WPS7232 Policy Research Working Paper 7232 Tax Evasion through Trade Intermediation Evidence from Chinese Exporters Xuepeng Liu Huimin Shi Michael Ferrantino Trade and Competitiveness Global Practice Group April 2015 Policy Research Working Paper 7232 Abstract Many production firms use intermediary trading firms to they sell differentiated products. Even for a moderate level export indirectly. This paper uses Chinese export data at of underreporting, the revenue loss is close to one billion the transaction level to investigate the tax evasion motive U.S. dollars. The paper also finds that such underreporting through indirect trade. The paper provides strong evi- behavior through domestic intermediaries may be associated dence that, under China’s partial export value-added with cross-border evasion through underreporting export tax rebate policy, production firms can effectively evade values to foreign partners. In addition, the results indicate value-added taxes by underreporting their selling prices that the evasion motive is stronger for larger transactions. to domestic intermediary trading firms, especially when This paper is a product of the Trade and Competitiveness Global Practice Group. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted at mferrantino@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team Tax Evasion through Trade Intermediation: Evidence from Chinese Exporters Xuepeng Liu† Huimin Shi†† Michael Ferrantinoξ Kennesaw State University Renmin University of China The World Bank JEL: F10, F14, H26, O24, O25 Keywords: Trade Intermediation; Value Added Tax; Tax Evasion; China's Export Tax Rebates Acknowledgement: We thank Carlos Ramirez, Mark Rider and the participants at the International and Development Economics Workshop at the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta,the North America Chinese Economists Society Meetings at Purdue University,and China Meeting of Econometric Society at Xiamen University for comments and suggestions. † Xuepeng Liu, Department of Economics & Finance, Coles College of Business, Kennesaw State University (email: xliu6@kennesaw.edu). †† Huimin Shi (corresponding author), School of Economics, Renmin University of China (email: huiminshi@ruc.edu.cn). ξ Michael Ferrantino, Trade and Competitiveness Global Practice, the World Bank (email: mferrantino@worldbank.org). Disclaimer: The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the 1. Introduction Production firms can export directly by themselves or rely on intermediary trading firms to export for them (indirect exports).1 Intermediary trading firms play an important role in international trade. In the U.S., wholesale and retail firms account for about 11 percent and 24 percent of exports and imports, respectively (Bernard et al., 2010). In the early 1980s, 300 Japanese trading firms (sogo shosha) handled 80 percent of Japanese trade (Rossman 1984). According to the data from China Customs, indirect exports in China accounted for 38 percent of the shipments and 21 percent of the value in the year of 2005. Despite the extensive studies at the firm level in the recent trade literature, the role of trading firms has not been fully explored. This paper investigates the tax evasion motive behind indirect exports in China, stemming from the partial export value-added tax (VAT) rebate policy. In countries that adopt a destination-based VAT, including China, the VAT should be collected on domestic transactions, but not on exports. The VAT on the value added at the final stage before exporting should be exempted, and the previously paid input VAT should be fully refunded in principle so that exporters can regain their initial competitiveness. Unlike the full rebate policy in the EU and elsewhere, China has a partial rebate system with rebate rates less than or at most equal to collection rates. The unrebated part of the VAT becomes effectively an export tax,2 which is calculated based on the export prices for direct exporters but domestic purchasing prices for trading firms (indirect exporters). To evade such an export tax, exporters have an incentive to underreport either their export prices or domestic purchasing prices.3 If a production firm exports its products 1 Our focus is on the case where a production firm sells its products to an intermediary trading firm, with the trading firm taking charge of the tax rebate. Alternately, the intermediary’s main role may be to help a production firm to find buyers, while the production firm is still in charge of the tax rebate itself. We analyze the former case because we do not observe the latter case directly. 2 Feldstein and Krugman (1990) show that a destination-based VAT system should provide exporters full rebates and an incomplete rebate is equivalent to an export tax. 3 The evasion behaviors discussed in this paper are different from another popular type of VAT evasion by firms within a VAT-adopting country in which they over-report their input VAT using fake invoices to obtain more input VAT credits and hence reduce their VAT liabilities. 2 directly, its export VAT rebate is calculated based on the final export prices.4 If a production firm exports indirectly through a trading company, however, its export VAT rebate in China is calculated based on its domestic selling prices (i.e., the domestic purchasing price of the trading company), rather than the final export price by the trading firm. In this case, firms may have incentive to underreport the domestic purchasing or selling price to evade the VAT. This paper explores how firms evade such an export tax in the case of indirect exports. The above discussion suggests a positive correlation between export tax rates (i.e., the nonrefundable part of VAT) and the probability of indirect exporting, which is measured by the share of indirect exports in our product level analysis. That is, the higher the implicit export tax, the more likely it is that exporting will be done through an intermediary. We test this hypothesis using China’s Customs export data at the transaction level for the year 2005, which is the first year after the full liberalization of trading rights under China’s WTO commitments.5 This correlation is empirically robust, especially for differentiated products whose values are easier to underreport than homogenous products, and is also stronger for the exports of state-owned enterprises (SOEs), which are more politically connected with the government than private or foreign firms. In addition, although the VAT rebate in the case of indirect exporting is not based on the final export price of a trading company, the trading company may also have an incentive to underreport its exporting prices to minimize the chance of being caught because the purchasing and selling price differential is used by the Chinese tax authorities to detect evasion behaviors. Such a view is supported by a product-country level analysis. This implies that the tax evasion through domestic trading firms may be associated with cross border evasion in the case of indirect exports. Therefore, both types of evasion should be reflected in the underreported export values and the data reporting discrepancies between China and 4 Ferrantino, Liu and Wang (2012) provide empirical evidence for how production firms may have incentive to underreport their export values in the case of direct exports, while the current paper investigates the evasion through indirect exporting. 5 We choose to use the data for year 2005 for the following reasons. First, before 2005, the export and import right was under the examination and approval system. Production firms would have to choose indirect exports if they did not have export right, which is unrelated to tax evasion. Second, two other related papers on Chinese intermediary firms, Ahn, Khandelwal, and Wei (2011) and Tang and Zhang (2012), also use the data of 2005. To facilitate the comparison with their work, we follow them by choosing the same year. 3 importing countries. The current paper provides a complete explanation for the export price underreporting by both direct and indirect exporters, which in turn helps to explain why China’s reported exports are significantly smaller than the corresponding imports reported by partner countries such as the U.S. The fast-growing trade of China, especially its exports and large trade surplus, has drawn increasing attention. Investigating the incentives behind the underreporting of China’s exports not only provides policy makers a clearer picture of China’s trade, but also helps authorities to detect and curb evasion behaviors. Our results suggest that the partial rebate policy can motivate firms to evade VAT, although the scope of VAT evasion is usually considered to be small because this tax is imposed at every stage of production and it is difficult for all of the involved firms to collude. We show how firms respond to tax incentives by choosing to export either directly or indirectly through intermediaries. Anecdotal evidence shows that some production firms export indirectly through trading companies or establish seemingly separate but actually related trading companies simply to facilitate tax evasion. Such kinds of related transactions are usually difficult to observe and to identify. The methodology in this paper provides evidence that is consistent with such kinds of evasion behaviors. In fact, there are explicit provisions in China for production companies to own and control trading intermediaries (Ministry of Foreign Trade, 1999).6 Our estimate implies that, even for a moderate level of underreporting (understating the true value by one-third), the revenue loss is close to one billion U.S. dollars, a sizable amount. This is also how much tax revenue the government can potentially obtain in the absence of such evasion. The evasion comes with a real cost over and beyond the tax revenue loss. For instance, the evasion has implications for the ability of the Chinese government to use variable VAT rebates as a policy instrument with various aims: to promote high-technology sectors, reduce energy/pollution/resource-intensive products, promote phasing out of obsolete capital, reduce trade frictions, etc. It may be questioned a priori whether a single policy instrument can bear the weight of being addressed to so many objectives simultaneously. Our results imply that the effectiveness of variable VAT rebate 6 See Circular [2004] No. 14 “The Act of Foreign Trade Business Registration”. Before July 1, 2004, there are restrictions on establishing an intermediary trading firm by a production firm. After that date, China opened the export and import rights to both production firms and pure trading firms. Under this rule, production firms can establish the intermediary firm legally. 4 rates as a policy instrument can be undermined by widespread evasion of the VAT on the part of exporting firms. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. We review the literature in Section 2. In Section 3, we introduce the policy background of China’s export tax rebate and the tax evasion mechanism. Section 4 discusses the empirical strategy and data. Section 5 presents the empirical results. Robustness checks are provided in Section 6. And Section 7 concludes. 2. Literature review Our paper is related to the recent literature on tax evasion in international trade and trade intermediation. Tax evasion has been studied extensively in the public finance literature.7 The review of the literature in the current paper focuses on tax evasion in international trade. One thread of the existing papers in this area follows the approach suggested by Fisman and Wei (2004), identifying evasion behaviors based on a correlation between tax or tariff rate and trade data reporting discrepancy (see also Javorcik and Narciso, 2008; Mishra, Subramanian, and Topalova, 2008; and Ferrantino, Liu, and Wang, 2008, among others). Another thread of related papers studies the transfer pricing behaviors of multinational firms and how countries’ tax rates affect firms’ intra -firm trade prices and trade flows (see, e.g., Swenson, 2001; Clausing, 2003 and 2006; Bernard, Jensen, and Schott, 2006). The current paper, however, proposes a completely different approach to identify another evasion behavior, based on a correlation between unrefunded export VAT and the tax benefit to indirect exports compared to direct exports. To the best of our knowledge, the only existing paper investigating explicitly the role of trade intermediation in tax evasion is Fisman, Moustakerski and Wei (2008), who find evidence that Hong Kong SAR, China, intermediaries that re-export Chinese products help to facilitate tariff evasion, and the incentive to evade tariffs increases with tariff rates. In their paper, the middlemen are trade intermediaries in Hong Kong SAR, China, helping foreign exporters to evade Chinese tariffs. Different from their paper, we study how intermediary trading companies may help domestic production firms to evade value added taxes. We add new evidence to the 7 See, e.g., Slemrod and Yitzhaki (2000) for a review of the literature on income tax evasion. 5 growing empirical literature on tax evasion in international trade. The practice of using middlemen for purposes of tax avoidance (legal) or tax evasion (illegal) and underreporting trade values appears to exist throughout the world. Thus, we believe that our findings are of more general relevance as well. Much of the literature on trade intermediation focuses on the legitimate roles of intermediaries or middlemen in trade, such as guaranteeing product quality, matching sellers with buyers, liquidity provision, and contract enforcement. As Spulber (1996) puts it, “Intermediaries, by setting prices, purchasing and sales decisions, managing inventories, supplying information and coordinating transactions, provide the underlying microstructure of most markets.” More recently, Feenstra and Hanson (2004) show that intermediary firms mitigate adverse selection by acting as guarantees of quality. Rauch and Watson (2004) model the emergence of trade intermediaries as an outcome of search frictions and networks in international trade. Bernard et al. (2010) find a greater penetration of U.S. intermediate exports into smaller markets and a larger dominance of wholesalers in agriculture-related trade. Antras and Costinot (2011) study the welfare impact of trade liberalization in the form of a reduction in search frictions with the help of intermediaries. Felbermayr and Jung (2011) examine the effects of hold-up in trade intermediation in destination countries, emphasizing the relationship specificity of the products. In addition, several recent papers find a positive correlation between intermediated trade and various proxies for fixed trade costs (see, e.g., Bernard, Grazzi, and Tomasi, 2011; and Akerman, 2013). Unlike previous papers, we investigate the tax evasion incentive behind trade intermediation in China’s exports. Our paper is closely related to Ahn, Khandelwal, and Wei (2011) and Tang and Zhang (2012), both of which also study trade intermediation in China’s exports, but have very different focuses from ours. Ahn, Khandelwal, and Wei (2011) build a model in which firms with different productivity levels endogenously select to export directly, indirectly, or do not export at all. In their model, the most productive firms export directly; the firms with intermediate levels of productivity export indirectly; and the rest of the firms do not export. They also provide empirical evidence that the intermediaries play a more important role in the markets that are more difficult to penetrate. Tang and Zhang (2012) study the roles of the intermediaries in quality differentiation and signaling. They test the story of quality verification by establishing a model with heterogeneity in productivity. 6 They distinguish horizontal differentiation, which is the elasticity of substitution of consumers’ preference, from vertical differentiation, which is the quality difference. Under the assumption that firms cannot write contracts ex ante to specify the division of surplus between producer and intermediary, the investment by intermediaries to investigate quality will be too low from the perspective of producers. Because such underinvestment is especially detrimental to high quality products, we should expect to see a negative correlation between indirect exporting and vertical differentiation. For more horizontally differentiated products (less substitutable), the quality concern is less important; so their model predicts a positive correlation between the prevalence of trade intermediation and cross product horizontal differentiation, which is consistent with Feenstra and Hanson (2004). Finally, our paper is also related to a growing literature on China’s export VAT rebates. Besides the several already mentioned papers on tax evasion, several other existing papers study the effect of China’s export tax rebates on exports, e.g., Chao, Chou, and Yu (2001), Chao, Yu, and Yu (2006), Chien, Mai, and Yu (2006), and Chandra and Long (2013), Gourdon, Monjon, and Poncet (2014). These papers find a positive relationship between rebate rates and exports, as what the policy was intended to do. Our paper is different from these papers as we study how VAT rebates affect the modes of exports (direct or indirect), instead of the level of exports. 3. Policy background and tax evasion mechanism 3.1. Export VAT rebate policies in China Our findings exploit a feature of the Chinese VAT system. The VAT rebate rates for exports in China vary across products and over time, unlike the case of a pure destination-based VAT (e.g. that of the European Union). Since this feature of the system, giving rise to a de facto variable export tax, is central to our results, some background on the institutional framework is warranted. Export tax rebates are a common practice in international trade. To avoid double taxation, tax authorities usually return to exporters the indirect taxes (e.g., VAT) firms have already paid in the production and distribution process. This practice is permitted under the GATT/WTO, as long as the tax rebate rates are no higher than the actual collection rates. For 7 a long time, China has applied different taxes to domestic sales and foreign trade: domestic sales are subject to VAT; exports are VAT-free (i.e., no VAT on the value added at the final stage before exporting) and are usually eligible for rebates of previously paid input VAT; imports sometimes are exempt from duties. As documented by Cui (2003), China implemented the export tax rebate policy in 1985 and established the “full refund” principle in 1988. After a major tax reform in 1994, the old industrial and commercial standard tax (gong shang tong yi shui) was replaced with a new VAT system. In principle, the VAT paid on previous paid inputs of exported products is supposed to be fully rebated. At first, tax rebates increased dramatically with the surge in exports, but only for a brief time. Because VAT refunds had been treated as a budgeted expenditure rather than as entitlements, the central government, facing a budget shortfall, was forced to reduce the rebate rates twice in 1995 and 1996.8 To counter the negative impact of the 1997 Asian financial crisis and to promote exports, China increased the export tax rebates for various products nine times from 1998 to 1999. In recent years, China has adjusted the rebate rates frequently, especially since 2004.9 Variations in the rebate have been employed for multiple policy objectives; for example as an industrial policy (e.g. to encourage high-tech sectors or discourage polluting sectors) or to manage trade frictions (address foreign calls for appreciation of the yuan 10 or frequent anti-dumping investigations affecting Chinese exports). This use of the varying VAT rebate causes China’s VAT to depart fr om a pure destination-based system. It also gives rise to the variation in the tax rate we are able to exploit. Since 2002, the most common method of export tax rebate is called “Exemption, 8 The central government was responsible for all the VAT rebates during 2000-2003. In 2004, the central government set the amount of tax rebates in 2003 as the benchmark; within the benchmark, the central government is still responsible for all the rebates; beyond the benchmark, local governments share 25% of the rebate burden, which was adjusted to 7.5% in 2005. 9 See Circular [2003] No. 222: “Notice of Adjusting Export Tax Rebate Rates,” issued jointly by the Ministry of Finance and the State Administration of Taxation in October 2003. 10 See the following link for an interview with Chinese economist Lin, Yifu (former Chief Economist of the World Bank). http://english.people.com.cn/200310/05/eng20031005_125408.shtml. He said explicitly that abolishing or cutting tax rebates to Chinese exporters would help relieve the pressure for appreciation of Yuan. 8 Credit, and Refund (ECR)”.11 “Exemption” means that export sales are exempt from output VAT. “Credit” means that input VAT on raw materials and supplies used for production can be credited against the output VAT on domestic sales. “Refund” means that the excess amount of input VAT over the output VAT will be rebated until a threshold, usually export value times rebate rate, is met. For intermediary trading firms, the method is called “Exemption and Refund”: exemption means the same thing as in the case of ECR, and refund refers to the rebate of previously paid VAT on domestic purchases. The rebate policies also differ across customs regimes.12 China has two major types of customs regimes: normal trade and processing trade. Normal trade refers to imports intended for domestic markets and exports using mainly local inputs. Processing trade refers to the business activity of importing all or part of the inputs from abroad duty-free, and then exporting the finished products after processing or assembly. It includes processing with supplied materials and processing with imported materials.13 Firms under normal trade regime need to pay VAT on inputs purchased in China or imported abroad, and are qualified for rebates when exporting their final products. Processing firms can import inputs duty-free; they will not get tax rebate on imported inputs since they do not pay the taxes in the first place. For the inputs purchased domestically within China, the rebate policies are different for different types of processing firms. Similar to exporters under the normal trade regime, processing firms with imported materials, after completing their export process in China, can obtain at least partial rebates according to the ECR method. By contrast, the “no collection and no refund” VAT policy applies to processing trade with supplied materials; this means that no output VAT is collected and they are not qualified for input VAT rebates 11 For a more detailed description of this method, see Circular [2002] No . 7: “Notice of Further Implementing the ‘Exemption, Credit and Refund’ System of Export Tax Rebates ,” issued jointly by the Ministry of Finance and the State Administration of Taxation in October 2002. 12 See Circular [1994] No. 31: “Notice of Printing and Distributing the Methods of Tax Refund (Exemption) for Exported Goods,” issued by the State Administration of Taxation in 1994. It is still in force according to the official Chinese central government website: http://www.gov.cn/gongbao/content/2011/content_1825138.htm 13 The major difference between them is that local firms in processing with supplied materials are pure processors without obtaining the ownership of the supplied materials or final goods. In comparison, local firms in processing with imported materials obtain the ownership of the imported materials and are responsible for exporting the finished goods. 9 either.14 This implies that export VAT evasion is less relevant to processing firms with supplied materials. For this reason, we leave out this type of processing trade and many other minor types of regimes out of our data used for the subsequent empirical analysis, and keep only normal trade regime and processing trade with imported materials, to which the ECR rebate method applies. 3.2. Tax evasion through indirect exports and main hypotheses Because we do not observe the domestic purchasing price when a trading firm buys products from a producer in the customs data, we cannot test our hypothesis based on the price differential. Instead, we identify the evasion behaviors by examining the correlation between export tax rates and the probability of indirect exports. In the following, we explain the benefits and costs of this type of evasion and propose the testable hypotheses. We assume that a production firm A can directly export a certain amount of goods at an FOB value of X; t is the VAT rate; and r is the VAT tax rebate rate. Under the ECR method, the total amount of tax burden firm A bears for this transaction is X(t − r).15 Instead of exporting directly, production firm A may sell the same shipment to firm B, an intermediary trading firm, at the value of Y (VAT included). The amount of VAT firm B pays to A should be t ∗ Y/(1 + t), which is included in B’s purchasing value of Y. We denote ̂ = Y/(1 + t). The trading firm B does not pay the net of VAT domestic purchasing price as X VAT when exporting, and can get a VAT rebate calculated as ̂ X × r.16 Therefore, the total amount of export tax burden on this transaction is ̂ X × (t − r). ̂. In the case of indirect exporting of the To evade taxes, firms may underreport X or X 14 Another VAT method in China is “Refund After Collection”: collect the VAT first on exports and refund later. This method, rarely used after 2002, is less relevant to our analysis which covers year 2005. 15 The exact formula for VAT liabilities is more complicated when a firm also sells in China, but here we consider only the part relevant to exports. See Ferrantino, Liu, and Wang (2008), and Liu (2013) for additional discussion on China’s export VAT rebate calculation. 16 ̂, rather than their exporting The rebates for trading firms are based on their purchasing price Y or X price. See Circular [1994] 31: “Notice on the Issuance of the Methods of Export Tax Refund (Exemption),” issued by the State Administration of Taxation in 1994; and Circular [2004] 64: “ Notice on the Issues of the Managing Export Tax Refund (Exemption), ” issued by the State Administration of Taxation in 2004. 10 products produced by firm A through a trading firm B, we also use X to denote the export value firm A would otherwise report under the hypothetical scenario of direct exporting, which can be different from trading firm B’s export FOB price Xi nd, where the subscript ind denotes indirect exporting. A direct exporter (production firm) may unde-report X for tax evasion purpose if it has a foreign partner to collude to recover later the losses due to export price underreporting.17 A trading firm, when underreporting its domestic purchasing price, may also underreport export value Xi to reduce the purchasing and selling price differential as discussed later. ̂ is generally more ̂ and X may be understated, we believe that X Although both X likely to be underreported than X for two reasons. First, it is arguably easier for firms to underreport ̂ X domestically than underreporting the export price X, for which firms need to find foreign partners to collude. Second, trading companies are usually larger and more familiar with foreign markets than production firms, so they are more likely to underreport export prices than direct exporters are, which in turns helps to explain why trading firms are also more likely to underreport their domestic purchasing price ̂ X without worrying too much about the purchasing and selling price differentials. In other words, firms are less likely to underreport export price X when exporting directly, but are more likely to ̂ (and export price Xind) when exporting underreport the domestic purchasing price X ̂ in general is expected to be smaller than X, the export value a firm indirectly. Hence, X would report when exporting directly.18 Taking the export tax burden in both cases together, we can write the joint tax benefit to firms A and B from indirect exporting as follows (compared to the hypothetical case of 17 As an illustrative example, the foreign partner (importer) may agree to remit a fraction of the true purchasing price directly to the exporter, causing an understatement for tax purposes, and place the rest in an offshore account for the benefit of the exporter. The balance in the offshore account can either be repatriated in a second, possibly concealed, transaction or used for such expenses as foreign education of the exporter’s children. Another example is transfer pricing, a tax evasion scheme to shift income from high tax locations to low tax locations through manipulating trading prices within a multinational firm. 18 For a trading firm, its export selling price can be larger than its domestic purchasing price for legitimate (e.g., markup, and/or compensation for packaging and labeling services, and/or the provision of quality guarantee) or illegitimate reasons (e.g., tax evasion). The latter is what we consider in this paper. 11 direct exporting by firm A). X(t − r) = (X − ̂ Benefit = X(t − r) − ̂ X)(t − r) (1) If X is larger than ̂ X for reasons discussed earlier, the benefit will be positive as long as t > r. When t = r, Benefit = 0. In other words, exporting through intermediary trading firm brings no benefit when export tax rate (t-r) is zero. This benefit is always non-negative ̂ = uX as a proportion of X, where 0 ≤ u ≤ 1 because r is no higher than t. If we express X measuring the ratio of the reported value to the true value (lower u means a larger degree of underreporting), we can rewrite Equation (1) as follows: Benefit = (1 − u)(t − r)X (2) Tax evasion not only can bring benefits to firms, but also can incur penalty when they get caught. The more taxes a firm evade, usually the heavier the penalty will be. The Criminal Law of China19 has a specific article on the crime of defrauding national export tax rebates and tax evasion (Article 204): “those evading a large amount of export VAT rebates through false-reporting exports or other fraudulent means will be subject to up to five years of imprisonment or criminal detention and a fine of one to five times of the defrauded tax amount; those defrauding a huge amount of tax or belonging to other serious circumstances will be subject to five to ten years of imprisonment and a fine of one to five times of the defrauded tax amount; those defrauding an especially huge amount of tax or belonging to other especially serious circumstances will be subject to at least ten years of term imprisonment or life imprisonment, and a fine of one to five times of the amount defrauded or confiscation of property.” In addition, the State Administration of Taxation issued a circular on some general rules of tax evaluation in March 2005.20 In January 2007, the State Administration of Taxation issued another circular specifically about the evaluation of tax rebates.21 There are five categories of indicators for the intermediary trading firms: export price, export growth rate, domestic flow of export products, customs office, and unclaimed tax rebate. Under the export price category, two of indicators the government considers are 19 The new criminal law of 1997, vis-à-vis the old law of 1979, was distributed on March 14, 1997, and came into force from October 1, 1999. So the new law applies to our sample year 2005. 20 See Circular [2005] No. 43, “The Notice on Issuance of the ‘The Administrative Measures of Tax Assessment (Trial)”, the State Administration of Taxation of China in 2005. 21 See Circular [2007] No. 4, “The Notice on Strengthening the Assessment of Export Tax Rebates (Exemption)”, the State Administration of Taxation of China. 12 purchasing price differential (PPD) and purchasing and selling price differential (PSD), among others. PPD = 100%*(Purchasing Price - Average Purchasing Price)/Average Purchasing Price PSD = 100%*(Export Price - Purchasing Price)/Purchasing Price Here the average price, used as a reference price level, means the average of all the prices within a particular industry. The larger are these price differentials or the extent of ̂ underreporting, the more likely a tax evading firm will be caught. The purchasing price is X as in Equation (2), while the export price and average purchasing price can be reasonably considered a proxy for X, the “true” value.22 The above laws and rules suggest that the ̂) or (1 − u)X. Therefore, we can write the net benefit of penalty is proportional to (X − X tax evasion through intermediaries as follows: ∆= (1 − u)(t − r)X − b(1 − u)X = (1 − u)(t − r − b)X (3) where b is a penalty parameter, which can vary with firm or product characteristics. 23 A couple of notes on b are in order here. First, some of the supervision rules actually came into force after 2005, the year covered by our analysis. This is not necessarily a problem because b captures not just the above-mentioned government supervision. Even before this particular policy came into force, other factors could still influence the cost (e.g., the above-mentioned Criminal Law) or at least the perceived cost of evasion. For example, if a firm consider it unsafe to underreport the price of homogenous goods such as wheat or rice, it will be less likely to do so even without an explicit supervision policy in place. Second, there are certainly other benefits or costs firms would consider when they decide to export directly or indirectly. For example, one important factor behind exporting directly is to save the fixed cost of direct exporting. Here, we choose to simplify away all of the other benefits or costs resulting from choosing direct or indirect export modes. This simplification is not a problem because the other benefits or costs are unlikely related to export tax. 22 The comparison between a firm’s price with the average industrial level price is a useful indicator. Alternatively, the differential between a trading firm’s own purchasing and selling prices may also be used, but it can be rendered ineffective if the firm underreports both of its purchasing and selling (export) prices. 23 b measures the expected level of punishment, determined by the probability of a firm being caught and the level of punishment once it gets caught. Because we cannot distinguish the two from each other in our empirical analysis, we simply take b as the expected level of punishment. 13 If we ignore all of other benefits or costs related to indirect exports, the probability of a firm choosing to export indirectly can be written as follows: Prob(indirect export) = Prob(∆> 0) = P[(t − r) > b] (4) In our empirical analysis, the probability of indirect export is captured by a continuous measure of the share of indirect exports in total exports for each product. For a given b, the larger (t − r) is, the stronger is the motive of exporting through trading firm. Hence, we have the following hypothesis: HYPOTHESIS 1 The probability of exporting indirectly should be higher in industries facing larger unrebated export VAT rates (i.e., t-r). Equation (3) also suggests that a production firm is more likely to choose to export indirectly when b (the degree of penalty) is lower. For example, the probability of evasion through indirect exporting would be higher when they are unlikely to be caught or unlikely to be heavily penalized (b is small). In addition, a marginal increase in (t-r) will be more likely to make a difference in determining firms’ choice of export modes when b is low. On the contrary, when b is high, the condition in Equation (4) will be less likely to hold and a small increase in (t-r) may not change firms’ choices of export modes. Hence we have another hypothesis as follows: HYPOTHESIS 2 The tax evasion motive through indirect exports should be higher when the firms are less likely to be penalized for such behaviors, ceteris paribus. We previously mentioned that the benefit in Equations (1) and (2) should be nonnegative. The same is true for the net benefit in Equation (3). If (t − r) > b, then the net benefit is positive and a production firm will choose to export indirectly to evade taxes. If (t − r) ≤ b, then the net benefit will be censored at zero (not negative) because the production firm will not export indirectly for tax evasion purpose. Therefore, we can just consider the case when (t − r) > b, and the production firm exports indirectly for tax evasion purpose. When the benefit is bounded below by zero, a larger transaction value (X) can only increase the benefit from the evasion through intermediaries. Moreover, if we also consider the fixed cost of evasion, a production firm will export indirectly only if the net tax 14 benefit (∆) as in Equation (3) exceeds the fixed cost, ceteris paribus. Because the net benefit increases with X, we have the following hypothesis, which can be tested using transaction level data rather than HS8 product level data. HYPOTHESIS 3 The tax evasion motive through indirect exports should be higher for larger transactions (larger X). 4. Empirical strategy and data 4.1. Empirical strategy We aim to examine empirically how export VAT taxes affect indirect exports. The dependent variable is the indirect export share, measured in both conservative and liberal versions as defined later in Section 4.2. For explanatory variables, we have the data on export VAT tax rates (t-r), the shares of exports by firm ownership types, and trade regimes (normal or processing trade). As control variables, we include prc_sh (share of exports under processing trade with imported materials), taking share of exports under normal trade as the omitted variable; we also include collpriv_sh (share of exports by collective and private firms) and for_sh (share of exports by foreign firms), with the share of exports by SOEs as the omitted variable. The share of processing trade can also help to control for the value-added content of a product as processing trade with imported materials is usually associated with lower share of domestic value added contents. For simplicity, all of the other minor types of trade regimes and ownership types are left out of our data. Because China applies the same VAT rebate rate on a product exported to all of the destination countries, we are able to test the tax evasion hypothesis using data at the product level without importing countries’ information. Our benchmark regressions will be carried out at the HS 8-digit product level (HS8) to test the first two hypotheses, using the following specification: indirect _ shi   0  1(t  r )i  Zγ  ei (5) where the subscript i denotes the Harmonized System (HS, version 2002) 8-digit product24; Z 24 The Harmonized System, as agreed by the World Customs Organization, is standardized at the 6-digit level (HS6). HS8 here refers to the local tariff-line implementation of the HS by China Customs, which differentiates products and duties at a finer level. 15 is a vector of control variables including trade regime and firm ownership type variables, measures of product differentiation, etc.; γ is the coefficient vector for Z; and ei is the error term. To test the second hypothesis, we examine how the tax evasion motive varies with product and firm characteristics. Similar to Javorcik and Narciso (2008) and Mishra, Subramanian, and Topalova (2008), we argue that evasion through price underreporting might be easier for differentiated products than homogenous products whose prices are often standard. Rauch (1999) defines homogeneous goods as products whose price is set on organized exchanges, defines reference priced goods as those not traded on organized exchanges but possessing a benchmark price, and defines the goods whose price is not set on organized exchanges and which lack a reference price because of their intrinsic features as differentiated products. We would expect to find stronger support for the evasion hypothesis from differentiated products, while weaker evidence from referenced and especially homogenous products. We will run regressions for different subsamples grouped based on the level of product differentiation or include interaction terms between export tax rate and the trade regime and firm ownership type variables.25 4.2. Customs trade data China’s shipment level trade data are released by the China Customs Office. The data are organized monthly based on the shipment documents that firms submit to the corresponding customs offices. In our paper, we use only the information of destination/source country, HS 8-digit product codes, firm IDs, firm names, trade regimes, ownership types, and the values of the shipments. As a commitment made under the WTO, 25 The different findings from homogenous and differentiated products can also help to invalidate alternative interpretations other than tax evasion. For instance, in a standard Melitz-type model, higher export tax rates would reduce profits from direct exporting, making indirect exporting relatively more profitable. In terms of Ahn, Khandelwal, and Wei (2011), this means that the cutoff productivity level for direct exporting increases, and thus indirect export share also increases. Although our empirical findings of a positive correlation between unrebated VAT rates and indirect exports share are also consistent with the productivity sorting mechanism, this mechanism cannot explain the stronger support from differentiated products. 16 the Chinese government fully opened export and import rights to all firms since mid-2004.26 Under the new system, all firms can export regardless of their sales, ownership types, and ages. For this reason, we use only 2005 data in our analysis, not the data before 2005. In the data, China Customs does not directly distinguish the production firms from the intermediary trading firms, but firms’ Chinese names include the words like “Jinchukou”, “Jingmao”, “Maoyi”, “Waimao”, “Kemao”, “Waijing”, and “Gong Mao”. Ahn, Khandelwal, and Wei (2011) classify all of them except “Gongmao” as trading firms, while Tang and Zhang (2012) include also “Gongmao”.27 Following them, we also use these keywords to identify trading firms and create two measures: a conservative measure as in Ahn, Khandelwal, and Wei (2011); and a liberal measure as in Tang and Zhang (2012). In 2005, the share of indirect exports among total exports in China is about 20% based on the conservative definition of indirect exports (21%, based on the liberal definition). Because the average size of shipments tends to be smaller for indirect exports than that for direct exports, the corresponding shares are larger in terms of the number of shipments: 37% and 38% based on the conservative and liberal measures of trading firms respectively. In sum, indirect exports constitute a large percentage of Chinese exports in 2005. There are 16 types of trade regimes in the trade data from China Customs, but we consider only normal trade and processing trade with imported materials.28 We leave out the processing trade with supplied materials for reasons discussed in Section 3.1 and all of the other 13 trade regimes when calculating the shares by trade regimes. 29 This is acceptable because the export values under most of the other regimes are very small, and 26 See Circular [2003] 1019 , “Forwarding the Notice of Adjusting the Export and Import Eligibility Criteria and Approval Procedures by Ministry of Finance” issued by the State Adm inistration of Taxation of China in 2003. The registration method started from July 1, 2004. 27 Gongmao firms, also involved in the design and production of their products, are not pure intermediary trading companies. 28 The other 16 trade regimes are: entrepôt trade by bonded areas, international aid, donation by overseas Chinese, compensation trade, goods on consignment, border trade, equipment for processing trade, goods for foreign contracted project, goods on lease, equipment investment by foreign-invested enterprise, outward processing, barter trade, duty-free commodity, warehousing trade, equipment imported into EPZs, and others. 29 The results are very similar when only normal and processing exports are used for the dependent variables. 17 we have limited information on the policies applied to these trade regimes. Eventually, we only have two types of trade regimes in the product-level analysis: normal trade and processing trade with imported materials whose shares sum to one for each HS 8-digit product. In total, there are seven firm types in the 2005 data, including three types of domestic firms (state-owned enterprises, collective firms, and private firms), three types of foreign firms (equity joint ventures, contractual joint ventures, and wholly foreign-owned enterprises) and a category for all of the other types. To simplify the analysis, we combine collective with private firms, and combine the three foreign firm types together, but leave out all the other types when calculating the shares of exports by SOEs, collective and private firms, and foreign firms (soe_sh, collpriv_sh, and for_share). The three shares sum to one. Appendix 1 provides a cross-tabulation of China’s exports in 2005 by trade regimes and ownership types for indirect, direct, and total exports respectively. Panel I shows that Chinese indirect exports are dominated by normal exporters, whose share accounts for 93% of the total indirect exports in 2005. In terms of the firm ownership, indirect exporters are almost completely domestic firms (61% for SOEs and 39% for collective and private firms), with foreign firms accounting for a negligible share (0.26%). By comparison, Panel II shows that the direct exports are dominated by foreign firms and processing trade. These facts help to explain the empirical results reported later. For total exports, Panel III suggests that normal trade and processing trade are overall equally important, and foreign firms play a larger role than domestic firms in China’s 2005 exports. The trade regimes of exports are strictly supervised by the Customs, and do not change regardless of the export modes (direct or indirect exports). However, the ownership of an intermediary trading company can be different from the ownerships of the producers of the exported products, so the shares by ownership types of indirect exports may not reflect correctly the production structure of exported products in their production process. Keeping this mind, we should be cautious when using the ownership variables and interpreting the results. With no access to better measures, we believe that they can still provide useful information and choose to include these ownership variables in our empirical analysis.30 30 It is tempting to calculate ownership shares based only on direct exports. Implicitly, this method 18 4.3. VAT rebate rate and other data The VAT rebate rates data are from the State Administration of Taxation. The data are available at the tariff-line level. There are many rate changes in the middle of a year. If a product has multiple rates in 2005, we use their average rates weighted by the number of days during which each rate applies. The more detailed information at levels higher than HS 8-digit is averaged first to the HS 8-digit level. The major VAT rebate rates (r) in 2005 are 0% (3.87%), 5% (9%), 13% (72.3%), and 17% (7%), with the shares of the HS 8-digit product lines under each rebate rate in parentheses. The corresponding figures for statutory VAT collection rates (t) for normal tax payers are 13% (13.3%) and 17% (84.3%). The major rates for the tax net of rebate (t-r) are 0% (7.5%), 4% (70.5), 8% (11.1%), and 17% (3.4%). In line with the WTO rules, the VAT rebate rates are always no higher than the collection rates. The data used in our country-product level and transaction level analysis will be described in Sections 5.2 and 5.3 respectively. Other variables used in the robustness checks will be discussed in Section 6. Appendix 2 lists some descriptive statistics of the variables used in the paper. 5. Empirical results 5.1. A product level analysis Table 1 reports the baseline regression results at the HS8 level, using the conservative measure of indirect export share as the dependent variable. Because our key variable of interest, (t-r), is at HS 8-digit level and we have the data only for year 2005, we cannot include HS8 product fixed effects. Nevertheless, we always include HS 4-digit level fixed effects to control for any unobserved heterogeneity at HS4 level (about 1300 products).31 In assumes that the ownership structure of the products exported indirectly is the same as that of directly exported products. If this assumption is correct, then the ownership shares should not affect the indirect export shares and hence should not be included in the regressions in the first place. If the production structures are different for directly and indirectly exported products, then using the ownership based only on direct exporters will also be problematic. This is why we continue to calculate ownership shares based on total exports. Dropping these ownership variables from our regressions does not affect our main findings at all. 31 We do not use HS6 fixed effects because only about 8% of the HS6 products lines have more than two HS8 lines. Including HS6 fixed effects would be too demanding because they would absorb most of the variations in (t-r). 19 most tables (except Table 4 on transaction level analysis), the dependent variable is the share of indirect exports, ranging from 0 to 100; (t-r) is also measured in percentage point, ranging from 0 to 17. But the export shares by trade regime and firm ownership type are measured in percent, between 0 and 1. The omitted trade regime is normal trade. The omitted firm type is SOE. The first regression uses the full sample, while the next three regressions use the subsamples of homogenous, referenced, and differentiated products respectively according to the Rauch’s product classification.32 In the last column, we combine homogenous with referenced products, and call them together non-differentiated products. The estimated coefficient of (t-r) is positive and significant at the 5% level in the regressions using the full sample, supporting our Hypothesis 1. For regressions based on subsamples, the coefficient of (t-r) is positive and significant only for differentiated products, but insignificant for homogenous and referenced products. In addition, the estimated coefficient is much larger for differentiated products in absolute value (-1.481). The result that (t-r) is positive and significant only for differentiated products but not for other products supports our second hypothesis. Finally, in the last column, we combine homogenous with referenced products to increase the number of observations and find that the coefficient of (t-r) is still highly insignificant, suggesting that the insignificant result in Columns (2) and (3) are not simply driven by smaller observations. Our estimates also imply that the impact of avoidance behavior is economically significant. The estimate reported in Column (4) implies that a one percentage increase in (t-r) would lead to about a 1.5 percentage increase in the indirect export share of differentiated products; when a differentiated product changes from zero export tax to a full 17% tax, its indirect export share would increase by 25.5%. We can also show the potential tax revenue loss from evasion through trade intermediation, as a back-of-envelope calculation. Using Equation (3) and assuming away the penalty of evasion (b) for now, the tax benefit to firms or revenue loss to government is (1-u)*(t-r)*X, where X refers to the expected value of indirect export value for tax evasion purpose. To estimate X, we first calculate the probability of indirect export for tax evasion purpose as the product of the 32 We concord the original liberal measure of Rauch’s classification at 4-digit SITC level to HS 6-digit level, and then to HS 8-digit level. 20 coefficient estimate for differentiated products (i.e., 1.5 percentage points increase for a percentage increase in export tax) and export tax rate, and then multiply this probability by the total export value (direct plus indirect export) for each differentiated product. Using Equation (3) and assuming u = 0, the estimated revenue loss for all of the differentiated products can be as large as 2.73 billion U.S. dollars in 2005. Even for a moderate level of underreporting (let’s say u = 2/3, implying that the true transaction value is underreported by 1/3), the revenue loss is close to one billion U.S. dollars, a sizable amount. This is also how much tax revenue the government can potentially obtain in the absence of such evasion. The results in Table 1 also suggest that processing firms, already teamed up with foreign partners, are significantly less likely to export indirectly compared to normal firms (the default category). Collective, private, and especially foreign firms are less likely to export indirectly as compared to state-owned firms (the omitted category). These results can also reflect partly the entry rules of the intermediary firms imposed by the government. It was much more difficult to establish a foreign or private trading firm than a SOE trading company for a long time. Even after the relaxation of the entry policy in 2004, the SOE share of intermediary trading firms remained much higher than that of the production firms for a while. In addition, foreign firms usually export directly because the fixed cost of direct exporting is low due to their close connections to foreign markets and they may be more capable of evading taxes through other means such as transfer pricing through intra-firm transactions. Considering that exporters belonging to different trade regimes and ownership types may have different levels of evasion incentive, we include in the regressions on Table 2 the interaction terms between (t-r) and the shares by trade regimes and firm ownership types. The regressions in Table 2 are analogous to those in Table 1, except that we include these interaction terms. These interaction terms are mostly negative but almost always insignificant at the 10% level. Although the results suggest that processing firms and non-SOE firms seem to be less likely to evade taxes through intermediaries than normal and SOE firms (the default category), the evidence is weak. Because these interaction terms are mostly insignificant, we do not include them in our baseline regressions. 5.2. A product-country level analysis: Domestic evasion and cross-border evasion 21 In this subsection, we instead examine whether domestic evasion and cross-border evasion are linked to each other. As discussed above, one of the criteria Chinese tax authorities adopt to detect evasion behavior is based on purchasing and selling price differential (PSD). As a result, trading companies that have purchased products from production firms at an underreported price (i.e., domestic evasion) will also have an incentive to underreport export prices (i.e., cross-border evasion), to avoid large PSD and minimize the chance of being caught. Following the approach proposed by Fisman and Wei (2004), we calculate the discrepancies between China’s reported exports to each importing country in logarithms and partner country reported imports from China in logarithms at HS 6-digit level for year 2005, using the trade data from the UN COMTRADE (i.e., GAP = log(partner reported imports from China) – log(China reported export). When export values are underreported at the Chinese border, GAP tends to be positive. If the evasion through underreporting domestic purchasing price of a trading company is associated with its cross-border evasion through underreporting export prices, we would expect to see stronger evidence of tax evasion through indirect exports for products whose values were underreported at the Chinese border (positive GAP). To test this hypothesis, we carry out a product-country level analysis. Many characteristics of the importing countries of Chinese products, such as geographic distance and destination market size can also affect firms’ choice of export modes. For example, geographic distance adds to the transportation costs of exporting, so firms tend to avoid exporting directly to countries far away; the probability of indirect exporting to a large foreign market is low because it is worthwhile to invest in the fixed costs of direct exporting when a destination market is large enough. Although these factors are interesting, they are not the focus of this paper and have already been studied by existing papers (e.g., Bernard et al., 2010; Ahn, Khandelwal, and Wei, 2011). Since country fixed effects will be used in our product-country level analysis, all of these country characteristics are absorbed by the fixed effects. In Table 3, we report the results from regressions at the HS8 product-country level. The dependent variable is the indirect export share calculated at the product-country level. The key explanatory variable is (t-r), which still varies only across products as before because the same rate applies to a product exported to all destination markets. The control 22 variables include the export shares by trade regimes and firm ownership types, calculated at the product-country level. The first regression is based on the subsample with positive GAP, while the second columns are for the subsample with negative or zero GAP. HS4 product and country fixed effects are always included. As expected, (t-r) has a positive and significant effect on indirect export share only for products with positive GAP that indicates a higher chance of export underreporting at Chinese border. This implies that the underreporting behaviors through domestic intermediaries may be associated with cross-border evasion through underreporting export values. The magnitude of the coefficient of (t-r) for the positive GAP subsample is very similar to that reported in Column (1) of Table 1 for the whole sample (0.667 vs. 0.673). The coefficients of other variables also have expected signs: non-SOEs (especially foreign firms) and processing firms are less likely to use intermediaries than SOEs and normal firms. 5.3. A transaction level analysis Our third hypothesis states that the evasion motive is stronger for larger transactions. To test it, we need to carry out a transaction level analysis. In Table 4, we report the results from regressions at the transaction level. Here the dependent variable is a dummy indicating whether the final exporter in a transaction is a production firm (0) or trading firm (1), based on the conservative classification. (t-r) is still measured at HS8 product level.33 log(value) is the logarithm of the value of an export transaction, where value is measured in current million U.S. dollars. Since a firm may exports multiple products at the tariff line level and each product may be exported through multiple transactions in a year, the number of observations at transaction level is extremely large, up to nearly 14 million in the regression. To avoid intensive computation, we adopt a linear probability model (LPM) rather than a logit or probit model. To prevent the variable (t-r) from being dropped, we include HS 4-digit fixed effects rather than HS 8-digit fixed effects. We also include country fixed effects to control for the unobserved heterogeneity at country level. In regression (1), we include only 33 Because the dependent variable is a dummy, which is on average much smaller than the indirect export share in percentage (ranging from 1 to 100), the coefficients can be much smaller than what we got from the product-level analysis. To avoid very small estimated coefficients of (t-r) and its interaction with log(value), we divide (t-r) by 100, so that it is now measured in percent, not in percentage as in our product-level analysis. 23 (t-r), log(value) and their interaction term as the explanatory variables. The coefficient of (t-r) is still positive as expected and is highly significant. The negative coefficient of log(value) suggests that firms involving in larger transactions are less likely to use intermediaries on average probably because the fixed costs of direct exporting becomes less important for large transactions. More importantly, the positive coefficient of (t-r)*log(value) implies that firms involved in larger transactions are more likely to evade taxes through indirect exports, all else equal. This lends strong support to Hypothesis 3. In regression (2), we also control for the trade regimes and ownership types of the transactions. At the transaction level, these variables are simply indicators rather than shares as in the product level analysis. In addition to the dummy for both types of processing firms together, we also add a dummy for all other trade regimes (oth_regime), taking normal trade as the default category. If we leave out the processing trade with supplied materials and all of the other regimes as what we did for the product level analysis, the results do not change much. In addition to the dummies for collective-private firms and foreign firms, we also include a dummy for all other ownership types (oth_owner), taking SOEs as the default category. The sign pattern of the first three variables is the same as that in regression (1), and all of three coefficients are highly significant. Same as what is shown by the previous product-level regression results, collective-private firms, foreign firms, processing firms are found to be less likely to export indirectly than SOEs and exporters under normal trade. 6. Robustness checks and other issues In this section, we perform a number of robustness checks and discuss several additional issues. First, we always use the conservative measure of indirect export share in our previous analysis. In Table 5(1), we check the robustness of our results to the alternative liberal measure. The first three regressions are based on the full sample, and subsamples for differentiated and non-differentiated (i.e., homogenous and referenced) products, respectively, without including any interaction terms. The next three regressions are analogous to the first three ones, with additional interaction terms between (t-r) and processing trade share and the shares by ownership types. The results are very similar to the corresponding regressions using the same specifications reported earlier, except that 24 the interactions between (t-r) with firm ownership shares (especially with the foreign share) are more significant. We find stronger evidence for the evasion by SOEs probably because SOEs are more familiar with the domestic policies and are better connected to government officials, and hence can do better than foreign firms to take advantage of the policy loopholes in China. The results from the previous country-product level and transaction level analyses are also robust to the alternative liberal definition of trading firms, but are not shown in tables to save space. This is to be expected given the small difference between the conservative and liberal definitions of trading firms as reported in Section 4.2. Second, we consider some additional variables that may also explain the variations in indirect export share. As discussed in the literature, trading firms can play a role in verifying product quality for buyers. Therefore, different product quality heterogeneity across industries can affect the choice of exporting modes. Following Tang and Zhang (2012), we examine both the horizontal differentiation and vertical differentiation, together with the tax evasion motivation. For the horizontal differentiation, we use the elasticity of substitution estimated by Broda and Weinstein (2006). For vertical differentiation, we use R&D and advertising intensity of each industry constructed from the NBS industrial census data as in Tang and Zhang (2012).34 In Table 5(2), we add the two variables to regressions based on the full sample, and subsamples for differentiated and non-differentiated products respectively. Although the number of observations is greatly reduced owing to missing data in the two additional variables, our main finding remains robust: (t-r) is positive and significant not only for differentiated products but also in the full sample, but not significant for non-differentiated products. The coefficient of the measure of elasticity of substitution (sigma) is never statistically significant at the 10% level. Advertising and R&D intensity, when significant at the 10% level, has a negative effect on indirect export share. This is consistent with the argument in Tang and Zhang (2012). We do not include these variables in our baseline regressions to avoid dropping a large number of observations due to missing data. Third, we examine some alternative stories which can also be consistent with our results. China has used the rebate rates frequently as an industrial policy to promote the 34 This census covers all of the SOEs and all of the other types of firms with sales above 5 million RMB. First, we calculate the ratio of advertising and R&D expenditure to sales for each firm (Ad-R&D-Sales). Then, we take the average of this ratio for each Chinese Industry Code (CIC). Finally, we concord CIC to ISIC Revision 3 and then to HS6 and HS8. 25 exports of high-tech and deep processed products and discourage the exports of pollution and resource intensive products and primary products. To curb the exports of resource-intensive products such as rare earths, for example, China reduced their rebate rates in 2004, leading to higher unrefunded export VAT rates (t-r) for these products. Because these resource-based products are also more likely to be state-owned than other products and SOEs are more likely to export indirectly as shown previously, this may also lead to a positive correlation between indirect export share and (t-r). Based on the classification for primary products and resource-based products as in Lall (2000), we find that the average unrefund rates for primary products and resource-based products in our sample are indeed higher than that of other products (7.06% and 5.84% vs. 4%), and the average indirect export shares of primary and resource-based products are also higher than that of other products (35% and 33% vs. 31%).35 On the contrary, high-tech products have been encouraged by the Chinese government and received relatively higher rebate rates (in other words, lower (t-r)). If high-tech products which are usually associated with higher quality are less likely to be exported indirectly according to Tang and Zhang (2012), this can also lead to a positive correlation between (t-r) and the share of indirect exports. Based on China’s official classification of advanced technology products as published on the 2005 China Statistical Yearbook on Science and Technology 36 , we find that the average unrefund rate for advanced-technology products in our sample is higher than that of other products (5.84% vs. 4.45%), but the average indirect export share of advanced-technology products is only slightly higher than that of other products (32.5% vs. 31.6%). Although including HS4 product fixed effects can help to alleviate the above concerns, we also take them as problems of omitted variable bias by checking the robustness of our 35 These data are based on the sample used in the first regression in Table 1. The three groups of products (Primary Products, Resource-based Products, and others) are mutually exclusive, accounting for 840, 1317 and 4,852 observations respectively. 36 The original primary product and resource-based product data in Lall (2000) are in SITC 3-digit level. We concord them to HS 6-digit. The original ATP data are at 4-digit Chinese Industrial Classification (CIC). We first concord CIC to 4-digit ISIC, and then to HS 6-digit. Although we have access to other classifications of high-tech products such as those in Lall (2000) and Ferrantino et al. (2007), we choose to use China’s own official definition because that is what the rebate rates are actually based on. 26 previous main finding after including dummies for primary products (Primary), resource-based products (Resource), and advanced-technology products (Advanced-tech). The results are reported in the first three regressions of Table 5(3), where with the three additional dummies in addition to the product differentiation measures (Ad-R&D-Sales and sigma). Similar to what we found earlier, the key covariate (t-r) remains positive and significant in the regressions based on the full sample and the subsample for differentiated goods, but insignificant for non-differentiated goods, with little change in the magnitude of the estimated coefficients compared to the previous result table. The coefficients of these newly added dummies suggest that primary and high-tech products are more likely to be exported through trading firms, but they are not always significant and sometimes bear mixed signs for the two subsamples. We conclude that omitting them from our baseline regressions does not significantly bias our estimated coefficients. For similar reasons as stated above, some products are subject to zero or full rebates when the government intended to promote or discourage the exports in certain sectors. To make sure that our results are not driven by various other unobserved policies besides the VAT rebates, we also add to our regressions in the last three columns of Table 5(3) a dummy indicating if a product is subject to zero or full rebate rate. This variable, however, turns out to be insignificant. Although this variable is likely correlated with rebate rates, it may not vary with indirect export share in a significant way. The estimated coefficients of other variables change little, suggesting that our results are not driven by these factors. In addition, besides the use of the export rebate rate as an industrial policy, other factors may also affect the rebate rates. For example, as described in Section 3.1, China started with a full rebate system but changed it to a partial rebate system due to budget constraint. Ignoring the budget issue is not a problem for us unless it is also correlated with indirect export share. Although budget shortfall might motivate the government to tackle tax evasion problems, there is no evidence showing that the evasion through indirect exports in particular has already been in the radar of the government when it adjusts rebate rates. Moreover, rebate rates may also be adjusted in response to the level or the growth rate of exports in an industry. However, this is not a problem either as long as the level or the growth rate of exports is not correlated with indirect export share. All of these concerns, together with those considered in Table 5(3), are related to the endogeneity of VAT rebate rates. In our opinion, however, the endogeneity issues do not seem to be a major concern. 27 Fourth, we have so far split the full sample into differentiated and non-differentiated products. Alternatively, we can also create a dummy variable indicating if a product belongs to differentiated product and then interact it with export tax rate. The benefit of doing this is that we can retain all the products in the regressions to increase the sample size. The result is reported in the first column of Table 5(4). The result shows that (t-r) has a significant and positive effect on indirect export share only for differentiated product, which is the same as what we found earlier. For non-differentiated products, the effect is insignificant, as shown by the coefficient of (t-r). An F-test, reported at the bottom of the table, shows that the sum of the first and the third coefficients are significantly different from zero at the 1% level. Moreover, alternative to Rauch’s nomenclature, we could also use an interaction term between export tax and some proxies defined using continuous indicators to account for product differentiation. The results in Tables 5(2) and 5(3) show that products with high advertising and R&D intensity (Ad-R&D-Sales) is significantly associated with lower trade intermediation. In the second column of Table 5(4), we include the interaction between Ad-R&D-Sales and export tax rate as an additional regressor. As expected, the interaction term is estimated to have a significant and positive effect on indirect export share. This is consistent with our previous finding based on Racuh’s classification, even th ough the correlation between “Diff” dummy defined according to Rauch (1999) and Ad-R&D-Sales is quite weak with a simple correlation coefficient at 0.2. The result suggests that our results are robust to alternative measures of product differentiation. Fifth, as mentioned earlier, export VAT rebate does not apply to processing trade with supplied materials, and this is why we exclude this type of trade from our previous analysis.37 To assure that our result is indeed driven by tax evasion rather than some other mechanisms, we run similar regressions using only exports under processing trade with supplied materials as a falsification exercise. The results are reported in Table 5(5). As only one type of trade regime is kept, the export share variables by trade regime are dropped from the regressions. The export tax variable is significant for neither non-differentiated products nor differentiated products, as we expect. This is consistent with the fact that 37 This fact is also used by Gourdon, Monjon, and Poncet (2014) to identify the effect of VAT rebate on exports. 28 processing trade with supplied materials is not qualified for export VAT rebates and provides further assurance for our tax evasion story.38 Finally, as discussed earlier, it should be easier for a production firm to find a domestic trading firm to evade taxes through underreporting domestic selling prices than to find a foreign partner to collude through underreporting export prices. If this is true, then indirect exports will be more likely to be underreported than direct exports when (t-r) is high. As a result, the indirect export share (our dependent variable) will be lower than its true value when (t-r) is high. It can only lead to a negative correlation between indirect export share and (t-r). Given that we have already found a positive and significant correlation between them, the true coefficient should be even more positive and significant. 7. Concluding remarks We have identified a significant role for domestic middlemen in facilitating tax evasion in Chinese export trade. This supplements the classic roles of middlemen in helping to overcome imperfect information about markets, connecting buyers and sellers, and certifying product quality, etc. We have identified systematic differences in the effectiveness of this evasion strategy for different types of trade, and traders. The use of middlemen is more likely to be associated with tax evasion for differentiated products, which are more difficult for the authorities to assign benchmark prices to for enforcement purposes. This is consistent with other research on tax and tariff evasion in trade, such as the literature on transfer pricing. The association of middlemen with tax evasion is also stronger for state-owned enterprises than for either foreign enterprises or other Chinese domestic enterprises, suggesting that SOEs may have an institutional or political-economy advantage when it comes to tax evasion. One open research question relates to the relationship between ownership type and tax evasion. The organizational type of the producer may easily be different than the organizational type of the middleman. The official data record the ownership type of the exporter of record, and as we have shown, the largest share of Chinese export middlemen are SOEs. However, for China as for other countries, it is not easy to determine the 38 Because export VAT rebate does not apply to export processing zones (EPZs), this can be used to perform another possible falsification exercise. Unfortunately, we do not have the access to the information on EPZs in the customs data. 29 ownership type of the producers of goods in all cases. An SOE middleman may be handling the goods of SOEs, domestic private enterprises, collective enterprises, or even foreign enterprises. The same goes for other domestic middlemen. This problem is endemic to any analysis involving export middlemen in which it is desired to identify a firm attribute. For example, exports of small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) may be handled by large-firm export wholesalers and vice versa (USITC 2010, Chapter 5). It is entirely possible that the organizational type of the producer exerts a separate, or complementary, effect on both the use of middlemen and the incentives for tax evasion. Thus, for example, if the production of steel in China is dominated by SOEs, the relationship between the SOE status of the producers and the use of middlemen or the likelihood of tax evasion is likely more complex than that explored in this paper. Analysis of this problem would require matched firm-level data on the attributes of producers and the wholesalers they use. References Ahn, JaeBin, Amit K. Khandelwal, and Shang-Jin Wei, 2011. “The role of intermediaries in facilitating trade.” Journal of International Economics 84: 73-85. Akerman, Anders, 2013. "A Theory on the Role of Wholesalers in International Trade Based on Economies of Scope." Working paper. Antras, Pol, and Arnaud Costinot, 2011. “Intermediated Trade.” Quarterly Journal of Economics,126: 1319-74. Bernard, Andrew B., Bradford J. Jensen, Stephen J. Redding, and Peter K. Schott, 2010. "Wholesalers and Retailers in U.S. Trade", American Economic Review 100(2), 408-413. Bernard, Andrew B., Marco Grazzi, and Chiara Tomasi, 2011. “Intermediaries in International Trade: Direct versus Indirect Modes of Export.” NBER Working Paper No. 17711. Bernard, Andrew B., Bradford J. Jensen, and Peter K. Schott, 2006. “Transfer Pricing by U.S.-Based Multinational Firms.” NBER Working Papers No. 12493. Broda, Christian, and David E.Weinstein, 2006. “Globalization and the gains from variety.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 121, 541-585. Chandra, Piyush, and Cheryl Long, 2013. “VAT Rebates and Export Growth in China: Firm Level Evidence”, Journal of Public Economics 102, 13–22. 30 Chao, Chi-Chur, Win-Lin Chou, and Eden S.H. Yu, 2001. “Export Duty Rebates and Export Performance: Theory and China's Experience.” Journal of Comparative Economics 29(2): 314-26. Chao, Chi-Chur, Eden S.H. Yu, and Wusheng Yu, 2006. “China's Import Duty Drawback and VAT Rebate Policies: A General Equilibrium Analysis.” China Economic Review 17(4): 432-48. Chen, Chien-Hsun, Chao-Cheng Mai, and Hui-Chuan Yu. 2006. “The Effect of Export Tax Rebates on Export Performance: Theory and Evidence from China.” China Economic Review 17(2): 226-35. Clausing, Kimberly A., 2003. “Tax-motivated Transfer Pricing and US Intrafirm Trade Prices.” Journal of Public Economics 87(9-10): 2207-23. Clausing, Kimberly A., 2006. “International Tax Avoidance and U.S. International Trade.” National Tax Journal 59(2): 269-87. Cui, Zhiyuan, 2003. “China’s Export Tax Rebate Policy.” China: An International Journal 1(2): 339-49. Feenstra, Robert, and Gordon Hanson, 2004, “Intermediaries in Entrepôt Trade: Hong Kong Reexports of Chinese Goods,” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 13(1): 3–35. Felbermayr, Gabriel J., and Benjamin Jung (2011). "Trade Intermediaries, Incomplete Contracts, and the Choice of Export Modes". Review of International Economics 19: 634-48. Feldstein, Martin, and Paul Krugman, 1990. “International trade effects of value-added tax.” In: Razin, A., Slemrod, J. (Eds.), Taxation in the Global Economy. University of Chicago Press, pp. 263–282. Ferrantino, Michael, Robert Koopman, Zhi Wang, and Falan Yinug, Ling Chen, Fengjie Qu, and Haifeng Wang, 2007. “Classification and Statistical Reconciliation of Trade in Advanced Technology Products: The Case of China and the United States,” Bookings-Tsinghua Center for Public Policy Working Paper Series – WP20070906EN. Ferrantino, Michael, Xuepeng Liu, and Zhi Wang, 2012. “Evasion Behaviors of Exporters and Importers: Evidence from the U.S.-China Trade Data Discrepancy.” Journal of International Economics 867(1): 146-57. Fisman, Raymond, Peter Moustakerski, and Shang-Jin Wei, 2008. “Outsourcing Tariff Evasion: A New Explanation for Entrepôt Trade.” Review of Economics & Statistics 90(3): 587-92. Fisman, Raymond, and Shang-Jin Wei, 2004. “Tax Rates and Tax Evasion: Evidence from ‘Missing Imports’ in China.” Journal of Political Economy 112(2): 471-96. Gourdon, Julien, Stéphanie Monjon, and Sandra Poncet, 2014. “Incomplete VAT rebates to exporters : how do they affect China's export performance?” Working Paper. 31 Javorcik, Beata S., and Gaia Narciso, 2008. “Differentiated Products and Evasion of Import Tariffs.” Journal of International Economics 76(2): 208-22. Khandelwal, Amit K., 2010. The long and short (of) quality ladders. Review of Economic Studies 77: 1450-76. Lall, Sanjaya, 2000. “The Technological Structure and Performance of Developing Country Manufactured Exports, 1985-1998”, QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS44. Liu, Xuepeng, 2013. “Tax Avoidance through Re-imports: The Case of Redundant Trade.” Journal of Development Economics 104: 152-64. Mishra, Prachi, Arvind Subramanian, and Petia Topalova, 2008. “Policies, Enforcement, and Customs Evasion: Evidence from India.” Journal of Public Economics 92(10-11): 1907-25. Rauch, James E., 1999. “Networks versus markets in international trade.” Journal of International Economics 48, 7-35. Rauch, James E., and Joel Watson, 2004. "Network Intermediaries in International Trade", Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 13: 69-93. Rossman, Marlene, 1984. "Export Trading Company Legislation: U.S. Response to Japanese Foreign Market Penetration", Journal of Small Business Management, 22: 62-66. Slemrod, Joel, and Shlomo Yitzhaki, 2000, “Tax Avoidance, Evasion, and Administration,” Handbook of Public Economics No. 3, pp 1423-1470. Spulber, Daniel F., 1996. “Market Microstructure and Intermediation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Volume 10, pp. 135-52. Swenson, Deborah L., 2001. “Tax Reforms and Evidence of Transfer Pricing.” National Tax Journal 54(1): 7-25. Tang, Heiwai, and Zhang, Yifan, 2012. “Quality Differentiation and Trade Intermediation.” Working Paper. U.S. International Trade Commission, 2010. Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises: Characteristics and Performance. USITC Publication 4189, November. 32 Table 1: Baseline product level regressions (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Full Homogenous Referenced Differentiated Non-differentiated (t-r) 0.667** -0.090 0.565 1.481*** 0.335 (0.297) (0.770) (0.556) (0.498) (0.472) prc_sh -9.405*** -19.994*** -10.645*** -7.611*** -12.242*** (1.399) (5.515) (2.743) (1.857) (2.405) collpriv_sh -17.978** -14.072* -14.931*** -21.337*** -14.751*** * (2.254) (7.954) (3.947) (3.140) (3.499) for_sh -50.835** -47.018*** -49.217*** -52.549*** -48.783*** * (1.758) (7.234) (3.192) (2.388) (2.910) HS4 fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 7,009 522 2,011 4,176 2,533 R-squared 0.546 0.708 0.473 0.563 0.537 Notes: The regressions are at HS8 level. The dependent variable is the share of indirect exports (conservative measure), ranging from 0 to 100. The export shares by trade regime and firm ownership type variables range from 0 to 1. The omitted trade regime is normal trade. The omitted firm ownership type is SOE. The last column is for non-differentiated products, including both homogenous and referenced products. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. 33 Table 2: Product level regression, with interaction terms (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Full Homogenous Referenced Differentiated Non-differentiated (t-r) 1.055** -0.439 1.307* 2.500*** 0.861 (0.474) (1.561) (0.747) (0.837) (0.671) prc_sh -8.580*** -17.318* -6.836 -10.758*** -8.612** (2.396) (9.931) (4.647) (3.869) (4.175) collpriv_sh -15.957*** -19.535 -7.973 -15.913*** -10.044 (3.801) (14.396) (6.797) (5.827) (6.144) for_sh -48.065*** -49.712*** -44.589*** -45.818*** -45.800*** (2.919) (13.241) (5.533) (4.280) (5.159) (t-r)*prc -0.210 -0.393 -0.668 0.880 -0.617 (0.404) (1.156) (0.610) (0.937) (0.545) (t-r)*collpriv -0.436 0.822 -1.204 -1.469 -0.799 (0.609) (2.016) (0.861) (1.256) (0.799) (t-r)*for -0.600 0.340 -0.870 -1.861* -0.543 (0.494) (1.613) (0.742) (1.016) (0.687) HS4 fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 7,009 522 2,011 4,176 2,533 R-squared 0.546 0.708 0.474 0.564 0.538 Notes: The regressions are at HS8 level. The dependent variable is the share of indirect exports (conservative measure), ranging from 0 to 100. The export shares by trade regime and firm ownership type variables range from 0 to 1. The omitted trade regime is normal trade. The omitted firm ownership type is SOE. The last column is for non-differentiated products, including both homogenous and referenced products. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. 34 Table 3: Product-country level analysis, positive and negative GAP subsamples (1) (2) GAP>0 GAP<0 (t-r) 0.673** 0.195 (0.265) (0.319) prc_sh -9.324*** -9.184*** (0.392) (0.457) collpriv_sh -22.778*** -22.515*** (0.403) (0.471) for_sh -63.470*** -61.554*** (0.344) (0.412) HS4 fixed effects Yes Yes Country fixed effects Yes Yes Observations 102,567 76,742 R-squared 0.326 0.333 Notes: Dependent variable is the share of indirect exports at product-country level (conservative measure), ranging from 0 to 100. The export shares by trade regime and firm ownership type variables range from 0 to 1. GAP is the trade data reporting discrepancy, defined as log(importing country reported imports from China)-log(China reported exports). *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. 35 Table 4: A transaction level analysis, LPM (1) (2) (t-r) 0.629*** 0.556*** (0.029) (0.026) log(value) -0.011*** -0.002*** (0.000) (0.000) (t-r)*log(value) 0.042*** 0.010*** (0.004) (0.003) prc -0.059*** (0.000) oth_regime -0.251*** (0.001) collpriv -0.214*** (0.000) for -0.623*** (0.000) oth_owner -0.616*** (0.001) HS4 fixed effects Yes Yes Observations 13,716,691 13,716,691 R-squared 0.051 0.305 Notes: A linear probability model is adopted. Dependent variable is a dummy indicating whether the final exporter is a producing firm (0) or trading firm (1), using the conservative classification. (t-r) refers to the unrefunded export VAT rate in percent, ranging from 0 to 0.17 (not in percentage as in other tables, adjusted to avoid very small coefficient estimates). log(value) is the logarithm of the transaction value in million current dollars. prc equals one if the exporting firm involved in the transaction belongs to processing trade, and zero otherwise. oth_regime equals one if the exporter involved in the transaction belongs to any of the trade regimes other than normal trade and processing trade, and zero otherwise. collpriv equals one if the exporter involved in the transaction is either a collective or a private firm, and zero otherwise. for equals one if the exporter involved in the transaction is a foreign wholly owned company, or an equity joint venture, or a contractual joint venture, and zero otherwise. oth_owner equals one if the exporter involved in the transaction belongs to any of the ownership types other than SOEs, collective & private, and foreign firms, and zero otherwise. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. 36 Table 5(1): Robustness checks, using liberal measure of indirect export share (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Full Diff Non-diff Full Diff Non-diff (t-r) 0.606** 1.487*** 0.227 1.262*** 2.482*** 1.197* (0.295) (0.477) (0.468) (0.469) (0.828) (0.665) prc_sh -9.954*** -8.155*** -13.313*** -9.766*** -11.220*** -11.031*** (1.402) (1.858) (2.411) (2.388) (3.904) (4.165) collpriv_sh -17.732*** -20.570*** -14.893*** -13.723*** -15.338*** -5.852 (2.270) (3.156) (3.532) (3.811) (5.869) (6.185) for_sh -51.697*** -52.720*** -50.537*** -46.729*** -46.093*** -42.923*** (1.760) (2.390) (2.905) (2.878) (4.305) (5.071) (t-r)*prc -0.097 0.857 -0.470 (0.400) (0.946) (0.537) (t-r)*collpriv -0.847 -1.418 -1.508* (0.604) (1.266) (0.792) (t-r)*for -1.059** -1.832* -1.293** (0.474) (1.021) (0.652) HS4 fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 7,009 4,176 2,533 7,009 4,176 2,533 R-squared 0.550 0.566 0.542 0.551 0.567 0.545 Notes: The regressions are at HS8 level. The dependent variable is the share of indirect exports (liberal measure), ranging from 0 to 100. The export shares by trade regime and firm ownership type variables range from 0 to 1. The omitted trade regime is normal trade. The omitted firm ownership type is SOE. “Diff” refers to differentiated products according to Rauch’s classification. “Non-diff” products include both homogenous and referenced products. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. 37 Table 5(2): Robustness checks, with horizontal and vertical product differentiation (1) (2) (3) Full Non-diff Diff (t-r) 0.791** 1.682*** 0.242 (0.372) (0.511) (0.522) prc_sh -7.828*** -5.872*** -11.528*** (1.582) (2.055) (2.616) collpriv_sh -14.089*** -17.993*** -9.811** (2.604) (3.567) (4.014) for_sh -47.525*** -50.000*** -44.243*** (1.978) (2.590) (3.269) Ad-R&D-Sales -4.236* -0.566 -4.726* (2.328) (5.160) (2.678) sigma 0.026 0.024 0.024 (0.019) (0.024) (0.029) HS4 fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Observations 5,315 3,332 1,806 R-squared 0.489 0.519 0.460 Notes: The regressions are at HS8 level. The dependent variable is the share of indirect exports (conservative measure), ranging from 0 to 100. The export shares by trade regime and firm ownership type variables range from 0 to 1. The omitted trade regime is normal trade. The omitted firm type is SOE. Ad-R&D-Sales refers to the advertising and R&D intensity. Sigma refers to elasticity of substitution. “Diff” refers to differentiated products according to Rauch’s classification. “Non-diff” products include both homogenous and referenced products. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. 38 Table 5(3): Robustness checks, with more control variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Full Diff Non-diff Full Diff Non-diff (t-r) 0.811** 1.686*** 0.277 0.806** 1.703*** -0.130 (0.373) (0.514) (0.521) (0.365) (0.539) (0.552) prc_sh -7.844*** -5.875*** -11.446*** -7.849*** -5.876*** -11.692*** (1.588) (2.064) (2.636) (1.588) (2.064) (2.655) collpriv_sh -14.064*** -17.927*** -9.855** -14.063*** -17.937*** -9.612** (2.601) (3.569) (4.010) (2.601) (3.571) (4.003) for_sh -47.351*** -49.948*** -44.224*** -47.347*** -49.952*** -43.877*** (1.979) (2.594) (3.276) (1.979) (2.595) (3.278) Ad-R&D-Sales -9.777** -2.613 -5.880 -9.787** -2.642 -5.896 (3.825) (5.593) (6.899) (3.828) (5.605) (6.916) sigma 0.026 0.023 0.025 0.026 0.023 0.025 (0.019) (0.024) (0.029) (0.019) (0.024) (0.029) primary 14.456** -1.344 10.450* 14.494** -1.341 11.931** (6.376) (9.977) (5.778) (6.372) (9.978) (5.272) resource 2.301 4.118 1.428 2.299 4.119 1.311 (2.902) (4.123) (4.155) (2.903) (4.125) (4.159) advanced-tech 11.302* 7.299 2.074 11.323* 7.308 2.127 (5.953) (5.887) (12.126) (5.957) (5.890) (12.156) zero/full rebate 0.297 0.468 11.045 (2.895) (3.285) (7.135) HS4 fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 5,315 3,332 1,806 5,315 3,332 1,806 R-squared 0.490 0.520 0.460 0.490 0.520 0.461 Notes: The regressions are at HS8 level. The dependent variable is the share of indirect exports (conservative measure), ranging from 0 to 100. The export shares by trade regime and firm ownership type variables range from 0 to 1. The omitted trade regime is normal trade. The omitted firm type is SOE. Ad-R&D-Sales refers to the advertising and R&D intensity. Sigma refers to elasticity of substitution. Primary refers to the primary product dummy. Resource refers to the resource based product dummy. Advanced-tech refers to the advanced technology products dummy. Zero/full rebate dummy controls for the products with either a zero or a full rebate rate. “Diff” refers to differentiated products according to Rauch’s classification. “Non-diff” products include both homogenous and referenced products. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. 39 Table 5(4): Robustness checks, using (t-r)*differentiated interaction (1) (2) (t-r) 0.154 0.176 (0.428) (0.402) diff -2.064 (3.588) (t-r)*diff 1.120* (0.603) Ad-R&D-Sales -8.488*** (3.067) (t-r)*Ad-R&D-Sales 1.184** (0.512) prc_sh -8.645*** -8.813*** (1.386) (1.447) collpriv_sh -16.060*** -14.176*** (2.288) (2.401) for_sh -47.938*** -46.444*** (1.775) (1.827) HS4 fixed effects Yes Yes F statistics for H0: b1+b3=0 7.34 (p-value) (0.007) Observations 6,719 6,098 R-squared 0.519 0.489 Notes: The regressions are at HS8 level. The dependent variable is the share of indirect exports (conservative measure), ranging from 0 to 100. The export shares by trade regime and firm ownership type variables range from 0 to 1. The omitted trade regime is normal trade. The omitted firm ownership type is SOE. “diff” is a dummy variable which equals one if a product belongs to differentiated product and zero for both homogenous and referenced products. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. 40 Table 5(5): Robustness checks, a falsification exercise (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Full Diff Non-diff Full Diff Non-diff (t-r) -0.408 -0.650 -0.304 -0.507 -0.240 -1.166 (0.559) (0.854) (1.242) (0.673) (0.920) (1.063) collpriv_sh_prcs -12.174*** -14.619** -10.795*** -13.149*** -12.747* -12.854*** (3.243) (6.621) (3.997) (3.608) (6.947) (4.458) for_sh_prcs -54.529*** -48.573*** -56.795*** -55.151*** -49.360*** -58.362*** (1.827) (4.312) (2.121) (2.106) (4.613) (2.451) primary -8.265 -8.894 (8.994) (23.015) resource -8.458 -8.250 -9.084 (8.997) (11.283) (23.016) advanced-tech -11.802 -35.417* -10.619 (12.407) (19.636) (15.718) Ad-R&D-Sales 23.051*** 31.169*** 35.719*** (7.978) (11.587) (13.472) sigma 0.002 0.015 -0.011 (0.031) (0.039) (0.076) HS4 fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 3,590 861 2,548 2,853 691 2,052 R-squared 0.592 0.643 0.579 0.596 0.619 0.595 Notes: The regressions are at HS8 level, covering only processing trade with supplied materials (prcs). The dependent variable is the share of indirect exports (conservative measure), ranging from 0 to 100. The export shares of prcs by trade regime and firm ownership type variables range from 0 to 1. The omitted trade regime is normal trade. The omitted firm ownership type is SOE. “Diff” refers to differentiated products according to Rauch’s classification. “Non-diff” products include both homogenous and referenced products. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. 41 Appendix 1: Shares by trade regimes and ownership among China’s exports in 2005 Panel I: For indirect exports only Normal trade Processing trade Total SOEs 0.5614 0.0485 0.6099 Collpriv 0.3676 0.0199 0.3875 Foreign 0.0024 0.0002 0.0026 Total 0.9314 0.0686 1.0000 Panel II: For direct exports only Normal trade Processing trade Total SOEs 0.0783 0.0205 0.0988 Collpriv 0.1366 0.0199 0.1564 Foreign 0.1654 0.5794 0.7448 Total 0.3803 0.6197 1.0000 Panel III: For total exports Normal trade Processing trade Total SOEs 0.1724 0.0259 0.1983 Collpriv 0.1816 0.0199 0.2014 Foreign 0.1337 0.4666 0.6002 Total 0.4876 0.5124 1.0000 Notes: Processing trade – processing with imported materials. SOE – state-owned enterprises; Collpriv – collective and private firms. Foreign – foreign wholly owned companies, equity joint venture, and contractual joint ventures. All other trade regimes and ownership types are left out from the above calculation. 42 Appendix 2: Descriptive statistics of the variables Panel I: Product level data, based on the sample in column (1) of Table 1 Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev Min Max ind_sh_con 7,009 31.6587 25.4603 0 100 ind_sh_lib 7,009 32.4761 25.7032 0 100 (t-r) 7,009 4.7150 3.1034 0 17 prc_sh 7,009 0.2124 0.2899 0 1 collpriv_sh 7,009 0.3196 0.2532 0 1 for_sh 7,009 0.3605 0.3111 0 1 Notes: ind_sh_con refers to the indirect export value share in percentage under the conservative measure. ind_sh_lib refers to the indirect export value share in percentage under the liberal measure. (t-r) refers to the unrefunded export VAT rate in percentage. prc_sh is the export value share of processing trade with imported materials (in percent). collpriv_sh is the export value share of private and collective firms. for_sh is the export value share of foreign wholly owned companies, equity joint venture, and contractual joint ventures (in percent). Panel II: Product-country level data, based on the sample in column (1) of Table 3 Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev Min Max ind_sh_con 60,952 41.2524 37.4467 0 100 (t-r) 60,952 4.1616 1.9537 0 17 prc_sh 60,952 0.1408 0.2822 0 1 collpriv_sh 60,952 0.4086 0.3753 -2.98e-08 1 for_sh 60,952 0.2510 0.3394 0 1 Notes: See the notes of Panel I above. Panel III: Transaction level data, based on the sample used in Table 4 Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev Min Max ind_sh_con 13,716,691 0.3696 0.4827 0 1 (t-r) 13,716,691 0.0402 0.0151 0 0.17 log(value) 13,716,691 -5.1174 2.1422 -13.8155 6.3493 prc 13,716,691 0.1953 0.3964 0 1 oth_regime 13,716,691 0.0471 0.2119 0 1 collpriv 13,716,691 0.4130 0.4924 0 1 for 13,716,691 0.3095 0.4623 0 1 oth_owner 13,716,691 0.0012 0.0345 0 1 Notes: ind_sh_con is a dummy variable for a trading firm based on the conservative definition. (t-r) refers to the unrefunded export VAT rate in percent, ranging from 0 to 0.17 (not in percentage, adjusted to avoid very small coefficient estimates). log(value) is the logarithm of the transaction value in million current dollars. prc equals one if the exporting firm involved in the transaction belongs to processing trade, and zero otherwise. oth_regime equals one if the exporter involved in the transaction belongs to any of the trade regimes other than normal trade and processing trade, and zero otherwise. collpriv equals one if the exporter involved in the transaction is either a collective or a private firm, and zero otherwise. for equals one if the exporter involved in the transaction is a foreign wholly owned company, or an equity joint venture, or a contractual joint venture, and zero otherwise. oth_owner equals one if the exporter involved in the transaction belongs to any of the ownership types other than SOEs, collective & private, and foreign firms, and zero otherwise. 43