LEBANON Lebanon ECONOMIC Sinking MONITOR (To the Top 3) Spring 2021 Middle East and North Africa Region Lebanon Economic Monitor Lebanon Sinking (To the Top 3) )لبنان يغرق (نحو أسوأ ثالث أزمات عاملية Le Naufrage du Liban (Top 3 des pires crises mondiales) Spring 2021 Global Practice for Macroeconomics, Trade & Investment Middle East and North Africa Region LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR Document of the World Bank The Delibera Depressi TABLE OF CONTENTS Acronyms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vii Preface . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ix Executive Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xi الموجز . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xv Résumé . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xix 1. The Policy Context . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 2. Recent Macro-Financial Developments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 Output and Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .3 Fiscal Developments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4 The External Sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 Money and Banking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .11 3. Global Crises Comparators: Looking for the Minimum . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19 Per Capita Output . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 Depreciation-Inflation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .22 Fiscal . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .23 Debt . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 External Position . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .24 Overall . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25 4. Outlook and Risks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .27 The FX Subsidy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .28 Large Scale Interruptions to Vital Public Services . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .28 Special Focus I: FX Subsidy Reform in the Deliberate Depression . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .31 Background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .31 Macroeconomic Considerations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 Design a Broad-Coverage Subsidy Reform Compensation Scheme . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .36 iii Implementing Broad-Coverage Subsidy Reform Compensation Scheme . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .38 Complementarities between the BC-CT Program and other SSN Programs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39 Special Focus II: Public Service Delivery in the Deliberate Depression . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41 The Electricity Sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .41 Water and Sanitation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42 Education . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .43 Annex . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47 Forecasts of Lebanon’s Real GDP Growth Using MIDAS Regressions: An Update for 2020 and 2021 47 Dynamic Response of Inflation to Currency in Circulation in Lebanon . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51 Unit Root Tests . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51 VAR Variables in Difference . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .52 VAR Variables in (Log) Levels . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53 The Cointegrated VAR: Vector Error Correction Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55 References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57 Global Financial Crises Episodes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .58 The Argentinian Banking Crisis of 1980 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58 The Philippines Financial Crisis of 1981 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59 The Mexican Debt Crisis of 1981–82 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60 The Chilean Banking Crisis of 1981 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .61 The Venezuelan Banking Crisis of 1994 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63 The Argentinian Financial Crisis of 2001–02 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64 The Uruguayan Banking Crisis of 2002 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64 The Greek Financial Crisis 2009 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .66 References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 List of Figures Figure 1 While the Contraction in Real GDP Commenced in 2018, it Accelerated Sharply in 2020 . . . . . . .4 Figure 2 Net Exports are Expected to Be the Sole Positive Contributor to Real GDP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .4 Figure 3 Firm Status . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .5 Figure 4 Large Shortfalls in Revenues Will Induce a Significant Deterioration in the Fiscal Position . . . . . 10 Figure 5 Valuation Effects from Exchange Rate Depreciations Will Pressure the Debt-to-GDP Ratio . . . . .10 Figure 6 A Steady Depletion in the Gross Foreign Exchange Position at BdL. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 Figure 7 Ratios of C1, C2b, Luxury and Other Imports Were Stable Until the Period Leading to the Crisis… . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 Figure 8 …when Ratios of C1 and C2b Imports Rose at the Expense of those for Luxury and Other Goods. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 Figure 9 A Sharp Depreciation in the Exchange Rate along with Surging Inflation and Narrow Money 13 Figure 10 Inflation in Basic Items is a Key Driver of Overall Inflation, Hurting the Poor and the Middle Class . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 Figure 11 Food Expenditure Shares by Deciles for Lebanese Nationals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .13 Figure 12 Heavy Deleveraging of Assets (Private Loans) and Liabilities (Private Deposits) in Financial Sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 Figure 13 A Steady and Sharp Deterioration in Credit Performance as Measured by NPL Ratio for Banks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18 iv LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) Figure 14 Lebanon’s Real GDP is a More Accurate Reference Point for the Start of the Financial Crisis than Real GDP/Capita . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .21 Figure 15 Real GDP Per Capita for G8 Plus Lebanon . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .22 Figure 16 Real GDP Per Capita for G8 Plus Lebanon . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .22 Figure 17 CPI Indices for G8 Plus Lebanon . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 Figure 18 Overall Fiscal Balance for G8 Plus Lebanon . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 Figure 19 CPI Indices for G8 Plus Lebanon . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 Figure 20 Overall Fiscal Balance for G8 Plus Lebanon . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 Figure 21 Gross Debt for G8 Plus Lebanon . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 Figure 22 Current Account Balance for G8 Plus Lebanon . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .25 Figure 23 A Steady Depletion in the Gross Foreign Exchange Position at BdL . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33 Figure 24 Upon Removal of FX Subsidy, Direct Effects on Inflation Are Substantial . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35 Figure 25 Proposed Monthly Benefit Amount (US$), and Coverage (%), by Year . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37 Figure 26 Compensation Program Outlay and Net Savings from Phase I Subsidy Withdrawal, US$ mn 37 Figure 27 Evolution of High Frequency Indicators Used to Nowcast and Forecast Lebanon’s Real GDP Growth in 2020 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 Figure 28 Growth of High Frequency Real Economy Indicators Used to Nowcast and Forecast Lebanon’s Real GDP Growth in 2021 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .50 Figure 29 Time Series Dynamics of the Variables in Changes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53 Figure 30 Responses to a 1 Percent Increase in the Growth of Currency in Circulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54 Figure 31 Time Series Dynamics of the Variables in Log Levels . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .55 Figure 32 Responses to a 1 Percent Increase in the (Log of) Currency in Circulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56 Figure 33 Responses to a 1 Percent Increase in (the Log of) Currency in Circulation from a VECM . . . . . .57 List of Tables Table 1 Average Change in Full-Time Employees by Gender for All Firms Surveyed. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .6 Table 2 Summary of Fiscal Accounts Showing Actual Numbers, WB Estimates and Government Budgets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 Table 3 Crisis Severity: Percent Decline in Per Capita GDP, Duration of Contraction, and Years to Full Recovery in 25 of the Worst Systemic Banking Crises, 1857–2013 . . . . . . . . . 20 Table 4 Selected Macroeconomic Indicators for Lebanon; 2016–2021 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29 Table 5 Cost of FX Import Subsidy and Impact of its Removal . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 Table 6 Real GDP Growth Forecasts for 2020 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 Table 7 Candidate Predictor Variables for the Real High Frequency Indicators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .49 Table 8 Forecasts of Real GDP Growth for 2021 Using Real Activity Indicators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .49 Table 9 Forecasts of Real GDP Growth for 2021 Using Real Activity and Financial Indicators . . . . . . . . . 51 Table 10 Unit Root Tests . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52 Table 11 Cumulative Effect of a 1 Percent Increase in Currency in Circulation on Inflation . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52 Table 12 Cumulative Effect of a 1 Percent Increase in Currency in Circulation on Inflation . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54 Table 13 The Johansen (1988) Trace Statistic . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .56 Table 14 Cumulative Effect of a 1 Percent Increase in Currency in Circulation on Inflation . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57 List of Boxes Box 1 The Impact of Multiple Crises on Formal Firms and the Labor Market in Lebanon . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 Box 2 Lebanon’ 2021 Budget Draft Proposal . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 Box 3 Impact of Crises on Poverty . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .13 Box 4 The Most Recent Financial Operation by BdL with Commercial Banks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .14 TABLE OF CONTENTS v ACRONYMS AER Average Exchange Rate LBP Lebanese Pound BdL Banque du Liban LEM Lebanon Economic Monitor BoP Balance of Payments MIDAS Mixed-Data Sampling CA Current Account MoET Ministry of Economy and Trade CBP Central Bank of the Philippines MTO(s) Money Transfer Operator(s) CBV Central Bank of Venezuela NGO(s) Non-governmental Organizations CD(s) Certificate of Deposit(s) NID National ID CFF Compensatory Financing Facility NIR Net International Reserve CPI Consumer Price Index NPL(s) Non-performing Loan(s) CSI Crisis Severity Index NPTP National Poverty Targeting Program DBP Development Bank of the Philippines NSSF National Social Security Fund ECB European Central Bank O&M Operation and Maintenance EdL Electricité du Liban PEP(s) Politically Exposed Person(s) EFF Extended Fund Facility PISA Programme for International Student EFF Extended Fund Facility Assessment EMU European Monetary Union PMI Purchasing Manager’s Index ES Enterprise Survey PNB Philippines National Bank ESSN Emergency Crisis and COVID-19 PoB Port of Beirut Response Social Safety Net Project POS Point-of-Sale FCV Fragility, Conflict, and Violence Pp Percentage Points FI(s) Financial Institution(s) PSI Private Sector Initiative FSBS Fund for the Stability of the Banking RDNA Rapid Damage and Needs Assessment System SBA Stand-by Arrangement FX Foreign Exchange SDC(s) Social Development Center(s) GDP Gross Domestic Product SSN Social Safety Net GFSM International Government Accounting TB(s) Treasury Bond(s) Standards TD(s) Time Deposit(s) GNI Gross National Income (per capita) UN United Nations GNP Gross National Product US$ United States Dollar GOL Government of Lebanon WE(s) Water Establishment(s) GRM Grievance Redress Mechanism WSS Water Supply and Sanitation IADB Inter-American Development Bank xM 2020 First x months of 2020 IMF International Monetary Fund yoy Year over Year vii PREFACE T he Lebanon Economic Monitor provides (Senior Economist). Special Focus II: Public Service an update on key economic developments Delivery in the Deliberate Depression, has been led by and policies over the past six months. It also Wissam Harake (Senior Economist), Sameh Mobarak presents findings from recent World Bank work on (Senior Energy Specialist), Amal Talbi (Lead Water Lebanon. The Monitor places them in a longer-term Resources Management Specialist), Sally Zgheib and global context and assesses the implications of (Senior Water Supply and Sanitation Specialist), and these developments and other changes in policy on Nathalie Lahire (Senior Economist). The Lebanon the outlook for Lebanon. Its coverage ranges from Economic Monitor has been completed under the the macro-economy to financial markets to indicators guidance of Christos Kostopoulos (Lead Economist), of human welfare and development. It is intended for Eric Le Borgne (Practice Manager) and Saroj Jha a wide audience, including policy makers, business (Country Director). Zeina Khalil (Communications leaders, financial market participants, and the Officer) is the lead on communications, outreach and community of analysts and professionals engaged in publishing. Lebanon. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions The Lebanon Economic Monitor is a product expressed in this Monitor are those of World Bank of the World Bank’s Lebanon Macroeconomics, staff and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Trade and Investment (MTI) team. It was prepared Executive Board of The World Bank or the govern- by Wissam Harake (Senior Economist), Ibrahim ments they represent. Jamali (Consultant) and Naji Abou Hamde For information about the World Bank and its (Economic Analyst) with contributions from Lars activities in Lebanon, including e-copies of this publi- Jessen (Lead Debt Specialist), Haocong Ren (Senior cation, please visit www.worldbank.org.lb Financial Sector Economist), Zeina El Khoury To be included on an email distribution list (Private Sector Specialist), Angela Elzir Assy (Labor for this Lebanon Economic Monitor series and Market Specialist), Ganesh Kumar Seshan (Senior related publications, please contact Alain Barakat Economist), Bilal Malaeb (Economist), Fahmina (abarakat@worldbank.org). For questions and com- Rahman Dutta (Social Protection Specialist) and ments on the content of this publication, please Haneen Ismail Sayed (Lead Operations Officer). contact Wissam Harake (wharake@worldbank.org) Special Focus I: FX Subsidy Reform in the Deliberate or Christos Kostopoulos (ckostopoulos@worldbank. Depression, has been led by Haneen Ismail Sayed org). Questions from the media can be addressed to (Lead Operations Officer), and Wissam Harake Zeina Khalil (zelkhalil@worldbank.org). ix EXECUTIVE SUMMARY T he Lebanon financial and economic crisis is less due to knowledge gaps and quality advice is likely to rank in the top 10, possibly and more the result of a combination of (i) a lack of top three, most severe crises episodes political consensus over effective policy initiatives; globally since the mid-nineteenth century. and (ii) political consensus in defense of a bankrupt This is a conclusion of the Spring 2021 Lebanon economic system, which benefited a few for so long. Economic Monitor (LEM) in which the Lebanon crisis In the face of these challenges, Lebanon lacks a fully- is contrasted with the most severe global crises functioning executive authority and is currently in the episodes as observed by Reinhart and Rogoff (2014)1 process of forming its third Government in a little over over the 1857–2013 period. In fact, Lebanon’s GDP a year. This debilitating institutional void has lasted plummeted from close to US$ 55 billion in 2018 to over 8 months so far. an estimated US$ 33 billion in 2020, with US$ GDP/ The social impact of the crisis, which is capita falling by around 40 percent. Such a brutal already dire, could rapidly become catastrophic; and rapid contraction is usually associated with more than half the population is likely below conflicts or wars. Even prior, the World Bank has long the national poverty line. Those paid in Lebanese identified Lebanon as a Fragility, Conflict & Violence Lira—the bulk of the labor force—are seeing potent pur- (FCV) State, and as such, the dire socio-economic chasing power declines. Phone surveys conducted in conditions risk systemic national failings with regional the end of 2020 by the World Food Program found and potentially global consequences.2 This illustrates that 41 percent of households reported challenges the magnitude of the economic depression that the country is enduring, with sadly no clear turning point on the horizon, given the disastrous deliberate policy 1 Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff (2014), inaction. Recovery from Financial Crises: Evidence from 100 In the Fall 2020 LEM, Lebanon’s economic Episodes, American Economic Review: Papers & crisis was termed The Deliberate Depression. Proceedings 2014, 104(5): 50–55. For over a year, Lebanese authorities countered an 2 In Amin’s Maalouf’s Le Naufrage des Civilisations, translated as The Wreckage of Civilizations, the assailment of compounded crises—namely, the coun- Lebanese author highlights how the failings of the try’s largest peace-time economic and financial crisis, Levant are propagating into a failing of all civilizations. COVID-19 and the Port of Beirut explosion—with delib- Maalouf, Amin (2019), Le Naufrage des Civilisations, erately inadequate policy responses. The inadequacy French & European Publications, Inc., April 2, 2019. xi in accessing food and other basic needs. The share Real GDP growth is estimated to have con- of households having difficulties in accessing health tracted by 20.3 percent in 2020, on the back of a care rose from 25 percent (July-August) to 36 percent 6.7 percent contraction in 2019. In a large part due (Nov-Dec). The unemployment rate also rose among to COVID-19, the tourism sector has been particularly the respondents, from 28 percent in February (pre- hit; tourist arrivals fell by 71.5 percent, (yoy), over the COVID) to nearly 40 percent in Nov-Dec. first five months of 2020 (5M-2020). Meanwhile, con- Lebanon, with a history of civil war and con- struction permits and cement deliveries (proxies for flicts, faces realistic threats to its already fragile the construction and real estate) suffered respective social peace. As previously argued (World Bank, declines of 26.9 percent (yoy) and 44.7 percent (yoy) 20163), the key overarching constraints to develop- over the first 10 months of 2020 (10M-2020). ment in Lebanon are i) elite capture hidden behind the An ostensible improvement in some fiscal veil of confessionalism, and ii) conflicts and violence, indicators (as a percentage of GDP) masks an with these two having a symbiotic relationship: they actual deterioration. Revenues are estimated to feed and strive on each other. Demonstrations, while have declined sharply as a result of the severe eco- more modest in numbers, have recently grown angrier, nomic contraction, with the ratio to GDP falling further erupting in cities across Lebanon to protest against due to an inflation-driven increase in nominal GDP. the dire economic conditions; vital routes are being However, this is more than offset by a larger decline cut off causing significant disruptions to mobility and in current expenditures, which benefited from: lower livelihood; increased crime rates threaten personal interest payments (due to the Eurobond default and security; national fragmentation can allow infiltration a favorable arrangement with BdL on domestic debt); of sinister groups with grave security implications. cuts in transfers; and also a denominator-led GDP Hence, there is growing wariness of potential triggers effect. Hence, while the 2020 overall fiscal balance is to social unrest. estimated to have improved by 0.7 percentage points (pp) to reach –4.9 percent of GDP, the primary bal- ance deteriorated by 2.3 pp to –2.8 percent of GDP. Recent Economic Developments The sharp economic contraction implied a commensurate drop in imports, and conse- Monetary and financial turmoil are driving crisis quently, an anticipated narrowing of the current conditions, more palpably through interactions account deficit. During 10M-2020, merchandize between the exchange rate, narrow money and imports shrank by 45 percent, which drove a 54.8 inflation. Acute exchange market pressures in percent decrease in the trade-in-goods deficit. We Lebanese markets are reflected by heavy fluctuations estimate that the current account deficit fell by 10 pps in the US$ banknote exchange rate, which temporarily to reach 11 percent of GDP in 2020, compared to a breached LBP 15,000/US$, before falling back down. medium-term (2013–2019) average of 22.5 percent of This is within the context of a multiple exchange rate GDP. Nonetheless, the sudden stop in capital inflows system, which includes the official exchange (LBP has implied a steady depletion of foreign exchange 1,507.5/US$) as well Banque du Liban’s (BdL) (FX) reserves at BdL, which exacerbates constraints platform rate set at LBP 3,900/US$. Overall, the World on imports. Bank Average Exchange Rate (AER) depreciated by The burden of the ongoing adjustment/ 129 percent in 2020. Exchange rate pass through deleveraging in the financial sector is highly effects on prices have resulted in surging inflation, regressive, concentrated on smaller depositors, averaging 84.3 percent in 2020. Meanwhile, the stock the bulk of the labor force and smaller busi- of currency in circulation increased by 197 percent, nesses. De facto lirafication and haircuts on dollar even as broad money supply (which includes bank deposits) declined, with the latter weighed down by 3 World Bank (2016) “Lebanon Systematic Country deleveraging in the financial sector. Diagnostic”. xii LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) deposits are significant despite BdL’s and banks’ public services: electricity, water supply, sanita- official commitment to safeguarding deposits. The tion and education. The Deliberate Depression has burden of the ongoing adjustment/deleveraging is further undermined already weak public services via regressive and concentrated on the smaller deposi- two effects: (i) it has significantly increased poverty tors, who lack other source of savings, the local labor rates expanding the demography that is not able to force, that is paid in lira, and smaller businesses. The afford private substitutables (the way citizens had pre- banking sector is advocating for mechanisms that viously adapted to abysmal quality of public services), incorporate state owned assets, gold reserves, and and are thus more dependent on public services; and public real estate in order to overhaul their impaired (ii) threatens financial viability and basic operability balance sheets. This constitutes a bailout of the of the sector by raising its costs and lowering its financial sector and is inconsistent with restructuring revenues. Specifically, principles that protect taxpayers and depositors. These principles include bail in solutions based on • Severe shortage of foreign currency threatens a hierarchy of creditors, starting with banks share- termination of private sector contracts for holders. Government can also apply a wealth tax (on power plant maintenance and temporary power financial and real assets) as a tool to progressively generation. Meanwhile, Electricité du Liban restructure the financial sector. (EdL) revenues, which are in Lebanese pound, are shrinking because of increasing technical, commercial and collection losses. EdL is likely to Special Foci increase rolling blackouts to manage its cashflow shortfalls. The financial and economic crisis has intensified • In 2020, the Water Establishments (WEs) Lebanon’s fragility and fragmentation, increasing witnessed serious depletions in supplies, the risk to social and civil unrest. The crisis revenues, and financial and human resources, has exacerbated long-term national deficiencies while affected by an upward spiral in costs. Due including institutional weaknesses, failed economic to reduced water supply from the WEs in 2020, and social policy, and dismal public service delivery. people have had to rely more on other costlier In such an environment, there is growing weariness and less convenient water alternatives, such as of triggers for social unrest. In this LEM, we highlight water tankers and bottled water, whose prices two potential economic triggers that are under have surged. increased scrutiny, and which can have significant • The breakdown in sanitation services risks social implications. intensifying the spread of water-borne diseases, The first Special Focus examines Lebanon’s adversely impacting an already vulnerable public FX subsidy for critical and essential imports, health. which offers a serious political and social chal- • Compounded crises have placed Lebanon’s lenge. On the one hand, the current FX subsidy education sector under severe strain. The is both distortionary, expensive and regressive. It increase in poverty rates is leading to an exodus exerts considerable stress on Lebanon’s balance of of students from private to public schools—this payments. On the other hand, the subsidy prevents year alone, 54,000 students (11 percent of public the prices of these products from increasing, which sector students)—as well as higher student drop- would exacerbate inflationary-depreciation pressures, outs, especially from the most marginalized further striking at residents purchasing power. households. Further, the most recent school The second Special Focus discusses the closures due to the COVID-19 pandemic have impact that the crises are having on four basic effectively cost students a “lost year” of learning. Executive Summary xiii الموجز ية .وقد أظهرت مسوحات أجراها برنامج األغذية العاملي عرب الهاتف يف أواخر 2020أن دية وس ّ وتهم الرشائ ّ الساحقة للقوى العاملة — تراجعاً بالغاً يف ق ّ 41يف املئة من األرس يصعب عليها الحصول عىل املواد الغذائ ّ عل األزمة االقتصاديّة واملالية التي ترضب لبنان من بني األزمات يا منذ أواسط ً وربا من بني األزمات الثالث ،األكرث حدة عامل ًّ القرن التاسع عرش .إنّها إحدى خالصات تقرير مرصد االقتصاد العرشّ ، ل ّ حاجاتها األساسيّة األخرى .وارتفعت نسبة األرس التي تواجه صعوبات يف اللبناين لربيع ،2021الذي يقارن أزمة لبنان مع األزمات العامليّة األكرث ية من 25يف املئة (متوز/يوليو-آب/أغسطس) الحصول عىل الرعاية الصح ّ ة وفق رينارت Reinhartوروغوف Rogoff (2014)4خالل الحقبة حد ً إىل 36يف املئة (ترشين الثاين/نوفمرب — كانون األول/ديسمرب) .كام أن .2013–1857يف الواقع ،تراجع إجاميل الناتج املحيل يف لبنان من حواىل دل البطالة ارتفع يف صفوف املشمولني باملسح ،فانتقل من 28يف املئة مع ّ 55مليار د.أ .يف العام 2018إىل حواىل 33مليار د.أ .يف العام ،2020 يف شباط/فرباير (ما قبل كوفيد) إىل حواىل 40يف املئة يف ترشين الثاين/ مع تراجع إجاميل الناتج املحيل للفرد بالدوالر األمرييك بنسبة حواىل 40 نوفمرب — كانون األول/ديسمرب. با ما يُعزا مثل هذا االنقباض القايس والرسيع إىل نزاعات يف املئة .غال ً ية،يواجه لبنان ،وهو ذو تاريخ حافل بالنزاعات والحرب األهل ّ نف البنك الدويل لبنان عىل أنّه أو حروب .وحتى قبل ذلك ،لطاملا ص ّ الهش أصالً .فوفق تقرير التشخيص ية تُهدّ د سلمه االجتامعي ّ مخاطر واقع ّ دد الظروف االقتصاديّة دولة هشاشة ،ونزاع ،وعنف ،وبالتايل ،قد تُه ّ املنهجي للبنان (البنك الدويل ،) 2016 ،يعترب العنرصان التاليان من القيود 6 واالجتامعيّة املرتدية بانهيار وطني منهجي تكون له انعكاسات محتملة ية التي ت ُعيق عملية التنمية يف لبنان ( )iالحكم الطائفي ،أي تويل األساس ّ جسد حجم الكساد االقتصادي مم يُ ّ ي االقليمي والعامليّ ،5 عىل املستويَ ْ الحكم من قبل طبقة نخبوية تستخدم ذريعة الطائفية قناعاً لها و()ii الذي يشهده البلد ،من دون بارقة أمل بتغيري تلوح يف األفق ،نظرا ً إىل النزاعات والعنف الناجامن جزئياً عن رصاعات واسعة النطاق يف منطقة التقاعس املتعمد عن اتخاذ السياسات املالمئة. الرشق األوسط ،وهام عنرصان عىل عالقة متكافلة مع بعضهام البعض، وصفت األزمة يف تقرير مرصد االقتصاد اللبناين لخريف ُ ،2020 دة غضب التظاهرات يتغذيان وينموان من بعضهام البعض .وازدادت ح ّ مد» .عىل مدى رض لها لبنان بأنّها «الكساد املتع ّ االقتصاديّة التي يتع ّ جا عىل الظروف االقتصاديّة املرتدية وإن الناشئة يف املدن اللبنانيّة احتجا ً أكرث من عام ،كانت السلطات اللبنانية تواجه وابل األزمات املتعاقبة مم أعاق عا؛ وقُطعت الطرق الحيويّةّ ، كانت أعداد املتظاهرين أكرث تواض ً يام أكرب أزمة مالية واقتصاديّة يشهدها البلد يف زمن السلم، — ال س ّ دد أمن دل الجرمية يُه ّ التنقّالت وكسب لقمة العيش؛ كام أن ارتفاع مع ّ وكوفيد– ،19وانفجار مرفأ بريوت — بسياسات غري مالمئة عمدا ً .وال تعود هذه االستجابات غري املالمئة إىل نقص يف املعلومات أو إىل توجيهات Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff (2014), Recovery 4 دة ،منها( )iغياب اإلجامع خاطئة ،بل هي نتيجة توليفة من عوامل ع ّ from Financial Crises: Evidence from 100 Episodes, American عالة؛ و( )iiاالجامع السيايس يف الدفاع السيايس بشأن مبادرات سياسات ف ّ .Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2014, 104(5): 50–55 دا .ويف وجه هذه مفلس ،أفاد البعض لفرتة طويلة ج ً عن نظام اقتصادي ُ 5يف كتاب أمني معلوف Le Naufrage des Civilisationsالذي تُرجم يف التحديات ،يفتقر لبنان إىل سلطة تنفيذيّة تعمل بشكل كامل وهو يف طور االنجليزيّة إىل ،The Wreckage of Civilizationsيُسلّط الكاتب اللبناين الضوء تشكيل حكومته الثالثة يف أكرث من عام واحد بقليل .ويستمر هذا الفراغ عىل فشل الرشق املتفيش الذي يؤدي إىل فشل الحضارات كلّها. & Maalouf, Amin (2019), Le Naufrage des Civilisations, French وق من أكرث من 8أشهر وحتى هذا التاريخ. املؤسيس املع ّ .European Publications, Inc., April 2, 2019 قد يُصبح األثر االجتامعي لألزمة ،الصعب أصالً ،مأساويًّا .”World Bank (2016) “Lebanon Systematic Country Diagnostic 6 جح أن يكون أكرث من نصف السكان دون خط الفقر الوطني. برسعة؛ يُر َّ (البنك الدويل ( )2016التشخيص املنهجي يف لبنان). يشهد الذين يتقاضون رواتبهم وأجورهم باللرية اللبنانية — أي الغالبية xv در أن يكون عجز الحساب الجاري قد تراجع 10نقاط مئويّة ليبلغ 11 نُق ّ الناس الشخيص؛ وقد يسمح التفكّك الوطني باندساس مجموعات ذات دل عجز ة مع مع ّ يف املئة من إجاميل الناتج املحيل يف العام ،2020مقارن ً نوايا سيئةّ ، مم يولّد انعكاسات خطرية عىل مستوى األمن .وبالتايل يزداد متوسط األجل ( )2019–2013نسبته 22.5يف املئة من إجاميل الناتج القلق ،يف لبنان ،من العوامل التي ميكن أن تؤدي إىل اضطرابات اجتامعية. املحيل .ومع ذلك ،أدّى التوقّف املفاجئ يف التدفقات الرأسامليّة الوافدة إىل تراجع مضطرد الحتياطي مرصف لبنان من العمالت األجنبيةّ ، مم يفاقم القيود عىل الواردات. التط ّ ورات املاكرو-اقتصادية واملالية األخرية عتب عبء التكيف الجاري /تقليص ميزانية القطاع املرصيف ي َُ ية الساحقة يا بشكل كبري ،يُركّز عىل املودعني الصغار ،والغالب ّ تراجع ًّ تضح ذلك بشكل ية والنقديّة ظروف األزمة ،و ي ّ تقود االضطرابات املال ّ عتب ترصيف الودائع إىل اللرية ُ َ ي الصغرية. واملؤسسات العاملة، للقوى يةّ النقد والكتلة ّم، خ والتض الرصف، سعر بني التفاعل ملموس من خالل اللبنانيّة واالقتطاع من الودائع بالدوالر األمرييك أمرا ً واقعاً ،بالرغم من مبعناها الضيق .تنعكس الضغوط الحادة لسوق الرصف عىل األسواق اإللتزام الرسمي من قبل املصارف ومرصف لبنان بحامية الودائع .يُ َ عتب ية عىل شكل تقلّبات كبرية يف سعر رصف الدوالر األمرييك مقابل اللبنان ّ عبء التكيف الجاري /تقليص ميزانية القطاع املرصيف تراجعيًّا ويُركّز اللرية اللبنانيّة ،الذي تجاوز بشكل مؤقت 15ألف لرية لبنانيّة ،قبل أن عىل املودعني الصغار ،الذين يفتقرون إىل مصادر ادخار أخرى ،والقوى ددة تشمل يرتاجع مجددا ً .ويندرج ذلك يف سياق نظام أسعار رصف متع ّ العاملة املحلية التي تتقاىض أجورها ورواتبها باللرية اللبنانيّة ،واملؤسسات سعر الرصف الرسمي ( 1د.أ 1507.5 = .ل.ل ،).باإلضافة إىل سعر رصف يات تشمل أصوالً متلكها الصغرية .يدعو القطاع املرصيف إىل وضع آل ّ منصة مرصف لبنان البالغ 1د.أ 3900 = .ل.ل ،.وبشكل عام ،تراجع الدولة ،واحتياطي الذهب ،والعقارات العامة من أجل إصالح ميزانيّاتهم متوسط سعر الرصف الذي يحتسبه البنك الدويل بنسبة 129يف املئة يف مم يُشكّل عملية إنقاذ من القطاع العام للقطاع املايل ،ال الضعيفةّ ، مم أدّى إىل زيادة العام .2020وأث ّرت تقلّبات سعر الرصف عىل األسعارّ ، تتامىش مع مبادئ إعادة الهيكلة التي تحمي دافعي الرضائب .وتشمل التضخّم ليبلغ 84.3يف املئة يف العام .2020ويف موازاة ذلك ،ازداد مخزون ية الدائنني، هذه املبادئ حلول إنقاذ مبشاركة داخل ّية عىل أساس هرم ّ العملة املتداولة بنسبة 197يف املئة ،حتى بعد تراجع الكتلة النقديّة يكن للحكومة أن تفرض رضيبة ءا من املساهمني يف املصارف .كام ُ بد ً مبعناها الواسع (التي تشمل الودائع املرصفيّة) ،والتي تأث ّرت بدورها ية) كأداة من أجل إعادة ّ املال واألصول ةّ ي العقار األصول (عىل الرثوات عىل بتقليص ميزانية القطاع املرصيف. هيكلة القطاع املايل بشكل تقدمي. يُقدَّ ر تقلّص منو إجاميل الناتج املحيل الحقيقي بنسبة 20.3 يف املئة يف العام ،2020إثر تقلّص بنسبة 6.7يف املئة يف العام .2019 رض قطاع السياحة إىل رضبة قويّة بشكل خاص ،ناجمة إىل حد وقد تع ّ مجاالت الرتكيز الخاصة بعيد عن كوفيد – 19؛ وتراجع عدد املسافرين الوافدين بنسبة 71.5يف املئة (من سنة ألخرى) ،عىل مدى األشهر الخمسة األوىل من العام 2020 ية من هشاشة لبنان وتفكّكه ،مام زاد من زادت األزمة املالية واالقتصاد ّ يات تسليم ( .)5M-2020ويف موازاة ذلك ،شهدت تراخيص البناء وعمل ّ خطر االضطرابات املدنية واالجتامعية .وزادت األزمة من أوجه الخلل االسمنت ،وهي من مؤرشات أنشطة قطاعي البناء والعقارات ،تراج ً عا ية ية ،والسياسة االجتامع ّ الطويلة األمد ،مبا يف ذلك مكامن الضعف املؤسس ّ سنويًا قدره 26.9و 44.7يف املئة عىل التوايل ،خالل األشهر العرشة األوىل واالقتصاديّة الفاشلة ،والخدمات العامة السيئة .ويف ظل هذا السياق، من العام .)10M-2020( 2020 يزداد القلق ،يف لبنان ،من العوامل التي ميكن أن تؤدي إىل اضطرابات تحسن ظاهري يف بعض املؤرشات املالية يخفي ّ يف الواقعُ ، َي ي محتمل ْ اجتامعية .يف هذا التقرير ،نسلّط الضوء عىل محركّني اقتصاديَّ ْ در تراجع را فعل ًّ يا .يُق َّ (كنسبة مئويّة من إجاميل الناتج املحيل) تدهو ً ية ملحوظة. يكن أن يكون لهام انعكاسات اجتامع ّ قيد التدقيق املتزايدُ ، االيرادات بشكل حاد نتيجة االنقباض االقتصادي الشديد ،مع تراجع ينظر مجال الرتكيز األول يف دعم الرصف األجنبي يف لبنان النسبة إىل إجاميل الناتج املحيل بشكل أكرب بسبب زيادة إجاميل الناتج ياً. يا وسياس ًّ يا جدّ ّ يا اجتامع ًّ مة ،والذي يشكّل تحد ً ية وامله ّللواردات األساس ّ املحيل اإلسمي الناجمة عن التضخّم .لكن ،يُقابل ذلك تراجع أكرب يف عتب دعم الرصف األجنبي الحايل تشويهيًّا ،ومكلفًا ،وتراجعيًّا. من جهة ،يُ َ مم ييل :انخفاض تسديدات الفوائد النفقات الجارية ،التي تستفيد ّ فهو يشكل ضغوطًا كبرية عىل ميزان املدفوعات يف لبنان .ومن جهة أخرى، (بسبب عدم سداد اليوروبوندز وبسبب ترتيب مالئم مع مرصف لبنان مم يزيد من ضغوط يحول الدعم دون زيادة أسعار هذه املنتجاتّ ، د من التحويالت؛ باإلضافةهنا أيضاً إىل أثر بشأن الدين املحيل)؛ والح ّ ية للمواطنني. ّ رش ائ ال د أكرث من القدرة التضخّم-انخفاض قيمة العملة ،فيح ّ ارتفاع إجاميل الناتج املحيل (الذي يؤدي إىل انخفاض النسبة) .وبالتايل، رق مجال الرتكيز الثاين إىل وقع األزمات عىل أربع خدمات ويتط ّ تحسن امليزان املايل الكيل للعام 2020بقدر 0.7نقطة مئوية ليبلغ مع ّ ية :الكهرباء ،وإمدادات املياه ،والرصف الصحي ،والتعليم. عامة أساس ّ -4.9يف املئة من إجاميل الناتج املحيل ،تراجع الرصيد األويل 2.3نقطة مد بشكل أكرب الخدمات العامة الضعيفة أصالً فقد أضعف الكساد املتع ّ مئويّة إىل -2.8يف املئة من إجاميل الناتج املحيل. فتوسع بشكل ملحوظ عدد ّ الفقر الت د ّ مع زيادة ريْن)i( : من خالل أث َ أدى االنقباض االقتصادي الحاد إىل تراجع متناسب يف الواردات، ّ السكان غري القادرين عىل تكبّد كلفة الخدمات البديلة الخاصة (السبل وبالتايل ،من املنتظر أن يؤدي إىل تقلّص يف عجز الحساب الجاري .خالل ية الخدمات العامة يف مع نوع ّ التي اعتمدها املواطنون يف السابق للتك ّ األشهر العرشة األوىل من العام ،2020تقلّصت واردات السلع بنسبة 45 املرتدية) ،فباتوا يعتمدون بالتايل بشكل أكرب عىل الخدمات العامة؛ و()ii عا يف عجز التجارة يف السلع قدره 54.8يف املئة. مم ولّد تراج ً يف املئةّ ، xvi )LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3 التكاليف .وبسبب تراجع إمدادات املياه من مؤسسات املياه يف العام تهديد االستمراربة املالية للقطاع وعمله األسايس من خالل زيادة ة وأقل ،2020كان عىل املواطنني االعتامد عىل بدائل أخرى أكرث كلف ً تكاليفه وخفض إيراداته. مالءمةً ،عىل غرار صهاريج املياه وقوارير املياه ،التي ارتفعت أسعارها. وبشكل خاص، دد تراجع خدمات الرصف الصحي بزيادة انتشار األمراض املنقولة •يُه ّ با عىل الصحة العامة الهشّ ة أصالً. ً سل ّر ثيؤ مم ّ املياه، يف ية بإنهاء عقود القطاع الخاص •يُه ّ دد االفتقار الحاد للعمالت األجنب ّ •شكّلت األزمات املتعاقبة ضغوطًا كبرية عىل قطاع التعليم يف لبنان. لصيانة محطات توليد الطاقة الكهربائيّة وتوليد الطاقة املؤقت .ويف دالت الفقر إىل نزوح جامعي للطالب من املدارس تؤدي زيادة مع ّ الوقت نفسه ،تتقلّص إيرادات رشكة كهرباء لبنان ،التي هي باللرية الخاصة إىل املدارس الرسمية — بلغ هذا العام وحده 54000 اللبنانيّة ،بسبب الخسائر الفنية والتجاريّة املتزايدة وتلك املرتبطة دل تلميذ ( 11يف املئة من تالمذة القطاع العام) – باإلضافة إىل مع ّ بالجباية .ويُتوقَّع أن تزيد مؤسسة كهرباء لبنان من فرتات التأنني يف رسب مدريس أعىل ،ال سيّام من األرس األكرث تهميشً ا .إىل ذلك ،خرس ت ّ التغذية بالتيار الكهربايئ إلدارة القصور يف تدفقاتها النقديّة. را ً مؤخ أبوابها املدارس إقفال مع ّم ل التع من ا م ً عا ً ا فعلي التالمذة •يف العام ،2020افتقرت مؤسسات املياه إىل اإلمدادات وااليرادات بسبب جائحة كوفيد.-19 واملوارد البرشية واملاليّة بشكل خطر ،يف ما شهدت زيادة مضطردة يف الموجز xvii RÉSUMÉ L a crise économique et financière qui sévit an, les autorités libanaises ont été assaillies par une au Liban est probablement l’une des dix, série de crises successives — à savoir, la plus grande voire l’une des trois pires crises que le crise financière et économique du pays en temps de monde ait connu depuis le milieu du XIXe siècle. paix, la COVID-19 et l’explosion du Port de Beyrouth Telle est la conclusion de l’édition Printemps 2021 de — auxquelles ils ont apporté des réponses politiques l’Observatoire économique du Liban (ou LEM, pour délibérément inadéquates. Inadéquations qui mal- Lebanon Economic Monitor), dans laquelle la crise au heureusement ne proviennent pas d’un manque Liban est considérée comme l’une des crises mondiales d’informations ou de mauvaises directives mais d’une les plus sévères au regard de la liste établie par Reinhart combinaison (i) d’un manque de consensus politique et Rogoff (2014)7 durant la période 18572013. En effet, à l’égard d’initiatives de politiques effectives ; et le PIB du Liban a chuté de 55 milliards de dollars en (ii) d’un consensus politique qui défend un système 2018 à environ 33 milliards de dollars en 2020, avec économique en faillite — un système qui a profité à une baisse d’environ 40 % du PIB par habitant. Une certains pendant longtemps. Face à ces défis, le pays telle contraction, si brutale et rapide, est d’habitude est actuellement doté d’un pouvoir exécutif qui n’est attribuée à des conflits ou des guerres. La Banque pas pleinement fonctionnel, attendant la formation mondiale a longtemps considéré le Liban, et ce, bien de son troisième gouvernement en un peu plus d’un avant la crise, comme un pays en situation de fragilité, an, et est paralysé par un vide institutionnel qui dure conflit et violence (FCV). À ce titre, il est possible que depuis plus de 8 mois. les conditions socio-économiques difficiles que connaît L’impact social de la crise, déjà désastreux, le pays risquent d’entraîner une faillite systémique à peut rapidement devenir catastrophique; plus de l’échelle nationale, avec d’éventuelles conséquences la moitié de la population serait en-dessous du mondiales.8 Ceci illustre la magnitude de la dépression économique que le pays subit, et, malheureusement, 7 Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff (2014), le fait qu’aucune perspective de changement ne soit Recovery from Financial Crises: Evidence from 100 à l’horizon eu égard à l’inaction désastreuse mais Episodes, American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2014, 104(5): 50–55. néanmoins choisie des politiques. 8 Dans l’ouvrage d’Amin Maalouf (2019), Le Naufrage des Dans l’édition Automne 2020 du LEM, la Civilisations, l’Académicien et auteur libanais montre crise économique que traverse le Liban a été qua- comment les échecs du Levant se transforment en un lifié de Dépression Délibérée. Pendant plus d’un échec de toutes les civilisations. xix seuil national de pauvreté. Ceux qui sont payés en et l’augmentation rapide de la masse monétaire, livres libanaises — soit la majorité de la main-d’œuvre sont des conditions génératrices de crises. — ont vu et voient leur pouvoir d’achat se rétrécir Les sévères pressions du marché de change sur comme une peau de chagrin. Selon des sondages les marchés libanais sont illustrées par de lourdes téléphoniques menés fin 2020 par le Programme fluctuations du taux de change de la livre face au alimentaire mondial (PAM), 41 % des ménages ont dollar américain, qui a temporairement dépassé rapporté des difficultés à accéder à la nourriture LBP 15 000/US$, avant de baisser à nouveau. Ceci et à d’autres besoins fondamentaux. La part des s’inscrit dans le cadre d’un système à taux de change ménages connaissant des difficultés à accéder aux multiples, qui comprend le taux de change officiel à services de santé est passée de 25 % en juillet-août à LBP 1 507,5/US$, ainsi que celui de la plateforme 36 % en novembre-décembre. Le taux de chômage a de la Banque du Liban (BdL) à LBP 3 900/US$. En également augmenté parmi les répondants, passant général, le taux de change effectif moyen calculé de 28 % en février (avant la COVID) à environ 40 % en par la Banque mondiale (AER) a baissé de 129 % novembre-décembre. en 2020. L’impact des fluctuations des taux de Le Liban, historiquement touché par les change sur les prix a provoqué une recrudescence conflits et la guerre civile, est confronté à des de l’inflation, enregistrant une moyenne de 84,3 % en menaces réalistes qui mettent en danger sa 2020. En parallèle, le stock de monnaie en circulation paix sociale déjà fragile. Comme il a été mis en a augmenté de 197 %, même si la masse monétaire évidence par le passé (Banque mondiale, 20169), les au sens large (qui comprend les dépôts bancaires) principales contraintes au développement au Liban s’est réduite en raison du désendettement du secteur sont i) l’accaparement des ressources par l’élite, financier. sous couvert de confessionnalisme et ii) les conflits La croissance du PIB réel a connu une et la violence — ces deux facteurs entretenant une contraction de 20,3 % en 2020, aggravant celle relation symbiotique, l’un se nourrissant de l’autre déjà importante de 6.7 % observée en 2019. Le pour se développer mutuellement. La colère des secteur du tourisme a été particulièrement touché, manifestations, bien que plus modestes en nombre, en grande partie en raison de la COVID-19 ; les est récemment montée d’un cran, émergeant dans arrivées de touristes ont baissé de 71,5 %, (d’une des villes à travers le Liban pour protester contre année sur l’autre), durant les cinq premiers mois de les conditions économiques exsangues. De ce fait, 2020 (5M-2020). Dans le même temps, les permis l’accès à des routes vitales est coupé, entraînant des de construction et les livraisons de ciment (moyens interruptions prolongées qui entravent la mobilité et intermédiaires pour la construction et l’immobilier) réduisent plus encore les moyens de subsistance ; ont baissé de 26,9 % (d’une année sur l’autre) et de l’augmentation des taux de criminalité menace la 44,7 % (d’une année sur l’autre) durant les dix pre- sécurité des personnes ; et la fragmentation nationale miers mois de 2020 (10M-2020). peut permettre l’infiltration de groupes menaçants, ce Une amélioration apparente de certains qui aurait des implications graves sur la sécurité du indicateurs fiscaux (en pourcentage du PIB) pays. Les politiciens-timoniers du Liban, bloquant la masque une détérioration effective et notoire. barre du pays, le rapprochent ainsi inexorablement Les revenus ont baissé de manière significative de récifs meurtriers et d’un naufrage tragique. en raison d’une sévère contraction économique, le ratio au PIB se détériorant davantage à cause d’une augmentation du PIB nominal due à l’inflation Les récents développements galopante. Toutefois, cette situation est largement économiques compensée par une baisse plus importante des Les turbulences monétaires et financières, et 9 World Bank (2016) “Lebanon Systematic Country plus concrètement le taux de change, l’inflation Diagnostic”. xx LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) dépenses courantes, ayant bénéficié des éléments des principes de restructuration visant à protéger les suivants : des paiements d’intérêts inférieurs (en contribuables et les déposants. Ces principes com- raison du défaut de paiement des Eurobonds et d’un prennent des solutions de cautionnement basées arrangement favorable, bien qu’illusoire au niveau du sur une hiérarchie de créditeurs, à commencer par secteur publique consolidé, avec la BdL concernant les actionnaires des banques. Le gouvernement peut la dette intérieure) ; des baisses de transferts ; et d’un également imposer un impôt sur la fortune (actifs PIB sur la base d’un dénominateur. Ainsi, alors que le financiers et biens immobiliers) comme moyen de res- solde budgétaire global de 2020 a progressé de 0,7 tructurer de manière progressive le secteur financier. point de pourcentage (pp) pour atteindre –4,9 % du PIB, le solde primaire a régressé de 2,3 pp, atteignant –2.8 % du PIB. Les champs d’intérêt particuliers La contraction économique accrue signifie une baisse conséquente des importations, et La crise économique et financière a accentué la donc, une réduction anticipée du déficit du compte fragilité et la fragmentation du Liban, augmentant courant. Durant les dix premiers mois de 2020 ainsi le risque de mécontentement social et civil. (10M-2020), les importations de marchandises ont La crise a exacerbé les déficiences nationales à régressé de 45 %, provoquant une baisse de 54,8 % long terme, y compris les fragilités institutionnelles, du déficit lié aux échanges de biens. Nous estimons la politique socioéconomique tenue en échec que le déficit du compte courant a baissé de 10 et la mauvaise prestation des services publics. points de pourcentage pour atteindre 11 % du PIB en Dans un tel contexte, le pays connaît une lassitude 2020, à comparer avec la moyenne à moyen terme grandissante face à d’éventuels facteurs susceptibles (2013–2019) de 22.5 % du PIB. Toutefois, l’arrêt sou- de déclencher un mécontentement social. Dans cette dain et soutenu des flux de capitaux entrants signifie édition du LEM, nous mettons l’accent sur deux un épuisement continu des réserves de change (FX) éventuels éléments déclencheurs qui sont de plus en à la BdL, accentuant par là-même les contraintes sur plus l’objet d’une attention particulière, et qui auraient les importations. des implications sociales de grande envergure. Le fardeau de l’ajustement en cours/du Le premier champ d’intérêt particulier désendettement dans le secteur financier est concerne la bonification des réserves étrangères particulièrement régressif, concentré sur de au Liban pour les importations essentielles petits déposants, la plus grande majorité de la et critiques, ce qui constitue un véritable défi maind’œuvre, et des entreprises de taille plus sociopolitique. D’une part, en plus d’être onéreuse modeste. De facto, la « lirafication » et les « haircuts » et régressive, la bonification des réserves étrangères (les « ponctions ») sur les dépôts en dollars sont a présentement un effet de distorsion et exerce en importants, malgré l’engagement officiel de la Bdl et outre des pressions considérables sur la balance des des banques à sauvegarder les dépôts. Le fardeau paiements du Liban. D’autre part, elle empêche une de l’ajustement en cours/du désendettement dans augmentation du prix de ces produits, ce qui accen- le secteur financier est particulièrement régressif tuerait les pressions générées par l’inflation et la et concentré sur de petits déposants qui n’ont pas dépréciation et porterait un coup au pouvoir d’achat d’autres sources d’épargne, une maind’œuvre locale de la population. rémunérée en livres libanaises et des entreprises de Le deuxième champ d’intérêt particulier taille plus modeste. Le secteur bancaire appelle à la porte sur l’impact que les crises ont sur quatre mise en place de mécanismes qui tiennent compte services publics de base : l’électricité, l’eau, les des biens de l’État, des réserves en or et des actifs services sanitaires et l’éducation. La Dépression immobiliers publics afin de rétablir l’équilibre de Délibérée a davantage fragilisé les services publics ses bilans déficients. Il s’agit d’un renflouement du déjà vulnérables de deux façons : (i) elle a augmenté secteur financier qui ne s’inscrit pas dans le cadre de manière significative les taux de pauvreté, Résumé xxi élargissant ainsi la portion de la population n’ayant en eau, de revenus et de ressources financières pas les moyens de se payer des biens et services et humaines, qui est venue s’ajouter à la privés de substitution (ce qui était la manière dont la flambée des coûts. En 2020, en raison de cet population s’était auparavant adaptée à la prestation approvisionnement limité, la population a été de services publics de mauvaise qualité) et étant, par obligée de recourir à d’autres alternatives plus conséquent, davantage dépendante des services onéreuses et moins pratiques, telles que les publics ; et (ii) elle menace la viabilité financière et citernes d’eau et l’eau en bouteille, dont les prix l’opérabilité fondamentale du secteur en augmentant se sont envolés. ses coûts et en baissant ses revenus. L’on retient plus • La dégradation des services d’assainissement particulièrement les éléments suivants : risque d’intensifier la propagation de maladies transmises par l’eau, ce qui affectera de manière • Une sévère pénurie de devises étrangères négative la santé publique déjà vulnérable. menace la résiliation des contrats du secteur • Les crises successives auxquelles le Liban a été privé pour l’entretien des centrales électriques confronté ont exercé de sévères pressions sur et la génération provisoire d’électricité. Dans le le secteur de l’éducation. En raison des taux de même temps, les revenus d’Électricité du Liban pauvreté élevés, les élèves ont abandonné les (EdL), qui sont en livres libanaises, ont été réduits écoles privées au profit des écoles publiques — considérablement en raison des pertes techniques cette année seulement, 54 000 élèves (11 % des et commerciales et du manque de paiements élèves du secteur public). À noter également : collectés. Il se pourrait donc qu’EdL augmente un taux d’abandon scolaire plus élevé, ses coupures de courant rotatives afin de pouvoir particulièrement au sein des ménages les plus gérer son manque de flux de trésorerie. marginalisés. En outre, la récente fermeture des • En 2020, les Offices des Eaux ont connu une écoles en raison de la COVID-19 a fait perdre aux grave pénurie en matière d’approvisionnement élèves une année d’apprentissage. xxii LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) 1 THE POLICY CONTEXT L ebanon faces a dangerous depletion of the local labor force and smaller businesses. De resources, including human capital since facto Lirafication and haircuts on dollar deposits are brain drain has become an increasingly ongoing despite BdL’s and banks’ official commit- desperate option. Over a year into the financial crisis, ment to safeguarding deposits. The burden of the Lebanon has yet to identify, least of all embark upon, a ongoing adjustment/deleveraging is regressive credible path toward economic and financial recovery. and concentrated on the smaller depositors who In fact, Lebanon lacks a fully-functioning executive lack other source of savings, the local labor force authority and is currently in the process of forming that is paid in LBP, and smaller businesses. The its third Government in a little over a year. Meanwhile, banking sector is advocating for mechanisms that social discontent has spilled over to street action incorporate state-owned assets, gold reserves, and even under COVID-19 conditions; internal political public real estate in order to overhaul their impaired discord and fragmentation continues; and geopolitical balance sheets. This constitutes a bailout of the tensions complicate solutions. In consequence, highly financial sector and is inconsistent with the restruc- skilled labor is increasingly likely to take up potential turing principles that protect taxpayers. These opportunities abroad, constituting a permanent social principles include bail in solutions based on a hier- and economic loss for the country. archy of creditors, starting with banks’ shareholders. Lebanese authorities and the IMF began Government can also apply a wealth tax (on financial discussions in May 2020. The discussions even- and real assets) as a tool to progressively restructure tually stalled as differences and inconsistencies the financial sector. emerged within the Lebanon team regarding the Lebanon urgently needs to adopt and Government’s financial recovery program. IMF dis- implement a credible, comprehensive and coor- cussions await the formation of new Government. dinated macro-financial stability strategy, within The burden of the ongoing adjustment/ a medium-term macro-fiscal framework. This deleveraging in the financial sector is highly strategy would be based on: (i) a debt restructuring regressive, concentrated on smaller depositors, program that would achieve short-term fiscal space 1 and medium-term debt sustainability; (ii) comprehen- confidence and stability in the exchange rate; (iv) a sively restructuring the financial sector in order to phased fiscal adjustment aimed at regaining confi- regain solvency of the banking sector; (iii) adopting dence in fiscal policy; (v) growth enhancing reforms; a new monetary policy framework that would regain and (vi) enhanced social protection. 2 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) 2 RECENT MACRO- FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS Output and Demand is the lowest PMI recorded since it was first published in 2013 (see Box 1 for the impact on firms and labor The compounded crises, namely, the financial market). Meanwhile, the real estate sector has been crisis, COVID-19 and the Port of Beirut (PoB) subject to two offsetting factors; on the one hand, con- explosion, have had staggered impacts on struction permits and cement deliveries—considered output and with differentiated magnitudes. Due to to be indicators of future and ongoing construction, insufficient high frequency data, precise identification respectively—suffered respective declines of 26.9 of each of those impacts is a challenging task. In percent (yoy) and 44.7 percent (yoy) over 10M-2020. order to draw empirical conclusions, we resort to a On the other hand, throughout 2020 real estate combination of methodologies and models. To gauge sales thrived as some depositors sought means to the impact of financial crisis along with COVID-19 utilize their otherwise untransferable bank deposits.13 effects, we use Mixed-Data Sampling (MIDAS) methods to assess the state of the economic cycle 10 World Bank (2020), Beirut Rapid Damage and Needs using available high frequency measures of economic Assessment, August 2020. activity (See Annex A). The World Bank had earlier 11 According to the RDNA, the disaster event is estimated to cause (i) up to 0.4 and 0.6 percentage point (pp) declines in estimated the economic impact of the PoB explosion the growth rate of real GDP in 2020 and 2021, respectively, through a Rapid Damage and Needs Assessment due to losses in the stock of physical capital; plus potentially (RDNA).10,11 (ii) import constraints that could subtract an additional of 0.4 Real GDP is estimated to have contracted and 1.3 pps from growth in 2020 and 2021, respectively. by 20.3 percent in 2020 (Figure 1).12 High frequency 12 This represents a slight downward revision from the Fall indicators support a substantial contraction in eco- 2020 LEM which projected a 19.2 percent contraction in real GDP growth for 2020. nomic activity. BLOM’s monthly Purchasing Manager’s 13 The financial sector facilitated real estate purchases using Index (PMI), which captures private sector activity, pre-October 2019 dollar deposits under conditions of capital averaged 41.1 over 2020—PMI values below 50 rep- controls (and therefore, lack of alternatives to get those resent a contraction in economic activity. In fact, this deposits out), leading to an increase in such purchases. 3 While the Contraction in Real GDP FIGURE 1 • Net Exports are Expected to be the FIGURE 2 • Commenced in 2018, it Accelerated Sole Positive Contributor to Real GDP Sharply in 2020 Real GDP Components Real GDP Growth (%) 15 20 10 16.4 5 15 11.3 10.8 0 10.2 9.1 9.3 10 8.1 –5 8.0 7.5 2.7 6.4 –10 3.9 3.8 3.8 5 3.9 3.4 2.5 2.5 1.7 1.5 1.5 –0.8 1.1 0.9 0.9 –15 0.2 0 –20 –1.9 –5 –25 –6.7 –10 –30 –35 –15 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020e –20 Private Consumption Government Consumption 2020 –20.3 –25 Gross Fixed Capital Investment Net Exports 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 Statistical Discrepancy Real GDP Growth Sources: CAS and WB staff calculations. Sources: CAS and WB staff calculations. Real estate registration fees increased by 104.8 Fiscal Developments percent in 2020. The retail sector suffered siz- able losses, due to a combination of the financial An ostensible improvement in fiscal indicators crisis and the COVID-19 lockdown measures. BTA (as a percentage of GDP) masks an actual Fransabank retail trade index (in real terms) declined deterioration. While both revenue and expenditure by 73.1 percent over the first nine months of 2020 sharply contracted as a ratio of GDP due to the (9M-2020). crisis, the net impact on the overall fiscal balance On the demand side, net exports was the was positive. Revenues are estimated to have sole contributor to growth in 2020, for the second reached 11.5 percent of GDP in 2020, down by a year in a row (Figure 2). According to Custom’s data, staggering 9.1 pp of GDP from the previous year. the merchandise trade deficit was reduced by 54.8 This deterioration was the result of a two-pronged percent (yoy) over the first 11 months of 2020 (11M- development. First, depressed economic activity 2020), benefitting from a 45.4 percent (yoy) retraction induced significant reductions in tax and non-tax in imports and despite a 4.2 percent (yoy) decrease revenues in nominal terms. Second, a substantial in exports. The improving merchandise trade balance increase in nominal GDP—as a sharp increase in has been partially offset by a deterioration in the the GDP deflator more than offset the contraction in trade in services balance, as a result of COVID-19’s real economic activity—created a denominator effect, substantial impact on the tourist sector; tourist arrivals adding to the sharp decline of revenues as a percent decreased by 71.5 percent (yoy) in the first five of GDP. Similarly, expenditures are estimated to have months of 2020, and hotel occupancy rate (published fallen to 16.4 percent of GDP in 2020, down by a by Ernst & Young) averaged a mere 16.6 percent mammoth 14.8 pp of GDP compared to 2019. This over 9M-2020. Similarly, private consumption, which fall is primarily attributed to a decrease in current averaged 92.3 percent of GDP over 2015–2018, is expenditures, which benefited from: lower debt- estimated to have taken a severe blow in 2020; Byblos servicing costs due to the default on foreign debt; Bank/AUB’s consumer confidence index declined a favorable arrangement with BdL on its holding by 65.1 percent in 9M-2020, compared to the same of Treasury Bonds (TBs); lower transfers; and a period in 2019. denominator-led GDP effect. As a result, overall fiscal 4 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) BOX 1: THE IMPACT OF MULTIPLE CRISES ON FORMAL FIRMS AND THE LABOR MARKET IN LEBANONa,b Impact on Firms The World Bank conducts Enterprise Surveys regularly in active member countries. It conducted one such survey in Lebanon in 2019/2020; this happened to be a pre-crisis survey, as the country would be subsequently hit by compounded crises—the financial crisis, COVID-19 and the August 4th explosion at the Port of Beirut (PoB). To assess the impact on firms from these crises, a follow up survey was conducted in Lebanon in November 2020. From the surveys, we find that almost one out of five firms originally surveyed are confirmed or assumed permanently closed,c manufacturing firms that remain open are operating at 35 percent of capacity, and almost half of the firms have been affected by the PoB explosion. As illustrated by Figure 3, 16.6 percent of firms surveyed are confirmed or assumed permanently closed, while 72 percent have been temporarily closed at some point since the beginning of the pandemic due to Covid-19, with a 10 week average closure period. Further, 46 percent of all surveyed firms—both in Beirut and elsewhere—have been affected by the August 4 explosion either directly or indirectly. In fact, 22 percent of firms had to close temporarily because of the explosion and 17 percent experienced interruption of their supply chain. Four out of five firms say their sales declined significantly together Firm Status FIGURE 3 • with demand. Since the beginning of the financial crisis (October 2019), 79 percent of firms surveyed reduced sales (nominal) 100% 14% by an average of 69 percent, with small firms bearing a greater 90% 19% 15% 18% 31% 29% 29% impact. In reflection, firms reported a 74 percent drop in (real) 80% demand for their products and services. The lack of demand is 70% affecting the manufacturing sector the most severely; 81 percent 60% 62% 62% 60% 63% of surveyed manufacturing firms reported a drop in sales that is 50% 45% equivalent to 70 percent on average. Exporters were also hit 40% 56% 66% hard. One out of four firms reported an average 70 percent drop 30% 4% 6% in exports. However, 20 firms were able to increase their exports; 20% 5% 7% 3% 21% 3% half of these firms were in the manufacturing sector, mainly food 10% 17% 16% 16% 19% 13% 1% and machinery, but also in retail and ICT. This increase could be 0% 4% All Manufacturing Wholesale & Retail Other Services Small Medium Large linked to the improved competitiveness resulting from the severe unofficial depreciation of the currency, or the drop in domestic demand due to the crisis, forcing firms to look for customers overseas. Share of Firms with Unknown Status or Refused to Answer More than half of firms surveyed are experiencing liquidity Share of Firms Open Share of Firms Temporarily Closed challenges. Since the beginning of the financial crisis, 55 Share of Firms Confirmed and Assumed Closed percent of firms experienced a decline in their cashflow and around 75 percent of firms decreased sales and purchases on Source: 2021 Follow up to the Enterprise Survey. credit. Only 13 percent of firms reported relying on banks or financial institutions to finance their liquidity shortfalls. Instead, 28 percent of firms are financing their needs through equity, and 8 percent through delayed payments.d The future looks bleak and uncertain. One out of four firms does not think recovery is possible. Twenty-four percent of firms expect to fall (further) into arrears and default on liabilities in the next 3 months, projecting their survival at less than 7 months or 27 weeks, given current costs. In sum, and according to firms reported expectations, one out of four firms will have to exit by June 2021. COVID-19 adaptation is relatively low, with few firms ramping up online operations. Around 6 percent of firms have either started or increased their online activities, while 8 percent increased online delivery. A relatively higher share of firms (18 percent) have started to increase or has already increased remote work. There is a significant gap between small and large firms, with the latter showing more capacity to adapt. Firms surveyed rank credit guarantees, tax deferrals and exemptions for social security contributions as the most helpful policy potential responses. But preferences vary by firm characteristics and by gender ownership. When asked “What would be the most effective policy to help firms cope with the crisis?” 30 percent of firms indicated credit guarantees, 18 percent pointed to tax deferrals and 16 percent of firms expressed a preference for exemptions to National Social Security Fund (NSSF) contributions. Small firms preferred credit guarantees, with tax deferrals in second place, while large firms preferred NSSF exemptions at a slightly higher rate than tax deferrals. Meanwhile, 34 percent of male owned firms ranked credit guarantees as more effective, while 43 percent of female owned firms ranked NSSF exemptions as their top choice. (continued on next page) Recent Macro-Financial Developments 5 BOX 1: THE IMPACT OF MULTIPLE CRISES ON FORMAL FIRMS AND THE LABOR MARKET IN LEBANONa,b (CONTINUED) Impact on Jobs The multiple crises exacerbated unemployment. One in five workers lost their jobs since October 2019, while 61 percent of firms surveyed decreased the number of permanent workers by 43 percent on average. Medium-size and large firms laid-off a larger number of workers: 76 percent of large firms surveyed downsized by an average of 37 percent, while 70 percent of medium firms downsized by 43 percent. That smaller firms shrunk relatively less could be due to the different nature of the relationship between managers and workers, or the fact that small firms may have less flexibility in scaling back production. These numbers cover only formal firms. The impact is expected to be worse amongst informal firms and micro-sized formal firms, which are not included in the survey. Only 16 percent of workers in the survey sample are women; in large firms, the female share of workers is only 10 percent (Table 1). The crisis appears to have hit female employees relatively less than male employees. The net job loss was 2 percentage points (pp) lower for women than men on average (5 pp less in the case of small firms, but 1 pp more in large firms). Although the crises can impact women’s access to economic opportunities in different ways, the pandemic-related school closures are likely to have made it particularly difficult for women to juggle work and care responsibilities. In addition, the firm survey shows that 10 percent of business affected by the PoB explosion were female-owned, out of which more than half (54 percent) were of small size and 29 percent were medium sized. This loss of women-led businesses diminishes future employment opportunities for women. According to a study conducted by Stand for Women, half the businesses that closed will not be able to reopen without some form of assistance.e TABLE 1 • Average Change in Full-Time Employees by Gender for All Firms Surveyed Average percentage change in full-time employees Size Number of Average percentage of females to total (in full-time employees) firms Average size full-time employees Male Female 5–19 219 8.4 16% –25% –20% 20–99 123 37.1 20% –30% –27% 100 or more 37 171.3 10% –22% –23% All firms 379 24.8 16% –27% –25% Relatively few firms surveyed have resorted to other labor adjustment measures, such as reducing salaries, benefits, or working hours. Only, 13 percent of firms have decreased salaries by around 45 percent, while 29 percent of firms increased salaries of their employees by around 40 percent. Note that these nominal increases were in fact negative in real terms, as inflation reached triple digits during this period. Additionally, according to the survey, 23 percent of firms have decreased benefits to their workers, by 79 percent on average, while 41 percent of firms have decreased working hours by 36 percent on average (the other 59 percent of firms reported no change to workers’ hours). a This Box was prepared by Zeina El Khoury (Private Sector Specialist, FCI) and Angela Elzir Assy (Labor Market Specialist, Jobs Group, SPJ); with inputs from Elizabeth Ruppert Bulmer (Lead Economist, Jobs Group), and data analysis by Reyes Aterido (Consultant). Survey design was supported by Patricia Haydamous (Economist, ETC). The survey was implemented in collaboration with DEC Enterprise Analysis Unit. The survey and analysis are funded through the Lebanon PROSPECTS Partnership. b Unless otherwise stated, the analysis is based on the November 2020 follow-up survey to the standard Enterprise Surveys (ES). This follow-up survey aims to measure the impact of multiple crises (the financial and COVID-19 crises and the explosion at the PoB) on the private sector, by combining the baseline ES data collected with the follow-up data. The survey topics cover the following dimensions: sales, production, labor, finance, preferred support policies, future prospects and business closures. Of the 532 originally surveyed firms, only 379 were reached between November and December 2020. Surveys were phone-based, and multiple contact attempts were made. c There are two estimates of the share of firms that have closed, the share of firms that were confirmed to have closed since the COVID-19 pandemic was declared (3.6 percent), and another wider definition of closed firms, which includes the firms that closed since the baseline ES, and also the firms that could not be contacted during fieldwork [either those with non-functioning phone lines (2.8 percent), or did not answer multiple calls (10.2 percent)] and therefore are assumed to have closed (16.6 percent). d Fifty-two percent of firms experiencing liquidity shortfalls reported that they used “other” sources of cash flow shortages. Given that all formal sources of financing operations are included in the response options, we assumed that a large proportion of firms did not finance their shortages but rather either reduced operation costs or financed through informal channels like family or friends. e UN Women, 2020. Gender Alert on COVID-19 Lebanon. 6 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) deficit is estimated to have shrunk to 4.9 percent of a large part of the macro adjustment, even if not by GDP, a narrowing of 5.6 pp of GDP from 2019, and design from policy makers, is de facto taking place compared to a medium-term average of 8.6 percent through (1) an inflation tax on the revenue side (for (Figure 4). However, the primary balance is estimated items other than those where the tax is set in fixed Lira to have worsened in 2020, reaching –2.8 percent terms such as most fees);16 and (2) a real cut on the of GDP, compared to –0.5 percent in 2019, and a expenditure side. Both are blunt instruments, but with medium-term average of 0.5 percent. This widening high inflation they generate a huge and fast adjust- is surprising for countries that are in sovereign ment. Hence, as is illustrated by the 2021 Budget default as financing shortages usually forces them to proposal (Box 2), keeping the overall deficit at the run a primary balance. In the case of Lebanon, BdL is same nominal number implies a sharp consolidation. providing the required financing for the government, Public debt ratios, which were already noto- notwithstanding its own financial difficulties. riously unsustainable, are further aggravated by Fiscal data available over the first eight the economic crisis. Debt-to-GDP is estimated to have months of 2020 confirm fiscal distress, despite reached 174 percent by the end of 2020, increasing the apparent improvement in the overall bal- by 3 pp from the 2019 ratio. The sharp depreciation ance. Revenues were down by 20.2 percent (yoy) in the local currency has implied a significantly lower over 8M-2020, with across the board decreases in dollar value for domestic debt in 2020, lowering the tax and non-tax revenues. VAT and custom revenues dollar value for total debt (the numerator in the debt- were highly affected by the contraction in economic to-GDP ratio); this is, however, more than offset by a activity, registering respective decreases of 49.7 per- significantly lower denominator, GDP in US$, due cent (yoy) and 34.5 percent (yoy); telecom revenues also to the currency depreciation, leaving a slightly were also down by 56.5 percent (yoy) in 8M-2020. larger debt-to-GDP ratio.17 The expected worsening Meanwhile, total expenditures declined by 18.4 of the exchange in 2021 will further exacerbate this percent (yoy), over the same period. This was partly dynamic (Figure 5). So, whereas the surge in inflation a result of a 58.9 percent (yoy) decrease in interest payments driven by (i) a 87.9 percent (yoy) decline 14 The agreement entails non-payment of coupon in foreign debt interest payments, an implication of obligations on Treasury bonds held by BdL. the Eurobond default; and (ii) a 41.3 percent (yoy) 15 This is driven by a combination of lower oil prices, falling decrease in domestic debt interest payments due to demand due to economic crisis, and increased power a preferential agreement between BdL and Ministry cuts as tool for savings by EdL. 16 This effect on the revenue side in Lebanon, however, is of Finance.14 Decreases of 37.1 and 39 percent (yoy) weakened by a combination of (i) a large chunk of the in transfers to EdL,15 and municipalities, respectively, tax base is on imported goods, which for tax reasons are also contributed to the total decline in expenditures. still valued at the official, thereby generating artificially Hence, while the overall fiscal deficit narrowed by lower revenues; (ii) a collapse in compliance; and (iii) the 13.1 percent over 8M-2020, the primary balance Tanzi effect—the reduction in the volume of tax collection deteriorated by 409 percent, flipping from a surplus and a deterioration of real tax proceeds being collected resulting from high inflation in a country. of LBP 555 billion to LBP –1,713 billion. Tanzi, Vito (1977), Inflation, Lags in Collection, and the High inflation rates drive a sharp fiscal Real Value of Tax Revenue, Staff Papers, vol. 24, March adjustment. For nominally fixed fiscal items, more 1977, IMF, pp. 154–167. typically expenditure items, high inflation induces not 17 Taken at the official exchange rate, the share of foreign only a reduction of the ratio to GDP, but also a reduc- currency-denominated debt to the total outstanding tion in real terms. For fiscal items that are indexed to stock of debt was 36 percent by end-2020 (amounting to 42 percent of GDP), mostly held by domestic banks; for inflation, more typically revenue items, high inflation illustration, if one were to use instead a simulated exchange will induce a nominal increase in these items (in rate of LBP 3,555/US$, foreign currency-denominated principal maintaining real value), thereby partially debt would surge to 57 percent of the total outstanding offsetting the denominator-led GDP effect. Hence, stock of debt (amounting to 100 percent of GDP). Recent Macro-Financial Developments 7 BOX 2: LEBANON’ 2021 BUDGET DRAFT PROPOSALa The 2021 budget draft proposal targets an overall fiscal deficit equivalent to 2.4 percent of GDP, and a primary deficit of 0.8 percent of GDP.b This marks a consolidation when compared to 2020 estimates for the overall and primary deficits of 4.9 and 2.8 percent of GDP, respectively (Table 2). Nominally, total revenues and expenditures, and thus the overall fiscal balance, in Budget 2021 are largely unvaried from those in Budget 2020; only the primary balance deteriorates, signaling the re-allocation of savings from interest payments to primary spending. In the 2021 draft, total revenues are projected to continue contracting to 7.3 percent of GDP, compared to 11.9 percent in 2020. The change is mainly due to a denominator-led effect, resulting from a rise in nominal GDP; in fact, revenues in both 2020 and 2021 budgets are almost unchanged (LBP 14,176 billion in 2020 and LBP 14,140 billion in 2021): the carry-over of the depressed economic activity in 2020 and the continued sharp fall in 2021 are dragging down revenue collection, notwithstanding the inflation-creep “tax” that is common in rapid and high inflation environments. Tax revenues represent the main component of total revenues, budgeted to reach 5.4 percent of GDP in 2021, compared to 8.4 percent of GDP in 2020 budget; in nominal terms the 2021 budget marks a nominal increase in tax revenues—LBP 10,493 billion compared to LBP 9,966 billion, which is, however, well below the projected 100 percent in inflation for 2021, so tax collection is falling in real terms. The budget draft proposes new measures, including a newly introduced “national solidarity tax” and an adjustment to tax on interest profits. The “national solidarity tax” imposes a (i) 1 percent tax on deposits between US$1 million and US$20 million; (ii) 1.5 percent on deposits greater than US$20 million but less than US$50 million; and (iii) 2 percent on deposits greater than US$50 million. This tax applies to equivalent deposits in LBP, calculated at the official exchange rate of LBP 1,507.5/US$, as well as to deposits in other foreign currencies. Summary of Fiscal Accounts Showing Actual Numbers, WB Estimates and Government TABLE 2 • Budgets 2019 2020 2021 2020 2021 Central Government Finance (in percent of GDP) Actual WB estimates Budget Budget draft Revenue (including grants) 20.6 11.5 6.9 11.3 6.3 o/w. tax revenues 15.5 8.1 4.9 8.4 4.9 Total expenditure and net lending 31.2 16.4 12.2 15.4 8.5 Current 29.9 15.2 10.9 14.9 8.2 o/w interest payment 10.0 2.1 1.4 4.0 1.4 Capital & net lending (excluding foreign financed) 1.3 1.2 1.3 0.4 0.3 Overall balance (deficit (–)) –10.5 –4.9 –5.3 –4.1 –2.2 Primary balance (deficit (–)) –0.5 –2.8 –3.9 –0.1 –0.7 (in LBP bln) Revenue (including grants) 16,678 13,706 14,750 13,396 13,572 o/w. tax revenues 12,533 9,593 10,500 9,966 10,493 Total expenditure and net lending 25,180 19,492 26,132 18,232 18,259 Current 24,152 18,090 23,356 17,738 17,524 o/w interest payment 8,067 2,504 2,949 4,695 3,106 Capital & net lending (excluding foreign financed) 1,028 1,402 2,776 493 735 Overall balance (deficit (–)) –8,502 –5,786 –11,382 –4,836 –4,687 Primary balance (deficit (–)) –435 –3,282 –8,433 –141 –1,581 (continued on next page) 8 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) BOX 2: LEBANON’ 2021 BUDGET DRAFT PROPOSALa (CONTINUED) World Bank estimates suggests that, as of December 2020, this tax can generate revenues in the amount of around LBP 165 billion on LBP deposits, and a US$750 billion on dollar deposits. Another measure is a tax on interest income paid on bank deposits, certificates of deposit and treasury bills, which currently stands at 10 percent. The adjustment proposed imposes a 30 percent tax on the part of interest rates that exceeds 3 percent and 5 percent on US$ and LBP accounts, respectively. This effectively targets the financial sector’s interest earned from government bonds. Bank customers’ deposits will largely be exempt since interest rates on US$ and LBP deposits have generally fallen below these thresholds. Expenditures in 2021 budget draft are also projected to drop, to 9.4 percent of GDP, compared to an estimated 16.4 percent of GDP in 2020. In nominal terms, expenditures would rise by a mere 0.2 percent compared to the 2020 budget, but would fall by 84.1 percent in real terms (when considering the official aggregate Consumer Price Index). Sharp nominal cuts in spending (33.8 percent) arise in debt service thanks to the Eurobond default and favorable arrangement with BdL. Capital expenditures are projected at 0.4 percent of GDP, marking a 49 percent increase in nominal terms, from those in the 2020 budget. Notable new expenditure items include: (1) the rescheduling arrears due to the National Social Security Fund (NSSF) to be paid in equal installments in Treasury Bonds over the next 20 years, with the first such payment due in September 2021; (2) in a bid to encourage employment of Lebanese in firms, the Government will pay, on their behalf, their due contributions to NSSF for a period of two years, as long as (i) they are hired before December 31, 2021; (ii) they were either unemployed or entering the job market for the first time; and (iii) each employee’s salary does not exceed LBP 18 million per year; (3) the amount of bank deposit guaranteed by the National Deposit Guarantee Institution increases to LBP 300 million, from a previous LBP 75 million; and (4) an obligation for banks to pay new foreign currency deposits in the currency of the deposit, upon the request of the involved person, in a bid to attract new deposits in foreign currencies. Relatedly, new deposits in FX will be exempt from tax on interest income, in hope of attracting FX deposits to the banking sector. Irrespective of new expenditure items, the proposed 2021 budget allocations to primary expenditures constitute a decrease of around 12 percent compared to what are estimated for 2020. We note that our projections suggest the persistence of exceptionally high inflation rates in 2021. This predisposition can either (i) degrade the proposed budget’s creditability, due to expected social pressures and real costs resulting from the high inflationary environment; or, if forced through, (ii) further entrench the severe decline in purchasing power for another year. a The budget draft proposal has yet to be discussed by Cabinet and will need to be ratified by Parliament. Hence, measures and numbers in the budget draft are subject to revisions by Cabinet and Parliament before the budget is passed as a law. b It is important to note that these numbers exclude a transfer to EdL in the amount of LBP 1,500 billion (0.7 percent of GDP), since this transfer is considered by the Ministry of Finance as a treasury advance, and is therefore excluded from Central Government fiscal balance. Since EdL has no capacity and poor prospects of ever repaying this and previous Treasury advances, under international government accounting standards (GFSM), they should be recorded as transfers. is rapidly eroding the real value of domestic debt, the current account deficit took place. Specifically, over sharp depreciation of the currency continues to make 11M-2020, a 44 percent decline in merchandize im- Lebanon’s sovereign debt burden unsustainable. ports more than offset a 5 percent drop in exports, shrinking the trade in goods deficit by a drastic 54.8 percent in one year. Net remittances is estimated to The External Sector have increased from 6.1 percent of GDP in 2019 to 9.7 percent of GDP in 2020. The increase is a result As foreign financing of the current account (CA) of (i) a sharp decline in US$ GDP (a denominator deficit came to a sudden stop in late 2019, a effect); (ii) large decreases in remittances outflows, massive contraction of the CA took place in 2020 as foreign workers in Lebanon suffer from the eco- driven by a sharp contraction in imports. Fol- nomic contraction; and (iii) some remittances inflows lowing the de facto introduction of capital controls, incentivized by the well-documented “insurance”18 the sovereign default, capital inflows into Lebanon stopped. While BdL made use of its limited foreign 18 The “insurance” behavior suggests that diaspora exchange reserves in 2020, a forced and massive increases remittances back home in case of natural adjustment/re-sizing of the previously massive disasters. Recent Macro-Financial Developments 9 Large Shortfalls in Revenues Will FIGURE 4 • FIGURE 5 • Valuation Effects from Exchange Rate Induce a Significant Deterioration in Depreciations Will Pressure the Debt- the Fiscal Position to-GDP Ratio Fiscal Aggregates (% of GDP) Gross Public Debt 5 100 250 3 90 0 80 200 Percent of GDP (%) –3 70 –5 US$ Billion 60 150 –8 50 Percent (%) –10 40 100 –13 30 –15 20 50 –18 10 –20 0 0 –23 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 2018 2021 –25 –28 External Public Debt (US$ bln) Domestic Public Debt (US$ bln) 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 External Public Debt, at an Gross Public Debt (US$ bln) Illustrative Exchange Rate, Gross Public Debt as Overall Fiscal Balance as a Percentage of GDP (rhs, %) Percentage of GDP (rhs, %) Primary Fiscal Balance, Excluding Interest Payments External Public Debt, at Official Rate, as a Percentage of GDP (rhs, %) Sources: Lebanese authorities and WB staff calculations. Sources: Lebanese authorities and WB staff calculations. and other countercyclical19 behaviors observed in not publish net reserves, which are estimated to be countries with large diasporas. Nominally, howev- significantly negative. er, remittances inflows are estimated to have been A high import ratio for the consumption negatively impacted by an impaired banking sector— basket, along with the shortage of dollars in the the traditional conduit for remittances—and the CO- market suggest an implicit tradeoff between VID-19 global impact. Overall, we expect the current (i) importation of goods and services and account deficit in 2020 to contract, falling by almost (ii) BdL’s stock of foreign exchange reserves. This 10 pps to reach 11 percent of GDP, compared to a compelled authorities to prioritize imports. First, and medium-term (2013–2019) average of 22.5 percent early on in the crisis, BdL identified a list of highly of GDP. critical goods (denoted as C1 goods)—namely, fuel, The sudden stop in capital inflows, medicine and wheat—to be backed by its stock of coupled with a smaller but still large current foreign exchange reserves at the official exchange account deficit, has steadily depleted BdL’s rate.20 The Government followed suit in July 2020 with foreign exchange (FX) reserves (Figure 6). By a list of other critical goods, issued by the Ministry January 2021, gross FX reserves at BdL (excluding of Economy and Trade (MoET), which BdL agreed gold reserves) reached $23.5 billion, declining by to back up at the platform exchange rate (LL 3,900 $13.8 billion since end-2019. BdL’s gross position includes US$5 billion in Lebanese Eurobonds and 19 During economic hardships in the home country, an unpublished amount lent out to banks since expatriates can also boost transfers back home in October 2019. Much of the remainder is required support of family. reserves on banks’ customer FX deposits, which is 20 BdL set up a mechanism via commercial banks whereby importers of highly critical goods can exchange LBP for estimated at US$16.7 billion. Critically, BdL’s gross dollars at the official exchange rate for 85 to 90 percent position differs widely from its net reserves (i.e., gross of the cost of their imports, while sourcing the remaining FX reserves at the central bank net of FX liabilities to 15 to 10 percent from the market at the US$ banknote others); contrary to other central banks, BdL does rate. 10 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) A Steady Depletion in the Gross FIGURE 6 • Ratios of C1, C2b, Luxury and other FIGURE 7 • Foreign Exchange Position at BdL Imports Were Stable until the Period Leading to the Crisis… Gross Reserves at BdL 50,000 Critical and Essential Imports 45,000 100% 40,000 90% 35,000 30,000 80% US$ mln 25,000 70% % of Total Imports 20,000 60% 15,000 10,000 50% 5,000 40% 0 30% Jan-13 Apr-13 Jul-13 Oct-13 Jan-14 Apr-14 Jul-14 Oct-14 Jan-15 Apr-15 Jul-15 Oct-15 Jan-16 Apr-16 Jul-16 Oct-16 Jan-17 Apr-17 Jul-17 Oct-17 Jan-18 Apr-18 Jul-18 Oct-18 Jan-19 Apr-19 Jul-19 Oct-19 Jan-20 Apr-20 Jul-20 Oct-20 Jan-21 20% 10% Foreign Currencies Foreign Securities 0% Gross FX Reserves Compulsory FX Reserve 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 Sources: BdL and WB staff calculations. Critical 1 Critical 2b Luxury Other Note: Compulsory FX reserves are World Bank estimates based on published data, and a 15 percent required reserve ratio on FX deposits in commercial banks. Sources: Customs, MOET, BdL and WB staff calculations. per US$). This list was updated in November 2020 to FIGURE 8 • …when Ratios of C1 and C2b Imports include almost half the number of items that were in Rose at the Expense of those for Luxury and Other Goods. the original list. Hereafter, the original list will be called C2a while the latest will be called C2b. Critical and Essential Imports An examination of historical and recent 100% trends for C1 and C2b imports are revealing. 90% The shares of C1, C2b, luxury and other imports to 80% total imports are presented annually from 2011 to 70% % of Total Imports 2019 and monthly over 2019–20 in Figures 7 and 8, 60% respectively. Figure 7 illustrates relative stability in the 50% respective shares until 2019. Meanwhile, as foreign 40% exchange constraints became binding, the ratios 30% of C1 imports, and to a lesser extent C2a and C2b 20% imports, rose at the expense of those for luxury and 10% other goods (Figure 8). The average monthly values 0% over the January 2019 to October 2020 period for C2a Jan-19 Feb-19 Mar-19 Apr-19 May-19 Jun-19 Jul-19 Aug-19 Sep-19 Oct-19 Nov-19 Dec-19 Jan-20 Feb-20 Mar-20 Apr-20 May-20 Jun-20 Jul-20 Aug-20 Sep-20 Oct-20 and C2b are US$180 and US$161 million, indicating unsubstantial savings by the second MoET list. Critical 1 Critical 2b Luxury Other Importers from across the economy com- Sources: CAS and WB staff calculations. pete for access to these FX-backed facilities. However, less transparent demand is also well-docu- mented in countries with capital controls and multiple exchange rate systems; specifically, corruption and Money and Banking misclassification of imports to benefit from cheap foreign exchange. As importers adapt to capital con- Monetary and financial turmoil are driving crisis trols and more depreciated black-market rates, this conditions, specifically through interactions incentive will grow. between the exchange rate, narrow money and Recent Macro-Financial Developments 11 inflation. Acute exchange market pressures in As inflation has surged during that same period, Lebanese markets are reflected by heavy fluctuations real interest rates in the country are highly negative in the US$ banknote exchange rate,21 which breached across the board. LL 15,000/US$, before falling back down. This is Since the eruption of the financial crisis, within the context of a multiple exchange rate system, BdL has been almost an exclusive policy maker, which includes the official exchange (LBP 1,507.5/ with the exception of a brief period in which US$) as well BdL’s platform rate set at LBP 3,900/ Government defaulted on its Eurobond obliga- US$. Overall, the World Bank calculated Average tions and unsuccessfully proposed its Financial Exchange Rate (AER)22 depreciated by 129 percent Recovery Plan. The Fall 2020 LEM listed in detail in 2020 (Figure 9). the slew of BdL circulars, which formalized BdL’s Limited economic utility for electronic dol- crisis management strategy. The main BdL policy lars, along with scarcity of dollar banknotes, and 23 initiatives/updates since then include (i) a new minimum incentives to save in LBP, all rendered financial operation; (ii) an announcement by BdL the economy heavily cash-based in local currency. to allow commercial banks to conduct currency In 2020, the stock of currency in circulation increased exchanges at the market rate; and (iii) the expiration by 197 percent (yoy), even as M2 increased by a of a deadline for commercial banks to meet Circular mere 6.3 percent, while M3 declined by 1.4 percent. 154 provisions. The latter two money supply measures reflect the In March 2021, BdL announced a new deleveraging that is going in the financial sector (see financial operation. Details of this operation and below). an illustrative example are presented in Box 4. In Exchange rate pass through effects on this most recent operation, BdL offers banks FX in prices have resulted in surging inflation, hitting exchange for LBP, increasing its liabilities in FX and the poorest and most vulnerable the most. The 12-month inflation rate has risen steadily and sharply from 10 percent in January 2020, to 89.7 percent in 21 The US$ banknote market has become a main supply June 2020, 120 percent in August 2020, and most channel for dollars for both real and financial activity, recently, to 157.9 percent in March 2021. Inflation is as commercial banks heavily restricted withdrawals and a highly regressive tax, disproportionally affecting transfers of customers’ dollar deposits. the poor and vulnerable (Box 3), and more generally, 22 The AER is derived by applying consumption-based people living on fixed income like pensioners. This is weights on the official, the platform and the US$ banknote exchange rates. For a detailed derivation please refer to: especially so in Lebanon’s case where basic items of World Bank (2020), The Lebanon Economic Monitor: the consumption basket are primary drivers of overall The Deliberate Depression, Fall 2020. Since then, we inflation. In fact, the main contributors of inflation make adjusted the AER per the following: are food and non-alcoholic beverages, followed by We account for a reduced MoET list of subsidized goods clothing and footwear, and then furnishing and house- starting in November 2020. hold equipment (Figure 10); prices for these basic Beginning in August 2020, 75 percent of the non- imported services is linked to the official exchange consumption items have surged by 254.3, 289.8 and rate (compared to 100 percent prior), while 25 percent 389.7 percent, respectively, in 2020. is linked to the platform rate. The reason being is The severe restrictions on capital outflows that, around that time, certain prominent hospitals have given the monetary authorities room and universities announced that they will start billing to lower interest rates. From October 2019 to according to the BdL platform rate. December 2020, BdL lowered interest rates on 23 This refers to dollar deposits from prior October 2019, which are subject to strict capital controls and can banks’ LBP and dollar deposits by 639 and 567 generally be withdrawn only in LBP at the platform rate basis points (bps), respectively. Banks’ lending rates (LBP 3,900/US$), a significant haircut compared to the in LBP and US$ have mirrored this effect, falling by value of the dollar being traded in the parallel banknote 342 and 332 bps, respectively over the same period. market. 12 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) FIGURE 9 • A Sharp Depreciation in the Exchange Inflation in Basic Items is a Key FIGURE 10 • Rate along with Surging Inflation and Driver of Overall Inflation, Hurting Narrow Money the Poor and the Middle Class Exchange Rate-Currency in Circulation-Inflation Contributions to Overall Inflation in 2020 5.0 4.0 100.0 4.5 80.0 4.0 3.0 60.0 3.5 Percent 3.0 Percent Percent 40.0 2.5 2.0 2.0 20.0 1.5 0.0 1.0 1.0 0.5 –20.0 0 0 Headline Inflation growth Food & Non-alcoholic Beverages Aug-19 Sep-19 Oct-19 Nov-19 Dec-19 Jan-20 Feb-20 Mar-20 Apr-20 May-20 Jun-20 Jul-20 Aug-20 Sep-20 Oct-20 Nov-20 Dec-20 Jan-21 Feb-21 Mar-21 Clothing & Footwear Furnishings, Household Equipment Transportation Alcoholic Beverages & Tobacco Communication Water, Electricity, Gas, & Other Fuels US$ Bank Note Rate WB Average Exchange Rate Owned Occupied Health Inflation Rate (rhs) Currency in Circulation (rhs) Actual Rent Education Other Sources: CAS, BdL and WB staff calculations. Sources: CAS and WB staff calculations. BOX 3: IMPACT OF CRISES ON POVERTYa The multiplicity of crises affecting Lebanon is likely to have Food Expenditure Shares by Deciles FIGURE 11 • an escalating impact on poverty. After remaining in the single for Lebanese Nationals digits for over a decade, average annual inflation ballooned to 84.3 percent in 2020, while average food inflation alone grew 40% 37.4% by a record 254 percent over 2020. The annual rates do not fully reflect the rapid rise in monthly inflation wherein the year- 35% on-year inflation rate reached 146 percent in December 2020 Food Share with a corresponding food inflation rate of over 400 percent. 30% The growth in food inflation is particularly concerning, as food consumption forms a larger proportion of the expenses incurred 25% by poorer households (Figure 11). 20% The deteriorating purchasing power is causing households 20.2% to struggle in making ends meet. Phone surveys conducted 15% during November and December 2020 found that 41 percent 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 of households reported challenges in accessing food and other Per-Capita Expenditure Deciles (HBS, 2012) basic needs. The share of households facing difficulties in Source: Staff calculation using HBS 2012. accessing health care was at 36 percent, up from 25 percent in July-August 2020. Unemployment rate also rose among the respondents, from 28 percent in February 2020 (pre-COVID) to nearly 40 percent in the Nov-Dec period. The absence of timely and relevant data makes it very difficult to reasonably predict the state of poverty in the country. The last household budget survey was completed in 2011–2012 under conditions very different from the state of the country today. The pandemic has further heightened the vulnerability of the poor whose living, working and health conditions place them at greater risk compared to wealthier segments of the population. Under highly inflationary conditions, poorer households have limited means of preserving their purchasing power and are likely to resort to a variety of last-resort coping strategies, including ceasing their medications, borrowing at extortionary rates and selling of assets to simply put food on the table. Tentative projections using the older data suggest that well over half the population is likely to be under the national poverty line. The economic crisis and resulting rising in poverty raise an urgent need for social assistance. High levels of poverty can have a long-lasting impact on Lebanon’s human development and increases vulnerabilities across the lifecycle. Adequate social assistance will therefore be critical both in the short term to provide emergency relief, and in the medium-long term to improve resilience to shocks among vulnerable Lebanese. a This box has been prepared by Ganesh Kumar Seshan (Senior Economist, EMNPV), Bilal Malaeb (Economist, EMNPV), Fahmina Rahman Dutta (Social Protection Specialist, HMNSP) and Haneen Ismail Sayed (Lead Operations Officer, HMNSP), under the guidance of Johannes G. Hoogeveen (Practice Manager, EMNPV). Recent Macro-Financial Developments 13 BOX 4: THE MOST RECENT FINANCIAL OPERATION BY BDL WITH COMMERCIAL BANKS The most recent financial operation employed by BdL involves the following steps: 1. Banks discount medium- to long-term LBP Time Deposits (TDs) and/or Certificates of Deposits (CDs) at a discount rate of yield plus up to 1 percent. 2. With the proceeds from the above operation, banks buy US$ at LBP 1514/US$ from BdL and deposit this amount at their US$ current account with BdL, receiving zero interest rate. 3. Banks are also required to unwind LBP financial engineering structures at least equivalent to the US$ amount bought (at least 1 to 1 ratio). The unwinding process consists of discounting at par LBP TDs as well as their linked LBP Repos. 4. Banks would sign an undertaking to sell back to BdL the amount US$ bought at the electronic platform rate upon the first demand from BdL, through discounting US$ TDs and CDs. 5. The amount of US$ the bank is committed to sell back to BdL will be reduced by the amount of US$ the bank sells to BdL under Circular 151, from January 2021 until the call back date (as per Central Decision Council amendment). For illustrative purposes, we present a simplified example. Steps 1–3 are Spot Transactions Suppose step 1 involves discounting LBP 1,514,000 in face value divided evenly between TDs and CDs. Long term average interest rates for LBP TDs and CDs are around 3.5 and 8.5 percent, respectively. Hence the average yield for step 1 is 6 percent (= 0.5*3.5 + 0.5*8.5). Moreover, we assume the average maturity for these TDs and CDs is 10 years. Hence, the present value for this operation is calculated by discounting (i) coupon payments, which we are assuming annual; and (ii) the face value payment at maturity, such that: 6%*(1,514,000) 1,514,000 ∑ 10 + = LBP 1,514,000 = US $ 1000 (at LBP 1,514 /US $) n=1 (1+ 6%)n (1+ 6%)n Hence, banks use the proceeds to purchase US$1,000 from BdL, which is deposited at a non-yielding current account with the central bank. Further, per step 3, banks unwind LBP 1,514,000 of financial engineering TDs and repos by discounting at par. These TDs were created as part of BdL’s financial engineering operations in which BdL lent banks LBP at 2 percent annual rates on the condition they were placed as TDs with BdL earning 10.5 percent annually. Hence, the net return on these TDs for banks was 8.5 percent annually. Hence, as earlier, we discount (i) the annual net return on these TDs; and (ii) the repayment of loan principal at maturity; this generates a present value of LBP 1,514,000. Steps 4 and 5 are Future Transactions At future dates, banks are obliged to sell back US$ 1000 minus whatever dollars they sell under Circular 151, herein denoted by X. The dollar value is exchanged to LBP at the platform rate of the time, denoted by E, and which is currently at LBP 3,900/US$. The combination of steps constitutes a call option for BdL to buy back the US dollars, albeit, with undefined terms, due to uncertainty over key parameters, such as X, E, and time to expiration of the call option. Hence, for simplification purposes in this illustrative example, we assume away the accounting and pricing implication of the call option for BdL, and symmetrically for Banks. Hence, according to the numbers used in this illustrative example, a balance sheet analysis suggests (with spot transactions in light green background and future transactions in white): BdL Banks Assets Liabilities Assets Liabilities LBP –1,514,000 LBP –1,514,000 US$ +1000 US$ +1000 LBP –1,514,000 LBP –1,514,000 LBP –1,514,000 LBP –1,514,000 US$ –(1000-X) US$ –(1000-X) LBP +[($1000-$X)*E] LBP +[($1000-$X)*E] (continued on next page) 14 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) BOX 4: THE MOST RECENT FINANCIAL OPERATION BY BDL WITH COMMERCIAL BANKS (CONTINUED) For BdL: At spot • BdL’s liabilities are lower by LBP 3,028,000 (=1,514,000+1,514,000) but higher by US$1000. • BdL’s assets are lower by LBP 1,514,000 • Net impact on BdL’s capital would thus be • Positive (i.e., capital increases) if the exchange rate is lower than LBP 1,514/US$ • Negative (i.e., capital decreases) if the exchange rate is higher than LBP 1,514/US$ Over time • BdL’s liabilities are lower by LBP [1,514,000+1,514,000-($1000-$X)*E] but higher by US$X. • BdL’s assets are lower by LBP 1,514,000 • Net impact on BdL’s capital would thus be • Positive (ie. capital increases) if the exchange rate is lower than LBP (1,514,000)−(1000−X)*E per US$ X • Negative (ie. capital decreases) if the exchange rate is more than LBP (1,514,000)−(1000−X)*E per US$ X For Banks: At spot • Bank’s assets are lower by LBP 3,028,000 but higher by US$1000. • Banks’ liabilities are lower by LBP 1,514,000 • Net impact on banks’ capital would thus be • Negative (i.e., capital decreases) if the exchange rate is lower than LBP 1,514/US$ • Positive (i.e., capital increases) if the exchange rate is greater than LBP 1,514/US$ Over time • Banks’ assets are lower by LBP [1,514,000+1,514,000-($1000-$X)*E] but higher by US$X. • Banks’ liabilities are lower by LBP 1,514,000 • Net impact on Banks’ capital would thus be • Negative (ie. capital decreases) if the exchange rate is lower than • LBP (1,514,000)−(1000−X)*E per US$ X • Positive (ie. capital increases) if the exchange rate is more than • LBP (1,514,000)−(1000−X)*E per US$ X From an income perspective, and according to the numbers used in this illustrative example, in the absence of this operation, banks (BdL) would be earning (paying) a return of • an average of 6 percent from LBP TDs and CDs; • an average of 8.5 percent from LBP TDs and repos; for a total of 14.5 percent on LBP instruments. Meanwhile, in this operation • 14.5 percent earnings on LBP instruments for banks are eliminated; hence BdL saves 14.5 percent; • BdL does not pay interest on Banks’ dollar deposits; Overall, from an income perspective, and according to the numbers used in this illustrative example, BdL saves (banks lose) 14.5 percent annually. Recent Macro-Financial Developments 15 decreasing it in LBP, with the exchange occurring • This would be based on the current “Sayrafa” at the official exchange rate. It then compels banks platform, which is now set at LBP 3,900/US$.28 to sell this FX back to BdL (whether directly or via Indeed, after the Baabda Palace announcement, the ongoing Lirafication scheme24) at the platform BdL sent a “Request” to banks and exchange rate, which is currently set at LBP 3,900/US$. With dealers to register on Sayrafa. the caveat that a comprehensive assessment of this • This is not meant to completely replace the operation is more accurate from a hindsight per- parallel market. spective, as it is able to better capture interactions • It is not clear how close the Sayrafa rate would be and incentives that might not be clear at this point, to US$ banknote rate; or how responsive it would we present some preliminary observations: be to changes in the banknote rate.29 • Transactions would be restricted to exchange of • As a spot transaction, the operation will cancel currency notes only (LBP and US$). out LBP assets and liabilities that resulted from • On the demand side (of FX): the announced BdL’s previous financial operations.25 intention is to allow access to only those engaged • As a spot transaction, BdL will incur an FX liability in “legitimate economic transactions”, (i.e., to banks and hence worsen its net international traders/industrialists/businesses, for trade and reserve (NIR) position. Since the FX offered by business activities). BdL to banks is not real liquidity, or “fresh dollars,” its use is limited to closing banks’ FX positions with BdL (i.e., banks’ deleveraging schemes such 24 BdL has regulated that dollar deposits that existed as Lirafication). prior to October 2019 can be withdrawn only in LBP • As a spot transaction, this operation will worsen at the platform rate, thereby effecting Lirafication and (improve) BdL’s (banks’) capital position. a haircut (up to 70 percent) on these deposits. More • Over time, all things equal, this operation will formally, Circular 151, as part of a sequence of circulars (148, 151, 549, 565), allowed the withdrawal of pre- interact with Circular 151, with a likelihood that, crisis deposits at exchange rates that are higher than on the net, BdL will increase its FX liabilities. the official rate, but lower than the US$ banknote rate. Commercial banks’ deleveraging, as incentivized This rate eventually settled at the platform rate, which is by Circular 151,26 would be occurring currently set at LBP 3,900/US$. irrespective of this operation and will not be 25 In previous financial engineering schemes, BdL incurred further incentivized by it. Hence Step 5 in Box 4. LBP liabilities, which were offered as an incentive to commercial banks to purchase Eurobonds from BdL, The most recent financial operation by BdL with allowing BdL to raise its gross foreign exchange reserves commercial banks27 suggests that this operation by tapping into commercial banks’ foreign assets. would prevent a larger overall reduction to BdL 26 These deleveraging schemes have resulted in reductions FX liabilities that would have occurred in the in customers FX deposits with banks, which effected absence of this operation. commensurate reductions in banks’ FX deposits with • Over time, and after banks have sold back this BdL, and hence, reductions in BdL’s FX liabilities, and improvements in BdL’s NIR. FX liquidity to BdL, BdL would have replaced the 27 Step 5 states: the amount of US$ the bank is committed LBP liability with currency in circulation. to sell back to BdL will be reduced by the amount of US$ the bank sells on an annual basis to BdL under Also in March 2021, a Baabda Presidential Circular 151. Palace announcement stated that BdL will start 28 In fact, the Sayrafa platform was initially set up by Circular allowing commercial banks to conduct currency 149 (April 3, 2020), in which BdL announced a special unit comprising BdL, banks and exchange bureaus that transactions similar to legal exchange dealers, at exchanges foreign currencies. The Sayrafa was intended a rate to be set by the Central Bank’s electronic as electronic board that publishes exchange rates. platform. While information on this has been scarce, 29 Minister of Finance, in an interview to a TV channel, notable factors include: mentioned the rate LL10,000/US$. 16 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) • On the supply of FX: the sources for US$ FIGURE 12 • Heavy Deleveraging of Assets (Private banknotes to be exchanged through this platform Loans) and Liabilities (Private Deposits) in the Financial Sector are not clear. Options or combinations thereof include: Bank’s Deposits and Loans (% yoy change) • Commercial banks’ own FX liquidity. 30 20 • A new set-up where exporters are incentivized 10 to repatriate FX dollars they have been Percent (%) 0 depositing in foreign banks. –10 • BdL’s own FX reserves. –20 –30 Ultimately, if BdL wants to control/influence –40 –50 the US$ banknote rate, then it has to find a suf- Jan-15 Apr-15 Jul-15 Oct-5 Jan-16 Apr-16 Jul-16 Oct-16 Jan-17 Apr-17 Jul-17 Oct-17 Jan-18 Apr-18 Jul-18 Oct-18 Jan-19 Apr-19 Jul-19 Oct-19 Jan-20 Apr-20 Jul-20 Oct-20 Jan-21 ficient supply of FX to inject at a rate lower than the banknote market rate, so as to attract buyers LBP Credit Outstanding FX Credit Outstanding of dollars. Essentially, this would act as a more to Private Sector to Private Sector Private Sector Deposits in LBP Private Sector Deposits in FX traditional FX intervention in the market in defense of the exchange rate. In such a case, it can be used Sources: CAS and WB staff calculations. as a monetary tool to mop up currency in circulation from the market, as more orthodox monetary tools are ineffective.30 However, even if currency in circulation Conditions in the financial sector continue is reduced, this operation would be inconsistent with to deteriorate, while a consensus among key other policies (Lirafication and monetization of the stakeholders on the burden-sharing of losses has deficit), making the overall monetary stance of BdL proven to be elusive, and is further complicated unclear. This can weaken the impact of a reduction in by the lack of progress in government formation. currency in circulation on inflation. A larger question Customer deposits at commercial banks declined would be, in absence of a more comprehensive and by US$19.8 billion (or 12.6 percent) in 2020, further sustainable solution, would BdL/banks spend from deepening the liquidity shortage. Liquidity needs in their very valuable (i.e., limited and dwindling) FX the banking system have been met mainly through resources? deleveraging and reduction in net foreign assets. Officially, BdL did not extend the deadline for Deleveraging had resulted in banks’ domestic credit Lebanese commercial banks to meet new param- portfolio shrinking by US$12.1 billion (or 27.5 percent) eters set by BdL via Circular 154; that deadline during the same period (Figure 12), mainly in foreign was February 28, 2021. Key stipulations of Circular currency loans, although it partially reflected cus- 154 include: raising bank capital by 20 percent; banks tomers settling loans backed by real estate collateral, to place funds in correspondent banks amounting to using deposits locked up in bank accounts. a minimum of 3 percent of customers’ FX deposits; Lending from BdL has allowed Lebanese banks to convince customers to repatriate 15 percent commercial banks to pay off liabilities to of deposit outflows above US$500,000 since end- 2017; banks’ shareholders and politically exposed persons (PEPs) to repatriate 30 percent of deposit 30 In more conventional monetary and financial conditions, outflows above US$500,000 since end-2017. BdL and increasing policy rates can be used to effect monetary the Banking Control Commission are reported to be tightening. However, this is no longer an option as the banking system is dysfunctional and the monetary currently undertaking a bank by bank examination transmission channel impaired. In addition, under of compliance. There is a lack of clarity on follow up capital controls, monetary authority has more flexibility and next steps, and there have been no subsequent in not increasing interest rates as capital is captive even initiatives since the passing of the deadline. with hugely negative real interest rates. Recent Macro-Financial Developments 17 correspondent banks in order to retain linkages FIGURE 13 • A Steady and Sharp Deterioration in to the global financial system. As of December Credit Performance as Measured by NPL Ratio for Banks 2020, commercial banks’ placements in and liabilities for non-resident financial institutions (FIs) amounted NPLs by Sector to US$4.7 and US$6.6 billion, respectively, compared Total Credit Portfolio to US$6.8 and US$8.8 billion in December 2019. Consumption Foreign correspondent banks have significantly Housing tightened conditions and reduced lines to Lebanese Financial Intermediation banks. As a condition on continuing to transact via Retail Trade Wholesale Trade correspondent banks, commercial banks have had to Contracting and Construction pay down liabilities to these banks, partially financed Processing Industries by lending from BdL. This allowed a marginal 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% improvement in the net position of commercial banks Dec-19 Dec-20 at non-resident FIs, which nonetheless remained Sources: BdL and WB staff calculations. negative at –US$1.8 billion in end-2020, compared to –US$2.1 billion in end-2019. Large losses associated with the sover- eign exposures of the banking sector remain 19.6 percent a year earlier. NPL ratio for construction, unresolved. Exposures to the sovereign amount to processing industries and wholesale and retail trade 70 percent of total banking assets or roughly 250 reached 51 percent, 50 percent and 43 percent, percent of 2019 GDP. These include US$110 billion respectively (Figure 13). Provisioning coverage was in BdL instruments, US$10 billion in Lebanese gov- at just over 50 percent as of end-2020. Continued ernment Eurobonds and US$11 billion in domestic deterioration in the quality of the remaining credit government securities at the official exchange rate. portfolio (US$40 billion at the official exchange rate The credit portfolio of the banking sector and 61 percent denominated in US$) would be has substantially deteriorated during recent expected, given the lack of progress in government months. The non-performing loan (NPL) ratio—that formation and necessary restructuring and reform. is, gross NPLs including unearned interests as a Losses arising from the rapid deterioration of assets percentage to total loans—stood at 33.0 percent (37.7 quality, although paling in comparison to the losses percent for FX loans) as of end-2020, compared to from sovereign exposures, will need to be addressed 13.3 percent at end-June 2019 before the crisis and in a comprehensive balance sheet cleanup. 18 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) 3 GLOBAL CRISES COMPARATORS: LOOKING FOR THE MINIMUM W e continue to monitor the Lebanon of crisis or the year of the financial crisis. There financial crisis in the context of Global are cases where the downturns start earlier but Crisis Comparators.31 In this LEM, we these are less frequent. compare the Lebanon crisis with the most severe • A substantial number of these crises are not global crises episodes as observed by Reinhart “pure” banking crises in that these unfold and Rogoff (2014), henceforth referred to as R&R.32 alongside a currency crash and often involve a Based on the most extensive financial crises database sovereign default as well. available,33 R&R calculate a crisis severity index (CSI) for a sample of 100 crisis episodes over the 1857– 31 The Fall 2020 LEM, entitled The Deliberate Depression, 2013 period. The CSI is computed based on (i) the compares Lebanon’s macroeconomic fundamentals in depth of the crisis episode—the peak-to-trough decline the lead-up to the crisis to two groups of global crises in real GDP per capita, and (ii) its duration—the number comparators: the Asian crisis countries of 1997–98, and of years it takes to reach the prior peak in real per a more eclectic set of crises that occurred in the 2000’s capita income. Specifically, for each crisis episode: [Argentina (2001), Greece (2008), Ireland (2008), Iceland (2008) and Cyprus (2012)]. We conclude that, leading up to the crisis point, Lebanon’s macroeconomic CSI = −1*(peak-to-trough percentage change) + fundamentals were weak compared to these global number of years from peak to recovery to prior peak crises comparators, suggesting that the adjustment process will be more painful and will take longer, even R&R’s 25 most severe crises and associated with optimal policy measures in place. results are presented in Table 3. Some notable find- 32 Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff (2014), ings include: Recovery from Financial Crises: Evidence from 100 Episodes, American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2014, 104(5): 50–55. • A typical recurring pattern across time and space 33 Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogoff (2009), in these cycles is one in which economic activity This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. reaches a peak either the year before the onset Princeton: Princeton University Press. 19 Crisis Severity: Percent Decline in Per Capita GDP, Duration of Contraction, and Years to Full TABLE 3 • Recovery in 25 of the Worst Systemic Banking Crises, 1857–2013 (Reinhart and Rogoff, 2014) Peak to Trough Peak to Trough Peak to Recovery Double Dip Rank Year Country % change # years # years CSI Yes or No 1 1926 Chile –46.6 3 16 62.6 Y 2 1931 Spain (civil war) –34.6 9 26 60.6 Y 3 1983 Peru –32 11 25 57 Y 4 1931 Uruguay –36.1 3 17 53.1 Y 5 1893 Australia –28 8 20 48 Y 6 1929 Mexico –31.1 6 16 47.1 Y 7 1921 Italy –25.5 3 21 46.5 Y 8 1890 Brazil –21.7 4 21 42.7 Y 9 1923 Canada –30.1 4 10 40.1 N 10 1890 Uruguay –21 2 19 40 Y 11 1981 Philippines –18.8 3 21 39.8 Y 12 1980/1985 Argentina –21.8 11 18 39.8 Y 13 1929 India –8.2 9 31 39.2 Y 14 1929/1933 US –28.6 4 10 38.6 Y 15 1994 Venezuela –24.2 11 14 38.2 Y 16 1939 Netherlands –16 6 21 37 Y 17 2009 Greece –24 6 12 36 Ya 18 1931/1934 Argentina –19.4 3 15 34.4 Y 19 1931 Poland –24.9 4 9 33.9 N 20 1929/1931 Austria –23.4 4 10 33.4 N 21 1981 Mexico –14.1 7 17 31.1 Y 22 1920 UK –18.7 3 11 29.7 Y 23 2001 Argentina –20.9 4 8 28.9 N 24 1980 Chile –18.9 2 8 26.9 N 25 2002 Uruguay –18.9 4 8 26.9 N Average –24.3 5 16 40.5 a This is listed as N in Reinhart and Rogoff (2014), since until its publication, Greece had not yet experienced its double dip which subsequently occurred in 2016. • Out of the 100 episodes, 63 were in advanced Lebanon’s real GDP per capita has been on a economies and 37 in emerging economies. continuous decline since the onset of the Syria war • While emerging market peak-to-trough average in 2011, with a much sharper drop commencing in output declines are about 5 percent larger than 2018 (Figure 14). Prior to 2018, Lebanon’s per capita those in the advanced economies, they are not GDP declined as a direct consequence of the war in statistically significantly more protracted. • A double dip34 is observed for 45 percent of the whole 34 A double dip is when the post-trough, but pre-recovery sample and two-thirds of the most severe crises. growth is interrupted with a real GDP contraction. 20 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) neighboring Syria; both real economic activity slowed FIGURE 14 • Lebanon’s Real GDP is a More appreciably,35 and population increased significantly Accurate Reference Point for the Start of the Financial Crisis than due to the refugee influx.36 R&R calculations of crisis Real GDP/capita depth and duration, and hence, the CSI, depend on the identification of peak year—the year in which the per Real GDP per Capita 15% capita real GDP reached a pre-crisis peak. However, 10% due to the impact of the Syrian crisis, and in order 5% to more accurately gauge the depth and duration of Percent (%) 0% the Lebanon financial crisis, it would be unbalanced –5% to identify the peak year in Lebanon by the pre-crisis –10% peak in real GDP per capita as in R&R. Instead for the –15% –20% Lebanon episode, we identify the peak year by the pre- –25% crisis peak in real GDP, which is 2017. 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 The Lebanon financial crisis is likely to rank Real GDP Growth Population Growth in the top 10, possibly three, most severe crises Real GDP/Capita Growth episodes globally since 1900. In order to compute Sources: CAS and WB staff calculations. a CSI for the Lebanon financial crisis, we make assumptions commensurate to (relatively) good and bad case scenarios. In the good case scenario, we assume: (i) real GDP per capita trough occurs in 2021 Annex C for each of these episodes. To the extent at the World Bank projected growth rate (–9.5 per- data is available, we plot each macroeconomic indi- cent), inducing an overall –35.1 percent peak (2017) cator for the G8 plus Lebanon over the years leading to trough (2021) change in real GDP per capita; and to the crisis point and observe dynamics in years that that (ii) it takes 12 years for Lebanon to recover to follow.37 2017 real income per capita levels, the average crisis duration of those cases ranking 16–25 in Table 3. The good case CSI would be 47.1, ranking the Lebanon Per Capita Output episode 6th after Australia (1893) and aligned with Mexico (1929) in Table 3. In the bad case scenario, While Lebanon’s real GDP per capita has faltered we assume: (i) real GDP trough occurs in 2022 at an since 2011, 2018 marks the beginning of a much additional 5 percent annual contraction in real GDP, sharper decline. Only Argentina (01) and Uruguay resulting in an overall –38.6 percent peak (2017) to (02) share Lebanon’s consistent negative growth in trough (2022) change in real GDP per capita; and that (ii) it takes 19 years for Lebanon to recover to 2017 real GDP levels, the average crisis duration of 35 Annual real GDP growth fell from a pre-Syria war average the top 10 cases in R&R. Bad case CSI would be 57.6, of 4–5 percent to 1.8 percent over the 2011–2017 period. 36 Total population expanded by 27.3 percent from 2010 ranking the Lebanon financial crisis third after Chile to 2017. (1926) and the Spanish civil war. 37 In these charts, the indicator is plotted from 3 years prior We also cross-compare key macroeco- to crisis year (t–3), to 5 (or 6) years post-crisis (t+5 or t+6), nomic indicators for Lebanon with those for R&R’s of course going through crisis year (t). In such a way, relatively more recent episodes. Specifically, we even when crisis years differ (say 2009 for Greece and compare Lebanon to the following R&R episodes, 2001 for Argentina), plotting in reference to a crisis point rather than the calendar year superimposes the same henceforth referred to as G8: Chile (1980), Argentina indicator for Lebanon with global crises comparators (1980), Philippines (1981), Mexico (1981), Venezuela on one chart. This allows us to cross-compare how the (1994), Argentina (2001), Uruguay (2002) and Greece macro indicator developed as the crisis is approached, (2009). A summary of crisis events is presented in and how it evolved afterwards. Global Crises Comparators: Looking for the Minimum 21 FIGURE 15 • Real GDP Per Capita for G8 Plus FIGURE 16 • Real GDP Per Capita for G8 Plus Lebanon Lebanon Real GDP per Capita Growth Real GDP per Capita Growth 10 10 5 5 0 0 Percent (%) Percent (%) –5 –5 –10 –10 –15 –15 –20 –20 t–3 t–2 t–1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 t–3 t–2 t–1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 Chile '80 Argentina '80 Philippines '81 Venezuela '94 Argentina '01 Uruguay '02 Mexico '81 Lebanon '19 Greece '09 Lebanon '19 Sources: WDI, CAS and WB staff calculations. Sources: WDI, CAS and WB staff calculations. per capita real GDP in the period leading to the crisis by the Lebanon financial crisis. To the extent point (Figures 15 and 16). While the contraction in data allows, we examine the trajectories of both the real GDP commenced in 2018, it accelerated sharply exchange rate and inflation in G8 plus Lebanon. in 2020. However, Lebanon stands out in magnitude Crisis-related currency depreciations were most of the contraction at time t and t+1. Further, the severe in Argentina (80) (Figure 17), and to a lesser protracted nature of the crises in the G8 countries extent in Mexico (81), Venezuela (94) and Argentina is reflected in the difficulty for these economies to (01) (Figure 18). Exchange rate depreciation in regain growth in their per capita GDP. Only Argentina Lebanon has so far been comparable to the latter (01) and Uruguay (02) amongst the G8 were able to three. Loss in value for local currencies was relatively regain consistent per capita growth by t+2. moderate in Chile (80) and the Philippines (81), The contraction in Lebanon’s real GDP and mild in Uruguay (02). Meanwhile, Greece (09) per capita is already worse than any of the had successfully retained membership of the Euro G8’s Peak to Trough changes. The contraction monetary area. in Lebanon’s real GDP per capita from its level in Inflation in Lebanon, long subdued since peak year 2017 had already reached an estimated the early nineties in reflection of exchange rate 27.9 percent by 2020, and is projected to be 35.1 stability,38 has come to resemble the worst of percent by 2021. This is significantly larger than G8 G8 episodes. Exchange rate pass-through effects Peak to Trough changes in per capita GDP: –24.2 on prices have implied a correlation between cur- percent for Venezuela (94); –24 percent for Greece rency depreciations and inflation rates. Due to data (09); –21.8 percent for Argentina (80); –20.9 percent limitations, we examine inflation in a subsample of for Argentina (01); –18.9 percent for each of Chile the G8 episodes, namely, Chile (80), Philippines (81), (81) and Uruguay (02); –18.8 percent for Philippines Mexico (81), Uruguay (02) and Greece (09). Among (81); and –14.1 percent for Mexico (81) (Table 3). this subsample, inflation was most severe in Mexico (81), relatively moderate in Chile (80) and Philippines (81), and mild in Uruguay (02) and Greece (09). This Depreciation-Inflation A potent depreciation-inflation dynamic is a key 38 This is the case since the last exchange rate collapse, driver of macroeconomic instability for half of which saw the currency depreciate by over 400 percent the G8 episodes, a characteristic also shared from January 1990 until Fall of 1992. 22 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) FIGURE 17 • CPI Indices for G8 Plus Lebanon FIGURE 18 • Overall Fiscal Balance for G8 Plus Lebanon Exchange Rates 150 900 Exchange Rates 130 800 250 110 700 200 600 Percent (%) Percent (%) 90 150 Percent (%) 500 70 400 100 50 300 30 50 200 10 100 0 –10 0 –50 t–3 t–2 t–1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 t–3 t–2 t–1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 Chile '80 Philippines '81 Mexico '81 Venezuela '94 Argentina '01 Uruguay '02 Lebanon '19 Argentina '80 (rhs) Greece '09 Lebanon '19 Sources: WDI, CAS and WB staff calculations. Sources: WDI, CAS and WB staff calculations. correlates to the extent of exchange rate volatility in FIGURE 19 • CPI Indices for G8 Plus Lebanon each of these episodes. Notably, at time t, Lebanon’s CPI Indices inflation rate is even starker than that of Mexico 300 1,800 (81) (Figure 19); specifically, Lebanon’s inflation rate 1,600 250 1,400 in t+1 (2020) was 84.3 percent, while in Mexico (81) it 200 1,200 Percent (%) Percent (%) was 58.9 percent.39 Even though official inflation data 1,000 150 for Argentina (01) is lacking, the failure of the cur- 800 100 600 rency board rendered inflation a main vulnerability in 400 50 the post-crisis period. 200 0 0 t–3 t–2 t–1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 Chile '80 Philippines '81 Uruguay '02 Fiscal Greece '09 Lebanon '19 Mexico '81 (rhs) Sources: WDI, CAS and WB staff calculations. Lebanon’s overall fiscal balance stands out as a main vulnerability in the lead-up to the crisis, comparable to Greece’s fiscal position on the emerged from their crises. The overall fiscal balance eve of its crisis. Due to data limitations, we examine for each of Chile (80) and Mexico (81) deteriorated the overall fiscal balance for a subsample of the G8 by around 10 pp of GDP (Figure 20). For the former, episodes, namely, Chile (80), Mexico (81), Argentina (01), Uruguay (02) and Greece (09). From this 39 In the period leading up to the crisis, Mexico’s inflation subsample, only Chile (80) enjoyed fiscal surpluses rate fluctuated between 17.5 to 29.1 percent annually, in the lead to the crisis point. Meanwhile, Mexico (81), while Lebanon’s hovered between a minor deflation and Argentina (01) and Uruguay (02) entered the crisis a moderate 6.1 percent. with a modest deficit position, whereas Greece (09)’s 40 A noteworthy event in the Greek episode is that data fiscal deficit was in double digits (as a percentage of revision by the authorities on October 2009, which GDP), as was Lebanon’s.40 entailed a sizeable increase in the projected fiscal deficit from 4 to 12.5 percent of GDP, constituted a trigger to the An ostensible improvement in Lebanon’s Greek crisis. The data revision came amidst concerns fiscal indicators (as a percentage of GDP) masks raised by Eurostat—the statistical office of the European an actual deterioration. There were variations in Commission—regarding the quality of Greece’s fiscal the fiscal performances of the G8 subsample as they data on five occasions over the period 2005–2009. Global Crises Comparators: Looking for the Minimum 23 FIGURE 20 • Overall Fiscal Balance for G8 Plus FIGURE 21 • Gross Debt for G8 Plus Lebanon Lebanon Gross Debt Overall Fiscal Balance 250 10 200 5 0 150 % of GDP % of GDP –5 100 –10 50 –15 –20 0 t–3 t–2 t–1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 t–3 t–2 t–1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 Chile '80 Mexico '81 Argentina '01 Chile '80 Philippines '81 Mexico '81 Uruguay '02 Greece '09 Lebanon '19 Argentina '01 Greece '09 Lebanon '19 Sources: WDI, CAS and WB staff calculations. Sources: WEO and WB staff calculations. this reflected a similar deterioration in the primary GDP) for a subsample of the G8 episodes, namely, balance, driven by larger primary expenditures (from Chile (80), Philippines (81), Mexico (81), Argentina 23.5 percent of GDP in t–1 to 31.1 percent in t+2). In (01) and Greece (09). Leading to the crisis year, the the Mexico (81) case, however, the primary balance public debt-to-GDP ratio was below 60 percent for first deteriorated significantly (by about 6 pp of GDP the G8 subsample (Figure 21), with the exception of from t to t+1) but eventually improved into a surplus. Greece.41 However, in all cases, the debt-to-GDP ratio Interest payments, on the other hand, surged from deteriorated in varying degrees, even for Greece, 1.6 percent of GDP at t–1, to 8.5 percent at t+2. which benefitted from a large haircut on its public debt. Meanwhile, the overall fiscal positions for Argentina (01) and Uruguay (02) each improved by around 3 pp of GDP from t to t+3. In both cases, this reflected External Position commensurate improvements in the primary balance. While an improvement in Lebanon’s overall fiscal bal- A deteriorating current account balance in the ance seems to resemble that of Argentina (01) and lead to crises is a recurring feature in emerging Uruguay (02), it masks an actual deterioration. This economies, and we see evidence of this in deterioration is partially driven by crashing revenues the G8 countries (Figure 22). A worsening of the and despite significantly lower interest payments as external position raises risk exposures to external a result of the Eurobond default and non-payments shocks and increases dependence on more volatile on coupon rates for Eurobonds and TBs held by the portfolio financing. The current account balance central bank. for large commodity exporters, in this case Chile and Venezuela, would be highly dependent on international commodity prices and are more exposed Debt to commodity price shocks. While commodities are also important exports for Argentina, Uruguay and Public debt in Lebanon has consistently been Mexico, it is so to a much lesser extent; for these one of the highest globally (as a ratio of GDP), countries, consumption and investment are significant and as a result, a key source of macroeconomic instability, comparable to only Greece among the 41 The 60 percent of GDP is the debt ceiling identified by G8 episodes. Due to data limitations, we examine the Maastricht Treaty, which set macroeconomic targets the central Government gross debt (as a ratio of for countries to qualify for the Euro membership. 24 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) FIGURE 22 • Current Account Balance for G8 the current account balance. This channel, however, Plus Lebanon was not available for Greece, as its strategic objective Current Account Balance was to remain in the Eurozone. Instead, the correction 20 in the Greek external position occurred as a result 15 10 of an internal adjustment mechanism, typically more 5 painful and prolonged. 0 % of GDP –5 –10 –15 –20 Overall –25 –30 t–4 t–3 t–2 t–1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 t+6 Lebanon’s financial crisis stands out as a Chile '80 Argentina '80 Philippines '81 particularly arduous episode even when compared Mexico '81 Venezuela '94 Argentina '01 to some of the most severe crises observed since Uruguay '02 Greece '09 Lebanon '19 1900. In estimating the R&R CSI for the Lebanon Sources: WDI and WB staff calculations. financial crisis, we make reasonable assumptions on its depth and duration. The results suggest that the Lebanon crisis is likely to be of the 10, possibly three, most severe global crises episodes, as observed drivers for current account balance through imports. It and examined by Reinhart and Rogoff (2014) over a is noteworthy that of the G8 countries, only Argentina period surpassing a century and half. This is further (01) and Uruguay (02) did not experience a worsening confirmed when we compare select macroeconomic of the current account balance up to the crisis point. indicators for Lebanon with those for R&R’s relatively A clear implication of the crises in most more recent crises. G8 countries is a sharp correction in the external As such, we expect the adjustment process position. Only Chile (81) deviates as prices of min- to be more painful and to take longer, even with erals, oils and metal were falling in 4 of the 5 post optimal policy measures in place. As it currently crisis years.42 For Mexico (81), the Philippines (81), stands, however, the absence of a comprehensive Venezuela (94) and Argentina (01), the correction in and consistent adjustment strategy can only make the current account balance occurred as a result of this more difficult. depreciations in the exchange rates, which increased the competitiveness of their economies. Mild depreciation in Uruguay (02) corresponds to mild 42 According to UNCTAD, Free Market Commodity Price post-crisis correction in the current account balance. Indices, the annual percentage change in the price for Noteworthy, Argentina (80) currency collapse cor- minerals, oils and metal, was –15.6, –12.2, 7.9, –8.1, responded to only a minor post-crisis improvement in –4.6 percent from 1981 to 1985, respectively. Global Crises Comparators: Looking for the Minimum 25 4 OUTLOOK AND RISKS S ubject to extraordinarily high uncertainty, Lirafication and monetization of the fiscal deficit, will we project real GDP to contract by a continue to be critical to the inflationary environment. further 9.5 percent in 2021. Our projections Assuming that in 2021, the Lebanese pound suffers a (Table 4) assume that COVID-19 conditions carry comparable depreciation in the US$ banknote market through 2021, while macro policy responses remain as it did in 2020, we expect inflation to remain highly inadequate. We also assume a minimum level of elevated in 2021, possibly surpassing 2020 rates. stability on the political and security scenes, but On the fiscal front, a continued collapse in refrain from assuming runaway inflation-depreciation, revenues is expected to lead a deterioration in which is a realistic scenario. For more empirical Lebanon’s fiscal position compared to 2020. On discussion on our projection, please refer to Annex A. revenues, we assume marginal nominal increases As mentioned earlier, monetary and compared to 2020, as the economic contraction is financial turmoil are driving crisis conditions, expected to be less severe and high inflation boosts more acutely through interactions between the collection in nominal (but not real) terms. Very high exchange rate, narrow money and inflation. The inflation rates will drive a denominator-led shrinking unusual centrality of this dynamic on the macro of the revenues-to-GDP ratio by a projected 4.6 pps, framework is an important caveat regarding our mac- to reach almost 7 percent, compared to a medium- roeconomic outlook for 2021. In an attempt to pin term average of 20.7 percent. On expenditures, and down the framework and help narrow the confidence despite proposed 2021 Budget numbers, we factor intervals for our outlook, we undertake crisis-specific a 30 percent increase in nominal primary spending, econometric estimations; specifically, we assess due again to inflationary pressures. As a ratio of the response of inflation to changes in currency in GDP, however, primary current expenditures are also circulation using multivariate time series models. The projected to decline due to the same denominator- results, which are presented in Annex B, suggest that led effect. Based on this, the overall and primary a 1 percent shock to currency in circulation gener- balances are expected to deteriorate in 2021.43 ates a response of 0.80 pp increase in the inflation rate over a twelve-month horizon. Hence, policy 43 That suggests that BdL will have to keep financing the with implications on narrow money supply, such as deficit which will accelerate its FX reserve losses. Hence, 27 Lebanon’s recession is likely to be arduous Therefore, the removal of the subsidy will have significant and prolonged given the lack of policymaking lead- social implications due to direct and indirect effects ership and reforms. Lebanon’s GDP/capita has fallen on residents’ purchasing power. Further, Lebanon’s by around 40 percent over the 2018–2020 period and political economy suggests that, much like solutions (or is expected to decline further. Hence, Lebanon’s World lack thereof) to other burdens and deficiencies, there is Bank income classification is likely to be downgraded a high likelihood of suboptimality. Possible scenarios from an upper-middle income economy, which should and associated social implications include: enjoy a GNI per capita of between U$4,046 and US$12,535, to a lower-middle income status.44 a. An orderly FX subsidy removal. This would involve Lebanon faces realistic threats to its already effectual political and security coordination, fragile social peace. Angry demonstrations have along with its replacement with a more effective been erupting in cities across Lebanon, protesting the and efficient pro-poor (targeted) program. In this depreciation of the local currency and the associated case, social implications can be mitigated. very high inflation rates, as well as general economic b. Non-coordinated FX subsidy removal. This can and political conditions. While numbers have not been involve BdL unilaterally halting the subsidy, with large, these demonstrations have been spread across minimal political and security coordination. In this the country, and have cut off important roads and case, BdL will carry the political cost, and can highways, thereby causing significant disruptions. A involve increased demonstrations targeting BdL. more recent phenomena has involved scuffles in super- The political class can pass on the blame and markets and angry protests outside over access to feel somewhat relieved, but to many, the obvious subsidized products. This is even occurring in high end responsibility of the political class will remain. supermarkets. Further, the volatile situation allows for c. Disorderly FX subsidy removal due to depletion parasitic groups that can be of a more sinister nature of FX reserves at BdL. This traverses subsidy to usurp legitimate popular discontent creating grave management to constitute a balance of security implications. This is in addition to Lebanon’s payments crisis within a balance of payments long-term sectarian fragmentation. Hence, there is crisis—the complete depletion of FX resources in growing wariness of potential triggers to social unrest. In an economy that has been trying to ration these this LEM, we highlight two potential economic triggers. resources to pay for critical needs. It can trigger an inflationary-depreciation spiral and cause import shortages. Naturally, there are definite significant The FX Subsidy45 social and possible security implications. The first Special Focus of the LEM examines Lebanon’s FX subsidy for critical and essential Large Scale Interruptions to Vital imports, which offers a serious political and social Public Services challenge. On the one hand, the current FX subsidy is both distortionary, expensive, and regressive. Its The second Special Focus of the LEM discusses elimination and possible replacement with a more the impact that the crises are having on four basic effective and efficient pro-poor (targeted) program would improve Lebanon’s balance of payments, meaningfully extend the time-till-exhaustion of the fiscal trajectory is contingent on BdL having sufficient remaining BdL reserves, and help cushion the impact reserves to continue to finance the government. 44 Latest available Gross National Income per capita for on Lebanon’s poor and middle class. On the other Lebanon is for 2019 US$7,380. hand, the subsidy prevents, in the very short-term, 45 For a more detailed analysis on the FX subsidy, please the prices of these products from increasing, which refer to: World Bank (2020), Lebanon Subsidy Reform would exacerbate inflationary-depreciation pressures. Note, December 2020. 28 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) TABLE 4 • Selected Macroeconomic Indicators for Lebanon; 2016–2021 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 Est. 2020 2021 Proj. Real sector (annual percentage change, unless otherwise specified) Real GDP 3.8 2.5 0.2 1.5 0.9 –1.9– 6.7 –20.3 –9.5 Real GDP per capita 1 –2.8 –3.2 –3.9 –1.2 –0.6 –2.5 –6.8 –20.7 –10.0 Agriculture (share of GDP) 3.9 4.4 3.8 4.0 4.5 4.4 5.0 5.0 6.0 Industry (share of GDP) 14.2 13.4 12.7 12.8 12.3 12.0 10.6 13.5 13.5 Services (share of GDP) 70.9 71.3 72.0 71.5 71.6 72.2 74.3 77.6 78.3 Net indirect taxes (share of GDP) 11.0 10.9 11.5 11.7 11.6 11.4 10.1 3.9 2.2 Money and prices CPI Inflation (p.a) 2.7 1.2 –3.7 –0.8 4.5 6.1 2.9 84.3 100.0 Money2 9.0 6.0 5.1 7.3 4.2 3.0 –6.7 198.0 125.0 Investment & saving (percent of GDP, unless otherwise specified) Gross capital formation 27.6 24.9 22.2 22.7 21.4 20.8 18.5 10.0 8.1 o/w private 25.8 23.4 20.8 21.3 19.9 19.1 17.2 8.8 6.8 Gross national savings 2.1 –1.3 5.1 2.2 –1.5 –3.5 –2.7 –1.0 –1.1 o/w private –1.8 –3.9 1.0 –1.0 –4.8 –5.3 7.9 2.7 2.9 Central government finance (percent of GDP, unless otherwise specified) Revenue (including grants) 20.1 22.6 19.2 19.4 21.9 21.0 20.6 11.5 6.9 o/w. tax revenues 14.3 14.3 13.7 13.7 15.5 15.4 15.5 8.1 4.9 Total expenditure and net lending 29.0 28.9 26.9 28.6 28.6 32.0 31.2 16.4 12.2 Current 27.3 27.3 25.5 27.3 27.1 30.3 29.9 15.2 10.9 o/w interest payment 8.1 8.7 8.9 9.3 9.4 9.8 10.0 2.1 1.4 Capital & net lending (excluding 1.8 1.5 1.4 1.4 1.5 1.7 1.3 1.2 1.3 foreign financed) Overall balance (deficit (-)) –9.0 –6.3 –7.7 –9.3– 6.7 –11.0 –10.5 –4.9 –5.3 Primary balance (deficit (-)) –0.9 2.4 1.2 0.0 2.7 –1.2 –0.5 –2.8– 3.9 External sector (percent of GDP, unless otherwise specified) Current account balance –25.6 –26.2 –17.0 –20.5 –22.9 –24.4 –21.2 –11.0 –9.2 Trade balance –28.4 –29.9 –22.9– 23.6 –24.7 –24.8 –24.9 –17.9 –21.9 o/w export (GNFS) 44.5 40.0 39.7 37.3 36.0 35.7 35.4 26.9 41.9 Exports of goods 11.0 9.5 8.0 7.7 7.6 7.0 9.3 12.1 18.7 Exports of services 33.5 30.6 31.7 29.6 28.4 28.7 26.1 14.8 23.3 o/w import (GNFS) 73.0 69.9 62.6 60.9 60.8 60.5 60.3 44.8 63.8 Imports of goods 45.3 42.5 35.2 35.0 34.7 34.4 35.0 27.5 39.2 Imports of services 27.7 27.4 27.4 25.9 26.1 26.1 25.2 17.3 24.6 (continued on next page) Outlook and Risks 29 TABLE 4 • Selected Macroeconomic Indicators for Lebanon; 2016–2021 (continued) 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 Est. 2020 2021 Proj. Net private current transfers: 3.4 4.9 6.8 4.8 2.3 2.5 5.6 9.6 16.7 Net remittances 5.0 5.8 7.2 6.6 5.2 4.2 6.1 9.7 16.5 Net income receipts –0.6 –1.2 –0.9 –1.7 –0.5 –2.1 –1.9 –2.7 –4.1 Capital accounts 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gross reserves (months of imports 11.7 13.1 13.8 15.2 15.6 14.3 14.3 19.8 10.6 GNFS)c,d Total public debt Total debt stock (in million US$) 63,490 66,564 70,325 74,900 79,530 85,139 88,900 58,082 43,958 Debt-to-GDP ratio (percent) 135.3 138.3 140.8 146.3 149.7 154.9 171.0 174.0 197.2 Memorandum items: GDP (in million US$) 46,909 48,134 49,939 51,205 53,141 54,961 51,992 33,383 22,297 Source: Government data, and World Bank staff estimates and projections. a Population figures, which include Syrian refugees registered with the UNHCR, are taken from the United Nations Population Division. b Prior to 2020 this is M3, including non-resident deposits; 2020 and after, this is M0 (currency in circulation). c Gross Reserves (months of imports GNFS) = (Imports of Goods & Services / Gross Res. excl. Gold)*12. d Total Imports using the BOP data from the Quarterly Bulletin of BDL. public services: electricity, water supply, sanitation further undermined this set up via two effects: (i) it has and education. While Lebanon’s public service significantly increased poverty rates, expanding the delivery has long been notoriously deficient relative demographic that is not able to afford these private to its upper middle-income status, long established substitutables, and are thus more dependent on mitigation measures and private substitutables have public services; and (ii) it threatens financial viability traditionally filled the gap, particularly for those with and basic operability of the sector by raising its costs economic means. The Deliberate Depression has and lowering its revenues. 30 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) SPECIAL FOCUS I: FX SUBSIDY REFORM IN THE DELIBERATE DEPRESSION T he real question regarding BdL’s FX subsidy Background for imports of critical and essential goods, is when and how to remove it, not whether. This Policymakers in Lebanon are considering a shift note shows that the sooner the subsidy is replaced away from the FX subsidy for imports of critical with a cheaper and more effective compensation and essential goods, towards direct transfers to scheme, the better for the economy and for people’s households. The decision to remove the FX subsidy welfare. This is because the current FX subsidy is for imports of critical goods and essential food and both distortionary, expensive (costing an estimated other items (henceforth referred to as essential US$287m/month), and regressive (i.e., benefits items) should be based on the most efficient and predominantly wealthier consumers). Its elimination cost-effective use of pro-poor public spending. The and possible replacement with a more effective and subsidy concerns import of critical goods—energy, efficient pro-poor (targeted) program would improve medicine, wheat—and essential items (as identified Lebanon’s balance of payments, meaningfully extend by the MoET. The estimated cost of the subsidy the time-till-exhaustion of remaining BdL reserves, amounts to a monthly average of US$287 million and help cushion the impact on Lebanon’s poor and (Table 5).46 Maintaining the current subsidy scheme middle class. This note suggests a broad-based cash accelerates the steady depletion of FX reserves at transfer program as one such option, which should BdL and reduces the time available to undertake be in place prior to subsidy removal. However, while reforms to avoid a forced and disorderly adjustment the removal of the FX subsidy would be welcome, it of the exchange rate. On the other hand, the subsidy is a mere short-term patch as only a comprehensive prevents, in the very short-term, the prices of these reform package that is consistent with a credible macroeconomic framework can prevent the country from running out of reserves and being forced into 46 This is distinguishable from the total value of the subsidy, a disorderly and highly disruptive exchange rate which amounts to an estimated US$437 million per adjustment. month. 31 products from increasing, which would exacerbate and health externalities—namely, local air pollution, inflationary-depreciation pressures. The question congestion, accidents and roadway wear and tear. policymakers ought to consider is: can a cheaper and Hence, there is a socio-economic benefit in replacing more effective compensation scheme be immediately the regressive portion of the subsidy with a targeted, implemented to both protect poor and vulnerable and therefore cheaper, transfer program. households, and gain some time to protect the Inflation is a highly regressive tax, dispro- official exchange rate until a comprehensive set portionally affecting the poor and vulnerable, of policy reforms that are consistent with a stable and more generally, people living on fixed macroeconomic framework can be introduced? incomes, such as pensioners. This is especially so in Lebanon’s case where key basic items of the consumption basket are primary drivers of overall Macroeconomic Considerations inflation, which has reached 145.8 percent in 2020. In fact, the average yoy inflation rate over 2020 As it stands, half of the cost of the FX subsidy for food and non-alcoholic beverages was 254.3 is directed toward energy items, which are percent, while that for clothing and footwear was regressive in nature. Higher-income earners are 289.8 percent, and 386.7 percent for furnishings and more likely to consume more fuel, and thus profit household equipment. more from the subsidy. The gains associated Lebanon’s sudden stop in capital inflows by implicitly subsidizing road transport are not has implied a steady depletion of FX reserves at distributed fairly; by income, the poorest 20 percent BdL, notwithstanding the introduction of informal of the population receives only 6 percent of the capital controls (Figure 23). As of end-February subsidy, while the richest 20 percent receives 55 percent.47 Finally, low fuel prices encourage over- 47 UNDP, 2015, “Fossil Fuel Subsidies in Lebanon: Fiscal, consumption, adding to negative environmental Equity, Economic and Environmental Impacts.” TABLE 5 • Cost of FX Import Subsidy and Impact of its Removal BoP Impact due to Estimated Reduction in Demandd Estimated Low 2020 Subsidized Subsidy in Cost of elasticity-high consumptiona exchange % subsidizeda valueb subsidyc High elasticity Low elasticity passthrough Product ($, mlns) Rate1 (LL/S) (%) ($, mlns) ($, mlns) ($, mlns) ($, mlns) ($, mlns) Fuel EdL 1,000 1,515 90% 900 661 NA NA NA Gaz (LPG) 110 1,515 90% 99 73 80 39 66 Mazout 1,195 1,515 90% 1,076 790 867 418 717 Other fuel 1,070 1,515 90% 963 707 776 375 642 Medication/supplies 1,300 1,515 85% 1,105 811 1,067 455 780 Wheat 150 1,515 90% 135 99 57 57 96 Essential items 960 3,900 100% 960 303 367 367 612 Total 5,785 1,911 91% 5,238 3,444 3,213 1,710 2,913 a Source: Ministry of Economy and Trade (MoET). b Calculated as: (estimated 2020 consumption) * (the subsidized exchange rate). c Calculated as: [(the average black market exchange rate—the subsidized exchange rate)/ (the average black market exchange rate)] * (subsidy in value). d Calculated as: (estimated 2020 consumption) * (percentage change in demand per selected scenario per product) Average black market exchange rate in 2020 is assumed at 5,700 LL/US$. 32 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) FIGURE 23 • A Steady Depletion in the Gross Foreign Exchange Position at BdL Gross reserves at BdL 50,000 45,000 40,000 35,000 US$ mln 30,000 25,000 20,000 15,000 10,000 5,000 0 Jan-13 Apr-13 Jul-13 Oct-3 Jan-14 Apr-14 Jul-14 Oct-14 Jan-15 Apr-15 Jul-15 Oct-5 Jan-16 Apr-16 Jul-16 Oct-16 Jan-17 Apr-17 Jul-17 Oct-17 Jan-18 Apr-18 Jul-18 Oct-18 Jan-19 Apr-19 Jul-19 Oct-19 Jan-20 Apr-20 Jul-20 Oct-20 Jan-21 Foreign currencies Foreign securities Gross FX reserves Compulsory FX reserve Sources: WB staff calculations based on WDI data. 2021, BdL’s gross foreign asset position reached Demand effects resulting from the removal US$22.9 billion, declining by US$14.4 billion since of subsidies are a key factor for an impact on end-2019, and by US$1.2 billion from end-2020. The the balance of payments (BoP). In principal, the gross position, however, differs widely from its net absence of demand effects, dragged by the fall in reserves (i.e., FX reserves at the central bank net of FX income and increase in prices, would leave the BoP liabilities to others).48 BdL’s gross position includes unchanged by the removal of subsidy. To estimate US$5 billion in Lebanese Eurobonds, an unpublished the impact on demand, we use country specific, amount lent out to banks since October 2019, and product-based, income and prices elasticities of required reserves on banks’ customer FX deposits demand as presented in Seale et al (2003).50 Notably, (estimated at US$16.7 billion). the study finds that energy products and medical care BdL officials have warned that falling FX are generally elastic for most countries, including in reserves will force the central bank to halt its sup- Lebanon; that is, if consumers’ incomes decline by port for imports of critical goods and essential half, or if product prices increase by 50 percent, then items at lower exchange rates. The officials indi- demand for these products declines by half or more. cated that in the next few months BdL’s FX reserves Meanwhile, demand for food items are relatively will drop to the level of the Required Reserves on inelastic; that is, if consumers’ incomes decline by banks’ customer FX deposits. Should BdL abandon half, or if product prices increase by 50 percent, its support for imports of critical goods and essential then demand for these products declines by less items (i.e., including energy products, medicine and food essentials), importers will be forced to fully revert to the US$ banknote market rate49 for the needed 48 BdL, contrary to other central banks, does not publish hard currency. New imports would thus be priced at net reserves. the going US$ banknote market rate, exacerbating 49 This refers to the street market access to dollar inflationary pressures and potentially stoking an banknotes, which has depreciated the Lira by up to 90 percent. inflationary-depreciation spiral. In fact, in anticipation 50 James Seale, Anita Regmi, and Jason Bernstein (2003), of higher prices, importers, retailers and customers International Evidence on Food Consumption Patterns, are already hoarding critical and essential goods, United States Department of Agriculture, Electronic bringing forward price and volume implications. Report from the Economic Research Service. Special Focus I: FX Subsidy Reform in the Deliberate Depression 33 than half.51 We shall preclude from our simulations and disorderly exchange rate adjustment. The EdL due to the company’s obvious deficiencies, spe- sudden stop in capital inflows has induced a more cifically the severe and chronic shortages in power direct trade-off between the stock of FX reserves at supply and tariff regulations that distort the impact BdL and the import bill. As a result, the BoP relief on demand. Further, there is uncertainty regarding shown will reflect on the foreign exchange reserves the elasticities for these consumption goods in the at BdL. We stress that the improvement in the BoP Lebanese economy. Specifically, other literature position and the extension of reserves are temporary suggest that energy products and medical care are and come at the expense of worsening economic inelastic goods.52 For robustness, we also re-run activity and declining standard of living. simulations based on relative in-elasticities of energy As a result of subsidy removal, inflationary products and medical care.53 We shall henceforth pressures would materialize via direct and itera- refer to simulations based on Seale et al (2003) as tive effects. Through the direct effect, the inflation High Elasticity Scenario, and those that assume the rate would increase as prices for critical goods and inelasticity of energy products and medical care as the essential items reflect the higher US$ banknote Low Elasticity Scenario. We proceed by (i) assuming exchange rate.55,56 Additionally, an iterative effect that income contracts by 20 percent across all sce- arises from an increased demand for dollars in the narios; and (ii) simulating two scenarios for product dollar-note market, which further depreciates the price increases: a 50 percent increase in prices of currency, fueling inflation. With surging inflation, energy products, medicine and food items, and a 100 demand for narrow money increases. Meeting this percent increase (dubbed the High Passthrough). Hence, we present three scenarios: 51 According to Seale et al. (2003), income elasticities of 1. High Elasticity Scenario: a high elasticity scenario demand for Lebanon are 0.632 for food, beverage and that assumes a 20 percent contraction in income tobacco, 1.2 for gross rent, fuel and power, and 1.357 for medical care. The authors also present price elasticities and a 50 percent increase in prices of energy of demand for Lebanon, which are –0.511 for food, products, medicine and food items; beverage and tobacco, –0.971 for gross rent, fuel and 2. Low Elasticity Scenario: a low elasticity scenario power, and –1.098 for medical care. that assumes a 20 percent contraction in income 52 Accurate elasticities can be derived from more recent and a 50 percent increase in prices of energy and comprehensive Lebanese household surveys which products, medicine and food items; are not available. 53 Toward that end, we assume income (price) elasticities 3. Low Elasticity-High Passthrough Scenario: a low of demand for Lebanon to be 0.5 (–0.5) for gross rent, elasticity scenario that assumes a 20 percent fuel and power and 0.5 (–0.5) for medical care. contraction in income and a 100 percent increase 54 Here we omit a High Elasticity-High Passthrough in prices of energy products, medicine and food scenario that assumes a 20 percent contraction in items.54 income and a 100 percent increase in prices of energy products, medicine and food items. The reason is that when price elasticity of demand is at or lower than –1, a Removal of subsidies on imports of critical 100 percent increase in prices would wipe out demand, goods and essential items can lead to some BoP which is not a realistic outcome. relief. The sharp declines in consumption of the 55 We note that energy products are final and intermediate subsidized products translate into BoP relief; all three goods, and changes to their prices impose economy- scenarios suggest improvements to the BoP, ranging wide effects. from US$1.7 to US$3.2 billion depending on the 56 While this will naturally reflect on volumes imported— since consumers will cut down on purchases, and there scenario (Table 5). will be some substitutional effects for food products that Based on the above, the removal of subsidy can be manufactured locally (a process likely ongoing)— can meaningfully extend the time-till-exhaustion being critical goods, they will still be demanded in of remaining BdL reserves, thus delaying a forced substantial volumes. 34 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) FIGURE 24 • Upon Removal of FX Subsidy, Direct Effects on Inflation are Substantial 140 130 120 110 100 CPI index 90 80 70 60 50 40 Aug-19 Sep-19 Oct-19 Nov-19 Dec-19 Jan-20 Feb-20 Mar-20 Apr-20 May-20 Jun-20 Jul-20 Aug-20 Sep-20 Oct-20 Nov-20 Dec-20 Jan-21 Feb-21 Mar-21 Apr-21 May-21 Jun-21 Jul-21 Aug-21 Sep-21 Oct-21 Nov-21 Dec-21 CPI, status quo scenario (Dec 2020 = 100) CPI, sudden stop scenario (Dec 2020 = 100) Sources: WB staff calculations based on WDI data. demand with a corresponding increase in money supply—BdL’s current response—would lead to exac- 57 There are also stock implications, whereby high inflation imposes a wealth effect via transfers from creditors to erbated pressures on the exchange rate. Moreover, debtors; ceteris paribus borrowers would owe less— under panic conditions, inflation and exchange rates and hence, creditors would receive less—in real terms are key observables that drive sentiment, and their than what was determined at the time the contract was deterioration re-enforces the inflationary-deprecia- signed. Consequently, public debt denominated in local tion cycle.57 currency would be worth less in real terms, providing a Removing the subsidy is estimated to fiscal benefit. 58 We note that this estimation does not take into increase inflation through the direct effect by 24 consideration the iterative effects, which can potentially percentage points (Figure 24).58 This inflationary drive an inflation-depreciation spiral. impact is frontloaded, hitting hardest the first months 59 The AER is calculated using consumption-based and diminishing over the course of the year. We weights applied on multiple exchange rates, specifically, caveat that this does not account for the impact on the official exchange rate, the platform rate at BdL and inflationary expectations and other related iterative the US$ banknote rate. For further details on the AER, please refer to: The Lebanon Economic Monitor, Fall effects, which are likely to be forceful dynamics. The 2020, The Deliberate Depression. inflation results are generated from an estimated 60 The exchange rate pass-through rate on inflation is AER59 and an exchange rate pass-through effect on calculated by first dividing the inflation rate by the AER prices of about 50 percent60 applied to the following depreciation rate for the same month and multiplying by two scenarios: (1) a hypothetical continuation of the 100. This generates a series of pass-through rates for the time period August 2019 to September 2020, which FX subsidy through 2021, which we will refer to as the we averaged out. The estimated exchange rate pass- Status Quo Scenario;61 and (2) a full termination of through rate will likely change as more actual data are the FX subsidy on January 2021, dubbed the Sudden populated. Stop Scenario.62 61 This scenario is used for illustrative purposes and is not The Government of Lebanon (GOL) needs a likely option. Sharply falling FX reserves at the central to prioritize a comprehensive, consistent and bank precludes the option of continued support for the full list of critical goods and essential items. credible macroeconomic stabilization plan, the 62 The Sudden Stop Scenario assumes (i) the subsidy is fiscal part of which should include a social safety eliminated on January 2021; and (ii) the US$ banknote net (SSN) component. Given Lebanon’s rapidly exchange rate deteriorates to LL 10,000 per US$ by and continuously deteriorating macroeconomic January 2021, stabilizing thereafter. Special Focus I: FX Subsidy Reform in the Deliberate Depression 35 conditions, a social safety net by itself will be compensation program proposed is of a ‘broad insufficient, and indeed, as shown above, can coverage’ nature.67 In year 1, the broad-coverage trigger additional macroeconomic risks. Lebanon subsidy reform compensation scheme (Broad needs to incorporate a SSN into a macroeconomic Coverage-Cash Transfer [BC-CT]) could aim to stabilization strategy that prioritizes the arrest of cover approximately 80 percent of the Lebanese hyperinflation, currency depreciation and prolifera- population. To ensure progressive coverage, the tion of multiple exchange rates. This strategy would BC-CT will seek to exclude the top 20 percent of be based on: (i) a debt restructuring that would the population as they are better able to absorb the achieve short-term fiscal space and medium-term price increases and can afford to pay for the cur- debt sustainability; (ii) comprehensively restructuring rently subsidized items at market price. The broad the financial sector in order to regain solvency of the coverage approach would involve identifying and banking sector; (iii) creating a new monetary policy excluding the top 20 percent of the population (in framework that would regain confidence and stability terms of income/economic wellbeing) and covering in the exchange rate; (iv) a phased fiscal adjustment the remaining 80 percent of the population. Unlike aimed at regaining confidence in fiscal policy; traditional poverty-targeted programs that seek to (v) growth enhancing reforms; and (vi) enhanced identify the poor (bottom 10–40 percent, depending social protection. on the country), in this case, the identification of the richest 20 percent would be based on affluence tests (i.e., markers of affluence to identify the ineli- Design of a Broad-Coverage Subsidy gible) such as asset filters, dwelling ownership and Reform Compensation Scheme63 characteristics, and formal incomes. Preliminary analysis undertaken by the World Bank points to Governments often use generalized subsidies as a the potential use of indicators such as number of tool to lower the cost of living for poor households rooms/bathrooms per household member, dwelling and to shield households from price fluctuations— area per household member, and thresholds for Lebanon is not alone in this approach. However, wages and other formal income for such an afflu- subsidies are a blunt and inefficient instrument, and ence test. Implementing such an approach would some are regressive, benefiting the rich more than the require careful integration of data across multiple poor. International experience shows that a shift from databases to ensure reliability and automation of generalized subsidies to direct support to the poor eligibility decisions. In subsequent years, as the could result in an improvement in public welfare.64 The subsidy reform being considered by the GOL aims to replace implicit FX subsidies 63 The proposal in this section reflects the recommendations for fuel, medicines, wheat and essential items of the World Bank and not necessarily what GOL will with direct cash transfers to Lebanese resident adopt. households.65 The direct cash transfers should offer 64 Ruslan Yemtsov and Amr Moubarak “Assessing the readiness of Social Safety Nets to Mitigate the Impact of some compensation to households to purchase items Reform”; World Bank Good Practice Note 5. at market prices (which will increase following the 65 This section refers to the GoL subsidy reform proposal withdrawal of subsidies as discussed previously) and as presented by the Minister of Economy and Trade in should not be restricted in their use (allowing greater April 2021 and published on the MoET website. As of autonomy and a dignified freedom of choice on the the publication of this note, the GOL has not reached best use of assistance while offering compensation a decision on what kind of scheme will replace the generalized subsidies scheme. for the anticipated increase in prices). 66 Especially as higher fuel prices will lead to increases in As the withdrawal of FX subsidies will prices of several other goods and services. result in a considerable price shock66 that will 67 Covering the majority of Lebanese households though be felt by large sections of the population, the not attempting universal coverage. 36 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) population adjusts to the new (market) prices for FIGURE 25 • Proposed Monthly Benefit Amount the currently subsidized items and as economic (US$), and Coverage (%), by Year recovery begins, the coverage of this compensa- 60 90% tion program may be progressively reduced, along 80% 50 80% with the level of benefits (per adult and per child) to 50 70% 70% ensure a smooth phasing out of the compensation 40 40 40 60% 60% Benefit Amount program that dovetails with more sustainable and Coverage 30 30 50% 30 45% assured financing for a targeted safety net program 25 40% 20 20 that covers around 30 percent of the population 20 30% 30% 15 15 over time. 20% 10 We specifically (and demonstratively) 10% analyze one proposal of a benefits scheme under 0 0% Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 which Lebanese adults (age 23 and above) receive Amount Adult Amount Child % Population Covered US$50 per month in year 1 of the compensation program, US$40 in years 2 and 3, and US$30 in years 4 and 5. Children get half this amount. The cov- erage progressively declines from 85 percent of the FIGURE 26 • Compensation Program Outlay and Lebanese population in the first six months, to 75 per- Net Savings from Phase I Subsidy cent in the next six. Over the next 4 years, coverage Withdrawal, US$ mn declines to 70 percent, 60 percent, 45 percent and Adult $50 Adult $40 Adult $30 30 percent of the population, respectively (Figure 25.) 3,500 Child $25 Child $20 Child $15 2,906 3,060 The scheme described represents compen- 3,000 2,751 2,592 2,500 2,407 sation equivalent to 41 percent of the average 1,835 2,000 Lebanese household’s monthly consumption 1,500 1,536 964 expenditure in Year 1, 28 percent in years 2 and 1,000 779 620 465 3, and 21 percent in years 4 and 5, reflecting a 500 311 substantial level of support to recipient households 0 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 Average 5 Years (compared to most unconditional cash transfer pro- Cash Transfer Program Outlay ($ mn) Savings ($ mn) grams in upper-middle income countries that provide 22 percent of beneficiary welfare).68 One option we model is a phased approach to subsidy removal: Phase 1 is removal of FX subsidy for the MOET essential items and million. The removal of phase I subsidies and the fuel (except for EdL) to take place in January 2021. introduction of the cash transfer compensation as Phase 2 is removal of fuel subsidy for EdL along described will result in a net savings of an average with a reform of EdL’s pricing reform to take place annual value of around US$2.6 billion over the on Jan 2022. Phase 3 is removal of medication 5-year period.69 subject to broad medical coverage for Lebanese BC-CT financing options and associated citizens to take place in January 2023. risks necessitate a credible medium-term mac- Figure 26 shows the required outlay of roeconomic framework. In principle, financing the program and the resulting savings against options for the BC-CT include: (i) money printing by Phase 1 of the removal of subsidies. The bud- getary outlays start at US$1.5 billion in year 1 (80 68 World Bank (2018) The State of Social Safety Nets 2018. percent coverage) and decline to US$311 million Washington DC: The World Bank. in year 5 (30 percent coverage); equivalent to an 69 These savings do not account for administrative costs of average annual expenditure of around US$779 implementing the compensation program. Special Focus I: FX Subsidy Reform in the Deliberate Depression 37 the central bank (i.e., monetization); (ii) budgetary communication is critical for successful subsidy allocations; and (iii) international assistance.70 In light reforms. In Jordan, for example, a widely cast and of BC-CT’s large financing needs, monetization risks well-designed communication strategy played a significantly exacerbate current macroeconomic crucial role in addressing uncertainties and managing conditions, further entrenching macroeconomic expectations during the 2008 and 2011/12 subsidy instability. This option will lead to further deteriora- reforms. Making an effective use of available tion in monetary conditions, potentially stoking the channels to project transparency, clarity on the role afore described inflationary-depreciation effects. of the program, public information on objectives, Alternatively, fiscal financing via additional (unfunded) operational rules, and results are necessary to tackle budgetary allocations would not be qualitatively dif- information asymmetries and concerns of different ferent from the monetization option; currently, the stakeholders. Bringing in different stakeholders in fiscal deficit is de facto monetized. The previous the design of the program would enrich the scheme two options are also likely to preclude effective and its acceptability. Reforms can succeed only international assistance (option iii), which can only be if an informed public accepts and supports the as part of a credible medium-term macroeconomic reform’s rationale. Clearly communicating who will be framework. As mentioned above, this framework impacted, and how, is vital to generate public buy-in. should include: (a) a debt restructuring program that would achieve short-term fiscal space and Identification and Beneficiary Selection medium-term debt sustainability; (b) comprehensivly restructuring the financial sector in order to regain The BC-CT scheme would aim to cover the solvency of the banking sector; (c) creating a new Lebanese population residing in Lebanon only monetary policy framework that would regain confi- (which refers to individuals who spend at least dence and stability in the exchange rate; (d) a phased 183 days in the country). The program is proposed fiscal adjustment aimed at regaining confidence in to involve a simple mobile-based registration (self- fiscal policy; (e) growth enhancing reforms; and (f) declared information) to be completed by the enhanced social protection (i.e., the BC-CT program). applicant. No household visits will be undertaken. The program will require ownership of a National ID71 (NID). Individuals who do not have a NID will be required to Implementing a Broad-Coverage obtain an NID before registering. The program should Subsidy Reform Compensation provide two different registration options: (i) online Scheme through citizen interface (for individuals who can access the internet72) or (ii) physical visit to one of the Delivering a broad-coverage cash transfer (BC- registration sites which could include the LibanPost, CT) scheme requires careful design, transparent and the Social Development Centers (SDCs), or the implementation, and adequate financing. It involves the following broad steps: (i) consultations and communications; (ii) identification and beneficiary 70 For illustrative purposes here, we assume each of selection; (iii) payment of benefits; and (iv) monitoring these options are utilized exclusively, when in practice and grievance redress mechanism (GRM). there are financing modalities that use combinations thereof. Consultations & communication 71 Initial assessment indicates that 78 percent of the Lebanese population have NIDs, World Bank Technical Mission for a Digital Transformation Project, ID4D, A well-prepared communication and out-reach Sept 2019. campaign must precede and accompany the 72 Share of population who uses internet is 75.9 percent subsidy reform program. International experience (penetration rate), Internet usage, Broadband and demonstrates that well-planned and consistent Telecommunications report by Internet World Stats, 2016. 38 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) use of registration trucks. Each entry point will use to the financial institution(s) based on the applicant’s the same “basic delivery system” accessible through preferred payment choice. Giving recipients the a mobile compatible citizen interface. A selfie- choice of the financial service provider often improves based registration will be utilized for onboarding to customer experience by incentivizing providers to the program.73 During the registration, additional offer the best services, while allowing governments information will be requested to exclude well-off to cut on costs and avoid lengthy procurement segments of the population. processes.75 For recipients opting to receive physical The exclusion criteria will be based on notes, identification information, including biometrics a phased approach whereby in Phase I basic where possible, will be used for authentication at demographics and information on income and disbursement time, hereby ensuring that the applicant assets will be collected for immediate exclusion. and whomever is redeeming the funds are the same Households who pass the eligibility for Phase I will be person. onboarded and start receiving the benefits based on It is important to note that the payment their preferred payment modality (see payment sec- mechanism depends on whether GOL opts for tion). Phase II exclusion will be a recurrent process and a restricted or an unrestricted use of funds. The will commence 3 months after the onboarding. Detailed above applies to an unrestricted use of funds, whereby demographics, information on employment, the value recipients can spend the funds without any condition, of assets and ownership, etc. will be collected at Phase be it digitally or in physical notes. It is not possible to II for exclusion purposes. The program should con- use transfer to bank accounts as a payment modality struct interlinkages with other governmental databases if funds are restricted in their use. at Phase II depending on technical availability and IT infrastructure. A call center and a back-office team Monitoring & GRM need to be developed to perform random spot checks (up to 3–5 percent of beneficiaries) to decrease poten- An effective GRM and an effective monitoring tial fraud and/or under/misreporting (which would be system is critical for the success of any social communicated via a set of outreach and communica- safety net program and for establishing channels tion activities). The back-office team will also manage of trust with the communities. A back-office the program’s GRM to ensure fairness, transparency, team needs to be put in place to manage appeals, objectiveness, and accessibility. complaints, data updates, etc. through a GRM module. Payments Mechanism Upon registering for the program, applicants Complementarities Between the BC- will be able to choose their preferred payment CT Program and Other SSN Programs modality among the options currently available in the Lebanese market, receiving funds: (i) on an The main targeted SSN program in Lebanon is the individually or jointly held bank account (58 percent National Poverty Targeting Program (NPTP) which of Lebanese residents being banked);74 (ii) on a is being scaled up. The scale up will be financed physical or virtual banking card, with funds redeemed at automated teller machines (ATMs), or digitally spent for purchases on point-of-sale (POS) devices; 73 For each HH member, a photo of the NID and a selfie will or (iii) in LBP physical notes, with funds redeemed be taken to create a user profile in the system. Please note that this option is only valid for polycarbonate type of IDs . through money transfer operators (MTO) agents 74 Financial Inclusion Demand Side Survey Report, BDL, and/or LibanPost offices. Other payment modalities, 2018. including mobile wallets, can be added once available 75 The Future of G2P Payments: Expanding Customer in the market. The GOL will send the payment orders Choice, CGAP, 2019. Special Focus I: FX Subsidy Reform in the Deliberate Depression 39 through a US$246 million World Bank supported time-bound. The NPTP/ESSN is a long-term sustained Emergency Crisis and COVID-19 Response Social SSN program aimed at protecting extreme poor house- Safety Net Project (ESSN) and support from donors. holds facing multiple shocks. The two programs, which The ESSN aims to provide cash transfers and access to can carefully be run in parallel, are complementary to social services to 147,000 extreme poor and vulnerable each other with gradual dovetailing over the next 4–5 Lebanese households (approximately 20 percent years, especially as the necessary delivery systems are of the population), as well as top-up cash to 87,000 developed. The BC-CT program is likely to be financed children ages 13–18 who are at risk of dropping out by GOL and will entail a gradual reduction in coverage from school. In addition, funding from donor partners over 5 years. By year 5, the level of coverage would be will support an additional 50,000 households reaching in line with a sustainable GOL-financed social safety net a total of 200,000 of the poorest households—i.e., 27 program as the current crisis subsides. The 4–5-year percent of the Lebanese population. horizon will also enable a smooth (rather than abrupt) While the BC-CT and the ESSN have simi- reduction of coverage, as well as the establishment of larities and can both be considered types of SSN a fully functional SSN delivery system (including social programs, they have different (albeit related) registry, GRM, and payments system). The proposed objectives and could be run in parallel. The timeframe is also suitable for the transition to a new BC-CT is a compensation for subsidy reform aimed macroeconomic framework, allowing it to settle in and at the general public and likely will be temporary and support an adequate and robust social safety net. 40 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) SPECIAL FOCUS II: PUBLIC SERVICE DELIVERY IN THE DELIBERATE DEPRESSION 76 L ebanon is enduring a severe and prolonged therefore more dependent on public services; and (ii) it economic depression. These conditions threatens financial viability and basic operability of the transverse the financial and economic spheres public services sector by raising its costs and lowering to directly impact the wellbeing of residents. Critical to its revenues. In this Special Focus, we shed light on 4 this wellbeing is delivery of essential public services. basic public services: electricity, water supply, sanita- A sharp deterioration in basic services would have tion and education. long-term implications, incurring permanent damage to human capital, which should be a matter of grave concern. Mass migration, loss of learning, poor health The Electricity Sector outcomes, and lack of adequate safety nets, among other consequences, would lead to a human capital The electricity sector has been suffering for catastrophe, from which recovery would be very decades from a financial deficit that required difficult. Perhaps this dimension of the Lebanese constant annual budgetary transfers of US$1–2 crisis makes the Lebanon episode unique compared billion to EdL. Using simple back-of-the-envelope to other crises comparators presented in the report. calculations, these cumulative deficits amount to Lebanon’s public service delivery has long been around US$40 billion as of 2020, a considerable notoriously deficient relative to its upper middle-income share of public debt. status. Nonetheless, long-established mitigation mea- sures and private substitutables have traditionally filled the gap, particularly for those with economic means. 76 This Special Focus section is a product of the Lebanon country team, led by Wissam Harake (Senior Economist), The Deliberate Depression has further undermined this Sameh Mobarak (Senior Energy Specialist), Amal Talbi set up via two effects: (i) it has significantly increased (Lead Water Resources Management Specialist), Sally poverty rates, expanding the demographic that is not Zgheib (Senior Water Supply and Sanitation Specialist), able to afford these private substitutables, and are and Nathalie Lahire (Senior Economist). 41 While EdL’s generation production has A SECTOR IN CRISIS: already fallen significantly by 19 percent (yoy) Annual budget transfers US$1–2 billion over the first 11 months of 2020, more rolling Accumulated budget transfers US$40 billion, almost half of blackouts are expected, starting in April, if extra- as of 2020 the national debt budgetary allocations of 1,500 billion LBP ($996 Generation decline 19% year-on-year over the first million at the official rate) for EdL to purchase fuel 11 months of 2020 are not approved by parliament. This reinforces Collection losses increase 20% existing socio-economic inequalities. Meanwhile, over 2020 EdL revenues, which are in Lebanese pounds, are EdL cashflow decline 50% compared to 2019 shrinking because of increasing technical, commer- EdL accrued arrears to private $320 million at the end of 2020 cial and collection losses that exacerbate the impact sector power barges, operation of the related non-cost recovery tariffs that have and maintenance contractors, and remained unchanged since 1994. This financial drain distribution service providers in 2020—collection losses of 20 percent and decline Private diesel generators Cost of up to US¢30/kWh, 13,200 labor force of EdL cashflow of 50 percent compared to 2019—is expected to get worse. EdL is likely to increase rolling blackouts to manage its cashflow shortfalls. The fragile condition of EdL is exacerbated of private generators. As such, consumers may start by a severe shortage of foreign currency needed cutting back on using private generators because of for maintenance of power plants and purchase economic pressures, which may affect this industry’s of temporary generation. There are already estimated 13,200 labor force. accrued arrears to the power barges, operations and Urgent action to address these issues is maintenance contractors, and distribution service needed to avoid the sector’s complete collapse providers, estimated to be US$320 million at the end in the immediate future. In the short-term, there of 2020. Many of these private sector contractors is a need to address EdL’s cash shortfall to avoid have threatened termination of their contracts unless increased blackouts. paid. Suspension of operations of these contrac- tors will dramatically affect electricity production; 15 percent is generated from the Karadeniz barges and Water and Sanitation 40 percent from Deir Amar and Zahrani power plants operated and maintained by PrimeSouth. Moreover, The WEs have witnessed serious depletions in contracts for the barges and distribution service supplies, revenues, and financial and human providers end in September and December 2021, resources. At the same time, WEs are affected by an respectively, without clarity on the plan going forward. upward spiral in costs in the aftermath of the economic To manage decreasing supplies from EdL crisis (since October 2019), the ongoing COVID-19 over the past year, consumers have been forced pandemic (since March 2020), and the Beirut Port to increase their dependence on expensive and explosion (August 4, 2020). Further, the water supply highly polluting private diesel generators, which and sanitation (WSS) service delivery has suffered have an estimated cost of up to US¢30/kWh. from weakened institutions, limited mobility (due to This is expected to intensify as EdL’s increases its COVID-19 lockdown), lack of funds, limited human dependence on rolling blackouts as a cash manage- resources, and reduced subsidies due to the economic ment tool. To make matters worse, as the economic crisis. The WEs are struggling to sustain their level of crisis continues to deteriorate and the BdL’s foreign services by increasingly depending on their own funds currency reserves become increasingly depleted, and the short-term support available from humanitarian the Government is seriously considering lifting diesel actors (UN and NGOs) that help maintain the pumping subsidies, which would significantly increase the cost systems and purchases of chlorine for water treatment 42 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) plants. Moreover, due to ongoing water shortages and the delivery of WSS services through delays in intermittent water supply from the WEs—with hours addressing breakages and repairing leaks and of supply further reduced in 2020—people have had assets, possibly leading to the non-operation of to rely more on other costlier water alternatives such treatment plants. WEs might start diverting funds as water tankers and bottled water. The cost of these from resource monitoring to other immediate O&M alternatives is increasing. For example, since 2020, needs. Consequently, there is a risk of intensified the cost of supply from water tankers increased by spread of water-borne diseases, adversely impacting about 35 percent, while prices of bottled water almost an already vulnerable public health system. Thus, doubled. there is urgent need for the following: More specifically, WEs are facing the fol- lowing challenges: • Reliable electricity supply is one of the main limiting factors in ensuring operational continuity • Lack of coverage for operation and maintenance of WSS service delivery. WEs require electricity (O&M) costs further exacerbated by poor and to produce, treat and distribute water supply falling collection rates. Even prior to the economic and continue treating wastewater. Thus, the crisis, the applicable yearly flat fee (approximately Government of Lebanon should prioritize power LBP 295,000) already failed to cover the full supply to WEs during this crisis despite delayed cost of O&M. The crisis further exacerbated the payments to avoid shutting-off of the pumping situation, leading to a 20 percent fall in collection stations and treatment plants. in 2020 compared to 2019.77 • Maintaining the WSS services at a minimum • Increase in service delivery costs. Financial crisis operating capacity to safeguard public health. conditions—including FX shortages and sharp The ongoing humanitarian support can include depreciation of the local currency—along with an contracting out emergency rehabilitation of WSS inefficient FX subsidy on fuel imports compounded systems to construction firms (where and when by rising global oil prices, have led to fuel supply possible) and providing spare parts (e.g., pumps, shortages in the country. All this has resulted in an motors, pipes, valves, fittings, repair clamps, increase in the service delivery costs. transformers) and consumables (e.g., chemicals for • Poor incentives for staff. Staff are paid in LBP. water treatment and disinfection, fuel, lubricants). As such, very high inflation rates have resulted in • Continue sustaining the flow of funds to procure sharp declines in their real wages. In addition, the the spare parts and consumables. Standby WEs have struggled to pay salaries and statutory financing mechanisms from the Government commitments to retirees resulting in an adverse are needed to sustain the flow of spare parts impact on staff morale. and consumables to WEs, to maintain personnel • Delays in implementing ongoing work paid in (e.g., operators and technicians) and must be US$. The WEs are facing challenges and delays equipped and able to meet the capital costs of in paying contractors in US$, which are needed system repairs and rehabilitation. to import the necessary goods and equipment, thus delaying or blocking the work. • Limited availability of stock of materials. The Education available stock of material and equipment at WEs is limited and will not sustain beyond the next In 2021, Lebanon’s education sector has to few months. The need to import replenishments respond to five major crises, rather than just necessitates access to FX. Should the situation continue to dete- 77 This is according to unaudited 2020 accounts for the riorate, these challenges will seriously impair Beqaa Water Establishment (BWE). SPECIAL FOCUS II: PUBLIC SERVICE DELIVERY IN THE DELIBERATE DEPRESSION 43 one—the Syrian crisis, economic collapse, political financing.84 Expected austerity measures implemented instability, the COVID-19 pandemic, and the PoB by local universities, will lead to a further decline in explosion—putting severe strain on an already higher education quality, likely exacerbating a brain struggling education system. Pre-COVID-19 learning drain as youth graduates seek employability abroad, levels were already comparatively low, with only particularly in critical sectors such as medicine. 6.3 years of learning taking place, once schooling is adjusted for actual learning.78 The most recent school Impact on learning closures due to the COVID-19 pandemic—with schools closed over 75 percent of the school year between The recent Programme for International Student January 2020 and February 202179—will likely lead to a Assessment (PISA) (OECD 2019) and Trends in further and significant decrease in learning. Effectively, International Mathematics and Science Study students are facing a “lost year” of learning. (TIMSS) (IEA 2020) show Lebanon as one of the lowest ranked countries in the region in terms of Impact on access to education student learning outcomes. Time trends show that learning outcomes have consistently declined over The many crises severely impacted demand the last decade, pointing at systematic issues with for education and student retention, especially quality of education. While quality of education is low as many parents can no longer afford private overall, learning outcomes are highly unequal across education for their children. School completion the country. The differences in the quality of individual rates in primary (78 percent) and lower secondary schools are very large—more than in other countries— education (59 percent) have already been declining and disproportionately affect students in public schools over the last years,80 with completion rates being and those from lower socio-economic backgrounds. The significantly lower among poorer students.81 The prolonged school closures and interrupted education burden of education in Lebanon, which enrolled about service delivery will have long lasting negative effects 1.2 million students in 2019/2020, falls on parents’ on learning for all children, exacerbating inequalities shoulders, who pay a combined US$1.5 billion and impacting the most marginalized. annually, with the government paying an additional US$1.2 billion (World Bank 2017).82 Impact on equity in education This school year alone, 54,000 students (11 percent of public sector students) transi- The prolonged school closures have tioned from private to the public schools, putting disproportionately affected the most marginalized additional strain on a public education sector, which already faced severe constraints in terms of available school infrastructure, education quality 78 World Bank Human Capital Index (2020). Learning- and service delivery.83 It is estimated that through adjusted years of schooling. this shift, the private sector is losing at least 8 percent 79 This amounts to 154 days of full closure according to World Bank & UNICEF 2021. of its financing, either through per-student tuition or 80 Abdul-Hamid and Yassine 2020 direct subsidies that are linked to enrollment. 81 Only half of 18-year-olds from the lowest economic The contraction in the economy and quantiles completed school prior to the economic crisis increase in poverty rates will likely lead to more in the country (CAS 2020). parents shifting their children to public schools 82 Households private expenses comprise fees for private in the coming years, as well as higher student schools or out-of-pocket expenses in public schools, such as transportation costs and textbooks. drop-outs, especially from the most marginalized 83 Most public schools are located in the poorest areas, households. These large-scale shifts will change the where demand is greatest. setup of the Lebanese education sector fundamen- 84 World Bank. 2020. “Emergency Social Safety Net Project tally, necessitating re-evaluation of education sector Appraisal Document.” 44 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) students, who had little access to continued access to broadband and computers needed for learning. Since February 2020, schools were mostly online education, to resourceful home environments closed and remote learning the default for most needed to support learning, up to the misalignment months. Remote learning requires availability of IT and between resources provided by the education sector other resources. About 60 percent of students either and education needs. do not have a computer or have to share it with at least 3 other family members. Recent estimates show 85 Gajderowicz, Tomasz, and Maciej Jakubowski. that only about 50 percent of students are connected Forthcoming. “PISA In-Depth Analysis of Results to online learning.85 Inequities in the education system for Jordan and Lebanon (draft).” Washington, DC: have been further exposed with the pandemic—from World Bank. SPECIAL FOCUS II: PUBLIC SERVICE DELIVERY IN THE DELIBERATE DEPRESSION 45 ANNEX Forecasts of Lebanon’s Real GDP Forecasting Real GDP Growth for 2020 Growth using MIDAS Regressions: An Update for 2020 and 2021 The high frequency indicators used to nowcast and forecast Lebanon’s real GDP growth in 2020 are: annual growth rates in claims of the commercial Introduction banking sector on resident customers, outstanding lines of credit for imports, non-resident deposits and The forecasts of Lebanon’s real GDP growth for the resident deposits (Figure 27). That is, in the MIDAS year 2020 and 2021 are updated based on the new setup, our vector of high frequency indicators is, incoming data for the high frequency indicators. The x tH = (cl , lc , nr , r ) , where cl, lc, nr and r denote, data on the high frequency indicators are available for respectively, annual growth rates in claims of the the first eleven months of 2020 at the time of writing.86 commercial banking sector on resident customers, The data for real GDP growth are available until 2019. outstanding lines of credit for imports, non-resident In forecasting growth in 2020 and 2021, we deposits and resident deposits. We also aggregate make a distinction between the utility of financial versus the information from the four high frequency real economy indicators. Financial indicators are likely indicators using principal components analysis. More to better first capture financial crisis dynamics, making specifically, we extract the first principal component them more relevant leading indicators for 2020 than from the four indicators and use it to forecast real real economy indicators. However, over the course of GDP growth for 2020. The MIDAS model, which uses 2020, the financial sector became increasingly inop- the first principal component of the four indicators, erative and segmented from both the local and global economy. Meanwhile, real indicators increasingly 86 In the previous update to the MIDAS forecasting exercise, capture the extent of the economic crisis and become the data on the high frequency indicators were available more relevant leading indicators for 2021. until May 2020. 47 FIGURE 27 • Evolution of High Frequency Indicators Used to Nowcast and Forecast Lebanon’s Real GDP Growth in 2020 Growth in Claims on Resident Sector Growth in Outstanding Lines of Credit for Imports 30 80 20 40 10 0 0 –10 –40 –20 –80 –30 –40 –120 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Growth in Nonresident Deposits Growth in Resident Deposits 60 30 40 20 20 10 0 0 –10 –20 –10 –40 –20 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 is referred to as the factor augmented MIDAS TABLE 6 • Real GDP Growth Forecasts for 2020 model. The low frequency variable of interest in the Real GDP growth forecasts nowcasting or forecasting exercises is y tL = (gdpg ) for 2020 where gdpg is the growth rate in GDP. Baseline The dynamic (i.e., multi-step-ahead) forecasts Growth in non-resident deposits –12.6% of real GDP growth rates are generated using an ADL-MIDAS model, which is employed to introduce Growth in resident deposits –14.8% dynamics. The high frequency indicators are available Growth in claims on the resident –13.5% sector until November 2020. Forecasts of real GDP growth for 2020 are pro- Growth in lines of credit for imports –14.4% duced from the ADL-MIDAS using each of the above Factor Augmented MIDAS –20.3% high frequency indicators. The forecasts of real GDP growth are provided in Table 6. Forecasting Real GDP Growth for 2021 This poses an immediate challenge: The set of candidate high frequency indicators of economic Under the assumption that the constraints relating activity that can be used to forecast real GDP to import demand are less binding in 2021 and that growth is sizeable. Tiffin (2016) employs a machine the bulk (but not the entirety) of the adjustment in learning approach to identify the best predictors of the banking sector occurs in 2020, the set of high economic activity. More specifically, Tiffin (2016) frequency indicators is enlarged to encompass real resorts to random forests, Least Absolute Shrinkage activity indicators. and Selection Operator ridge and elastic net 48 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) TABLE 7 • Candidate Predictor Variables for the Forecasts of Real GDP Growth for 2021 TABLE 8 • Real High Frequency Indicators Using Real Activity Indicators Observations Forecast for 2021 Candidate predictor variables available until BDL Coincident Indicator (annual change, –19.6% BDL Coincident Indicator (annual change, percent) (CI) 2020:09 percent) (CI) World Bank Coincident Indicator (annual change, 2020:09 World Bank Coincident Indicator (annual change, –16.0% percent) (WBCI) percent) (WBCI) Cement Deliveries (annual change, percent) (CD) 2020:09 Cement Deliveries (annual change, percent) (CD) –9.9% Customs Receipts in Real Terms (annual change, 2020:09 Customs Receipts in Real Terms (annual change, –24.5% percent) (CR) percent) (CR) Import of Petroleum Derivatives (annual change, 2020:09 Import of Petroleum Derivatives (annual change, –8.7% percent) (PI) percent) (PI) Incoming Freight at the Port of Beirut (annual change, 2020:09 Incoming Freight at the Port of Beirut (annual change, –8.7% percent) (IF) percent) (IF) Outgoing Freight at the Port of Beirut (annual change, 2020:09 Outgoing Freight at the Port of Beirut (annual change, –7.1% percent) (OF) percent) (OF) Primary Spending in Real Terms (annual change, 2020:08 Primary Spending in Real Terms (annual change, –6.7% percent) (PRIM) percent) (PRIM) regressions to select the best predictor of quarterly nowcast of 2020 (i.e., it is a dynamic forecast). This GDP growth from a pool of noisy high frequency translates into more uncertainty. Further, the forecast indicators.87 The MIDAS setup is different from that of real GDP growth for 2021 will not reflect any used in Tiffin (2006). Tiffin (2016) predicts quarterly positive developments on the policy front given that it GDP using quarterly indicators and, therefore, does builds on an extrapolation of time series dynamics.88 not mix low and high frequency data. Nonetheless, a The forecast of GDP growth for 2021 should therefore subset of the candidate predictor variables that are be used with these caveats in mind. The advantage entertained by Tiffin (2016) is considered in addition of using a large pool of predictor variables is the to the four high frequency indicators considered ability to generate a large set of forecasts of real previously. The candidate predictor variables are GDP growth, which can then be combined. This will provided in Table 7 and illustrated in Figure 28. attenuate uncertainty related to the forecast. The nominal series are deflated by the As noted in Timmermann (2006), combining Consumer Price Index (CPI). The data for the CPI are forecasts is desirable for a number of reasons.89 First, available starting in January 2008. The availability of identifying the best performing model is not a straight- the CPI data dictates the starting date of the MIDAS forward endeavor. Therefore, combining forecasts forecasting exercise to be January 2009. The same provides diversification gains. Second, the combined starting date is employed for all of the models to place forecast is more robust to structural breaks in the them on an equal footing. individual forecasting models. Third, given that every Forecasting Lebanon’s real GDP growth for 2021 is more complicated and subject to considerably more uncertainty than nowcasting real GDP growth 87 Tiffin (2016) notes that machine learning methods for 2020. To start with, none of the high frequency are particularly adept at prediction and that the best predictor is determined based on its out of sample indicators are observed for 2021. Therefore, monthly predictive accuracy. forecasts of the four high frequency indicators for 88 This extrapolation embeds mean reversion, but this is not the year 2021 should be generated. In addition, the sufficient to reflect the positive effects of policy action. forecast of real GDP growth for 2021 builds on the 89 This discussion is based on Jamali and Yamani (2019). Annex 49 model is likely to be misspecified, combining forecasts 2016). Fourth, Timmermann (2006)’s synthesis of the will alleviate the effects of misspecification in indi- empirical literature suggests that combining forecast vidual forecasting models (Elliott and Timmermann, yields gains in predictive accuracy relative even to FIGURE 28 • Growth of High Frequency Real Economy Indicators Used to Nowcast and Forecast Lebanon’s Real GDP Growth in 2021 CIG WBCIG 40 40 20 20 0 0 –20 –20 –40 –40 –60 –60 –80 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 CDG CRG 80 120 80 40 40 0 0 –40 –40 –80 –80 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 PIG IFG 100 60 75 40 50 20 25 0 0 –20 –25 –40 –50 –60 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 OFG PRIMG 80 120 60 80 40 20 40 0 0 –20 –40 –40 –60 –80 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 50 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) the best performing individual forecasting model. The Forecasts of Real GDP Growth for TABLE 9 • simple mean, the trimmed mean and the median are 2021 Using Real Activity and Financial Indicators three simple forecast combination methods that can be applied in this setup. Forecast for Dynamic forecasts of the growth in the high Indicator 2021 frequency indicators are generated from a well- BDL Coincident Indicator (annual change, percent) (CI) –19.6% specified Autoregressive Moving Average model. The World Bank Coincident Indicator (annual change, –16.0% forecast sample begins on the month following the percent) (WBCI) last for which an observation on the high frequency Cement Deliveries (annual change, percent) (CD) –9.9% indicator is available. The forecast sample for the Customs Receipts in Real Terms (annual change, –24.5% high frequency indicators ends in December 2021. percent) (CR) The set of high frequency candidate predictors is Import of Petroleum Derivatives (annual change, –8.7% x tH = (ci , wbci , cd , cr , pi , if , of , prim ). percent) (PI) The time series dynamics of the high frequency Incoming Freight at the Port of Beirut (annual change, –8.7% indicators of economic activity are provided. percent) (IF) The simple average of the forecasts for 2021 is Outgoing Freight at the Port of Beirut (annual change, –7.1% –12.65 percent whereas the median is –9.32 percent. percent) (OF) The growth forecasts using the main high Primary Spending in Real Terms (annual change, percent) –6.7% frequency indicators are provided in Table 9. (PRIM) Again, given that the import constraint is likely Growth in non-resident deposits (NR) –10.5% not binding in 2021, the GDP growth forecast for 2021 Growth in resident deposits (R) –11.3% obtained from the growth in lines of credit for imports as Growth in claims on the resident sector (CL) –8.9% a high frequency indicator is dropped from the forecast Growth in lines of credit for imports (LC) –12.6% combination. Combining the forecasts from Tables 8 and 9 yields an average growth rate of –11.6 percent in 2021 and a median growth rate of –9.90 percent. If the forecast of real GDP growth obtained with lines of credit Dynamic Response of Inflation to for imports is included in the forecast averaging, the Currency in Circulation in Lebanon average growth rate for 2021 becomes –12.05 percent while the median growth rate is –10.22 percent. This section offers an assessment of the response of inflation to changes in currency in circulation using References multivariate time series models. The variables of interest are the percentage change (growth) in the Elliott, G., & Timmermann, A 2016. Economic currency in circulation, inflation and the percentage Forecasting. Princeton University Press. change in the World Bank coincident indicator. The Jamali, I., & Yamani, E. 2019. Out-of-sample exchange coincident indicator is employed to control for real rate predictability in emerging markets: economic activity. Fundamentals versus technical analysis. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions Unit Root Tests and Money, 61, 241–263. Tiffin, A. 2016. Seeing in the dark: a machine-learning We begin the exercise by testing for stationarity for each approach to nowcasting in Lebanon. IMF Working of the series using the augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF) paper WP/16/56, International Monetary Fund, (1979) and the Phillips and Perron (PP)(1988) tests. The Washington DC. null hypothesis for both the ADF and PP tests is that the Timmermann, A. 2006. Forecast combinations. Hand- series contains a unit root. The ADF test is known to book of Economic Forecasting, 1, 135–196. exhibit low power when the alternative is near unit root Annex 51 behavior (Elliot et al., 1996). Therefore, the ADF test with TABLE 10 • Unit Root Tests GLS detrending of Elliott et al. (1996) is also employed. ADF PP ADF-GLS ZA The existing literature shows that the ADF–GLS test has Growth of currency in –3.29 –11.29*** –2.62 –5.49*** good power properties against near unit root behavior. circulation The crisis dynamics pervading the post Inflation –4.33*** –7.46*** –4.18*** –6.27*** October 2019 period imply that the series might be subject to a structural break. Therefore, the Zivot and Percentage change in the –12.96*** –13,08*** –4.01*** –5.36*** World Bank coincident Andrews (ZA) (1992) test, which allows for a break in indicator the intercept and the trend, is also employed. Notes: This table provides the results from the Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF), Phillips The results from the unit root tests suggest that and Perron (PP), Elliott, Rothenberg and Stock (1996) ADF test with GLS detrending (ADF-GLS) as well as the Zivot and Andrews (ZA) (1992) tests. all three series are stationary. The tests also indicate that the growth in currency in circulation can be char- acterized as a stationary variable that is subject to a in circulation is significant. More specifically, the structural break. The Perron (2006) test designates response of inflation peaks five months following the August 2019 as the break point.90 shock and remains positive and significant. The growth in the WBCI exhibits a negative response to the shock VAR Variables in Difference to currency in circulation. This response is significant in the two to five months following the shock. Let M0t, Pt and WBCIt denote, respectively, the The cumulative effect of the shock to the cur- level of the currency in circulation, the CPI and the rency in circulation on inflation for the entire forecast World Bank Coincident Indicator index. The natural horizon (12 months) can be computed by accumu- logarithms of the currency in circulation and the lating the responses in inflation. The effect is provided price level are denoted, respectively, mot and pt. The in Table 11. The results suggest that a 100 percent percentage change in the WBCIt is computed as increase in the currency in circulation increase prices WBCIt −WBCIt −1 . by 129 percent annually, which averages about 10.75 wbgt = 100 x WBCIt percent per month. The vector of variables in the VAR is thus y t = [ Δm0t , Δpt ,wbgt ]’. Namely, the vector of variables VAR Variables in (Log) Levels yt includes the percentage change in the currency in circulation, inflation as measured by the percentage The robustness of the results is assessed by estimating change in the CPI, and lastly, the percentage change the VAR model in log levels. More specifically, the VAR in the World Bank Coincident Indicator index. The in log levels comprises in the following order: mot, pt VAR model is estimated using percent changes in and wbcit, where wbcit is the natural logarithm of the the variables to circumvent non-stationarity. A recursive ordering (Cholesky decomposi- tion) is employed to identify the VAR. An optimal lag Cumulative Effect of a 1 Percent TABLE 11 • Increase in Currency in Circulation on length of five is used based on the Akaike Information Inflation Criterion (AIC). The analysis is carried out at the monthly frequency over the period January 2008 to Percentage increase in currency in circulation Cumulative effect on CPI September 2020. The times series of the variables are displayed in Figure 29. 1% 1.29% The effects of a shock to currency in circula- 100% 129% tion are assessed using impulse response analysis. Figure 30 provides the responses of each of the vari- ables to a 1 percent shock to currency in circulation. 90 Other unit root tests that account for a break include Lee The response of inflation and the World Bank and Strazicich (2003) as well as Lumsdaine and Papell coincident indicator to a 1 percent shock to currency (1997). 52 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) Time Series Dynamics of the Variables in Changes FIGURE 29 • Growth of Currency in Circulation 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 –5 –10 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 Inflation 25 20 15 10 5 0 –5 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 Change in the World Bank Coincident Indicator 15 10 5 0 –5 –10 –15 –20 –25 –30 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 Notes: This figure provides the time series of the variable used in the estimation of the VAR. The shaded area is the post October 2019 period, which corresponds to the period of the financial crisis. World Bank coincident indicator.91 The variables in The effect of a 1 percent increase in the log levels are displayed in Figure 31. currency in circulation on inflation is gauged by exam- Again, the effects of a shock to currency ining the response of the logarithm of the CPI. The in circulation are gauged using impulse response analysis. Figure 32 provides the responses of 91 The variables in log levels are non-stationary. However, each of the variables to a 1 percent shock to cur- empirical analyses of the macroeconomic effects of rency in circulation. The sample period is January monetary policy shocks commonly use a specification in 2008 to September 2020 and the optimal lag log levels. See, for example, Faust (1998) and Christiano, length of the VAR is determined using the AIC. Eichembaum and Evans (1999). Such a specification Annex 53 Responses to a 1 Percent Increase in the Growth of Currency in Circulation FIGURE 30 • Response of MOG to MOG 1.00 0.75 0.50 0.25 0.00 –0.25 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Response of INF to MOG 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 –0.1 –0.2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Response of WBCIG to MOG 0.2 0.1 –0.0 –0.1 –0.2 –0.3 –0.4 –0.0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Notes: This figure provides the responses of each of the variables to a 1 percent shock to currency in circulation. The 95 percent confidence intervals are constructed using the bootstrap method. results are summarized in Table 12. A 100 percent Cumulative Effect of a 1 Percent TABLE 12 • increase in the currency in circulation increase prices Increase in Currency in Circulation on by 76 percent, annually averaging 6.33 percent per Inflation month. Percentage Increase in Currency in Circulation Effect on CPI The Cointegrated VAR: Vector Error 1% 0.76% Correction Model 100% 76% The response of inflation to a shock to currency in circulation is examined next via a cointegrated VAR is not invalid, but care must be exercised to account for or vector error correction model. Figure 31 suggests cointegrating relation if such long-run relations are present. 54 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) Time Series Dynamics of the Variables in Log Levels FIGURE 31 • log of Currency in Circulation 10.5 10.0 9.5 9.0 8.5 8.0 7.5 7.0 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 log of CPI 6.0 5.8 5.6 5.4 5.2 5.0 4.8 4.6 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 log of WBCI 5.25 5.00 4.75 4.50 4.25 4.00 3.75 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 that the logarithms of the currency in circulation and where r is the number of cointegrating vectors under –Τ∑ i =r +1ln ˆi )is the estimated ith ordered (1– λ g the CPI may exhibit a long-run cointegrating relation. λ trace ( the r)= null hypothesis and The presence of a cointegration relation in eigenvalue of the matrix Π. The trace statistic tests the VAR in log levels is tested using the Johansen the null hypothesis that the number of cointegrating (1988) approach. More specifically, the existence vector is r or less against the alternative hypothesis of cointegrating vectors can be examined using the that there are more than r cointegrating vectors. The trace statistic: trace statistic is reported in Table 13. The null hypothesis of no cointegrating vector ˆi ) ,(5) λtrace (r ) = –Τ∑ i =r +1ln(1– λ g is marginally rejected (at the 10 percent level). The null hypothesis of one or less cointegrating vector Annex 55 Responses to a 1 Percent Increase in the (log of) Currency in Circulation FIGURE 32 • Response of LMO to log of MO 1.50 1.25 1.00 0.75 0.50 0.25 0.00 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Response of LCPI to log of MO 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 –0.2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Response of LWBCI to long of MO 0.2 –0.0 –0.2 –0.4 –0.6 –0.8 –1.0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 is not rejected. The null of two or less cointegrating A VECM is estimated and the response to a one vectors is rejected at the 5 percent. standard deviation shock are provided in Figure 33. The 95 percent confidence bands are generated using Monte Carlo simulation. The impulse response analysis suggests that TABLE 13 • The Johansen (1988) Trace Statistic a 1 percent shock to currency in circulation gener- Trace statistic ated a response of 0.80 percent increase in CPI over r =0 28.30* a twelve-month horizon. This result is summarized in Table 14. Hence, an increase in currency in circulation r ≤1 12.86 by a 100 percent results in an 80 percent increase in r ≥2 4.66** 56 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) Responses to a 1 Percent Increase in (the Log of) Currency in Circulation from a VECM FIGURE 33 • Response of log of MO to log of MO 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 Response of log of CPI to log of MO 0.30 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.0 –0.05 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 Response of log of WBCI to log of MO 0.05 0.00 –0.05 –0.10 –0.15 –0.20 –0.25 –0.30 –0.35 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 the price level, annually, which averages about 6.66 References percent per month. Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M., & Evans, C. L. 1999. Monetary policy shocks: What have TABLE 14 • Cumulative Effect of a 1 Percent we learned and to what end?. Handbook of Increase in Currency in Circulation on Macroeconomics, 1, 65–148. Inflation Elliott, G., Rothenberg, T. J., & Stock, J. 1996. Percentage increase in currency in circulation Effect on CPI Efficient tests for an autoregressive unit root. Econometrica, 64(4), 813–36. 1% 0.80% Faust, J. (1998). The robustness of identified 100% 80% VAR conclusions about money. In Annex 57 Carnegie-Rochester conference series central bank, however, was not properly equipped to on public policy (Vol. 49, pp. 207–244). supervise a banking sector that grew precipitously. North-Holland. At the monetary policy level, a crawling peg Johansen, S. 1988. Statistical analysis of cointegration system became a main stabilization tool to rein in vectors. Journal of Economic Dynamics and inflation; pre-announced devaluations of the Perso was Control, 12(2–3), 231–254. hoped would reduce uncertainty and guide tradable Perron, P. 2006. Dealing with structural breaks. prices along international prices (with non-tradables Palgrave Handbook of Econometrics, 1(2), following). Exchange rate policies “had important 278–352. effects on the soundness of the financial system, Lee, J., & Strazicich, M. 2003. Minimum Lagrange directly by influencing the capital flows and the value multiplier unit root test with two structural of the foreign debt of firms, and indirectly by dramati- breaks. Review of Economics and Statistics, cally changing many relative prices in the economy—in 85(4), 1082–1089. particular, asset prices” (Balino 1991, pg. 71). Lumsdaine, R. L., & Papell, D. H. 1997. Multiple trend Enterprise indebtedness increased signifi- breaks and the unit-root hypothesis. Review of cantly, leading to business failures and soaring levels Economics and Statistics, 79(2), 212–218. of NPLs, which increased from 1.7 percent in 1975 Phillips, P. C., & Perron, P. 1988. Testing for a unit root to 11.7 percent in 1980 in the primary sector and in time series regression. Biometrika, 75(2), from 3 percent in 1975 to 12.8 percent in 1980 in the 335–346. manufacturing sector (Balino 1991). The rapid dete- Sims, C. A. 1980. Macroeconomics and reality. rioration in the bank-lending portfolio in 1980 spelled Econometrica 48(1), 1–48. trouble for the banking sector. Zivot, E., & Andrews, D. W. K. 2002. Further evidence The crisis broke on March 18, 1980 with the on the great crash, the oil-price shock, and the failure of Banco Intercambio Regional, one of the unit-root hypothesis. Journal of Business & largest private banks in the country. This failure Economic Statistics, 20(1), 25–44. struck at confidence in the domestic private banking model, prompting a reallocation of deposits to State banks and foreign affiliates. Further, the interbank Global Financial Crises Episodes lending market froze. Despite a retroactive increase in deposit insurance, uninsured Peso deposits The Argentinian Banking Crisis of 1980 exceeding 100 million Pesos were lost. Dollar deposi- tors in failed institutions suffered a complete loss. The Prior to 1976, the Argentinian economy contended central bank was forced to intervene to rescue three with high inflation, balance of payments pressures major banks, two of which were ultimately liquidated and fiscal deficits. Since 1976, and in a bid to address (Balino, 1991). these chronic imbalances, policymakers undertook The adverse developments in the banking short-term and structural reforms that predominantly sector strained the crawling peg regime. The affected the financial sector. exchange rate devalued by about 23 percent on A rapid liberalization of the financial sector June 2 owing to losses in foreign exchange reserves was in full swing in 1977. The central bank gradually at the central bank. A two-tiered exchange rate regime loosened prudential regulations relating to capital emerged: a commercial rate set by the central bank requirements, asset immobilization and limits on bank and a market determined rate for financial markets. lending. It also eased its heavy regulatory oversight Confused and inconsistent exchange rate policies on the establishment of new banks as well as new ensued by subsequent governments; first liberaliza- branches of existing banks. The changes effectively tion and unification in December 1981, and then the transformed the Argentinian banking sector from reintroduction of a dual exchange rate system in July a 100 percent to a fractional reserve system. The 1982, before unification again in November 1982. 58 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) In response to the crisis, authorities pursued a The large capital inflows stoked inflationary three-pronged solution. “First, they had to take emer- pressures and pushed real lending rates below zero gency measures to avoid a bank panic; second, they in 1980, further enticing credit growth and a misal- had to search for longer-term solutions to the private location of resources. An overreliance by enterprises debt problem and its effects on financial institutions; and the nongovernment sector on debt to finance and third, they had to find ways to restructure the finan- expansion doubled the outstanding debt between cial system.” (Balino 1991, pg. 92). The emergency 1972 and 1980 and quadrupled foreign currency measures included liquidating Banco Intercambio denominated debt. The external imbalances and the Regional, establishing a new credit facility as well sharp rise in foreign savings as a percent of GDP as retroactively increasing the deposit insurance. made the Philippines economy vulnerable to shocks. The central bank also intervened with three troubled In January 1981, confidence in the financial banks on April 28, 1980. The authorities addressed system of the Philippines was shaken by fraud in the the private debt problems via maturity extensions commercial paper market—an episode that became and refinancing schemes. Despite the central bank’s known as the Dewey Dee affair. The confidence crisis success in stemming the run on deposits, the crisis rapidly spread from the periphery of the financial had far-reaching consequences and resulted in the sector to its core. Rippling through the system, it first liquidation of 71 financial institutions between 1980 caused a collapse of the commercial paper market, and 1982. failures of nonbank money market institutions and the crash of the two largest investment houses The Philippines Financial Crisis of 1981 belonging to two major holding companies, which also subsequently failed. Wealth holders reacted by The Philippines crisis followed a boom-bust shifting savings to the commercial banking sector. phenomenon typical of those analyzed in crisis The loss of confidence consequently afflicted the literature (Nascimento 1991). Over the 1970’s, The thrift banking system and precipitated failures in Philippines experienced high growth rates in its real rural banks. As the year progressed, it became Gross National Product (GNP). It was a demand- readily apparent that the Dewey Dee affair had driven economic boom that reflected an investment- lasting effects on public trust in the financial system intensive development strategy by the Government. as it triggered bank runs, capital flight and a “flight to In order to finance this boom and attract quality” towards the (perceived) relative safety of the foreign capital, The Philippines authorities and the commercial banking sector. Central Bank of the Philippines (CBP) embarked In this first phase of the crisis, between 1981 over the 1972–81 period on a liberalization pro- and 1983, authorities’ priority focused on containing gram in the financial sector and the capital controls the spread of financial distress. The CBP extended regime. The authorities and the CBP relaxed emergency lending to quasi banks through a special controls on foreign capital, facilitated the entry of rediscount facility. An Industrial Fund, co-financed by foreign banks and encouraged the establishment Government budget and the CBP, was also estab- of “universal” banks—commercial banks whose lished and, in early 1982, replaced with a special activities encompass, in addition to retail banking, rediscount window. The CBP used the rediscount securities transaction and investment banking. The window to extend medium and long-term loans CBP introduced important changes to prudential to universal banks and to the Government-owned regulations by lowering banks’ capital requirement Philippines National Bank and Development Bank from 15 percent in 1972 to 6 percent in 1980, of the Philippines. These two banks accounted for a thereby encouraging loose lending practices. significant share of credit to the private sector. The An investment (and credit) boom ensued and the Government also provided emergency lending and external debt burden increased from 31.3 percent equity contributions to nonfinancial public corpora- of GDP to 48.9 percent in 1980 (Nascimento 1991). tions from 1981 to mid-1983 (Nascimento 1991). Annex 59 However, increasing uncertainty in the political Bank of International Settlement (on behalf of main climate and unfavorable external conditions caused central banks), and commercial banks, both large a balance of payments crisis in the second half of and small. Significant linkages to the global financial 1983. Faced with these adverse developments, the system implied serious implications of a Mexican Government declared a moratorium on external debt default to its commercial creditors; indeed, this fact repayments on October 1983. This renewed the run ironically bestowed some leveraged on the Mexican on banks and deprived the Philippines from external negotiating position. The role of commercial banks in financing. this mechanism can be considered as a progenitor of The CBP injected reserve money to meet the later participations in crisis resolutions (i.e., Greece, increase in currency demand and provided extensive bail ins etc.). monetization of the fiscal deficit. This policy stance In 1970s, on prospects of expanded volumes caused inflation to jump from 12 percent in 1983 to of oil exports, the Mexican Government borrowed 50 percent in 1984, and led to a crowding out of the heavily in foreign currency from commercial markets to private sector. Inflationary pressures and accelerated finance a rapid rise in public expenditures (Dornbusch depreciation in the Peso in 1983 and 1984 exac- and Werner 1994; van Wijnbergen 1991). The rise in erbated financial difficulties of the corporates and expenditures stoked inflationary pressures, caused increased distress among banking institutions. an appreciation in the real exchange rate and led to The Government extended emergency lending a rapid accumulation of debt; inflation averaged 20.6 and equity contributions to Government financial percent over the 1972–1981 period (Dornbusch institutions from 1983 to 1985. The assistance aimed and Werner 1994). Meanwhile, the external debt at financing acquisitions of distressed institutions and of the public sector, a significant part of which was facilitating the conversion of debt owed to Government short-term, increased at an annual rate exceeding 30 financial institutions into equity (Nascimento 1991). percent from US$4 billion in 1973 to US$43 billion in The volume of CBP assistance soared from 1981 (Boughton 2001). 3,054 million Pesos in 1981 to 13,549 million Pesos The Mexican economy faced a significant external in 1985 (Nascimento, 1991). The financial crisis, shock as the price of oil, its major export, declined by which erupted in 1981 and lasted until mid-1987, 65 percent between 1981 and 1986 (Cantu, Park and resulted in a major contraction in the financial system. Tornell 2015) due to a softening in the demand for oil In total, the authorities intervened with 128 rural (Boughton 2001). The tightening of monetary policy in banks, 32 thrift institutions and 2 private banks. The the US and Europe—in a bid to combat inflation—in the Government-owned commercial banks, PNB and late 1970s pushed world interest rates higher than 15 DBP, became practically insolvent in 1986 and their percent (Cantu, Park and Tornell 2015) exacerbating non-performing assets were transferred to the Asset Mexico’s financing difficulties. Privatization Fund, a special purpose entity created On February 17, 1982, the authorities to manage impaired assets. Between 1985 and 1986, announced that the central bank will temporarily CBP finally brought inflation under control by main- withdraw from the foreign exchange market. The taining a tight policy. Peso immediately depreciated by more than 40 per- cent (Boughton 1991), worsening Mexico’s external The Mexican Debt Crisis of 1981–82 debt servicing prospects. By April 1982, capital flight accelerated and Mexico’s largest conglomerate, The intrigue and distinction of the Mexican debt crisis Alfa Industrial Group, defaulted on debt payments of rest with its globally systemic nature that necessitated US$2.3 billion (Boughton 1991). a complicated multi-stakeholder coordination and co- On April 20, Mexico’s Minister of Finance, financing mechanism. This mechanism involved, in Silva Herzog, announced a stabilization program that addition to Mexican authorities, the US Government, lowered the fiscal deficit by 3 percent by year-end. multilateral organizations, especially the IMF and the This announcement, however, was insufficient to 60 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) stem the crisis. Faced with dwindling foreign cur- Bank of International Settlements was announced on rency reserves, the Bank of Mexico drew US$800 August 28. The IMF conditioned a Mexico program million on a swap line with the Federal Reserve. A on a clear contribution by private creditors, which large debt repayment was looming in August 1982 involved rolling over the debt and extending further and prospects for meeting this obligation appeared credit to close a US$ 7 billion funding gap. Once this impossible (Oks and van Wijnbergen 1994). In July, was secured, an IMF Extended Fund Facility (EFF) of commercial banks expressed increasing reluctance US$3.75 billion was announced on December 23. to roll over their maturing debt or to extend more funding to Mexico. This caused a widening in spreads The Chilean Banking Crisis of 1981 relative to the LIBOR. Mexico’s political transition, from outgoing Following the overthrow of the left-leaning, President Lopez Portillo to President-elect Miguel de democratically elected President Salvador Allende by La Madrid following presidential elections on July 4, General Augusto Pinochet on September 11, 1973, 1982, complicated and increased vagueness around Chile embarked on an intensive market-oriented political consensus on a crisis management strategy. liberalization of the economy; indeed, “the dictatorship It was not clear the extent to which Herzog had a that supplanted Allende used its powers to open the political mandate from his superiors to structure a economy and to give market economics as free a rein strategy and negotiate with the IMF, US and other as Latin America had ever seen” (Boughton 2001, pg. counterparts; decisions made in Mexico City contra- 346). This developed to be one of the more prominent dicted those made by the Mexico negotiating team macroeconomic liberalization case studies, especially (Boughton 1991). espoused by free-market proponents. By August, the crisis was in full swing. On Prevailing conditions at the time of the coup August 4, 1982, the Bank of Mexico drew a three- included a stagflationary economy with rising month loan of US$700 million on a swap line with the government expenditures, import controls and an Federal Reserve. A dual exchange rate system was overvaluation of the currency, with black-market rates announced on August 5 with the aim of restricting that were over 10 times the official rate. Pinochet speculative capital flows. At that point, it became handed economic management to the so-called apparent that Mexico’s debt problems could not be “Chicago boys”—a group of Chilean economists resolved solely via negotiations with commercial educated at the Department of Economics of the creditors. Instead, on August 12, authorities closed University of Chicago. The economic team, led by the foreign exchange market, restricted banks’ for- finance minister Sergio de Castro, undertook fiscal eign exchange operations to the Bank of Mexico at consolidation and structural reforms that succeeded a rate that was less favorable than the market rate, in raising growth to 7.5 percent. The reform program and paid out dollar-denominated deposits in Pesos. was supported by the IMF in January 1974 via a In addition, commercial creditors, the US Treasury, one-year stand-by arrangement (SBA) of about $95 and the Federal Reserve were notified that Mexico is million as well as a Compensatory Financing Facility unable to honor the principal debt payment. (CFF) that allowed for weathering the effects of export The implication of a Mexican default on its shortfalls and the 1973 oil supply shock. international commercial creditors directly threatened The economic team proceeded with the liber- the global financial system. Faced with that fact, a alization of domestic markets, including the following: concerted, multilateral funding effort was required removal of controls on interest rates and credit to stem the crisis. Such an effort was underway by growth; lowering of reserve requirements; reduction August 15. The US Treasury extended a line of credit of barriers to entry into the banking sector, including of US$1 billion to Mexico, while the US Department of for foreign banks; the privatization of previously Agriculture offered credit guarantees of US$1 billion nationalized banks; open access to foreign borrowing on August 15. A US$925 million bridge loan by the by private banks and businesses. Chile, however, Annex 61 did not adequately adapt and update its supervisory confidence. Despite official reaffirmations of the peg, capabilities and prudential regulations over the authorities could not honor this commitment; on June financial sector; “supervision continued to focus on 13, 1982, the Minister of Economy, Luis Francisco reviewing compliance with accounting rules and Danus, announced a devaluation in the Peso of about related regulations, but did not concentrate on the 18 percent vis-à-vis the dollar. Danus also announced overall risks affecting the operations of each bank” that the Peso would continue to be depreciated at (Larrain 1989, page 10). a fixed rate vis-à-vis a basket of the currencies. The Starting in 1978, these changes resulted in a crawling peg regime subsequently collapsed on substantial accumulation of foreign currency debt August 5, 1982 causing a run on bank deposits and by the private sector. Buoyed by the high economic forcing the authorities to float the Peso. growth, on June 29, 1979, the crawling peg regime The depreciation of the Peso severely ham- was replaced with a firm peg. The move to a firm peg pered firms’ ability to repay or service their foreign aimed at establishing a nominal anchor to counter currency debts to the banking sector. Non-performing stubbornly high inflation rates. Nonetheless, inflation loans soared from 2.3 percent in 1981 to 18.4 percent and inflation expectations continued to be elevated in 1983. Domestic banks borrowed more in foreign and the firm peg resulted in a further loss of com- currencies to honor their obligations to foreign banks. petitiveness and a widening current account deficit. On January 10, 1983, Chile secured a 24-month Indeed, the current account deficit stood at 18.9 SBA from the IMF in the amount of US$550 million, percent of GDP in 1981 (Larrain 1989). and drew an additional US$325 million CFF. This, Toward end-1981, domestic and external factors however, was insufficient to reverse the spiral. On helped plunge the economy into a recession and made January 14, eight financial institutions (seven banks the debt burden more formidable. Difficulties included and one finance company) became insolvent and a decline in copper prices, Chile’s main export. Further, required intervention, 3 of which were subsequently an increase in global interest rates stalled the domestic liquidated. A bank holiday was declared. At that stage, credit boom and led to soaring domestic real interest the IMF program was off track. rates in a bid to stanch capital flight. By year-end, the On March 22, 1983, the new finance minister current account deficit stood at 15 percent of GDP and announced an emergency economic program, which the annual lending rate reached 63 percent (Boughton consisted of accelerating the Peso’s devaluation, fiscal 2001). This made the servicing of bank loans more measures and the tightening of foreign exchange con- challenging for debtors and forced the central bank to trols. In addition, a US$1.3 billion funding and public supply liquidity to the banking sector. debt rescheduling package, supplanted with a bridge A systemic banking crisis was in full swing by loan from the Bank of International Settlements, was November 1981 (Laeven and Valencia 2014); eleven agreed upon with the banks. In light of the agreement financial institutions were intervened between 1981 with the banks, the IMF disbursed based on a new and 1982 and eventually liquidated (Larrain 1989). shadow program on July 27. These institutions accounted for about 14.5 percent Efficient and sensible restructuring of the of deposits in the banking sector. The two largest banking sector and the credit portfolio were critical banks were put into receivership and their assets for an accelerated recovery. This included bank were transferred to other institutions. The govern- re-capitalization and incentives for recouping bad ment and shareholders absorbed the losses of the loans. Further, debt relief was offered to borrowers failed institutions and depositors were compensated. who were assessed to be “productive.” These inter- The pressures on a weakened banking sector ventions were expensive; the cost of foreclosure of were exacerbated by adverse macroeconomic insolvent institutions was 10.6 percent of the GDP developments in 1982 and 1983. Rising fears of and the cost of portfolio purchase under conditions an impending devaluation were met with a cabinet of repurchase reached 6.7 percent of the GDP shuffle on April 11, 1982, aiming at shoring up (Sanhueza 2001). 62 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) The Venezuelan Banking Crisis of 1994 adopted a crawling peg. The rising interest rates precipitated a recession, reduced bank lending and In the period preceding Venezuela’s financial crisis, led to an increase in non-performing loans from 4 per- the country’s banking system was oligopolistic cent in 1991 to 10 percent in 1993 (Garcia-Herrero in nature, composed of a large number of 1997). Higher interest rates did not curtail the outflow specialized banks belonging to financial groups of deposits to the offshore banking sector. Indeed, that were ultimately owned by a few individuals. This deposits decreased in real terms by 11 percent in concentration encouraged lax supervision, resulting 1993 relative to 1991 (Garcia-Herrero 1997) and in low capitalization and incentives to divert losses banks siphoned their liquidity to their offshore facili- and problem loans to offshore branches, which were ties. Despite liquidity injections by the CBV, rumors subject to even less supervision. This created large off- concerning the health of the banking sector continued balance sheet items for Venezuela’s financial sector, unabated at end-1993. which was not monitored by authorities. Moreover, The crisis broke with the collapse of Banco the share of state banks was relatively low compared Latino in mid-January of 1994, the second largest to other Latin American economies; as of June 1993, bank in terms of deposits, prompting a run on two private banks held about 90 percent of total assets, other banks that belonged to the same financial group. with the largest six banks holding 52 percent of the This affected over 10 percent of commercial banks’ total (Garcia-Herrero 1997). deposits. Hence, panic soon spread to other banks. The state of the macroeconomy in the 1980s The Deposit Guarantee Fund reacted by assisting reflected anemic growth and rising inflation. This the distressed banks and the CBV continued to inject resulted in negative real interest rates causing liquidity into the banking sector. The resources of the disintermediation and capital outflows; in the late Deposit Guarantee Fund were depleted by February part of the decade, large amounts of deposits were 1994 and the foreign currency reserves of the CBV transferred to banks’ off-shore facilities. In 1989, the diminished considerably amid an unrelenting run on Venezuelan government, in coordination with the IMF, deposits and capital flight. launched a macroeconomic adjustment program in a The authorities responded by passing a law bid to stimulate the economy. The program consisted on March 1994 to protect depositors, nationalizing of abandoning interest rate controls and shifting to Banco Latino and reopening it with withdrawals indirect monetary policy tools, as well as the unifica- limits on deposits that were frozen, even those in tion and floating of the Bolivar. off-balance sheet accounts. The Deposit Guarantee Nonetheless, the resurgence of inflationary Fund injected the equivalent of 3.6 percent of GDP pressures led the Venezuelan authorities to rein- to cover the losses of Banco Latino (Garcia-Herrero state the peg in 1990. Two coup attempts in 1991 1997). and political instability throughout 1992 aggravated These actions proved insufficient to shore capital flight and made the economy more vulner- up the public’s feeble confidence in the banking able. An exchange rate crisis occurred in October sector. Deposit runs continued in light of fears of 1992 following the loss of about US$1 billion in partial deposit freezes, devaluation and exchange reserves (Garcia-Herrero 1997). The Venezuelan rate controls. When the CBV ceased supplying the economy depended heavily on oil exports and the Deposit Guarantee Fund with liquidity in June 1994, weakening demand for oil in 1993, political uncer- eight distressed financial institutions, accounting for tainty and loose fiscal policy weighed negatively on 21 percent of deposits, had to be intervened despite a the economic outlook and exerted pressure on the massive liquidity injection of 6 percent of GDP by that Bolivar. date (Garcia-Herrero 1997). In an attempt to restore Amid these adverse conditions and due to confidence in the banking sector, the authorities a significant loss in reserves, the Central Bank of established a Financial Emergency Board. However, Venezuela (CBV) tightened monetary policy and the financial distress of the Deposit Guarantee Fund Annex 63 continued to weigh heavily on confidence in the liquidity held by banks and international reserves. As public sector. the system lacked a lender of last resort in dollars, the In the following weeks, capital flight led to financial system was inherently unstable, subject to a large loss of reserves at the CBV. The authorities bank runs (Kiguel 2016). responded by fixing the exchange rate, and insti- In the period just prior to the abandonment tuting price and exchange rate controls. Rumors of the currency board (1998–2001), the economy surrounding two large banks—Banco Consolidado witnessed a deep contraction, exposing mounting and Banco Venezuela—renewed the deposit run and vulnerabilities in the economy. The hard peg and the authorities decided to nationalize both banks. In a lack of fiscal space precluded countercyclical December, two additional banks—Banco Progreso macroeconomic measures. In response, in January and Republica—were in distress. Authorities closed 2001, the IMF approved an augmentation of the former and nationalized the latter. Further, financing, boosting an existing SBA program, to the liabilities of Banco Progreso were migrated to an equivalent of US$14 billion, centered on fiscal the nationalized banks (Banco Latino, Venezuela, adjustment and accelerated structural reforms Consolidado and Republica) without a corresponding (IMF 2003). However, this failed to achieve stability. transfer of assets (due to large one-sided off-balance So did various attempts by the Government for sheet items in the form of deposits that suddenly voluntary debt arrangements. The IMF approved a appeared), thus placing enormous pressure on the new program, disbursing US$5 billion immediately four banks which continued to experience deposit and pledging another US$3 billion in support of withdrawals. prospective debt restructuring. The passage of a Financial Emergency Law The crisis broke with a run on private deposits, in July 1995, which gave broader powers to the which fell by more than US$3.6 billion (6 percent of the Financial Emergency Board and eased restrictions deposit base) over November 28–30, 2001. The authori- on the liquidation of impaired assets at the Deposit ties responded with a wide range of controls on banking Guarantee Fund, succeeded in mitigating, but not and foreign exchange transactions. As the economy completely resolving, the banking crisis. Deposit flight faltered, social and political unrest ensued, forcing the continued, albeit at a slower rate, and a small bank resignation of President de La Rua on December 20, was intervened in August 1995. followed by 4 other (Congress-appointed) Presidents within 3 weeks. On December 23, President Sáa The Argentinian Financial Crisis of 2001–02 declared a default on Government debt; on January 3, 2002, President Duhalde announced the end of the The Argentine Currency Board—via the so-called convertibility regime (IMF 2003). Convertibility Law—pegged the Argentine peso to the U.S. dollar at a parity from March 1991, until its failure The Uruguayan Banking Crisis of 2002 in January 2002 (Spiegel 2002). Argentina adopted the hard peg in an attempt to eliminate hyperinflation On the eve of the crisis, Uruguay’s banking sector, and stimulate economic growth following a which consisted of two large public banks—Banco tumultuous economic performance in the 1980s. de la Republica Oriental del Uruguay and Banco While successful initially, it became a main constraint Hipotecario del Uruguay—and approximately thirty on the economy’s competitiveness in general, and private banks, was widely regarded as sound and on countercyclical macroeconomic management healthy (de la Plaza and Sirtaine 2005). The banking in particular. Moreover, there was a large degree sector, however, was highly dollarized on the asset of financial dollarization in the economy with the and liability sides and, although not as highly exposed banking system functioning mainly in US dollars. The to the sovereign as its neighbors, it was prone to banking system’s dollar-denominated, short-term external shocks and to cross-border bank runs due liabilities exceeded its stock of dollar assets—namely to its exposure to Argentina. On the liabilities side, 64 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) foreign currency deposits constituted 90 percent of May of 2002. The deposit withdrawals, which were total deposits in the system, with the latter amounting no longer confined to specific banks, accelerated to US$ 15.4 billion (representing 83 percent of in May and June of 2002. On June 21, 2002, Banco Uruguay’s 2001 GDP). Further, 47 percent of foreign de Monteviedo-Caja Obrera, the third largest private currency deposits were held by non-residents. The bank experienced severe liquidity shortages causing dollarization of assets reached 75 percent of the total the authorities to intervene. As sentiment deteriorated loan book of the system, with the latter amounting to further in July 2002 and government spreads widened, US$ 11.5 billion. The banking sector also suffered the bank run extended to local currency deposits. By from currency mismatches as 71 percent of foreign the end of July 2002, a cumulative 38 percent of total currency loans were extended to residents, the vast deposits had been withdrawn from the system. The majority of who earned in Pesos (de la Plaza and majority of banks had become technically insolvent Sirtaine 2005, pg. 4–5). (de la Plaza and Sirtaine 2005, pg. 11). A weakening macroeconomic environment Faced with declining foreign currency reserves weighed on banks’ profitability. Uruguay had due to liquidity support to the banking sector, the experienced a prolonged recession since 1999 authorities were forced to abandon the crawling peg. and recurrent fiscal deficits were financed by As a result, the Peso immediately depreciated by 27 issuing mostly foreign currency denominated debt. percent forcing the authorities to declare a five-day Government debt increased from 38 percent of banking holiday on July 30, 2002; by then, the Peso GDP 1998 to 58 percent of GDP in 2001. The fixed had lost 57 percent of its value. exchange rate regime (Roubini and Sester 2004), The bank run had turned into a system-wide which weakened external competitiveness, became credit crunch; credit to the non-financial sector untenable with devaluations in the currencies of shrunk by 37 percent in 2002, greatly contributing to Uruguay’s two largest neighbors and trading partners, a GDP contraction of 10.7 percent for that same year Brazil and Argentina, in 1999 and 2001, respectively. (de la Plaza and Sirtaine 2005, pg. 11). The two public In the lead up to the banking crisis, the Uruguayan banks were in a perilous position. The Banco Galicia economy was characterized by a high level of foreign Uruguay had been suspended and the government currency indebtedness and a significantly overvalued took control of the Banco Commercial and Banco de exchange rate vis-à-vis its major trading partners and Montevideo-Caja Obrera. the rest of the world. In the first stage, the authorities’ response to The crisis broke in December 2001 when the crisis consisted of: provision of ample liquidity Argentina imposed deposit freezes (“el corralito”). support via already established lender of last resort Two of Uruguay’s largest private banks—Banco Galicia facilities; the restructuring and/or liquidation of Uruguay (a subsidiary of an Argentinian bank) and troubled institutions; and the expansion of the Banco Commercial—which combined accounted for crawling exchange rate band from 6 to 12 percent. around 20 percent of the deposit base, came under While this response appeared to stem cross-border intense pressure due to their exposure to Argentinian bank run, the deepening of the crisis in June and July depositors and debt. Deposit withdrawals continued 2002 compelled the authorities to scale up and better unabated as the crisis in Argentina deepened. target their response. By March 2002, deposit withdrawals, mostly The central bank of Uruguay subsequently by non-residents (i.e., Argentinians), amounted to 12 prioritized liquidity support to core banks, which percent of the deposit base (de la Plaza and Sirtaine played an instrumental role in the payment system; 2005). Argentina’s tightening of its deposit freeze in non-core banks, which were mostly Uruguayan February 2002 (“El Corralon”) as well as Uruguay’s branches of foreign banks, were to rely on liquidity downgrade from investment grade prompted a support from their headquarters abroad. In light of the second wave of withdrawals by residents and non- central bank’s diminishing scope to act as a lender of residents totaling 18 percent of deposits in April and last resort, the authorities established in June 2002 a Annex 65 US$2.5 billion facility, the Fondo para la Fortificacion crisis, Greece was gripped with deep twin structural del Sistema Bancario (FFSB), to provide equity and deficits, lack of competitiveness as wage growth liquidity support to the core banks. The FFSB was outpaced productivity growth and a real exchange funded by an augmentation of the SBA with the IMF, rate overvaluation (IMF 2012a). other multinational institutions and the government. The onset of the global financial crisis exacer- The FFSB ultimately proved to be insufficient bated the mounting imbalances of the Greek economy. and was suspended. Following the five-day bank After the failure of Lehman brothers in September holiday that was declared on July 30, the authorities 2008, the spread between the Greek Government announced on August 5, 2002 the creation of US$1.4 bonds and the German bunds soared to 100 basis billion stabilization fund, the Fund for the Stability of the points (IMF 2013) and led to downgrades by Standard Banking System (FSBS), that was funded by the IMF, and Poor’s. A main trigger to the Greek episode was the World Bank and the Inter-American Development data revision by the authorities in October 2009, which Bank (IADB). The FSBS was sufficient to fully back the entailed a sizeable increase in the projected fiscal remaining US$ deposits at core banks (Seeling 2007; deficit from 4 to 12.5 percent of GDP.92 This roiled de la Plaza and Sirtaine 2005). The establishment of markets further, weakened confidence in the Greek the FSBS, coupled with maturity extensions of dollar economy and prompted a downgrade by Fitch (IMF deposits in the public banks and changes to macropru- 2013). The loss of confidence in the Greek economy dential regulations, succeeded in stopping the bank prompted capital outflows from the banking sector run. The IMF’s exposure (of US$1.3 billion) to Uruguay, estimated at 30 percent of the deposit base. It also relative to GDP, was its largest to date (Seeling 2007). suspended Greece’s access to financial markets by significantly widening yields on Greek bonds to unaf- The Greek Financial Crisis 2009 fordable rates. Given that Greece is an EMU member, a Greece’s accession to the European Monetary Union nominal currency devaluation that corrects the built- (EMU) in 2001 did not correct structural imbalances up imbalances was not possible. Instead, under the that included large internal and external deficits Troika of the IMF, the European Commission and the coupled with a low growth environment. Public sector European Central Bank (ECB), Greece underwent a net borrowing averaged around 7 percent of GDP very sharp internal devaluation, including a reduction annually in the Euro-but-pre-crisis period (2002– in the wage bill and pension benefits. A deep reces- 2008), compared to 6.7 percent in the pre-Euro sion ensued over the next decade. period (1994–2000). Public debt remained relatively In return, the Greek authorities secured a €30 stable over the former period fluctuating between billion SBA from the IMF in May 2010, complemented 100 and 110 percent of GDP. Externally, the current with a cooperative package of financing from the account deficit rose from a pre-Euro average of 3.3 European Union amounting to €110 billion (IMF, percent of GDP to Euro-pre-crisis average of 10.5 2012b). The SBA was underpinned by a stringent percent. Moreover, external debt also rose decidedly fiscal consolidation program that aimed at putting from about 100 percent of GDP end-2003, to 133 Greek debt on sustainable footing. However, key percent by end-2008. Clearly, the EMU facilitated SBA macro-fiscal targets, namely, fiscal and current easier access to foreign financing for both the public account indicators, failed to be met. The SBA was as well as the private sectors; by 2009, private sector subsequently cancelled in 2012 and was replaced external debt stood at 175 percent of GDP (IMF with an Extended Fund Facility (EFF) arrangement 2017a). The adoption of the Euro also adversely affected the Greek economy’s competitiveness 92 The data revision came amidst concerns raised relative to its trading partners, given that wages in by Eurostat—the statistical office of the European the European periphery countries rose relative to the Commission—regarding the quality of Greece’s fiscal core countries (Hale 2013). Hence, on the eve of the data on five occasions over the period 2005–2009. 66 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) on March 15, 2012, also under the Troika. The EFF 1982 Mexican Debt Crisis for Greece | VOX, arrangement included financing of about €173 billion CEPR Policy Portal (voxeu.org). over four years. de la Plaza, L. and Sirtaine, S. 2005. An Analysis of the Critically, and as a prior action for the EFF, a 2002 Uruguayan Banking Crisis, World Bank Private Sector Initiative (PSI) was announced on June Policy Research Working Paper 3780, World 2011 for a voluntary debt swap of Greek sovereign Bank, Washington DC. bonds involving a haircut on private creditors who Dornbusch, R., Werner, A. 1994. Mexico: stabilization, were represented by the Institute of International reform, and no growth. Brookings Papers on Finance. This haircut, which was subsequently imple- Economic Activity, 253–315. mented on March 2012, was equivalent to a 53.5 Garcia-Herrero, A. 1997. Banking crises in Latin percent cut in the face value (principal) of the bonds, America in the 1990s: Lessons from Argentina, corresponding to an approximately €107 billion Paraguay, and Venezuela. IMF working paper reduction in Greece’s debt stock.93 WP/97/140, International Monetary Fund, The internal adjustment proved harsh and Washington DC. counter-productive, as macro-fiscal targets remained Hale, G. 2013. Balance of Payments in the European elusive due to unaccounted for economic contrac- Periphery, Federal Reserve Bank of San tions and an unsustainable public debt that persisted Francisco Economic Letter. despite the PSI. This translated into social pain and IMF 2003. Lessons from Argentina, Washington DC, political instability. A banking sector crisis ensued October 2003. in 2015, which required the introduction of capital IMF 2012a. Greece: Request for Extended controls. Once again, the EFF program faltered Arrangement Under the Extended Fund and was eventually cancelled in January 2016 (IMF Facility, Washington DC. 2017a). The prolonged economic contraction helped IMF 2012b. Press Release: IMF Executive Board drive the debt-to-GDP ratio to a peak of 180 percent Approves €30 Billion Stand-By Arrangement of GDP in 2016. In July 2017, the IMF approved a for Greece. precautionary €1.6 billion SBA for Greece (IMF IMF 2013. Greece: Ex-Post Evaluation of Exceptional 2017b). This time the program explicitly noted that, Access Under the 2010 Stand-By Arrangement, without debt relief, Greece’s debt would continue to Washington DC. be unsustainable. IMF 2017a. Greece: Ex-Post Evaluation of Exceptional Access Under the 2012 Extended Arrangement, References Washington DC. IMF 2017b. Greece: Request for Stand-By Balino, T. J., T. 1991. The Argentine Banking Crisis Arrangement, Washington DC. of 1980. In Banking Crises: Cases and Issues, Kiguel, Miguel 2016. Argentina’s 2001 Economic edited by V. Sundararajan and Tomâs J. T. Balino, and Financial Crisis: Lessons for Europe, International Monetary Fund, Washington DC. Brookings, June 2016. Boughton, J. 2001. The Crisis Erupts. In Silent Laeven, L., and Valencia, F. 2014. Systemic Revolution: The International Monetary Fund, Banking Crises. In Financial Crises: Causes, International Monetary Fund, Washington DC. Consequences and Policy Responses, edited Boughton, J. 2001. The Mexican Crisis: No by Stijn Claessens, M. Ayhan Kose, Luc Laeven Mountain Too High?. In Silent Revolution: The International Monetary Fund, International 93 The European Stability Mechanism: https://www. Monetary Fund, Washington DC. esm.europa.eu/content/what-was-private-sector-debt- Cantu, C., Park, K .Y., and Tornell, A. 2015. Lessons restructuring-march-2012#:~:text=Also%20known%20 from the 1982 Mexican Debt Crisis for Greece. as%20the%20PSI,lighten%20Greece’s%20overall%20 VoxEU, CEPR, retrieved from Lessons from the debt%20burden. Annex 67 and Fabian Valencia, International Monetary Sanhueza, G. I. 2001. Chilean Banking Crisis of the Fund, Washington DC. 1980s: Solutions and Estimations of the Costs. Larrain, M. 1989. How the 1981–1983 Chilean Central Bank of Chile Working Paper No 104. Banking Crisis was Handled, Working Paper Seeling, S. 2007. Resolving the Banking Crisis in WPS 300, World Bank, Washington DC. Uruguay. In Building Monetary and Financial Nascimento, J. C. 1991. Crisis in the Financial Sector Systems: Case Studies in Technical Assistance and the Authorities’ Reaction: The Philippines. edited by Charles Enoch, Karl Habermeier and In Banking Crises: Cases and Issues, edited Marta Castello-Branco, International Monetary by V. Sundararajan and Tomâs J. T. Balino, Fund, Washington DC. International Monetary Fund, Washington DC. Spiegel, Mark 2002. Argentina’s currency crisis: Oks, D., and S van Wijnbergen 1994. Mexico after the lessons for Asia, Federal Reserve Bank of San debt crisis: is growth sustainable?, World Bank Francisco, December 2002. Policy Research Working Paper, WPS 1378. Van Wijnbergen, S. 1991. Mexico and the Brady plan Roubini, N., & Setser, B. 2004. Bailouts or bail-ins?: Economic Policy, 6 (12), 14–56. responding to financial crises in emerging economies. Peterson Institute. 68 LEBANON ECONOMIC MONITOR: LE NAUFRAGE DU LIBAN (AU NUMÉRO 3)/LEBANON SINKING (TO THE TOP 3) 1818 H Street, NW Washington, DC 20433