BACKGROUND PAPER GOVERNANCE and THE LAW Domestic Resource Mobilization and the Poor Nora Lustig Tulane University Disclaimer This background paper was prepared for the World Development Report 2017 Governance and the Law. It is made available here to communicate the results of the Bank’s work to the development community with the least possible delay. The manuscript of this paper therefore has not been prepared in accordance with the procedures appropriate to formally-edited texts. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect the views of The World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Domestic Resource Mobilization and the Poor Nora Lustig1 May 26, 2016 Background paper for the World Development Report 2017 [Draft for comments; please cite with permission] At the UN General Assembly of September 2015, countries around the world committed to the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs). By 2030, counties committed to attain poverty and hunger eradication, healthy lives, quality education, gender equality and sustainable development. Countries also committed to promoting full-employment growth, decent work, peaceful societies and accountable institutions as well as to reducing inequality and strengthening global partnerships for sustainable development. One key factor to achieving the SDGs will be the availability of fiscal resources to deliver the floors in social protection, social services and infrastructure embedded in the SDGs. A significant portion of these resources is expected to come from domestic sources in developing countries themselves, complemented by transfers from the countries that are better off. The conference on Financing for Development in July 2015, for example, set the framework for where the resources to achieve the SDGs and other commitments endorsed in the numerous global and regional compacts will need to come from. The report states that “… For all countries, the mobilization and effective use of domestic resources [emphasis added] is at the crux of our common pursuit of sustainable development and achieving the SDGs… .”[2] Moreover, countries will be expected to set spending targets to deliver social protection and essential public services for all and set nationally defined domestic revenue targets. As is typical with these exercises designed to identify priorities and commitments which the great majority of countries endorse, the proposals shy away from acknowledging that goals have trade- offs. In particular, that raising additional revenues domestically for infrastructure, protecting the environment or social services may leave a significant portion of the poor with less cash to buy food and other essential goods. It is not uncommon that the net effect of all governments taxing and spending is to leave the poor worse off in terms of actual consumption of private goods and services. Achieving the new Sustainable Development Goals will depend in part on the ability of governments 1Nora Lustig is Samuel Z. Stone Professor of Latin American Economics and director of the Commitment to Equity Institute at Tulane University. She is also a nonresident senior fellow at the Center for Global Development and the Inter-American Dialogue. The author is very grateful to Sandra Martinez, Israel Martinez and Cristina Carrera for their excellent assistance in the preparation of tables and graphs. She also wants to thank Ruoxi Li for her excellent research assistance. 1 to improve their tax collection and enforcement systems. However, demand for investments into infrastructure and public services must be balanced against the competing need to protect low-income households that may otherwise be made worse off from misaligned tax and transfer policies. Based on the fiscal incidence studies by the Commitment to Equity Institute at Tulane University, this document addresses three questions: 1. To what extent do fiscal systems leave the poor worse off in terms of consumption of private goods and services? 2. How frequently fiscal systems may be inequality reducing but at the same time leave the poor worse off in terms of their purchasing power of private goods and services? 3. In what countries are the poor and the vulnerable net payers of the fiscal system? The data used for the analysis is based on household surveys of around 2010 for the following twenty- five countries: Argentina (Rossignolo, 2016), Armenia (Younger and Khachatryan, 2016), Bolivia (Paz- Arauco et al., 2014), Brazil (Higgins and Pereira, 2014), Chile (Martinez-Aguilar et al., 2016), Colombia (Lustig and Melendez, 2016), Costa Rica (Sauma and Trejos, 2014), Dominican Republic (Aristy- Escuder et al., 2016), Ecuador: (Llerena et al., 2015), El Salvador (Beneke et al., 2014), Ethiopia (Hill et al., 2016), Georgia (Cancho and Bondarenko, 2016), Ghana (Younger et al., 2015), Guatemala (Cabrera, Lustig and Moran, 2015), Honduras (Castañeda and Espino, 2015); Indonesia (Afkar et al., 2016), Jordan (Alam et al., 2016), Mexico (Scott, 2014), Peru (Jaramillo, 2014), Russia (Lopez-Calva et al., 2016), South Africa (Inchauste et al., 2016), Sri Lanka (Arunatilake et al., 2016), Tanzania (Younger et al., 2016), Tunisia (Shimeles et al., 2016), Uruguay (Bucheli et al., 2014). In Table 1, one can observe the change in headcount ratio from market income to consumable income (income after net direct and indirect taxes) for three poverty lines: US$1.25, US$2.50 and US$4 dollars per day (2005 ppp), lines that the World Bank has used to measure global poverty and extreme and moderate poverty in middle income countries, respectively.2 These results are for twenty five countries for which CEQ Assessments are available. Using the US$1.25 poverty line, fiscal policy increases the headcount ratio in Ghana, Sri Lanka and Tanzania. That is, in these countries the number of poor people who are made poorer through the taxing and spending activities of governments exceeds the number who actually benefit from those activities. When using the US$2.50 poverty line, the headcount ratio increases in Armenia, Bolivia, Brazil, Ethiopia, Ghana, Guatemala, Honduras, Sri Lanka and Tanzania. And the same countries experience an increase in the headcount ratio with the US$4 line. 2 All the CEQ studies applied the common fiscal incidence methodological framework discussed in Lustig and Higgins (2013) and Lustig, ed. (2016). Results presented here considers contributory pensions as deferred income. The definition of income concepts and a brief methodological overview is in the Appendix. 2 Table 1 – Fiscal policy and poverty: headcount ratio in % (circa 2010) Poverty line: $1.25 2005PPP/day Disposable Market Income Headcount Income ($1.25 Consumable Headcount 2005 PPP) (Pensions Income ($1.25as 2005 deferred PPP) income) Headcount ($1.25 2005 (Pensions PPP) (Pensions as deferred income)as deferred income) Contributory pensions as deferred income Market Disposable Consumable Disposable Consumable Country income plus income: income: income income pensions change in % change in % Argentina (2012) 1.1% 0.1% 0.2% -88.2% -82.0% Armenia (2011) 12.8% 9.6% 11.9% -24.9% -7.5% Bolivia (2009) 10.0% 8.4% 9.7% -16.1% -2.3% Brazil (2009) 5.8% 2.7% 4.5% -54.2% -23.0% Chile (2013) 0.8% 0.2% 0.3% -69.8% -66.2% Colombia (2010) 7.0% 5.7% 5.3% -18.5% -24.6% Costa Rica (2010) 2.2% 1.2% 1.7% -45.5% -22.7% Dominican Republic (2013) 5.7% 4.7% 4.9% -18.0% -14.1% Ecuador (2011) 3.4% 1.9% 1.6% -45.9% -53.8% El Salvador (2011) 4.3% 2.9% 3.6% -31.8% -15.7% Ethiopia (2011) 31.9% 30.9% 33.2% -3.3% 4.2% Georgia (2013) 20.5% 6.0% 9.4% -70.7% -54.2% Ghana (2013) 6.0% 5.9% 6.8% -1.7% 13.3% Guatemala (2011) 5.6% 5.2% 5.8% -8.3% 2.4% Honduras (2011) 10.2% 9.1% 9.3% -11.5% -8.8% Indonesia (2012) 12.1% 10.8% 10.5% -10.3% -12.7% Jordan (2010) 0.5% 0.1% 0.1% -69.6% -76.4% Mexico (2010) 5.0% 3.3% 3.2% -33.9% -35.0% Peru (2009) na na na -- -- Russia (2010) 2.6% 1.4% 1.6% -44.9% -37.8% South Africa (2010) 37.0% 16.1% 21.2% -56.4% -42.7% Sri Lanka (2010) 5.0% 4.2% 4.3% -16.5% -14.1% Tanzania (2011) 43.7% 43.6% 51.5% -0.2% 17.8% Tunisia (2010) 0.5% 0.3% 0.2% -34.6% -53.8% Uruguay (2009) 1.3% 0.0% 0.2% -97.0% -82.6% Poverty line: $2.5 2005PPP/day Disposable($2.5 Market Income Headcount 2005 Consumable Income PPP) (Pensions HeadcountIncome ($2.5 2005 as Headcount deferred PPP) (Pensions ($2.5 2005 income) deferred asPPP) income) (Pensions as deferred income) Contributory pensions as deferred income Disposable Consumable Market income Disposable Consumable Country income: change in income: change plus pensions income income % in % Argentina (2012) 4.7% 1.8% 3.0% -61.0% -35.4% Armenia (2011) 31.3% 28.9% 34.9% -7.7% 11.4% Bolivia (2009) 19.6% 17.6% 20.2% -10.4% 3.3% Brazil (2009) 15.1% 11.2% 16.3% -26.1% 8.1% Chile (2013) 2.8% 1.2% 1.3% -58.4% -51.8% Colombia (2010) 20.3% 18.9% 18.5% -7.0% -9.0% Costa Rica (2010) 5.4% 3.9% 4.2% -27.8% -22.2% Dominican Republic (2013) 19.5% 18.2% 19.5% -6.5% -0.2% Ecuador (2011) 10.8% 7.7% 7.0% -28.5% -35.1% El Salvador (2011) 19.2% 17.3% 19.1% -10.1% -0.8% Ethiopia (2011) 81.7% 82.4% 84.2% 0.9% 3.1% Georgia (2013) 39.2% 23.3% 30.0% -40.6% -23.3% Ghana (2013) 26.4% 26.8% 28.8% 1.5% 9.1% Guatemala (2011) 33.3% 32.3% 35.1% -2.8% 5.5% Honduras (2011) 25.1% 24.2% 25.2% -3.3% 0.5% Indonesia (2012) 56.4% 55.9% 54.8% -1.0% -2.9% Jordan (2010) 5.2% 4.0% 3.4% -24.0% -34.8% Mexico (2010) 12.6% 10.7% 10.7% -14.9% -15.1% Peru (2009) 15.2% 14.0% 14.5% -7.3% -4.4% Russia (2010) 4.0% 2.6% 2.8% -35.9% -29.1% South Africa (2010) 49.3% 38.7% 44.1% -21.4% -10.6% Sri Lanka (2010) 38.9% 38.2% 39.4% -1.8% 1.1% Tanzania (2011) 83.5% 84.4% 88.3% 1.1% 5.7% Tunisia (2010) 5.0% 4.6% 3.8% -8.3% -25.2% Uruguay (2009) 5.0% 1.4% 2.5% -71.4% -51.1% Poverty line: $4.0 2005PPP/day Disposable($4 Market Income Headcount 2005 Consumable Income PPP) (Pensions Income Headcount ($4 2005 asHeadcount deferred PPP) (Pensions ($4 2005 income) deferred asPPP) income) (Pensions as deferred income) Contributory pensions as deferred income Disposable Consumable Market income Disposable Consumable Country income: change in income: change plus pensions income income % in % Pensiones contributivas como ingreso diferido Ingreso de Ingreso Ingreso Ingreso Ingreso disponible: mercado más consumible: disponible consumible cambio en % pensiones cambio en % Argentina (2012) 12.3% 7.3% 12.5% -41.0% 1.6% Armenia (2011) 55.1% 55.5% 62.7% 0.7% 13.7% Bolivia (2009) 32.5% 30.7% 33.9% -5.6% 4.4% Brazil (2009) 26.2% 23.2% 31.0% -11.4% 18.2% Chile (2013) 7.5% 4.4% 5.7% -41.2% -24.2% Colombia (2010) 36.3% 35.5% 35.5% -2.1% -2.3% Costa Rica (2010) 10.8% 9.3% 11.1% -13.9% 2.8% Dominican Republic (2013) 37.0% 35.9% 37.7% -2.9% 1.9% Ecuador (2011) 24.1% 21.0% 20.3% -12.9% -15.6% El Salvador (2011) 39.3% 38.3% 40.8% -2.7% 3.8% Ethiopia (2011) 95.2% 95.6% 96.1% 0.4% 1.0% Georgia (2013) na na na na na Ghana (2013) 48.9% 49.9% 52.1% 2.0% 6.6% Guatemala (2011) 58.5% 58.3% 60.9% -0.4% 4.1% Honduras (2011) 39.7% 39.0% 41.6% -1.7% 4.9% Indonesia (2012) 78.4% 78.3% 77.8% -0.2% -0.8% Jordan (2010) 25.8% 24.6% 23.6% -4.7% -8.4% Mexico (2010) 24.7% 23.1% 23.8% -6.2% -3.5% Peru (2009) 28.6% 27.8% 28.7% -2.7% 0.4% Russia (2010) 6.3% 4.6% 5.5% -26.8% -12.5% South Africa (2010) 57.5% 52.9% 57.3% -8.0% -0.3% Sri Lanka (2010) 69.8% 69.7% 71.2% -0.1% 1.9% Tanzania (2011) 93.7% 94.6% 96.3% 1.0% 2.8% Tunisia (2010) 14.3% 14.9% 14.7% 4.3% 2.7% Uruguay (2009) 11.4% 6.6% 8.9% -42.0% -21.8% Source: based on Argentina (Rossignolo, 2016), Armenia (Younger and Khachatryan, 2016), Bolivia (Paz-Arauco et al., 2014), Brazil (Higgins and Pereira, 2014), Chile (Martinez-Aguilar et al., 2016), Colombia (Lustig and Melendez, 2016), Costa Rica (Sauma and Trejos, 2014), Dominican Republic 3 (Aristy-Escuder et al., 2016), Ecuador: (Llerena et al., 2015), El Salvador (Beneke et al., 2014), Ethiopia (Hill et al., 2016), Georgia (Cancho and Bondarenko, 2016), Ghana (Younger et al., 2015), Guatemala (Cabrera, Lustig and Moran, 2015), Honduras (Castañeda and Espino, 2015); Indonesia (Afkar et al., 2016), Jordan (Alam et al., 2016), Mexico (Scott, 2014), Peru (Jaramillo, 2014), Russia (Lopez-Calva et al., 2016), South Africa (Inchauste et al., 2016), Sri Lanka (Arunatilake et al., 2016), Tanzania (Younger et al., 2016), Tunisia (Shimeles et al., 2016), Uruguay (Bucheli et al., 2014). Notes: The year for the study is in parenthesis. For definitions of income concepts see Diagram in appendix. The numbers in red font with a positive sign indicate an increase in the headcount ratio. As shown by Higgins and Lustig (2016), conventional measures of poverty such as the headcount ratio can fail to capture whether the poor are made worse off (and the nonpoor made poor) by fiscal interventions. A stylized illustration of fiscal impoverishment can be seen in Figure 1. The areas in dark grey indicate the order of magnitude of fiscal impoverishment and the areas in light grey show the extent of fiscal gains to the poor. Figure 1 – Fiscal Impoverishment and Fiscal Gains to the Poor: A Stylized Illustration Source: Higgins and Lustig (2016). Table 2 presents the proportion of individuals that are fiscally impoverished (i.e., the equivalent of those for which the blue line falls below the orange line in the stylized figure above) as a share of the total population (column 6) and of the population classified as poor with consumable income (column 7) for eighteen countries for which these calculations were available. To measure fiscal impoverishment Table 2 shows indicators for consumable income as the relevant after taxes and transfers income concept even though taxes are used to fund more than just direct cash and food transfers and indirect subsidies from the government (e.g., they are used to fund public goods and services, many of which also reach the poor) because this is the income concept relevant for measuring 4 poverty: it is “disposable money and near-money income” that should be compared to the poverty line when the latter is based on “a poverty budget for food, clothing, shelter, and similar items” (Citro and Michael, 1995, p. 212, 237).” For low and lower-middle income countries, a poverty line of $1.25 per person per day is used; for upper middle income countries, $2.50 per day is used. Table 2 column 1 shows the market income poverty headcount and column 2 shows the change in poverty from market to consumable income. Moving to the progressivity of the tax and transfer system and change in inequality in each country, column 3 shows the market income Gini coefficient and column 4 shows the Reynolds and Smolensky (1977) index of global progressivity (the Reynolds-Smolensky equals the market income Gini minus the concentration coefficient of consumable income with respect to market income, and thus globally progressive systems have a positive Reynolds-Smolensky index). Column 5 shows the change in inequality, with negative numbers indicating that inequality declined as a result of the tax and transfer system. Table 2. Fiscal Impoverishment (from market income plus pensions to consumable imcome; circa 2010) Market Income Change in Market Income Reynolds- Change in Fiscally Fiscally Impoverished plus pensions poverty plus pensions Smolensky inequality Impoverished as % as % of consumable Cuntry (Survey year) Poverty headcount inequality (▲ Gini) of population income poor ) Headcount (%) (p.p) ( Gini) Panel A: Upper-middle income countries, using a poverty line of $2.5 PPP 2005 per day Brazil (2008-2009) 16.8 -0.8 57.5 4.6 -3.5 5.6 34.9 Chile (2013) 2.8 -1.4 49.4 3.2 -3.0 0.3 19.2 Ecuador (2011) 10.8 -3.8 47.8 3.5 -3.3 0.2 3.2 Mexico (2012) 13.3 -1.2 54.4 3.8 -2.5 4.0 32.7 Peru (2011) 13.8 -0.2 45.9 0.9 -0.8 3.2 23.8 Russia (2010) 4.3 -1.3 39.7 3.9 -2.6 1.1 34.4 South Africa (2010-2011) 49.3 -5.2 77.1 8.3 -7.7 5.9 13.3 Tunisia (2010) 7.8 -0.1 44.7 8.0 -6.9 3.0 38.5 Panel B: Lower-middle income countries, using a poverty line of $1.25 2005PPP per day. Armenia (2011) 21.4 -8.4 47.4 12.9 -9.2 6.2 52.3 Bolivia (2009) 10.9 -0.5 50.3 0.6 -0.3 6.6 63.2 Dominican Republic (2007) 6.8 -0.9 50.2 2.2 -2.2 1.0 16.3 El Salvador (2011) 4.3 -0.7 44.0 2.2 -2.1 1.0 27.0 Ethiopia (2010-2011) 31.9 2.3 32.2 2.3 -2.0 28.5 83.2 Ghana (2013) 6.0 0.7 43.7 1.6 -1.4 0.1 76.6 Guatemala (2010) 12.0 -0.8 49.0 1.4 -1.2 7.0 62.2 Indonesia (2012) 12.0 -1.5 39.8 1.1 -0.8 4.1 39.2 Sri Lanka (2009-2010) 5.0 -0.7 37.1 1.3 -1.1 1.6 36.4 Tanzania (2011-2012) 43.7 7.9 38.2 4.1 -3.8 50.9 98.6 Source: Higgins and Lustig (2016). Note: Year of survey in parenthesis. Note that although fifteen of the eighteen countries in Table 2 experienced a reduction in poverty and inequality due to the tax and transfer system, they experienced various degrees of fiscal impoverishment.3 In ten countries—Armenia, Bolivia, Brazil, El Salvador, Guatemala, Indonesia, Mexico, Russia, Sri Lanka, and Tunisia—between one-quarter and two-thirds of the post- fisc poor lost income to the fiscal system. In other countries, this figure is much lower, at 13.3% of 3 Note that Brazil here appears with a reduction in the headcount ratio because poverty was measured differently than the results shown in Table 1. 5 the post-fisc poor in South Africa (but, due to the high proportion of the total population that is poor, still 5.9% of the total population) and 3.2% of the post-fisc poor in Ecuador. In the three countries where the headcount ratio rose (Ethiopia, Ghana and Tanzania), the proportion of the poor who were impoverished by the fiscal system is staggering (above 75 percent). It should also be noted that “even if we add the value of public spending on education and health (imputed at their government cost to families who report a child attending public school or who report using public health facilities), fiscal impoverishment is still high in several countries: in Armenia, Ethiopia, Indonesia, Tunisia, and Russia, between 25 and 50% of those who are fiscally impoverished before adding in benefits from public spending on health and education are still fiscally impoverished when these benefits are included as transfers.” (Higgins and Lustig, p. 8) This undesirable outcome of the poor being made worse off by the combination of taxes and transfers is the consequence of primarily consumption taxes—e.g., value added or excise taxes—. For example, the Brazilian tax system results in heavy taxes on such basic staples as rice and beans. For many households, transfers from Bolsa Familia are not there or are not large enough to compensate what they pay in consumption taxes (Higgins and Pereira, 2014). This is not the result of a “diabolical” plan: it is the outcome of targeting schemes which select households on their characteristics (poor with school-age children), a very complex cascading tax system and consumption patterns of the poor. In the case of Ethiopia, it is mainly the result of taxes on agriculture, even small-holder agriculture. The big risk in setting an ambitious domestic resource mobilization agenda is that in the process governments will impoverish poor people even further. As it stands, the SDGs list of targets would not alert us of such a perverse outcome. Under Goal One on poverty reduction, there should be a Target 1.6: “By 2030 to ensure that the fiscal system does not reduce the income of the poor.” On Figure 2, one can observe which deciles, on average, are net receives or net payers (in orange) to the fisc in cash terms (that is, excluding benefits derived from public goods and services such as public education and health). As one can observe, in thirteen out of the twenty-five countries analyzed here, net payers are found in all deciles (Ghana) or in three (Argentina, Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Peru and Russia), two (Armenia, Bolivia, Chile, the Dominican Republic, Ethiopia, Honduras, Tunisia and Uruguay) or at least the fourth decile (Brazil and Sri Lanka) of the bottom 40 percent of the population, the target group of the World Bank’s shared prosperity goal. 6 Figure 2 - Net payers and receivers to the fiscal system by decile (circa 2010) Net receivers Net payers Indonesia (2012) Jordan (2010) Georgia (2013) Ecuador (2011) Colombia (2010) South Africa (2010) Mexico (2010) Sri Lanka (2010) Brazil (2009) Uruguay (2009) Tunisia (2010) Honduras (2011) Ethiopia (2011) Dominican Republic (2013) Chile (2013) Bolivia (2009) Armenia (2011) Russia (2010) Peru (2009) Guatemala (2011) El Salvador (2011) Costa Rica (2010) Argentina (2012) Ghana (2013) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Source: based on Argentina (Rossignolo, 2016), Armenia (Younger and Khachatryan, 2016), Bolivia (Paz-Arauco et al., 2014), Brazil (Higgins and Pereira, 2014), Chile (Martinez-Aguilar et al., 2016), Colombia (Lustig and Melendez, 2016), Costa Rica (Sauma and Trejos, 2014), Dominican Republic (Aristy-Escuder et al., 2016), Ecuador: (Llerena et al., 2015), El Salvador (Beneke et al., 2014), Ethiopia (Hill et al., 2016), Georgia (Cancho and Bondarenko, 2016), Ghana (Younger et al., 2015), Guatemala (Cabrera, Lustig and Moran, 2015), Honduras (Castañeda and Espino, 2015); Indonesia (Afkar et al., 2016), Jordan (Alam et al., 2016), Mexico (Scott, 2014), Peru (Jaramillo, 2014), Russia (Lopez-Calva et al., 2016), South Africa (Inchauste et al., 2016), Sri Lanka (Arunatilake et al., 2016), Tanzania (Younger et al., 2016), Tunisia (Shimeles et al., 2016), Uruguay (Bucheli et al., 2014). Notes: The year for the study is in parenthesis. For definitions of income concepts see 7 Appendix Fiscal Incidence Analysis: Methodological Highlights4 Fiscal incidence analysis is used to assess the distributional impacts of a country’s taxes and transfers. Essentially, fiscal incidence analysis consists of allocating taxes (personal income tax and consumption taxes, in particular) and public spending (social spending in particular) to households or individuals so that one can compare incomes before taxes and transfers with incomes after taxes and transfers. Transfers include both cash transfers and benefits in kind such as free government services in education and healthcare. Transfers also include consumption subsidies such as food, electricity and fuel subsidies. As with any fiscal incidence study, let’s start by defining the basic income concepts. Here there are four: market, disposable, post-fiscal and final income. These income concepts are described below and summarized in Diagram 1. Market income5 is total current income before direct taxes, equal to the sum of gross (pre-tax) wages and salaries in the formal and informal sectors (also known as earned income), income from capital (dividends, interest, profits, rents, etc.) in the formal and informal sectors (excludes capital gains and gifts), consumption of own production,6 imputed rent for owner occupied housing, and private transfers (remittances, pensions from private schemes and other private transfers such as alimony). Disposable income is defined as market income minus direct personal income taxes on all income sources (included in market income) that are subject to taxation plus direct government transfers (mainly cash transfers but can include near cash transfers such as food transfers, free textbooks and school uniforms). Post-fiscal (also called consumable) income is defined as disposable income plus indirect subsidies (e.g., food and energy price subsidies) minus indirect taxes (e.g., value added taxes, excise taxes, sales taxes, etc.). Final income is defined as post fiscal income plus government transfers in the form of free or subsidized services in education and health valued at average cost of provision7 (minus co-payments or user fees, when they exist). One area in which there is no clear consensus is how pensions from a pay-as-you-go contributory system should be treated. Arguments exist in favor of both treating contributory pensions as deferred 4 This section is based on Lustig and Higgins (2013) and Lustig (2016). 5 Market income is sometimes called primary or original income. 6 Except in the case of South Africa, whose data on auto-consumption (also called own-production or self-consumption) was not considered reliable. 7 See, for example, Sahn and Younger (2000). 8 income8 or as a government transfer, especially in systems with a large subsidized component.9 Since this is an unresolved issue, CEQ studies present results for both methods. One scenario treats social insurance contributory pensions (herewith called contributory pensions) as deferred income (which in practice means that they are added to market income to generate the original or “pre-fisc” income). The other scenario treats these pensions as any other cash transfer from the government. 10 The studies analyzed here present results considering contributory pensions as deferred income. For consistency, when pensions are treated as deferred income, the contributions by individuals are included under savings (they are mandatory savings) while when they are treated as government transfers, the contributions are considered a direct tax. It is important to note that the treatment of contributory pensions not only affects the amount of redistributive spending and how it gets redistributed, but also the ranking of households by original income or pre-fiscal income. For example, in the scenario in which contributory pensions are considered a government transfer, households whose main (or sole) source of income is pensions will have close to (or just) zero income before taxes and transfers and hence will be ranked at the bottom of the income scale. When contributory pensions are treated as deferred income, in contrast, households who receive contributory pensions will be placed at a (sometimes considerably) higher position in the income scale. Thus, the treatment of contributory pensions in the incidence exercise could have significant implications for the order of magnitude of the “pre-fisc” and “post-fisc” inequality and poverty indicators. In the construction of final income, the method for education spending consists of imputing a value to the benefit accrued to an individual of going to public school which is equal to the per beneficiary input costs obtained from administrative data: for example, the average government expenditure per primary school student obtained from administrative data is allocated to the households based on how many children are reported attending public school at the primary level. In the case of health, the approach was analogous: the benefit of receiving healthcare in a public facility is equal to the average cost to the government of delivering healthcare services to the beneficiaries. In the case of Colombia, however, the method used was to impute the insurance value to beneficiary households rather than base the valuation on utilization of healthcare services. This approach to valuing education and healthcare services amounts to asking the following question: how much would the income of a household have to be increased if it had to pay for the free or subsidized public service (or the insurance value in the cases in which this applies to healthcare benefits) at the full cost to the government? Such an approach ignores the fact that consumers may value services quite differently from what they cost. Given the limitations of available data, however, 8 Breceda et al. (2008); Immervoll et al. (2009). 9 Goñi et al.(2011); Immervoll et al. (2009).; Lindert et al. (2006). 10 Immervoll et al. (2009) do the analysis under these two scenarios as well. 9 the cost of provision method is the best one can do for now.11 For the readers who think that attaching a value to education and health services based on government costs is not accurate, the method applied here is equivalent to using a simple binary indicator of whether or not the individual uses the government service.12 13 Diagram 1 The welfare indicator used in the fiscal incidence analysis is income per capita. The fiscal incidence analysis used here is point-in-time and does not incorporate behavioral or general equilibrium effects. That is, no claim is made that the original or market income equals the true counter-factual income in the absence of taxes and transfers. It is a first-order approximation that measures the average incidence of fiscal interventions. However, the analysis is not a mechanically applied accounting exercise. The incidence of taxes is the economic rather than statutory incidence. It is assumed that individual income taxes and contributions both by employees and employers, for 11 By using averages, it also ignores differences across income groups and regions: e.g., governments may spend less (or more) per pupil or patient in poorer areas of a country. Some studies in the CEQ project adjusted for regional differences. For example, Brazil’s health spending was based on regional specific av erages. 12 This is of course only true within a level of education. A concentration coefficient for total non-tertiary education, for example, where the latter is calculated as the sum of the different spending amounts by level, is not equivalent to the binary indicator method. 13 In order to avoid exaggerating the effect of government services on inequality, the totals for education and health spending in the studies reported here were scaled-down so that their proportion to disposable income in the national accounts are the same as those observed using data from the household surveys. 10 instance, are borne by labor in the formal sector. Individuals who are not contributing to social security are assumed to pay neither direct taxes nor contributions. Consumption taxes are fully shifted forward to consumers. In the case of consumption taxes, the analyses take into account the lower incidence associated with own-consumption, rural markets and informality. In general, fiscal incidence exercises are carried out using household surveys and this is what was done here. The surveys used in the country studies are the following: Bolivia: Encuesta de Hogares, 2009 (I); Brazil: Pesquisa de Orçamentos Familiares, 2009 (I); Chile: Encuesta de Caracterización Social (CASEN), 2013 (I); Colombia: Encuesta de Calidad de Vida, 2010; Costa Rica: Encuesta Nacional de Hogares, 2010 (I); Ecuador: Encuesta Nacional de Ingresos y Gastos de los Hogares Urbano y Rural, 2011-2012 (I); El Salvador: Encuesta de Hogares de Propósitos Múltiples, 2011 (I); Guatemala: Encuesta Nacional de Ingresos y Gastos Familiares, 2011 (I); Mexico: Encuesta Nacional de Ingreso y Gasto de los Hogares, 2010 (I); Perú: Encuesta Nacional de Hogares, 2009 (I) Uruguay: Encuesta Continua de Hogares, 2009 (I)14. [TO BE COMPLETED] 14 Las letras "I","C" indican si el estudio se basó en una encuesta con datos de ingreso o consumo, respectivamente. 11 REFERENCES [to be completed] Aranda, R., Scott, J., 2015. CEQ Master Workbook for Mexico. Mimeo. Beneke, Margarita, Nora Lustig y José Andrés Oliva. 2014. El impacto de los impuestos y el gasto social en la desigualdad y la pobreza en El Salvador. CEQ Working Paper No. 26, Center for Inter-American Policy and Research and Department of Economics, Tulane University and Inter-American Dialogue and CEQ Master Workbook: El Salvador, June 26. Birdsall, Nancy, Nora Lustig and Christian Meyer. 2014. “The Strugglers: The New Poor in Latin America?,” World Development, August 2014, Volume 60, pp132-146. Bucheli, Marisa, Nora Lustig, Máximo Rossi, and Florencia Amábile. 2014. “Social Spending, Taxes and Income Redistribution in Uruguay.” In Lustig, Nora, Carola Pessino and John Scott. 2014. Editors. The Redistributive Impact of Taxes and Social Spending in Latin America. Special Issue. Public Finance Review, May, Volume 42, Issue 3, pp 413-433. Cabrera, Maynor, Nora Lustig, and Hilcías Morán. 2014. Fiscal Policy, Inequality and the Ethnic Divide in Guatemala. CEQ Working Paper No. 20, Center for Inter-American Policy and Research and Department of Economics, Tulane University and Inter-American Dialogue. October. CEQ Master Workbook: Guatemala, August 27, 2014 and CEQ Masterworkbook, CEQ Institute, Tulane University. (May 6, 2015) Ferreira, F. H. G., Messina, J., Rigolini, J., López-Calva, L.-F., Lugo, M. A., & Vakis, R. 2012. Economic Mobility and the Rise of the Latin American Middle Class. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Higgins, Sean and Nora Lustig. 2013. “Fiscal Incidence, Fiscal Mobility and the Poor: A New Approach,” Tulane Economics Department Working Paper 1202, New Orleans, Louisiana, April 2012; CIPR (Center for Inter-American Policy & Research) Working Paper, New Orleans, Louisiana, August 2012; ECINEQ (Society for the Study of Economic Inequality) Working Paper Series 265, September 2012; and CEQ Working Paper No. 4, January 2013. Higgins, Sean, and Claudiney Pereira. 2014. “The Effects of Brazil’s Taxation and Social Spending on the Distribution of Household Income.” In Lustig, Nora, Carola Pessino and John Scott. 2014. Editors. The Redistributive Impact of Taxes and Social Spending in Latin America. Special Issue. Public Finance Review, May, Volume 42, Issue 3 and CEQ Master Workbook: Brazil, November 4. Higgins, Sean and Nora Lustig. 2015. Can a Poverty-Reducing and Progressive Tax and Transfer System Hurt the Poor? CEQ Working Paper No. 33, Center for Inter-American Policy and Research and Department of Economics, Tulane University and Inter-American Dialogue, April 8. Jaramillo, Miguel. 2014. “The Incidence of Social Spending and Taxes in Peru.” In Lustig, Nora, Carola Pessino and John Scott. 2014. Editors. The Redistributive Impact of Taxes and Social Spending in Latin America. Special Issue. Public Finance Review, May, Volume 42, Issue 3 and CEQ Master Workbook: Peru, June 21, 2013. Jaramillo, Miguel, L de la Flor, and Barbara Sparrow. 2015. Are ethnic groupings invisible for fiscal policy in Peru? An incidence analysis of taxes and transfers on indigenous and non indigenous Peruvians. Mimeo. Llerena Pinto, Freddy Paul, María Christina Llerena Pinto, Roberto Carlos Saá Daza, and María 12 Andrea Llerena Pinto. 2015. Social Spending, Taxes and Income Redistribution in Ecuador. CEQ Working Paper No. 28, Center for Inter-American Policy and Research and Department of Economics, Tulane University and Inter-American Dialogue, February. López-Calva, L. F., & Ortiz-Juarez, E. (2011). A Vulnerability Approach to the Definition of the Middle Class (Policy Research Working Paper Series No. 5902). Washington, DC: The World Bank. Lustig, Nora and Sean Higgins. 2013. “Commitment to Equity Assessment (CEQ): Estimating the Incidence of Social Spending, Subsidies and Taxes. Handbook.” CEQ Working Paper No. 1, July 2011; revised January 2013, Center for Inter-American Policy and Research and Department of Economics, Tulane University and Inter-American Dialogue. ______ . 2015. “Fiscal Policy, Inequality and the Poor in the Developing World.” CEQ Working Paper No. 23, Center for Inter-American Policy and Research and Department of Economics, Tulane University and Inter-American Dialogue. ______ editor. 2016. Commitment to Equity Handbook: Estimating the Redistributive Impact of Fiscal Policy , Tulane University and the World Bank. ______ and Marcela Melendez. 2015. “The Impact of Taxes and Transfers on Inequality and Poverty in Colombia.” CEQ Working Paper No 24, Center for Inter-American Policy and Research and Department of Economics, Tulane University and Inter-American Dialogue. Forthcoming. Martinez-Aguilar, Sandra, Alan Fuchs and Eduardo Ortiz-Juarez. 2016 “The Impact of Fiscal Policy on Inequality and Poverty in Chile.” CEQ Working Paper No. 46, Commitment to Equity Institute, Tulane University and the World Bank, forthcoming Paz Arauco, Verónica, George Gray Molina, Wilson Jiménez Pozo, and Ernesto Yáñez Aguilar. 2014. “Explaining Low Redistributive Impact in Bolivia.” In Lustig, Nora, Carola Pessino and John Scott. 2014. Editors. The Redistributive Impact of Taxes and Social Spending in Latin America. Special Issue. Public Finance Review, May, Volume 42, Issue 3, pp 326-345, CEQ Master Workbook: Bolivia, August 8, 2013. Sauma, Pablo and Juan Diego Trejos 2014. Gasto público social, impuestos, redistribución del ingreso y pobreza en Costa Rica. CEQ Working Paper No. 18, Center for Inter-American Policy and Research and Department of Economics, Tulane University and Inter-American Dialogue, January. CEQ Master Workbook: Costa Rica, September, 2014. Scott, John. 2014. “Redistributive Impact and Efficiency of Mexico’s Fiscal System.” In Lustig, Nora, Carola Pessino and John Scott. 2014. Editors. The Redistributive Impact of Taxes and Social Spending in Latin America. Special Issue. Public Finance Review, May, Volume 42, Issue 3. 13