69046 Making Finance Work for Uganda December 2009 The World Bank Financial and Private Sector Development Africa Region Acknowledgments This report was produced by a team led by Michael Fuchs and Ravi Ruparel of the Financial and Private Sector Development Unit of the Africa Region of the World Bank. Team members included Andrew Lovegrove, Robert Cull, Faith Stewart, Carlo Corazza, Csaba Feher, Simon Walley, Kameel Virjee, Rajesh Advani, Moses Kibirige, Rekha Reddy, and Edward Al-Hussainy. The team received significant support from the Bank of Uganda‘s Banking Supervision and Research Departments. The team wishes to express its sincere appreciation to the Ugandan authorities and private sector officials for their excellent cooperation. The team‘s analysis was enriched by discussions with officials and authorities from the Bank of Uganda, the Ministry of Finance Planning and Economic Development, the Uganda Stock Exchange, the Capital Markets Authority, the Uganda Bankers Association, commercial banks, the Privatization and Utility Sector Reform Project, the National Water and Sewerage Corporation, the Uganda Electricity Transmission Company, Limited, and other public and private sector institutions. Table of Contents Executive Summary ........................................................................................................... i Summary of Key Recommendations .............................................................................. vi 1. Introduction ................................................................................................................... 1 Part 1: Improving Access to Financial Services 2. Expanding Access through the Banking System ........................................................ 5 3:.Developing Rural and Agricultural Finance ............................................................ 25 4. Improving Payments and Remittances Systems ...................................................... 39 Part 2: Improving the Supply of Term Finance 5. Reforming the Uganda Pension System .................................................................... 55 6. Developing the Housing Finance Market ................................................................. 66 7. Increasing the Private Financing of Infrastructure ................................................. 79 Annexes Annex A: References....................................................................................................... 90 AnnexB: Banking Sector Efficiency .............................................................................. 92 Annex C: Overview of Water Sector Infrastructure ................................................. 112 Annex D: Overview of Electricity Sector Infrastructure .......................................... 123 Annex E: Overview of Roads Sector Infrastructure ................................................. 137 Annex F: Overview of Airports Sector Infrastructure .............................................. 140 Abbreviations and Acronyms AML/CFT Anti-Money Laundering/Combating the Financing of Terrorism BOU Bank of Uganda BOURD Bank of Uganda Research Department CEM Country Economic Memorandum CMA Capital Markets Authority CPSS Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems CRB Credit Reference Bureau DvP Delivery versus Payment EADB East Africa Development Bank EFT Electronic Funds Transfer ESW Economic & Sector Work FIA Financial Institutions Act FIRST Financial Sector Reform and Strengthening Initiative FSAP Financial Sector Assessment Program GoU Government of Uganda IFC International Finance Corporation IFRS International Financial Reporting Standards MDI Microfinance Deposit Taking Institution MFI Microfinance Institution MoFPED Ministry of Finance, Planning and Economic Development MSME Micro, Small, and Medium-Size Enterprises MTN Medium-Term Note MTO Money Transfer Operator NDP National Development Plan NBFI Nonbank Financial Institutions POS Point of Sale PSCPII Private Sector Competitiveness Project II RSDP Road Sector Development Program RSP Remittance Service Provider RTGS Real Time Gross Settlement SACCO Savings and Credit Cooperatives UBA Uganda Bankers Association UCSCU Uganda Credit and Savings Cooperatives Union UGS Uganda Shillings USD US Dollars USE Uganda Stock Exchange Executive Summary Background i. The Ugandan financial system stands at a crossroad. It performs a number of crucial tasks, such as banking for medium to large corporations, and effectively providing payments and savings services to sizeable segments of the population. However, much remains to be done to increase the depth and breadth of the financial sector in order to contribute to both higher economic growth and increased poverty reduction. Countries with higher levels of financial development experience better resource allocation, higher GDP per capita growth, and faster rates of poverty reduction. Thus, achieving a sustainable increase in financial deepening remains an important goal for Uganda‘s development agenda. ii. The majority of the Ugandan population lack financial services. Despite considerable progress in the expansion of Uganda‘s financial services, 62 percent of Ugandans (about 18.1 million people) are unserved by any kind of financial institution, formal or informal. Uganda suffers from a low savings rate, low levels of lending, high costs, and high margins. While liquidity within the system is considerable, banks prefer to invest in treasury securities rather than servicing a broader segment of the enterprise sector. iii. The local market for term finance remains underdeveloped. While the financial system is able to provide bank financing for segments of the enterprise sector, financing for maturities longer than about seven years is largely unavailable. This is a major constraint to the financing of much-needed infrastructure investment and severely curtails the development of finance for the housing market. The dearth of investment in infrastructure has repeatedly been identified as a major constraint to economic development. Objectives iv. The objective of this report is to contribute to the continuing policy dialogue on financial sector development. It is intended that the analysis and recommendations from this report will contribute towards the preparation and implementation of the National Development Plan (NDP) and the implementation of the Financial Markets Development Plan. v. The Making Finance Work for Uganda report was produced as a result of the studies undertaken in Uganda during 2008 and 2009. The specific topics for the studies were identified in consultation with the Ugandan authorities as areas of particular relevance in following up on the FSAP Update (2005) and the Country Economic Memorandum (CEM, 2007). The report is part of a broader working paper i series that complements the broader review of the financial policy agenda provided in Making Finance Work for Africa (Honohan and Beck 2007). vi. This report has two parts: “Improving Access to Financial Services� and “Improving the Supply of Term Finance.� Thus it continues the approach of Making Finance Work for Africa which took a panoramic view of Africa‘s financial systems, both at the large scale (―finance for growth‖) and the small scale (―finance for all‖). The first part of this report focuses on three ways of improving access: expanding access though the banking system, developing rural and agricultural finance, and improving payments and remittances systems. The second part looks at three ways of improving the supply of term finance: reforming the pension system, developing the housing finance market, and increasing the private financing of infrastructure Part 1: Improving Access to Financial Services a. Expanding Access through the Banking System vii. Uganda’s banking sector is sound, but inefficient. Banks are well capitalized and the nonperforming loans ratio is low. Deposit levels are growing but still low as well. Despite growth in asset levels, this remains a low intermediation banking system. viii. There are a number of constraints to expansion of lending. These constraints can be grouped into two main categories: (i) legal and regulatory constraints, and (ii) information and capacity constraints. Some of the key constraints include: insufficient support for creditor rights, excessive provisioning requirements, and difficulties in obtaining land title information. ix. The report suggests both policy reforms and institutional reforms. These include reviewing unnecessarily restrictive bank regulations and supervisory practices, introducing a small-claims procedure system for resolution of commercial disputes, expanding the scope of the credit reference bureau to include collection of data on nonbank payments, completing computerization of the land and company registries, and strengthening the court system by installing computerized case management. b. Developing Rural and Agricultural Finance x. Access to finance in rural areas is limited. According to a 2006 Finscope survey, 62 percent of Uganda‘s population has no access whatsoever to financial service. The divide between urban and rural areas is significant, with 52 percent of the urban population and 65 percent of the rural population unserved. The government is implementing a Rural Financial Services Strategy that involves having a strong Savings and Credit Cooperative‘s (SACCOs) in every sub county. However much remains to be done to have promote a savings culture and to have sustainable SACCOs and greater financial inclusion. ii xi. Agricultural finance is still limited and does not reach the majority of the population. Some of the larger farmers get some funding, but even they do not get long- term funding. Subsistence farmers, who are the majority, get very little short- term funding, mainly through microfinance institutions (MFIs). The collateral requirements of banks are still a hindrance to financing. The potential for leasing has not been fully developed. xii. The report suggests both policy and institutional reforms to develop rural and agricultural finance. To achieve these reforms, the report recommends that the authorities continue the efforts to strengthen the Uganda Cooperatives Savings & Credit Union (UCSCU) as an apex institution for SACCOs, promote improved governance of SACCOs, enact a leasing law, strengthen the agricultural credit guarantee scheme, and facilitate the development of crop/livestock insurance products. c. Improving Payments and Remittance Systems xiii.The Bank of Uganda (BOU) has taken some important steps to modernize the payment systems. The program began five years ago with the goal of achieving high quality, accessible, reliable, and affordable payment services, increasing confidence in the banking system, and reducing the dependency of the Ugandan economy on cash and checks. xiv. However, implementation of this vision appears to be lagging. In particular there are significant delays in enacting payment system legislation. Despite significant progress by the central bank in upgrading the safety and efficiency of the payments systems, as yet the efficiency gains from new technology are not being translated into lower fees to bank customers. High bank charges are a major disincentive to the use of electronic payment services. xv. The report suggests both policy and technology reforms to expand the systems. To achieve meaningful reform, the report recommends that the authorities expedite the enactment of payments systems legislation, increase access to the payments system to include Tier 2 and Tier 3 financial institutions, encourage greater competition to reduce bank charges for provision of payment services, require interoperability among bank payment switches, and integrate the electronic securities and fund transfer systems. Part 2: Improving the Supply of Term Finance d. Reforming the Pension System xvi. There is a need for an overall pension regulatory framework. The MoFPED is already working on a pension regulatory Bill. This Bill and a set of implementing regulations should be enacted and implemented as soon as possible. The Act should give the pension regulator authority over the NSSF, the Public Service Pension Scheme (PSPS), and all the occupational schemes. Having an overarching pension regulatory iii authority is important to improving the governance of the sector, promoting reform, and advancing liberalization. xvii. The private pension system needs to be fully liberalized. Currently, private formal sector employees are required to contribute 15 percent of their salary to a monopoly pension fund, the National Social Security Fund (NSSF). As a result, NSSF had amassed a portfolio worth more than UGS 1.42 trillion (USD 768 million) as of September 2009, approximately 5 percent of GDP, making it the only major source of term financing in Uganda. Despite recently improved investment returns, a history of repeated governance and management failures has focused the authorities on the short- term need for strengthening the governance of NSSF. The report supports the intentions of the authorities‘ ―once the legal and regulatory foundation for private pension fund administration is in place― to remove NSSF‘s monopoly position, with a view to full liberalization of private sector pension provision. xviii. The government’s commitment to public service pension payments is unsustainable and undermines confidence in fiscal management. The government‘s commitment to provide public sector employees with an unfunded Public Service Pension Scheme (PSPS) has resulted in a large implicit pension debt. Although the government has embarked on an accelerated amortization of historic arrears, according to the Ministry of Public Service, new arrears are being accumulated every year, due to under-budgeting of the government's commitments. Changes in the parameters of the PSPS will be required to reform the current defined benefit system and move to a fiscally sustainable system. The envisaged reform of the PSPS would alleviate pressure on the government‘s financing needs while also contributing to the development of the local capital market through gradual transition to fully funded public sector pensions. e. Developing the Housing Finance Market xix. The new legal framework could help to expand housing finance. The mortgage act was passed by parliament in April 2009 and became and Act in October 2009. The new act should help provide a suitable regulatory environment for secured lending. The authorities are encouraged to prepare the rules and regulations for implementation of the act. xx. The establishment of a liquidity facility could provide long-term funding. Growth of the housing finance market has also been slowed by issues such as the severe shortage of long-term funding. To alleviate this constraint, the authorities are encouraged to consider the establishment of a liquidity facility that would allow banks to overcome some of the maturity mismatch issues and provide investors and pension funds with a supply of bonds, yielding a better return than treasury bills, without a significant increase in risk. xxi. Creative options are needed to address the growing housing gap. Although the Ugandan mortgage market is developing at a steady pace, there is a huge need to accelerate the development of housing that can be eligible for mortgage financing. A iv large housing gap exists, in terms both of absolute numbers and of the quality of the housing stock, which is particularly lacking in urban areas. f. Increasing the Private Financing of Infrastructure xxii. The condition of potential issuers is the key demand driver for infrastructure finance in Uganda. The case of the National Water and Sewerage Corporation (NWSC) is a good example of a local infrastructure provider with a strong potential to attract private financing for a portion of its overall capital investment program. Furthermore NWSC is a reformed infrastructure parastatal whose need for commercial finance was a driver of its reform process. The preparation of the NWSC bond shows that reform issues such as tariff predictability and sufficiency, along with operational efficiency, will be the key drivers of demand for private financing. Critically, the capital structure of potential issuers will affect their likely success in raising commercial finance. The removal of legacy debt from the balance sheet of potential issuers through equity swaps or otherwise is also critical. xxiii. There is a need to strengthen the transaction advisory sector. Potential issuers and lenders require good transaction advisory services to make credit decisions. By placing debt in the wider East Africa region, issues of liquidity and completion among investors will help to allocate capital more efficiently. This is particularly relevant where the markets are not fully developed (as in Uganda) and market players are not fully equipped to evaluate documentation and the structure of financing. External support for transaction structuring and advisory would help to catalyze Ugandan infrastructure finance while building capacity in the local advisory sector. xxiv. Consider developing a term transformation facility. Ideally, the long-term liquidity contained in the unreformed pension sector would be used to provide the required long- term finance for infrastructure projects. However, because of the concentration of that liquidity, there is a risk that liquidity will be unavailable when it is required. As such, benefits to the infrastructure sectors could be developed through the development of term transformation interventions. These could include the development of refinance options, which allow banks to provide longer-term finance. Facilities such as the Uganda Energy Capital Corporation set up under the Energy for Rural Transformation Project (ERT) will be particularly useful in the small project finance segment of the wider infrastructure sector. v Summary of Key Recommendations Part 1. Improving Access to Financial Services Expanding Access through the Banking System Area Short Term Medium Term Expected Outcomes [year 1] [years 2-3] Regulations Review BOU regulations Revise regulations on core Increased lending to MSMEs requiring minimum deposits to allow a provisions (fully implement proportion to be treated as Increased longer-term lending IFRS) long-term liabilities Lower costs for bank Review BOU stipulations Increased number of bank and on branch opening MDI branches requirements. Commercial Install a computerized case Implement small claims Increased trade credit Courts management system procedure system Increased MSME lending Present small claims procedure system Reduced cost of collection regulations to Chief Justice. Credit Ensure full participation of Expand the scope of CRB‘s Improved access to trade credit Reference all financial institutions and activity to collect data on by MSMEs Bureau customers in CRB nonbank payments and allow nonbank firms to obtain credit data Branchless/ Issue mobile banking Issue branchless banking Wide range of mobile and Mobile Banking licenses guidelines branchless banking services available Reduction in bank charges vi Developing Rural and Agricultural Finance Area Short Term Medium Term Expected Outcomes [year 1] [years 2-3] SACCOs Submit Tier 4 regulatory bill Set up Tier 4 regulatory Increased confidence in MFIs to parliament authority and SACCOs Strengthen UCSCU Complete external audits of Increased bank lending to licensed SACCOs SACCOs Leasing Submit leasing bill to More banks providing leasing parliament Insurance of Develop crop and livestock Increase in number of insurance Crops and insurance products companies providing crop and Livestock livestock insurance Improving Payments and Remittances Systems Area Short Term Medium Term Expected Outcomes [year 1] [years 2-3] Legal Present payment system bill Strengthen oversight Secure and efficient payment Framework to parliament capacity at BoU system EFT and RTGS Provide Tier 2 and Tier 3 Upgrade RTGS system Increase in proportion of institutions access to EFT electronic transfers and reduced system costs Faster execution of cross border payments Retail Payments Establish foundation for a Require all licensed Increased usage of ATM and common switch financial institutions to use POS terminals central switch with common tariffs for all transfers Remittances Prohibit exclusivity Publish information on Increased number of remittance agreements between banks remittance flows and costs service providers and remittance service on a quarterly basis providers Increased access to remittance services Improve information on remittance flows and costs Reduced cost of remittances vii Part 2. Improving the Supply of Term Finance Reforming the Pension System Area Short Term Medium Term Expected Outcomes [year 1] [years 2-3] Regulatory Submit Uganda Retirement Appoint URBA board and Regulated, competitive private Framework Benefits Authority (URBA) operationalize URBA pension industry catering for bill to Parliament both mandatory and voluntary Submit draft amendments to pension savings Prepare draft amendments parliament to existing legal framework Effective regulatory framework (for example trust law, Sign MoU between URBA, and supervision of pension CMA act, tax law, CMA, and UIC to ensure products and service providers accounting regulations) coordination among NBFI regulators Issue regulatory guidelines for pension schemes (both private and public) Private Sector Include private sector Develop and disseminate Less concentrated institutional Pensions pension liberalization transition guidelines to all investor base principles in URBA Bill private schemes More choice available to pension Delegate NSSF investment Submit amendments to scheme members according to management responsibilities NSSF act to parliament their risk-preference and to private asset managers individual circumstances License all private schemes Regulated competition, leading to lower fees, higher returns, more transparency, improved financial literacy Public Sector Establish working group on Complete actuarial Lower public pension debt and Pension Reform PSPS reform. valuation fiscal gap Undertake diagnostic review Prepare and present PSPS Actuarially more fair and of PSPS organization and reform options paper to fiscally more sustainable pension processes cabinet (including system for government projections of the expected employees; Initiate actuarial valuation fiscal and welfare impact of of PSPS ( under a no policy options) Improved service quality and change scenario) accountability at PSPS Submit amended Public Service Pensions Bill to parliament viii Developing the Housing Finance Market Area Short Term Medium Term Expected Outcomes [year 1] [years 2-3] Legal Prepare rules and regulations Present consumer protection Increase in mortgage lending Framework for the mortgage act law presented to parliament Design legal framework for securitization Valuation Revise valuation policy Strengthen capacity of Increased efficiency in valuation office mortgage transactions Financing Develop strategy for long-term Issue long-term benchmark Increased tenure of mortgages benchmark issues bonds Undertake initial design of Establish liquidity facility liquidity facility Rental Housing Complete strategy for Develop incentives for Increase in construction of development of rental market rental housing rental housing Increasing Private Financing of Infrastructure Area Short Term Medium Term Expected Outcomes [year 1] [years 2-3] Capacity of Develop and adopt financing Obtain credit ratings for all Increased capacity of Infrastructure policy for parastatal parastatals providing parastatal infrastructure Providers infrastructure providers infrastructure services companies to manage the borrowing process Financing Complete NWSC bond Complete preparation of Reduced burden on GoU fiscal transaction another parastatal bond resources to finance transaction parastatals Develop asset backed securities policy Submit regulations for asset Increased bond financing of backed securities to cabinet infrastructure Prepare design of term transformation facility for Establish term Increased long-term bank infrastructure (similar to transformation facility (or financing for infrastructure Uganda Energy Capital expand Uganda Energy Corporation) Capital Corporation to cover other sectors) PPP Framework Prepare PPP framework Prepare PPP Bill and submit Increased capacity to manage cabinet paper to parliament PPP project development efficiently Establish PPP unit and develop guidelines Increased service delivery levels Complete one PPP transaction ix 1. Introduction Objectives 1-1. ―Making Finance Work for Uganda‖ was produced as a result of studies undertaken in Uganda during 2008 and 2009 The specific topics for the study were identified in consultation with the Ugandan authorities as areas of particular relevance in following up on the Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP) Update (2005) and the Country Economic Memorandum (CEM) (2007). The report is part of a broader working paper series that complements the broader review of the financial policy agenda provided in ―Making Finance Work for Africa‖ (Honohan and Beck 2007). 1-2. The objective of this report is to contribute to the continuing policy dialogue on financial sector development. It is intended that the analysis and recommendations from this report will contribute towards the preparation and implementation of the National Development Plan (NDP) and the implementation of the Financial Markets Development Plan.1 Background 1-3. The 2005 FSAP Update characterized the Ugandan financial system as stable and growing, but also small relative to its peers, underdeveloped, and not able to fully support economic growth. While recognizing the remarkable progress that the authorities had made in implementing the recommendations of the 2001 FSAP and thereby laying the foundations for a sound and profitable financial system, the FSAP Update noted that the key challenge facing the authorities is to create conditions that would lead to increased intermediation, and therefore a greater role for the financial sector in supporting economic development. 1-4. The 2007 CEM noted that Uganda‘s financial system is still quite shallow, and that considerable benefit, in terms of both higher growth and faster poverty reduction, would result from increasing the depth and breadth of the financial sector. The CEM highlighted that the binding constraint in the financial system seems to be intermediation, rather than the low savings rate: even if banks are provided with additional savings, under present circumstances, they prefer not lend them to the private sector. This observation is supported by the extreme imbalance between increases in deposits and increases in lending to private sector borrowers. 1-5. The Ugandan financial market has a growing commercial banking sector and a nascent bond market dominated by a single investor. Local banks tend to have low asset- to-deposit ratios, preferring to instead to use their deposits to fund treasury bills and 1 The preparation of the Narional Development Plan (2009–2013) is being led by the National Planning Authority. The preparation of the Financial Markets Development Plan (2008–2012) was led by the Bank of Uganda. Its implementation is being coordinated by an FMDP steering group at the BoU. 1 bonds. The larger banks have excess liquidity that they are willing to deploy in financing medium-term assets (5–7 year tenure). The loan covenants required under such lending, however, can be onerous. Given the limited competition within the banking sector (and between banks and the wider capital markets) loan spreads remain high. 1-6. While the situation may be improving, Uganda still lags behind many of its neighbors with its small financial sector and excessive liquidity. Uganda‘s ratio of private credit to GDP lags below its peers as does its ratio of domestic deposits to GDP. Furthermore, Uganda has a low level of access to finance, as shown in Figure 1.3.2 1-7. The 2007 CEM also noted that ―the single most important measure to support the development of the market for term finance in Uganda will be pension reform. Pension reform can have a significant positive impact both in providing protection to Ugandans in old age and in stimulating savings and the development of the market for longer-term finance.‖ 1-8. The pension reform process, which had been stalled for several years, gained momentum with the cabinet approval in February 2008 of a policy paper on pension sector regulation. This is an important first step as it will lead to new legislation to be enacted to establish an independent regulatory authority for both public and private pension funds. However, for the reform process to be completed, two further important steps are necessary: (i) for private pensions, liberalizing the sector by allowing qualifying occupational schemes to cease contributing to the NSSF, and (ii) for public pensions, converting the public service pension scheme into a self-sustaining scheme. The creation of a multipillar pension system is an important step. Private occupational schemes currently hold an estimated value of US$60 million.3 Pension providers are natural investors for mortgages, given that they have long-term liabilities and seek to bridge their mismatch by investing in long-term assets. The key is to ensure that an efficient mechanism exists for channeling the pension funds‘ long-term liabilities into the mortgage lenders‘ long-term assets. This study examines these issues in detail and provides recommendations for implementing such reforms. 1-9. The need for housing finance and investment in housing in Uganda is clear. A large housing gap exists in terms of absolute numbers and of the quality of housing stock. As with much of Sub-Saharan Africa, there is a trend toward increased urbanization. This presents a set of new challenges for urban planners and financial authorities that are not being addressed adequately at present. Growth of the housing finance market has been slowed by issues such as high interest rates, difficulties in accessing credit, an underdeveloped financial system, and uncertainties in the regulatory structure.4 This 2 The Finscope survey 2007 showed that in spite of a strengthened banking, system 62 percent of Ugandans are unserved by any kind of financial institution, formal or informal. Of the 38 percent that are served, only 18 percent are served by a formal provider (commercial bank, MDI, or credit institution), while 20 percent are served by semiformal or informal providers. 3 Kalema 2008. 4 Extensive studies on the Uganda mortgage market by Finmark Trust (2008) and IFC (2005) point to a number of deficiencies, which, despite some recent changes, remain major obstacles to the development of a widely accessible housing finance system in Uganda. 2 study provides a practical framework for the policy and institutional reforms necessary to increase the level of long-term financing directed toward housing and housing construction. 1-10. The role of private financing of infrastructure development is increasingly being highlighted as necessary in the African context. Despite its limited size, Uganda‘s financial sector has the potential to make a meaningful contribution to infrastructure term finance as shown in the National Water and Sewerage Corporation (NWSC). NWSC is currently in the final stages of approval for a UGS 100 billion medium-term note program to issue relatively long-term listed bonds. Leveraging work undertaken in the context of the CEM, and based on recent NWSC experience, the team has identified constraints to expanding private financing of infrastructure and provided recommendations for further stimulating the development of the Ugandan bond market. Structure of the Report 1-11. This report has two parts: Improving Access to Financial Services and Improving the Supply of Term Finance. The first part focuses on three areas: expanding access though the banking system; developing rural and agricultural finance; and improving payments and remittance systems. The second part focuses on three key areas: reforming the pension system; developing the housing finance market; and increasing the private financing of infrastructure.5 1-12. Each chapter has the following structure: the first section provides an overview of the chapter topic; the second presents an analysis of the results of the survey (where applicable) and interviews, and categorizes constraints; the third section provides recommendations to address the constraints. 5 The subject of ―Branchless Banking,‖ which was in the original concept note for this study, was not studied. The World Bank was informed that GTZ and the Bank of Uganda were going to undertake a study on this subject during 2008. It is now expected that this study will be undertaken in 2009. 3 Part 1 Improving Access to Financial Services Making Finance Work for Uganda 2. Expanding Access through the Banking System 2-1. This chapter identifies obstacles to the expansion of financial service provision by formal financial institutions. The first section describes characteristics of the banking sector, including banking sector soundness and the efficiency of the banking system. The second section discusses the findings of the joint World Bank/BOU survey of financial institutions. The final section describes a set of recommendations which could assist in expanding access to finance through the banking system. Overview of the Banking Sector 2-2. The Ugandan banking sector has grown rapidly in the last three years. While Stanbic has dominated the sector in terms of its overall size and branch network, almost without exception all of its competitors (such as Barclays) are seeking to provide greater geographical coverage by opening new branches outside Kampala. The driving factor in this expansion has been the emergence of strong competition in the corporate banking market, which has in turn forced the larger banks to start looking for loan clients well below the thin tier of ―blue chip‖ corporate clients they have traditionally served. 2-3. Total assets and deposits have increased by about 20 percent per year. . Total lending rose at an average rate of almost 36 percent, as shown in figure 2.1. This reflects the physical expansion of the sector in terms of numbers of branches and increased efforts by banks to market deposit products to retail customers and private sector businesses. Retail deposits are particularly attractive to banks, because of the low rates paid on savings and the wide margins earned from on-lending deposits. This has led to a more active approach to increasing deposits. Figure 2.1: Growth in Banking System Source: Bank of Uganda; World Bank analysis 5 2-4. Lending to government and parastatals accounts for less than one percent of total loans. This suggests that the relatively low ratios of loans to total assets and total deposits are not caused by the crowding out of the private sector by the state and state- owned enterprises. Nevertheless, the high real rates of return available from investments in treasury bills (above 14 percent) provide banks with an attractive alternative to lending, and consequently set a high base rate for all other types of lending. Lending was highest to the category ―other services,‖ which includes small businesses, with lending to utilities (transportation, communication, water, and electricity) showing an increase in the last three years (figure 2.2) Figure 2.2 Structure of Bank Lending (UGS billions) Source: Bank of Uganda; World Bank analysis 2-5. Banks continue to maintain high levels of liquidity. While the trends in asset and deposit growth would suggest that banks were reallocating assets into lending, the ratios of loans to total assets and loans to deposits remains low, at only about 43 percent and 69 percent, respectively, at the end of 2008. Banks continued to maintain very high levels of liquidity, with the ratio of liquid assets at about 45 percent at the end of 2008 (table 2.1). 2-6. Banks remain well capitalized. The banking sector‘s capital also rose quickly during the period 2006 to 2008, increasing by an average of almost 55 percent per year. Average returns on Tier I and Tier II capital were about 32 and 30 percent, respectively and were accompanied by significant increases in the amounts of capital invested in banks. As a result, total capital ratios remained stable at above 8 percent of assets throughout the period (table 2.1). 6 Table 2.1: Trends in the Ugandan Banking System 2005-2008 Ratio 31/12/2005 12/31/2006 12/31/2007 12/31/2008 Mean Loans to Deposits 46.34% 55.15% 58.58% 68.56% 57.16% Loans to Total Assets 32.58% 36.62% 37.72% 42.61% 37.38% Liquid Assets to Total Assets 55.06% 51.91% 51.54% 44.79% 50.82% Deposits to Total Liabilities 79.63% 75.37% 73.53% 73.27% 75.45% Deposits to Total Liabilities & Capital 70.30% 66.41% 64.40% 62.15% 65.81% Total Capital to Total Assets 11.72% 11.88% 12.42% 15.17% 12.80% Return on Tier 1 Capital 43.02% 36.68% 41.65% 27.67% 37.25% Return on Total Capital 28.58% 25.71% 27.65% 20.10% 25.51% Return on Assets 3.35% 3.06% 3.43% 3.05% 3.22% Total Provisions to Total Loans 10.09% 9.43% 8.44% 7.00% 8.74% Source: Bank of Uganda, World Bank analysis 2-7. The turmoil in the global financial markets has not directly affected Uganda. Due to the financial crisis, economic activity in most industrialized countries has declined sharply, with financial institutions particularly affected. The financial system in Uganda has remained largely stable over the period. There have not been any cases of severe liquidity problems, distress or capital inadequacy in Uganda. However, there is still some uncertainty over the magnitude of the effect of the global financial crisis on the macroeconomy in general, and the financial sector in particular. 7 Table 2.2: Consolidated Balance Sheet of the Ugandan Banking System ITEM (UGS ‘000) Dec-06 Dec-07 Dec-08 Assets Cash on Hand 219,257,967 232,387,914 337,381,772 Due from Bank of Uganda 255,942,087 296,763,249 462,669,790 Due from Banks & Financial Institutions 830,106,062 962,133,783 1,050,527,067 Securities 1,009,307,544 1,400,556,263 1,532,841,313 Total Liquid Assets 2,314,613,660 2,891,841,209 3,383,419,941 Financing Schemes - - - Loans, Overdrafts & Discounts 1,632,994,375 2,116,498,574 3,219,281,350 Administered Advances 69,591,112 57,482,237 185,500,758 Total Lending Assets 1,702,585,487 2,173,980,811 3,404,782,108 Investments 2,839,843 3,685,989 21,476,229 Fixed Assets 232,847,324 248,499,224 376,057,834 Items in Transit 3,338,066 337,466 282,200 Other Assets 202,643,270 292,209,355 368,754,091 TOTAL ASSETS 4,458,867,650 5,610,554,053 7,554,772,403 Liabilities Deposits 2,961,191,870 3,613,067,008 4,695,566,412 Certificates of Deposit 50,000 50,000 - Borrowings from Bank of Uganda 332,800 - 1,485,544 Due to Banks & Financial Institutions 224,721,254 567,152,679 680,804,284 Administered Funds 115,130,831 122,909,104 323,709,397 Bills Payable 38,135,124 26,610,747 24,220,649 Items in Transit 111,504 578,083 234,143 Other Liabilities 435,408,569 404,874,568 456,965,313 Provisions 153,931,078 178,606,945 225,357,167 Reconciliation Adjustment Total Liabilities 3,929,013,030 4,913,849,133 6,408,342,908 Tier I Capital 371,464,655 462,469,967 832,652,074 Tier II Capital 22,147,707 41,619,298 83,383,902 Current Year Profit 136,242,257 192,615,656 230,393,518 Total Capital 529,854,619 696,704,920 1,146,429,495 TOTAL LIABILITIES & CAPITAL 4,458,867,650 5,610,554,053 7,554,772,403 Source: Bank of Uganda 8 Banking Sector Soundness 2-8. The Banking sector remains sound. The soundness indicators show a consistent pattern. The nonperforming loan ratio has hovered between 2 and 4 percent since 2004, while Return on Assets has held near 4 percent and the capital adequacy ratio near 20 percent since 2002. In all, the evolution of the soundness indicators point to a stable banking system in Uganda (figure 2.3). Figure 2.3: Banking Sector Soundness Source: Bank of Uganda; World Bank analysis 2-9. Uganda compares well to other countries. The banking system also appears to be sound relative to a number of developing countries (figure 2.4). The capital adequacy ratio (CAR) for Uganda is 20.1 percent, higher than most comparators. 6 Similarly, at 2.2 percent Uganda‘s ratio of nonperforming to total loans is the lowest compared to other sub Saharan African countries (figure 2.5) Figure 2.4: Capital Addequacy Ratio (%) – Regional Comparison 25 20.5 20.7 19.5 20 18.3 18 16.9 Uganda 15 Ghana Kenya 10 Nigeria South Africa 5 0 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Source: GFSR; World Bank analysis 6 The CAR is the ratio of banks‘ regulatory capital to risk-weighted assets. 9 Figure 2.5: Non Performing Loans / Total Loans (%) – Regional Comparison 40 35 30 25 Uganda Ghana 20 Kenya 15 Nigeria South Africa 10 7.2 5 4.1 2.2 2.3 2.9 2.2 0 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Source: GFSR; World Bank analysis Banking Sector Development and Efficiency 2-10. Uganda performs relatively poorly on development and efficiency indicators. International comparisons show a general tendency for more developed banking sectors— in terms of deposits and lending relative to GDP—to have relatively low ratios of costs to total assets, net interest margins, deposit interest rates, and interest spreads. 2-11. Deposit levels are growing, but are still low. The ratio of bank deposits to GDP has grown from 11 percent in 2000 to 16 percent in 2008 (figure 2.6). However it is still low compared to neighbors Kenya and Tanzania (38 percent and 24 percent, respectively) and also to countries such as Ghana (32 percent), Nigeria (33 percent) and South Africa (66 percent). Figure 2.6 Domestic Deposits/ GDP – Regional Comparisons 70% 60% 50% Uganda 40% Ghana Kenya 30% Nigeria 20% 14.8% 14.6% 16.0% South Africa 13.5% 13.4% 13.6% Tanzania 10% 0% 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Source: IFS; World Bank analysis 10 2-12. Uganda remains a low intermediation banking system. Uganda‘s ratio of bank credit to the private sector relative to GDP, while growing from 8 percent in 2003 to 12 percent in 2008, is still low (figure 2.7). This is in comparison to neighbours Kenya and Tanzania (29 percent and 15 percent respectively) and also other sub Saharan Africa countries such as Ghana (23 percent), Nigeria (35 percent) and South Africa (79 percent). Uganda‘s spreads are also high in relation to the same comparators (figure 2.8) Figure 2.7 Private Sector Credit / GDP – Regional Comparisons 90% 80% 70% Uganda 60% Ghana 50% Kenya 40% Nigeria 30% South Africa 20% 9.2% 11.9% Tanzania 8.1% 7.7% 7.6% 9.0% 10% 0% 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Source: IFS; World Bank analysis Figure 2.8 Lending – Deposit Spread (%) – Regional Comparisons 14 12.9 12 10.9 9.6 9.8 9.8 10 9.1 Uganda 8 Kenya 6 Nigeria South Africa 4 Tanzania 2 0 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Source: IFS; World Bank analysis [ note Ghana spread figures not available] 11 2-13. The low levels of intermediation could be attributable to the high interest net interest margins. Uganda‘s net interest margin while coming down is higher than that of all comparator countries (figure 2.9). Perhaps the high margins could be explained by the need to cover the costs of lending to hard-to-serve customers. Uganda‘s ratio of overheads to total assets has remained at around 6% and is higher than all other comparators except Ghana. (figure 2.10). Figure 2.9 Net Interest Margin (%) – Regional Comparisons 12% 11.2% 11.4% 10.6% 10.5% 10% 9.8% 9.0% 8% Uganda Ghana 6% Kenya Nigeria 4% South Africa Tanzania 2% 0% 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Net Interest Margin = Net Interest Revenue / Total Earning Assets Source: Bankscope; World Bank analysis Figure 2.10 Overheads / Total Assets (%) – Regional Comparisons 12% 10% 8% Uganda 6.4% 6.4% 6.5% Ghana 5.9% 5.8% 6% 5.7% Kenya Nigeria 4% South Africa Tanzania 2% 0% 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Source: Bankscope; World Bank analysis 12 Banking Sector Efficiency Analysis 2-14. The efficiency of intermediation has not improved over the years. Bank-level time series data on deposit and loan rates was provided by the Bank of Uganda.7 Spreads calculated from those data show no strong trend over time. Spreads in 2008 are at the same level as in 2005 (12 to14 percent range), as shown in figure 2.11. There is no evidence of a decline in recent years, despite the decline in overhead costs indicated. This is the most convincing evidence that the efficiency of intermediation has not improved in Uganda in recent years. Figure 2.9: Spreads between Lending and Deposit Rates 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 2005.32005.42006.12006.22006.32006.42007.12007.22007.32007.42008.12008.22008.3 Source: Bank-level data from Bank of Uganda. 2-15. Persistently high spreads reflect a lack of competitive pressure. Arithmetic decompositions of banks‘ interest spreads (described in detail in the annex on bank efficiency at the end of this report) showed no tendency for overhead costs, the primary component of spreads, to decline from 2005 to 2008. Similarly, the portion of the interest spreads ascribed to taxes, reserve requirements, and loan loss provisions remained more or less stable throughout the period. The end result was a stable interest rate spread in the neighborhood of 14 percent. Profit margins, the residual factor in the decomposition exercise, hovered from 5 percent to 6.5 percent. If anything, they were larger at the end of the period than at the beginning. In all, the decompositions point to a lack of competitive pressure in the Ugandan banking sector. 2-16. Market segmentation accounts for much of the lack of competitive pressure. The decompositions also reveal that domestic and foreign banks do not tend to compete with each other. The overhead costs of domestic banks are actually lower than for the 7 The most reliable available indicator of the efficiency of financial intermediation comes from the spreads between the interest rates charged on loans and those paid for deposits. Those figures are based on benchmark deposit and lending rates in order to facilitate as consistent a comparison across countries as possible. Those benchmark rates, especially interest rates on loans, are likely to be more reflective of the situation facing prime customers. 13 sector as a whole, as are their loan loss provisions, indicating that they focus on a credit- worthy market segment and can do so at relatively low cost. And yet the customers of the domestic banks pay substantially higher interest rates on their loans (17-19 percent) than customers in the rest of the banking sector, while domestic banks pay only slightly more for their deposits than the rest of the sector. Together, these factors produce much higher interest spreads for the domestic banks (near 16 percent) than for the foreign banks. The largest component of those spreads is profit margins (around 10 percent), yet another indication that the domestic banks‘ market niche is not highly competitive. 2-17. Foreign banks operate in a selective, but somewhat more competitive, niche. While one might expect that foreign banks would compete for the clientele of the private domestic banks, exerting downward pressure on spreads and profit margins, the decompositions indicate that foreign banks deal with a very different segment of the market. Foreign banks‘ overhead costs are substantially higher than those of the domestic banks (6 percent versus 2.5 percent), presumably because their borrowers receive loans that are more costly to evaluate and maintain, and yet their spreads are much lower. This is true despite the facts that loan loss provisions are slightly higher for foreign banks and the rate that they pay for deposits is somewhat lower than domestic banks, both factors that should contribute to relatively higher spreads. The relatively low interest spreads of the foreign banks can therefore only be achieved by having smaller profit margins, and theirs are well less than half of those of the domestic banks. 2-18. While lower than domestic banks, the spreads of foreign banks have not declined. There is also no strong pattern with regard to the overhead costs, profit margins, or interest spreads of the foreign banks, which have remained around 12-13 percent since 2005. This persistence is further evidence consistent with market segmentation between foreign and domestic banks. 2-19. Spreads have, however, declined for a subset of the foreign banks. Regressions that control for more determinants of interest spreads than the arithmetic decompositions reveal that a subset of the foreign banks has put pressure on spreads. Since 2005, spreads declined for those foreign banks that increased their market shares, intermediation ratios (net loans/liabilities), and the ratio of interest income to total income. Further analysis reveals that those banks hail from developing rather than industrialized countries. It could be that the foreign banks from developing countries contribute to lower spreads, but that this comes at a cost in terms of their profitability and, ultimately, the stability of the banking sector. Given the weak regulatory capabilities of the home countries of some of these banks, this could be cause for concern, and should be monitored. 2-20. Foreign banks from industrialized countries pursue a different strategy. The regressions also reveal that foreign-owned banks from industrialized countries operate in a market niche where cost considerations are much more important in setting spreads (that is, overhead costs are a much more pronounced determinant of their spreads than those of other banks). In contrast to foreign banks from developing countries, we find no significant relationships between spreads and the lending variables, and that the foreign 14 banks from developed countries that were increasing their market share during this period were also ratcheting up spreads. Given other indications that these banks operate in a very specific market niche, the results could be seen as troubling for that group of clients. Finally, the private foreign banks from developed countries have increased their shares of lending to traditional sectors such as manufacturing and trade, yet further indication that they are concentrating on a narrow market segment. 2-21. Lending by private domestic banks has increased, but spreads have not declined. Private domestic banks have seen an increase in their interest income ratios and a large jump in their intermediation ratios. Unfortunately, the regressions indicate that the jumps were not associated with reduced interest spreads. In fact, private domestic banks that were increasing their market shares tended also to increase their spreads from 2005 to 2008. In addition, private domestic banks saw steep increases in the shares of their loan portfolios where increased lending was associated with higher spreads (trade, building and construction, and a catch-all category called other lending). Their spreads might be sufficient to counter the risks, but it is difficult to know at the current point. 2-22. Interest rates for different sectors do not show any pattern. There were no significant changes in the portfolio shares of the banking sector as a whole. And the slight changes in portfolio orientation have not coincided with reductions in the interest rates charged on loans (figure 2.12). The only sector that shows a decline in interest rates is manufacturing, and its portfolio share has remained stable. Lending rates for agriculture are high, but they have always been relatively high, which makes it unlikely that they can account for the decline in lending to that sector. The increase in lending to the trade and commerce sectors cannot be explained by a decline in spreads which have remained at the same level over the past few years. Figure 2.12: Average Lending Interest Rate, Selected Sectors 25 20 15 A g ric ulture Manufac turing T rade & c ommerc e 10 5 0 2005 2006 2007 2008 Source: Bank of Uganda; World Bank analysis 15 Constraints to the Expansion of Lending 2-23. The BOU undertook a lending survey in 2007.8 In 2008 the BOU published the results of ―The Lending Survey for the Second Half, 2006/2007.‖ The survey was conducted by the BOU research department. The results of that survey indicated that the key constraints to the expansion of lending were (i) insufficient information from customers, (ii) unviable business proposals, (iii) lack of adequate collateral, and (iv) frauds and delays at the lands office. 2-24. The WB/BOU banking survey was both quantitative and qualitative. For this survey the Bank team, with the assistance of the BOU Banking Supervision Department, surveyed all 24 formal financial institutions in Uganda during May and June, 2008. The goal of the survey was to determine obstacles to lending, and provide the banks with several open-ended opportunities to express their views.9 The findings generally confirm,10 and also provide additional depth for the conclusions of, the Bank of Uganda Research Department (BOURD) lending survey. 2-25. There is a positive outlook for the expansion of access to finance. The general outlook described by senior bank managers for continued expansion of the banking system was very positive. Each of the banks interviewed reported that it planned to continue to expand both MSME (micro-, small- and medium-size enterprise) lending and to open new branches (over 100 new branches planned for 2008)11 outside Kampala to access new markets. 2-26. However, there are some key constraints to expansion of lending. The WB/BOU survey identified ten key constraints. These can be grouped into two main categories: (i) legal and regulatory constraints, and (ii) information and capacity constraints. Many of these constraints are not new, having been previously identified in the FSAP and CEM. 8 Bank of Uganda (2008). ―The Lending Survey for the Second Half, 2006/07.‖ 9 Although all banks responded, responses to the qualitative section of the questionnaire were generally brief and often incomplete, and few banks completed the quantitative sections of the questionnaire because of difficulties in segregating lending data according to the size of loan and type of borrower. As a result, most useful qualitative information was gathered during interviews conducted in June 2008 with the senior management of 12 formal banks. 10 One exception was the lending survey‘s analysis of the rejection rate for loan applications: the lending survey table 2 indicated that for almost all categories of loans, the approval rate for applications was close to 90 percent. The WB/BOU survey‘s interviews with banks found that in fact, the real rejection rate for would-be borrowers is most likely closer to 30 percent, with the differential being explained by a very high informal rejection rate caused by bank officers simply declining to process applications because the applications would have no chance of being approved. The BOU Research Department agreed with the Bank team that its finding in this regard is likely correct. 11 The number of branches of Tier 1 institutions increased from 194 in Dec 2007 to 301 in Dec 2008. 16 Legal and Regulatory Constraints 2-27. There is insufficient support for creditor rights. The land and mortgage bills under consideration by parliament present a major threat to creditor rights and place burdens on the banks which, in combination, may result in a major reduction in lending. Borrowers for construction and housing loans, and lending to MSME and moderate- to low-income individual borrowers, would likely be severely constricted because they are the most dependent on collateral to obtain finance. Some micro borrowers may not be affected because they receive loans through group lending that is generally not collateralized. 2-28. The legal system is inefficient and ineffective. Despite improvements in the functioning of the legal system as a result of the establishment of separate commercial courts, creditors still face long delays in being able to enforce debt contracts. Erratic decision making by judges often necessitates appeals of what should be routine debt enforcement decisions to higher courts. Even at the highest levels, judges make decisions which appear to reflect a lack of understanding of the role of debt contracts in the economy and the need for firm precedents to create certainty for lenders. Many of the banks interviewed said they feel that the unpredictability and inefficiency of the courts is indicative of a need for greater training of judges at all levels. Separately, the banks indicated that the commercial courts are already becoming clogged by a shortage of judges, the lack of a small claims court system to hear low value cases, and a lack of computerized case management systems. 2-29. The legal framework has not kept up to date with technological advancements. The ability of banks to expand access to financial services using technology (for example, telephone and Internet) is limited by the lack of a legal framework for electronic transactions. Furthermore, the legal framework for advancements in branchless banking is missing. 2-30. The provisioning requirements are stringent. BOU regulations on provisioning are not in compliance with International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS).12 As a result, banks are required to mechanically calculate provisions based on the number of days a credit is overdue, and also to exclude the realizable value of collateral, which results in provisioning in excess of IFRS requirements, thus potentially increasing the cost of lending to higher-risk borrowers.13 The analysis in table 2.5 shows the difference between IFRS specific provisions (which are designed to reflect the economically- required provision against an impaired asset) and the provisions required by BOU 12 Banks prepare their accounts in accordance with IFRS, but the difference between regulatory provisions and IFRS provisions is shown as ―Regulatory Reserves‖ in the capital account. 13 BOU also requires a general provision against credit exposures. This is permissible under IFRS (the same approach is taken in a few other developing countries, but not in Kenya or Tanzania) but, as table 3 shows, can result in excessive levels of provisioning. 17 regulations. The analysis shows that this difference was an average of about 6 percent of total loans for the period 2005 through 2007. Table 2.5: Excess Provisioning by Ugandan Banks, 2005 - 2007 Ratio 31/12/2005 31/12/2006 31/12/2007 Mean Total Provisions to Total Loans 7.81% 7.41% 7.34% 7.52% Specific (IFRS) Provisions to Total Loans 1.18% 0.98% 2.54% 1.57% Implied Excess Provisions 6.63% 6.44% 4.80% 5.95% Source: Bank of Uganda; World Bank analysis 2-31. Opening new branches is costly. The BOU stipulates that banking facilities should provide security for cash and records as well as providing guidance on staffing of new branches. This results in the BOU‘s Banking Supervision Department functioning, in effect, as a city building inspector (checking for the installation of sprinklers, alarms, and the like). This has resulted in very high costs for new branches. Banks reported capital costs of US $35,000 to US $150,000 per new branch opened.14 This is compounded by high operating costs as a result of BoU guidance on staffing and, increasingly, vigorous competition among banks for the limited supply of bank staff, which is driving up wages and consequently escalating the costs of staffing. One result of this is that banks face a significant barrier to entry in smaller towns and rural areas due to the imposition of high costs by this guidance. 2-32. Regulations discourage longer-term lending. BOU regulations and supervisory practices encourage match-funded balance sheets. Given a system-wide paucity of term deposits, this encourages banks to only lend short-term (many banks classified any lending over 12 months as long term). This negatively impacts the availability of appropriately structured lending products for business investment, construction, and housing. Information and Capacity Constraints 2-33. Obtaining land title information is difficult. Improvements are starting to be made in the operations of the land registry, but banks still face delays in getting title information, particularly because of the centralization of the registry in Kampala and a requirement to value each transaction for tax purposes. Computerization of the companies register has not yet started, and banks described it as slow and prone to fraud and incomplete information. 2-34. Credit information is unavailable. The survey identified this as a major constraint. However, the financial institutions were hopeful that the opening of the Credit 14 Some large banks mentioned that part of the high capital costs were to a result their own corporate requirements for maintaining an appropriate image. However, even the more frugal banks expressed concern about the high capital costs required to open a new branch. The costs are high, considering the fact that banks in Latin America and Asia are able to open new rural branches with a capital cost of USD 8,000 - 10,000. 18 Reference Bureau (CRB) would help to solve this problem by collecting data on all bank lending. Particularly for MSMEs and individuals, the banks highlighted the need to expand the CRB—or a private sector alternative—over time, to capture nonbank credit and payments data (such as utility payments) that could provide these types of individual borrowers with bankable credit histories, and thus improve their access to credit. 2-35. There is no crop insurance. The lack of a system of crop insurance is a major barrier to lending to small farmers. Only one bank reported doing any lending to small farmers, and bank financing for agriculture is generally limited to lending to agroprocessors. These agroprocessors in turn extend credit to farmers to purchase inputs such as feed and fertilizer. No information was available on the effective interest rate charged for supplying these inputs. 2-36. Financial literacy is limited. MSME access to credit is limited by a severe lack of basic business skills on the part of entrepreneurs. Banks highlighted the need for extensive outreach programs to develop skills in the areas of bookkeeping, accounting, business plan preparation, and borrower education. Banks identified these issues as the driving force behind the high real rejection rate for loan applications discussed above. Furthermore, the increasingly critical shortage of trained bank staff reinforces this constraint by limiting the availability of staff to work with potential borrowers. 19 Recommendations 2-37. Based on the results of the survey Box 2.1: Introduction of Small Claims Courts in the Philippines and team analysis, the team highlighted a ―The small claims court (SCC) will certainly help small businesses settle disputes without going through long and expensive legal battles. The number of Supreme Court had recently designated 24 first-level courts in Metro recommendations. Manila and selected cities and municipalities all over the country to These related to handle cases involving monetary claims below P100, 000. One of the specific policy or biggest problems faced by small entrepreneurs involves collecting money institutional reforms from delinquent clients, bouncing checks and the like. In such disputes, one of the main problems is the high cost of litigation (usually from that would strengthen attorney‘s fees) as well as the long and arduous legal process which could the ability of banks to tax the resources of a small-scale businessman who is just trying to provide access to recover what is due him. The SCC will certainly be favorable to people finance and to improve who have limited resources, especially if one considers the possibility that the quality of credit the amount of compensation could turn out to be far less than the expenses a litigant would have incurred in the process. ―Small claims‖ provided by, for refers to cases that involve amounts below P100,000, such as debt example, extending the incurred through loans, unpaid mortgages or rentals, and even claims for term of loans being damages to vehicles, property or persons. Perhaps what‘s really striking made available. The about the SCC is the fact that lawyers will not be needed, since the recommendations are disputing parties will be allowed to represent themselves. In the event that a certain party cannot properly present his claim or defense and the judge addressed to the rules that he needs assistance, the court may allow another person to assist primary stakeholders in the plaintiff or defendant – provided that he is not a lawyer. The only time the sector—BOU and a lawyer will be allowed to appear is when he is the plaintiff or defendant. the MoFPED. Policy The SCC judges will also act as ―interventionist umpires,‖ where they reforms include all will be conducting a ―judicial dispute resolution‖ through mediation, conciliation or any other mode to encourage the amicable settlement of recommendations disputes. But if the contending parties refuse to settle amicably, then the related to new laws, judge will schedule a date where the case will be heard and resolved all in regulations or one day….In the Philippines, it takes five to six years to resolve an supervisory practices. ordinary case, and if a party decides to go on appeal, this will take another Institutional reforms five to six years. Ralph Recto (during his stint as senator) had also pointed out the need to strengthen dispute mediation and ―barangay-level‖ relate to strengthening arbitration to lessen the number of cases that are being sent up to the institutions, improving courts - which are already facing a shortage of judges. Obviously, the information, and sheer volume of cases and the lack of judges to handle them have building capacity. contributed to the huge backlog of cases all over the country. In 2005, there were close to 750,000 cases pending in lower courts – and this despite the fact that almost 350,000 cases have been disposed of that year. Policy Reforms In 2007, the backlog in the lower courts remains pretty much the same at approximately 700,000 cases. The SCC is one of the things that a lot of 2-38. Enact an businessmen and ordinary people have been waiting for, since it does electronic transactions away with the high cost of litigation and shortens the legal process which can drag on for years considering the huge number of cases that judges law. To create a have to dispense with. And as Chief Justice Reynato Puno had also supportive legal pointed out, the creation of the small claims courts has ―shortened the framework for distance between our dream of justice for the poor and the cruel reality on innovation, legislation the ground.‖ to establish a legal basis for contracts entered Source: Babe Romualdez 7 October 2008. Philippines Star, ―Small Claims Court Will Help Small Businessmen.‖ 20 into using electronic signatures should be enacted. The legislation should incorporate consumer protection for electronic transactions covering both bank and nonbank (mobile telephone and Internet service) providers. It should also provide a legal basis for existing telephone banking and Internet banking products, reducing banks‘ risks in providing these services. This should encourage the introduction of a wide range of mobile telephone based services, including instant loans, mobile-to-mobile payments, and mobile-to-bank-account payments, similar to those provided by M-PESA in Kenya. Furthermore, opening the market to nonbanks and requiring adequate disclosure should provide a spur to innovation and transparent price competition. This will assist in providing access to the payments system and to banking services for rural areas and unbanked urban populations. Consumer protection features would provide sufficient disclosure to allow customers to understand costs and comparison shop. Any funds held in accounts operated by nonbank service providers could be protected by some form of deposit insurance. 2-39. Establish a small claims procedure system. A small claims procedure system would provide a venue for claims below (for example) UGS 1 million, and provide fast judgment in a single hearing. The design of a small claims procedure system should be ―consumer friendly‖ and the services of a lawyer not required. Judgment is normally rendered on the spot after a short hearing to establish the facts of a case (box 2.1).15 Computerized case management systems are used to provide efficient and timely access to justice. Appeal of small claims procedure decisions requires posting of a significant bond, which encourages litigants to accept the court decisions as final. By providing a cheap, fast mechanism for enforcing small credit claims, small claims procedures encourage banks to lend to MSMEs and individuals by lowering the costs, delays, and risks attendant on enforcement through the regular commercial courts. Routing small claims to the small claims procedure system should help unclog the commercial courts, which are becoming heavily overloaded. Trade credit should also expand because of the reduced cost and ease of collection through such a court. 2-40. Expand the scope of CRB’s activities. The FIA could be amended to allow the CRB to collect data on nonbank payments (for example, utility payments and trade credit) and to enable development of private sector credit information services. Access to credit data would be expanded to nonbank firms seeking data on other firms. With this change, banks would have access to significantly greater amounts of data on actual and potential borrowers. This would allow improved monitoring of clients to reduce risk and allow the development of credit ratings for previously unbanked customers. Furthermore, opening the market to competitors to CRB would allow the introduction of new technologies, and encourage price competition in the credit information market. MSMEs and individuals would be able to establish credit histories using nonbank payments in order to qualify for bank credit. Thus the MSMEs would have improved access to trade 15 The American Bar Association Rule of Law Initiative provides technical assistance (funded by US AID) for the establishment of pilot small claims courts. The Philippines pilot program described in box 2.1 received such technical assistance. (See: http://www.abanet.org/rol/news/news_philippines_small_claims_courts_feature.shtml). 21 credit by being able to establish credit histories based on nonbank payments. Business risk for MSMEs would be reduced by being able to access credit histories of potential credit-based customers. 2-41. Review BOU’s stipulations on branch opening requirements. If the BOU‘s decision making with respect to new branches were limited to deciding if a bank is eligible to open a branch on a prudential basis, the cost structure of new bank branches would be aligned to the services a bank decides are needed for its location. Since alignment of costs should render banks more willing to open more branches, rural and marginal urban areas should see improved access as a result of the reduced cost of opening branches and limited service offices. Increased flexibility should allow banks to design new means of providing physical access to banking services adapted to local market needs. 2-42. Review BOU regulations requiring minimum provisions. By fully implementing IFRS provisions with respect to asset impairment, rather than requiring minimum provisions, the significant cost of excess provisioning required under present regulations would be eliminated. Lower costs for banks to provide credit, especially in a context of intensifying competition within the banking system, should increase lending to MSME and individual clients while also reducing lending rates, thereby reducing spreads. However, it can also be argued that a significant degree of caution should be applied to reducing provisioning requirements in order to take into account: (i) the risks posed by the weaknesses in the framework for creditor rights (for example, the realizable value of collateral is clearly negatively affected by the uncertainties attached to enforcing security), and (ii) the different stages of development of Ugandan banks‘ risk management systems. In light of these factors, reductions in provisioning requirements should be aligned with both improvements in the creditor enforcement framework and the BOU‘s supervisory assessment of each bank‘s risk management capabilities (as the BOU moves to implement risk- based supervision, it will be Box: 2.2: Estimating Core Deposit Maturity—Best Practice making such an assessment as part of its supervisory ―A more robust approach is to calculate the average life of every balance sheet (or perhaps some sufficient strategy for each bank). deposit on the bank‘sis an intractable number)—an alternative sample, if the total Accordingly, changes in would be to calculate the average life of every closed deposit provisioning requirements during some time period. Obviously either of these approaches should be phased in rather requires extensive data on deposits, which many banks do not than introduced all at once, collect or keep. and initially restricted to well ―Many banks are beginning to analyze their core deposits at the capitalized banks with account level, which should be classified as a ―best practice.‖ As prudent risk management they accumulate data, they will be in a position to perform an systems. ongoing analysis of the maturity of these deposits. As a result, they can have more confidence in their estimates of changes in earnings and economic value in different interest rate 2-43. Explore the environments. The results of their models will be more useful in possibility of treating core the bank‘s budget process, to risk managers and to supervisors.‖ deposits as long-term liabilities. The BOU could Source: ―Modeling Core Deposits,‖ Craig West, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, June 2002. 22 conduct a study to determine if a proportion of core deposits could be treated as long- term liabilities for the purpose of assessing asset/liability matching. If a proportion of core deposits were treated as long-term liabilities, banks would be able to increase the supply of term funding for investment lending and mortgages while remaining in compliance with the BOU‘s requirements for matched asset/liability risk. As described in box 2.2, accurately estimating the amount of a bank‘s core deposits requires sophisticated analysis; Accordingly, the BOU should mitigate the risks of loosening matched funding requirements by restricting the ability of banks to treat core deposits as term funding to banks which (i) are capable of carrying out and maintaining the analysis required, and (ii) have strong asset/liability management systems in place. 2-44. Study tax incentives for providing access to finance in rural areas. Tax incentives could have a significant impact in reducing the cost of opening rural branches. The study could examine whether tax incentives (for example, tax exemptions for income earned on small agricultural loans, accelerated depreciation for fixed investments in rural branches) could be used to encourage banks to provide financial services in rural areas.16 If the after-tax profitability of rural lending could be increased sufficiently to encourage more banks to lend directly to farmers, improved rural access to finance and availability of credit for small farmers could increase. Institutional Reforms 2-45. Complete computerization of land and companies registers. With these registers, all land and company records would be computerized and made accessible via the Internet. Liens on land could be registered electronically. As a result, banks and borrowers using land as collateral would face significantly lower transaction costs as a result of elimination of the delays and costs of verifying company records. Furthermore, computerization of the companies register would help to eliminate a significant fraud problem, reducing banks risks. Finally, MSME and individuals‘ access to credit would be significantly improved by allowing land to be efficiently used as collateral. 2-46. Strengthen the court system. There exist multiple ways to strengthen the court system. They include the installation of computerized case management systems, both to increase the efficiency of the courts and to reduce opportunities for corruption. Increasing the number of judges to better match the workload of the commercial courts and providing of training for judges in finance and business to improve the quality of judgments are also key ways to build capacity. By improving the efficiency of the courts, banks would face fewer and lesser delays in enforcing debts, reducing risk and costs and making them more willing to lend. Improved training of judges should result in greater consistency of judgments, increasing confidence in the system and reducing costs and risks by reducing the need for appeals. 2-47. Develop a pilot program for a crop insurance scheme for small farmers. Such a scheme could make the provision of credit to small farmers feasible for banks. A 16 For example, Mozambique provides import duty exemptions for bank branch equipment imported by the first bank to open a branch in a rural area. 23 number of innovative crop insurance programs have been introduced in developing countries, such as Malawi‘s weather insurance scheme. They have the potential to promote the availability of credit for small farmers at commercial bank rates rather than higher microfinance rates. 2-48. Establish financial training programs to improve capacity of entrepreneurs and MSMEs. Capacity-building efforts could provide training in basic accounting, bookkeeping, financial reporting, and basic business planning. Improved understanding of financial management should result in the improved quality of credit applications and reduce the banks‘ costs of providing small loans, ultimately leading to improved access to credit for entrepreneurs and SMEs. Training may also lead to better business performance, leading to improved profits and growth as a result of better planning and investment decisions. If banks provide the training themselves, they may improve their ability to design and deliver appropriate financial products for entrepreneurs and MSMEs by growing more familiar with their target client. The government should explore the options available. For example, the International Finance Corporation (IFC) is supporting entrepreneur education (including in Uganda) through its SME credit lines for banks, and in 2008 the UK Department for International Development (DFID) established the Financial Education Fund for Africa to provide technical assistance to both the banks and NGOs to increase the availability of training. 24 3: Developing Rural and Agricultural Finance 3-1. This chapter provides an overview of the status of and constraints to developing rural and agricultural finance in Uganda. For rural finance, the chapter focuses on the activities of the Savings and Credit Cooperative‘s (SACCOs), which have been identified as the providers of choice in the GoU‘s Rural Financial Services Strategy. The first section provides an overview, while the second section identifies some key obstacles. The third section provides a prioritized framework for improving the efficiency of the system. It should be noted that although there is significant overlap between rural finance and agricultural finance; the two sub-areas are presented separately for ease of analysis. Overview 3-2. Access to finance in rural areas is limited. According to a 2006 Finscope survey, 62 percent of Uganda‘s population has no access whatsoever to financial service (table 1). The divide between urban and rural areas is significant, with 52 percent of the urban population and 65 percent of the rural population unserved. Among the regions, the Central region (excluding Kampala) has the highest proportion of unserved (72 percent), followed by the East and North, while the Western region has fewer people (50 percent) who are unserved than any other region with the exception of Kampala.17 Table 3.1: Financial Access, by Provider Category and Location Population Total (%) Urban (%) Rural (%) Unserved 62 52 65 Banks 16 28 12 Formal MDI 2 3 2 Credit 0 1 0 Institution SACCO 2 2 2 Semiformal MFI 1 1 1 Informal 11 6 12 (excluding Informal ASCAs) ASCAs 5 6 5 VSLA 1 1 1 Source: Steadman Group (2007). 3-3. Formal, semiformal, and informal institutions serve the rural population. Formal financial institutions include commercial banks and micro-deposit taking institutions (MDIs), which are supervised by BoU under the Financial Institutions Act 2004 and the MDI Act 2003, respectively. Semiformal financial institutions have some form of legal status, but are not supervised by BoU. These include SACCOs registered 17 Steadman Group 2007. ―Results of a National Survey on Access to Financial Services in Uganda.‖ Produced for DFID Financial Sector Deepening Project/Finscope. 25 under the Cooperative Societies Statute of 1991, MFIs registered under the Companies Act (CAP 110, Laws of Uganda 2000) and microfinance NGOs registered under the Non- governmental Organizations (NGO) Act (NGO Registration Act CAP 113, Laws of Uganda). Informal institutions encompass all other member-based associations, including village savings and loan associations (VSALs), accumulated savings and credit associations (ASCAs), and rotating savings and credit associations (ROSCAs). 3-4. Formal financial institutions are less prominent in rural areas than in urban areas. Although formal institutions are largely found in urban and periurban areas, they also serve approximately 14 percent of the rural population. Commercial banks have traditionally provided services such as large loans for commodity processing firms and trading companies, letters of credit for importers and exporters, and loans to individual large farmers.18 Some of them, notably Centenary Rural Development Bank, Global Trust Bank (which acquired Commercial Microfinance, Ltd.), and the three MDIs have significant outreach into more rural areas. 3-5. Informal institutions play an important role in rural financial service provision. Informal institutions serve approximately 12 percent of the rural population. ROSCAs and ASCAs, providing small loans and savings services for rural farmers, traders, nonfarm firms, and households are the most common of these informal entities.19 They enjoy significant advantages in proximity and low cost, but some lack security and none can meet the needs of those who want to save or borrow significant amounts of money. Loan delinquencies are often high due to poor lending and collection practices and a high-risk repayment culture. Rural Finance 3-6. The GoU initiated a new Rural Financial Services Strategy (RFSS) to expand rural financial services through SACCOs. The initiative to create new and strengthen existing SACCOs in every sub county aims at encouraging rural households to hold saving accounts and eventually access credit through an established relationship with a SACCO. SACCOs are effective in rural areas because of their simple, cost-effective organizational structures, and—as they are member-based and member-governed—their ability to respond to client needs. The GoU has also increased funding to rural areas through the Microfinance Support Center Limited (MSCL), which provides wholesale lending to SACCOs, who then retail the funds to their members. The 2006 Finscope data show that 2 percent of the rural population is served by SACCOs. This percentage is believed to have increased since the new rural strategy was implemented in 2008. 3-7. There are a total of 1,881 registered SACCOs distributed as shown below and in maps A and B. The main concentration of SACCOs is in the eastern, central, western, and southern regions; in the northern and northeastern regions the concentration 18 Meyer, Richard L. et. al. 2004. ―Agriculture in Uganda: The Way Forward.‖ June. Financial System Development Program Series No. 13 SIDA/GTZ/BoU/KfW 19 Meyer, Richard L. et al. 2004. ―Agriculture in Uganda: The Way Forward.‖ June. Financial System Development Program Series No. 13 SIDA/GTZ/BoU/KfW 26 is low. The combined membership is 644,318.20 Despite the large number of SACCOs, there are still rural areas where they are needed, but none operate. This has hampered access to financial services by the rural poor. Table 3.2: Distribution of SACCOs, by District REGION No. of Districts No. of SACCOs Kigezi 4 105 Central 6 210 Victoria-Masaka 6 136 Mbale 11 243 Busoga 7 293 West nile 7 100 Karamoja 5 42 Teso 5 129 Ankole 6 196 Bunyoro 5 79 Luweero 4 61 Northern 9 162 Midwestern 5 125 80 1881 Source: Department of Microfinance, Ministry of Finance Planning and Economic Development (MoFPED) (March 31, 2009) 20 UCSCU July 2008. 27 Map A: Distribution of SACCOs and MFI Companies in Uganda Note: NGOs are not counted 28 Map B: Coverage of Sub-counties by SACCOs Note: Sub-counties as of 2001. Source: MoFPED 2006. ―Report of a Census of Financial Institutions.‖ 29 3-8. The GoU created a new Department of Microfinance (DMF) in the MoFPED to manage the government’s Rural Financial Services Strategy. It also designated UCSCU to become the primary apex organization for all SACCOs, and to provide advocacy, training, and education for its members—in particular for the establishment and strengthening of SACCOs under RFSS. 3-9. Improved operational performance is needed in the SACCO subsector. Some SACCOs and other MFIs have failed to deliver promised services, leaving their members without financial services and diminishing confidence in SACCOs and MFIs generally. Improvements could be achieved by establishing basic, mandatory prudential standards, by enforcing governance and transparency requirements, and by providing technical assistance to help meet those standards within an established strategy. This strategy is being spearheaded by the Rural Finance Services Programme (RFSP), funded by the International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD) and managed by the World Bank. UCSCU is responsible for the self-regulation and supervision of SACCOs, but lacks institutional capacity to carry out these duties. 3-10. SACCOs have no legal or regulatory framework as financial intermediaries. With the evolution of microfinance as a profitable business sector, most of the SACCOs now are concentrating on mobilizing savings and advancing loans to their members on a commercial basis. This has made the Cooperative Statute (1991) inadequate for regulating and supervising SACCOs. Agricultural Finance 3-11. Agriculture is a key sector in Uganda’s economy. It contributes up to 21 percent21 of GDP, accounts for 48 percent of exports (Uganda Bureau of Statistics [UBOS] 2008), provides a large proportion of the raw materials for industry, and employs 73 percent of the population aged 10 years and older (UBOS 2005).22 The sector comprises mainly small-scale, low-technology farmers with low levels of investment. These characteristics, and the sector‘s dependence on rainfed agricultural production, contribute to the general perception among formal lenders that agriculture-based clients- represent high levels of risk. 3-12. Real growth in agriculture output declined from 7.9 percent in 2000/01 to 0.7 percent in 2007/08 (UBOS 2008).23 This decline starkly contrasts with the same period‘s average national GDP growth rate of 6.5 percent and is below the population growth rate of 3.4 percent. As shown in table 3.3, the decline affected several subsectors of agriculture: cash, and food crops, livestock, and fisheries. 21 This is based on the re-based GDP calculation. Under the original series, it was 31 percent. 22 UBOS 2005. 2002 Population and Housing Census. Main Report. 23 UBOS 2008. Statistical Abstract. 30 Table 3.3: Industry, Services, and Agricultural Sector Growth Rates Sector 2003/4 2004/5 2005/6 2006/07 2007/08 Agriculture 1.6 2.0 0.5 0.1 0.7 Cash crops 7.3 -5.5 -10.6 5.4 2.2 Food crops -1.5 -0.2 -0.1 -0.9 2.4 Livestock 4.7 3.0 1.6 3.0 3.0 Fisheries 9.6 13.5 5.6 -3.0 -12.4 Industry 8.0 11.6 14.7 9.9 6.4 Services 7.9 6.2 12.2 8.8 13.0 Source: Background to the Budget 2008/09 FY 2008. MoFPED. 3-13. The agricultural sector’s contribution to overall growth of GDP is important. The sector‘s contribution to GDP growth was projected at 1 percent for 2007/08, compared to 3 percent for industry and 3 percent for services—the two more powerful sectors in terms of share in total GDP. Though the share of agricultural production in total GDP has fallen from its 2002/03 level of 24 percent, it remains a key sector, contributing 21 percent in 2007/08 (table 3.4). Table 3.4: Sector Contribution to GDP at Current Prices (%) Sector 2003/4 2004/05 2005/06 2006/07 2007/08 Agriculture/* 23.8 25.1 24.1 22.5 21.4 Industry 22.9 23.5 22.8 24.4 24.4 Services 47.4 45.4 47.2 47.4 49.0 Source: UBOS (2004 and 2007). Statistical Abstracts *including forestry 3-14. The continued decline in the agriculture sectors’ growth rate and contribution to GDP growth raise concerns regarding performance of the sector. Agricultural exports (primarily coffee, fish, and flowers24) have traditionally brought foreign exchange income into the country. Given the concentration of employment in the agricultural sector, the decline in growth is a setback in the drive to eradicate poverty. 3-15. Agricultural finance significantly impacts the overall performance of the economy. Given that the majority of all households in Uganda are engaged in agriculture, agricultural finance (the subset of rural finance dedicated to financing agriculture-related activities, such as input supply, production, marketing, and distribution) plays a critical role. Agricultural lending has doubled since 2006 (table 3.5). Still, the vast majority of bank funding has been provided in the form of short-term working capital loans to nonagricultural sectors. 3-16. Agricultural Credit Facility. The GoU announced in the 2009/10 budget speech25that it will provide UGS 30 billion for borrowers in the agricultural sector. Participating financial and credit institutions will provide an equivalent amount, creating a revolving pool of loanable funds amounting to UGS 60 billion. 24 :MoFPED. 25 MoFPED Budget Speech 2009/10. 31 Table 3.5: Agriculture Lending by Banks (billions) Year 2006 2007 2008 Agricultural 117 197 236 Lending Source: Bank of Uganda (2008). Annual Supervision Report. 3-17. The demand for financial services varies among categories of farmers. Three broad groups of farmers operate in Uganda: commercial farmers, semicommercial farmers, and subsistence farmers. A 2004 estimate cited more than 60,000 farmers and fishermen operating on a commercial scale.26 Some demands by larger entities for agriculture finance are met, but even for these clients, there is unmet demand for term loans and other financial products such as insurance. The demand for funds among semicommercial farmers is similar to that of commercial farmers, though on a smaller scale. Some farmers in this category are linked to nucleus estates where they are outgrowers but still require their own source of funding. Kinyara Sugar, Ltd. in Masindi, has an outgrowers scheme for sugarcane. A total of about 3,17627 farmers are presently supplying 27,000 tons of cane per annum—42 percent of the company‘s annual requirement. This has boosted farmer‘s incomes by about UGS 6 billion, in the form of loans from KSL to its farmers. 3-18. Subsistence farmers and rural villagers present the greatest challenge to the supply of financial services because they are a high risk. With more than three million households involved in subsistence farming, they are by far the most numerous of the farmer groupings. Rural villagers who do not produce enough for market also have financing needs.28 There is a great need to develop and disseminate efficient screening techniques that can identify creditworthy borrowers among these groups and increase their chances of obtaining needed funds. 3-19. Banks primarily finance large agricultural entities. Commercial banks make large loans for agricultural commercialization. They finance import and export operations and provide services to large farms and major fishing entities, processors, and marketers. According to the Finscope study (see table 3.6), 13 percent of agricultural loans were provided by banks and other formal financial institutions in 2007. Although the number of bank branch networks has increased in recent years, their relevance in the form of services to small, dispersed agricultural producers and marketers is likely to remain limited. Two banks that are particularly active in providing agricultural finance are Centenary Rural Development Bank and DFCU Bank, both of which take advantage of a Danish International Development Agency (DANIDA) fund that guarantees 50 percent of the banks loans to agriculture. In the three years since the fund‘s inception, it has performed well, with guarantees totalling UGS.28 billion.29 26 Meyer, Richard L. et. al. 2004. ―Agriculture in Uganda: The Way Forward.‖ June. Financial System Development Program Series No. 13 SIDA/GTZ/BoU/KfW. 27 Agriculture Finance Year Book 2008. SIDA/GTZ/BoU/KfW. 28 Meyer, Richard L. et. al. 2004. ―Agriculture in Uganda: The Way Forward.‖ June. Financial System Development Program Series No. 13 SIDA/GTZ/BoU/KfW. 29 ASPS-DANIDA Report June 2009. 32 3-20. Informal sources play an important role in the provision of inputs. Funding for purchase of seeds and fertilizers comes mainly from informal financial groups and other informal sources in rural areas. Nearly two-thirds of financing for agricultural purposes in rural areas, and nearly all of the agricultural financing in urban areas (funding traders in agricultural inputs and produce) comes from such informal financial groups as ROSCAs, ASCAs, and other sources (table 3.6). Table 3.6: Incidence of Borrowing for Agricultural Purposes, by Source and Location Population Total (%) Urban (%) Rural (%) Formal 11 0 13 (Banks, MDIs, and credit institutions) Semiformal 25 0 31 SACCOs and other MFIs Informal Financial Groups 35 41 34 ROSCAs, ASCAs, and other informal groups Other informal sources 31 66 21 Individuals, friends, family members, traders in fertilizers, traders in seeds, growers, etc Source: Steadman Group 2007. ―Results of a National Survey on Access to Financial Services in Uganda.‖ Produced for DFID Financial Sector Deepening Project/Finscope. 3-21. Microfinance institutions and SACCOs have mixed performance records. MFIs make mostly short-term loans, often with group guarantees and frequent payment schedules. This type of financing is better suited to trading enterprises with high turnover, and not to farming enterprises with more irregular and seasonal cash flows. Some MFIs in rural areas have experienced rapid growth and high loan recovery rates, demonstrating a demand for services in these areas. SACCOs also provide agricultural finance in the rural areas. However, as mentioned earlier, they need improved performance to play a broader role in the sector. 3-22. Leasing for agricultural finance has been limited. Although leasing has a long history in Uganda, leasing of agricultural machinery and equipment has been limited. Leasing affords the lessee the advantage of possessing the asset to generate revenue without paying for it with up-front capital. The asset becomes the collateral and the farmer gets the benefit of using productive assets without necessarily owning it.30 However, tax treatment of leasing is one of the many factors that have inhibited growth of leasing in Uganda. The absence of a strong secondary market for leased equipment also affects development. 3-23. Efforts have been made to broaden the usage of warehouse receipts. Until recently, larger traders were the primary recipients of bank advances secured by warehouse receipts. The Ugandan government started a program in 2001 to widen the 30 FSD Programme – SIDA/GTZ/BoU/KfW. Policy paper on Leasing and Agricultural Finance. 33 scope of warehouse receipt system by implementing a regulated warehouse receipt system. In May 2006, in response to a key requirement of the banks, government passed the Warehouse Receipt System Act and created a regulatory authority for the system called the Uganda Commodity Exchange (UCE). The UCE has designed and put in place the general regulatory system and developed the contractual framework governing the operation of licensed warehouses; developed grading systems for grains and drafted the standards for coffee, cotton, beans, maize and rice; implemented a form of electronic warehouse receipts for Uganda; and managed the development of the electronic system linked to that of South Africa.31 Constraints 3-24. This section discusses key constraints to the expansion of rural finance, focusing on problems affecting SACCOs and impediments to increasing access to agricultural finance. Rural Finance 3-25. A legal and regulatory framework for Tier 4 institutions as financial intermediaries is lacking. During 2009 MoFPED has been working on preparing a Tier 4 regulatory bill for presentation to parliament. When approved, a new Tier 4 Act will allow for all MFI‘s (including SACCOs) to be formally regulated, supervised, and considered as financial cooperatives. Currently, there is no effective supervisory function for SACCOs and no monitoring system for supervisors. 3-26. Capacity to supervise and regulate SACCOs is low. UCSCU was chosen a year ago by the government as the main apex entity for all SACCOs in the country. It does not currently possess a national apex structure that can be responsive to the needs and issues of SACCOs at the regional and local levels. UCSCU needs to be strengthened to deliver services to its members on a sustainable basis, especially in terms of strategic planning, operational procedures, experience and training of new staff. Strong regional networks of SACCOs that would facilitate a more effective interaction between UCSCU and its members, as well as with other national structures and programs, are absent. 3-27. Financial products are limited. Other than basic savings and loan products, few other financial services are available to SACCO members, particularly for those involved in the agriculture sector. There are no insurance products, including for crops and livestock. Limited financial literacy in rural areas also constrains SACCO activities. 3-28. Human resources and skills are often lacking. SACCOs often lack qualified staff to manage their operations. Despite their rapid growth, limited skills development opportunities for SACCOs are available. A cooperative training college exists, but this 31 FSD Programme SIDA/GTZ/BoU/KfW. Policy paper by Baine, Christian, Executive Director, Coronet Group, Ltd. ―Development of Warehouse Receipt Instruments in Uganda and the Role of the Uganda Commodity Exchange.‖ 34 expertise is limited to those few who already have a basis of training. There is insufficient pool expertise to push development forward on the scale required. 3-29. Basic infrastructure and MIS technology are inadequate. Many rural areas are quite remote and lack good roads and power. Mobility is often a problem as roads are not passable in the rainy season. Without power, computers and mobile phones that have become a regular part of financial service provision in Uganda cannot be used. SACCOs could utilize technology-driven remote access to serve clients in areas away from their physical presence. However, where packages are available and affordable, there is often inadequate expertise within the SACCOs to fully utilize these tools. 3-30. The availability of credit information continues to be problematic for MFIs, including SACCOs. It is difficult to obtain reliable credit information when considering an applicant for a loan. The lack of a national ID compounds the problem by making it difficult even to verify the identity of a prospective borrower. While the recently launched Credit Reference Bureau should reduce this problem nationally, MFIs are not members of CRB. Agriculture Finance 3-31. Collateral remains a key impediment to agriculture finance. The present status of land titling, registration and security of land tenure prevent the use of land as collateral for loans.32 To engage in agricultural lending, Centenary Bank has accepted collateral such as dated checks, equipment acquired through micro-leasing and animal traction loans for purchase of ox ploughs and oxen. DFCU Bank has also used the leasing of machinery and equipment to expand access to finance. There is also scope to improve the efficiency and lower the cost of managing stored products as collateral, to enable more traders to take advantage of warehouse receipts. 3-32. Agricultural leasing has been constrained by unsupportive taxation. The growth of the leasing portfolio in Uganda has been limited. All interest payments for leased VAT-exempt assets are subject to VAT of 18 percent, whereas if these assets are borrowed as loans, they have no VAT on interest payments. This makes leasing, which is otherwise a suitable financial mechanism for all types of businesses, less attractive than it should be and more expensive than a loan. The capital allowance (wear and tear) on equipment is for income tax purposes allowed to the lessee, who in most cases does not keep records and therefore cannot benefit from the allowance. Other impediments to agricultural leasing include the fact that agricultural equipment is often small, relatively inexpensive, and not easily identifiable, and costs to repossess assets in rural areas are higher than in urban areas.33 3-33. The scale of warehouse receipt operations has been limited by lack of economies of scale and limited tolerance for risk from banks. Warehouse receipt systems favor major scale economies, both in terms of managing warehouses and 32 Meyer, Richard L. et. al. 2004. ―Agriculture in Uganda: The Way Forward.‖ June. Financial System Development Program Series No. 13 SIDA/GTZ/BoU/KfW 33 FSD Programme SIDA/GTZ/BoU/KfW. Policy paper on Leasing and Agricultural Finance 35 providing regulatory oversight or certification. The management and regulatory costs associated with servicing small and large warehousing sites are not very different. Banks have demonstrated limited tolerance for risk from the agricultural sector, and will only lend to farmers or traders with contracts for selling produce. Initial findings indicate that the banks are showing strong interest, but are concerned that the system should be sufficiently regulated by UCE to minimize performance risk and risk of fraud at the producer level, and to facilitate the liquidation of collateral quickly and at low cost.34 3-34. Factoring has been limited by insufficient credit information about companies. Factoring enhances cash flow by enabling suppliers to be paid by the bank upon presentation of invoices for goods supplied. The bank is then paid by the buyer of the goods. Factoring is not frequently used as a formal product among banks, although it can be used by both new and mature companies. Invoices are discounted but the volumes are small. The main impediment to factoring is that there is no credit rating for factoring companies; it is difficult, or impossible, to determine the inherent risk in the invoices being discounted. 3-35. Long-term funds. There is limited availability of long-term funds for agriculture. Periods given by FIs are short—less than 12 months. This is mainly for working capital. FIs mention that agriculture entails high risk due to weather, disease, and post-harvest handling, storage, and market conditions. They also complain about recipients not paying, but this is being addressed by the introduction of the Credit Reference Bureau. 3-36. The funds for agricultural credit guarantees scheme are limited. A partial agricultural credit guarantee mechanism, funded by DANIDA, has reportedly been successful, as already noted. The risk is shared on a 50-50 basis between the banks and guarantor. More capital is needed to increase the guarantee fund and incentivize banks to participate. Recommendations 3-37. A number of specific policy and institutional reforms would strengthen the ability of providers to supply access to finance and to improve the quality of services provided. The recommendations below are focused on strengthening SACCOs and the supply of agricultural finance, and should be addressed by the primary stakeholders in the sector— BoU and the MoFPED. Policy reforms include all recommendations related to new laws, regulations, or supervisory practices. Institutional reforms relate to strengthening institutions, improving information, and building capacity. Rural Finance 34 FSD Programme SIDA/GTZ/BoU/KfW. Policy paper by Baine, Christian, Executive Director, Coronet Group, Ltd. ―Development of Warehouse Receipt Instruments in Uganda and the Role of the Uganda Commodity Exchange.‖ 36 3-38. Strengthen UCSCU as an apex organization for SACCOs. The GoU has been undertaking this activity under the IFAD funded Rural Financial Services Program. This activity should be continued so that UCSCU can provide the necessary support to SACCOs with the ultimate aim of having strong sustainable SACCOs that can be licensed once the regulatory framework is in place. 3-39. Institute a legal and regulatory framework for Tier 4 institutions, including SACCOs. Well directed political will and changes in the regulatory environment could create the necessary momentum for investment into the rural finance sector to begin scaling up to the levels necessary to close the gap. The MoFPED should present to parliament the draft legislation for regulation and supervision of Tier 4 institutions. A suitable regulatory structure in the form of an independent Tier 4 Regulatory Authority (Tier 4-RA) should be established once the Tier 4 Bill is passed by parliament. 3-40. Develop an interim supervisory function for Tier 4 institutions including SACCOs. While waiting for the creation of an independent Tier 4-RA, the supervision of the SACCOs and other Tier 4 organizations should be assumed by the DMF at MoFPED. DMF should also work on the licensing criteria and the regulatory and supervision frameworks to effectively supervise SACCOs. DMF is planning to undertake a survey of existing SACCOs in the country for proper classification for regulation and supervision purposes. 3-41. Promote external audits of SACCOs. Licensed SACCOs will require two-year audits of their accounts. The Performance Monitoring Tool (PMT) developed by the Association of Microfinance Institutions of Uganda (AMFIU) is an effective management tool that is used to collect data and generate reports to show performance. The DMF should verify the proper execution and completion of these audits. Agricultural Finance 3-42. Institute an independent leasing law. A well drafted leasing law governing leasing operations should be of substantial benefit to the industry. Contractual provisions between parties (the lessor and the lessee) currently present challenges, as enforcing them can become an extremely lengthy and costly process. The legislation is particularly important to small businesses that require simple documentation. This will ultimately lead to simpler and shorter lease contract documents. 3-43. Develop cost-effective crop and livestock insurance products. Reducing yield risk through crop and livestock insurance could potentially have significant impact in Uganda—particularly because it is the only country in the region capable of producing two crops a year (for most crops). A cost-effective means of reducing production risk, such as index-based (weather-based) insurance, would substantially mitigate the risk a lender perceives when lending to farmers. Donors are looking into the relative importance of different sources of risk in Ugandan agriculture, for example, price volatility versus yield variability. Livestock insurance policy was available in the past from the (then) National Insurance Corporation; it was discontinued because of low 37 demand, despite its profitability. The policy was a mortality cover only for cross-bred cattle (not indigenous breeds). The biggest population of cattle is indigenous and that is what the small farmers have. . Life insurance could also be explored when linked to term loans as a way of mitigating the risks faced by lenders. 38 4: Improving Payments and Remittances Systems 4-1. This chapter first provides an overview of the current payment, remittances, and securities settlement arrangements in Uganda, and then moves to future implementation plans. Following these are the results of an assessment based on international standards and best practices, identification of key challenges for the improvement and future development of the payment, remittances, and securities clearance and settlement arrangements. The final section provides recommendations that can provide tangible and timely results in the short to medium term and contribute to significant enhancement of the systems. Overview of the Payments System 4-2. BOU provides the interbank settlement infrastructure. This allows final settlement of the main payment systems in central bank money. The main cashless payment instruments available in Uganda are large-value credit transfers, checks, electronic retail debit and credit transfers, and payment card systems. 4-3. BOU has taken some important steps to modernize the large value payment system. A realtime gross settlement (RTGS) system was launched by BOU in 2005. The system allows secure electronic interbank and third-party customer transfers with immediate finality across the counterparty accounts at the central bank. Furthermore, the system is now integrated with the central securities depository for government and central bank securities, which ensures the settlement of government securities transactions on a delivery versus payment (DvP) basis. 4-4. The operations of the RTGS system are generally compliant with international standards for risk mitigation and efficiency. To encourage timely initiation of payments throughout the day, the BOU has implemented a tiered pricing structure. Three payment windows have been defined, with transaction fees ranging from UGS 750 to 1,500, depending on the time of day. These relatively low fees were designed to encourage migration from checks and promote the use of the RTGS system for interbank and third-party payments. However, third-party users (bank customers) have not benefited from this pricing structure, as banks still charge high fees, ranging from UGS 10,000 to UGS 100,000 per transaction. 4-5. The liquidity optimizing feature of the RTGS is not operational. BOU postponed the commissioning of the liquidity optimizing feature of the RTGS system, choosing instead to enforce the prefunding requirement in order to encourage the banks to prioritize their own payments before transmitting payment requests, rather than relying on the system‘s queuing capability. In addition, the BOU believes that the current high levels of liquidity in the banking system make liquidity optimization less critical. This policy could be revisited in light of current liquidity pressures worldwide. 39 4-6. The BOU has also implemented an electronic retail payment system. This system is meant to improve the efficiency of the clearing process and to expand electronic check clearing nationwide in order to reduce and standardize the clearing period for checks to T+3. Electronic debit and credit payment instructions are settled through an electronic funds transfer system for retail payments. 4-7. In recent years, there has been a steady migration from checks to electronic instruments. This has been aided by the BOU‘s July 2007 imposition of a UGS 20 million limit on checks processed in the electronic clearinghouse. The table below shows the declining trend in check usage and the increase in RTGS transactions. Table 4.1: Non-Cash Payment Instruments Value of Transactions Volume of Transactions (UGS in Billions) 2006 2007 2008 2006 2007 2008 RTGS 40,402 61,167 55,603 RTGS 169,655 229,477 229,059 80.9% 87.1% 86.0% 9.1% 11.6% 6.5% EFT 123 1,799 4,501 EFT 167,021 398,439 1,872,830 0.9% 2.5% 7.0% 9.0% 20.0% 53.5% CHECKS 9,438 7,279 4,535 CHECKS 1,523,348 1,357,817 1,397,954 18.2% 10.4% 7.0% 81.9% 68.4% 40.0% TOTAL 49,963 70,245 64,639 TOTAL 1,860,024 1,985,733 3,499,843 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% Source: Bank of Uganda. 4-8. The card infrastructure is quite limited, and card-based systems are not integrated. The infrastructure consists of 340 ATMs and 279 POS terminals. A private entity, Bankom, operates a switch under an exclusive license from the BOU. The license was granted on the expectation that all banks would use Bankom‘s switch infrastructure, and that this would contribute to the wider distribution and use of payment cards and other electronic payment services. The envisaged system-wide interoperability has not yet been achieved, however, as only the smallest banks use the Bankom network. Participating banks charge high fees, especially on interbank transactions, which makes it uneconomical for customers to use other banks‘ machines. Both factors have contributed to a low usage of ATMs and POS terminals. 4-9. Mobile payment services are not yet available. At least one telecommunications company is preparing to launch a mobile payment service. The BOU is committed to making mobile payment services available to rural and unbanked citizens as a cornerstone of its strategy to promote and encourage the wider use of banking services and ultimately increase access to finance. However, the BOU has not yet determined the appropriate legal and regulatory framework under which mobile payment service providers would operate. 4-10. There is an “unofficial� foreign currency payments system. Customers maintain foreign currency accounts with the local banks, and there is an ―unofficial‖ clearing among banks where foreign checks are exchanged. The BOU does not participate in this clearing, nor does it receive reports of the outputs from the process. 40 Information on the number and value of items cleared is therefore not available, but is said to be significant. 4-11. The government is the single largest user of the payments system. The treasury has made significant progress in reducing the use of checks for government payments and is executing the bulk of its payments electronically. Already, salaries of public employees are paid by direct credit transfers in commercial bank accounts. This not only makes the internal operations of the treasury and government agencies more efficient, it also provides a major opportunity for commercial banks to attain the critical mass of customers to achieve viability in the development and delivery of new electronic payment instruments such as payment cards and direct credit and direct debit services. 4-12. Government accounts are held in the central bank. In addition, the BOU is spearheading a project which will give the treasury origination access for the transfer of funds via the interbank settlement system. It is also envisaged that eligible microfinance institutions will be linked to the payments system so that payees/recipients who do not maintain traditional bank accounts can receive payments electronically and in a timely way. 4-13. International remittances are increasingly relevant for Uganda. In 2006, remittances received represented 8.7 percent of the GDP, while those sent by migrants in Uganda amounted to 3.5 percent of the GDP. From an end-to-end perspective, the remittance market in Uganda is mainly cash to cash, and there are no reliable estimates on the average cost of sending money into the country, as approximately 80 percent of all remittances are deemed to be channelled through nonlicensed entities and/or through individuals. On the basis of the figures provided by the various remittance service providers (RSPs) interviewed, the team calculated a cost range from a minimum of 6 percent to a maximum of 14 percent. 4-14. The licensed remittance sector is dominated by a limited number of big players. These are mainly money transfer operators (MTOs) such as Western Union and MoneyGram, both of which are affiliated with large financial conglomerates and to the postal system. Most of the agreements between local agents and international MTOs are service-based agreements in which the international companies provide their partners with their collection network and local agents disburse the remittances to the final beneficiary in Uganda. Banks, in particular, rely on the international platform and collection network of major international MTOs. Smaller remittance service providers (RSPs) usually only have local representation in foreign exchange bureaus. Constraints to the Expansion of the Payments System 4-15. The Bank team identified a number of constraints to the expansion of the payments system. These can be grouped into two main categories: (i) legal and regulatory constraints, and (ii) infrastructure, information, and capacity constraints. Legal and Regulatory Constraints 41 4-16. There is no comprehensive payments systems law. At present there is no comprehensive law to support payments, remittances, and securities settlement arrangements. A payments system bill has still not yet been drafted, while companion bills governing electronic transactions and securities transactions have remained in draft form for several years. As a result of this void, the BOU is in the main relying on the law of contract. This is generally inappropriate, given that contract law does not provide the level of legal protection necessary to secure payment and settlement arrangements. Furthermore, contract law does not address important issues such as (i) clarity of timing of final settlement, especially when there is an insolvency; (ii) legal recognition of (bilateral and multilateral) netting arrangements; (iii) recognition of electronic processing of payments (for example, can electronic signatures/documents be used as evidence in the court of law?); (iv) absence of any zero-hour or similar rules; (v) enforceability of security interests provided under collateral arrangements, and of any relevant repossession agreements; (vi) protection from third-party claims on securities and other collateral pledged in a payment system; (vii) payment system oversight powers of the central bank; and (viii) regulation of the remittance market and RSPs. 4-17. BOU does not have formal and explicit powers to perform payment system oversight. Even though BOU currently carries out many of the typical oversight functions, this is not explicitly provided for in legislation. Such authority normally derives from statute and could be addressed in the new legislation. 4-18. Access to the electronic funds transfer system is inequitable. Licensed deposit- taking institutions have different levels of access to the interbank settlement systems. Only Tier 1 institutions have direct access to these systems, with all other institutions participating through them. Tier 2 and Tier 3 institutions, though supervised by the BOU, are not permitted to operate accounts with the central bank. The tiered access to the core payment infrastructures gives Tier 1 institutions an unfair advantage over Tier 2 and 3 institutions. In addition, this system may be hindering competition, limiting consumer access to payment services, and keeping the price of payment services high. 4-19. Charges for electronic payment services are high. BOU provides the interbank settlement infrastructure that allows final settlement for the key retail systems in central bank money. However the high charges levied by banks for payment services are a disincentive to their use, and frustrate the BOU‘s intention that the benefits of the enhanced payments infrastructure be passed on to users. In particular, the BOU has moderated its charges to the commercial banks in an effort to encourage migration from checks, and to promote the use of the RTGS system for interbank and third-party payments. Banks have not, however, reciprocated to reduce their RTGS customer charges. These fees can be up to 100 times the BOU charge to the bank. 4-20. Lack of effective oversight of the payment system. High bank charges have long operated as a disincentive to the use of payment and banking services and have stymied growth in the use of electronic instruments. Within the ambit of its oversight role, the BOU would normally seek to promote competition in the provision of payment 42 services and ensure the protection of consumer interests. This is especially important given the absence of a formal ―competition authority.‖ 4-21. The oversight of remittance service providers needs to be strengthened. Different RSPs interviewed had adopted manuals, codes, and good governance procedures, and stated that their employees have been properly trained. However, although every RSP is required to comply with internal AML/CFT guidelines issued by the BOU, the practical enforcement of these guidelines is in doubt. Most of the RSPs interviewed had no clear idea how to address possible warnings of suspicious transactions and were unsure of the detailed procedures to be followed in reporting such activity. Infrastructure, Information, and Capacity Constraints 4-22. Lack of an integrated service platform for card payments. Card payment systems in Uganda are for the most part a collection of individual services and instruments provided by commercial banks and nonbank financial institutions. The significant variation among banks in the charges they levy for ATM use, and the relatively high commissions paid by merchants for POS transactions—on average 5 percent—effectively neutralize the intended benefits of interoperability. 4-23. Bankom has an exclusive license to operate a central card switch, but interoperability has still not been achieved. Four years ago, the BOU issued an exclusive license to Bankom, a private company, to operate a central card switch in order to achieve interoperability among the banks‘ card-based systems. (The license expires in November 2009.) Bankom utilizes a shared electronic transaction switching network that allows withdrawals at cash dispensers (ATM); electronic funds transfer (EFT); facilitates payments through debit point of sale (POS) terminals; and effects settlement between members. Debit cards used for withdrawing cash or making payments in this EFT/POS environment are fully interoperable among Bankom members, providing customers the added convenience of being able to make and receive payments at any participating bank. 4-24. The Bankom license has not been effective in rationalizing payment service provision. So far, only five smaller banks have joined, so a significant proportion of bank customers are not provided with the envisaged convenience of being able to access a wider network of ATMs and POS terminals. The larger banks have been unwilling to participate, as for some, the size of their ATM operations rivals or exceeds the size of the Bankom network. The market remains segmented, so that even among the Bankom participants, utilization of other banks‘ machines is low and declining sharply (table 4.2). Table 4.2: Bankom’s Interbank Settlement Totals (in UGS millions) 2006 2007 2008 2009 (upto oct) Total 11,772 16,904 1,964 1,340 Average Monthly 981 1,408 163 111 Lowest Monthly 298 558 14 18 Source: Bank of Uganda. 43 4-25. Bankom’s viability is threatened. The low network usage is due, inter alia, to the fact that transaction fees tend to be particularly high on interbank transactions. Significantly, for a four-week period during April and May 2008, no interbank usage was recorded among the participant banks, which suggests that customers are either using their own bank‘s machines or none at all. As a result of the foregoing, Bankom‘s viability is threatened, customers are not afforded the convenience of a wider network of ATMs and POS terminals, and the authorities‘ goal of wide reach and full geographic coverage of electronic payment services in Uganda, especially to the unbanked rural populace, is not being achieved. 4-26. Overall card usage is low, but there is potential to leverage the credit bureau infrastructure to expand access to, and use of, cards. At the end of 2007, 1.5 million cards had been issued and 340 ATMs and 279 POS terminals were deployed by banks. For POS terminals, this is a ratio of less than 10 terminals per 1 million persons, extremely low compared to other countries in Africa: 130 POS terminals per 1 million inhabitants in Zimbabwe, 350 in Egypt, 500 in Morocco, and nearly 14,000 in South Africa. One significant recent development in Uganda is the commissioning of the Credit Reference Bureau (CRB), which uses smart-card technology. The significantly higher cost of this technology may not be justified unless these cards are used for multiple purposes. In particular, smart-card technology could be used for payment services (as a debit card) and as a national identification card. One well-known benefit of smart-card technology is improved security (with associated fraud reduction), and the possibility of use of "offline" card transaction approvals, so unreliable telephone communications becomes less of a problem. 4-27. Tax collection arrangements are inefficient. In contrast to electronic government payments, the current arrangements for tax collection are inefficient and costly to both the Uganda Revenue Authority and the taxpayer. URA maintains over 60 accounts at commercial banks, to which all payments are credited. Separate accounts are held at the various branches of each bank. This appears to be a legacy arrangement which predates the modernization and integration of the banks‘ internal systems—which now make possible seamless intrabank/interbranch transfers. The operation of such a large number of accounts is unnecessary, inefficient, and costly. In addition, the fees charged by banks to receive these payments appear to be unreasonably high, ranging from UGS 1,000 to 2,000 per transaction. 4-28. There are risks in the securities settlement process. Securities settlement arrangements in Uganda do not comply with the CPSS-IOSCO Recommendations for Securities Settlement Systems, the international standards for this segment of the National Payments System. The Uganda Stock Exchange (USE) currently engages in a very cumbersome settlement process. Checks are exchanged among brokers for settlement of equity trades. Settlement is performed on a gross basis. USE is not currently permitted to operate an account at the central bank. It does not utilize an electronic depository and there is currently no DvP settlement for capital market trades, with the resultant settlement risk and delays. The USE has indicated that it plans to implement a depository. These plans have reportedly been stalled pending the passage of enabling 44 legislation to support securities market arrangements. The current (low) level of trading on the USE and the current size of Uganda‘s capital and money markets do not seem to support the operation of two depositories. 4-29. Infrastructure for cross border transactions is inadequate. The clearing of foreign checks currently occurs between banks on an informal basis. BOU is not involved, and information on the number and value of items cleared is therefore not available, but is said to be ‗significant.‘ Funds from these foreign checks are subject to fairly long hold times that can be up to several months. Although development of the East African Payment System (EAPS) is progressing, the system is not yet operational. When online, it will reduce foreign exchange risk in intraregional transfers. Harmonization is envisaged in the areas of high-value payment systems, automation of clearinghouse s, payment system risk management, legal frameworks, and operational standards. Uganda‘s RTGS system will need to be upgraded to integrate fully with the EAPS when it is implemented. 4-30. There is no adequate network of disbursement points for remittances. Although many market players have been seeking innovative mechanisms to expand the network of remittance disbursement points, including the use of correspondent agents and the expansion of the ATM network, there is still a recognized need to expand service levels out of the metropolitan area. In Uganda this is critically important, due to the difficulties in reaching remote areas and isolated villages. In those areas, the cost of receiving remittances can be multiplied; this is where the illegal market has its main source of profit, providing informal services that cannot be replicated by financial institutions. Uganda‘s banks do not seem keen to exploit the potential of leveraging remittances to develop client profiles, then using this information to provide broader banking services (such as consumer credit) and expand their customer base. 4-31. The remittance sector lacks transparency. RSPs are legally obligated to be transparent in remittance transactions. Commercial banks and other regulated financial institutions that provide remittance services are obliged to publicly disclose their tariffs for all the services they provide to the public, including remittances. Disclosure of fees, exchange rate, speed, and service level seem to be in place, and this information is made available to consumers at the point of distribution, while RSPs provide this data to customers in a written form. However, disclosure of fees only partially reveals the cost of making remittances. In 98 percent of remittance transfers, the amount is remitted in Ugandan shillings, so that part of the remittance cost is concealed in a currency conversion operation. And there is room for greater compression of remittance costs, as phone channels, Internet, and other means of communication are not being used to their full extent. 4-32. Competition in the remittance sector is limited. Most of the agreements between local agents (banks) and international MTOs are service-based agreements. Competition is hindered by the Ugandan authorities‘ permitting (or not disallowing) exclusivity agreements that require distributing agents to work with only one money transfer operator. This is a major impediment to further cost reduction for remittances in several countries like Uganda, as it discourages competition among MTOs. 45 Recommendations 4-33. Based on their analysis and the survey results, the team has highlighted a number of recommendations. The following recommendations are categorized on the basis of the five General Principles and two Roles of the Public and Private Sector identified in the report General Principles for International Remittance Services, published by the World Bank and the Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems. The recommendations are related to specific policy or institutional reforms that would strengthen the payments systems and hence contribute to improving access to finance. The recommendations are addressed to the primary stakeholders in the sector—BOU and the MoFPED. Policy reforms include all recommendations related to new laws, regulations, or supervisory practices. Institutional reforms relate to strengthening institutions, improving information, and building capacity. Policy Reforms 4-34. Enact a new payment systems law. Authorities and stakeholders have indicated their intention and desire to upgrade the legal framework and should move quickly to enact the new legislation for the payment and settlement systems. Given the time needed to implement new legislation, work in this area should commence immediately, with the contracting of an international legal expert to help develop the legislation. The legal framework should :  Support key aspects of the payment and settlement processes, as well as others related to securities settlement, such as: the protection of customer assets (particularly against insolvency of custodians); immobilization and dematerialization of securities; validity of netting arrangements; the holding, transfer, pledging, and lending of securities (including repurchase agreements and other economically equivalent transactions); liquidation of assets pledged or transferred as collateral; and protection of the interests of beneficial owners, among others.  Establish clear responsibilities, vest authority for oversight of the payment and settlement systems in the central bank, and include provisions that satisfy the legal and regulatory requirements for electronic banking, including mobile banking  Provide the legal basis for technological advances and support the operation and future development of the system, while ensuring that risks are adequately mitigated. In addition to the legislation, regulations will be required to allow the BOU, as overseer, to react to the changing environment through the issuance of rules and directives and the imposition of sanctions. As the mobile payments industry is faced with two regulatory environments—telecommunications and banking— 46 dialogue between the two sets of regulators and between the regulators and service providers is critical to develop appropriate regulations and ensure the potential of mobile transactions is realized  Remove inconsistencies and lack of clarity from various laws and legal concepts affecting the operation and performance of the clearing system. Contract laws, company laws, bankruptcy and insolvency laws, custody laws, and property laws may have a bearing on the operation and performance of the clearing system. Other legal pieces, not yet available in Uganda and which have an important effect on payment system services in general, and remittances in particular, are economic competition law and consumer protection laws and regulations, among others. 4-35. Increase the Bank of Uganda’s oversight capacity and enhance the governance arrangements within the National Payments System. BOU should ensure it has appropriate and adequate capacity to carry out the oversight function. It will require additional staff with expertise in policy, economics, legal, operational, and technical aspects. The BOU also needs to encourage collaboration and cooperation among stakeholders, including joint education and promotion campaigns. The team recommends that the authorities challenge the bankers as a group, ideally through the Bankers Association, to collaborate, even while competing, in order to achieve specific financial inclusion targets and the overall goals of the payment system reform effort. Through the National Payments Council (NPC), banks could be encouraged to endorse and buy in to what is now seen as exclusively BOU‘s vision for the national payments system. The NPC provides a formal forum, under the chairmanship of the BOU, to bring together and resolve the competing and conflicting interests of all stakeholders within the payments infrastructure. 4-36. Establish a formal complaints resolution mechanism/body for the financial sector. The creation of a dedicated and independent ombudsman‘s office can be an effective way to resolve consumer disputes and build trust in formal (institutional) payment system channels. Public disclosure of conflict resolution mechanisms, including the specific role and powers of the ombudsman, will ensure that providers, regulators, and users of the payment systems know what action to take, or body to appeal to, when problems arise in the payment systems. Figure 4.1: General Principles of International Remittance Services Principles Transparency and consumer protection General Principle 1. The market for remittance services should be transparent and have adequate consumer protection. 47 Payment system infrastructure General Principle 2. Improvements to payment system infrastructure that have the potential to increase the efficiency of remittance services should be encouraged. Legal and regulatory environment General Principle 3. Remittance services should be supported by a sound, predictable, nondiscriminatory, and proportionate legal and regulatory framework in relevant jurisdictions. Market structure and competition General Principle 4. Competitive market conditions, including appropriate access to domestic payments infrastructures, should be fostered in the remittance industry. Governance and risk management General Principle 5. Remittance services should be supported by appropriate governance and risk management practices. Roles of remittance service providers and public authorities  Remittance service providers should participate actively in the implementation of the General Principles  Public authorities should evaluate what action to take to achieve the public policy objectives through implementation of the General Principles. 4-37. Expand access and competition in the payments system. The RTGS system, a systemically important payment system, should be characterized by fair and open access and appropriate governance arrangements. Clear and objective participation criteria for potential new entrants should be developed and published by the BOU. The following changes should be considered:  Tiers 2 and 3 institutions could be permitted to operate accounts35 with the BOU and have direct access to the electronic funds transfer systems (retail and high value) if they can meet proportionate risk management and operations criteria. For instance, routing remittance transfers as credit transfers through networks offered by Tier 2 and Tier 3 banks could leverage the network effects of the infrastructure that is already in place and expand outreach.  The range of primary dealers could be expanded to include Tier 2 and Tier 3 entities, thereby enhancing competition, not only with respect to payment services but in the development of the secondary market for securities as well. These entities may be differentiated in the extent of collateral required to mitigate settlement risk, and in their access to central bank liquidity. This will enhance competition in the provision of high-value (third party) payment and settlement services, and contribute to more competitive pricing for these services. 4-38. Implement strategies to reduce charges for certain payment transactions. At minimum, BOU can mandate limits on RTGS charges, as these can be justified on the 35 More stringent terms would be applied to these accounts, for example, no access to central bank liquidity intraday. 48 basis that the system is provided by BOU, for very modest fees. Banks‘ RTGS customer charges of UGS 10,000 up to UGS 100,000 seem unreasonable relative to BOU‘s charge of UGS 750 to UGS 1,500. Additionally, it is appropriate to delay any further reduction of the check threshold until banks have reduced and streamlined their charges. Lastly, BOU can encourage banks to reduce their charges through moral suasion, or direct such reduction36 so as to foster widespread use of electronic instruments. ATM/POS consumer and merchant fees also need to be monitored and addressed as necessary. 4-39. Achieve interoperability in retail payment systems. Mandating the use of the Bankom switch to achieve interoperability among the banks‘ card-based systems is inconsistent with the BOU‘s oversight role (to promote competition) and the free market principles it espouses. The BOU should evaluate Bankom operations (its technical and operational capacity and its governance arrangements) and if deemed adequate, acquire majority (or full) control and take over operations. This could involve Bankom becoming an operator of other parts of the payments system, such as the electronic clearinghouse. Simultaneously, the BOU could use moral suasion to encourage banks to participate in the Bankom switch, and secure their agreement at the outset to take over the BOU‘s equity stake in Bankom. Alternatively, the banks could be mandated to establish and use a central switch, Bankom‘s or another, within a specified timeframe. The BOU‘s involvement is recommended and required to (i) coordinate all efforts so that a real national system for retail payments is implemented to avoid duplications and misuse of infrastructure and resources; (ii) ensure that the system operates optimally by securing the participation of all banks and other major participants; (iii) ensure that effective standards (for example,. standardization of bank accounts) and infrastructure agreements are implemented; and (iv) determine the guiding principles for interbank and final user fees, conflict resolution mechanisms, and so on.. 4-40. Encourage collaboration among banks to optimize the usage of ATMs and POS terminals. Debit cards could be issued routinely when accounts are opened. The use of POS terminals in particular could be promoted through a joint advertising and education campaign, targeted to merchants as well as consumers, to create awareness of the new payment instruments and circuits and provide information on their features and benefits. Payment service providers should be encouraged to agree on developing a set of incentives for consumers as well as merchants to use these services. Leveraging the credit bureau smart-cards for other purposes could be considered in a few years, after the UCB is fully operational. 4-41. Formalize a local clearing arrangement for foreign checks. The BOU can leverage the existing administrative arrangements for local check clearing to establish a formal clearing for foreign currency checks issued by or drawn on local banks. Appropriate rules relevant to foreign items would be required; these can be incorporated into the existing clearinghouse rules. This arrangement will expedite funds availability, allowing banks to standardize and reduce the hold period on these foreign items, which is said to average several months. Eligible items could include (i) drafts/checks drawn by local banks in major 36 This was successfully implemented in Australia, where the Reserve Bank imposed limits and reduced the interchange fees for card transactions. 49 foreign currencies; (ii) drafts/checks drawn by account holders in major foreign currencies on their accounts at local commercial banks; and (iii) checks drawn on ―payable through‖ accounts maintained by local commercial banks with overseas correspondents. 4-42. Improve the overall efficiency and safety of the remittance market with additional oversight for RSPs. A first priority is the promotion of competition in the remittance market. It may be helpful for the BOU to work to implement the international standards in the field of remittances, the CPSS-World Bank General Principles for International Remittance Services. In keeping with these standards, the BOU should consider prohibiting exclusivity agreements for remittance distributing agents, as they are an impediment to greater competition and lower prices. Exclusivity agreements that require distribution agents to work with only one money transfer operator are important obstacles to further cost reduction for remittances. If a remitter abroad wants to send money to a place in Uganda where there is only one distributor, and if the latter is obliged by an exclusivity agreement with an international money transfer operator, the remitter has no choice but to work with the latter. From another perspective, exclusivity agreements can impede new potential distributors from achieving the volume of transactions and network efficiencies that would make their presence in the market viable, making it virtually impossible to enter the market. 4-43. Develop minimum performance levels for RSPs. In addition to meeting their legal obligations, RSPs could be encouraged to adopt rules and internal standards that guarantee minimum levels of performance in areas including: (i) the maximum time necessary to carry out transfers; (ii) information about the differences in delivery time for less-expensive services; (iii) information that must be included in transaction receipts; (iv) an explanation of exchange rates and commissions to be charged; (v) procedures for presenting complaints and the process to resolve them; and (vi) safety measures, including the segregation of clients‘ funds from those of the service provider. RSPs should be involved in developing sound governance mechanisms. As payment service providers, they have a particular responsibility to ensure that both they and any capturing or disbursing agents they use comply with applicable regulations, including AML/CFT rules. 4-44. Enhance regulations on remittance services. The criteria for obtaining an RSP license should be objective, clear, and publicly available, and as far as possible, should regulate according to type of activity, not type of entity carrying it out. Regulations should not aim to apply all rules for deposit institutions to all types of RSPs, only the more pertinent regulations complying with existing laws should be applied. It is important not to stymie innovation in drawing up the rules. Care needs to be taken to heed the business models of nonfinancial RSPs, (that is, telecommunication companies) so that regulation does not create unnecessary barriers to entry. Whenever possible, the application of any regulation should allow RSPs with few resources to comply gradually and progressively. Regulation should not limit the activities that RSPs can carry out (that is, payment of invoices, sale of related products, exchange services). Institutional Reforms 50 4-45. Upgrade the RTGS system to implement multicurrency functionality and a liquidity optimization module. Within the region, there is agreement to implement an East Africa payments system and a cross-border model to eliminate foreign exchange risk in intraregional transfers. The RTGS system will need to support credit transfers in other countries‘ currencies so cross border foreign exchange transactions are settled safely and efficiently on a payment-versus-payment basis. Implementing such an arrangement would make it more important to address legal issues associated with foreign jurisdictions, as new issues will arise with operating with multiple currencies and across borders. It is also timely for the BOU to implement liquidity optimization mechanisms in the RTGS system so that liquidity is managed more efficiently. 4-46. Create an electronic depository for equities and introduce a new trading platform to facilitate the efficient settlement of trades. An electronic depository for equities, linked to the RTGS system, will facilitate the settlement of trades on a DvP basis. The feasibility of utilizing the existing BOU depository for equities, as well as government securities, should be carefully assessed, and USE‘s planned implementation of a new depository be deferred pending this evaluation. This is especially relevant in the context of the proposed implementation of a regional depository. To ensure the smooth operation of securities clearing and settlement systems, it is proposed that the BOU co- operate with the capital markets regulator (CMA) and where appropriate, with other relevant authorities, to address these problems and issues of common interest. A new trading platform for the secondary market trading of government securities should be introduced, for both outright transactions and repurchase agreements. An electronic trading system is also needed for equities. A unified trading platform, if properly managed, allows for greater market efficiency. Participants post bid and ask prices continuously and settle transactions more efficiently. This eliminates information asymmetries and allows for more efficient price discovery than is achievable with bilateral phone calls in an over-the-counter market, and will foster the development of the financial markets. An efficient secondary market for government securities will provide more liquidity, make primary debt issues more attractive to the market, and provide more information to the central bank on the liquidity exchanged among financial institutions and the possible needs for intervention. When linked to the electronic securities depository and the RTGS system, this trading platform would support efficient trade initiation and the straight-through processing of securities market transactions. Additionally, to ensure that the goals of risk reduction and enhanced efficiency are achieved, the team recommends that the BOU mandate primary /money market dealers to settle all securities trades, including repurchase (repo) transactions within the depository and through the RTGS system. 4-47. Improve the efficiency of government tax collections. The Uganda Revenue Authority (URA) should begin the process of discontinuing the legacy arrangements for payments transfers and rationalize and reduce its operational accounts. The electronic funds transfer system facilitates interbank settlement and obviates the need for these multiple accounts. Also, banks‘ internal systems are now integrated, allowing seamless intrabank transfers. The Perago Pay upgrade will level the playing field among banks 51 and increase efficiency in payment flows, as transfers to the URA account(s) at the BOU will be made continuously, so lower idle balances (float) will be maintained in bank accounts. In addition to expanding the range of options and convenience points for tax payments, efforts should also be made to reduce fees charged to taxpayers. URA reports average monthly collections of over UGS 250 billion. This can be used as leverage to induce banks to reduce fees charged to taxpayers for collecting taxes. 4-48. Promote knowledge and awareness of payment systems through educational campaigns. As part of its oversight function, BOU should conduct educational campaigns so that the population (individuals, corporate entities, merchants) sees the benefits that can accrue to them, and to the economy as a whole, through greater access, more convenient access points for payment initiation and receipt, and active use of electronic payment instruments and the clearing and settlement systems. The public should be informed by means of an ongoing program of the rules and standards of the payments system. Financial education programs are key to improving customers‘ understanding of financial services such as remittances. Providing such education through the Ministry of Foreign Affairs‘ new Diaspora Unit would create greater awareness of the safer, cheaper, and faster ways to send money home. Education could also be provided on the possibilities of linking remittances to other financial services such as deposit accounts, microfinance, and SME lending. RSPs also have a role in engaging in ground-level education of remittance recipients to promote the use of efficient payment instruments and the use of broader banking and financial services. In all these areas, the market as a whole could benefit from cooperation between the Bankers‘ Association and remittance industry representative bodies to identify common interests. 4-49. Promote transparency by publishing remittance costs. The BOU, the Ministry of Foreign Affairs, and other government agencies could play a key role in advancing transparency by producing and publishing tables with comparative information on costs and other relevant variables. To ensure the widest reach, all relevant dissemination channels should be used (for example, leaflets, newspapers, the Internet, consumer friendly phone number, and so on), both in Uganda and in the main sending countries, through consular offices, migrant associations, and other bodies. In several countries around the world, authorities are already engaging in this exercise. The World Bank has launched an online database containing detailed information on the cost of sending money in 120 corridors worldwide. The Bank of Uganda could either take into consideration the applied methodology to set up a similar database or could include the information on the main corridors in Uganda in the database hosted by the World Bank. 4-50. Facilitate competition in disbursement of remittances. BOU, the Ugandan Bankers Association, and the Ugandan Money Transmitters Association could disseminate information to increase awareness of the remittances market in Uganda and the different business opportunities available, and to facilitate dialogue among national and regional or international counterparts. In particular, the involvement of Posta Uganda, MFIs, and SACCOs in the remittances market could potentially expand the available disbursing network. Improved competition could lead to the involvement of 52 Posta Uganda, which has an extensive network of postal delivery outlets down to sub county level. Improved competition among existing money transfer services, coupled with direct access to the national payment system, could significantly reduce many of the logistical problems Uganda faces in remittances delivery. The role of authorities working together with RSPs is fundamental in the implementation of international standards and best practices in the field. The National Payments System Council can be a useful forum to discuss possible actions and coordinate efforts to ensure international remittances policy is consistent, as it must be. 4-51. Improve information on remittance flows. BOU, working with the Uganda Bureau of Statistics (UBOS), could develop more comprehensive statistics on remittance flows and on organizations providing remittance services and remittance-related activities. This would help give the financial sector reliable, official information on the different aspects of the remittance business. The Ministry of Foreign Affairs has just begun to create an official network of Ugandans abroad, through the creation of a designated Diaspora Unit. Its main objectives could be not only to maintain and reinforce links between Ugandans living abroad and their home country, and provide assistance to migrants in a number of areas, but also to promote awareness of safer, cheaper, and faster ways to send money home. 53 Part 2 Improving the Supply of Term Finance Making Finance Work for Uganda 5. Reforming the Uganda Pension System 5-1. The first section of this chapter provides an overview of current pension schemes and the regulatory framework in Uganda. The second section discusses key challenges to the pension sector. The last section provides recommendations for pension reform, in light of current pension-related government proposals and efforts to liberalize the pension sector overall. Overview of the Pension System 5-2. The Ugandan pension system serves a small portion of the population. For private sector employees, the primary fund is the National Social Security Fund (NSSF) to which all formal sector employees are obliged to contribute. Many private sector employers have also set up occupational schemes to accumulate additional pension benefits for their employees. For public sector employees, the main scheme is the Public Service Pension Fund (PSPF). Additional schemes include an armed forces scheme and a local government scheme. The characteristics of the major pension schemes in Uganda are described in table 5.1. The NSSF does not cater to firms with fewer than five employees, to self-employed individuals, or to informal sector enterprises. 5-3. The NSSF is a defined contribution provident fund. It collects mandatory contributions at a rate of 15 percent of gross employee wages, 5 percent of which is deducted from employees, topped up by 10 percent paid by their employers. NSSF operates on a defined contribution basis, that is, as an investment fund where accrued balances can only be withdrawn at retirement. As such, its assets and liabilities are by definition matched. The fund does not guarantee a rate of return on the contributions it collects. Therefore, there are no contingent liabilities that would need to be covered by the scheme sponsors or a pension administrator. 5-4. The NSSF has approximately 300,000 members. It pays lump sum benefits to an average of 1,200 members every month. Total assets under management were UGS, UGS 1.42 trillion (USD 768 million) as of September 2009, approximately 5 percent of GDP, making it the only major source of term financing. Assets were invested in: fixed income (government bonds), 70 percent; real estate, 20 percent; equity, 10 percent. Historically, NSSF‘s returns on its investment portfolio have been lower than expected, and often negative in real terms, largely reflecting poor returns on its investments and high operating costs. This has led to disillusionment among both individual members and sponsoring employers, who view NSSF as little more than a tax. This also prompted more employers to set up occupational schemes. 5-5. There are more than 50 private sector occupational schemes. It is estimated these schemes have an estimated value of UGS 120 billion. Most large employers, such as the Bank of Uganda and the telecommunications companies, operate such schemes. In addition to the single-employer schemes, there is also one multi-employer pension fund, which is organized and operated by Alexander Forbes an international company which 55 provides risk and insurance services. Participation in these schemes is voluntary; both employees and the employer make contributions (in addition to the mandatory NSSF contributions). The presence of these schemes is a result of the historically weak/negative investment returns on NSSF's asset portfolio that have severely eroded public confidence in NSSF's ability to provide old-age income security to formal sector employees. Table 5.1: Ugandan Pension Schemes National Social Occupational Public Service Armed Forces Security Fund Provident Schemes Pension Fund Pension Scheme (NSSF) (PSPF) General Private sector Private sector Public sector Public sector Population employees employees employees employees Served Specific All private sector Employees of private Civil servants, Military officers Population employees of sector firms that elect to public Served companies with contribute funds in employees, more than five addition to NSSF funds teachers, police employees officers # Members Approx. 300,000 N/A (approx 50-60 Approx. 250,000 N/A schemes) Financing of Mandatory Voluntary contributions Non-contributory Non-contributory Benefits contribution (budget- (budget-financed) financed) Type of Benefit Defined Defined contribution Defined benefit Defined benefit contribution and defined benefit Legal NSSF act Uganda insurance act or Pensions act Armed forces Framework unregulated pensions act Source: Ministry of Finance Planning and Economic Development. 5-6. The PSPS, a defined benefit scheme funded by the budget, is the primary scheme for public sector employees. It is a non-contributory scheme that promises the participant a specific amount at the time of retirement. It covers approximately 250,000 active civil servants, public employees, teachers, police officers, and municipal workers, and pays pension benefits to approximately 56,000 pensioners. 5-7. The PSPS pays benefits in the form of both annuities and lump sums. The payout rules for benefits (old age, survivor, and disability) are unusual, because at retirement, beneficiaries receive one-third of the present value of their expected future pension as a lump sum and are paid an annuity based on the remaining two-thirds of accrued entitlements. After the first fifteen years of retirement, the annuity is recalculated as if no lump sum payment had been made at retirement. 5-8. Other public sector schemes are operated by the armed forces and local governments. Little information is available about these schemes, but since they operate on a defined benefit basis, it is expected that they have accrued certain unfunded liabilities. To what extent the central government is liable for their obligations is unclear. However, it can be assumed that the army scheme is fully underwritten by the central government. 56 Constraints to Pension Sector Development 5-9. There are a number of constraints impeding the development of a fully mature and functioning pension sector. Although the essential elements and players are in place, to initiate funded pension reform and create more competition, the industry must develop and broaden further. The constraints identified by the team are summarized below in two areas: (i) legal and regulatory constraints, and (ii) financing and capacity constraints. Legal and Regulatory Constraints 5-10. There is no overall regulatory framework. NSSF and PSPS are regulated by separate laws. NSSF is governed by a board and reports to the Minister of Finance, while PSPS37 is under the direct control of the Ministry of Public Service. No universally applicable regulation exists for any other pension scheme; indeed, the concept of pension schemes, pension funds, or other pension products and providers has yet to be legally defined and protected against misuse. Occupational provident funds, set up as deposit administration funds, are regulated by Uganda‘s insurance act, but no legislation exists to ensure the exclusivity of this legal form. If an employer decides to set up a scheme for his workers according to the provisions of the Insurance Act, then the scheme is licensed, regulated, and supervised by the Uganda Insurance Commission. Since no other laws exist in these areas, an employer or financial service provider who wishes to offer pension schemes or other pension products, or who would like to follow different operational procedures and invest assets outside the restrictions of the Insurance Act, can easily do so by giving the scheme or product a different name. 5-11. NSSF has a monopoly over mandatory pension contributions. This leads to NSSF being the biggest ―institutional investor‖ in Uganda. It has the size and clout to make or break bond issues. But with its poor track record in investment, and shaky governance structure, it is not the best vehicle for investing and allocating scarce long- term funds. 5-12. NSSF is a de facto publicly managed fund. NSSF is a sui generis institution, regulated by a dedicated article of law, the NSSF Act of 1985. Its problems, including recent cases of alleged fraud as well as poor investment performance, are related to shortcomings in its governance structure. Although not directly under government management, the composition, selection, and rules of accountability of its board make it a publicly managed provident fund. This kind of structure has often failed in other countries. Financing and capacity constraints 37 The PSPS is technically not even a fund. It is a ―scheme‖ that has to be transformed into a fund with an appropriate governance structure. 57 5-13. The generous benefit rules of the PSPS have created a large pension liability. The rules include the age of retirement, required length of service, accrual rate, assessment base, and indexation of benefits in service. They have resulted in a large implicit pension liability equal to approximately 27 percent of GDP. The PSPS arrears as at mid-2007 were estimated at UGS 280 billion.38 The government has embarked on an accelerated amortization of the arrears, and it is expected that by the end of this fiscal year (June 2009) all historic arrears will have been cleared. However, according to the Ministry of Public Service, the agency overseeing PSPS, at the same time that the historic arrears are cleared, new benefit arrears of approximately UGS 60 billion will be accrued by mid-2009. The new arrears, which partially offset the amortization of the old ones, are attributable to insufficient resource allocations in the 2009 budget. 5-14. The number of service providers is limited. Presently, there are four asset managers that manage the assets of occupational pension schemes. Each has been licensed by the Capital Markets Authority (CMA) in the last three years. One of these, African Alliance, has begun to manage and distribute retail investment funds as well. Two banks (Barclays and Stanbic) provide custody services to these pension funds. The insurance market, especially life insurance, is also underdeveloped. No annuity products are available commercially, and the life insurance market consists of group term life policies. Uganda does not have a single qualified actuary, which is particularly problematic for the government. Whereas private sector entities can always find and hire such experts abroad, this constraint is serious for the Uganda Insurance Commission. 5-15. Capital markets lack depth. Uganda‘s capital markets, both for fixed income and equity, are very shallow. Only six local stocks and a few cross-listings are listed on the Uganda Securities Exchange. Turnover and capitalization are meagre. The government securities market is also thin. Once a greater demand from pension funds emerges for investable securities, this level of domestic supply will be insufficient. Even today, with such a low level of assets under management, fund managers complain that they cannot always purchase what they wish. The supply of other instruments, such as corporate bonds, is practically nonexistent. Pension funds (including NSSF) invest in property as well, but this segment is not securitized. The funds buy property directly, which is questionable for various reasons, including asset valuation and liquidity. A number of pension funds diversify by investing regionally, typically in Kenya. Recommendations 5-16. Based on interviews, analysis, and comparison with global good practice, the team has highlighted a number of recommendations. These relate to (i) policy reforms to improve the overall framework, (ii) reforms of private sector schemes, and (iii) reforms of public sector schemes. Policy Reforms 38 The team observed that the Ministry of Public Service and MFPED had different estimates of the pension arrears. 58 5-17. Develop a long-term pension policy. Uganda has yet to establish a long-term pension policy, which makes discussion about particular schemes, reforms, and options difficult. A pension policy could provide useful guidance in areas such as which groups, if any, should be mandated into pension schemes, and the appropriate level of mandatory pension savings and contributions. Pension policy would also address the level of budget subsidy the government is able and willing to devote to giving incentives, the form such incentives could take (tax incentives, matching contributions, and the like), the expansion of coverage, and how the government wishes to balance the welfare of retired civil servants and the minority of formal sector employees with the needs of the vast majority of the population. This policy could then serve as guidance for practical questions concerning targeted coverage and replacement rates. 5-18. Prepare a high-quality pension regulatory act. The MoFPED is already working on a pension regulatory act, which, with a set of implementing regulations, should be enacted and implemented as soon as possible. The act should give the pension regulator authority over the NSSF, PSPS, and all occupational schemes. Having an overarching pension regulatory authority is important for improving the governance of the sector, promoting reform, and advancing liberalization. At the same time, it is important that the principles of universal applicability of the regulations and the freedom to choose among providers are enshrined in the act. Such liberalization, whether partial or full, can only occur when there are regulated private pension schemes that are ready to accept members—and their account balances and new contributions—and invest them safely and efficiently, as prescribed by a uniformly applicable pension law. Every permissible retirement savings instrument (including guaranteed schemes offered by insurance companies and individual retirement accounts) should be regulated in the regulatory act, which reference other laws whenever possible (such as accounting, audit, custody, and so on) in an effort to avoid different laws regulating the same issue. 5-19. Reconsider the decision to establish a specialized pension regulatory authority. While it is very important to have an independent pension regulator, it is not necessary to set up a new, specialized agency to perform this role. The team believes that it would be more effective and efficient to expand the role of the Capital Markets Authority to include oversight of pension schemes and their service providers. This view is broadly shared by the industry, as well as by some GoU officials. Building a strong pension regulatory authority may prove difficult and time-consuming. Using the structure and capacity of the CMA can make the process run more smoothly. Furthermore, to avoid the possibility of regulatory arbitrage, and to maintain uniform legal standards and requirements, the new pension regulator would in any case need to rely on the CMA in terms of licensing, regulating, and supervising fund managers and custodians. Similarly, in the payout phase, at least as pertains to annuities, the pension regulator needs to rely on the Uganda Insurance Commission. Under these conditions, creating a new agency— which will have a vested interest in carving out a regulatory niche—sounds impractical and unnecessary. Finally, it would take, under the best of circumstances, at least five years for a new regulator to become effective. Thus, it is unclear how the current proposal of a new regulator would contribute to the expedient implementation of pension reform and ensure the security and safety of pension savings. 59 5-20. Develop a trust law and a custodian law. Pension regulations rely on and refer to existing laws. It is neither feasible nor desirable to make the pension act the primary regulatory instrument of areas which have general applicability outside the pension system or the private pension industry. In this respect, Uganda‘s lack of a trust law and of a law defining custodians and custodial duties is a cause for concern. The two most important players in terms of fiduciary duties, with the means and capacity to ensure the safe accumulation of contributors‘ funds, are the board of trustees and custodians. Their roles cannot be substituted by expanding or defining other stakeholders‘ rights and obligations differently. Until these two areas are properly regulated by legislation, the idea of the safe functioning and effective supervision of pension schemes will fall short. 5-21. License all schemes and providers. Once the new pension regulatory framework is in place, all schemes and providers wishing to continue operating will need to be licensed. Consequently, the private pension law will need to prescribe clear transitional provisions, including the period within which existing schemes, funds, and providers have to comply with the new regulations. These transitional provisions will need to apply to all schemes, including NSSF and PSPS. Private Section Pension Reforms 5-22. Improve the governance of NSSF. Independent trustees should be appointed to its board to assist in decision making and to function as whistleblowers. Given the highly politicized nature of this institution, and the small, closely-knit nature of the Ugandan political and business elite, it is recommended to appoint foreign experts, with established track records and reputations to protect, as independent trustees. This will make them more likely to represent members‘ interests above any other consideration. These experts should be from countries with an established private pension market operating within a legal tradition similar to that of Uganda. 5-23. Allow for full liberalization of the sector. Liberalization involves allowing employers and employees the option of making mandatory contributions to funds other than NSSF. These could be single-employer occupational funds or multi-employer funds. If employers are allowed to do this, they would have the choice whether or not to continue with voluntary contributions. Two modes of liberalization have been discussed in Uganda. One is partial liberalization, whereby employees have the option to make new mandatory contributions to NSSF or a new fund, while past contributions remain with NSSF. In full liberalization, the past contributions can be moved from NSSF to another fund. From the perspective of members, the main difference between partial and full liberalization is that full liberalization allows members to stay with NSSF if its performance is convincing, but switch the management of their pension savings to an alternative fund manager if NSSF‘s performance is regarded as less effective. Partial liberalization forces members to keep a potentially significant portion of their retirement savings with NSSF regardless of its performance. Thus, for members, full liberalization is clearly superior to partial liberalization. With respect to partial versus full liberalization, divergent opinions exist, primarily driven by stakeholders‘ interest in 60 maintaining or changing the status quo. However, the small investment management industry may be more interested in maintaining the NSSF monopoly than in dealing with a more fragmented market. Thus, the entire investment industry may not necessarily favor liberalization, and it is expected that incumbent investment service providers already working for NSSF would be particularly disinterested in dismantling the NSSF monopoly. 5-24. Define the future role of NSSF. It is difficult to identify areas where, following the introduction of the new pension regulatory framework, NSSF would be able to demonstrate comparative advantages. At the same time, it is possible that NSSF could remain the most experienced and effective pension scheme and be the dominant market player—through competition instead of administrative rules. Another option is for the GoU to play a more developmental role and focus its efforts on two key areas: (i) broadening the coverage to employees in firms with fewer than five employees, and (ii) designing and implementing an approach for serving informal sector employees and employers. 5-25. Develop a vision of the liberalized pension sector and its operation. With a clear vision and blueprint, the different elements of the liberalization process can fit together well. The following factors need to be considered in the context of liberalization of mandatory pension savings. First, liquidating individual account balances prior to members‘ switching may have a pronounced impact on liquidity and asset prices. Second, the rationale for liberalizing the pension market is to allow choice among financial service providers of different performance and operational standards and fee levels. As part of this process, service providers will need to gain skills in providing sufficiently diverse products and services. Third, liberalization will have an impact on tax policy, tax administration, labor regulations, and banking—areas outside of pensions where regulations may need to be amended to reflect changes in the pension system. Fourth, collection mechanisms will need to be redesigned to deal with the potential to have pension accounts maintained at numerous institutions. The advantages and disadvantages of centralized versus decentralized collection must be considered, as well as the possibility of using the tax office or a dedicated agency (contribution clearinghouse) for this purpose. Lastly, liberalization will make the difference between institutional and functional (product-based) regulation and supervision more pronounced. A clear understanding, preferably delineated by law, of the division of labor and responsibilities, and modes of cooperation among financial sector regulators, will be crucial if the retirement market is to be supervised effectively. 5-26. Carefully define the design parameters of the liberalized system: Some specific recommendations for the design are:  Maintain the requirement of a mandatory contribution. Absent a major cultural shift, pension savings are unlikely to become the preferred method of accumulating wealth. Pension savings are inaccessible for extended periods (until retirement), and people may not be convinced to lock their savings into institutions which may or may not continue operating in a prudent manner. Furthermore, few Ugandans are 61 sufficiently well-off to risk not having access to savings accumulating in pension products when hardship strikes. Therefore, it is important that the requirement of a mandatory contribution be maintained.  Limit the number of mandatory pension accounts to one. For the sake of administrative simplicity (including tax administration), the number of mandatory pension accounts should be limited to one, except for the transition period when members may, as a result of graduated liquidation, have a residual account balance with NSSF while their ―live‖ pension account is already with a different scheme/fund.  Define the requirements for funds to be eligible to receive mandatory contributions. Defining permissible retirement products also entails determining which service providers and products will be permissible for accumulating mandatory pension savings. This is important from the perspective of tax policy, tax administration, and regulating investments, withdrawals, and guarantees. This will also require a legal framework governing investment funds, fund managers, and permissible annuity products. As a consequence of allowing defined contribution funds, at retirement, permissible annuity products will have to be purchased from licensed annuity providers (life insurance companies).  Permit only defined contribution schemes to collect mandatory contributions. Only defined contribution occupational pension schemes operating as trusts, and open pension funds operating as specialized investment funds, should be permitted to collect mandatory contributions. Employers operating defined benefit schemes should be required to set up a separate defined contribution scheme to collect mandatory contributions. This will make liberalization more practical, as portability is less complicated with defined contribution schemes.  Require private pension funds to employ external asset managers, custodians, and administrators. This would apply to both single- employer funds and multi-employer funds. This limits the board‘s fiduciary duties to exercising due care in selecting and contracting service providers and to establishing service standards, investment policies, and other issues related to scheme governance. 5-27. Implement the transition to a fully liberalized system gradually. The transition to a fully liberalized system will have its challenges. These need to be tackled, and the process will need to be carefully managed to ensure that employees and employers do not get discouraged. Some initial specific recommendations include:  Liquidate account balances at NSSF gradually. In the first months after switching is permitted, a large number of NSSF affiliates may choose to switch, which may cause downward pressure on asset prices. As the 62 liquidation deadline approaches, newly established pension schemes will have a chance to force lower prices, which will create a demand equal to the supply of assets to be liquidated by NSSF. It will also be in their interest, as depressed prices will help to present their future investment performance in a better light. Therefore, a graduated liquidation of account balances at NSSF should take place, putting a ceiling on the share of securities (by asset class) that can be liquidated at any given period. The period may be defined as a month, quarter, half-year, and so on.  Impose a two-year minimum period of fund affiliation. This would avoid frequent switches and minimize associated costs. In terms of switching among schemes, the actual change of affiliation and redirecting new contributions should happen immediately, that is, the technologically shortest possible time, but no longer than 30 days after the member indicates his intention (which may be limited to a particular period of the year). Transfer of balances, under ordinary circumstances, should occur no later than 45 days after the member‘s indication to change affiliation, and on the basis of the latest valuation date (asset value at valuation date plus contributions collected).  Increase the frequency of asset valuations. This issue also impacts how transfer of assets occurs. In developed markets, assets under management are typically valued at market prices on a daily basis, except for direct investment in real estate—an asset class that is much smaller in mature market pension portfolios than in Uganda (or other African countries). If valuation dates are infrequent but switching happens continuously, members‘ account value will have a somewhat arbitrary relationship to its liquidation value, and the regulator will need resort to some artificial valuation technique, such as last market value plus real value of contributions received in the interim.  Involve a custodian bank in the trading of securities. Particularly for securities held in other parties‘ name, this should occur under all circumstances. Custodians compare portfolios to legal instructions provided by the investors (scheme trustee, in this case) and execute only those trades which meet all legal and other requirements to the custodian‘s satisfaction. If switching among pension schemes is permitted, the role of custodians will be even more important, as the former and new scheme‘s custodians will have to make sure that the liquidation, transfer, and re- investment of individual accounts takes place in an orderly and safe manner. Thus, making sure that all schemes, including NSSF, employ a custodian bank is crucial for the successful liberalization of the mandatory pension system. Public Service Pension Reforms 63 5-28. Reduce unfunded pension liabilities for PSPS. The primary objective of any reform of PSPS should be to reduce unfunded pension liabilities. The PSPS is accumulating unfunded public pension liabilities at a rapid rate. As the budget cannot finance these liabilities, the PSPS in its current form is fiscally unsustainable. However, reducing benefits, and hence liabilities, is feasible only with regard to those employees who have not yet retired and who, because of their age, have the time and capacity to make up for any loss suffered as a result of changing the pension rules of the current system. To reduce PSPS liabilities, the GoU should:  Delink the age of retirement from civil service/public employment from the age of eligibility for pension withdrawals. Eligibility for pension benefits should be made conditional on reaching 60 years of age, even if the person has retired earlier from civil service.  Reduce the calculation (assessment) base. Instead of using the member‘s final salary to calculate the pension assessment, move gradually toward using career average earnings.  Reduce the accrual rate of 2.4 percent, possibly according to a sliding scale (with younger members‘ accrual at a lower rate than older members).  Apply price- rather than wage-indexation to all pension benefits.  Change the current rule requiring one-third of the expected pension value to be paid out as lump sum at the time of retirement, making the full entitlement payable as a life annuity. 5-29. Consider converting the PSPS to a two-pillar, defined benefit plus defined contribution scheme. This was previously recommended in the FSAP and a follow-up study.39 The MPS has developed a proposal based on this concept. Under the proposal, employees eligible for PSPS would be required to contribute 5 percent of their salary, augmented by another 10 percent paid by the employer (that is, from the government budget). For those earning below a yet unspecified threshold, all contributions would be directed to the defined benefits pillar. Those earning above the threshold would be in a ―hybrid‖ system where the contributions would be split (probably 7.5 percent–7.5 percent) between the defined benefit and defined contribution pillars. Since the threshold would be fixed in nominal terms, wage growth would put more and more people into the hybrid system. The proposal does not discuss some crucial parameters, such as the eligibility and accrual rules of the new contributory defined benefit or the threshold determining whether an employee contributes to the defined contribution pillar or not. Under the current MPS proposal, there are two factors that will define the speed of building up defined contribution assets: the income thresholds above which employees start contributing to the defined contribution pillar and the share of contributions directed to the new pillar. 39 The World Bank 2005. ―A Simulation Analysis of the Public Service Pension Scheme in Uganda.‖ 64 5-30. Carefully calculate the fiscal consequences of the new scheme. The current proposal keeps the defined benefits at the level of the current scheme, and hence is unlikely to have any significant impact on the budget or unfunded liabilities. With regard to the contribution to be made, it is expected that employees will only make their 5 percent contribution if there is first a 5 percent increase in wages. Hence, there would be no budget savings. And with regard to the benefits, if the parameters are not changed, the benefits would remain the same and would keep accruing. Since the new defined benefit rules and the structure of the reformed PSPS have short-, medium-, and long-term implications, it is advisable that all proposals be prepared jointly by MPS and MFPED, and be accompanied by detailed fiscal projections, including sensitivity analyses. 5-31. Place the new PSPS under the purview of the new pension regulator, without special provisions. Pension schemes catering to civil servants are often regulated separately from private occupational schemes. If the state, in its role as employer, were subject to the oversight of the pension regulator, this would be highly commendable and in line with international best practices. This would also mean that the PSPS will need to prepare standard financial statements. The balance sheet of the defined benefit pillar will show a very large liability and no assets. As the new, contributory pillar is introduced, the stock of net (unfunded) liabilities may increase or decrease, depending on whether new defined benefit rules are actuarially neutral, worsen the balance sheet, or gradually reduce total unfunded liabilities. 65 6: Developing the Housing Finance Market 6-1. The first section of this chapter describes the current environment in which lenders operate to provide housing finance and construction finance. The second section draws from a World Bank/Bank of Uganda survey to identify some of the key obstacles preventing the housing finance system from increasing its breadth and depth. The third section provides a prioritized framework for improving the efficiency of the system. Overview of Ugandan Housing Finance 6-2. The Uganda mortgage market is relatively small and underdeveloped. However, it is growing steadily. The number of loans outstanding rose to 3,700 by mid- 2008 (from 2,000 a year ago), and the value of the loans outstanding reached almost 1 percent of GDP. Table 6.1 provides a comparison to other Sub-Saharan African markets. Table 6.1 Mortgage Debt to GDP–2007 Mortgage US $ GDP/Head Debt/GDP (2007) Nigeria 0.5% 944 Uganda 1.0% 382 Senegal 2.0% 941 Ghana 3.9% 749 Namibia 20.0% 3,502 South Africa 34.0% 6,185 Source: Various sources compiled by World Bank. 6-3. Access to mortgage finance is limited. Of 5.2 million households in the country, only 0.6 percent can access mortgage loans through commercial banks, 19.9 percent can access housing microfinance loans through microfinance deposit taking institutions, 7.2 percent can access loans from microfinance institutions and savings and credit cooperatives, 10.3 percent can access loans through savings and credit cooperatives only, and 62.3 percent have no access to financial services. 40 6-4. The range of mortgage products is varied. They are typically offered for up to 20 years to maturity and at variable rates. A standard loan-to-value (LTV) ceiling is 70 percent of the appraised value of the property. Interest rates are still relatively high at between 16 and 18 percent. Loans are repaid in equal monthly installments, with the monthly payment not exceeding 40 percent of the ascertainable monthly income. Loans are available for construction, for house purchase, for incremental construction (10-year loan only and for shorter term, less than 10 years) and equity release mortgages 40 See Kaleema 2008. 66 (maximum LTV of 60 percent and for shorter terms also). Land loans are also available with a maturity of just 4 years and a rate of 20 percent. Finally, buy-to-let loans are also available, which allow prospective landlords to invest in rental properties. 6-5. Housing demand is growing, and a large housing gap exists. The country‘s population is expected to grow from 26 million now to 45 million in 2020, and the urbanization rate—about 15 percent in 2002, as compared to an average of 37 percent in Sub-Saharan Africa—can only increase. The present housing gap, both in quantity and quality, is estimated to be at least 300,000 housing units per year overall, 70 percent of which should be built in urban areas. The formal sector could contribute significantly to closing this gap if it were able to better service groups further down the income distribution scale. 6-6. Housing supply is increasing but still lags behind demand. The Commissioner for building at the Ministry of Works and Transport says the housing industry witnessed impressive growth in the 2007/2008 fiscal year—13 percent up from 11.3 percent during the previous year. However, it is still well short of reaching a level of construction which even stabilizes the housing gap. On the supply side, the improvement of lending conditions would have a strong impact, not just on the purchasing capacity of the borrowers, but also by providing increased liquidity to private developers for residential development. 6-7. Construction costs continue to rise. The problem is compounded by the fact that Uganda is landlocked. Staple products such as cement, tiles, and steel mostly must be imported, which adds to building material costs. For example, cement is shipped to Mombasa in Kenya and then transported by road, which can double the price. There are efforts to source primary materials locally and to construct cement plants, but this will be a gradual change.41 Construction costs are further inflated by the acute skills shortage of qualified builders, plasterers, project managers, bricklayers, electricians, plumbers, and the like. There are very few training facilities in Uganda; without the human resources needed, it will take much longer to scale up construction of housing. 6-8. The owner occupancy rate is falling. A further trend, linked to growing urbanization and reflecting the rising cost of land, is that the owner-occupation rate is falling as individuals opt to rent. This reflects the increasing levels of urbanization. The proportion of people renting houses rose to 65 percent in 2002/03 from 14 percent in 1992/93.42 However, in rural areas the home ownership rate is still around 90 percent. 6-9. Policymakers are taking concrete actions to increase the flow of investment into housing. A key development has been the reduction in of Value Added Tax (VAT) charged on housing from 18 percent to 5 percent. The step was taken to encourage development of large-scale, well-planned residential areas. This reduction demonstrates a willingness on the part of the GoU to grow this sector, even at the short-term cost of 41 Uganda Clays, Ltd. at Kajjansi, the manufacturers of clay-based products like tiles and bricks, has commissioned a new factory in Eastern Uganda that will increase production of these materials. 42 Uganda National Housing Survey 2002/03. 67 some tax revenue. The reduction will cost the government an estimated UGS 2 billion in revenue annually. 6-10. The banks are also responding. A recent notable development is the increased appetite of banks to engage in retail business, both on the lending and the deposit side. More banks have applied to the BoU to take on a mortgage business, and there is rapid branch expansion by a number of the major banks. Increasing their outreach enables them to access greater numbers of savers and increase their level of deposits. 6-11. New real estate developers have entered the market. Some of the developers are backed by foreign capital. They vary in size, and while there is still a focus on the luxury side, as the market expands a move down-market will inevitably occur. These new entrants alone do not yet provide the necessary production capacity to close the housing gap in Uganda, but this interest seems to be indicative of confidence in the prospects for the house-building sector, as well as a reflection of the potential profitability of real estate development. This should have a positive effect in terms of competition in the sector, in increasing capacity, and in bringing in innovations.43 6-12. The capital market is expanding. Another positive development on the funding side has been the expansion of the capital markets, with a number of corporate bond issuances and plans to tap these as a source of funding by a number of banks. There is still much to be done, but as liquidity grows it will become easier for banks to raise longer-term funds and even look to start a secondary mortgage market. 6-13. Housing microfinance products are being introduced. A growing number of institutions are expanding their product ranges into housing micro-finance products. This is the case both for some banks, microdeposit institutions (MDIs) and microfinance institutions (MFIs). The types of products on offer include small loans targeted at incremental construction without the need for collateral. The main constraint on further growth of this product range is a BoU restriction that the term of lending by these institutions cannot exceed five years. Constraints to the Expansion of Housing Finance 6-14. Constraints to housing finance are present in every step of the lending process. There are several constraints that in combination prevent banks from making the necessary level of returns on lending for housing finance to allow them to expand significantly into this sector. The obstacles are present at every stage of the lending process, and affect obtaining collateral, the registration process, obtaining long-term funding, assessing credit risk, and the foreclosure process. 43 A good example of this is the proposal by Avarts Housing, Ld. and the Good Earth Trust to start developing low-cost ecohousing units in Uganda. The houses are targeted at the affordable housing market with a sales price in the range of UGS 17.25 million. One of the new technologies being promoted as part of the initiative is the use of interlocking soil stabilized blocks that provide an alternative to increasingly expensive traditional bricks. 68 6-15. The constraints were identified through the WB/BoU banking survey. For this survey, which was both quantitative and qualitative, the Bank team, with the assistance of the BoU Banking Supervision Department, surveyed all 24 formal financial institutions in Uganda during May/June 2008. The goal of the survey was to determine obstacles to lending and provide the banks with several open-ended opportunities to express their views.44 The findings generally confirm, and provide additional depth to, the conclusions of the BoU lending survey.45 6-16. The survey identified 10 key constraints. The constraints can be grouped into four main categories: (i) legal and regulatory constraints, (ii) information constraints, (iii) financing constraints, and (iv) housing supply constraints. Legal and Regulatory constraints 6-17. Implementation of the new Mortgage Act. There is no question that the mortgage act of 1974 was in dire need of modernization. During the course of writing this report, the mortgage bill was passed in March 2009 and became an Act in October 2009. . The Act consolidates the laws relating to mortgages, revamp the mortgage industry, and make a law that is consistent with the constitution and the land act. The mortgage act is certainly to be welcomed, and the version passed by parliament resolved many of the proposed amendment issues that threatened to make mortgage lending uneconomical for banks. Most notably, clauses that would give courts unilateral rights to change mortgage contract terms for a borrower in default have been removed. Additionally, the issue of spousal consent has put greater onus on the borrower making a full declaration. Fines or even imprisonment can result from failure to disclose full marital status and enter into a loan without full spousal consent. The challenge now is to prepare the necessary regulations for the act and to begin implementation. 6-18. Mortgages on customary land – A large proportion of land in Uganda is ―customary,‖ which can be owned either communally or individually. The bill has differentiated between ownership types for this land, allowing mortgages only on individually owned customary land. There was a concern that allowing mortgages on communally owned land could result in banks taking over tribal land that is seen as a public good for the entire community. 6-19. Length of mortgage foreclosure process – Until the new law is tested through the courts, it is difficult to fully know the impact on the time and cost of foreclosing on a property. However, the mortgage act as passed would result in a slight increase in the time—from 21 to 45 days—between serving a notice of default and being able to take further action.. On the whole, the ‗power of sale‘ mechanism in the act is a strong one, which should make foreclosure a reasonably straightforward process. 44 Although all banks responded, responses to the qualitative section of the questionnaire were generally brief and often incomplete, and few banks completed the quantitative sections of the questionnaire because of difficulties in segregating lending data according to the size of loan and type of borrower. As a result, most useful qualitative information was gathered during interviews conducted in June 2008 with the senior management of 12 formal banks. 45 Bank of Uganda Lending Survey 2006/07. 69 6-20. Uncertainty regarding the land act amendment bill. The discussions around the land act amendment bill are highly political in nature. It is beyond the scope of the study to comment on the rights of bona fide tenants to land that they already regard as theirs in most senses, even if it is not formally recorded as their land. A major land reform was initiated in the 1998 land act and the subsequent 2002 strategic land plan, however it is clear that these have not fully achieved their intended objectives. The team‘s main observations on the bill are:  Any new reform should ensure first that a degree of equity is included between long-term sitting tenants and land-owners. Each should have the right to a fair hearing and be able to rely on a process to resolve any disputes. The reestablishment of district land boards may be the most appropriate forum to resolve some of these issues.  Uganda needs large tracts of land to be made available for development to develop its housing supply at a sufficient pace and scale. One of the concerns under the current proposals is that landowners may not have the ability to fully develop their land because of residual claims by tenants. Again, a fair process is needed, but ultimately compulsory purchase orders or some form of arbitrated compensation may be necessary to free up the necessary land. This could also be a role for reestablished district land boards.  An issue that is deeply rooted in the current discussions of the land act amendment bill is that of land administration. The original land act, while deficient in some respects, did provide for the creation of district land boards. These have been set up and are operational all over the country. This will solve land allocations and resolve land disputes. For land to be used easily and efficiently as collateral throughout the country, many of these land allocations issues will need to be resolved, which will allow a move from sporadic registration (that is, on a case-by-case basis) to a more comprehensive systematic registration process. Aside from the primary benefit of providing security of tenure to many land- and homeowners, it will create a pool of properties for banks to lend against.  A final consideration is the need for transparency. As the district land boards have been reestablished it should be very clear what their remit is, what powers are delegated to these boards, and how they are to be held accountable for their actions. Likewise, the vested interests of many defaulters (including some members of parliament) may result in legislation which is too consumer friendly, and will push lenders away from entering the mortgage lending business. Information Constraints 70 6-21. Slow property registration. The ability to use real estate in the form of land or buildings as collateral promotes growth. It allows borrowers to leverage one of their few assets, while banks are able to lend with greater confidence in an environment where credit information is lacking and credit risk high. Borrowing collateralized by real estate is still relatively uncommon in Uganda for companies and individuals. This can in part be attributed to the slow property registration process. The table below from the World Bank‘s ―Doing Business‖ report ranks Uganda at 166 of 178 countries in terms of the cost, number of steps, and time required to register property.46 A fundamental impediment to the registration process is the delay caused by the lack of capacity of the Chief Valuer‘s Office. At present every property transaction has to be independently valued by the Chief Valuer‘s Office for the purposes of levying stamp duty. Lack of capacity in the office means that this process can be extremely slow. The ―Doing Business‖ survey shows that this single step takes by far the most time to achieve, on average, compared to the 12 other steps. Some of the capacity issues arise from a shortfall in trained surveyors, which is not helped by the lack of a training course in Uganda for this profession.47 Table 6.2: Registering Property Ranking Number of Steps Number of Days Cost as % of (out of 178) Property Sudan 29 6 9 3.3 Botswana 34 4 30 4.9 Malawi 90 6 118 3.4 Mozambique 105 8 42 5.4 Kenya 115 8 73 4.1 Zambia 119 6 70 9.6 Tanzania 157 10 123 5.5 Uganda 166 13 227 6.9 Sub-Saharan Africa - 7.0 104.6 11.1 OECD - 4.9 28.0 4.6 Source: ―Doing Business,‖ World Bank. 2008. 6-22. Unreliable property registration. The responses submitted to the WB/BoU banking survey suggest that the delay in obtaining title is significantly better than the ―Doing Business‖ survey suggests, and for most of the banks the timing does not seem to 46 Some progress is occurring in computerizing title documents. Computerization should yield multiple benefits in terms of accuracy of the records, speed of searching, and reduced cost. With support from the World Bank‘s Private Sector Competitiveness Project II (PSCPII), the Ministry of Lands is improving some of the systems and processes, but as with all titling projects, the results take time. Nevertheless, a backlog of registrations has been cleared, regional offices are being upgraded, a land information system is coming online, and processes across the board are being improved 47 However, at the time of writing, a course which had closed several years ago is being re-initiated at the University of Makerere. The IFC‘s Uganda Mortgage Project is also actively providing training in property valuation skills. 71 be the key issue. The main concern is the reliability of the title. The title may prove incorrect either because of errors in the search and registration processes or because of fraud. The high incidence of invalid titles taints every title to some degree, even valid ones. From a bank‘s perspective, the value of the collateral has to be discounted to allow for the possibility of fraud, or extra expenses need to be incurred either by the bank or the borrower to perfect the title. 6-23. Difficulties in assessing credit risk. A final obstacle raised by a number of lenders to explain their reluctance to engage in the mortgage market is the difficulty in accessing reliable information in the underwriting process. It is hoped that the recently launched Credit Reference Bureau will resolve this problem. It may take a year or two for credit histories to build up and for the database to grow into a tool capable of significantly lowering credit risk at the mortgage underwriting stage. Other issues that have been raised and are seen as concerns are the lack of a national ID scheme, which makes it difficult to verify the identity of a borrower. Secondly, the lack of a civil registry makes it difficult to assess civil status of potential borrowers. If the provisions in the draft law go through, this will put a significant onus on the bank to find a way to check whether a prospective borrower is married and if spousal consent has been obtained. Financing Constraints 6-24. There is a lack of long-term funds. The problem is twofold: first, the absolute lack of long-term funds due to the absence of private or public contractual savings products, and second, for those limited long-term funds that do exist, there is reluctance to invest over the long term. Given the relative macroeconomic stability of Uganda over the last decade, investors should now feel more comfortable about taking a long-term view. The National Social Security Fund (NSSF) has in the past been an investor in real estate, but on its own account, as a developer of residential and commercial real estate, rather than as a provider of long-term funds. It is currently engaged in discussions to make more funds available to the banking sector for investment in real estate, but even the NSSF funds are limited relative to the financing needed to close the housing gap. Housing Finance Bank (HFB) is by far the largest provider of housing finance in Uganda, accounting for around 70 percent of the entire market. It is a state-owned institution, but does nevertheless operate on a market basis. In August 2007 it accessed the capital markets in a corporate bond issue of UGS 30 billion. It was clear from the pricing of that issue that the market does not consider it to have a full guarantee from the government of Uganda. Even though they raised a bond, their main constraint is access to long-term funds to finance their business. Housing Supply Constraints 72 6-25. High cost of infrastructure for development. Developers have to cover the full cost of infrastructure development, which makes it difficult to create affordable housing. Infrastructure includes construction of access roads, provision of utilities (water and electricity), and the addition of drainage and sewerage facilities. For large developments, it is likely that any water treatment facility would also have to be paid for by the developer and would thus be included in the price of units for sale. The infrastructure is typically built by the utility company and paid for by the developer. The utility company gains ownership over the asset once completed. The extra cost of infrastructure can be prohibitive and for large developments requires a large upfront investment that developers may not have or may not want to risk. 6-26. Lack of credible developers/builders. Uganda suffers from a shortage of developers who have the capacity to engage in large-scale construction projects. This is the root cause of the housing supply problem, which is then exacerbated by lack of financing from banks. Developers lack many of the necessary project management skills, financial discipline, and technical knowledge to be seen as attractive credit risks by banks. This means that the only way to finance projects is through equity investments by the developers. The inability to leverage banking finance acts as a major constraint to the growth of the sector. Real estate development is an industry that is very dependent on cash flow and has long lead times between initiating a project and seeing final returns. Not having financing available creates a major barrier to enter the market, and for those who do, it is an added cost which will be reflected in the pricing of the units they produce. 6-27. Lack of real estate training. Activities which would be expected in an active real estate development market, such as research and development or market surveys, are also absent. No real estate education courses are available in Uganda, which means that expertise is limited to those few developers who have been able to build experience of their own, and Ugandans who have had the opportunity to study abroad or nonresidents. Overall this is an insufficient pool of expertise and talent to push forward development on the scale required. 6-28. Lack of large-scale development. All of the issues detailed above conspire to make large-scale developments almost nonexistent in Uganda. It can be difficult to obtain the necessary land, financing can be problematic, and the cost of developing the infrastructure restricts affordability and thereby the potential clientele. In addition to the weak project management skills of contractors and developers mentioned earlier, the logistical coordination of suppliers may not be sufficient to handle large-scale projects. However, without a major scaling up of development, many economies of scale, such as reducing some of the fixed costs of infrastructure, will not be attained. Without a significant scaling up in housing production, it is unlikely that affordable housing can be produced in the numbers necessary in a viable way. Recommendations 73 6-29. Based on their analysis and the results of the survey, the team has highlighted a number of recommendations. These relate to specific policy or institutional reforms that would strengthen the ability of banks to provide access to finance and to improve the quality of credit provided by, for example, extending the term of loans being made available. The recommendations are addressed to the primary stakeholders in the sector— the BoU and the MoFPED. Policy reforms include all recommendations related to new laws, regulations, or supervisory practices. Institutional reforms relate to strengthening institutions, improving information, and building capacity.48 6-30. Well directed political will and changes in the regulatory environment could create the necessary momentum for investment in the housing sector to start scaling up to the levels necessary to close the housing gap. The way forward will need to include measures to increase the amount of financing directed at the supply of housing and funding to create effective demand for housing. This means creating a mortgage market accessible to a broader swathe of the population and creating the rights conditions for banks to finance increased levels of development. Policy Reforms 6-31. Resolve land act amendment bill issues. The passage of the mortgage bill is a major positive step that will resolve some of the uncertainty preventing some lenders from fully committing resources to developing a mortgage product. Further work is required on the land act amendment bill to ensure that landowners are fully able to develop their land and construct homes on them by accessing long-term finance from the financial system. 6-32. Establish consumer protection rules. Much of this can be done without the need for a legal framework, through a voluntary industry agreement. The key to ensuring it is properly applied and implemented is to have a monitoring system with the option to pass it into law if the voluntary system does not deliver the desired results. The measures could include guidelines on information provision, transparency of charges and comparability of rates; on best practice for handling delinquent loans, including forbearance practices; on creation of an ombudsman to hear complaints, and on allowing consumers a cooling-off period. 6-33. Review valuation policy. Consider whether a formal valuation is required in every instance by the Government Value‘s Office. Could the transaction value be used as the tax base? This is the standard practice in most countries, and although it can encourage values to be illegally under declared, it is possible to put in preventive safeguards. Rather than value every property, this could be done on a sample basis. The samples could help build a database of values that would provide a rapid way to check the values of properties not subject to full valuation. 48 Implementation of the recommendations can be supported by existing initiatives such as the IFC‘s Uganda Primary Mortgage Market Initiative (UPMMI), the World Bank‘s Private Sector Competitiveness Project II (PSCPII), and the project funded by FIRST focusing on specific aspects of the Ugandan housing finance system. 74 6-34. Consider establishing a liquidity facility. The facility would allow banks to overcome some of the maturity issues and provide investors and pension funds with a supply of simple bonds yielding a better return than treasury bills without a significant increase in risk. A further advantage of a liquidity facility would be to leverage the short- term deposit base. By providing a safety net protecting banks from liquidity concerns, lenders can engage in a higher level of maturity transformation, thereby making better use of limited retail deposits. 6-35. Develop savings products with longer terms. A range of new savings products could be considered, including saving for housing schemes. These products are already present to some extent in the informal/semiformal sector, but rarely for housing. Other products could include the expansion of term deposits, such as certificates of deposits. In this context, the scope of the existing deposit protection scheme should be reviewed to see if it is adequate and provides enough of a safety net to create trust in the banking system. 6-36. Consider making longer-term benchmark issues. The pricing of long-term funds is very difficult and cannot be done accurately without a yield curve. The Bank of Uganda/Ministry of Finance should give consideration to making longer-term benchmark issues to build sufficient liquidity in long-term debt to get pricing points for a yield curve. 6-37. Allow for advance sales of unbuilt properties. Making advance sales of unbuilt properties easier and more secure is another means of reducing the financial risk for banks. Ensuring that a proportion of a development is pre-sold, and that future cash flows are guaranteed by deposit payments, provide some comfort to the bank that a development will be successful. A number of measures are necessary to allow pre-sales to take place in secure way for the bank, the developer, and the end customer. The main one is the ability to create an escrow account to protect the deposits of prospective buyers. The deposit should be ring-fenced and not be accessible to the developer or used as security by the developer. This can be done through a law, or in the case of Uganda, it is likely that a secure contractual form can be achieved. Other options could also be assessed, such as a mutual insurance scheme for developers or a surety bond system to be provided by specialized insurance companies. Both of these schemes provide some guarantee the development will be completed even if the developer goes out of business. 6-38. Privatize the Housing Finance Bank (HFB). The government-owned HFB is the largest provider of housing finance in Uganda. While HFB does operate along market lines at present, no compelling reason exists for it to remain in public hands. Privatizing HFB may present a number of benefits, including improved access to capital markets for raising equity. If HFB is to scale up its lending business to more than a few thousand loans, it will need a significant capital injection. Fiscal constraints may prevent the government from providing the necessary levels of investment as and when it is needed. Private sector ownership may also help in terms of defining more innovative strategies, partnering with private sector developers, or partnering with a bank as a distribution channel. These benefits are separate from the removal of credit risk from the government‘s balance sheet. Although at present HFB operates on market lines, the 75 experience with state housing banks49 around the world is that during downturns, it is politically very difficult for an entity known to be state owned to enforce its debts, and when necessary to repossess homes. 6-39. Review the urban planning strategy. Improving access to long-term finance alone cannot resolve all the issues preventing the housing gap from being closed. A coordinated approach is necessary to link together the financing aspects of housing and an urban planning strategy. Urbanization is going to increase in the coming years, and this will necessitate new approaches in terms of urban planning. Land will need to be made available for new construction, but it will also have to be used in a smarter way, with higher density construction. This is necessary to maximize the value of expensive urban land parcels and to facilitate the development of utilities. Overarching much of the discussion on urban policy are land issues. There is a need to carry out a detailed inventory of public land assets. The government could then consider making more effective use of this land, by auctioning off tracts of land to developers.50 6-40. Promote other forms of tenure. The promotion of rental housing should also be considered as part of an integrated urban housing policy. Mortgages and home ownership alone are unlikely to resolve the issues in cities like Kampala, where the majority of people rent their properties. Further work should be done to consider whether the right policy framework and mix of incentives exists to encourage landlords to develop good quality rental accommodation. Questions that should be considered are: how can landlords be incentivized to upgrade their properties, or connect them to utilities? Can investors be encouraged to put money into rental housing through schemes such as real estate investment trusts (REITS)? 6-41. Consider a formal registration for mortgage brokers. This could be accompanied by a set of regulations. A voluntary code of conduct or certification scheme may not be sufficient, given the high levels of fraud already present in the housing market. 6-42. Design a legal framework for securitization. This would be complemented by originating standardized mortgages and by collecting data, which will allow investors to assess the quality of the underlying mortgage assets. This should be seen as a long-term initiative which will only come into force when the mortgage market has grown significantly and reached a critical mass, allowing securitization to become economically viable. Institutional Reforms 6-43. Improve knowledge of mortgage lending in the judiciary. Many lenders have observed that the judicial system seems to invariably favor the borrower when it comes to 49 See Chiquier and Lea 2008, chapter 10 by Olivier Hassler and Bertrand Renaud, ―State Housing Banks.‖ 50 An example of this policy being implemented can be found in Egypt. The government has held a series of auctions to sell off large parcels of state-owned land to developers as a means of encouraging developers to put land to the specific use of building residential housing. 76 court cases. Judges should receive training to understand the importance of having legally enforceable collateral. Consumer protection measures can provide some counterbalance to a more rigorous enforcement of the secured lending laws. 6-44. Strengthen capacity of the government Valuer’s Office. There is a lack of qualified surveyors, which means that the workload is beyond what can comfortably be handled by the government Valuer‘s Office. The reintroduction of a surveying course should help in increasing the number of qualified professionals. 6-45. Increase level of data and market information. A common problem in developing mortgage/housing markets is the lack of data or information to help guide policy makers and regulators. Uganda does collect some information, but this is often insufficient, not timely, or not on a sufficiently regular basis. A particular need exists for more information on the housing market. The information provided by the housing census is useful, but is difficult to track over time or to use as a market indicator. The improvements in the land registry should enable an upgrade in information provision on housing transactions. This should include data on number of transactions, property prices, regional breakdowns, and sales by type of housing (for example, single-family house or apartment). A working group should be formed on the topic of housing and housing finance statistics to catalog the data currently available from various sources and prepare a gap analysis setting out data needs. The working group should contain a combination of public and private sector actors. Likewise, the solutions should include measures designed to improve the functioning of the market by providing credible and timely information and longer-term strategic information to serve policymakers. 6-46. Support development of industry professionals. For housing finance to grow in a sustainable way, it needs the support of a number of professionals who each play an important part in the secured lending process. These professionals include realtors, valuation professionals, mortgage brokers, bailiffs, and insurers. Likewise, the construction and real estate development sector is facing a great shortage of skills at every level, from project managers to craftsmen. Specific suggestions include:  Facilitate trade associations or professional group for many of these categories. These groups are necessary to create balance in these sectors and to coordinate activities such as training, data collection, certification, and conferences. A number of these are now being created, notably the Association of Estate Agents of Uganda (AREA) and the Mortgage Association of Uganda (MAU). These should be supported as a way of developing best practices and providing policy makers and development organizations with a single counterparty.  Develop training programs for the various professionals. Industry bodies should take the lead in assessing the training needs for the development of their sectors. For surveyors, a program is being reestablished and will provided a much needed increase in the number of professionals able to do property valuations. 77  Introduce a real estate development course. This would help to ground developers in the necessary skills to manage a development project. These skills would include elements of project management, finance, human resources, and marketing. The recent creation of a real estate developers association could be the necessary catalyst to help push for such a course and to help design some of its key features. It is recommended that the Real Estate Developers Association come up with proposals and initial design concepts for such a qualification in Uganda. 6-47. Strengthen capacity of lenders. The banks also need to upgrade their knowledge, capacity, and products for lending to developers. They need to be able to monitor and understand construction projects, build up experience in underwriting developer loans, and be able to disburse in tranches as projects evolve. 78 7. Increasing the Private Financing of Infrastructure 7-1. This chapter discusses the financial capacity of infrastructure providers to engage in local long-term debt financing for their capital development plans. Specific focus is on parastatal infrastructure companies and their capacity to raise debt. The use of special purpose vehicles, particularly in the case of public private partnerships, is not discussed in detail, though this avenue of infrastructure development will become increasingly relevant as the balance sheets of the utility infrastructure providers take on debt for expansion of assets in the short-term. The first section reviews the key infrastructure sectors and providers and their current financing strategies. The second section assesses the constraints to private financing of infrastructure, using the lessons from the case of the upcoming National Water and Sewerage Corporation (NWSC) bond transaction. The final section discusses recommended actions to increase the private financing of infrastructure. Overview 7-2. Infrastructure providers in Uganda are primarily monopolies. There are two organizational forms that exist—the parastatal monopoly provider and the independent project operator. The water, electricity transmission, and transport sectors all have single monopoly, government-owned service providers, while energy generation and distribution are undertaken by private sector ‗project‘ operators. Detailed descriptions of the sectors, providers, tariff structures, financial position, and capital requirements are provided in annexes 1 to 4. 7-3. Infrastructure service providers require long-term debt at, ideally, fixed interest rates. There are four primary sources of financing for infrastructure providers. These include two public sources—the treasury and foreign donors—and two private or commercial sources—loans from commercial banks and bond issuances on the capital markets (or through private placements). Further nuances of private borrowing from the bond markets are whether the bonds are issued directly by the infrastructure provider (corporate bonds) or issued by the treasury (sovereign debt), and where the proceeds are on-lent to infrastructure providers. Issues linked to treasury intermediation are summarized in box 7.1 below. 7-4. Public funding from foreign donors has its disadvantages. The development finance institutions (DFIs) are able to mobilize required funds using subsovereign, borrower-targeted products, often at rates lower than available in the local market. However, this funding is characterized by long approval lead times, frequent currency risks, and onerous loan covenants. Dependence on such funding also prevents the development of local long-term funding sources. Foreign donor inflows can also create excess liquidity, which may lead to pressure on the exchange rate. Increased domestic demand increases the supply of nontradables at the expense of tradables, leading to real exchange rate appreciation and reduction in export competitiveness. However, it may be possible to mitigate these demand effects by targeting capital investments to increase 79 supply-side productivity. By intermediating liquidity and savings toward infrastructure investments, local financial markets increase the absorptive capacity of the economy, thereby reducing the risk of Dutch disease.51 Box 7.1: Corporate (subnational) versus Sovereign Debt for Infrastructure Finance Some commentators argue that instead of infrastructure providers borrowing directly, the treasury (with its higher credit rating) should borrow funds from the capital markets and on-lend these funds to parastatal and other potential borrowers. The pooling and diversification logic that this implies is particularly attractive where there are a number of smaller potential borrowers that would face very high costs in accessing the capital markets, for example, where local governments may be looking to issue debt. Even where small issuer size makes pooling efficient, a separate institution is more efficient to act as a financial intermediary than the treasury. Essentially a number of risks are associated with treasury intermediating funds to public borrowers: Moral hazard –If treasury lends to a parastatal, there is a risk that such funding is perceived as soft or grant funding by the ultimate borrower. It is not prioritized as a core operating cost and repayment risk is increased. This factor is fundamentally affected by the accountability framework affecting the parastatal. Complexity – Where the issuer is relatively large (as is the case with NWSC), intermediation will add complexity and cost without the associated economies of scale. Ultimately this will increase cost of borrowing to the utility. Lack of planning independence – By using the MoF/treasury to provide due diligence associated with intermediation, there is a risk that planning systems at the parastatal level are undermined. This will possibly lead to the erosion of planning capacity. Fundamentally, in the case of NWSC, corporate reforms (including the development of a board to oversee operations) necessitate that planning and financing decisions happen at the corporate rather than treasury level. The board of directors is the key agent charged with preserving shareholder value, as is the case in any normal private corporation. The continued efficacy of a well-functioning board is the foundation of the continued success of NWSC‘s operations. 7-5. Private financing from commercial banks is limited. Infrastructure providers can be attractive borrowers for bank lenders. Given the daily cash flow associated with the utilities bill collection process, and possibilities of assigning particular receivables, lenders can be very secure about their payback if debts are structured well. Utilities often access a number of banking services (collection services, cash management, working capital, and the like) so they can have good bargaining power with banks where the various portfolio services are being procured together. Bank loans also allow for a drawdown of the loan (over, for example, the construction period) where interest charged is on outstanding principal only. These advantages, however, do not compensate for a fundamental constraint faced by the banks: the nature of their short-term liabilities. Due to the nature of the deposits financing most bank lending, the ability of banks to offer long-term fixed rate finance is very limited. In Uganda, the banks may be able to issue 51 Manroth, Astrid ―Uganda CEM: Making Fiscal Space for Infrastructure.‖ 80 loans with seven-year tenures, but only at a floating rate. Even this relatively long tenure is a direct result of the considerable liquidity in the Ugandan banking sector. Furthermore, loan covenants required by banks may be overly restrictive and limit a utility‘s ability to raise further debt finance as it requires. 7-6. The bond market is ideally suited to provide funding to infrastructure service providers. By intermediating between institutions with long-term liabilities (such as pension funds and insurance companies) and borrowers requiring longer-dated fixed- rate debt, the bond market in many countries is a major financier of infrastructure. Further, the bond market provides for a further diversification of lenders, reducing the flexibility risk that defines borrowing from one banking agency. It is not uncommon in Uganda for bonds to have 10 or more buyers. Bond issuances, however, are complex and time consuming, and due to their structure, induce a ‗negative carry,‘ whereby funds being held prior to being spent attract interest payments (in contrast to bank loans where unspent funds are not drawn down and so do not attract interest charges). A summary of bond issuances to date in Uganda is presented in the table below. Table 7.1: Bond Issuances in Uganda Bond Size Interest Rate Listing Issuer Name (bn UGS) Tenure Floating / Fixed Status Issue Date 30 Stanbic Bank (indicative) 10 Upcoming Housing Finance Dec 07 to Jul Company Uganda 30 10 Fixed 13.05%(3 tranches) Listed 08 182 day t-bill + 1.25% / Standard Chartered 23 10 15.75% Fixed Listed Jan-06 EADB 20 7 182 day t-bill + 0.75% Listed Dec-05 UTL 30 5 182 day t-bill + 1.65% Listed Sep-03 MTN (Tranche 3) 2 4 182 day t-bill + 1.75% Not listed Dec-01 MTN (Tranche 2) 2.5 4 182 day t-bill + 1.75% Not listed Nov-01 MTN (Tranche 1) 5 4 182 day t-bill + 1.75% Not listed Aug-01 PTA 10.36 5 182 day t-bill + 1.75% Matured Mar-99 EADB 10 4 182 day t-bill + 2.00% Matured Jan-98 Source: Capital Markets Authority, Uganda 7-7. Bond financing can be cheaper than bank borrowing. Early indications suggested that in terms of interest rates, the cost of borrowing through bond instruments in Uganda would be lower than bank borrowing by about 2 percent per annum when looking at corporate borrowings at the long end of the yield curve (tenures of 7-10 years). Further, the bond market could finance tenures of up to 10 years. Interestingly, financial origination costs (at about 1-1.5 percent) are also lower for bonds than most bank loans (1.5 percent+). Nonfinance costs of bond origination, however, can be considerable. In contemplating a bond transaction, capital markets regulation must be followed. The Ugandan Capital Market Authority is the primary regulator of debt instruments. The CMA application fee is 0.1 percent of issue size. If the bond is to be listed, the Ugandan Stock Exchange must approve the bond prospectus or information memorandum. Listing fees are 0.1 percent of total issue size up to a maximum charge of UGS 20 million. Issuance costs for two recent bonds in the Ugandan market are shown below. 81 Table 7.2: Issuance Costs for Recent Bonds Bond 1 – Bond 2 – % of Issuance % of Issuance Bond Cost Cost Issue Size - - Application & listing fees payable to CMA & USE 0.20% 0.20% Professional & advisory fees paid to all advisors 0.74% 0.90% Printing costs / miscellaneous costs 0.05% 0.04% Total Issuance Costs 0.99% 1.14% Source: Capital Markets Authority, Uganda 7-8. The success of bond issuance depends on the liquidity available with institutional investors. In Uganda, the unreformed pension sector has led to a concentration of liquidity with the National Social Security Fund (NSSF). The NSSF does not have very rigid investment guidelines or asset allocation rules and as such, either listed or privately placed infrastructure related debt can attract their investment. Smaller pension funds have also participated in bond issuances in the past, however, the NSSF has acted as a de facto underwriter for most issues. Recently, the NSSF has been engaged in an enquiry into its investment decisions. This enquiry has left the fund without a functioning investment committee, essentially removing the considerable liquidity it holds from the market. Given the dearth of corporate bond issues in the country however, the appetite of remaining investors for corporate and infrastructure debt is considerable—but this short-term limitation of NSSF‘s ability to invest in debt instruments may limit the success of bond issuances in the country. In the longer-term, an unreformed pension sector poses a liquidity risk to potential issuers of debt instruments. 7-9. Increasingly, regional investors are looking for debt instruments in countries outside of their own. Investors in Kenya (where a considerable portion of the total pension assets are under private management) and specialized funds based in South Africa are looking to purchase debt in other African countries. Liquidity in Kenya also poses an opportunity for Ugandan debt issuances in that the pension sector regulator in Kenya, the Retirement Benefits Authority (RBA), classifies Uganda and Tanzania as on- shore investments. The RBA requires that at least 85 percent of pension assets be invested onshore, and due to the limited number of debt instruments in Kenya, there is appetite to place some of the considerable pension liquidity in instruments issued in Uganda. Until recently, global liquidity had also contributed to interest in African corporate debt denominated in local currency. Hedge funds based in North America and Europe were actively seeking debt in a variety of countries, due to the perceived lack of correlation between those countries and the global economy. Recent events, in the form of the global credit crisis, have reduced this liquidity, preventing such cross border 82 investments in foreign currencies where there is no currency swap market. A key feature of such cross border investments is the currency risk taken by the investor. Given the dearth of currency-hedging products available in Africa, limiting exposure to currency is not possible in many cases. Most debt investors require extra yield to compensate for the additional risk being taken. Constraints 7-10. There is considerable potential for bond financing for infrastructure in Uganda. Liquidity in the capital markets is relatively high. Both the pensions and banking sector are over-reliant on treasury bills for longer-dated assets. There is therefore considerable interest in diversification into corporate bonds. Corporate bonds issued to finance infrastructure are of particular interest to the pensions sector, given the longer required tenure, which matches their liability profile. However, there are a number of constraints to facilitating such finance. These have been identified by the team‘s analysis and also through team member support to the ongoing NWSC bond issue (discussed in detail in annex 1). The constraints have been grouped into (i) institutional constraints, and (ii) financing constraints. Institutional Constraints 7-11. The condition of potential issuers is the key demand driver for infrastructure finance in Uganda. The case of the National Water and Sewerage Corporation (NWSC), which is discussed in detail later in this chapter, is about a local infrastructure provider with strong demand for commercial finance to develop at least a portion of its overall capital investment program. Key issues affecting the demand for such finance are linked to wider reform areas. NWSC provides a case of a reformed infrastructure parastatal where the need for commercial finance was a driver of its reform process. Therefore, reform issues, such as tariff predictability and sufficiency and operational efficiency, will be the key drivers of demand going forward. Critically, the capital structure of the potential issuers will affect their likely success in raising commercial finance. The removal of legacy debt from the balance sheet of potential issuers through equity swaps or otherwise is also critical, as this will provide the equity cushion required by lenders even where cash flows are strong. The table below summarizes the nature of the funding required, and key issues linked to that borrowing, for the different infrastructure sectors reviewed in this report. Table 7.3: Infrastructure Financing Needs and Key Issues Sector Service Nature of Debt Finance Key Issues Provider Required Water NWSC Capital finance for Commercial finance must target viable network expansion and investments due to rigid (if predictable) tariff rehabilitation structure Small IPPs Debt (possibly in hard Limited long-term liquidity and experience in currency) required on a project finance with the banking sector 83 project finance basis means that support (in project development) and credit enhancement may be required Uganda Transmission expansions Exposure to tariff risk, as both generation and Electricity linked to significant distribution companies are protected Electricity Transmission increase in generation Legacy debt on balance sheet Company, capacity Limited Umeme Distribution investments Limited interest in expanding distribution required by concession network given limited bulk energy supply in contract country Roads Investment in Uncertain whether any leveraging is really Authority maintenance (as major necessary given scale of funds availability capital investment is Transport largely treasury financed) Civil Aviation No immediate new Cash flows make debt service difficult Authority financing required, Limited ability to increase revenues however debt restructuring necessary Source: NWSC, UMEME, UETCL, UNRA and CAA 7-12. Sector reform processes are needed to increasing viability. Sector reform can contribute to creating bankable issuers. The role that longer-term sector reform plays in the infrastructure sectors is critical in the development of viable debt issuers. Pre- conditions to successful bond issuance are driven by classic sector reform issues such as tariff reform, regulatory regime, corporate governance mechanisms and autonomy, and capacity to plan investments. 7-13. Limited transparency in tariff setting can pose a significant cash flow risk for infrastructure providers. Power Purchase Agreements (PPAs) for energy generators and tariff indexations, like that of NWSC, limit such risks. In Uganda, UETCL is probably most exposed to such tariff risk, linked to it being situated between energy generator and distribution company. Where energy costs are not being passed completely through to the customer, it is likely that financing the mismatch in costs will be the responsibility of the transmission company, which may or may not get a reliable subsidy to do this. Over time, with the country‘s generation mix shifting to sources driven by fixed cost, exposure to variation in input prices should stabilize energy costs and so reduce risk to the transmission company. 7-14. Infrastructure providers may not have absorption capacity. Many of the infrastructure providers discussed here have articulated capital investment plans that are far larger than historical levels. This, together with risks linked to infrastructure development more generally, implies that there is a risk that funds, once raised, are not used, or are used poorly. This is especially an issue for the use of bond finance, where significant negative carry can be associated with project delays. A core reform issue, then, is to ensure that projects are well prepared and capacity is allocated to the implementation of projects prior to the drawdown of funds. Further, by structuring financing to be timed with capital plans, this risk can be reduced. The use of medium- term note programs may be beneficial in this context. 84 Financing Constraints 7-15. The approval process can be complex, leading to delays in raising finance. Given the innovative nature of bond issues into a nascent capital market; approval processes are not fully standardized. Given this uncertainty, initial debt issuances in Uganda will receive increased scrutiny from regulators and the Ministry of Finance (where issuer is a parastatal), effectively increasing transaction costs. Once an issuer is established, this time frame is likely to be reduced. By seeking approval for bond programs linked to their capital investment plans, utilities can get the most from the long and complex regulatory process. Figure 4.1 shows a continuum of bond market development. As markets get more developed, the focus of support will shift from developing issuers to come to the market toward assisting market regulators and policy makers to develop interventions that increase market efficiency. Uganda is on the left hand side of the figure currently. As such, focus is required at the sector and issuer levels to increase issuances into the nascent capital markets. The increase in frequency of such issues will naturally highlight wider financial markets issues such as CMA approval processes and pricing, pension reform, and the development of a government yield curve to act as a pricing anchor. Figure 7.1: Bond Market Development Continuum Sector/Issuer Level Support Capital Markets Support Small transactions Larger transactions Infrequent issues – illiquid Issuer benchmarks created by market frequent issues Bond Market Development 7-16. The structure of the pensions sector adds considerable liquidity risk to potential bond issuers. The short-term nature of bank deposits implies a liquidity risk to banks lending long-term. Given the concentration of liquidity at the NSSF, there is a concern that if NSSF becomes unable to make investment decisions, potential bond issuers will experience considerable difficulty in placing their debt in the market. Given the large-scale and often multiyear investment projects that infrastructure providers are exposed to, this risk can be expensive and a significant deterrent. 85 7-17. The advisory services market in Uganda is nascent. The role of financial advisors is critical in the issuance of either bond debt or in securing a loan. Advisors have the critical role of handholding new issuers (which defines the Ugandan potential pool) and connecting them to the capital markets. In the case of a bond, advisory services are required by the Capital Markets Authority, whereas in the case of loan finance, these services are optional, but can add value due to the specialized nature of the product being secured (long-term finance). Mortgage Brokers of East Africa (MBEA) are the leading corporate finance and advisory firm in the country, having been involved in all bond issuances to date and many other additional corporate financings. More recently, African Alliance (operating in 14 countries across Africa) and Dyer and Blair (of Kenya) have invested in local presence in the market; these should help deepen the market for financial advice and increase skills capacity. Given that the overall capital markets are relatively shallow in Uganda, successful bond issuances are relationship driven in addition to being driven by the credit quality of the issuer and instrument. The primary function of the financial advisor therefore is blunted. 7-18. Credit enhancement facilities are unavailable. Another factor affecting the cost and ability to place corporate or infrastructure debt in Uganda is the use of credit enhancements. Particularly given the short-term nature of bank deposits and wider economic risks in the country, tenure extension products are perceived as having value. Such products would ensure lenders that in the case of a liquidity event, they would have the option to sell a long-term asset. In its simplest form, the liquidity facility could be a refinancing of the debt, though this is relatively inefficient as it does not make use of what liquidity there is in the market and does not achieve any leverage from public funds used to provide long-term liabilities to banks. Investors may require some sort of credit guarantee to insure against credit default of the issuer. In Kenya, where there has been a de facto requirement of such guarantees on bond issuances, there is an expectation from investors that such guarantees will be present. Uganda does not have a market culture of demanding such credit enhancements, but where the issuer or instrument is of perceived marginal creditworthiness, such products may add value. In the case of NWSC, the usefulness of a credit guarantee as a credit risk-sharing device has not been stressed by any investors. It has been recognized, however, as potentially providing a way to achieve some degree of political risk cover. The perspective among investors has been that if they engage an international credit guarantee (such as those offered by bilaterals and multilaterals), the government will be less inclined to interfere with the operations and debt servicing of the issuing entity. In a counterintuitive way, some investors also consider different international guarantees to be of different quality, based on the international rating supporting them, even though the international ratings may be above the Ugandan Sovereign rating (implying that they would all carry a local AAA rating). For instance, investors may prefer a US government backed guarantee to one issued by Guarantee companies as it carries a higher international rating. Recommendations 7-19. By developing a series of infrastructure finance transactions in Uganda, the capital markets will increase their capacity to finance both infrastructure and other 86 sectors. Liquidity will find a home and infrastructure development will be accelerated. A number of actions can facilitate this process. Institutional Reforms 7-20. Improve the financial position of the infrastructure providers. Each of the providers could use support to asses— and if appropriate—restructure its portfolio. For example, in the case of UETCL, a large portion of the company‘s fixed assets have been recorded at their book values under UEB ownership, and while no formal revaluation has been done since, it is thought that the company‘s assets are worth more than their book value.52 Proper evaluation of assets could therefore create a significant revaluation reserve that would boost the value of the company‘s equity. 7-21. Conduct capacity-building efforts for potential issuers. Issuers in Uganda, as was the case with NWSC, will benefit from specific capacity-building efforts around optimization of their financing. Such support should include discussion with other potential infrastructure issuers within the country, but also sharing experiences with good practice issuers, in the region and further afield. Such efforts should be in the form of specific handholding support to issuers to ensure they move speedily through debt management strategy development and into the capital raising process. Such handholding support also has a significant role to play in the development of public-private partnerships in the country. Ideally, a central institution could both provide debt raising advice to corporate infrastructure providers and enter into joint ventures with the private sector or structure other forms of PPPs. Such a unit could further advise line ministries in the structuring of their PPPs. A support unit such as this could be viewed as a PPP unit with an expanded mandate to support capital raising efforts of parastatal infrastructure providers, as well. 7-22. Obtain independent views on infrastructure performance. For those seeking project or balance sheet finance, credit ratings will provide comfort to potential lenders through their independent assessment of financial performance. Even though these are traditionally used for capital markets ratings, local banks, due to their unfamiliarity with infrastructure finance issues, would benefit from the additional information provided by credit ratings. For parastatals, credit ratings provide independent analysis to shareholders (the government) and will allow easier discussions with treasury on the provision of no objections to pursue commercial financing. Thus far, only NWSC has obtained a shadow credit rating. A structured support to develop such credit ratings will expedite these benefits. 7-23. Conduct capacity building efforts for financiers. Lenders lack familiarity with project finance and the financial structures used for utility borrowers. Enhancing infrastructure and project evaluation skills will allow lenders to approach transactions with more confidence and may allow them to make better pricing decisions. 52 Discussion with UETCL Deputy Managing Director August 29, 2008. 87 7-24. Provide support to the transaction advisory sector. Potential issuers and lenders require good transaction advisory services to make credit decisions. By placing debt in the wider East Africa region, issues of liquidity and completion among investors will help allocate capital more efficiently. This is particularly relevant where the markets are not fully developed (as in Uganda) and market players are not fully equipped to evaluate documentation and the structure of financing. External support for transaction structuring and advisory would help to catalyze Ugandan infrastructure finance while building capacity in the local advisory sector. Financing Reforms 7-25. Develop term transformation facilities. Ideally the long-term liquidity contained in the unreformed pension sector could be used to provide the required long- term finance for infrastructure projects. However, because of the concentration of that liquidity, there is a risk it will be unavailable when it is required. As such, debt access by the infrastructure sectors could be developed through the construction of artificial term transformation facilities. These could include, as in the energy sector, the development of refinance options, which allow banks to provide longer-term finance and so compete with naturally long-term liquidity such as that in the pension sector. Such facilities would be particularly useful in the small-project finance segment of the wider infrastructure sector. Under the second phase of the Energy for Rural Transformation (ERT) project, an updated refinance instrument will be used. Liquidity guarantees will be offered in the place of direct refinance at the point of loan origination. Essentially such facilities remove the internal refinance risk faced by banks when they use short-term liabilities to fund long-term assets. Such facilities carry considerable startup costs, but provide the possibility of catalyzing a culture of lending long term, which could benefit the pension sector by providing long-term assets matched to their long-term liabilities. To avoid contingent liabilities on the treasury balance sheet, such options or guarantees need to be funded and so housed in their own corporate entity. A pilot example is the Uganda Energy Capital Corporation (UECC), which was created expressly to provide liquidity guarantees under ERT II. 7-26. Develop credit enhancement facilities. Credit enhancements will also be required in some cases to address perceived credit quality issues with issuers and the debt instruments they issue. 7-27. Mitigate currency risk. The creation of specific currency-risk mitigation instruments will be critical to leverage regional liquidity pools. Policies should also focus on encouraging potential issuers to seek funds locally, rather than from development finance institutions or in international currencies. It is not advisable to pass currency risk to the customer when local currency funding could prevent it altogether. Intermediation for infrastructure finance by local financial markets will also increase the absorptive capacity of the economy and help avoid problems created by excess liquidity. 88 Annexes Making Finance Work for Uganda Annex A: References Avarts Housing Limited and Good Earth Trust. 2008. ―Concept Note: Low Cost Eco- Housing Development in Uganda.‖ Kampala, Uganda. Bank of Uganda. 2007. ―The Lending Survey for the Second Half, 2006/07.‖ Bank of Uganda. July 2007. Office of the Executive Director Supervision. ―Circular to all Commercial Banks and Credit Institutions: Additional Guidance Note on Mortgage Banking Class.‖ Bank of Uganda. October 2006. Office of the Executive Director Supervision. ―Circular to all Commercial Banks and Credit Institutions: Guidance Note on Mortgage Banking Class.‖ Boleat, Mark. 2005. ―Housing Finance in Uganda.‖ Prepared for IFC. Chiquier, Loic and Michael Lea (editors). 2008. Duebel, Achim (author of chapter). ―Housing Finance Policy in Emerging Markets. chapter 6, ―Consumer Information and Protection.‖ The World Bank, Washington D.C. Chiquier, Loic and Michael Lea, (editors). 2008. Hassler, Olivier and Renaud, Bertrand (authors of chapter), ―Housing Finance Policy in Emerging Markets.‖ Chapter 10, State Housing Banks.‖ The World Bank, Washington D.C. Economist Intelligence Unit. 2007. Uganda Country Profile. September. FitchRatings. 2008. ―Sub-Saharan Africa Sovereign Outlook 2008.‖ IFC. 2007. ―Presentation on the Draft Mortgage Bill (2007) – Finding a middle ground‖ IFC. 2008. ―Legal Requirements for mortgage lending in Uganda‖ Kalema, Dr. William S. 2005. ―Strategies for facilitating the financing of affordable housing in Uganda by the formal private sector.‖ Prepared for UN-HABITAT. Kalema, Dr. William S. 2008. ―Access to Housing Finance in Africa: Overview of the housing finance sector in Uganda.‖ Prepared for FinMark Trust. Manroth, Astrid. ―Uganda CEM: Making Fiscal Space for Infrastructure.‖ Steadman Group. 2007. ―Finscope–Financial Access Survey.‖ Prepared for DFID, Financial Sector Deepening Uganda. August. Uganda Banker‘s Association. 2008. ―The Land (Amendment) Bill 2007: Potential Collateral Damage for Banks.‖ Uganda Banker‘s Association. 2008. ―The Mortgage Bill 2007: Proposals for Amendments.‖ World Bank. 2005. ―A Simulation Analysis of the Public Service Pension System in Uganda.‖ Washington D.C. June. 90 World Bank. 2007. ―Moving beyond Recovery: Investment and Behavior Change for Growth.‖ Country (Uganda) Economic Memorandum, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Unit, Washington D.C. 91 Annex B. Banking Sector Efficiency B-1. In this section, we begin by offering a simple decomposition of Ugandan banks‘ interest spreads to better understand the factors driving their persistently high levels (see figure 2.7 in the text). In the decomposition exercise, we follow the method used in Beck and Fuchs (2004), subtracting the interest rate paid for deposits from the ex ante interest rates charged on loans. We have unusually high- quality data on the ex ante interest rates charged for loans—by duration, recipient sector, and currency—that enable us to calculate a weighted average interest rate charged by each bank in each quarter. The spreads in figure 1 and table 1 are a weighted average for the banking sector as a whole (rather than a simple average across banks).53 B-2. Banks charge higher interest rates to riskier borrowers in anticipation of defaults, and so we therefore account for loan loss provisions in the decomposition. We also account for overhead costs, taxes, and required reserves, all factors that contribute to higher spreads. The overhead costs are those attributable to loans, which we identify by calculating the share of loan interest revenue in total revenue. Profit margin is a residual after adjusting for loan loss provisions, the tax rate, reserve requirements, and overheads.54 Table B.1: Decomposition of Weighted Average Spread, All Banks 2005 2006 2007 2008 Q4 Q4 Q4 Q2 Average Lending Rate 14.66 15.17 15.31 16.72 Average Deposit Rate 1.57 1.70 2.00 1.97 Spread 13.09 13.48 13.31 14.75 Overhead Costs 4.77 4.09 3.47 4.66 Loan-loss Provisions 1.17 0.74 1.67 0.72 Reserve Requirement 0.17 0.19 0.22 0.22 53 For each quarter, we first calculated the total value of loans (similarly for deposits) at a given interest rate across all banks. We then applied the appropriate interest rates to those values and summed across all interest rates. We then divided that figure by the total value of loans (or deposits). 54 The formula we use is: Profit margin = (1-tax rate) x (weighted average lending rate – weighted average deposit rate/(1 – Reserve Requirement) – operating costs/loans – loan loss provisions/loans) The tax rate is calculated from actual tax payments. The reserve requirement is 10 percent. Operating costs are those attributable to lending, and thus are equal to the share of income from lending multiplied by total costs. 92 Taxes 2.01 1.85 1.51 2.51 Profit Margin 4.97 6.61 6.44 6.65 B-3. While table 1 indicates a reduction in overhead costs from 2005 to 2007, that figure increased in 2008. The most recent figures are for the second quarter of 2008, rather than the end of the year, so they could be less accurate. However, the quarterly decompositions in figure 1 also show no strong tendency for overheads to decline. Similarly, the portion of the interest spreads ascribed to taxes, reserve requirements, and loan loss provisions remained more or less stable throughout the period. The end result was a stable interest rate spread in the neighborhood of 14 percent. Profit margins, the residual factor in our decomposition exercise, hovered from 5 percent to 6.5 percent. If anything, they were larger at the end of the period than at the beginning. In all, the decompositions point to a lack of competitive pressure in the Ugandan banking sector. Figure B.1: Decomposition of Weighted Average Spread, All Banks B-4. There are also indications that the banking sector is segmented so that domestic and foreign banks do not tend to compete with each other. Table B.2 shows the decomposition of the interest spreads of domestic banks. Their overhead costs are actually lower than for the sector as a whole, as are their loan 93 loss provisions, suggesting that domestic banks focus on a creditworthy market segment and can do so at relatively low cost. Table B.2: Decomposition of Weighted Average Spread, Domestic Banks 2005 2006 2007 2008 Q4 Q4 Q4 Q2 Average Lending Rate 17.97 17.07 19.15 18.44 Average Deposit Rate 2.19 2.30 2.37 2.31 Spread 15.77 14.77 16.78 16.13 Overhead Costs 3.02 2.30 2.52 2.74 Loan-loss Provisions 0.95 0.39 0.49 0.38 Reserve Requirement 0.24 0.26 0.26 0.26 Taxes 2.96 1.98 1.50 3.34 Profit Margin 8.60 9.84 12.01 9.42 B-5. And yet table 2 also shows that customers of the domestic banks pay substantially higher interest rates on their loans (17-19 percent) than do customers in the rest of the banking sector, while domestic banks pay only slightly more for their deposits than the rest of the sector. Together, these factors produce much higher interest spreads for the domestic banks than for the foreign banks. Both table 2 and figure 2 indicate that the largest component of the domestic banks‘ interest spreads is their profit margins (around 10 percent), and figure 2 makes it clear that those margins have not declined. Spreads therefore remained stubbornly high (near 16 percent) throughout the period. Figure B.2: Decomposition of Weighted Average Spread, Domestic Banks 94 B-6. The spread decompositions therefore indicate that domestic banks generate high profit margins from a group of borrowers that repay their loans at a high rate. One would expect foreign banks to compete for this clientele, exerting downward pressure on those spreads and profit margins, and yet the decomposition of the interest spreads of foreign banks in table B.3 suggests that they deal with a different segment of the market. Foreign banks‘ overhead costs are substantially higher than those of the domestic banks (6 percent versus 2.5 percent), and yet their spreads are much lower. This is true despite the facts that loan loss provisions are slightly higher for foreign banks and the rate that they pay for deposits is somewhat lower than domestic banks, both factors which should contribute to relatively higher spreads. The relatively low interest spreads of the foreign banks can therefore only be achieved by having smaller profit margins, and theirs are well less than half of those of the domestic banks. Table B.3: Decomposition of Weighted Average Spread, Foreign Banks 2005 2006 2007 2008 Q4 Q4 Q4 Q2 Average Lending Rate 12.31 13.38 12.93 15.24 Average Deposit Rate 1.47 1.60 1.93 1.90 Spread 10.84 11.78 11.00 13.34 Overhead Costs 6.04 5.81 4.08 6.22 Loan-loss Provisions 1.33 1.08 2.40 1.01 Reserve Requirement 0.16 0.18 0.21 0.21 95 Taxes 0.96 1.07 0.92 1.64 Profit Margin 2.34 3.64 3.39 4.26 B-7. Table B.3 and figure B.3 show little difference in the spreads of the foreign banks and their determinants over the period. Figure B.3 indicates that there were some subperiods in which overheads appeared to be declining, but all of them were eventually met with a sizable increase. There is also no strong pattern with regard to profit margins, and interest spreads remained around 12-13 percent throughout the period. This persistence is further evidence consistent with market segmentation between foreign and domestic banks. B-8. The relatively high overhead costs and low profit margins for the foreign banks could be consistent with the idea that they deal with a set of ―blue-chip‖ clients whose projects are more costly to evaluate and maintain. Relative to that limited client pool, there appear to be enough competing foreign banks to produce low spreads. However, it is also possible that there are different types of foreign banks pursuing different strategies with differing levels of success. Recent research suggests that foreign banks tend to perform better compared to domestic banks when coming from a high-income country, but worse when coming from a developing country (Claessens and Van Horen 2009). Since the foreign banks in Uganda come from both developed and developing countries, this factor could be relevant. Moreover, some of the foreign banks from developing countries are actually partially state-owned banks, such as KCB Uganda, which is an offshoot of Kenya Commercial Bank. That is, these are state-owned banks that have set up operations outside their national borders.55 It seems likely that the banks from developed countries could be pursuing the blue-chip strategy described above, while those from developing countries might be engaged in different activities. High overheads and loan loss ratios for that second group might reflect inefficiency and relatively poor credit allocation. Figure B.3: Decomposition of Weighted Average Spread, Foreign Banks 55 In addition to KCB, this category includes Banque du Caire of Egypt and Tropical Bank of Libya. 96 B-9. Two tentative conclusions from the simple decomposition exercise are that there is (i) little competitive pressure in the Ugandan banking sector, as reflected in the persistence of high interest spreads and their determinants, and (ii) market segmentation between the foreign and domestic banks, as reflected in different spread levels and determinants of those spreads. In the next section, we build regression models to test these ideas more formally, and to explore whether the differences between foreign and domestic banks can be explained by the types of activities that they pursue. Spread Regressions B-10. The regression model is based on that in Martinez Peria and Mody (2004) for developing countries in Latin America and in Beck and Hesse (2009) for Uganda:56 56 That model is motivated by the dealership model of banks spreads developed in Ho and Saunders (1981), in which banks are risk-averse dealers trying to balance loan and deposit markets. Because loan requests and deposit flows can be asynchronous, spreads are seen as fees charged by banks for the provision of liquidity under uncertainty. See Martinez Peria and Mody (2004) for further description of the model and extensions by other authors. 97 Spread it  �  � 1 overheadsit  � 2 liquidity it  � 3 equity it  � 4 provisionsit  � 5 market shareit � 6 int erest income it  � 7 loan shareit  � 8 Herfindahl t  � 9 T bill ratet  � 10 inf lation t  � 11industrial production t  � 12 Foreign it  � it (1) —where the interest spread is calculated as described above for bank i at time t. Overheads are the ratio of overhead costs to total assets. As in the simple decomposition, we expect that higher overheads costs are passed on to borrowers in the form of higher spreads. Liquidity is the ratio of liquid assets (cash and deposits with other banks) to deposits. In the Latin American context, high liquidity was thought to inflict a cost on banks, since a bank must forego the opportunity to hold a higher-yielding instrument. Thus, Martinez Peria and Mody (2004) hypothesize that banks will try to transfer this cost to borrowers, resulting in a positive association between liquidity and spreads. Similarly, those authors hypothesize that there is an opportunity cost associated with holding excessive capital, and thus they expect a positive relation between equity (bank capital plus reserves, over total assets) and spreads. B-11. Provisions are the ratio of loan loss provisions to total loans, our measure of portfolio quality. As described above, we expect that higher loan provisions reflect riskier borrowers, which raises ex ante interest rates charged on loans, resulting in higher calculated spreads. Market share is the bank‘s share of total banking sector deposits, our measure of bank size. To the extent that larger banks can take advantage of economies of scale, we would expect market share to be negatively related to spreads. This is consistent with some of the regression results in Beck and Hesse (2009) for Uganda from 2000 to 2004. Martinez Peria and Mody (2004) note, however, that market share could also be equated with market power, and thus the ability to charge higher rates on the loans. The coefficient on this variable will therefore indicate which of these two hypotheses is better supported by the data. B-12. We control for bank orientation using interest income, the ratio of total interest income to operating income, and intermediation, the ratio of net loans and advances to total liabilities. Using bank-level data across countries, Laeven and Levine (2005) demonstrate that specialized loan-making banks have different performance characteristics than specialized investment banks, and that loan- making banks tend to have a higher share of interest income. We expect competitive pressure in the lending market to be better reflected in the banks specialized in that area, and thus we expect a negative association between interest income and spreads. Similarly, we expect those banks that lend a relatively high share of their available liabilities to be most responsive to the same 98 competitive pressures, and thus a negative relation between intermediation and spreads. B-13. Following the literature, in some specifications we include a control for banking sector structure and three macroeconomic control variables. Herfindahl is a standard index of sector concentration, which we calculated based on bank shares of total deposits.57 If deposits are concentrated in the hands of a few banks, those banks might be able to drive up lending rates, as they control the supply of funds. We would therefore expect a positive relation between concentration and spreads. The macroeconomic controls are the T-bill rate, inflation, and industrial production. The T-bill rate is the rate of interest on short- term treasury bills, which is included as a proxy for the marginal cost of funds faced by banks. Inflation is included because price shocks might not be passed through equally to the nominal lending and borrowing rates, and thus these differential effects would be reflected in the spread. Industrial production is an index measuring the change in industrial production, which is included to capture business cycle effects that are reflected in spreads. As an economy slumps and production slows, borrowers become less creditworthy, and thus banks must charge higher lending rates, which are then reflected in higher spreads (all else equal). B-14. Finally, Foreign is a dummy variable equal to 1 if a bank is owned by foreign interests. The coefficient on this variable therefore is intended to capture any differences in spreads between foreign and domestic banks that are not accounted for by the other explanatory variables. Summary statistics and correlations for all of the variables in the regression analysis are presented in table B.4. 57 The index is calculated by summing the squared market shares of all banks. 99 Table B.4: Summary Statistics, Correlations Descriptive Correlations Statistics Loa Ind Herf Variable Stand n- Mar Inte Inte Real ex M Ove Liq in- Infl ard Spre Equ loss ket rest rme Fore T- of ea rhea uidit dahl atio Devi ad ity prov shar inco diati ign bills ind n d y inde n ation isio e me on rate pro x n d 0. Spread 0.05 1.00 15 0.36 0. Overheads 0.01 4** 1.00 02 * - 0. 0.07 Liquidity 0.27 0.32 1.00 54 5 *** 0.35 0. 0.23 0.16 Equity 0.08 3** 1.00 14 4** 3* * - Loan-loss 0. 0.15 0.08 0.13 0.03 0.09 1.00 provisions 02 1* 7 2 6 - - - - - 0. Market share 0.08 0.26 0.08 0.16 0.50 0.03 1.00 07 *** 9 0* *** 5 - - - - Interest 0. 0.03 0.05 1.00 0.11 0.01 0.67 0.22 0.12 income 73 7 7 00 4 *** 2** 0 - - Intermediati 0. 0.11 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.09 0.17 0.38 0.12 1.00 on 45 4 5 2 5 51 *** 9 - - - - - - 0. 0.15 0.20 Foreign 0.45 0.19 0.06 0.38 0.00 0.21 0.21 1.00 72 4* 2** 3** 5 *** 5 1** 5** - - - Herfindahl 0. 0.03 0.01 0.11 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.004 0.06 0.02 0.13 1.00 index 16 3 1 2 9 0 2 7 33 0 - - - 0.33 Real T-bills 0. 0.11 0.00 0.03 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.05 0.03 0.01 5** 1.00 rate 06 1 9 1 1 13 6 5 3 9 * - - - - - - - - 0. 0.05 0.05 0.04 Inflation 0.02 0.09 0.03 0.03 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.41 0.95 1.00 02 3 1 8 1 7 8 5 8 5 *** *** Index of 13 - - - - - - 0.05 0.07 0.01 0.11 0.07 0.22 1.0 industrial 6. 8.95 0.05 0.01 0.11 0.01 0.25 0.13 1 3 7 0 9 7** 0 prod 2 5 2 73 9 *** 9 ***, **, * denotes significance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent levels, respectively. Regression Results B-15. The base results appear in table B.5. All models are estimated via OLS, and models 2 and 4 include bank-specific fixed effects.58 In those models, the estimated coefficients therefore reflect departures from each bank‘s average spread for the period. The models also include year and quarter dummies to capture trends and shocks that affected all banks. The insignificant coefficients on 58 As described in the tables, in our models standard errors are clustered at the bank level. 100 the year dummies tell a story consistent with the decompositions: interest spreads remained more or less at the same level over the period. B-16. The simplest OLS specification (column 1) confirms a number of the hypotheses described above. There is a strong positive relationship between overhead costs and interest spreads, as there was in Beck and Hesse (2009) for the period from 2000 to 2004. The equity ratio is positively associated with spreads, as was true in Martinez Peria and Mody (2004) for Latin America. Banks‘ market shares, interest income ratios, and intermediation ratios are all negative, as hypothesized, but only the intermediation ratio is significant. B-17. There are also some results that do not confirm our hypotheses. First, the liquidity ratio, which we hypothesized as representing an opportunity cost to banks, does not have the anticipated positive coefficient, but rather a negative and significant one. We interpret this as a sign that the banks that were best able to attract deposits during this period, and thus were flush with liquidity, were also the ones that tended to charge lower spreads. Second, loan loss provisions are not significantly linked to interest spreads, though the decompositions revealed that these were low and uniform across banks, and so it is little surprise that they do not explain significant variation in our regressions. Finally, the coefficient on the foreign ownership dummy variable is insignificant, suggesting that the other factors that we control for in the regressions explain the lower levels of spreads for foreign banks summarized in the decomposition exercise. B-18. In the simplest regression that includes bank fixed effects (column 2), most of the bank-level variables that were significant in the simple OLS regression (overheads, liquidity, and equity) are insignificant, and loan loss provisions remain insignificant. Since coefficients from that model summarize the effect on spreads of departures from bank-specific means on those variables, the lack of significance is consistent with the stagnation suggested by the decompositions. By contrast, the overhead cost ratio was positive and significant in the fixed effects regressions in Beck and Hesse (2009) for the period 2000 to 2004, indicating that reductions in overheads during that period were associated with declines in spreads. B-19. There are, however, some variables in the fixed effects regression that are significant. Among the bank-level variables, the ratios of interest income and intermediation are significant and negative, suggesting that those banks that 101 increased their lending activities during this period reduced their interest spreads. At the same time, the market-share variable is positive and significant, indicating that the banks that were growing most rapidly were increasing their interest spreads. Table B.5: Base Regressions OLS Fixed effects OLS Fixed effects (1) (2) (3) (4) Overheads 4.8711*** 0.4375 3.7402*** 0.8707 (0.7824) (1.2941) (0.951) (1.2454) Equity 0.2632*** -0.0233 0.1459*** -0.0149 (0.0444) (0.0906) (0.0476) (0.0926) Liquidity -0.0831** 0.0026 -0.0541** 0.0019 (0.0305) (0.0093) (0.0256) (0.0097) Loan-loss provisions 0.0013 -0.0861 -0.0456 -0.0757 (0.0715) (0.0656) (0.0532) (0.0658) Market share -0.0440 0.4368*** -0.0439 0.2684* (0.0558) (0.1521) (0.067) (0.1426) Interest income -0.0045 -0.1397*** 0.0137 -0.1476*** (0.0452) (0.0481) (0.038) (0.049) Intermediation -0.0975*** -0.0676** -0.0923*** -0.0595* (0.0245) (0.0326) (0.0284) (0.0314) Foreign 0.0127 0.0074 (0.008) (0.0118) Herfindahl index 0.0107 -0.3223 -0.1500 -0.3122 (0.8084) (0.6147) (0.9043) (0.6379) Real T-bills rate -0.1584 0.2622 -0.1969 0.1093 (0.5324) (0.3986) (0.4986) (0.3911) Inflation -0.3082 0.1608 -0.3023 0.0679 (0.5586) (0.4072) (0.5466) (0.3989) Index of industrial production -0.0011 -0.0010 0.0000 -0.0006 (0.0019) (0.0015) (0.0019) (0.0014) year==2006 -0.0149 0.0050 -0.0172 -0.0009 (0.0174) (0.0089) (0.0133) (0.0085) year==2007 0.0139 0.0223 -0.0045 0.0117 (0.0419) (0.0294) (0.0384) (0.0268) year==2008 0.0126 0.0167 -0.0194 0.0005 (0.0558) (0.0353) (0.0514) (0.0325) Portfolio share (govt) 0.6858 0.2531 (0.5056) (0.4467) Portfolio share (agric) 0.1468* 0.0109 (0.0744) (0.0417) Portfolio share (manuf) 0.1379** 0.0454 (0.0584) (0.0378) Portfolio share (trade) 0.1962*** 0.0712* (0.0508) (0.0361) Portfolio share (transport) 0.0926* 0.0262 102 (0.052) (0.034) Portfolio share (building and construction) 0.2270*** 0.1057** (0.0554) (0.0439) Portfolio share (other) 0.2100*** 0.0840** (0.0436) (0.0379) Constant 0.3273 0.4221* 0.0307 0.3314 (0.2464) (0.2213) (0.2622) (0.2195) Observations 178 178 178 178 Number of banks 18 18 18 18 Adjusted R2 0.4418 0.7858 0.5718 0.8067 ***, **, * denotes significance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent levels, respectively. Reported in the parentheses are p-values computed using standard errors clustered at the bank level. B-20. When we include variables summarizing the composition of banks‘ loan portfolios (models 3 and 4), results are similar to the base results, though some of the significant coefficients are a bit smaller. In both the OLS and the bank fixed effects regressions, the coefficients for construction and building, trade, and a catch-all category called ‗other‘ lending, are positive and significant. The OLS results indicate that the spread levels in those sectors tend to be higher than in others, while the fixed effects regressions indicate that banks that increased their lending shares to those sectors during this period also tended to have higher spreads. Since these regressions already control for bank-level and macroeconomic fundamentals, and many of those variables remain significant when we control for portfolio shares, the fixed effects results suggest a true change in activities. At the same time, the positive coefficients for those sectors are consistent with some banks lending to new borrowers at higher interest rates, rather than lowering rates for the existing pool of borrowers. B-21. When we allow the determinants of spreads to vary by ownership type, most of the coefficients for the foreign banks are insignificant, indicating that similar factors play a role in pricing loans for both types of banks. For example, overheads are significantly associated with higher spreads for both foreign and domestic banks.59 But there are also some revealing differences that speak to the market segmentation described above. First, the foreign ownership dummy variable is now negative, in line with the decompositions described above, though admittedly the coefficient does not achieve significance. More importantly, the market share variable is positive and highly significant, indicating that the largest domestic banks charge the highest spreads (column 1). The effects are economically large: an increase in market share by 10 percent is associated with a 6 percentage point jump in the spreads of domestic banks. 59 More precisely, the insignificant coefficient on foreign*overheads means that we cannot reject the hypothesis that the positive relationship between overheads and spreads holds for both foreign and domestic banks. 103 B-22. By contrast, the coefficient for market share is negative and highly significant when multiplied by the foreign ownership dummy. This coefficient needs to be evaluated jointly with the one for the simple market share variable. Those two coefficients are of opposite signs, and the one for foreign banks is larger (in absolute value). When summed, the coefficients are negative and significant (at the ten percent level), indicating that there is a negative relationship between market share and interest spreads for foreign banks. The results are consistent with the idea that the domestic banks with the largest market shares have the highest interest spreads. Below, we explore whether the activities of those banks are markedly different from foreign banks and other domestic banks. 104 Table B.6: Determinants of Interest Spreads, by Ownership Type OLS Fixed effects (1) (2) Overheads 3.5118*** -0.4623 (0.3903) (1.1028) Equity 0.2547*** 0.0946 (0.0442) (0.1603) Liquidity -0.0042 -0.0009 (0.0081) (0.0101) Loan-loss provisions -0.0046 0.0044 (0.0276) (0.0334) Market share 0.5693*** 0.9842* (0.1174) (0.5239) Interest income -0.0710 -0.0523 (0.1064) (0.0662) Intermediation -0.0804*** 0.0517 (0.026) (0.053) Foreign -0.2621 (0.2197) Herfindahl index -0.6737 -0.4209 (0.6806) (0.6338) Real T-bills rate -0.6976 -0.7295* (0.4465) (0.4229) Inflation -0.8365* -0.9130** (0.4483) (0.4546) Index of industrial production -0.0006 -0.0012 (0.0018) (0.0015) Foreign * Overheads -1.3312 1.7360 (2.3131) (2.0264) Foreign * Equity -0.1624* -0.1675 (0.0928) (0.1486) Foreign * Liquidity -0.0882*** -0.0148 (0.0296) (0.0211) Foreign * Loan-loss provisions -0.0294 -0.2728* (0.1608) (0.1617) Foreign * Market share -0.6743*** -0.6985 (0.1597) (0.5612) Foreign * Interest income 0.0437 -0.1291 (0.1181) (0.084) Foreign * Intermediation -0.0225 -0.1283** (0.0575) (0.0602) Foreign * Herfindahl index 0.7513 -0.0253 (1.1217) (0.7895) Foreign * Real T-bills rate 0.8311 0.9805** (0.5251) (0.4896) Foreign * Inflation 0.9066 1.1272* (0.6328) (0.6065) Foreign * Index of industrial production 0.0013*** 0.0010** (0.0004) (0.0004) Portfolio Shares Included? YES YES Year Dummies Included? YES YES Quarter Dummies Included? YES YES Constant 0.2870 0.3422 (0.2409) (0.2278) Observations 178 178 Number of banks 18 18 Adjusted R2 0.6176 0.8163 105 ***, **, * denotes significance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent levels, respectively. Reported in the parentheses are p-values computed using standard errors clustered at the bank level. B-23. The models with ownership interactions also reveal which banks were responsible for the significant relationships in the base regressions. For example, equity was positively associated with spreads in the base regressions. In table B.6, column 1, the simple equity variable is positive and significant, while the interaction with foreign ownership is negative and significant.60 The pattern indicates that domestic banks are responsible for the positive relationship in the base regression. By contrast, the interaction term is negative and highly significant for liquidity, while the simple liquidity variable is insignificant. And so, it was the foreign banks that were flush with liquidity that had lower interest spreads. Finally, the intermediation ratio is significantly negatively associated with spreads for both ownership types—all banks that lent a higher share of their deposits tended to charge lower spreads.61 B-24. The fixed effects regression (column 2) also shows that many of the results in the base regressions were driven by domestic or foreign banks, but rarely by both. For example, the negative relationship between spreads and intermediation ratios is driven by the foreign banks. The same is also true for the ratio of interest income.62 These results suggest that competitive pressures were more pronounced in the lending markets in which foreign banks participated. By contrast, as in the OLS model, the relationship between changes in market share and increased spreads holds for domestic banks but not for foreign ones. B-25. As a final empirical exercise, we divide the foreign-owned banks into three categories—those with owners from industrialized countries, those with private owners from developing countries, and those owned by governments of developing countries—and re-run the models in table B.6 with interaction terms for each of the three categories. Rather than present the full specification, we present the effect of each variable on the spreads of each bank ownership type. What appears in table B.7 is the coefficient for each variable for each ownership category and a test of whether the coefficient is different from zero. P-values appear in parentheses below the coefficients. 60 We cannot therefore reject the hypothesis that there is no relationship between equity and spreads for foreign banks. 61 The simple intermediation coefficient is negative and significant, while the coefficient for intermediation*foreign is insignificant. Thus, we cannot reject the hypothesis that the relationship is the same for both bank types. 62 This is harder to see from table B.6. The simple interest income variable and its interaction with foreign ownership are negative, but neither is significant. However, when we sum those coefficients, the result is significantly less than zero, indicating that a negative relation holds for foreign banks. 106 B-26. These results enable us to further pinpoint the type of banks that are responsible for the significant relationships in our base regressions. In panel A, which summarizes the results from the OLS model, the positive relationship between overhead costs and interest spreads is much stronger for foreign banks from industrialized countries than for the other bank groups. This could reflect the importance of recovering the substantial costs associated with serving a relatively ―blue-chip‖ clientele. Table B.7: Determinants of Interest Spreads, by Bank Ownership Type Panel A. OLS Foreign, Developing Country Private Foreign State- Domestic Industrialized Private Owned Overheads 3.7014*** 6.7777*** 1.4316 -13.2690*** (0.3900) [0.0006] [0.5364] [0.0000] Equity 0.2676*** -0.1288 -0.3673 -0.0950 (0.0535) [0.3218] [0.2054] [0.4036] Liquidity -0.0005 -0.0222 -0.0689*** -0.0676* (0.0063) [0.1613] [0.0089] [0.0998] Loan-loss provisions -0.0033 -0.3970*** 0.3305 0.9813** (0.0254) [0.0000] [0.1254] [0.0314] Market share 0.5879*** -0.1587*** -0.2637*** -0.6347 (0.0700) [0.0006] [0.0061] [0.7803] Interest income -0.0795 -0.0841 -0.0359 -0.0327 (0.1180) [0.2028] [0.6548] [0.6402] Intermediation -0.0941*** -0.0229 -0.2468*** 0.1827*** (0.0318) [0.2814] [0.0007] [0.0073] Herfindahl index -0.6673 -1.0202 0.3822 -1.0552 (0.6924) [0.3661] [0.7145] [0.4538] Real T-bills rate -0.9866** -0.3054 0.2544 -0.6675 (0.4363) [0.6685] [0.6898] [0.3747] Inflation -1.0255** -0.2922 0.6258 -1.0210 (0.4279) [0.7095] [0.4591] [0.2835] Index of industrial production -0.0022 -0.0009 -0.0007 -0.0013 (0.0018) [0.6117] [0.6951] [0.3889] Panel B. Fixed Effects Foreign, Developing Country Private Foreign State- Domestic Industrialized Private Owned Overheads -0.1001 2.4436 4.6166 -6.6224 (1.1684) [0.3053] [0.1753] [0.1945] Equity 0.1482 -0.0712 -0.1719 -0.1632 (0.1641) [0.6630] [0.6175] [0.3238] Liquidity 0.0014 0.0018 -0.0078 -0.0627* (0.0116) [0.9237] [0.8444] [0.0732] Loan-loss provisions 0.0128 -0.4813*** 0.3344 0.5108 (0.0379) [0.0061] [0.2367] [0.5121] Market share 0.8655 0.4946** -0.5905 -7.6979* (0.6065) [0.0282] [0.2039] [0.0635] Interest income -0.0379 -0.0363 -0.1897** -0.1616 (0.0784) [0.6430] [0.0331] [0.2427] Intermediation 0.0266 -0.0465 -0.1947* 0.1007 (0.0584) [0.4075] [0.0814] [0.2578] 107 Herfindahl index -0.3291 -0.7268 0.2539 -1.3492 (0.6782) [0.4043] [0.7952] [0.3687] Real T-bills rate -0.7649 -0.2405 0.4115 -0.7570 (0.5072) [0.7010] [0.4771] [0.4675] Inflation -0.9297* -0.2788 0.7173 -1.0470 (0.5329) [0.6932] [0.2958] [0.3641] Index of industrial production -0.0014 0.0002 -0.0004 0.0002 (0.0018) [0.9175] [0.8282] [0.9224] B-27. As was clear from the regression in table B.6, private domestic banks were responsible for the positive relationships with spreads for the equity and market share variables. In table B.7, we see that the equity variable is negative and insignificant for all three types of foreign-owned banks. In stark contrast to the private domestically owned banks, privately owned foreign banks from both developed and developing countries show a negative and significant relationship between market share and interest spreads. The negative relationship between liquidity and spreads is driven by foreign banks from developing countries, especially those privately owned. Finally, the negative relationship between the intermediation ratio and spreads is also driven primarily by the privately owned foreign banks from developing countries, though there is also a significant (though much less pronounced) relationship for private domestic banks. B-28. In all, the results from the OLS regression summarized in table B.7, panel A, indicate that privately owned foreign banks from developing countries are responsible for increased intermediation and lower interest spreads. In contrast, the foreign-owned banks from industrialized countries seem to operate in a market niche where cost considerations are much more important in setting spreads. The results from the regression with bank fixed effects (panel B) further support this impression. The interest income and intermediation ratios are negative and significant only for private foreign banks from developing countries, indicating that those that were increasing their lending were also reducing their spreads during this period. For foreign banks from developed countries, we find no significant relationships for the lending variables, and in fact, the market share variable is positive and significant, indicating that foreign banks from developed countries that were increasing their market share during this period were also ratcheting up spreads. Given the other indications that these banks operate in a very specific market niche, the results could be seen as troubling for that group of clients. Table B.8 Market presence and lending activities of banks under different types of ownership. Foreign, Developing Countries Domestic Foreign Private State 108 Industrialized 2005q3 2008q2 2005q3 2008q2 2005q3 2008q2 2005q3 2008q2 Total loans, millions (sum) 232 529 197 399 58 178 12 33 Market share (sum) 0.15 0.20 0.43 0.41 0.39 0.35 0.02 0.03 Interest income (mean) 0.74 0.79 0.78 0.68 0.70 0.78 0.71 0.72 Intermediation (mean) 0.44 0.64 0.41 0.46 0.40 0.40 0.34 0.40 Portfolio shares (weighted sum) - government 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 - agriculture 0.25 0.11 0.10 0.04 0.23 0.07 0.03 0.06 - mines 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 - manufacturing 0.11 0.05 0.19 0.26 0.19 0.20 0.04 0.06 - trade 0.19 0.24 0.07 0.12 0.22 0.20 0.34 0.18 - transportation 0.06 0.03 0.17 0.10 0.15 0.03 0.00 0.05 - building 0.03 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.04 0.03 0.05 0.11 - other 0.36 0.51 0.41 0.44 0.16 0.47 0.53 0.55 Source: Bank of Uganda: World Bank Analysis B-29. To put our results in context, table B.8 provides information on market presence and lending activities of banks under different types of ownership. Private foreign banks from developing countries have been losing market share to private domestic banks and foreign banks owned by governments of developing countries. The market share of foreign banks from developed countries has remained more or less the same. While the private foreign banks from developing countries have increased their interest income ratio, private domestic banks have seen a similar increase in their interest income ratio and a large jump in their intermediation ratio. Unfortunately, the regressions indicate that the jumps were not associated with reduced interest spreads for private domestic banks. B-30. It is also revealing that the private domestic banks have seen large increases in the share of their loan portfolios devoted to trade, building and construction, and ‗other‘ lending. To a lesser extent the same is true of the state- owned banks from other developing countries.63 Recall from the base results that these were the three categories where increased lending was associated with higher spreads. These spreads might be sufficient to counter the risks, but it is difficult to know at the current point. Finally, the private foreign banks from developed countries have increased their shares of lending to traditional sectors such as manufacturing and trade, yet further indication that they are concentrating on a narrow market segment. B-31. At first blush, our results on the relative dynamism of private foreign banks from developing countries would seem to be at odds with the cross-country 63 Again, these are KCB, Banque du Caire, and Tropical. 109 results in Claessens and Van Horen (2009), who find that performance tends to be better for foreign banks from developed countries. We should emphasize that those authors define performance more broadly to include measures of profitability and they consider issues related to stability. Here we confine ourselves to a study of efficiency as measured by spreads. It could be that the foreign banks from developing countries do contribute to lower spreads, but that this comes at a cost in terms of their profitability and, ultimately, the stability of the banking sector. However, the analysis in the text suggests that a lack of stability is a much less serious concern than lack of banking sector growth in Uganda. Also, the CVH (2009) analysis is based on cross-country regressions that summarize average relationships that might not reflect the situation in all countries. In particular, the colonial roots of foreign banks in many African countries, including Uganda, might have produced a group of banks from industrialized countries that are narrowly focused on only a subset of potential borrowers. At the very least, our results point out that the private banks from developing countries are taking a different approach in Uganda than are the others. 110 References Beck, Thorsten and Heiko Hesse. 2009. ―Why Are Interest Spreads So High in Uganda?‖ Journal of Development Economics, 88(2): 192-204. Beck, Thorsten and Michael Fuchs. ―Structural Issues in the Kenyan Financial System: Improving Competition and Access.‖ World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3363, July 2004. Claessens, Stijn and Neeltje Van Horen. 2009. ―Being a Foreigner among Domestic Banks: Asset or Liability?‖ IMF mimeo. Ho, Thomas and Anthony Saunders. 1981. ―The Determinants of Bank Interest Margins: Theory and Empirical Evidence.‖ Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 4: 581-600. Laeven, Luc and Ross Levine 2005. ―Is There a Diversification Discount in Financial Conglomerates?‖ Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming. Martinez Peria, Maria Soledad and Ashoka Mody. 2004. ―How Foreign Participation and Market Concentration Impact Bank Spreads: Evidence from Latin America.‖ Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 36(3): 511-537. 111 Annex C: Overview of Water Sector Infrastructure C-1. The Ministry of Water and Environment (MWE) is the ministry in charge of water services in Uganda. Its primary responsibility is for policy setting and developing regulatory frameworks for the sector. Rural,64 small towns, and urban water are treated separately with different implementation modalities, technology options used for service delivery, and levels of financial sustainability. C-2. The Directorate of Water Development (DWD) within the MWE is responsible for providing technical oversight for all water services development. It provides support in the form of standards development and capacity building for local governments, which are the implementing agencies for rural water supply services.65 Given the small scale and high level of grant finance in this subsector, commercial financing opportunities for rural water projects are not analyzed here. C-3. The National Water and Sewerage Corporation (NWSC) is responsible for providing ‗urban‘ water. It serves 23 towns and almost 2 million people through about 200,000 connections. NWSC of Uganda was created in 1972 by decree. The NWSC Act Chapter 317 of 1995 further clarifies the roles and responsibilities of NWSC as a body corporate. NWSC Financial Performance C-4. NWSC has demonstrated considerable improvements in financial performance over the past 10 years. Gross turnover has increased from UGS 22 billion (USD 13 million) to UGS 79 billion (USD 47 million) since 1998. Key financial indicators for the past three years are shown below. Turnover continues to increase, driven primarily by increasing the number of connections. There continues to be a large service backlog (coverage is 71 percent of the urban population) and rapid urban growth rate (projected to be over 5 percent until 2030)66 in NWSC‘s service area. If capital investment persists, the observed growth in turnover will be maintained for the foreseeable future. 64 A number of different infrastructure options are developed by local governments for the rural population. While most of the infrastructure is in the form of point sources (springs, wells, boreholes, and so on), local governments also support the construction of piped water systems (both gravity and pumped) in the country‘s rural growth centers. NGOs also construct rural water supplies that are coordinated by the Ugandan Water and Sanitation Network, their umbrella organization. 65 A variety of institutional models are being used for water supply provision in the small towns sector . Modalities tend to be project based. GoU/donor projects provide funds and implementation units to develop the systems for small towns. Systems generally include water treatment, reticulation, and both individual household and shared connections. There are 160 small towns in the country;113 have piped water systems. Coverage is relatively low at 46 percent. Performance varies considerably in this subsector. In all, 69 small towns are monitored by the MWE. Unaccounted for water is on average 26 percent of production and revenue collection efficiency is at 85 percent. Management contracts with private sector operators are used to encourage operational efficiency and recent renegotiations of these contracts has increased performance incentives by linking remuneration of the contractors with revenues levels they manage to collect. 66 UN Population Division estimate at globalis.gvu.unu.edu/. [[provide full URL]] 112 C-5. Over the past 10 years NWSC has achieved a number of significant operational improvements. It is now one of the best performing water utilities in Africa and its newly created External Services department provides considerable advisory inputs to utilities in the region. The corporation has reduced nonrevenue water in its system from over 50 percent to 32 percent. The number of customers has increased to 200,000 from less than 100,000. Staff per thousand connections has reduced from 35 to 7. The corporation has also been ISO 9001 certified. Current water access in large towns stands at 72 percent of the total population. Figure C.1: Water Sector Schematic Water sector map Creation of national policies & Managing, monitoring & regulation of water resources by standards issuing water use, abstraction & waste water permits Policy & regulation Ministry of Directorate of Water, & Water Resources Environment Management Monitoring & Water Regulation assessme quality nts Ownership: GoU. Management: GoU Directorate of Implementation at Ownership: GoU. government level Water Management: autonomous body of GoU Development National Water Planning, implemenation, & supervision of & Sewerage delivery of urban, rural & production water in non-NWSC areas Corporation Supplier of water & Rural Urban Water for sewerage services in 23 water water production major towns by private sector Implementation Private operators in 57 small towns C-6. Profitability indicators remain strong despite the increased connectivity (which could otherwise imply an erosion of revenue per connection). Operating margins are high compared to other well-performing utilities in Africa.67 Similarly, NWSC‘s collection performance outperforms its peers, though at 133 days it reflects the traditional 67 Based on a draft creditworthiness review conducted by Global Credit Ratings (South Africa) of NWSC, NCWSC (Kenya), AWSB (Kenya), ONEA (Burkina Faso), SDE (Senegal), SONES (Senegal), SONEDE (Tunisia) commission by the Water and Sanitation Program–Africa. 113 receivable management challenges faced by water utilities in general. Prepayment agreements are in place with government accounts to reduce the likelihood of these contributing to increasing receivables. C-7. The tariff structure used underpins the utility‘s performance. NWSC operates under a tariff regime that is formula-driven and requires parliament to ratify any changes. This provides protection against key cost drivers such as inflation but limits NWSC‘s flexibility. The tariff is designed to cover operational, depreciation, and some capital costs (a summary of NWSC‘s tariff indexation formula is provided in table A1.5). C-8. Over the 1980s and 1990s, a number of concessional loans were on-lent to NWSC. As of June 2006, there was an outstanding principal of UGS 85 billion (USD 50 million) and accrued interest of UGS 68.6 billion (USD 40.4 million). The servicing of this debt had been frozen as per government performance contracts with NWSC in order to allow for cash surpluses to be used to invest in infrastructure. On May 30, 2007 cabinet approved (and parliament subsequently ratified on February 14, 2008) the capitalization of the outstanding debt (both principal and interest) by converting it into equity. NWSC therefore is currently debt free and fully financed by equity. Going forward, the company‘s policy of matching the rate of return of specific investments with the cost of funds used to develop assets will ensure that such an accrual of outstanding debts is avoided. NWSC Capital Expenditure Plans C-9. NWSC‘s capital investment plan focuses on improving existing water infrastructure, especially in Kampala, and on extending services to high growth and unserved areas that have recently been transferred into the corporation‘s portfolio. Targeted investments include system upgrades in Kampala to address infrastructure backlogs (for example, water losses from dilapidated infrastructure) as well as investments to satisfy unmet demand. C-10. The strategy to finance various investments is guided by the investment plan and an internal prioritization process that focuses on the viability of the project as well as its relevance to existing and future customers. The focus is on ensuring that there is a positive net present value for all investments and no erosion in NWSC ‗s profitability. C-11. The source of finance used to fund various investments depends, therefore, on the rate of return anticipated from the project. Where projects will drive returns commensurate with commercial capital costs, commercial finance will be mobilized to fast-track those investments. Such investments will include the rationalization of high cost infrastructure (for example, optimization of bulk water intakes to reduce treatment costs, replacement of old and inefficient electromechanical equipment, and so on) and investments that yield high marginal revenues at a relatively low marginal cost (for example, network infilling where bulk capacity is sufficient). 114 Table C.1.: Key Financial Indicators for the National Water and Sewerage Corporation FY06 FY07 FY08 (unaudited) Core Incomesa (USD million) 33.7 40.1 46.6 Turnover growth 13% 19% 16% Earnings Before Interest, Tax, Depreciation, 8.3 10.7 14.5 and Amortization (EBITDA) (USD million) Net Cash from Operations (USD million)b 10.4 20.0 7.5 Operating profit (%) 7.0% 9.7% 12.9% EBITDA: Revenues 23.9% 26.4% 31.1% EBITDA: Assets 5.1% 5.4% 5.9%c Notes: a- Figures are given in USD (exchange rate of 1,700 UGS: USD). b- FY06 and 07 include value of assets transferred from GOU. c- Assets were revalued upwards in FY08. Table C.2: Summary of NWSC’s Capital Expenditure Plans Estimated Cost Project Name (m Ushs) Mukono Network Densification 14,380 Bushenyi Water supply Project 2,740 Gulu water supply and sewerage project 14,800 Arua water supply and sewerage project 1,861 Sewerage works Kasese, Arua, Bushenyi 12,500 Kampala Network Restructuring and Expansion 78,900 Electrical Mechnaical Equipment 9,300 Gaba III 282 Entebbe Kampala Corridor 4,564 Construction of Kampala Jinja intake inner Bay 20,000 Kampala Sanitation Project 120,714 Kampala Urban Poor Project 1,500 Buloba Water Supply 275 Lugazi Water supply system 2,000 Fort Portal W&S Expansion 2,000 Kasese WSP 2,000 Mbale Rehabilitation and Expansion (Bond) 4,000 Other Projects (other NWSC Towns Expansion) 3,001 NWSC Minor Works+ purchase of Prop&equip 62,413 TOTAL 357,229 C-12. Over the past three years, NWSC‘s capital works have been financed through internally generated resources from cash flow (91 percent), donor grants (7 percent) and government grants (2 percent). NWSC has also relied on donor projects funded outside of their own cash flow. C-13. Given the dearth of concessionary funds from donors or the government budget, and the reliance on internally generated funds to expand the corporation‘s asset base, there has been a strategic review of various leveraging options available to NWSC. 115 Grants and concessional finance are not available in sufficient quantities to impact the corporation‘s service backlog. Financing NWSC Capital Expansion C-14. The financing of capital expansion in the water sector will require considerable resources, as suggested in the preceding section. NWSC will consume a considerable share of these resources and its financial viability, relative to the small towns, makes it a more likely candidate to access term finance. Due to its increasingly good financial performance, from the perspective of cash flow, the utility is in a position to explore commercial debt finance for at least a part of its capital investment plan (where investments are likely to generate sufficient returns to justify the higher cost of capital associated with commercial finance). One key constraint to accessing commercial finance however, was legacy debt on the corporation‘s balance sheet. C-15. In preparing the utility to access commercial finance, considerable levels of grant funds have been made available, primarily by KfW- Kreditanstalt für Wiederaufbau. These funds have been used to extend bulk water intakes further into Lake Victoria, construct a new treatment works (Gaba III), and improve different aspects of network performance. These grants essentially acted to remove some of the infrastructure backlog associated with years of insufficient capital investment (or years where depreciation exceeded capital investment). C-16. A number of financing options present themselves, as discussed below. Direct financing is not an optimal option, given restrictions placed on nonconcessional foreign borrowings associated with the Highly Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) Initiative. Further, the NWSC Act differentiates between local borrowings and those from outside of the country. Due to macroeconomic management and contingent fiscal risk considerations, foreign borrowings require both a ministry of finance approval and also a central government guarantee. This has specific implications for development finance institutions who aim to provide financing at pseudo commercial rates. C-17. The NWSC act discusses the power of the corporation to borrow. These powers are vested in the board of directors and should be in accordance with the responsibilities of NWSC as spelled out in the act. Further borrowings should be along the plans laid out in the three-year corporate plan. The terms and conditions of any borrowings, if locally sourced, are subject to approval (under the act) of the board of directors. C-18. Strategically, in accessing debt markets, NWSC would aim to draw down funds as an when they are needed. This, however, comes at some increased cost and risk compared to borrowing the total quantity of funds required at once. In developed financial markets, where refinancing risk is lower, an infrastructure corporation may use a short-term facility to fund infrastructure development and then use issuances in the capital markets to refinance the construction facility into a longer-term finance facility. In less developed markets (such as Uganda), the refinance risk associated with such strategies probably exceeds the likely benefits. It is probably most appropriate, therefore, 116 for utilities to limit their capital spending to the amount of long-term finance they are able to raise. Bank Financing Options C-19. In financing its capital works, NWSC has two primary sources of commercial finance (in addition to DFI funds, which are able to circumvent rules governing external finance). In evaluating its options, the corporation sought indicative term sheets from local banks. A summary of these terms are presented in table C.3. Table C.3 : Indicative Commercial Bank Terms & Conditions Given to NWSC Effective Interest Interest Fixed/ Rate Upfront Other Frequenc Bank Rate Floating (current) Tenor charges Charges y Collateral Notes Bank Loan 1 14.0% Fixed 14.0% 4 or 7 1.00% GoU guarantee May be able to offer fixed rate finance in early 2007 - Bank Loan 2 2.5% Floating 15.4% 4 or 7 1.70% offer a floating convertible to fixed Bank Loan 3 16.0% Fixed 16.0% 4 or 7 0.75% 0.35% quarterly NWSC assets + LOC from GOU Up to 1 year grace period Bank Loan 4 3.0% Floating 15.9% 4 or 7 0.75% 0.35% quarterly NWSC assets + LOC from GOU Up to 1 year grace period Required 1.5 billion Ushs in current account - Priced off Bank Loan 5 14.0% Fixed 14.0% 4 1.50% NWSC assets 364 t-bill - currently at 12.4% Required 1.5 billion Ushs in current account - Priced off Bank Loan 6 2.5% Floating 14.9% 4 1.50% NWSC assets 364 t-bill - currently at 12.4% Required 1.5 billion Ushs in current account - Priced off Bank Loan 7 3.0% Floating 15.4% 7 1.50% NWSC assets 364 t-bill - currently at 12.4% Bank Loan 8 2.5% Floating 15.4% 4 NWSC assets and cash flow lock Bank Loan 9 3.0% Floating 15.9% 7 NWSC assets and cash flow lock NWSC assets (at least 1.5x Bank Loan 10 14.0% Floating 14.0% 5 2.00% value of facility) Amount offered is 750000USD Will use internal reference rate (subtract 50 basis points) - appraisal fee of 1% will be charged - EADB Bank Loan 11 3.0% Floating 15.9% 15 1.00% 1% uncertain NWSC assets etc procurement rules Source: NWSC C-20. Loan covenants tended to be restrictive. Often banks were approaching the request for loan funds as an opportunity to control operational accounts of the utility, for the extra liquidity it would provide. In one case, a bank required cash collateral to be held against the loan in a current account. This provides the bank with considerable security at a considerable opportunity cost to NWSC. Bond Financing Options C-21. NWSC considered raising infrastructure bonds on the local capital markets as an alternative to bank financing. In deciding to explore a bond transaction, a number of key factors were considered advantageous to NWSC:  Tenure – Ugandan banks were able to offer debt facilities with a maximum of seven years tenure. Early discussions with potential bond 117 investors suggested that a bond issuance would allow for tenures of at least ten years, and possibly longer in subsequent issues.  Currency – While domestic banks were able to provide local currency facilities, DFIs were constrained in this regard. NWSC felt, correctly, that given a revenue base in Ugandan shillings, foreign currency exposure was not prudent.  Flexibility – The issuance of a bond allowed for a flexible amortization schedule and reduced covenant constraints. Local banks would require onerous loan covenants which would restrict the corporation‘s cash management.  Cost – Given limited competition in the local banking sector, initial investigations suggested that the bond market, by competitively placing the debt, would allow for lower-cost debt. Since a bond issuance would provide access to institutional funds (seeking to match their longer-term liabilities), a fixed interest rate was likely to be available, easing long-term debt service planning for the corporation. C-22. Upon consideration of the options, NWSC‘s board of directors decided to explore the development of a medium-term note (MTN) program along the lines of the very successful program used to raise capital finance by the City of Johannesburg. An MTN program allows the debt issuer to raise debt in a series of tranches as and when the funds are required. The issuer takes liquidity risk, as there may be limited appetite for its debt when it is required. However, the issuer avoids negative arbitrage associated with raising large amounts of debt and then holding the funds until they are required for use. Further, an MTN program allows the issuer to raise debt quickly as a master prospectus is used for each subsequent tranche, with only financials updated. By varying details in the relevant pricing supplement, the issuer is able to raise debt with the conditions it requires under the master prospectus. Given the nascent development status of the Ugandan capital markets, NWSC believed an MTN program would expedite the issuance of debt tranches beyond the initial tranche. C-23. The MTN program envisages UGS 100 billion (about USD 60 million) of debt issued over 3 years. The size of the program is in line with NWSC‘s commercial capital investment plans. The MTN program‘s proceeds will only be focused on commercially viable projects so as to prevent the erosion of the firm‘s financial health. Where the government requires investment with an explicitly social (and financially unviable) mandate, NWSC will try to source funds whose costs match the projected financial returns of those social investments. C-24. A draft information memorandum has been prepared and reviewed by the Uganda Securities Exchange and the Capital Markets Authority (CMA). Provisional approval has been granted by both bodies subject to a ‗no objection‘ by the ministry of finance; it should be forthcoming, given the recent debt conversion. While this is not a statutory requirement for the debt issuance, it is within the CMAs prerogative to request such further documentation. The perceived rationale for this request relates to the pioneering nature of the bond and its relatively large size. 118 C-25. NWSC is also pursuing a corporate entity credit rating. This rating will provide clear indications to the market as to the credit quality of the utility. It will also provide a diagnostic for internal management controls and reforms. Critically, such independent reviews of performance and the impacts of that performance on creditworthiness are likely to provide, in the medium term, the best indication to shareholders that financial management (including debt finance management) is acceptable. In the UK, for instance, the water regulator requires that water utilities maintain an investment-grade level rating. C-26. Upon receiving the no objection from the MoFPED, final, unconditional approvals from the financial regulators will be granted. The first tranche of the MTN program will be marketed to potential investors, who, as discussed above, are likely to include both those in Uganda and possibly investors in other countries interested in gaining exposure to UGS-denominated corporate debt. Successive tranches will be structured to reflect the objectives of NWSC. NWSC is considering issuing a retail tranche aimed to tap the considerable liquidity, as demonstrated by recent equity offerings in the region, of that investor segment. Lessons Learned C-27. The pilot NWSC transaction presents a number of key lessons around the issuance of domestic currency denominated debt in Uganda.  NWSC provides a case of a reformed infrastructure parastatal that demands commercial finance. The case study shows that the utility reform agenda leads to increased bankability and the development of potential issuers. In moving toward market finance, however, utilities will require a second generation of reform (around issues of improved project level capital planning, treasury management, and so on), both in anticipation of raising finance and in a post-transaction sense. Reform issues such as tariff predictability, and sufficiency and operational efficiency, will be the key drivers of demand going forward.  The process of developing infrastructure transactions in Uganda is long. As the market is relatively new, any bond issuance will set a new norm. The time needed for capital markets transactions can be considerable.  The unreformed pension sector in the country poses a significant liquidity risk, and in a certain sense imposes a limitation on potential bond market benefits. In most countries, bond markets provide a diverse mix of lenders and so reduce the concentration risk associated with bank borrowing.  For such finance to have a developmental impact on the market, it will need to be in local currency. Where revenue streams have currency adjustment pass-through (such as with the electricity sector), there is limited incentive to prepare local currency issues. This needs to be modified, as it is inefficient to pass currency risk to the customer where local currency pools could prevent its development in the first place. 119 120 Table C.5: Tariff Structure of NWSC T1 = T0 (A∆I + B∆FI∆FX + C∆K) Where: T1 = Indexed tariff for the next year T0 = Tariff level at end of year zero A = Proportion of tariff associated with local salaries and locally sourced goods based on audited financial accounts of the previous year ∆ = Change I = Domestic retail price index as published by the Uganda National Bureau of Statistics and based on the underlying inflation rate B = Proportion of the tariff associated with foreign costs, that is, foreign inputs in the production process, based on the audited financial accounts of the previous years FI = Foreign retail price index based on the United States Bureau of Labour Statistics FX = US Dollar to Uganda Shilling exchange rate based on the Bank of Uganda mid exchange rate as at the 30th June of each financial year C = Proportion of tariff associated with electrical power, based on the percentage of electricity cost to total cost as a proxy, based on audited financial accounts of the previous year K = Price of electrical power per unit. 121 Table C.6: NWSC Summary Financials & Ratios th All figures in UGX billions Year ended 30 June Balance Sheet summary 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 Non-current Assets 430.7 356.0 241.7 236.1 196.9 Current assets 52.3 49.9 37.4 37.4 28.8 Of which inventory 9.1 7.9 7.5 7.4 3.8 Total Assets 483.0 405.9 279.1 273.5 225.7 Shareholder's equity 314.8 251.8 78.0 90.3 65.9 Long-term liabilities 149.9 141.2 79.8 94.9 92.1 Of which, deferred income 121.6 116.2 22.1 0.6 0.6 Current liabilities 18.3 13.0 121.2 88.3 67.7 Of which, current portion of long-term debt 0.0 0.0 41.4 18.9 14.3 Total Liabilities 483.0 406.0 279.0 273.5 225.7 Total outstanding interest bearing debt + interest 0.0 0.0 153.6 144.2 134.3 Income Statement summary Water & sewerage 79.3 68.2 57.3 50.9 39.1 Other income 1.5 1.0 0.6 1.6 2.3 Deferred income recognised 3.3 1.2 0.6 1.3 1.2 Total revenue 84.1 70.4 58.5 53.8 42.6 Operating, admin & staff costs -68.4 -52.4 -44.5 -40.5 -31.6 Depreciation -12.4 -11.5 -9.8 -9.5 -9.7 Net operating income 3.3 6.5 4.2 3.8 1.3 Finance (expenses )/income 0.5 0.4 -9.2 -9.3 -7.0 Of which interest 0.0 0.0 9.0 10.1 7.7 Reversal of impairment charge 26.2 Net profit (Loss) before tax 3.8 6.9 -5.0 20.7 -5.7 Tax (charge) / credit 0 -5.8 -12.2 3.7 0.0 Net profit (Loss) after tax 3.8 1.1 -17.2 24.4 -5.7 Cash Flow Statement summary Net cash from operating activities 14.8 14.8 9.1 10.6 12.6 Net cash used in investments -16.6 -10.7 -10.8 -18.7 -10.8 Net cash from financing activities 0.6 0.4 0.8 5.4 1.6 Cash & equivalents at 30th Jun 9.4 10.7 6.2 7.1 9.8 Key financial ratios Year ended 30 th June Liquidity & debt ratios 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 Debt / Equity Ratio - - 1.97 1.60 2.04 Debt Service Cover Ratio - - 0.36 0.71 0.92 Current Ratio 2.86 3.84 0.31 0.42 0.43 Quick Ratio 2.36 3.23 0.25 0.34 0.37 Profitability and asset use ratios 2007 2006 2005 2004 EBITDA / Revenue 19% 26% 24% 75% 27% Net profit / Revenue 4.5% 1.6% -29.4% 45% -13% Asset Turnover Ratio 0.16 0.17 0.21 0.19 0.17 122 Annex D: Overview of Electricity Sector Infrastructure D-1. The electricity sector in Uganda today is dominated by private companies operating in the generation and distribution subsectors, while a government owned company manages the transmission subsector, and the Electricity Regulatory Authority (ERA) oversees and guides the operations of the sector overall. The key issues affecting the sector are: a low electrification rate estimated at 9 percent of the population; low generation capacity with a peak shortfall of up to 150MW; the high cost of energy due to overreliance on diesel-generated thermal energy; and substantial technical and nontechnical distribution losses amounting to 37 percent of energy produced. D-2. The entire electricity sector was initially managed by the state owned Uganda Electricity Board (UEB). In 2001 however, as part of the reform process, UEB was broken up into three different government-owned companies with separate responsibilities for the generation, transmission, and distribution of electricity: the Uganda Electricity Generation Company, Limited (UEGCL), the Uganda Electricity Transmission Company, Limited (UETCL), and the Uganda Electricity Distribution Company, Limited (UEDCL). The operations of UEGCL and UEDCL were subsequently leased to private companies through concession agreements, while the responsibility for transmission of bulk electricity remained with UETCL. A number of independent power producers (IPPs) were also licensed by the ERA to meet the growing demand for energy. D-3. Further reform was undertaken to address the low electrification rates in rural areas, estimated at less than 1 percent under the UEB era,68 by establishing the Rural Electrification Agency (REA) that is mandated to initiate rural electrification projects, subsidize their costs, install and maintain the rural transmission network, and monitor and evaluate rural electricity providers. Additionally, the Energy for Rural Transformation (ERT) project was developed as a three-part program that incorporates the activities of a variety of stakeholders, including the REA as a key implementing agency, to increase electricity access in rural areas as part of GoU‘s poverty eradication strategy. The target rate for rural electrification set by the ERT program is 10 percent by 2012, and by the end of 2005, rural electricity access had increased to 3 percent.69 The ERT program is funded by the International Development Agency (IDA) and the Global Environment Fund (GEF). In addition to main-grid and off-grid network investments, the project also finances small-scale renewable energy projects. D-4. As a result of increasing access to electricity countrywide, and the fact that 60 percent of medium-sized firms and 92 percent of large firms rely on the use of internal generators to provide supplementary power at triple the cost of power from the grid, demand for electricity is estimated to be growing at up to 11.5 percent p.a70. 68 World Bank PAD No 23195-UG; Electricity for Rural Transformation Project. 69 ERT Factsheet. 70 Country Economic Memorandum Vol II pg 169; World Bank Report No: 39221-UG. 123 Electricity sector map Policy Ministry of Partly finances Energy & Mineral Rural electrification Development Ownership: GoU. Management: GoU Governed by REB & financed by REF Regulator Electricity Rural Regulatory Electrification Authority (ERA) Agency (REA) Functions: Overall industry Functions: Initiates rural electrification projects & regulator, licensing, tariff setting, passes on to ERA for licensing. Subsidizes rural performance monitoring projects, and monitors & evaluates them. Ownership: 100% GoU. Ownership: Private Uganda Electricity Generation IPP Company Ltd Aggreko Int IPP Small scale IPPs Generation (UEGCL) Projects Ltd Jacobsen Kasese Cobalt, 100MW from 2 Electro Kilembe Mines, 20 year concession to diesel thermal 50MW HFO Kakira Sugar manage Nalubaale & Kiira dams plants 18MW to Grid Eskom Ltd Max 380MW; Current max supply est: 308MW current 140MW Sale to national grid Transmission Uganda Electricity Transmission Ownership: 100% GoU Company Ltd (UETCL) Function: Transmission & sale of bulk electric power in local & export markets (single buyer). Owns & operates grid 33kva-132 kva, buys & distributes power from IPPs, imports/exports power Sale to national distributor Ownership: Private Ownership: 56% Globeleq, Ownership: 100% GoU WenRECO off-grid 44% Eskom Distribution operator generates, Uganda Electricity transmits & distributes in Distribution 20 yr concession West Nile districts UMEME LTD Company Ltd effective 2005 1.5MW HFO, 3.5MW (UEDCL) hydro under construction Functions: Owner & operator of national distribution network Generates & distributes power to final consumers. Reports to REA Regulatory Framework D-5. The overall electricity sector policy maker is the Ministry of Energy and Mineral Development (MEMD); the sector is governed by the Electricity Act of 1999, which 124 established the Electricity Regulatory Authority (ERA). The ERA commenced operations in 2000 and its functions include: licensing the generation, transmission, distribution, sale, import and export of electricity; establishing tariff structures and approving tariffs; developing and enforcing industry performance standards; and responsibility for ensuring consumer protection. D-6. On the generation side, ERA issues prospective project developers one-year permits to conduct commercial, technical, financial, environmental, and social feasibility studies, which are reviewed by the authority. If a feasibility study meets ERA and MEMD criteria for approval, a project is issued a license to carry out the planned development. Large-scale electricity projects are initiated by government and put through the ERA regulatory process, while private investors are encouraged to go through the ERA process for licensing small-scale renewable projects that have either already been identified by ERA or are brought to its attention by intending developers. The operations of the transmission company, the national distributor, and off-grid operators are also licensed and monitored by the ERA. D-7. Tariffs71 form the revenue base of all companies operating in the sector, all of them determined and reviewed by the ERA depending on the revenue requirements of each individual company. These are described in detail by subsector in the tariff section later in this annex. Power Generation Overview D-8. The River Nile is Uganda‘s principal source of renewable energy, with an estimated potential of over 2000MW.72 The government‘s medium-term electricity generation strategy (2007–2011) is to develop three large hydro plants, at Bujagali, Karuma, and Isimba, to supplement existing hydro generation at Nalubaale and Kiira power stations in Jinja, which have an installed capacity of 180MW and 200MW respectively, and are owned by UEGCL but managed by Eskom, Ltd. of South Africa under a 20-year concession agreement effective 2002. Further medium-term electricity generation initiatives include government entering PPP type arrangements to develop small-scale renewable energy projects supplying at least 50MW to the national grid, and enhancing the promotion of solar photovoltaic and solar water heaters in homes to reduce peak power demand.73 D-9. Although the combined capacity of Nalubaale and Kiira power stations is 380MW, in practice they can manage to generate only about 140 MW of power because of low water levels at Owen Falls, which have forced the Directorate of Water Resources 71 Report 57/01 Amended Regulatory Framework for Uganda; ECON Centre for Economic Analysis; ERA website; review of available PPAs; World Bank Energy for Rural Transformation PAD. 72 The Energy Policy for Uganda; MEMD September 2002. 73 Ministry of Energy & Mineral Development Annual Report. 2006. 125 Management (DWRM) to restrict the volume of water released through the dams.74 The drop in generating capacity caused severe shortages of electricity that were partly addressed by leasing two 50MW alternative diesel oil (ADO) thermal energy plants from Aggrekko, Ltd., a Scotland-based IPP. The first of these plants was set up at Lugogo in Kampala in April 2005 and connected directly to Kampala‘s distribution network, while the second was set up at Kiira Power Station in November 2006 to supplement the supply of power to the national grid. Each plant was leased for a period of three years, hence the Aggreko 1 project, which commenced in 2005, was decommissioned at the end of August 2008. A new 50 MW ADO thermal plant at Mutundwe in Kampala has, however, been set up by the same company to replace the plant at Lugogo from September 2008. D-10. At a current estimated cost of UGS 476/kWh (USD 0.238/kWh) however, the variable cost of energy from ADO is greater than the bulk supply tariff for electricity supplied to the national grid. In an attempt to reduce thermal energy costs, ERA has licensed a number of heavy fuel oil (HFO) plants, which are expected to supply energy at a variable cost of UGS 400/kWh (US$ 0.200/kWh),75 however, these are interim measures to supplement the shortage of hydro power because the electricity tariff only supports a variable generation cost of UGS 260/kWh (US$ 0.13/kWh.)76 The first 50MW HFO plant is currently undergoing testing and is expected to be commissioned in September 2008. This plant has been built by a Norwegian company, Jacobsen Electric, on a Build Own Operate and Transfer (BOOT) arrangement with GoU. D-11. Assuming an annual growth rate of 11.5 percent as estimated in the World Bank‘s CEM, current peak demand could be in the region of 460MW; UETCL, however, estimates 2008 unconstrained peak demand to be 410MW.77 The existing capacity and supply to the national grid in Uganda as of the end of August 2008 is detailed in annex 7. Financing Generation Capacity D-12. Looking to the future, generation capacity will be financed on a project finance basis in general in two major market segments, often utilizing the private sector, as well. Large-scale projects will attract international finance and are likely to tax local liquidity if they were to depend on it for finance. Smaller projects, especially those depending on renewable energy sources, could possibly rely more heavily on local currency finance. A key driver required to promote the use of local currency finance will be a shift away from PPAs denominated in USD. This section discusses the financing of smaller scale projects, given the greater likelihood of dependence on local liquidity pools. D-13. The Energy for Rural Transformation Project, (now under design for a second phase) sought to promote local currency debt finance for small generation companies by using a refinance facility to provide increased liquidity to debt providers. Participating Financial Institutions (PFIs) are availed funds at the prevailing (at time of contract) 74 REA strategic plan 2003-2013 revised Dec 2006. Page 22. 140MW current production rate estimated by ERA. 75 Actual rate for diesel thermal and assumed rate for HFO thermal excluding capacity costs; Electricity Generation & Finance Plan 2008/9–2010/11, May 2008; sub-group of Energy & Mineral Development Sector. 76 Tullow Oil, Plc. drilling and development activity report. October 2007. 77 UETCL Deputy Managing Director. 126 weighted average term deposit rates calculated and made public by the BoU. The funds can either be on a floating (re-set annually) or a fixed basis and are disbursed in either local or foreign currency. The maximum tenure of finance is 15 years; BoU will refinance a maximum of 90 percent of the total loan size. In practice, the pre-selected projects negotiated with potential PFIs to select the actual PFI to provide finance. The borrowers are expected to contribute a minimum of 25 percent of the cost of the project/assets to be acquired, using debt originating from the ERT I Refinance Facility, and maintain at all times a maximum debt equity ratio of 3:1 during the period of the loan. The borrower is also expected to maintain a minimum debt service cover of 1.5 times and a minimum liquidity ratio of 1.0.78 The table below summarizes key aspects of the refinance used by the two projects that have thus far used the facility. Table D.1: Major Beneficiaries of the ERT I Refinance Facility Project Lender Amount Tenure of Base interest Lender Fixed/ refinanced loan rate (at margin floating (USD) signing) Kakira EADB 7.730 m 10 years ~7% 3% Floating WENRECO Barclays 3.735 m 15 years ~7% 2% Fixed Source: D-14. Going forward, provided that small-scale renewable energy sources remain a key feature in the government‘s energy strategy, it is likely that considerable local currency finance could be required for such projects. Annex 1 summarizes projects under development (as permitted or licensed by the Energy Regulatory Authority) suggesting that there could be considerable demand for finance from this subsector. D-15. To catalyze demand for finance from small-scale energy providers, lenders (either from banks or directly from the capital markets) will require a deeper understanding of project finance. In developing such capacity in the financial markets, some support may be required. Tenure extensions where the banks are intermediating deposits may be required but need to be structured more efficiently than a simple refinancing. Also, early experience with ERT I suggests that some credit enhancement may be required to overcome difficulties in managing projects as opposed to balance sheet debt A credit enhancement package (including both liquidity and partial credit risk protection) will be included in ERT II. This protection will help local banks extend the tenure of finance they can offer and will also address perceived excessive construction phase implementation risks. D-16. The support provided by ERT I has helped local generators access local currency debt, though it is through the maturity transformation of short-term bank intermediated deposits. In the longer term, the capital market, with its appetite for longer-term assets, should play a larger role in financing energy expansion. Transmission Overview 78 ERTRF Regulations. Bank of Uganda. July 2002. 127 D-17. The transmission of bulk electricity in Uganda is done through the high- voltage national grid, rated at 33 kVa to 132 kVa, which is owned and maintained by the government-owned UETCL. The company effectively purchases over 99 percent of electricity generated in Uganda and distributes it by way of bulk sale to the national distributor. As of September 2007, the national grid comprised 1,366 km of 132kV,38 km of 66kV high-voltage network, and 12 primary substations. In rural areas, REA is responsible for installing low-voltage transmission lines, and by the end of 2007 had made investments in building mini-grids at Kalangala and Ngoma, and in installing the following transmission lines: Kakumiro–Kibaale, Kibaale–Kagadi, and Rukungiri– Kanungu. It outsources maintenance of these to the private sector. D-18. Investment in building transmission capacity hinges on the development of generation capacity, which is why Power Purchase Agreements (PPAs) are signed with new generators before construction of any planned project commences. The heavy investment in generation anticipated over the next five years is expected to triple the country‘s hydro capacity and to provide thermal energy from Uganda‘s own oil resources, measures which should boost the energy supply by sufficient amounts to allow for greater electrification within the country and facilitate the net export of energy to neighboring countries. D-19. However, only small investments have been made in the transmission grid in the recent past, and it is poorly equipped to handle increased loads. The grid currently suffers network constraints, and 80 percent of its overhead lines are more than 45 years old; as of the end of 2007, the transmission network suffered from a 29 percent overload on the Owen-Falls–Kampala North high-voltage line, low voltages at Mbarara North substation, overloaded transformers at Tororo substation, and beyond-limit fault levels at Lugogo and Kampala North stations.79 Average transmission losses are reported to be around 3.6 percent80 and of late, UETCL has experienced a surge in the difference between volume power sales and purchases, which suggests greater inefficiencies in both transmission and distribution. Financing Transmission Capacity D-20. UETCL, as the single transmission services provider in the country, could in the future be a significant issuer of local currency debt. The company has considerable capital investment plans, as suggested below, with a planned capital funding gap of about 60 percent of UGS 1,200 billion (USD 600 million), This does reflect a considerable increase over past capital investment (ostensibly linked to the acceleration in generation capacity efforts in the country). D-21. Investment in transmission capacity has thus far been largely funded by the treasury through budget support to UETCL, international development partners, and to a lesser extent to REF. UETCL in particular has also used debt from GoU and the 79 UETCL Grid Development Plan. 2007–2022. 80 Average transmission loss in MWh for the 1st Quarter 2006–1st Quarter 2008 as recorded by ERA. 128 Norwegian government to finance part of its capital investment program, and the company intends to use the treasury as its main source of external funding for the next five or so years81. Lines of credit worth UGS 150 billion (USD 75 million) for the construction of transmission lines and USD 31.5 million for rural electrification have been established with the African Development Bank, and GoU is in negotiations with the government of Norway to establish a line of credit worth USD 40 million to finance the Karuma Interconnection project. Finance for the development of the rural transmission network is closely tied with the sale of bulk electricity, as there is a 5 percent levy on bulk power sales allocated to the development of rural electrification. Table D.2: UETCL’s Capital Expenditure Plan 2007 - 201379 Estimated Total % planned GoU Project Nature of works project cost funding Bujagali HEP plant 97.5 Km transmission lines, substations, $ 84.47 22% equipment & civil works Karuma HEP plant 444 Km transmission lines, substations, $ 119.90 11% equipment & civil works Thermal Plant at Kaiso- 273 Km transmission lines, substations, $ 60.91 100% Tanyo equipment & civil works Re-Investment 261 Km Tororo-Opuyo-Lira transmission $ 35.10 23% line System extensions 618 Km transmission lines, substations, $ 160.14 57% equipment & civil works Regional power trade 354 Km transmission lines & equipment $ 88.88 9% Power IV Equipment $ 16.18 19% Various small-scale UETCL Rehabilitation, extensions, substations & $ 37.23 100% projects equipment Total financing required: $ 602.81 Of which planned GoU funds: $ 238.44 40% UETCL – Financial Capacity to Raise Debt D-22. Between 2004 and 2007, UETCL‘s annual gross energy sales grew at a CAGR (compound annual growth rate) of 71 percent to UGS 360 billion (180 million), but its cost of sales grew at a CAGR of 144 percent to UGS 286 billion. Profitability was severely affected in 2005 when thermal energy was introduced into the supply mix, causing losses which continued into 2006 and resulted in only negligible profits in 2007. The company‘s operating, administration, and staff costs remained fairly constant throughout the period, averaging UGS 15.7 billion for the four-year period 2004 to 2007, 81 UETCL corporate business plan. 2007. 129 although these costs dropped from 26 percent of total costs in 2004 to only 4.7 percent in 2007. The company currently has a staff base of 223 contract employees and a further 231 employed on a casual basis.82 D-23. As of 31st December 2007, UETCL had total debt of UGS 79.3 billion outstanding on its balance sheet, the bulk of which relates to term loans provided by GoU and the Norwegian government; a book value of equity of UGS 89.5 billion;and a total asset base of UGS 323 billion, 44 percent of which relates to noncurrent assets (see appendix 1B for list of debtors and terms and conditions of outstanding loans). The company has maintained short-term liquidity throughout the four-year period analyzed (2004–2007), even when stagnant dues to and from related parties UEGCL and UEDCL are removed from its balance sheet, although it is noteworthy that UETCL‘s quick ratio has steadily declined from 1.96 in 2004 to 1.19 in 2007. D-24. The declining liquidity is largely due to the impact of high input costs from thermal energy on the company‘s cash flows, which caused a net operating cash outflow of UGS 81 billion between 2005 and 2006, resulting in negative debt service cover in both these years and a net operating loss of UGS 30 billion in 2005. Although the company did have sufficient cash reserves to meet its debt obligations, the government deferred its debt service payments in 2005, 2006, and 2007. The company returned to profitability in 2007 and generated UGS 22 billion cash from operations, giving it sufficient debt service cover of 2.2 times. (Refer to table A2.4 for summary financials). Issues Affecting UETCL’s Debt Carrying Capacity D-25. Impact of tariff rebates. The volatility observed in the company‘s operating cash flow appears to be closely linked with government subsidies and tariff rebates. As long as thermal electricity continues to be a major part of the company‘s energy purchases, volatile oil prices will continue to impact cash flow, yet the Bulk Supply Tariff (BST) cannot be altered in quick response to commodity price fluctuations because of government concerns about increased energy costs in the economy. While private companies in the generation and distribution subsectors seem to be well protected from commodity price and exchange rate fluctuations by means of ERA tariff mechanisms, UETCL is bearing the burden of sector losses. At the same time however, for UETCL to be financially viable, it is essential that the tariff structure enables the company to earn an income that properly values the goods and services it provides. This could include ex ante agreement on subsidies required to maintain more stable prices. D-26. Restructuring of legacy debt. Included as part of short-term assets and liabilities are amounts of UGS 36.8 billion and UGS 31 billion, respectively, that refer to related party financial obligations arising from government rebates to electricity consumers in 2001. Restructuring focused on ridding the three energy parastatals of these obligations has already been suggested by industry stakeholders and should be implemented as soon as possible. There is no movement in these balances, and continuing to keep these 82 ERA statistics for 1st Quarter 2008. 130 figures on UETCL‘s balance sheet when there is clearly no intention that they will be settled hinders financial planning. D-27. Capacity to take on more debt. Although the company‘s debt to equity ratio has steadily increased from 0.45 in 2004 to 0.89 in 2007, it does have a stable business model and its investments are made in core infrastructure assets that are generally not subject to sharp fluctuations in value unless major changes in technology occur. These factors, coupled with the fact that average gearing ratios in infrastructure sectors can comfortably be as high as 3:1 (debt:equity), afford UETCL the opportunity to target a higher debt ratio. Furthermore, a large portion of the company‘s fixed assets have been recorded at their book values under UEB ownership, and while no formal revaluation has been done since, it is thought that the company‘s assets are worth more than their book value.83 Proper evaluation of assets could therefore create a significant revaluation reserve that would boost the value of the company‘s equity. Distribution D-28. Under the terms of the concession agreement with UEDCL, Umeme is obligated to invest a minimum of USD 65 million in upgrading the distribution network in its first five years of operation. By the start of 2009, the company had invested USD 46 million in the network and operational assets. D-29. The incentive for Umeme to invest in network expansion at present is constrained by the power supply problems that have afflicted the country since it took over operations of the distribution network from UEDCL. But assuming that the supply problems afflicting the country are addressed in the medium term through the range of initiatives being undertaken in the generation subsector, the biggest challenge facing the electricity sector is the expansion of the distribution network. The network currently suffers from years of neglect of maintenance, inadequate investment, poor management practices, and antiquated billing and accounting systems.84 Yet the low electrification rate of 9 to 10 percent, coupled with a growing economy and increasing urbanization, points to the existence of sufficient latent demand that could boost volume energy sales in the coming years if the distribution network is upgraded and its coverage expanded. D-30. Umeme, due to its legal investment requirement, is potentially also a significant issuer of local currency debt. However, this demand for infrastructure finance will be constrained until new generation capacity is made available through Bujagali and other generation projects under development. 83 Discussion with UETCL Deputy Managing Director. August 29, 2008. 84 Bujagali PAD. 131 List of Generation Projects Licensed by the Energy Revenue Authority D-31. The following table lists the generation projects that have been licensed by the Energy Revenue Authority (ERA). Licensing signifies that the research and approval phases have been completed, power purchase and sale agreements have been negotiated where applicable, and the respective companies have been granted permission to implement the projects. Project Capacity & Source License Issue Date / Notes Bujagali Energy, Ltd. 250 MW Large hydro Licensed 1 June 2007. Expected to commence operations Dec 2010. Jacobsen Electro at Namanve 50 MW–HFO thermal Licensed 1 August 2007. Currently undergoing testing and expected to commence operations in September 2008. Electromaxx plant in Tororo 10 MW–HFO thermal Licensed 1 March 2008. No further information on expected date of commencement. Sugar Corporation of Uganda 3.5MW–Bagasse Licensed 1 January 2006. No further Limited Cogeneration project, information on expected date of Lugazi commencement. Hydromax Limited, Buseruka, 9MW–Micro hydro Licensed 1 November 2007. Expected to Hoima commence operations 2009. China Shan Sheng Industry Int 10MW–Micro hydro Licensed 1 January 2007. Expected to (U), Ltd., Kikagati HEP Project, commence operations 2010. Isingiro West Nile Rural Electrification 3.4MW–Micro hydro Licensed 12 March 2003. Expected to Company, Ltd., Nyagak HEP commence operations December 2007. Project, Nebbi Tronder Power, Ltd., Bugoye 13MW–Micro hydro Licensed 1 April 2008. No further information HEP Project, Kasese on expected date of commencement. Eco Power (U), Ltd., Ishasha 6.6MW–Micro hydro Licensed 1 July 2007. Expected to commence HEP Project, Rukungiri operations 2010. TOTAL 355.5MW D-32. The following projects have been granted ERA permits valid for one year to carry out feasibility studies but have not yet been licensed by ERA to implement their projects. Many of the permits have since expired, and the expiry date is given below. Project Capacity & Source Permit Expiry Date/Notes Norpak Power, Ltd. project at Phase 1: 105 MW ERA Permit expired 22 May 2008. Karuma Falls Phase 2: 150 MW GoU in negotiations to arrange project finance. Large hydro Energy Systems for Africa, Ltd. 50MW–Solar ERA Permit expired 31 July 2007. project at Namugoga, Busiro Kabale Energy, Ltd., Kabale 30MW–Peat-fired plant ERA permit expires 31 Oct 2008 Aldwych International in Aswa- 50MW–Biomass fired plant ERA permit expired 1 January 2008 Lolim area China Shan Sheng Industry Int. 22MW–Mini hydro (own ERA permit expires 31 January 2009. Only (U) Ltd Nshungyezi HEP distribution => only excess will expected to be implemented on completion of Project, Isingiro be sold to national grid Kikagati project. Energy & Power Developments, 10-20MW–Biomass & ERA permit expired 1 January 2008 Ltd. municipal solid waste Empower Ltd. (Umeme HFO) 10 MW–HFO thermal ERA permit expired 31 May 2008 Invespro Uganda, Ltd., Njeru, 10 MW–HFO thermal ERA permit expired 5 February 2008 Jinja Kalangala Infrastructure 2-3MW–Solar, diesel & ERA permit expired 31 March 2008 132 Services, Ltd. biomass South Asia Energy Management 18MW–Micro hydro ERA permit expired 1 January 2008 Systems Mpanga HEP Project, Kamwenge South Asia Energy Management 5.2MW–Micro hydro ERA permit expired 1 January 2008 Systems, Kyambura Gorge HEP Project, Bushenyi Mt Elgon Hydro Power 9MW–Micro hydro ERA permit expired 1 September 2004 Company, Ltd. Muyembe – Sirimityo HEP Project, Mbale Eco Power (U), Ltd. Kakaka 7.2MW–Micro hydro ERA permit expired 30 July 2007 HEP Project, Kabarole Uganda Energy for Rural 3MW–Micro hydro ERA permit expired October 2006 Development, Ltd. R. Mahoma HEP project, Kabarole Adjumani Rural Electrification 1MW–Micro hydro ERA permit expired 28 February 2008 Company, Ltd., Moyo Uganda Sustainable Energy 2.2MW–Micro hydro ERA permit expired September 2006 Company, Ltd. Nyamabuye Mini-HEP Project, Kisoro Table D.3: Existing Capacity and Supply to the National Grid in Uganda (August 2008) Company Source Max Installed Approx Volume Notes Capacity Sold to National Grid Eskom, Ltd. Large hydro 380MW 140MW As of Aug ‘08, ERA reports capacity varies 120– 150MW, UETCL estimates low hydrology at 140MW Aggreko, Ltd. at Thermal diesel 50MW 50MW Kiira Power Station, Jinja Aggreko, Ltd. at Thermal diesel 50MW 12MW Plant not complete as of end Mutundwe, Kampala Aug ‘08, but 100% capacity is expected on completion. Plant replaces Lugogo 50MW diesel which is being decommissioned. Kakira Sugar Works, Bagasse 18MW 12MW Ltd. Kilembe Mines, Ltd. Micro hydro 5MW 4MW Kasese Cobalt Micro hydro 10MW 2MW Supply to grid varies Company, Ltd. 2–3MW TOTAL as of Aug 513MW 220MW 2008 Once the 50MW HFO thermal plant at Namanve and the diesel thermal plant at Mutundwe become fully operational, the maximum expected supply capacity to the national grid should be 308MW, which amounts to approximately 82 percent of the peak demand requirement estimated at between 360MW to 390MW by end 200685 85 Energy Institute of Uganda. http://www.energyinstug.org/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=10&Itemid=25 133 Tariff Structure in the Electricity Sector Generation D-33. In the case of large hydros, payment for bulk electricity supplied to the national grid is determined according to a capacity price based on the generator‘s revenue requirement. The capacity price is paid per kW per hour and is reviewed annually and adjusted quarterly for changes in tested capacity, inflation, and exchange rate. The revenue requirement is made up of the following cost components, and differs according to the operational setup and cost structure of the generator:  The investment component  The operating and maintenance (O&M) component  The concession fee or lease component  Other costs such as regulatory fees and loyalties. D-34. In the case of thermal energy supplied to the national grid, an additional energy charge is levied, made up of an O&M component and a fuel component, which covers the cost of fuel logistics as well as the mean of platts pricing for diesel fuel. The portion of the revenue requirement that is designated ―foreign exchange based‖ is indexed to the USD/UGS exchange rate, while the portion not indexed to the exchange rate is indexed to Ugandan inflation. The licensee has the right to apply for tariff adjustments in addition to the quarterly adjustments under circumstances of extraordinarily high inflation or sudden movements in foreign exchange rates. By linking earnings under PPAs to hard currency, the ERA encourages foreign investment in electricity generation while allowing companies to borrow at lower interest rates. Transmission D-35. The ERA establishes a Bulk Supply Tariff (BST) that is levied by the transmission company on electricity distributors for power purchased from the national grid. The BST is a time-of-use energy charge, with peak, shoulder, and off-peak prices maintained at a constant ratio of 120:100:74. This is determined by the revenue requirement of the transmission company, which includes:  Net power purchase costs, that is, total cost of power purchased from generators and imports less export revenues  O&M expenses of the transmission company  Allowance for debt service. D-36. The BST is updated on a quarterly basis to reflect actual costs and volumes of power purchases and exports, while the revenue requirement of transmission is reviewed on an annual basis to reflect the effects of inflation and changes in foreign exchange rates. Distribution 134 D-37. End user tariffs levied by Umeme, Ltd., the national distributor, vary according to customer category, that is, domestic or industrial. ERA determines the tariff according to the following factors: o Revenue requirement of the distribution company, which constitute: O&M costs indexed to inflation and exchange rates; depreciation; return on assets; return on working capital; allowance for bad debts and distribution losses; income tax o Allocating this revenue requirement to the different customer categories o Converting this revenue requirement into fixed, energy, and capacity tariff as appropriate for each tariff category. D-38. End user prices are updated on a quarterly basis to reflect changes in the BST, inflation, and exchange rates. Umeme has the right to apply for tariff adjustments in addition to the quarterly adjustments under circumstances of extraordinarily high inflation or sudden movements in foreign exchange rates. Tariffs charged by off-grid licensed operators, such as WenRECO, which generates, transmits and distributes electricity on its own network, are established by ERA on the basis of the tariff methodology described above. D-39. Table D.4: UETCL Summary Financials & Ratios 135 All figures in UGX billions Year ended 31 st December Balance Sheet summary 2007 2006 2005 2004 Non-current Assets1 142.8 112.1 109.0 100.5 Current assets less due from UEDCL 143.8 162.3 129.1 133.9 Amount due from UEDCL 36.8 36.8 36.8 36.8 Of which inventory 2.7 2.8 2.7 3.0 Total Assets 323.4 311.2 274.9 271.2 Shareholder's equity 89.5 88.5 88.9 108.3 Long-term liabilities 84.8 66.6 65.9 65.1 Current liabilities less due to UEGCL 118.1 125.1 89.1 66.8 Amount due to UEGCL of long-term Of which, current portion 31.0 31.0 31.0 31.0 debt 9.2 7.3 5.1 8.0 Total Liabilities 323.4 311.2 274.9 271.2 Total outstanding interest bearing debt + interest 79.3 59.0 55.6 49.2 Income Statement summary Gross Energy sales 359.8 192.2 101.7 71.2 Tariff rebate -117.9 -92.9 -25.4 0.0 Government subsidies 76.4 150.3 38.5 0.0 Other income 5.0 4.1 4.3 4.1 Total revenue 323.3 253.7 119.1 75.3 Cost of sales 286.0 225.6 103.3 19.7 Rural electrification levy 11.3 8.3 21.1 18.7 Operating, admin & staff costs 15.1 14.3 18.7 14.7 Depreciation 5.1 4.8 4.7 4.2 Net operating income 5.8 0.7 -28.7 18.0 Finance expenses 4.5 0.5 1.1 3.0 Of which interest 2.1 2.4 2.3 2.8 Net profit (Loss) before tax 1.3 0.2 -29.8 15.0 Tax (charge) / credit -0.4 -0.6 10.3 -5.1 Net profit (Loss) after tax 0.9 -0.4 -19.5 9.9 Cash Flow Statement summary Net cash from operating activities 22.5 -30.3 -50.9 53.3 Net cash used in investments -35.8 -7.8 -13.2 -15.8 Net cash from financing activities 20.3 3.4 8.3 10.3 st Cash & equivalents at 31 Dec 29.3 22.3 57.1 113.0 st Key financial ratios Year ended 31 December Liquidity & debt ratios 2007 2006 2005 2004 Debt / Equity Ratio 0.89 0.67 0.63 0.45 Debt Service Cover Ratio 2.18 -2.88 -6.57 5.19 Current Ratio 1.22 1.30 1.45 2.00 Quick Ratio 1.19 1.27 1.42 1.96 Profitability and asset use ratios 2007 2006 2005 2004 EBITDA / Revenue 3% 3% -19% 29% Net profit / Revenue 0.3% -0.2% -16% 13% Asset Turnover Ratio 1.11 0.62 0.37 0.26 136 Annex E: Overview of Roads Sector Infrastructure Overview E-1. National roads are the focal point of Uganda‘s road network, with Kampala‘s paved road network carrying 28 percent of total traffic and other national roads carrying 57 percent.86 Planning for the maintenance and development of the network is guided by the Roads Sector Development Program (RSDP), which was initiated in 1996/97 with the implementation of RSDP1, a 10-year program estimated to cost USD 1.5 billion at the time. RSDP1 was replaced after five years of operation, having received cumulative funding of USD 305 million. The figure below gives an overview of the roads sector structure. Figure E.1: Roads sector schematic Roads sector map regulation Ministry of Policy & Ministry of Ministry of Works & Finance Local Transport (MoFPED) Government (MoWT) Urban Councils Finances devt Fuel levy Implement Road Sector National roads Road Agency 10,800 Kms Devt Program 2 2001-2011 Formation Unit est cost of $2.3 billion (RAFU) Uganda National Uganda Road Transformation Roads Authority Fund (UNRA) Finances MoWT Road maintenance est maintenance Maintenance $40 million p.a. division Finance on cost-share basis Lesser roads 27,500 Kms District roads 4,300 Kms Urban roads 30,000 Kms Community roads E-2. The overall roads sector regulator is the Ministry of Works and Transport. The mandate to maintain and develop the national road network rests with UNRA while other 86 Updated 10-year Road Sector Development Program (RSDP-2: 2001/02–2010/11). March 2002. 137 roads fall under the jurisdiction of local government. A summary of the authorities responsible for various roads is presented below.87 Table E.1: Responsibility for Road Networks Portion of road network Responsible Authority 10,800 km of national roads (2700 km UNRA paved; 8,100 km gravel) 27,500 km of district roads Ministry of local government 4,300 km of urban roads Urban Councils 30,000 km community access roads Lower tier of local government responsibility (LC III) 6 ferry crossings Ministry of Works & Transport (others are privately owned) Financing of the Roads Sector E-3. The roads sector is financed through a combination of treasury and development partner finance. Maintenance and rehabilitation is classified as recurrent expenditure while network improvement is classified as development expenditure. A summary of planned finance measures for the ten year period 2001/02–2010/11 under RSDP2 is presented in table A3.3. E-4. The anticipated finance gap at the inception of RSDP2 amounted to USD 925 million over the 10 year period; however, there has been a considerable increase in funds for roads made available by the treasury, with a total sector budget allocation of USD 637 million for works and transport for FY2008/09, of which USD 385 million is for roads network development and USD 94 million is for road maintenance. Roads network development is 47 percent donor-funded through the treasury, while only 14 percent of road maintenance is funded by development partners. UNRA is currently developing the RSDP 3 capital development program for the roads network,which is not expected to include plans for which financial commitments have not been secured from either the treasury or donors.88 This is in light of previous experiences under RSDP1 and 2, for which the implementation of sector plans was inhibited by a lack of funding. E-5. With the introduction of the road fund, which is expected to become operational in July 2009, road user charges in the form of a fuel levy, license fees, tolls, and fines are to be credited to a separate road fund account with BoU and used specifically for road maintenance activities. MoWT had requested an annual budget for road maintenance of UGS 202 billion, while MoFPED has committed UGS 191 billion (USD 112 million) as initial funding for the Road Fund once it becomes operational. Once implemented, the fuel levy on diesel and petrol sales is expected to make up the bulk of the Road Fund‘s 87 Source: Road Fund website; www.unra.go.ug. 88 Engineer David Luyimbazi‘s presentation at JSTR 2008. 138 income, although modalities of how the system will actually work are still being worked out by the ministries of finance and works and transport.89 Table E.2: Capital Expenditure Plans under RSDP2 Network Figures in USD thousands Finance measure Type of expenditure Est total cost GoU Donors Shortfall Recurrent $ 542.18 $ 472.16 $ 61.41 $ 8.61 l iona Improvement $ 1,042.04 $ 116.17 $ 410.82 $ 515.05 Nat Total for national roads $ 1,584.22 $ 588.33 $ 472.23 $ 523.66 Est total cost GoU & local authorities Shortfall District, urban District roads $ 510.00 $ 225.82 $ 284.18 & community Urban roads $ 65.00 $ 49.58 $ 15.42 access roads Community access roads $ 2.00 $ 2.00 $ - (Recurrent only) Total for DUCAR network $ 577.00 $ 277.40 $ 299.60 Est total cost GoU Donors Shortfall Institutional development $ 118.84 $ 16.38 $ 102.46 & capacity building Est total cost GoU Donors Shortfall Grand total for roads sector $ 2,280.06 $ 882.11 $ 472.23 $ 925.72 Potential for Private Financing E-6. The roads sector is characterized by considerable financial requirements and considerable financial resources. Challenges facing the sector appear to center more on operational and absorptive capacity issues, resulting from the inadequacy of the local construction industry to absorb budgeted resources, rather than on the availability of finance. As such, the role that the capital markets (or local banking sector) can play in the short term is likely to be limited. The fuel surcharge collected could provide a revenue stream for the roads fund to leverage, however, it remains uncertain as to whether large- scale road maintenance contracts will be required, and whether such leverage will be efficient in the short term. 89 Joint Transport Sector Review Workshop. 2008. 139 Annex F: Overview of Airports Sector Infrastructure Overview F-1. The civil aviation sector in Uganda is governed by the Civil Aviation Authority (CAA), an autonomous organization owned by GoU that is mandated to regulate air transport, provide air traffic and air navigation services, and to own, operate, and develop airports around the country. The civil aviation sector in Uganda is regulated by the Civil Aviation Authority Act Chapter 354, which provides for the CAA to promote the safe, regular, secure, and efficient use and development of civil aviation inside and outside Uganda. The CAA was created in 1991. F-2. The authority‘s activities are concentrated at Uganda‘s Entebbe International Airport, which is managed by CAA, and which handles practically all international passenger and air cargo traffic in the country. CAA has awarded concessions to private companies to run certain non-core functions at Entebbe, such as ground handling services and parking lot management. Additionally, there are 13 small aerodromes operated by CAA at: Arua, Gulu, Kasese, Kidepo, Soroti, Mbarara, Masindi, Jinja, Lira, Moroto, and Kisoro, which are used to ferry passengers and minimal volumes of cargo around the country by light aircraft; the first five facilities listed are designated entry and exit points to handle cross-border air traffic within the region, although only Arua and Gulu currently operate as entry/exit points, because of cross-border traffic with Sudan. There are also a number of privately owned airstrips dotted around the country that are licensed by CAA, for example, Kajjansi and Kakira. Capital Expenditure F-3. CAA‘s long-term capital investment program was adjusted in 2006/07 and 2007/08 to accommodate upgrades and improvement at Entebbe International Airport in preparation for the CHOGM summit held in Kampala in November 2007. A total of UGS 71 billion was invested in financial years 2006/07 and 2007/08, the bulk of which went toward upgrading and modernising at Entebbe. These investments included: acquisition of a new ATC radar system and automatic weather observation system; procurement of two aerobridges, two conveyor belts, and an escalator; IT upgrades; and significant refurbishments throughout the airport‘s main building and grounds. As a result of the improvements made at Entebbe, other capital investments planned by CAA were delayed, and the authority is now in the process of developing a new long-term capital expenditure program. The immediate capital expenditure budget for the financial year 2008/09 is in table A4.1.90 Two other major items of capital expenditure budgeted for financial year 2007/08 that have not been implemented are in table F.2.91 90 CAA Budget estimates. 2008/09. 91 CAA 5-year business plan 2007/08 to 2011/12. 140 Civil Aviation sector map regulation Policy & Ministry of Works & Transport (MoWT) Civil Aviation Authority CAA Board of Directors (Chairman + 8 members inc MD) Directorates Finance & Human Air Transport Airports & Air Navigation Accounting Resource & & Regulatory Aviation services (49 staff) Administration services Security (112 staff) (137 staff) (23 staff) (347 staff) Subsidiary Entebbe Cold Stores Ltd Service provision & regulation (Planned for divestiture) Private sector Commercial and Private airstrips private aircraft Financing Civil Aviation Infrastructure F-4. Since its inception in 1991, CAA has been financed by the treasury and by soft loans from the Spanish and Danish governments to GoU that were on-lent to CAA. Additionally, CAA has received grants of FF 27.5 million from the French government, USD 0.94 million from USAID, and USD 0.4 million from Safeskies, Ltd. to fund specific capital developments at its facilities. These grants are being amortized in CAA‘s books of accounts over the useful lives of the assets acquired. F-5. By 2006, the company had a total asset base of UGS 90 billion but a debt burden of UGS 152 billion or USD 81.2 million (USD 51.8 million principal + USD 29.8 million accumulated interest) from loans originating from the Spanish and Danish governments. 141 CAA‘s equity at the time consisted of government contributions totalling UGS 38.7 billion that had been wiped out by accumulated losses of UGS 99 billion, giving the company a negative book value of equity. In a financial restructuring measure approved by parliament in 2005/06, CAA‘s outstanding debt was converted into equity and its assets were revalued, effectively leaving it debt-free with a book value of equity of UGS 272 billion.92 Table F.1: Capital Expenditure Plans for CAA Total est cost in UGS Capital expenditure item billions Buildings, taxiways, pavements & other 1 airport facilities 25.38 2 Other capital projects 3.09 3 Electrical, electronics & mechanical 7.36 4 Rescue & fire equipment 4.09 5 Security equipment & facilities 2.13 6 Air navigation equipment 2.72 7 Computerisation 0.77 8 Upcountry airports 24.45 9 Other capital costs 1.45 GRAND TOTAL 71.44 USD equivalent $ 42,023,529 Table F.2: Capital Expenditure Plans for CAA Total estimated Capital expenditure item cost (USD) New cargo centre at Entebbe $ 25,000,000 Free trade zone at Entebbe Airport $ 18,670,000 TOTAL $ 43,670,000 F-6. With a clean balance sheet, CAA entered into a loan agreement to borrow UGS 72 billion from a syndicate of banks led by Stanbic in 2006/07 in order to finance its medium-term capital expenditure program. By June 30th 2006, CAA had drawn down UGS 60.5 billion of this amount, largely to finance developments at Entebbe Airport, giving the company a debt to equity ratio of 0.27. The treasury also provided CAA grants amounting to UGS 13.7 billion to help finance CHOGM related expenditure, which, coupled with the drawn down amount from Stanbic Bank, is approximately equivalent to the UGS 71.2 billion investment expenditure made by CAA in the two financial years 2006/07 and 2007/08.93 92 CAA financials 2006. 93 CAA draft financials for 2007/08. 142 F-7. CAA was generating operating profits prior to 2006, but it has incurred operating losses of UGS 5.1 billion in both 2006/07 and 2007/08. It has, however, generated positive cash flow from operations, because approximately one-third of its operating expenses relate to noncash items, that is, charges for depreciation and doubtful debts. Prior to undergoing financial restructuring in 2006, CAA generated an operating profit of 9 percent and 13 percent in 2003/04 and 2004/05, respectively. However, with a debt service cover of 0.28 and 0.18 in both these years, it was not generating sufficient cash to meet its debt obligations. The company was also illiquid during this period, with a current ratio of less than 0.40. F-8. Through financial restructuring in 2005/06, the company‘s debt was converted into equity by way of a GoU debt swap, and the book value of its equity was further enhanced after its assets were revalued. CAA then entered into a loan agreement with Stanbic Bank to borrow a total UGS 72 billion, USD 20 million of which was denominated in US dollars and UGS 36 billion of which was Uganda shilling denominated. The term of the loan is for seven years with a two year grace period during which time only interest is payable, and is subject to a floating interest rate charge of TB + 3.25 percent on the UGS component and LIBOR + margin on the USD component. However, the loan was availed to CAA only on the basis of an undertaking by the treasury to repay UGS 54.4 billion of the principal amount due on the loan in four equal installments of UGS 13.6 billion.94 Additionally, CAA has an interest liability owed to Bank of Uganda on loans written off under the restructuring plan. F-9. CAA‘s post-restructuring debt service cover was 0.7 times in 2006/07 and 2.7 times in 2007/08; however, only interest due on the Stanbic loan and the residual interest due to Bank of Uganda were owed during this period. Hence, while CAA‘s 2007/08 free operating cash flow was sufficient to meet its interest obligation, it is not adequate to meet the principal repayments on the Stanbic loan that begin to fall due in 2008/09. And while the company‘s short-term liquidity situation has improved considerably since restructuring, with a quick ratio of 3.5 as of 30th June 2008, this is likely to deteriorate considerably once the principal repayments on the loan fall due in 2008/09 if budgetary support from the treasury is not forthcoming. A summary of CAA‘s financials is presented in A4.3. F-10. In the absence of budgetary support from the treasury, CAA‘s cash flows are insufficient to meet its current debt service obligations; hence, the company is reluctant to take on more debt and is currently looking to refinance the Stanbic loan in order to reduce its debt repayment burden.95 F-11. Refinancing the existing Stanbic loan is likely to reduce costs. Key considerations of this cost reduction will be center around the ability of CAA to extend the debt tenure. The capital markets again are likely to be better placed to provide longer-term finance than the local banks. Given the relative weakness of CAA‘s cash flow, borrowing costs 94 CAA budget 2008/09 and communication with Emmanuel Kiberu, CAA. 95 Communication with Emmanuel Kiberu, CAA. 143 will be higher due to increased credit risk. The purchase of credit guarantees may provide some overall cost reduction. A fundamental aspect linked to CAA‘s use of commercial centers on its weak cash flow, and improving this should be considered a precursor to any further commercial finance activity. 144 Table F.3: Summarized Financials: CAA All figures in UGX billions Year ended 30 th June Balance Sheet summary 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 Non-current Assets 265.6 225.6 218.4 50.8 53.4 Current assets less inventory 58.7 72.5 64.4 37.8 32.3 Inventory 0.6 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.2 Total current assets 59.4 73.7 65.7 39.0 33.5 Total Assets 325.0 299.3 284.0 89.8 86.9 Total capital & reserves 234.9 254.1 272.1 -60.2 -67.7 Long-term loans 60.5 23.1 0.0 51.1 58.8 Deferred income 12.7 4.2 0.9 1.3 1.1 Current liabilities 16.8 17.9 11.1 97.5 94.7 of which, Current portion of long-term debt 0.0 0.0 0.0 39.1 34.0 of which, loan interest provision 2.2 2.3 2.7 50.5 47.6 Total liabilities 325.0 299.3 284.0 89.8 86.9 Total outstanding interest bearing debt + interest - 0.0 140.8 140.4 Income Statement summary Operating income 56.9 44.6 42.7 41.7 42.1 Less operating expenses -49.0 -49.8 -42.8 -36.4 -38.4 Depreciation -13.1 -9.1 -7.4 -6.6 -6.6 PROFIT/(LOSS) FROM OPERATIONS -5.1 -5.2 -0.1 5.2 3.7 Finance Costs and Exchange Differences -5.8 -0.9 5.6 2.7 14.6 Of which interest 5.0 1.0 0.0 4.5 4.6 PROFIT/(LOSS) BEFORE TAXATION -10.9 -6.1 5.6 7.9 18.3 Income Tax 0.0 -9.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 NET PROFIT /(LOSS) -10.9 -15.6 5.6 7.9 18.3 Cash Flow Statement summary 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 Net cash from operating activities 14.5 1.3 6.4 12.4 19.6 Net cash used in investments -56.0 -28.6 -0.1 -3.8 -7.0 Net cash from financing activities 2.0 -2.3 0.0 -9.9 -7.8 Cash & equivalents at 30th Jun 10.8 8.9 11.0 11.1 12.7 Debt related cash flow Long-term loans -0.1 -0.4 0.0 -7.6 -14.0 Medium-term loans 37.4 23.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 Short-term loans 0.0 0.0 0.0 5.1 2.9 Key financial ratios Year ended 30 th June Liquidity & debt ratios 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 Debt to Equity Ratio 0.27 0.10 0.01 -2.34 -2.07 Debt Service Cover Ratio 2.72 0.71 2.38 0.18 0.28 Current Ratio 3.54 4.11 5.93 0.40 0.35 Quick Ratio 3.50 4.04 5.82 0.39 0.34 Profitability and asset use ratios EBITDA / Revenue 12% 9% 30% 46% 70% Net profit / Revenue -9% -12% 0% 13% 9% Asset Turnover Ratio 0.18 0.15 0.15 0.46 0.48 145