ENERGY SUBSIDIES GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1 Identifying and Quantifying Energy Subsidies Masami Kojima i  CONTENTS Acknowledgments iv About the Author iv Acronyms and Abbreviations iv 1. Introduction 1 2. Definition, Categories, and Questions for Analysis of Subsidies 2 Definition and Categories 2 Purposes of Analysis of Subsidies 9 3. Pricing and Related Issues Specific to Fuels 11 Drivers of Price Distortions 11 Price Controls. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 Trade Restrictions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 Purchase or Supply Mandate. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 Price Gap 14 Refined Products, Their Alternatives, and LPG.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 Natural Gas and Coal .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18 Subsidy for Start-up Costs Price Subsidy Delivery Mechanism 19 How Many Suppliers Receive Compensation?. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19 How Is Compensation to Producers Determined?. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20 Is Compensation Self-Administered by Fuel Suppliers?. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 Is Subsidized Fuel Rationed?. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 Is There a Fuel Price Stabilization Fund?. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22 Unintended Consequences of Fuel Price Subsidies 23 Declining Sector Performance. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 Commercial Malpractice. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 Higher Prices. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 Amplification of Fuel and Power Sector Subsidies 4. Pricing and Related Issues Specific to Electricity 25 Price Distortions 27 Tariff Setting. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27 Cost Recovery 28 i GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 Hidden Cost Analysis Data Sources. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33 Impact of Sector Structure. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34 Cross-Subsidies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34 Start-up Subsidies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35 Unintended Consequences of Power Sector Subsidies 35 5. Tax Expenditures and Other Support Measures 36 Tax Expenditures 36 Other Support Measures 37 6. Considerations for Subsidy Policy Reform 39 Annex: Examples Data Sources and Ease of Evaluation 47 Endnotes 54 References 55 BOXES Box 1: Externalities and Measurement of Subsidies 4 Box 2: Price Control in an Officially Deregulated Market 12 Box 3: Start-up Costs for Different Forms of Energy 19 Box 4: Rapid Growth of Certified Fuel Suppliers 20 Box 5: Smart Cards for Rationing 22 Box 6: Commercial Malpractice in Kerosene Trade in Nigeria 25 Box 7: Components of Hidden Costs 32 Box 8: Multiple Connections in Sub-Saharan Africa 35 Box 9: Underpricing of permits 37 TABLES Table 1: Fuels and Their Uses 5 Table 2: Major Mechanisms Used to Provide Energy Subsidies 6 Table 3: Types of Analysis for Cost Recovery 31 Table 4: Considerations for Fuel Subsidy Policy Reform 40 Table 5: Considerations for Power Subsidy Policy Reform 44 ii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS ACKNOWLEDGMENTS This is the first in the series of 10 good practice notes under the Energy Sector Reform Assessment Framework (ESRAF), an initiative of the Energy Sector Management Assistance Program (ESMAP) of the World Bank. ESRAF proposes a guide to analyzing energy subsidies, the impacts of subsidies and their reforms, and the political context for reform in developing countries. The author thanks Ani Balabanyan, Vivien Foster, and David Santley, all of the World Bank, and David Coady of the International Monetary Fund for their useful comments on this note. ABOUT THE AUTHOR Masami Kojima is Lead Energy Specialist in the Energy and Extractives Global Practice of the Sustainable Development Vice Presidency at the World Bank. She has worked on energy subsidies, biofuels, energy poverty, air pollution from urban transport, indoor air pollution, and access of the poor to clean modern energy. ACRONYMS AND ABBREVIATIONS ESRAF Energy Subsidy Reform Assessment Facility EITI Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative FOB free on board kg kilogram kWh kilowatt-hour LNG liquefied natural gas LPG liquefied petroleum gas OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development SOE state-owned enterprise VAT value added tax iii GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES This note provides guidance on how to approach and assess energy subsidies, quantifying them where possible. It suggests a definition of subsidies and describes options for categorizing and measuring subsidies. It also outlines policy issues to consider in reforming the subsidies in developing countries. These issues include different ways in which subsidies can arise and be delivered, pitfalls in subsidy design and delivery, frequently observed discrepancies between design and implementation, and unintended consequences, including effects on energy suppliers. The note describes the challenges of quantifying subsidies in both data collection and subjective judgment, and how the magnitude of subsidies so calculated may differ markedly from subsidies received by its intended beneficiaries. It covers fuels, electricity, and district heating. It also touches on non-energy use of oil, gas, and coal, such as naphtha, liquefied petroleum gas (LPG), and natural gas serving as feedstocks to make petrochemicals and fertilizers. ESRAF uses the word “prices” to refer to prices paid for all forms of energy, and “tariffs” to refer to a schedule of prices subject to economic regulation, such as those for electricity, natural gas, and district heating. This note excludes from detailed discussion subsidies specifically targeting renewable energy, except certain liquid biofuels that are blended with petroleum fuels and renewable energy that is part of the power mix. Because district heating is confined largely to Europe and Central Asia, it is covered in the definition and categories of subsidies, but is otherwise not treated in detail. iv 1. INTRODUCTION 1 1. INTRODUCTION The typical issues linked to subsidies that call challenge is to ensure that these subsidies for examination include do not entrench market distortions over the long term. • Budgetary transfers to pay for energy subsidies; Although the scale of budgetary support for subsidies attracts attention, some forms of • Determination of the energy price increases subsidies are less visible or not amenable to needed for subsidy removal; quantification without considerable uncertainty. • Consumer price subsidies that are needed to Subsidies that do not directly affect prices paid restore energy suppliers’ financial viability; by consumers or that do not appear as line items in government budgets often escape • Forgone government revenue because of attention. The underpricing of goods and fiscal and other concessions granted to services provided by the government and energy suppliers to pay for subsidies; and the preferential access to state-owned banks • How energy prices and subsidies in a given granted to state-owned energy suppliers are country compare to those in neighboring two examples. They are seldom quantified, countries or similar economies. nor is their quantification straightforward, but noting the presence of the subsidies and The economic effects of subsidies are usually recommending a review alone would be useful. negative, but not always. Many subsidies If certain energy suppliers or forms of energy decrease efficiency in the economy, and benefit disproportionately from subsidies that those that benefit producers may decrease are difficult to quantify—and they have been operational efficiency. However, some subsidies escaping scrutiny as a result—this should are retained on equity grounds or to advance be taken into account when assessing the technology, even in countries with mature prevalence and distribution of subsidies. energy markets. Among the examples are Purely economic analysis of subsidies rarely, • The cross-subsidization of rural electricity if ever, exists. The quantification of oil price users by the other users; subsidies in every case starts with the international prices of crude oil and petroleum • Heating assistance for the poor in Europe products. These subsidies, however, are not and North America; and economic costs, partly because of market • Subsidies to promote the early stages of concentration. Nor do they account for the technology development, such as carbon shadow price of a depletion premium or for capture and storage, or the early adoption environmental and other externalities. of new energy sources, such as second- generation liquid biofuels. Yet using prices other than world prices would make the calculations more subjective and In such cases, the policy question for the would depart too much from the widely government is whether the benefits far accepted practice in the literature. By contrast, outweigh the costs. An important policy 2 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES financial analysis would ignore input subsidies approaches. A generalized template to be and other forms of subsidies. followed under most circumstances would be unwieldy and prone to large margins of error. What is presented here is not financial analysis The objective of this note is therefore not to of subsidies. Neither is it an economic analysis, provide a universally applicable template for as discussed below. Because of wide variation quantification, but rather to lay out general in market conditions, market structure, pricing principles and issues to consider in formulating and subsidy policies, and data availability, most the methodology for quantification. subsidy calculations require case-by-case 2. DEFINITION, CATEGORIES, AND QUESTIONS FOR ANALYSIS OF SUBSIDIES DEFINITION AND CATEGORIES Specificity in targeting means that a policy that affects the economy as a whole—for example, An energy subsidy—as defined in this note—is lowering the corporate income tax rate or a deliberate policy action by the government the general consumption tax rate—would not that specifically targets electricity, fuels, or be considered an energy subsidy. Subjective district heating and that results in one or more judgment is inevitable, and subsidy analysis in of the following effects: a given country is best carried out by taking A | It reduces the net cost of energy purchased. the country’s circumstances into account when making that subjective judgment. B | It reduces the cost of energy production or delivery. It is only in cross-country comparisons that broadly comparable rules must be followed. C | It increases the revenues retained by those In comparing subsidies across developing engaged in energy production and delivery countries, large differences in data availability (energy suppliers). compound the difficulties encountered in making subjective judgments. The definition contains several terms— “deliberate,” “action,” and “specifically The definition of subsidies in this note is targets”—that limit the coverage of subsidies confined to government action—not inaction. and that may actually exclude certain subsidies. Because of this, financial incentives offered This is because all too often governments by businesses as marketing decisions—such provide subsidies without actually saying so as selling LPG cylinders at a loss as a means in their policy statements through inaction, of attracting new customers—would not be the “moral suasion” of state-owned energy considered subsidies, unless the marketing companies to keep prices low, and other means decisions cause large financial losses and the that are not deliberate actions specifically government steps in to rescue the energy targeting energy. suppliers. 2. DEFINITION, CATEGORIES, AND QUESTIONS FOR ANALYSIS OF SUBSIDIES 3 Unless accompanied by budgetary transfers excluded is one in which the main policy to make up for financial losses, not attributing objective is not the provision of energy subsidies to government inaction would subsidies. Examples include unconditional exclude from the definition the following cash transfers as social safety nets, even if situations because they are often not a direct one of the reasons for the introduction of result of a deliberate government policy action: cash transfers is higher energy prices, and generation of fundamental knowledge such as • Losses suffered by energy suppliers or basic research and development, as opposed the government through commercial to support for commercial development of malpractice and criminal activities (such specific technologies. as theft of energy, reduced or nonpayment by consumers bribing energy company staff, Subjective judgment and associated illegal diversion of subsidized fuels for fuel uncertainties are unavoidable in calculating adulteration or smuggling). subsidies. When the government’s inaction (such as persistent failure to act on commercial • Weak administrative capacity on the part malpractice or enforce payment discipline) of the government (such as the lack of or an unwritten strategy (such as applying enforcement of regulations against short- pressure on state-owned energy suppliers selling or weak tax administration). to keep prices low) becomes a de facto • Weak managerial capacity of energy deliberate policy is subjective—although if suppliers (such as the failure to bill and prices of internationally traded fuels are clearly low bill collection rates). too low on the domestic market because of government pressure on state-owned • Political difficulties in implementing enterprises (SOEs), analysts usually conclude disciplinary procedures (such as the inability that price subsidies exist. to disconnect government ministries or the military for nonpayment of energy bills). The definition of an energy subsidy also raises the question of how to define the reference When tolerance for their consequences case—the counterfactual—against which becomes an ill-defined de facto regulatory the subsidy is defined and measured. The policy, what makes sense in the country’s reference cases for some types of subsidies, context should guide analysts and policy such as tax expenditures and non-tax fiscal makers rather than literal adherence to the concessions, can vary significantly from definition in this note. country to country and are therefore difficult to compare internationally (OECD 2014, p. 36). The definition excludes certain government actions that have the same effects as in A, B, Identification and quantification of subsidies or C above. Examples include the promotion inevitably entail varying degrees of analyst of efficiency improvement along the supply judgment. Anderson (1990) illustrated this chain and in end-use and of fair and healthy point by examining a major greenfield coal competition in the market, and changing the project in Canada to establish whether there fuel mix (such as switching from imported were large subsidies. The study found that the fuel oil to domestic natural gas in power results were highly sensitive to the assumptions generation). Another policy action that is made about such standard parameters as 4 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES costs, selling price, capacity utilization, the a price subsidy—both lower end-user prices— project life, discount rate, and inflation, and but import duty reduction decreases, while different but plausible assumptions had led to a price subsidy (such as a negative fuel- the opposite conclusions about the presence specific consumption tax) increases, economic of subsidies. distortions. One could also argue that optimal taxation should be taken as the reference case At a minimum, to enable sensible interpretation for tax expenditures. However, energy taxation of the results, all assumptions should be generally and fuel taxation in particular are transparently documented, so that subsidy vast and complex topics, and the rest of this quantification will clearly be a function of the note does not consider optimal taxation. assumptions—and not of who has computed the numbers. Specificity in targeting energy could This note also excludes uninternalized costs be particularly problematic. It immediately of externalities in the definition of subsidies. raises the question of how specific—if a tax There are divergent views on whether or not policy affects only three sectors, including and how to capture uninternalized externalities energy, and energy prices fall as a result, is in subsidy measurement, ranging from not that an energy subsidy? More importantly, a counting them as subsidies to classifying all policy may not specifically target energy on uninternalized externalities that are in any paper, but it may be designed to benefit the way associated with energy production or energy sector disproportionately. If energy consumption as energy subsidies. Inclusion suppliers capture the bulk of the benefits or exclusion of uninternalized externalities is of a tax break, not including that tax break what accounts for the difference of trillions in the subsidy calculations on the grounds of dollars in the calculation of global fossil that the tax relief did not “specifically” target fuel subsidies by different institutions. energy, they would underestimate support to The International Energy Agency and the producers (effect C above). Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) consider such Optimal taxation is outside the scope of this externalities to be outside the scope of subsidy note. However, subsidies and taxes would measurement. For reasons discussed in box 1, ideally be considered together, because tax this note follows that approach. By contrast, policy and subsidy policy actions can have the International Monetary Fund assigns all essentially the same effects on fuel prices, externalities associated with fossil fuels to but with the opposite effects on economic fossil fuel subsidies in its post-tax subsidy distortions. For example, reducing the import calculation. duty on a fuel has the same effect as providing BOX 1: EXTERNALITIES AND MEASUREMENT OF SUBSIDIES Because many externalities relate to environmental damage and large associated health costs, environmental economists have long argued for charging corrective taxes as a means of internalizing (pricing) externalities. While appealing from one point of view, inclusion of uninternalized externalities in subsidies poses difficulties, including reconciliation with how practitioners in other sectors understand box continues next page 2. DEFINITION, CATEGORIES, AND QUESTIONS FOR ANALYSIS OF SUBSIDIES 5 the concept of subsidy. For example, in agriculture, which is more advanced than energy in measuring subsidies in a consistent way across countries, uninternalized externalities are not included in the definition of subsidies, so that inclusion of uninternalized externalities in energy would make comparison of energy and agricultural subsidies not meaningful. Another significant challenge is attribution. Taking vehicular air pollution as an example, pollutant emissions today are determined largely by vehicle technology and driving patterns, not fuel consumption and properties. An accurate corrective tax would therefore be driven far more by vehicle technology (including the state of vehicle maintenance) than fuel. Attributing all externalities to fuel consumption alone would not only be inaccurate, but rather could lead to suboptimal, if not misguided, policies. Linked to the challenge of attribution is source apportionment. Health effects depend on the ambient concentrations of harmful pollutants and human exposure. Estimating how much different emission sources contribute to ambient concentrations is another area of difficulty. The only exception is carbon dioxide emissions from the combustion of oil, gas, and coal, which is a function largely of the carbon content of each fuel (unless carbon is captured and permanently stored). There could also be double-counting. For example, health and accident insurance premiums cover the costs of vehicle accidents, and therefore where such insurance is mandated or universal, they should not be included in subsidy calculations because these externalities have been internalized. The question of whether to include uninternalized externalities in subsidy measurement is separate from that of quantifying externalities of subsidies. Good Practice Note 8 suggests steps to compute the economic costs of outdoor air pollution caused by over-consumption of fossil fuels due to consumer price subsidies. The results can be added to the costs of energy subsidies and used to weigh the economic (as opposed to fiscal or financial) benefits and costs of subsidies. TABLE 1: Fuels and Their Uses Category Fuel Common uses and comments Oil Gasoline Automotive (light and medium duty, including motor bicycles), aviation,a and marine transportation; limited use in very small-scale electricity generation. Bioethanol Automotive (usually blended with gasoline). Kerosene Heating, cooking, lighting, aviation.a Diesel Automotive (medium and heavy duty), rail, marine transportation, aviation,a heavy equipment, electricity generation, irrigation. Biodiesel Automotive and aviationa (usually blended with petroleum diesel fuel), electricity generation, heavy equipment. Fuel oil Electricity generation, industrial application, marine transportation. Natural Natural gas Electricity generation, industrial application, space and gas water heating, cooking, refrigeration, automotive, marine transportation. LPGb Cooking, heating (water, space, process), lighting, refrigeration, automotive. Coal Lignite (brown coal), anthracite, Electricity generation, industrial heat, space heating, bituminous, sub-bituminous cooking. a. Aviation fuels are rarely subsidized. b. Globally more LPG is sourced from natural gas than from oil refining. Because LPG is typically stored under pressure as a liquid, it is treated a liquid fuel here and elsewhere. 6 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES The term fuel subsidies in this note covers Table 2 presents a framework that categorizes subsidies for fuels in different applications, as possible policy actions that could yield energy well as infrastructure and appliances associated subsidies. A comprehensive examination of with fuel supply and use. Supply infrastructure energy subsidies would draw up such an includes fuel pipelines, oil refineries, import inventory of possible avenues for subsidies terminals, and LPG bottling plants. Kerosene and investigate each category one by one. and LPG stoves and lamps, as well as LPG Additional examples of different types of cylinders, are examples of appliances using energy subsidies, data sources, and the ease fossil fuels. Among them, LPG cylinders and of evaluation are discussed in the annex. The stoves are most likely to be subsidized. Table categories in the table are not necessarily 1 describes the fuels covered in this note and mutually exclusive. For example, a superfund their uses. to clean up contamination caused by legacy projects falls under both budgetary transfers Subsidies are provided through four primary and shifting of risk burdens. A cash transfer mechanisms: scheme is a form of direct transfer of government funds, and may also be associated • Budgetary transfers of government funds with government control of energy prices. • Government-induced transfers between When to consider which category of subsidies producers and consumers is also explained in more detail at the end of this note in table 4 for fuels and table 5 for • Foregone taxes and other government electricity. revenues • Underpricing of goods and services TABLE 2: Major Mechanisms Used to Provide Energy Subsidies Category Explanation or example Direct transfer of government funds Direct transfers of funds to energy Budgetary support to compensate producers for price producers (whether on- or off-budget controls. Budgetary support to fund applied research transfers). and development, demonstration projects in commercial development of an energy technology, and other types of support for energy or firms engaged in energy trade and transformation. Cash transfers to consumers, where Cash transfers to the poor intended to increase transfers are directly linked to energy affordability of a specific form of energy and linked to its consumption. consumption. Government-induced transfers between producers and consumers Government control of energy prices Prices or price limits set by government. Price regulation in a market where competition is possible Direct regulation of prices, price ceilings, or (absence of high market concentration and of natural price floors at any point along the supply monopoly). High guaranteed prices to attract investment, chain to reduce costs to producers or such as feed-in tariffs. Excludes economic regulation based consumers, or to increase prices paid to on prices corresponding to benchmark sector performance producers. prompted by concerns over market concentration. 2. DEFINITION, CATEGORIES, AND QUESTIONS FOR ANALYSIS OF SUBSIDIES 7 Category Explanation or example Domestic price effects of import or export Applicable largely to fuels. Excludes import or export measures. Import duties or quantitative duty reduction as part of trade liberalization that does not restrictions that raise the domestic target a specific form of energy. Import bans or restrictions price received by producers and paid by and high import duties benefit certain domestic producers; consumers; export duties or quantitative export bans or restrictions and high export duties benefit restrictions that reduce the domestic domestic consumers. price received by producers and paid by consumers. Special case of cross-subsidy. Policies that Lifeline rates for electricity and natural gas, whereby reduce energy costs to particular types the first block of residential tariffs is priced low and of customers or regions by increasing cross-subsidized by higher blocks. Pan-territorial pricing charges to other customers or regions, irrespective of cost of delivery to different parts of the or by requiring firms to use profits in one country. Underpricing of refined products using surplus segment of the supply chain to reduce profits in upstream oil. Underpricing of oil or natural prices charged to consumers in another gas on the domestic market by using export profits and segment of the supply chain. mandating domestic supply obligation. Underpricing of LPG sold to households, compensated by higher unit prices charged to non-residential consumers. Purchase or supply mandate Purchase requirement. Required purchase Requiring every fuel wholesaler to purchase from the of a particular form of energy, typically monopolistic domestic refinery (which cannot compete when other choices are more financially with imports). Dispatch order not based on increasing attractive. cost and instead favoring certain producers or sources of electricity. Domestic supply obligation. Required sale Domestic gas supply obligation with low domestic prices of a fuel on the domestic market, typically in exchange for a license to export gas. Requirement to when domestic prices are kept artificially blend a certain percentage of biofuel in gasoline or diesel. low compared to export markets or alternatives. Foregone government revenue Tax expenditure. Corporate income tax, Reduction on corporate income tax targeting certain firms, environmental tax, land tax, import duties, such as a tax holidays for a new refinery and a new power value added tax (VAT), excise tax, general generation plant. Differentiation in excise tax between consumption tax, and other taxes reduced gasoline and bioethanol, or between petroleum diesel or waived. Acceleration of allowable and biodiesel. Environmental tax that is not based on deductions. Additional deductions over and environmental outcome, such as taxing gasoline more than above what is generally allowed. diesel. Carbon tax that is not consistent with each fuel’s carbon content. Carbon tax exemption for energy-intensive industries. Tax-exempt operating status for SOEs. VAT or import-duty exemption for LPG cylinders. Lower VAT for electricity, and VAT exemption for residential consumers. Other fiscal revenues. Bonuses for oil Differences in rates that cannot be traced to costs or blocks, royalties, production share, and profitability, seemingly favoring certain projects or firms. other non-tax fiscal payments reduced or waived in upstream oil and gas.a Government revenue from energy suppliers. Reduction in government revenue as a result of state- owned energy suppliers—such as national oil companies providing subsidized fuels—deducting subsidies from dividends to be transferred to the government. 8 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES Category Explanation or example Underpricing of other goods and services, including risk Subsidized inputs. Subsidies for large- A significant price discount for domestic crude oil sold volume inputs to energy suppliers, such as to a domestic refinery. Subsidized or free diesel, fuel oil, fuels and water. or natural gas supplied to power utilities. Subsidies for water charges to biofuel feedstock growers or hydraulic fracturing for natural gas production. Subsidized rail freight for coal suppliers. Lending and credit. Loan guarantees, Soft loans, typically for SOEs. below-market provision of loans, and grants for energy production and supply. Goods and services provided by Excludes goods and services provided to the broader government. Underpricing of access to land economy, such as roads and rail used by many sectors. and other goods and services. Permits. Underpricing of permits and Freezing of the permit fee for years or decades. licenses. Shifting of risk burdens. Government Assumption of risks must be specific to the energy supply assumption of price, safety, and other risks; chain. A superfund to clean up legacy projects (such as consumer or resident assumption of risks coal mines), paid for by taxpayers, would be an example. through limits on commercial liability. Government financing of a diesel price insurance in Chile in 2005–06 is another example. Special treatment of SOEs. Undue risk- Benefiting energy producers and suppliers: Implicit taking, soft budget constraints leading to government guarantee; state-owned energy suppliers contingent liabilities, debt cancellations. enjoying ready access to state-owned banks. Benefiting SOEs buying fuels from state-owned fuel suppliers: Late or no payment with no penalties or supply termination. Benefiting consumers: Not requiring SOEs to make reasonable profits in order to keep end-user prices low. a. Fiscal terms for upstream oil and gas need to be considered together in their entirety in the light of their higher tax rates and the existence of other fiscal payments (such as royalties, bonuses, and government’s profit share) that are not imposed in other sectors. Because of complexity, upstream oil and gas fiscal terms are excluded from this note, except where they affect or are affected by downstream subsidies. Where there appears to be sufficient evidence of large subsidies, these cases may be flagged as an area for further investigation. Another useful way of looking at subsidies prices are lowered, B is also. C is a type of is to map them to three categories defined producer support, and B also represents by the OECD:1 producer support if suppliers can retain additional revenue over and above what would • Consumer support be considered a reasonable return. General • Producer support services support, such as government-funded applied research that will ultimately benefit the • General services support sector, does not necessarily support current energy supply or consumption. However They are added to arrive at total support. subsidies are categorized, the goal is to A in the above definition of subsidies is a capture all types of subsidies in a unified form of consumer support and, if end-user framework. 2. DEFINITION, CATEGORIES, AND QUESTIONS FOR ANALYSIS OF SUBSIDIES 9 PURPOSES OF ANALYSIS OF policy question closely watched by the public. SUBSIDIES The price adjustment needed is also referred to as the price gap, defined as the difference It would be rare to carry out a comprehensive (gap) between a likely unit price of energy in examination of all the policy options laid out a competitive market (called reference price, in table 2, nor is doing so a realistic objective after adjusting for local costs and quality) in many cases for reasons of costs and data and the official or actual unit price on the limitations. It is more common to focus on a local market (local price). The total value of subset of the subsidy measures in the table to the subsidy for a particular form of energy address specific questions that are the focus is its price gap multiplied by the total units of policy makers and analysts. Frequently subsidized. The price gap is positive for encountered questions for investigation posed consumer support and negative for producer by policy makers, researchers, and civil society support. Positive and negative price gaps are at large are discussed below. It is important also referred to as underpricing and price to note that the questions posed are not support, respectively. necessarily confined to subsidies and may have broader scope, with subsidies constituting Financial viability of energy suppliers . one of several components of the question Subsidies may be among the factors being posed, as in the case of the financial threatening energy suppliers’ financial viability. viability of energy suppliers below. In the extreme, energy suppliers are forced to operate at a loss and absorb the subsidies, Budgetary transfers. Budgetary transfers to prompting bankruptcies and withdrawal of pay for subsidies compete with other priorities investment from the sector. What follows and attract policy makers’ attention, especially may be energy shortages, unreliable supply of when such transfers force other essential energy, and increasing reliance on fuel imports spending to be cut. Transfers for subsidies in countries with domestic fuel resources— tend to be large particularly when they further amplifying subsidies, foreign exchange are not targeted. Two important questions shortages, and budgetary transfers. Energy are what determines the magnitude of the suppliers may not be financially viable for any budgetary allocation for subsidies and how one of the following reasons: to reduce them. The factors determining the magnitude include international fuel prices, • The subsidy policy is not implemented as inter-country or inter-fuel price differences stated. The policy may state that energy causing substantial out-smuggling and black suppliers will be reimbursed for subsidies, marketing, operational inefficiencies raising but reimbursements may be delayed for costs unnecessarily, and corruption in subsidy months or years, leading to serious cash delivery. Information on budgetary transfers flow problems and forcing suppliers to take should be available from the finance ministry. out bank loans. Reimbursement calculations may favor the government, computing Magnitude of price adjustments needed. smaller reimbursements than what energy In countries with large price subsidies, how suppliers should get. much official prices may need to be raised to attain cost recovery (which could eliminate the • The pricing policy is not implemented as need for budgetary transfers) is an important stated. The pricing policy on paper may 10 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES state that prices set by the government 2 | Use the same assumptions and calculation should cover costs, but the government procedure in every country. The same may not raise prices when costs in local methodology is applied across the sample currency increase (for example, higher costs of countries, assuring consistency but also induced by large currency depreciation). risking “a race to the bottom,” in that the country with least data may determine • Suppliers suffer from large operational the assumptions made. inefficiencies. Prices may be sufficient for efficient suppliers, but state-owned energy In practice, a compromise approach between suppliers may be grossly inefficient with the two is likely, in which a broadly consistent large technical and commercial losses. methodology is applied and additional simplifying assumptions are made in countries Data on financial viability may be difficult with less available information. to disentangle for opaque SOEs, and disaggregating different causes may present Full landscape. Sometimes governments or a further challenge. researchers wish to understand how many different types of subsidies there are, who Fiscal losses. Subsidies may be provided benefits from them, and how large they are. through fiscal losses rather than budgetary That is to say, the goal is to understand how transfers. Very large fiscal losses—for example, many of the subsidy categories in table 2, tax exemption in Nigeria for certain oil and gas elaborated further in the annex, are found in companies has been calculated to amount to the energy sector or any of its sub-sectors, billions of dollars2—could attract the attention and assess their relative importance. of policy makers and prompt re-examination of the policy. Practitioners are not faced with two mutually exclusive approaches to examining subsidies: Regional and global benchmarking . A price gap or inventory. The two most commonly comparison with peers—neighboring used methods for measuring subsidies are the countries, similar economies, or similar energy price-gap approach—quantifying departures markets—can help gain a better understanding from prices that would have prevailed in of whether a country’s subsidy policies are a competitive market—and the inventory reasonable, how they can be reformed, and approach, which constructs an inventory of what is achievable in the short term as well as government actions benefiting production and over a longer time period. The more countries consumption of energy. Practitioners do not are covered, the more simplifying assumptions have to choose between the two. An inventory are needed because of substantial differences based on a full accounting framework for in data availability. There are two approaches producer and consumer support estimates in to benchmarking at the opposite ends of the fact captures price gaps as market transfers spectrum: to producers or consumers. The two methods 1 | Use all the data available in each country. are complementary, and ideally should be This will enable detailed calculations used together. in countries with good data, but the Price gaps create distortions with ripple calculation methodology will likely differ effects throughout the economy and from country to country. 3. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO FUELS 11 arguably represent the most serious form in more detail in this note than other means of energy subsidies. This would be the case of delivering subsidies. The next section even if the subsidies take the form of cross- discusses issues related to pricing. Because subsidies and there are no net subsidies; there are significant differences between fuels economic distortions can still lead to economic and electricity, they are treated separately. inefficiency. Therefore, price gaps are described 3. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO FUELS This section covers the following: All too often, however, governments control prices even when market determination of • Policies that cause fuel price distortions, prices would be less distorting. Indirect forms such as price controls, trade restrictions, of policy action include trade restrictions and and purchase or supply mandates purchase or supply mandates. • An outline of the procedures and data requirements for calculating so-called price PRICE CONTROLS gaps Analysis of price controls can begin with • Price subsidy delivery mechanisms and identification of fuel prices the government what to watch out for controls officially or unofficially, whether the government sets price ceilings or price • Examples of the unintended consequences levels, where along the supply chain prices of fuel price subsidies are controlled, and how large an area each price or price ceiling covers (entire country, DRIVERS OF PRICE DISTORTIONS state or province, city). Policy actions that affect fuel prices can cause Official price controls take the form of the price distortions. The most common and government’s setting price levels or price direct policy action is government control ceilings somewhere along the supply chain: of fuel prices, which can occur at different wellhead for natural gas and mine mouth for points along the supply chain. Government coal; the refinery gate for crude oil or refined influence over prices may be justified where products and LPG, district heating plant gate there are natural monopolies, such as pipeline for coal and natural gas, gas separation facility transportation of gaseous or liquid fuels. for LPG, and central gas processing facility Government influence over pricing may also for natural gas; the fuel supply point for be needed if there are multiple fuel suppliers certain intermediate consumers, such as the but competition among them is inadequate. In power plant gate for fuel oil, natural gas, coal, both cases, economic regulation is required. diesel fuel, and biomass; ex-depot for refined Economic regulation typically sets prices or products and LPG; wholesale; and end-use. price ceilings for fairness. The price levels Prices of liquid biofuels may be controlled chosen are intended to enable the dominant by decisions outside the energy sector. Price companies to earn reasonable returns on their ceilings allow the level of competition to be investments but not exorbitant profits. 12 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES gauged—if the prices observed are all at the as a disincentive to following market prices price ceiling, either the price ceiling is too low in a timely manner. or there is inadequate competition. Provided the price ceiling is set at a level that would allow efficient fuel suppliers to compete on price, BOX 2: PRICE CONTROL IN AN the degree of departure from the price ceiling OFFICIALLY DEREGULATED MARKET suggests the degree of price competition in Without any overt government intervention, the market. Another form of price control prices may still be unofficially controlled. An is freight equalization, whereby transport example is freezing of the producer price of costs are equalized throughout a certain LPG sold in 13-kilogram (kg) cylinders in Brazil geographical area through a complex system between December 2002 and September 2015, fixed at R$0.87 (varying between of cross-subsidies, sometimes accompanied by US$0.25 and US$0.55 depending on the a small fee to pay for freight. To that end the exchange rate) per kg before tax—significantly government may set up a freight equalization below the import-parity level for this net LPG fund, which is often open to abuse. importer. Price controls may be restricted to certain grades of the same fuel (for example, the price Pricing principles for fuels may be imprecise, of low-octane gasoline may be controlled vague, or absent, leading to ad hoc pricing. and subsidized, whereas that of high-octane The pricing formula may be generic, open- gasoline may be deregulated), the size of ended (with many unspecified cost elements), individual sale (the price of LPG sold in 12-kg or both. Even if there is a well-defined cylinders may be set but not that of LPG sold pricing formula, pricing principles may be in larger cylinders), or consumer category subject to socioeconomic considerations. (prices of natural gas for the fertilizer industry Such considerations are usually invoked to and district heating utilities may be subsidized depart from the stated pricing principles or but gas sellers and buyers may be allowed regulations to forgo price increases, leading to negotiate over prices of natural gas for to revenue shortfalls for fuel suppliers. petrochemicals, and similarly diesel fuel for public passenger transport, agriculture, and One issue common to all fuels is the question fishing boats may be offered subsidized diesel of pass-through: whether fluctuations in fuel but not other purchasers). international fuel prices and exchange rates are automatically passed through to end- Prices may be deregulated in principle but consumers. This is important for internationally controlled in practice (box 2). Identifying traded fuels that are sold on the domestic these cases requires a detailed examination market, including fuel inputs for electricity and of price history at several points along the district heating. It is not uncommon for the supply chain. Unofficial price controls usually pass-through principle to be stated but not take the form of government pressure on fuel implemented in times of rising international suppliers, especially SOEs. If fuel suppliers fuel prices in local currency. have to obtain authorization for price increases, the government can influence price levels by While adoption of an automatic pricing delaying authorization. Even the requirement mechanism based on a formula that covers to seek authorization in the first place acts reasonably and prudently incurred costs may 3. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO FUELS 13 be a step in the right direction in subsidy collapse of 2014, Argentina imposed high reform, it does not fully “depoliticize” price- export duties on crude oil; in 2015 the setting. As long as a government agency is government unusually kept domestic crude applying the formula and announcing prices, oil prices artificially high to make up for the government can still come under political past losses and attract investment. The pressure to stop applying the formula in Russian Federation has historically imposed times of rising world fuel prices. Automatic relatively high export duties on crude oil price adjustment mechanisms have been and refined products, especially gasoline, abandoned in a number of countries for this to keep domestic prices artificially low. The reason, such as in the first half of 2015 when duties are changed once a month, based on some fuel prices on the world market rose by well-defined formulas—an exception to the as much as 50 percent. non-quantitative rules commonly employed elsewhere. In both cases, this consumer TRADE RESTRICTIONS subsidy increases government revenue and punishes producers. A very large export Trade restrictions benefit consumers or duty is tantamount to an export ban, and producers. Trade restrictions tend not to be can have a larger effect on domestic prices based on quantitative rules, although there than an outright ban. are exceptions. • Export ban. An export ban is designed to • Import duty. Relatively high import duties keep domestic prices low. Absent the ban, protect domestic fuel suppliers from fuels would be exported in search of higher competition and benefit the government prices on the world market. Kazakhstan has budget. A country with inefficient and high- made extensive use of an export ban on cost domestic refinery (typically partly or diesel fuel and other petroleum products in fully state-owned) may impose a higher the recent past, and China had a temporary import duty on petroleum products than on ban on diesel fuel in 2011. crude oil to protect the refinery. Consumers pay through higher domestic prices. PURCHASE OR SUPPLY MANDATE • Import ban. An import ban on all firms other A domestic purchase requirement is intended than the fuel producer is another form of to guarantee a market for domestic producers, producer protection. The most common and introduced when buying from the specified example is the government’s granting producers is more costly. A blanket requirement import licenses only to the refiners in the that only fuels from domestic suppliers be country, so that they do not face competition purchased is a form of producer support. from independent importers. A historical Kenya used to have such a requirement for example is Mexico, although the August its (now defunct) refinery. 2014 Hydrocarbons Law stipulates that gasoline and diesel imports be liberalized A domestic supply obligation is common by no later than January 1, 2017. for natural gas and is imposed typically in a country where the government keeps domestic • Export duty. An export duty that is large gas prices below export parity. There are and out of line with those on other goods also similar cases with coal in coal-exporting is a consumer subsidy. Until the oil price 14 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES countries. The domestic supply obligation This note uses net-of-tax unit reference and may be written into the license to produce local market prices to compute price gaps. hydrocarbons, and an export license may be Net-of-tax prices are the relevant metrics granted only on condition that the supply so as to distinguish price subsidies from obligation is met. In imposing a domestic tax expenditures, and to enable like-with- supply obligation, the government is often like comparison with prices in comparator most concerned to keep gas prices to the countries. Taxes being netted out do not power sector low. The net result is a cross- include corporate income tax and other subsidy, whereby domestic consumers benefit direct taxes paid by fuel suppliers (or else from artificially low prices, cross-subsidized by calculations would become intractably export profits and, in the case of natural gas, complex), but capture such indirect taxes as possibly by upstream oil profits in addition. import duties, excise duties, VAT, and general consumption tax. PRICE GAP Where there is a flourishing black market, the The foregoing section covered how fuel prices official price gap could be considerably larger may be higher or lower due to government than the actual price gap. The official gap intervention than if they are determined by affects the subsidy bill, while the actual price market forces in the presence of adequate gap faced by consumers could be substantially competition, resulting in price subsidies for smaller or even negative, decreasing the consumers or producers. Arguably the most adverse impact of price subsidy reform on commonly applied method in quantifying price end-users. Positive price gaps signal consumer subsidies is the so-called price-gap approach. support, while negative price gaps could It attempts to quantify the difference between denote producer support. For fuels, artificially the price set by the government or the price high prices are much rarer than artificially charged by the fuel seller (depending on the low prices. It is important to note that the circumstances) and the price prevailing in a number of units subsidized is not the same as competitive market (without government that consumed by the intended beneficiaries. intervention in pricing, price collusion, Fuel consumption may occur even outside and market concentration). The price gap the country: official prices that are lower than multiplied by the total units subsidized gives those in neighboring countries can lead to out- the total value of subsidies: smuggling, sometimes conducted on a large scale, resulting in a portion of subsidized fuel being consumed outside the country. Subsidy= (adjusted net-of-tax reference unit price – local net-of-tax unit price) x units subsidized = ( Price gap ) x units subsidized 3. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO FUELS 15 There are several factors that illustrate how tax, computing net-of-tax prices may be complex these calculations may become. straightforward. If, however, several taxes are levied, complications can arise. If there • The fewer the number of places where prices are local taxes that differ significantly from are controlled, the easier the calculations. location to location, computing net-of- If there is only one refinery in the country, tax prices back from end-user prices may and prices are controlled only at the refinery become very complex. gate, reference and local prices need to be calculated only at the refinery. Accurate • Fuels with multi-tier pricing (different prices information on the quantities sold should depending on end use) require volume also be available. By contrast, if end-user differentiation by end use, for which credible prices are controlled and are location- information may not be available. specific, there will be multiple local unit • Calculations have to be repeated if there prices. Data on quantities sold at each are several grades of a given fuel, such as location may not be available. three different octane numbers for gasoline • Even if there is a single price for the entire or viscosity and sulfur levels for fuel oil. country, reference unit prices differ by Complications are amplified if prices are location. Remote areas lacking economies further differentiated by end use. of scale, for example, will be much more costly to supply than concentrated urban In most studies, it is likely that many centers, especially if such urban centers are simplifying assumptions will have to be made. close to sources of supply. Information on Uncertainties in calculation results are likely to volumes associated with different reference be correspondingly large, suggesting caution prices may be difficult to obtain. in interpreting the calculated price gaps. One implication is that small price gaps maybe • Freight equalization requires estimation of within calculation uncertainties and do not transportation costs, which are location- necessarily denote consumer or producer specific, and volumes transported. support. • If the government sets price ceilings rather If producers are cross-subsidizing across than price levels, the actual prices charged different fuels, negative price gaps for may be different from the ceilings. In a certain fuels may be used to offset losses subsidizing environment actual prices may from price subsidies for other fuels. In such be at the price ceilings, but it is also possible cases, negative price gaps may not represent that some firms, such as state-owned fuel producer subsidies. Judging where such cross- distributors, come under political pressure subsidies exist requires some knowledge of to sell below the price ceilings, possibly the fuel sector. suffering even larger financial losses. A more likely situation is that price ceilings are not Where subsidized fuels are diverted to black adjusted frequently enough, resulting in markets or smuggled out of the country—two sporadic periods of price subsidies. forms of commercial malpractice that primarily affect liquid fuels—estimation of actual units • Fuel taxes may be difficult to net out. If there consumed is virtually impossible by the very is only an ad valorem tax or one specific clandestine nature of these illegal activities. 16 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES The total value estimated using the official price data. It is important to identify the net price and officially reported consumption trade status of each fuel—several large net therefore exaggerates the actual value of crude oil exporters are net importers of refined price subsidy received by the intended products (almost always because of a long beneficiaries on two accounts: higher prices history of fuel price subsidies), for which actually paid by these beneficiaries, and a import-parity prices, and not export-parity, smaller volume actually purchased. However, should be used. Prices should be adjusted the (overestimated) total value may match for fuel quality, importantly octane number the budgetary transfers to fuel suppliers. In for gasoline and, if possible, sulfur content for extreme cases, subsidy reimbursement bills fuel oil, diesel, and gasoline (listed in order of are submitted to the government by firms decreasing importance). that did not sell subsidized fuels, resulting in fictitious consumption inflating apparent Quite a few papers speak of domestic retail demand. prices being below “international” prices. Such statements reflect a misunderstanding The next sections discuss the issues to of world fuel markets. FOB prices are the only consider in calculating price gaps for liquid international fuel prices. Calculating the rest fuels, natural gas, and coal, and appliances of the costs along the supply chain is market- and equipment needed to use fuels. specific and can be challenging.3 Costs to be added include profit margins in addition to REFINED PRODUCTS, THEIR costs for shipping, storage, pipeline/rail/road ALTERNATIVES, AND LPG transportation, retail, and, in the case of LPG, bottling and cylinder management costs. Liquid fuels are global commodities with only All of these costs depend on economies of minor differences in quality and free-on-board scale, the state of infrastructure (roads, rail, (FOB) prices across different regions of the pipelines, ports), terrain, distances, and other world. As such, computing price gaps calls for factors. Unless detailed studies are carried less subjectivity than for coal or natural gas. out, simplifying assumptions will have to be made, making it likely that only relatively For importing countries, the reference price large price gaps can be identified. There estimation starts with import-parity prices, are, however, qualitative indications of price and conversely it starts with export-parity subsidies, which could help identify areas for prices for net exporters. FOB prices of major further investigation: refined products (gasoline, kerosene, diesel, and fuel oil) and LPG in major markets (U.S. • Relative prices may be inconsistent with Gulf Coast, northwestern Europe, Persian Gulf, economies of scale (for example, LPG sold and Singapore for petroleum fuels; and Persian in small cylinders having a unit price that Gulf, Algeria, North Sea, and U.S. state of Texas is the same as, or lower than, that for LPG for LPG) can be obtained through public and sold in larger cylinders or bulk LPG sale). industry sources, such as the U.S. Energy This would signal cross-subsidies in addition Information Administration, which makes to overall subsidies that may be present. spot prices in the United States available for • The same fuel may have different prices free, and Platts and Argus, which require paid depending on end-use that cannot be subscriptions to the publications containing 3. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO FUELS 17 explained by economies of scale alone, sugarcane-based ethanol, the alternative signaling cross-subsidies. market for the feedstock is sugar. For maize to ethanol, the alternative market is food and • A given fuel may have prices that are animal feed. For plant oil to biodiesel, the the same or similar, independently of the alternative markets are food, detergents, and distance from the source of supply, signaling pharmaceuticals. Their costs should be based spatial cross-subsidies. on these economic opportunity costs, and not • Freezing of prices for weeks or months on only the actual production costs. Not factoring end at one point in the supply chain, such in their economic opportunity costs would be as ex-refinery or wholesale, would signal equivalent to not considering international temporal cross-subsidies at a minimum. prices of crude oil and refined products in countries that are net exporters of petroleum • Very large differences in fuel prices that are oil, and instead using production costs—which out of proportion to the quality differences could be much lower in times of high world oil (such as regular gasoline being considerably prices. Because biofuels blended in gasoline cheaper than premium gasoline) would and diesel are almost universally subsidized signal a price subsidy for the cheaper fuel (through mandates, price support, and tax and a cross-subsidy provided by the more expenditures), examination of consumer and expensive grade. producer support for biofuels is important for many governments. • A “self-financing” fuel price stabilization fund should be investigated as a matter of routine, as described in more detail on NATURAL GAS AND COAL page 25. In Thailand, where the government Natural gas and coal are traded across borders exercises a measure of control over retail less frequently than liquid fuels, making prices using an oil fund, the government computation of price gaps more challenging. began heavily subsidizing fuels in the run-up Where there is cross-border trade, import- to the presidential election in 2011, and or export-parity prices would be a good when it came under criticism, it stopped starting point, as with liquid fuels. In such publishing the fund balance, which it had cases, significant trade restrictions—such as previously made public every month (Kojima a ban on exports without meeting a domestic 2013). supply obligation first—are likely to signal • Domestic refineries may be too small and domestic prices being kept artificially low. lack conversion capacity to be competitive. Small hydroskimming refineries4 may be Although growing, cross-border trade in uneconomic and require protection for natural gas—using pipelines or in the form survival. The presence of such refineries may of liquefied natural gas (LNG)—is still much suggest producer support for the refinery. less common in developing countries than trade in oil products, and globally cross-border Some countries add biofuels to gasoline and trade in coal is even less common. In countries diesel. Calculating their benchmark prices with no cross-border trade, one indication of needs to take into account the fact that price support may be a substantial supply feedstocks used to produce first-generation shortfall in the presence of consumers who biofuels have alternative markets. For are willing and able to pay more than the 18 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES official price. To estimate the price gap in such are two possible conclusions: either it does circumstances, there are several options for not make economic sense to develop and the reference price. use that domestic fuel, or pricing the fuel at the level of the most likely lowest-cost • Price of a most likely lowest-cost alternative. alternative is not appropriate. The risk with For example, if natural gas is consumed selecting the first approach is the possibility primarily in baseload power generation, and of creation of a single-fuel economy (namely the cheapest alternative for comparable the least-cost fuel) with no diversification service delivery is coal, the equivalent gas and hence exposure to a significant price price that would make a power producer risk. For example, the first approach could be indifferent between coal and natural gas interpreted as suggesting that any gas price could be taken as the reference price of gas. above the coal-equivalent alternative is a Calculations to arrive at the price should subsidy and that subsidy reform would mean take all costs into account—capital and all turning away from domestic gas to coal, while operating costs, and not just fuel costs. there may be many reasons to keep domestic In this example, the calculated cost is the natural gas in the portfolio: diversification, price of gas at the power plant gate that supply security, and environmental benefits would make a power generation company of natural gas over coal, to name a few. indifferent between coal and natural gas. The wellhead prices can be calculated on Pipeline tariffs are subject to economic a netback basis, subtracting pipeline and regulation for natural monopolies. Main cost processing costs from the power plant gate drivers include the pipeline diameter, distance, price. Prices elsewhere along the supply terrain, and utilization factor. Calculating price chain can be similarly computed. subsidies for pipeline tariffs is likely to require a dedicated study. Information on rail tariff • Likely price of imported natural gas or subsidies for coal is best obtained from the coal. Even if there are no imports today, a rail authorities. likely import price presents another option. • Cost-plus. The reference price may be set at SUBSIDY FOR START-UP COSTS a level that would cover efficiently incurred costs. Cost-plus from the lowest-cost gas Subsidies for the initial uptake of a fuel—most fields or coal mines represents the floor, or commonly natural gas and LPG—can also be else no gas or coal would be delivered to quantified using price gaps. Many households the domestic market. One problem with cannot pay the cost of the initial connection cost-plus alone is that it removes market to natural gas, and to a lesser extent the cost signals that might have told investors when of the LPG cylinder deposit fee and the to stop investing in projects that would not purchase price of an LPG cook stove. The be economic if left to market forces. cost of a high-pressure kerosene stove, which can burn as cleanly as an LPG stove, is also Which reference price would make most a barrier for many households. There are sense depends on how these prices compare. fundamental differences between start-up For example, if the price of a most likely subsidies for natural gas and those for LPG lowest-cost alternative is too low to recover or kerosene (box 3). costs (that is, lower than cost-plus), there 3. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO FUELS 19 BOX 3: START-UP COSTS FOR DIFFERENT FORMS OF ENERGY Because they are not recurring costs, start-up subsidies are generally considered more sustainable than fuel price subsidies. However, they are not efficient if the subsidized consumers cannot afford to pay for the operating costs; the relationship between start-up costs and monthly fuel bills can affect the efficiency of the subsidy. For natural gas and electricity, many households who find consumption of natural gas or electricity affordable find the initial connection fees unaffordable. This is because the upfront cost is considerably higher than the monthly payment for consumption, sometimes being orders of magnitude larger than monthly bills. As a result, connection subsidies can be effective in enabling consumption of gas or electricity. One option is to include assets associated with new connections in gas distribution companies’ regulatory assets and recover costs from all customers, especially since there is no compelling argument for separating network assets and service connections By contrast, the relationship between start-up costs and monthly fuel bill is quite different for LPG. The cost of an LPG cylinder deposit fee may be only 2-4 times higher than the monthly cost of cooking with LPG. A household that cannot pay US$35 for the cylinder deposit fee may have trouble paying US$15 a month for LPG refill. The much smaller difference between the start-up cost of LPG and monthly fuel costs substantially reduces the number of households that can benefit from the start-up subsidy, as experience with one such subsidy program (called the Deepam scheme) in Andhra Pradesh, India, has shown (Rajakutty and others 2002). Some governments provide free start-up kits, HOW MANY SUPPLIERS RECEIVE such as a single burner that sits atop a small- COMPENSATION? size LPG cylinder (say, 3–6 kg). The companies subsidizing start-up costs are best placed The smaller the number of suppliers on whom to provide the data. As mentioned earlier, the direct subsidy incidence falls, the easier subsidized cylinders and stoves offered as loss it may be to administer the subsidy, but leaders to attract new customers on a strictly possibly at the expense of growing market business basis are not considered subsidies. concentration. Consider two contrasting cases. In the first, there is one national oil company through which all price subsidies for refined PRICE SUBSIDY DELIVERY products are channeled. The company is MECHANISM reimbursed for the price gap, and any other How price subsidies are delivered affects the company wishing to enter the market has to extent of subsidy effectiveness and leakage. compete with subsidized fuels. In such There are also unintended consequences, circumstances, the national oil company will ranging from criminal activities to the fuel be a monopoly supplier. Not facing any sector languishing for investment and falling competition, there is little incentive to into disrepair. maximize efficiency and minimize costs. Worse, market concentration tends to perpetuate price subsidies, because price deregulation would be undesirable if there is inadequate competition, as a result of which the government feels compelled to maintain price control. In the second case, any licensed 20 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES importer is authorized to apply for subsidy unfavorable to the importer, resulting in losses. reimbursement and participate in the market. If foreign exchange is rationed, fuel sellers may This approach potentially reduces market not have ready access to the official rate and concentration, but confirming delivery of the parallel market rate may make imports subsidized fuel to the intended end-users much more expensive. Even a small difference arguably becomes more challenging when can lead to a large loss if the volume involved the government has to monitor dozens of is large. (b) Benchmark prices are lower than firms (box 4). what the fuel supplier paid in practice—for example, if benchmark prices are based on large cargos while the country imports in BOX 4: RAPID GROWTH OF small parcels. (c) Payment arrears owed by CERTIFIED FUEL SUPPLIERS the government cause cash-flow problems and increase total costs to fuel suppliers. (d) The number of eligible importers entitled to reimbursement for the gasoline subsidy in Costs allowed for reimbursement have been Nigeria increased sharply from six in 2006 to fixed for years in nominal terms, not adjusted 140 by 2011 (Nigeria 2012), prompting several for inflation, and are now too low. government investigations after charges of fraud had been brought. Firms with no access In some cases, producers are not compensated. to import terminals, storage facilities, and retail outlets managed to register officially, If private producers are not compensated made claims, and received reimbursements. for long, they eventually leave the market— uncompensated losses suffered by oil companies led two private firms, Reliance and Essar, to shut down all their retail outlets HOW IS COMPENSATION TO PRODUCERS DETERMINED? in India at one point, because the government policy was to compensate only state-owned oil How the reimbursement amount is calculated firms. Because SOEs do not have the option can be a gray area. Even where there is a of leaving, and even they are not necessarily precise mathematical formula, certain cost adequately compensated, contingent liabilities elements are location-specific and likely to can grow. In some countries, free or heavily be self-reported by the suppliers. This is discounted fuels, cross-subsidized by upstream all the more so when there is only one or profits, are provided as intermediate goods. just a handful of companies involved in the For example, the Egyptian General Petroleum subsidy delivery. It would also not be in the Corporation has historically received free crude interest of any fuel supplier to suggest that oil and natural gas as part of its production current reimbursements are adequate, let sharing contracts (Kojima 2016). Diesel fuel for alone generous, lest the government starts power generation, which accounted for one- cutting back on reimbursements. Where there fourth of total diesel consumption, was free are serious questions about reasonableness of in Angola as of 2015 (IMF 2015). The power the costs cited by fuel suppliers, a dedicated sector in Côte d’Ivoire receives free natural study may be needed. Reimbursements are gas based on the government’s 15-percent often contested for a number of reasons, some equity share in domestic gas fields (Trimble examples of which follow. (a) The exchange and others 2016). The state-owned refineries rate used to convert to local currency units is in Algeria and Tunisia have been purchasing domestic crude oil at heavily discounted, 3. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO FUELS 21 fixed prices (Kojima 2016). These prices can implementation challenges, because restricting be compared to economic opportunity costs the quantity of subsidized fuel makes diversion to arrive at the scale of price subsidies. It is all the more financially attractive. And the more important not to count these subsidies twice: complicated the allocation of the subsidized as fuel input subsidies for the power sector or fuel (for example, the quantity depending on crude oil subsidy for refining first, and then as several household-specific factors), the more power subsidies or refined product subsidies difficult the verification and subsidy delivery. the second time. There are many approaches, some examples of which are given below. IS COMPENSATION SELF- • Universal price subsidy for households, ADMINISTERED BY FUEL irrespective of income status, with or SUPPLIERS? without quantity limits per household or A unique case of compensation occurs when per person. a state-owned fuel supplier, say a national • Price subsidy only for certain consumers. oil company, provides subsidized fuels for Eligibility criteria may be classification which there is no budgetary allocation, and as officially poor, disabled, historically then deducts the subsidy amount from the disadvantaged, or living in a remote and dividends the company is supposed to transfer economically depressed area; no connection to the government. The budget may show to electricity (for kerosene subsidy); no zero fuel subsidy, and there may be no tax connection to a gas pipeline (for LPG expenditure. The government revenue is subsidy); fishing boats; taxis and buses; reduced, but because calculation of the national automotive fuel subsidy for certain engine oil company’s dividends is not part of the sizes (say small ones belonging to less budget or tax analysis, this self-administered well-off consumers); power plants, fertilizer compensation largely escapes scrutiny, with manufacturers, petrochemicals, and any few in the government even being aware of other industry considered strategic. the subsidy delivery mechanism. • Price subsidy for appliances used by the IS SUBSIDIZED FUEL RATIONED? lesser well-off, such as a kit consisting of a small burner on top of a small LPG cylinder. Rationing of subsidized fuels is another policy decision. Subsidized kerosene and LPG used • Subsidies only for those consuming less than for cooking and lighting fuels are usually a capped amount per month (administration restricted: only households are eligible, in some of which is possible with natural gas). cases only poor households, and there could In the past, paper vouchers and cards were also be monthly limits. While intended for used to ration subsidies. More recently, pro-poor use of limited government budget, electronic forms of record keeping and delivery rationing also creates lucrative opportunities have been increasingly used. They should be for black marketing. better at reducing leakages, although Rationing enables targeting of subsidies, implementation challenges remain, especially making them more efficient in principle. for liquid fuels (box 5). Smart cards combined At the same time, rationing adds to the with electronic banking can be used to reduce 22 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES government interference in the market by absence of subsidies, and the political pressure lifting price control and enabling targeted to increase the size of the lifeline block. subsidies to be delivered directly to consumers (say through direct bank deposits) for their IS THERE A FUEL PRICE fuel purchases. However, the knowledge that STABILIZATION FUND? consumers are being compensated for high prices would affect the behavior of fuel Price stabilization funds often develop suppliers, who feel less pressure to keep prices large deficits, which are eventually filled by as low as possible. budgetary transfers. The idea of charging more when world fuel prices are low and using the savings to subsidize prices when world BOX 5: SMART CARDS FOR fuel prices are high has an intuitive appeal. It RATIONING suggests the possibility that the government can moderate the transmission of world price Paper vouchers and cards are susceptible volatility to the domestic market at little or to large-scale fraud. Thanks to advances in technology, smart cards can tackle many no budgetary cost. The basic idea is to have problems associated with a system based on a floor and a ceiling for the domestic price. paper. But where there are powerful financial When the world price is low, the difference incentives, people have been known to find between the market-based price and the floor ways to defraud the system. The government of Malaysia, one of the earliest adopters of (over-recovery) is set aside. The savings so smart cards, has openly and repeatedly accumulated are used to subsidize domestic acknowledged abuses at every level of the prices when the market-based price exceeds supply chain in the form of diversion of low- the ceiling (under-recovery). The premise price fuels for illegal uses. Smart cards are used to control sales of subsidized fuels to of such a scheme being self-financing rests public transport operators and fishers, but the critically on fuel prices (typically refined government has admitted their ineffectiveness. products) reverting to a mean on a fairly In June 2014, for example, the Public Accounts regular basis, so that under-recoveries are Committee said in a press conference that the fleet card for diesel for public transport followed by over-recoveries frequently. If, operators could be used by anyone to buy instead, there is a long period of steady an unlimited supply of diesel fuel (Bernama price increases or high prices, punctuated Daily 2014). by periodic price collapses, there would be a long period of a growing deficit, which has to be paid for by other means. There is an important difference between liquid fuels and energy distributed through The movement of the oil price level over the a network (natural gas, district heating, and past 15 years indicates that a mean-reversion electricity). As long as each consumer is model has not held, and price stabilization accurately metered, rationing can be precisely funds have virtually universally failed to achieve targeted with the latter, because, unlike liquid their original objectives without incurring large fuels, it is essentially impossible to store and fiscal costs. This confirms the experience of transport subsidized natural gas for diversion. developed countries earlier in the aftermath The two main challenges are the high upfront of the first oil price shock of 1973, when many costs of the initial connection to the network, governments tried to dampen price volatility. deterring the poor from connection in the These governments soon found that their 3. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO FUELS 23 interventions to smooth price volatility on the Faced with financial losses, fuel suppliers may world market were costly, and abandoned cut spending on required maintenance. It is not them. unusual for there to be a large gap between installed nameplate capacity and actual If there are budgetary transfers to top up operational capacity in refining and pipelines, the fund, it is likely to receive scrutiny. An and this is one reason some large crude oil alternative scenario is that there are no exporters with historically large subsidies and budgetary transfers but the fund is not doing large-enough markets to enjoy economies of much to smooth price volatility, and in some scale (such as the Islamic Republic of Iran, cases it effectively serves to amplify it—in Iraq, and Nigeria) have become net importers times of high world oil prices, the fund is of refined products. In upstream oil and gas, already exhausted; in times of low oil prices, facing an unattractive investment environment, as the fund starts building reserves, they are investors may increasingly shift funding to drawn down to subsidize prices and make low other countries. Oil and gas exploration and prices even lower on the domestic market, development decline. In some cases former as in Vietnam in 2015 (Kojima 2016). These hydrocarbon net exporters with substantial observations suggest that there are large remaining reserves have turned into importers. opportunity costs associated with government interventions targeting significant price Because of the inability of refineries to smoothing, if not creation of more market invest in unit upgrades to produce cleaner distortions. Costs and the perceived benefits of fuels and policies in place to protect them such smoothing schemes should be weighed from competition from imports, fuel quality against those of other alternative uses of the standards can lag behind those in developed same financial resources. countries by years or even decades. In some countries the octane number of gasoline is UNINTENDED CONSEQUENCES OF markedly lower than what is acceptable for FUEL PRICE SUBSIDIES modern ignition engines. Similarly, fuel sulfur levels may be high enough to deactivate Declining Sector Performance catalytic converters and other exhaust control devices. Price subsidies discourage investment because investors fear that there may not be a level Commercial Malpractice playing field (such as the government’s favoring state-owned fuel suppliers over Diversion to black markets and smuggling private companies) and reimbursements may is financially attractive as long as prices are be late, inadequate, or both. The whole sector kept low, and especially easy for liquid fuels. may decay over time if subsidized prices Fishing boats are ideally suited for smuggling are below economic opportunity costs, let subsidized fuels provided to fisheries. The alone supply costs; if reimbursements are government of Malaysia announced in 2012 perpetually late, inadequate, or both; and if that state inspectors would start verifying subsidies are channeled through one or only catch from time to time to ensure that the a handful of companies facing no effective operators of fishing boats were fishing and competition. not smuggling diesel fuel (Kojima 2016). Illegal financial gains also create powerful 24 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES vested interest groups determined to entrench state in the country, and provides concrete price subsidies so that they can continue to evidence that consumers are paying prices far benefit (illegally). And seeing poor governance in excess of the official subsidized price (box in the sector (if not a race to the bottom), 6). The gasoline price survey data collected respectable firms do not enter the market, helped push for gasoline pricing reform in perpetuating corruption and inefficiency. May 2016. These financial incentives are so powerful that various schemes designed to prevent Amplification of Fuel and Power Sector illegal diversion are seldom successful. Subsidies Kerosene is a nearly perfect substitute for Where fossil fuels are used in power generation, diesel fuel, and a price difference between the power sector subsidies combined with fuel two in favor of kerosene can lead to widespread subsidies can aggravate an already precarious adulteration of diesel by kerosene. Subsidized financial viability for both sectors. As an LPG is an attractive fuel for restaurants illustration, if power tariffs are too low for and hotels, prompting some to engage in cost recovery, generation companies may not large-scale diversion from the residential to be able to pay gas producers even when gas commercial sectors. Subsidized low-octane prices are kept artificially low. A combination gasoline may be sold as unsubsidized higher- of growing payment arrears and low gas octane gasoline or used to adulterate it, and prices discourages investment in the gas subsidized gasoline and diesel for public sector, leading to gas shortages. Gas shortages passenger transportation may similarly be in turn reduce the load factor in electricity sold on the black market. generation, thereby increasing the unit cost of generation. The unit cost of electricity Higher Prices supply and the price gap in the power sector rise further, making it even more difficult to Late subsidy reimbursements combined with pay gas producers. This scenario has played diversion to black markets and smuggling out in Nigeria, which has the ninth largest have created serious fuel shortages in some natural gas reserves in the world (Oil and Gas countries. Fuel shortages raise prices and harm Journal 2016). Despite plentiful gas, Nigeria the economy, while subsidies are captured suffers from chronic and acute gas shortages, by criminal elements. In the extreme, fuel caused in part by growing nonpayment for gas importers cannot raise letters of credit and (World Bank 2015). Gas shortages in turn have have to pay cash upfront, exacerbating fuel caused severe power shortages throughout shortages further. The National Bureau of the economy and further reduced the power Statistics in Nigeria conducts surveys of sector’s financial viability. gasoline, kerosene, and diesel prices in every 4. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO ELECTRICITY 25 BOX 6: COMMERCIAL MALPRACTICE IN KEROSENE TRADE IN NIGERIA For years, the price of kerosene for household use was set at N50 (US$0.17) per liter, until it was raised to N83 (US$0.42 at the time, but now US$0.26) per liter in January 2016. The government deregulated the price of diesel several years ago. The National Bureau of Statistics has been conducting monthly price surveys of gasoline, kerosene, and diesel in the 36 states and the Federal Capital Territory. Because world prices of kerosene and diesel are very close, it is informative to compare the actual prices paid for the two fuels. The results are shown below. Kerosene price survey, naira per liter Diesel price survey, naira per liter 800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 7 6 6 16 6 6 6 17 7 17 7 6 6 16 6 6 6 7 7 17 -1 -1 -1 -1 -1 -1 -1 -1 -1 -1 -1 -1 -1 -1 -1 b- n- n- n- n- pr ug ug pr ct pr ec b ct ug pr ec b ug b Ju Ju Fe Ju Fe Ju Fe Fe O A O A A A D D A A A A Min Max Average Source: http://www.nigerianstat.gov.ng/. It is immediately clear that if the kerosene subsidy were to be abolished, consumers would pay less than they are paying today, and virtually all price subsidies are captured by those engaged in illegal diversion of subsidized kerosene, creating severe kerosene shortages and pushing up prices paid by households to levels markedly above what a free market might deliver. 4. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO ELECTRICITY The word subsidies tends to be used firms that have gone bankrupt are usually more loosely in the power sector, often not considered to have been “subsidized” by interchangeably with a lack of cost recovery. them. But the need for economic regulation The inability of a company to recover costs for electricity transmission and distribution— alone does not automatically signal the and hence government control of prices— existence of subsidies. As an analogy, in a raises the question of whether the regulated competitive market in which companies are tariffs may have been too low for the utilities free to set prices, some firms do not recover to recover costs, subsidizing consumers. A costs and go out of business, but consumers clear example is when tariff adjustments do who have purchased goods and services from not allow utilities to pass through fuel price 26 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES increases and currency depreciation (both If the focus is on fossil fuel subsidies, isolating of which are beyond the utilities’ control) to them in the power sector poses additional consumers. challenges: Cost recovery and affordability are two • If the power sector as a whole receives a net important price-related policy questions in subsidy, it could be difficult to assign the the power sector. A typical scenario is that of a net subsidy to different stages of the supply power utility not recovering costs for a number chain (generation, transmission, distribution, of reasons, resulting in increasing power auxiliary services, overhead administrative shortages, a need for budgetary transfers costs). Fuels consumed in the power sector (today or in the future), or both. Where utilities are used primarily in electricity generation. are not recovering costs and power outages If generation is fully recovering costs, but are frequent and long-lasting, the economy- transmission or distribution is not, is there wide effects can be substantial. In countries no subsidy for fossil fuels, or should the where many people still live without electricity, subsidies for transmission and distribution how to make electricity affordable is at the be prorated according to the share of fossil heart of the effort to achieve universal access, fuels in generated power? including how to make subsistence electricity • If power generation consists of fossil fuels, consumption affordable to all poor people hydropower, solar power, and wind power, and the degree to which their consumption with feed-in tariffs for solar and wind power, can be cross-subsidized by others. disaggregating subsidies becomes all the more challenging. Some subsidies could Many governments are less concerned about make other forms of power generation whether the inability to achieve cost recovery is uneconomic. An example is the guaranteed a result of subsidies as defined at the beginning access to the grid granted to solar and of section 2 than understanding what factors wind power with guaranteed prices, making are responsible for the lack of cost recovery. natural gas uneconomic in certain European There also tends to be greater subjectivity in countries. Restoring financial viability to identifying subsidies in the power sector than those forms of generation that have become for fuels, because some factors that make uneconomic as an unintended consequence power utilities not financially viable do not of certain subsidies may call for creation of neatly fit the definition, “a deliberate policy additional subsidies. action by the government that specifically targets electricity … [that reduces] … the net • If generation using fossil fuels is not cost of [electricity] purchased.” For example, recovering costs because the transmission a power utility is most unlikely to cut off capacity is limited and power generation electricity to the military or the ministry plants have to cut back on generation, of power for nonpayment, but forbidding lowering the load factor and raising the disconnection in such cases is usually an unit cost of power generation, there may unspoken policy and not a “deliberate policy be little that generation companies can do action by the government.” to achieve cost recovery. Does this situation create a fossil fuel subsidy? 4. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO ELECTRICITY 27 Governments typically wish to gain a better them are examples of price distortions. A understanding of the subsidies for the lack of accurate metering that is a result of entire power sector, inclusive of all forms the utility’s operational inefficiencies would of generation. The question of fossil fuel not be considered a deliberate government subsidies in the power sector tends to arise action. However, where the practice of more in an international setting—such as the charging a fixed amount not linked to actual Group of Twenty or Asia-Pacific Economic consumption is accepted by the regulator, it Cooperation—than in domestic policy would be reasonable to consider such practice discussion. a deliberate government action. For example, there may be only two meters measuring PRICE DISTORTIONS electricity consumption for an entire village, one for all households and the other for all Price distortions for electricity typically arise farming activities. Even if tariffs recover costs— from deficient economic regulation in design, which frequently they do not—this means implementation, or both, and deficiencies in widespread cross-subsidization at a minimum. metering practices. Electricity is subject to economic regulation much more frequently TARIFF SETTING than liquid fuels and natural gas. Electricity transmission is a natural monopoly and is The dual question of whether tariffs are too always regulated. Some countries have a low to recover costs, and why costs exceed single vertically integrated state-owned utility, revenues, is important for assessing whether requiring economic regulation across the there are price subsidies in the power sector. supply chain. The regulation of distribution In virtually all countries, tariff reviews are varies greatly across countries, but in the conducted periodically, ranging from several developing world there tends to be much months to several years. Utilities make a tighter economic regulation than, for example, submission, there may be a public hearing and Finland.5 comment period, and decisions are announced by the regulator. The documents submitted for Along the supply chain, power generation tariff reviews vary in the level of detail; in some comes closest to delivering a market reference countries detailed spreadsheets showing costs price, which is the price that would prevail in the and calculations are submitted and posted on absence of government intervention in pricing, the utility’s or the regulator’s Web site. price collusion, and market concentration. As one illustration, market reference prices No regulator sets out under-recovery of costs for generation could be energy and capacity and eventual financial bailouts of power utilities charges at which investors would be willing as a stated policy goal. Utilities are intended to invest in the sector through auctions. to be financially viable, but many are not. They may be inefficiently run, making costs The failure to meter each individual consumer higher than necessary and revenues lower accurately results in consumers paying than what they could be. In addition, tariffs for electricity not consumed, not paying are frequently not at the cost recovery level: for electricity consumed, or paying prices they would not have paid had they been metered individually and accurately. All of 28 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES • The tariff reviews may not be conducted at setting. International experience suggests that the specified intervals, delaying the needed the degree of cost recovery from consumer tariff increases. payments depends largely on the level of development of the power sector. Where the • The review may conclude that tariffs need to sector is far from mature, the medium- to be raised, but the regulator may nevertheless long-term goal is to reach tariff levels that fully decide that, for a variety of socioeconomic cover all reasonably and prudently incurred reasons, this is not the time to be raising costs. If revenues fall far short, the first priority tariffs. for the utilities in the sector is to meet all • If tariff increases are subject to cabinet or cash obligations, which may be reduced by presidential approval, even if the regulator subsidies provided to the sector by various recommends tariff increases with ample means. These subsidies in turn may help justification, tariff adjustment could become improve the financial health of the utilities, politicized and the recommendation may but if significant subsidies are provided by be rejected. the government’s budget, they will threaten provision of other essential services and the • There may even be a provision for automatic government’s fiscal sustainability. price adjustments for fuel price and currency changes with regular frequency, but just Different levels of costs to be recovered may as with liquid fuel pricing, the so-called be characterized as follows: automatic price adjustments may not be • Level 1: Operating cost recovery. The so automatic and not implemented if they lowest level of cost recovery considers point to large tariff increases. only operating costs and minor repair expenses, but not capital costs (including COST RECOVERY major repairs). The threshold level above Cost recovery arguably attracts the most policy which repair expenses become capital costs attention and analysis in developing countries. is situation-specific. In most cases, level If costs are not being recovered, the funding 1 excludes depreciation, debts, bad debt gap may eventually have to be filled somehow allowance (allowance for collection losses through debt forgiveness, budgetary transfers, that will not be recovered), and other similar and other means. However, it is important to revenues and expenses that do not directly bear in mind that under-recovery of costs affect the utility’s cash flows. Operating cost by itself does not automatically translate to recovery is appropriate when the policy there being an energy subsidy. In the rest of question is whether the utility is financially this section, whether the under-recovery of sustainable for the purpose of operating its specific costs is an energy subsidy will need business in the short term. However, it does to be assessed in the light of the definition of not capture the full scope of price subsidies energy subsidies at the beginning of section as defined in this note. 2 and the subsidy categories outlined in table • Level 2: Operating and limited capital cost 2 and the annex. recovery The question of which costs should be recovered 2a. Inclusion of ongoing capital costs through revenue collection influences tariff and taxes. Also called the cash-needs 4. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO ELECTRICITY 29 approach, level 2a considers taxes and long-term system-wide optimization analysis the financing of ongoing capital costs is carried out to identify new investments. in addition to operating costs. This In the absence of such analysis, utility approach requires information about investment plans, the government’s strategic debt and equity financing, including documents, and other relevant plans may debt repayment schedule. Ongoing be used. capital costs alone may not enable • Level 4: Full cost recovery and capture continuing operation of currently of unpaid externalities. Level 4 includes operating assets if major repairs are externality costs of producing and delivering needed in the near term. electricity, such as the economic costs 2b. Inclusion of ongoing capital costs, taxes, of local air pollution and emissions of and near-term major repairs. Level 2b greenhouse gases. Because uninternalized adds to level 2a capital costs associated externalities are excluded in this note for with major repairs that are likely to the reasons cited in box 1, level 4 is not be undertaken in the near to medium applicable. term to keep on operating important existing assets. In summary, cost recovery at level 3 is the 2c. Inclusion of full replacement value subject of this note. Who pays for the various of existing assets. In the absence of cost components at level 3, what is the information about debt and equity magnitude of the costs not covered by the financing, costs of major future repairs, or utilities, and how much of that gap is the both, an alternative is to calculate the full government covering or will the government replacement value of the existing assets. eventually be asked to cover are the three In a country where supply falls far short key questions in subsidy analysis. Costs that of demand, as in every country in Sub- need to be covered by the utilities (net of Saharan Africa, level 2c approximates subsidies provided) are computed using utility the annual funding required to maintain financial analysis, and what the government is the current stock of assets. In countries covering or may eventually cover is computed where demand is stagnant or falling and using fiscal analysis. The sum of costs covered some units need to be decommissioned, by the utilities and the government do not level 2c needs to be modified to capture usually cover opportunity costs of goods decommissioning costs as well as the and services, external concessional financing, replacement value of assets that will subsidized goods and services provided by be maintained in the future to match foreign governments, and tax expenditures demand. not captured in fiscal analysis, all of which are captured in full analysis, as described below. • Level 3: Full cost recovery of operating and capital costs, including future investments. • Utility or power sector financial analysis. Level 3 adds to level 2c the capital and This financial analysis considers only the associated operating costs associated costs that the utility or the power sector with planned new investments for system needs to cover. Any subsidies provided expansion and modernization, prioritizing by the government are not captured investment projects as needed. Ideally, because the subsidies are funded out of the 30 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES government’s budget, and not the utilities’ tariffs, requiring the utility to seek concessional revenue. The analysis excludes depreciation, financing (grants, low-interest loans, long grace bad debt allowance (for routinely uncollected periods, partial risk guarantees) or budgetary revenue), and revaluation of assets. This type transfers for major capital expenditures. The of financial analysis is undertaken when the reality is that available concessional financing policy question is whether the utility or the and budgetary transfers to meet future power sector is financially viable. demand for electricity in most developing countries are far from sufficient. The hope • Fiscal analysis. Fiscal analysis addresses the is that future economic growth will increase overall cost of the power sector to the state, consumers’ ability to pay and eventually with the magnitude of the burden that the enable full cost recovery defined in column C. power sector is imposing on the government budget being an immediate priority. Fiscal By definition, costs are not recovered when analysis captures all budgetary transfers they are higher than revenues, but it does not to the utilities, forgone revenue (from necessarily mean that tariffs are too low. Cost providing subsidized goods and services), recovery can be attained by lowering costs, and contingent liabilities (such as risks borne increasing revenues, or doing both. Sustainable by the government on behalf of the power means of lowering costs (optimizing the sector or state-owned utilities). However, power system, and increasing the efficiency while it may be significant, fiscal burden of procurement, project execution, and represents only one aspect of subsidies. operation) and alternative means of increasing revenues (such as by increasing the bill • Full analysis. Full analysis considers all costs, collection rate and ensuring accurate metering including opportunity costs and provision and billing) can minimize the need for tariff of loans at below-market rates provided increases. Therefore, for all of the nine possible by international donors. Full analysis is sets of calculations in table 3, two sets of appropriate when the policy question is calculations can be performed. The first is the scale of the real cost of utility service to use costs and revenues as they are today. provision to the economy without donor The second is to compute costs and revenues support and trade restrictions (for fuels and at benchmark performance. The benchmark other goods sold at prices that are below performance may assume, amongst others, opportunity costs). Full analysis is what is a 100-percent bill collection rate, minimal needed to estimate subsidies. However, commercial losses, total technical losses of externally provided subsidies (subsidized (say) 8 percent, proper maintenance of all interest rates provided by donors) are units and equipment, replacement of aging sometimes omitted for the purpose of units in line with good industry practice, and policy analysis. developing the power infrastructure in line Table 3 summarizes the foregoing categories with long-term system-wide optimization. (excluding level 4). If cost recovery is used to Where to set the benchmark performance set tariffs, A2 and A3 in table 3 reduces the varies by country and the maturity of the short-term impact of capital expenditure on power market. 4. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO ELECTRICITY 31 TABLE 3: Types of Analysis for Cost Recovery A. Financial analysis B. Fiscal analysis C. Full analysis Level 1 A1: Only those operating B1: Operating costs that are C1: All operating costs, Operating costs that are covered covered on behalf of the irrespective of who bears cost by the utility (excluding utility by the government them, valued at opportunity recovery various reserves, such as through budgetary transfers costs depreciation, bad debt and provision of subsidized allowance, and revaluation goods and services of assets) Relevant Level 1 would not be analyzed in detail unless the utility Examination of input subsidies context or the sector is in poor financial state and cannot even valued at opportunity meet its cash needs (A2a below). Correspondingly, in such costs—such as domestically situations, government subsidies are provided for even produced fuels—is important the most basic of costs through budgetary transfers or in nearly all cases, but other provision of subsidized inputs, such as fuels. subsidies (such as external concessional financing or tax expenditures) are unlikely to attract attention in the face of the urgent need to cover basic operating costs. Level 2 A2: A1 plus taxes and any B2: B1 plus the capital costs C2: C1 plus capital costs at Operating capital costs as defined in covered through sovereign market-based rates and levels 2a, 2b, and 2c above funding/guarantee, assessed limited that are paid for by the at the expected weighted capital utility, such as debt service, average cost of capital cost required equity payments, incurred by the government recovery and internally funded (which may include investments, assessed at the concessional finance) expected weighted average cost of capital for the utility or the sector Relevant Also referred to as cash needs, A2a is the minimal revenue C2 would be the relevant context requirement for the utility’s financial viability. Level 2 metric for near to medium- would be relevant where the utility or the sector is already term analysis of subsidies in covering operating costs, and are at varying stages of many developing countries. meeting costs of asset maintenance, renewal, acquisition, or enhancement. Level 3 A3: A2 plus all omitted B3: B2 plus all omitted C3: C2 plus all omitted Full cost capital and associated capital and associated capital and associated recovery operating costs, including operating costs, including operating costs, including new of current the cost of financing new the cost of new investments investments and future investments costs Relevant Level 3 is relevant for long-term planning, or in countries C3 would be the relevant context with mature power sectors where most costs are already metric for full subsidy analysis. adequately covered by utilities with possible gaps for significant new investments (which may be needed to adapt to new technology even in markets where demand is stagnant or falling). Level 3 would also be relevant in a financially healthy sector with rapidly rising demand. However, there is subjectivity in deciding when to charge customers for major new investments. 32 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES HIDDEN COST ANALYSIS in hidden-cost analysis is a subsidy. Other hidden costs—corresponding to operational A useful concept in analyzing the gap between inefficiencies—are not necessarily subsidies, revenue and expenditures in the power sector unless they are covered using budgetary is a quasi-fiscal deficit, which is the difference transfers and other types of subsidies between the net revenue of an efficient utility described in table 2. That said, governments (where revenue is designated by Rbenchmark) are generally not concerned about what these and the net current revenue (Rcurrent). Quasi- factors contributing to quasi-fiscal deficits fiscal deficits can help distinguish between are called. Their main interest is to eliminate subsidies that can be reduced only by raising quasi-fiscal deficits so as to set the power tariffs and those that could be avoided by sector on a financially sustainable path over optimizing the power system and minimizing the long run. Elimination of subsidies is one operational inefficiencies (box 7). of the steps toward cost recovery, but not necessarily the only one. In the illustration in box 7, quasi-fiscal deficit is equal to underpricing plus transmission In carrying out the calculations, it is important and distribution losses + bill collection losses to include reasonable returns on equity. One + overstaffing. At benchmark performance, way of keeping power tariffs artificially low is the last three terms are zero, leaving only to limit the rate of return at a level so low as underpricing. Underpricing as calculated not to attract investment, such as 1 percent BOX 7: COMPONENTS OF HIDDEN COSTS A simplified example illustrates how the gap between revenue and expenditures may be decomposed into avoidable and unavoidable revenue shortfalls. Let capex designate benchmark capital expenditure, opex designate benchmark operating expenditure, and Q designate dispatched kilowatt hours (kWh). If the benchmark performance is defined as having combined system losses (technical and non-technical losses in transmission and distribution) of 10 percent and a bill collection rate of 100 percent, the tariff at benchmark performance, tariffbenchmark, becomes (capex + opex)/0.9Q and the revenue of an efficient utility is tariffbenchmark0.9Q, where 0.9 takes into account combined transmission, distribution, and billing losses of 10 percent. The revenue at current performance by contrast is tariffcurrentQ(0.9 – TDL)(1 – BL), where TDL is transmission and distribution losses in excess of 10 percent and BL is bill collection losses. Consider a simplified case where the only additional cost of current performance is overstaffing (that is, capital costs are the same and the operating costs are higher than opex by the cost of overstaffing only). The current cost is then capex + opex + overstaffing cost. Using  to designate unit tariff shortfall (tariffbenchmark – tariffcurrent), the quasi-fiscal deficit becomes Rbenchmark – (capex + opex) – {Rcurrent – (capex + opex + overstaffing)} = Overstaffing + tariffbenchmark  0.9Q – tariffcurrent  Q  (0.9 – TDL)  (1 – BL) = Overstaffing + tariffbenchmark  0.9Q – (tariffbenchmark – )  Q  (0.9 – TDL)  (1 – BL). The quasi-fiscal deficit can be decomposed into four hidden-cost components, defined as Q(0.9 – TDL)(1 – BL) + tariffbenchmarkQTDL + tariffbenchmarkQ(0.9 –TDL)  BL + Overstaffing. Underpricing System losses Bill collection losses 4. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO ELECTRICITY 33 in the distribution segment in one developing • Amounts billed and amounts collected country. should be available in financial statements. Subsidies in the form of direct transfers from While the last three terms are zero at the government or international donors benchmark performance, elimination of these may be reported. It is important to separate and other operational inefficiencies is not revenues specifically tied to electricity from costless. Setting aside underpricing, utilities such unrelated items as revenues earned have to incur additional expenditures to move from the sale of water for utilities that from their current quasi-fiscal deficit position provide both services. to the deficit position they would experience at benchmark performance. Identifying the • Fixed and variable operational and most cost-effective ways of doing so—starting maintenance expenditures as reported in with low-cost/high-return investments—would financial statements may not represent what require a separate study. Another cause of should have been spent. The utility may under-recovery is high costs of purchase when have growing payment arrears for fuels or utilities are not creditworthy. If the utility is other goods and services, may be skipping asked to pay cash upfront for fuels and has to essential maintenance and repair to cut borrow money to do so, financing costs could costs, or the government may be paying push up fuel prices considerably, widening directly for certain goods and services, the gap between current and benchmark bypassing the utility. Frequent, unscheduled quasi-fiscal deficits. power outages due to equipment failure may be an indication of inadequate expenditures DATA SOURCES on maintenance and repair. As explained in table 2, indirect taxes should be excluded Financial statements issued by utilities should from the calculations but direct taxes paid provide information on capital, operational, should be considered costs to the utilities. and maintenance expenditures, although • What assets capital expenditures should some utilities, and especially SOEs, have cover is arguably the most challenging. only scant, unaudited financial statements One simplified approach is to compute new that are several years out of date. Moreover, replacement values of current assets found in financial statements are on an accrual basis, utilities’ annual reports or the government’s introducing complications especially when database for the sector, annualized by the calculations are intended to be linked amortizing the asset value over a chosen to budgetary transfers, cash transfers, and period of time, such as the economic life of other payments assessed on a cash basis. the assets. However, especially in developing Utilities’ annual reports and the database countries, it is unlikely that all assets of the regulator or the ministry in charge (especially generation) would be replaced of the power sector can provide additional in the future as they exist today—nor should information, such as bill collection rates and they be if asset allocation is suboptimal. system losses. Utilities’ submissions for tariff Changes are likely, but it may be difficult to increases to the regulator can be another tell today whether four 50-megawatt diesel useful source of information. power plants will be replaced and absorbed by a single 500-megawatt combined-cycle 34 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES gas power plant, especially if that decision to large customers in most developing hinges on parallel development of fuel countries, making like-with-like comparison supply infrastructure, such as the start-up difficult. of a floating storage and regasification unit for LNG. Further, detailed information on CROSS-SUBSIDIES distribution assets for lines below 1 kilovolt is usually not available, requiring further In the power sector, cross-subsidies are far simplification or else use of the findings from more common than for liquid fuels. Cross- a detailed analysis elsewhere. Economies subsidies such as lifeline rates for the poor of scale influence the unit capex, as do the may enhance equity, but they can also cause asset location and creditworthiness of the economic distortions and even threaten the investor. Taking each of these factors into long-term sustainability of the users being account increases data requirements. cross-subsidized (such as low electricity tariffs for agriculture leading to excessive IMPACT OF SECTOR STRUCTURE use of irrigation and causing permanent water depletion). In a partially deregulated sector, The structure of the sector affects the risk of cross-subsidies are generally confined to double counting and the ease of estimation. regulated customers—deregulated customers can switch suppliers because they have a • If there is a single vertically integrated utility, choice, whereas regulated customers have all assets and costs are with that utility. no choice, even if they know that they are Generation, transmission, and distribution paying higher tariffs to cross-subsidize others. should be disaggregated to see where subsidies and operational inefficiencies Cross-subsidies may be across different may exist. tariff categories (agriculture and households cross-subsidized by industry) as well as • If the sector is unbundled to varying degrees, within the same consumer category (low- care should be taken to avoid double consumption households cross-subsidized counting. For example, the cost of power by high-consumption households). In purchase by a transmission company should completely deregulated markets, large- not be added to the cost of generation of volume consumers purchasing power at high the power purchased. Only additional costs voltage are charged lower unit prices than incurred in that segment of the supply low-volume consumers at low voltage, and at chain should be captured at each point the same voltage economies of scale would along the chain. imply decreasing unit price with increasing • If the sector is partially deregulated— consumption. Affordability for the poor is some customers can choose electricity better addressed through means other than suppliers and pay deregulated prices, while tariff manipulation, such as cash transfers others have no choice and pay regulated or energy assistance programs. By contrast, prices—comparison of regulated tariffs with tariff schedules in a number of developing deregulated prices may give an indication countries depart from the relative tariff levels of the degree of subsidization of regulated in deregulated markets. In some countries, tariffs. However, this comparison is limited by large-volume consumers with electricity the fact that deregulation applies primarily supplied at high voltage are charged higher 4. PRICING AND RELATED ISSUES SPECIFIC TO ELECTRICITY 35 unit prices than low-volume, low-voltage fees lead to multiple connections to a single consumers. Developing countries also make meter, making several poor households appear extensive use of volume-differentiated or rich to the utility and depriving them of the increasing block tariffs6 with lifeline rates for benefits of lifeline rates (box 8). residential consumers, who as a group may also be cross-subsidized by other consumer categories. BOX 8: MULTIPLE CONNECTIONS IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA In countries that export electricity, export Practice of connecting several houses to a revenues may be used to cross-subsidize single meter is widespread in Sub-Saharan domestic supply. This is similar to natural Africa. In Ethiopia, the lowest connection gas pricing in many developing countries. charge represents 130 percent of average The presence of such cross-subsidies can monthly household income. Multiple connections are the norm: comparison of be checked by comparing export tariffs with the findings from a recent national household domestic tariffs. survey and the utility’s annual report found that there were two and a half times as Quantifying cross-subsidies requires many grid-connected households as utility cost calculations for different volumes of customers. Source: Kojima and Trimble 2016. consumption and voltage levels. Looking at broad patterns in the tariff schedules can help prioritize areas for further analysis by identifying where large cross-subsidies are If the initial connection fees for some customers likely to be found. For example, if average are explicitly subsidized, calculating total residential and agricultural tariffs are the connection subsidies would be straightforward. lowest tariff categories, it is virtually certain If, however, the regulator decides that isolating that these two consumer categories are installation of new connections from other cross-subsidized. components of a network enhancement project is economically inefficient, that there is no START-UP SUBSIDIES compelling argument for separating network assets and service connections, and that it is As is the case with natural gas, connecting a more efficient to build all infrastructure needed building to the grid for the first time can be to connect new users in a single project to costly, and extending the grid to a new location optimize technical and financial arrangements, certainly is. The start-up costs of rural then it is probably not worthwhile trying electrification are similarly costly. Charging to “unbundle” the integrated project in an newly connected customers fully for the attempt to estimate start-up subsidies. start-up costs would exclude many poor households from access to electricity. Some UNINTENDED CONSEQUENCES OF countries, such as Mozambique and South POWER SECTOR SUBSIDIES Africa, waive the initial connection fees altogether for the poor. In other countries, Commercial malpractice in the power sector the initial connection cost can be several times is much less linked to subsidies than for liquid the average household income and much fuels, because, just as with natural gas, it is more for the poor. Unaffordable connection essentially impossible to store low-priced 36 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES electricity and sell it to a customer in a subsidies (see page 26). They all reduce higher-price category or “smuggle” it to a returns on investment, and can even lead to country with higher electricity prices. Under- negative returns. Companies that are already metering, collusion between large customers operating in the power sector cannot invest and utility staff to underbill, and other forms of for modernization and expansion, and often commercial losses occur largely independently cash-strapped utilities struggle to maintain of subsidies. The financial incentives to conduct existing assets. The assets fall into disrepair, the these activities are only indirectly linked to quality of service declines (or has never been subsidies, for example if cross-subsidies raise good to begin with), power shortages become prices for certain customers markedly above the norm, and households and businesses what they would have been in the absence do without electricity or pay much more for of cross-subsidies. Otherwise, price subsidies private diesel generation. reduce, not increase, the financial incentives for commercial losses because the lower the In most circumstances, the poor performance prices, the smaller the financial gains. of the power sector cannot be blamed only on underpricing. There are many other factors Underpricing, late subsidy reimbursements, that contribute to such a state, and that is the and inadequate subsidy reimbursements subject of a much larger literature on power have the same impact on investment and sector reforms. sector performance as with fuel price 5. TAX EXPENDITURES AND OTHER SUPPORT MEASURES TAX EXPENDITURES by inadequate reporting and accounting practices, particularly in developing countries. Tax expenditures are less transparent than In contrast to the scrutiny to which government subsidies financed out of the budget because spending is usually subjected, tax expenditures tax expenditures seldom appear as line do not usually have to be approved by the items in the budget and are therefore not legislature year after year, and many have no subject to annual budgetary scrutiny by the expiration dates. While there are ceilings on legislature. Tax expenditures take a variety direct expenditures, tax expenditures often of forms, including tax-rate reductions, tax escape such spending discipline. Some high- allowances, tax credits, and tax deferrals income countries have laws that require annual (through accelerated depreciation and other reporting of tax expenditures. means). Budgetary transfers can achieve the same outcome as tax expenditures, Tax expenditures may or may not affect prices. but unlike direct government spending, tax For example, accelerated depreciation—or expenditures are almost always deliberated even corporate tax exemption, say for the outside of the budgetary framework. The first five years of operation—granted to a assessment of tax expenditures is hampered domestic refinery may not affect domestic fuel 5. TAX EXPENDITURES AND OTHER SUPPORT MEASURES 37 prices if they are based on import- or export- appliances in Kenya, and exemption from the parity prices. In such cases, tax expenditures 6-percent goods and services tax for lower- represent producer support with no benefits octane gasoline, diesel, and LPG in Malaysia. to consumers. In other cases, tax expenditures Inter-fuel tax differences to keep prices low are used primarily to lower domestic prices. for certain fuels—higher tax on diesel fuel An example would be a market in which than kerosene being a common example—are domestic gas prices are kept artificially intended to make household fuels affordable, low with no budgetary support, providing but provide powerful financial incentives for little incentive to engage in natural gas diversion of lower-taxed fuel to alternative production. To provide incentives to upstream markets. Tax expenditures in such cases can gas producers, the government may grant be quantified by multiplying the difference sweeping fiscal incentives—such as allowing between the standard rate and the reduced all costs associated with gas production and rate by the volume sold. delivery to offset oil revenue, corporate tax exemption for gas, zero royalty rates, and so A special case of tax expenditures through on—in the hope that investors could still earn tax-rate adjustment is when indirect taxes are reasonable returns on investment despite low reduced or eliminated only when world prices gas prices. Quantifying the subsidy in such soar in local currency so as to minimize price a case would entail fiscal modeling without increases. Vietnam has historically used import concessions to compute the wellhead price duty adjustment to smooth domestic prices of gas that would deliver the same return as of petroleum fuels, but trade liberalization in with concessions, and computing the price the form of declining import duties has largely gap accordingly. ended this approach to smoothing prices. Some governments reduce or waive indirect OTHER SUPPORT MEASURES taxes for certain fuels or electricity and equipment associated with them. Examples Other support measures include provision of this practice include corporate income tax of free water, cash transfers conditional on holidays and tax-rate reduction for new power energy purchase, underpricing of other inputs generation projects in Vietnam, exemption and licenses (box 9), implicit government from excise and special petroleum taxes for guarantees for SOEs, soft loans, and shifting premix (fuel for fishing boats) in Ghana, VAT of risk burdens. Cash transfers financed by exemption for LPG and locally-produced LPG the budget can be quantified—it is a matter of BOX 9: UNDERPRICING OF PERMITS Underpricing of inputs (such as government-owned land) and licenses or permits can be difficult to quantify, not least because it may not be immediately obvious what the “right” charge should be. As one example, the minimum bid for coal leases in the Powder River Basin in the United States, which is on federally owned land, has been frozen at US$100 per acre since 1982. Any freezing of a price would suggest underpricing. Accounting for inflation alone would more than double the bid price. General inflation cannot be the only driver of the permit price, suggesting considerable underpricing for the coal lease in this basin. 38 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES finding the data sources—but others present In all cases, the amount of cash transferred is larger challenges. In some cases, quantification normally available from the finance ministry, may not be possible, but noting that a form of budget documents, or other government subsidy is provided (typically in the form of agencies and documents. producer support) is important in assessing the overall subsidy policy framework and New support measures may be introduced examining options for subsidy reform. even as governments embark on subsidy reform. For example, very large price increases Provision of free fuels to end-users is rare. are more likely to prompt governments to offer Turkmenistan took the decision to end unconditional cash transfers, especially when provision of free natural gas to households many basic goods and services are affected. In only in June 2017 (Energo 2017). Provision of the Islamic Republic of Iran in 2010, the price free electricity to the poor is more common. of fuel oil was raised 20-fold, diesel fuel nine- Examples include free electricity given to fold, natural gas five-fold, water and electricity households consuming less than 50 kWh a nearly three-fold, and kerosene two-fold; month in Thailand, and varying amounts up the price of bread was also increased. The to as much as 150 kWh a month given to the government transferred US$80 a month to poor in South Africa. each individual (not household) (Amuzegar 2011). Unconditional cash transfers, as those Cash transfers may be conditional or implemented in Indonesia and the Islamic unconditional, and can be implemented in Republic of Iran, do not specifically target several different ways: purchase of energy, even if the rationale for introducing them was to compensate for • Cash is transferred to energy purchasers higher energy prices, and hence they are upon confirmation of energy purchase by not considered energy subsidies as defined the seller (LPG in India). in ESRAF. Unconditional cash transfers are • The amount of cash for transfer is deducted treated in detail in Good Practice Note 5 on from some other purchase, such as the social safety nets. electricity bill for LPG in Peru for eligible poor households. Contingent liabilities arising from implicit government guarantees can be calculated as • A fixed amount is transferred every month quasi-fiscal deficits (see a detailed discussion (monthly bill for 30 kWh at the lifeline rate on quasi-fiscal deficits starting on page 35). transferred to two categories of eligible Calculation of costs of efficient operations to poor households in Vietnam). arrive at quasi-fiscal deficits at benchmark performance is likely to require a combination • Cash is transferred to a target population of costs from comparable markets with whether they purchase energy or not, in efficient operation and location-specific cost response to energy price increases (cash estimation. Efficient comparators may be transfers to the poor in Indonesia in 2005, difficult to find, however, because efficient, 2008, 2013, and 2014; cash transfers to low-cost markets tend to be in countries nearly all households in the Islamic Republic with more developed infrastructure and of Iran starting in 2010 when energy and economies of scale. Isolating net-of-tax costs other prices were raised significantly). 6. CONSIDERATIONS FOR SUBSIDY POLICY REFORM 39 in examination of fuel subsidies for proper that no bank would provide a loan without comparison also presents a challenge. an implicit government guarantee. It would also be difficult to quantify the SOE’s ease Quantification of subsidies provided by of access to state-owned banks. These are concessional loans entails identifying market likely to be quantified primarily when banks terms and rates for an enterprise of similar are burdened with non-performing loans, risk. Such terms may not exist if, for example, threatening the banks’ viability. the SOE is perceived to be sufficiently risky 6. CONSIDERATIONS FOR SUBSIDY POLICY REFORM This note has described various ways in a series of questions that can help diagnose which subsidies may be delivered as well as subsidies, determinants of their effectiveness, diverted from the intended beneficiaries, and and factors contributing to their retention, so reimbursed (or not) to subsidy providers. as to help design sustainable reform measures. Being aware of different possibilities for these Based on international experience, table 4 (for mechanisms is critically important in assessing fuel subsidies) and table 5 (for electricity) energy subsidies and developing a subsidy suggest a sequence of questions, akin to a reform policy. In the extreme, policy makers check list, that policy makers and analysts may not even be aware that subsidies are examining subsidies can go through to ensure being provided—for example, a national oil that key issues to consider have not been left company without audited financial statements out in developing a subsidy reform policy. The may simply deduct what it considers to be tables also refer to other ESRAF notes where its subsidy burden from the dividends due more detailed discussion can be found. All the to the national treasury, escaping attention questions are also relevant in considering the and scrutiny. political economy of subsidy reforms, which is the subject of Good Practice Note 9. Given the diversity of situations in which subsidies can arise, it would be useful to ask 40 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES TABLE 4: Considerations for Fuel Subsidy Policy Reform Consideration Specific issues Starting conditions in the fuel sector Gap between Is the gap becoming an important fiscal concern? If the gap is large, what time period current price for bridging the gap is likely to find public acceptance, and how large a price increase and market- could be taken at a time? Is there an appetite for making a small, fixed increase every based price month (or any other short time interval) until the gap is substantially narrowed or levels eliminated? If the gap is relatively small, how soon could a formula-based market pricing mechanism be adopted or resumed? How prices are Price levels or price ceilings? At retail, wholesale, refinery gate, import terminal, set and who sets wellhead or mine moth, or elsewhere? Pan-territorial pricing or geographical them variation? Is there a formula for setting prices? Is the formula being followed, or has it been suspended in practice? Is there an agency in charge of setting prices, is the decision to change prices a cabinet decision, is it subject to parliamentary approval, or is it made by different political groups depending on the state of politics at the time? Are price increases subject to approval by different levels of the government depending on the magnitude of the price increase (for example, by the ministry in charge up to 10 percent, and by the prime minister above 10 percent)? Who determines Is the size of under-recoveries based on self-reporting of costs by fuel suppliers, a under- combination of international benchmarks with self-reported local cost elements, or recoveries, who benchmark costs only? If only benchmark costs, was there adequate consultation with pays for them, fuel suppliers to obtain their buy-in to a reasonable extent? Does the government and how reimburse fuel suppliers fully or partially, and in a timely manner or often with long delays? Is the fuel supply infrastructure languishing for lack of investment because of price controls? Are reimbursements for under-recoveries channeled through state- owned fuel suppliers? Is the government’s share of subsidies clearly shown in the budget, or are there off-budget transfers of funds, obscuring the magnitude of the subsidies? Are tax expenditures used to cover under-recoveries? Are there caps on returns on SOEs’ investments to keep prices low? Are oil and gas exports used to cross-subsidize downstream subsidies? Tax expenditures How widespread is the use of tax expenditures to provide producer or consumer and other support? How frequently are they quantified, re-assessed, and subject to scrutiny forgone as part of the budget preparation? A complex web of tax expenditures obscures government transparency and makes it difficult to monitor and track them. Are state-owned fuel revenues (Good suppliers subsidizing prices, and then deducting the subsidies from dividends due Practice Note 2) to the government? This makes for even more opaque subsidy delivery, because subsidies are internally managed by SOEs. Competition in How concentrated is the market at various points along the supply chain? Are there the market regional monopolies, even if there is an appearance of there being a sufficient number of suppliers? Does a national oil company or any other state-owned fuel supplier dominate the market? Are inefficient refineries, state-owned oil companies, or state- owned coal suppliers protected by trade restrictions, subsidy delivery mechanisms, or other means? Is hospitality or third-party access encouraged to facilitate new entry, avoid duplication of infrastructure, and reduce costs? Subsidies in Are these universal or targeted subsidies? Who is targeted and how? Are subsidized place fuels rationed, and if so, how? Do some firms receive subsidies and not others? Subsidies vs. If the country is a major oil or gas exporter, what is the relative size of subsidies government compared with government revenue from upstream oil and gas? In times of collapsing revenue from world oil prices, as in 2015 and 2016, the loss of government revenue from oil and gas upstream oil and could far exceed any potential savings from subsidy reduction or even elimination, gas leaving little “savings” to redirect to essential social services for compensation, limiting what the government can offer in return. 6. CONSIDERATIONS FOR SUBSIDY POLICY REFORM 41 Consideration Specific issues Who uses which Is there widespread use of gasoline or diesel for standby electricity generation? If so, fuel and for higher fuel prices could threaten electricity supply. Is gasoline used primarily by the what purpose better-off, or is there widespread use of gasoline in motorbikes by small businesses and lower-middle class families , making gasoline a fuel of the lesser-off as well as the rich? Is kerosene or LPG widely used for cooking? There is more resistance to raising cooking fuel prices that affect a majority of households. Is there widespread use of kerosene for lighting? If so, pro-poor arguments could be used to argue against raising kerosene prices without compensation. Commercial Are there flourishing black markets? Are actual prices paid by consumers markedly malpractice higher than official prices due to fuel shortages? If so, raising official prices would have much less adverse impact. Is short-selling (selling less than the stated quantity) routine? Where short-selling is rampant, enforcing rules against it would lower the effective price increases when official prices are raised. Is fuel smuggling widespread? Is there diversion of subsidized fuels to consumers who are not eligible? Is there adulteration of higher-priced fuels with subsidized fuels? Perception of Is it considered opaque, corrupt, politically well-connected, or a state within a state the fuel sector (an issue primarily with national oil companies)? Are there scandals to do with large leakages in subsidy delivery? Raising prices could be difficult if the public is angry about corruption. On the other hand, it might be possible to persuade the public that higher prices get to the source of the corruption and help stamp it out. If the state is a large oil producer, is the country a member of the Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI; for more information, see eiti.org)? Social protection (Good Practice Note 5) Safety nets Is there an up-to-date database of beneficiaries? Is there an administrative system in place to deliver benefits? Does the government have a national identity and smart card system for cash transfer to the needy? Does the government have safety nets that can be scaled up in terms of benefits, coverage, or both, to compensate the vulnerable for higher fuel prices in a way that would be consistent with medium- and long-term goals for social protection? Or will deployment of sound social safety nets require considerable preparatory work and development? Delivery of What is the state of primary education, primary health, access to safe water, access essential social to sanitation, pension, unemployment benefits, and other social services? Is the track services record of delivery such that the public would consider credible the government’s promises of putting the savings from subsidy reduction to better uses? Reform steps Sector structure Is the market sufficiently large, capable of becoming competitive over time, making and regulation price deregulation a realistic goal? If the market is concentrated, what are the physical assets that protect the market power of the incumbents—import terminals, refineries, depots, or pipelines? How can their market power be broken? Are there laws or regulations on supply that need to be amended? Do regulations and standards reflect current international good practice, or do they need to be updated? Is there monitoring and enforcement, and if so, how can they be strengthened? How is commercial malpractice tackled and is there a plan to reduce it further? Who will set Will there be an independent regulatory agency in charge of setting prices? Are prices and how there laws or regulations on pricing that need to be amended? If there are large price subsidies, what transition steps are needed before an automatic, formula-based pricing mechanism can be adopted or prices deregulated? 42 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES Consideration Specific issues Parliamentary Is information on tax expenditures made available and debated on a regular basis? scrutiny Aside from budgetary transfers, how aware are members of the parliament about off-budget transfers, implicit government guarantees, and contingent liabilities (Good Practice Note 2)? If such information is not readily available, a team may have to be set up to gather the information so that the parliament has a good understanding of the scale and nature of fuel subsidies. Timing Are there events outside the fuel sector that could affect timing—national elections, natural disasters, food crisis, power crisis, large-scale agricultural crop failure, domestic or international financial crisis, soaring unemployment, or collapsing prices of other commodities, such as coffee or minerals, that the economy depends on? Most of these would call for greater social protection measures in response to fuel price subsidy reforms. Is there a time when fuel consumption is higher—major national holidays, winter in cold-climate areas, summer travel period—that should be avoided for raising official fuel prices? Beneficiaries, Is there a reasonable understanding of effects of subsidy reforms on different losers, and link segments of society and income groups, including likely effects on inflation and which to other sectors sectors would be particularly affected (Good Practice Notes 3, 6, and 7)? What are the relative effects of higher food prices, higher transport fares, and higher energy prices on the poor (Good Practice Note 3)? If food prices are more important because of the expenditure patterns of the poor, that would argue even more for moving away from sectoral approaches and combining safety nets for all risks under one umbrella. Are fuel suppliers currently benefiting from producer support (such as tax reduction and deferrals or import restrictions) likely to be able to cope with their elimination, or are they inefficient and not in a position to compete with imports and other (unsubsidized) suppliers? Is there a credible roadmap for helping them to stand on their own? Or should the government help with orderly closure of some fuel supply companies? Does the financial viability of some businesses depend on fuel price subsidies (Good Practice Note 6)? If so, they will lobby to oppose subsidy reforms through industry associations, trade unions, and other groups. Are some of them likely to cease to be viable if subsidies are eliminated, and if so, is there a need for managed closure of these businesses and retraining of staff? Would it be possible to make small, regular, incremental price increases that minimize adverse effects? Would it make sense to provide support for fuel switching or fuel efficiency improvement? Does the electricity sector rely on subsidized diesel, fuel oil, natural gas, or coal? Is underpricing of electricity a problem? Can electricity utilities pass on fuel price increases to consumers, or will the utilities have to bear financial losses until large electricity tariff increases are eventually effected? Are there large payment arrears for fuel purchases? If fuel price increases will significantly increase electricity supply costs, affect the financial viability of electricity utilities, or do both, careful consideration needs to be given to coordination between the fuel and electricity sectors, and to the political economy of electricity tariff reforms. Otherwise, fuel pricing reform may merely serve to aggravate poor payment discipline in the power sector. For regulated transport fares (taxis, buses, some freight rates), do the authorities tend to freeze them for a long period at a time, raising them only when fuel prices are raised? If so, the public may have come to equate transport fare hikes with fuel price hikes. Such a perception grossly exaggerates the effect of fuel price increases on transport fares and gives fuel pricing reform a bad name. Transport and fuel sector policies need to be better coordinated. Are there powerful groups benefiting from subsidies that can exercise their influence to block subsidy reforms? A powerful national oil company that is a state within a state could be one such example. Are some groups benefiting illegally from subsidies by engaging in smuggling, black marketing, diversion, and fuel adulteration? Do they include high-level government officials and high-level oil-company officers? If so, building a broad-based coalition of supporters for price reforms would be all the more important (Good Practice Note 9). 6. CONSIDERATIONS FOR SUBSIDY POLICY REFORM 43 Consideration Specific issues Immediate, Would it be possible to deliver immediate benefits of the subsidy reform? In the oil tangible benefits sector, such benefits could be no more queues, much less fuel adulteration, much lower or elimination of black market prices, and a crackdown on short-selling. For natural gas and coal, elimination of fuel shortages would similarly be a possible benefit, although it would be difficult to increase the supply of natural gas over the short run because ramping up production or imports takes much longer than for liquid fuels. Outside the fuel sector, are there existing administrative systems in place that can deliver compensation immediately and is visible to the public? If not, is there something that could be set up quickly, and could the start of any large price adjustments be postponed until that setup is nearly, if not fully, operational (Good Practice Note 5)? Longer-term Aside from initial compensation to help consumers adjust to higher prices, is there assistance a need for longer-term compensation or assistance, such as an energy efficiency improvement fund or tax expenditures for acquisition of more efficient equipment and appliances to reduce fuel consumption, increases in food assistance, and long-term cash compensation to the poor? Similarly, if producer support is being withdrawn, what assistance is appropriate and realistic? Communication (Good Practice Note 10) About the Is the public aware of the size of subsidies, who is benefiting, the distortions caused current state by the subsidies, their opportunity costs, and the scale of corruption spawned by the subsidies? Is information on current and past subsidies accessible to the public? Is there a national dialogue on the pros and cons of the current subsidy policy? About future Are options or a proposal for subsidy reform being communicated effectively and options and plan accurately? Or are rumors causing panic buying and hoarding? Is there a mechanism to consult different stakeholders and include them in deliberation and decision- making to the extent possible? Is communication about compensation plans undertaken far in advance of the implementation of the subsidy reform, so that the public is well prepared? Means of Are all forms of communication being exploited? Is consideration being given to a communication Web-based national conversation, giving many people an opportunity to be heard? Are all segments of society being reached, including those without access to the internet or TV? Is electronic communication being complemented by face-to-face stakeholder meetings? Communication Is there a plan to make price, production, and consumption information available about the fuel regularly and in a timely manner so that consumers and potential investors can sector take informed decisions? As competition begins to emerge, could the government make price information readily available to further promote price competition? The government of Chile requires that all fuel marketers post all prices at all times on the Web and make them readily available on smart phones. Is there a mechanism for registering complaints? Are companies found in violation of rules named with specific charges outlined? Are all regulations and rules, announcements about pricing policy, calculations of controlled prices, the magnitude of the remaining subsidies and how they are channeled, and any other information related to prices consolidated in one place so that they can be easily found? Where tax expenditures are large and being reduced, is the public being informed about the loss of fiscal revenue? Is information provided in plain language and comprehensible to many, if not most, people in the country? 44 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES TABLE 5: Considerations for Power Subsidy Policy Reform Consideration Specific issues Starting conditions in the power sector Cost recovery Does cash collected cover all costs? If not, which level of cost recovery in table 3 does the sector achieve? Is there a reasonable understanding of the relative importance of the contributing factors (for example, using hidden-cost analysis)? Quality of Is electricity reliable, or are blackouts and brownouts frequent, forcing those who can service afford it to resort to private electricity generation? Is there an accessible mechanism for reporting outages and other complaints? Are utilities responsive to complaints? How tariffs are Are relative tariffs by consumer category broadly in line with costs of service, or set and who are some categories clearly cross-subsidized? Are tariffs too low for cost recovery approves across the board (generation, transmission, and distribution), or is generation more deregulated than transmission and distribution? Is there geographical variation or is there nationally uniform pricing? What are allowed losses for tariff-setting? Are there caps on SOEs’ return on investment or equity to keep prices low? Is there an automatic mechanism for passing through higher input costs due to currency depreciation or higher fuel prices? Is automatic pass-through implemented as stated? How frequently are tariffs reviewed? Are the reviews transparent, with sufficient public disclosure? Are tariff increases subject to approval by different levels of government depending on the magnitude (for example, by the regulator for up to 5 percent, the power ministry between 5 and 10 percent, the cabinet between 10 and 15 percent, and the prime minister above 15 percent)? Who determines Are the rules for calculating reimbursements for under-recoveries clear? Does the under- government make payments fully or partially, and in a timely manner or often with recoveries, who long delays? Is the power supply infrastructure languishing for lack of investment pays for them, because of cost under-recovery? Are the reimbursements by the government clearly and how shown in the budget, or are there off-budget transfers of funds, obscuring the magnitude of the subsidies? Are tax expenditures or power exports used to cover under-recoveries? Tax expenditures How widespread is the use of tax expenditures to provide producer or consumer (Good Practice support? How frequently are they quantified, re-assessed, and subject to scrutiny Note 2) as part of the budget preparation? A complex web of tax expenditures obscures transparency and makes it difficult to monitor and track them. What consumers Are consumers charged for electricity individually consumed, or is consumption pay for estimated? In some countries consumers are charged based on estimated consumption. Where there are daily blackouts, estimated consumption could routinely exceed actual consumption. Where every consumer is charged the same fee, some may be consuming large quantities for almost nothing. Where there are lifeline rates and several poor households share a single meter, they appear to the utility as one rich family and cannot take advantage of low rates set for the poor. Are there many electricity customers benefitting from underbilling, tolerance of nonpayment, or both? Perception of Is it considered opaque, corrupt, or incompetent? Raising tariffs could be difficult if the power sector the public is angry about corruption or does not believe that service quality could improve measurably on account of incompetence. 6. CONSIDERATIONS FOR SUBSIDY POLICY REFORM 45 Consideration Specific issues Social protection (Good Practice Note 5) Cross-subsidies Would it make sense to rely primarily on cross-subsidies to help the poor use or generalized electricity (such as lifeline rates) for the foreseeable future? If so, are poor households safety nets individually, accurately, and regularly metered? Will there be sufficient revenue from medium and large consumers to cross-subsidize the potential pool of poor consumers? If social protection is well developed and the decision is to help the poor through safety nets, is there an up-to-date database of beneficiaries? Is there an administrative system in place to deliver benefits? Does the government have safety nets that can be scaled up in terms of benefits, coverage, or both, to compensate the vulnerable for higher electricity prices in a way that would be consistent with medium- and long-term goals for social protection? Delivery of What is the state of primary education, primary health, access to safe water, access essential social to sanitation, pension, unemployment benefits, and other social services? Is the track services record of delivery such that the public would consider credible the government’s promises of putting the savings from subsidy reduction to better uses? Reform steps Sector structure Is the sector partially deregulated, does the deregulated power market account for a and regulation sizable portion of total consumption, and are regulated customers heavily subsidized? If so, tariffs for regulated customers may have to rise appreciably before reaching cost recovery. Who will set Will there be an independent regulatory agency in charge of setting prices? Are there prices and how laws or regulations on tariff-setting that need to be amended? If there are large price subsidies, what transition steps are needed before reaching cost recovery? If approval for tariff increases currently depends on different levels of government depending on the size of the increase, would it make sense to change the approval process to depoliticize tariff adjustment more? Parliamentary Is information on tax expenditures made available and debated on a regular basis? scrutiny Aside from budgetary transfers, how aware are members of the parliament about off-budget transfers, implicit government guarantees, and contingent liabilities (Good Practice Note 2)? If such information is not readily available, a team may have to be set up to gather the information so that the parliament has a good understanding of the scale and nature of electricity subsidies. Timing Are there events outside the power sector that could affect timing—national elections, natural disasters, food crisis, fuel crisis, large-scale agricultural crop failure, domestic or international financial crisis, soaring unemployment, or collapsing prices of other commodities, such as coffee or minerals, that the economy depends on? Most of these would call for greater social protection measures in response to power tariff reforms. Is there a time when electricity consumption is higher—heating in winter in cold-climate countries and air conditioning in summer in warm-climate countries—that should be avoided for raising tariffs, if possible? 46 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES Consideration Specific issues Beneficiaries, Is there a reasonable understanding of effects of subsidy reforms on different losers, and link segments of society and income groups, including likely effects on inflation and which to other sectors sectors would be particularly affected (Good Practice Notes 3, 6, and 7)? Does the financial viability of some businesses depend on power tariff subsidies (Good Practice Note 6)? If so, they will lobby to oppose subsidy reforms through industry associations, trade unions, and other groups. Are some of them likely to cease to be viable if subsidies are eliminated, and if so, is there a need for managed closure of these businesses and retraining of staff? Would it be possible to make small, regular, incremental tariff increases that minimize adverse effects? Would it make sense to provide support for energy efficiency improvement? Alternatively, if there is a realistic possibility of markedly improving service reliability as a result of subsidy reform, what will be the magnitude of net savings for those currently using private diesel generation? Are there consumers who are benefitting from the corruption and inefficiency in the sector, such as large industrial consumers colluding with utility employees to engineer underbilling, free riders taking advantage of deficiencies in metering, and consumers with large payment arrears that they have no intention of paying? All of them will lose from more accurate metering and billing, and improvement in bill collection efficiency. If poor households who are currently connected to a neighbor’s meter can be given individual meters or pre-paid meters, they may end up paying less than at present. Immediate, Would it be possible to deliver immediate benefits of the subsidy reform? In tangible benefits anticipation of higher revenue, utilities may spend money to set up call centers and respond to reports of power outages, reducing the duration of each outage. Outside the power sector, are there existing administrative systems in place that can deliver increased social services immediately in a way that is visible to the public (Good Practice Note 5)? Longer-term Could affected consumers benefit from longer-term compensation or assistance, such assistance as an energy efficiency improvement fund or tax expenditures for acquisition of more efficient equipment and appliances to reduce electricity consumption, and could such assistance be offered cost-effectively? Communication (Good Practice Note 10) About the Is the public aware of the size of subsidies, who is benefiting, the distortions caused current state by the subsidies, and their opportunity costs? Is information on current and past subsidies accessible to the public? Is there a national dialogue on the pros and cons of the current subsidy policy? Where tax expenditures are large and being reduced, is the public being informed about the loss of fiscal revenue? Is information about service quality being provided and updated regularly? Is information provided in plain language and comprehensible to many, if not most, people in the country? About future Are options or a proposal for subsidy reform being communicated effectively and options or plan accurately? Are programs that will benefit consumers—especially for improving service reliability and customer service in general—being communicated? Is there a mechanism to consult different stakeholders and include them in deliberation and decision-making to the extent possible? If compensation is to be offered for higher electricity tariffs, is communication about such plans undertaken far in advance of the implementation of the subsidy reform? Means of Is information about the power sector accessible to the public, including tariff communication schedules, conclusions of tariff reviews, and grievance redress mechanisms? Are all forms of communication being exploited? Is consideration being given to a Web- based national conversation, giving many people an opportunity to be heard? Are all segments of society being reached, including those without access to the internet? Is electronic communication being complemented by face-to-face stakeholder meetings? ANNEX: EXAMPLES DATA SOURCES AND EASE OF EVALUATION This annex provides additional details on table 2. Effects A, B, and C listed in the third column are those found in the definition of an energy subsidy: A | Reducing the net cost of energy purchased. B | Reducing the cost of production or delivery of fuels, electricity, or heat. C | Increasing revenues retained by resource owners, or suppliers of fuel, electricity, or heat. The table starts with potential concerns that are applicable to all forms of energy, followed by sector-specific concerns. Potential Nature of subsidy and subsidy delivery Common data sources and ease of Ease of evaluation if data are Sector subsidy mechanism (effect A, B, or C) data acquisition available All sectors Budgetary 1. Transfers of government funds to For budgetary transfers, budget as For SOEs not operating on commercial and off- compensate producers for price controls executed, and in its absence, budget as principles (for example, an SOE that is budget that keep prices below cost-recovery or presented; company financial statements; not allowed to retain earnings and is ANNEX: EXAMPLES DATA SOURCES AND EASE OF EVALUATION transfers to trade-parity levels (A), or for producer’s EITI audit reports for upstream funded through the budget), separation producers inefficiencies (C). Examples include production. Off-budget transfers are of transfers for legitimate business or transfers to an oil price fund to keep generally difficult to obtain. The level expenditures from support over and consumers end-user prices low (A), to a rural of disaggregation in the government above them can be difficult. electrification fund (A), to utilities to budget may not be sufficient. Publicly upgrade transmission and distribution traded companies are more likely to lines to reduce technical losses (B, C), to have detailed financial statements, but if refineries for modernization to produce numerous companies are involved, such cleaner fuels (B), and to any energy as in the downstream petroleum sector, company to install new capacity (B). it may become difficult to keep track. Although not covered in this version of Good Practice Note 1, district heating is often subsidized by municipalities, making data collection across the country challenging. 47 48 Potential Nature of subsidy and subsidy delivery Common data sources and ease of Ease of evaluation if data are Sector subsidy mechanism (effect A, B, or C) data acquisition available 2. Transfers of government funds to For budgetary transfers, budget as If data are available and disaggregated enable consumers to purchase specific executed, and in its absence, budget sufficiently, evaluation is straightforward. energy items where the compensation as presented. Ministry Web sites and cannot be used for other purposes. press releases. Off-budget transfers to Heating degree-days, the energy share consumers would be rare. of expenditures exceeding a threshold level, and energy price levels (possibly combined with monthly consumption) are examples of parameters determining the level of compensation. 3. Applied research and development Government sources, but level of Research grant amounts may be easy benefiting largely energy suppliers (B). disaggregation may not be sufficient but financial benefits would be difficult except for very large grants (such as to quantify. for demonstration projects for carbon capture and sequestration). Forgone 4. Reduction of taxes paid. Examples Finance ministry; ministry or regulator A good fiscal specialist should be able government include exemptions or reductions from in charge of the sector; laws, decrees, to compute the loss of government revenue taxes normally applied, such as VAT (A), regulations, notices, circulars; EITI audits revenue. A significant challenge that tax holidays for corporate income tax for upstream oil, gas, and coal. Costs and requires analyst judgment is the (C), land tax (C), and tax credits (C); revenue data, and all tax terms with and definition of the reference tax structure, special rules to accelerate or increase without tax concessions, may be needed. which depends on the reference time deductions from taxable income (C); and Tax concessions often target specific period and other factors (such as access to special tax-favored corporate investments without public disclosure in estimation of costs). Tax expenditure forms (C). developing countries. Sub-national tax estimation can vary, depending on how expenditures are particularly challenging the reference tax structure is selected. to collect. Where taxes are frequently adjusted, it may be difficult to ensure the accuracy of time-series data. 5. Lower government revenue due to state- Financial statements of state-owned If the amount withheld is a separate owned energy suppliers deducting the energy suppliers. Many state-owned line item, the subsidy can be easily subsidy burden from dividends to be energy suppliers do not have adequately calculated. transferred to the government (A, C). audited financial statements, disclosure of financial statements may be years behind in schedule, and the level of detail provided may not allow identification of withholdings for subsidies. GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES Potential Nature of subsidy and subsidy delivery Common data sources and ease of Ease of evaluation if data are Sector subsidy mechanism (effect A, B, or C) data acquisition available Shifting 6. Limits on commercial liability and ability Government sources for statutory limits. Quantifying the ability to sue would of risk of injured parties to sue energy suppliers Damage costs covered by government be difficult. Value of liability caps can burdens for compensation (B, C). or citizens would require compilation of be estimated by extrapolating from all such cases, which would be difficult. required coverage or comparable Information on the ability to sue may be liabilities in related sectors. difficult to obtain. 7. Government assumption of risks and Government sources. For large If data are available and disaggregated damages, including assumption of remediation projects, the total cost may sufficiently, evaluation is straightforward. legacy or current health, safety, and not become known for a long time, environment problems in violation of making data collection difficult. regulations and standards, such as environmental damage associated with field abandonment, oil spills, and mine closure (B). Other examples include severance package for employees for mine closure (B), oil price hedging for refineries (B), and insurance against price surges (A). 8. Soft budget constraints for companies Government sources and SOE financial Difficult to quantify across each sub- with partial or full state ownership, statements. sector, and virtually impossible where leading to contingent liabilities for the eventual effect is to increase the government (C). sovereign borrowing rate on account of contingent liabilities lowering the ANNEX: EXAMPLES DATA SOURCES AND EASE OF EVALUATION government’s credit rating. 9. Debt cancellations and clearance of Government sources; company financial Relatively straightforward. arrears, typically for SOEs (C) but can statements. also be for consumers (A), especially if consumers are themselves SOEs or government agencies. Subsidized 10. Subsidized water, fuel (crude oil for Various government ministries and Difficult to keep track of various sources inputs refineries, fuels for power or heat agencies. If the sectors involved are of subsidized inputs. Quantification may producers), electricity (for energy opaque, it may be difficult to obtain data require calculating subsidies in other suppliers other than power), heat (for on subsidized crude oil sold to a state- sectors, such as water and transport. energy suppliers other than heat), rail owned refinery, subsidized fuels sold to freight transport of coal and oil, trucking state-owned utilities (power, heat), or of refined products (B). subsidized rail freight fares offered by a state-owned rail company to a state- owned coal company. 49 50 Potential Nature of subsidy and subsidy delivery Common data sources and ease of Ease of evaluation if data are Sector subsidy mechanism (effect A, B, or C) data acquisition available 11. Underpricing of goods and services Various government ministries and May be difficult to quantify market provided by government, such as access agencies. Data difficult to obtain, although values of some items, such as land. to land (B). a review of leasing or sale procedures may highlight whether subsidies are likely to exist. 12. Subsidized loans, guarantees, and Government sources. Total amounts may Subsidized interest rates and loan other forms of concessional financing be available, but disaggregation by sector terms can be quantified, although or financing support for exploration, or sub-sector is not common, making assumptions must be made about risk- development, production, transport, data collection difficult. adjusted market rates for the companies delivery, or export. Examples include involved. Challenges to quantifying loan support for rural electrification, guarantees are similar. development of unconventional oil and gas, and establishment of filling stations for rural consumers or for compressed natural gas7 (B). 13. Underpricing of permits, such as Ministry or regulator in charge of the Relatively straightforward at the market allowances for carbon dioxide or sulfur permits and licenses. price of the permit, but calculating dioxide emissions in a market with what the price might have been is not emissions trading and license to operate straightforward for emissions trading. (B). Cross- 14. Maintenance of low domestic end-user Ministry of trade, finance ministry, or Note that high tariffs represent border trade prices by export restrictions on crude ministry or regulator in charge; press additional government revenue, not restrictions oil, refined products, natural gas, or coal releases and announcements. Data are government spending. Estimating (export ban, export quota, domestic generally available, but there may be a the counterfactual may not be supply obligation, high export tariffs) long time lag for data on quantities sold. straightforward, especially for fuels sold (A); or of high prices paid to producers on long-term contracts. enabled by import restrictions (import ban, import quota, high import tariffs) (C). Upstream oil, gas, and coal Licensing 15. Overly generous fiscal and other terms Typically no data except where Difficult except where market-tested and contract offered in contract award (C). information is leaked to the media or analogous situations exist, but even award there is some type of a commission of so consideration of the impact of inquiry. geopolitical and other risks unique GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES to the country makes quantification challenging, Potential Nature of subsidy and subsidy delivery Common data sources and ease of Ease of evaluation if data are Sector subsidy mechanism (effect A, B, or C) data acquisition available Non-tax 16. Concessions on non-tax fiscal terms, Finance ministry; ministry or regulator in If royalties and bonuses depend only fiscal such as production share in production charge of the sector; EITI audit reports. on gross revenues, production, physical concessions sharing contracts, royalties, and bonuses These concessions tend to be investment- characteristics of fields (such as water (C). specific and often not disclosed. Sub- depth), or some combination of these, national fiscal concessions are particularly they are relatively easy to calculate. Note: Royalties and bonuses are not taxes. challenging. Price 17. Government control of crude oil, gas, or Finance ministry; ministry or regulator Once controlled and trade-parity prices controls coal prices on the domestic market at in charge of the sector; government and quantities are known, subsidies are and levels lower than trade parity (A). announcements; company financial easy to calculate. support statements. Data on controlled prices are generally available. Trade parity prices are difficult to obtain for gas and coal purchased on long-term contracts. Data on quantities involved may become available with a time lag, which can be long. Obtaining information on dates of bills of lading and exchange rates realized presents additional challenges. 18. Cross-subsidization of domestic Government sources for end-user prices, Benchmark market prices of downstream end-user prices using and company financial statements for downstream prices, which are always upstream oil and gas earnings, often cross-subsidies. Level of disaggregation location- and time-specific, will need to from exports8 (A). may not be sufficient to enable be calculated. estimation. ANNEX: EXAMPLES DATA SOURCES AND EASE OF EVALUATION 19. Price support for producers, such as Ministry or regulator in charge of the Quantification is straightforward. for unconventional gas in a sector with sector. Usually information available. regulated gas prices (for example, where the price of conventional natural gas is low, and government sets a higher price for unconventional gas) (C). Supply 20. Mandate to supply a fuel, setting both Ministry or regulator in charge of price Calculation is straightforward if prices mandate prices and quantities. The price is and quantity regulation. The price in the and quantities are known. typically at a lower price than in the absence of the mandate may not be absence of the mandate. obvious in the absence of international trade. 51 52 Potential Nature of subsidy and subsidy delivery Common data sources and ease of Ease of evaluation if data are Sector subsidy mechanism (effect A, B, or C) data acquisition available Midstream oil, gas, and coal Pricing 21. Regulated transport and storage Fees from asset owners or operators; Calculation of long-run cost recovery policy fees that do not allow for reasonable ministry or regulator in charge. Fees is likely to require dedicated studies. earnings (A). at long-run cost recovery in a sector with growing demand require data to estimate the cost of capacity expansion. 22. Government policy, explicit or implicit, Finance ministry; ministry or regulator It may be difficult to distinguish of keeping ex-refinery prices low in in charge; cabinet decision; company between losses from normal business part through financial losses that are financial statements. If the price control cycles—refining losses are common not covered by budgetary transfers is at the ex-refinery level, data may be even in completely deregulated (A). more difficult to obtain than at ex-retail. markets—and producers’ lack of In addition to ex-refinery price levels, competitiveness on the one hand the cost of transport to or from ports is and losses due to prices that are set needed to derive reference prices from artificially low on the other. international benchmark prices. Purchase 23. Mandate imposed on oil marketing Ministry or regulator in charge. Financial Quantification is straightforward if mandate and other companies to purchase statements and annual reports of alternative free-market sources also certain quantities from domestic companies involved. The text on the exist. refineries (C). mandate is generally available. 24. Mandate on power companies and Ministry or regulator in charge. Financial Quantification is straightforward if others to purchase domestic coal and statements and annual reports of alternative free-market sources also refined products, especially if both companies involved. The text on the exist. sellers and buyers are state-owned (C). mandate is generally available. Downstream oil, gas, and coal Pricing 25. Price controls at wholesale or retail to Finance ministry, or ministry or Because of the large number of policy keep end-user prices lower than in a regulator in charge of controlling price suppliers involved, assumptions competitive market, with losses not levels. The counterfactual requires will have to be made to arrive at covered by government compensation largest data collection at the end of reference retail prices. This may not to oil or coal marketers. Variations in the supply chain because of all the be straightforward where costs vary government control of prices include costs incurred in the different stages in significantly from location to location. cross-subsidies across fuels (such the chain. Data on transportation and GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES as gasoline sales cross-subsidizing storage may be difficult to obtain. kerosene sales), and differentiating prices for the same product by consumer category or geographical locations (A). Potential Nature of subsidy and subsidy delivery Common data sources and ease of Ease of evaluation if data are Sector subsidy mechanism (effect A, B, or C) data acquisition available Downstream oil, gas, and coal Access Priority access to the grid, equivalent 26. Ministry or regulator in charge, and Estimating the utilization factor in the to a purchase mandate, such as utilities. “Must-run” power plants are absence of the mandate may require electricity from certain plants to help usually renewable or nuclear energy but some work. with their capital cost recovery rather fossil fuel plants in financial trouble can than dispatch based on merit order be among them. (C). Tariff 27. Tariffs and other charges below cost Government policies and regulations; Dedicated studies likely required. structure recovery (A). ministry or regulator in charge of tariffs and and other charges; utilities; cost-of- connection service and financial viability studies. charges Tariffs for residential and other small to medium-size consumers are usually available, but connection charges and tariffs for larger consumers are often bilaterally negotiated and not publicly available. Long-run recovery costs in an expanding market need data on expansion costs, which requires a study. Cross-subsidies across consumer 28. Government policies and regulations; Dedicated studies required. categories and geographical regions9 ministry or regulator in charge; utilities; ANNEX: EXAMPLES DATA SOURCES AND EASE OF EVALUATION (A). specialized commissioned studies. Tariffs are easy to obtain for residential consumers, but for larger consumers they are often bilaterally negotiated and undisclosed. 53 GOOD PRACTICE NOTE 1: IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING ENERGY SUBSIDIES ENDNOTES 1 It is important to note that not all forms of support studied by the OECD are subsidies as defined in this note. 2 For example, see NEITI (2013, p. 100) for a discussion of the Pioneer Status granted to a dozen oil and gas companies. 3 An example of a detailed formula with examples can be found on the website of the South African Department of Energy (www.energy.gov.za/files/petroleum_frame. html). Working rules can be found at www.energy.gov.za/files/esources/pdfs/energy/ liquidfuels/annexure_A_05.pdf. 4 A short introduction to refinery economics in two four-page parts can be found at http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/695521468015275586/ World-Bank-Cambodia-oil-gas-special-supplement-refining-crude-oil-part-1 and http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/547781468017980604/ World-Bank-Cambodia-oil-gas-special-supplement-refining-crude-oil-part-2. 5 The Finnish Electricity Market Act (386/1995) specifies only that distribution pricing be reasonable and that distribution companies operate efficiently. 6 Increasing block tariffs apply rising unit prices to incremental consumption, whereas volume-differentiated tariffs apply a single unit price to the entire consumption depending on the volume of consumption. Increasing block tariffs benefit the rich and the poor alike, making the subsidies inefficient. Volume-differentiated tariffs can be punishing for the poor because exceeding the lifeline block size by even 1 kWh would catapult the household into the next block, which could have a much higher unit price. 7 The government may decide to subsidize establishment of retail outlets in rural areas that might otherwise not be served, or to kick-start establishment of a network of filling stations for compressed natural gas—which is much more costly than those for liquid fuels—to promote fuel diversification. 8 Governments seldom explicitly order upstream companies to subsidize downstream consumers. One exception is India. The presence of upstream operations in the country, however, is an important consideration in the government’s decision, formal or otherwise, to set low domestic fuel prices. Further, these low prices may be “voluntary” on paper, as in Argentina and Brazil in the recent past. 9 Cross-subsidization is an important component of an electrification program to achieve universal access, one of the three goals of Sustainable Energy for All. 54 REFERENCES REFERENCES Amuzegar, Jahangir. 2011. “Iran's Subsidy Reform: A Progress Report.” Middle East Economic Survey 54(25): 23–28. Anderson, David L. 1990. “Subsidy measurement problems in new mining project.” New Resources Policy. September 1990:162–171. Bernama Daily. 2014. “PAC claims subsidized diesel distribution has many weaknesses.” June 19. Energo. 2017. “Turkmenistan ends golden era of utility subsidies.” June 15. IMF (International Monetary Fund). “Angola: Technical Assistant Report - Fuel Price Subsidy Reform the Way Forward.” IMF Country Report No. 15/28, Washington, DC. http://www.imf. org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2015/cr1528.pdf Kojima, Masami. 2013. “Petroleum product pricing and complementary policies: Experience of 65 developing countries since 2009.” Policy Research Working Paper 6393, World Bank, Washington, DC. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/13201 ———. 2016. “Fossil Fuel Subsidy and Pricing Policies: Recent Developing Country Experience.” Policy Research Working Paper 7531, World Bank, Washington, DC. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/23631 Kojima, Masami, and Chris Trimble. 2016. “Making Power Affordable for Africa and Viable for Its Utilities.” World Bank, Washington, DC. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/ handle/10986/25091OECD OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2013, Inventory of Estimated Budgetary Support and Tax Expenditures for Fossil Fuels 2013, OECD Publishing, Paris. DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264187610-en NEITI (Nigerian Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative). 2013. Financial, Physical and Process Audit: An Independent Report Assessing and Reconciling Physical and Financial Flows within Nigeria’s Oil and Gas Industry 2013. http://www.neiti.gov.ng/index.php/neiti-audits/oil-and-gas/ category/161-2013-audit-report?download=607:2013-oil-gas-audit-final-report Nigeria. House of Representatives. 2012. “Report of the ad-hoc committee to verify and determine the actual subsidy requirements and monitor the implementation of the subsidy regime in Nigeria.” www.letemps.ch/rw/Le_Temps/Quotidien/2012/10/06/Economie/Images/ FUEL_SUBSIDY_PROBE_REPORT.pdf Oil and Gas Journal. 2016. “Worldwide look at reserves and production.” December 5. Rajakutty, S., Masami Kojima, V. Madhava Rao, Kumpatla Jayalakshmi, D.P.R. Reddy, Suman Chandra, V. Annamalai, and Nagaseshna. 2002. “Promoting Clean Household Fuels Among the Rural Poor: Evaluation of the Deepam Scheme in Andhra Pradesh.” South Asia Region Internal Discussion Paper, World Bank, Washington, DC. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/ INTOGMC/Resources/promoting_clean_household_fuels.pdf Trimble, Christopher, Masami Kojima, Ines Perez Arroyo, and Farah Mohammadzadeh. 2016. “Financial Viability of Electricity Sectors in Sub-Saharan Africa: Quasi-Fiscal Deficits and Hidden Costs.” Policy Research Working Paper 7788, World Bank, Washington, DC. https:// openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/24869 World Bank Group. 2015. “Nigeria Economic Report, November 2015.” World Bank, Washington, DC. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/23581 55 Energy Subsidy Reform Assessment Framework LIST OF GOOD PRACTICE NOTES NOTE 1 Identifying and Quantifying Energy Subsidies NOTE 2 Assessing the Fiscal Cost of Subsidies and Fiscal Impact of Reform NOTE 3 Analyzing the Incidence of Consumer Price Subsidies and the Impact of Reform on Households — Quantitative Analysis NOTE 4 Incidence of Price Subsidies on Households, and Distributional Impact of Reform — Qualitative Methods NOTE 5 Assessing the readiness of Social Safety Nets to Mitigate the Impact of Reform NOTE 6 Identifying the Impacts of Higher Energy Prices on Firms and Industrial Competitiveness NOTE 7 Modeling Macroeconomic Impacts and Global externalities NOTE 8 Local Environmental Externalities due to Energy Price Subsidies: A Focus on Air Pollution and Health NOTE 9 Assessing the Political Economy of Energy Subsidies to Support Policy Reform Operations NOTE 10 Designing Communications Campaigns for Energy Subsidy Reform