Polloy Research FORKING PAPERS Transport Infrastructure and Urban Development Department The World Bank June 1992 WPS 926 Options for Reshaping the Railway Neil E. Moyer and Louis S. Thompson Changing transport demands and growing competition from trucks, autos, and air transport are forcing the monolithic railway to change. Options for change must be adapted to different national Pad other circumstances, with a suitable tradeoff be- tween efficiency of production and effectiveness in meeting market needs. Pohcy Re carchWoddngPpe diseinatethe findings ofwoik in prognss and eouDgetheexchangcofideasamongBank staffand aU otheas interested in development issues. These papers carry the name of the authors, rflect only their views, and should be used and cited accordingly. The findings. interpetations, and conclusions are the authors' own. They should not be attributed to the World Bank, its Board of Directors. its management, ot any of its member countnies. Policy Research| Transport WPS 926 This paper - a product of the Transport Division, Infrastructure and Urban Development Department - is part of a larger effort in the Department to analyze and improve the effectiveness of transport enterprises. Copies of the paper are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Please contact Barbara Gregory, room S1O-049, extension 33744 (June 1992, 59 pages). Li many countries, the mismatch between whRt the railways unlikely to permit a serious level of competition in markets offer and what customers want has caused significant they have traditionally controlled. A need for intranodal econonic inefficiency and severe financial strains for the rail competition - either in large countries with well- railways and their government owners. The concept of the developed rail systems or in adjacent countries with railway as a monolithic entity is so strong in many countri.s integrated economies, as in the European Community - as to be a roadblock against reshaping the railway. Yet such could promote greater use of competitive access solutions. reshaping has already taken place successfully in such The "wholesaler" option should accomplish an countries as Canada, Japan, New Zealand, Spain, Sweden, excellent marketing job, but the actual operation would the United Kingdom, and the United States - and shows remain in monolithic hands. When the quality of customer promise elsewhere. service is paramount (as in container landbridge services or Where incremental approaches are feasible, a useful in certain unit train applications) or when the rail service is first step in bringing the market to the railway is a transition driven by external requirements (as in container dry ports), to some form of lines-of-business strategy, which, like it may be best if the railway is a "wholesaler" selling to a British Rail, could be intensified in stages. Where incre- "retailer" who relates directly (and more effectively) with mental approaches have not worked, cannot work, or have the customer. reached the limits of their effectiveness, a country should The "toll rail enterprise" might come closest to consider the full range of options Moyer and Thompson reflecting a theoretical model of marketing effectiveness, explore in this paper. yet it would generate potential operating conflicts and The nonolithic railway rates high on apparent higher transaction costs - and would also call for the technical efficiency (conflicts are decided by executive fiat greatest administrative capability in the owning govern- and transacdon costs are minimized) but low on marketing ment. Where a rail service is easily separable from other effectiveness. A monolithic railway might be an appropriate services, or where the service does not confli't heavily with choice for a fully planned, command economy (or for a true other services, a "toll rail enterprise" solution may be single-purpose operator such as a mining evacuation desirable - as with Amtrak, VIA (the Canadian Amtrak), railway) - although a desire for better measurement of and the Japanese Rail Freight Corporation. Situations in performance might still lead to a line-of-business organiza- which this approach might work best: granting trackage tion. rights to Zimbabwe to serve the port of Beira in Mozamn- The lines-of-business option improves accountability bique and to Russian Railways to serve the port of Tallinn and responsiveness to markets but operating conflicts and in Estonia. transaction costs increase as the monolith becomes divided. One generalization holds true in all circumstances: a Economies in transition, small railways with a restricted monolithic railway does not function well in a market number of customers, or larger railways seeking to depart economy in competition with privately owned, properly incrementally from a monolidtic framework will probably (lighdy) regulated competitors - especially trucking. All find the line-of-business approach the best first step. attempts to commercialize, corporatize, or increase the role The corretitive access option introduces intramodal of the private sector in railway activities have started with competition in selected markets, while maintaining unitary one or another form of reshaping the railway entity. control over most railway operations. Unless the distribu- Soludons will vary, but the universal objective as an tion of "franchises" is self-balancing - providing clear economy becomes more market-driven is to make the benefits to all participants - the owning railways are railway more market-sensitive. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work under way in the Bank. An objective of the series is to get these fndings out quickly, even if presentations are less than fully polished. The fndings, interpretations, and conclusions in these papers do not necessarily represent official Bank policy. Produced by the Policy Research Dissemination Center CONTENTS Acknowledgement Summary and Conclusions ....................................... i 1 Background ........................................ 1 Historical Context ....... 1 Separation is Not the Only Option ........ .................. 4 2 hIe Generic Options ...................................... 6 Option 1: The Monolithic Railway ......................... 7 Option 2: Lines-of-Business Organization ..................... 9 Option 3: Competitive Access ......................... 17 Option4: The"Wholesaler" . ......................... 28 Option 5: The "Toll Rail" Entexprise ....................... 30 3 Imues and Technical Considerations .......... ................. 36 Issues .................................... 36 Technical Considerations ............................... 46 Bibliography ....... 53 Acronyms ......... 59 TABLE SC.1 ....... v SC.2 ....... v SC.3 ........ -i 2.1 .. 10 2.2 ....... 18 2.3 .............................. 20 2.4 ........ 21 2.5 ........ 23 3.1 ........ 37 3.2 ....... 40 3.3 ....... 40 3.4 ....... 42 3.5 ....... 42 3.6 ........44 3.7 ....... 44 3.8 ....... 45 CONTENTS FIGURES 2.1 .8 2.2 .. 2.3 .14 2.4 .16 2.5 .24 2.6 .29 2.7 .31 2.8 .33 3.1 .39 ACKNOWLDGEMENT The authors express their gratitude to Clell Harral, Hans Apitz, Richard Scurfield, Glen Fisher, Phil Anderson, Cliff Winston, Jean Bouley, Larry McCaffrey, and Robert W. Blanchette for their time and incisive comments. This paper is stronger because of their thoughts and (in some cases continuing) differences of opinion. Special thanks to Jeff Gutman who recognized the need for this paper, and who supported it and shaped it at the very beginning. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS Background: Why Reshape the Railway? i. Historically, railways throughout the world developed as monolithic organizations, controlling their own facilities, performing all operating and administrative functions, and unilateraily determining what services to provide to an often captive market. Such an evolution faithfully reflected the conditions of the times. In the nineteenth century, railways represented the vanguard of technology; they could reliably depend only on themselves to produce most of their material needs. Moreover, as the dominant means of overland transport, railways from their inception could essentially dictate the products they would offer (without much regard to customer preferences) and the prices they would charge (without attention to cost considerations), subject only to any. available intramodal competition. Acknowledging this monopoly status, regulatory structures arose to control it, and in many countries perpetuated the illusion of monopoly long after competing modes had emerged in the transportation marketplace. In the socialist economies, the adoption of central planning reinforced the railway as a unitary organization. Throughout the world, therefore, autarky and monopoly produced and preserved the railway monolith. ii. In most countries, the production, market, and political conditions originally favoring monolithic rail transport entities no longer exist. Although constantly evolving and improving, railway technology is esoteric no longer. Railways are increasingly able to rely on a host of outside suppliers and service organizations to perform infrastructure, maintenance, adminis- trative, and even operating functions, as dictated by economic considerations. Moreover, in the presence of mature, competing transport modes, railways can no longer be oblivious to customer preferences in designing services, nor can they price services without regard to their costs. Finally, the extreme centralization of all economic decisions that formerly characterized the socialist states (and their railways) is dissipating. In light of all these changes, the traditional unitary railway -- in which the lowest official dealing with both revenues and costs may well be the general manager or the president -- has become incongruous, and not just from a theoretical viewpoint. iii. In many countries, the mismatch between what the railways offer and what customers want has caused both pronounced economic inefficiencies and severe financial strains for the railways and their government owners. In much of the world, the railways' losses of market share, burgeoning deficits, and mushrooming demands for State funding have led to enormous pressures on governments to effect a fundamental restructuring of the railway entity itself, and of its relationship with the State. iv. These underlying pressures may manifest themselves in explicit and implicit Government objectives for reshaping the railway. Typical objectives may include: Improve economic efficiency; * Reduce railway deficits and government funding burdens; * Promote creative and aggressive management; * Allow and encourage the railway to function as a market-sensitive, commercial enterprise; * Enhance intramodal or intermodal transport competition; * Obtain improved management information and performance evaluation through financial separation; * Equalize conditions for rail vis-a-vis other modes; * Increase the role of the private sector in railways; * Foster public policy in planning and national development; and * Shake the foundations of the old railway order and its entrenched interests. V. One approach -- "separation" of fixed facility ownership from train operations -- has gained prominence in recent years as a response to some of the objectives above. This emphasis on 'separationI has, to some degree, misrepresented and overimmplified the issue. In fact, a full continuum of options exists for reshaping the railway entity. 'a any country, the aptness of each option depends on the relative weight and urgency of governmental objectives; on the relative importance of the various markets served by the railway; on the available technology; on the scale of railway operations as a whole; and on the administrative capabilities of the government and of the railway. Moreover, in practice, the vastly complex three-dimensional matrix of operating functions, service types, and geographic zones that characterizes mature railway systems may call for a sophisticated combination of restructuring options, rather than for any single solution. One option might be chosen for freight (or freight sub-markets), another for intercity passenger, and yet another for suburban passenger. vi. Focusing on selected points on the continuum, this paper explores generic reshaping options that can be altered or combined to fit the unique circumstances of individual railway entities. The Generic Options vii. In essence, each option expresses a possible set of relationships between the railway entity/entities, the markets served, and the functions performed. Indeed, today's railways perform a wide range of rail transportation services. Typically, this range includes intercity passenger, suburban passenger, and freight markets; each market can, in turn, be further categorized (for example, into "for-profit" and "not-for-profit" segments; by geographic region, - iii - line, or city-pair; by class of service for passenger; and by commodity or service characteristics for freight). In serving these markets, regardless of the level of service differentiation, railways must somehow manage the following basic functions: • Ownership, improvement, and maintenance of fixed facilities; * Control of operations (i.e., dispatching); * Train movement; * Equipment provision and maintenance; * Marketing; and * Financial control and accountability. yiii. Option 1: The Monolithic Railway (Status Quo Option). Traditionally, the monolithic railway was almost wholly production-oriented, and was organized so that each functional department exercised total and undifferentiated responsibility over all services. For example, a single department might control maintenance of all coaches, wagons, and locomotives; or the train movement department might maintain a single roster of employees who could be assigned indiscriminately to freight, intercity, or suburban passenger jobs. ix. Option 2: Lines-of-Business Organization. As markets, technology, and operating practices have evolved, even on monolithic railways, commonality has diminished to a surprising degree among many of the assets and resources used in different markets. Thus, for instance, electrified suburban passenger services employ self-propelled, multiple-unit coaches necessitating specialized workshops; tracks with heavy commuter flows tend not to have much freight. Advances in management information systems have, furthermore, improved the accuracy and timeliness with which direct as well as remaining common costs can be assigned to particular services. These two converging trends have enabled railway entities to reorganize themselves (to varying degrees of depth) according to lines of business so as to foster comprehensive business planning, market- and cost-sensitive decisions, and more responsive operations for each service performed. In essence, this is an option for maldng the monolithic railway less monolithic in a service, if not in a production sense, while reducing the entity start-up costs implicit in other alternatives. X. Option 3: Competitive Access. Under this option, competing railway companies would have exclusive control over some trackage, but would also have (and give) the right of competitive access over the trackage of (to) other companies. One variation within this option would be a "regional overlap" approach, wherein regional (or national) operators would be given the right to operate over tracks leading to major traffic centers in adjoining regions (or countries). Smaller-scale options such as trackage rights and joint terminal agreements provide miniature examples of the cowpetitive access approach. - iv - xi. Option 4: The "Wholesaler." The railway entity would own and operate the fixed facility and perform all operations on behalf of marketing entities who would be the 'retailers." This would mean that the railway itself would only haul trains; it would do no marketing to shippers. It r;ght famish some, or all, of the rolling stock and crews, at the retailer's option. xii. Option 5: The "Toil Rail" Enterprise. The entire fixed facility (track, signals, communications, electrification, and so forth), except for exclusive facilities, would be the property and responsibility of one owner. There could be one or more authorized user(s), each of which would pay tolls for use of the facility. The tolls would be public and non- discriminatory, but might well vary by train size, axle load, direction of travel, time of day, season, and similar criteria. In a sense, the toll rail enterprise would be much like a regulated public utility. xiii. For each of the above options, Table SC. 1 shows how functions would be assigned to entities, and Table SC.2 refers to examples among today's railways. lssues xiv. In evaluating these options, railway planners need to consider a series of issues that reflect both actual experience and a priori analysis. The list of issues below is indicative, not exhaustive; not all issues will apply to all options. As evidenced by successful initiatives in such countries as the United Kingdom, Canada, Japan, Spain, and the United States, these issues do not constitute insuperable obstacles to reshaping railway entities. xv. Market Definition. Will the resultant entity/entities have a clear and better view of the markets they serve and the full impacts of their business decisions on those markets? xvi. Financial Accountability. Will mechanisms exist to fix both cost and revenue responsibility at appropriate locations in the organization(s), so that effective business planning and decisions can occur? xvii. Operations Coordination. If the monolith is divided, what mechanism(s) will be established to resolve the inevitable operating conflicts among entities, or even among lines of business subsidiary to a single entity? Will the option in and of itself minimize or exacerbate such operating conflicts? xviii. Intramodal Competition. Does the option permit an appropriate level of intramodal competition? xix. Appropriate Maintenance Levels. Will the option encourage or discourage continuous maintenance of the fixed facility at a level of utility that.fily satifes, but does not exceed, the needs of users? v - Table SC.1 Assignment of Functions to Entities under Reshaping Options (Note: In any one country, options can be combined or altered to fit conditions) Options __ _ (1) Monolith (2) Lines-of- (3) Competitive (4) Wholesaler (5) "Toil Rail' Business Access Enterprise R=Parent -owing L=Line of Railway F=Fixed Business R2=Railway Facility LP=Primary havbig R=Railway Owner Function R=Railway Line-of-Business Trackage Rights W=Wholesaler O=Operator PFxed Facility Ownership R R (parent) RI R P Fixed Facility Maintenance R LP RI R P Operations Control R LP RI R P or 0 Train Movement R L RI, R2 R 0 Equipment Provision R L RI, R2 R (W) 2 0 Equipment Maintenance R LI/ RI, R2, R (W)2/ 0 Marketing R L R1, R2 W 0 Accountability R L RI, R2 R, W F, 0 W/ Where one line of business performs equipment maintenance for another, intemal charges would be reciprocally assessed. 2v In this case the railway would nornally be the primary supplier, but the wholesaler could well be an optional source of supply for railway rolling stock. Table SC.2 Examples of Reshaping Options Options Examples" (1) Monolithic Railway Bolivia, China, USSR, Zimbabwe (2) Lines-of Business Organization British Rail, RENFE21, United States (as a whole: freight railways, Amtrak, commuter authorities) (3) Competitive Access Canada (freight; CP and CN are to operate over some parts of each other's track); United States (trackage rights and joint teminal agreements); Council of the European Communities' directive (competitive access concepts) (4) "Wholesaler" American President Lines (double stack), Norfolk Southern Triple Crown, haulage agreements, Australia (5) 'Toll Rail" Enterprise Amtrak, Japan Preight Railway Company, Japan's Shinkansen services, Swedish Railways (Sl)/Banverket, State Railways of Thailand 1' Not all these examples are discussed in the text of this paper. 7' Spanish National Railways. A list of acronyms appears at the end of this paper. - vi - xx. Track Maintenance Coordination with Operations. How will the safety and work efficiency needs of the entity maintaining the track be reconciled with the needs of other entities for timely, unrestricted access to fixed facilities? xxi. Private Sector Development. Will the option afford an opportunity for increased involvement of the private sector in railway transportation? xxii. Startup/Transaction Costs. Do the initial costs of implementing the option, and the administrative costs of perpetuating it, outweigh its likely benefits? xxiii. Table SC.3 evaluates the generic options in very broad terms according to their responsiveness to each of the issues. As might be expected, the monolithic railway rates high on apparent technical efficiency (since conflicts are decided by executive fiat and transaction costs are minimized), but low on marketing effectiveness considerations. The lines-of-business option offers improved responsiveness to markets and accountability, but reflects increased operating conflicts and transaction costs as the monolith becomes divided. The competitive access option introduces intramodal competition in selected markets, while maintaining unitary control over most railway operations. Unless th., distribution of "franchises" is self-balancing, providing clear benefits to all participants, the owning railways are unlikely to permit a serious level of competition in markets which they have traditionally controlled. Thus, competitive access is often an evolutionary approach. The 'wholesaler' option should accomplish an excellent marketing job, but the actual operation would remain in monolithic hands. Finally, the 'toll rail" enterprise might come closest to reflecting a theoretical model of marketing effectiveness; yet it would generate potential operating conflicts and higher transaction costs. This option would also call for the highest degree of administrative capability in the owning government. xxiv. Circumstances differ in every country and for each railway. Since the relative values applied to each objective (row) in Table SC.3 will vary by country, the ratings shown in each column cannot simply be added together to determine an optimum. Thus, no a priori conclusions are possible as to which generic option (or combination) would be "best" in a specific circumstance. Nevertheless, certain country types and railway characteristics would, in principle, lend themselves most readily to certain reshaping options. For example, a monolithic railway might be an appropriate choice for a fully planned, command economy (or for a true single purpose operator such as a mining evacuation railway) -- although a desire for better measurement of performance might lead to a line of business organization even in these circumstances. Economies in transition, small railways with a restricted number of customers, or larger railways seeling to depart incrementally from a monolithic framework, will probably find a lir.: zf business organization to be a useful first step. A need for intra-modal rail competition, either in large countries with well developed rail systems or in adjacent countries with integrated economies, could promote greater use of competitive access solutions, as in the European Community's recent order. When customer service quality needs are paramount (as in container landbridge services or in certain unit train applications), or when the rail service is driven by external requirements (as in container dry ports), it may be best if the railway is - vii - a "wholesaler' selling to a "retailer" who relates directly (and mo(re effectively) with the customer. Finally, where a rail service is easily separable from other services, and where the service does not conflict heavily with other services, a "toll rail" enterprise solution may be desirable. Examples of this possibility are Amtrak, VIA and the Japanese Rail Freight Corporation: potential situations could be the granting of trackage rights to Zimbabwe to serve the port of Beira in Mozambique, and to Russian Railways to serve the port of Tallinn in Estonia, the port of Riga in Latvia, or the port of Odessa in Ukraine. Table SC.3 Characterization of Generic Reshaping Options (Options are rated High (H), Medium (M), or Low (L) according to their responsiveness to each issue. The characterizations are for generic options and would naturally vary with the particulars of specific options scrutinized.) Options and Characterizations (1) (2) (5) Monolithic Lines-of- (3) "Toil Raiway Business CompeUtive (4) Rail" Issues (status quo) Organization Access 'Wholesaler" Enterprise Market Definition L H M H M Financial Accountability L MorL M or L M H Ease of Operations Coordination H M M M L Intramodal Competition L L H H M Appropriate Maintenance _ Levels M M M M+ (Depends on l___________ ______________ _____________ ______________ pricing) Track Maintenance Coordi- H M M M L nation with Operations Private Sector Development L M M H H Start-up Problems and Transaction Cost Burdens L M M M H xxv. Underlying all these issues and options is the basic tradeoff between efficiency of producton and effectiveness in meeting market needs. The traditional monolithic railway, organized in a strictly hierarchical pattern along departmental lines, is geared to producing maximal amounts of relatively undifferentiated output with minimal inputs. However, what the customer wants and what the competition will provide do not necessarily mesh fully with the railway's technical production efficiency. Thus, by contrast, the reshaped railway -- whatever the depth of the attempted restructuring -- seeks to serve each market in a manner that maximizes either profits or other benefits dictated by its agreement with the State. Regardless - viii - of the precise objective, a market-sensitive railway might appear to be less "efficient" than a well-managed monolithic entity in terms of production, and yet be much more effective in fulfilling its goals of improved service quality and commercial performance because the customer is interested in minimum logistic costs, not just the lowest railway rates and minim"lm service quality. xxvi. For example, a reshaped railway will typically establish separate "commercial" and "noncommercial" lines of business. The former would be operated on a commercial, for-profit basis and would be self-supporting and generally unregulated; the latter would be operated under contract with government at some level(s), and would receive operating subventions under the "public service obligation (PSO)" rubric. This dichotomy would free the railway to operate as a commercial enterprise by reducing the govemment's span of control to separable PSO functions only, and would encourage both railway and govemment to view PSO functions as a business relationship between customer (i.e., govemment) and contract supplier (the railway). By the railway's traditional measures of technical operating efficiency (e.g., coach-kilometers per locomotive-kilometer), the restructured services, taken together, may appear to fall below historical levels. This decrease, however, may mask a host of steps taken by the respective lines of business to boost the responsiveness of each service to customers' needs and willingness to pay. The result should be a more profitable railway in the case of commercial services, and noncommercial services that better fulfill explicit public policy objectives. Conclusions xxvii. The concept of the railway as a unitary entity is so strong and self-perpetuating in many countries as to form a roadblock against reshaping the railway in ways akin to those broached in this paper. Yet such reshaping has already taken place with success in the U.S., Canada, Japan, Sweden, Finland, Argentina, Spain, and New Zealand (among others) and offers clear promise elsewhere. Technology, competition, and historical forces have eroded the foundation of the unitary railway; rail entities that are driven by production rather than market considerations are no longer necessary. As a result, where incremental approaches are feasible, transition to some form of lines-of-business organization would be a useful first step in bringing the market to the railway. Such a reorganization, whatever its depth, would improve market definition and financial accountability without undue startup and transaction costs. Following the example of British Rail, the lines-of-business strategy could be intensified in stages. xxviii. Reshaping need not stop with lines of business, however. Where incremental approaches have not worked, cannot work, or have reached the limits of their effectiveness, the full spectrum of options exemplified in this paper will merit careful consideration. Experience has clearly demonstrated the feasibility and desirability of mixing and matching these options to fit national needs. Experience has also shown that, despite the difficulty of making valid generalizations, one broad statement can be made: the monolithic railway simply does not function well in a market economy in competition with pnvately owned, properly (i.e., lightly) regulated competitoir - especially trucking. AU attempts to "commercialize" or 'corporatize," or to increase the role of the private sector in railway activities, have started with one or another - ix - form of reshaping of the railway entity. Thus, while the detailed solution will vary from one country to another, as an economy becomes more market-driven with wider competition in the transport sector, the need to reshape the monolithic railway into a market-sensitive transport entity remains a vital and universal objective. 1 BACKGROUND: WHY RESHAPE THE RAILWAY? Historical Context 1. Historically, railways throughout the world developed as monolithic organizations, controlling their own facilities, performing all operating and administrative functions, and unilaterally determining what services to provide to an often captive market. Such an evolution faithfully reflected the conditions of the times. In the nineteenth century, railways represented the vanguard of technology; they could reliably depend only on themselves to produce most of their material needs. Moreover, as the dominant means of overland transport, railways from their inception could essentially dictate the products they would offer (without regard to customer preferences) and the prices they would charge (without attention to cost considerations), subject only to any available intramodal competition. Acknowledging this monopoly status, regulatory structures arose to control it, and in many countries perpetuated the illusion of monopoly long after competing modes had emerged in the transportation marketplace. In the socialist economies, the adoption of central planning reinforced the railway as a unitary organization. Throughout the world, therefore, autarky and monopoly produced and preserved the railway monolith. 2. In most countries, the production, market, and political conditions originally favoring monolithic rail transport entities no longer exist. Although constantly evoiving and improving, railway technology is esoteric no longer. Railways are increasingly able to rely on a host of outside suppliers and service organizations to perform infrastructure, maintenance, administrative, and even operating functions, as dictated by economic considerations."/ Moreover, in the presence of mature, competing transport modes, railways can no longer be oblivious to customer preferences in designing services, nor can they price services without regard to their costs. Finally, the extreme centralization of all economic decisions that formerly characterized the socialist states (and their railways) is dissipating. In light of all these changes, the traditional unitary railway -- in which the lowest official dealing with both revenues and costs may well be the general manager or the president -- has become incongruous, and not just from a theoretical viewpoint. 3. In many countries, the mismatch between what the railways offer and what customers want has caused both pronounced economic inefficiencies and severe financial strains for the railways and their government owners. In much of the world, the railways' losses of market share, burgeoning deficits, and mushrooming demands for State funding have led to enormous pressures on governments to effect a fundamental restructuring of the railway entity itself, and of its relationship with the State. 1/ Alice Galenson and Louis S. Thompson, The Bank's Experience with Railway Lending: An Evolving Approach, pp. 30-31. -2 - 4. These underlying pressures may manifest themselves in explicit and implicit Government objectives for reshaping the railway. Typical objectives, based on enhancing overall economic efficiency, may include: 5. Promote creative and aggressive management. To the extent existing bureaucracies hamper new modes of thought, reshaping the railway may be essential if new services and operating methods are to be instituted. However, railways since the 19th Century have added creative services without submitting to fundamental restructuring, simply by the accretion of n, / organizations on the old. For example, sleeping car services over both the private carriers . a the United States and the national railways of Europe were operated by companies especially established for that purpose (e.g., Pullman, Wagons-Lits), as were many other specialized types of freight, express, and passenger services.2' In Europe as elsewhere, opportunities for creative international and other services may exist with or without fundamental reshaping of the constituent state railways. 6. Free the railway to function as a market-sensitive, commercial enterprise. Some reshaping schemes relieve the railway operator of its huge fixed asset base and accumulated long-term debt. These actions, in conjunction with other restructuring techniques, may yield a more commercially sensitive railway. 7. Enhance intramodal or intermodal transportation competition. Certain reshaping options (competitive access, for example) allow participants to expand into additional markets while spreading fixed costs over a wider traffic base and keeping new investment to a minimum. 8. Obtain improved management information and performance evaluation through financial separation. Traditional railway organizational structures, as discussed in Chapters 2 and 3, lend themselves to financial reporting by department rather than by service or market segment. Reshaping the railway may be a means (although not necessarily the most cost-effective means) of accomplishing a substantive change in financial reporting systetns. For instance, under the "toll rail" option, assignment of fixed plant and operational responsibilities to two or more separate organizations would result in the substitution of more-or-less arm's length transactions for internal accounting allocations. 2/ See Community of European Railways (CER), "Reply of the CER to the document of Mr. Van Miert (Ref: COM (89) 564 final of 1/25/90)," in which European railway management lists numerous instances of international cooperative freight and passenger ventures under the existing regime (for freight: Trans Europe Container Express, fast, cheap and safe trains, and Intercontainer among others; for passenger, examples include EuroCity trains, fare and equipment collaborative efforts). The CER therefore "calls on the Community's institutions and leaders to ensure that there is genuine complementarity between the political proposals put forward by the Commission and the often innovatory strategies already laid down by the railways in their international fora." See also International Union of Railways (UIC), Transformation of the International Railway System as Part of New European Transport Policy. - 3 - 9. Equalize conditions for rail vis-a-vL- other modes. The competition to railways generally operates under totally different ground rules. Separation of fixed facilities from transportation operations and vehicle ownership is the norm; government itself -- not a subsidiary or private enterprise -- owns and maintains the highways, waterways, or airports as public amenities, with equal access opportunities to all operators. While the essential characteristics, capabilities, and functions of the ubiquitous highway and fixed rail modes will inevitably differ, policy makers in many countries perceive a need to equalize the conditions, in particular the proportions of fixed to variable costs (though not necessarily the total of both) applicable to these competitors. This attempt at equalization can take several forms: differential fuel and other taxes as users' fees, carefully balanced government subsidies, regulatory initiatives, and making the ground rules for the two modes more similar. Under the last rubric, although highways cannot ordinarily be made analogous to railways, the reverse arguably can occur; such a purpose invariably calls for reshaping options, akin to the "toll rail" enterprise, involving the separation of railway operations from the fixed facility. Sweden has effected such a restructuring for this reason, with the express goal of placing public policy decisions on transportation investments on an equal footing for the two modes.' 10. Increase the role of the private sector in railways. If dictated by public policy, transfer of railways from the public to the private sector can theoretically occur in toto, by region, by market, by function, or by some combination of the last three factors. Transfer by function may have special appeal if policy makers view the railway fixed plant as part of the inalienable national patrimony, and therefore nontransferable. Argentina, for example, has undertaken to award franchises on specific operations, but retains national ownership of the rights-of-way.4' 11. Reduce railway deficits and governmental funding burdens. As indicated above, this objective is of surpassing importance in much of the world as a motivating factor for reshaping the railway. 12. Foster public policy in planning and national development. A country's needs for rail service in specific markets may persistently differ from the services that the railway actually provides. If so, the government may have no choice but to restructure the railway so as to fulfill the role assigned to it by national transport and development policy. 13. Shake the foundations of the old railway order and its entrenched interests. Railways are often venerable entities, with entrenched bureaucracies in both management and labor, and among governmental regulators and supervisory agencies. In the ranks of management, self-interest frequently equates to preservation of existing ways of thinking and functioning. In such cases a production rather than a profit or customer satisfaction orientation can plague the many layers of management. In the labor unions, job preservation may outweigh 3/ Stig Larsson, "The Restructuring of SJ," p. 4. 4/ Galenson and Thompson, op. cit., p. 32. - 4 - considerations of the long-term health of the industry. Compounding the ossification may be an accretion of governmental regulations and implementing bureaus of hoary antiquity. If management, labor, and regulators are so encrusted in their thinking and intransigent in their behavior as to resist all attempts to make the railway more responsive to modem needs for both transportation and fiscal responsibility, then only a complete upheaval -- effectively dismantling the existing entity from top to bottom -- may effect the necessary changes. Some of the reshaping options discussed in Chapter 2 may provide approaches to achieving such a deliberate and controlled upheaval. The total restructuring of the Japanese National Railways (JNR) exemplifies a reorganization deliberately undertaken to create new railway entities in place of the old.5' Separation Is Not The Only Option 14. One approach -- "separation" of fixed facility ownership from train operations -- gained prominence in recent years as a response to some of the objectives above. This emphasis on "separation" has, to some degree, miscast and oversimplified the issue. In fact, a full spectrum of options exists for reshaping the railway entity.6' In any country, the aptness of each option depends on several complex factors, including the following: 15. The relative weight and urgency of governmental objectives. If totally eliminating the railway's operating deficit is the primary goal, then dividing the system into "commercial" and "noncommercial" markets -- the latter to be funded with a PSO -- will help, but not suffice. (Uruguay, for instance -- faced with exhausted assets, vanishing traffic, and soaring operating ratios and deficits -- chose to eliminate the entire passenger market in an effort to control the railway's costs.)7' Likewise, if governmental development plans call for increased industrial development in a remote area at the end of an unprofitable branch line, then complete privatization of the rail network will not necessarily protect the government's long-term interest. These are extreme examples illustrating a basic principle: the form of the reshaping must follow its intendedfunction. 16. The relative importance of the various markets served by the railway. If the railway primarily carries bulk freight, with insignificant passenger or parcel services, then a 5/ Kato, Hiroshi, Ihe Japanese Economy in Transition, see especially the appendix "Privatization in Japan." See also Tanahashi, Yasushi, Reform of Railways in Japan. 6/ This paper focuses on options for reshaping the railway entity per se. For more specifics on the restructuring of relationships between the railway and the State, see (for example) Lee Huff and Louis S. Thompson, Techniquesfor Railway Restructuring, and Galenson and Thompson, op. cit. 7/ J.F. Berchesi, "The Rebirth of the Railway in Uruguay," in International Union of Railways (UIC), "Management and Policy Studies (MAPS)," seminar, Paris, September, 1989. See also Louis S. Thompson and Jorge C. Kohon, Institutional Reform in Iransport, Case Study: Uruguayan Railway. - 5 - lines-of-business option may serve no purpose (unless it can usefully apply to submarkets within "bulk freight"). If all the markets are important and clearly identifiable, however, the lines-of-business approach may merit investigation. 17. The available technology. Options calling for detailed cost accounting manipulations may not prove beneficial in countries where computer installations are nonexistent or basic cost-accounting concepts are unfamiliar. 18. The scale of railway operations as a whole. All the reshaping options entail startup and transaction costs; in smaller systems, the costs of some reshaping options may sometimes outweigh their benefits, however attractive the end results may appear on paper. 19. The administrative capabilities of the government and of the railway. Creating new structures with theoretical advantages over the old may have negative results if one of the new entities is less insulated from political pressures, or less capable of making well-reasoned, independent decisions, than was the old. Conceivably, a fixed facility authority, divorced from the railway operator but wedded to the government, could become a convenient recipient of largesse in the form of insufficiently justified projects or overmaintained permanent way. On the other hand, some countries may not possess sufficient depth of managerial resources to operate a large and complex, monolithic railway. In such cases, a judicious division into functional and/or market-based components might yield smaUer, simpler, more manageable entities that would better suit localy available expertise. Thus, the capabilities of and likely relationships between the government and the reshaped railway entity (or entities) require intense scrutiny. 20. Moreover, in practice, the vastly complex three-dimensional matrix of operating functions, service types, and geographic zones that characterizes mature railway systems may call for a sophisticated combination of restructuring options, rather than for any single solution. One option might be chosen for freight (or freight sub-markets), another for intercity passenger, and yet another for suburban passenger. Such is the case in Japan, where a separate entity provides freight services over the facilities of the regional passenger railways that succeeded the Japanese National Railways (JNR), and where certain of the regional railways in turn operate high-speed trains over assets of the Shinkansen Holding Corporation. The United States, where separate freight, intercity passenger, and suburban passenger operators have different functional relationships in different parts of the country, further demonstrates that complex transport requirements may necessitate intricate schemes for railway restructuring. 21. Focusing on selected points on the continuum, this paper explores generic reshaping options that can be altered or combined to fit the unique circumstances of particular countries and their railway entities. -6 - 2 THE GENERIC OPTONS 22. In essence, each option in this chapter expresses a set of relationships between the railway entity/entities, the markets served, and the functions performed. Today's railways undertake a wide range of rail transportation services. Typically, this range addresses intercity passenger, suburban passenger, and freight markets; each market can, in turn, be further categorized (for example, into "for-profit" and "not-for-profit" segments; by geographic region, line, or city-pair; by class of service for passenger, and by commodity, lading, or service characteristics for freight). In serving these markets, regardless of the level of service differentiation, the following basic functions8' must somehow be managed: * Fixed facility ownership; * Fixed facility improvement; * Fixed facility maintenance; * Control of operations (i.e., dispatching); * Train movement; * Equipment provision; * Equipment maintenance; * Marketing; and * Financial control and accountability. 23. The order of the options, as presented below, reflects a theoretical spectrum ranging from a single entity accomplishing aU basic functions, to multiple entities performing different basic functions. As the examples illustrate, no such smooth continuum exists in practice: under the "toll rail" option, a primary operator may fulfill all functions for one market while providing the fixed facility over which a secondary operator conducts train operations in a lesser market. Indeed, these generic options are by no means mutually exclusive. Even the monolithic railway has (in some countries) traditionally lent itself to small-scale "competitive access" agreements and, more recently, to lines-of-business marketing initiatives. 8/ The list of "basic functions" is intended to be illustrative, not exhaustive. Obviously, railway planners need to accord serious attention to such other important functions as stations (which the Spanish have explicitly and properly addressed in their restructuring plan - see Chapter 3). - 7 - OPrION 1: THE MONOLTmuc RAILWAY 24. Over time and throughout the world, railways have typically been integrated transport entities, owning and operating their own fixed facilities and vehicles.9' Historically, these monolithic railways have conducted a variety of transportation businesses over their fixed plants, and have generally lacked precise management information as to the relative profitability of these businesses. 25. Figure 2.1 depicts the traditional, monolithic railway structure. The vertical columns represent the three essential markets usually addressed by railways; further subdivisions are, of course, possible (for instance, freight into "bulk,' "carload," "less than carload," "intermodal") but are omitted for simplicity's sake. Also, railways typically have such ancillary businesses as real estate, hotels and seaports, which are extraneous to this discussion but which may be significant in any given country.10' The horizontal rows in Figure 2.1 represent the basic functions performed in support of the railway's businesses. In Figure 2.1 and similar charts, boxes in the body of the schematic indicate distinct entities performing the functions and/or services. 26. Thus, in the traditional paradigm, a single corporate entity performs all services and functions, without necessarily isolating the financial results of the various markets. Such an isolation would be impossible in some companies, and undesirable in others, since the status quo option can effectively serve to conceal cross subsidies in several dimensions -- not only among service types, but among specific lines and trains, and between the taxpayer at large and railway labor. The traditional structure is self-perpetuating: by concealing actual results, it often serves to preserve the status quo and is generally championed by those whose benefits exceed their costs under the status quo. 27. The monolithic railway was almost wholly production-oriented. Typifying ailing systems in many countries, Uruguay's railways before the restructuring lived by "a production-oriented rather than a market-led philosophy in that the enterprise provided services irrespective of market requirements and sold products of decreasing quality in terms of reliability, safety, and 9/ United Nations Economic and Social Council, Economic Commission for Europe, Inland Transport Committee, Principal Working Party on Rail Transport, "Draft study (white paper) concerning the development of an international rail transport system in Europe," p. 11. 10/ Also, railways may even have subsidiaries totally divorced from transportation, or may use "surplus" capacity of transport assets for unrelated businesses, such as printing (see Galenson and Thompson, op. cit., p. 27). Such ancillary businesses can be very important: British Rail's surplus in 1989/90 stemmed entirely from property development, according to 'iR optimistic as it rides the storms," Modern Railways, August 1990, pp. 394-395. Thus, far from being "ancillary," consideration of important side-businesses must enter into any planning for restructuring. - 8 - Figure 2.1 Functions and Services of the Traditional Monolithic Railway Services Offered Functions Intercity Suburban Performd Freight Passenger Passenger Fixed Facility I I Ownership ......................................................... .................... ............. . ................................... ..................... .............................................. Fixed Facility Improvement J I -................................ "" " 1""""'""'""""" ""'" Fixed Facility Maintenance Control of I Operations l All functions and I ... . . -....... . . ...... . ..... by a single entity Train l Movement . .... . . ....... ...... - . .. Equipment (provision, maintenance) II Marketing l "......................................I.... ........................... Financial X I Accountability I - 9 - punctuality [which] the market rejected . . .""'1 Embodying this attitude, the typical monolithic railway was organized so that each functional department exercised total and undifferentiated responsibility over all services. Thus, for example, in the organization chart of a typical North American railway circa 1960, the Baltimore & Ohio (Table 2.1), all "marketing" (actually "sales") functions, for both freight and passenger, reported through a single vice president for traffic. All operational functions (maintenance of way, maintenance of equipment, movement control, train movement, and clerical activities) reported through a single vice president for operations in a complex geographical/functional matrix. In effect, the only person with jurisdiction over both revenues and expenses was the president of the railway himself. The same was true in British Rail before the 1980's, where plenipotentiary Regional General Managers and traditionally strong functional hierarchies (e.g., engineering and personnel departments) obstructed comprehensive, market-based business planning. 12/ OPTION 2: L s-OF-BUsNESS ORGANIZATION 28. As markets, technology, and operating practices have evolved, even on monolithic railways, commonality has diminished to a surprising degree among many of the assets and resources used in different markets. Thus, for instance, electrified suburban passenger services employ self-propelled, multiple-unit coaches necessitating specialized workshops; tracks with heavy commuter flows tend not to have much freight. Advances in management information systems have, furthermore, improved the accuracy and timeliness with which direct as well as remaining common costs can be identified with particular services. These two converging trends have enabled railway entities to reorganize themselves (to varying degrees of depth) according to lines of business so as to foster comprehensive business planning, market- and cost-sensitive decisions, and more responsive operations for each service performed. In essence, this is an option for making the monolithic railway less monolithic in a service, if not in a production sense, while reducing the entity start-up costs implicit in other alternatives. Example: British Rail 29. British Rail (BR) has divided itself into five lines of business that are financially accountable to top management and that "purchase" service by contract from an operating department that is organized along a matrix of regional and functional lines. The lines of business include "commercial" InterCity, Freight, and Parcels. Noncommercial services include Network SouthEast (primarily commuter) and Provincial. As currently structured, BR's lines of business undertake marketing, and are financially accountable, for their respective markets. 1/ Berchesi, op. cit., p.2. 12/ Sir Robert Reid, CBE, "Presentation to the World Bank," November 1990. For a conceptual model of market-driven planning, see Neil E. Moyer and Louis S. Thompson, Northeast Corridor: Achievement and Potential, pp. 3-1 and 3-2. - 10- Table 2.1 Example of Typical Monolithic Railway Orgaizatlon (Note: Elements are presented in the exact order and hierarchy shown by the carrier. No attempt has been made to "rationalize" the structure or correct "mistakes.") Chairman President Law Department: Vice President and General Counsel Public Relations Department: Director Finance and Accounting Departments: Vice President Treasury Relief Department - Employee Benefits Insurance Accounting and Freight Claim Accounting Freight Claim Traffic Department: Vice President Freight: General Freight Traffic Manager Freight Traffic Manager - Rates, System Freight Traffic Manager - Sales and Service, System Freight Traffic Manager -- Eastern Region Coal Traffic Manager Foreign Freight Traffic Manager Manager, Railroad Trailer Service Manager, Merchandise Traffic (less than wagon-load) General Perishable and Livestock Agent Assistant General Freight Agent Freight Traffic Managers by [other] Region (Note: traffic regions do not exactly match ope,rating regions) New York Central Northwestern Southwestern Industrial Development Agricultural Development Passenger: General Passenger Traffic Manager General Passenger Agent - Sales, System General Passenger Agents in Major Traffic Generating Points General Passenger Agent - Rates, System Advertising Manager General Eastern Passenger Agent Mail, Express, and Baggage: Manager Superintendent, Mail Traffic Superintendent, Express Traffic - 11 - Table 2.1 (continued) Operating Department: Vice-President Assistant to Vice-President Manager, Budget Controls and Statistics General Superintendent, Motive Power and Equipment Chief Engineer, Motive Power and Equipment Manager, Research General Superintendent, Transportation Chief of Yard and Terminal Operations Superintendent, Car Service Chief [Civil] Engineer Signal Engineer Superintendent, Communications Fuel Agent Manager, Station Operations Manager, Highway Transportation and Warehouses Superintendent, Safety Department Superintendent, Floating Equipment New York Terminal Region: General Manager Central Region: General Manager Westem Region: General Manager Chicago Terminal Region: General Manager Police: General Superintendent Dining Car and Commissary: Manager Personnel Department: Vice President Research and Development Department: Vice President Purchasing Department: General Purchasing Agent Source: Adapted from the reprentation of The Baltimore & Ohio Railroad Company in the Official Guide of the Railways, February 1959, pp. 352-353. - 12 - While the lines of business perform comprehensive business planning and define service requirements, all facilities, equipment, and train movements remain under the aegis of the regions, as depicted in Figure 2.2. The result is an "appallingly complex matrix" of internal contracts between the people specifying the services and those providing them. According to John Welsby, BR's chief executive, "we were spending an ever-increasing portion of our time chasing this internal matrix around rather than addressing our attention where it really should be -- to the needs of our passenger and freight customers."131 Moreover, it is unclear exactly how fixed facility costs are apportioned to the services concerned, and the degree to which "profitable" services reflect in their internal financial statements the fixed and variable costs for the facilities they use. 30. Whatever its drawbacks, the reorganization of the 1980's seemingly achieved, without undue disruption or startup costs, an opportunity to give commercial sectors a realistic profitability goal, and incentives to "noncommercial" lines of business to reduce their losses. Having met its financia-l objectives in the 1980's, BR reports that "the railway now costs the taxpayer 51 percent less in real terms than in 1982. "14/ Even the restructured BR cannot avoid cyclical business swings, however: the recession-induced results for 1990-91 have by no means accorded with the objectives of the current three-year plan."5' 31. Spurred by the successes of its restructuring initiative and recognizing its failings, BR is now abolishing the regions totally and allocating their resources to the lines of business to which they most closely pertain. Where two or more lines of business make use of the same assets or staff, the primary user will rent the property or services to secondary lines of business on a "toll-rail" basis. Thus, InterCity will "own" King's Cross Station, London, which Network SouthEast (the commuter operator) will share as a "tenant." This important elaboration of the lines-of-business option appears in Figure 2.3.16/ Other Examples of Lines-of-Business Organization 32. Viewed in the large, the massive restructurings in the United States, Japan, and Canada partake of the lines-of-business concept because they assign the freight, intercity passenger, and 13/ Richard Tomkins, "A new track to profit centres," The Financial 7lmes [no date or page number; presumably June 19911. 14/ Reid, Presentation to The World Bank, p. 8. The same author provides further details on the internal organization of British Rail in his discussion paper, Insi'ional Reform in Transport: The British Rail Experience, pp. 20-24. 15/ "Sir Bob takes the initiative in hard times," Modern Ra lways, XLVIH (August 1991), 393-394. Moreover, according to "Misty Vision" in the September 1991 Railway Gazette International, both staffing levels and passenger complaints have allegedly shown increases since 1989. 16/ Tomkins, op. cit. - 13 - Figure 2.2 Lines-of Business Options (British Rail Version, 1980's) Markets Addressed Passenger Functions Perfodrme Parcels Freight InterCity Provincial SouthEast Fixed Facility j II Ownership I .. . -........,z.. ~ . ... ....... ............ .............. ............. ........ .... ....... Fixed Facility Improvement Fixed Facility Maintenance . t I . ly regions for . Control of iall markets I Operations I Train Movement Equipment (provision, maintenance) Marketing i FunctionsI by the respective Financial lines-of-business Accountability _ Accunabiit Public Service Obhgation - 14 - Figure 2.3 Lines-of Business Options (British Rail Vrsion, 1990's) Markets Addressed Passenger Functions Perfonre1 Parcels Freight InterCity Provincial SouthEast Fixed Facility Ownership Fixed Facility Improvement Fixed Facility Most main linep "owned" a!d Maintenance controlled b y InterCity.! ............n it.es p.ima.H usedbyoher m4rkets would Pe "owned" nd Control of c)ntrolled by tesp ive linps Operations of buliness. ~~~~~~~~~~~~~............................ , Train Movement ........ .................. .. .. ...... ..... ......... ... . ..... ............................. .... ... . .................... ....... Equipment (provision, maintenance) Marketing Financial Accountability Public Service Obligation (PSO) - 15 - suburban passenger markets to separate institutions. More akin to the original BR approach are the internal reorganizations in France (SNCF) and Spain (RENFE); the Swedish rail operator (SJ), shorn of its fixed facilities (see below under the "toll-rail enterprise") has also organized itself along market lines.17' 33. Faced with the need to consolidate the East and West German railways, a German government commission has developed a coordinated set of restructuring proposals. These embody several elements of recent reshaping schemes elsewhere: a new State-owned company, Deutsche Eisenbahn AG (DEAG) would "manage and maintain the infrastructure, receiving fees for its usefrom its own business groups and possibly from other operators [emphasis added]. " Incorporating aspects of the lines-of-business and, potentially, competitive access options, this arrangement would follow the EC directive in requiring separate cost centers and accounting for fixed facilities and operations, respectively. Services would be divided along commercial/ noncommercial lines, with the latter receiving PSO payments from regional and local authorities. The commission's report does not explicitly delve into DB's overstaffing problem, nor does it promise to eliminate the civil service status of current employees.18' 34. In 1990, RENFE unveiled an ambitious restructuring plan. In essence, it created two distinct types of business units (BUs): "market" BUs to plan, market, coordinate, and be financially accountable for the various lines of business; and "functional" BUs to perform operations and maintenance according to "profit performance criteria," by agreement with the "market" BUs. One "market" BU, High-Speed, will exercise a greater degree of direct control than will the others over facilities and operations. Figure 2.4 illustrates the Spanish restructuring scenario.19' Because the matrix of functional and market business units is innovative, RENFE's experience in applying this model will spark interest among railway managers throughout the world. 17/ Galenson and Thompson, op. cit., pp. 23-24. 18/ 'Strategic report forms basis to build commercial railway," Railway Gazeue International, CXLVII (September 1991), p. 555. 19/ The figure is extrapolated from RENFE, "New Corporate Model," March 1990. This source is unclear as to the precise span of control of the "high speed" BU - i.e., whether it purchases some services from the functional BUs or is entirely insulated. The "ownership" function is arbitrarily identified with the Infrastructure Maintenance and High Speed BUs; of course, ownership actually rests with RENFE as a whole. The source also provides an organization chart showing how complex the model actually is. For example, the BUs are grouped into larger "directorates" as follows: high-speed and suburban each have a "directorate" of their own; infrastructure maintenance, "traffic" (operations analysis and control), freight, and parcel constitute a third directorate; regional and long distance passenger, with station services, constitute a fourth; and rolling stock maintenance, with "traction" (seemingly "train movement"), comprise the fifth. - 16 - FIgure 2.4 Spanish Restructuring Markets Served Passenger Functions Long High Performecl Freight Parcels Distance Regional Suburban Speed - zI - ,1 - - Fixed Facility I 1 I Ownership j I Fixed Facility | Functonal Busmels Unit: I Improvement i InfrastMicture Maiitenance | Fixed Facility I i Maintenance e I I Control of F Functional Busine'ss Unit: .2 Operations "'rrarric" 1 I - - Is 1 Train i Funct4nal Busm Unit: Movement I i'Traction"0 I Stations and * Functxon BusinA s Unit: Common Svcs. Staions nd Comm Services I I z 11; l,II Equipment nal Busineis Unit: (provision, Rollingt0ck MaintenanCe maintenance)-mm- Marketing Financial .e Accountability .l -b-.. = PSO - 17 - OpTON 3: COMi'Errr ACCESS 35. Under this option, competing railway companies would have exclusive control over some trackage, but would also have (and give) the right of competitive access over the trackage of (to) other companies. One variation within this option would be a "regional overlap" approach, wherein regional (or national) operators would be given the right to operate over tracks leading to major traffic centers in adjoining regions (or countries). Smaller-scale options such as trackage rights and joint terminal agreements provide useful practical examples of the competitive access approach. Small-Scale Approaches to Competitive Access. 36. For more than a century, railways have made use of small-scale competitive access arrangements to reduce their operating and capital costs and to reach important markets in a mutually beneficial manner. Examples of these arrangements include the following: 37. Trackage Rights. Table 2.2 summarizes a typical trackage rights agreement between the Norfolk & Western Railway ("Railway A") and another carrier ("Railway B"). It reflects, in microcosm, the larger issues that arise in a competitive access scenario: assignments of functions and markets, costing, upgrading decisions, maintenance, operating rules, liabilities, mechanisms for dispute resolution, term of the agreement, and what happens if the owner wishes to abandon the track. The greatest level of detail in the agreement applies to liability and procedures in case of abandonment. Clearly, when separate entities are involved, legal complexities multiply. (Fortunately, these are standard agreements so that legal fees, at least, are subject to economies of scale. The same would not necessarly hold true for a major restructuring.)20/ 38. Interchange Agreement. Even smaller in scope is an interchange agreement (Table 2.3), in which two railroads wishing to interchange freight cars designate properties on which such transfer is to be effected and the terms and conditions governing joint use of such properties. Again, the agreement devotes considerable detail to liability considerations. 39. Joint Terminal Agreement. A third type of small-scale competitive access arrangement is a joint terminal agreement, which affords Railway B an opportunity to make use of Railway A's freight handling facilities at a particular location. The example (described in Table 2.4) uses a two-tiered cost alocation appriach: a fixed rental, based on the value of the property and the cost of capital at that time; and a vnriable component, based on the expense of Railway A's operating the joint terminal, shared in proportion to the tons of freight handled by each carrier. 20/ Cf. Daniel L. Overbey, Railroads: The Free Enterprise Alternative, pp. 68-69. - 18 - Table 2.2 Summary of Typical Trackage Rights Agreement Basic Concept Railway A allows Railway B to operate its own trains with its own crews over a specified portion of Railway A's track. Contents of the Agreement: Identification of Trackage: * The covered trackage is clearly demarcated. Railway A Retains All Rights: | * Management control of, operation over the track. { * Right to award trackage rights to third part, es. Limitations on Railway B's rights: * . To provide a specific service only (e.g., serve one company). * . No other service to be provided (e.g., no other local freight service on Railway A). | * Trackage rights may not be sublet to other railways. Cost: * Base charge: per wagon-mile. Amount specified in agreement (23 cents). * Calculate by multiplying Railway B's units times mileage of joint trackage. I Escalation clause: per-wagon-mile cost will rise with inflation. * Accounting/billing procedures specified. * To be renegotiated every five years. 0 Incidental costs (other than base charge): direct labor and materials, plus established overheads and equipment rentals. Upgrading: * g Railway A may upgrade joint trackage as it desires. | * Improvements made to accommodate Railway B to be paid for by the latter, including initial capital and incremental maintenance costs. |Maintenance: * Will be Railway A's responsibility. * Performance standard: to allow Railway B to operate 263,000 pound wagons and six-axle locomotives [no speed standard specified]. * Beyond that, condition and availability of trackage not guaranteed. * Railway B to hold Railway A harmless for consequences of Railway A's failure Fo maintain. * If Railway B pays, Railway A will do more maintenance. Operation: * Railway B to comply with Federal and State safety laws and be responsible for same. * Railway B to comply with Railway A's rules and movement orders. * Railway B to assure and pay for its employees' qualification to operate over Railway A's trackage. * Railway B to obtain and pay for radio equipment for use on Railway A. * Procedures for disciplinary actions. * Railway B to pay Railway A for any assistance rendered if equipment breaks down. - 19 - Table 2.2 (continued) Liabilities: l * Extensive provisions, in which all conceivable occurrences are provided for. l * In general: Each railway is responsible for its own losses regardless of fault. l * Labor claims to be borne by each party for its own employees, except: Employees hired by Railway A for the benefit of Railway B will be covered by Railway B. Arbitration Clause Terms of Agreement; Termination; Event of Abandomnent: | * Term is set at 30 years in the example. | * One year's notice is required for termination by Railway B. l * Railway A can abandon the line; Railway B would then have an option to purchase. Successors and Assigns Source: Norfolk & Western Railway Company, sample trackage rights agreement with general conditions [no bibliographic data available]. - 20 - Table 2.3 Summary of Typical Interchange Agreement Basic Concept Railways A and B wish to interchange cars at a specific location. In this example, Railway A provides the specific track on which such interchange will occur. Railway A also permits Railway B to operate over so much of Railway A as to reach the interchange track. Contents of the Agrement Identification of Interchange Track Predse Definition of Interchange: * Occurs when locomotive is uncoupled from cars left on track. * [Precision is important because of car hire charges.] Railway A to Maintain Track Cost Arrangement: .! * Railways A and B to split 50/50 the "annual normalized maintenance costs." * Current cost level is specified. e [There is no guarantee that Railway A will actually spend that money on maintenance of the covered trackage.] Applicable lRules: * Interchange rules of Association of American Railroads (AAR). * Federal/State safety rules: each party is responsible for its own adherence to the rules; each may reject rolling stock not in compliance with the rles. Wrecks and Liabilities: * Complex provisions. * In general, each railway is responsible for its own rolling stock, and "no fault" applies. Arbitration Clause Source: Norfolk & Western Railway Company, sample interchange agreement. - 21 - Table 2.4 Summary of Typical Joint Terminal Agreement Basic Concept Railway A owns and operates a freight terminal at a specific location. Railway B obtains the right to use this facility jointly with Railway A. Contents of the Agreement Identification of Facilities Functional Responsibilities: * Railway A to perform all business and operational functions at the terminal. Costs Charged to Railway B (annual): Fixed Amount: * For existing facilities, 2.5 percent of the value stated in the agreement. * For incremental improvements if made by Railway A, 3.5 percent of their value. Variable Amount: * Railway A's Costs to be AUlocated: * Train movements within terminal (including salaries for switching forces). * Taxes and assessments. * Salaries of agents and clerks. * Utilities for buildings. * Maintenance of covered properties. * Allocation Basis: * Proportion of each railway's freight tonnage to total freight tonnage handled at terminal in any month. Accounting and Billing Procedures Liabilities: * As usual, provisions are complex. * Each party is generally responsible for loss and damage which is the fault of its sole employees or of defects in its own equipment. * But: if loss or damage is caused by agents or employees involved in the joint operation, then no-fault prevails. Default and Termination; Arbitration Note: Not only does Railway A fail to assure that it will handle B's traffic with the same dispatch as its own, it makes itself non-liable for any deficiency or act done or omitted by A's agent with respect to B's business. Source: Pittsburgh, Chartiers & Youghiogheny Railway Co. and Pittsburgh & Lake Erie Railroad Co., joint terminal agreement for McKees Rocks, Pennsylvania, August 1, 1902. - 22 - 40. Joint Switching Agreement. Finally, the joint switching agreement described in Table 2.5 has particular relevance because it rotates responsibility for all switching at a particular plant among three carriers. This is one self-balancing technique to counteract the natural tendency, on the part of the entity in control at any given time, to give preferences to its own operations. 41. Advantages of Small-Scale Options. These small-scale options developed because they mutually benefitted aU parties concerned: were the benefit not mutual, such agreements would not have been signed or carried out between private, for-profit carriers. With the traffic of more than one carrier concentrated on a single facility, fixed maintenance, transportation, and investment costs could be spread over a larger traffic base, thus contributing to the landlord railway's profitability. The tenant, for its part, could enter new markets without making the capital investments that a duplicate facility would otherwise require. Such arrangements often yielded enhanced competition in the transportation marketplace -- a benefit to shippers and, allegedly, to the public. Since these small-scale options usually spawned no new, large corporate entities, the startup costs were low and implementation could occur relatively quickly. 42. Administratively simple, inexpensive, and beneficial to aU parties directly involved, trackage rights and other joint agreements offer intriguing options for application on a larger scale as part of national restructurings. The examples below rely heavily on trackage rights as a basis for large scale competitive access scenarios. Large-Scale Paradigm. 43. Building on the smaUer-scale competitive access concepts described above, the paradigm in Figure 2.5 assumes a national railway comprising largely autonomous regions, exemplified by Regions A, B, and C. Each region behaves like a separate corporation that contains, on the one hand, line-of-business profit centers and, on the other, a cost center that controls and maintains the fixed facility and charges the lines of business for its use. Internal charges are set so that the fixed facility cost center breaks even. 44. The large half-tone dots in Figure 2.5 are traffic generating nodal points. Via trackage rights and appropriate terminal arrangements, each regional railway provides service at least over all the links for which its nodes are endpoints, and possibly beyond. Thus, between major traffic generating centers, one or more additional regional railways (beyond the "owning" regional railway) would be authorized to market and haul traffic. (is illustration is based on trainload freight between the traffic generation points.) To assure competition, the fixed facility cost center in Region A exacts the same user charges from the Region A profit centers as it does from those of Regions B and C, and so forth in the other Regions. I this way each major transportation market can have competitive service throughout much of the network.21' Shippers would, of course, have the right to designate which railway would handle their traffic between the competitive nodal points. 21/ Most intraregional freight would still be captive to one regional carrier; where truck competition is weak or non-existent, the regional railway would still exercise a monopoly over such traffic. Hence the regulatory concerns addressed below. - 23 - Table 2.5 Summary of Typical Joint Switching Agreement Basic Concept Railways A, B, and C agree to share the switching responsibilities at a major industrial plant; each road will do the switching for all three, for a four-month period. [Ownership of the track here is evidently divided between the plant, and Railways A, B, and C.] Contents of the Agreement Identification of Facilities Responsibility of the Switching Railway: * Provide crews and locomotives and switch all cars to, from, and within the plant. * The switching road will 'give no preference" to its own traffic. [The rotational scheme helps to assure this; see text.] Revenues: * Will always accrue to the carrier on whose behalf the cars are switched. Expenses: * Variable costs only are allocated. * Costs covered: * Engines and supplies at standard rate (here $7.50/hour). * Engines and switching crews: standard rate paid each employee. * Allocation formula: Based on each road's projected share of loaded cars. Liabilities: * Very complex; occupies 50 percent of agreement's length and provides for every contingency. * Under certain circumstances, liability is allocated in proportion to car counts for the six months preceding an accident. Source: Wheeling & Lake Erie Railway Co., Pennsylvania Railroad Co., and Baltimore & Ohio Railroad Co., joint switching agreement for Massillon, Ohio, July 20, 1932. Figure 2.5 Competitive Access Option: Regional Overlap Concept Boundary of Regional Railway A C Operations ........ - A Operations Boundary of A Potential Regional Railway -C) _. Shortline- f *,- …= -… oj=: -==t _* - --- Operations Boundary of T Regional Railway B [ *~Traffic Generating Nodal Point - 25 - 45. Such a paradigm may be particularly appropriate in countries with heavy rail freight densities and virtually no competing transportation modes. In addition, the competitive access model can be applied to groups of countries, the national railways of each would function as the "regional" entities assumed in the paradigm. 46. Over a broad range of applications, this paradigm evokes two critical issues: trackage use charges and regulation. 47. Trackage use charges. Both the structure and level of the trackage fees will be important in determining how well this approach would work. If the fee levels are too high (reflecting inefficiency in the cost of providing capacity), then traffic will be depressed. The identical "tolls" for all users would provide some incentive for the owning railway to control its costs. Similarly, the development and publication of comparative maintenance cost statistics among the regional railways would identify poor performers and lead to pressure from the marketing departments. No matter what else happens, the principle must be established that the fixed facility cost centers must recover from users all their costs (so that fee levels are not too low). As explained in detail under "technical considerations" in Chapter 3, the fee structure is vital because it can determine the way in which the operators perceive their incentives to design services, load wagons, organize trains, and so forth. For example, a fee structure based on axles (weighted by tonnes per axle), trains, and track usage time (weighted by peak hours versus off-peak hours) would provide an incentive to run heavy wagons (subject to the axle load weights), long trains, adequate power (in order to reduce running time and the costs of delay due to locomotive failure), and at the right times (due to peak charges). To be fair, the fixed facility cost center would probably have to provide a rebate based on the number of minutes of delay caused by problems (dispatching errors, track maintenance, signal failure, and the like) which were not the fault of the train operator. By contrast, a fee structure solely based on wagon-kilometers (as is common in the U.S.) would reduce the incentive to run long and full trains. 48. Regulation. Depending on the economic conditions and transportation environment of the country or countries adopting this paradigm -- in particular, if no inter- or intramodal transportation competition to the state railway now exists -- rate and service regulation may prove necessary. This regulation might base itself on such principles as the following: * Non-discrimination between essentially similar shippers under similar circumstances (useful in principle, although almost unenforceable in practice); * No single rate can exceed its variable (avoidable) cost by an excessive amount without good reason. In the U.S., this amount is 100 percent (i.e., the rate cannot be more than twice the variable cost), but almost any other target can be established. * The overall rate of return earned by the regional railway as a whole would have to be at or near the opportunity cost of capital. - 26 - 49. Furthermore, the national government(s) might have to determine which railways may serve which n.arkets. Even with this implied level of governmental interference, the competitive access paradigm could lead to more competition and more effective railway management than presently exist in countries with heavy freight densities and virtually no competing transportation modes. European Community Directive 50. Containing elements of several reshaping options, the European Community directive most closely resembles the competitive access paradigm. Each country would carve out its fixed facility either as a separate entity or as a distinct cost center; in either case, the State would ensure non-discriminatory, equitably priced access to its railway network for "international groupings of railway undertaldngs, and for railway undertakings engaged in the international combined transport of goods." In other words, competitive access would have to be provided for international traffic.22' The directive also addresses concerns common to railway re- structurings throughout the world: for example, the separation of commercial and noncommercial services and the provision of public service obligation grants by the State or local authorities, the enhancement of railway managers' commercial orientation, and the rationalization of the railway's debt structure to strengthen the autonomous management of the railways.23/ 51. The proposals antecedent to the EC directive engendered controversy. The concept of the monolithic railway as an integrated organism, in which a central controlling "brain" regulates all "bodily" functions, inheres in many railway managers and experts. Indeed, the organic concept underlies the negative reply of the Community of European Railways (CER) to the European Commission Communication on a Community railway policy. In itself, according to the CER, the proposed separation of fixed plant from operations "does not . . . justify a full-scale debate." Citing the "grave implications" of the Commission's proposal, the CER goes on to say: Unlike other modes of transport, the rail system is an integrated system. All the means of production are managed accordingly. The separation, other than in accounting terms, of rail infrastructure and rail services calls for very detailed consideration of . . . legal status, financial liability, planning, responsibility for services, and relations between the infrastructure management and the operator. Different criteria . . . apply in each Community member State. 52. Similarly, the CER inveighs against the competitive access element of the proposal. 22/ Council of the European Communities, "Council Directive of 29 July, 1991, on the development of the Community's Railways,' Preamble and Articles 1, 8, and 10. 23/ Ibid., Articles 5 and 9. - 27 - Access should be restricted to undertakings which bring genuine added value to the railway system ... The majority of Community rail networks are not yet convinced that such a proposal would have beneficial consequences for the operation of the European netwyork.24' 53. By way of a counterproposal, the CER points to the existing European subsidiaries (e.g., Intercontainer, InterfrigoP) to show that options short of competitive access, and under the aegis of the existing railways, are fully available to meet the objectives set by the Community proposal. Implications of Competitive Access 54. The concept of expanded access to rail facilities theoretically represents a spectrum ranging from commonplace, highly controlled arrangements (e.g., trackage rights) to uncontrolled competition for available capacity. 55. The latter is indeed an extreme. Totally free access, in which vehicles operated by different entities present themselves randomly for passage over a given railway link, will not work because: A railway's capacity is determined not just by endpoint terminal "slots" but by mine capabilities, which are always limited by the number of tracks, the spacing and configuration ,f interlockings and line junctions, the signalling system, differential time/distance curves of various service types, and related physical and operational factors. While the theoretical capacity of a line segment may be great, its ability to accommodate a given type of service making given stops at a particular time of the day may be limited in the extreme. * Thus, introduction of random vehicles into a necessarily carefully scheduled railway operating plan will result in inevitable and material delays. * While a single entity exercising complete control over facility and operations may make advance policy decisions that would allow unscheduled operations and pre-plan the effects of consequent delays, and while multiple entities can agree in advance on policies for dealing with scheduled services, totally free access in a railway setting would result in regular infringements by independent entities on each other's operations and could degenerate into unacceptable service levels for all. 24/ Community of European Railways (CER), "Reply of the CER to the document of Mr. Van Miert (Ref. COM (895) 564 final of 1/25/90)," p. 10. 25/ It is interesting to note, in passing, that these entities, the existence of which the CER supports, themselves represent departures from the monolithic railway. - 28 - 56. The specter of disorganization -- so foreign to the organic concept of the railway, discussed above - underlies the CER's obvious disdain for competitive access. However, since competitive access is a continuum of possibilities, the options need not totally undermine the central control of railway operations. When the EC directs that access to member States' railways be accorded to international traffic,26 it does not specify that the access shall be "on any terms" or haphazard in any way. The Swedish restructuring explicitly allows for a form of competitive access at some time in the future: "As a government agency Banverket must plan for a neutral treatment of different transport companies, which may become competitors for future access to the tracks. "27' "Neutrality" in this context does not necessarily connote a lack of discipline. Finally, although Isabel Benham promotes a revolutionary "open access" concept to be applied throughout the United States, her idea of a "Roadway Corporation" to own, maintain, and manage the fixed facilities still preserves a high degree of centralized control over train operations.28/ 57. Competitive access to rail facilities is not a new concept, as the examples indicate. The trackage rights agreements dating to the nineteenth century represented attempts by railway companies to expand beyond their physical limitations. As railway restructuring proposals become larger in scale, competitive access will become more feasible. Yet however free the access, considerable planning of train operations and detailed protocols for resolving conflicts will still be necessary because of the inherent nature of the railway. OpIoN 4: THE "WHOLESALR" 58. Functioning as a "wholesaler," the railway entity could own and operate the fixed facility and perform all operations on behalf of marketing entities which would be the "retailers. " This would mean that the railway itself would only haul trains; it would target its marketing efforts at retailers, not at shippers. It might furnish some, or all, of the rolling stock and crews, at the retailer's choice. Figure 2.6 displays a "wholesaler" option; many variations on the theme are possible, even over a single railway. 59. For instance, American President Lines (APL) functions as a transportation "retailer," marketing the business (double-stack containers), collecting the revenues, and dealing with shippers. The performing railway hauls complete APL trains, provides crews and locomotives, and charges APL. In Australia, a number of freight forwarders function as retailers using the state railways' "wholesale" services. As multimodal transport providers, these forwarders conduct a large, deregulated trucking business. They control their own rail terminal and yard 26/ Council of the European Communities, op. cit., Preamble and Article 1. 27/ Banverket, "Information about the new Swedish National Rail Administration," p. 3. 28/ Isabel Benham, "Open Access: A Concept for the Railroad Industry's Survival." - 29 - Figure 2.6 Wholesaler Option (Relates to single line of business only. Specific wholesaler/retailer agreements will govern specific functional responsibilities) Functions Line-of-Business erfomd (e.g., double-stack container freight) Fixed Facility Ownership ........... ..................... ........................................... ................................................................................................... ... . ...... Fixed Facility Improvement Fixed Facility WHOLESALER (RAILWAY) FUNCTIONS Maintenance Control of Operations Train Movement .~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~. _. . . ....................................... -... _._. _.._ Lo,ocomotives Wagons ~~~~~~~~~~~~. . ._ . .......... ............. . . ...... ............ .. ......... .... . Marketing RETAILER FUNCTIONS Financial Accountability - 30 - operations and negotiate on the open market with the railways to charter unit trains with agreed- upon service specifications. As a result, despite a state monopoly on railway ownership, competition among these efficient intermodal "retailers" flourishes.29' OPTION 5: TIlE "TOLL RAIL" ENTERPRISE 60. Under this option, the entire fixed facility (track, signals, communications, electrification, and so forth), except for exclusive facilities, would be the property and responsibility of one owner. There would be one or more authorized user(s), each of which would pay tolls for use of the facility. In some forms of this option, the tolls would be public and nondiscriminatory, but might well vary by train size, axle load, direction of travel, time of day, season, and similar criteria. In a sense, the "toll rail" enterprise would be much like a regulated public utility.30 61. Although the "toll rail" may well include elements of "competitive access" and vice versa, the two approaches differ in emphasis: under the "toll rail" approach, separate entities provide the fLxed facility and conduct operations, whereas under "competitive access," more than one entity operates in a given market over a particular fixed facility. 62. Examples of the "toll rail" option range from Sweden, which has completely sundered fixed facility from operating functions, to the United States and Japan, which have very complex arrangements containing significant "toll rail" components, at least in certain regions. In none of these examples does competitive access play a large-scale role, although Sweden is studying the possibility. Sweden 63. In July 1988, Sweden embarked on a very ambitious restructuring centering on a complete separation of fixed facility from operating functions -- a pure example of the "toll rail" option. As shown in Figure 2.7, a facility entity (Banverket) now owns and maintains all railway track in the country. The Swedish State Railways (SD) has become an operator only, with responsibility for all commercial passenger and freight services, as well as the mandate to operate such noncommercial freight, intercity passenger, and commuter services as national or local authorities do not elect to operate themselves or under contract to others. Reorganized on a lines-of-business basis, SJ will not provide non-commercial services unless appropriate subsidies are paid by the cognizant government authorities. In theory, an opportunity exists for 29/ Theodore Keeler, Railroads, Freight, and Public Policy, p. 131. 30/ For typical "toll rail" proposals, some of which contain competitive access elements, cf.: Daniel L. Overbey, Railroads: the Free Enterprise Alternative, pp. 127 ff.; D. Daryl Wyckoff, RaUroad Management, pp. 130 ff.; and Benham, op. cit. In the United States, this concept entered (at least "cursorily") into the Preliminary System Plan developed in response to the Northeastern rail crisis of the 1970's (see Eric W. Beshers, Conrail: Government Creation and Privatization of an American Railroad, ch. VI, p. 4). - 31 - Figure 2.7 "Toil Rail" Enterprise Option (Swedish restructuring, 1988) Markets Addressed Freight Passenger Functions Non- Inter- Performed Commercial Commercial Commercial Regional Regional Suburban Fixed Facility I I Ownership } I I ! Fixed Facility N VIBRKET Improvement | ; (Facility LEntity) j ........................... ......... ......... ........ ........................................ Fixed Facility I I Maintenance Control of i Operations §gl ............. ... .. .... ... . ............. . ......................... ........ Train II Movement .......... ..... ....................................... ........................... ................. ........ .. ............................. LOC4L Equipment (Operating Entity) AUTHORITIES (Provision, (Organtzed by (most colitract Maintenance) business rwith j) Marketing .......................... ............. ........... ... ...I. . ....... ....-...... ............. ..... Financial i Accountability COUNTY STATE P8O i_ i - 32 - competitive access in the new Swedish arrangement; in one of fifteen regions, SJ in fact lost the tendering of the 1989 service contract to a small, private operator.31 SJ and the private operator are not, however, directly competing against each other in that region for that market. 64. The documentation from Sweden32 suggests that the prime purpose for effecting the separation was to place the railways conceptually on the same footing as roads, so that investment and maintenance decisions would take into account the full range of public costs and benefits. 65. Although long-term trends have not yet emerged, SJ has apparently upgraded its productivity and financial performance since the restructuring occurred.33' The Swedish Government plans to complete a major assessment of its new policy in 1992,34' and has recently instructed the Banverket to investigate the possibility of reintroducing competition into the rail sector.35/ Japan 66. The documentation for the April 1987 restructuring36' points to its underlying goal: to create a cataclysm so complete in the JNR that the latter's intractable problems of excess labor, bloated size, and flabby management would disappear in favor of smaller, leaner organizations, most of which would have hope for profitability. The -toll rail" was a key element of this complex plan; the basic structure, as diagrammed in Figure 2.8, consists of six regional owner/operators that are both facility entities and operators of the prinary service, intercity passenger. A single national freight operator operates on trackage rights over the six regional railways; payments are calculated separately for the major facility components. Pure separation of fixed facility ownership from operation occurs only with respect to the high-speed lnes, which the separate Shinkansen Holding Corporation owns and leases back to the passenger railways. Improvement projects extending the Shinkansen system are the responsibility of the Japan Railway Construction Corporation.37/ 31/ Stig Larsson, "The Restructuring of SJ," p. 4. 32/ See the long list of references for Sweden in the bibliography. In particular, the works of Lars Hansson describe the theoretical and ideological underpinnings of Sweden's complete separation of fixed plant from operations. 33/ Galenson and Thompson, op. cit., p. 23. 34/ Jan Brandborm and Lars Hellsvik, "The New Railway Policy in Sweden: Separation of Network and Operations," p. 10. 35/ Jan-Eric Nilsson, letter to Jose Carbajo. 36/ See, in particular, Yasushi Tanahashi, Reform of RaUlways In Japan, and Hiroshi Kato, The Japanese Economy in Trans1on. 37/ "Shinkansen extensions to go ahead," Railway Gazete Intnaional, CXLVII (September 1991), p. 561. - 33 - Figure 2.8 JNR Restructuring Markets Addressed Intebty Passenger Commercial Functions Non- Suburban Performed Freight Commerclal High-Speed Other Passenger I Shinkansen Fixed Facility I Holding Ownership Company I I I Japan Fixed Facility I Railwayon Improvement Construction Pusenger Company Fixed Facility ReCpona! i I Maintenance i .. __ .... _ ._ L"_ ......... "_ . _ ". _" ....... _." ....... _". .. _ ._..... "... " . ......................... Control of 3 ISLAND Operations PASSENGER private _ COMPANMES . -... . _Urban (K-yushu, 3 MA-NL4 ND PASSEI GER Rail- Train Hokkaido, CC MANIES ways Movement Shikoku) (East, 1est, Centn aI) Equipment (Provision, Mainteniance) FREIGHT . COMPANYj Marketing Financial Accountability | J- - 34 - 67. Sufficient time has not elapsed to judge whether this total restructuring wiUl achieve success. However, the results for the first three years afford some encouragement. First, the three commercial intercity railways are showing operating profits higher than originaly projected. For these companies, there is hope that commercial management principles are indeed flourishing. Second, the freight railway appears to be at least marginally profitable.38' Third, total employment has declined drastically from the JNR days. And fourth, anecdotal evidence suggests that attitudes among the staff have matured from the days of the JNR "unsinkable ship" -- a prerequisite to the marketing sensitivity that must precede railway survival and growth in societies that present the public with other transportation options. 68. The critical test for the JNR restructuring is not whether the commercial networks can endure -- they seem to be self-sufficient for the time being -- but whether the noncommercial networks can survive on the interest from the "stabilization fund" that endows their public service obligation. Thus far the three island companies have generated deficits which were manageable on the income from their "endowment. " Yet two out of the three island companies did not fully meet the financial targets of the reform plan; traffic levels have not shown satisfactory increases; and depopulation and road improvement continue on the islands. Still another goal of the restructuring, repayment of the long-term debt, has lagged. In sum, the reshaping of Japan's railways has produced results warranting guarded optimism for the moment.39' United States: Amtrak 69. Viewed in the large, the situation in the United States has gradually evolved since the late 1960's into a lines-of-business structure, with different entities addressing different markets and considerable intramodal competition remaining in the freight market. Elements of the "toll rail" option pervade the new structure, nevertheless. 70. In most of the country, the facility owner/operators are the freight ailways, with Amtrak using trackage rights or paying fees as a secondary operator. In the Northeast Corridor, however, the situation is more complex. There, three primary facility entities exist: Amtrak south of New Rochelle, New York, and between New Haven, Connecticut and the Massachusetts state line; the States of New York and Connecticut, represented by Metro North and the Connecticut Transportation Authority, between New Rochelle and New Haven; and the Commonwealth of Massachusetts for the portion of the line in its territory. Commuter operators abound in this region and are very important over much of the line; their influence over the facility varies. 38/ Galenson and Thompson, op. cit., Annex B, pp. 59-62. 39/ For a measured appreciation of those results, see Tanahashi, op. cit., pp. 24 ff. It is significant to note that the Shinkansen Leasing Corporation is being terminated and the lines divided among the three using railways, apparently because the expected benefits of the leasing arrangement did not justify the added complexity of the arrangement (p. 22). - 35 - 71. Overall, this "restructuring" -- achieved by fits and starts over a 20-year period, with no preordained master plan -- has fulfilled the very important goals of separating the responsibilities for different types of services, assigning common costs by negotiation, and revealing, at least grossly, the transport economics of the lines of business involved. With regard to the intercity passenger market, Amtrak has improved the percentage of costs covered by revenues, and in many submarkets (particularly in the Northeast Corridor) has upgraded service, sometimes dramatically. From a service standpoint nationwide, however, perfection has yet to be attained. Whether the system is providing the quality and quantity of transport that national policy would demand is unknown, since national policy toward Amtrak tergiversates between the Executive and Legislative branches. For the freight railways, now relieved of a passenger burden which most found more unprofitable than freight, the partial separation of fixed plant from operations has proven very beneficial. Canada: VIA 72. In 1977, Canada created VIA, a crown corporation charged with intercity rail passenger service throughout the Dominion. (Regional carriers continue to operate some provincial services.) Like much of Amtrak, VIA operates over trackage owned and controlled by the freight railways, Canadian National (CN) and Canadian Pacific (CP). From the CN/CP perspective, VIA has accomplished its chief goal -- extricating the railways from the passenger business and its associated deficits. However, VIA's troubled history, lack of long-term policy guidance and legislative authority, and recent service reductions offer no clear prognosis for the future of intercity rail passenger service in Canada.Y' 40/ Galenson and Thompson, op. cit., p. 22. - 36 - 3 IssuEs AND TECHNICAL CONSIDERATIONS 73. The government objectives exemplified in Chapter 1 give rise to a series of issues reflecting both actual experience and a priori analysis. As evidenced by successful initiatives in such countries as the United Kingdom, Canada, Japan, Spain, and the United States, these issues raise no insuperable obstacles to reshaping the railway. They do, however, provide a basis for characterizing each generic option for its responsiveness to national goals. This chapter concludes with a discussion of two topics which, although technical in nature, have important implications for long-term performance of a restructured railway: cost assignment and fixed facility maintenance. ISSUES Market Derinition 74. Whether the intent of the reshaping effort is to convert the railway into a commercial enterprise, to enhance competition, to simply reduce the funding burden, or all three, proper business planning requires a clear understanding of the railway's markets and their commercial potentials (if any). Market definition implies an appreciation of what the markets are and where they are tending with respect to traffic trends, developments in competing modes, changing demographics, and economic development plans. Unless a reshaping plan incorporates this degree of understanding, the production-oriented railway will persist, thus thwarting fundamental restructuring efforts. 75. Table 3.1 therefore assesses how well each generic option lends itself to identifying and analyzing the railway's major markets. Financial Accountability 76. Knowing what the markets are provides only incomplete information for business planning and management. In order to identify commercially viable services, to profitably tailor services to market demand, and to intelligently conduct and improve daily operations, railway managers need to know and exercise control over both revenue and expense characteristics of each market. Accountability for both costs and income is essential to the market-driven railway. 77. The traditional monolithic railway, by contrast, ordinarily fails to provide for accountability on a market-by-market basis; it does not even generate the accurate knowledge that is prerequisite to accountability. (Before restructuring, BR could not provide reasonable financial performance indicators for the regional general managers because of irremediable flaws - 37 - Table 3.1 Characterization of Generic Options Based on Market Definition (Ratings are H=High, M=Medium, or L=Low.) Option Rafn Discussion (1) Monolithic railway (status quo) L Traditional departmental organization makes it difficult to differentiate functions (2) Lines-of-business organization H Differentiation by market is the very raison d'etre of the lines-of-business organization. (3) Competitive access M Wil vary with the specific option selected. Trackage rights exchanges between two monolithic railways, in the absence of market differentiation, can still be considered 'competitive access". (4) "Wholesaler" H In this option, the "retailers" must concentrate on particular markets. (5) "Toil rail" enterprise M While "toil rail" type arrngements customarily include market differentiation on the part of the operating railway, such a split between fixed facility and operaing functions could still occur in the absence of a lines-of-business approach. Again, it would depend on the specific circumstances. in the allocation techniques.411) While identification of revenues with markets should present few problems (because a paper trail normally links receipts with the type of transportation provided), a monolithic railway can assign costs to markets only with the greatest difficulty 41/ Reid, op. cit., p. 2. 'The Regions were not separate businesses with profit accountability. Their revenues and costs were only those which originated within the boundaries of their territories, and since many passenger and freight trains moved between Regions, there were major discrepancies in revenue and cost attribution. Moreover, until 1983, infrastructure costs were allocated from the annual total on a route-mile basis, no matter whether a length of track had been renewed or was scheduled for renewal. So while the command structure of the Regional General Manager system was strong, the business basis of their operations was weak." - 38 - because of the allocation methodology involved. Figure 3.1 shows those cost areas which a tradidonal railway can relatively easily isolate by function and service, and those which are not so easily done. In particular, facility-related costs require allocation, which is at best theoretical (since it reflects no arm's length transaction) and which requires sophisticated analytical techniques to be of genuine helpfulness to management and the owners. This is why the objective of "improved management information" (cf. Chapter 1) may require a complete restructuring of the railway entity under certain circurntances. 78. The monolithic railway therefore ranks poorly on Table 3.2, which characterizes the degree to which each generic option would encourage accountability on a market-by-market basis. Operations Coordination 79. Some of the generic options involve multiple entities in operations, thus undermining one of the clear advantages of the monolith -- its ability to solve conflicts by command. Operating conflicts are indeed inevitable when two carriers use the same fLxed facility. Even when operators are geographically separated (for instance, commuter services at city A and at city B on the through intercity line AB), their schedules can conflict because of impacts on and from through services. These facts require the institutional plan for reshaping the railway to incorporate mechanisms that will prevent or reduce operating conflicts, or which will cause people and organizations to look beyond their immediate gains to longer-term impacts of selfish behavior. 80. While the appropriate mechanism will depend on the specific situation in the country at hand, planners may wish to emulate existing approaches. On the Northeast Corridor, which belongs to several owners and serves various commuter and freight operators and one intercity passenger operator, a train planning unit emerged in the late 1970's to work out scheduling problems for all users before they became operating problems. Where two entities jointly use a facility, a rotating responsibility for movement control may act to curb the short-term tendencies of the controlling organization to afford operating preference to its own trains. This self-balancing mechanism is the plan for the new Harold Tower, a shared facility between Amtrak and the Long Island Rail Road. The former Washington Terminal Company, jointly owned by competing railways until 1971, had rotating personnel in certain management positions. The joint switching agreement described in Chapter 2 provided for each of three railways to switch a major industry for four-month intervals. Not only did the agreement state the admirable principle that all traffic would be handled equitably, but the rotation provision could act as a powerful motivation against infringements of the principle. 81. Table 3.3 evaluates each option in terms of its implied ease of operations coordination through prevention and resolution of conflicts. Based on the available mitigating measures, this issue clearly poses no threat to railway restructuring. - 39 - Figure 3.1 Cost Isolation in Traditional Railways Services Offered Fiunctions Performed Freight Passenger Commuter Fixed Facility Ownership Costs necessitating interna Fixed Facility accounting allocation Improvement (except for facilities dedicated to a specific service, e.g., freight yards or passenger stations without suburban Fixed Facility service) Maintenance Control of Operations Train Movement./ Freight Intercity ]Equipment (Provision, Senc assenger Commuter Costs Maintenance)v2 Costs Costs Marketing Accountability was traditionally on a corporate basis. Financial To establish credible accountability by service requires Accountability deft alocation of facility-related costs. (U.S. railways could not do it by and large until separation of non-freight services actualy occurred.) Occasionaly trains are mixed, requing allocations. 21 Sometimes locomotives are used for more than one service, requirng allocations. - 40 - Table 3.2 Characterization of Generic Options Based on Financial Accountability (Ratings are H=High, M=Mediurn, or L=Low.) Option Rating Discussion (1) Monolithic railway (status quo) L Too many non-arm's length cost allocations are necessary, as depicted in the chart. (2) Lines-of-business organization M or L If the lines of business are merely superimposed over the existing regional/functional matrix, then allocations will still be necessary. (3) Competitive access M or L In some versions, monolithic railways may be exercising access over each other, so that allocations will be required. (4) "Wholesaler- M While the existence of retailers will necessitate market differentiation, transportation may still be provided by traditional monolithic carriers. (5) "Toll rail' enlerprise H The separation of fixed plant and operating functions will absolutely necessitate arm's-length transactions for fixed facility cost assignment. Table 3.3 Characterization of Generic Options Based on Ea-e of Operations Coordination (Ratings are H=Hligh, M=Med;um, or L=Low.) Option Rating Discussion (1) Monolithic railway (status quo) H Entire entity is under unified, authoritarian control. (2) Lines-of-business organization M Varies with depth of lines-of-business organization. If the underlying railway is monolithic, then operations coordination should be easy. As lines of business acquire asets and act independently, operations coordination may become somewhat more difficult. (3) Competitive access M Each segment of railway may stiUl be under monolithic control; conflicting user needs and desires could stiU lead to conflict. (4) "Wholesaler" M The railway itself may remain monolithic; the large retailers, depending on the functions t} v perform, could create conflict. (5) -Toll rail enterprise L Total finctional separation could lead to built-in operating conflicts, requiring institutional mechanisms for resolution. - 41 - Intramodal Competition 82. In certain countries, railways maintain a monopolistic position.42 Where such monopolies exist, the quickest way to effect transport competition would often be to introduce it within the rail mode itself. Such a step could foster responsiveness to user needs, spur technological modernization and service innovation, and instill an entrepreneurial spirit in railway management. Some of the generic options, in particular competitive access, would offer opportunities for healthy intramodal rivalry. Table 3.4 rates the generic options on their responsiveness to this issue. Appropriate Maintenance Levels 83. A scenario for railway restructuring should encourage maintenance of the fixed facility at exactly the level of utility required to serve the markets - no more, and no less. This requires forethought because some generic options may increase the number of entities and government agencies participating in rail transport decisions. In turn, each of these participants may have inherent short- and long-term confhicts of interest with respect to defining and protecting the capabilities of the permanent way. As a result, in crafting a solution for a given country, planners need to envision these conflicting viewpoints so as to set them in equipoise. Table 3.5 assesses the generic options for their amenability to a balanced maintenance regimen. This intricate yet important topic receives further treatment under "technical considerations" later in this chapter. Track Maintenance Coordination with Operations 84. Just as the multiplication of operators can set the stage for disputes among them, the separation of fixed facility from movement functions may draw attention to the competing requirements of plant maintenance and train operations. Indeed, situations involving a primary owner/operator (Railway A) and a secondary operator (Railway B) imply a three-way conflict: between A's and B's train movements; between A's maintenance function and B's train movoments; and, intenally, between A's train movements and maintenance function. Whatever the specifics, a restructuring scenario should anticipate confficts of this nature and incorporate mechanisms to prevent and resolve them. Since this issue (although important in its own right) resembles the "operations coordination" question, the characterizations of the options in Table 3.3 apply here as well. 42/ In particular, Galenson and Thompson (Annex 3, Table 3) show that in five socialist countries - Romania, the USSR, Czechoslovakia, China, and Poland - rail holds a share of from 74 to 94 percent of the total rail-plus-truck freight market. - 42 - Table 3.4 Characterization of Generic Options Based on Intramodal Competition (Ratings are H=High, M=Medium, or L=Low.) Option Rating Discussion (1) Monolithic railway (status quo) L Inherent in monolithic railway in most countries. (2) Lines-of-business organization L All the lines of business are facets of a single company and would be intended better to position the railway in relation to other modes. (3) Competitive access H By definition, this option is intended to introduce intramodal competition in specified markets. (4) "Wholesaler" H The existence of the railway "wholesaler" implies more than one "retailer"in a given market. (5) "Toil rail" enterprise M Unless the toil rail is specifically open to more than one operator per market, there is no guarantee that intramodal competition will increase by means of this option. Table 3.5 Characterization of Generic Options Based on Appropriateness of Maintenance Levels (Ratings are H=Hligh, M=Medium, or L=Low.) Option Rating Discussion (1) Monolithic railway (status quo) M See conflicting tendencies described in text. (2) Lines-of-buiness organization M Depends on depth of lines-of-business organization, and its relationship with the facility maintenance department. (3) Competitive access M Can involve monolithic railways with conflicting tendencies (see text). (4) "Wholesaler" M+ Presumably governed by detailed agreements between wholesaler and retailers. (5) "Toll rail" enterprise ?* Whetier appropriate maintenance levels are likely in a "toil rail" option will depend on the way in which tolls are set and the specific functional responsibilities of the operating and facility entities. * Depends on pricing - 43 - Private Sector Development 85. Among other objectives, a government may reshape its railway so as to enhance the role of the private sector. Few of the Bank's borrowers will wish to divest the railway in its entirety to private ownership; many would, however, consider allowing multiple institutions, private and/or public, to provide services over a publicly owned infrastructure with prospects for an expanding role over time. Table 3.6 rates each generic option on its ability to foster private involvement. Start-up/Transaction Costs 86. Reshaping the railway implies both a startup investment and changes in continuing transaction expenses. In some cases, particularly those involving the creation of multiple entities in place of the monolithic railway, both the initial and subsequent administrative cost burdens will be relatively high and must be weighed against other factors (e.g., changes in transportation revenues and expenses; likely gains on sales of property; service benefits and public policy considerations). However attractive the long-term outlook may be for a given scenario, its startup costs must obviously be affordable. As a result, this issue will enter into railway planning at its earliest stages. Table 3.7 characterizes the initial and continuing administrative cost burden of the various options. Summary Discussion of Issues. 87. Table 3.8 describes the generic options in terms of their responsiveness to each of the issues. As might be expected, the monolithic railway rates high on technical efficiency (since conflicts are decided by executive fiat and transaction costs are minimized), but low on marketing effectiveness considerations. The lines-of-business option offers improved responsiveness to markets and accountability, but reflects increased operating conflicts and transaction costs as the monolith begins to crumble. The competitive access option introduces intramodal competition in selected markets, while maintaining unitary control over most railway operations. Unless the distribution of "franchises" is self-balancing, providing clear benefits to aU participants, the owning railways are unlikely to permit a serious level of competition in markets which they have traditionally controlled. Thus, competitive access is an evolutionary approach. The 'wholesaler" option should accomplish an excellent marketing job, but the actual operation would remain in monolithic hands. Finally, the "tol rail" enterprise might come closest to reflecting a theoretical model of marketing effectiveness; yet it would generate potential operating conflicts and higher transaction costs. This option would also caU for the highest degree of administrative capability in the owning government. 88. Underlying aU these issues and options is the basic tradeoff between efficiency of production and effectiveness in meeting market needs. The traditional monolithic railway, organized in a strictly hierarchical pattern along departmental lines, is geared to producing maximal amounts of relatively undifferentiated output with minimal inputs. However, what the customer wants and what the competition will provide does not necessarily mesh fully with the - 44 - Table 3.6 Characterization of Generic Options Based on Private Sector Development (Ratings are H=High, M=Medium, or L=Low.) Option Raing Discussion (1) Monolithic railway (status quo) L The monolithic railway, by definition, is not to be sold off piecemeal, although some contracting is possible. (2) Lines-of-business organization M Although still subsidiary to the monolith, the lines of business may lend themselves at least to joint-venture or other creative arrangements with the private sector. (3) Competitive access M This option is still conducted by monolithic carriers, although some private involvement in the reshaping is possible. (4) "Wholesaler" H Presumably the "retailers" would come from the private sector. (5) "Toll rail" enterprise H The splitting of functions could easily lend itself to private sector participation. Table 3.7 Characterization of Generic Options Based on Startup/Transaction Costs (tatings are H=High, M=Mediun, or L=Low.) Option Rating Discussion (1) Monolithic railway (status quo) L By definition, a single entity in a status quo situation must have zero "startup" costs and low transaction costs. (2) Lines-of-business organization M Startup costs would vary with the scope of the changes made; transaction costs would have to increase as more precise accounting is introduced for internal transactions. (3) Competitive access M WiU vary with the precise nature of the operation. Trackage rights operations will, at the very least, lead to new transactions among the competitors. (4) "Wholesaler" M Although the nature of the tansactions wil be more complex than under the status quo, the number of transactions should decrease because of the relatively small number of "retail" customers of the railway "wholesaler". (5) "Toll rail" enterprise H The complete separation of functions envisioned in this option should lead to the highest startup and transaction costs. -45 - Table 3.8 Summary Characterization of Generic Reshaping Options (Options are rated High (H), Medium (M), or Low (L) according to their responsiveness to each issue. The characteriations are for generic options and would nawally vary with the particular of specific options scrutinized.) ______._____ ,___ Options and Characterizations (1) (2) (S) Monolkhic Lines-of- (3) "Toll Railway Business Competive (4) Rail" Issues (status quo) Organization Access "Wholesaler" Enterprise MarketDefinition L H M H M Financial Accountability L M or L M or L M H Ease of Operadons Coordination H M M M L Intamodal Compeution L L H H M Appropriate Maintenance ? Levels M M M M+ (Depends on . pricing) Track Maintenance Coordi- H M M M L nation with Operations l Private Sector Development L M M H H Start-up Problems and Transaction Cost Burdens L M M M H railway's production efficiency. Thus, by contrast, the reshaped railway - whatever the depth of the attempted restructuring - seeks to serve each market in a manner that maximizes either profits or other benefits dictated by its agreement with the State.43' Regardless of the precise objective, a market-sensitive railway may be less "efficient" than a well-managed monolithic entity in terms of production, and yet be much more effective in fulfilling its goals of improved service quality and commercial performance. 89. For example, a restructured railway will typically establish separate "commercial" and "noncommercial" lines of business. The former would be operated on a commercial, for-profit basis and would be self-supporting and generally unregulated; the latter would be operated under contract with government at some level(s), and would receive operating subventions under the "public service obligation (PSO)" rubric. This dichotomy would free the railway to operate as 43/ For a detailed discussion of contracts between the State and the railway (among other steps in a methodical restructuring approach), see Huff and Thompson, op. cit. - 46 - a commercial enterprise by reducing the government's span of control to separable PSO functions only, and would encourage both railway and government to view PSO functions as a business relationship between customer and contract supplier. By the railway's traditional measures of technical operating efficiency (e.g., coach-kilometers per locomotive-kilometer), the restructured services, taken together, may appear to fall below historical levels. This decrease, however, may mask a host of steps taken by the respective lines of business to boost the responsiveness of each service to customers' needs and willingness to pay. The result should be a more profitable railway in the case of commercial services, and noncommercial services that better fulfill their public policy motivations. TEcENcAL CONSIDERATIONS 90. The following topics, while highly technical in nature, require careful consideration in the planning and implementation phases of railway restructuring. Cost Assigment Techniques 91. Cost assignment44' under some of the options undergoes the test of inter-entity nego- tiations. In such negotiations, each entity looks out for itself first. To assure long-term viability of the entire structure, nevertheless, the cost assignment scheme should pass additional tests: measurement of the comprehensive cost effects on all entities, and assessing the relationship of costs to benefits. 92. Comprehensive Cost Effects on all Entities. Cost assignment techniques, however equitable and plausible on the surface, influence operating decisions by railway entities. The general rule is that, whatever cost factor is used, the paying railway will seek to minimize it over the long term. Through minimization of that cost factor, additional long-term costs may unwittingly accrue to all entities involved. 93. Assume, for example, a "toll rail" option involving a facility entity and several operators. If the facility entity charges other users by the wagon-kilometers they generate, then the operators will have an added incentive to reduce the number of wagons operated. In freight service, for example, this additional impetus can accelerate the trend toward larger wagons, heavier axle loadings, and potentially increased long-term degradation of the track structure. Each year, the operator saves, while the extent and cause of the incremental damage may pass 44/ In this paper, the term "cost allocation" denotes a division of common costs among elements of a single organization by management fiat, and connotes a mostly theoretical (paper) exercise. "Cost assignment," on the other hand, implies any means of ascertaining cost responsibilities, fixing the operating parameters (cost factors) on which charges are based, establishing unit rates, and passing the costs through to the responsible organizations. "Cost assignment" therefore subsumes, in addition to "allocation," negotiations and agreements among different entities or among clearly delineated business units of a single entity. - 47 - undetected and uncharged for. In the end, someone must pay for heavier maintenance or even for an "upgrading" project; or the operating capabilities and profitability potential of the railway deteriorate. 94. By the same token, if the facility entity charges by the train-kilometer, then the operator will have an incentive to run fewer, but longer, trains. This step degrades service frequency and may adversely affect market share and long-term revenues in both freight and passenger service. 95. Thus, the total costs and business implications of a particular cost assignment policy over the long term may be very different than the initial prospect to both the facility and operating entity, or to the responsible ministry. Indeed, a separation of functions implies a fragmentation of civil, mechanical, movement, and marketing decisions among separate entities. Monolithic railways have often failed to synthesize engineering, operating, and economic decisions, but have at least had the opportunity to do so; reshaped railways, on the other hand, must often overcome deliberately created institutional barriers in making long-term decisions that are optimal for all entities and concerned polities taken together. 96. Cost assignment-driven trends such as this would not operate immediately or with scientific precision, and would not necessarily overwhelm all other management decisions. Hidden costs may arise even without such scenarios as those described above. Yet an unconsidered choice of cost assignment parameters can influence engineering and operating decisions over the long term. These influences may manifest themselves in almost imperceptible distortions in trajectory rather than overt changes in direction. 97. Relationship of Costs to Benefits. Typically, a large-scale railway restructuring aims at affording maximal flexibility to the successor operating companies to act as businesses. The chosen cost assignment scheme can affect this flexibility by encouraging or discouraging innovation and expansions into new and potentially profitable lines of business. As an elementary example, again based on the "toll rail" option, the fixed facility entity may charge a standard per-unit rate for track maintenance (or some other function). The operating entity may be considering the addition of a new dedicated train to serve a completely new market with no adverse effect on existing revenue sources. Depending on how the rate was originally calculated, the incremental track maintenance imposed by the new service could be far less than the charges it will have to bear at the standard rate. If the cost assignment scheme makes no allowance for opportunities such as this, including (of course) a mechanism for long-term alterations to fit changing circumstances and to avoid shortfalls in meeting total costs, then the transportation economics of both entities may suffer. This situation points to a potential pitfall in some reshaping options: cost assignments may become ossified, necessitating formal negotiations to develop quick responses to marketing opportunities. A monolithic entity, on the other hand, if creatively managed, may be able to respond to situations like the example above much more quickly. - 48 - 98. Moreover, depending on the mechanism yielding the costing formulas, special interests may be able to influence the assignments so as to convert them into cross-subsidies. Likewise, assignment schemes may become rigid over time, thus incrementally creating cross-subsidies and beneficiary groups as underlying conditions change while the formulas remain fixed. 99. Creative Approaches to Cost Assignment. While cost assignment schemes based on traditional units of measurement (train-km, wagon-km, gross ton-km) may appeal in that they intuitively relate to the consumption of the track structure, they can have negative long-term impacts through the subtle distortions they may induce in marketing, movement, and mechanical policies. Therefore, developers of the cost assignment scheme for a given reshaping application might consider introduction of cost factors related to revenue generation (revenue ton-km, revenue passenger-kIn, percentage of revenues) where they can serve as rough surrogates for use of the property and where they will give operating management the "right" incentives. Sliding scales based on levels of service (i.e., different rates for different traffic densities), compound calculations (use of more than one cost factor: e.g., X per wagon-km plus Y per revenue ton-kie45), or some combination of all these approaches might produce a more supple costing technique that avoids long-term distortions and encourages the entrepreneurial spirit in the operator(s). 100. Cost assignment techniques clearly have implications far beyond the transportation economics of the railway entities. Public policy may dictate certain objectives in terms of quantities of rail transportation produced, in order to meet energy consumption, environmental, development, or other social goals. If the cost assignment techniques ignore these implications, then the underlying purpose of the entire reorganization scheme may be subverted. Techniques for Developing Appropriate Fixed Facility Maintenance and Investment Levels 101. In any reshaping option, the proper matching of maintenance to needs would benefit from three techniques: (1) institutionalizing the process for establishing maintenance standards for each facility; (2) designating an appropriate maintaining entity; and (3) providing arrangements to insure future equilibrium in the facility maintenance function. The balance of this chapter treats these techniques in turn and concludes with a related topic: planning for investments in the fixed plant. 102. Maintenance Standards. An appropriate protocol for developing maintenance standards in an option involving more than one entity might include the following. (The suggested procedures assume, for simplicity, that the facility condition on the effective date of the option requires no immediate capital investment.) 45/ See, for example, the suggested cost assignment regime under the competitive cost accesa option in Chapter 2. - 49 - (a) Identify Required Line Capabilities. Wherever a reshaping occurs, the successor companies need to establish what services will operate over each facility and what will be the performance characteristics for each service over that facility. (b) Match Maintenance Standards to Required Capabilities. For each facility, the parties need to agree on the standard to which it will be maintained to fulfill the highest requirements placed upon it while meeting the needs of all services. For track, appropriate performance and design standards for geometrics and components would solidify at this point. In such negotiations, the intended service levels for some operators may have to give way in the face of likely cost levels. (c) Develop a Maintenance Plan. Based on the intended uses of, and agreed upon standards for, the properties, the parties will need to develop a maintenance plan showing the procedures that will constitute "normalized" maintenance into the future. Because actual experience may vary widely from the pro-forma definition, periodic review of track conditions and adjustments in the maintenance plan will be necessary in accordance with an agreed procedure. (d) Develop Data Underlying Cost Assignment. If more than one operator uses the facility, three basic issues inhere in maintenance cost allocation: * The levels of service, hence plant, required by each operator. (All other things being equal, the operator who imposes the highest standards would pay the highest unit cost.) 3 The unit degradation imposed on the plant by each operator. (An operator may cause disproportionate maintenance expense even if the standards it requires, and the volumes of traffic it carries over the line, are relatively low.) * The volumes envisioned by each operator. (Low volumes may, in some cases, reduce the operator's fair share of some fixed costs.) Documentation supporting the above issues would be assembled during the planning process to form a basis for cost assignment decisions. In reality, however, these issues often defy quantification (or the expense of quantification exceeds the benefits in terms of accuracy) and the "truth" emerges through negotiation rather than through science. 103. Selection of Maintaining Entity. Since maintenance standards and cost allocations raise so many tricky issues in a reshaping option, the choice of maintenance entity plays a critical role in assuring a constant and appropriate level of physical capability. The organization performing the maintenance will either be the primary operator, the facility entity, or a monolithic entity that - 50 - controls both facilities and operations. The institutional framework for the maintenance function will depend on whether single or multiple operators use the facility. Conceivably, the maintenance function could devolve to more than one entity based on geographical or detailed functional breakdowns. (It is hard to see, however, a case in which more than one entity could perform maintenance of a single subsystem, for example track, in a single location.) If two operators over a given facility have equal primacy, the selection of a maintaining entity would be made by negotiation. Finally, in unusual circumstances, the least important of multiple operators could indeed have maintenance responsibility; a short line owner/operator could, for example, do the maintenance even though the bulk of the tonnage results from trackage rights. Such a case actually exists in the Midwestern United States. 104. As with all decisions in a reshaping scenario, the choice of maintaining entity should consider the natural tendencies of the parties involved. The following discussion focuses, first, on the two principal parties in a "toll-road" option (the facility entity and the operator), and then covers the monolithic railway. (a) Tendencies of the Facility Entity. The facility entity has a long-term goal of protecting the utility, productivity, and value of its property. Nevertheless, in the short term, its high fixed costs (interest on debt, and potentially taxes) may give it an incentive to charge maximal fixed and variable fees to users while skimping on variable maintenance expense. This tendency may arise at the outset of the restructuring if the facility entity receives the plant in outstanding condition, since degradation may occur very slowly. Such a tendency will gain momentum if the financial arrangements with the govemment allow the facility entity to look with confidence to the future funding of an "upgrading" project to restore any maintenance deferrals. Countermeasures do exist to such a predilection to deferral. First, if the facility entity has modest operating and financial goals and a well-assured revenue stream, then its short-term tendency to skimp on maintenance will wane. Also, if the facility entity's management perceives a clear financial link between the quantity and quality of maintenance performed, and the fees paid by users, then such management will have greater incentive to perform the required maintenance, especially if the verification methods and penalties discussed below are effected. Finally, if nothing else, liability considerations should motivate the fixed facility entity to fulfill its obligations. Indeed, the examples in Chapter 2 show how large liability concerns loom even in a small-scale separation. (b) Tendencies of the Operating Entity. An operating entity would likewise have a long-term goal of protecting its operating capabilities, both to enhance service marketability and to reduce movement costs. Nevertheless, an operating entity maintaining the track could also have short term profitability incentives to skimp on maintenance if the facility starts out in relatively good condition, if degradation is gradual, if the facility entity neglects to observe the condition of - 51 - its property, and if there are no secondary operators to notice the cutbacks. Such shortsighted tendencies would weaken if the operator begins its corporate life with an ample positive cash flow, and if it perceives direct and immediate benefits from adhering to the maintenance plan. Since the facility entity will benefit from the preservation of the property, and since certain types of deterioration result from the passage of time rather than trains, discreetly couched incentive payments from the facility to the operating entity may prove appropriate. Verifying performance or neglect, an independent inspection program would serve as a powerful negative motivation for the operator to adhere to the maintenance plan. (c) Tendencies of a Monolithic Entity. A facility entity/primary operator (monolithic entity) would have short- and long-term tendencies somewhat similar to those of completely separated entities. In fact, a unitary entity might deliberately embark on a program of maintenance deferrals more easily, and with less commotion and adverse publicity, than a pure facility or operating entity: the decision to defer could be made at the top, subordinates would simply carry it out quietly, and outside authorities (for example, government safety inspectorates) might discover it only after the fact. With separate owning and operating entities, deferral decisions would come to light with a speed proportionate to the vigilance of the non-maintaining entity. If strong enough and operating at enough volume, the secondary operator(s) might insist on higher maintenance levels, but these might only be reflected in higher trackage rights fees in the next year. Indeed, the sample trackage rights agreement (in Chapter 2) explicitly provides that the secondary operator may request as much maintenance as it wants -- if it is willing to pay. 105. Although aU entities could share long-term tendencies to maintain, and short-term inclinations to neglect, the property, the operator may perform the maintenance function more assiduously than the facility entity (if different). The operator would feel the effects of deterioration relatively quickly, both through declines in service and revenues, and through increases in movement expenses. On the other hand, the facility entity would at first perceive shortfalls on the revenue side only. As the presumed dispatcher, the operator would also coordinate the interaction of maintenance and train movements more readily than the facility entity. 106. Continuing Arrangements. Owing to the complexities of facility maintenance issues, a strategic plan for a reshaping option should propose a continuing institutional arrangement to deal with all these concerns. Verification and inspection of facility maintenance on a periodic basis by an impartial party, coupled with appropriate and automatic monetary incentives and disincentives, would help to assure adherence to the planned standards. Such inspections would also confirm whether the pro-forma maintenance plan matches actual needs, and would pinpoint recommended changes. Evolving marketing approaches, hence service requirements, of the operators would also motivate maintenance plan changes, which should take place in a collegial and technical forum. - 52 - 107. Investment Decisions. LUke maintenance planning, investment and disinvestment decisions require close coordination between all entities involved in railway restructuring. Such decisions also entail early participation by the financing authorities, both governmental and private. Thus, the evaluator of a reshaping scheme should ask: during and after the restructuring, who will be choosing to upgrade or downgrade facilities, how will the choices be made, and who will have responsibility for implementation? Will the established process lead to comprehensive, businesslike decisions that encompass future marketing considerations, revenue streams, expenses, and the initial investment to be made? Under proper management, a monolithic railway would at least have the potential to set its investment priorities systematically and comprehensively. In some reshaping options, by contrast, the evaluation of a project may be so fragmented among entities as to permit only analysis of its elements rather than synthesis of its overall costs and benefits. 108. Clearly, a reshaping scheme would call for an especially methodical program for making investment/disinvestment decisions. Unless such a mechanism is in place, the self-interest of the parties involved may distort the decision-making process and result either in a 'bad" decision (as measured against the goals of the restructuring) or no decision at all, which could also impede the achievement of the goals. However, a methodical, consultative approach to such decisions would -- at best -- make spontaneous responses to fleeting opportunities difficult to obtain. - 53 - BIBLIOGRAPHY (By country, in alphabetical order. Within each country, unattributed articles precede other entries. Documents of global import appear under "General.") Britain "BR optimistic as it rides the storms," Modern Railways, XLVH (August 1990), 394-395. "Misty Vision," Railway Gazette International, CXLVI (September 1991), p. 559. "Sir Bob takes the initiative in hard times," Modern Railways, XLVm (August 1991), 393-394. Palmer, M.J. [Deputy Secretary, Department of Transport, United Kingdom], "Government-Railway Relations," in International Union of Railways (UI), "Management and Policy Studies (MAPS)," seminar, Paris, September 1989. Reid, Sir Robert, CBE, "Presentation to The World Bank," November 1990. Reid, Sir Robert, CBE, Institutional Reform in Transport. The British Rail Experience, Washington: The World Bank, June 1989. (Discussion paper for the Infrastructure and Urban Development Department.) Tomkins, Richard, "A new track to profit centres," The Financial TImes [no date or page number; presumably June 1991]. Canada Thoms, William E., "Canada's Lawless Railroad," Trains, XLI (October 1991), 25-26. EC Blanchette, Robert W., Mark J. Andrews, and John R. Mietus, "The Emerging European Community Transportation Market: ChaUenge or Caveat," Washington: Verner, Liipfert, Bernhard, McPherson and Hand, May 1990 (prepared for Transportation Lawyers Association 53rd Annual Conference). Community of European Railways (CER), "Reply of the CER to the document of Mr. Van Miert (Ref.: COM(89)564 final of 1/25/90)," document annexed to telefaxed letter from C. Ryan of the CER Secretariat, Brussels, to Louis S. Thompson of the World Bank. [This is the railway managements' reply to the European Community proposals.] - 54 - Council of the European Communities, "Council Directive of July 29, 1991 on the development of the Community's Railways," Official Journal of the European Communities, August 24, 1991, No. L237/25FF. Fournier, Jacques [President, SNCF], letter to Karel Van Miert [Commissaire charge des transports, Commission des Communautes Europ6ennes], 20 March 1991. Gardner, David, "EC moves to end European national railway monopolies," The Financial 7imes [no date or page number; presumably June 1991]. Gardner, David, and Richard Tomkins, "Patchwork could become a network," The Financial Times, June 24, 1991 [no page number]. International Union of Railways (UIC), "Transformation of the International Railway System as Part of New European Transport Policy," Paris, France, October 1991. United Nations Economic and Social Council, Economic Commission for Europe, Inland Transport Committee, Principal Working Party on Rail Transport, "Draft study (white paper) concerning the development of an intemational rail transport system in Europe," December 5, 1989. France "Des modifications dans l'organisation des Directions gdn6rales," Revue generale des chemins defer, CIX (May 1990), 62-64. "Le contrat de plan Atat/SNCF," Revue gen£rale des chemins defer, CIX (May 1990), 50-56. Allen, G. Freeman, "SNCF in the 1990s," Modern Railw4ys, August 1990, 418-419. Pellegrin, J. [Director of Studies, Planning and Research, SNCF], "Relations between State and Railway," in International Union of Railways (UIC), "Management and Policy Studies (MAPS)," seminar, Paris, September 1989. SNCF, Contratde plan ktat-SNCF1990-1994 [annotated edition], Paris: SNCF (no date) SNCF, Contrat de plan kbat-SNCF 1990-1994, Paris: SNCF (no date) SNCF, Plan d'entreprise 1990-94, Paris: SNCF (no date) - 55 - General Allston, L.L., "Railway Investments" and "Review of Investment Sessions," in International Union of Railways (UIC), "Management and Policy Studies (MAPS)," seminar, Paris, September 1989. Bouley, Jean [Secretary-General, UIC], Summary of Theme II, "Managing the Railway," in International Union of Railways (UIC), "Management and Policy Studies (MAPS)," seminar, Paris, September 1989. Galenson, Alice, and Louis Thompson, The Bank's Experience with Railway Lending: An Evolving Approach, Washington: The World Bank. Huff, Lee W., and Louis S. Thompson, Techniques for Railway Restructuring, Washington: Infrastructure and Urban Development Department, The World Bank, March 1990. International Union of Railways (UIC), "Management and Policy Studies (MAPS)," seminar, Paris, September 1989. Keeler, Theodore, Railroads, Freight, and Public Policy, Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1983. Norfolk & Western Railway Company, sample interchange agreement [no bibliographic data available]. Norfolk & Western Railway Company, sample trackage rights agreement with general conditions [no bibliographic data available). Overbey, Daniel L., Railroads: the Free Enterprise Alternative, Westport, Connecticut: Quorum Books, 1982. Pittsburgh, Chartiers & Youghiogheny Railway Co. and Pittsburgh & Lake Erie Railroad Co., joint terminal agreement for McKees Rocks, Pennsylvania, August 1, 1902. Thompson, Louis S., "Summary of Theme I: Government-railway relations," in International Union of Railways (UIC), "Management and Policy Studies (MAPS)," seminar, Paris, September 1989. Wheeling & Lake Erie Railway Co., Pennsylvania Railroad Co., and Baltimore & Ohio Railroad Co., joint switching agreement for Massillon, Ohio, July 20, 1932. Wyckoff, D. Daryl, Railroad Management, Lexington, Massachusetts: D. C. Heath and Company, 1976. - 56 - Germany "Strategic report forms basis to build commercial railway," Railway Gazette International, CXLVH (September 1991), p. 555. Stockmann, D. [Senior Railway Engineer, Kreditanstalt fulr Wiederaufbau, Federal Republic of Germany], Government-Railway Relations, in International Union of Railways (UIC), "Management and Policy Studies (MAPS)," seminar, Paris, September 1989. Japan 'Results of Railways in Japan," unpublished and unattributed income statements and balance sheets for fiscal years 1987 and 1988 for successor companies to JY1R. "Shinkansen extensions to go ahead,' Railway Gazette International, CXLVI (September 1991), p. 561. East Japan Railway Company, Restructuring of the Japanese National Railways: Process Leading to Privatization and Division, Tokyo: East Japan Railway Company, August 1987. Kato, Hiroshi, The Japanese Economy in Transition, Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shinposha [no date], cf. especially the appendix "Privatization in Japan." Sumita, S., "Outline of Privatization and Division of Japanese National Railways," Rail International, XI (May 1990), 14-19. Tanahashi, Yasushi [Vice President, Japan Railway Construction Corporation], Refonn of Railways in Japan, Washington: The World Bank, March 1992. (Discussion paper for the Infrastructure and Urban Development Department.) Various sources, "JNR Restructuring: Important Points," compendium of unpublished questions and answers apparently developed in correspondence between The World Bank and Japanese railway officials, no date provided. Yamanouchi, S. [Executive Vice President, East Japan Railway Co.] "Managing the Railway," in International Union of Railways (UIC), "Management and Policy Studies (MAPS)," seminar, Paris, September 1989. - 57 - Malaysia Price, Waterhouse & Co., Study on the Regulatory Frameworkfor Privatised Monopolies in Malaysia, Volume IV: Transport Sectors, Chapter 5: Railways, report for The World Bank [no further bibliographic data available]. Spain RENFE, "Annual Report," 1989. RENF13, "New Corporate Model," March 1990. Sweden "Zweden's track authority sparks a quiet revolution," article [presumably in International Railway Journal; no bibliographic reference available.] Banverket, "Information about the new Swedish National Rail Administration," information sheet, Stockholm: Banverket, September 29, 1988. Brandborn, Jan [Director General, Banverket], and Lars Hellsvik, "The new railway policy in Sweden: separation of network and operations," Rail Engineering International Edition, XX (1991, Number 2), 7-10. EHansson, Lars, "The Swedish Approach to Multi-Modal Transportation Planning," paper presented at 1990 AAR Intermodal Policy Conference, Key Largo, Florida. Hansson, Lars, "Transport Policy Strategies for the Railways," paper presented at 11th International Symposium on Theory and Practice in Transport Economics, Brussels, September 1988. Hansson, Lars, and Jan-Eric Nilsson, "A New Swedish Railroad Policy: Separation of Infrastructure and Traffic Production," Transportation Research-A, Vol. 25A, No. 4 (1991), 153-159. Hansson, Lars, letter to Louis S. Thompson of The World Bank, October 6, 1991. Jansson, Jan Owen, and Peter Cardebring, "Swedish Railway Policy 1979-88," Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, XXII (September 1989), 329-337. Larsson, Stig, "The Restructuring of SJ," paper presented at the General Assembly of the Union Internazionale des Chemins de Fer, Sofia, June 13, 1990. Nilsson, Jan-Eric [Banverket, Sweden], letter to Jos6 Carbajo of The World Bank, March 11, 1991. - 58 - Nilsson, Jan-Eric, "Second Best Problems in Railway Infrastructure Pricing and Investment," unpublished article included with letter to Jose Carbajo. Swedish Ministry of Transport and Communications, Government Bill on Transpbrt Policy for the 1990s, English summary, Stockholm: Ministry of Transport and Communications [no date shown]. Uruguay Berchesi, J.F. [Chairman of the Board of the Uruguayan State Railway Administration], 'The Rebirth of the Railway in Uruguay," in International Union of Railways (UIC), "Management and Policy Studies (MAPS)," seminar, Paris, September 1989. US Benham, Isabel, "Open Access: A Concept for the Railroad Industry's Survival," statement prepared for the 3rd American Railroad Conference, New York: Printon, Kane Research, Inc., November 1989. Beshers, Eric W., Conrail: Government Creation and Privatization of an American Railroad, Washington: The World Bank, Policy, Planning & Research Staff, Infrastructure and Urban Development Department, March 1989. Moyer, Neil E., and Louis S. Thompson, Northeast Corridor: Achievement and Potential, Washington: U.S. Department of Transportation, 1986. - 59 - LIST OF ACRONYMS This acronym... ...refers to AAR Association of American Railroads APL American President Lines BR State railway of the United Kingdom (British Rail) BU "Business unit" as referred to in the Spanish restructuring CER Community of European Railways CN Canadian National Railways CP Canadian Pacific Railway DB State railway of the former German Federal Republic (Deutsche Bundesbahn) DEAG Deutsche Eisenbahn AG (proposed successor to state railways of Germany) DR State railway of the former German Democratic Republic (Deutsche Reichsbahn) EC European Community JNR Former State railway of Japan (Japanese National Railways) (now restructured into smaller companies, see text) PSO Public service obligation: the British term for explicit government subventions to preserve rail services of no redeeming commercial value, but of perceived social value. This term is used in that sense throughout the report. RENFE State railway of Spain Si State railway of Sweden SNCF State railway of France (Societe nationale des chemins defer firanfais) UIC International Union of Railways (Union internationale des chemins de fer) Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS906 Bulgaria's Evolving Legal Framework Cheryl W. Gray May 1992 CECSE for Private Sector Development Peter lanachkov 37188 WPS907 Institutional Reform in Emerging Robert Pardy May 1992 Z. Seguis Securities Markets 37664 WPS908 Tax Incentives, Market Power, and Dagmar Rajagopal May 1992 C. Jones Corporate Investment: A Rational Anwar Shah 37669 Expectations Model Applied to Pakistani and Turkish Industries WPS909 Parallel Markets, the Foreign Janine Aron May 1992 V. Barthelmes Exchange Auction, and Exchange Ibrahim A. Elbadawi 39175 Rate Unification in Zambia WPS910 Policy Issues in Financial Regulation Dimitri Vittas May 1992 W. Pitayatonakarn 37666 WPS911 Does Exchange Rate Volatility Hinder Ying Qian May 1992 D. Gustafson Export Growth? Additional Evidence Panos Varangis 33714 WPS912 Understanding the Investment Cycle Andr6s Solimano May 1992 E. Khine in Adjustment Programs: Evidence from 39361 Reforming Economies WPS913 The Women's Development Program Maitreyi Das May 1992 L. Bennett in Rajasthan: A Case Study in Group 82772 Formation for Women's Development WPS914 Health Personnel Development in J. Patrick Vaughan May 1992 0. Nadora Sub-Saharan Africa 31091 WPS915 Trade Policy and Exchange Rate W. Max Corden May 1992 CECTP Issues in the Former Soviet Union 37947 WPS916 Measuring the Risk of Default In Six Marc Chesney June 1992 S. King-Watson Highly Indebted Countries Jacques Morisset 31047 WPS917 Creditor Country Regulations and Asli DemirgOg-Kunt June 1992 K. Waelti Commercial Bank Lending to Developing 37664 Countries WPS918 Tax Evasion and Tax Reform in a Jaime de Melo June 1992 D. Ballantyne Low-income Economy: General David Roland-Holst 37947 Equilibrium Estimates for Mona Haddad Madagascar WPS919 Fiscal and Quasi-Fiscal Deficits, Roberto de Rezende June 1992 L. Ly Nominal and Real: Measurement Rocha 37352 and Policy Issues Femando Saldanha Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS920 Economic Incentives and Point Raymond J. Kopp June 1992 C. Jones Source Emissions: Choice of 37764 Modeling Platform WPS921 Road Infrastructure and Economic Cesar Queiroz June 1992 M. Laygo Development: Some Diagnostic Surhid Gautam G! 261 Indicators WPS922 Central America at a Crossroads Sylvia Saborio June 1992 M. Colinet Constantine Michalopoulos 37044 WPS923 Listening to Firms: How to Use Firm- Andrew H. W. Stone June 1992 P. Infante Level Surveys to Assess Constraints 37642 on Private Sector Development WPS924 How Reduced Demand for Children Rafael Rofman June 1992 0. Nadora and Access to Family Planning 31091 Accelerated the Fertility Decline in Colombia WPS925 A General-Equilibrium-Based Social Ngee-Choon Chia June 1992 A. Cox Policy Model for C6te d'lvoire Sadek Wahba 34778 John Whalley WPS926 Options for Reshaping the Railway Neil E. Moyer June 1992 B. Gregory Louis S. Thompson 33744