DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1610 Pension Systems in Sub-Saharan Africa: Brief Review of Design Parameters and Key Performance Indicators Miglena Abels and Melis U. Guven October 2016 Pension Systems in Sub-Saharan Africa: Brief Review of Design Parameters and Key Performance Indicators Miglena Abels and Melis U. Guven October 2016 Abstract The paper summarizes key design characteristics and performance indicators of national and civil service pension schemes in Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA). It is intended to serve as a resource in pension reform efforts in the region. The note delivers an up-to date assessment of the main design parameters, key performance metrics, and main challenges facing pension systems in SSA. The information provided in the note aims to capture current trends in the region and benchmark performance and pension system design choices made by countries against international experience. Section I provides an overview of mandatory national pension systems in the region whereas Section II presents the key design features of civil service pension schemes. Section III analyzes the performance of both national and civil service pension schemes; particular attention is paid to the fiscal performance and equity of the pension schemes. Pension system design parameters of both national and civil service pension schemes are discussed in section IV. Section V aims to enhance the paper by providing relevant demographic data and analysis. JEL Classification: H55, J26 Key Words: national and civil service pension systems in Africa, public pension system expenditure, design and performance indicators of civil service pension systems Abbreviations DB Defined Benefit DC Defined Contribution FDC Funded Defined Contribution GDP Gross Domestic Product PAYG Pay-As-You-Go SSA Sub-Saharan Africa 1 Acknowledgements This paper was written by Miglena Abels (Research Analyst, World Bank) and Melis U. Guven (Senior Social Protection Economist, World Bank). The authors gratefully acknowledge the useful contributions of a number of people who provided data during the preparation of the document: Adrianus Vugs, Fiona Stewart, Gbetoho Joachim Boko, Kouakou Bruno Tano, Lucilla Bruni, Paulette Castel, Sergiy Biletsky, Solene Marie Paule Rougeaux, Benhildah Mundangepfupfu, and Tavares Priscilla. The paper was prepared under the direction of Dena Ringold and Stefano Paternostro, practice managers in the Social Protection and Labor Global Practice. Authors are grateful for the helpful feedback and comments received from Robert Palacios and Will Price of the World Bank. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this document are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Executive Directors of the World Bank, the governments their represent, or the counterparts consulted during the preparation of the document. i Contents I. Mandatory national pension systems..................................................................................................... 1 II. Civil service pension systems .................................................................................................................. 4 III. Performance of national and civil service pension systems .............................................................. 7 Fiscal performance ....................................................................................................................................... 7 Elderly coverage ......................................................................................................................................... 11 IV. Design parameters and characteristics of national and civil service pension systems ................... 14 Contribution rates ...................................................................................................................................... 14 Accrual rates ............................................................................................................................................... 16 Wage base for pension calculation ............................................................................................................ 18 Retirement ages ......................................................................................................................................... 20 Indexation ................................................................................................................................................... 21 V. Demographics ........................................................................................................................................ 22 VI. Annex ................................................................................................................................................. 27 Retirement Ages in National and Civil Service Pension Schemes in SSA .................................................... 27 Parameters of a traditional pension system .............................................................................................. 28 Glossary of Pension Terms ......................................................................................................................... 29 References ...................................................................................................................................................... 32 List of Figures Figure 1: Pension Expenditures on National Pension Scheme as a Share of GDP ................................................ 7 Figure 2: Pension Expenditures on Civil Service Pension Scheme as a Share of GDP........................................... 9 Figure 3: Spending on non-contributory pensions as a share of GDP ............................................................... 10 Figure 4: National and Civil Service Pension Coverage of the Population over the Age of 60 ........................... 13 Figure 5: Total pension spending as a share of GDP vs. Total pension coverage of the population 60+ ........... 14 Figure 6: National Pension System Contribution Rates ...................................................................................... 15 Figure 7: Civil Service Pension Scheme Contribution Rates................................................................................ 16 Figure 8: National Pension System Accrual Rates and Simulated Replacement Rates with 30 years of contributions....................................................................................................................................................... 17 Figure 9: Civil Service Pension Scheme Accrual Rates ........................................................................................ 18 Figure 10: Wage Base in National and Civil Service Pension Schemes in SSA .................................................... 19 ii Figure 11: Expected years in retirement, expressed as life expectancy at retirement age, in select SSA countries and the OECD ...................................................................................................................................... 21 Figure 12: Average Retirement Ages across SSA and the OECD ......................................................................... 21 Figure 13: Indexation Measures ......................................................................................................................... 22 Figure 14: Historic and Projected Total Fertility and Crude Death Rates in Sub-Saharan Africa........................ 23 Figure 15: Population over the Age of 65 as a Share in Total Population .......................................................... 24 Figure 16: Projected Child Dependency Ratio .................................................................................................... 24 Figure 17: Projected Total Dependency Ratio .................................................................................................... 25 List of Tables Table 1: Design of mandatory national pension schemes .................................................................................... 3 Table 2: Design of Civil Service Pension Schemes................................................................................................. 6 Table 3: Non-contributory pension programs in select SSA countries ............................................................... 12 iii Summary This paper summarizes key design characteristics and performance indicators of national and civil service pension schemes in Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA). It is intended to serve as a resource in pension reform efforts in the region. The paper delivers an up-to date assessment of the main design parameters, key performance metrics, and main challenges facing pension systems in SSA. The information provided in the paper aims to capture current trends in the region and benchmark performance and pension system design choices made by countries against international experience. Section I provides an overview of mandatory national pension systems in the region whereas Section II presents the key design features of civil service pension schemes. Section III analyzes the performance of both national and civil service pension schemes; particular attention is paid to the fiscal performance and equity of the pension schemes. Pension system design parameters of both national and civil service pension schemes are discussed in section IV. Section V aims to enhance the note by providing relevant demographic data and analysis. I. Mandatory national pension systems Out of the 44 countries in Sub-Saharan Africa 1 where at least some information is available, 38 countries have mandatory contributory national 2 pension schemes. Out of the 38 countries, 31 are defined benefit (DB) 3 systems financed on a pay-as-you-go (PAYG)4 basis; four countries have provident 5 funds (Uganda, Swaziland, Kenya, and Gambia); two countries (Malawi 6 and Nigeria) have funded defined contribution schemes (DC), 7 and one country (Ghana) has a hybrid of a DB and a DC system. Six countries (Botswana, Eritrea, Lesotho, Namibia, South Sudan, and South 1 There are a total of 48 countries in Sub-Saharan Africa. 2 In this note, national pension schemes refer to schemes operated by the Government which cover private sector workers, and in the case of integrated system, also cover public sector workers. 3 A Defined Benefit pension plan (DB) is a pension plan with a guarantee by the insurer or pension agency that a benefit based on a prescribed formula will be paid; it can be fully funded or unfunded and notional. 4 Pay‐as‐you‐go (PAYG) is a method of pension system financing whereby current outlays on pension benefits are paid out of current revenues from an earmarked tax, often a payroll tax. 5 Provident fund is a publicly run fully funded defined contribution fund. 6 Malawi has recently established a DC scheme. 7 A Defined Contribution pension plan (DC) is a pension plan in which the periodic contribution is prescribed and the benefit depends on the contribution plus the investment return. Can be fully funded or notional and nonfinancial. 1 Africa) do not have a mandatory national contributory pension scheme and instead only have civil service pension schemes for public sector workers, occupational 8 pension schemes for private sector workers provided by employers, and non-contributory old age benefits to those who qualify. Labor force coverage of national pension schemes varies significantly across the region, but on average it is quite low. Over half of the labor force in Mauritius and Seychelles contributes to the national pension system; coverage is also relatively high in Zimbabwe with around 33 percent of the labor force accruing pension rights. However, across the remaining SSA countries, pension coverage is less than 10 percent of the labor force. The potential issues impeding pension coverage expansion in the region are many. First, mandatory defined benefit pension schemes financed from payroll taxes are typically most successful in countries where the majority of workers are in the formal labor market and hold employment contracts which enable them to contribute to the pension system in a systematic manner. The situation is quite the opposite in Africa where the majority of employment takes place outside the formal economy. As such, one of the defining challenges facing SAA is to think about designing systems which will prove to be attractive and beneficial for the working age population. Table 1 provides an overview of the different pension design choices made by countries in SSA; it also presents latest figures available on labor force and elderly coverage of national pension systems for the countries where recent data are available. 8 An occupational pension scheme is an arrangement by which an employer provides retirement benefits to employees. 2 Table 1: Design of Mandatory National Pension Schemes Active Coverage, % Beneficiaries, % Country National Pension Scheme Design Integrated Labor Foce Population 60+ 1 Angola PAYG DB 2 Benin Caisse Nationale de Sécurité Sociale (CNSS) PAYG DB 4.1% 3 Botswana no national mandatory contributory pension scheme 4 Burkina Faso PAYG DB 5 Burundi PAYG DB 6 Cabo Verde Instituto Nacional de Previdencia Social (INPS) PAYG DB X 23.0% 17.1% 7 Cameroon PAYG DB 8 Central African Rep. PAYG DB X 9 Chad PAYG DB X 10 Congo, Dem. Rep. PAYG DB 11 Congo, Rep. PAYG DB 12 Cote d'Ivoire Caisse Nationale de la Prevoyance Sociale (CNPS) PAYG DB 7.1% 13 Ethiopia Private Organization Employees Social Security Agency (POESSA) PAYG DB 1.9% 14 Gambia National Provident Fund (NPF) Provident Fund 15 Ghana Basic National Social Security Scheme Tier 1 Hybrid X 10.1% 9.7% 16 Guinea PAYG DB 17 Guinea Bissau National Insitute of Social Security (INSS) PAYG DB 0.2% 2.2% 18 Kenya National Social Security Fund - NSSF Provident Fund 7.8% 2.3% 19 Lesotho no national mandatory contributory pension scheme 20 Liberia The National Pension Scheme (NPS) PAYG DB 5.4% 3.7% 21 Madagascar PAYG DB 22 Malawi FDC 23 Mali PAYG DB 24 Mauritania PAYG DB 25 Mauritius National Pensions Fund (NPF) first pillar PAYG DB 54.2% 47.7% 26 Mozambique INSS PAYG DB 4.0% 27 Namibia no national mandatory contributory pension scheme 28 Niger PAYG DB 29 Nigeria CPS (RSA Scheme) FDC X 8.8% 1.5% 30 Rwanda Pension and Occupational Hazards Scheme (managed by RSSB) PAYG DB X 6.0% 6.3% 31 Sao Tome & Principe National Institute of Social Security (INSS) PAYG DB X 19.0% 65.0% 32 Senegal Provident Institution Retreat Senegal (IPRES) PAYG DB 33 Seychelles Seychelles Pension Fund PAYG DB X 63.0% 37.0% 34 Sierra Leone National Social Security and Insurance Trust PAYG DB X 9.4% 6.4% 35 Somalia 36 South Africa no national mandatory contributory pension scheme 37 South Sudan 38 Sudan PAYG DB 39 Swaziland National Provident Fund Provident Fund 19.0% 12.5% 40 Tanzania NSSF PAYG DB 1.7% 0.3% 41 Togo La Caisse Nationale de Sécurité Sociale (CNSS) PAYG DB 2.8% 10.9% 42 Uganda National Social Security Fund (NSSF) Provident Fund 3.9% 0.8% 43 Zambia National Pension Scheme (NAPSA) PAYG DB X 8.8% 1.0% 44 Zimbabwe National Pensions Scheme PAYG DB 14.7% 26.2% Source: National sources; staff calculations. 3 II. Civil service pension systems Having two separate pension schemes operating in parallel for public and private sector workers is a pronounced characteristic of old age income provision in SSA. Civil servants are covered by pension schemes in all Sub-Saharan Africa countries. Out of the 44 countries where information is available, 33 have separate schemes for public sector workers. In seven countries (Botswana, Lesotho, 9 Liberia, Mauritius, Namibia, South Africa, and Swaziland) public sector workers are typically covered by some type of social pension, in some cases a means or pensions tested benefit, in addition to their civil service pension. Swaziland has a universal non- contributory scheme which is pensions-tested, although it is not clear if the pensions test is applied in practice—potentially meaning that civil servants could benefit from both the civil service scheme as well as the non-contributory program. In Liberia, public sector workers are members of the national pension scheme but also receive a top-up arrangement. Ten countries (Cape Verde, Central African Republic, Chad, Ghana, Nigeria, Rwanda, Sao Tome e Principe, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, and Zambia) have an integrated pension system meaning that it covers both public and private sector workers alike and there is no separate special civil service scheme for public sector workers. In the case of Cape Verde, integration of the national and civil service pension schemes has been done quite recently. Eritrea and South Sudan have not yet established private sector pension schemes. The South Africa Government Employees Pension Fund (GEPF) is one of the largest pension funds in the region with over 1.2 million active contributors and over 406 thousand beneficiaries in 2015. GEPF beneficiaries account for 10 percent of the population over the retirement age. The Government Institutions Pension Fund (GIPF) of Namibia is another example of large and well- managed pension fund in a country where there is no national contributory pension scheme. In 2013, GIPF had over 94 thousand contributors, or 11 percent of the labor force, and provided pensions to 56 thousand elderly, or 45 percent of the population above the retirement age. 9 In Lesotho and Swaziland, social pension programs are pensions tested – eligibility is limited to individuals without access to a contributory pension. However, in practice both countries do not apply the pensions test and all elderly above the eligibility age are effectively included in the program. 4 In Lesotho, the Public Officers’ Defined Contribution Pension Fund—civil service pension scheme—accounts for the largest pension scheme in the country. The Public Officers’ Defined Contribution Pension Fund was created through an act of Parliament in 2008; the reform converted the system from a PAYG DB to a DC system. The fairly recent establishment of the DC scheme helps to explain the very low coverage 10 of the elderly of less than 1/10 of a percent in 2015. During the same year the fund had 36 thousand contributors, or 4.1 percent of the labor force. Botswana and South Sudan also fall into the category of countries where there is only a civil service pension scheme for public sector employees and a non-contributory old age benefit. South Africa, Namibia, Botswana, and Lesotho also have significant non-contributory pension programs for the elderly. Namibia and Botswana have a universal pension, whereas South Africa and Lesotho provide means-tested and pension-tested benefits respectively. Civil service pension schemes in SAA are mostly defined benefit, financed on a pay-as-you-go basis. Botswana, Lesotho, and Nigeria 11 have funded DC schemes; Kenya is introducing a DC scheme; in 2013, Mauritius introduced a DC scheme for new entrants to civil service; Swaziland has a funded defined benefit scheme for civil servants; Ghana has a hybrid of DB and a DC scheme. The majority of civil service pension schemes in SSA are contributory schemes, however, nine countries (Burundi, Cameroon, Congo, Dem. Rep., Gambia, Malawi, Mozambique, Uganda, Mauritius, and Angola) fully or partially finance civil service pensions directly from the government budget. It is important to note that in the case of civil service pension schemes where the government is also the employer, financing the employer share of the pension contribution rate is a direct cost for the government. Having a specified contribution rate may improve transparency and promote long term financial planning, however, financing civil service pensions is a direct fiscal obligation for the government—with our without a specified contribution rate. The recommended design for a civil service pension system is often to integrate it with the national system (Palacios & Whitehouse, 2006). Integration typically allows for better labor 10 Overall elderly pension coverage is higher as there are individuals drawing pensions under the previous, now closed system. 11 As discussed earlier, Nigeria’s civil service scheme is integrated with the national scheme. 5 market mobility (as it provides for increased portability of pension rights) and may help to avoid some of the inequities observed between civil service and less generous private sector schemes in the region. International experience suggests that either fully, or at least partially integrated pension systems are strongly preferred over maintaining a dualism in old-age income provision between public and private sector. Table 2: Design of Civil Service Pension Schemes 6 III. Performance of national and civil service pension systems Fiscal performance Based on the countries included in the analysis, spending on national pension systems in SSA is low as a share of GDP, amounting to an average of 0.5 percent. Spending on national pensions in SSA is currently low primarily because of two reasons: (1) the small share of elderly in total population and (2) and even smaller share of elderly in receipt of a national pension. The small number of pensioners also results from the fact that in a number of countries the national pension funds were set up fairly recently. For example, all pension funds in Tanzania (except for PPF) were converted from DC to PAYG DB between 1999 and 2003. Therefore, the relative immaturity of pension systems is also a contributing factor for the low levels of pension spending currently observed in the region. Figure 1: Pension Expenditures on National Pension Scheme as a Share of GDP National Pension Scheme Expenditures, % GDP (latest year available) 1.0% 0.9% 0.9% 0.9% 0.8% 0.8% 0.8% 0.7% 0.6% 0.6% 0.6% 0.60% 0.6% 0.5% 0.5% 0.4% 0.4% 0.3% 0.3% 0.3% 0.2% 0.2% 0.2% 0.2% 0.2% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0% Source: Administrative data from respective countries. The majority of national contributory pension schemes in SSA are fairly immature and currently enjoy fiscal surpluses as the ratio of eligible beneficiaries to system contributors is low. As pension systems begin to mature, the ratio of pension system beneficiaries to pension system contributors—also known as a system dependency rate—increases, increasing the fiscal burden on each contributor to finance pension benefits (in the case of pay-as-you-go financed systems). 7 It is important to note that in the beginning—when pension systems are immature—no matter how generous or actuarially unbalanced they may be, they typically generate surpluses. As pension systems mature, these surpluses fall and can be transformed into deficits if the parameters are misaligned. Evaluating the long term financing needs of pension systems under baseline and alternative reform scenarios could help countries adjust system parameters accordingly and also improve long term financial planning overall. While countries may be able to afford the generous benefits now, they may become unaffordable in the future as the ratio of pensioners to contributors increases. Civil service schemes, on the other hand, are generally much more mature and their demographic profiles are often more advanced (i.e., older median age) than the national population. The civil service in many SSA countries expanded and grew in the 1960s and 1970s. While some increases in civil service positions, such as in education, are often tied to growth in the population, in many other cases, the size of the civil service is affected by other factors, such as budgetary expansions and slowdowns. After an initial ramping up of the civil service, most countries have slowed the growth of the civil service due to budgetary pressures. And the life expectancy of civil servants who have higher income and are better educated than the general population is often much higher than the general population. With fewer, young new entrants, and aging of the existing civil servants, the age structure of participants often looks more like that of an aging country than of a young country, with all the fiscal problems that older countries face in financing pensions. In the majority of the countries where data are available, civil service pension schemes tend to be more expensive than national pension schemes. For example, in Mauritius, national pension scheme which is primarily for private sector workers costs 0.4 percent of GDP, whereas civil service pension costs exceed 1 percent of GDP. This also holds true for Tanzania, Uganda, Ethiopia, Benin, and Togo. Even though spending on both national and civil service pension schemes in SSA may not appear high relative to spending in other countries, it is high relative to the number of people receiving pensions—especially when looking at civil service pension schemes. The relatively high cost of civil service pensions can be attributed to a number of factors including: (i) generosity of benefits; and (ii) long duration of benefits, partly attributable to low 8 retirement ages and early retirement provision. Generosity of benefits can arise from a number of parameter choices of a pension scheme: (i) the accrual rate, the rate at which the benefit entitlements build up for each year of service; (ii) the averaging period for wages included in the pensionable wage; (iii) indexation of the pension post-retirement; and (iv) commutation options. 12 The generosity of the civil service schemes is important since the civil service schemes in a country often guide the expectations for what private employers should be expected to provide. It is also important because it results in an increasing fiscal burden, potentially crowding out spending on other key areas essential for human development and poverty reduction such as health, education, and safety nets. Figure 2: Pension Expenditures on Civil Service Pension Scheme as a Share of GDP Civil Service Pension Scheme Expenditure, % GDP in Select Sub- Saharan Africa Economies 3.5% 3.0% Expenditure, % GDP 2.5% 2.0% 1.5% 1.0% 0.5% 0.0% 13 Source: Administrative data from respective countries. 12 Commutation in the pension context occurs where a retiree surrenders part of his or her rights to receive a pension in the form of a future income stream in exchange for receiving an immediate lump sum payment. Commutation rate (factor) defines the relationship between the lump sum payment received and the future income stream foregone. A rate of 10:1 means that a person commuting would receive $10 now for every $1 of future annual income foregone. An actuary normally calculates the commutation rate using life expectancy tables, pension indexation rules and expected interest rates. 13 Civil Service Pension Fund total program expenditure in Zimbabwe was US$ 477,600,000 in 2015. GDP for 2015 was 14.269 billion US dollars; the source for the GDP data is International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database, April 2016. 9 Spending on non-contributory elderly assistance programs in SSA varies between countries and largely depends on the level of the benefits, eligibility age and the size of the elderly population. In 2013, Mauritius spent 2.9 percent of GDP on the universal basic pension program which provides a pension to everyone above age 60 (Mauritius is the oldest country demographically in the region, see Figure 15). Seychelles and Lesotho also allocated a comparatively large share of national income to non-contributory elderly assistance benefits, 1.5 percent and 2.28 percent respectively (Seychelles is the second oldest country in the region whereas Lesotho is the 7th). Nigeria, Kenya, and Uganda have non-contributory pilot pension programs which have not yet been scaled-up for implementation on a national scale. South Africa has a means-tested old age pension paid from age 60 which covers a significant share of the eligible elderly. Even though non-contributory pension programs play an important role in alleviating old age poverty, they typically do so at a substantial cost. Even now, when Africa is still young and the share of population over the age of 60 in total population is quite small – resulting in a small pool of eligible social pension beneficiaries, non-contributory pension costs already range between 1 and 3 percent of GDP in six out of the eight countries with established social pension schemes. Figure 3: Spending on Non-contributory Pensions as a Share of GDP Expenditures % GDP: Universal/Social Pensions 3.50% 2.90% 3.00% 2.50% 2.28% 2.00% 1.52% 1.50% 1.31% 1.15% 0.93% 1.00% 0.50% 0.25% 0.26% 0.00% Swaziland Botswana Cape Namibia South Seychelles Lesotho Mauritius Verde Africa Source: (Pension Watch, 2016), Administrative Data, Statistics Mauritius 10 Elderly coverage While pension spending in Africa may not appear high relative to spending in other countries (OECD countries spend on average of 9 percent of GDP on national pensions), 14 spending is high relative to the numbers of pension system beneficiaries. Generally, the share of elderly in receipt of a contributory pension is very low. On the other hand, the share is high in countries with large social pension schemes (Figure 4 and Figure 5). National pension systems in SSA are accessible to a very narrow share of the elderly population and as a result come at a relatively low cost. First, looking at the elderly coverage of the national pension system, a few countries stand out namely Mauritius, Seychelles, and Cabo Verde for having achieved markedly higher coverage rates in their national pension systems. 15 However, in the majority of the countries, less than 10 percent of the population above age 60—the prevailing retirement age in the region—is in receipt of a national pension. Currently, the footprint of national pension systems in SSA is low—they are relatively inexpensive, but also only cover a very narrow percentage of the elderly population. As such, one of the biggest challenges facing SSA national pension systems remains coverage expansion. The reasons behind low pension coverage in the region are many. Limited to no capacity to save due to low incomes and the large size of the informal labor market rank towards the top of the long list of potential impediments to coverage expansion. A set of countries have non-contributory social pension programs in place which are either universal or means/pensions-tested. Universal pension eligibility criteria are not contingent on prior contributions and are therefore accessible to a much broader share of the elderly population. Eight countries as shown in Table 3 have national social pension programs— Botswana, Namibia, Swaziland, Mauritius, Lesotho, South Africa, Cape Verde, and Seychelles. Generally, pension coverage of the elderly population in the countries with significant non- 14 OECD Pensions at a Glance 2015: Between 2010 and 2015, on average, OECD countries spent 9 percent of their national incomes on public pensions. 15 Mauritius, Seychelles, Cabo Verde, and Botswana also have significant non-contributory pension programs in place which further contribute to higher pension coverage rates among the elderly. 11 contributory pension programs tends to be markedly higher as compared to the countries without non-contributory old age schemes. Table 3: Non-contributory Pension Programs in Select SSA Countries Country Design 16 Beneficiaries, % Spending, % GDP Population 60+ Botswana Universal old age pension paid 88% 0.26% from age 65 Lesotho Pensions-tested benefit paid 62% 2.28% from age 70 Mauritius universal basic pension paid 103% 2.9% from age 60 Swaziland pensions-tested old age grant 77% 0.25% paid from age 60 Cape Verde Means-tested 68% 0.93% Seychelles Universal 88% 1.52% Namibia Universal paid from age 60 114% 1.15% South Africa Means-tested 74% 1.31% Source: (Pension Watch, 2016); Administrative data Elderly coverage of civil service pension schemes is even lower, though absorbing a markedly larger share of GDP than national pension systems. For example, in Uganda, currently 0.4 percent of GDP is being spent on civil service pensions—but this is being spent on only 2.5 percent of the elderly population. Botswana spends 1.7 percent of GDP on civil service pensions which reach only 6 percent of the population over the age of 65. The relatively high cost of civil service pensions (as a share of national income), combined with low coverage of the elderly signals that these scheme are providing pensions that are a very high, especially relative to income per capita. Aside from equity and fiscal sustainability considerations, the generosity of the civil service schemes is also important since the civil service schemes in a country often guide the expectations for what private employers should be expected to provide. 16 Lesotho and Swaziland perform a pensions test to establish eligibility, though in practice the pensions test may not be actually performed. 12 Figure 4: National and Civil Service Pension Coverage of the Population over the Age of 60 National Pension System 70.0% 60.0% 50.0% 40.0% 30.0% 20.0% 10.0% 0.0% Civil Service Pension System 16% 14% Beneficiaries, % Population 60+ 14% 13% 12% 10% 9% 9% 9% 10% 10% 10% 10% 8% 6% 6% 5% 4% 3% 2% 2% 2% 0% 0% Source: Administrative data from respective countries. 13 Figure 5: Total Pension Spending as a Share of GDP vs. Total Pension Coverage of the Population 60+ Total pension spending, % GDP 5.0% 4.5% 4.0% 3.5% 3.0% 2.5% 2.0% 1.5% 1.0% 0.5% 0.0% Ethiopia Zambia Madagascar Cote d'Ivoire Zimbabwe Mauritius Kenya Botswana Benin Liberia Tanzania Seychelles Rwanda Sierra Leone Ghana Guinea Bissau Namibia Uganda Lesotho South Africa Gambia, The Cabo Verde Togo Swaziland Beneficiaries, % population 60+ (total) 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% Sao Tome and… Nigeria Zambia Madagascar Zimbabwe Mauritius Cote d'Ivoire Kenya Botswana Benin Tanzania Rwanda Sierra Leone Liberia Seychelles Namibia Uganda Guinea Bissau Ghana South Africa Gambia, The Lesotho Cabo Verde Togo Swaziland Source: Administrative data from respective countries. IV. Design parameters and characteristics of national and civil service pension systems Contribution rates All national, mandatory contributory pension schemes collect contributions from participants in order to finance system expenditures. The average total contribution rate based on the countries covered (employee and employer) is 12 percent of wages. This is low relative to other regions and is partly explained by the immaturity of most pension schemes which reduces 14 financing needs on a pay-as-you-go basis. Some are already relatively high. The average contribution rate across OECD converges around 18 percent while Ghana, Togo, Ethiopia, Sierra Leone, Tanzania, and Uganda all have rates of at least 15 percent (Figure 6). Figure 6: National Pension System Contribution Rates National Pension System Contribution Rates 25% 20% 20% 18% 18% 16% 17% 14% 15% 15% 15% 15% 12% 12% 9% 10% 10% 10% 10% 10% 6% 6% 7% 4% 5% 0% Source: Administrative data from respective countries. Civil service pension schemes have considerably higher contribution rates in many cases. In fact, in many of the SSA countries, civil service contribution rates approach levels seen in demographically much older countries. This trend is also reflective of the fact that many civil service pension schemes in SSA are already quite mature and as a result have higher financing needs (having been set up decades before the national pension systems). As mentioned above, the demographic composition of civil service schemes can be much older than the demographic profile of the overall population. The already high contribution rates are of concern because there may not be much room to further raise contributions rates in the future when systems become even more mature. It is also important to mention that in a civil service system, as compared to a national system, raising employer contribution rates essentially raises the government costs. Whether the government faces additional deficit to finance or higher contribution costs is immaterial from the government’s perspective. The only way a higher contribution rate would improve government finances is if it is fully paid for by employees, a measure which would result in a decline in their net salaries. 15 Figure 7: Civil Service Pension Scheme Contribution Rates Civil Service Contribution Rates 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% Central African… Mauritania Zambia Ethiopia Madagascar Cote d'Ivoire Burkina Faso Kenya Senegal Lestho Botswana Benin Seychelles Tanzania Average Rwanda Ghana Guinea Bissau Namibia South Sudan Niger Cabo Verde Mali South Africa Chad Swaziland Togo Eritrea Employer Employee Source: Administrative data from respective countries. Accrual rates In the countries where data is available, national pension benefit formulas provide an average 2 percent of individual’s last wage per year of contributions. This parameter is also known as an accrual rate and it is quite high compared to international standards—twice as high as the OECD average, and especially high considering that the average national pension contribution rate is 12 percent of wage. As pension schemes mature, the average length of service should be expected to reach at least 30-35 years, as is the experience in medium to high income countries. A simple calculation of multiplying the accrual rate by the number of covered years can expose that on average SSA economies are promising a replacement rate of 60 percent. Furthermore, longer careers of 35 or more years could result in unsustainably high benefit levels for many countries over the long run. It is important to note that in many countries, contribution histories can be significantly shorter, resulting it markedly lower pensions than would be expected if a person contributed for 30 or more years. The vast majority of SSA countries have an accrual rate that is higher in the first years of employment and lower during the later years of employment. The national pension scheme in Tanzania has an accrual rate that is higher for the first 15 years; in Ethiopia—both national and civil service pension schemes—the accrual rate during the first 10 years is more than twice the 16 accrual rate applied after the first 10 years; the pension system in Ghana also provides for a higher accrual rate during the first 15 years of employment. Most OECD countries have moved to linear accrual rates given the potential distortions in behavior that such non-linear accrual schedules may cause. Against the backdrop of changing demographics, the key question to ask is what governments can afford to provide in benefits in the longer run. In defined benefit plans, changing population structure, characterized by aging, will, over time, cause pension system dependency rates to increase. If one assumes that in the long run there will be about three workers for every pensioner and, if you expect people to work from age 20 to age 65 (45 year career span), a rate of 15 percent average wage can cover a pension of 45 percent of average wage or a 1 percent accrual rate. Therefore, it is important to think about the benefit structure today as not to overpromise when revenues are flush because reducing benefits later on is much more difficult. Figure 8: National Pension System Accrual Rates and Simulated Replacement Rates with 30 years of contributions Country National Pension System Simulated Replacement Accrual Rates Rate After 30 Years Cabo Verde 2.0% 60% Guinea Bissau 2.8% 84% Rwanda 2.0% 60% Tanzania 2 %( 15yrs.) + 1.5% 53% Zambia 1.3% 40% Ghana 2.5 %( 15yrs.) + 1.1% 54% Benin 30% (15 yrs.) + 2% 60% Burkina Faso 2.0% 60% Cameroon 2.0% 60% Central African Republic 1.3% 40% Chad 2.0% 60% Congo, Dem. Rep. 1.7% 50% Ethiopia 30% (10 yrs.) + 1.25% 55% Mozambique 1.7% 51% Sao Tome and Principe 2.5% 75% Sierra Leone 2.0% 60% Togo 1.3% 40% Seychelles 1.8% 53% average 1.9% 57% Source: Administrative data from respective countries. 17 Civil service pension scheme accrual rates are even higher, averaging about 2.5 percent. An accrual rate of 2 percent, assuming a full-career, translates into very high replacement rates especially when compared to lifetime average earnings. Figure 9: Civil Service Pension Scheme Accrual Rates Accrual Rates in SSA Civil Service Pension Schemes vs. OECD 3.5% 3.0% 2.5% 2.0% 1.5% 1.0% 0.5% 0.0% United States Norway Iceland Turkey Zambia Madagascar Austria Kenya Mozambique Slovak Republic Canada Netherlands Poland Korea Slovenia Germany Spain Tanzania Namibia Uganda Italy Luxembourg Cabo Verde Congo, Dem. Rep. Estonia Japan Sweden Belgium Togo Cameroon Swaziland SSA - Civil Service Pension Schemes OECD - National Pension Systems Source: Administrative data from respective countries; OECD Pensions at a Glance 2015 Wage base for pension calculation The wage base—the income measure on which accrual rates are applied—in both national and civil service pension schemes in SSA tends to include only the final few years of employment. The wage base is an important parameter which has a significant impact on the generosity of the pension benefit. OECD countries have almost universally moved to long or even lifetime earnings bases where past earnings are revalued to take into account changes in the average wage of all workers. This approach is more appropriate in terms of the consumption smoothing objective, avoids inequities between workers with different age-earnings profiles and reduces the incentive for gaming the system by inflating salaries just prior to retirement. The issue of equity is best illustrated if we consider the issue that different workers have different salary growth paths. Higher income earners tend to have steeper age earnings profiles, so their pensionable income ends up being much higher than the income on which they have paid contributions throughout their entire career. As a result, there is a transfer in the system to higher income earners. 18 Conversely, lower income individuals typically experience flatter age-earnings profiles so their pensionable income is about the same as the income on which they’ve paid contributions. As a result, lower income earners may receive a lower return compared to higher income earners. On top of that, lower income earners also tend to have shorter life expectancy, drawing a pension for fewer years. Applying accrual rates to final three or five years of income could also induce individuals or employers to seek a drastic increase in income in those final years in order to secure a higher pension, a practice which can be extremely expensive for the pension system. Basing civil servant pensions on final salary can be particularly expensive, since civil servants often receive significant promotions at the end of their career and face a steadily increasing wage based on seniority. Private sector salaries, by contrast, often peak earlier in the career around the late 40s or early 50s and then either hold steady or decline slightly. As a result, the overpayment in benefits relative to average contributions tends to be much higher for civil servants. Additionally, in many cases, civil servants receive promotions and large salary increases just before retirement, which inflate their pensionable salaries, but result in huge costs to the pension system. Figure 10: Wage Base in National and Civil Service Pension Schemes in SSA wage base for pension pension scheme country calculation national Benin final 5 both national and civil service Ethiopia final 3 civil service Swaziland final salary integrated Seychelles last 5 civil service Mauritius last 5 integrated Cabo Verde final salary civil service Madagascar final salary national Sierra Leone best 5 avg. both national and civil service Togo final salary civil service Uganda final salary national Mozambique final salary national Ghana best 3 avg. civil service Tanzania final salary national Tanzania best 5 avg. civil service Namibia final salary civil service Zambia final salary civil service Liberia final salary national Zimbabwe final salary Source: Administrative data from respective countries. 19 Retirement ages Retirement ages in SSA rank on the low side of the international spectrum, with the majority of countries having an official retirement age of 60 or lower. Additionally, in a number of countries—including Gambia, Uganda, and Botswana—there are early retirement provisions which permit retirement as early as age 45. Ghana, Tanzania, and Ethiopia provide the option for early retirement from age 55. On the other hand, the average OECD retirement age is 64 for men and 63 for women. One may argue that since African countries have lower life expectancies than higher income countries, they should also have lower retirement ages. Although life expectancy at birth across the majority of SSA countries is considerably lower than the OECD average, when comparing life expectancy ate age 60—which is the metric one should use when working with pension systems—the difference between the two sets of countries is considerably smaller. Taking the analysis one step further, one could also safely assume that pension system contributors—typically formal workers who tend to have higher wages (better healthcare, safer jobs)—can have even higher life expectancy than the general population, thus justifying an ever higher retirement age and smaller difference between African and OECD countries. Currently, the retirement gap between the two sets of countries is far greater than the gap in life expectancy at age 60, which suggest that retirement ages across a number of SSA countries probably need to start rising, or early retirement needs to be reduced to enable average effective 17 retirement age to increase. 17 Age at which older workers withdraw from the labor force. 20 Figure 11: Expected Years in Retirement, Expressed as Life Expectancy at Retirement Age, in Select SSA Countries and the OECD Expected years in retirement 25 20 15 years 10 5 0 male female Source: Administrative Data, OECD Statistics Figure 12: Average Retirement Ages across SSA and the OECD Normal Retirement Ages 68 66 66 66 64 64 63 62 60 60 59 58 56 54 SSA Africa (average of 20 OECD average current OECD average planned country sample) male female Indexation The experience in SSA has been that most countries adjust pensions in payment to either growth in wages or on an-hoc basis. Indexation post-retirement aims to preserve the relative value of the pension benefit throughout retirement. Most OECD countries have moved to price 21 indexation in order to reduce spending while protecting the real value of pensions. Wage or ad hoc indexation also subject pensioners in specific cohorts to volatility in the real value of their pensions. International best practices suggest that the best approach is to uprate pensions by increases in prices only, with the logic that the individual’s purchasing power should be maintained throughout retirement. Ethiopia and Togo (national system) do not index pensions in payment. While indexing pensions to wage growth could prove expensive, a complete lack of indexing of pensions in payment could put elderly at an increased risk of old age poverty. The lack of any indexation measure would result in a decline in the real value of the pension benefit overtime. Figure 13: Indexation Measures Country National Civil Service Cabo Verde ad-hoc ad-hoc Kenya inflation Namibia higher than inflation Seychelles inflation Tanzania ad-hoc ad-hoc Uganda wages Zambia wages ad-hoc Ghana wages 18 Benin wage Ethiopia none none Madagascar ad-hoc Sierra Leone wages Togo no indexation wages South Africa at least 75% inflation Sao Tome inflation Source: Administrative data from respective countries V. Demographics Over the last six decades, Africa has gone through a demographic transition, moving from a period of high mortality and high fertility rates to one of lower mortality, though still high fertility rates. Historical fertility rates have declined from an average of 6.5 in 1950-1955 to 5.1 18 In the case of Ghana, the national pension scheme indexation policies in practice tend to resemble much more of an ad hoc approach with wage-based as well as flat nominal uprates of pensions. 22 in the 2010-2015. Total Fertility Rate (TFR)19 projections indicate that by 2080, the average TFR in Sub-Saharan Africa would decline to 2.4 births per woman. Between 1950 and 2015, TFRs in Sub-Saharan Africa decreased by 22 percent. In comparison, TFRs across high-income countries during the same period decreased 41 percent from 2.97 to 1.75. Over the coming three decades, TFRs in SSA are projected to further decrease by 28 percent, reaching 3.4 by 2040 while TFRs across high-income countries are projected to remain largely unchanged during the same period. Figure 14: Historic and Projected Total Fertility and Crude Death Rates in Sub-Saharan Africa Total Fertility Rate in Sub-Saharan Africa Crude Death Rate in Sub-Saharan Africa 8.00 30.0 7.00 6.56 25.0 6.00 5.10 20.0 5.00 4.00 15.0 3.00 2.47 10.0 2.00 5.0 1.00 0 0 1950-1955 1960-1965 1970-1975 1980-1985 1990-1995 2000-2005 2010-2015 2020-2025 2030-2035 2040-2045 2050-2055 2060-2065 2070-2075 1950-1955 1960-1965 1970-1975 1980-1985 1990-1995 2000-2005 2010-2015 2020-2025 2030-2035 2040-2045 2050-2055 2060-2065 2070-2075 Source: United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division (2015). World Population Prospects: The 2015 Revision Child Dependency Ratios (CDR) 20 are projected to decrease at a faster pace than the growth in the Old-Age Dependency Ratio (OAD)21 as the steep decline in fertility rates over the past few decades influences the age composition of the population. The result is a projected decline in the Total Dependency Ratio (TDR) 22 providing a “demographic dividend” which may afford an 19 A basic indicator of the level of fertility, calculated by summing age-specific birth rates over all reproductive ages. It may be interpreted as the expected number of children a women who survives to the end of the reproductive age span will have during her lifetime if she experiences the given age-specific rates. 20 The child dependency ratio is the ratio of the population aged 0-14 to the population aged 15-64. 21 The old-age dependency ratio is the ratio of the population aged 65 years or over to the population aged 15-64. 22 The total dependency ratio is the ratio of the sum of the population aged 0-14 and that aged 65+ to the population aged 15-64. 23 ideal opportunity for some countries to invest in more resilient social protection systems. According to UN Population Projections, Total Dependency Ratios (TDR) are expected to decline in the majority of Sub-Saharan Africa countries in the coming several decades. Figure 15: Population over the Age of 65 as a Share in Total Population Population 65+, % total population 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% 2015 2080 Source: United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division (2015). World Population Prospects: The 2015 Revision. Figure 16: Projected Child Dependency Ratio Projected Child Dependency Ratio <15/(15-64) 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 2015 2080 Source: United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division (2015). World Population Prospects: The 2015 Revision. 24 Figure 17: Projected Total Dependency Ratio Projected Total Dependency Ratio (<15 & 65+)/(15-64) 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 Chad Gambia Guinea Sao Tome and Principe Sub-Saharan Africa Côte d'Ivoire Guinea-Bissau Zambia Benin Eritrea Ethiopia Sudan Namibia Niger Burkina Faso Malawi United Republic of Tanzania Burundi Lesotho Sierra Leone South Sudan Liberia Rwanda South Africa Cabo Verde Congo Togo Kenya Mozambique Mauritania Swaziland Seychelles Uganda Madagascar Mauritius Mali Senegal Central African Republic High-income countries Angola Nigeria Cameroon Zimbabwe Botswana Western Europe 2015 2080 Source: United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division (2015). World Population Prospects: The 2015 Revision The share of the population over the age of 65 in total population is projected to increase on average four fold in Sub-Saharan Africa (Figure 15). Currently, the elderly account for about 3 percent of the population; by 2080 the elderly will compose on average 12 percent of the population. In some countries, including Seychelles, Cabo Verde, and Mauritius, the demographic shift will result in one fourth of the population being over the age of 65. Although elderly in SSA on average account for only 3 percent of the population, well below the OECD average of 16 percent, in the coming decades, about half of all SSA countries will approach a similar demographic composition to that of OECD countries today. The projected demographic change, driven by declines in fertility and increases in longevity, will mean that without improvements in the mechanisms for old-age income support that can reach the majority of the population, many SSA countries may be faced with increased rates of old-age poverty. Demographic projections show that Africa’s window to realize the benefits of this demographic transition will likely be open for a couple of more decades. However, the opportunity will not last forever and the region will need to act in order to translate these favorable demographic 25 trends into a demographic dividend. This argument is especially important when it comes to pension system reforms, which typically take several decades to fully materialize. Pension reforms are generally introduced in a way that current pensioners, as well as those individuals that are relatively close to retirement, remain unaffected by the reforms—the approach known as “grandfathering” of rights. Since pension reforms would typically only apply to younger cohorts, the full effects of a reformed pension system may only become visible several decades following the introduction of new parameters. That is why it is important to start thinking about pension reforms now, even though the majority of countries are still enjoying young demographics. The projected growth in the 65 plus population will negatively affect the Old-Age Dependency ratio which is important for the fiscal sustainability of pension systems, particularly under defined-benefit pension systems financed on a pay-as-you-go basis (PAYG). On average, in 2015, there were 13 people of working-age for every person over the age of 65; by 2080, projections show there will only be five people of working-age for every elderly person. Worsening population dependency rates would likely translate into a decline in pension system contribution revenue and a simultaneous increase in pension expenditure—reflecting an increase in the number of elderly eligible for a pension. An unfavorable shift in pension system dependency rates—defined as the number of pension system beneficiaries to the number of pension system contributors—may result in a fiscal shortfall, particularly in the absence of commensurate reforms to account for the changing age structure of the covered population. 26 VI. Annex Retirement Ages in National and Civil Service Pension Schemes in SSA Country Name of Scheme Male Female Benin - national Caisse Nationale de Sécurité Sociale (CNSS) 60 60 Benin - cs FNRB 60 60 Nigeria - integrated CPS (RSA Scheme) 60 60 Liberia - national The National Pension Scheme (NPS) 60 60 Botswana - cs Public Officers Pension Fund (BPOPF) 60 60 Cabo Verde - integrated Instituto Nacional de Previdencia Social (INPS) 65 60 Madagascar - cs CRCM and CPR 60 60 Sierra Leone - integrated National Social Security and Insurance Trust 60 60 Togo - national La Caisse Nationale de Sécurité Sociale (CNSS) 60 60 Guinea Bissau - national National Insitute of Social Security (INSS) 60 60 Guinea Bissau -cs Civil Service Pension Scheme 60 60 Uganda - cs Public Service Pension Fund (PSPF) 60 60 Uganda - national NSSF 55 55 Rwanda - cs Pension and Occupational Hazards Scheme 55 55 Mauritius - national National Pensions Scheme (NPS) 60 60 Mauritius - civil service Civil Service Pension Scheme (CSPS) 65 65 The Gambia - cs Public Service Pension Scheme (PSPS) 60 60 The Gambia - national National Provident Fund (NPF) 60 60 Mozambique - national INSS 60 55 Ghana - integrated SSNIT 60 60 Tanzania - cs PSPF 60 60 Tanzania - national NSSF 60 60 Kenya - cs CSPS 60 60 Kenya - national NSSF 55 55 Seychelles - integrated Seychelles Pension Fund 63 63 Ethiopia - cs Public Servants Social Security Agency (PSSSA) 60 60 Ethiopia - national Private Organization Employees Social Security Agency 60 60 (POESSA) Zambia - national NAPSA 55 55 Zambia - cs PSPF 55 55 Swaziland - cs Public Service Pension Fund (PSPF) 60 60 Swaziland – national Provident Fund 50 50 Sao Tome - national National Institute of Social Security (INSS) 62 57 Namibia - cs GIPF 60 60 Source: Administrative data from respective countries 27 Parameters of a Traditional Pension System Parameters of a traditional pension system include: Eligibility Conditions - Retirement age: Normal age at which people can retire. - Years of service: Minimum years of service required to qualify for a pension (for some occupations, the years of service awarded exceed the years actually worked). Benefit Parameters - Accrual rate: Percentage of wage base earned per year of service. - Wage base: Wage on which pension benefits are calculated, typically average wage earned during a specified period of time. - Averaging period for wage base: Number of years included in the average wage on which the pension benefits are calculated. This can range from last salary to full-career average. - Valorization of past wages: Parameter used to revalue past wages when averaging to account for the fact that wages were earned at different points in time when the cost of living and economy- wide average wages differed from what exists at the time of retirement. This is typically the economy-wide average wage growth between the time the wages were earned and the time of retirement. - Indexation: Parameter that determines how pensions are increased after retirement. It is typically linked to inflation or wage growth or some combination of the two. Contribution Rates Workers, their employers, and sometimes the government make contributions as a percentage of the net or gross wage. These contributions are typically subject to a ceiling and sometimes subject to a minimum as well. Source: Schwarz, Anita M., Omar S. Arias. 2014. The Inverting Pyramid: Pension Systems Facing Demographic Challenges in Europe and Central Asia. 28 Glossary of Pension Terms Accrual rate. The rate at which pension entitlement is built up relative to earnings per year of service in earnings‐related schemes—for example, one‐sixtieth of final salary. Benefit rate. The ratio of the average pension to the average wage, which could be expressed as relative to the economy wide average wage or to the individual’s specific average or final wage. Commutation. Exchange of part of the annuity component of a pension for an immediate lump sum. Defined benefit. A pension plan with a guarantee by the insurer or pension agency that a benefit based on a prescribed formula will be paid. Can be fully funded or unfunded and notional. Defined contribution. A pension plan in which the periodic contribution is prescribed and the benefit depends on the contribution plus the investment return. Can be fully funded or notional and nonfinancial. Full funding. The accumulation of pension reserves that total 100 percent of the present value of all pension liabilities owed to current members. Funding. Accumulation of assets in advance to meet future pension liabilities. Indexation. Increases in benefits by reference to an index, usually of prices, although in some cases of average earnings. Means‐tested benefit. A benefit that is paid only if the recipient’s income falls below a certain level. Occupational pension scheme. An arrangement by which an employer provides retirement benefits to employees. Old‐age dependency ratio. The ratio of older persons to working‐age individuals. The old‐age dependency ratio may refer to the number of persons over 60 divided by, for example, the number of persons ages 15–59, the number of persons over 60 divided by the number of persons ages 20–59, and so forth. 29 Pay‐as‐you‐go. In its strictest sense, a method of financing whereby current outlays on pension benefits are paid out of current revenues from an earmarked tax, often a payroll tax. Pension coverage rate. The number of workers actively contributing to a publicly mandated contributory or retirement scheme, divided by the estimated labor force or by the working age population. Pensionable earnings. The portion of remuneration on which pension benefits and contributions are calculated. Portability. The ability to transfer accrued pension rights between plans. Provident fund. A fully funded, defined contribution scheme in which funds are managed by the public sector. Replacement rate. The value of a pension as a proportion of a worker’s wage during a base period, such as the last year or two before retirement or more, or the entire lifetime average wage. Also denotes the average pension of a group of pensioners as a proportion of the average wage of the group. System dependency ratio. The ratio of persons receiving pensions from a certain pension scheme divided by the number of workers contributing to the same scheme in the same period. System maturation. The process by which a pension system moves from being immature, with young workers contributing to the system, but with few benefits being paid out since the initial elderly have not contributed and thus are not eligible for benefits, to being mature, with the proportion of elderly receiving pensions relatively equivalent to their proportion of the population. Universal flat pension. Pensions paid solely on the basis of age and citizenship, without regard to work or contribution records. Valorization of earnings. A method of revaluing earnings by predetermined factors such as total or average wage growth to adjust for changes in prices, wage levels, or economic growth. In pay‐ as‐you‐go systems, pensions are usually based on some percentage of average wage. This 30 average wage is calculated over some period of time, ranging from full‐career average to last salary. If the period for which earnings history enters into the benefit formula is longer than the last salary, the actual wages earned are usually revalued to adjust for these types of changes. Vesting period. The minimum amount of time required to qualify for full and irrevocable ownership of pension benefits. 31 References (2016). Retrieved from Statistics Mauritius: http://statsmauritius.govmu.org/English/Pages/default.aspx Dorfman, M. 2015. "Pension Patterns in Sub-Saharan Africa", Social Protection & Labor Discussion Paper No. 1503, World Bank, Washington, DC. Filmer, D., and L. Fox. 2014. Youth Employment in Sub-Saharan Africa. Africa Development Forum Series. Washington, DC: World Bank. International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2015. "World Economic Outlook Database", October, IMF, Washington, DC. Nigeria National Pension Commission. 2016. Retrieved from http://www.pencom.gov.ng/index.php Organisation for Economic Development and Co-operation (OECD). 2015. Pensions at a Glance 2015: OECD and G20 indicatord. Paris: OECD. Palacios, R. 2016. "Ethiopia’s Pension System: Background, Current Status And Prospects For Future Expansion", World Bank, Washington, DC. Palacios, R., and E. Whitehouse. 2006. "Civil-Service Pension Schemes around the World", SP Discussion Paper No. 0602, World Bank, Washington, DC. Pension Watch. 2016. "Pension Watch: Social Protection in Older Age", Retrieved from HelpAge International Pension Watch Database: http://www.pension-watch.net/ Sluchynsky, O. 2015. "Defining, Measuring, and Benchmarking Administrative Expenditures of Mandatory Social Security Programs", Social Protection & Labor Discussion Paper No. 1501, World Bank, Washington, DC. Towers Watson. 2014. "Nigeria: Changes in 2014 Pension Reform Act Increase Need for Preparation and Communication", August 27, Retrieved from Towers Watson Global News Briefs: https://www.towerswatson.com/en/Insights/Newsletters/Global/global-news- 32 briefs/2014/08/nigeria-changes-in-new-2014-pension-reform-act-increases-need-for- preparation-and-communication United Nations. 2015. "Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division", Retrieved from World Population Prospects . World Bank. 2014. World Bank Workshop on Coherent Pension Policy in Africa, Accra, Ghana, December. ____. 2016. World Development Indicators. Washington, DC: World Bank. Zviniene, A., and M. Guven. 2015. Cabo Verde: Long Term Projections of the Pension System. Washington, DC: World Bank. 33 Social Protection & Labor Discussion Paper Series Titles 2014-2016 No. Title 1610 Pension Systems in Sub-Saharan Africa: Brief Review of Design Parameters and Key Performance Indicators by Miglena Abels and Melis U. Guven, October 2016 1609 Household Enterprises in Fragile and Conflict-Affected States: Results from a Qualitative Toolkit Piloted in Liberia, Volume 2 – Annexes by Emily Weedon and Gwendolyn Heaner, August 2016 1608 Household Enterprises in Fragile and Conflict-Affected States: Results from a Qualitative Toolkit Piloted in Liberia, Volume 1 – Report by Emily Weedon and Gwendolyn Heaner, August 2016 1607 Benefits and Costs of Social Pensions in Sub-Saharan Africa by Melis U. Guven and Phillippe G. Leite, June 2016 1606 Assessing Benefit Portability for International Migrant Workers: A Review of the Germany- Turkey Bilateral Social Security Agreement by Robert Holzmann, Michael Fuchs, Seçil Paçacı Elitok and Pamela Dale, May 2016 1605 Do Bilateral Social Security Agreements Deliver on the Portability of Pensions and Health Care Benefits? A Summary Policy Paper on Four Migration Corridors Between EU and Non-EU Member States by Robert Holzmann, May 2016 1604 Assessing Benefit Portability for International Migrant Workers: A Review of the France-Morocco Bilateral Social Security Agreement by Robert Holzmann, Florence Legro and Pamela Dale, May 2016 1603 Assessing Benefit Portability for International Migrant Workers: A Review of the Belgium-Morocco Bilateral Social Security Agreement by Robert Holzmann, Jacques Wels and Pamela Dale, May 2016 1602 Assessing Benefit Portability for International Migrant Workers: A Review of the Austria-Turkey Bilateral Social Security Agreement by Robert Holzmann, Michael Fuchs, Seçil Paçaci Elitok and Pamela Dale, May 2016 1601 The Greek Pension Reform Strategy 2010-2016 by Georgios Symeonidis, July 2016 1507 Integrating Disaster Response and Climate Resilience in Social Protection Programs in the Pacific Island Countries by Cecilia Costella and Oleksiy Ivaschenko, September 2015 1506 Effectiveness of Targeting Mechanisms Utilized in Social Protection Programs in Bolivia by Ignacio Apella and Gastón Blanco, September 2015 1505 Kyrgyz Republic: Social Sectors at a Glance by João Pedro Azevedo, Paula Calvo, Minh Nguyen and Josefina Posadas, August 2015 1504 Entering the City: Emerging Evidence and Practices with Safety Nets in Urban Areas by Ugo Gentilini, July 2015 1503 Pension Patterns in Sub-Saharan Africa by Mark Dorfman, July 2015 1502 Social Protection in Fragile and Conflict-Affected Countries: Trends and Challenges by Mirey Ovadiya, Adea Kryeziu, Syeda Masood and Eric Zapatero, April 2015 1501 Defining, Measuring, and Benchmarking Administrative Expenditures of Mandatory Social Security Programs by Oleksiy Sluchynsky, February 2015 1425 Old-Age Financial Protection in Malaysia: Challenges and Options by Robert Holzmann, November 2014 1424 Profiling the Unemployed: A Review of OECD Experiences and Implications for Emerging Economies by Artan Loxha and Matteo Morgandi, August 2014 1423 Any Guarantees? An Analysis of China’s Rural Minimum Living Standard Guarantee Program by Jennifer Golan, Terry Sicular and Nithin Umapathi, August 2014 1422 World Bank Support for Social Safety Nets 2007-2013: A Review of Financing, Knowledge Services and Results by Colin Andrews, Adea Kryeziu and Dahye Seo, June 2014 1421 STEP Skills Measurement Surveys: Innovative Tools for Assessing Skills by Gaëlle Pierre, Maria Laura Sanchez Puerta, Alexandria Valerio and Tania Rajadel, July 2014 1420 Our Daily Bread: What is the Evidence on Comparing Cash versus Food Transfers? by Ugo Gentilini, July 2014 1419 Rwanda: Social Safety Net Assessment by Alex Kamurase, Emily Wylde, Stephen Hitimana and Anka Kitunzi, July 2012 1418 Niger: Food Security and Safety Nets by Jenny C. Aker, Carlo del Ninno, Paul A. Dorosh, Menno Mulder-Sibanda and Setareh Razmara, February 2009 1417 Benin: Les Filets Sociaux au Bénin Outil de Réduction de la Pauvreté par Andrea Borgarello et Damien Mededji, Mai 2011 1416 Madagascar Three Years into the Crisis: An Assessment of Vulnerability and Social Policies and Prospects for the Future by Philippe Auffret, May 2012 1415 Sudan Social Safety Net Assessment by Annika Kjellgren, Christina Jones-Pauly, Hadyiat El-Tayeb Alyn, Endashaw Tadesse and Andrea Vermehren, May 2014 1414 Tanzania Poverty, Growth, and Public Transfers: Options for a National Productive Safety Net Program by W. James Smith, September 2011 1413 Zambia: Using Social Safety Nets to Accelerate Poverty Reduction and Share Prosperity by Cornelia Tesliuc, W. James Smith and Musonda Rosemary Sunkutu, March 2013 1412 Mali Social Safety Nets by Cécile Cherrier, Carlo del Ninno and Setareh Razmara, January 2011 1411 Swaziland: Using Public Transfers to Reduce Extreme Poverty by Lorraine Blank, Emma Mistiaen and Jeanine Braithwaite, November 2012 1410 Togo: Towards a National Social Protection Policy and Strategy by Julie van Domelen, June 2012 1409 Lesotho: A Safety Net to End Extreme Poverty by W. James Smith, Emma Mistiaen, Melis Guven and Morabo Morojele, June 2013 1408 Mozambique Social Protection Assessment: Review of Social Assistance Programs and Social Protection Expenditures by Jose Silveiro Marques, October 2012 1407 Liberia: A Diagnostic of Social Protection by Andrea Borgarello, Laura Figazzolo and Emily Weedon, December 2011 1406 Sierra Leone Social Protection Assessment by José Silvério Marques, John Van Dyck, Suleiman Namara, Rita Costa and Sybil Bailor, June 2013 1405 Botswana Social Protection by Cornelia Tesliuc, José Silvério Marques, Lillian Mookodi, Jeanine Braithwaite, Siddarth Sharma and Dolly Ntseane, December 2013 1404 Cameroon Social Safety Nets by Carlo del Ninno and Kaleb Tamiru, June 2012 1403 Burkina Faso Social Safety Nets by Cécile Cherrier, Carlo del Ninno and Setareh Razmara, January 2011 1402 Social Insurance Reform in Jordan: Awareness and Perceptions of Employment Opportunities for Women by Stefanie Brodmann, Irene Jillson and Nahla Hassan, June 2014 1401 Social Assistance and Labor Market Programs in Latin America: Methodology and Key Findings from the Social Protection Database by Paula Cerutti, Anna Fruttero, Margaret Grosh, Silvana Kostenbaum, Maria Laura Oliveri, Claudia Rodriguez-Alas, Victoria Strokova, June 2014 To view Social Protection & Labor Discussion papers published prior to 2013, please visit www.worldbank.org/spl. Social Protection & Labor Discussion Paper Series Titles 2014-2016 No. Title 1612 How to Target Households in Adaptive Social Protection Systems? Relative Efficiency of Proxy Means Test and Household Economy Analysis in Niger by Pascale Schnitzer, October 2016 1611 Pensions for Public-Sector Employees: Lessons from OECD Countries’ Experience by Edward Whitehouse, October 2016 1610 Pension Systems in Sub-Saharan Africa: Brief Review of Design Parameters and Key Performance Indicators by Miglena Abels and Melis U. Guven, October 2016 1609 Household Enterprises in Fragile and Conflict-Affected States: Results from a Qualitative Toolkit Piloted in Liberia, Volume 2 – Annexes by Emily Weedon and Gwendolyn Heaner, August 2016 1608 Household Enterprises in Fragile and Conflict-Affected States: Results from a Qualitative Toolkit Piloted in Liberia, Volume 1 – Report by Emily Weedon and Gwendolyn Heaner, August 2016 1607 Benefits and Costs of Social Pensions in Sub-Saharan Africa by Melis U. Guven and Phillippe G. Leite, June 2016 1606 Assessing Benefit Portability for International Migrant Workers: A Review of the Germany- Turkey Bilateral Social Security Agreement by Robert Holzmann, Michael Fuchs, Seçil Paçacı Elitok and Pamela Dale, May 2016 1605 Do Bilateral Social Security Agreements Deliver on the Portability of Pensions and Health Care Benefits? A Summary Policy Paper on Four Migration Corridors Between EU and Non-EU Member States by Robert Holzmann, May 2016 1604 Assessing Benefit Portability for International Migrant Workers: A Review of the France-Morocco Bilateral Social Security Agreement by Robert Holzmann, Florence Legro and Pamela Dale, May 2016 1603 Assessing Benefit Portability for International Migrant Workers: A Review of the Belgium-Morocco Bilateral Social Security Agreement by Robert Holzmann, Jacques Wels and Pamela Dale, May 2016 1602 Assessing Benefit Portability for International Migrant Workers: A Review of the Austria-Turkey Bilateral Social Security Agreement by Robert Holzmann, Michael Fuchs, Seçil Paçaci Elitok and Pamela Dale, May 2016 1601 The Greek Pension Reform Strategy 2010-2016 by Georgios Symeonidis, July 2016 1507 Integrating Disaster Response and Climate Resilience in Social Protection Programs in the Pacific Island Countries by Cecilia Costella and Oleksiy Ivaschenko, September 2015 1506 Effectiveness of Targeting Mechanisms Utilized in Social Protection Programs in Bolivia by Ignacio Apella and Gastón Blanco, September 2015 1505 Kyrgyz Republic: Social Sectors at a Glance by João Pedro Azevedo, Paula Calvo, Minh Nguyen and Josefina Posadas, August 2015 1504 Entering the City: Emerging Evidence and Practices with Safety Nets in Urban Areas by Ugo Gentilini, July 2015 1503 Pension Patterns in Sub-Saharan Africa by Mark Dorfman, July 2015 1502 Social Protection in Fragile and Conflict-Affected Countries: Trends and Challenges by Mirey Ovadiya, Adea Kryeziu, Syeda Masood and Eric Zapatero, April 2015 1501 Defining, Measuring, and Benchmarking Administrative Expenditures of Mandatory Social Security Programs by Oleksiy Sluchynsky, February 2015 1425 Old-Age Financial Protection in Malaysia: Challenges and Options by Robert Holzmann, November 2014 1424 Profiling the Unemployed: A Review of OECD Experiences and Implications for Emerging Economies by Artan Loxha and Matteo Morgandi, August 2014 1423 Any Guarantees? An Analysis of China’s Rural Minimum Living Standard Guarantee Program by Jennifer Golan, Terry Sicular and Nithin Umapathi, August 2014 1422 World Bank Support for Social Safety Nets 2007-2013: A Review of Financing, Knowledge Services and Results by Colin Andrews, Adea Kryeziu and Dahye Seo, June 2014 1421 STEP Skills Measurement Surveys: Innovative Tools for Assessing Skills by Gaëlle Pierre, Maria Laura Sanchez Puerta, Alexandria Valerio and Tania Rajadel, July 2014 1420 Our Daily Bread: What is the Evidence on Comparing Cash versus Food Transfers? by Ugo Gentilini, July 2014 1419 Rwanda: Social Safety Net Assessment by Alex Kamurase, Emily Wylde, Stephen Hitimana and Anka Kitunzi, July 2012 1418 Niger: Food Security and Safety Nets by Jenny C. Aker, Carlo del Ninno, Paul A. Dorosh, Menno Mulder-Sibanda and Setareh Razmara, February 2009 1417 Benin: Les Filets Sociaux au Bénin Outil de Réduction de la Pauvreté par Andrea Borgarello et Damien Mededji, Mai 2011 1416 Madagascar Three Years into the Crisis: An Assessment of Vulnerability and Social Policies and Prospects for the Future by Philippe Auffret, May 2012 1415 Sudan Social Safety Net Assessment by Annika Kjellgren, Christina Jones-Pauly, Hadyiat El-Tayeb Alyn, Endashaw Tadesse and Andrea Vermehren, May 2014 1414 Tanzania Poverty, Growth, and Public Transfers: Options for a National Productive Safety Net Program by W. James Smith, September 2011 1413 Zambia: Using Social Safety Nets to Accelerate Poverty Reduction and Share Prosperity by Cornelia Tesliuc, W. James Smith and Musonda Rosemary Sunkutu, March 2013 1412 Mali Social Safety Nets by Cécile Cherrier, Carlo del Ninno and Setareh Razmara, January 2011 1411 Swaziland: Using Public Transfers to Reduce Extreme Poverty by Lorraine Blank, Emma Mistiaen and Jeanine Braithwaite, November 2012 1410 Togo: Towards a National Social Protection Policy and Strategy by Julie van Domelen, June 2012 1409 Lesotho: A Safety Net to End Extreme Poverty by W. James Smith, Emma Mistiaen, Melis Guven and Morabo Morojele, June 2013 1408 Mozambique Social Protection Assessment: Review of Social Assistance Programs and Social Protection Expenditures by Jose Silveiro Marques, October 2012 1407 Liberia: A Diagnostic of Social Protection by Andrea Borgarello, Laura Figazzolo and Emily Weedon, December 2011 1406 Sierra Leone Social Protection Assessment by José Silvério Marques, John Van Dyck, Suleiman Namara, Rita Costa and Sybil Bailor, June 2013 1405 Botswana Social Protection by Cornelia Tesliuc, José Silvério Marques, Lillian Mookodi, Jeanine Braithwaite, Siddarth Sharma and Dolly Ntseane, December 2013 1404 Cameroon Social Safety Nets by Carlo del Ninno and Kaleb Tamiru, June 2012 1403 Burkina Faso Social Safety Nets by Cécile Cherrier, Carlo del Ninno and Setareh Razmara, January 2011 1402 Social Insurance Reform in Jordan: Awareness and Perceptions of Employment Opportunities for Women by Stefanie Brodmann, Irene Jillson and Nahla Hassan, June 2014 1401 Social Assistance and Labor Market Programs in Latin America: Methodology and Key Findings from the Social Protection Database by Paula Cerutti, Anna Fruttero, Margaret Grosh, Silvana Kostenbaum, Maria Laura Oliveri, Claudia Rodriguez-Alas, Victoria Strokova, June 2014 To view Social Protection & Labor Discussion papers published prior to 2013, please visit www.worldbank.org/spl. Abstract This paper summarizes key design characteristics and performance indicators of national and civil service pension schemes in Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA). It is intended to serve as a resource in pension reform efforts in the region. The paper delivers an up-to date assessment of the main design parameters, key performance metrics, and main challenges facing pension systems in SSA. The information provided in the paper aims to capture current trends in the region and benchmark performance and pension system design choices made by countries against international experience. Section I provides an overview of mandatory national pension systems in the region whereas Section II presents the key design features of civil service pension schemes. Section III analyzes the performance of both national and civil service pension schemes; particular attention is paid to the fiscal performance and equity of the pension schemes. Pension system design parameters of both national and civil service pension schemes are discussed in section IV. Section V aims to enhance the note by providing relevant demographic data and analysis. About this series Social Protection & Labor Discussion Papers are published to communicate the results of The World Bank’s work to the development community with the least possible delay. This paper therefore has not been prepared in accordance with the procedures appropriate for formally edited texts. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed herein are those of the author(s), and do not necessarily reflect the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgement on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. For more information, please contact the Social Protection Advisory Service, The World Bank, 1818 H Street, N.W., Room G7-803, Washington, DC 20433 USA. Telephone: (202) 458-5267, Fax: (202) 614-0471, E-mail: socialprotection@worldbank.org or visit us on-line at www.worldbank.org/spl. © 2016 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank