77552 Land Tenure, Investment Incentives, and the Choice of Techniques: Evidence from Nicaragua Oriana Bandiera The choice of cultivation techniques is a key determinant of agricultural productivity and has important consequences for income growth and poverty reduction in develop- ing countries. Household data from Nicaragua are used to show that the choice of cultivation technique depends on farmers’ tenure status even when techniques are observable and contractible. In particular, tree crops are less likely to be grown on rented than on owner-cultivated plots. Further evidence indicates that the result follows from landlords’ inability or unwillingness to commit to long-term tenancy contracts rather than from agency costs due to risk aversion or limited liability. JEL codes: D23, D82, O12, Q15. The importance of agriculture for the welfare of the poorest can hardly be overstated. The adoption of new cultivation techniques is a key determinant of agricultural productivity, and their promotion is often at the core of develop- ment projects. Thus, identi�cation of obstacles to the diffusion of new tech- niques is crucial to the design of development policies. This article assesses whether cultivation techniques differ on plots cultivated by their owners from those on plots cultivated by tenants. The analysis looks at the effect of ownership status on the cultivation of trees in combination with annual crops in a sample of Nicaraguan farms. Growing a mix of trees and annual crops is generally more pro�table than growing annual crops alone. Trees are both pro�table in their own right and enhance nutrient recycling, conserve soil moisture, maintain fertility, and reduce soil erosion. Oriana Bandiera is assistant professor at the London School of Economics and Political Science (LSE) and research af�liate at the Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) and at the Bureau for Research and the Analysis of Economic Development; her email address is o.bandiera@lse.ac.uk. The author thanks Abhijit Banerjee, Tim Besley, Robin Burgess, Raquel Fernandez, Markus Goldstein, Gilat Levy, Andrea Prat, and Imran Rasul for insightful discussions. Jaime de Melo and three anonymous referees offered useful comments. The author would also like to thank participants at the CEPR Public Policy Symposium, the Northeast Universities Development Consortium, and seminars at Essex University, the World Bank, and the LSE for useful discussions. Barbara Veronese provided excellent research assistance. Financial support from Suntory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related Disciplines and the Economic and Social Research Council is gratefully acknowledged. THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW, VOL. 21, NO. 3, pp. 487 –508 doi:10.1093/wber/lhm005 Advance Access Publication 9 May 2007 # The Author 2007. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / THE WORLD BANK. All rights reserved. For permissions, please e-mail: journals.permissions@oxfordjournals.org 487 488 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW The analysis �nds that Nicaraguan farmers are more likely to grow trees on plots they own than on plots they rent. The result holds both in a sample of farmers that cultivate an owned and a rented plot and in a cross-section of pure owners and pure tenants. Following the �nding that ownership status does matter, the article seeks to shed some light on the mechanisms that drive the difference between owners and tenants. The separation of ownership and cultivation rights is key because landowners cannot observe the effort exerted by tenants. This affects the choice of cultivation techniques through two channels. First, landowners might not adopt techniques that are complementary to unobservable production effort if they cannot provide the tenants with suf�ciently strong effort incen- tives.1 Second, landowners might not adopt techniques that require noncon- tractible investment, for instance in maintenance, if they cannot commit to letting tenants reap the bene�ts of their investment. The �rst channel implies that tenants’ wealth determines incentive costs and hence the equilibrium choice of effort and techniques. Indeed, theories of moral hazard in agriculture indicate that landowners might not be able to provide tenants with suf�ciently strong effort incentives because of either risk aversion or limited liability, both of which are more important when the tenant is poor (Stiglitz 1974; Braverman and Stiglitz 1986; Mookherjee 1997; Banerjee, Gertler, and Ghatak 2002). Contrary to this prediction, however, tenants’ wealth is not a signi�cant determinant of tree cultivation in Nicaragua. Further analysis reveals that the probability of tenants’ farming trees is higher when their tenancy contract is longer. The results indicate that long- term commitment is important. This �nding is in line with the observation that since a tenant’s effort affects tree productivity in the future, proper incentives can be provided only by offering a long-term contract that makes the tenant’s pay conditional on future output. Long-term contracts, however, are rare in Nicaragua. A cursory look at the history of land policies and current land laws suggests a number of reasons why landlords might be unwilling to commit to long-term contracts. Following the 1979 Sandinista revolution, large landholdings not managed by their owners were expropriated and redistributed to former tenants and landless peasants. Landlords may fear another reform and hence prefer not to make long-term commitments. In addition, current land laws grant strong rights to long-term tenants and make their eviction dif�cult, effectively increasing the cost of long-term commitments. The �ndings in this article are in line with those of Shaban (1987), who shows that the productivity differential between owner-cultivated and share- cropped plots in a sample of Indian farms derives from different levels of both 1. It is important to note that, in contrast to noncontractible effort, contractible techniques can be chosen by the owner of the land regardless of whether the land is rented out or cultivated directly. In other words, the fact that tenants face different incentives has no direct consequence for the choice of techniques if these are subject to contract. Bandiera 489 observable and unobservable inputs. In addition, the evidence on the effects of ownership status on tree cultivation is complementary to Besley’s (1995) �nd- ings for Ghana, where owners-cultivators who hold secure rights to their plots are more likely to grow trees. This article instead compares plots cultivated by tenants with plots cultivated by their owners and also �nds that tenure security goes together with tree cultivation. It also �nds that on tenant-cultivated plots trees are more likely to be grown by tenants who have long-term contracts.2 Section I presents the data and the empirical strategy. Section II illustrates the main results. Section III discusses the predictions of a tenancy theory and offers an interpretation of the results. Section IV briefly touches on policy implications and areas for further research. I . D ATA D E S C R I P T I O N AND EMPIRICAL STRATEGY This section describes the data, the main variables, and the empirical approach. Data Description Nicaragua is one of the poorest countries in Latin America. In 1998, the year of the survey data used in this study, per capita GNP was $430, about half the population lived below the poverty line. The economy relies heavily on the rural sector. In 1998, agriculture accounted for a third of GDP and almost half the population lived in rural areas. The distribution of landholdings and hence the incidence of tenancy derive from a number of land reforms implemented between 1981 and 1997. In 1981, the Sandinista National Liberation Front (FSLN) expropriated large land holdings and redistributed them to landless peasants, tenants, and farmers cooperatives (Decretos 760 and 782). The democratic government elected in 1990 privatized and redistributed state-owned land and recognized the property rights acquired by both individ- ual farmers and farmers cooperatives through the FSLN land reform.3 Land distribution is still very unequal. According to the latest Agricultural Census (2001), the Gini coef�cient is 0.71, only slightly improved from 0.79 in 1963. Household data from the 1998 Nicaragua Living Standard Measurement Study survey are used for the analysis. The survey covers the entire country, and 2. To the extent that trees increase agricultural productivity, the evidence in this article speaks to the microfoundations of the well-known aggregate relationship between land inequality and agricultural productivity. A large literature suggests that small owner-cultivated farms are more productive than large farms that rely on hired labor and than farms operated by tenants, yet there is little evidence on the determinants of such differences. The issue is especially relevant in Central and South America, where land distribution is highly unequal and the productivity differential in favor of small family farms is the largest in the world (Binswanger, Deninger, and Feder 1995 Banerjee 1999). 3. See Ley de Proteccion a la Propiedad Agraria. Ley 88 (April 2, 1990) Decreto-Ley de revision de con�scaciones Decreto 11 –90 (May 11, 1990), Ley de estabilidad de la propriedad Ley 209 (November 30, 1995), and Ley sobre propriedad reformada urbana y agraria Ley 278 (November 26, 1997). 490 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW the sampling strategy is based on population data from the 1995 Census. The survey contains detailed information on the agricultural activities of 1,258 house- holds. Of these, 57 percent farm their own plots, 36 percent farm rented plots, and 7 percent farm both an owned and a rented plot. In addition, 11 percent of owner-cultivators also rent out land. No household in the sample rents in and out at the same time. Finally, most farms in the sample consist of one or two plots. The unit of analysis is the household. In general, one household member— typically the household head—is solely responsible for agriculture and takes all farming decisions, whereas other household members provide farming labor. Interviews about the farming activities of the household are held with the household member who manages the farm in 97 percent of the cases. Dependent Variables This article analyzes the choice between growing a mix of annual and tree crops and growing annual crops only. The combination of annual and tree crops has recently been promoted by most agricultural development institutions and nongovernmental organizations since tree crops enhance nutrient recycling, conserve soil moisture, maintain fertility, and reduce soil erosion. The opportu- nity cost in terms of other crop yields is low because annual crops can be grown under the trees. Evidence from agroforestry projects in Central America suggests that this practice is pro�table under a broad range of conditions (Current, Lutz, and Scherr 1995).4 With a few exceptions, the main tree crops grown in Nicaragua—coffee, citrus, bananas, and mangoes—are more pro�table, but also more expensive and effort intensive, than the main annual crops (maize, beans, and cassava). The sample average fertilizer expenditure, for instance, is about twice as high for farmers who grow a combination of trees and annual crops (406 cordobas com- pared with 217 cordobas). The relative pro�tability of one technique over the other is therefore likely to depend on the level of effort exerted by the farmer. The survey asks farmers to name the two main crops they grow and collects information on every crop grown in the last 12 months. To separate farmers who grow a mix of trees and annual crops from those who grow annual crops only, two variables are de�ned. The �rst, tree_mix, is equal to one when the farmer grows at least one tree crop. The second, tree_main, is equal to one when at least one of the main crops is a tree. To be clear, tree_mix is de�ned at the farm level; whether the farmer grows trees is known but not on which plot if the farm com- prises more than one. In contrast tree_main is de�ned at the plot level. These two variables represent an upper and a lower bound estimate of the number of farmers who grow trees. The �rst variable overestimates the number 4. There is a clear positive correlation between national income and tree cultivation in Central America. Trees cover about 10 percent of Nicaragua’s agricultural land, compared with 55 percent in Costa Rica, 30 percent in El Salvador, 29 percent in Guatemala, and 19 percent in Honduras. The correlation between share of tree crops and 1998 GDP per capita is 0.94. (Crop data are from FAO, FAOSTAT Land Use; GDP data are from World Bank World Development Indicators.) Bandiera 491 of farmers who choose a combination of tree and annual crops because, according to the de�nition, even a farmer who grows only one tree is counted as growing trees. About 58 percent of the farmers in the sample grow a mix of annual and tree crops (table 1), which is in line with the 2001 rural Census �gure of 52 percent. The second variable underestimates the number of farmers who grow trees because it counts only farmers for whom trees are one of the two most important crops, whereas farmers grow on average four different crops. The sample average of tree_main is just 9 percent. The main tree crops in the sample are coffee, banana, mango, and citrus. Since coffee and citrus are more expensive and more effort intensive than annual crops while mangoes and bananas may not be, the dependent variable was also rede�ned as tree_mix2, equal to one when the farmer farms at least one coffee or citrus tree together with annual crops. About 42 percent of farmers in the sample grow coffee or citrus according to this de�nition. Unconditionally, there is a clear difference between crops grown by tenants and those grown by owner-cultivators. In particular, trees are more likely to be grown on owner-operated plots: 63 percent of owners grow at least one tree, whereas 49 percent of tenants do. The difference is more striking for the tree_main variable: 13 percent of owners grow trees as a main crop compared with only 4 percent of tenants. All the differences are statistically signi�cant at conventional levels. Farmers who cultivate both owned and rented plots are more similar to the owner-cultivators. Trees are one of the two main crops in 12 percent of the plots cultivated by these farmers. The structure of the survey is such that the other two measures of tree cultivation (tree_mix and tree_mix2) cannot be built in this sample. Indeed, while respondents were asked to report the two main crops grown on each plot separately, information on other crops is pooled at the farm level, and it is therefore impossible to establish whether these are grown on the rented or the owned plot. T A B L E 1 . Descriptive Statistics for Dependent Variables Farmers who Farmers who Farmers who cultivate both Dependent cultivate owned cultivate tenanted owned and variable All farmers plots only plots only tenanted plots Tree_mix 0.58 0.63 0.49 (0.49) (0.48) (0.50) Tree_mix2 0.42 0.48 0.34 (0.49) (0.49) (0.47) Tree_main 0.09 0.13 0.04 0.12 (0.29) (0.33) (0.19) (0.32) Note: Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations. Source: Author’s analysis based on data from the 1998 Nicaragua Living Standards Measurement Study survey. 492 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW Looking at the statistics for the individual crops reveals that owners and tenants are equally likely to grow any type of annual crop, but owners are sig- ni�cantly more likely to grow any type of tree. The difference is particularly striking for coffee (14 and 4 percent), which is possibly the most effort inten- sive but also most pro�table crop. Farmer and Household Characteristics The empirical analysis identi�es the effect of ownership on tree cultivation both from the cross-section of farmers who either own or rent a plot and from the sample of farmers who cultivate both an owned and a rented plot. The survey does not contain information on the plots that are rented out by a subset of the owners. Table 2 presents the descriptive statistics for a number of farmer and house- hold characteristics. Two patterns emerge for every wealth measure. First, tenants are signi�cantly poorer than owner-cultivators. Second, owners who rent out are signi�cantly richer than owners who do not. In the presence of moral hazard in both the credit and tenancy markets, household wealth plays an important role for the choice of technique for both owner-cultivators and tenants. Indeed, for owner-cultivators, wealth deter- mines the relevance of credit constraints and hence whether the farmers can afford to grow trees. Credit constraints themselves matter much less for tenants, as the owners of their plots are typically wealthy and can �nance tree cultivation if they �nd it pro�table. Nevertheless, models of moral hazard with either risk aversion or limited liability indicate that tenants’ wealth determines the cost of providing incentives for noncontractible effort and hence the choice of cultivation techniques when these are complementary to effort. Farmers who manage household agricultural activities are on average 44 years old and have two years of formal education (see table 2). Most (93 percent) of them are male. To control for scale effects in wealth and the avail- ability of family labor, household size is controlled for throughout. The average household size is about six, regardless of ownership status. Households that cultivate both a tenanted and an owned plot tend to be larger (seven) than households that own or rent only (six). Other measures of household structure, such as the number of adults or the dependency ratio, also do not vary by own- ership status and are not reported for reasons of space. The average farm is 25 manzanas (about 18 hectares) and owner-cultivated farms are on average sig- ni�cantly larger than tenanted farms. The standard deviation of farm size is quite high in all samples. Finally, table 2 reports two town-level variables that are employed in the analysis: population, a measure of town size, and the sample average distance to the closest market for agricultural produce. The average town has a popu- lation of 40,000 and the average farm is about 2 hours from the market. Both variables are included because most of the yield of tree crops is likely to be sold rather than consumed at home, and exchange is presumably easier in T A B L E 2 . Descriptive Statistics for Farmer and Household Characteristics Farmers who Farmers who Farmers who Farmers who cultivate owned Farmers who cultivate cultivate both cultivate owned plots and do cultivate owned tenanted plots owned and plots and rent not rent out Test 2, Farmer characteristics plots only only Test 1, p-value tenanted plots out some land some land p-value Household wealth*1024 9.30 1.17 0.00 6.23 14.7 8.6 0.043 (25.14) (2.98) (9.03) (29.5) (24.5) Durables value *1024 0.130 0.066 0.00 0.071 0.225 0.118 0.056 (0.469) (0.165) (0.129) (0.590) (0.452) House value*1024 1.42 0.725 0.00 1.26 2.18 1.32 0.011 (2.83) (2.29) (2.11) (5.11) (2.40) Number of bedrooms 2.05 1.72 0.00 2.16 2.44 2.01 0.002 (1.21) (0.949) (1.23) (1.76) (1.12) Farmer’s age 47.0 39.0 0.00 44.2 47.1 47.0 0.941 (15.3) (14.5) (15.8) (15.7) (15.2) Farmer’s gender (female ¼ 1) 0.086 0.053 0.03 0.035 0.101 0.084 0.617 (0.281) (0.224) (0.184) (0.306) (0.278) Farmer’s education (years) 2.34 2.09 0.17 1.78 2.91 2.26 0.087 (3.16) (2.65) (2.60) (3.40) (3.13) Household size 6.37 6.13 0.18 7.09 5.97 6.42 0.202 (2.94) (2.86) (3.58) (2.72) (2.97) Farm size (manzanas) 37.2 6.79 0.00 8.86 44.4 36.40 0.438 (87.1) (23.8) (24.5) (79.9) (88.1) Town size (population in 37.1 43.6 0.07 42.5 31.2 37.8 0.299 thousands) (53.1) (66.2) (37.2) (22.3) (55.7) Bandiera (Continued ) 493 494 TABLE 2. Continued Farmers who Farmers who Farmers who Farmers who cultivate owned Farmers who cultivate cultivate both cultivate owned plots and do cultivate owned tenanted plots owned and plots and rent not rent out Test 2, Farmer characteristics plots only only Test 1, p-value tenanted plots out some land some land p-value THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW Average distance to 1.90 1.82 .21 1.89 1.95 1.89 0.641 market-town (1.02) (0.98) (0.92) (0.99) (1.03) Number of observations 718 454 86 79 639 Note: Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations. Source: Author’s analysis based on data from the 1998 Nicaragua Living Standards Measurement Study survey. Bandiera 495 larger towns and transportation costs are lower in towns that are closer to a market. Owner-cultivators, tenants, and landlords are equally distributed across towns. Empirical Strategy Let mixi be a variable that equals one if farmer i grows a combination of trees and annual crops and zero otherwise. Trees will be grown when the expected return, Ri (trees), is larger than the expected return from growing annual crops, that is mixi ¼ 1 if Ri ðtreesÞ À Ri ðannualÞ . 0 ð1Þ mixi ¼ 0 otherwise: Two samples from the 1998 survey are used to identify the effect of owner- ship status on tree cultivation. The �rst contains information on farmers who cultivate both an owned and a rented plot. The second contains information on farmers who cultivate either an owned or a rented plot. Farmer Fixed-Effect Speci�cation First, the effect of ownership status on tree cultivation is analyzed by compar- ing owned and rented plots cultivated by the same farmer. Throughout, a linear probability model is used to estimate the choice in equation (1). The crop-choice equation estimated is of the form: mixij ¼ a þ bownij þ gsize j þ bi þ eij ð2Þ where mixij denotes the choice of farmer i on plot j, ownij equals one when farmer i owns plot j, sizej is the area of plot j, and bi is the farmer �xed effect. Using a linear probability model instead of a discrete choice model entails both advantages and disadvantages. The main reason to use it in this context is that including farmer �xed effects does not bias the coef�cients when the model is linear. In addition, measurement error (misclassi�cation) of the depen- dent variable can strongly bias the coef�cient estimates in discrete models, while it is of much less consequence when the model is linear (see, for example, Hausman, Abrevaya, and Scott-Morton 1998). In addition, omitted variables are less troublesome in a linear model than in a probit because the coef�cients of the included variables are biased only if the two are correlated (see Yatchew and Griliches 1985). The main advantage of �xed-effect estimates is that the effect of ownership on tree cultivation does not suffer from selection bias on individual unobserva- bles. However, �xed-effect estimation, by de�nition, does not allow comparing the effect of ownership status with the effect of other farmer characteristics on the choice of production techniques. To this purpose, the remainder of the 496 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW analysis focuses on the cross-sectional evidence from the sample of pure owners and pure tenants. Cross-Section Speci�cation: Least Squares Estimates The general crop choice equation estimated by least squares is: mixiv ¼ a þ bowniv þ xiv g þ zv d þ h p þ eiv ð3Þ where mixiv denotes the choice of farmer i in town v. The variable owniv equals one if farmer i owns the land and zero otherwise. The xiv term is a vector of household and farmer characteristics, which include household wealth and size and farmer’s age, gender, and educational achievement. Town characteristics, zv, include town population and the sample average distance to market. To control for other geographic and policy characteristics, all regressions include province �xed effects (hp). Cross-Section Speci�cation: Matching Estimates Nonexperimental matching procedures might yield estimates that improve over linear regression estimates in the sense of being closer to those produced by a randomized experiment. The main difference between linear regression and matching estimators is the weighting scheme; matching estimators give more weight to the difference between similar observations. This might lead to differ- ent point estimates if the effect of ownership on the probability of growing trees varies with observable characteristics. To allow for this, the following section reports estimates for the average treatment effect of ownership on tree cultiva- tion, using nearest neighbor matching over farmer and town characteristics. II. THE EFFECT OF OW N E R S H I P S TAT U S ON T R E E C U L T I VA T I O N Following Abadie and Imbens (2004), the bias-adjusted estimator is used to purge the estimates of the bias due to matching over several covariates. The inverse of the sample variance–covariance matrix of the covariates is used to specify the weight given to each variable in de�ning nearest neighbor matches. Main Results FIXED-EFFECTS ESTIMATES. The estimates of crop-choice equation (2) are pre- sented in table 3. The effect of ownership is identi�ed from the comparison of owned and rented plots cultivated by the same farmer. The dependent variable is tree_main, which equals one when one of the two main crops is a tree. The structure of the survey does not permit building the other two measures (tree_mix and tree_mix2) in this sample. The results show that ownership status matters: farmers are more likely to grow trees on the �elds they own than on the �elds they rent. The coef�cient T A B L E 3 . Land Ownership and Trees: Linear Probability Model Fixed-Effect and Cross-Section Estimates Cross-section Fixed effects Tree_mix Tree_mix2 Tree_main Tree_main Variable (1) (2a) (2b) (3a) (3b) (4a) (4b) Farmer owns plot 0.182*** 0.144*** 0.120*** 0.135*** 0.108*** 0.090*** 0.073*** (0.045) (0.03) (0.032) (0.029) (0.031) (0.015) (0.016) Household wealth*1026 0.127* 0.129** 0.198*** (0.065) (0.056) (0.046) Farmer’s age 0.002** 0.004*** 0.001** (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) Farmer’s gender 0.013 2 0.005 0.039 (0.054) (0.057) (0.038) Farmer’s education (years) 0.009* 0.005 0.009** (0.005) (0.005) (0.004) Household size 0.011** 0.007 2 0.007*** (0.005) (0.005) (0.002) Farm size*1023 2 0.562*** 2 0.381** 2 0.235* (0.207) (0.188) (0.131) Plot size*1023 2 668 (1.25) Town size*1026 0.354 0.336 0.180 (0.228) (0.236) (0.186) Average distance to market town 2 0.063*** 2 0.046*** 2 0.029*** (0.016) (0.016) (0.010) Percent increase in probability when 29 24 39 30 248 157 moving from tenancy to ownership Province �xed effect No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Number of observations (farmers) 86 1172 1172 1172 1172 1172 1172 R2 0.08 0.02 0.10 0.02 0.10 0.02 0.15 Bandiera *Signi�cant at the 10 percent level; **Signi�cant at the 5 percent level; ***Signi�cant at the 1 percent level. Note: Numbers in parentheses are standard errors based on White’s robust “sandwich� estimator for the asymptotic covariance matrix. The percen- 497 tage change is calculated as the percentage change in the predicted probability of cultivating trees evaluated at the sample mean of all dependent variables when the ownership dummy goes from zero (tenant) to one (owner). Source: Author’s analysis based on data from the 1998 Nicaragua Living Standards Measurement Study survey. 498 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW on the ownership variable is signi�cant at more than the 1 percent level, which is quite surprising given the small sample size. The marginal effect of tenure is 0.18, which is large considering that the sample mean of tree_main is 0.12. Similar results are obtained in a random-effects model, and the Hausman test fails to reject the null hypothesis of systematic difference in the coef�cients, with a p-value of 0.7764. While the power of the test is low because of the small sample size, the result is nevertheless reassuring for the cross-sectional estimates that follow. LEAST SQUARE ESTIMATES. For all three de�nitions of the tree variable, the �nd- ings indicate that owners are more likely than renters to grow trees (see table 3). The effect is signi�cant at the 1 percent level in all cases. The uncondi- tional effect of ownership on tree cultivation is very close in magnitude to the conditional estimate, suggesting that although owners and tenants differ on a number of observable characteristics, most notably wealth and age, these do not drive the difference in crop choice. In all cases, ownership status has the largest effect on the probability of growing trees. For instance, for the tree_mix variable, the estimates in column 2b of table 3 indicate that the probability of growing trees is 0.12, or 24 percent higher on owner-operated farms. This is equivalent to an increase in educational achievement of 12 years (or four standard deviations), namely the difference between no schooling and completion of basic secondary education. The effect of ownership is also equivalent to an increase of wealth of �ve stan- dard deviations, or 1 million cordobas ($100,000) and to a decrease in the travel time to the market of 2 hours. The effect of ownership on tree_mix (all trees) and tree_mix2 (citrus and coffee) is very similar, while it is much bigger for tree_main. Education, wealth, age, and household size are also signi�cant determinants of tree cultivation. Trees are more likely to be grown by better-educated, richer, and older farmers. The effect of household size depends on how the dependent variable is de�ned. It is positive for tree_mix, zero for tree_mix2, and negative for tree_main. Including other measures of household structure, such as number of adult males or number of children, does not yield additional insights. The results also show that trees are more likely to be grown on smaller farms, which rules out the hypothesis that there are increasing returns to scale to tree cultivation and that the observed difference between owners and tenants is due to the fact that owners farm larger plots. Finally, trees are more likely to be grown by farmers in larger towns and in towns that are closer to agricultural markets. The province �xed effects are jointly signi�cant. The percentage increase in probability that is imputable to the ownership variable is generally large, particularly so for tree_main (see table 3, last Bandiera 499 T A B L E 4 . Land Ownership and Trees: Nearest Neighbor Matching Estimates (1) (2) (3) Tree_mix Tree_mix2 Tree_main Farmer owns plot 0.191* 0.159* 0.082* (0.036) (0.035) (0.017) Number of observations 1172 1172 1172 *Signi�cant at the 1 percent level. Note: Numbers in parentheses are standard errors based on Abadie and Imbens (2004). Heteroskedasticity robust estimator of the variance uses one match within treated and control units. Observations are matched on the same farmer and town characteristics used in table 3 Source: Author’s analysis based on data from the 1998 Nicaragua Living Standards Measurement Study survey. column), indicating that tenants are less likely to grow trees and very unlikely to grow them as a main crop. MATCHING ESTIMATES. Table 4 reports the nearest neighbor estimates of the average treatment effect, using the same set of farmer and town characteristics as in table 3 and a single match for each of the three de�nitions of the depen- dent variable. The results show that the effect of ownership is, if anything, larger when identi�ed from the comparison of the most similar observation. The nearest neighbor estimates of the average effect of ownership on tree_main is comparable to the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimate, whereas the nearest neighbor estimates of the average effect of ownership on tree_mix and tree_mix2 is one and a half times the OLS estimate. The results indicate that the effect of ownership status on tree cultivation varies with observable characteristics. Further analysis reveals that the effect is increasing in wealth (discussed subsequently). Finally, the results do not differ with different de�nitions of the dependent variable. For ease of exposition, and without loss of generality, the analysis that follows employs the more general de�nition of tree_mix. Econometric Concerns The analysis raises two main econometric concerns, one due to the unavailabil- ity of soil quality measures and the other due to the potential endogeneity of wealth. First, the fact that soil quality is in the error term biases the estimates if soil quality is correlated with the ownership variable. In particular, if tree crops necessitate a speci�c soil type and all plots of that speci�c soil type are culti- vated by owners, the ownership variable would also capture the effect of the omitted soil type. Three strategies are applied to address the issue of omitted soil quality. First, land rental value is used as a proxy for soil type. Second, the effect of 500 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW T A B L E 5 . Soil Type Controls: Linear Probability Model (dependent variable, tree_mix) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Baseline Town �xed Segment Land Variable speci�cation Land value effects �xed effects reform Farmer owns plot 0.120*** 0.102*** 0.092*** 0.068* 0.134*** (0.032) (0.033) (0.033) (0.037) (0.033) Land rental value 0.117** (0.005) Individual land reform 2 0.048 (0.076) Collective land reform 2 0.105 (0.066) Household wealth 0.127* 0.135* 0.102 0.186 0.119* *1026 (0.065) (0.073) (0.076) (0.149) (0.063) Farmer’s age 0.002** 0.002** 0.002* 0.001 0.002** (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) Farmer’s gender 0.013 0.038 0.011 – 0.068 0.010 (0.054) (0.058) (0.057) (0.068) (0.054) Farmer’s education 0.009* 0.006 0.009* 0.002 0.009* (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.007) (0.005) Household size 0.011** 0.010** 0.009* 0.005 0.011** (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.006) (0.005) Farm size*1023 2 0.562*** – 0.478** 2 0.374 2 0.651** 2 0.555*** (0.207) (0.217) (0.228) (0.292) (0.204) Town size*1026 0.354 0.305 0.379 (0.228) (0.232) (0.234) Average distance to 2 0.063*** 2 0.063*** 2 0.065*** market-town (0.016) (0.017) (0.016) Province �xed effects Yes Yes No No Yes Town �xed effects No No Yes No No Segment �xed effects No No No Yes No Number of 1172 1100 1172 915 1172 observations R2 0.10 0.10 0.22 0.31 0.10 *Signi�cant at the 10 percent level; **Signi�cant at the 5 percent level; ***Signi�cant at the 1 percent level. Note: Numbers in parentheses are standard errors based on White’s robust “sandwich� esti- mator for the asymptotic covariance matrix. In columns 3 and 4, the town level variables are absorbed by the �xed effects. The number of observations is lower in column 2 because of missing values in the rental value variable, and in column 4 because segments with no variation in ownership status are dropped. Source: Author’s analysis based on data from the 1998 Nicaragua Living Standards Measurement Study survey. ownership is identi�ed from within small geographic areas where the variation in soil type is likely to be small. Third, information on the mode of acquisition of the plot is exploited. To the extent that the suitability of soil for trees is reflected in the rental value of the land, this can be used to proxy for soil type. The survey asks both Bandiera 501 owner-cultivators and tenants to report how much their land could be rented for per year. This amount is used to build a measure of rental value for one unit (manzana) of land. Table 5 includes the land value variable in the crop-choice equation. Note that this variable is likely to be endogenous because trees might increase the value of the land. Thus, the coef�cient of land value cannot be interpreted as the causal effect of land value on tree cultivation. That notwithstanding, if the ownership variable were exclusively proxying for land type, its coef�cient should drop once land value is controlled for. Instead, the estimated effect of ownership does not change from the base speci- �cation when the land-value variable is added (see table 5, column 2). Land value has a positive and signi�cant effect, but it does affect the estimates of the other coef�cients. Results are similar in the �xed-effect speci�cation. Land rental value has a positive effect on tree cultivation, and the estimated coef�- cient of tenure status is unchanged.5 The second test identi�es the effect of ownership status by comparing owners and tenants within small geographic areas that have more homo- geneous soil types because of their size. The survey data permit identi�cation of two such areas: townships and census segments. Town population varies between 3,000 and 900,000 for the capital, Managua. The median size is 20,000, or about 4,000 households. Town dummy variables explain 67 percent of the variation in unit land value in the sample. Census segments identify very small geographic areas of 50–60 house- holds. They are thus much smaller than a rural village and unlikely to exhibit meaningful soil variation. Not surprisingly, census segment dummy variables explain 80 percent of the variation in unit land value. If the previous results for ownership status were driven entirely by unobser- vable soil quality, this should, at least in part, be picked up by the town and segment-�xed effects, resulting in a large drop in the ownership coef�cient. Results for the crop-choice equation with town and segment dummy variables show that the tenure effect is robust to the inclusion of town and segment controls (see table 5, columns 3 and 4). Point estimates are somewhat smaller (0.07 and 0.09) but not signi�cantly different from the baseline esti- mate (0.12). Note that ownership status and farm size are the only two signi�- cant determinants of tree cultivation in the segment �xed-effect regression. The �nal test augments the estimated equation with an interaction term between ownership and a dummy variable that equals one when the land was obtained through land reform rather than purchase or inheritance. The reform redistributed only land that had previously been rented out, implying that if all tenanted land is unsuitable for tree cultivation, all farms obtained through land 5. The average rental value is higher for owner-operated than for tenanted land, but the difference is due entirely to the top 3 percent of the rental value distribution. Results are unchanged if these observations are dropped from the sample. 502 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW reform must be unsuitable for tree cultivation. Therefore, if ownership were proxying for soil type, owners who have obtained their farms through land reform should be less likely to grow trees than owners who purchased or inher- ited their farms.6 The results indicate that owners who got their farm through land reform do not make different choices than owners who bought or inherited their farm, implying that not all rented land is unsuitable for trees (see table 5, column 5). Second, farmers’ wealth might be endogenous to crop choice if cultivating trees makes farmers richer. In this case the OLS estimate of the ownership effect in equation (3) is inconsistent. The root cause of the problem is that many of the characteristics that make the farmer choose to grow trees are not observable, and some of these also affect the farmer’s ability to accumulate wealth. To the extent that omitted variables affect wealth and tree cultivation in the same direction, such that, for instance, more able farmers are more likely to cultivate trees and more able to accumulate wealth, the OLS estimate of the ownership effect is biased downwards.7 The data do not contain information on exogenous variations in wealth that can be exploited to address this issue. III . WH Y AR E TENA N TS L ES S LI K E LY TO FARM TREES? This section examines theoretical and empirical evidence on why tenants may be less likely to farm trees. Theoretical Background The key difference between owners and tenants is that ownership and cultiva- tion rights are separated for tenants. This might explain the observed difference in crop choice if information is asymmetric, in that the owner of the plot cannot observe the effort exerted by the tenant. Moral hazard theories suggest that asymmetric information might affect the choice of cultivation techniques through two channels. First, landowners might not adopt techniques that are complementary to unobservable production effort if they cannot provide tenants with suf�ciently strong effort incentives because of risk aversion or limited liability. If the tenant is risk averse, providing strong incentives through a �xed-rent contract is suboptimal because the tenant bears the entire production risk (Stiglitz 1974). A risk-neutral landlord can achieve a higher payoff by insuring the tenant against bad outcomes, by making the tenant’s pay less sensitive to 6. To keep the comparison clean, it is important to distinguish between farms that were assigned to individual farmers and farms that were assigned to a farmers group or cooperative, whose organizational form results in a different incentive structure. Ley 88 (April 2, 1990), Ley 209 (November 30, 1995), and Ley 278 (November 26, 1997) recognize the property rights acquired by individual farmers and farmers cooperatives with the Sandinistas Land Reform (Decreto 782 and Ley 14, July 19, 1981). See Article 1 Ley 88 and Article 3 Ley 209 and Ley 278. 7. The formal proof is available from the author on request. Bandiera 503 output. Insurance, however, reduces the tenant’s stake in success and leads to the underprovision of effort. Or tenants’ productivity might be lower than �rst best if they are subject to limited liability (Shetty 1988; Mookherjee 1997; Banerjee, Gertler, and Ghatak 2002). Limited liability makes incentive pro- vision costly by imposing an upper bound on the feasible punishment. When the limited liability constraint binds, the landlord can provide incentives only by increasing the reward for success. Since rewards are costly, the landlord might achieve a higher payoff by providing weaker incentives. Thus if effort provision is below �rst best, because of either risk aversion or limited liability, the landowner might resist adoption of techniques that are complementary to effort, even when these are contractible and more pro�table in a �rst-best sense (Braverman and Stiglitz 1986; Banerjee, Gertler, and Ghatak 2002). Second, landowners might not adopt techniques that require noncontractible investment if they cannot provide incentives for the tenant to undertake such investment. For instance, trees require maintenance, but the effects of mainten- ance investments on productivity go beyond the period in which the invest- ments are undertaken. Tenants will choose the optimal level of maintenance if they can reap the bene�ts of increased future productivity. Incentives to invest in maintenance can thus be provided by offering tenants a contract long enough to bene�t from higher future productivity. Landlords might be unable to commit not to expropriate the tenant’s invest- ment if, for instance, courts are ineffective at enforcing contracts or judges can be bribed. In this case, long-term contracts are ineffective because tenants anticipate that once their investments are sunk, they will be held up (Masters and McMillan 2003). Even if landlords can credibly commit to a long-term contract, doing so might be costly since they give up the possibility of adjusting the terms of the contract to changes in the environment. They give up the option of cultivating the land themselves for the duration of the contract, and the contract reduces the resale value of the land if a buyer is bound to honor an existing tenancy agreement. Empirical Evidence This section examines whether trees are not cultivated on rented plots because effort incentives are low-powered (due to risk aversion or limited liability) or because tenants fear their maintenance investment will be expropriated. Although not mutually exclusive, the two hypotheses have distinct predictions on the effect of wealth and contract duration. Since poorer tenants are more likely to be risk averse (Binswanger 1980) and because the limited-liability constraint is more likely to be binding for poor tenants, models of risk aversion or limited liability share the prediction that tenants’ wealth determines the cost of providing incentives and hence effort and the choice of production techniques. In particular, poor tenants should be less likely to cultivate trees. In contrast, if the mechanism driving the result is 504 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW that trees require maintenance effort, tree cultivation and contract duration should be correlated. In particular, tenants with short-term contracts should be less likely to cultivate trees. PREDICTION 1: TENANTS’ WEALTH AND TREE CULTIVATION. To establish whether poorer tenants are less likely to cultivate trees, in line with the predictions of moral hazard models with risk aversion or limited liability, the effect of wealth is permitted to differ for owners and tenants in equation (3). The effect of wealth is positive and signi�cant for owner-cultivators and negative and not signi�cant for tenants (table 6, column 1).8 That wealth affects crop choice for owner-cultivators is consistent with the notion that moral hazard generates credit constraints, but the result might also reflect unobservable farmer characteristics that drive both wealth and the decision to grow trees, such as entrepreneurship.9 Identifying the precise mech- anism through which owners’ wealth affects tree cultivation is beyond the scope of this article, however. That wealth is not a signi�cant determinant of crop choice in rented plots, in contrast, goes against the predictions of moral hazard models with risk aver- sion or limited liability, suggesting that low-powered effort incentives are not the binding constraint in this setting. A possible concern is that the coef�cient of wealth is biased toward zero because of endogenous matching of tenants and soil types.10 The argument runs as follows. Assume that poorer tenants are more risk adverse and there- fore have a strong preference for land of higher quality if this is also less risky. If, at the same time, land of higher quality is better suited for trees, no relation- ship would be observed between tree cultivation and wealth because poor tenants who farm the right type of land cannot afford tree cultivation while richer tenants who can afford tree cultivation do not farm land that is suitable for trees. However, the �ndings indicate that wealth is a signi�cant determinant of tree cultivation for owner-cultivators, suggesting that if matching takes place at all it has a substantially different impact according to ownership status, which is implausible. As noted, owner-cultivators have a higher average wealth with a higher var- iance than tenants (see table 1). Another possible concern is that wealth does 8. There are not enough farmers who cultivate both an owned and a rented plot to estimate the interaction between wealth and ownership status with farmers’ �xed effects. 9. Results from the questionnaire show that only 20 percent of owner-cultivators are currently in debt. About 20 percent of nonborrowing farmers do not borrow because they do not need or do not want to. The rest state that they wanted to borrow but could not, because they thought they would be rejected, because loans are too expensive, or because there are no lenders in the community. Results from the Rural Census (2001) exhibit a similar pattern: only 24 percent of the 200,000 farmers interviewed asked for credit in 2001. Of those who asked, more than a third (37 percent) were turned down. 10. For a detailed analysis of endogenous matching and tenancy see Ackeberg and Botticini (2002). Bandiera 505 T A B L E 6 . Empirical Predictions of Moral Hazard Models: Linear Probability Model (dependent variable, tree_mix) (1) (2) Variable All Tenants Farmer owns plot 0.111*** (0.033) Owner*household wealth *126 0.131** (0.068) Tenant*household wealth *1026 2 0.541 1.01 (0.584) (0.967) Farmer’s age 0.002** 0.003 (0.001) (0.002) Farmer’s gender 0.024 0.186* (0.054) (0.107) Farmer’s education (years) 0.009* 0.004 (0.005) (0.010) Household size 0.011** 0.011 (0.005) (0.008) Farm size*1023 2 0.005*** 2 0.002* (0.002) (0.001) Town size 0.351 0.203 (0.223) (0.332) Average distance to market-town 2 0.064*** 2 0.080*** (0.016) (0.029) Number of years farming the same 2 0.005 plot (0.004) Contract length: two years 0.223*** (0.067) Contract length: three years 0.268*** (0.079) Contract length: more than three 0.351*** years (0.087) Contract type: sharecropping 0.097 (0.118) Province �xed effects Yes Yes Number of observations 1172 397 R2 0.4744 0.1870 *Signi�cant at the 10 percent level; **Signi�cant at the 5 percent level; ***Signi�cant at the 1 percent level. Note: Numbers in parentheses are standard errors based on White’s robust “sandwich� esti- mator for the asymptotic covariance matrix. The residual category for contract length is one year. Contract type ¼ one if the landlord gets a share of the produce (sharecropping) and zero other- wise (�xed rent). Source: Author’s analysis based on data from the 1998 Nicaragua Living Standards Measurement Study survey. 506 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW not exhibit suf�cient variation in the tenant sample compared with the owner sample, which makes the coef�cient estimates less precise and so makes it harder to reject the null. Standard measures of dispersion, however, take similar values in the two samples; the coef�cient of variation is 2.4 for tenants and 2.7 for owners. To investigate whether the wealth coef�cient is biased toward zero because the relationship between wealth and tree cultivation is assumed to be linear, the relationship is estimated nonparametrically for both owners and tenants. The nonparametric estimates, not reported for reasons of space, show that for the sample of tenants the effect of wealth on the probability of tree cultivation is not signi�cantly different from zero. In contrast, the relationship between tree culti- vation and wealth is positive for owner-cultivators, and linearity cannot be rejected. PREDICTION 2: CONTRACT DURATION AND TREE CULTIVATION. To assess the import- ance of noncontractible investment, for instance in tree maintenance, the effect of contract duration on the probability of tenants cultivating trees is estimated. While the relevant variable for investment incentives is the expectation of being able to appropriate future returns—and hence the future duration of the contract—this might be correlated with the duration of previous contracts and hence capture plot-speci�c skills that the farmer might have accumulated in the past. To address this issue, the speci�cation also controls for the number of years the farmer has been cultivating the same plot. Finally, the speci�cation also controls for the type of tenancy contract, whether sharecropping or �xed rent. The results indicate that the duration of the tenancy agreement is strongly correlated with tree cultivation: tenants who are employed on contracts longer than one year are more likely to grow trees (see table 6, column 2). The esti- mated effect of contract duration is large, with the coef�cients implying that moving from a one-year contract to a more than three-year contract increases the probability of cultivating trees by 80 percent. It is the length of the contract not the duration of the relationship that matters. Tenants who have been farming the same plot longer than other tenants are not more likely to grow trees if they are employed on short-term contracts. Finally, the type of tenancy contract (sharecropping or �xed rent) is not correlated with tree cultivation. This suggests that in line with the previous �ndings on wealth, the duration of the agreement is the only binding con- straint. Since both contract duration and crop type might be chosen simul- taneously by the landlord, the coef�cient of contract length should be interpreted as a correlation with tree cultivation rather than as a causal effect. What is surprising is that long-term contracts are so rare: 60 percent of con- tracts are one year long, 20 percent are two years long, and only 6 percent last longer than �ve years. It may be that most landlords cannot credibly commit to a long-term contract, perhaps because courts are unable to enforce them or Bandiera 507 because the contracts are too complex, possibly requiring history-dependent payments. Alternatively, landlords might simply be unwilling to commit to long-term contracts. Although quantitative evidence is unavailable, it could be that Nicaraguan landlords are unwilling to commit to long-term contracts for fear of granting too many rights to tenants. In 1981, rented land was redistributed from large landowners to tenants and landless peasants, and the Constitution (Titulo VI, Cap. II) and reform laws favor small owner-cultivators and make the eviction of long-term tenants dif�cult. I V. C O N C L U S I O N S This analysis of cultivation techniques by Nicaraguan farmers indicates that owner-cultivators are more likely than tenants to grow trees, an effect that seems to derive from ownership status rather than from unobservable farmer characteristics. The effect is due not to risk aversion or limited liability but to the fact that long-term agreements, necessary to provide incentives for noncon- tractible maintenance investment in tree cultivation, are rare. The results suggest scope for further investigation of the effect of ownership status on other types of contractible techniques and �xed investments. While immobile investments such as irrigation and farm equipment in this setting are rare, the few that exist are on owner-cultivated plots.11 The results have important implications for land policy, a core issue in most developing countries. First, encouraging the use of long-term contracts might lessen the bias against tree cultivation and other long-term investments on rented farms. Operation Barga tenancy reform, implemented in West Bengal in the late 1970s, provides a somewhat extreme example. The reform gave all registered tenants the right to cultivate their plots inde�nitely, provided they gave 25 percent of their annual output to the landlord. Operation Barga had a large positive impact on agricultural productivity (Banerjee, Gertler, and Ghatak 2002). Second, the success of a redistributive land policy depends crucially on the identity of the bene�ciaries. In this sample, poor owners are as unlikely as poor tenants to grow trees, while the effect of ownership status is strong for weal- thier farmers. Whether this is a pure wealth effect whose impact could there- fore be undone by a transfer of resources to the poorest farmers, or whether wealth proxies for unobservable farmer characteristics cannot be identi�ed from the data used in this study. The issue is of fundamental importance for 11. With the same speci�cation as in table 3, analysis shows some evidence that owner-cultivators are more likely to have immobile equipment such as irrigation systems, silos, and barns, while ownership does not affect mobile capital such as water pumps, trucks, and horse carts. Since immobile investments are rare in this setting, the nature of the data precludes further analysis along these lines. 508 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW evaluating the impact of land redistribution and is left as an open question for future research. REFERENCES Abadie, Alberto, and Guido. Imbens 2004. Large Sample Properties of Matching Estimators for Average Treatment Effects. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University, Kennedy School of Government. Ackeberg, Dan, and Maristella Botticini. 2002. “Endogenous Matching and the Empirical Determinants of Contract Form.� Journal of Political Economy 110(3):564– 91. Asamblea Nacional de la Republica de Nicaragua, Ley 209, La Gaceta 227, 1 December 1995; Ley 278, La Gaceta 239, 16 December 1996. Decreto 11-90, La Gaceta 98, 23 May 1990. Banerjee, Abhijit. 1999. “Land Reforms: Prospects and Strategies.� Working Paper 99/24. Cambridge, Mass: Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Department of Economics. Banerjee, Abhijit, Paul Gertler, and Maitreesh Ghatak. 2002. “Empowerment and Ef�ciency: Tenancy Reform in West Bengal.� Journal of Political Economy 110(2):239–80. Besley, Timothy. 1995. “Property Rights and Investment Incentives: Theory and Evidence from Ghana.� Journal of Political Economy 103(5):903 – 37. Binswanger, Hans. 1980. “Attitude toward Risk: Experimental Measurement in Rural India.� American Journal of Agricultural Economics 62(3):395 –407. Binswanger, Hans, Klaus Deininger, and Gershon. Feder 1995. “Power, Distortions, Revolt, and Reform in Agricultural Land Relations.� In J. Behrman, and T.N. Srinivasan, eds. Handbook of Development Economics. Vol. 3B. Amsterdam, North-Holland. Braverman, Avishay, and Joseph Stiglitz. 1986. “Landlords, Tenants, and Technological Innovations.� Journal of Development Economics 23(2):313 – 32. Current, Dean, Ernst Lutz, and Sara. Scherr 1995. “Costs, Bene�ts, and Farmer Adoption of Agroforestry: Project Experience in Central America and the Caribbean.� Environment Paper 14. World Bank, Washington, D.C. FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization). FAOSTAT database. Rome. (http://faostat.fao.org/site/336/ default.aspx). Hausman, Jerry, Jason Abrevaya, and F.M. Scott-Morton 1998. “Misclassi�cation of the Dependent Variable in a Discrete-Response Setting.� Journal of Econometrics 87(2):239–69. Junta De Gobierno De Reconstruccion Nacional, Decreto 782, Published in La Gaceta 188, 21 August 1982. Masters, William, and Margaret McMillan. 2003. “An African Growth Trap: Production Technology and the Time-Consistency of Agricultural Taxation, R&D, and Investment.� Review of Development Economics 7(2):179–91. Mookherjee, Dilip. 1997. “Informational Rents and Property Rights in Land.� In J. Roemer, ed. Property Rights, Incentives and Welfare. New York: MacMillan Press. Shaban, Radwan. 1987. “Testing between Competing Models of Sharecropping.� Journal of Political Economy 95(5):893–920. Shetty, Sudhir. 1988. “Limited Liability, Wealth Differences, and the Tenancy Ladder in Agrarian Economies.� Journal of Development Economics 9(1):1– 22. Stiglitz, Joseph. 1974. “Incentives and Risk Sharing in Sharecropping.� Review of Economic Studies 41(2):219–55. World Bank. World Development Indicators. Various years. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. Yatchew, Adonis, and Zvi. Griliches 1985. “Speci�cation Error in Probit Models.� Review of Economics and Statistics 67(1):134– 39.