WPS7695 Policy Research Working Paper 7695 Non-Renewable Resources, Fiscal Rules, and Human Capital Paul Levine Giovanni Melina Harun Onder Finance and Markets Global Practice Group June 2016 Policy Research Working Paper 7695 Abstract This paper develops a multi-sector, small open economy investment between infrastructure, education, and health. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium model, which The model is applied to Kenya. For impacts on the non- includes the accumulation of human capital, built via public resource economy, efficiency of spending, and sustainability expenditures in education and health. Four possible fiscal of fiscal outcomes, the analysis finds that, although invest- rules are examined for total public investment in infrastruc- ment frontloading would bring high growth in the short ture, education, and health in the context of a sustainable term, the permanent income hypothesis approach is overall resource fund: the spend-as-you-go, bird-in-hand spending; more desirable when fiscal sustainability concerns are taken moderate front-loading, and permanent income hypothesis into consideration. Finally, a balanced composition is the approaches. There are two dimensions to this exercise: the preferred structure of investment, given the permanent scaling effect, which describes the level of total investment, income hypothesis allocation of total investment over time. and the composition effect, which defines the structure of This paper is a product of the Finance and Markets Global Practice Group. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted at honder@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team Non-Renewable Resources, Fiscal Rules, and Human Capital∗ Paul Levine† Giovanni Melina‡ Harun Onder§ June 4, 2016 JEL Codes : Q32; E22; E62; F34 Keywords : Natural Resources, Public investment, Human Capital, Debt Sustainability, Developing countries, DSGE ∗ This paper was prepared as a background note to the World Bank Country Economic Memorandum (CEM) for Kenya “From Economic Growth to Jobs and Shared Prosperity”. Giovanni Melina acknowledges the support from U.K.’s Department for International Development (DFID) under the project Macroeco- nomic Research in Low-Income Countries, with project ID number 60925. We are grateful to Diarietou Gaye, Albert Zeufack, Apurva Sanghi, Alan Gelb, Auguste Kouame, Havard Halland, Borko Handjiski, and Jane Bodoev for useful comments and suggestions to the version of this paper that appeared in the CEM. All remaining errors are ours. † School of Economics, University of Surrey, Guildford, Surrey GU2 5XH, United Kingdom. E-mail: p.levine@surrey.ac.uk. ‡ International Monetary Fund, 700 19th Street N.W., Washington, D.C. 20431, United States; and Department of Economics, City University London, UK. E-mail: gmelina@imf.org. § Macroeconomics and Fiscal Management Global Practice, World Bank, 1818 H Street, N.W., Wash- ington, DC 20433. E-mail: honder@worldbank.org. 1 Introduction There is growing emphasis on investing oil revenues domestically in oil-rich countries. During the oil price boom in 2000s, many oil rich countries began to break away from their traditional investment strategies, which focused on channeling the money back into financial systems of the advanced economies, and undertook ambitious domestic invest- ment programs.1 Despite the sharp decline in oil prices in recent years, the trend towards domestic investments seems to have gained momentum with anemic recovery and ever increasing economic and financial uncertanties in the advanced markets. For instance, the officials in the Kingdom of Saudi Arabia have recently announced publicly selling shares of the state oil giant, Saudi Aramco, and routing much of its worth, an estimated $ 2 trillion, into a public investment fund.2 With persistently low interest rates in the aftermath of the global financial crisis, it may seem obvious that some of those domestic projects which were deemed not desirable before may become attractive. Notwithstanding the immediate appeal of such arguments, however, is the fact that policy makers, who are to act on behalf of all constituents in their jurisdictions, typically operate with complex objectives. Successful implementation of public investments are bounded with both the availability of projects with good re- turns and the capacity of authorities to manage them.3 In addition, fiscal solvency and sustainability constraints may prevent governments from incurring large deficits and ac- cumulating excessive public debt. Last, but not least, policy makers are also concerned with the distribution of wealth across generations. Thus, facing different implementation constraints, resource horizons, and initial conditions, the desired scale and pace of such investments may be determined differently across different economies. In this paper, we compare alternative public investment paths in terms of their impact on growth in the non-oil sector and fiscal outcomes. Central to the conduct of fiscal policy is a resource fund that receives inflows from revenue from the taxation of oil profits and interest payments from the accumulation of assets. Public investment is part of the 1 See Abdelal et al. (2008) for an analysis of this shift in investment strategies in the context of the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC). 2 See http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2016-04-01/saudi-arabia-plans-2-trillion-megafund-to- dwarf-all-its-rivals 3 See Albino-War et al. (2014) for an analysis on the importance of public investment management in oil-rich countries. 2 outflow from the fund. Then our aim is to answer the following questions for a sizeable oil discovery in a small economy that adds to the fund: • What are the desired scale and pace of public investments over time? • How should public investments be allocated over physical and human capital? In order to answer these questions, we develop a multi-sector, small open economy Dy- namic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model that is based on Melina et al. (2016). We add to the latter, on the one hand, the accumulation of human capital, built via public expenditures in education and health expenditures; and, on the other, a richer array of fiscal options as far as the usage of natural resource revenues is concerned. These include Permanent Income (PIH) and Bird-in-Hand (BIH) based rules. The model characterizes multiple types of public sector debt, multiple tax and spending variables, and a resource fund. The country produces a composite of traded goods and a nontraded goods using capital, labor, and its productivity is affected by government- supplied infrastructure, health and education. It is also endowed with natural resources, the production and prices of which are assumed to be exogenous. Since the time horizon is 20+ years, the model abstracts from money and all nominal rigidities.4 The model has a number of important features specific to LIDCs. These are finan- cially constrained households who do not have access to capital and financial markets and consume all of their disposable income each period; remittances received by households; a productivity effect of health and education; investment adjustment costs; international grants received by the government; public investment inefficiencies and absorptive capac- ity constraints, and finally a resource fund. It includes also standard distortionary taxes and investment adjustment costs. We calibrate our model by using the available data from Kenya, which discovered an estimated 600 million barrels of oil in 2012 and is expected to start commercial production in the early 2020s. Although the proven reserves are relatively small in comparison to other oil producers, the revenues generated from them, which could reach 16 percent of GDP annually at peak, are likely to be significant for the Government of Kenya. 4 The nominal side and New Keynesian features may be added if the model is used to study the short-run policy effects of fiscal management to resource revenue flows. 3 Overall, our analysis suggests that the permanent income hypothesis approach best suits the characteristics of Kenya’s economy. The most relevant criteria for Kenya in de- ciding on the optimal approach are the impacts on the non-resource economy, efficiency of spending, and sustainability of fiscal outcomes. The simulations show that spending resource revenues as they become available is wasteful and incapable of delivering a better result than other approaches in promoting non-resource growth and sustainability in fiscal balances. Moreover, this approach is most likely to trigger Dutch disease symptoms in the medium term. In contrast, saving all the revenues (as in the BIH approach) is too strin- gent. Although this approach helps to build large quantities of fiscal buffers, it falls short of boosting the non-resource economy with much needed investments in infrastructure, education, and health. In comparison, the PIH and MF approaches facilitate non-resource growth; however, the PIH approach performs much better in fiscal outcomes. Similarly, a balanced investment composition is expected to deliver the best long- term development results in Kenya. The simulations in this section show that a BC investment approach brings the highest boost to non-resource GDP and leads to favorable fiscal outcomes. This outcome is derived from the economic principle of diminishing returns to investment, which is especially true when there are implementation constraints. Therefore, even if investments in physical capital are scaled up rapidly, in the absence of accompanying improvements in public investment efficiency and matching buildup of private and human capital, resources are likely to be wasted. This paper contributes to a growing literature on managing resource revenues for de- veloping countries. This has evolved from advising to save most of a resource windfall in a sovereign wealth fund (e.g., Davis et al., 2001; Barnett and Ossowski, 2003; Bems and de Carvalho Filho, 2011), to recommending to invest the windfall to build productive cap- ital (e.g., van der Ploeg, 2010; Venables, 2010; van der Ploeg and Venables, 2011; Araujo et al., 2013). DIGNAR encompasses many of the issues at stake in resource abundant countries by combining the models developed in Buffie et al. (2012) and Berg et al. (2013) into a suitable framework for assessing debt sustainability and growth benefits of public investment surges. DIGNAR, however, does not allow to make the distinction between enor and Nganou (2013) physical and human capital, which we make in this paper. Ag´ consider different forms of physical and human capital in an overlapping generations frame- 4 work for Uganda; however, their analysis is concerned with steady state results and does not investigate dynamic aspects of the problem. The paper continues as follows. The next section introduces the building blocks of a small open economy that lies at the foundation of the model. The third section adds the characteristics of natural resource finds in a low income country. The fourth section describes the fiscal approaches we use in simulations. The fifth section summarizes the simulation results for Kenya, and the final section provides concluding comments. 2 The core small open economy model For the sake of exposition, in this section we present a simplified core small open economy model featuring public investment in physical and human capital, abstracting from dis- tortionary taxes and a number of frictions and additional features that instead we present in Section 3. 2.1 Households Households consume a consumption basket ct , which is defined as a constant-elasticity-of- substitution (CES) function of traded goods, cT,t , and nontraded goods, cN,t . Thus, the consumption basket is χ 1 χ−1 1 χ−1 χ−1 ct = ϕ (cN,t ) χ χ + (1 − ϕ) (cT,t ) χ χ , (1) where 1 − ϕ indicates the degree of trade openness. The consumption basket is the numeraire of the economy; pN,t represents the relative price of non-traded goods, and pT,t is the relative price of traded goods to the consumption basket. Assuming that the law of one price holds for traded goods implies that pT,t also corresponds to the real exchange rate, defined as the price of one unit of foreign consumption basket in units of the domestic basket. The unit price of the consumption basket therefore is 1 −χ 1−χ 1 = ϕp1 1−χ N + (1 − ϕ) pT,t . (2) 5 The representative household maximizes its inter-temporal utility at time t ∞ Et s β t+s U ct+s , lt+s , (3) s=0 s }, subject to the following budget constraint, with respect to {ct+s }, {lt+s ct + bt + pT,t b∗ s ∗ ∗ ∗ t = wt lt + Rt−1 bt−1 + pT,t Rt−1 bt−1 − Θ(bt , bt ) + exogenous income, (4) where Et is the rational expectation operator at time t, β is the subjective discount factor s is labor supply. Households have access to government bonds b that pay a gross and lt t real interest rate Rt , hold net foreign assets b∗ ∗ t that pay a gross real interest rate Rt , and are remunerated for their labor services at the wage rate wt . To prevent b∗ t from being a unit-root process we introduce Θt ≡ η (b∗ ∗ 2 2 t − b ) , which are portfolio adjustment costs associated to foreign liabilities, where η controls the degree of capital account openness and b∗ is the initial steady-state value of private foreign debt.5 Households also receive exogenous income in the form of profits from firms in the traded and non-traded goods sectors and a lump-sum transfer from the government (which can be negative). There are no distortionary taxes at this stage of the modeling. First order conditions for households are: ct cN,t = ϕ , (5) (pN,t )χ ct cT,t = (1 − ϕ) , (6) (pT,t )χ βRt ∗ uc,t = βRt Et uc,t+1 = Et st+1 , (7) pT,t − η (b∗ ∗ t −b ) ul,t wt = − . (8) uc,t 2.2 Firms The economy has three production sectors: (i) a non-traded good sector indexed by N , producing output yN,t ; (ii) a (non-resource) traded good sector indexed by T , producing output yT,t ; and (iii) a natural resource sector indexed by O, producing output yO,t . Since 5 These adjustment costs also ensure stationarity in this small open economy model, as discussed in e and Uribe (2003). Schmitt-Groh´ 6 resource-rich developing countries tend to export most of the resource output, for simplicity we assume that this is exported in its entirety. Total real GDP yt in the economy is yt = pN,t yN,t + pT,t yT,t + pT,t yO,t . (9) 2.2.1 Non-traded and traded goods sectors In both sectors N and T , a representative firm produce output yN,t and yT,t with the following Cobb-Douglas technology, yj,t = zj (Aj,t lj,t )αj (kj,t−1 )1−αj (kG,t−1 )αG , j = N, T (10) where zj is a total factor productivity parameter, Aj,t is labor productivity, lj,t is the labor input, kj,t is end-of-period private capital, kG,t is end-of-period public capital, αj is the labor share of income, and αG is the output elasticity to public capital. Labor productivity, Aj,t , is in turn given by β β Aj,t = zj,a et j,E ht j,H , (11) where zj,a is a scaling parameter, et represents the average education of the labor force, ht represents the average health status of the labor force, while βj,E and βj,H are the elasticities of labor productivity to education and health, respectively. Both education and health, which are inputs to all sectors, are provided by the govern- ment, and the relationship between government expenditures and education and health outcomes are given by E et = (1 − δE ) et−1 + (γ E gt−jE ) ψE , (12) and H ht = (1 − δH ) ht−1 + (γ H gt−jH ) ψH , (13) E and g H are public education and health expenditures, δ and δ where gt t E H are the re- spective depreciation rates, γ E ∈ [0, 1] and γ H ∈ [0, 1] are the respective efficiencies, and ψ E ∈ [0, 1] and ψ H ∈ [0, 1] are concavity parameters capturing absorptive capacity constraints. Time-to-build lags are accounted for when setting jE > 1 and jH > 1. 7 Private capital evolves as kj,t = (1 − δj ) kj,t−1 + ij,t , j = N, T, (14) where ij,t represents investment expenditure, δj is private capital depreciation in sector j , and there are no investment adjustment costs. Aggregate private investment is then given by χ 1 χ−1 1 χ−1 χ−1 it = ϕ (iN,t ) χ χ + (1 − ϕ) (iT,t ) χ χ . (15) The representative firm maximizes its discounted lifetime profits weighted by the marginal utility of consumption of households λt . These profits are given by ∞ Ωj,t = Et β t+s λt+s [pj,t+s yj,t+s − wj,t+s lj,t+s − ij,t ] , j = N, T. (16) s=0 First order conditions are: αj pj,t yj,t wt = d ; j = N, T, (17) lj,t Et Rkj ,t+1 = Rt ; j = N, T, (18) (1 − αj )pj,t yj,t = Rkj ,t − 1 + δj ; j = N, T, (19) kj,t and as for consumption goods, it iN,t = ϕ , (20) (pN,t )χ it iT,t = (1 − ϕ) . (21) (pT,t )χ 2.2.2 Natural resource sector Since often most natural resource production in resource-rich developing countries is cap- ital intensive, and much of the investment in the resource sector is financed by foreign direct investment, natural resource production is simplified in the model as follows. The value of resource production (in terms of the foreign consumption basket), yO,t , follows an exogenous path. Each period, the government receives a constant fraction τ O of gross 8 revenues, capturing royalties and other taxes, tO,t = τ O pT,t yO,t . (22) Zero profits are assumed in the natural resource sector. 2.3 Government The core model abstracts from government consumption and hence government purchases, I , education g E and health g H . Like gt are all for public investment in physical capital, gt t t private consumption, government investment is also a CES aggregate of domestic traded goods, gT,t and domestic non-traded goods, gN,t . Thus, χ 1 χ−1 1 χ−1 χ−1 χ gt = ϕI (gN,t ) χ + (1 − ϕI ) (gT,t ) χ χ . (23) As for consumption and investment goods we then have gt gN,t = ϕI (24) (pN,t )χ gt gT,t = (1 − ϕI ) (25) (pT,t )χ Public capital accumulation evolves as equation as I kG,t = (1 − δG ) kG,t−1 + gt , (26) where δG is the depreciation rate of public capital. The government flow budget constraint is given by bt = Rt−1 bt−1 + pG t gt − tO,t (27) where I E H gt = gt + gt + gt (28) 9 and pG t is the government spending price index, 1 1−χ 1−χ 1−χ pG t = ϕpN,t + (1 − ϕ) pT,t . (29) The levels of public education, health and physical capital expenditures are set as fractions of total government investment, E gt = φE t gt , (30) H gt = φH t gt , (31) I gt = 1 − φH E t − φt gt , (32) with  φE  for t = 0, init φE t = (33) φE  for t > 0, new  φH  for t = 0, init φH t = (34) φH  for t > 0, new where fractions φE H init , φinit ∈ [0, 1] are the observed fractions at the initial steady state, and φE H new , φnew ∈ [0, 1] are policy parameters that determine the allocation of the public investment scaling up among education, health and physical capital expenditures. The path for total investment gt is set according to one of the fiscal regimes described in Section 4. 2.4 Identities and market clearing conditions To close the model, the goods market clearing condition and the balance of payment condition are imposed. The market clearing condition for non-traded goods is yN,t = cN,t + iN,t + gN,t , (35) The balance of payment condition corresponds to cat = ∆b∗ t, (36) pT,t 10 where cat is the current account surplus, ∗ ∗ cat = yt − ct − it − gt + Rt−1 − 1 pT,t bt−1 . (37) where tbt = yt − ct − it − gt is the trade balance. The labor market equilibrium implies that d d s lN,t + lT,t = lt . (38) To complete the solution for numerical computation we choose a standard household utility function 1 1−σ κ u (ct , lt ) = ct − (ls )1+ψ (39) 1−σ 1+ψ t where σ is the inverse of the inter-temporal elasticity of substitution of consumption, ψ is the inverse of the inter-temporal elasticity of substitution of the labor supply and κ is the disutility weight of labor. Then uc = c− t σ (40) s ψ ul = −κ(lt ) (41) 3 Additional features Following Melina et al. (2016) we enrich the core model by adding model features particu- larly relevant for LIDC. Three of these – distortionary taxes, credit-constrained consumers and investment adjustment costs – are now very common in DSGE models and we refer the reader to Melina et al. (2016) or similar papers for details. The remaining features are less standard, hence we report them in turn. 3.1 Public investment efficiency and absorptive capacity constraints Public investment features inefficiency and absorptive capacity constraints. Hulten (1996) and Pritchett (2000) argue that often high productivity of infrastructure can coexist with very low returns on public investment in developing countries, because of inefficiencies in investing. As a result, public investment spending does not necessarily increase the stock 11 of productive capital and, therefore, growth. Similarly, absorptive capacity constraints related to technical capacity and waste and leakage of resources in the investment process— which impact project selection, management, and implementation—can have long lasting negative effects on growth, as suggested by Esfahani and Ramirez (2003), among others. To reflect these inefficiencies and constraints, we assume that effective investment I γ GI is a function of the public investment growth rate (γ GI ) relative to its steady gt t t I gt state value, and γ GI t ≡ gI − 1. Specifically,    I, gt if γ GI ≤ γ GI  I t gt = , (42)  ¯I + 1 + γ GI g γ GI t 1 + γ GI t −γ ¯I , if γ GI GI g t >γ GI  where ∈ [0, 1] represents steady-state efficiency and γ GI t ∈ (0, 1] governs the efficiency of the portion of public investment exceeding a threshold γ GI , in percent deviation from the initial steady state. We assume that γ GI t takes the following specification: γ GI t = exp −ς γ GI t −γ GI . (43) In other words, if the growth rate of government investment expenditure from the initial steady state exceeds γ GI , then the efficiency of the additional investment decreases, re- flecting the presence of absorptive capacity constraints. The severity of these constraints is governed by the parameter ς ∈ [0, ∞). The law of motion of public capital is described as I kG,t = (1 − δG,t ) kG,t−1 + gt , (44) where δG,t is a time-varying depreciation rate of public capital in the spirit of Rioja (2003). Since insufficient maintenance can shorten the life of existing capital, we assume that the depreciation rate increases proportionally to the extent to which effective investment fails 12 to maintain existing capital.6 Therefore   δG kG,t−1 I <δ k  φδG I gt , if gt G G,t−1  δG,t = , (45) I δ G,t−1 + (1 − ρδ ) δG , if gt ≥ δG kG,t−1  ρ δ  where δG is the steady-state depreciation rate, φ ≥ 0 determines the extent to which poor maintenance produces additional depreciation, and ρδ ∈ [0, 1) controls its persistence.7 3.2 The resource fund and the fiscal gap Central to fiscal policy is the resource fund which we model along the lines of Berg et al. (2013). A resource windfall is defined as resource revenues that are above their initial steady-state level, i.e., tO O ∗ t − t . Let ft be the foreign financial asset value in a resource fund and f ∗ be its initial steady state. Each period, the resource fund earns interest income pT,t Rrf − 1 ft∗ rf −1 , with a constant gross foreign real interest rate R . The resource fund evolves by the process fin,t fout,t ft∗ − f ∗ = max ff loor − f ∗ , ft∗ −1 − f ∗ + − , (46) pT,t pT,t where fin,t represents the total fiscal inflow, fout,t represents the total fiscal outflow, and ff loor ≥ 0 is a lower bound for the fund that the government chooses to maintain. If no minimum savings are required in a resource fund, the lower bound can be set at zero. At each point in time, if the fiscal inflow exceeds the fiscal outflow, the value of the resource fund increases. Instead, if the resource fund is above ff loor , any fiscal outflow that exceeds the fiscal inflow is absorbed by a withdrawal from the fund. Whenever the floor of a resource fund binds, the fiscal gap is covered via borrowing and/or increases in taxes (on consumption and factor incomes) or cuts in government non-capital expenditures (government consumption and transfers). 6 Adam and Bevan (2014) find that accounting for the operations and maintenance expenditures of installed capital is crucial for assessing the growth effects and debt sustainability of a public investment scaling-up. 7 Rioja (2003) separates investment expenditures between those for new projects and those for main- tenance, and the depreciation rate is correlated positively with private capital to capture the intensity of public capital usage and negatively with maintenance expenditures. 13 The fiscal inflow and outflow are given by fin,t = tO,t + pT,t Rrf − 1 ft∗ −1 + tax revenues and international grants (47) fout,t = pG t gt + interest rate payments on borrowing (48) where resource revenues tO,t = τ O pT yO,t , where yO,t and τ O are oil production and the royalty tax rate follow exogenous paths discussed below. Then the the fiscal gap is given by gapt = fout,t − fin,t + pT,t ft∗ − ft∗ −1 , (49) Covering the fiscal gap then requires a combination of borrowing and adjustments to gov- ernment spending and tax rates. Apart from the two components of government invest- I and g E , considered later, the latter respond to the fiscal gap so that government ment, gt t debt is placed on a stable sustainable path.8 4 Four fiscal regimes One of the purposes of the model is to analyze the effects of investing a resource windfall. The simulations presented in this paper focus on four investing approaches: spend-as-you- go (SAYG), bird-in-hand spending (BIH); moderate front-loading (MF) and permanent income hypothesis (PIH). These approaches are formulated as follows. • Spend-as-you-go (SAYG). With spend-as-you-go, the resource fund stays at its initial level (ft∗ = f ∗ , ∀t), and the entire windfall is spent in public investment projects: tO t tO pG G t gt − p g = − . (50) pT,t s • Bird-in-hand spending (BIH). With bird-in-hand, only the interest earned is spent: pG G t gt − p g = pT,t R rf − 1 ft∗ −1 (51) • Moderate frontloading (MF). With moderate frontloading, investment is delinked 8 See the Appendix and Melina et al. (2016) for full details of the fiscal rules. In addition to these, to guarantee that the resource fund is not an explosive process, we assume that in the very long run, a small ∗ ∗ autoregressive coefficient ρf ∈ (0, 1) is attached to (ft −1 − f ). 14 from the resource fund. Then a scaling-up path of public investment is specified as a second-order delay function, gt = 1 + [1 + exp (−k1 t) − 2 exp (−k2 t)] gnss , (52) g where gnss is the scaling-up investment target expressed as percentage deviation from the initial steady state, k1 > 0 represents the speed of adjustment of pub- lic investment to the new level, and k2 ≥ k1 represents the degree of investment frontloading.9 In particular, if k1 = k2 = 0, public investment stays at its original steady-state level, i.e., gt = g ∀t. • Permanent income hypothesis (PIH). This approach is arrived at by letting k1 , k2 → ∞ and setting gnss according to the PIH annuity as shown in Section 5. Then public investment jumps to the new steady-state level immediately. 5 Policy scenarios: application to Kenya A series of commercial oil explorations in Northern Kenya have recently boosted prospects for Kenya’s upstream oil industry. Discovered reserves estimated at 600 million barrels were announced in February 2014, and follow up explorations and appraisals have further de-risked the discovered resources. In addition, several companies have acquired blocks and are drilling (or planning to drill) both onshore and offshore. It will take several years before Kenya’s oil and gas reserves have been assessed and the current slump in oil prices does not accelerate this process; nevertheless, the authorities are already considering the policy and development implications of this discovery. In global terms, Kenya’s discovered resources are relatively small. Kenya’s 600 million barrel stock puts Kenya at 47th position worldwide in terms of oil reserves, just ahead of Uzbekistan. This quantity constitutes a small fraction of the reserves in resource rich African countries like Libya, Nigeria, Angola and Algeria, both in terms of absolute and per capita amounts. For comparison, Saudi Arabia produced about 11.5 million barrels 9 Differentiating (52) it can be shown that for k2 > k1 , gt reaches a maximum at time tmax = 1 k2 −k1 log( 2 k2 k1 ) and that tmax is a decreasing function of k2 k1 . Thus as k2 increases the investment path be- comes more front-loaded. In principle k1 and k2 can be chosen to be optimal in relation to a policymaker’s objectives. This aspect is left for future research. 15 of oil per day in 2012. With this speed of production, Kenya’s reserves would be depleted only in 52 days. In practice, however, the production in Kenya will be spread over a broader time frame, which reflects the time required to develop the fields and optimize the costs of production. Hence, based on the current exploration results, oil production will not be substantial over decade’s period and is unlikely to provide a global market niche for Kenya to specialize. 5.1 Fiscal revenue projections Despite being small in global standards, oil and gas production is expected to have a non-negligible impact, especially on fiscal revenues. Kenya’s possible recoverable reserves could reach about 1.4 billion barrels of oil and 1.7 billion barrels oil equivalent of natural gas (PWC 2015). The most recent estimates show that oil production will start in 2022, and reach a plateau of about 77 million barrels a year soon after that (figure 5.2). Starting in 2032, production will decrease gradually, reflecting the maturing of existing fields. In comparison, the production of natural gas is estimated to start in 2025 and peak at 95 million barrels of oil equivalent per year in 2033. Calculating the fiscal revenues associated with these production profiles requires a detailed approach with information on cost profiles and the production agreements between the Government of Kenya and the producing companies. In the absence of such information, rough estimates, using World Bank oil price projections and general industry rules of thumb, show that Kenya’s fiscal revenues from oil production are projected to peak at about US$8.9 billion in 2033. This is roughly equivalent to 16 percent of Kenya’s 2013 gross domestic product (GDP). In light of these fiscal revenue projections, we next investigate the implications of alternative fiscal rule scenarios characterized in the previous section. 5.2 Calibration The full model, which is reported in the Appendix, is calibrated to Kenya at an annual frequency. Table 1 summarizes the baseline calibration, which is explained as follows.10 • National accounting. To reflect Kenya’s recent experience, the shares of exports and imports are set at 19 and 35 percent of GDP, respectively; government consumption 10 This section should be read in conjunction with the Appendix A. 16 Figure 1: Estimates for Oil Production and Fiscal Revenues (2015-2070) Volumes of Production Oil Prices and Fiscal Revenues 180 10 120 160 9 8 100 140 7 120 80 Billion USD 6 USD MBBoe/year 100 5 60 80 4 60 3 40 2 40 1 20 20 0 0 -1 0 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 Oil, MBBL/year Gas, MBBoe/year Fiscal Revenue Oil Prices (RHS) and public investment are set at 16 and 8.6 percent of GDP, respectively, and private investment is set at 13.7 percent of GDP. We choose the shares of traded goods to be 60 percent in private consumption and 40 percent in government purchases, as government consumption typically have a larger component of nontraded goods than private consumption. The share of natural resources is 40 percent of GDP at the initial steady state. • Assets, debt and grants. Government savings are 0 percent of GDP (RFshare = 0) at the initial steady state. For government domestic debt, concessional debt, grants, as well as private foreign debt and government external commercial debt we rely on World Bank data. This implies bshare = 0.268, dshare = 0.114, grshare = 0.01, b∗ share = 0 and dc,share = 0.063. • Interest rates. We set the subjective discount rate such that the real annual interest rate on domestic debt (R − 1) is 2.3 percent. Consistent with stylized facts, domestic debt is assumed to be more costly than external commercial debt. We fix the real annual risk-free interest rate (Rf − 1) at 1.13 percent. The premium parameter υdc is chosen such that the real interest rate on external commercial debt (Rdc − 1) is 7 percent, and the real interest rate paid on concessional loans (Rd − 1) is 1 percent. We assume no additional risk premium in the baseline calibration, implying ηdc = 0. The parameter u is chosen to have R = R∗ in the steady state. Based on the average 17 Parameter Value Definition Parameter Value Definition exp share 0.19 Exports to GDP ω 0.40 Measure of optimizers in the economy impshare 0.35 Imports to GDP χ 0.44 Substitution elasticity b/w traded/nontraded goods C gshare 0.16 Government consumption to GDP η 1 Elasticity of portfolio adjustment costs I gshare 0.086 Government investment to GDP τO - Royalty tax rate on natural resources ishare 0.137 Private investment to GDP f 0.50 User fees of public infrastructure yO,share 0.40 Natural resources to GDP τL 0.05 Labor income tax rate C gT ,share 0.40 Share of tradables in government purchase τ 0.10 Consumption tax rate cT ,share 0.60 Share of tradables in private consumption τK 0.20 Tax rate on the return on capital RFshare 0 Stabilization fund to GDP ff loor 0 Lower bound for the stabilization fund bshare 0.268 Government domestic debt to GDP κ 1 Adjustment share by external commercial debt b∗ share 0 Private foreign debt to GDP λ1 1 Adjustment share by consumption tax dshare 0.114 Concessional debt to GDP ζ1 0.5 Adjustment speed of consumption tax to target dc,share 0.063 Government external commercial debt/GDP ζ1 0.001 Adjustment speed of consumption tax to target C grshare 0.01 Grants to GDP τceiling +∞ Ceiling on consumption tax (R − 1) 0.023 Domestic net real interest rate ν 0.6 Home bias of government purchases RF R −1 0.027 Foreign net real interest rate on savings νg 0.4 Home bias for additional spending (Rd − 1) 0.01 Net real interest rate on concessional debt αG 0.12 Output elasticity to public capital Rf − 1 0.013 Net real risk-free rate δG 0.10 Depreciation rate of public capital Rdc,0 − 1 0.07 Net real interest rate on external commercial debt ¯ 0.50 Steady-state efficiency of public investment ηdc 0 Elasticity of sovereign risk k1 - Speed of scaling up plan αN 0.45 Labor income share in nontraded sector k2 - Degree of frontloading αT 0.60 Labor income share in traded sector ρδ 0.80 Persistence of depreciation rate of public capital δN 0.10 Depreciation rate of kN,t φ 1 Severity of public capital depreciation δT 0.10 Depreciation rate of kT ,t ς 50 Severity of absorptive capacity constraints ρyT 0.10 Learning by doing in traded sector ¯ GI γ 0.60 Thresholds of absorptive capacity constraints ρzT 0.10 Persistence in TFP in traded sector ψH , ψE 0.60 Concavity parameters in human capital investment κN 25 Investment adjustment cost, nontraded sector γH , γE 0.19 Efficiency of human capital investment κT 25 Investment adjustment cost, traded sector jE 5 Time to build lag for education stock ψ 10 Inverse of Frisch labor elasticity jH 1 Time to build lag for health status σ 2.94 Inverse of intertemporal elasticity of substitution E 0.1 Output elasticity to education investment ρ 1 Intratemporal substitution elasticity of labor H 0.03 Output elasticity to health investment Table 1: Baseline calibration real return of the Norwegian Government Pension Fund from 1997 to 2011 (Gros and Mayer, 2012), the annual real return on international financial assets in the resource fund (RRF − 1) is set at 2.7 percent. • Private production. Consistent with the evidence on Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) surveyed in Buffie et al. (2012), the labor income shares in the nontraded and traded good sectors correspond to αN = 0.45 and αT = 0.60. In both sectors private capital depreciates at an annual rate of 10 percent (δN = δT = 0.10). Following Berg et al. 18 (2013), we assume a minor degree of learning-by-doing externality in the traded good sector (ρYT = ρzT = 0.10). Also as in Berg et al. (2010), investment adjustment costs are set to κN = κT = 25. • Households preferences. The coefficient of risk aversion σ = 2.94 implies an inter- temporal elasticity of substitution of 0.34, which is the average LIC estimate accord- ing to Ogaki et al. (1996). We assume a low Frisch labor elasticity of 0.10 (ψ = 10), similar to the estimate of wage elasticity of working in rural Malawi - see Goldberg (2013). The labor mobility parameter ρ is set to 1 as in Horvath (2000), and the elasticity of substitution between traded and nontraded goods is χ = 0.44, follow- ing Stockman and Tesar (1995). To capture limited access to international capital markets, we set η = 1 as in Buffie et al. (2012). • Measure of intertemporal optimizing households. Since a large proportion of house- holds in LICs are liquidity constrained, we pick ω = 0.40, implying that 60 percent of households are rule-of-thumb. Depending on the degree of financial development of a country, the measure of intertemporal optimizing households can be lower than 40 percent in some SSA countries. Based on data collected in 2011, Demirguc-Kunt and Klapper (2012) report that on average only 24 percent of the adults in SSA countries have an account in a formal financial institution. • Mining. The royalty tax rate τ O is made time-varying to match the projections of natural resource revenues for Kenya in Subsection 5.1. • Tax rates. Consistently with data collected by the International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation in 2005-06, the steady-state taxes on consumption, labor and capital are chosen so that τ C = 0.10, τ L = 0.15, and τ K = 0.20, respectively. • Fiscal rules. In this application we use only the consumption tax rate as the instru- ment that stabilizes government debt. We impose a non-negativity constraint for the stabilization fund by setting ff loor = 0. In the baseline calibration, the fiscal C instrument does not have a ceiling. This translates in setting τceiling = 100, 000. The baseline calibration also implies that the whole fiscal adjustment takes place through changes in external commercial borrowing and consumption taxes. This is 19 achieved by setting κ = λ1 = 1. To smooth tax changes, we choose an intermediate adjustment of the consumption tax rate relative to its target (ζ1 = 0.5) and a low responsiveness of the consumption tax rate to the debt-to-GDP ratio (ζ2 = 0.001). The selection of values for these policy parameters should be guided by the policy scenario that the team wants to simulate as well as by what they consider feasible as a fiscal adjustment. • Public investment. Public investment efficiency is set to 50 percent (¯ = 0.5), follow- ing estimates in Pritchett (2000) for SSA countries. The annual depreciation rate for public capital is 10 percent (δ G = 0.10). The home bias for government purchases ν and for investment spending above the initial steady-state level ν g are 0.6 and 0.4, respectively. The smaller degree of home bias in additional spending reflects that most of the investment goods are imported in LICs. The output elasticity to public capital αG is set at 0.12. The severity of public capital depreciation corresponds to φ = 1 and the change in the depreciation rate of public capital is assumed to be a persistent process by setting ρδ = 0.8. In the baseline, absorptive capacity constraints start binding when public investment rises above 60 percent from its γ GI = 0.60). The calibration of absorptive capacity constraints initial steady state (¯ with ς = 50 implies that the average investment efficiency approximately halves to around 25 percent when public investment spikes to around 200 percent from its initial steady state. • Education and Health Parameters Taking logs of the production functions in the non-traded and traded sectors we have log (yj ) = αj ψE βj,E log(g E ) + αj ψH βj,H log(g H ) + other terms ; j = N, T (53) from which the elasticities of expenditure are given by i = αj ψi βj,i , ; j = N, T ; i = E, H from which given ψi , αj and j,i , we can pin down βj,i . The value chosen for the concavity parameter is ψi = 0.55, the efficiency parameters are γE = γH = 0.19, which imply an effective efficiency of 40 percent. In addition, we assume that health expenditures affect the stock of human capital after one year, while education expenditures after 5 years (jH = 1, jE = 5). Last a larger elasticity is assigned to 20 Figure 2: Alternative Fiscal Rules Spend as You Go (SAYG) Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH) 10 10 9 9 8 8 Oil Revenues Oil Revenues 7 7 6 6 Billion USD Billion USD 5 5 PIH Annuity Savings 4 4 Spending 3 3 2 2 Use of interest Borrowing earnings 1 1 0 0 -1 -1 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 Bird in Hand (BIH) Moderate Frontloading (MF) 10 10 9 9 8 8 Oil Revenues Oil Revenues 7 7 BIH Annuity 6 6 Savings Billion USD Billion USD 5 5 Savings 4 4 3 3 Borrowing Use of interest Use of interest earnings and other earnings 2 2 resources 1 1 0 0 -1 -1 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 education ( E = 0.1) relative to health ( H = 0.03). 5.3 Spending under alternative fiscal rules At the beginning of the resource boom, the PIH leads to a deficit that needs to be financed externally. However, once the production of natural resource comes to an end, PIH and BIH imply an equivalent annuity that is equal to the returns on financial assets. Using the baseline revenue projections for Kenya, and assuming a 2.7 percent real interest earnings on savings, annuities under each fiscal rule is calculated and shown in the following figures. The SAYG approach does not lead to any savings; therefore, transfers to the budget from the resource boom diminish over time, following the resource revenue depletion. Under PIH, the government transfers about $2.7 billion to the fiscal budget annually (figure 2, black line in panel b). In the short term, this is financed by borrowing from 21 abroad (the first yellow shaded area), as resource revenues are relatively low at this stage. In the medium term, the resource revenues pick up and reach a peak of about $9 billion. The difference between revenues and transfers is saved in a sovereign wealth fund (green shaded area). Finally, as the revenues gradually die out, interest earnings on the welfare fund assets are used to supplement the transfers to the budget (second yellow shaded area). Under BIH, transfers to the fiscal budget are scaled up over time as resource revenues are saved in the sovereign wealth fund and interest earnings on wealth fund assets increase (black curve line in panel c). Until the early 2040s, resource revenues exceed the transfers; therefore, reserves continue to build up. Later in the projection horizon, accumulation comes to a halt and the BIH annuity reaches a plateau. Finally, the “big push” under the MF approach leads to investments that are financed by borrowings in the short term (first yellow-shaded area). In the medium term, resource revenues exceed spending; however, the difference is smaller than with PIH or BIH. More- over, the spending converges to the PIH annuity in the long-term; however, spending remains above the PIH. Therefore, stabilization fund savings would be a lot smaller than the levels with PIH or BIH. 5.4 Implications of fiscal rules for growth and public finances All approaches assume an increase in public investments; the difference between them lies in the timing and scale of the increases. Figure 3 shows the evolution of investments under each approach using the baseline oil price, output and exchange rate projections. The SAYG approach mimics the dynamics of oil revenues illustrated by the inverted-U shape in figure 1, panel b; it thus leads to an aggressive scaling-up of public investment expenditures toward the middle of the projection horizon. In about two decades, this approach reaches a maximum, more than doubling public investment expenditures compared with the initial level. In comparison, the MF and PIH approaches bring about a permanent and relatively moderate rise at the outset. The MF approach increases public investment expenditures to a maximum of 100 percent relative to the initial level before it gradually approaches about 50 percent; the steady increase implied by the PIH. The BIH approach gradually scales up public investments, reaching SAYG only in the mid-2040s when the expenditures 22 under the latter approach are reduced rapidly. However, absorptive capacity constraints impose a “speed limit” on scaling up public investments in an efficient manner. The simulations show that higher spending does not automatically translate into a proportionate increase in public capital. In the short term, a rapid scaling-up under the MF approach leads to significant losses in average infrastructure efficiency. However, the loss is significantly larger under the SAYG approach. As a result, although the SAYG spends significantly more, the two approaches lead to similar levels of public capital accumulation (about 60 percent greater than the initial equilibrium) by the mid-2050s. This shows that the additional spending under the SAYG is wasted. Non-resource GDP responds to higher public expenditure levels; yet, this impact is not sustainable under the SAYG approach. Although the speed limit reduces public capital accumulation under the SAYG approach, the large scaling-up of investments still has a significant medium-term impact on non-resource GDP. At its peak, non-resource GDP is about 13 percent greater than its initial equilibrium value. This is partially because higher expenditures not only increase the infrastructure investments, but also build up more physical and human capital, which do not suffer from absorptive capacity constraints. However, this impact is not sustainable, because the resource revenues are depleted toward the end of the projection horizon. In comparison, steady spending under the PIH and MF approaches brings the non-resource GDP close to or even higher than the SAYG value in the long term, with the MF exceeding it by more than 5 percentage points. The BIH approach, by contrast, keeps the non-oil GDP close to its initial levels for a long time before the interest earnings become large enough to have a significant impact on non-resource GDP, which occurs only around three decades after the revenue starts to flow. The sector composition of the GDP shifts significantly under the different expenditure policies. All the approaches, apart from SAYG, lead to a gradual and relatively balanced expansion of non-resource GDP over the projection horizon. In contrast, the SAYG ap- proach leads to more prominent Dutch disease–like symptoms. Under the MF and PIH approaches, the tradable and non-tradable sectors grow at a relatively stable rate. For the BIH approach, the growth rates in both sectors are relatively back-loaded, but they are balanced across sectors. In contrast, the SAYG approach leads to a rapid expansion of the non-tradable sector early in the projections (up to 12 percentage points higher than 23 the initial equilibrium), which is sustained for a prolonged period of time. The expansion of the tradable sector comes in the second half of the projection horizon, and is relatively short-lived. These differences in the sector compositions can be traced back to Dutch disease symptoms in the economy. The rapid escalation of expenditures under the SAYG approach leads to a significant and sustained appreciation of the domestic currency in the first half of the projection horizon. This leads to an erosion of competitiveness in the tradable sector. Currency appreciations under the PIH and MF approaches, however, are relatively short-lived and limited to the early years. The PIH and BIH approaches lead to better and more sustainable fiscal outcomes. The simulations evaluate the fiscal implications by comparing asset and liability accumulations under each approach. The lowest debt-to-GDP ratio is generated by the SAYG approach, because there is no debt issuance for financing investments in this case. The debt-to-GDP ratio thus decreases from about 45 percent in the beginning of the projections to 42 percent by 2075. However, there is no accumulation of savings either. In contrast, the MF approach raises public debt the most because of the initial “big push.” The debt-to-GDP ratio increases from about 45 percent to close to 60 percent over the projection horizon. At the same time, the oil revenue savings reach about 90 percent of the current GDP. However, the true winners for fiscal sustainability are the more conservative approaches. Under the BIH approach, the debt-to-GDP ratio decreases by about 2 percentage points, and stabilization fund balances exceed four times the current GDP by 2075. Similarly, the savings under the PIH approach exceeds 3.5 times the GDP. A slightly smaller accumulation compared with the BIH approach reflects the borrowings to finance the initial escalation of public investments. 24 Figure 3: Real Economy and Public Finance Implications of Alternative Fiscal Rules a. Public Investment b. Average Infrastructure Efficiency c. Public Capital (% Deviation from Initial Steady state) (%) (% Deviation from Initial Steady state) 200 45 70 180 60 160 40 140 50 120 40 35 100 30 80 30 20 60 40 10 20 25 0 0 -20 20 -10 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 d. Non-Oil Output e. Tradable Non-Oil Output f. Non-Tradable Output (% Deviation from Initial Steady state) (% Deviation from Initial Steady state) (% Deviation from Initial Steady state) 18 25 14 16 12 20 25 14 10 12 15 10 8 8 10 6 6 4 5 4 2 2 0 0 0 -2 -5 -2 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 g. Real Exchange Rate h. Public Debt i. Sovereign Wealth Fund Savings (% Deviation from Initial Steady state) (% of GDP) (% of GDP) 2 70 600 1 65 500 0 60 400 -1 55 300 -2 50 200 -3 45 100 -4 40 -5 35 0 -6 30 -100 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 Spend-As-You-Go Bird-in-Hand Permanent Income Moderate Frontloading 5.5 Taking investment composition into consideration The fiscal rule exercise in the previous section analyzed the effects of changing intertem- poral composition of public investments on the real economy and public finances. This has been done while holding the allocation of investments across alternative uses fixed at their initial levels. The simulations in this section do the opposite: they compare alterna- tive compositions of public investments on the basis of their long-term implications while holding the intertemporal allocation of aggregate public investments fixed at a given path. In order to see the intuition for such an exercise, note that actual investment paths for education, health, and infrastructure are determined by two forces that are defined by policy decisions. The first one is the ‘scale effect’, which describes the changes in the level of total public investments. Public investment expenditure scenarios described in the pre- vious section determine the magnitude of this effect. The second one is the ‘composition effect’, which describes the structure of spending. In order to analyze the latter effect, the scale of expenditures will be held fixed as given by the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH) approach. Then, three alternatives to the allocation of spending on infrastructure, education, and health will be compared on the basis of their long-term growth and fiscal implications: • Aggressive Infrastructure-based Composition (AIC): This approach keeps the shares of all components in total public investments fixed at their current levels, which are already high. These shares are, approximately: 70 percent infrastructure investments, 24 percent education, and 6 percent health. Total public investments are set as implied by the PIH approach; thus, both the size and composition of the investments are kept constant throughout the projection horizon. • Aggressive Skill-based Composition (ASC): The share of education in pub- lic investments is gradually increased from the initial level to about 40 percent at the expense of investments on infrastructure, whereas the share of health is kept constant. • Balanced Composition (BC): The share of health in public investments is grad- ually increased from the initial level to about 11 percent at the expense of infras- tructure, whereas the share of education is kept constant. 26 For all types of investments, the scale effect dominates the composition effects. In the long term, education and health investments are higher than their initial levels under all three scenarios. Figure 4 shows that by the end of the projection horizon, investments in education increase from about 2 percent of 2020 GDP to about 3 percent, and health investments increase from about 0.6 percent of 2020 GDP to about 0.8 percent, even when the AIC is chosen. The investments in each category never fall below the initial levels in these simulations, mainly because the additional investments generated by the PIH ap- proach are large enough to compensate any potential losses if an unfavorable composition approach is chosen. This is particularly clear in the case of infrastructure investments: they increase from about 6 percent of GDP in 2020 to about 6.5 percent in the same period if ASC is chosen. Proportionately this increase is small because physical capital depreciates faster than education and health. Gross investments in this case are just large enough to offset the depreciation under the ASC. Simulations show that the limited scaling-up under the PIH approach saves the AIC from being punished heavily by the absorptive capacity constraint. A rapid scaling-up of public investments does not necessarily mean that public capital is scaled up quickly. Efficiency constraints in public investment projects bind most when infrastructure invest- ments are scaled up rapidly as under the AIC approach. As a result, higher spending in this approach does not necessarily translate into faster capital accumulation if public investments are scaled up more rapidly than what the PIH approach suggests. However, when the PIH is chosen, this is not a problem. Thus, figure 4 shows that the gap between the public capital levels among the three approaches widens over time. By the end of the projection horizon, the gap between the AIC and BC is relatively small, whereas public capital shrinks toward its initial level under the ASC. BC public investments translate into higher growth in the non-resource sector. Public capital stock under the BC approach is smaller than under the AIC in the second half of the projections. However, the human capital stock is greater. As a result, non-resource GDP under the BC approach grows more than it would under the AIC approach. This is mainly because infrastructure and human capital complement each other’s productivity. With diminishing returns to each factor, this implies that increasing one factor at the expense of the other one would eventually decrease the total output. The BC approach leads to 27 a more balanced combination of physical and human capital, which is more conducive to long-term growth. The three composition approaches bring about similar fiscal sustainability outcomes; however, the fiscal buffers are lower in the ASC case. Total public debt as a share of GDP remains similar in all the composition scenarios. In all cases, the public debt-to-GDP ratio climbs from about 45 percent in 2020 to about 55 percent in the medium term, and then stabilizes around 50 percent in the long term. Accumulation of savings in the stabilization fund exhibits significant differences. By the end of the projection horizon, the BC and AIC approaches lead to savings that are about 350 percent of GDP. The savings under the ASC approach are about 290 percent of GDP. As the GDP under the ASC approach is lower than the ones under other approaches, the gaps in savings-to-GDP ratios imply greater differences in savings in nominal terms. 28 Figure 4: Real Economy and Public Finance Implications of Alternative Fiscal Rules Infrastructure Ivestment Education Investment Health Investment (% of Initial GDP) (% of Initial GDP) (% of Initial GDP) 9.5 6 1.6 9 1.4 5 8.5 1.2 8 4 1 7.5 3 0.8 7 0.6 6.5 2 0.4 6 1 5.5 0.2 5 0 0 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 Average Infrastructure Efficiency Public Capital Non-Oil Output (%) (% Deviation from Initial Steady state) (% Deviation from Initial Steady state) 45 60 14 40 50 12 29 35 10 30 40 25 8 30 20 6 15 20 4 10 10 2 5 0 0 0 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 Real Exchange Rate Public Debt Sovereign Wealth Fun Savings (% Deviation from Initial Steady state) (% of GDP) (% of GDP) 1.5 60 400 1 350 55 0.5 300 0 50 250 -0.5 45 200 -1 150 -1.5 40 -2 100 35 -2.5 50 -3 30 0 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 Balanced composition Aggressive infrastructure composition Aggressive skill-based composition 6 Conclusions This paper has developed a multi-sector, small open economy Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model based on Melina et al. (2016), to include the accumulation of human capital, built via public expenditures in education and health expenditures. We have calibrated the model to Kenya and examined four possible fiscal rules for total public investment in infrastructure, education and health in the context of a sustainable resource fund. There are two dimensions to this exercise: the scaling effect which describes the level of total investment and the composition effect which defines the structure of investment between infrastructure, education and health. In terms of the impacts on the non-resource economy, efficiency of spending and sustainability of fiscal outcomes, we find that the the PIH approach provides the best balance between effects on non-oil growth and fiscal sustainability in the case of Kenya. A balanced composition is the preferred structure of investment given the PIH allocation of total investment over time. Our DSGE modeling approach to these issues offers an internally coherent framework for making conditional (i.e., ceteris paribus) forecasts of the effects of different fiscal poli- cies. For the MF or PIH approaches these are defined in terms of parameters k1 and k2 that define the scaling effect, while the composition is driven by the share parameters at the beginning and end of the simulation period. Instead of restricting the choice to a limited and finite number of scenarios, future work could examine a welfare optimal choice of these parameters. Our exercise has been purely deterministic, ignoring uncertainty in crucial areas such as the world price of oil. A further line of research could study welfare- optimal state-contingent rules that indicate how policy would be adjusted in the face of unanticipated changes to the price of oil and other relevant exogenous macro-economic variables. References Abdelal, R., Khan, A., and Khanna, T. (2008). Where oil-rich nations are placing their bets. Harvard Business Review, 86(9), 119–128. Adam, C. and Bevan, D. (2014). Public investment, public finance, and growth: the impact 30 of distortionary taxation, recurrent costs, and incomplete appropriability. Manuscript, University of Oxford. enor, P.-R. and Nganou, J.-P. (2013). Expenditure allocation and economic growth in Ag´ uganda: An olg framework. unpublished. Albino-War, M., Cerovic, S., Grigoli, F., Flores, J., Kapsoli, J., Qu, H., Said, Y., Shukurov, B., Sommer, M., and Yoon, S. (2014). Making the most of public investment in MENA and CCA oil-exporting countries. IMF Staff Discussion Note, 14(10). Araujo, J., Li, B. G., Poplawski-Ribeiro, M., and Zanna, L.-F. (2013). Current account norms in natural resource rich and capital scarce economies. IMF Working Paper 13/80, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C. Barnett, S. and Ossowski, R. (2003). Operational Aspects of Fiscal Policy in Oil-Producing Countries. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C. Bems, R. and de Carvalho Filho, I. (2011). The current account and precautionary savings for exporters of exhaustible resources. Journal of International Economics, 84(1), 48– 64. Berg, A., Gottschalk, J., Portillo, R., and Zanna, L.-F. (2010). The macroeconomics of medium-term aid scaling-up scenarios. IMF Working Paper 10/160, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C. Berg, A., Portillo, R., Yang, S.-C. S., and Zanna, L.-F. (2013). Public investment in resource-abundant developing countries. IMF Economic Review, 61(1), 92–129. Buffie, E. F., Berg, A., Pattillo, C., Portillo, R., and Zanna, L.-F. (2012). Public invest- ment, growth, and debt sustainability: Putting together the pieces. IMF Working Paper WP/12/144, the International Monetary Fund. Davis, J., Owssowski, J., Daniel, J., and Barnett, S. (2001). Stabilizing and Saving Funds for Non-Renewable Resources: Experience and Fiscal Policy Implications. IMF Occa- sional Paper No. 205. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C. Demirguc-Kunt, A. and Klapper, L. (2012). Measuring financial inclusion: The global findex. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 6025. 31 Esfahani, H. S. and Ramirez, M. T. (2003). Institutions, infrastructure, and economic growth. Journal of Development Economics, 70(2), 443–477. Goldberg, J. (2013). Kwacha gonna do? Experimental evidence about labor supply in rural Malawi. Manuscript, Economics Department, University of Maryland. Gros, D. and Mayer, T. (2012). A Sovereign Wealth Fund to Lift Germany’s Curse of Excess Savings. CEPS Policy Brief No. 280, August 28, Centre for European Policy Studies. Horvath, M. (2000). Sectoral shocks and aggregate fluctuations. Journal of Monetary Economics, 45(1), 69–106. Hulten, C. R. (1996). Infrastructure capital and economic growth: How well you use it may be more important than how much you have. NBER Working Paper, No. 5847. Melina, G., Yang, S.-C. S., and Zanna, L.-F. (2016). Debt sustainability, public invest- ment, and natural resources in developing countries: The DIGNAR model. Economic Modelling, 52, Part B, 630 – 649. Ogaki, M., Ostry, J., and Reinhart, C. (1996). Saving behavior in low- and middle-income developing countries: A comparison. IMF Staff Papers, 43(1), 38–71. Pritchett, L. (2000). The tyranny of concepts: CUDIE (cumulated, depreciated, invest- ment effort) is not capital. Journal of Economic Growth, 5(4), 361–384. Rioja, F. K. (2003). Filling potholes: Macroeconomic effects of maintenance versus new investments in public infrastructure. Journal of Public Economics, 87(9-10), 2281–2304. e, S. and Uribe, M. (2003). Closing small open economy models. Journal of Schmitt-Groh´ International Economics, 61(1), 163–185. Stockman, A. C. and Tesar, L. L. (1995). Tastes and technology in a two-country model of the business cycle: Explaining international comovements. American Economic Review, 85(1), 168–185. van der Ploeg, F. (2010). Why do many resource-rich countries have negative genuine savings? Anticipation of better times or rapacious rent seeking. Resource and Energy Economics, 32(1), 28–44. 32 van der Ploeg, F. and Venables, A. J. (2011). Harnessing windfall revenues: Optimal policies for resource-rich developing economies. The Economic Journal, 121(551), 1– 30. Venables, A. J. (2010). Resource rents; when to spend and how to save. International Tax and Public Finance, 17, 340–356. Appendix A The Full Model Notation for the full model is as in Section 2 plus new variables: qT,t , qN,t for the price of capital in sectors T,N (arising fom the introduction of adjustment costs of investment); consumption and labour distortionary taxes, τtC , τtL ; and external concessional commercial debt, dt , dc,t with loan gross rates Rd,t , Rdc,t respectively. There are two sets of consumers: optimizing (OPT) and rule of thumb (ROT), the latter being credit-constrained and consuming disposable income in each period. χ 1 χ−1 1 χ−1 χ−1 ci t = ϕ χ ci N,t χ + (1 − ϕ) χ ci T,t χ for i = OP T, ROT (A.1) −χ i −χ i ci N,t = ϕpN,t ct ; ci T,t = (1 − ϕ) st ct ∀i = OP T, ROT (A.2) 1 −χ −χ 1 = ϕp1 + (1 − ϕ) s1 1−χ N t (A.3) ρ 1+ρ 1 1+ρ 1 1+ρ i −ρ i −ρ i lt = δ lN,t ρ + (1 − δ ) lT,t ρ , for i = OP T, ROT (A.4) ρ ρ i wN,t i i wT,t i lN,t =δ lt , lT,t = (1 − δ ) lt , for i = OP T, ROT (A.5) wt wt −σ λt 1 + τtC = cOP t T (A.6) ψ OP T κOP T lt = λt 1 − τtL wt (A.7) λt = βEt (λt+1 Rt ) (A.8) 33 λt+1 st+1 Rt∗ λt = βEt T ∗ − bOP T ∗ (A.9) st − η bOP t ∗ Rt = Rdc,t + u (A.10) 1 + τtC cROT t ROT = 1 − τtL wt lt + st rm∗ t + zt − µkG,t−1 (A.11) 1 ROT 1 1 − τtL ROT −σ ψ lt = c wt (A.12) κROT 1 + τtC t ct = ωcOP t T + (1 − ω ) cROT t (A.13) OP T ROT lt = ωlt + (1 − ω ) lt (A.14) bt = ωbOP t T ; b∗ OP T ∗ t = ωbt (A.15) yN,t = zN (kN,t−1 )1−αN (AN,t lN,t )αN (kG,t−1 )αG (A.16) 2 κN iN,t kN,t = (1 − δN ) kN,t−1 + 1 − −1 iN,t (A.17) 2 iN,t−1 yN,t wN,t = αN pN,t (A.18) lN,t λt+1 yN,t+1 qN,t = Et β (1 − δN ) qN,t+1 + 1 − τ K (1 − αN ) pN,t+1 (A.19) λt kN,t 2 1 κN iN,t iN,t iN,t = 1− −1 − κN −1 qN,t 2 iN,t−1 iN,t−1 iN,t−1 2 λt+1 qN,t+1 iN,t+1 iN,t+1 +Et β κN −1 (A.20) λt qN,t iN,t iN,t yT,t = zT,t (kT,t−1 )1−αN (AT,t lT,t )αN (kG,t−1 )αG (A.21) ρzT ρyT zT,t zT,t−1 yT,t−1 = (A.22) zT zT yT 2 κT iT,t kT,t = (1 − δT ) kT,t−1 + 1 − −1 iT,t (A.23) 2 iT,t−1 yT,t wT,t = αst (A.24) lT,t λt+1 yT,t+1 qT,t = Et β (1 − δT ) qT,t+1 + 1 − τ K (1 − αT ) st+1 (A.25) λt kT,t 34 2 1 κT iT,t iT,t iT,t = 1− −1 − κT −1 qT,t 2 iT,t−1 iT,t−1 iT,t−1 2 λt+1 qT,t+1 iT,t+1 iT,t+1 + Et β κT −1 (A.26) λt qT,t iT,t iT,t ρyo yO,t yO,t−1 = exp (εyo t ) (A.27) yO yO ρpo p∗ O,t p∗ O,t−1 = exp (εpo t ) (A.28) p∗ O p∗ O yO,t = st p∗ O,t yO,t (A.29) yt = pN,t yN,t + st yT,t + yO,t (A.30) ∗ tO O t = τ st pO,t yO,t (A.31) dt + dc,t d + dc Rdc,t−1 = Rf + υdc exp ηdc − (A.32) yt y χ 1 χ−1 1 χ−1 χ−1 χ gt = νt (gN,t ) χ + (1 − νt ) (gT,t ) χ χ (A.33) −χ −χ pN,t st gN,t = νt gt , gT,t = (1 − νt ) gt (A.34) pG t pG t 1 1−χ −χ + (1 − νt ) s1 1−χ pG t = νt pN t (A.35) pG g ν + pG G t gt − p g νg νt = (A.36) pG t gt    I, gt if γ GI ≤ γ GI  I t gt = (A.37)  ¯I + 1 + γ GI g γ GI t 1 + γ GI t −γ GI ¯I , if γ GI g t >γ GI  γ GI t = exp −ς γ GI t −γ GI (A.38) I kG,t = (1 − δG,t ) kG,t−1 + gt (A.39)   δG kG,t−1 I <δ k  φδG I gt , if gt G G,t−1  δG,t = (A.40) I δ G,t−1 + (1 − ρδ ) δG , if gt ≥ δG kG,t−1  ρ δ  fin,t fout,t ft∗ − f ∗ = max ff loor − f ∗ , ft∗ −1 − f ∗ + − (A.41) st st 35 gapt = ∆bt + st ∆dc,t + τtC − τ C ct + τtL − τ L wt lt − pG C t gt − g C − (zt − z ) (A.42) K fin,t =τ C ct + τ L wt lt + 1 − ϑK τ K rT,t K kT,t−1 + rN,t kN,t−1 + tO,t + µkG,t−1 + st a∗ ∗ t + st grt + st R RF − 1 ft∗ −1 + st ∆dt (A.43) fout,t = pG I G C t gt + pt g + z + (st Rd − 1) dt−1 + (Rdc,t−1 − 1) st dc,t−1 + (Rt−1 − 1) bt−1 (A.44) κ ∆bt = (1 − κ ) st ∆dc,t (A.45) C C gapt τtarget,t = τ + λ1 (A.46) ct I E H gt = gt + gt + gt (A.47) C τtC = min τrule C ,t , τceiling (A.48) C C C C τrule ,t = τt−1 + ζ1 τtarget,t − τt−1 + ζ2 (xt−1 − x) , with ζ1 , ζ2 > 0 (A.49) −χ pN,t yN,t = ϕp− χ N,t (ct + iN,t + iT,t ) + νt gt (A.50) pG t cad ∗ t = grt − ∆ft∗ + ∆dt + ∆dc,t + ∆b∗ t (A.51) st OP T ∗ cad G t =ct + iN,t + iT,t + pt gt + Θt − yt − st rm∗ t + (Rd − 1) st dt−1 ∗ ∗ + (Rdc,t−1 − 1) st dc,t−1 + Rt−1 − 1 st bt−1 − R RF − 1 st ft∗ −1 (A.52) I E H gt = gt + gt + gt (A.53) β β Aj,t = zj,a et j,E ht j,H (A.54) E et = (1 − δE ) et−1 + (γ E gt−jE ) ψE (A.55) H ht = (1 − δH ) ht−1 + (γ H gt−jH ) ψH (A.56) E gt = φE t gt (A.57) H gt = φH t gt (A.58) K gt = 1 − φH E t − φt gt (A.59) 36  φE  for t = 0 init φE t = (A.60) φE  for t > 0 new  φH  for t = 0 init φH t = (A.61) φH  for t > 0 new 37