WPS4546 Policy ReseaRch WoRking PaPeR 4546 Integration of Markets vs. Integration by Agreements Nathalie Aminian K.C. Fung Francis Ng The World Bank Development Research Group Trade Team March 2008 Policy ReseaRch WoRking PaPeR 4546 Abstract This paper provides an analysis of the two channels regional trade treaties until recently, East Asia is more of regional integration: integration via markets and integrated among itself than Latin America. Third, from integration via agreements. Given that East Asia and a purely economic and trade standpoint, the proper Latin America are two fertile regions where both forms sequence of integrations seems to be first integrating of integrations have taken place, the authors examine via markets and subsequently via formal regional trade the experiences of these two areas. There are four related agreements. Fourth, regional trade agreements often results. First, East Asia had been integrating via markets serve multiple constituents. The reason why integrating long before formal agreements were in vogue in the via markets first can be helpful is because this can give region. Latin America, by contrast, has primarily used stronger political bargaining power to the outward- formal regional trade treaties as the main channel of looking economic-oriented forces within the country. integration. Second, despite the relative lack of formal This paper--a product of the Trade Team, Development Research Group-- is part of a larger effort in the department to analyze regional integration and trade policy. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ. worldbank.org. The author may be contacted at fng@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team Integration of Markets vs. Integration by Agreements Nathalie Aminian 1 K.C. Fung 2 Francis Ng 3 JEL classification numbers: F10, F13, F15 Keywords: Regionalism, Economic Integration, Regional Agreements, Trade Policy __________________________________________ Paper presented at the International Seminar on The New Agenda for International Trade Relations as the Doha Round Draws to an End, January 29-30, Barcelona, Spain. We are grateful to the participants of the international seminar, particularly Ramon Torrent, Roberto Bouzas and Pierre Sauve for very useful comments. All findings in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessary reflect the views of the World Trade Organization or The World Bank Group, its Executive Directors, or its staff. 1University of Le Havre, France, email: nathalie.aiminian@univ-lehavre.fr 2University of California, Santa Cruz and University of Hong Kong, email: kcfung@ucsc.edu 3The World Bank ­ Development Research Group, email: fng@worldbank.org 2 1. Introduction During the last decade, we witnessed a major transformation in the global governance of international trade relationships. The first development occurred in 1995 with the creation of the World Trade Organization (WTO), which is the foremost global institution governing the conduct of international trade. Rules contained in the Uruguay Round which created the World Trade Organization are the most ambitious and comprehensive multilateral trade laws ever ratified by member countries and they provide an anchor and a set of norms for all contracting parties. Paradoxically, parallel to the development of these multilateral rules since 1995 is the second major development in international trade relationships--the proliferation of bilateral, regional and other preferential trade agreements among nations. As the Doha Round of negotiations is currently indefinitely suspended, it is expected that regional and bilateral trade deals will become even more prevalent. The creation of Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs) such as Free Trade Areas (FTAs) is by no means new. But the sheer number and the speed with which these agreements have been negotiated in the past ten years are simply astonishing. By 2005, all but one WTO member was trading under one or more PTAs (Limao 2005). In this paper, we would like to analyze the recent history, characteristics and the political economy of regional and bilateral trade integration from the viewpoint of two core concepts: integration of markets vs. integration by agreements. As its name suggests, the concept of integration of markets focuses on the idea that economies can integrate among themselves through the use of the marketplace, i.e. allowing the private sector to be the vanguard of trade integration. This can also be described as regional integration via de facto agreements. More concretely, this means that the economies in a region trade intensively among themselves without explicit formal preferential trade agreements. To facilitate intra-regional trade without the help of regional legal trade agreements, some of the economies may pursue policies of unilateral domestic deregulation and trade liberalizations, while others may improve their infrastructure (such as ports and highways), streamline their custom procedures or pursue policies that may facilitate inward foreign direct investment. In other words, even integration via the markets can entail the use of some business-friendly policies by individual economies, even though no legal regional trade treaties are signed by governments. 3 The second core concept is integration by agreements, which focuses on trade integration via the use of formal or de jure trade treaties. This channel of integration emphasizes the primacy of legal instruments to further economic integration among countries. There is no doubt that these two instruments of integration are very much related and indeed ultimately they are complementary. Integration of neighboring markets without formal regional trade agreements can create uncertainty among businesses since the institutional foundations may not be sufficiently clear and transparent. Integration by agreements can be vacuous if the underlying economic factors are not favorable for integration. Nonetheless, it is important to ask the following questions: Which instrument of integration is more successful and more fundamental in driving trade integration? Is there a logical sequence for policymakers to consider when examining these two channels of integration? In this paper, we will examine these and other questions in detail. Furthermore, given that East Asia and Latin America are two fertile territories in which various forms of PTAs proliferate, we will use the experiences of these two regions extensively as useful illustrations for our work in this paper. To look ahead, using the experiences of East Asia and Latin America as our guide, our research on the topic of integration of markets vs. integration by agreements suggests four conclusions. First, until fairly recently (say the late 1990s), East Asian countries have integrated among themselves primarily via the markets and not by formal, de jure trade agreements. In contrast, Latin America has a long history (since the 1960s) of legal trade treaties that attempt to bind themselves together. Second, using various indicators of trade and economic integration, it is clear that East Asian economies are much more integrated among themselves than the economies of Latin America. At least for the important cases of East Asia and Latin America, integration using the marketplace or via de facto agreements (together with business-friendly policies by individual countries) leads to more intense integration than de jure agreements. Third, from the viewpoint of policymakers who want to strengthen trade relationships regionally, this suggests that the proper sequencing of the two forms of integration should first be the freeing of the domestic private sectors which allow them to mature and to use the international markets to integrate, before establishing legal treaties to further deepen the relationships. Lastly, from a political-economic standpoint, it can be seen from the examples in East Asia and Latin America that regional trade agreements often serve several constituents. Trade agreements are both economic agreements as well as foreign policy agreements. Regional trade agreements can also be inward-looking or outward- 4 oriented. To keep the primary focus on the open-trade and economic objectives, it is thus important to first develop a thick market for exporters and traders, who can pressure the government to pay attention to the signals of the economic forces. We will use a generalized Nash bargaining analysis to illustrate this point. In the next section, we provide a detailed overview of recent development of regional trade agreements in East Asia and in Latin America. In section 3, we provide some information of the extent and characteristics of the trade integration in these two regions. In section 4, we provide a simple analysis of trade policy implementation that illustrates how integration of markets first can lead to more successful trade connections than integration via trade agreements. In section 5, we conclude. 2. Regional Trade Agreements in East Asia and Latin America In the wake of the progress achieved in Europe and North America, regional cooperation has recently gained momentum all over the world. Regional cooperation is of course not an end in itself but has to be considered as a way of enhancing economic growth and development. Most of the industrial and developing countries have concluded some regional trade and investment agreements. Compared to other international regions, for instance Latin America, Asia lagged in concluding formal trade agreements as East Asian countries have been more supportive of an open multilateral system. The Asian regional integration can be regarded as a de facto regional integration even though recently, by the end of 1990s, most East Asian countries have showed strong interest about de jure regionalism. However, the momentum for formal regional integration has been accompanied by the proliferation of bilateral FTAs not only within Asia but also with extra-regional countries, in particular with Latin America. Latin American countries adopted formal/de jure regional integration in the early 1990s, such as NAFTA or MERCOSUR, but in addition to these sub-regional schemes, various bilateral FTAs have emerged both among Latin American countries and with the extra-regional countries by the end of 1990s. It is noteworthy that, given different choices of regional integration, intra-regional trade in Latin America is much less than that of East Asian countries. We will highlight this 5 contrast of trade integration in section 3. First let us next discuss the recent history of free trade agreements in East Asia and Latin America. 2.1 Trends of Free Trade Areas in East Asia It is generally recognized that the FTA of ASEAN (The Association of Southeast Asian Nations) countries signed in 1992 was the starting point of East Asian regionalism. However, in the Asia-Pacific region, regional cooperation took shape as APEC (Asia-Pacific Economic cooperation) at the end of the 1980s. APEC1 is not a regional trade agreement, but a unique form of economic cooperation for promoting trade and investment liberalization, economic and technical cooperation among Asia-Pacific countries. Although APEC is not an FTA in legal terms, it has a plan to achieve free trade in the region. At the APEC Summit Meeting in Bogor, Indonesia in 1994, the leaders adopted the "Bogor goal", where they announced their commitment to complete trade and investment liberalization by 2010 in the case of industrial country members and by 2020 in the case of developing country members. At Osaka in November 1995, an agreement was reached on a set of fundamental principles to bring about the liberalization of trade and investment. If the "Bogor goals" are realized and the commitments of the member countries are fully implemented, APEC countries can enjoy a substantial welfare improvement through free trade opportunities in the region, without creating formal trade agreements. APEC adopted an "open regionalism" as the underlying paradigm i.e. with the intention of sharing benefits of free trade with non-members and thus trying to comply with the most favored nation (MFN) principal of the WTO. The work of APEC in trade liberalization did not achieve much success. However, it should not be viewed as a failure of "open regionalism", but rather the result of the diversification of the APEC agenda, which now includes such topics as anti-terrorism and weapons of mass destruction. In the late 1990s, Asian economies appeared to seek another path for regional integration, namely Free Trade Areas (FTAs) in the subset of the Asia-Pacific region. ASEAN country members (Brunei, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand) have taken action toward trade liberalization. In 1992, the ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA) was set up formally to realize a free trade area within 15 years beginning 1 January 1993. In 1The original 12 members that participated in the first APEC meeting in Camberra I 1989 were Japan, Korea, six ASEAN countries, the US, Canada, Australia and New Zealand. Later its membership expanded to 21 economies including China, Russia and Mexico. 6 September 1994, the time frame was shortened to 10 years with the aim of achieving the AFTA goals by 2003. The membership has been expanded to ten countries to include Vietnam, Myanmar, Laos and Cambodia. ASEAN countries agreed to eliminate tariffs among the original six members by 2010 and for new members by 2015. Moreover, the leaders of ASEAN announced that they aimed to transform AFTA into an ASEAN Economic Community by 2020. Individual countries in ASEAN pursue separate FTAs, which may affect cooperation among the ASEAN countries as a whole. Singapore has signed FTAs with New Zealand, Japan, Australia and the US, and Thailand has concluded an FTA with Australia. Although the ASEAN economy and trade volume is small compared to major trading blocs, ASEAN became the target of FTAs inside and outside the region. More recently, there have been agreements to study FTAs for broader groups. China has proposed an FTA between China and ASEAN country members. However, the ASEAN countries put forward an ASEAN+3 (including China, Japan and Korea). India also has agreed on a framework of comprehensive economic partnership with ASEAN. Despite the rise of regionalism in East Asia, regional integration has not long been prevalent in Northeast Asian countries2. So far, Northeast Asian countries have not been part of any formal trading areas. There is now some willingness to form FTAs on bilateral sub- regional levels. Korea took the first step in policy shift to free trade agreements. The Korean government decided to pursue FTAs with its trading partners at the Ministerial Committee on International Economic Policy in 1998. Chile was chosen as the first partner for the negotiation of an FTA because of the small size of the bilateral trade and distance between the two countries. Korea's second FTA was with Singapore, also a country with a relatively small bilateral trade volume and less sensitive products. The Korean government is currently undertaken formal negotiation with Japan but the process is not easy. Japan is targeted for a short-term conclusion. The FTA with ASEAN is considered for mid-term, and the US, China and EU for the long run. Currently, Korea is involved with "simultaneous multi-track" negotiations with Japan, ASEAN and Canada. Joint studies for bilateral FTAs are being conducted for India, Mexico, Russia and MERCOSUR. 2There are different geographical definitions of Northeast Asia. The broadest definition would include China, Japan, North and South Korea, Mongolia, Hong Kong, Taiwan and the Russian Far East and Siberia. This paper, concentrates on the three major Northeast Asian economies i.e. China, Japan and South Korea. 7 Japan has also begun to study the potential of FTAs in the late 1990s. The initial motivation was to defend export market from the regional agreements of other countries. In particular, since the NAFTA greatly affected the Japanese export performance in the region. Japan first thought an FTA with Mexico but negotiations with the Mexican government did not progress smoothly. The first FTA signed by Japan was a "New-age" free-trade agreement3 with Singapore in October 2002. The agreement included promoting mutual recognition on some licensing procedures and increasing worker mobility between the two countries. In 2004, Japan finally agreed on a FTA with Mexico. Japan also concluded the FTA negotiations with the Philippines in 2004. Currently, Japan is undertaken official negotiations on FTA with Korea and Malaysia. Negotiations for an FTA with Indonesia are also expected to follow and formal negotiation with ASEAN started in April 2005. China joined the WTO in 2001 and is in the process of meeting its WTO obligations. This is why China's interest in regional trade agreements is limited. However, China also took initiative in an FTA with ASEAN and has made progress in these negotiations. At a summit meeting held in Phnom Penh in 2002, the leaders of China and ASEAN countries announced the signing of a framework agreement with the objective to establish a FTA within ten years. China, Japan and Korea have also been discussing and investing the feasibility of a trilateral FTA. Separately, Japan and Korea have announced that they will conclude a bilateral FTA by the end 2005. A China and Korea bilateral FTA may be the next one. China is hesitant to form a FTA with Japan and competes with Japan in the race for FTAS with ASEAN. It seems that China is ahead in a FTA with ASEAN as a group, but with regard to FTAs with individual ASEAN countries, Japan is further along. China is also seeking FTAs with Chile, New Zealand. Table 1 gives an overview of the intra-regional and extra-regional arrangements in East Asia. These are manifestations of a real willingness in East Asia toward closer regional cooperation. While ASEAN is often presumed to be the most important economic cooperation in the region, its impact on promoting intra-regional trade and investment has been limited. The initiation of FTAs was soon followed by the 1997 financial crisis affecting the region. Since then, paradoxically, the regional financial proposals are moving faster than any serious 3The « New Age » Partnership goes beyond a traditional free trade agreement. It focuses on new issues such as: "rules governing foreign investment, e-commerce regulations, trade in services, harmonization of technical standards, sanitary and phyto-sanitary regulations, and the streamlining of customs procedures" Hertel, Walsley and Itakura (2001). 8 intention of regional economic cooperation4. Traditionally, trade arrangements are most prominent regional groupings and, precede any financial integration. The European Monetary Union started with a customs union, and developed into a single currency full-fledged economic area. In comparison, the relationship between the economic and financial components of the East Asian regional process is ill defined. There now appears to be little or no coordination between economic and financial initiatives. In any case (economic or financial cooperation), Northeast Asian economies are expected to play a key role in regional integration. Further, a change in the attitudes of Japan and China is emerging. Both countries seem to be more resolute about a regional grouping than before. A shift of the center of gravity of political initiatives toward closer economic and financial cooperation has been perceivable. Given the slow progress within AFTA and the importance of the Northeast Asian countries in terms of size and weight in the Asian economy, a free trade arrangement between China, Japan and Korea could be achieved prior to wider agreements in the style of ASEAN+3. Furthermore, since it is difficult to expect an East Asia FTA in which at least one of the three major Northeast Asian countries does not participate, a de facto Northeast Asia cooperation is a necessary condition for an East Asian integration. Thus, a China-Japan-Korea cooperation is crucially important for the formal economic integration of both Northeast and East Asia. 4 The new international environment and the Asian currency crisis have created a strong impetus for regional financial cooperation and have provided Asian countries with a common interest, which has led to the Chiang Mai Initiative (CMI) agreement (May 2000) on bilateral swaps and discussions of the possibility of creating a monetary union among the ASEAN+3 as a long-run objective. More recently, at the informal ASEAN+3 Finance and Central Bank Deputies' Meeting held in Tokyo on 13 November 2002, Korea made a proposal to discuss regional bond market development under the ASEAN+3. In furtherance of this proposal, Japan presented a comprehensive approach to foster bond markets in Asia, the "Asian Bond Markets Initiative" at an ASEAN+3 informal session held in Chiang Mai on December 2002. 9 Table 1: Economic Cooperation Agreements in East Asia Intra-Regional Year of in force Type of agreement Status Multi-Countries Agreements Asia-Pacific Trade Agreement (APTA) 1976 Partial Scope Implemented ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA) 1992 Free Trade Agreement Implemented East Asia Free Trade Area (EAFTA) 2000 Free Trade Agreement Proposed China-Japan-Korea Free Trade Area 2000 Free Trade Agreement Proposed APTA-Accession of China 2002 Partial Scope Accession Implemented Signed and Japan-ASEAN Closer Economic Partnership 2002 Partial Scope realization by 10 yrs Singapore-EFTA (Iceland, Norway, Switzerland) 2003 Free Trade Agreement Implemented Signed and ASEAN-China Free Trade Area (ACFTA) 2003 Partial Scope realization by 2010 ASEAN-India Regional Trade Agreement 2003 Econ Integration Agreement Signed ASEAN-Korea Free Trade Area 2004 Partial Scope On-going negotiations Trans-Pacific Strategic Economic Partnership 2006 Free Trade Agreement Signed Korea-EFTA (Iceland, Norway, Switzerland) 2006 Free Trade Agreement Signed Bilateral Agreements Laos-Thailand 1991 Partial Scope Implemented Singapore-New Zealand 2001 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented Singapore-Japan 2002 Free Trade Agreement Signed Singapore-Australia 2003 Free Trade Agreement Implemented Japan-Korea 2003 Free Trade Agreement On-going negotiations Thailand-India 2003 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented China-Hong Kong (CEPA) 2004 Econ Integration Agreement Signed China-Macao 2004 Econ Integration Agreement Signed Korea-Chile 2004 Econ Integration Agreement Signed Singapore-United States 2004 Econ Integration Agreement Signed Hong Kong-New Zealand 2005 Econ Integration Agreement On-going negotiations Japan-Mexico 2005 Econ Integration Agreement On-going negotiations Thailand-Australia 2005 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented Thailand-New Zealand 2005 Free Trade Agreement Signed Singapore-Canada 2006 Free Trade Agreement On-going negotiations Singapore-Chile 2006 Free Trade Agreement On-going negotiations Singapore-India 2005 Free Trade Agreement On-going negotiations Singapore-Jordan 2005 Free Trade Agreement On-going negotiations Singapore-Korea 2006 Free Trade Agreement On-going negotiations Singapore-Mexico 2006 Free Trade Agreement On-going negotiations Singapore-Panama 2006 Free Trade Agreement On-going negotiations China-Chile 2006 Free Trade Agreement On-going negotiations Japan--Canada 2006 Econ Integration Agreement On-going negotiations Japan-Malaysia 2006 Free Trade Agreement On-going negotiations Korea-Australia 2006 Econ Integration Agreement On-going negotiations Korea-New Zealand 2006 Econ Integration Agreement On-going negotiations Korea-United States 2007 Econ Integration Agreement On-going negotiations Korea-Mexico 2007 Econ Integration Agreement On-going negotiations Japan-Chile 2007 Econ Integration Agreement On-going negotiations Malaysia-United States 2007 Econ Integration Agreement On-going negotiations Philippines-United States 2007 Econ Integration Agreement On-going negotiations Sources: WTO web data and various info from the web. 10 2.2 Origins of the New Asian Regionalism Before 1997, most Asian economists considered East Asian economic cooperation (through trade and investment) as an example of a successful de facto regionalism i.e. explained by the play of pure economic forces. However, the financial crisis of 1997-98 demonstrated the weaknesses of informal regional cooperation and gave East Asians a strong impetus to search for a regional mechanism that could forestall future crisis. This search is now gathering momentum and opening the door to possibly significant de jure integration in East Asia. The Asian financial crisis is often regarded as the outbreak for the rise in regionalism in East Asia. The crisis and its subsequent contagion to a number of economies in Northeast and Southeast Asia painfully demonstrated that the East Asian economies were closely related and a resolution to the crisis could require a regional cooperation. A rising sense of East Asian identity has emerged since the crisis. After the proposal to create an Asian Monetary Fund (AMF) failed to lead to progress, the leaders of ASEAN responded by inviting China, Korea and Japan to join in an effort to seek economic cooperation in the region. The ASEAN+3 Summit in November 1999 released a "Joint Statement on East Asian Cooperation" that covers a wide range of possible areas for regional cooperation. In the early 2000s, other new economic situations - such as the quick recovery and recurring growth in Korea, the emergence of China as a fast post-crisis growing economy and the continuing stagnant state of Japan - gave rise to a new Asian economic regionalism and FTAs. It is noteworthy that FTAs projects are numerous and proliferating at startling speed. These include regional agreements as well as bilateral treaties5. Although the financial crisis might have been the direct cause, a number of additional factors contributed to the breakthrough and proliferation of the policy-led regionalism in East Asia. First, regionalism was the natural result of decades of fast growth and a number of economic restructuring and industrial transformations in East Asia, particularly in Northeast Asia (with the emergence of Japan as a major industrial power in the 1960s, and rapid growth of the newly industrializing economies of Northeast and Southeast Asia in the late 1970s and 1980s). These economic developments have created a new center of East Asia economic 5Most intra-regional trade agreements of Asian countries are FTAs, the effect of which is to eliminate trade barriers between members. Following the Japanese, the term "Economic Partnership Agreement" (EPA) is also used, which intends to imply that the scope of the agreement is broader than the elimination of barriers of trade in goods. 11 power that has begun to compete with North America and Europe in terms of its contribution to world output and world trade. Second, it was the result of a "benign neglect" from international organizations such as the IMF in the aftermath of the Asian crisis (Tran Van Hoa, 2002). East Asian economic policy makers perceived international institutions and the main global trading powers (especially, the US) fell short in their support for the region. That is why to escape this crisis, countries initially attempted some kind of "go-it-alone" strategy (for example, uncontrolled devaluations, interruption of payments...). These countries were rapidly called to order by the IMF in the name of global world interest. The IMF's reaction illustrated for regional policy makers not only the inefficiency of a "go it alone" strategy but also the lack of institutional regional coordination in Asia. Finally, the successful integration initiatives in other parts of the world, such as the EU and NAFTA, illustrated for academics and politicians the possibilities that deepening and widening economic cooperation could bring in East Asia. For a long time most East Asian countries, and in particular Japan, considered multilateral agreements (in the sense of WTO) alone sufficient to establish fair economic relationships. They were strongly encouraged by the USA in that way of thinking. However, when the USA itself decided to engage in regional agreements with first Canada and then Mexico in 1992, the Asian countries started to dread being left isolated between what seemed to be possible future trade blocs. Understanding the logic of NAFTA and EU was a lesson to Asian countries: regional agreements are a mix of political and economic objectives. Once traditional barriers to trade and investment are eliminated, there are still many other impediments to abolish. The regional integration is in fact a result of economic forces and political willingness. In the case of East Asia, political issues have long been major obstacles to regional economic cooperation. Nonetheless, prospect for de jure regionalism in East Asia is not totally disappeared as new approaches and initiatives are in recent times put forward by the regional states. East Asian regionalism is undergoing a phase of new interpretation. It is no longer limited in an economic sense. Growing interdependence and tightening financial links are not sufficient to make this regionalization more consistent: strategic thinking is being inserted as the concept of regionalism begins to expand in terms of both geography and agenda6. 6This has been done at the Chinese initiative, with Japan trying to follow. Beijing is increasingly driving East Asia's agenda. China's suggestion to extend invitation to India, New Zealand, and Australia, but not to the USA for the East Asian Summit meeting in November 2005 in Malaysia was accepted by the members of ASEAN+3, and it reflects China's growing influence over East Asia's emerging regional architecture. 12 2.3 Trends of Free Trade Areas in Latin America Free trade is not a new concept in Latin America. Globally, we can consider three phases of FTA process in Latin America. First stage (1960s): FTAs created in the context of import substitution industrialization Since the 1940s regional economic integration in Latin America was considered as an instrument of promoting economic growth and industrialization. In the 1960s, there were a number of arrangements in order to promote regional economic integration, most of which met with limited success. The Latin American Free Trade Association (LAFTA) created in 1960 incorporated the inward-looking import substitution orientation for Latin American industrialization policies. In order to deepen the import substituting industrialization process, those countries which had small markets tried to reach economies of scale through the preferential opening of their markets. In 1969, The Andean Pact was conducted as a sub- regional agreement within LAFTA. LAFTA and the Andean Pact were not capable of increasing trade in the region. These agreements were negotiated on a product-by-product approach instead of covering all sectors of the economy. The Central American Common Market (CACM) formed by Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, and Honduras followed an inward-oriented trade strategy but was more successful in promoting intra-regional trade. The objective was to reach a common market which would provide a preferential market for import substituting industries. During the 1970s, the CACM suffered a crisis and in 1986, the collapse of the Central American clearing mechanism marked the disintegration of the CACM. The 1980s were a decade of major economic transformation for the Latin American economies: Latin American countries started drastic policy reforms based on "neo- liberalism", abandoning interventionist strategy that had brought the region's financial and economic crisis. This context led to the liberalization of most Latin American trade policies and to the adoption of outward-oriented trade policies coupled with economic stabilization and the privatization of public firms. The Latin American countries made revisions to the trade agreements of the previous period with the idea of renewing the process of regional integration in the sense of taking into account the need of Latin American economies to compete in the international market and to improve market access for their exports. Bhagwati 13 (1992) considered that as a "second regionalization based on open trade compared to the first regionalization based on protection". Second stage (1990s): Intra-regional FTAs to complement and support the economic liberalization process The Andean Pact was reviewed in order to take into account not only trade in goods but also liberalization in other areas. In spite of this integration effort, the level of intra- regional trade remained quite low. In March 1991, Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay and Uruguay signed the Asuncion Treaty which established MERCOSUR. Later, Chile and Bolivia have joined MERCOSUR as associate members in the framework of an ECA. At the same time, there has also been a proliferation of bilateral or trilateral regional initiatives. The pioneering bilateral trade agreement between Chile and Mexico went into force in January 1992. The agreement was officially called ECA7 17 of ALADI (Latin American Integration Association). One year before the Mexico-Chile ECA was ratified, the Argentina-Chile ECA went into force, which was called ECA 16 of ALADI. These two ECAs as well as many other trade agreements among Latin American countries were negotiated in the framework of ALADI. This is why the ALADI can be regarded as a kind of "umbrella" agreement facilitating the negotiation and realization of regional trade arrangements. In 1994, the bilateral trade agreement between Canada and the US was extended to Mexico in order to form the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). Besides multi- country economic integrations such as NAFTA and MERCOSUR, many bilateral agreements have emerged in Latin America since the early 1990s. Particularly two Latin American countries, Chile and Mexico, have independently pursued bilateral FTAs with other countries in Latin America. After the NAFTA was established, Mexico extended FTAs to several countries of Latin America. In 1995, the trilateral FTA with Colombia and Venezuela was negotiated to form the G3 Agreement (El Grupo de los Tres). FTAs with Costa Rica and Bolivia went into force in 1995 and FTA with Nicaragua in 1998. Later, Mexico started the 7 Economic Complementation Agreements (ECAs) basically cover trade of goods although they give the possibilities of future negotiation of other areas. 14 negotiation with three other countries of Central America together (El Salvador, Guatemala and Honduras) and, individually with Panama, Ecuador, Peru, Belize, Trinidad and Tobago, and Dominican Republic. As for Chile, liberalization through bilateral FTAs was assumed to be one of the most effective instruments of trade policy for a small country such as Chile. Chile established bilateral ECAs with Argentina and Mexico and started FTAs in the ALADI framework with Venezuela and Bolivia in 1993, Colombia in 1994, Ecuador in 1995, MERCOSUR in 1996, and Peru in 1998. Chile also initiated bilateral negotiation with Canada which went into force in 1997, and with the Central American Common Market in 1999. In this way, Mexico and Chile have been converting into "hubs" of FTAs in Latin America from the mid 1990s. Third stage (end of 1990s-2000s): Inter-regional FTAs By the end of 1990s, both Mexico and Chile started to look for establishing FTAs with extra-regional countries. This trend can be considered as the new trade policy of these countries in order to diversify economic links with major extra-regional countries like European or Asian economies. This is why Mexico and Chile are assumed to be "hubs" that involves not only in Latin America, but also inter-regional FTAs connecting existing or newly establishing integration schemes in other regions. For instance, Chile formed FTAs with Canada, the US and Korea. It signed the Association Agreement with the EU in 2002. Mexico formed an FTA with the EU and Israel by the end of 2000. The two countries showed also strong interests in forming bilateral framework with Asian countries in particular. For instance, Chile signed FTA with Korea in 2002 and this is the first FTA between Asia and Latin America. Japanese government has already started negotiation with Mexican government about future economic cooperation that covers FTA between the two countries. Other negotiations are ongoing, focusing on trade relationship with the Unites States. Recently, some of the region's countries such as Colombia, Costa Rica, Panama and Peru, centred on trade links with the United States, showing that the integration process is in a change in Latin America. The Dominican republic-Central America-USA FTA has come into effect in all member countries, except in Costa Rica, where it is in the process of being 15 ratified. The Bolivarian Republic of Venezuela withdrew from the Andean Community concluded negotiations for a FTA with the United States. Table 2 illustrates effective regional arrangements in Latin America. It is noteworthy that these movements in Latin America towards bilateral FTAs could have significant influences on the recent movement in Asia for establishing bilateral FTA, thus accelerating initiatives for bilateral FTA in Asia-Pacific. Table 2: Economic Cooperation Agreements in Latin America Intra-Regional Year of in force Type of agreement Status Multi-Countries Agreements CACM (Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, 1961 Customs Union Implemented Nicaragua) CARICOM (incl. 15 Caribbean countries) 1973/97 Customs Union and EIA Implemented LAIA (Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Cuba, 1981 Partial Scope Implemented Ecuador, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru, Urugary, Venezuela) Andean (Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, Venezuela) 1988 Customs Union Implemented MERCOSUR (Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, Uruguay; 1991/05 Customs Union and EIA Implemented Venezuela joined 2006) NAFTA (Canada, Mexico, United States) 1994 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented G3 (Colombia, Mexico, Venezuela) 1995 Free Trade Agreement Implemented Chile-MERCOSUR 1996 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented Bolivia-MERCOSUR 1997 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented MERCOSUR-European Communities 1999 Cooperative Agreement Implemented Mexico-European Communities 2000 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented Mexico-EFTA 2001 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented Mexico-Central America 2001 Free Trade Agreement Implemented Mexico-MERCOSUR 2002 Econ Integration Agreement Signed Chile-European Communities 2003 Free Trade Agreement Signed Peru-MERCOSUR 2003 Econ Integration Agreement Signed MERCOSUR-India 2003 Econ Integration Agreement Signed Chile-EFTA 2004 Econ Integration Agreement Signed Dominican Rep.-Central America-United States 2006 Free Trade Agreement Signed Bilateral Agreements Chile-Argentina 1991 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented Mexico-Argentina 1991 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented EIA and Free Trade Chile-Mexico 1992/98 Agreement Implemented Chile-Bolivia 1993 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented Chile-Venezuela 1993 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented Chile-Colombia 1994 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented EIA and Free Trade Mexico-Bolivia 1994/95 Agreement Implemented Chile-Ecuador 1995 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented 16 Mexico-Costa Rica 1995 Free Trade Agreement Implemented Mexico-Peru 1996 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented Chile-Canada 1997 Free Trade Agreement Implemented Mexico-Nicaragua 1998 Free Trade Agreement Implemented Chile-Peru 1998 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented Mexico-Israel 2000 Free Trade Agreement Implemented Mexico-Cuba 2001 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented Mexico-El Salvador 2001 Free Trade Agreement Implemented Mexico-Guatemala 2001 Free Trade Agreement Implemented Mexico-Honduras 2001 Free Trade Agreement Implemented Mexico-Brazil 2002 Econ Integration Agreement Signed Chile-Costa Rica 2002 Free Trade Agreement Implemented Chile-El Salvador 2002 Econ Integration Agreement Implemented Costa Rica-Canada 2002 Free Trade Agreement Signed Chile-Korea 2003 Econ Integration Agreement Signed Mexico-Uruguay 2003 Free Trade Agreement Signed El Salvador-Panama 2003 Free Trade Agreement Signed Chile-United States 2004 Econ Integration Agreement Signed Sources: WTO web data and various info from the web. 2.4 Driving forces of the recent development of regionalism in Latin America The development of regionalism in Latin America in the 1990s can be explained by several factors (Hosono, A., Nishijima S., 2003). The most significant ones are the following: - Economic liberalization of the 1980s: Latin American countries started radical policy reforms in the middle of the 1980s, leaving behind interventionist policies responsible for economic crises in the 1980s. Upshots of these policy reforms were seen mostly in the trade and capital liberalization. - Increasing regionalism of the US: The US foreign trade policy had been based on a mix of multilateralism and bilateralism until the end of the 1980s. From then on, the US showed an inclination towards regionalism with the formation of NAFTA and APEC. In response to these changes in the US attitude towards regionalism, Latin American countries adopted different behaviors: · Some countries expressed strong impetus about joining FTA of Americas, on the US initiative and leadership; 17 · Other countries, such as Chile, started a negotiation to join NAFTA; · Southern Cone countries, such as Brazil and Argentina, formed a sub-regional integration i.e. MERCOSUR, to counterbalance against the regionalism of the US; · Mexico and Chile enhanced bilateral intra and extra-regional FTAs; · The Andean Community is recently going through a period of adjustment and redefinition following the withdrawal of Venezuela, the extend-membership to Chile and the signature by Colombia and Peru of bilateral trade agreements with the United States. The new trend of extra-regional integration in the 2000s, in particular the proliferation de bilateral FTAs, conducted by Mexico and Chile, could be explained as the natural result of the deepening and widening process of FTA. However, these two countries have different reasons for promoting their FTAs with extra-regional countries. Taking into account the dependency of Mexico on the US market after its participation to the NAFTA, Mexico showed an inclination to diversify and strengthen economic relationship with extra-regions through expanding bilateral FTAs. As for Chile, it is one of the most liberalized countries in the world, opting for unilateral trade liberalization. It is then very important for Chile to induce trade liberalization of partner countries within Latin America or outside the region. By examining the brief history of trade agreements in both East Asia and Latin America above, we can see the following: East Asia first integrated via the markets and then in the 1990s started integrating via agreements. Latin America since the 1960s has mainly used trade agreements as the primary channel for integration. It is then interesting to evaluate the depth of the trade integration for these two regions which have chosen two different ways of integration. 18 3. Characteristics and Intensity of Trade Integration in East Asia and Latin America In this section we will examine the characteristics and intensity of regional trade integration in both East Asia and Latin America. Table 3 compares the degrees of intra- regional trade for all goods in East Asia and Latin America over time. The East Asian economies considered include ASEAN countries (Cambodia, Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand and Vietnam) and North East Asian countries (China, Hong Kong, Japan, Macao, republic of Korea and Taiwan) while the Latin American economies include ANDEAN countries (Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru and Venezuela), MERCOSUR (Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay and Uruguay, Venezuela is excluded due to new membership in 2006) and NAFTA countries (Canada, Mexico and United States). It can easily be seen that the East Asian economies are much more integrated among themselves than the Latin American economies, excluding Canada and the United States. In 2005, 50.5% of East Asian exports went to other East Asian economies. The comparable figure for Latin America (LAIA including those countries in ANDEAN Community and MERCOSUR plus Chile and Mexico) was only 13.2%. Trade integration in East Asia was already high before the 1997-98 Asian financial crises. In 1995, 48.7% of East Asian exports were intra-regional, as compared with 17.2% in Latin America. One could assume that taking into account Northeast Asian countries, specially, China, Japan and Korea, could change results and produce very high level of integration comparing to Latin American countries. This is why it is interesting to compare ASEAN to Latin American countries with an additional distinction between Central and South America. Table 3 shows that, during the whole period under study, trade integration among ASEAN countries (25.2% in 2005) is higher than the trade integration among ANDEAN community (8.2% in 2005) or MERCOSUR countries (12.9% in 2005). Thus one can surmise that de facto trade agreements or integration via the markets were effective in helping East Asia integrate, while de jure trade agreements do not seem to lead to more intra-regional trade integration in Latin America. Generally one may surmise that trade integration may tend to occur to a greater extent for manufactured goods. Furthermore, given the rising importance of trade in components and 19 parts, it is expected that integration via trade in components and parts should be even more intense (Yi, 2003; Ng and Yeats, 2003). Global and regional production sharing and vertical specialization have become increasingly important. In the next Table we wish to highlight intra-regional trade of manufactured goods and components and parts within these two regions for various years. Table 4 shows clearly that for both manufactured goods and components and parts, intra-regional trade is relatively more pronounced in East Asia than in Latin America. 48.5% of East Asian exports of manufactured goods were shipped to other East Asian economies in 2005. The corresponding share for Latin America (LAIA) was only 17.1%. However, if we compare ASEAN to ANDEAN and MERCOSUR countries, results are different: 25.1% of ASEAN exports of manufactured goods were shipped to other East Asian economies in 2005; the corresponding share for ANDEAN countries was 34.3% and 20.2% for MERCOSUR. As for parts and components, the share of East Asian intra-regional exports of components and parts amounted to 59.3% in 2005, as compared to 14.00% in Latin America (LAIA). But if we compare ASEAN to ANDEAN and MARCOSUR countries, results are different: 29.6% of ASEAN exports of parts and components were shipped to other East Asian economies in 2005, while the corresponding share for ANDEAN countries was 39.5% and 22.6% for MERCOSUR. Table 3: East Asia and Latin America Intra-Regional Trade in Various Years Share of Intra-Regional Exports in Share of Intra-Regional Exports in East Asia to the World (%) Latin America to the World (%) Year ASEAN NE Asia East Asia ANDEAN MERCOSUR LAIA NAFTA LAC 1985 18.7 23.3 34.2 2.6 5.5 10.0 42.9 46.1 1990 19.0 27.8 39.8 4.2 8.9 10.9 41.3 44.5 1995 24.9 34.5 48.7 12.1 20.5 17.2 46.0 50.5 2000 23.0 34.5 47.3 9.1 20.9 13.1 55.7 58.8 2005 25.2 39.2 50.5 8.2 12.9 13.2 55.8 57.2 Notes: ASEAN includes Cambodia, Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand and Vietnam due to missing data for Brunie, Laos and Myanmar. Cambodia and Vietnam are missing data in 1985-1995. NE Asia includes China, Hong Kong, Japan, Macao, Korea Rep., and Taiwan. East Asia includes those countries in ASEAN and NE Asia. ANDEAN includes Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru and Venezuela. MERCOSUR includes Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay and Uruguay (Venezuela is excluded due to new member in 2006). LAIA includes those countries in ANDEAN and MERCOSUR plus Chile and Mexico. NAFTA includes Canadia, Mexico and United States. LAC includes all countries in LAIA and NAFTA. Source: Computations by authors based on UN COMTRADE Statistics. 20 Table 4: East Asia and Latin America Intra-Regional Trade of Manufactured Goods and Parts & Components in Various Years Share of Intra-Regional Exports in Share of Intra-Regional Exports in East Asia to the World (%) Latin America to the World (%) Year ASEAN NE Asia East Asia ANDEAN MERCOSUR LAIA NAFTA LAC Manufactured Goods 1985 22.1 19.0 25.7 13.5 7.8 18.4 46.7 50.9 1990 19.9 25.5 35.4 14.6 10.5 17.0 43.1 47.0 1995 26.3 32.3 46.0 39.3 26.5 19.6 47.8 53.7 2000 23.3 33.0 44.9 33.2 27.0 13.0 55.5 59.8 2005 25.1 38.3 48.5 34.3 20.2 17.1 54.3 58.9 Parts & Components 1985 22.8 23.2 31.2 9.5 8.0 17.3 41.3 46.1 1990 27.0 32.1 44.4 12.8 12.4 16.8 45.3 49.3 1995 32.1 34.3 51.9 40.1 34.2 17.5 45.9 51.3 2000 29.0 38.0 54.3 39.4 30.2 10.0 53.0 57.5 2005 29.6 45.8 59.3 39.5 22.6 14.0 53.0 58.0 Notes: Manufactured goods is defined as SITC 5+6+7+8-68 in Revision 2. Parts & components include 75 items of parts in machinery, transport equipment and textiles & clothing. Cambodia and Vietnam are missing data in 1985 to 1995 in East Asia. Source: Computations by authors based on UN COMTRADE Statistics. Table 4 also shows that the intensification of intra-regional trade in Latin America started in the 1990s, while the pace of trade integration started prior to the proliferation of formal regional trade agreements in East Asia. In 1990, the shares of ASEAN intra-regional exports of manufactured goods and components and parts were 19.9% and 27.00%, respectively. The corresponding shares in Latin America were 14.6% and 12.8% for ANDEAN community and 10.5% and 12.4% for MERCOSUR countries. Essentially East Asian integration was driven by market conditions. Integration via markets occurs before attempts to establish more formal regional trade agreements. For Latin America, de jure trade agreements seem to have led to a slight acceleration of the pace of intra-regional trade. Another way we can analyze the intensity of regional trade integration is through the use of the trade intensity index. The trade intensity index is defined as: 21 X ij X i X wj X w where Xij and Xwj are country i and world exports to country j; Xi and Xw are country i and world total exports. The numerator indicates the share of country i's export to country j in total export of the country i, and the denominator indicates the share of world's export to country j in its total export. If the bilateral trade intensity index has a value greater than one, the export of country i outperforms in country j. It implies that country j is relatively important to country i's exports. In Table 5, we present calculations of the trade intensity indices for East Asian countries as well as some of their major trading partners for 2005. To further highlight their trade relationship, we also provide the overall trade matrix for the region. The overall East Asia-East Asia trade index is 5.9, as compared to the Latin American (LAIA) trade index of 3.6 (Table 6). For an in-depth analysis, we compare ASEAN index to ANDEAN and MERCOSUR countries. The ASEAN index is 7.2 while the indices for ANDEAN and MECOSUR are respectively 13.5 and 12.6. These results show highlight that trade integration is higher among Latin American countries participating to regional agreements. However, the regional point of view highlights a more pronounced integration in East Asia (5.9), with more recent and less regional trade agreements, compared to Latin America, including the United States and Canada (5.0). 22 Table 5: Matrix of East Asian Trade in All Goods, 2005 Exporting Country Hong Partner (Importer) Cambodia China Kong Indonesia Japan Korea Malaysia Philippines Singapore Taiwan Thailand Vietnam ASEAN NE Asia E Asia-12 Export Value in All Goods ($ million) Cambodia 0 536 497 94 78 144 109 8 303 331 915 556 1,985 1,586 3,571 China 13 0 130,426 6,662 80,074 61,915 9,302 4,077 19,757 40,879 9,134 3,246 52,192 313,294 365,486 Hong Kong, China 616 124,473 0 1,492 35,960 15,531 8,242 3,341 21,522 30,721 6,128 353 41,694 206,685 248,379 Indonesia 2 8,350 1,265 0 9,214 5,046 3,322 476 22,103 2,336 3,960 469 30,332 26,211 56,543 Japan 25 83,986 15,304 18,049 0 24,027 13,184 7,206 12,532 14,481 15,029 4,340 70,366 137,798 208,164 Korea, Rep. 25 35,108 6,540 7,086 46,630 0 4,739 1,391 8,052 5,575 2,250 664 24,207 93,852 118,060 Malaysia 9 10,606 2,419 3,431 12,531 4,608 0 2,459 30,385 4,154 5,685 1,028 42,998 34,319 77,316 Philippines 2 4,688 2,635 1,419 9,057 3,220 1,974 0 4,184 4,220 2,050 829 10,459 23,820 34,279 Singapore 10 16,632 6,046 7,837 18,436 7,407 22,009 2,707 0 7,656 7,459 1,917 41,939 56,177 98,116 Taiwan, China 4 16,550 6,769 2,475 43,578 10,863 3,912 1,888 8,976 0 2,694 935 20,884 77,760 98,644 Thailand 17 7,819 3,001 2,246 22,451 3,381 7,586 1,169 9,402 3,718 0 863 21,284 40,370 61,654 Vietnam 42 5,644 1,308 678 3,592 3,432 1,160 312 4,421 4,057 2,357 0 8,971 18,032 27,003 ASEAN 83 54,276 17,170 15,706 75,359 27,237 36,162 7,131 70,798 26,472 22,426 5,662 157,968 200,514 358,482 NE Asia 682 260,117 159,039 35,764 206,243 112,336 39,380 17,903 70,839 91,655 35,235 9,538 209,343 829,390 1,038,733 East Asia (12) 765 314,393 176,209 51,470 281,602 139,573 75,542 25,034 141,637 118,127 57,662 15,200 367,310 1,029,904 1,397,214 EU (27) 593 145,613 42,942 10,347 87,819 44,354 16,614 7,014 27,907 22,124 15,019 5,547 83,041 342,851 425,892 LAC (13) 1,410 192,173 53,088 11,478 158,201 54,543 29,879 7,961 26,411 33,272 19,702 6,601 103,442 491,277 594,719 World 2,798 761,953 292,119 85,660 594,941 284,418 140,963 41,255 229,652 189,393 110,110 32,447 642,885 2,122,824 2,765,709 Share of Intra-Regional Trade in All Goods from Importer (%) Cambodia 0 15.0 13.9 2.6 2.2 4.0 3.1 0.2 8.5 9.3 25.6 15.6 55.6 44.4 100.0 China 0.0 0 35.7 1.8 21.9 16.9 2.5 1.1 5.4 11.2 2.5 0.9 14.3 85.7 100.0 Hong Kong, China 0.2 50.1 0 0.6 14.5 6.3 3.3 1.3 8.7 12.4 2.5 0.1 16.8 83.2 100.0 Indonesia 0.0 14.8 2.2 0 16.3 8.9 5.9 0.8 39.1 4.1 7.0 0.8 53.6 46.4 100.0 Japan 0.0 40.3 7.4 8.7 0 11.5 6.3 3.5 6.0 7.0 7.2 2.1 33.8 66.2 100.0 Korea, Rep. 0.0 29.7 5.5 6.0 39.5 0 4.0 1.2 6.8 4.7 1.9 0.6 20.5 79.5 100.0 Malaysia 0.0 13.7 3.1 4.4 16.2 6.0 0 3.2 39.3 5.4 7.4 1.3 55.6 44.4 100.0 Philippines 0.0 13.7 7.7 4.1 26.4 9.4 5.8 0 12.2 12.3 6.0 2.4 30.5 69.5 100.0 Singapore 0.0 17.0 6.2 8.0 18.8 7.5 22.4 2.8 0 7.8 7.6 2.0 42.7 57.3 100.0 Taiwan, China 0.0 16.8 6.9 2.5 44.2 11.0 4.0 1.9 9.1 0 2.7 0.9 21.2 78.8 100.0 Thailand 0.0 12.7 4.9 3.6 36.4 5.5 12.3 1.9 15.3 6.0 0 1.4 34.5 65.5 100.0 Vietnam 0.2 20.9 4.8 2.5 13.3 12.7 4.3 1.2 16.4 15.0 8.7 0 33.2 66.8 100.0 ASEAN 0.0 15.1 4.8 4.4 21.0 7.6 10.1 2.0 19.7 7.4 6.3 1.6 44.1 55.9 100.0 NE Asia 0.1 25.0 15.3 3.4 19.9 10.8 3.8 1.7 6.8 8.8 3.4 0.9 20.2 79.8 100.0 East Asia (12) 0.1 22.5 12.6 3.7 20.2 10.0 5.4 1.8 10.1 8.5 4.1 1.1 26.3 73.7 100.0 EU (27) 0.1 34.2 10.1 2.4 20.6 10.4 3.9 1.6 6.6 5.2 3.5 1.3 19.5 80.5 100.0 LAC (13) 0.2 32.3 8.9 1.9 26.6 9.2 5.0 1.3 4.4 5.6 3.3 1.1 17.4 82.6 100.0 World 0.1 27.6 10.6 3.1 21.5 10.3 5.1 1.5 8.3 6.8 4.0 1.2 23.2 76.8 100.0 23 Cont. Table 5 Hong Partner (Importer) Cambodia China Kong Indonesia Japan Korea Malaysia Philippines Singapore Taiwan Thailand Vietnam ASEAN NE Asia E Asia-12 Trade Balance in All Goods ($ million) Cambodia 0 509 488 93 -27 138 101 6 203 326 883 395 1,682 1,434 3,115 China -328 0 -4,540 819 -28,403 23,267 -3,871 943 -759 20,951 -2,024 -2,653 -7,873 11,275 3,402 Hong Kong, China 206 112,248 0 1,201 34,389 13,488 5,390 1,319 17,314 28,834 4,626 -882 29,175 188,960 218,134 Indonesia -77 -87 -659 0 -11,603 -3,139 -1,052 -616 11,656 -2,202 832 -231 10,510 -17,689 -7,179 Japan -59 -16,421 -17,732 11,143 0 -24,376 -3,450 -1,258 -6,702 -31,460 -11,020 266 -11,079 -89,988 -101,068 Korea, Rep. -74 -41,713 -6,723 4,217 22,215 0 -946 -995 -548 -7,629 -1,622 -2,930 -2,899 -33,849 -36,748 Malaysia -68 -9,487 -4,935 1,283 -2,138 -1,403 0 608 3,050 -1,039 -2,404 -228 2,242 -19,003 -16,761 Philippines -2 -8,182 -2,506 1,097 1,357 904 -1,246 0 -464 1,435 168 619 172 -6,992 -6,820 Singapore -132 118 -11,374 -1,634 11,741 2,089 8,594 -1,158 0 2,716 2,078 -2,565 5,183 5,289 10,473 Taiwan, China -239 -58,131 -14,874 1,134 25,514 2,813 -2,419 -1,754 -4,347 0 -1,808 -3,369 -12,802 -44,677 -57,479 Thailand -214 -6,173 -3,049 -1,201 6,893 692 1,544 -510 1,888 851 0 -1,511 -3 -786 -790 Vietnam -126 3,091 809 239 -952 2,738 139 -523 2,604 3,368 1,464 0 3,798 9,053 12,851 ASEAN -620 -20,211 -21,227 -122 5,271 2,018 8,080 -2,192 18,937 5,454 3,022 -3,521 23,584 -28,695 -5,111 NE Asia -495 -4,016 -43,869 18,514 53,715 15,193 -5,296 -1,744 4,959 10,697 -11,848 -9,569 -5,479 31,720 26,241 East Asia (12) -1,114 -79,390 -65,096 18,102 58,986 17,211 1,768 -3,936 23,896 16,151 -10,195 -13,090 15,431 -52,138 -36,707 EU (27) 492 71,641 20,169 4,488 28,976 16,940 3,260 3,121 4,612 4,599 4,211 2,950 23,135 142,325 165,460 LAC (13) 1,384 110,889 34,689 5,809 69,776 14,849 13,045 -2,280 552 7,622 8,528 5,082 32,121 237,825 269,946 World 735 102,001 -8,042 27,959 79,074 23,183 26,379 -8,233 29,602 7,801 -8,054 -4,314 64,074 204,017 268,092 Trade Intensity Index of Exports in All Goods Cambodia 0 1.8 4.3 2.8 0.3 1.3 2.0 0.5 3.4 4.5 21.2 43.8 7.9 1.9 3.3 China 0.1 0 8.2 1.4 2.5 4.0 1.2 1.8 1.6 3.9 1.5 1.8 1.5 2.7 2.4 Hong Kong, China 7.1 5.3 0 0.6 2.0 1.8 1.9 2.6 3.0 5.3 1.8 0.4 2.1 3.2 2.9 Indonesia 0.1 1.5 0.6 0 2.1 2.4 3.2 1.6 13.1 1.7 4.9 2.0 6.4 1.7 2.8 Japan 0.2 2.7 1.3 5.1 0 2.1 2.3 4.3 1.3 1.9 3.3 3.3 2.7 1.6 1.8 Korea, Rep. 0.4 2.3 1.1 4.1 3.9 0 1.7 1.7 1.7 1.5 1.0 1.0 1.9 2.2 2.1 Malaysia 0.3 1.3 0.8 3.8 2.0 1.5 0 5.6 12.5 2.1 4.9 3.0 6.3 1.5 2.6 Philippines 0.2 1.2 1.8 3.4 3.1 2.3 2.8 0 3.7 4.5 3.8 5.2 3.3 2.3 2.5 Singapore 0.2 1.4 1.3 5.8 2.0 1.6 9.9 4.1 0 2.6 4.3 3.7 4.1 1.7 2.2 Taiwan, China 0.0 0.8 0.8 1.0 2.6 1.4 1.0 1.6 1.4 0 0.9 1.0 1.2 1.3 1.3 Thailand 0.7 1.1 1.1 2.9 4.2 1.3 6.0 3.2 4.6 2.2 0 3.0 3.7 2.1 2.5 Vietnam 4.5 2.2 1.3 2.4 1.8 3.6 2.4 2.2 5.7 6.4 6.4 0 4.1 2.5 2.9 ASEAN 0.9 2.1 1.7 5.4 3.7 2.8 7.5 5.1 9.1 4.1 6.0 5.1 7.2 2.8 3.8 NE Asia 3.9 5.5 8.8 6.7 5.6 6.4 4.5 7.0 5.0 7.8 5.2 4.7 5.3 6.3 6.1 East Asia (12) 3.2 4.8 7.0 7.0 5.5 5.7 6.2 7.1 7.2 7.3 6.1 5.5 6.6 5.6 5.9 EU (27) 1.7 1.6 1.2 1.0 1.2 1.3 1.0 1.4 1.0 1.0 1.1 1.4 1.1 1.3 1.3 LAC (13) 4.4 2.2 1.6 1.2 2.3 1.7 1.8 1.7 1.0 1.5 1.5 1.8 1.4 2.0 1.9 Notes: EU(27) includes European Union 25 members plus new members of Bulgaria and Romania. LAC(13) includes LAIA(11) countries plus Canada and United States. Source: Computations based on UN COMTRADE Statistics. 24 Table 6: Matrix of Latin American Trade in All Goods, 2005 Exporting Country Partner (Importer) Argentina Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Ecuador Mexico Paraguay Peru Uruguay Venezuela Canada USA ANDEAN Mercosur LAIA(11) NAFTA LAC(13) Export Value in All Goods ($ million) Argentina 0 264 9,912 626 47 42 672 102 54 267 18 144 4,100 425 10,281 12,004 4,916 16,248 Bolivia 380 0 579 211 50 8 37 22 155 5 5 13 218 218 985 1,451 268 1,683 Brazil 6,328 1,016 0 1,729 141 89 890 312 453 458 187 912 15,345 1,887 7,099 11,605 17,147 27,862 Chile 4,497 41 3,611 0 296 301 668 30 1,129 83 103 340 5,198 1,871 8,221 10,759 6,206 16,297 Colombia 361 179 1,405 347 0 471 1,548 2 347 14 1,013 369 5,415 2,010 1,780 5,686 7,333 11,470 Ecuador 265 3 644 341 1,324 0 309 7 295 10 296 132 1,979 1,919 926 3,495 2,420 5,606 Mexico 1,158 20 4,062 1,582 611 58 0 5 332 139 470 2,690 120,048 1,491 5,363 8,436 122,738 131,174 Paraguay 509 22 960 40 2 1 14 0 0 56 4 8 896 29 1,525 1,609 918 2,512 Peru 599 126 932 725 710 869 345 20 0 37 151 218 2,289 1,856 1,588 4,514 2,853 7,021 Uruguay 862 2 848 72 7 3 66 451 7 0 1 20 354 20 2,161 2,318 439 2,692 Venezuela 510 159 2,214 359 2,098 122 1,289 9 299 33 0 567 6,408 2,677 2,767 7,091 8,264 14,066 USA+Canada 4,865 428 24,657 7,317 9,150 5,001 188,072 58 6,279 876 24,645 302,204 211,417 45,503 30,457 271,350 701,693 784,971 ANDEAN 2,114 466 5,773 1,983 4,182 1,470 3,528 60 1,095 99 1,466 1,300 16,310 8,680 8,046 22,237 21,138 39,847 MERCOSUR 7,699 1,305 11,720 2,467 197 135 1,642 865 514 781 211 1,084 20,695 2,361 21,066 27,536 23,421 49,314 LAIA (11) 15,467 1,832 25,166 6,032 5,286 1,964 5,838 960 3,070 1,103 2,249 5,414 162,250 14,402 42,696 68,967 173,503 236,632 NAFTA 6,023 448 28,719 8,899 9,761 5,059 188,072 63 6,611 1,015 25,115 304,894 331,465 46,994 35,820 279,786 824,431 916,145 LAC (13) 20,333 2,260 49,823 13,349 14,436 6,965 193,910 1,018 9,349 1,979 26,894 307,618 373,667 59,905 73,153 340,317 875,196 1,021,602 World 40,106 2,797 116,129 38,596 21,190 9,869 214,207 1,626 17,114 3,405 55,487 360,136 904,339 106,459 161,265 520,527 1,478,683 1,785,002 Share of Intra-Regional Trade in All Goods from Importer (%) Argentina 0 1.6 61.0 3.9 0.3 0.3 4.1 0.6 0.3 1.6 0.1 0.9 25.2 2.6 63.3 73.9 30.3 100.0 Bolivia 22.6 0 34.4 12.5 3.0 0.5 2.2 1.3 9.2 0.3 0.3 0.8 13.0 13.0 58.6 86.2 16.0 100.0 Brazil 22.7 3.6 0 6.2 0.5 0.3 3.2 1.1 1.6 1.6 0.7 3.3 55.1 6.8 25.5 41.7 61.5 100.0 Chile 27.6 0.3 22.2 0 1.8 1.8 4.1 0.2 6.9 0.5 0.6 2.1 31.9 11.5 50.4 66.0 38.1 100.0 Colombia 3.1 1.6 12.2 3.0 0 4.1 13.5 0.0 3.0 0.1 8.8 3.2 47.2 17.5 15.5 49.6 63.9 100.0 Ecuador 4.7 0.1 11.5 6.1 23.6 0 5.5 0.1 5.3 0.2 5.3 2.4 35.3 34.2 16.5 62.3 43.2 100.0 Mexico 0.9 0.0 3.1 1.2 0.5 0.0 0 0.0 0.3 0.1 0.4 2.1 91.5 1.1 4.1 6.4 93.6 100.0 Paraguay 20.3 0.9 38.2 1.6 0.1 0.0 0.6 0 0.0 2.2 0.2 0.3 35.6 1.2 60.7 64.0 36.5 100.0 Peru 8.5 1.8 13.3 10.3 10.1 12.4 4.9 0.3 0 0.5 2.2 3.1 32.6 26.4 22.6 64.3 40.6 100.0 Uruguay 32.0 0.1 31.5 2.7 0.3 0.1 2.4 16.8 0.2 0 0.1 0.7 13.1 0.7 80.3 86.1 16.3 100.0 Venezuela 3.6 1.1 15.7 2.5 14.9 0.9 9.2 0.1 2.1 0.2 0 4.0 45.6 19.0 19.7 50.4 58.8 100.0 USA+Canada 0.6 0.1 3.1 0.9 1.2 0.6 24.0 0.0 0.8 0.1 3.1 38.5 26.9 5.8 3.9 34.6 89.4 100.0 ANDEAN 5.3 1.2 14.5 5.0 10.5 3.7 8.9 0.2 2.7 0.2 3.7 3.3 40.9 21.8 20.2 55.8 53.0 100.0 MERCOSUR 15.6 2.6 23.8 5.0 0.4 0.3 3.3 1.8 1.0 1.6 0.4 2.2 42.0 4.8 42.7 55.8 47.5 100.0 LAIA (11) 6.5 0.8 10.6 2.5 2.2 0.8 2.5 0.4 1.3 0.5 1.0 2.3 68.6 6.1 18.0 29.1 73.3 100.0 NAFTA 0.7 0.0 3.1 1.0 1.1 0.6 20.5 0.0 0.7 0.1 2.7 33.3 36.2 5.1 3.9 30.5 90.0 100.0 LAC (13) 2.0 0.2 4.9 1.3 1.4 0.7 19.0 0.1 0.9 0.2 2.6 30.1 36.6 5.9 7.2 33.3 85.7 100.0 World 2.2 0.2 6.5 2.2 1.2 0.6 12.0 0.1 1.0 0.2 3.1 20.2 50.7 6.0 9.0 29.2 82.8 100.0 25 Cont. Table 6 Partner (Importer) Argentina Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Ecuador Mexico Paraguay Peru Uruguay Venezuela Canada USA ANDEAN Mercosur LAIA(11) NAFTA LAC(13) Trade Balance in All Goods ($ million) Argentina 0 -127 3,324 -4,178 -364 -304 -631 -560 -671 -519 -386 -230 -472 -1,852 2,245 -4,416 -1,332 -5,118 Bolivia 80 0 -593 173 -142 5 7 12 47 3 -205 -7 -75 -295 -497 -612 -75 -695 Brazil -4,297 503 0 -2,069 -1,242 -596 -4,324 -547 -575 -366 -1,808 -1,685 -9,091 -3,718 -5,211 -15,321 -15,100 -26,097 Chile 3,825 -122 1,838 0 -81 -109 -1,086 -9 514 14 -226 -1,033 -1,467 -24 5,668 4,558 -3,587 2,058 Colombia 304 121 1,253 3 0 -912 873 -1 -426 12 -1,384 -112 -3,431 -2,601 1,568 -157 -2,669 -3,700 Ecuador 202 -9 548 70 795 0 203 7 -619 8 141 37 -3,780 308 764 1,346 -3,539 -2,397 Mexico 419 -31 3,185 820 -1,146 -245 0 -12 -32 89 -1,074 -9,357 -50,146 -2,528 3,681 1,973 -59,502 -57,530 Paraguay 54 -1 631 -77 -9 -4 5 0 -82 36 -31 -4 844 -126 720 523 845 1,363 Peru 545 -26 456 -382 360 504 -100 19 0 32 -108 -903 -2,831 730 1,051 1,299 -3,835 -2,436 Uruguay 303 -4 338 -29 -21 -49 -197 388 -40 0 -45 -88 -378 -158 1,030 645 -664 179 Venezuela 474 120 1,925 223 878 -328 505 1 -230 -211 0 -943 -27,556 440 2,188 3,356 -27,994 -25,143 USA+Canada 247 87 10,131 2,203 2,727 3,041 62,930 -58 3,849 594 17,509 121,607 -76,375 27,212 10,914 103,258 108,161 148,490 ANDEAN 1,605 205 3,589 86 1,892 -731 1,488 37 -1,229 -157 -1,556 -1,928 -37,673 -1,418 5,074 5,231 -38,112 -34,370 MERCOSUR -3,940 372 4,293 -6,353 -1,636 -954 -5,147 -719 -1,367 -850 -2,269 -2,007 -9,097 -5,854 -1,216 -18,570 -16,251 -29,674 LAIA (11) 1,910 425 12,905 -5,446 -971 -2,038 -4,745 -703 -2,114 -905 -5,126 -14,324 -98,383 -9,825 13,207 -6,808 -117,453 -119,516 - NAFTA 666 56 13,316 3,023 1,581 2,795 62,930 -71 3,817 682 16,435 112,250 126,521 24,684 14,594 105,231 48,659 90,960 - LAC (13) 2,157 511 23,037 -3,243 1,756 1,002 58,185 -762 1,735 -311 12,383 107,282 174,758 17,387 24,121 96,450 -9,291 28,973 - World 11,418 454 39,693 8,738 -14 261 -7,612 -1,472 4,612 -474 33,639 45,700 766,390 38,952 49,165 89,244 -728,301 -631,446 Trade Intensity Index of Exports in All Goods Argentina -- 37.0 33.4 6.4 0.9 1.7 1.2 24.5 1.2 30.7 0.1 0.2 1.8 1.6 25.0 9.0 1.3 3.6 Bolivia 46.2 -- 24.3 26.6 11.5 4.0 0.8 67.3 44.2 6.6 0.5 0.2 1.2 10.0 29.8 13.6 0.9 4.6 Brazil 22.4 51.6 -- 6.4 0.9 1.3 0.6 27.3 3.8 19.1 0.5 0.4 2.4 2.5 6.2 3.2 1.6 2.2 Chile 41.0 5.3 11.4 -- 5.1 11.2 1.1 6.6 24.1 8.9 0.7 0.3 2.1 6.4 18.6 7.6 1.5 3.3 Colombia 4.8 34.2 6.5 4.8 -- 25.6 3.9 0.5 10.8 2.1 9.8 0.5 3.2 10.1 5.9 5.8 2.7 3.4 Ecuador 7.7 1.3 6.5 10.4 73.4 -- 1.7 5.1 20.3 3.6 6.3 0.4 2.6 21.2 6.7 7.9 1.9 3.7 Mexico 1.6 0.4 2.0 2.3 1.6 0.3 -- 0.2 1.1 2.3 0.5 0.4 7.5 0.8 1.9 0.9 4.7 4.1 Paraguay 38.1 23.8 24.8 3.1 0.3 0.2 0.2 -- 0.1 49.3 0.2 0.1 3.0 0.8 28.4 9.3 1.9 4.2 Peru 14.4 43.3 7.7 18.0 32.2 84.6 1.5 11.7 -- 10.5 2.6 0.6 2.4 16.8 9.5 8.3 1.9 3.8 Uruguay 50.8 1.4 17.3 4.4 0.8 0.8 0.7 656.0 0.9 -- 0.1 0.1 0.9 0.4 31.7 10.5 0.7 3.6 Venezuela 6.1 27.0 9.1 4.4 47.2 5.9 2.9 2.7 8.3 4.7 -- 0.8 3.4 12.0 8.2 6.5 2.7 3.8 USA+Canada 0.9 1.2 1.6 1.5 3.3 3.9 6.8 0.3 2.8 2.0 3.4 6.5 1.8 3.3 1.5 4.0 3.7 3.4 ANDEAN 8.7 27.5 8.2 8.5 32.6 24.6 2.7 6.1 10.6 4.8 4.4 0.6 3.0 13.5 8.2 7.0 2.4 3.7 MERCOSUR 18.5 45.1 9.7 6.2 0.9 1.3 0.7 51.4 2.9 22.2 0.4 0.3 2.2 2.1 12.6 5.1 1.5 2.7 LAIA (11) 10.4 17.7 5.9 4.2 6.8 5.4 0.7 16.0 4.9 8.8 1.1 0.4 4.9 3.7 7.2 3.6 3.2 3.6 NAFTA 1.3 1.4 2.1 2.0 4.0 4.4 7.6 0.3 3.3 2.6 3.9 7.3 3.2 3.8 1.9 4.6 4.8 4.4 LAC (13) 4.4 7.0 3.7 3.0 5.9 6.1 7.8 5.4 4.7 5.0 4.2 7.4 3.6 4.9 3.9 5.7 5.1 5.0 Source: Computations based on COMTRADE Statistics. 26 Yet another way to examine the characteristics of recent regional trade agreements is to note that one of the important motives of the so-called "New Regionalism", particularly for smaller economies, is to design rules to attract more foreign direct investment and to strengthen institutions in order to participate in global and regional production sharing (Ethier 1998, Salazar-Xirinachs 2005). Thus one way to evaluate the performance of FTAs of East Asian and Latin American countries is to examine the competitiveness of East Asian and Latin American countries in items such as components and parts, using the revealed comparative advantage (RCA) index. The index is defined as: X jk X RCA = k jk X wj X w where j indicates the product value and k home country. Xjk and Xwk represent the product value of j exported by country k and the world; Xk and Xw are total exports of j by country k and the world. If the index has a value greater than one, country k has a comparative advantage in the production of product j. If the index has a value smaller than one, the industry of the country has a comparative disadvantage. Suppose we go further and differentiate the RCA index for exports from that for imports. When the RCA index is greater than 1 for exports of components and parts,8 we can reasonably argue that the economy has a comparative advantage in "processing". When the RCA index is greater than 1 for imports, we say that the economy has comparative advantage in "assembly". The RCA indices for East Asian and Latin American imports and exports of parts and components for various years are shown in Table 7 and Table 8. 8The list of products that are classified as components and parts is available upon request. The list is compiled from the UN COMTRADE statistics by the authors. 27 Table 7: The Percentage of Parts and Components Products with Comparative Advantage in East Asian Countries Exports - Production Operations Imports - Assembly Operations ( % of Products with RCA > 1) ( % of Products with RCA > 1) Country 1985 1995 2005 1985 1995 2005 Cambodia .. .. 2.7 .. .. 6.7 China 12.0 20.0 30.7 40.0 44.0 34.7 Hong Kong, China 25.3 22.7 33.3 41.3 44.0 36.0 Indonesia 0.0 8.0 9.3 58.7 50.7 42.7 Japan 40.0 46.7 42.7 6.7 8.0 16.0 Korea Rep. 10.7 16.0 26.7 28.0 37.3 21.3 Malaysia 8.0 13.3 20.0 52.0 36.0 37.3 Philippines 5.3 4.0 17.3 34.7 36.0 25.3 Singapore 18.7 20.0 34.7 36.0 41.3 41.3 Taiwan, China 34.7 22.7 34.7 40.0 44.0 21.3 Thailand 10.7 20.0 24.0 33.3 41.3 29.3 Vietnam .. 1.3 12.0 .. 4.0 25.3 Average ASEAN 8.5 11.1 17.1 42.9 34.9 29.7 Average NE Asia 24.5 25.6 33.6 31.2 35.5 25.9 Average above all East Asia 16.5 17.7 24.0 37.1 35.2 28.1 Average above excluding Japan 13.9 14.8 22.3 40.4 37.9 29.2 Memo Items: Comparators Canada 17.3 20.0 24.0 76.0 52.0 53.3 United States 61.3 64.0 54.7 37.3 38.7 33.3 Germany 70.7 65.3 62.7 45.3 36.0 50.7 Mexico 12.0 22.7 29.3 66.7 41.3 38.7 Notes: Percentages based on the 75 products of parts and components from textiles & clothing and machinery & equipment at SITC 4/5-digit level in Revision 2. Due to the missing data, the 1995 data for Vietnam is replaced by 1997. Source: Computations based on UN COMTRADE Statistics. From Table 7, it is clear that East Asian revealed comparative advantage in processed exports of components and parts has been gaining over the years, starting way back from 1985. The percentage of products that the East Asian economies have comparative advantage in assembly has declined over time. The results for Latin America are given in Table 8. 28 Table 8: The Percentage of Parts and Components Products with Comparative Advantage in Latin American Countries Exports - Production Operations Imports - Assembly Operations ( % of Products with RCA > 1) ( % of Products with RCA > 1) Country 1985 1995 2005 1985 1995 2005 Argentina 1.3 9.3 10.7 32.0 36.0 38.7 Bolivia 0.0 0.0 2.7 44.0 22.7 24.0 Brazil 6.7 14.7 18.7 28.0 34.7 49.3 Chile 1.3 0.0 0.0 40.0 33.3 26.7 Colombia 4.0 4.0 4.0 30.7 34.7 32.0 Ecuador 0.0 1.3 0.0 45.3 34.7 25.3 Mexico 17.3 22.7 29.3 62.7 41.3 38.7 Paraguay 0.0 0.0 1.3 29.3 17.3 13.3 Peru 2.7 1.3 1.3 48.0 34.7 33.3 Uruguay 4.0 4.0 5.3 14.7 26.7 22.7 Venezuela 0.0 0.0 0.0 57.3 37.3 36.0 United States 61.3 64.0 54.7 37.3 38.7 33.3 Canada 17.3 20.0 24.0 76.0 52.0 53.3 Average ANDEAN 1.3 1.3 1.6 45.1 32.8 30.1 Average MERCOSUR 3.0 7.0 9.0 26.0 28.7 31.0 Average above Latin America (LAIA) 3.4 5.2 6.7 39.3 32.1 30.9 Average LAIA excluding Mexico 2.0 3.5 4.4 36.9 31.2 30.1 Average NAFTA 32.0 35.6 36.0 58.7 44.0 41.8 Average above all countries (LAC) 8.9 10.9 11.7 41.9 34.2 32.8 Memo Items: Comparators China 12.0 20.0 30.7 40.0 44.0 34.7 Korea Rep. 10.7 16.0 26.7 28.0 37.3 21.3 Malaysia 8.0 13.3 20.0 52.0 36.0 37.3 East Asia (12) average 16.5 17.7 24.0 37.1 35.2 28.1 Notes: Percentages based on the 75 products of parts and components from textiles & clothing and machinery & equipment at SITC 4/5-digit level in Revision 2. Due to the missing data, the 1985 data for Mexico is used 1986. Source: Computations based on UN COMTRADE Statistics. 29 Except for Mexico and, in a lesser extent, Brazil, that show a rising comparative advantage in processing, other Latin American economies have not shown significant increases in the percentage of components and parts that they have comparative advantage. Our result from this section is as follows: East Asia has more intense integration with itself compared to the case of Latin America. East Asia also has a growing comparative advantage in the processing of exports of components and parts. Notwithstanding the recent regionalism in East Asia and the absence of a regional trade arrangement for the whole region, intra-regional-trade has expanded rapidly and has been deeper compared to Latin America. 4. A Simple Bargaining Analysis of the Implementation of Regional Trade Agreements In our discussions of East Asian regional as well as Latin American regional agreements, it is clear that trade policies as well as regional trade agreements often serve at least two purposes. One on hand, trade and trade agreements are about promoting economic growth and development. This objective is thus economic. One the other hand, trade agreements are often done with foreign policy goals in mind. For example, analysts often point out that both Japan and China are jockeying for positions of political and diplomatic influence when they attempt to form bilateral trade deals in Asia, including their interest in ASEAN. Similarly, Brazil is often seen to be using their position in MERCUSOR to thwart the power of the United States in Latin America (Jose M. Salazar-Xirinachs 2005). Indeed, in most countries, trade policy formulations and implementations include representatives of foreign policy interests (Barfield 2005). Furthermore, within economic interests, as we can see from our discussion of the early form of trade agreements in Latin America, some trade agreements are inward-looking, while others are outward-oriented. Thus implementations of regional trade agreements will depend on the internal bargaining of various objectives. Suppose we take the example of how trade policies are implemented in a particular East Asian country, say Japan. Japan's trade policy formulation and implementation are the 30 responsibilities are several Ministries, in particular, The Ministry of Foreign Affairs (MOFA) and The Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry (METI), with the overall coordination responsibility being shouldered by the Cabinet (WTO 2007). When the WTO was established, Japan was not a member of any of the then existing 62 formal regional trade agreements (Sapir 1998, Mavroidis 2005). Japan now has several formal bilateral trade agreements, including agreements with Singapore, Mexico and Malaysia. According to Aoki (1988), policy implementation and formulation (including trade policies) in Japan can be seen as a bargaining of the various Ministries. Furthermore, certain bureaus of each Ministry (genkyoku) maintain contact with their constituents and the Ministry can be understood to be maximizing a weighted sum of the interests of its constituents as well as the national interest. The argument for this view is that when the bureaucrats from each Ministry retire, they often will "descend from the heaven" (amakudari) and obtain high positions in the private sector, usually in the constituents' industries. While this aspect of industry-government linkage has been weakened in recent years, nonetheless it still exists and is a strong reason for the Ministries to pay attention to the interests of their constituents. At the same time, each Ministry cannot stray too often and too far from the national interest or it risks the loss of reputation within the government and among the public. Generally MOFA can be viewed as paying particular attention to the diplomatic and security interests of Japan, while METI is viewed as paying special attention to the economic and international trade interests of the country. The implicit bargaining of these two Ministries, together with the participation and coordination of other government entities, will decide how trade policies and regional trade agreements will be implemented. To simplify our analysis, suppose trade policy formulation is represented in a model of generalized Nash bargaining game. The policymaker is the Nashian arbitrator maximizing a weighted sum of the economic and foreign policy interests (the interests of MOFA and METI, respectively). We further assume for simplicity the overall national interests can be subsumed within the economic and the foreign policy objectives. Then we can write down the maximization of the national objective N of a country, say Japan, is: Max N= (E-E0) a (F-F0)b t 31 where N is the national objective, E represents the economic interest, F is the foreign policy goal, a is the bargaining power of the economic interest (as ultimately represented in the implementation of the regional trade agreement by economic agents such as traders, exporters, retailers which import cheaper import goods, etc), and b is the bargaining power of the foreign policy establishments. E0 and F0 are the respective threat points of the economic and foreign policy interests. There may be a formally agreed (via a de jure trade treaty) trade instrument T, but the effective trade policy to be implemented in each country is actually t, the policy instrument to be bargained by various groups within each country. This can be something transparent such as foreign investment policy or a more opaque instrument such as a trade facilitation policy (custom procedure, technical standards, etc.). We can further assume that within the economic interests, the interests of trade agreement implementations can be divided into two camps: the interests of the inward- looking group M and the interests of the outward-looking group X. The three parties form the negotiated national objective function of: N = (M- M0) am(X- X0)ax (F-F0 )b where M0 and X0 are the respective threat points for the inward-looking group and the outward-looking group. For example, in the earlier periods, when Japan's METI was Ministry of International Trade and Industry (MITI), the powerful agency that was focused on industrial policy implementations, the outward-looking economic interests can be interpreted as the interests of the exporters, while the inward-looking economic interests represent the constituents who wanted to restrict imports and restrict inward direct investment (Noland and Pack 2003). All the interests of the parties are related to the effectively implemented trade policy instrument t. It is assumed that M increases with an increase in t (i.e. the interests of the inward-looking group rise with a rise in protection). X decreases with a rise in protection, while F can vary for a country located in different regions at different periods. In East Asia, foreign policy interests tend to be more pro-trade, so there is a sense that F rises with a lower t. In other cases, a component of foreign policy may be to go against open trade, particularly U.S.-led regional trade agreements. In that case, F rises with an increase in protection, at least for some range of t. 32 In essence, we assume that if there is a formal regional trade contract which establishes the formal trade policy instrument T, it is an incomplete contract. An incomplete trade contract is one where it cannot specify all contingencies. Regional trade dispute settlement can help, but even there the process is slow and can be inconsistent. Thus national governments have the leeway to implement trade instruments to various degrees of openness. In effect, we assume that the implemented trade policy, t, can be higher or lower. The implementation process is decided by internal bargaining of various groups within the country. As is well-known the generalized Nash bargaining formulation can be mathematically derived from a more detailed bargaining process (Binmore, Rubinstein and Wolinsky 1986). The bargaining power of each party depends on how patient the party is able to be while waiting out an impasse, how averse the party is to the risk of a collapse of an agreement and what alternative is available to the party in the event that the bargaining breaks down. Given that East Asia already has a deep degree of trade integration via the market, we can argue that the bargaining power of the outward-oriented group is high. Furthermore, given that the foreign policy establishments in East Asia tend to be pro-exports (as e.g. under MOFA), an active role played by the foreign policy interests will tend to coincide with the outward-oriented interests. Assuming that we have an unique maximum for N and that t* solves the maximization, we have dN/dt=0 or arg max N = t* Furthermore, we have dt*/d(am) >0, dt*/d (ax) <0. For an East Asian economy where foreign interests generally are pro-trade, dt*/db<0. For a country whose foreign policy interests are anti-trade, we have dt*/db>0. In internal deliberations concerning how the trade agreement should be implemented, the various parties attempt to reach an agreement. These three sets of interests may go against each other and the internal equilibrium may break down. The threat points and the bargaining power of each party will determine which direction the implementation of the regional trade agreement may go.9 For example, it may be to the nation's outward-oriented economic advantage to be welcoming foreign direct investment. However to the inward-looking group and to some foreign policy analysts, this may represent a loss of influence and sovereignty. 9For an application to trade negotiations, see Fung, Iizaka, Lin and Ng (2004). 33 Even for the case of Japan, liberalization of inward foreign direct investment is effectively a relatively recent event (Noland and Pack 2003). If the economy is already fairly integrated with other regional trading partners via the market first, there is a thick group of outward-looking economic interests (such as exporters, traders, shippers, etc) that may raise the bargaining power of the outward-looking open-trade economic constituency (an increase in ax). This will tilt the implementation of the trade agreement in favor of pursuing further liberalization in response to the correct market signal. If however, there is only limited market integration and the inward-looking and certain types of foreign policy interests dominate (an increase in am and an increase in b of the protectionist foreign policy interests), then the regional agreement will in actually not be implemented for economic integration. Instead it will be used mainly as a tool for import- substitution and nationalistic foreign policy objectives. This simple analysis can thus be used to highlight why developing first a network of traders and exporters may help generate a more outward-looking economically friendly outcome.10 This may help explain why by integrating via markets and by pursuing policies that are generally business-friendly and foreign direct investment-friendly (even though formal regional trade agreements had been absent), East and Southeast Asia has been able to generate a deeper degree of regional integration in practice. Our result from this section can be summarized as: Integrating via the markets first and engaging in formal trade agreements later seem to be the better economic and trade policy sequence. One reason this is the case is because this sequence can enhance the internal bargaining power of the outward-looking trade interests first, which may tilt the implementation of the formal regional trade agreement to be more market-friendly. 10A much more familiar argument for having a formal trade agreement when there is already substantially a lot of trade is that this is less likely to generate trade diversion. For details, see e.g. Winters (1999). 34 5. Conclusion In this paper, we examine the two channels of regional integration: integration of markets vs. integration by agreements. Since East Asia and Latin America are two regions where preferential trade agreements have proliferated in recent years, we utilize the experiences of these two areas to illustrate our results. We have four related results in this paper. First, East Asia started their integration by primarily using the markets, then by the 1990s, the region started to turn to more formal agreements. Complementary policies in the drive for integration via the markets include business-friendly and FDI-friendly policies as well as domestic policies such as improvement of the infrastructure. Latin America, on the other hand, has relied mainly on formal, de jure regional agreements for integration. Second, using a variety of indicators, it seems that at least in terms of the extent of intra-regional integrations and in terms of advancing comparative advantage in the processing of components and parts, East and Southeast Asia has been more successful. Third, if the main objective is regional trade integration, then it seems that the proper sequencing of the two forms of integration is first to develop integration via the markets before engaging in more formal agreements. Lastly, an argument in favor of this sequence is that by developing the lobbying clout of the outward-looking economic and trade interests first, this will enhance the internal bargaining power of the outward-oriented constituency in the internal bargaining of trade policy, thereby tilting the implementation of the regional trade agreement to be more in line with the market signals. 35 References: Aoki, Masahiko (1988), Information, Incentives, and Bargaining in the Japanese Economy, Cambridge University Press. Binmore, Ken, Ariel Rubinstein and Asher Wolinsky (1986), "The Nash Bargaining Solution in Economic Modeling," The Rand Journal of Economics, 17 (2):176-88. Barfield, Claude (2005), "Bush Administration Trade Policy: The Role of RTAs," mimeo, American Enterprise Institute, Washington, DC. Bhagwati, Jagdish (1991), The World Trading System At Risk, Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press. Bhagwati, Jagdish (1992), "Regionalism and Multilateralism," The World Economy, vol. 15, N°5, September. Cuyvers, L., De Lombaerde, Ph., Verherstraeten, S. (2005), "Current Status of East Asian Economic Integration," University of Antwerp Working Paper, Belgium. Ethier, Wilfred, J. (1998), "The New Regionalism," Economic Journal, v.108, no.499, July. Fung, K.C., Hitomi Iizaka, Chelsea Lin and Francis Ng (2004), "Multilateral Trade Negotiations in the GATT and the WTO: Lessons for Asia," Asian Economic Papers, Fall. Hertwel, W.T., Walmsley, T. and K. Itakura (2001), "Dynamic Effects of the `New Age' Free Trade Agreement between Japan and Singapore," Journal of Economic Integration, 16, pp.446-484. Hosono, A., Nishijima S. (2003), "Prospects for Closer Relations between Latin America and Asia", RIEB Discussion Paper Series, N° 121. Limao, Nuno (2005), "Preferential vs. Multilateral Trade Liberalization: Evidence and Open Question," Mimeo, University of Maryland. Mavroidis, Petros C. (2005), "If I don't do it, somebody else will (or won't): Testing the Compliance of PTAs with the Multilateral Rules," mimeo. Ng, Francis and Alexander Yeats (2003), "Major Trade Trends in East Asia: What are Their Implications for Regional Cooperation and Growth?" Policy Research Working Paper, no. 3084, Washington DC: The World Bank. Noland, Marcus and Howard Pack (2003), Industrial Policy in an Era of Globalization: Lessons from Asia, Institute for International Economics, Washington, D.C. Rajapatirana, S. (1994), "The evolution of trade treaties and trade creation: lessons for Latin America", Paper presented at the annual regional Conference of the International Cooperative Alliance, August 23-27, Ecuador. 36 Salazar-Xirinachs, Jose M. (2005), "Regional vs. Multilateral Priorities for Developing Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean," paper presented for the International Trade Roundtable on The WTO at 10 Years--The Regional Challenge to Multilateralism, Brussels, June. Sapir, Andre (1998), "The Political Economy of EC Regionalism," European Economic Review, 42: 717-732. Tran Van Hoa (2002), "Korea, China, and Japan: Their Trade with the World and Its Impact on New Asian Regionalism ASEAN+3," University of Wollongong Working Paper, available online at www.uow.edu.au/commerce/econ/wplist.htlm Urata, Shujiro (1993), "Changing Patterns of Direct Investment and the Implications for Trade and Development," in C. Fred Bergsten and Marcus Noland (ed.), Pacific Dynamism and the International Economic System, Institute for International Economics, Washington, D.C. Winters, L. A. (1999), "Regionalism vs. Multilateralism," in R. Baldwin, D. Cohen, A. Sapir and T. Venables (ed.), Market Integration, Regionalism and the Global Economy, CEPR, Cambridge, United Kingdom. World Trade Organization (2007), "Trade Policy Review--Japan," Geneva: WTO. Yi, Kei-Mu (2003), "Can Vertical Specialization Explain the Growth of World Trade," Journal of Political Economy, vol.11, no.1, pp.52-102.