WPS5238 Policy Research Working Paper 5238 Assessing Ex Ante the Poverty and Distributional Impact of the Global Crisis in a Developing Country A Micro-simulation Approach with Application to Bangladesh Bilal Habib Ambar Narayan Sergio Olivieri Carolina Sanchez-Paramo The World Bank Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Network Poverty Reduction and Equity Group March 2010 Policy Research Working Paper 5238 Abstract Measuring the poverty and distributional impact of the with pre-crisis household data. The approach is then global crisis for developing countries is not easy, given the applied to Bangladesh to assess the potential impact of multiple channels of impact and the limited availability the slowdown on poverty and income distribution across of real-time data. Commonly-used approaches are of different groups and regions. A validation exercise using limited use in addressing questions like who are being past data from Bangladesh finds that the model generates affected by the crisis and by how much, and who are projections that compare well with actual estimates from vulnerable to falling into poverty if the crisis deepens? household data. The results can inform the design of This paper develops a simple micro-simulation method, crisis monitoring tools and policies in Bangladesh, and modifying models from existing economic literature, also illustrate the kind of analysis that is possible in other to measure the poverty and distributional impact of developing countries with similar data availability. macroeconomic shocks by linking macro projections This paper--a product of the Poverty Reduction and Equity Group, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Network--is part of a larger effort in the department to analyze the poverty and distributional impact of macroeconomic shocks.. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted at csanchezparamo@worldbank.org and anarayan@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team Assessing Ex Ante the Poverty and Distributional Impact of the Global Crisis in a Developing Country A Microsimulation Approach with Application to Bangladesh Bilal Habib, Ambar Narayan, Sergio Olivieri and Carolina SanchezParamo* Poverty Reduction and Equity Group, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management World Bank, Washington DC * This paper is the first in a series of country notes to be prepared under the work program on Analyzing the Distributional Impact of the Financial Crisis, in the Poverty Reduction Group of the PREM Network. We gratefully acknowledge the data, inputs and comments received from the Bangladesh PREM Team of the World Bank ­ in particular Zahid Hussain, Sanjay Kathuria, Lalita Moorty, Nobuo Yoshida and Sanjana Zaman. We also thank the participants at a seminar organized in South Asia Region of the World Bank, Washington DC for their insightful comments on the interim results of this work. 1. Introduction What began as a financial crisis in a few industrialized countries is quickly turning into a job crisis, with contractions in growth taking their toll on developed and developing countries alike. The projected economic slowdown across the world, recent World Bank global estimates for poverty suggest, could add an extra 50 million to the number of people living below $1.25 a day and 64 million to the number below $2 a day, compared to a scenario of uninterrupted growth in the absence of the crisis. By 2010, the crisis is projected to add an estimated 89 million to the number of people living below $1.25 a day and 120 million to the number below $2 a day (Chen and Ravallion, 2009). Along with the impact on poverty numbers, the crisis is also likely to have significant impacts on the distribution of income and consumption among the poor and nonpoor, both within and between countries. Evidence from previous crises suggests that the output elasticity of wages tends to be larger during downturns than during booms, and that relative inequality falls about as often as it rises during aggregate contractions (Paci et al, 2008). Further, the crisis is rapidly shifting across countries ­ via trade, financing, and remittances ­ as well as within countries ­ via adjustments in domestic credit and labor markets and fiscal policies. As a result, it is difficult to predict the distributional impacts of the crisis with a high degree of confidence. There are some hypotheses about how the impact of the crisis is likely to evolve between different groups in developing countries. The emerging consensus is that the initial impact is likely to be seen mainly on the emerging middleclass, since they are more likely to be employed in exportoriented industries and salaried jobs in the services sector, which appear to have suffered the largest labor market shocks.1 Approximately 90% of households entering the middleclass during 19902005 joined the lower tier ($29/day) (Ravallion, 2009), and thus risk falling back into poverty if they face large employment or earnings shocks. The initial impact on the poor may be limited due to the very isolation from the global markets (and the formal sector that gains the most from such linkages) in many countries that have prevented them from exiting poverty in the past. As the crisis unravels, however, the poor in developing countries are likely to be increasingly impacted. With labor markets in the formal sector being affected, job opportunities and wages are likely to fall, pushing more people into the informal sector, which could depress earnings in the informal sector. This can be accompanied by reverse migration from urban to rural areas, increasing the burden on poor rural households and drying up remittances from workers previously employed in the formal sector, leading to higher and deeper poverty. The distributional impact of the crisis is thus likely to be complex and dynamic. Some of the key questions an analysis of distributional impacts would need to address are: how are the impacts going to 1 There is little consensus in the development literature about who the "middle class" are. A number of different definitions have been used to study the evolution of the middleclass, such us Blackburn and Bloom (1987), Beach (1989), Levy and Murnane (1992), Jenkins (1995) and Burkhauser et. al (1999). For our purpose, we define the middleclass broadly, as those above the poverty line but below the richest decile (10%) of the population. In Bangladesh, this is the group between the 40th and 90th percentiles of per capita expenditure or income. 2 be shared across the distribution of income or consumption, which sectors, areas and regions are likely to be impacted, and what are the characteristics of those who would become poor as a result of the crisis? In order to be useful to policymakers in countries, these questions would have to be analyzed ex ante, with available data that in most cases predate the crisis, rather than be delayed till the time post (or during) crisis data become available. Even in cases where some realtime data is available from crisis affected sectors or countries, an ex ante approach can be useful to simulate future impacts for hypothetical scenarios that are not available from realtime data, especially in countries where the situation on the ground is changing rapidly. Current approaches to analyze ex ante the impact of a macroeconomic shock, with the limited data available in most countries, are somewhat inadequate in addressing the kind of questions posed above. To improve upon existing approaches given the typical data constraints seen in most developing countries, we develop in this paper a microsimulation model to evaluate exante the distributional impacts of the crisis. Section 2 outlines a rationale for building such a model, including the value added from this approach compared to existing methods. Section 3 presents the model, starting with an overview of the approach and subsequently outlining each step in detail, and ending with the key limitations and caveats to the model. In Section 4, we discuss a country case study with an application of our model (the case of Bangladesh). Section 5 concludes with implications of the results for Bangladesh and possible areas for extension in the course of future work. 2. Rationale for our approach Currently, there are two approaches commonly used within the World Bank to assess the welfare (primarily consumption or income poverty) impacts of the crisis: the output elasticity of poverty method, and PovStat (World Bank PovertyNet). The elasticity method involves using historical trends of output and poverty to determine the responsiveness of poverty rates to growth in output (and consumption), which is then combined with macroeconomic projections to estimate the impacts of future reduced growth on poverty. Although this method is easy to implement and serves as a convenient benchmark, it is limited in its predictive capability since it yields only aggregate poverty impacts, with no account of the broader distributional effects. It may also prove deficient in predicting poverty impacts during a crisis that affects output growth in a way not entirely consistent with the recent growth experience in a country. This crisis, for example, is likely to impact some sectors more than others and have a disproportionate impact on inflows like external remittances that directly impact household income. PovStat is an EXCELbased World Bank simulation package, which uses household survey data and macroeconomic projections as inputs and estimates changes in poverty and inequality indicators. Although it allows for the impacts to occur through multiple channels, it offers no easy way to account for changes in nonlabor income (such as remittances), which has important implications in the context of this crisis in some countries. By focusing exclusively on household heads (and ignoring the employment status of other household members), PovStat also does not allow for a full accounting of labor market impacts. Perhaps the most important limitation of PovStat is that it generates estimates for poverty and inequality (aggregate or disaggregated by regions/groups) but not the kind of distributional 3 results that require individual or household level projections. For example, an important distributional question like how the impact of the crisis is likely to be distributed across different groups (differentiated by income status, sector, region or any other relevant attribute) cannot be answered with PovStat. More sophisticated simulation approaches than Povstat have been used in some cases by the World Bank (see Bourguignon et al, 2008).2 All of them are based on a Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) or General Equilibrium macroeconomic model that demand a lot of information (for constructing Social Accounting Matrices or timeseries of macroeconomic data) in order to create the "linkage aggregate variables" (LAVS) that are fed into the microsimulation model. At the same time, these models do not allow for changes in some key features of the population, such as gender or age composition, and the economy (Ferreira et al, 2008). The main advantages of these models are related to improved accuracy of the counterfactual and consistency of the analysis. Notably, the information demands of these models make them hard to apply in most developing countries, and calls for an approach that is workable with available data and macroeconomic projections. Because the nature of the crisis is difficult to pin down, any valid impact assessment needs to account for multiple transmission mechanisms and capture impacts at the micro level over the entire income distribution. In the microsimulation model presented here, we do this by focusing on labor market adjustments in employment and earnings, nonlabor income, and price changes (with a view to the variation in food/nonfood prices). Note that for the purposes of this exercise, we use the terms "labor income" and "earnings" interchangeably.3 Our proposed methodology can be seen as a compromise between the "simple" methodologies like PovStat and the "complex" ones using general equilibrium models ­ with the attendant advantages and disadvantages. Compared against the simpler approaches, the value added by our approach is twofold. First, the model is able to generate estimates for individuals and households across the distribution with and without the crisis, which can be used for detailed poverty and distributional analyses of impact. Second, the model uses income rather than consumption; this allows us to model labor and nonlabor incomes separately, which is particularly important for countries in which remittances and public transfers form a large proportion of incomes. In comparing our approach with PovStat, the pros and cons of either method should be kept in perspective. Our model in its most basic form has data requirements similar to that for PovStat, and adds value along the two important dimensions stated above. At the same time, it requires considerably more computational resources and time than PovStat, which can be run as a simple Excelbased model once the household and macroeconomic data are ready to be fed into the model. Compared with the complex approaches, the primary advantage of our approach is the lower demand for information, 2 These include the micro accounting approach (Computable General EquilibriumRepresentative Household Groups), topdown micro simulations models (CGEMicro or Macro models) and Feedback loops from bottomtop (Bourguignon et. al 2008). 3 In fact, "labor income" is defined here as the total income earned from any sort of labor activity by all members of a household, including wages and profits. 4 which would make it practical to apply in many cases where the more complex approaches would have to be ruled out. 3. Proposed approach We propose to use a microsimulation model that combines macroeconomic projections with precrisis micro data from household and/or labor force surveys to predict income and consumption at the individual and household level under different scenarios, which can then be compared to measure poverty and distributional impacts. Comparisons will be made between different projected scenarios (most commonly a crisis or low scenario and a benchmark or base scenario) rather than a time comparison (i.e. a comparison between 2005 and 2009 or 2010 in the case of Bangladesh). Figure 1 presents a stylized representation of the methodology. The model focuses on labor markets and Figure 1: Microsimulation methodology migration as transmission mechanisms and allows for two types of shocks: shocks to labor income, modeled as employment shocks, earnings shocks or a combination of both; and shocks to nonlabor income, modeled as a shock to remittances. Shocks can be positive or negative depending on the trends outlined by the macroeconomic projections. In most cases labor income and remittances account for at least 7580% of household income. Minimum assumptions are made about other sources, such as capital and financial income or public transfers, as discussed below. The data requirements can be summarized as follows. At the macro level, information is needed on projected (i) output, employment, remittances and (ideally) labor earnings growth; (ii) population growth and (iii) predicted price changes. At the micro level, information is needed on (i) labor and non labor income and consumption, and (ii) labor force status and basic job characteristics, including earnings. Needless to say, the reliability and accuracy of the simulation results is a direct function of the quality and level of detail of the information available at the macro and micro levels. Finally, the income and consumption projections from the model can be used to produce a variety of outputs, including aggregate poverty and inequality comparisons across scenarios, poverty and vulnerability profiling of specific groups and/or areas, and various summary measures of distributional impacts, such as growth incidence curves and state transition matrices. We comment on these extensively for the case of Bangladesh below. 5 3.1 Overview of simulation exercise In this Section we provide a brief overview of the mechanics underpinning the simulation exercise. The exercise can be broken down into three distinct steps: calibration, simulation and assessment of impacts. A description of each step follows and a schematic of the complete model is presented in Figure 2. Figure 2: Schematic of the microsimulation model Calibration. Calibration is the process by which household and individuallevel information is used to model labor market behavior and outcomes and to predict the likelihood of receiving remittances.4 This is done in three steps. First, we model labor force status for all working age individuals (1564) as a function of household and individual characteristics, where labor force status can be nonemployed,5 employed in agriculture, industry or services. Although ideally we would like to work with a more detailed menu of options (e.g. "employed in tradeables" and "employed in nontradeables" instead of "employed in industry"), the number of labor force states that can be considered is dictated by the level of disaggregation available for the macro projections. We then use a multinomial logit to estimate the parameters of the model, as well as the individuallevel probability of remaining in a particular state and/or changing to a different one, as given by (1). The approach is similar to that used in Ferreira et al (2009). We estimate the model separately for high and lowskill individuals to allow for structural differences in the labor market behavior of the two groups.6 4 We estimate a reduced form of the household incomegeneration model which is based on Bourguignon and Ferreira (2005) and Alatas and Bourguignon (2005) 5 This includes "out of the labor force" and "unemployed". The decision to pool both states into a single category is motivated by the fact that the unemployment rate is extremely low in Bangladesh, even during crisis times. 6 For Bangladesh, low and highskilled refer to individuals with 0 ­ 9 and >10 years of education, respectively. 6 , I iGj s Ind a s zi b s uis a j zi b j uij | j s (1) where s = Labor force status; G = labor skill level (high/low); z = gender, age, education, region, remittances, and land ownership. Second, we model labor earnings for all employed individuals ages 15 to 64 as a function of individual and job characteristics and use a standard Mincerian OLS regression to estimate the parameters of the model, as given by (2) (similar to Ferreira et al. 2008). We use a fairly broad definition of labor earnings for the purpose of the exercise that includes wages and salaries, but also income from selfemployment. This is particularly important in the case of agriculture and for economies with large informal sectors, such as Bangladesh, since wage and salaried workers constitute a limited fraction of those employed in these sectors. It may lead however to a loss in precision and/or predictive power given that the structural relationship between individual and job characteristics and earnings could be different for salaried and nonsalaried workers. To allow for maximum flexibility and (indirectly) account for some of these differences we estimate the model separately for agriculture, industry and services and for low and highskill workers.7 log wiG sG xi sG vsG,i (2) where x =gender, age, education, region, land ownership, and indicators for export industry, salaried and public employment. The results of the estimation of equations (1) and (2) and a full description of all variables can be found in Annex 1. Finally, we model nonlabor income with a focus on international remittances and make some minimal assumptions about other sources of nonlabor income. Ideally, we would estimate a probit model to estimate the probability of how likely a household would be to receive international remittances, given its characteristics. However, if the migrationrelated information in the survey is poor or insufficient and/or the predictive power of probability model is low (as is the case for Bangladesh), we are betteroff relying on a simple nonparametric assignment rule that is consistent with the existing evidence (the specific rule used for Bangladesh is discussed in more detail when we describe the simulation process). Simulation. Simulation is the process by which information on aggregate projected changes in output, employment and remittances is used to generate changes in labor and nonlabor income at the micro level using the structural models developed as part of the calibration.8 This is done in four steps.9 First, 7 Notice that, although we could estimate separate models for salaried and nonsalaried workers based on the information from the household survey, we would not be able to use these models for the purpose of predicting future earnings since we do not have earnings and employment information disaggregated by salaried/non salaried workers from macro data. 8 We do not assure consistency (i.e that absolute aggregate magnitudes are equal) between the data set used at the two modeling stages (see Bourguignon et. al 2008). Additionally, we assume equal changes at macro and micro levels. We cannot run a test if macro changes are similar or not to micro changes because of lack of a panel data at micro level (see Deaton 2001 and Bourguignon et al 2008). 9 This sequence for introducing changes in the model is based on Vos et al (2002) 7 we use population growth projections to adjust for demographic changes between 2005 (base year) and 20092010. This adjustment is particularly important in the case of Bangladesh because fertility rates are still high, which implies that the number of labor market entrants rises faster than overall population, and the baseline household survey is relatively old. In practical terms, taking into account population growth allows us to explicitly take into changes in the size of the working age population, and hence to distinguish between employment growth driven (or rather absorbed) by demographic trends and net (or additional) employment growth. Secondly, we use the projections from the labor force status and labor earnings models to replicate projected changes in aggregate total and sectoral output and employment. We start with employment and calculate the total number of individuals that need to be reassigned between employment and non employment and across employment sectors in order to match projected aggregate changes in total and sectoral employment. We then use the estimated probabilities from the multinomial model to select candidates for reassignment.10 The direction and magnitude of flows between employment and non employment and across sectors of employment is given by changes in the relative shares of different status with respect to the reference population. For instance, whether individuals must be reassigned from nonemployment to employment or viceversa depends on whether the employment rate of individuals ages 15 to 64 is increasing or decreasing. Similarly, workers are expelled from sectors whose relative share in total employment is declining and absorbed into sectors whose relative share in total employment is increasing will absorb workers (note that this is independent of whether employment in a sector is growing or contracting in absolute terms). The sequence in which individuals are reassigned across states and sectors matters for the final simulation results so we briefly describe here the procedure we follow: Step 1 Flows between employment and nonemployment: If the employment rate is increasing, nonemployed individuals with the lowest predicted probability of being non employed will be reassigned. If the employment rate is declining, employed individuals with the highest probability of being nonemployed will be reassigned. Reassignments will continue up to the point where the change in the employment rate at the micro level matches the change at the macro level. Step 2 Flows out of contracting sectors: For sectors whose share of total employment is declining, those individuals with the lowest predicted probability of being employed in the sector will be selected out and added to the pool of "eligible" workers to be employed in growing sectors (notice this pool also contains those who has been reassigned from non employment if the total employment rate is growing). Reassignments out of each sector will continue up to the point where the change in the sector employment share at the micro level matches the change at the macro level. 10 We add error terms which represent the unobserved heterogeneity of agents' labor supply behavior. These lead to some disparateness in responses to a change in the labor demand, capturing the fact that in the real world individuals who are identical in observables might still respond differently the same change in labor demand. 8 Step 3 ­ Flows into growing sectors: Individuals in the pool of "eligible" workers will be assigned to growing sectors on the basis of their predicted probability of being employed in each sector. Assignments are made sequentially with the sector whose employment share is growing fastest absorbing workers first and the sector whose employment share is growing the slowest absorbing workers last. Reassignments to each sector will continue up to the point where the change in the sector employment share at the micro level matches the change at the macro level. There are a few important features of this process that are worth mentioning. The reassignments described in steps 1 to 3 are calibrated so as to replicate net aggregate flows between employment and nonemployment and across sectors. In reality, movements across these different states are quite significant so that gross flows are usually larger than net flows. The order of proposed steps is such that it allows for nonemployed individuals to become employed and employed individuals to become non employed, but also for individuals to change sectors. In doing this we try to capture the fact that highly "employable" individuals are more likely to remain employed in one sector or another, at times at the expense of less "employable" workers (i.e. highly "employable" workers will crowd others out when employment opportunities become relatively more scarce). We next use the earnings model estimated as part of the calibration to predict earnings for two groups of workers: those with no previous earning history (i.e. nonemployed in 2005) and those who change sector of employment. Because earnings are a function of both observable and unobservable individual and job characteristics, we add a random element to the predicted earnings produced by the model to account for unobserved heterogeneity.11 For all other individuals, we use the earnings information available in the household survey. Once all workers have been assigned positive labor earnings, total earnings in a sector are adjusted to match aggregate projected changes in output. This step relies on the fact that that projected changes in sectoral output can be explained by projected changes in sectoral employment and projected changes in sectoral earnings and profits, and assumes that earnings and profits grow at the same rate. The treatment of public sector workers and those with more than one job differs slightly from what we just described. Total public sector employment is assumed to remain constant (i.e. no individuals are assigned to or out of the public sector) and labor earnings of public sector workers are adjusted in line with their sectoral mapping (agriculture, industry or services). Similarly for those holding more than one job, we assume the sector of employment of their secondary activity remains constant while earnings are adjusted in line with sectoral changes. The third step in the simulation process pertains to changes in international remittances. As mentioned above, in the case of Bangladesh we simulate these changes following a very simple allocation rule. We calculate the total change in international remittances between 2005 and 20092010,12 using actual and 11 Specifically, we draw an individual error from the error distribution generated during the estimation. 12 The nominal (in dollar terms) growth in external remittances is adjusted using the taka/$ exchange rates of the relevant years, to arrive at the value of change in remittances in constant 2005 takas. 9 projected data (this change is positive under both the crisis and the benchmark scenarios) and allocate the dividend as follows: (i) across divisions, remittances are allocated proportionally to the 2005 across division distribution; (ii) among households within divisions: recipient households are selected at random and given a remittance transfer equivalent in real terms to the median remittance transfer in that division in 2005, with the number of total transfers to be made within each division being equal to the total amount of additional remittances to be distributed divided by the 2005 median value.13 As a result of this process the overall distribution of remittances across divisions remains unchanged; while there is an increase in number of recipient households (both types of households, those who did or did not receive remittances in 2005, can receive new remittances in 200910). Finally we simulate changes in other sources of nonlabor income. For this we assume that capital and financial income grow at the same rate as real GDP, public transfers (primarily Social Security transfers) remain constant in real terms at 2005 levels, and domestic remittances change at the same rate as labor income. These assumptions appear to be reasonable for Bangladesh, and can be modified for other countries depending on country circumstances. Assessment of Impacts. Impact assessment is the process by which we use the information on individual employment status and labor income, as well as on nonlabor income at the household level, to generate income and consumption distributions and construct various poverty and distributional measures that can then be used to compare the crisis and the benchmark scenarios. This is done in three steps. First, we account for the fact that between 2005 and 20092010, food prices have increased at a higher rate than other prices. To ensure that the same food basket is affordable at the new prices, we adjust the 2005 poverty line to reflect the increase in food prices relative to that of other prices (for more details, see Section 4.4 below) 14. Second, we calculate total household income by aggregating labor income across all employed individuals and adding nonlabor income, and then use information on household size to construct a measure of percapita household income, as in (3). km * * NL wi I i ym * (3) PCI m * i 1 km Third, because poverty in Bangladesh is measured on the basis of percapita consumption, we need to map income to consumption. We do this by assuming that the householdlevel consumptiontoincome 13 To illustrate, 23% of additional remittances are allocated to rural Dhaka, equal to its share of remittances in 2005. Every randomly selected recipient household then receives 5,417 taka/month, equivalent to the median international remittance transfer in the division in 2005 (9 years of education Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Source: Own estimations based on HIES 2005 i Variable definitions for Occupational Decision Model Variable Definition male = 1 if gender is male yredu Maximum years of education yredu2 Square of maximum years of education age Age of the individual age2 Age squared enrolled = 1 if she is currently attending school hhead = 1 if she is household head remit = 1 if the household receive any kind of remittances (domestic or abroad) perce = ratio between total number of income preceptors in the household 1 and the total number of potential income preceptors within the household depen = dependency ratio between total number of members <15 or >64 years old and total number of members of the household hig_l (*) = 1 if the household operates high areas of land low_l (*) = 1 if the household operates low areas of land oth_pub = 1 if there is another member of the household with a public job urban = 1 if living in urban area sylh, bari, chit, khul, rajs Regional dichotomic variables gen_hhd; gen_rem; Interaction terms hhd_rem; gen_hhd_rem Note: (*) Land: 1 Per adult operating land: we divide the total amount of operating land by the total number of members above 15 years old; 2 Categories: we generate quintiles of per adult operating land and separate the distribution into two categories: low operating areas (low_l) includes those household between the first and forth quintile and high operating areas (hig_l) concentrates the fifth quintile; 3 The base category is households with no operating land ii LOG EARNING EQUATIONS (Individuals between 15 and 64 years old) Low skills (*) High skills (**) Agric Industry Services Agric Industry Services male 1.271*** 0.915*** 0.785*** 1.072*** 0.751*** 0.245*** (0.0405) (0.0407) (0.0481) (0.214) (0.128) (0.0517) yredu 0.0228*** 0.0396*** 0.0357*** 0.128*** 0.119*** 0.0934*** (0.00481) (0.00474) (0.00464) (0.0256) (0.0148) (0.00737) age 0.0549*** 0.0555*** 0.0730*** 0.0678*** 0.0996*** 0.0625*** (0.00559) (0.00702) (0.00739) (0.0221) (0.0187) (0.0103) age2 0.000666*** 0.000683*** 0.000867*** 0.000831*** 0.00114*** 0.000582*** (7.12e05) (9.20e05) (9.47e05) (0.000273) (0.000240) (0.000130) sylh 0.0877 0.0466 0.0690 0.205 0.414*** 0.208*** (0.0608) (0.0617) (0.0569) (0.229) (0.146) (0.0705) bari 0.0335 0.222*** 0.0960* 0.211 0.0728 0.0678 (0.0528) (0.0638) (0.0522) (0.177) (0.115) (0.0603) chit 0.175*** 0.176*** 0.298*** 0.291** 0.261*** 0.267*** (0.0391) (0.0410) (0.0418) (0.143) (0.0837) (0.0472) khul 0.119*** 0.332*** 0.102** 0.264* 0.269*** 0.174*** (0.0425) (0.0458) (0.0411) (0.138) (0.103) (0.0519) rajs 0.127*** 0.375*** 0.239*** 0.103 0.254*** 0.191*** (0.0345) (0.0356) (0.0376) (0.114) (0.0801) (0.0493) sala 0.228*** 0.158*** 0.190*** 0.656*** 0.179*** 0.222*** (0.0303) (0.0314) (0.0287) (0.138) (0.0613) (0.0401) low_l 0.200*** 0.729*** (0.0310) (0.121) hig_l 0.750*** 1.506*** (0.0454) (0.135) urban 0.00610 0.0702** 0.0653** 0.378*** 0.133** 0.163*** (0.0364) (0.0278) (0.0272) (0.104) (0.0628) (0.0352) hhead 0.180*** 0.0656 0.0806 0.0452 (0.0406) (0.0418) (0.0812) (0.0468) ind_exp 0.0627* 0.0698 (0.0331) (0.0696) public 0.404*** 0.254*** (0.0724) (0.0426) Constant 4.594*** 5.847*** 5.593*** 2.889*** 4.284*** 5.597*** (0.115) (0.132) (0.138) (0.495) (0.353) (0.195) Observations 4734 2384 2700 802 759 1938 Rsquared 0.272 0.376 0.262 0.247 0.319 0.281 Adj Rsquared 0.270 0.372 0.259 0.235 0.307 0.277 Notes: Dhaka is the base region; Nonland is the base category (*) Low skills includes those individuals with 08 years of education (**) High skills includes those individuals with more than 9 years of education Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Source: Own estimations based on HIES 2005 iii Variable definitions for Earning Equation Variable Definition male = 1 if gender is male yredu Maximum years of education age Age of the individual age2 Age squared hhead = 1 if she is household head hig_l (*) = 1 if the household operates high areas of land low_l (*) = 1 if the household operates low areas of land ind_exp = 1 if she works in an industry which belongs to the export sector (clothes production; garments; skins and chemicals) public = 1 if she works in the public sector (government organization, public factory or local government) urban = 1 if living in urban area sylh, bari, chit, khul, rajs Regional dichotomic variables Note: (*) Land: 1 Per adult operating land: we divide the total amount of operating land by the total number of members above 15 years old; 2 Categories: we generate quintiles of per adult operating land and separate the distribution into two categories: low operating areas (low_l) includes those household between the first and forth quintile and high operating areas (hig_l) concentrates the fifth quintile; 3 The base category is households with no operating land iv Annex 2 Table A.1: POPULATION GROWTH CHANGE (in millions medium variant) 014 1564 +65 Total Total 51.81 95.76 5.55 153.12 2005 Male 26.36 48.36 2.76 77.48 Female 25.45 47.40 2.79 75.64 Total 50.76 107.15 6.51 164.42 2010 Male 25.83 54.18 3.13 83.13 Female 24.93 52.98 3.39 81.29 Total (2.03) 11.89 17.39 7.38 % Male (2.02) 12.02 13.46 7.29 Female (2.04) 11.76 21.37 7.47 Source:World Population Prospects The 2008 revision UN Population Division Table A.2: SECTORAL OUTPUT GROWTH CHANGE (Base: 199596 = 100; Taka in Millions) Benchmark Crisis % Benchmark % Crisis 2005 2009 2010 2009 2010 09 vs 05 10 vs 05 09 vs 05 10 vs 05 TOTAL 2,560,897 3,311,735 3,546,604 3,286,805 3,469,363 29.3 38.5 28.3 35.5 GDP in Agriculture 570,367 674,336 700,754 678,417 702,840 18.2 22.9 18.9 23.2 constant Industry 724,890 985,917 1,077,113 976,016 1,034,577 36.0 48.6 34.6 42.7 prices Services 1,265,640 1,651,482 1,768,737 1,632,371 1,731,946 30.5 39.8 29.0 36.8 Total 5.93 6.62 7.09 5.82 5.55 (0.8) (1.5) Agriculture 2.21 4.00 3.92 4.63 3.60 0.6 (0.3) Annual Industry 8.28 7.00 9.25 5.93 6.00 (1.1) (3.2) Growth rate Services 6.36 7.50 7.10 6.25 6.10 (1.2) (1.0) 3,848 Remittances (US$ millions) 9,689 10,872 10,000 12,100 151.8 182.5 159.9 214.4 Source: BBS GDP of Blangadesh 2008 and Projections Table A.3: EMPLOYMENT SECTORAL GROWTH CHANGE HIES 2005 Individuals 1564 years old 2005 Benchmark Crisis 2009 2010 2009 2010 Millions % Millions % Millions % Millions % Millions % Total 79.7 89.6 89.6 89.6 89.6 Nonemployed 41.1 51.6 45.1 50.3 43.3 48.4 45.3 50.6 43.9 49.0 Employed 38.5 48.4 44.5 49.7 46.2 51.6 44.3 49.4 45.7 51.0 Agriculture 17.1 44.3 17.9 40.1 18.0 39.0 17.9 40.4 18.0 39.5 Industry 9.2 23.8 10.6 23.8 11.0 23.9 10.5 23.8 10.3 22.5 Services 12.3 32.0 16.1 36.1 17.2 37.2 15.9 35.8 17.4 38.0 Source: BBS GDP of Blangadesh 2008 and Projections v Table B DEMOGRAPHIC, HOUSEHOLD INCOME & LABOR MARKET OVERVIEW Benchmark Crisis 2005 2009 2010 2009 2010 Quantity % Quantity % Quantity % Quantity % Quantity % Population (million) Total 138.8 149.1 149.1 149.1 149.1 Urban 34.3 24.7 36.9 24.8 36.9 24.8 36.9 24.8 36.9 24.8 (1) Workingage 81.9 59.0 92.0 61.7 92.0 61.7 92.0 61.7 92.0 61.7 Household Income (Tk/month) Total 7,229.5 100.0 8,290.6 100.0 8,751.2 100.0 8,229.0 100.0 8,539.1 100.0 (2) Labor income 4,933.2 68.2 5,522.8 66.6 5,792.8 66.2 5,493.9 66.8 5,701.7 66.8 (3) Nonlabor income 1,757.5 24.3 2,226.2 26.9 2,416.8 27.6 2,193.5 26.7 2,295.9 26.9 Remittances 676.7 9.4 1,102.5 13.3 1,262.8 14.4 1,073.0 13.0 1,151.8 13.5 Implicit rent 538.9 7.5 541.5 6.5 541.5 6.2 541.5 6.6 541.5 6.3 (1) Workingage (million) Labor Force 79.7 100.0 89.6 100.0 89.6 100.0 89.6 100.0 89.6 100.0 Nonemployed 41.1 51.6 45.1 50.3 43.3 48.4 45.3 50.6 43.9 49.0 Employed 38.5 48.4 44.5 49.7 46.2 51.6 44.3 49.4 45.7 51.0 Mean earnings per worker (2) (Tk/month) 3,523.4 3,979.7 4,174.9 3,958.2 4,108.0 Education status 79.6 100.0 89.5 100.0 89.5 100.0 89.5 100.0 89.5 100.0 (4) Low skilled 59.5 74.8 67.4 75.3 67.4 75.3 67.4 75.3 67.4 75.3 (5) High skilled 20.1 25.2 22.1 24.7 22.1 24.7 22.1 24.7 22.1 24.7 Employment 38.5 100.0 44.5 100.0 46.2 100.0 44.3 100.0 45.7 100.0 (6) Salaried 21.1 54.8 24.2 54.5 25.4 54.9 24.1 54.4 25.0 54.7 Selfemployment 17.4 45.2 20.3 45.5 20.8 45.1 20.2 45.6 20.7 45.3 Economic sectors 38.5 100.0 44.5 100.0 46.2 100.0 44.3 100.0 45.7 100.0 Agriculture 17.1 44.3 17.9 40.1 18.0 39.0 17.9 40.4 18.0 39.5 Industry 9.2 23.8 10.6 23.8 11.0 23.9 10.5 23.8 10.3 22.5 Services 12.3 32.0 16.1 36.1 17.2 37.2 15.9 35.8 17.4 38.0 Notes: (1) Individuals in 1564 age category (2) Labor earnings from all activities (3) Includes capital(rent land, property, profits, etc), remittances, social(insurances, charity, etc) and other nonlabor income (4) Lowskilled = 09 years of education (5) Highskilled = +10 years of education (6) Include daily wage and salaried workers Source: Own estimations based on HIES 2005 and projections Table C FOOD PRICES COMPARED TO OVERALL CPI CPI Rural General Food NonFood Food vs Gral (1) (2) (3) Weight of food in CPI and Poverty Line (PL) in rural areas 2005 100.0 100.0 100.0 1.81 CPI Food 62.96 Projection Nonfood 37.04 2009 135.7 140.7 126.7 5.58 PL Rural Dhaka Food 67.10 2010 144.8 152.0 131.9 6.86 Nonfood 32.90 2010 (*) 134.3 132.5 137.4 0.49 % variation in PL '09 0.3093 Variation % variation in PL '10 0.4150 2009/05 35.7 40.7 41.7 % variation in PL '10 * (0.1086) 2010/05 44.8 52.0 31.9 (*) Considers the international rice price forecast of FAO for 2010 2010/05(*) 34.3 32.5 37.4 Source: BBS Consumer Price Index (CPI) and Inflation Rate several reports vi Table D.1: MAIN DISTRIBUTIVE RESULTS OF MACROMICRO SIMULATIONS Benchmark Crisis 2005 2009 2010 2009 2010 2010* Moderate poverty Headcount rate 40.0 28.2 24.6 28.6 25.8 25.4 Poverty gap 9.0 5.9 5.0 6.0 5.3 5.2 Severity of poverty 2.9 1.8 1.5 1.9 1.6 1.6 Extreme poverty Headcount rate 25.1 16.5 13.9 16.7 14.8 14.5 Poverty gap 4.7 2.9 2.4 3.0 2.5 2.5 Severity of poverty 1.3 0.8 0.6 0.8 0.7 0.7 Inequality percap. Exp Gini 0.310 0.321 0.324 0.341 0.320 0.320 Theil 0.186 0.197 0.199 0.222 0.194 0.194 Notes: Benchmark = economy growth on trend Crisis = financial crisis scenario (*) Crisis with FAO rice prices forecast (1) Per capita Expenditure (2) Total labor income (3) Main labor income Source: Own estimations Table D.2: MAIN POVERTY & INEQUALITY RESULTS DIFFERENT METHODOLGIES Benchmark Crisis 2005 2009 2010 2009 2010 Headcount Ratio Povstat 40.0 28.7 25.1 28.9 26.3 (1) Elasticity 40.0 27.4 24.4 28.0 25.6 Macromicro simulation 40.0 28.2 24.6 28.6 25.8 Poverty Gap Povstat 9.0 5.8 4.8 5.8 5.1 Macromicro simulation 9.0 5.9 5.0 6.0 5.3 Severity of poverty Povstat 2.9 1.7 1.4 1.7 1.5 Macromicro simulation 2.9 1.8 1.5 1.9 1.6 (2) Inequality percap. Exp Gini Povstat 0.01 0.31 0.31 0.31 0.31 Macromicro simulation 0.33 0.32 0.32 0.34 0.32 Theil Povstat 0.19 0.19 0.19 0.18 0.18 Macromicro simulation 0.21 0.20 0.20 0.22 0.19 Notes: (1) No food prices adjustment (2) Noncomparable because Povstat calculates over household head distribution Source: Own estimations & World Bank (2009) vii TABLE E POVERTY IMPACT BY AREA & REGION Table E.1: Household income (mean Tk/month at constant 2005 prices) AREA REGION TOTAL Rural Urban Barisal Chittagong Dhaka Khulna Rajshahi Sylhet Benchmark Total income 8,751 7,506 12,421 7,602 11,114 9,720 6,906 6,439 11,600 2010 Labor income 5,793 4,764 8,826 5,188 6,958 6,316 4,695 4,852 6,450 Remittances 1,263 1,326 1,078 881 2,514 1,318 563 296 3,461 Crisis Total income 8,539 7,318 12,137 7,456 10,748 9,480 6,793 6,353 11,159 2010 Labor income 5,702 4,699 8,657 5,115 6,836 6,208 4,633 4,788 6,347 Remittances 1,152 1,209 984 819 2,280 1,200 520 280 3,135 Loss of income with crisis (% of benchmark) 2.4 2.5 2.3 1.9 3.3 2.5 1.6 1.3 3.8 Loss of labor income (% of benchmark) 1.6 1.4 1.9 1.4 1.8 1.7 1.3 1.3 1.6 Loss of remittance (% of benchmark) 8.8 8.8 8.7 7.1 9.3 8.9 7.6 5.5 9.4 Table E.2: Poverty rate (% of population under Upper PL) AREA REGION TOTAL Rural Urban Barisal Chittagong Dhaka Khulna Rajshahi Sylhet HEADCOUNT 2005 40.0 43.8 28.4 52.0 34.0 32.0 45.7 51.2 33.8 Benchmark [B] 2010 24.6 26.7 18.1 37.8 12.4 19.2 31.7 36.5 16.3 Crisis [C] 2010 25.8 28.0 19.2 39.5 13.7 20.1 32.8 38.1 17.4 [C] [B] as % of [B] 2010 5.1 4.9 5.9 4.6 10.2 4.8 3.7 4.5 6.5 Table E.3: Extreme poverty rate (% of population under Lower PL) AREA REGION TOTAL Rural Urban Barisal Chittagong Dhaka Khulna Rajshahi Sylhet HEADCOUNT 2005 25.1 28.6 14.6 35.6 16.1 19.9 31.6 34.5 20.8 Benchmark [B] 2010 13.9 15.9 7.7 24.7 3.4 11.2 19.5 21.5 8.3 Crisis [C] 2010 14.8 16.9 8.4 25.8 4.3 11.9 20.7 22.6 9.3 [C] [B] as % of [B] 2010 6.6 6.4 8.4 4.7 26.5 5.6 5.9 5.1 13.0 viii TABLE F PEOPLE WHO ARE POOR "DUE" TO CRISIS 2010 Crisis General Structurally Household characteristics Vulnerable population poor Rural (%) 79.5 74.7 82.1 No. of members 4.90 4.86 5.19 Dependency ratio 0.42 0.39 0.48 Employed (individuals)* 54.8 50.3 53.3 Sectoral share of employment (% of total employed) Agriculture 26.7 39.0 45.6 Industry 27.1 23.9 19.4 Services 46.2 37.2 35.0 Household head Age (mean) 40.98 45.57 43.47 Male (%) 95.0 89.7 91.3 Education level 09 years 87.9 79.1 94.3 Household income (CrisisVulnerable) Benchmark Crisis Income (mean) Total Income (tk. 2005 prices) 6,741.2 5,165.2 23.4 Labor income 4,113.8 4,046.0 1.6 Nonlabor income 2,268.0 759.9 66.5 Remittances from abroad % of household receiving 45.7 9.9 78.5 Mean conditional on receiving 1,681.1 178.9 89.4 Implicit rent 359.4 359.4 Percapita Expenditure (mean) 1,278.9 785.9 38.5 TABLE G INCOME STATUS "CHANGES" Table G.1: Transition matrix: Benchmark Crisis Percapita income Crisis 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 100.0 2 2.79 97.21 3 0.68 4.21 95.11 4 0.34 0.46 6.18 93.03 Benchmark 5 0.69 0.68 1.33 5.79 91.50 6 0.60 0.35 0.39 0.58 6.89 91.18 7 0.33 0.14 0.71 0.38 2.62 7.26 88.55 8 0.25 0.49 0.27 0.92 0.93 7.34 88.58 1.10 0.12 9 0.11 0.23 0.32 0.49 1.32 0.32 6.30 90.91 10 0.11 0.04 0.17 4.72 0.61 94.35 Table G.2: Transition matrix: Benchmark Crisis Percapita Labor income Crisis 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 100.0 1.59 2 98.4 3 2.78 97.2 4 5.03 94.85 0.12 Benchmark 5 5.30 94.7 6 6.87 93.1 7 6.95 92.9 0.12 8 7.72 92.28 0.07 9 4.11 95.8 10 2.82 97.2 ix Figure A1: GICs (crisis vs. benchmark, 2010) Per capita labor income by sector 0.00 -1.00 -2.00 % Change -3.00 -4.00 -5.00 -6.00 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 Percentile Agriculture Industry Services Source: Own simulations based on HIES (2005) Note: 1) GICs have been smoothed 2) Percentiles of income (x axis) refer to the relevant sector x