finally, with the objective of ct containment in mind, trends in the unit costs of similar interventions at different points in time may be used to monitor efficiency in service provision. Source of finance. In a similar way, analysis of the sources of finance of existing healtbexpenditure patterns - by public revenues, external donors, private consumers, employers and charity organizations - can provide important signals to more efficient methods of mobilizing resources for the health sector. For example, available data showing that a major porticn of total health expenditure is financed by private consumers (WHO 1977) suggests the existence of a high level of private willingness (and ability) to pay for health services which remains largely untapped by the public sector. This type of analysis relates intimately to the analysis of expenditure patterns since the potential role of various financing mechanisms, ranging from direct user charges at one extreme to full subsidy from public revenues at the other, tends to vary across different interventions. Recurrent cost financing. A critically important aspect of the analysis of health sector financing, and one which emphasizes the importance of devel- oping alternative cost recovery mechanisms, concerns the future availability of fiscal resources to subsidize the recurrent costs generated by new invest- ment projects in the health sector. The availabil.ty of public funds to sub- sidize ongoing operating and maintenance costs is typically the binding constraint on health investments. The reason is that external finance from aid donors is often forthcoming to cover capital investment costs, while future recurrent costs have to be financed from domestic revenues after project implementation. -6- The problem of recurrent cost financing for social sector projects was recognized a long time ago (Stopler, 1966), and has recently attracted atten- tion throughout the public sector in LDCs (Heller, Club du Sahel, 1979).There are a number of reasons why it is especially important in the health sector. First of all, the neglect of project analysis criteria for health projects has tended to preclude attention even to elementary financial appraisal Second, the amount of recurrent expenditure generated per unit of investment in the health sector is typically higher than in most other sectors, princi- pally because of the labor and pharmaceutical requirements of health facili- ties. Nbreover, the amount of recurrent public subsidy paid per unit of recurrent expenditure is also relatively high in the health sector. Mbst public sector health projects are financed exclusively, or largely so, from public revenues. Health sector pricing policies are such that user charges are frequently nominal and recover only a low proportion of operating costs. In addition, the revenues generated by this or other cost recovery mechanisms usually accrue directly to the central goverment Treasury, without any ear- marked allocation to the health sector or to the project itself. Thus the allocation of investment resouces to health tends to have more onerous im- plications for recurrent expenduture financing in government than in other sectors. Public finance constraints have clear implications for the analysis of project choice in the health sector. Whether partially or totally financed by public subsidy, every project requires a cash flow of revenues to cover its financial costs in order to operate at optimal scale. Analysis of expec- ted future financial costs and revenues of the project is critically impor- tant to determine the feasibility of a project over its planned operating life. Indeed, analysis of long-run financial feasibility itself provides -7- a partial test of efficiency simply because future underfinancing of recur.- .rent costs will result in the operation of the project at less than optimal scale and, hence, .in a reduction in the net benefit of the investment. A useful way of summarizing the recurrent expenditure implications of health projects is to estimate the ratio of annual recurrent costs to total investment costs, the so-called 'r-coefficient'. For example, $1,000 in- vested in the health sector in Malawi is expected to generate, on average, $250 of incremental recurrent costs per year, compared with only about $100 resulting from the same investment in education or agriculture, and less than $30 for roads (World Bank, 1982) . Mbreover, the recurrent cost implications of health investment are higher at lower levels of the health sector. Esti- mated recurrent cost ratios in Malawi average 0.5 for clinics and primary iealth care compared to 0.2 for hospitals. Similar patterns have been observed in Kenya and Malaysia (Heller, 1974, 1975) and the Sahel countries (Over, 1979). Consideration of financial feasibility leads directly into the analy,sis of efficiency criteria. Clearly, the objective of planners is not just to ensure a financially feasible choice of health projects but the best choice from various possible alternatives. One approach, using cost-effectiveness analysis, is to select the mix of feasible projects which yields the largest expected improvement in health status, relative to cost. Ideally, the use of cost-benefit analysis would be preferable, to select those projects wtich have the largest net social benefit, defined in terms of a wider set of development objectives. Some of the key problems involved in cost- .effectiveness and cost-benefit analysis are considered below. -8 Cost-effectiveness analysis The least controversial efficiency criterion for health project selec-. tion, that of cost-effectiveness, is to choose projects which yield 7he maxi- mum health improvement subject to available resources. Alternatively, the problem can be inverted to choose projects which minimize the cost of meeting a specified objective or objectives. Cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA) is freqently used in sectors where problems of benefit valuation occur. For example, electricity investment planning models are typically specified in cost-minimization form, to find the least-cost solution to meeting an exogen- ous future demand upon which a value may or may not be placed (Turvey and Anderson, 1977). The method lends itself naturally to the health sector where the concept of meeting basic needs suggests that quantifiable minimum standards exist and can serve as planning objectives. Unfortunately, the basic needs literature is still distinguished by an absence of concrete sug- gestions as to what these standards should be (see, for example, Streeten, 1978, or Richards & Leonor, 1982). A fundamental problem in applying CEA to the health sector lies in the choice of an appropriate unit of effectiveness to measure the output of health projects. It may seem obvious that health improvement is the primary objective of public expenditure on health. Effectiveness measures framed in terms of intermediate service outputs, such as provision of tH services, are therefore inadequate tests since they do not measure actual improvements in health status. However, a central difficulty in measuring health status is that it is not homogenous, since the health project outputs comprise reduc- tions in both morbidity and mortality. These two types of health improvement can be measured in different ways or aggregated into a composite measure which can itself be constructed in different ways. Examples of alternative approaches are discussed below. -9- Mbrbidity reduction. The most straightforward, but limited, measure of health impact is the reduction in the prevalence or incidence of a .specific disease. An example is provided by Rosenfield et al (1977), who used a simple model of schistosomiasis transmission to simulate the effectiveness in Iran of different control techniques (mollusciciding, engineering measures, chemotherapy, and a combination of these) subject to a given resource con- straint over seven years. Maximum output, specified in terms of the greatest reduction in the prevalence rate obtained by the end of the seven year per- iod, was achieved with a combination of chemotherapy and mollusciciding. This intervention reduced the prevalence rate from 64% to 20%, whereas the next best alternative, chemotherapy, achieved a terminal prevalence rate of 60%. This measure of effectiveness did not take into account the prevalence reductions achieved during the period. A more appropriate measure, in terms of the total number of cases of schistosomiasis prevented over the period, changed the ranking of alternatives. Chemotherapy yielded the greatest out- put at a cost per case prevented of $1.26, followed by the combination of controls with a unit cost of $1.29. Yhasures of effectiveness specified in terms of cases of a disease pre- vented tend to limit the application of CEA to the.choice between different methods of controlling that disease, and preclude its use to evaluate the choice between interventions directed at different diseases. This is so be- cause different diseases have different effects on the duration and extent of morbidity, and also mortality, which are not obviously captured by measures of cases prevented. - 10 - A more useful measure which would permit comparison of the morbidity ef- fects of the prevention of different types of diseases is the number of days of disability prevented. This can be expressed as the number of days on which individuals would have experienced some degree of dysfunction,due to the relevant disease, and can be weighted to reflect the degree of impair- ment. Paqueo (1975) illustrates the use of a weighted measure to show higher morbidity rates below the poverty line in the Philippines. An unweighted measure has been used in Indonesia by Grosse et al (1979) and Grosse (19.80) in a detailed simulation of the effectiveness of alternative health interven- tions directed at 31 diseases, and subject to seven alternative resource con- straints. The choice of activities comprised 48 possible combinations of curative and preventive interventions based on*health centers, health sub- centers and village health workers, and sanitation, immunization and nutri- tion programs. Resource constraints varied from $2.06 to $30.00 per capita year. Simulations at each level of resource availability identified the mix of interventions which minimized the number of days of incapacitating illness per person per year from all causes. At all resource levels health centers were selected but with varying combinations of other inputs. At $5.00 per capita these included village health workers and an immunization program; at $15.00 a sanitation program only; and at $30.00 village health workers to- gether with sanitation, immunization and nutrition programs. Mbrtality reduction. As is the case with morbidity, mortality reduction can be quantified in different ways. The simplest measure, the number of deaths prevented, has the advantage of not being disease-specific and there- fore can be used to compare interventions against different diseases. How- ever, in the aggregation of deaths prevented it implicitly assigns the same . - 11 - weight to all deaths regardless of the age at death, whereas a social premium may be attached to the productive age groups. Social preferences of this kind can be introduced by using methods which weight deaths prevented at dif- ferent ages by the additional years of life accruing to the survivors. One approach is to assume that all survivors live to some arbitrarily determined age. For example, Romeder and tWhinnie (1977) suggest a measure of potential years of life lost (gained) given by taking the difference be- tween age at death and 70 years. Other methods take the terminal year as life expectancy at birth, or the life table age at which fewer than arbitrary proportion, such as 10%, of the original radix are survivors. These methods are unsatisfactory because they do not take account of the probability of survival from the age at death to the hypothetical terminal year. It is more appropriate to measure the potential years of life gained by the expectation of life at the age at which death is averted, estimated from the relevant life table. Other refinements have also been suggested, particularly to take account of selective biases which cause the survival changes of survivors from some causes of death to differ from the cohort average (Shepard and Zeckhauser, 1980), as may be the case with measles vaccination in LDCs (The Kasongo project Team, 1981). Preferential weighting for specific age groups can be made even more extreme by simply giving zero weight to certain age groups. Thus planners may be interested exclusively in minimizing infant and child mortality, or adult mortality. The conventional arguments for popula- tion control in LDCs could, of course, imply a very low weight for infant and child mortality reductions (depending on one's view of the child survival hypothesis). - 12 - The optimal choice of interventions indicated by mortality-based effec- tiveness measures tends to be different 'from that resulting from morbiuity criteria. For instance, the Grosse model also simulated the effectiveness of intervention alternatives in reducing mortality. For five of the seven dif- ferent resource constraints the optimal combination of inputs differed sub- stantially according to the choice of objective. For example at $15.00 per capita, the minimum crude death rate was obtained with a health center com- bined with village health workers and nutrition and immunization programs; this compared to the health center plus sanitation program choice which mini- mized days of illness. Adopting the minimization of infant mortaility in- stead of total mortality as the planning objective apparently altered the choice of interventions by introducing nutrition programs more frequently into the optimal solutions. A similar analysis using a programming model to determine the optimal mix of activities to minimize infant and child mortal- ity has been carried out by Barnum et al (1980) with data from Colombia. Composite measures. Since morbidity and mortality objectives tend to have different implications for the best choice of health interventions, it seems preferable to construct a composite measure of health improvement, that is one which aggregates morbidity and mortality reductions. Attempts to con- struct a so-called health status index have generated a considerable litera- ture relating to developed countries (Culyer et al, 1979; Berg, 1973) but very little concerning LDCs. The central concept underlying this approach is that at any point in time an individual occupies one of a continuum of pos- sible health states ranging from good health to death. For estimation pur- poses the continuua is divided into discrete health states, j = 1 ...n. Each state is assigned a value Uj on a utility scale ranging from 0 to 1. Health - 13 - interventions alter the probability of occupying different health states. The effectiveness of an intervention is measured in terms of the increment in health status units, defined as the discounted sum over all years of the number of days changed from state j to k in each year, multiplied.by the utility weight of state k net of the utility weight-of state j (Torrance, 1976). Methods which have been.used in attempts to derive utility weights on the basis of individual preverences, including the Von Neumann-Mbrgenstern standard gamble approach, are reviewed in Culyer (1978). Effectiveness mea- sures of this type are sometimes called quality-adjusted life years. An ill- ustration of the application of this approach to measurement of the health benefits of the reduction in schistosomiasis and cholera prevalence attribut- able to water supply improvement in LDCs is presented in Saunders and Warford (1976). A variant of the health status index approach has been developed and applied in Ghana by the Ghana Health Assessment Project Team (1981). Preven- tion of death from a specific cause results in a gain of healthy days of life: this gain is computed as the life expectancy at age at death from that cause, converted to the equivalent in days. Prevention of disability from a given cause yields an increase in healthy days equivalent to the expected duration of disability in days weighted by the degree of disability-per day (assigned arbitrarily). The sum of both the mortaility and morbidity compon- ents then provides a measure of effectiveness in terms of healthy days of life saved. An empirical application of this method of ranking 48 causes of morbidity and mortality in Ghana showed the dominant effect of mortality on the selection of disease prioritites. -14- These experiments with different approaches to cost-effectiveness analy- sis in LDCs suggest two important observations. First; since the most effec- tive choice of health interventions appears to be quite sensitive to changes in resource constraints, however health objectives are formulated, accurate specification of these constraints is critically important to avoid getting locked into inefficient strategies. As noted previously, an assessment of the future availability of recurrent cost financing is especially critical. Second, because the optimal mix of interventions is also sensitive to the choice of health objectives, it is equally important that these should be clearly articulated. This presents particularly formidable problems in prac- tice. 1bst health plans formulate health objectives in terms of desired re- source inputs or intermediate outputs rather than health improvement targets, in part because the health impact of particular inputs and interventions is often not known with any certainty. 1brevover, specification of the trade- off between morbidity and mortality objectives necessarily raises fundamental questions about the relative value of different types of health improvement which policy-makers are notoriously reluctant to confront explicitly, even though such trade-offs are implicit in all resource allocation decisions they make. Yet those value judgements have to be. made explicit in order to deter- mine, through CEA, an efficient allocation of resources between the full range of potential interventions. 4. Cost-benefit analysis The usefulness of CEA in project selection is strictly limited by its measurement of project outputs in physical units which cannot be compared directly with costs. The fact that a least-cost solution exists to meeting a given health objective says nothing about the desirability of achieving that - 15,- objective in terms of the relationship between social benefits and costs. bbreover its necessarily limited.focus on health benefits alone implies that other objectives are unimportant, whereas policy-makers typically seek to pursue several social objectives of which health improvement is only one. The idea that the social benefits of a health improvement project should be measured in terms of its contribution to different social objectives such as increased per capita income and equity in addition to health improvement is advocated by Feldstein (1970, 1972), Paglin (1974) and Barlow (1976, 1980), though a dissenting note is offered by Loucks (1975) who excludes health im- provement from a long list of development policy objectives. This section examines in the context of LDCs the distinctive problem which arises in applying the CBA approach to health projects, namely the choice of.an appro- priate measure of the value of health benefits. The conventional approach to benefit valuation in project analysis is to rely on individual valuations as revealed by consumer behavior. In a per- fectly competitive economy, consumers' willingness to pay for a project ouput is equal to the prevailing market price. Thus in many cases project outputs can be valued directly at market prices. However, health projects generally cannot be handled in this way. First, the prevalence of zero or heavily sub- sidized market prices in health sector results in an absence of observable market data from which to deduce willingness-to-pay. Second, where such data are available they may underestimate the true social benefits of intervention if, because of externalities, the consumer is not the sole beneficiary of the ouput. Preventive interventions directed at communicable diseases, such as immunizations, present a classic example of where the benefits to society are greater than those which accrue to their immediate consumers. Third, market - 16 - price data may also be unsatisfactory if consumers are not well informed about the benefit to themselves of health services. This again may be especially true of preventive interventions. Finally, even if acceptable measures of private valuations are available from market data, consumer pref- erences might be rejected in favor of socially-determined consumption pat- terns, not least because the consumption patterns of individuals will reflect a particular distribution of income and welath. The notion that health and certain other goods such as nutrition and education merit higher levels of consumption than would normally occur without public intervention underlies the basic needs approach to development planning. Consideration of these conceptual and empirical difficulties has neces- sitated resort to indirect methods of the valuation of health improvement. At least five major alternatives have been attempted: human capital valua- tion, implicit and explicit private valuations, and implicit and explicit public valuations. It should be noted parenthetically that the savings in costs that would have been incurred if a proposed project was not undertaken has often been recommended as a measure of benefits additional to the value of the health improvement provided by the project. This recommendation is strictly incorrect since a consistent analytical treatment would also require metting out the benefits which are foregone as a result of saving the costs that would have been incurred under the without-project alternative. Al- though this elementary point has long been recogn, ;ad in the general case (Steiner, 1965) the error is surprisingly persistent in the health economics literature. For a more detailed analysis, see Butler & Doessel (1981). The most common method is the human capital approach. Health improve- ment is treated as an investment in human capital formation which yields an incremental flow of future income or output (Grossman, 1972). - 17 - Health improvement exerts both quantity and quality effects on the effective supply of labor. bbrtality reduction increases the stock of potential work- ers and hence the potential flow of labor services. Mbrbidity reduction in- creases the potential number or efficiency of the flow of labor services. This increment in labor units over time can be estimated and multiplied by their marginal product in order to provide an estimate of the incremental output attributable to -any given health improvement (Mushkin, 1962). Classic applications of this method are estimates of the economic cost of disease in the United States by Weisbrod (1961), and Rice (1966). In the context of LDCs, the theme of the output-augmenting effects of disease control has been expanded to include its impact on the effective supply of land (attributable to migration induced by the elimination of disease vectors) and accumulation of the capital stock (resulting from a reallocation of private and public ex- penditure-from consumption to .savings and investment). For a general review, see Barlow (1979) and Ram and Schultz (1979). Application of the human capital approach faces certain empirical diffi- culties, notably in estimating the increment in effective labor supply re- sulting from morbidity reduction and the marginal product which should be assigned to it. As it is rather easy to apply compared with other approaches it has been used extensively, although there is widespread dissatisfaction with it on conceptual grounds. The method values health only to the extent that it is an investment good which increases aggregate output; it assigns no value to health as a consumption good. Accordingly, it implies that the value of health is greater for those with higher earnings and therefore can be said to discriminate against the young, the aged, females and the poor. Two alternatives to the human capital approach reflect a desire to base health benefit valuation on consumer preferences. Implicit private valua- tions have been sought in analyses of revealed market preferences in the - 18 - United States. Blomquist (1979) derived a value of life equal to $378,000 from an analysis of the use of automobile seat belts which yielded a small reduction in the statistical probability of death. In an analysis of risk- compensating wage differentials in the labor market, Thaler and Rosen (1975) estimated the implicit value of life at $176,000. An alternative approach using questionnaire surveys designed to elicit an explicit private valuation of mortality reduction has been applied by Acton (1973) to changes in the risk of cardiovascular mortality. He obtained a value of life ranging be- tween $28,000 and $43,000. For a review of these and other consumer prefer- ence models see Linnerooth (1979). This approach has not yet applied to changes in morbidity or in an LDC context. Other approaches attempt to replace individual valuations by social preferences. A number of attempts to elicit implicit public values, as re- vealed by government choices in the UK, are summarized by Card and mboney (1977). The range of implicit values placed on human life by various pro- grams or regulations were as follows: * 50 in screening maternal oestriol concentration to prevent stillbirths; i1,000 in the provision of child-proof drug containers; C100,000 in legislation on tractor cabs; (20,000,000 in building regulations for high-rise apartment blocks. The extreme inconsis- tency revealed in implicit values across these different public policy areas clearly suggests that this approach serves more as an indicator of the unde- sirable consequences of ad hoc decision-making rather than as a reliable guide to valuing benefits. Feldstein (1970) has suggested instead that explicit public values could be obtained by direct questioning of public policy-makers. This idea is similar to the general procedure proposed by Dasgupta et al (1972) for the derivation of social weights in project ap- - 19 - praisal, A variation of this approach, involving social specification of a basic needs standard for calorie consumption, has been developed by Scandizzo and Knudsen (1980). The health economics literature offers many examples of cost-benefit analysis (Culyer et al, 1977, Griffiths et al, 1980; Drummond, 1980a,b), but there have been few applications to LDCs. All of these concern communicable disease control projects, mainly immunization programs or parasitic disease control. Such analyses, especially of parasitic disease control, exemplify many of the empirical difficulties encountered in benefit valuation. For ex- ample, various studies have assumed that schistosomiasis entails, on average, an impairment of working efficiency ranging from between 4% to 100%. This upper limit is inconsistent with epidemiological evidence that only a minor- ity of infected cases sustain infections of sufficient intensity to provoke clinically severe morbidity, and corrobotative physiological evidence from Sudan that significant reductions in physical performance capacity (up to 20% of maximum aerobic power output) are obtained only at very high levels of in- fection intensity (2,000 eggs/g faeces in S. Mansoni infections) (Prescott, 1979a). Similarly, analyses of malaria control have included assumptions about the duration of disability associated with the acute clinical attack (varying from 6 to 44 days) in excess of that which has been observed empir- ically (2.4 to 5.7 days depending on the species of parasite and the level of host immunity). Such studies have also generally failed to recognize the zero marginal product of additional labor inputs at seasonal periods of labor surplus (Prescott, 1979b, 1980). Most fundamentally, these analyses have not made realistic predictions of the epidemiological effectiveness of disease control interventions. Like many estimates of the economic cost of disease in developed countries, they are really abstract measures of the gain that could be attributed to hypothetical elimination of a given disease for a - 20 - single year. Thus they have not addressed the policy-relevant question of what benefits could be generated over time with the application of feasible control techniques. It is clear that the issue of benefit valuation in health projects has not been resolved satisfactorily, and no single "correct' method exists which can be recommended to project analysts in LDCs. All of the approaches re- viewed have some merits and the choice of a benefit measure will vary in dif- ferent circumstances. At a minimum, efforts should be made to estimate the unit cost of achieving health improvements with different interventions, so that at least some sensible judgements may be made in the choice between alternative expenditures. Even this needs refinement of basic epidemiolog- ical data and analysis, and is but a first step to more powerful analysis in- volving benefit valuations. 5. Uncertainty and shadow pricing The need to take account of uncertainty and to use appropriate shadow' prices applies to project analysis, both CEA and CBA, in all sectors but these techniques deserve special mention in the context of health project in- vestment appraisal. Uncertainty. Uncertainty over the true value of basic parameters in CEA or CBA calculations is inherent in project analysis, partly because by defi- nition the future is unknown and partly because of practical limitations in the quality of relevant data. For instance, a special feature of health projects is the degree of uncertainty about the technology of health improve- ment. Not enough is known about the relevant production functions, that is the relationship between inputs and outputs, to predict with confidence the health outputs that will result from health project inputs. This fact partly stems from the unusual complexity of health sector production functions. - 21 - With the exception of preventive interventions which have the characteristic of 'public' goods, improvements in health are produced jointly by health service providers and consumers. Consumer demand is therefore one of the de- terminants of improved health but knowledge about its characteristics is lim- ited by a lack of empirical data on consumer demand functions for health services and health-related activities. Another source of uncertainty relates to the technical efficacy of some health interventions in compliant populations, for example BCG vaccination against tuberculosis (Tuberculosis Prevention Trial, 1979), or improved water supply and sanitation facilities (World Bank, 1975; Saunders and Warford, 1976). In addition, uncertainty exists about the accuracy of much of the basic epidemiological data on the incidence or prevalence of morbidity and mortality due to specific causes against which project interventions are directed. For example, estimates of the health benefits of schistosomiasis control are sensitive to asumptions about the morbidity and mortality which it causes, a matter which continues to be the subject of controversy. Apart from such uncertainty about quantifying the benefits of health projects, further uncertainty arises over the value which should be placed on them. In practice, this problem of uncertainty should be handled by basing the project analysis on best estimates of the basic project parameters, and then analyzing the sensitivity of the conclusions to plausible variations of the parameter values around their expected values. The sensitivity analysis will indicate which, if any, of the basic assumptions have a significant effect on the acceptability of a project. The converse approach is to estimate how much different parameter values would have to change before the project switches from being acceptable to unacceptable (or vice versa), and to check whether these are plausible. Such an approach is especially well suited to - 22 - handling the pervasive uncertainty in health sector projects. Given that in some projects only costs may be known with any confidence, the minimum health output (such as lives saved) required to make the project acceptable can still be estimated and then checked to see whether it is plausible. These estimates can be done within either a CEA or CBA framework. Shadow pricing. The idea of 'shadow' pricing is to determine the 'real' price of a good or service either where no market price exists or where such a market price is considered to be an incorrect indicator of its 'real' val- ue. In the analysis of health investments, two kinds of shadow prices need to be considered: economic (or efficiency) prices which correct for distor- tions in factor and product market prices; and social (or distributional) prices which reflect a government"s growth and equity objectives. The two main systems of shadow pricing are those developed by Dasgupta et al (1972) and Little and Mirrle e (1974), later refined by Squire and Van der Tak (1975). A full account of the justification for, and derivation of, shadow prices is available ia these original sources; only the major points are sum- marized here. The use of economic prices mainly affects the value of foreign exchange and labor inputs used by projects. In most LDCs it is common to encounter exchange rates which tend to underestimate the scarcity value of foreign exchange. Conversely, market wage rates often to overestimate the opportun- ity cost of labor. In these circumstances, the effect of the use of 'shadow prices will be to increase the cost of foreign exchange and reduce the cost of labor. These adjustments will discourage projects which use scarce for- eign exchange and favor those which are labor intensive. Likewise, if faster economic growth or income redistribution are key social objectives, then shadow prices in the form of social prices may be used to bias project selec- tion against investment projects which rely heavily on public sector financ- -23- ing, in favor of those which generate high rates of saving and reinvestment by, for example, generating additional public revenues from user charges and those which redistribute income to the poor. Some features of the health sector make consideration of shadow pricing of special interest, and the use of economic and social prices has important implications for the choice of health projects. The penalty attached to for- eign exchange intensive projects, as a result of the use of economic prices, gives particular importance to pharmaceuticals and increasing domestic pro- duction, including primary manufacture which may not rely on imported in- puts. The mutually reinforcing incentives to employ labor with a low oppor- tunity cost (for efficiency reasons) and to favor employment of the poor (for distributional reasons) emphasize the desirability of substituting lower for higher grade health workers where technically feasible. The disincentive to using scarce public resources to finance health projects directs attintion to exploring methods of self-financing. It is pertinent to observe that all.of these concerns - pharmaceutical policy, the use of village health workers and community participation in project financing - are currently the subject of intense policy debate and can each be accommodated through a straightforward application of shadow pricing in project selection. 6. Resource mobilization Existing and prospective financial -constraints in LDCs indicate a need to re-evaluate the traditional approach to health sector financing which re- lies-heavily on public; subsidies from central government revenues. A signif- icant increase in the allocation of public revenues to the health sector is unlikely to be a realistic option, given the traditional strength of compet- ing sectoral demands and the continuing difficulty of demonstrating that the marginal social rate of return on health expenditure exceeds the returns yielded in other sectors. Expansion of the health sector in many countries may, therefore, depend larg4ly on the implementation of cost recovery mechan- isms. Tn general, the relevance of alternative financing methods will vary, with the type of health intervention. In each case the choice between finan- cing alternatives can be assessed using the same frame-ork already developed for ther public sector projects in which efficiency, equity and fiscaj- ob- jectives ,re traded off for the various services provided (Ray, 1975). The benchmark for analysis of financig alternatives is given by long-run marginal cost of each intervention, though departures from marginal cost pricing can be justified in certain circumstances. In the presence of externalities or poorly informed consumers, both being characteristic of,pre ventive interventions aimed at individuals, marginal cost priods will fail to induce socially optimal levels of consumption, and subdid4zed prices are ap- propriate. Public health measures, such as molluscicidiig for schistosomia- sis control and aerial larviciding for onchocerciasis control, have some of the characteristics of 'public g6ods", whera the benefits of interviention are not consumed by any one individual and the exlusion princple thereford fails to apply, in that access to the benefits of intervention cannot be made conditional on payment of a user charge. Direct charges for such services, levied separately on each beneficiary, may eithe be co- expensive to admin- ister, or simply not feasible. The achievement of equity objectives will also be affected 'by the choice of financing mechanism. Interventions directed at L'bo income beneificiaries, for example, a program of primary health care, may be ineffective under a system of direct user charges if the price elasticity of demand is high, meaning that potential consumers are deterred from seeking care by the level of prices charged. Evidence on price elasticities for health services in I - 25 -. LDCs is scarce, but data from Malaysia indicate that .the total demand is highly inelastic with respect to cash prices, although there are significant .ross-price elasticities for the services of different providers (Heller, 1982), implying that consumers do switch between providers according to vari- ations in pricess Similar findings have been reported for the Philippines <',(Akin et al, 1982). If demand is inelastic, the impact of raising charges on the use of health services will by definition be minor and its fiscal impact positie but the income transfer from the beneficiary to the public sector may not'accord with distributional objectives. However, even where these difficulties apply, there may be no alternative but to generate revenues from beneficiaries ot- elsewhere in the private sector in order to finance the pro- vision of health services. It i. clear, nonetheless, that for some interventions reliance on direct user -harge$ will not be appropriate and other financing mechanisms will need to be explored. But whether the very limited resort to user charges in LDCs is appropriate - less than 10% of public sector costs are recovered by this means in countries such as Ghana (Brooks, 1981), Malaysia, Malawi, and Lesotho - require detailed examination. In general, the argumeats against pricing are stronger for prevrentive interventions and for lower icome bene- ! ciaries. Thus a ,system of selective charges for curative services, espe- cially for higher incom6 users, may be justified to cross-subsidize preven- tive activities and utilizationby the poor. Private sector experience, notably of mission facilities and traditional practitioners and birth attend- ants, deinonstrates the feasibility of recovering a high proportion of recur- rent costs frpmwUser charges without reducing utilization. In Lesotho, some 70% of recurr nt expenditure by private hospitals is recovered from user charges (Kolobe and Pekeche, 1980). -26- Alternatives to charges iii use in many countries itelude earmarked taxes, social security and insurance schemes, or indirect cost recovery by self-help (Evans et al, 1981, Stinson, 1982). Experience shows that a wide range of financing mechanisms can be employed in the health sector in LDCs. Nevertheless, the approaches generally used are dominated by the tradition of central government subsidy and the introduction of innovative methods en- counters very difficult political obstacles. The prevalent view that because health is good it should be free or subsidized may have to be increasingly challenged, however, if the goals set by WHO and UNICEF, referred to in the introduction, are to be achieved. Conclusion In general, conventional approaches to investment appraisal in the health sector are much less rigorous than in most other sectors. A major reason for this may be that there are greater difficulties of theory and mea- surement at all stages of project analysis, 'i'or example in the prediction of effectiveness of health interventions, the valuation of beneifts, and the de- sign of appropriate cost recovery policies. However, these problems differ in degree rather than substance from those found in other sectors such as water supply, energy and education, where considerable analytical progress has been acheived. They certainly do not justify the prevalent tendency to avoid rigorous analysis of investment decisions altogether simply because it is difficult. It may even be argued that many of the problems which are en- countered are the result of past neglect of economic analysis in the health sector. The potential role of economic appraisal is therefore very large, and indeed, essential to attainment of the dramatic improvements in health status which are now sought by LDCs. REFERENCES Acton, J. P., (1973), Evaluating Public Programs to Save Lives: The Case of Heart Attacks, R-950-RC, The Rand Corporation, Santa Mbnica, California. Akin, J. S., Griffin, C. C., Guilkey, D. K., and Popkin, B. M. (1982), The Demand for Primary Health Care Services in the Bicol Region of the Philippines. Paper presented at the Conference on Financing Health Services in Developing Countries, 14-16 June, National Council for International Health, Washington, D.C. Balassa, B. (1982) 'Structural Adjustment Policies in Developing Economies, World Development, 10(1), pp. 23-38. Barnum, H., Barlow, R., Fajardo, L., and Pradilla, A., (1980), A Resource Allocation Mbdel for Child Survival, Oelgeschlager, Gunn and Hain, Cambridge, Mass. Barlow, R., (1976), "Applications of a Health Planning bbdel in Ibrocco, International Journal of Health Services 6(1), pp. 103-121. Barlow, R., (1979), -Health and Economic Development: A Theoretical and Empirical Review, Research in Human Capital and Development, 1, pp. 45-75. Barlow, R., (1980), "Economic Goals in Health Planning,' Document TDR/SER/SWG(2)/80.WP.6, World Health Organization, Geneva. Berg, R. L. (ed.), (1973), Health Status Indices, Hospital Research and Educational Trust, Chicago. Blomquist, G., (1979), 'Value of Life Saving: Implications of Consumption Activity,( Journal of Political Economy, 87(3), pp. 540-558. Brooks, R. G., (1981), Ghana's Health Expenditures 1966-80: A Commentary, St7athclyde Discussion Papers in Economics No. 80/1, University of St7athclyde, Glasgow, Scotland. Butler, J.R.G., & Doessel, D.P. (1981) "Measuring benefits in health: a clarification", Scottish Journal of Political Economy", 28(2): 196-205. Card, W. J., and Iboney, G. H., (1977), "What is the Mbnetary Value of a Human Life?', British Medical Journal, 2, pp. 1627-1629. Club du Sahel, (1980), Recurrent Costs of Development Programs in the' Countries of the Sahel: Analysis and Recommendations, Club du Sahel, Paris. Culyer, A.J., (1978), 'Need, Values and Health Status Measurement,' in Culyer, A. J., and Wright, K. G. (eds.), Economic Aspects of Health Services, Martin Robertson, London, pp. 9-31. Culyer, A. J., Lavers, R. J., and Williams, A., (1971), 'Social Indicators: Health,' Social Trends, 2, pp. 31-42. -2- Culyer, A. J., Wiseman, J., and Walker, A., (1977), An Annotated Bibliography of Health Economics, English Language Sources, Martin Robertson, London. Dasgupta, P. S., Marglin, S. A., and Sen, A. K., (1972), Guidelines for Project Evaluation, United Nations Industrial Development Organization, New York. Drummond, M. F., (1980a), Principles of -Economic Appraisal in Health Care, Oxford University Press, New York. Drummond, M. F., (1980b), Studies in Economic Appraisal in Health Care, Oxford University Press, New York. Evans, J. R., Hall, K. L., and Warford, J. J., (1981), "Shattuck Lecture Health Care in the Developing World: Problems of Scarcity and Choice,' New England Journal of Medicine, 305, pp. 1117-1127. Feldstein, M. S., (1970), 'Health Sector Planning in Developing Countries," Economica, pp. 139-163. Feldstein, M. S., Piot, M. A., and Sundaresan, T. K. (1973), "Resource Allocation Mbdel for Public Health Planning: A Case Study of Tuberculosis Control,' Supplement to Vol. 48 of the Bulletin of the World Health Organization. Ghana Health Assessment Project Team, (1981), "A Quantitative ethod of Assessing the Health Impact.of Different Diseases in Less Developed Countries,0 International Journal of Epidemiology, 10(1), pp. 73-80. Griffiths, A., Rigoni, R., Tacier, P., and Prescott, N., (1980), An Annotated Bibliography of Health Economics, Western European Sources, Martin Robertson, Oxford. Grosse, R. N., De Vries, J. L., Tilden, R. L., Dievler, A., Day, S. R., (1979), A Health Development Mbdel: Application to Rural Java, Department of Health Planning and Administration, School of Public Health, The University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Michigan. Grosse, R. N., (1980), 'Interrelation Between Health and Population: Observations Derived from Field Experiences,' Social Science and Medicine, 14c(2)_, pp. 99-120. Grossman, M., (1972), "Qn the Concept of Health Capital and the Demand for Health,' Journal of Political Economy, pp. 223-255. Heller, P. S., (1974), "Public Investment in LDCs with Recurrent Cost Constraints: The Kenyan Case,' Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88(2), pp. 251-277. Heller, P. S., (1975), Issues in the Costing of Public Sector Outputs: The Public Medical Services of Malaysia, Staff Working Paper No. 207, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Heller, P. S., (1979), 'The Underfinancing of Recurrent Development Costs, Finance and Development, 16(1), pp. 38-41. Heller, P. S., (1982), -A bbdel of the Demand for edical and Health Services in Peninsular Malaysia,' Social Science and Medicine, (forthcoming). I.M.F., (1981), Government Finance Statistics Yearbook, Volume V, International bnetary Fund, Washington, D.C. Kolobe, P., and Pekeche, T., (1980), 'A Survey of the Financial Status of the Private Health kssociation of Lesotho's Hospitals," PrIvate Health Association of Lesotho, Maseru. Linnerooth, J., (1979), 'The Value of Human Life: A Review of the bbdels, Economic Inquiry, 17(1), pp. 52-74. Little, I. M. D., and Mirrlees, J. A., (1974), Project Appraisal and Planning for Developing Countries, Heinemann Educational Books, London. Loucks, D. P., (1975), 'Planning for Multiple Goals,' in Blitzer, C. R., Clark, P. B., and Taylor, L. (eds.), Economy-wide bdels and Development Planning, Oxford University Press, London, pp. 213-233. Mahler, H., (1977), 'Blueprint for Health For All,' WHO Chronicle, 31, pp. 491-498. Meerman, J., (1979), Public Expenditure in Malaysia: Who Benefits and Why, Oxford University Press, New York. Meerman, J., (1980), "Paying For Human Development,' in Knight, P. T. (ed.), Implementing Programs of Human Development, Staff Working Paper No. 403, The World Bank, Washington, D.C., pp. 111-182. Mushkin, J., (1962), "Health.As An Investment,' Journal of Political Economy, 70, pp. 129-157. Ofosu-Amaah, S., (1975), 'Reflections on the Health Budget: A Preliminary Analysis of the 1974/75 Ministry of Health Budget," Ghana Medical Journal, September, pp. 215-222. Over, A. M, (1979), ^Five Primary Care Projects i: the Sahel and the Issue of Recurrent Costs, Harvard Institute for International Development, Cambridge, ass. Paglin, M., (1974), "Public Health and Development: A New Analytical Framework,' Economica, 41(4), pp. 432-441. Paqueo, V., (1976), ^Social Indicators for Health and Nutrition,' in Nangahas, M. (ed.), hasuring Philippine Development: Report of the Social Indicators Project, Development Academy of the Philippines, Manila, pp. 41-115. Prescott, N. M., (1979a), 'Schistosomiasis and Development, World Development, (1), pp. 1-14. Prescott, N. M., (1979b), 'The Economics of Malaria, Filariasis and Human Trypanosomiasis, Document TDR/SER (SC-1)/80.4, World Health Organization, Geneva. Prescott, N. M., (1980), 'On the Benefits of Tropical Disease Control,' in Wood, C., and Rue, Y. (eds.), Health Policies in Developing Countries, Royal. Society of Medicine International Congress and Symposium Series No. 24, Academic Press, London, pp. 41-48. Ram, .R.., and Schultz, T. W., (1979), Life Span, Health, Savings and Productivity,' Economic Development and Cultural Change, 27(3), pp. 399-421. Ray, A., (1975), Cost Recovery Policies for Public Sector Projects, Staff Working Paper No. 206, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Rice, D. P., (1966), Estimating the Cost of Illness, Health Economics Series No. 6, PHS Publication No. 947-6, U.S. Government Printing.Office, Washington, D.C. Richards, P., and Leonor, M., (eds.) (1982), Target Setting for Basic Needs, International Labour Office, Geneva. Selowsky, M., (1979), Who Benefits from Government Expenditure? A Case Study of Colombia, Oxford University Press, New York. Shepard, D. S., and Zeckhauser, R. J., (1980), 'Long-Term Effects of Interventions to Improve Survival in Mixed Populations,OJournal of Chronic Diseases, 33(7), pp. 413-433. Smith, J., (1980), OA Review of the Resources and Service Area of the Health Facilities in the Kingdom of Lesotho,' Ministry of Health, Maseru. Squire, L., and Van der Tak, H. G., (1975), Economic Analysis of Projects, The Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore. Steiner, P.O. (1965) "The role of alternative cost in project design and selection", Quarterly Journal of Economics, 79(3): 417-430. Stinson, W. (1982) Community Financing of 'Primary Health Care, Primary Health Care Issues, Series 1, Number 4, American Public Health Association, Washington, D.C. Stolper, W. F., (1966), Planning Without Facts, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass. Streeten, P., et al, (1981), First Things First: Meeting Basic Human Needs in Developing Countries, Oxford University Press, New,York. Tait, A. A., Gratz, W. L. M., and Eichengreen, B. J., (1979), 'International ?omparisons of Taxation for Selected Developing-Countries,( International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, 26(1), pp. 123-156. -5- Tan, E. A., (1975), 'Taxation, Government Spending and Income Distribution in the Philippines,' Income Distribution and Employment Programme, Working Paper No. 26, International Labour Office, Geneva. Thaler, R., and Rosen, S., (1975), -The Value of Saving a Life,( in Terleckyj, N. E. (ed.), Household Production and -Consumption, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York. The Kasongo Project Team, (1981), 'Influence of Measles Vaccination on Survival Pattern of 7-35 Manth Old Children in Kasongd, Zaire,' The Lancet, 4th April, pp. 764-767. Torrance, G. W., (1976), 'Health Status Index Mbdels: A UnifiGd Mathematical View,' Management Science, 22(9), pp. 990-1001. Tuberculosis Prevention Trial, (1979), 'Trial of BCG Vaccines in South India for Tuberculosis Prevention: First Report,' Bulletin of the World Health Organization, 57(5), pp. 819-827. Turvey, R., and Anderson, D., (1977), Electricity Economics: Essays and Case Studies, The Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore. Weisbrod, B. A., (1961), Economics of Public Health: Measuring the Economic Impact of Diseases, University of Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia. World Bank, (1975), Measurement of the Health Benefits of Investments in Water Supply, Public Utilities Report No. PUN 20, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. World Bank, (1981), World Development Report 1981, Oxford University Press, New York. World Bank, (1982), Yalawi: Growth and Structural Change, A Basic Economic Report, Report No. 3082a-MAI, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. W.H.O., (1977), Financing of Health Services: Report of a W.H.O. Study Group, Technical Report Series No. 625, World Health Organization, Geneva. W.H.O., (1981), "Review of Health Expenditures, Financial Needs of the Strategy for Health for All by the Year 2000, and the International Flow of Resources for the Strategy,' Document EB69/7, World Health Organization, Geneva.