Regional Perspectives on World Development Report 1995 - LABOR AND ECONOMIC REFORMS IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN Regional Perspectives on World Development Report 1995 LABOR AND ECONOMIC REFORMS IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN THE WORLD BANK WASHINGTON, D.C. İD 1995 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street, N. W, Washington, D.C 20433, U.S.A. All rights reserved Manufactured in the United States ofAmerica FirstprintingAugust 1995 This report has been prepared by the staff of the Workl Bank. The judgments expressed do not necessarily reflect the views of the Board of Executive Directors or the governments they represent. Editing, layout, andproduction by American Writing Corporation ISBN 0-8213-3348-8 ISSN 1020-3648 Contents Foreword v 1 Policy Background 1 Reforms in the 1980s 1 Poverty and income distribution 1 2 Labor Market Conditions 3 Demographics and labor supply 3 Employment, unemployment, and real wages 5 T he special case of Caribbean countries 7 Changing labor market conditions in Latin America, 1960-95 7 3 Policy Reforms and International Integration 10 Trade reform 11 The real exchange rate and capital inflows 11 Broadly based reforms: The key to success 12 International migration 14 4 Current Labor Market Interventions and the Road to Reform 16 A role for governments in setting wages? 16 Dealing with wrongful dismissals 16 Contributions to social security 18 Labor-management relations 19 5 The Changing Role of the State 23 Public secror employment and wages 23 Setting priorities and choosing better policy instruments 23 6 The Outlook for Workers 25 References 27 iii This report was prepared in conjunction with World Development Report 1995: Workers in an Integrating World. It was written by Alejandra Cox Edwards under the direction of Michael Walton and in close collaboration with the Latin America and the Caribbean Regional Office. This collaboration was coordinated by Suman Bery. Meta de Coquereaumont and Paul Holtz edited the report. Christian Perez laid out the text. Ian Bannon, Daniel Cotlear, Sebastian Edwards, Edgardo Favaro, Norman Hicks, Homi Kharas, Danny Leipziger, Luis Londono, Raj Nalari, and Roberto Steiner revised and commented on eatlier drafts. Louise Cord, Geoffrey Shepherd, and Mateen Thobani helped draft Box 2. Many other professionals from the Latin America and the Caribbean Region helped with case studies, country reports, and other background materials. Luis Riveros (University of Chile) also commented on an earlier draft. iv Foreword ver the past decade most countries in the Latin The recent shift toward marker orientation and openness to ( ) America and Caribbean Region have stabilized their international trade requires a different approach to labor policy economies and lowered barriers to international trade. and different instruments for addressing income distribution These efforts, which have been rewarded by the restoration of goals. Labor policy has to be redirected toward enhancing positive economic growth, are ultimately driven by the need to employment opportunities and labor productivity throughout advance in the fight against poverty, which is the majoreconomic the economy. Market-based growth that makes efficient use of challenge facing the region. Although the reform process itself labor increases opportunities for all workers to better themselves. may sometimes produce transitory dislocations, deeper engage- But an unequal distribution of initial endowments (including ment with the world economy is the best assurance of rising liv- access to effective education as well as physical assets) tends to ing standards and reduced inequality for all. For countries in the perpetuate differences in income distribution across generations. region, the reform imperative is both strengthened and compli- To change these patterns, Latin American countries have to find cated by certain characteristics: an urbanized population, heav- ways to improve this initial distribution by promoting access to ily dependent on informal rather than formal sector activity; high education and targeting the delivery of services to the poor. payroll taxes, with their associated disincentive effects; consider- Deepening reform, including social sector and labor policy able inequality in education levels; and sizable social security reform, holds out the hope of large improvements in the incomes financing needs, stemming from the relatively advanced stage of and working conditions of most ofthe region's workers and a nar- several countries in the demographic transition. These factors, rowing of differentials between rich and poor. which diminish the impact of reforms already taken co improve This report gives special attention to four areas of labor pol- the living conditions of the population, need attention if the full icy. First, direct government intervention in wage determination benefits of liberalization are to be captured. and strict seniority rules have to give way to a system that rewards The goal of establishing an environment for market-based effort, high productivity, and good management within a frame- economic growth grounded in each country's comparative work that relies on voluntary negotiation of working conditions advantage represents a major departure from the past, when between workers and firms. Second, job security legislation has direct price interventions were used to address poverty goals and to be replaced by a more effective mechanism that protects work- import substitution was used to promote industrialization. ers when they change jobs. Third, mandatory contributions to Investments undertaken in these distorted economic environ- social security and other programs must be designed carefully in ments yielded only low rates of total factor productivity growth, order to minimize the distortionarv effect of labor taxes. Fourth, diminishing the capacity to increase per capita incomes. government subsidies for training and education must be redi- Governments attempted to make up for the failure of markets by rected to the demand side and targeted to those who cannot increasing public sector production, but that ultimately com- afford to pay. promised macroeconomic balance and resulted in inflation and Given a deepening both of engagement in the international recurrent balance of payment crises. economy and of internal reform, the countries of Latin America Many of the policies aimed at reducing poverty and tackling and the Caribbean have the potential for more rapid growth. inequality in the 1960-80 period-including agrarian reforms, fuller involvement of labor in the economic mainstream, and minimum wage legislation, and labor market regulations-were substantial poverty reduction in the years ahead. well intentioned, but the region made little or no progress in improving income distribution. Furthermore, such policies dis- couraged the effective use of the most abundant resources of the region, including labor. Labor policy was seen as a means of directly enhancing workers' well-being through government involvement in wage determination and mandates on fringe ben- (' efits and job security. At best, these attempts improved the con- Shahid Javed Burki ditions and security of the minority of formal sector workers, but Vice President they added a bias against overall labor demand. Latin America and the Caribbean Region v CHAPTER I Policy Background WorUDeT Tore lopment Report l995examines the relations economic growth. This improvement in aggregate indicators is between policy, economic performance, and the an important step in reducing poverty and reversing decades of Vi' well-being of workers. It concludes that there is no deplorable social conditions. The structural reforms started dur- more powerful mechanism to raise the incomes of workers than ing the last decade can be sustained only by reducing poverty and market-led development. Integration with the world economy increasing the equality of income distribution. Attending to the creates tremendous opportunities for countries that manage their needs of the poor for education, nutrition, and health will have domestic economies soundly. A market-based strategy requires important direct effects on economic growth as a larger propor- public action that enhances the functioning of markets, particu- tion of the population acquires basic human capital, growth larly the labor market-and that has important implications for should accelerate. the selection of instruments of social policy. Transitions to more market-oriented systems inevitably generate winners and losers. Refonns in the 1980s Transfer programs, reforms to promote labor mobility, and poli- After more than three decades of inward-oriented policies and cies to equip workers for change are all necessary to increase adapt- heavy state intervention, Latin American countries initiated a ability and spread the benefits of fiuture growth. series of market-oriented reforms in the 1 980s to achieve macro- These lessons are important for Latin American countries, economic stability and reestablish economic growth. Govern- which pursued industrialization based on import substitution ments imposed budgetary discipline in the public sector, in some and suffered frequent macroeconomic imbalances from the cases by privatizing state enterprises; reduced international trade 1950s through the 1970s. As a consequence they failed to estab- barriers and realigned exchange rates; and deregulated financial lish an environment conducive to sustained growth in labor pro- markets (World Bank 1993b). These reforms are changing the ductivity. Overvaluacion of the real exchange rate hurt role of the state as it pulls back as a producer of goods and ser- labor-intensive exports and agriculture, with detrimental conse- vices and reduces its intervention in the setting of prices and allo- quences for employment and wages, while inflation hit the poor cation of investment. Somewhat surprisingly, these reforms have particularly hard because they have fewer defenses against the barely affected labor markets in most Latin American countries. direct and indirect consequences of the inflation tax. Analysis of It is now apparent that fiscal discipline, removal of trade bar- the structural transformation of the region between 1950 and riers, and financial deregulation are not enough to encourage the 1980 reveals less reliance on exports than expected, investment private sector to invest and create jobs, at least not quickly enough at about the expected rate, and more rapid contraction in agri- to reduce poverty and build support for market-oriented policies. cultural employment than expected (Syrquin 1991). At the same In addition, governments need to do better in their traditional time governments tried to improve workers' welfare through role of providing public goods (basic infrastructure, police pro- interventions in wage determination and collective bargaining tection). And they need to find new instruments of social policy and through legislation on fringe benefits and job security. that do not distort (or that minimize distortions in) the allocation Market-oriented reforms have attempted to correct the biases of resources. This requires reforming tax policies, public funding that these policies introduced. In the process the role of the state for education, social security systems, subsidized housing, and is slowly being redefined. Some countries substantially reduced more. These reforms must reduce the distortions that persist in effective rates of protection to industrial activities and reestab- theseeconomies while preservingsocial goals-improvingthe liv- lished incentives for nontraditional export activities. But other ing standards and economic opportunities of the poor. areas of policymaking still need attention, including labor pol- icy, public sector employment, property rights, and the provision Poverty and income distribution of public goods and services. Despite considerable variation Poverty and inequality have long plagued Latin American within the region, there are clear patterns of labor policy that economies. Between 1950 and the late 1970s the share of income need revision, along with public sector employment and pay going to the poorest fifth of the population generally declined. polices that influence the functioning of the public sector. Although economic growth between 1960 and 1980 improved Since the mid-1980s many Latin American countries have living standards-as measured by school enrollments, health improved their macroeconomic stability and begun to restore conditions, nutrition levels, and other social indicators-by the L A, ra o R A N D D c o ND o M I C r F R M S Table 1. Population below the poverty line in selected Latin American countries, 1970 and 1981 Table 2. Social indicators, 1970, 1980, 1990 (percent) (weighted averages) Country 1970 1981 Indicator 1970 1980 1990 Argentina 8 8 Illiterate population Brazil 49 43 (percentage of population Chile 17 16 aged 15 or older) 29.0 23.0 15.3 Colombia 45 43 Enrollment ratios, Costa Rica 24 22 ages 6-11 71.0 82.3 87.3 Honduras 65 64 Mexico 34 29 Gross enrollment ratios, Panama 39 37 secondary level 31.6 47.4 54.9 Peru 50 49 Population per physician 2,053 1,315 1,083 Venezuela 25 24 Average for ten Latin Percentage of population American countries 39 35with access to safe water 53.7 70.1 79.8 Infant mortality rate Source: World Bank 1993b. (per 1,000 live births) 84.9 63.0 48.2 Life expectancy at birth early 1980s a large portion of the region's population still lived (years) 60.1 64.3 67.5 in poverty (Table 1). Note: Includes data for countries with populations above 1 million. Growth almost always reduces poverty, as demonstrated by Source: World Bank 1993b. Brazil, Colombia, Costa Rica, and Mexico during the 1970s. Morley (1992) calculates that as per capita income grew 41 per- market-oriented policies, labor-intensive activities expanded, and cent in Costa Rica between 1961 and 1971, poverty was cut in the accumulation offactors thatcomplement laboryielded higher half. Similarly, the region's declining incomes in the 1980s were returns. Rural employment increased substantially, lifting rural associated with a rise in the extent and severity of poverty. incomes. Rapidly growing demand for labor in urban markets Yet many social indicators-infant mortality, school enroll- allowed wages to rise, and the poor shared in rising living stan- ment, life expectancy-have continued to improve despite the dards. Investment in human capital-especially at the preschool rise in poverty (Table 2). Although it is believed that publicly pro- and primary levels-helped increase productivity and real wage vided services have declined substantially because of the large growth and reduced inequality (World Bank 1995). The higher budget cuts, the overall expenditure probably has not been wages induced further productivity increases throughout the reduced by much-and may have remained unchanged (Grosh economy and fed back into the growth process. 1992). The lag between budget cuts and measurable change in This report examines key aspects of labor market conditions, social indicators may be one reason for the continued improve- on the supply and demand side, as they are affected by the reform ment in these indicators. Another may be that aggregate trends process that is integrating Latin American economies with world hide worsening conditions in some parts of society. It is also pos- markets. Four areas are highlighted in which labor policy has sible that social spending has become more efficient. made a difference and reforms can benefit growth and improve East Asia's experience demonstrates how sustainable economic outcomes for workers. Issues of transition and the challenges fac- growth reduces poverty through many channels, including ing countries in the region in reforming their social delivery sys- employment creation and rising real wages. As the region adopted tems are also explored. 2 CHAPTER 2 Labor Market Conditions D uring 1965-93 the working-age population grew by Demographic trends affectgrowth in school-age populations, about 3 percent a year in all developing regions. This labor force participation, and old-age dependency (ratio of the consistent growth stands in sharp contrast to the large elderly to the working-age population). There are close links differences in GDP and productivity growth across developing between population age structure and labor supply, as is illus- regions. Annual GDP growth in East Asia, for example, reached trated by the cases of Brazil, Guatemala, and Mexico, which have 7.5 percent, in Latin America and the Caribbean it was 4.1 per- different population age structures (Figure 1). cent, and in Sub-Saharan Africa it was less than 3 percent. The Except for the young and old age groups, labor force par- evidence indicates that economic growth is not constrained on ticipation rates for men within age groups change little across the supply side. Sustained growth is possible through the efficient countries and over time. But for women they increase as fertil- use of natural endowments and the accumulation of comple- ity falls. A country's overall rate of participation is the result of mentary resources. The challenge facing Latin America and the interactions between individual behavior (participation) and Caribbean is to establish an environment that makes efficient use demographics (age distribution of the population). For exam- of the region's resources and expands demand for labor. ple, Brazil, which has a higher life expectancy than its neigh- There are a number of ways to look at labor market condi- bors, tends to support a large share of the elderly out of the tions. Workers are concerned with jobs and compensation levels. labor force. They make decisions about labor force participation based on labor market conditions and other variables that affect their costs Working-age population and labor force participation of living. Employers are concerned about worker availability and The working-age population (those between fifteen and sixty- reliability, as well as labor costs. Their hiring decisions are also five years old) grew by about 3 percent a year between 1965 and influenced by market prices and macroeconomic conditions. For 1993, and is now estimated at about 300 million. The labor force policymakers, rising real wages are often cause for concern, since participation rate (those of working age who are working or seek- they may signal a loss in competitiveness; declining real wages are ing employment) is estimated to be 56 percent. or nearly 165 also reason for concern because they represent a worsening situ- million. While the growth rate of the working-age population ation for workers. To be useful as indicators of performance, over the past three decades was comparable to that of other devel- labor market indicators must be examined along with other varn- oping regions, the labor force grew faster than in other regions ables. For example, it matters whether changes in real wages are (except for the Middle East and North Africa), fueled mostly by related to labor productivity, affect all workers, or reflect market the rising participation of women as fertility rates deciined and forces or policy interventions. female schooling levels rose. Like other regions. Latin America saw a decline in participation among the very young-as school- Demographics and labor supply ing increased-and the very old (see Figure 1). Population growth rates have been falling throughout Latin Labor force participation rates for women have increased America, dropping from 2 percent a year in the late 1980s to a from an average of 28 percent in the 1970s to 38 percent in the projected 1.6 percent for the late I 990s. The region is in a late early 1 990s. There are large variations across countries, with the stageofthedemographictransition, when concerns begin toshift rate ranging from a low of 24 percent in Bolivia (1989) to a high from schooling facilities to care of the elderly. Still, there are of 51 percent in El Salvador (1990). No direct linkexists between important variations in patterns of population growth. In some economic development and women's labor force participation. countries, mostly in Central America, populations are still grow- Still, rapid development is often accompanied by higher female ing rapidly, a result of high fertility. Population growth results participation, higher levels of schooling for girls, and lower fer- from the interaction of behavioral variables (fertility) and demo- tility rates. Labor market conditions matter too. In El Salvador, graphics (the age distribution of the population). For example, for example, military conflict and migration reduced the domes- Brazil has a lower fertility rate than Mexico, but because the share tic supply of male labor, inducing the entry of women into the of women of reproductive age is larger in Brazil, the population labor force. T he regional economic downturn of the 1980s also growth rate is higher in Brazil (2.1 percent) than in Mexico (1.9 had an impact on women's participation, which tends to rise with percent). recessions in low-income countries. 3 L A S r R AN N D E c D 1 O M I C R EF a R M S Figure 1. Population and labor force by age and gender in Brazil, Guatemala, and Mexico, 1965 and 1995 (millions) Brazil 1965 Brazil 1995 [EU 65 plus [f] 60-64 rEc 1E 1 55-59 50-54 45-49 40-44 35-39 30-34 men women 25-29 men women 20-24 15-§19 10-14 0-9 _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ 20 15 10 5 0 5 10 15 20 20 15 10 5 0 5 10 15 20 Guatemala 1965 Guatemala 1995 65 plus 60-64 55-59 50-54 EA I 45-49 L] H40-44 [2 _ 35-39 F D1 30 34 lm2gxs |33 men E D women 25-29 men women 13 D 202-24 15-19 1 10-14 0-9 , _ , _, _, 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 Mexico 1965 Mexico 1995 65 plus 60-64 m 55-59 50-54 E: 1 45-49 40-44 35-39 30-34 men women 25-29 men s women IES L: 20-24 E1 15-19 10-14 1 0-9 1 - 15 10 5 0 5 10 15 15 10 5 0 5 10 15 F Population E Labor force Source: ILO estimates and projections. Rising level of schooling differences in secondary schooling were already negligible in Primary schooling reached 100 percent coverage in most Latin the 1970s. American and Caribbean countries in the 1970s, although While Latin American and Caribbean countries have made secondary-level coverage continued to show large disparities considerable progress in providing education, other regions have across countries, ranging from 8 percent in Guatemala and done as well or better. In 1985 countries in Latin America and the Haiti to 70 percent in Barbados. Secondary schooling has since Caribbean and those in EastAsia had about the same share of pop- expanded rapidly, and by 1990 coverage rates had doubled in ulation with some schooling (Figure 3). EastAsia had a larger pro- most countries. Exceptions include El Salvador-where sec- portion of population with secondary schooling or more, while ondary coverage remains under 30 percent-and Brazil- Latin America and the Caribbean had a higher proportion with where it reached only 40 percent, a low rate for a country at its higher education. Since then East Asia has increased both overall income level (Figure 2). In contrast with other regions, gender enrollments and the share of students with secondary or more 4 L A B O R N1i A R KCET C ON 1 D I T IO r N S schooling faster than Latin America and the Caribbean, though Secondary school coverage expanded in the it still trails in higher education coverage. Note that overall edu- 1970s and 1980s cation levels change slowly, despite significant advances in cover- age. That is because investment is concentrated among the young, Figure 2. Secondary school coverage in Latin while the distribution takes into account the entire population. America and the Caribbean, 1970-90 The relative performance of schooling investment in Latin (percent) America and the Caribbean is heavily influenced by Brazil, which o 20 40 60 80 ioo represents a third of the region's population. Barbados ___________. __- Trinidad '' Employment, unemployment, and real wages Uruguay = Formal employment is an important fraction of the labor force. Chile_ Argentina =- - - - -fi_ The Economic Commission for Latin America and the Dominican Rep. . Caribbean estimates that in 1990 employers, employees in firms Peru with more than five employees, professionals, and the public sec- Guyana i'' tot accounted for 43 percent of the urban labor force in Bolivia, Panama [- i: 54 percent in Brazil, 60 percent in Chile and Panama, and nearly Venezuela 70 percent in Costa Rica and Venezuela. Public sector employ- Ecuador e- . e ' es make up a large share of formal employees: 37 percent in Colombia ___ Venezuela, 42 percent in Costa Rica, and 50 percent in Panama. Mexico --a Regionwide, 52 percent of employment is generated in the ser- Nicaragua | vices sector, 26 percent in industry, and 22 percent in agriculture. Costa Rica _ X--__ °i_ . i 1970 Central American countries are less urbanized (about 40 percent) Bolivia L_ 1985 and more agrarian than South American countries, where close onrazi 1990 to 80 percent of the population lives in urban areas (Table 3). Paraguay The rural economy is receiving considerable attention in El Salvador j 111 Latin American countries, after years of neglect. Recent reforms Guatemala E have given a boost to agriculture, which had been burdened bv Haiti years of macroeconomic instability, real exchange rate overvalu- Source: World Bank 1993a. ation, and import substitution to promote industrialization. (East Asia's more balanced policy toward agriculture, by contrast, East Asia has overtaken Latin America and the Caribbean in schooling coverage Figure 3. Education levels in Latin America and the Caribbean and East Asia, 1985-95 (percent) 100 rW 100 K I Rising stock of schooling Rising stock of schooling 80 r in Latin America and the Caribbean 80 r in East Asia 60 ( .? 60 401 ,'˘';tR';. l---1985 60 V 40 '' '40 _ ! ? s ?', . . *1995 _ - 20 _- ? - - ? c ' . ' -' ' '; 20 - _ 0 o H,gher Secondarv Some Some Higher Secondar secondary Prar mar Highrce Shoand Fm secondary Pri9ary primary Source: Ahuja and Filmer 1995. 5 L . A 1 a r A.4 E D r- c o M I c F2 E FI O r M S Table 3. Urban and rural employment in selected countries, 1990 (percent) Urban employment Rural employment Pnvate sector employers, Self- Urban professionals, employed, popu- and firms small firms, lation with more than and domestic Wage Self-employed Self-employed Country (share) five employees Public sector servants Employers employees farmn nonfarm Venezuela 84 45.6 22.5 31.9 6.9 46.2 33.1 13.2 Chile 81 59.4 40.6 2.9 64.7 25.1 7.2 Brazil 76 54.0 46.0 3.1 42.5 45.6 8.8 Panama 70 32.6 29.3 38.1 2.0 38.9 47.3 11.8 Costa Rica 46 42.5 25.0 32.5 5.1 66.3 16.8 11.8 Guatemala 38 31.3 14.6 54.1 0.5 38.3 47.9 13.2 Honduras 35 30.1 14.8 55.1 0.5 33.9 48.7 17.2 a. Included under private sector. Source: CEPAL 1992. encouraged the development of productive rural nonfarm activ- explain the incidence of urban informality: a pro-industry, anti- ities. A recent World Bank study found that the likelihood of agriculture bias, which encouraged faster rural-urban migration rural poverty in Ecuador falls significantly with increases in per than in other regions, and labor policies that overlooked the role capita landholdings, years of schooling, and the proportion of of wages and working conditions as incentives and market signals, household members with a regular off-farm job. reducing the number of formal jobs and encouraging the devel- In some countries nonfarm rural labor demand has arisen in opment of the informal sector. response to seasonal patterns, while in others it has been associ- ated with booms in the processing of local raw materials. In many countries workers move back and forth between rural and urban = _ areas, working in rural areas in peak seasons and as urban street vendors in the slack season. As a result, a large degree of season- Figure 4. Regional patterns of urban informality ality in the production of coffee or sugar can be accommodated (percent) by worker movements. Recognizing the importance of this Informal sector mobility in the design of labor legislation can be an important share of labor force K Sub-Saharan Africa step toward increasing overall efficiency, improving labor pro- 80 - El East Asia and the Pacific ductivity, and generating better opportunities. In a number of E South Asia countries labor legislation works against this pattern of rural- 70 -Burkina Faso Latin America and urban movement rather than supporting it. Temporary formal t 60 -x S>l Peru contracts are restricted in duration and renewability, hourly con- tracts are often restricted, and benefits required by law assume 50 °Senegal the existence of a long-term contract. In all economies there is a continuum of employment oppor- 40 * Mexico tunities, from self-employment within the household to formal Pakistan C Malaysia employment in registered enterprises. Informal activities are cho- 30 Argentina sen as a way of avoiding taxation. The urban labor force working 20 L . in the informal sector is as high as 75 percent in some developing countries (Burkina Faso. Sierra Leone). Informaliryand labor pro- °0 ductivity are negatively related. Holding GDP per worker con- 0 2.000 4,000 6.000 8,000 stant, the incidence of informality is highest in Latin America and GDP per worker (dollars: 1985 international prices) the Caribbean (Figure 4). Two policy-related factors help to Source: Banerji 1995; Summers and Heston 1991. 6 L.A 9 B O R M A R K E T CO N D I T I OCN 5t Social security systems with weak links between benefits and up (Figure 5). Countries that introduced economic reforms began mandated contributions encourage workers to avoid the payroll to recover in the 1 990s (Chile, Argentina), while those that did tax by working in the unregulated informal sector. A study of the not continued to lag (Brazil and others). Is the recovery sustain- Brazilian social security system found that workers stay in the able? The answer depends on whether reforms are continued, par- informal sector as long as possible, switching to formal employ- ticularly at the microeconomic level. Domestic macroeconomic ment only to meet the vesting requirements of the pension sys- policies and external conditions also will have important impacts. tem. During the late 1 980s private sector workers in Peru began The debt crisis, and the adjustment period that followed, hurt to abandon wage employment contracts to become short-term employment and real wages. Urban unemployment in the region independent contractors, which allowed them to use the equiv- typically rose in the early 1980s and declined thereafter (Table alent of the mandatory 9 percent payroll contribution for pub- 4). Figures are hard to compare across countries (data come from lic health insurance to buy private health insurance. survey questionnaires), but some trends are apparent. Argentina, Another reason that workers may stay in the informal sector Nicaragua, and Peru have seen unemployment rise in the 1990s, is that, where promotions are based on seniority, formal employ- while in Bolivia, Chile, Colombia, Guatemala, and Venezuela it ment may not reward entrepreneurship, initiative, or individual has fallen. effort. A study comparing the informal sectors in El Salvador, In Argentina and some other countries unemployment is Mexico, and Peru found that wages were higher in the informal closely linked to economic restructuring and sectoral shifts. sector than in the formal sector in Mexico, suggesting that Pessino and Giacchini (1994) find evidence of an increasing Mexican workers may be paying for the stability and pre- duration of unemployment. This finding suggests that, at least dictability of formal jobs by accepting lower wages. for some of the unemployed, the gap between their supply price Three types of policies should guide government responses to and market wages has risen, making them less likely to accept informal labor markets. First, antilabor biases, whether against job offers. This may reflect changes in the market value of some agricultural or formal sector employment, should be removed. skills, which is consistent with economic restructuring, and the Second, the tax and regulatory burden on formal activity should introduction of unemployment benefits. be set at moderate, enforceable levels. Third, there is scope for public action, especially in urban infrastructure provision. Policies Latin America saw labor productivity fall that subsidize credit for some farms over others should be avoided during the debt crisis as well. Small firms see lack of credit as a constraint, but the expe- riences of East Asian countries and, more recently, Bolivia show r that small firms can develop despite real interest rates on the order gr 5 reg dfensint g of 40 percent-as long as they have access to credit and markets. per worker, 1965-93 Price stability seems to be the necessary condition for credit to -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8 10 spread to the small firms and farms sector (Mosley 1993). r 196180 1 East Asia and the Pacific 1980-90 The special case of Caribbean countries 1990 93 The Caribbean countries, with a population of 20 million in Europe and Central Asia 1992, represent about 5 percent of the region's total population. This area contains the richest country of the region in terms of l GNP-the Bahamas-and the poorest-Guyana and Haiti. As Latin America and the Caribbean a group these countries differ significantly from the rest of Latin America. The Caribbean countries have high trade-to-output Middle East and North Africa ratios. The most open countries have trade ratios that exceed 80 percent, and even the least open (Haiti) has a trade ratio of more than 25 percent. As a result these economies often experience H,gh-inconneOECD large external shocks. South Asia Changing labor market conditions in Latin America, 1960-95 Output and labor productivity grew adequately in the region subsaharanAfrica between 1965 and 1980, but the debt crisis of the 1 980s marked the beginning of a sharp downturn as international credit dried Source: World Bank data and estimates. 7 L A 6 OR r A^N D E C ONO 0 M I C R E F O R M S Table 4. Average annual urban unemployment in selected Latin American countries, 1984-94 (percent) Country 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994a Argentina 4.6 6.1 5.6 5.9 6.3 7.6 7.5 6.5 7.0 9.6 11.2 Bolivia 6.9 5.8 7.0 7.2 11.6 10.2 9.5 7.3 5.8 5.4 5.8 Brazil 7.1 5.3 3.6 3.7 3.8 3.3 4.3 4.8 5.8 5.3 5.5 Chile 18.5 17.0 13.1 11.9 10.2 7.2 6.5 7.3 4.9 4.0 6.2 Colombia 13.4 14.1 13.0 11.8 11.2 9.9 10.2 10.2 10.2 8.7 9.3 Costa Rica 6.6 6.7 6.7 5.9 6.3 3.7 5.4 6.0 4.3 4.0 Ecuador 10.5 10.4 10.7 7.2 7.4 7.9 6.1 8.5 8.9 8.9 8.1 Guatemala 9.1 12.0 14.0 11.4 8.8 6.2 6.4 6.7 6.1 5.5 Honduras 10.7 11.7 12.1 11.4 8.7 7.2 7.8 7.4 6.0 5.9 Mexico 5.7 4.4 4.3 3.9 3.5 2.9 2.9 2.7 2.8 3.4 3.7 Panama 12.4 15.7 12.7 14.1 21.1 20.4 20.0 16.1 14.2 12.5 12.0 Paraguay 7.3 5.1 6.1 5.5 4.7 6.1 6.6 5.1 5.3 5.1 5.1 Peru 8.9 10.1 5.4 4.8 7.9 7.9 8.3 5.9 9.4 9.9 9.5 Uruguay 14.0 13.1 10.7 9.3 9.1 8.6 9.3 8.9 9.0 8.4 9.0 Venezuela 14.3 14.3 12.1 9.9 7.9 9.7 10.5 10.1 8.0 6.6 8.9 .. Not available. a. Preliminary. Source: CEPAL, Economic Survey of Latin America, various issues. The resumption of growth in Latin America has generally The challenge ofpoverty alleviation brought a recovery in real wages, although in Argentina, Peru, Access to basic education, rural and urban infrastructure, and and Uruguay real wages in 1993 were still below their 1980 lev- public goods affects the capacity of households and individu- els (Table 5). In some countries higher levels of schooling have als to perform in the market economy. Thus the government's contributed to higher wages. In Argentina, Brazil, Chile, and role in opening up market opportunities for all citizens is Mexico market-oriented reforms and trade liberalization have increasingly important. It is also essential that the social pro- been accompanied by increases in the relative wages of workers grams that accompany market-oriented reforms be designed to with more schooling. Data for Colombia and Costa Rica sug- spread economic opportunities, especially among the poor gest that other factors also play a role in boosting real wages. (Box 1). I I * I --IS-. Table 5. Average real wages in selected Latin American countries, 1984-94 (1980=100) Country 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1931 1992 1993 1994a Argentina 116.9 106.1 107.5 96.9 93.7 75.8 79.4 80.5 81.6 80.3 85.7 Brazil Rio de Janeiro .. .. 122.9 101.5 105.7 108.2 87.0 92.2 115.3 119.5 109.2 Sao Paulo 105.1 111.8 137.3 127.7 138.3 149.1 130.8 125.4 138.1 151.9 162.7 Chile 97.2 93.5 95.1 94.7 101.0 103.0 104.8 110.1 115.1 118.6 124.6 Colombia 118.1 114.6 120.1 119.2 117.7 119.5 116.0 115.3 117.3 122.8 122.2 Costa Rica 84.7 92.2 98.0 88.5 84.5 85.1 86.5 82.5 85.9 94.7 Mexico 74.8 75.9 73.2 72.0 71.3 77.8 79.4 84.7 92.9 100.2 Peru 87.2 77.6 101.1 108.9 82.1 44.8 39.1 42.1 41.6 41.3 47.4 Uruguay 72.2 67.3 71.7 75.0 76.0 75.8 70.4 73.0 74.6 78.2 79.2 .. Not available. a. Preliminary Source: CEPAL, Economic Survey of Latin America, various issues. 8 L AS rs o R M A R K E-T C O NI D I T I ON S 5 Box 1. Reaching out to the poor An important survival strategy for poor families is to increase the number of household members working to support the Poverty is high among indigenous groups group, including children. Child labor remains prevalent in Latin America despite legal restrictions. In Brazil, for exatnple, it is estimated that about 18 percent of children between the Box Table 1. Poverty among indigenous and ages of ten and fourteen work The incidence of child labor is nonindigenous groups high among low-income families and among poor female- (percentage below poverty line) headed households. But it is also high where the demand for coutsy I _mhn; Nonindigaious child labor is high and the quality and availability of school- ing are low. Enforcement of labor regulations may eliminate Bolivia 64.3 48.1 1. 1 l 1 . s . . r ~~Guatemala 86.6 53.9 child labor, but it also may worsen the situation of some poor Mexico 80.6 17.9 farnilies. Reaching our to the poor to increase their opportu- Peru 79.0 49.7 nities in the market economy requires a comprehensive approach that takes into consideration the interaction between labor market conditions, schooling availability, child formal schooling and health care. Projects to ease the isola- labor, and poverty. tion and deprivation of indigenous people can benefit from Poverty also manifests itself in street children-typically their participation in the design and implementation. teenagers-in many countries. Recent studies in Brazil Addressing these diverse social policy matters requires a found that street children differ from working children in multifaceted approach that combines legislation and specific several ways. They typically have broken off ties with their programs with the participation of nongovernmental orga- farnilies, particularly their fathers. They also tend to have nizations and other civic groups. Several countries in Latin behavioral problems, to have dropped out of school, and to America have begun to recognize the merits of targeting and be addicted to drugs. For years nongovernmental and reli- of decentralized programs. This approach recognizes the gious institutions have been reaching out to these children, advantage of funding private solutions to constantly chang- providing shelter, basic needs, and schooling. Preventive ing social problems. The effectiveness of the approach rests action is considered most effective in keeping children off on the division of responsibilities: while private organiza- the streets. tions focus on problem solving, the public sector pays atten- Poverty is pervasive and severe in Latin America's indige- tion to measurable results and cost-effectiveness. nous population (see Box Table 1). Poor indigenous groups tend to be concentrated in rural areas, isolated by bad roads Source. Psacharopoulos and Patrinos 1994; World Bank data; and lack of communications, and to have limited access to Vial and Valde 1994. A number of countries in the region are moving in this direc- obligations, and so on) for all workers. Such burdensome require- tion. A renewed interest in increasing enrollments, especially at ments discourage formal labor contracts, leaving informal work- the primary level, explains recent reforms from Argentina to ers with no legal protection. The requirements also constrain Nicaragua. Correcting problems in land markets is part of the pol- formal employment creation and have negative effects on the use icy agenda in Colombia, Ecuador, and Peru and was central to of labor. As the dynamic theory of labor demand emphasizes. hir- agriculture's recovery in Chile in the 1 980s. Yet in most countries ing and firing decisions have three distinct characteristics: they the formal labor market still is not open to active participation entail sunk costs, they take place in an uncertain environment, and negotiated wages, working conditions, and collective con- and they need to allow for some flexibility in timing tracts. For example, hourly contracts are not permitted under (Hamermesh 1993). Onerous job security regulations and an Ecuadorian legislation, leaving a large number of workers in the unpredictable system of worker representation and dispute reso- informal sector. lution add uncertainty to estimates of labor costs. This uncer- tainty has a direct negative impact on employment levels, as well The link between labor policy and labor demand as on the speed of adjustment (Dertouzos and Karoly 1992). Current labor legislation in many countries determines not only Reforms should aim at establishing basic rights, reducing distor- basic legal rights, but also detailed conditions of the labor con- tions and uncertainty, and enhancing the incentives for private tract (wages, job security, number of vacation days. employer employers to create formal sector jobs. 9 A I Policy Reforms and International Integration I nternational trade offers opportunities for efficient special- country takes will depend on its initial endowments and strate- ization but also brings new risks. How can the region avoid gic choices. As real wages rise, all countries see a shift from agri- the exchange rate volatility of the past? The answer lies in culture and primary production to manufacturing and strengthening the domestic economy and expanding the role and services-first labor-intensive goods and then increasingly skill- efficiency of factor markets. intensive products. But countries that are richer in natural The debt crisis made countries in Latin America and the resources will remain net exporters of primary products longer: Caribbean review their economic policies and consider more they will have to attain higher levels of skills and of capital per seriously the advantages of an export orientation. But it took worker before they start to specialize in manufactures. Many some time for policy reforms to be implemented. On the exter- countries in Latin America will likely follow such a path. The nal front terms of trade deteriorated and economic activity in experience of more industrialized countries shows that even industrial countries slowed in the late 1980s. But Latin American where natural resources are abundant, production patterns and Caribbean countries were able to borrow at low real interest change, particularly in the use of labor. This is mainly a reflection rates, and growth returned to the region in the 1990s. The com- of the required balance between rising real wages and rising labor bination of easy finance and tough competition in international productivity. As the newly industrialized economies of East Asia goods markets represented a danger for some countries. For example, in countries other than Brazil output grew by more than 15 percent during 1990-94; as a result, investment and con- sumption grew sharply and net exports deteriorated in relative _ terms. Current account deficits grew despite export expansion in most countries because imports increased even more. Exports Figure 6. Real wages and exports in developing and growth have not always been positively correlated. In countries, 1975-93 Argentina and Paraguay export volumes fell despite substantial Average growth in economic growth. In Brazil and much of the Caribbean eco- manufacturing real wages nomic growth has been substantially slower than export growth. 0.12 - International trade brings immediate gains through cheaper 0.10 i imports and long-term gains as resources are used more effi- 0.08 ciently. Workers can take advantage of better job opportunities as the economy grows. In fact, during the past two decades real 0.06 wages rose at an average annual rate of 3 percent in developing counrries where the growth of trade (exports as a share of GNP) 0.04 was above average, but stagnated in countries where trade 0.02 expanded least (Figure 6). This correlation does not necessarily mean that increased exports are a sufficient condition for faster 0 - - - ------ economic growth, but it does suggest that they are part of the o002 story. Trade brings mutual gains to all countries, but it can also have important distributional effects within national boundaries, -0.04- benefiting workers whose products are more in demand and _0.06 _ * . i hurting others who lose out to new competitors. -0.08 -0.06 -0.04 0.02 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 Countries pursuing an export-led growth strategy will be Average growth in export-GNP ratio induced to specialize in differenr ways. The growth path that each Source: World Bank estimates. 10 r- L I C Y r2 r EF O R M5 AN .4D IN C T1 " r r N A T I ON 1A L I N Trs EG R A TIO 1N show, countries that are able to expand domestic capacity by investing in human and physical capital are better prepared to Tariffs are falling in the region adopt new technologies when market conditions are appropriate. Trade reform Table 6. The opening of Latin America, selected Trade reform ~~~~~~~~countries and years, 198 5-92 Tariff reduction has proceeded rapidly in many Latin American c t) and Caribbean countries, but it is still at a relatively early stage for (percent) most of the countries (Table 6). It is therefore premature to assess Average tariff Average coverage the impact of reforms on growth or labor demand. Still, some con- pocn of 1985r7 1991-92 clusions can be reached. If we group countries according to the - -9 classification in Table 6 and estimate average labor productivity Early reformers Bolivia 20.0 8.0 25.0 0.0 growth, we find that the early reformers outperformed all other Chile 36.0 11.0 10.1 0.0 groups in the 1 980s and early 1 990s (Table 7). We also note that Recent reformers average productivity growth among recent reformers has been Costa Rica 92.0 16.0 0.8 0.0 negaeThis result is driven by Mexico, where a elabor pro- Mexico 34.0 4.0 12.7 20.0 negative, Thls result Is drlven by Mexlc where average labor pro- Uruguay 32.0 12.0 14.1 0.0 ductivity fell atan annual rateof 1.6 percent in the 1980sand con- Very recent reformers tinued to fall at an annual rate of 0.75 percent in the early 1990s. Argentina 28.0 15.0 31.9 8.0 Brazil 80.0 21.1 35.3 10.0 Greater exposure to international markets brings new oppor- Cm I bia 830 6 3.3 1.0 tunities for private investors and major changes in the way busi- Ecuador 58.0 .180 59.3 .0 ness is conducted. Attention to timing, quality, and reliability Guatemala 50.0 19.0 7.4 6.0 becomes critical. The exposure to more competition and to inter- Nicaragua 54.0 27.8 Paraguay 71.7 16.0 9.9 0.0 national trade is helping to improve labor-management relations. Peru 64.0 15.0 53.4 0.0 It is now clear that there is no fixed amount of "rents" to fight for Venezuela 30.0 17.0 44.1 5.0 and that workers and employers are better off working together Not available for a more successful enterprise. But industrial relations are very a. Average total charges (tariffs plus paratariffs), unweighted. much influenced by the methods of the past and by a legal frame- b. Unweighted. work that discourages cooperation between managers and work- Source: World bank data; Erzan and others 1989. ers. Such legislation requires reform. The real exchange rate and capital inflows Early reformers outperform others After the major effort associated with tariff reductions and the difficulties brought about by large devaluations in the early stages ThbIe 7 Annual rate of growth in labor produ y y of reform, a number of countries have allowed their real exchange group, 1965-94 rate to appreciate substantially. Changes in domestic policy and (percent) international market conditions have brought large flows of cap- Country group 1965-80 1980-90 1990 94 ital into the region in the 1990s. But the real exchange rate appre- C ciation has hurt exports and employment creation. Early reformers 1.38 -0.12 4.12 Real exchange rates in most countries have appreciated by 10 Recent reformers 2.72 -1.55 -0.51 Very recent reformers 3.41 -1.20 0.71 to 30 percent since 1990. There is a strong correlation between Nonreformers 2.49 -1.37 0.01 currency appreciation, capital inflows, and current account Total 3.09 -1.24 0.56 deficits. Adjusted for inflation, capital flows to the region were Note: Weighted averages based on population in 1995. larger in 1992 and 1993 than they had been at their peak dur- Source: World Bank data and estimates. ing the 1970s. The surge was also much more abrupt. Evidence from ten countries indicates that external factors played an and Reinhart (1993) found remarkable similarities in the rela- important role in the recent episode, which means that capital tive size of capital inflows between ten Latin American countries inflows are less likely to persist. (Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela) and eight Asian economies Using capita/flows most effectively (Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines. the Republic of Korea, Latin America has not been the only region to receive sizable Singapore, Sri Lanka, Taiwan (China), and Thailand). Capital capital inflows in recent years. A study by Calvo, Leiderman. account inflows amount to 3.3 percent of GDP in the Latin 11 L A ES O R AN N D E 3C DN M I C R E F U R- M American countries and 2.7 percent of GDP in the Asian advantageofchangesinmarketconditionsbyswitchingemploy- countries. Across countries and regions there is a marked menr, selling and buying assets, and starting new activities. increase in international reserves. In the early stages of the cap- Economic adjustment can also go faster if firms make decisions ital inflows there were sharp increases in stock prices, and in both about location, activity, and use of factors that respond to the regions capital inflows have been accompanied by accelerated economy's comparative advantages. An efficient response by agri- economic growth. culture to the new opportunities brought about by trade reforms What distinguished the Latin American countries from Asia rests on a functioning land market (Box 2). In countries such as was the degree of appreciation in the real exchange rate and the El Salvador and Nicaragua revolution and war have generated savings response to the capital inflows. While the Asian countries disputes over property rights, and governments are only begin- increased their savings ratio by 3 percentage points, the Latin ning to address the problem. Land markets in Latin American American countries, on average, reduced it. Yet the causal rela- and Caribbean countries are notoriously repressed and often dis- tion between domestic consumption and the real exchange rate torted. In some cases a substantial amount of land is held in large, is not clear. The Asian countries were more aggressive in steriliz- capital-intensive farms that employ very little labor, but that gain ing capital inflows to limit monetary growth. Asian countries also from credit and other subsidies. Half-hearred land reforms that received a larger share of capital inflows in the form of foreign sought or threatened to give land rights to tenants only sharp- direct investment, which makes sterilization less important since ened landowners' bias toward labor-saving production practices. there is less volatility associated with those flows. The optimal In Colombia, for example, potential crop land is used for ranch- policy response to capital inflows depends on their anticipated ing because policy biases favor large farms. persistence and the nature of domestic credit markets. If capital inflows are easily reversible, the conservative approach is to ster- Broadly based reforns: The key to success ilize 100 percent of the inflows. That is what Indonesia did to Successful reformers such as Chile and New Zealand have maintain macroeconomic stability during the oil boom. The aim demonstrated that the best response to the opportunities offered is to avoid a situation where real exchange rate appreciation hurts by trade liberalization is a broadly based approach. In Chile the export sector and leads to unsustainable current account reforms introduced in the mid-1970s have focused on enhanc- deficits, or where a sudden reversal of capital inflows leads to a ing the role of the private sector in a market-based approach to domestic financial crisis. economic development. Policymakers' short-term prioriry was to reestablish macroeconomic stability, whicih required reducing a Labor market effects substantial public deficit. The long-term goal was to reestablish Real exchange rate appreciations represent an increase in real the economy's growth potential, which required eliminating wages relative to tradable goods-an increase that can be sus- gross distortions in the allocation of resources. The first stage of tained only if real incomes are rising. Policymakers are often policy reforms included freeing retail prices, lifting interest rate tempted to ride on the popularity of a real exchange rate appre- controls, regularizing public sector accounts, introducing better ciation, especially when they believe that they can take correc- tax monitoring systems, establishing financial discipline, priva- rive action later. But real exchange rate appreciations also reduce tizing state-owned enterprises, and reducing import barriers. the international competitiveness of exports. Where the exports The second phase of reforms redefined the role of the state sector is small, policymakers may avoid hearing these com- and its interaction wich the private sector. The "seven modern- plaints. Yet evidence shows that the cycles generated by real izations" included labor law, social security law, educarion, health exchange rate instability create enormous dislocations in the services, land and water rights, judicial reform, and administra- economy, particularly in the labor market. These cycles are par- tive reform. The result was a modern regulatory framework that ticularly dangerous in countries that are emerging from years of guarantees free entry and property rights and that expands the failed policies. Mexico's recent experience with capital outflows realm of possible transactions. For example, land could be rented, indicates that there are important lessons to be learned with leased, divided, bought, and sold, increasing opportunities for respect to monetary management. landowners and the value of land. In the social sectors careful tar- But much more is going on as well. There are still major prob- geting and decentralization constituted an extraondinarily com- lems with the operation of land and water markers, with labor plex institutional, administrative, and political task. Programs management techniques, and with a tax system that continues to were restructured, complex legal issues were addressed, and subsidize certain sectors. To avoid large swings in the real opposition from those who had benefited from previous systen exchange rate, the domestic economy must be strengthened, subsidies had to be overcome. especially through better functioning of factor markets. In the early 1980s the Chilean economy suffered a major Economic adjustment can occur faster if individuals can take setback. In circumstances remarkably similar to the Mexican 12 P O L I C Y R E F O R M S AN " D I N TE E- R N A T I ON 1 A L I N TEr B R A T I O 13N Box 2. Making the land market work: Reforms In Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, and Peru Limited rights over land, including the virtual abolition of of land sales, defining water rights, and limiting the expro- tenancy, explain to a large degree the lack of land improve- priation of private land. A drive for the proper registration ments and the low demand for agricultural labor in many of land, combined with a reduction in agricultural subsi- Latin American countries. Recent efforts to reverse these con- dies that now favor large farmers, would have beneficial straints have met with tremendous opposition and require a effects for the poor. good dose of political will. Under the 1969 Agrarian Reform, 85 percent of Peru's pri- In Colombia a series of legalmeasures since the 1930s has vately held rural land was converted into cooperatives. had the effect of reducing incentives for large landowners to Although former workers got the mandate to administer the lease land to tenants. The right of landowners to employ land themselves, they could not use it as collateral, rent it, sharecroppers was formally outlawed in 1968. A steep fall in transfer it, or sell it. These reforms inhibited investment, and rural employment-3.9 percent a year-occurred between agricultural production stagnated during the 1970s. While a 1970 and 1975. Throughout the 1 970s there was a wave of 1980 law broke up most of the cooperatives into individual illegal occupations of farms, affecting 1,500 to 2,000 famns landholdings, it was only in 1991 that restrictions on sale and and roughly two-thirds of Colombia's departments. This rental were removed and land could be used as collateral. avenue for land acquisition was closed in 1988, and the poor Peru also has implemented a new law that greatly facili- began to occupy steep hills or marginal land at the edge of the tates the registration of rural property that was held in coop- rain forest. The limited opportunities for the poor to farm amr eratives, and of urban land that had been "invaded" in undermining the sustainabiity of farming for all and have previous years. Peru has made notable efforts in recent years incited rural violence. to reestablish property rights and markets, but the process has Colombia passed a new reform law in 1994 that is been mired in politics, in particular the opposition of those designed to increase the role of the market in transferring who benefited from the rents generated under the old law land to the rural poor. Eligible applicants will receive a sub- governing registration. sidy of 70 percent toward the purchase of a plot of land suf- In 1915 the government of Mexico gave 80 percent of its ficient to support a farm family; credit would be provided agricultural land to 25 Mexico No - 1 month 3W (20 days' wages)T restrictions Nicaragua 2 years, 12 months 1-2 months WT 2(WT) nonrenewable Peru 2 years, 3 months - Fund Fund + WTI nonrenewable Venezuela renewable 3 months 1-3 months T(10 to 30 days' 2(10 to 30 days' wages)T once wages) Note: W represents a monthly wage. T represents years of tenure on the job. a. The legislation generally lists a number of reasons that make a dismissal 'justified." These include serious misconduct (absenteeism, drunkenness) but do not include technical requirements or economic factors. b. The law establishes a maximum W. c. A minimum severance payment equivalent to 45 days' wages is payable in case of dismissal. d. The law establishes a maximum T. e. The burden of proof is on the employer. Failure to prove allegations of just cause may increase the penalty by up to 50 percent over the normal severance (WT). percent in Peru) to be made available in case of separation ("jus- America and the Caribbean were changed to defined contribu- tified" layoffs and quits). In Chile workers can choose this type tion funds, accessible in case of quits or layoffs, their economic of arrangement rather than the traditional severance payment effect would be virtually the same as that of the U.S. system. after seven years on the job. Employers are required to deposit one month's salary in a savings account in the employee's name. Contributions to social security A reformed system of severance payments provides insurance In most Latin American countries employers are required to con- for laid-off workers. A national unemployment insurance tribute to the social security system, which generally provides scheme-for formal sector workers-would do the same. The workers with pensions, health care, and accident insurance. Such systems are of equal merit so long as each is financed by the programs were very attractive in their early years, but as programs potential beneficiaries. This is generally done through payroll have aged some benefits have been rationed or eliminated. Until taxes on formal sector workers. In the United States "experience recently all formal sector business firms were required to con- ratings" create a direct link between employers' contributions tribute to the social security system, forcing users to rely on the and the probability of unemployment. The practical implication public system. is that the unemployment insurance tax rate goes up for employ- In terms of economic cost and equity, most social security ers whose unemployment insurance reserve has been used up by systems in the region have problems. First, most pension funds their former employees. If severance payment systems in Latin encourage early retirement, generating a serious economic burden 18 t u R r E N T L. A, c o R M A, R K E T I N T ER R V E N T I 0N N S if retirees are still in their most productive years. Second, pension required by law. About two-thirds of the countries that have these benefits are often unrelated to individual contributions to the sys- systems operate them through a central public fund. Among the tem. Higher-income individuals, in particular, often benefit out countries that rely on private arrangements, about twenty- of all proportion to their contributions. Third, social security sys- including the United States-require employers to insure their tems tend to encourage expensive health care services that empha- employees against the risk of injury on the job. In about half of size curative rather than preventive care. In most countries these, only private insurance is available. In the rest, a public fund contributions to the health component of the social security sys- exists, but employers are allowed to opt out of the public system. tem are independent of marital status, family size, and age. The premiums charged by private or mutual insurance com- Benefits, however, automatically extend to dependents. As the age panies for work-injury protection vary according to the history structure of the population has changed, the economically active of accidents in different industries. Some countries (notably population has become less willing to support these systems-as Norway and Sweden) have eliminated the risk factor, and all in Peru. Finally, the poor segments of society are often excluded employers contribute to the program at the same rate. In most from social security. In Brazil, for example, only 18 percent of the Latin American and Caribbean countries safety standards are poorest income groups-which account for more than 40 per- often the responsibility of the ministry of labor. Risk premiums cent of the population-are covered by social security. are set by industry. Whether levies such as social security contributions are per- An alternative arrangement could provide benefits-in the ceived as pure taxes or as delayed compensation depends on the form of lower insurance premiums-to employers who comply link between individual contributions and expected future ben- with safety regulations. In most countries in the region these pre- efits. In most Latin American countries social security benefits- miums are determined by sector, meaning that, for example, all pensions and health care provision-are unrelated to individual construction companies pay the same amount for workers' acci- contributions to the system. Mesa-Lago (1991) and Cox dent insurance. Reforms can expand the role of specialized insur- Edwards (1993) argue that this lack of balance causes people to ers in the provision of such insurance. In Chile, for example, such view contributions as a pure tax and benefits as entitlement (Box specialized agencies are more knowledgeable about safe practices 6). Furthermore, the social securiry systems in many of these and set insurance premiums according to safety standards. countries are financially insolvent, imposing increasing costs on the economy as a whole. Labor-management relations In addition to solvency problems, pay-as-you-go social secu- Most labor legislation in Latin America predates the region's rity systems distort labor markets because of the heavy burden of recent market-oriented reforms and suffers from two deficien- payroll taxes on formal sector firms. Basic pension benefits are cies. First, most workers are not able to choose their representa- extended to all retirees, while only a fraction of active labor force tion in labor disputes, since the right to representation is assigned participants contribute to the social security system. Uruguay's to official unions by the government. This has stunted the devel- system dependency rate (the ratio of pensioners to contributors) opment of labor organizations, which need to adjust to a more stands at 53 percent and its benefit ratio (average benefit over demanding labor market. Second, collective bargaining is too cut average wage) at 84 percent, while Brazil's ratio of retirees to off from market forces. Except for Chile, where labor reform was active labor force participants has risen from 10.4 percent in implemented in the early 1980s, the process is similar across the 1965 to 16.1 percent in 1995. Thus social security reform is region. Unions proposeacollectivecontract, andemployers must urgent in such countries as Brazil and Uruguay. Almost all coun- respond. The state is a part of the negotiations from the start, and tries in the region would benefit from pension system reform the final agreement applies to all workers represented. while their systems are still solvent. The case of autoworkers negotiating with General Motors in There are several reforms that could improve the efficiency of Brazil in April 1995 is representative. When negotiations social security systems. Pay-as-you-go schemes with no link between management and the union broke down, the case was between contributions and benefits should be replaced by a com- mediated by a labor court, which had to make a judgment and bination of individual accounts and minimum benefits ensured recommend a pay increase. This is a case of "interest" arbitration, by the government (World Bank 1994). This type of system has whereby the arbitrator determines the terms and conditions of a been used in Chile since the early 1980s and is being imple- new collective agreement. Court rulings are bound by labor mented in Argentina, Colombia, Mexico, and Peru. statutes and, often, by constitutional rights over aspects of the Programs that provide compensation for work-related labor contract. injuries and occupational illnesses have a long tradition. The two Strikes traditionally have been allowed as an expression of basic types of systems are social insurance systems that use a cen- political pressure-albeit with an economic impact on individual tral public fund and various private arrangements that are firms. In theory each party should have something to lose dur- 19 L.AS CO R AN D E C ON O 0 M I C R Ea FO R M S Box 6.' 1Payroll taxes and their Impact on workers Taxes on labor distort the: allocation of resources beause hey payroll taxes4are paid over a lifeBime ofwork Pension levels. are reduce h vaiilue of working time relatve to leisure, iincrease based on ihe contibutions made in the five years before retire- : :the t: f: la co : o pr6dii: Th :. ES onie the cost of labor and increased the cost of production.They. ment. Workers do not conside their monthly contributions also have distributional effects since paYll taxes and revenue to the social securit system as tipart of their compensation. benefits are likely to fall unevenly on different income groups. Relative to a no-tax situaton s tax raises the cost of labor Payioll taxes are tpicallyt high in industrial countnes, partic- Wit employers and reduces take-home pay for workers. ularly European countries, ranging fromn 20 to 50 percent of . *. i gross wages (Box Figure 2). But they are also hh int some _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ developing countries, notably in Latin America, where they are as high as 40 percent4of gross wages. Such taxes reduce the net wage that firms pay to workers by the fill amount of the: tax less the value employees attach to the benefits provided. B Figur 2 Payroll ta s a p n of n; 1g : : 1 1 17 r F D~.. Box Figure 2.:Pa 11 taxes As a percentage of Payroll taxes are generally earmarked to finance programs that benefit workers. The most common use of payroll taxes gross wages is thef fhunding of pensions, followed by health care programs o .1o 20 30o 40 SO eo (generally limited to workers or targeted to the poor, but in some cases extended to the entire population). Third in ca importance is the funding of workers compensation for work- related accidents. In some countries payroll taxes also fund .. ..l.m ... unemployment insurance pograms. In a number of countries ispan _ in Latin Amerca and the Caribbean payroll taxes fund train- New Zealand ing institutes. n Payroll taxes are often justified on the grounds that work- United States ers would not otherwise save for retirement or health insur- Arpntna ance and that employers would not insure againstfthe risk of work accidents or provide training programs. These man- Coio dates typically have three components. a forced savings Mee component, ian insurance premnium component and a distri- butional component. Venenla The most enforceablesystemscombine insurance policies F l with mandatorysavingsprograms toprovide abasicsetof ben- enya efits. Overly ambitious programs that requite high contiibu- Mmocc: tions are likely to distort the labor market and reduce formal Snge - employment. For example, in pay-as-you-go pension systems Sr tank:a ing the bargaining process; in this way delays in reaching agree- organization (including the right to join the union of their choice ments will be costly to both parties, encouraging a speedy and or not to join a union). Many countries' regulations also support efficient resolution of the conflict. In most Latin American cases, collective bargaining in the private and public sectors. however, the costs to employees of striking are low compared Decentralized bargaining obliges employers to bargain with with those incurred by employers (Table 9). plant-level unions but does not preclude them from bargaining at a more centralized level, such as with industry-level unions. Unions Competitive product markets limit the ability of unions to Howcanpolicymakerscreateanenvironmenttharminimizesthe obtain higher wages for their members. Raising wages would negative effects of trade unions while encouraging them to con- force unionized firms out of business unless the higher wages tributetoeconomicgrowthandequity?Experienceindicatesthat were justified by increased productivity. A survey of twenty such an environment usually includes competitive product mar- industrial firms in Brazil found that increased competition in kets and regulatory and institutional frameworks that are the output market, the result of trade liberalization, caused those designed to protect workers' rights to freedom of association and firms to introduce productivity-enhancing techniques and 20 C U R rr-- N JT L A S R o F M AR FK K E T INTER r_ E - v r- N T IO r N S Strikes are generally less costly to Latin American workers than to employers Table 9. Dispute resolution legislation in ten Latin American countries Employee rights To renounce Employer rights To wages union member- Judicial while ship and return To lock out To temporarily Maximum duration Country procedure To strike on strike to work employees replace workers of a strike Argentina Civil courts Must be called by union No, if workers fail No No, unless the No No maximum after conciliation channels to accept arbitration. strike is illegal. are exhausted. Ministry of Yes, if the employer Labor determines legality. locks out workers. Bolivia Labor courts After arbitration has No. Strike Yes Yes No No maximum. failed (requires 24 suspends labor Despite the law. many days after presentation contracts. strikes start before of petition to labor the Tribunal decision. inspector). A majority of the union or two-thirds of workers must agree. Brazil Labor courts In the context of No Yes. Strke does Requires prior No. unless the No maximum collective bargaining. not suspend labor authorization. strike is declared Quorum requirement contracts. "abusive' by decided by head-count the labor court. vote of union members. Chile Labor courts have In the context of No Yes Yes, if the strike Yes, from the first The strike ends if jurisdiction over collective bargaining. affects more than day of the strike if more than half of the questions half of workers the last offer is workers have returned of application or interrupts equivalent to the to work. of the law. essential work. previous contract adjusted for consumer price index. Only after 15 days otherwise. Colombia Labor courts. After direct negotiations. No. Strike No No, unless there is 60 days Ministry of Labor Must be agreed by suspends labor a risk of serious may call for absolute majority of contracts. damage to the arbitration within workers in a secret facilities. two days of a ballot. declared strike. Ecuador Labor Inspectorate After direct negotiations. Yes No No No The strike ends when Must be agreed by the tribunal has absolute majority of resolved it workers. 'Solidarity' strikes permitted. Mexico Labor courts Tripartite board No, unless the board No No No maximum must declare it legal. decides the strike is 'imputable' to the employer. Nicaragua Civil courts If agreed by head count Yes Workers can go Yes. after No No maximum majority. Does not have back to work. but conciliation to occur in the context wages are paid if authorized of collective bargaining. in any case. by Labor Inspectorate. Peru Ministry of Labor If the majority No. Strike Yes No Yes No maximum approves. Few limitations. suspends labor contracts. Venezuela Labor Inspectorate After direct negotiations. No. Strike No Yes Yes No maximum Must be agreed by suspends absolute majority of labor contracts. workers. "Solidarity' strikes permitted. Source: Dertouzos and Karoly 1992; Cox Edwards 1993. 21 L A r 3 0OR AN 1 D r co N D3 M I C R a F O R M S processes. Labor, keen to ensure continued competitiveness, did lation requires that workers be paid even when they are on not insist on past privileges but cooperated with management strike-a clear disincentive to compromise. Moreover, many in this process. governments refrain from providing loans or deferring tax In less competitive environments unions attempt to capture payments for firms during strikes or lockouts, and firms are economic rents and ally themselves with employers and politi- not allowed to hire temporary workers. Negotiations between cians who help to perpetuate those rents. This kind of behavior unions and public enterprises show how unions are able to by unions is evident in industrial countries, where union wage achieve distorted outcomes when third parties bear the cost premiums are highest in regulated sectors and concentrated of negotiated agreements. When a public enterprise can turn industries. In developing economies union opposition to trade to the government for subsidies or easy credit when it is in liberalization and privatization is a rational strategy for main- financial difficulty, the burden of high settlements falls on taining higher wages for unionized workers in the short run at those who pay higher prices or higher taxes to cover the enter- the expense of nonunion workers. If the state imposes regulations prise's increased costs, not on the workers or enterprise man- on minimum wages and restrictions on hiring and firing, the agers who negotiated the increase. nonunion sector will operate much less effectively as a constraint Legislating limits on the number of unions per enterprise is on unions' wage demands. Promoting domestic competition and viewed as an infringement of workers' rights. When workers openness to international markets will therefore help to curtail have the right to choose their own union, unions act as a gen- these negative effects. uine representative of the worker in collective negotiations. Furthermore, if the union is contestable (that is, if a new union Labor regulations and the system of industrial relations can be set up at any time), unions will be compelled to bargain Union behavior is conditioned by the structure of union orga- with employers to improve working conditions. Union frag- nization and the coverage of collective agreements. A key mentation and rivalry can be disruptive, however, and bargain- principle in industrial relations is to ensure that the parties ing costs rise if workers have many representatives. These issues engaged in bargaining absorb the costs of their actions rather are often dealt with through cooperation between unions and than shift them to third parties. But in some countries legis- employers. 22 CHAPTER 5 The Changing Role of the State L atin American and Caribbean countries have not yet Successful reform requires finding ways to isolate agencies addressed the problem of poorly performing bureau- from political forces. Their mandate has to be clear and their per- cracies. Efforts at decentralization often have devolved formance measurable. Naim (1995) observes that many coun- responsibilities without granting the authority to raise revenue or tries have been successful in isolating key public agencies from control hiring and wages. The problem of public services and political maneuvering, making them an island of efficient man- employee performance goes beyond organizational changes, agement and attention to results. These include national oil com- downsizing, and better reward systems. Government agencies panies such as Petroleos de Venezuela, Colombia's National must learn to see a direct connection between their revenues and Coffee Company, Chile's state-owned copper company, and their responsibilities. some Central American agencies that oversee banana exports. There are many ways to achieve this goal. All combine some Much can be accomplished by granting more autonomy to level of greater autonomy for agencies with clearly defined tasks, public agencies. But this approach cannot be generalized to the centrally established budgetary allocations, and a defined policy entire public sector. The previous section discussed the person- on raising additional revenue. More autonomy would allow nel management restrictions that are embodied in collective con- agencies (or local governments) to pursue the most efficient ways tracts throughout the region. In addition to these, there are often of providing public goods and services. This will mimic the oper- special labor statutes for workers in the social sectors (education, ation of private institutions, where goods and services are pur- health, and so on). As the experience of the 1980s showed, even chased or contracted out unless there is a comparative advantage the most protective legislation cannot shelter workers from reces- to producing them in-house. In addition, measurable goals and sions or budgetary cuts. The experience also showed workers that incentives that reward workers and management are precondi- they may be better off in a system that rewards them for being tions for good public sector performance. productive. In short, achieving more effective delivery of public services requires a pragmatic approach that recognizes the impor- Public sector employment and wages tance of local management, understands the incentives each In delivering public services central governments have no choice agency faces, and finds ways to correct incentives so that social but to rely on the administrative capacity of local managers. These objectives are consistent with those of the local agency. New managers need to be given autonomy in hiring, promoting, train- Zealand's recent experience with reforms in public sector man- ing, and firing employees. But in most cases they are not. More agement offers an interesting benchmark with which to compare often, job positions are predetermined, salaries are paid directly practices in other countries. by the central government, and promotion criteria are established by statute. This makes personnel management decisions some- Setting priorities and choosing better policy instruments what irrelevant to local operations. Breaking these molds requires Social expenditures are always limited by budgetary constraints. more than legal changes to the statutes governing individual agen- Moreover, the most important consideration for any social cies. It also requires significant political will, because public sec- expenditure is how efficiently funds are allocated, measured by tor unions have the power to paralyze entire administrations. results in relation to starting goals. Latin American countries The principal problem posed by public sector unionism is maintain elaborate bureaucratic structures and complex legisla- that disputes tend to be costly because the markets involved are tion that govern the delivery of social services. These countries generally monopolistic. For this reason, it is natural to seek alter- should initiate efforts to rationalize their social service institu- natives to strikes and lockouts. Arbitration by third parties is the tions. Governments should limit themselves to policy design, obvious alternative, and the mechanism recommended is "final control, evaluation, supervision, and financing, leaving execu- offer" arbitration, which compels the arbitrator to choose either tion of the programs to decentralized agencies such as munici- management's final offer or the union's. palities, local governments, and private organizations. 23 L A B o R AN D E C ON N 0 M I C RE F OR M S In terms of financing, subsidies that respond to demand have period of import-substitution industrialization, and most con- several advantages over indirect, supply-side subsidies. Demand tinue to provide the same training they always have. subsidies are easier to target to the neediest groups and are more But countries have made drastic changes in their economic likely to attract cofinancing. This principle applies to all areas policies, there have been significant changes in technology, and where the public sector has been heavily involved in the financ- demand for trained personnel has become less predictable. ing and production of services. Two cases that are of particular Training institutions must adapt to be effective. Some have importance for this report are education and worker training. started to change. In some cases pressures from legal reforms have deprived them of traditional sources of funding (Bolivia, Funding education Colombia, and Costa Rica); in others, pressures came from Higher education has traditionally been subsidized on the sup- greater exposure to competition for public funding (Chile). ply side in Latin America. This choice benefits those who qual- Entrepreneurs have been asked to participate more closely in pro- ify for a university education, irrespective of their capacity to gram development, as in Brazil, or to take over the management pay. That reduces the resources available to the poorest segments of the system, as in Peru (de Moura Castro 1994). of society. There is little doubt that education has to improve in Labor requirements are changing rapidly, yet most institutes order to continue the export-oriented drive of the last few years. continue to offer traditional training in electricity or mechanics. Changing the way that public funding for higher education is Most of the system's students over the past decade have become allocated would help expand coverage. Most university gradu- independent contractors or joined the informal sector. Thus the ates acquire an earning capacity that would enable them to pay system's funding has become a tax on modern sector labor and a for their education. Extending access to public funding to new transfer to the informal sector. Chile eliminated this earmarked institutions would give the state more for its money as old and tax and uses broadly based income taxes to subsidize training. In new institutions compete for funding. Establishing scholarship the formal sectors firms receive a tax credit of up to 1 percent of and loan systems would improve access to university training payroll if they spend that amount on worker training. This train- while permitting cost recovery. Chile adopted this principle to ing can be organized on the job or through public and private change the formula for grant funding to universities. There has training institutions. since been significant growth in the higher education system's Some traditional training institutes are transforming them- coverage. selves into centers of technology transfer. Several schools have assumed this function and offer a range of courses for private Worker training entrepreneurs. Traditional training courses remain as part of the Public training institutions in Latin America and the Caribbean, broader curriculum. This trend is not only an important way of with the exception of Argentina and Mexico, are based on the spreading technological innovations; it is also a useful tool for Brazilian SENAls model of an autonomous public agency training institutes to anticipate enterprise needs. These addi- financed by payroll contributions of I to 2 percent and man- tional activities have expanded the sources of funding for these aged jointly by government, workers, and employer representa- institutes, increasing their autonomy and creating clear links tives. These institutions played an important role during the between revenues and responsibilities. 24 CHAPTER 6 The Outlook for Workers M any Latin American countries have initiated reforms ios are illustrative only-the projections are based on many that will produce important gains for workers in the assumptions and certainly are not a forecast. But they are a years to come. Among the more advanced reform- plausible guide to the consequences of success and failure, and ers, some (Chile, Colombia) are showing signs of sustained they take into account likely trends in both economywide progress for workers. effects and international integration. Opening the formal labor market requires: The divergence scenario assumes that recent investment * Replacing job security legislation with a system that protects trends will continue or that investment will deteriorate, that a workers as they change jobs. This does not necessarily require sizable share of those enrolled in schools will drop out prema- establishing new unemployment insurance programs; it can be turely, and that the overall productivity of labor will not rise accomplished by improving the system of severance payments rapidly. The convergence scenario assumes that investment in countries that lack the administrative capacity to run an rates will pick up, that enrollment rates will stabilize at current unemployment insurance scheme. levels and dropout rates will decline, and that investments in * Recontracting social security, lowering payroll taxes, and infrastructure, technological transfers, and improvements in making pensions a function of individual savings. This does the quality of governance will contribute to labor productivity. not mean that the state should break promises made to those The convergence scenario must be supported by higher savings who have contributed to the system or to those who depend rates, lower fiscal deficits in the industrial countries, and rea- on pensions. And reform is not inconsistent with the estab- sonable amounts of international capital flows, including devel- lishment of transfer programs for the elderly poor. But opment assistance. reform can encourage employees to save for their retirement. In the divergence scenario we assume that protectionism The initial conditions in each country will determine the will not go away, and that countries will either drag their feet level of entitlements that will remain as a liability of the pub- in implementing the Uruguay Round agreement or offset gains lic sector. in one area with protectionism of another sort. Here, export * Establishing freedom to choose labor representation and dis- growth will be slow and there will be little change in the inter- pute resolution mechanisms that enhance negotiations at the national division of labor. In the convergence scenario the plant level. Uruguay Round is fully implemented and there is further * Transferring education and training subsidies to the demand progress in trade liberalization-including in agriculture-at side. This change will create training institutes that are better regional and multilateral levels. Global integration will interact able to respond to rapidly changing labor requirements, par- with domestic investment in capital and people to bring large ticularly in countries that are integrating with the world econ- net gains. Latin America will capitalize on its improved skills omy. Many countries concentrate their investment in training mix in the expanding global market, will recover its strength in on secondary school graduates, so public support to training is mining and agriculture, and will move into the production of generally not pro-poor. Subsidies based on demand not only more technologically demanding goods (Table 10). can accommodate on-the-job training, they also can be tar- Both scenarios assume that the technological bias favoring geted to specific groups. skilled workers will continue. Under the divergence scenario Two global scenarios, developed for World Development this bias reinforces slow accumulation and stagnating world Report 1995, illustrate what is possible and the dangers ahead trade and results in slow GDP growth in most regions and ris- for each of the world's main regions. The first scenario, based ing inequality among and within regions, including in Latin largely on past trends, projects current policies over the long America and the Caribbean. By contrast, the convergence sce- term. This scenario, which suggests a widening of differences nario finds incomes rising and inequality falling. Rapid accu- between some regions and a widening of inequality within mulation of skills reduces the pool of unskilled workers and so some countries, is one of slow growth and divergence. A sec- increases the demand for their services. Furthermore, rural ond scenario of inclusion and convergence explores the poten- areas gain from external conditions and demand for unskilled tial of strong domestic policy action in all parts of the world labor in agriculture and services rises. These factors all con- combined with deeper international integration. Both scenar- tribute to a reduction in inequalitv. 25 L A, E3 o R Al N I' E- c o " o M I c R Er F O r M S The success of these efforts will depend on both domes- sector. Better understanding of the link between govern- tic policies and international conditions. Labor policy has ment policy and private sector development will improve generally been overlooked, and this is a mistake. The capac- the chances for sustained recovery in the region and for a ity of an economy to modernize, turn toward exports, adapt more effective war against poverty. Labor markets must be new technologies, improve service delivery, and so on rests liberalized in order to expand employment opportunities in on a better use of resources and a more efficient productive all sectors. Table 10. The outlook for Latin America and the Caribbean, 1994-2010 (percent, except where otherwise specified) Variable Actual Divergence scenario Convergence scenario Inputs in the growth process Investment share in GDP (1992) 20.0 22.0 25.0 Average years of schooling (1992) 4.9 5.6 6.1 Annual growth in TFP (1960-87) 0.0 0.6 1.6 Annual growth GDP per capita growth (1970-90) 1.7 1.4 3.3 Export growth (1980-90) 2.4 3.8 7.0 Total increase in wages Unskilled wages -3.0 58.0 Skilled wages 45.0 62.0 Source: World Bank 1995; Lewis, Robinson, and Wang 1995. 26 References Ahuja, V., and D. Filmer. 1995. "Educational Attainment in Heppel, M., J. Spano, and L. Torres. 1993. "The 1992 Apple Developing Countries: New Escimates and Projections Harvest in West Virginia." Report prepared for the West Disaggegated by Gender." Background paper for World Virginia Bureau of Employment Programs. The Inter- Development Report 1995. World Bank, Washington, D.C. American Institute on Migration and Labor, Washington, Banerji, A. 1995. "Workers in the Informal Sector in Developing D.C. Countries." Background paper for World Development Report ILO (International Labour Organization). 1988. Summaries of 1995. World Bank, Washington, D.C. InternationalLabor Standards. Washington, D.C. Calvo, G., L. Leiderman, and C. Reinhart. 1993. "The Capital . 1994. List of Ratifications by Convention and by Inflows Problem: Concepts and Issues." IMF Paper on Policy Country (as of December 1993). Geneva: International Analysis and Assessment. International Monetary Fund, Labour Office. Washington, D.C. Kaufman, D. 1991. "The Forgotten Rationale for Policy CEPAL (Economic Commission for Latin America and the Reform: The Productivity of Investment Projects." Caribbean). 1992. El Perfilde la Pobreza en Amei'ca Latina a Background paper for World Development Report 1995. Comienzos de los Afios 90. Santiago: United Nations. World Bank, Washington, D.C. LC/L.716. Krueger, A. 1983. Trade and Employment in Developing .EconomicSurvey ofLatinAmerica. Various issues. Countries, Vol. 3: Synthesis and Conclusions. Chicago: Commission on Agricultural Workers. 1992. Report of the University of Chicago Press. Commission on Agricultural Workers. Washington, D.C. Marcouiller, D., V. Ruiz de Castilla, and C. Woodruff 1995. Cortazar, R. 1994. "Labor Policy in Democratic Chile." Paper "Formal Measures of the Informal Sector Wage Gap in presented at the International Forum on Latin American Mexico, El Salvador, and Peru." Paper presented at the Latin Perspectives. Paris, November 2-4. Inter-American American and Caribbean Economic Association meetings. Development Bank and OECD Development Center. Washington. D.C., January 5. Cox Edwards, A. 1993. "Labor Market Legislation in Latin Mesa-Lago, C. 1991. Social Security and Prospects for Equit in America and the Caribbean." Latin America and the Latin America. World Bank Discussion Paper 140. Caribbean Technical Department Regional Studies Report Washington, D.C. 31. World Bank, Washington, D.C. Morley, S. 1992. "Macroeconomic Conditions and Poverty in Cox Edwards, A., and J. Roberts. 1994. "Macroeconomic Latin America." Inter-American Development Bank. Influences on Female Labor Force Participation: The Latin Washington, D.C. American Evidence." EstudiosdeEconomia20: 89-106. Mosley, P. 1993. "Metamorphosis from NGO to Commercial de Moura Castro, C. 1994. "La Formaci6n Profesional en Bank: The Case of Bancosol in Bolivia." Working Paper 4. America Latina: Nuevos Remedios para un Nuevo Paciente." Department of Economics, University of Reading, Reading. Planeacidny Desarrollo 25 (special edition):237-56. Naim, M. 1995. "Latin America's Journey to the Market: From Dertouzos,J. N., and L.A. Karoly. 1992. Labor-Market Responses Macroeconomic Shocks to Institutional Therapy." Occa- to Employer Liability. Santa Monica, Calif: Rand, The sional Paper 62. San Francisco: International Center for Institute for Civil Justice. Economic Growth Erzan, Refik, Kiroaki Kuwahara, Saratino Marchese, and Rene Pencavel, John. 1995. "The Role of Labor Unions in Vossenar. 1989. "The Profile of Protection in Developing Fostering Economic Development." Background paper Countries." UNCTADReviewI(1). for World Development Report 1995. World Bank, Grosh, M. 1992. "From Platitudes to Practice: Targeting Social Washington, D.C. Programs in Latin America." Latin America and the Pessino, C., and L. Giacchini. 1994. "Rising Unemployment in Caribbean Human Resource Division Report 10720. World Argentina: 1974-1993." CEMA, Buenos Aires. Bank, Washington, D.C. Psacharopoulos, George, and Harry Anthony Patrinos, eds. Hamermesh, D. 1993. Labor Demand. Princeton, New Jersey: 1994. Indigenous People and Poverty in Latin America: An Princeton University Press. EmpiricalAnalysis. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. 27 L A D R O r A N D Ec C C N O M I C R E F M R M S Psacharopoulos, G., S. Morley, A. Fiszbein, H. Le, and B. Ismail Serageldin and Pierre Landell-Mills, eds., Overcoming Wood. 1992. "Poverty and Income Discribution in Latin Global Hunger: Proceedings ofa Conference on Actions to Reduce America: The Story of the 1 980s." Latin America and the Hunger Worldwide. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. Caribbean Technical Department Regional Studies Report World Bank. 1993a. "Human Resources in Latin America and 27. World Bank, Washington, D.C. the Caribbean: Priorities in Action." Latin America and the Summers, R., and A. Heston. 1991. "The Penn World Table Caribbean Regional Office, Washington, D.C. (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, . 1993b. "Latin America and the Caribbean: A Decade 1950-1988." Quarterlv lournalofEconomics 106 (2): 327-68. after the Debt Crisis." Latin America and the Caribbean Syrquin, M. 1991. "A Comparative Analysis of Structural Regional Office. Washington, D.C. Transformation in Latin America." In M. Urrutia, ed., Long- . 1994. Averting the OldAge Crisis: Policies to Protect the Term Trends in Latin American Economic Development. Old and Promote Growth. New York: Oxford University Washington, D.C.: Inter-American Development Bank. Press. Vial, I., and A. Valdes. 1994. "Targeting and Decentralization of . 1995. Wrorld Development Report 1995: Workers in an Health and Nutrition Programs: The Chilean Experience." In Integrating World. New York: Oxford University Press. 28 World Development Report 1995 Workers in an Integrating World Full text edition available in the following languages: English (Hardback) ISBN 0-19-521103-0 Stock No. 61103 $37.95 English (Paperback) ISBN 0-19-521102-2 Stock No. 61102 $19.95 Forthcoming: Arabic ISBN 0-8213-2897-2 Stock No. 12897 $19.95 Chinese ISBN 0-8213-2896-4 Stock No. 12896 $19.95 French ISBN 0-8213-2892-1 Stock No. 12892 $19.95 German ISBN 0-8213-2894-8 Stock No. 12894 $19.95 Japanese ISBN 0-8213-2895-6 Stock No. 12895 $19.95 Portuguese ISBN 0-8213-2899-9 Stock No. 12899 $19.95 Russian ISBN 0-8213-2898-0 Stock No. 12898 $19.95 Spanish ISBN0-8213-2893-X StockNo. 12893 $19.95 Regional Perspectives on World Development Report 1995 Seven companions to World Development Report 1995, each with additional material on the labor market issues in the particular region. Labor and the Growth Crisis in Sub-Saharan Africa ISBN 0-8213-3343-7 Stock No. 13343 $6.95 Jobs, Poverty, and Working Conditions in South Asia ISBN 0-8213-3344-5 Stock No. 13344 $6.95 Involving Workers in East Asian Growth ISBN 0-8213-3345-3 Stock No. 13345 $6.95 Will Arab Workers Prosper or Be Left Out in the Twenty-First Century? ISBN 0-8213-3346-1 Stock No. 13346 $6.95 Workers in Transition in Europe and Central Asia ISBN 0-8213-3347-X Stock No. 13347 $6.95 Labor and Economic Reform in Latin America and the Caribbean ISBN 0-8213-3348-8 Stock No. 13348 $6.95 The Employment Crisis in Industrial Countries: Is International Integration to Blame? ISBN 0-8213-3349-6 Stock No. 13349 $6.95 For order coupon, see back of this booklet World Development Report on CD-ROM 1978-95 A complete archive of all 18 World Development Reports. Now, for the first time, a new CD-ROM product, created by ASIA-CD, Hong Kong, a copublisher of the World Bank, brings you all 18 editions of the Report together with the World Development Indicators 1995. With its easy-to-use but powerful search engine, this product gives you an invaluable resource and a comprehensive database on the development debate. Specifications: Windows 3.1; Minimum 4MB free RAM 386 or faster processor; CD- ROM drive to MPC Level 1 specification. Forthcoming StockNo. 31590 /Single-user version. $375.00,IAbdJ1zi-userversion $750.00 Available in the U.S. from the World Bank and Oxford University Press. For availability in other countries, contact: Asia 2000 Ltd. Attn: Edowan Bersma, Sales & Circulation Dept 46-48 Wyndham Street Winning Centre, 7th Floor Central, Hong Kong World Development Indicators 1995 World Bank Data on Diskette Statistical tables providing instant access to the most comprehensive and current data available on social and economic development in more than 200 economies. Topics range from agricultural production to international trade. Included in the print version of the Re- port, the Indicators are also available separately on diskette. Each package includes a user's guide to the *STARS* retrieval system and a 31/2" double-density diskette for PCs with a hard disk, at least 512K RAM, and MS-DOS version 2.1 or higher. ISBN 0-8213-2921-9 / Stock No. 12921 . $45.00 For order form, see back of this booklet Distributors of World Bank Publications Prices and terms vary by country ARGENTINA COLOMBIA GREECE Carlos Hirsch, SRL Infoenlace Ltda. Papasotiriou S.A. Galeria Guemes Apartado Aereo 34270 35, Stournara Str. Florida 165, 4th Floor-Ofc. 453/465 Bogota D.E. 106 82 Athens 1333 Buenos Aires COSTA RICA, BELIZE, HONG KONG, MACAO Oficina del Libro Internacional GUATEMALA, HONDURAS, Asia 2000 Ltd. Alberti 40 NICARAGUA, PANAMA 46-48 Wyndham Street 1082 Buenos Aires Chispas Bookstore Winning Centre 75 Meters al Norte del Hotel 7th Floor AUSTRALIA, Balmoral en calle 7 CentraL Hong Kong PAPUA NEW GUINEA, San Jose FIJI, SOLOMON ISLANDS, HUNGARY VANUATU, AND COTE D'IVOIRE Foundation for Market Economy WESTERN SAMOA Centre d'Edition et de Diffusion Dombovari Ut 17-19 D.A. Information Services Africaines (CEDA) H-1117 Budapest 648 Whitehorse Road 04 B.P. 541 Mitcham 3132 Abidjan 04 Plateau INDIA Victoria Allied Publishers Private Ltd. CYPRUS 751 Mount Road AUSTRIA Center of Applied Research Madras - 600 002 Gerold and Co. Cyprus College Graben 31 6, Diogenes Street, Engomi INDONESIA A-1011 Wien P.O. Box 2006 Pt. Indira Limited Nicosia Jalan Borobudur 20 BANGLADESH P.O. Box 181 Micro Industries Development CZECH REPUBLIC Jakarta 10320 Assistance Society (MIDAS) National Information Center House 5, Road 16 P.O. Box 668 IRAN Dhanmondi R/Area CS-113 57 Prague 1 Kowkab Publishers Dhaka 1209 P.O. Box 19575-511 DENMARK Tehran BELGIUM SamfundsLitteratur Jean De Lannoy Rosenoerns Alle 11 IRELAND Av. du Roi 202 DK-1970 Frederiksberg C Government Supplies Agency 1060 Brussels 4-5 Harcourt Road EGYPT, ARAB REPUBLIC OF Dublin 2 BRAZIL Al Ahram Publicacoes Tecnicas Internacionais Al Galaa Street ISRAEL Ltda. Cairo Yozmot Literature Ltd. Rua Peixoto Gomide, 209 P.O. Box 56055 01409 Sao Paulo, SP The Middle East Observer Tel Aviv 61560 41, Sherif Street CANADA Cairo R.O.Y. International Le Diffuseur P.O. Box 13056 151A Boul. de Mortagne FINLAND Tel Aviv 61130 Boucherville, Qu6bec Akateeminen Kirjakauppa J4B 5E6 P.O. Box 23 Palestinian Authority/Middle East FIN-00371 Helsinki Index Information Services Renouf Publishing Co. P.O.B. 19502 Jerusalem 1294 Algoma Road FRANCE Ottawa, Ontario Kl B 3W8 World Bank Publications ITALY 66, avenue d'1ena Licosa Comrnissionaria Sansoni SPA CHINA 75116 Paris Via Duca Di Calabria, 1/1 China Financial & Economic Casella Postale 552 Publishing House GERMANY 50125 Firenze 8, Da Fo Si Dong Jie UNO-Verlag Beijing Poppelsdorfer Allee 55 JAMAICA 53115 Bonn Ian Randle Publishers Ltd. 206 Old Hope Road Kingston 6 JAPAN PERU SRI LANKA & THE MALDIVES Eastern Book Service Editorial Desarrollo SA Lake House Bookshop Hongo 3-Chome, Bunkyo-ku 113 Apartado 3824 P.O. Box 244 Tokyo Lima 1 100, Sir Chittampalam A. Gardiner Mawatha KENYA PHILIPPINES Colombo 2 Africa Book Service (E.A.) Ltd. International Book Center Quaran House, Mfangano St. Suite 720, Cityland 10 SWEDEN P.O. Box 45245 Condominium Tower 2 Fritzes Customer Service Nairobi Ayala Avenue, H.V. dela Regeringsgatan 12 Costa Extension S-106 47 Stockholm KOREA, REPUBLIC OF Makati, Metro Manila Daejon Trading Co. Ltd. Wennergren-Williams AB P.O. Box 34 POLAND P.O. Box 1305 Yeoeida International Publishing Service S-171 25 Solna Seoul Ul. Piekna 31/37 00-677Warszawa SWITZERLAND MALAYSIA Librairie Payot Unliversity of Malaya Cooperative PORTUGAL Case postale 3212 Bookshop, Limnited Livraria Portugal CH 1002 Lausanne P.O. Box 1127, Jalan Pantai Baru Rua Do Carmo 70-74 59700 Kuala Lumpur 1200 L-isbon Van Diermen Editions Techniques P.O. Box 465 MEXICO SAUDI ARABIA, QATAR CH 1211 Geneva 19 INFOTEC Jarir Book Store Apartado Postal 22-860 P.O. Box 3196 TANZANIA 14060 Tlalpan, Mexico D.F. Riyadh 11471 Oxford University Press Maktaba Street NETHERLANDS SINGAPORE, TAIWAN, P.O. Box 5299 De Lindeboom/InOr-Publikaties MYANMAR,BRUNEI Dar es-Salaam P.O. Box 202 Gower Asia Pacific Pte Ltd. 7480 AE Haaksbergen Golden Wheel Building THAILAND 41, Kallang Pudding, #04-03 Central Books Distribution Co. Ltd. NEW ZEALAND Singapore 1334 306 Silom Road EBSCO NZ Ltd. Bangkok Private Mail Bag 99914 SLOVAK REPUBLIC New Market Slovart G.T.G. Ltd. TRINIDAD & TOBAGO, JAMAICA Auckland Krupinska 4 Systematics Studies Unit P.O. Box 152 #9 Watts Street NIGERIA 852 99 Bratislava 5 Curepe University Press Lirnited Trinidad, West Indies Three Crowns Building Jericho SOUTH AFRICA, BOTSWANA Private Mail Bag 5095 For sinzgle titles: UGANDA Ibadan Oxford University Press Gustro Ltd. Southern Africa 1st Floor, Room 4, Geogiadis Chami- NORWAY P.O. Box 1141 bers Narvesen Information Center Cape Town 8000 P.O. Box 9997 Book Department Plot (69) Kampala Road P.O. Box 6125 Etterstad For subscription orders: Kampala N-0602 Oslo 6 International Subscription Service P.O. Box 41095 UNITED KINGDOM PAKISTAN Craighal Microinfo Ltd. Mirza Book Agency Johannesburg 2024 P.O. Box 3 65, Shahrah-e-Quaid-e-Azam Alton, Hampshire GU34 2PG P.O. Box No. 729 SPAIN England Lahore 54000 Mundi-Prensa Libros, S.A. Castello 37 ZAMBIA Oxford University Press 28001 Madrid University Bookshop 5 Bangalore Town Great East Road Campus Sharae Faisal Libreria Internacional AEDOS P.O. Box 32379 P.O. Box 13033 Consell de Cent, 391 Lusaka Karachi-75350 08009 Barcelona ZIMBABWE Longman Zimbabwe (Pte.) Ltd. Tourle Road, Ardbennie P.O. Box ST 125 Order Form CUSTOMERS IN THE UNITED STATES: CUSTOMERS OUTSIDE THE UNITED STATES: Complete this coupon and return to Contact your local World Bank publications The World Bank distributor for information on prices in local currency Box 7247-8619 and payment terms. If no distributor is listed for your Philadelphia, PA 19170-8619 country, use this order form and return it to the U.S. U.S.A. address. Orders that are sent to the U.S. address To have your order shipped faster, charge from countries with distributors will be returned to by credit card by calling (202) 473-1155 the customer. or send this completed order coupon by facsimile by dialing (202) 676-0581. Quantity Title Stock No. Price Total Subtotal US$ * SHIPP[NG AND HANDL[NG charges arc $5.0(J per Shipping and Handling* US$ order If a purchase order Is used, actual shipping will be charged. For air mail delivery outside the United States. Total US$ _ add $8.00 for one item plus S6.00 for each additional item CHECK METHOD OF PAYMENT O Enclosed is nws check pavable to The World Bank. O Charge my O VISA O MasterCard O American Express Credit card account number Expiration date Signature O Bill me. (Institutional customers only. Purchase order must be included.) PLEASE PRINT CLEARLY Name Address City State Postal Code Country Telephone_ 1163 THE WORLD BANK H EADQUARTERS 1818 H Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A. Telephone: (202) 477-1234 Facsimile: (202) 477-6391 Telex: MCI 64145 WORLDBANK MCI 248423 WORLDBANK Cable address: INTBAFRAD WASHINGTONDC Interne[ address: http://vvv.worldbank.org// EUROPEAN OFFICE 66, avenue d'I6na 75116 Paris, France Telephone: (1) 40.69.30.00 Facsimile: (1) 40.69.30.66 Telex: 640651 TOKYO OFFICE Kokusai Building 1 -1 Marunouchi 3-chome Chiyoda-ku, Tokyo 100, Japan Telephone: (3) 3214-5001 Facsimile: (3) 3214-3657 Telex: 26838 9 780821 333488 ISBN 0-8213-3348-8