SWP789 The Extent of Nontariff Barriers to Imports of Industrial Countries Julio J. Nogues Andrzej Olechowski L. Alan Winters WORLD BANK STAFF WORKING PAPERS Number 789 HG 3881.5 .W57 w W 67 no. 789 FILE CO Y c .3 WORLD BANK STAFF WORKING PAPERS Number 789 The Extent of Nontariff Barriers to Imports of Industrial Countries Julio J. Nogues Andrzej Olechowski L. Alan Winters INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND JOINT LIBRARY OCT 3 0 1986 INTERNA TOIQNAL LD'ANK VOY The World Bank Washington, D.C., U.S.A. Copyright (© 1986 The Intemational Bank for Reconstruction and Development/THE WORLD BANK 1818 H Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A. All rights reserved Manufactured in the United States of America First printing February 1986 This is a working document published informally by the World Bank. To present the results of research with the least possible delay, the typescript has not been prepared in accordance with the procedures appropriate to formal printed texts, and the World Bank accepts no responsibility for errors. The publication is supplied at a token charge to defray part of the cost of manufacture and distribution. The World Bank does not accept responsibility for the views expressed herein, which are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the World Bank or to its affiliated organizations. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions are the results of research supported by the Bank; they do not necessarily represent official policy of the Bank. The designations employed, the presentation of material, and any maps used in this document are solely for the convenience of the reader and do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the World Bank or its affiliates concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city, area, or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its boundaries, or national affiliation. The most recent World Bank publications are described in the annual spring and fall lists; the continuing research program is described in the annual Abstracts of Current Studies. The latest edition of each is available free of charge from the Publications Sales Unit, Department T, The World Bank, 1818 H Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A., or from the European Office of the Bank, 66 avenue d'1ena, 75116 Paris, France. Julio J. Nogues, Andrzej Olechowsky, and L. Alan Winters are economists in the Development Research Department of the World Bank. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Nogues, Julio J. The extent of nontariff barriers to imports of industrial countries. (World Bank staff working papers ; no. 789) Bibliography: p. 1. Nontariff trade barriers. I. Olechowski, Andrzej. II. Winters, L. Alan. III. Title. IV. Series. HF1430.N64 1986 382'.5 85-32287 ISBN 0-8213-0691-X Abstract This paper examines the extent of non-tariff barriers to sixteen industrial countries' visible imports. Using three alternative measures it shows that governmental commodity-specific border-measures affect over 27% of all imports and over 34% of imports from developing countries. It also shows that during the period 1981 - 83, NTBs became significantly more extensive. Detailed statistics reveal considerable variations in NTB coverage by commod- ity, type of barrier, importer and exporter. The data on which these conclu- sions are based are compiled from official information at the finest level of disaggregation; they are described in the paper. This paper is based on a joint UNCTAD/World Bank study on non-tariff bar- riers. J. Michael Finger's direction and comments have been instrumental to this paper's progress as have the programming skills and diligence of Jerzy Rozanski. Helpful contributions have also been made by Emmanuel Aniebonam, Shirin Fozouni, Paula Holmes, Farrokh Mamaghani, and Shahin Outadi. First rate typing by Nellie Artis and Jackson Magargee is also greatly appreciat- ed. Naturally none of these people are responsible for the paper's remaining shortcomings. The World Bank and the UNCTAD do not accept responsibility for the views expressed herein which are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the World Bank or UNCTAD or to their affiliated organizations. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions are the results of research supported by the Bank; they do not necessarily represent official policy of the Bank or UNCTAD. TABLE OF CONTENTS Page I. Non-Tariff Barriers Included ................... ........................... . 3 (1) Quantitative import restrictions ....................................... 4 (2) "Voluntary" export restraints (VER).Ooo ..... .................. .... 4 (3) Measures for the enforcement of decreed prices ................ 5 (4) Tariff-type measures ..... . .... .........o...................... . 5 (5) Monitoring measures................... ...... .......... .. ......... ... 5 II. Measurements of NTB Coverageo............. 0 ......... * ............. . 8 The Statistical Indicators. .............. ....... ....... ........ 8 The data....ta- .... ........... .... 12 III. Results, NTBs on Industrial Countries' Importsp...r.............. 14 Overall Prevalence of NTBs .... .................................... 14 Sectoral Covrg..* v..er.a...ogeo . o ...#..o ..*. 17 Types of Bariroa. rrie......r........s0 ....... 22 Country Comparisons ........ e ................ ..................... 23 IV. The Extent of NTBs on Developing Countries' Exports 25 V. The Growth of NTBs ....... ......... ......... ........... ....... 29 VI. The Comparison of Existing Estimates of NTB Coverage.............. 31 VII. Summary and Conclusions...... ... .... o ...... .... 33 Appendix 1 .. ..... ....... ...... ...........35 World Trade Weights for the Weighted Coverage Ratio.........o...... 35 (A) Non-USA Data..t..toa..0..O..*.........*.O 36 (B) EEC Data....ta....................... 36 (C) USA Data....t.a ...0. 0......0...0..... 37 Appendix 2.* ..o.. ..o ..e ... e ...... O ....to 39 References .... . . 40 Annex..... 42 Since the 1940s, considerable progress has been made in liberalizing tariff barriers to international trade through a series of multilateral nego- tiations. For example, the Tokyo Round concluded in 1979 with an agreement to lower industrial countries' tariffs by about 25% on average, and the Geneva (1956), Dillon (1962), and Kennedy Rounds (1968) produced similar reduc- tions. In consequence, the average level of the tariff of industrial coun- tries was reduced from about 40% in the mid-1930s to 4-8% after the Tokyo Round. As the GATT rounds have brought about a significant decline of tar- iffs as obstacles to trade, non-tariff barriers (NTBs) have become more pre- valent. The CATT itself, in attempting to limit the imposition of trade restrictions, specifically allows countries to impose several kinds of mea- sures; e.g., safeguard restrictions, antidumping and countervailing duties. In addition, governments and import competing interests have been quite inven- tive both in developing and implementing restrictions; e.g., "Voluntary" Export Restraints, which are outside of the GATT, and in adding provisions to the GATT to sanction widespread restrictions, e.g. on agricultural products, when the CATT was initially negotiated, and later, the Multifibre Arrangement for textiles and clothing. Behind this paper lies an interest, of course, in moving the inter- national community toward liberalization of such restrictions, but we do not address directly that topic here. This paper takes up an important pre- requisite to such work -- the presentation of credible information on the nature and extent of non-tariff barriers in international trade. The quantitative work reported here concentrates on a basic dimension, the amount of trade "subject to", or "covered by" NTBs. Within this quantitative dimen- sion the paper addresses three questions: (1) What is the prevalence of the most notable non-tariff barriers on industrial countries' imports? (2) Has it increased in recent years? (3) Are the imports from developing countries particularly subject to these NTBs? Section I describes the types of NTBs included in this study and discusses the sense in which each type is a restriction on international trade. Section II discusses the concept, data and statistical indicators used, while Sections III to V present the results. Section VI briefly compares our results with other recent estimates and finally, Section VII provides a summary and conclusions. - 3 - I. NON-TARIFF BARRIERS INCLUDED The array of trade practices considered by governments as non-tariff barriers to trade is very wide. For example the "Table of Contents of the Inventory of Non-Tariff Measures" which is used by the GATT Secretariat in its Report of the Group on Quantitative Restrictions and Other Non-Tariff Measures, enumerates over 40 categories of measures. In this paper we invest- igate a restricted selection of the measures, included in the GATT "Table of Contents": specifically those which are (a) product-specific (b) border mea- sures and (c) for which comprehensive and internationally comparable data are available. While there is room for debate about the composition of a complete set of NTBs, our selection, drawn from official definitions and based on official sources, represents a minimum list of non-tariff trade policies. It comprises five groups of the most common and explicit border measures used to control the inflow of foreign goods. There are many political and administrative mechanisms through which import restrictions are put in place, and many reasons, legal, political, and otherwise, why a government might argue against the application of the label ''protection" or "import regulation" to its policy measures. In certain cir- cumstances the GATT allows the use of some types of import restrictions, but whether or not an action is GATT-conforming is not a basis for sorting between protection and not protection. Safeguard actions, for example, are GATT- conforming, and are universally interpreted as trade restrictions or protec- tion. We deal here only with the economics of such measures -- only with the fact that they impose conditions on import sales which they (or parallel rules and regulations on domestic commerce) do not impose on sales by domestic firms. -4- (1) Quantitative import restrictions. Prohibitions, embargoes on the importation of a product. A pro- hibition may be total, may admit exceptions at the discretion of the competent authority, or may operate only under certain conditions. Quotas. Ceilings (specified in value or quantitative terms) are im- posed on the importation of a product for a given period of time; they may be global, country-specific or seasonal. Discretionary import authorizations. Permission to import is granted at the discretion of competent authorities (customs or other) upon completion of an application procedure. These are often used for the administration of quantitative limits. Conditional import authorizations. Permission to import is subject to the importer undertaking commitments in areas other than importation, or to specified overaLl economic conditions (e.g. authorization is dependent on export performance, or the purchase of an equivalent quantity of domestic out- put) or the unavailability of domestic supply. (2) "Voluntary" export restraints (VER). Agreements between an exporter and an importer as to the maximum amount of exports (specified in value or quantity terms) to be effected within a given period of time. This category covers, inter alia, measures employed for the administration of bilateral agreements on textile trade reached within the framework of the Multi-fibre Arrangement (MFA), i.e., specific limits, consultation levels, and export controls. 1/ 1/ While voluntary export restrictions are administered by exporting countries, they are monitored by the importing country and their impo- sition is the result of successful protectionist requests in importing countries. (3) Measures for the enforcement of decreed prices. Variable levies. Variable import charges serving to equalize the c.i.f. import price with a decreed price. Minimum price systems. A minimum import price is set by the import- ing country, and import prices below the decreed minimum trigger an additional duty or some other penalty. "Voluntary" export price restraints. This category covers agreements between the exporter and the importer on the minimum price to be observed by the exporter. (4) Tariff-type measures. Tariff quotas. Two tariff rates are applied, the higher rate coming into operation when the quantity of imported goods exceeds a specified level. Seasonal tariffs. Different tariff rates are applied to the same (agricultural) product according to the time of year. (5) Monitoring measures. Price and volume investigations, surveillance. Such practices are usually associated with charges by domestic producers about unfair trading practices of an exporting country. While an investigation is obviously neces- sary to determine the facts, there is evidence that the inquiry process itself has a protective effect, independent of the eventual findings (Finger, 1981). The investigative process or continued surveillance generates uncertainty about the exporter's continuing access to the market, and creates an incentive to raise his price, whether or not guilty of a legally unfair practice. A surveillance process is often the means by which a government monitors "vol- untary" price maintenance agreements or volume restraint agreements contracted between exporting and import-competing industries or governments. Surveil- - 6 - untary" price maintenance agreements or volume restraint agreements contracted between exporting and import-competing industries or governments. Surveil- lance is often the precursor to more formal import restrictions, 1/ or a signal to exporters to practice "self-restraint" to avoid a more formal "vol- untary restraint." "Automatic" licensing procedures are often restrictive, e.g., they serve to police bans on imports from certain countries, or to funnel all imports of a product through a government authorized association of import-competing local producers of that product, or of a finished good made from that product. Anti-dumping and countervailing duties. In theory, anti-dumping duties are levied on a product that is sold in the importing country at a lower price than in the exporting country, and countervailing duties are levied to offset rebates or subsidies provided for the production of a good for export. As to whether or not such trade practice regulations bear more heavily on import sales than on sales by domestic producers, William Dickey (1979) has explained for the United States several ways in which such rules on import sales practices are more restrictive than is comparable "domestic" (mainly anti-trust) law of domestic firms' sales practices. There is also evidence that the outcome of the pricing test in dumping and countervailing duty cases is significantly influenced by economic variables usually used (in the parallel injury test) to measure injury, i.e., that the economics of dumping and countervailing duties is much the same as the economics of safeguards cases [Finger, Hall & Nelson, 1982]. 1/ Indeed European Economic Community regulations [e.g., Council regulation (EEC) 288/82] explicitly refer to surveillance for this purpose. (See the Official Journal of the European Communities, 1982.) While our selection of NTBs includes a broad range of policies, it still constitutes only a sub-set of the trade restrictions included in the GATT and UNCTAD lists. 1/ For example, it does not include domestic policy measures (e.g. subsidies to import competing sectors, government procurement, restrictions on domestic sale of foreign goods), generalized procedures apply- ing to all imports, restrictive business practices, the use of technical or sanitary requirements as barriers to trade, or subtle forms of import restrictions such as changing ports of entry, any of which could affect international trade dramatically. 1/ See UNCTAD (1985) -8- II. MEASUREMENTS OF NTB COVERAGE The basic unit of measure used in this study is the amount, of share of a country's imports subject to NTB. Operationally, this concept is quanti- fied by marking on each line of a country's import list, which types of NTBs are applied to that line. Many such restrictions are not "global" or "m.f.n.", and apply only to imports from particular countries, hence the import list must be disaggregated by both product and country of origin. The sums of imports over lines "subject to NTB" divided by the sums over "all" import lines are the NTB prevalence or coverage ratios which we will pre- sent. Details are provided below. The prevalence or coverage ratio is a more elementary concept than a tariff average; a more appropriate parallel is the ratio of dutiable to total (dutiable plus duty free) imports. While a tariff rate provides a measure of the "intensity" of restriction it entails, non-tariff measures provide us with no such "natural" measure of intensity, nor has the analysis of NTBs yet brought us to the point where we have an estimated set of intensity figures for NTBs. We have only a "Yes or No" indicator -- a strictly qualitative indicator of whether or not governmental considerations, as opposed to just normal commercial considerations, influence the amount or the direction of international trade. The Statistical Indicators Three indices of the prevalence of NTBs are used below. Each summarizes the presence or absence of NTBs on several tariff headings simultaneously, but each uses a different scheme to combine observations. For any importer (i) and type of non-tariff barrier (b) let N = 1 if there is a barrier on imports of "q" from exporter "x" qx = 0 otherwise. -9- For sets of commodities (Q) and exporters (X), all three indices take the form: E Z W N qeQ xcX qx qx qEQ XeX qx While one might wish to combine NTBs with reference to the amount by which they reduce trade, or to the levels that trade would attain in the ab- sence of NTBs, this is not possible. Neither of these is observable. Indeed, one purpose of developing an NTB coverage index is to move us toward estimat- ing the trade effects of these NTBs, toward construction of the counterfactual "free trade" pattern of imports. 1/ The Own Imports Coverage Ratio (I c): defines Wqx as the value of i's actual imports of q from x. The World Trade Coverage Ratio (1w): defines Wqx as the value of world imports of q, shared over exporters (x) according to i's actual imports. (See Appendix 1 for details). The Frequency Ratio (If): defines Wqx as the presence or absence of a flow of q from x to i; thus Wqx = 1 if imports of q from x are non-zero, = 0 otherwise. 1/ There are many jokes about economists assuming away the problem, and the suggestion that the coverage ratio be based on "free trade" values is an example of why such jokes have an element of valid criticism in them. - 10 - Note that while both Nqx and Wqx must refer to particular years, these need not be the same, provided that, as here, both have been converted to the same classification. 1/ Each of the three indices has strengths and weaknesses. The own imports coverage ratio is possibly the most natural, in that the extent of an NTB is represented by the size of the particular trade flows it affects. Its drawback is that more restrictive NTBs tend to receive lower weight than less restrictive ones, because they reduce imports by more. In the extreme, a total prohibition shows up as zero imports covered by NTBs. This difficulty is reduced by allowing Wqx to refer to a year in which there were relatively few barriers. To the degree that a country's own restrictions are not correlated with those on world trade, then the weight that the world trade coverage ratio applies to a particular NTB will be largely independent of the latter's re- strictiveness. If, on the other hand, all importers restrict a particular commodity (e.g. textiles), its weight in world trade will still be under- stated relative to the free trade case and the NTBs it faces correspondingly underweighted in the overall index. The drawbacks of Iw as a measure of the "free trade" coverage of individual countries' NTBs are, first, that world imports may not be representative of the import pattern of a particular im- porter, because import bundles differ from country to country quite independ- ently of the level of NTBs, and, second, the inevitable inaccuracies in 1/ UNCTAD converts NTB information from the trade classification current when they are reported to the 1981 classification used for the trade data. To the extent that this is occassionally impossible our figures may slightly understate the prevalence of NTBs. - 11 - estimating world trade for each tariff-line of each importer's trade class- ification (see Appendix 1 of Nogues, Olechowski and Winters (1985) for details). Most current protection is of recent origin and is intended to prevent further increases in import shares, rather than to drastically roll back imports. Moreover, most industrial countries do tend to protect the same sectors, e.g. agriculture, textiles and iron and steel. Thus, when comparing NTB coverage between countries, we believe that "own imports" is a better proxy for free trade imports than are our constructed "world trade" data. The frequency ratio goes still further towards avoiding the downward bias in Ic relative to free trade imports coverage. The extent of NTBs is measured by the number of trade flows that are affected, so that every barrier on every observed trade flow receives equal weight. 1/ Its difficulties are twofold, however. First, it ignores the perfectly natural differences in the sizes of different trade flows, and second, it is exaggerated by the tendency of trade classifications to become more fragmented the more sensitive and restricted is a category of trade. None of our indices allows for the fact that some barriers are inherently more restrictive than others. For example, discretionary licenses could involve only the threat of a restriction or a very direct one, but our l/ The use of "observed" trade flows means that prohibitions are still excluded in If. This could be overcome by defining W as unity wherever N = 1, even if actual imports were zero. This invoives a certain aqitrariness, however, since it is not guaranteed that every zero trade subject to an NTB would be positive in the absence of the NTB. For example, suppose an importer has a global quota of zero on bananas: thus N = 1 for all x, when q = bananas. While we may like to have Wqx = 1 f3xr Trinidad, we would not wish it so for Iceland. - 12 - measures are insensitive to such dimensions. Thus it remains a large and speculative step to draw conclusions about the restrictiveness of trade regimes on the strength of these indices. In making comparisons of NTB coverage across time, we use import values from one period to calculate NTB coverage for both periods. Thus we get a reliable indicator of changes of the extent of NTB but, as the reader has been reminded before, not of the changes in their restrictiveness. The data The import data used in construction of the coverage ratios are provided by national authorities to the GATT and thence to UNCTAD. These data classify imports by tariff-line and distinguish trade with all partner coun- tries, except for EEC countries, where intra-Community trade is ignored. All trade data are annual and refer to 1981. Sixteen industrial country markets are examined in this paper: the ten EEC countries (with Belgium and Luxembourg combined), Australia, Austria, Finland, Japan, Norway, Switzerland and the USA. In 1981 these markets accounted for about 60% of total world imports and about 70% of imports from developing countries. The data on non-tariff barriers have been collected by UNCTAD within the framework of its Data Base on Trade Measures. This contains, inter alia, information on governmental product-specific border non-tariff measures ap- plied in most developed market-economy countries. The data are recorded at the tariff-line level (i.e. at the level at which they are applied), and are derived from official national and intergovernmental (e.g. GATT) publications. After the preliminary collection of information, or if - 13 - substantive changes are introduced, governments are invited to verify and comment upon the accuracy of the data on their import regimes. 1/ The UNCTAD data contain information on the dates of introduction and elimination (if applicable) of individual NTBs, thus enabling the investigation of changes in NTB import coverage over time. Our estimates refer to periods of one year, and we set Nqx = 1 for a barrier even if it has been in application for only part of the period concerned. This possibly imparts an upward bias to our ratios, but it allows us to capture a more representative sample of short-term and seasonal barriers than would a "snap- shot" view. 1/ For fuller details of the Data Base on Trade Measures see UNCTAD (1983 and 1985). - 14 - III. RESULTS, NTBs ON INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES' IMPORTS Tables A-C summarize the prevalence in 16 industrial economies of the NTBs we have been able to document. The discussion in this section will be focused on aggregate results. However, the Annex provides detailed figures underlying the text tables and discussion of this section. 1/ Overall Prevalence of NTBs Overall, 13% of these countries' tariff lines are subject to NTBs, and 27% of their imports fall into these categories. In comparison, tariff concessions negotiated at the Tokyo Round covered about 18% of the imports of the major developed countries. 1/ The value of imports influenced by the non- tariff trade policies of these 16 country governments (some $231 billion, based on 1981 trade flows) is almost half as large again as the total imports of the state-trading East European centrally planned countries. 1/ Text tables below are referred to by letter, annex tables by number. Each annex table is replicated for own imports coverage ratios (C), world imports coverage ratios (W) and frequency ratios (F). 1/ The total value of trade affected by m.f.n. tariff reductions and bindings at prevailing rates amounted to 17.8% ($125 billion) of 1976 imports of the major developed import markets (see GATT (1979) p.118). - 15 - Table A Extent of Industrial Countries' NTBs by Product Categories, 1983 16 industrial markets, all exporters, all NTBs Manufactures All All,less Agricul Iron & Electrical Vehicles Rest of Index Products Fuels Fuels tural All Textiles Footwear Steel Machinery Manuf. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) Coverage Ratio Own Imports 27.1 18.6 43.0 36.1 16.1 44.8 12.6 /35.4 10.0 30.4 8.8 World Imports 21.8 18.5 31.0 40.4 14.9 37.8 17.7 35.8 10.8 25.9 7.2 Frequency Ratio 12.8 12.7 23.9 29.5 10.8 38.1 13.5 18.3 5.4 7.4 3.2 Table B Extent of Industrial Countries' NTBs by Type of Measure, 1983 16 Industrial markets, all exporters, all products Quantitative Voluntary All NTBs: Import export Decreed Tariff- Monitoring Union of Index restrictions restrictions prices type Measures (1) thru (5) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Coverage Ratio: Own Imports 8.6 3.0 1.7 1.3 14.8 27.1 World Imports 9.5 1.4 3.4 1.6 9.8 21.8 Frequency Ratio 5.0 3.4 1.7 1.4 4.6 12.8 -16- IR8LE C Extent of Industrial Countries' NlTBs by Country, 1983 811 products, all exporters, all NIBs Coverage Ratios Industrial Country Own Uorld Frequency llarkets Inports Imports Ratio (1) (2) (3) EEC 22.3 18.9 13.8 Belgium-Luxenbourg 26.0 21.0 11.6 Dennark 11.7 13.3 11,4 france 57.1 44.2 24.0 Uest 6ernany 12.4 14.? 12.5 6reece 13.4 19.0 13.6 Ireland .13.4 13.0 9.1 Italy 6.9 10.0 9.7 Netherlands 25.5 21.4 13.1 United Kingdon 14.3 13.9 13.8 Rustralia 34.1 44.4 18.3- Rustria 4.9 7.5 5.4 Finland 34.9 34.3 13.4 Japan 11.9 9.0 9.3 Norway 5.7 6.1 9.7 Switzerland 32.2 42.9 19.4 USR 43.0 34.3 7.0 Rll 16 Markets 27.1 21.8 12.8 - 17 - Sectoral Coverage While NTBs affect almost all internationally traded goods, 1/ Table A shows that in the case of industrial countries they are especially prevalent in certain sectors. In particular, agricultural products, textiles, mineral fuels and iron and steel generally show a greater prevalence of NTBs than other product groups. It is quite common for imports of agricultural products to be regulated to such an extent that their origin, quantity, quality, price and time of entry are specified in advance by the importing country authorities. While the management of imports is particularly elaborate in the EEC, where, for example, minimum import prices for certain products are adjusted almost daily, agricultural products face a wide array of NTBs in all industrial countries. Among the measures employed are various kinds of quotas (global, bilateral, seasonal), varying (seasonal) tariff duties, minimum import prices and import authorizations including permits dependent, for example on the purchase of equivalent quantities of locally grown products. Their use is so widespread that in Switzerland they cover 73% of imports, in Austria and Japan 42%, in Australia 36%, etc. Even so, agriculture is certainly a case where our indices under- estimate the extent of NTBs. First, we do not account for such measures as quality standards or state trading, which are particularly frequent in agriculture and can restrict imports just as effectively as volume or price 1/ For example, about 98% of 4-digit CCCN product groups face some sort of volume restriction somewhere in the world and often in more than one country (UNCTAD (1983a) p.11). - 18 - measures. Second, existing trade restrictions are quite strenuous, 1/ and hence tend to push both the own imports and world imports coverage ratios downward; international trade in those agricultural products currently subject to restriction would certainly be considerably greater under free trade. Textile imports face NTBs to the same or higher degree than agriculture. Most international trade in textiles and clothing is governed by the MFA, an umbrella arrangement under which voluntary export restraints of a varying restrictiveness are negotiated between (industrial country) importers and (developing country) exporters. Countries which do not apply MFA restrictions, resort to other devices: for example, Australia imposes tariff quotas (with higher rates set at the prohibitive levels), Switzerland applies automatic licensing and monitors prices of products from certain suppliers, and Norway applied (until July 1984, when it introduced MFA measures) global quotas. As in the case of agriculture, our indices probably underestimate the extent of NTBs on textiles. First, textile measures are generally highly restrictive. For example, under the current MFA the annual growth rate of the US imports from Hong Kong is limited to 1.5% for textiles and 0.7% for clothing, while EEC imports of textiles from Colombia are allowed to grow by 0.3% and from Mexico by 0.1%. As recently concluded by the CATT Textiles Surveillance Body, "under MFA III, restraints have been more extensive and in many cases more restrictive [than under MFA II]. Most importing countries, in restraining imports under the MFA, had recourse to extensive invocation of 1/ See, for example, Bale and Koester (1983). - 19 - 'exceptional circumstances' or of the need to maintain 'minimum viable production"'. 1/ Second, volume and price restrictions are frequently accompanied and reinforced by other measures, particularly requirements of origin, which our indices do not include. Recent instances suggest that these measures are becoming progressively more restrictive, e.g., the new "Customs Regulating Amendments Relating to Textiles and Textile Products" in the USA, which provide more stringent guidelines for the determination of the origin of textile imports. Contrary to a popular belief that raw materials are free of trade barriers, mineral fuels are among the product groups subject to a close government control. The average coverage ratio for fuels is a high 42.9 reflecting licensing or quota requirements for all or selected imports of hydrocarbons into the USA, Finland, Australia, Norway, Switzerland and France. For example, in France petroleum imports are subject to a global quota. In the US a license is required for imports of natural gas, petroleum and all petroleum products. In all these categories the licensing is "inten- ded to restrict the quantity of imports", 2/ and in the case of natural gas to exclude those imports which are not "consistent with the public inter- est". 3/ Due to falling consumption, current petroleum imports are not formally restricted, but the authority to license imports enables government to affect its direction, e.g., imports into the US from Libya are prohibited. 1/ CATT (1984a) p.10. 2/ See GATT (1983) p.10. 3/ See Section 3 of the United States Natural Gas Act (1938). - 20 - The fourth product group strongly affected by non-tariff barriers is iron and steel. Relatively free in the 1970s, iron and steel imports have become - in a remarkably short period of time - almost as tightly regulated as textile trade, particularly in the EEC, USA and Australia. These three econ- omies maintain elaborate "umbrellas" shielding their structurally ailing industry from foreign competition. The EEC closely monitors its imports through the system of automatic licenses "to ensure that traditional trade patterns in steel products are not disturbed"; 1/ a number of "voluntary" export arrangements limit imports from the major suppliers, and minimum ("basic") import prices are established for selected products. In the US, additional duties and a global quota were imposed on the imports of specialty steel in 1983 and subsequently a number of "voluntary" export arrangements have been concluded with major suppliers. 2/ For certain carbon and alloy steel products a maximum level of import penetration was set (18.5%) and is enforced by "voluntary" export and "surge control" arrangements with major suppliers and countries whose exports have increased rapidly. Finally in Australia, the Steel Industry Plan provides, inter alia, for an "import watch system" and reviews of levels of protection (which relies on tariffs and bounties) if the domestic producers' market share falls below 80% or rises above 90% in specified product categories. 1/ GATT (1984) p.4. 2/ To "encourage" such agreements the US has advised its suppliets that the global quota would be divided between countries which concluded orderly marketing arrangements with only a small part (about 5%) left for other producers. - 21 - A common feature of the iron and steel protection is a frequent resort by all the countries to anti-dumping and countervailing actions. For example in 1982, 149 cases were initiated in the USA, 19 in the EEC and 13 in Australia. 1/ Anti-dumping and countervailing duty actions (along with Section 301 actions) are explicitly provided for in the Presidential decision on the protection for the US steel industry, while a "fast track dumping mechanism" is one of the elements of the Australian Steel Industry Plan. 2/ Both are examples of a measure established to regulate trade practices being applied to problems of a structural character. Other product groups are less restricted by NTBs. The relatively high ratios for vehicles reflect "voluntary" export arrangements on Japanese exports and surveillance of car imports in the EEC. Ratios for footwear and electrical machinery are moderate. This latter group includes electronics which (particularly from Japan, Republic of Korea and Hong Kong) meet increasing restrictions. However, due to the still relatively low value of trade in this category and the selective nature of import restrictions (usually "voluntary" export restraints or quotas by country) the ratios for the whole group of electrical products are not large. 1/ See UNCTAD (1984a) p.8. 2/ See Industries Assistance Commission (1984) pp.21-27. - 22 - Types of Barriers Table B gives the break-down of NTBs by type. 1/ Quantitative import restrictions and monitoring measures are the most pervasive of barriers according to all three indices. Since the latter are predominately concerned with the quantity of imports, it seems that qualitative measures far outweigh price measures in the set of NTBs. More revealing than the aggregate picture of Table B is the separate analysis of types of barrier for agriculture and manufactures found in Tables 5 and 6 of Annex A. It is obvious that different policies are emphasized in different sectors. Agricultural protection comprises mainly price measures and quantitative restrictions. The former are particularly important in the EEC, where much trade is subject to variable levies, but in other countries direct quantity restrictions are relatively more important, see, for example Japan, where over 46% of imports from developing countries or in Switzerland where 47% of imports from industrial countries are affected. Manufacturing is primarily protected by quantity measures and monitoring measures. In Europe surveillance is common - much of it quite explicitly warning exporters to restrain themselves (see footnote 1 on page 6 above) - but so too are more rigid restrictions in the form of quantitative restrictions and VERs. The USA's protection of manufacturing appears to be both more limited and more subtle, relying almost exclusively on monitoring through mechanisms intended to police trade practices, and "voluntary" agreements. Japan's manufactured imports appear to face very few barriers of the type discussed here. 1/ The sums of the ratios across groups of measures frequently exceed the totals quoted. This is because single trade flows are often subject to NTBs of two or more classes. Such flows are counted once for each class and once (only) for the total. - 23 - Country Comparisons All three indices in Table C point to France, Australia and Switzer- land as the countries where NTBs are most prevalent, while the two coverage ratios are also high for Finland and the USA. However when fuels are excluded from the product coverage the US and Finland shift to the group of countries with small or moderate ratios. Thus, NTBs on fuels are the prime source of their high coverage indices. Whether or not restrictions on imports of fuels are taken into ac- count, France, Australia and Switzerland remain among the countries with the highest NTB ratios. For the first two this is a reflection of an extensive system of quotas and licensing. Tables 2F and 2C indicate that about 10% of import flows accounting for over 47% of imports face these measures in France and about 13% of import flows or 27% of imports in Australia. Quantitative restrictions are also significant in Switzerland (8% of import flows or 12% of import value is subject to these restrictions) but the most extensive barrier is the system of automatic licensing which covers about 11% of import flows and 32% of total imports. Imports of Austria and Norway appear to be facing relatively few border non-tariff barriers, but both countries apply other import measures such as state trading, import charges, technical standards as well as grant direct assistance to several import-competing industries. In addition, Austria maintains relatively high tariff duties. 1/ 1/ Post Tokyo Round weighted average ratio is 10.1% compared with 3.6% average for major developed economies (see Olechowski, A. and Yeats, A. [1982], p.81). - 24 - The NTB ratios are also relatively low for Italy and Japan. Italy appears to apply fewer but tighter border measures than other EEC countries, for her frequency ratios consistantly and significantly exceed her import coverage ratios. Japan, as is well known, is often suspected of using meas- ures not covered in our exercise -- e.g., testing procedures, restrictions on retail outlets for foreign products, administrative guidances -- to restrict imports. In comparing the NTB coverage figures between countries the reader should remember that the information we have measures the extent of NTBs, and not the restrictiveness. It would be inappropriate to use these figures to argue that countries with higher indices "owe" the international community a unilateral "round" of trade liberalization, or that a country with a low coverage index is justified in imposing restrictions against its trading partners. - 25 - IV. THE EXTENT OF NTBs ON DEVELOPING COUNTRIES' EXPORTS Having discussed the prevalence of NTBs in aggregate we now turn to the question of whether NTBs impinge more heavily on the exports of developing countries than on intra-industrial country trade. The indices in Table D are aggregates over the 16 industrial markets for which we have NTB information, and present NTB coverage ratios for imports from four groups of exporters - industrial countries, all developing countries, major developing country exporters of manufactures, and major borrowers (these groupings are defined in the Annex). Table D shows that NTBs are significantly more prevalent on imports from developing countries than from industrial countries, and this is repli- cated for nearly all individual markets (see Table 3). Table D Extent of Industrial Countries NTBs on Imports from Industrial and Developing Countries 16 industrial markets, all products, all selected NTBs Exporters: Industrial Developing countries Index Countries All Major Exporters Major Borrowers Coverage ratio Own Imports 21.0 34.3 26.5 35.4 World Imports 17.1 27.0 24.6 29.4 Frequency Ratio 8.8 18.6 18.1 19.4 Not only the relative, but also the absolute, extent of NTB coverage is larger in the case of developing countries' products. For example, the value (in 1981 terms) of imports from developing countries subject to NTBs is - 26 - US$ 86 billion compared with US$ 79 billion in the case of imports from industrial countries. Another important implication of Table D is that NTBs are relatively extensive on the exports of the developing country major borrowers. For these countries all three indices assume values which are 1-2 percentage points higher than those for all developing countries and 7-8 percentage points higher than those for all exporters. This difference is partly due to the presence of three large oil exporters (Indonesia, Mexico and Venezuela) among the major borrowers. However, even if fuels are excluded, the coverage indices for major borrowers remain higher than those for all developing countries while the frequency ratio is marginally lower. 1/ Given that the major borrowers' ability to cope with current balance of payments difficulties depends to a large degree on their ability to export to the industrial coun- tries, these figures emphasise how closely linked are debt and trade policy issues. In the case of major exporters of manufactures, the evidence is less clear cut. It is often alleged that the newly industralized countries are the prime targets of protective actions, but the figures in Table D do not support this thesis. However, when fuels are excluded the values of all three indices for the exporters of manufactures are higher than for all developing countries. 2/ 1/ The respective values are: 25.5 (own imports coverage ratio), 24.0 (world imports coverage ratio) and 18.1 (frequency ratio) for major borrowers and 22.4, 22.7 and 18.5 for all developing exporters. 2/ They are: 23.8 (own imports coverage ratio), 24.5 (world imports coverage ratio) and 19.4 (frequency ratio). - 27 - The structure of the apparent discrimination against developing countries is explored in Table E and Annex Table 4. It shows that almost universally NTBs are less prevalent on industrial countries' imports of agricultural goods from developing countries than on those from other industrial countries, but that the reverse is true for manufactures. Nonetheless, developing countries still generally face more barriers on agricultural exports than on manufactures, and since agriculture accounts for a higher share of imports from developing countries than from industrial ones, agricultural protection still contributes to the differential incidence at the aggregate level. In the manufacturing sector developing countries face more barriers than industrial countries where their exports are large, e.g., in textiles and footwear, and fewer where they are small, e.g., in electrical machinery and vehicles. - 28 - Table E Extent of Industrial Countries NTBs on Imports from Industrial and Developing Countries 16 industrial markets, all selected NTBs Exporter: Industrial Countries Developing Countries Index agricultural manufactures agricultural manufacturing Coverage Ratio Own imports 40.5 14.5 31.2 21.3 World Imports 46.1 13.2 30.5 20.5 Frequency Ratio 31.9 6.7 25.6 17.4 A striking feature of Table 6 of the Annex is much greater prevalence of VER on imports of manufactures from developing countries than on those from industrial countries. For example, the overall world imports coverage ratio of VERs for developing countries' manufactures is 10.9% compared with 0.4% for industrial countries, and this pattern is repeated for every market with VERs. While our figures do not reflect the restrictiveness of trade regimes at all accurately, the evidence of a widespread bias in the application of voluntary export restraints seems overwhelming. - 29 - V. THE GROWTH OF NTBs The final issue we examine is the expansion of NTB coverage through time. Table F and Table 7 of the Annex present changes in the coverage of NTBs between 1981 and 1983. The UNCTAD Data Base does not provide precise information on the dates of introduction before 1981 and, at the time our investigation was carried out, did not contain data on measures imposed after June 1984. Table F Extent of Industrial Countries NTBs on Imports from Industrial and Developing Countries 16 industrial markets, all products, all selected NTBs, differences between indices for 1983 and 1981 in percentage points Exporter: All Industrial Developing Index Countries Countries Countries Coverage Ratio Own Imports 1.5 2.2 1.1 World Imports 1.8 2.3 1.1 Frequency Ratio 0.3 0.1 0.9 All three measures indicate that NTBs are encroaching progressively further on international trade. For the 16 markets whose NTBs have been tab- ulated, there was, between 1981 and 1983, a net increase of 2,486 in the num- ber of NTBs recorded. The NTBs in place in 1983 covered $12.8 billion more of 1981's imports than did those in place in 1981. This additional $12.8 billion - 30 - which came under NTBs was approximately 1.5% of these countries' total imports in 1981, and approximately 6% of the value of imports subject to NTBs. Note that these figures refer only to new NTBs and not to any tightening or rein- forcement of existing ones. According to the coverage ratios, the new measures seem to be aimed mostly at imports from the industrial countries. 1/ When the coverage and frequency indicators are compared, it appears that new NTBs were imposed on a larger number of small trade flows from developing countries and a smaller number of large flows from industrial countries. This is a reflection of concentration of new NTBs in areas such as iron and steel and electrical machinery, where developing countries are only now entering international trade. This pattern does not mean, however, that developing countries were exempt from the rise in protectionism, for their main exports (such as textiles and clothing) experienced considerable tightening of the existing restrictions. 1/ For description of new NTBs see UNCTAD (1984 and 1985) and IMP (1984). - 31 - VI. THE COMPARISON OF EXISTING ESTIMATES OF NTB COVERAGE While this study is a first attempt to estimate NTB prevalence in a comprehensive and precise fashion, there do exist some approximations in the literature. This section compares our results, with those of Balassa and Balassa (1984), Cline (1985) and Jones (1983). Balassa and Blassa define NTBs relatively narrowly - quotas, licens- ing, voluntary export restraints, orderly marketing agreements, safeguard measures and "restrictive application of standards" - and use 4-digit SITC(R) NTB data from the US Special Trade Representative's Office. Their trade sta- tistics - at 4-digit SITC(R) level - refer to 1980 and come from the World Bank Trade System. Balassa and Balassa!s higher level of aggregation tends to bias their estimates of coverage upward. However, when we recalculate our figures on their definitions (see Table 8 of the Annex); the results are rather similar, so in this case the bias appears small. A second comparison is with Cline (1985). Cline's figures, displayed in Table 9 of the Annex, suggest very much higher estimates than our own, despite his restricted definition of NTBs (decreed price measures plus quantity measures). However, he works with very aggregated NTB and trade data: 4-digit ISIC level. His exaggeration of the extent of protectionism probably arises from: (i) the high level of his commodity aggregation (the ISIC contains just 81 4-digit manufacturing categories); (ii) the combination of NTBs from a series of years - "broadly the middle 1970s to 1981"! (In fact, in no single year did all the NTBs Cline records for the USA apply); and - 32 - (iii) the counting of all imports of a good as "affected" even if trade with only certain partners is restricted. (For example, the UK VER with Japan over car imports, leads Cline to include all vehicle imports in his measure - even buses imported from Germanyl) A final comparison is with Jones' (1983) figures for the UK in 1980 (see Table 10 Annex). Jones uses a tighter definition of NTBs than ourselves - even if we exclude our "other import management measures" group - but he does work with tariff-line data. Taking account of differences in produce and country groupings, his results match our 1981 estimates quite closely. - 33 - VII. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS Given the lack of sound empirical evidence on the extent of non- tariff barriers, this paper has attempted to identify some basic features of the situation. By employing the most comprehensive and detailed existing NTB and trade information and calculating three indices of the prevalence of NTBs, we have generated the most comprehensive analysis extant. Four major conclusions emerge from the results. First, the extent of NTBs is indeed large. At least 27% of the sixteen major industrial economies' imports, some $230 billion of 1981 imports, would have been covered by one or more of the selected NTBs as they applied in 1983. NTBs are particularly widespread in agricultural products, textile and clothing, mineral fuels and iron and steel. Second, volume controls appear to be the most prevalent of individual NTBs -- much more so than price controls which are applied mainly to agricul- tural imports. Three different measures indicate that NTBs are significantly more prevalent on imports from developing countries than from industrial coun- tries. The NTBs applied in 1983 by the sixteen industrial markets examined here would have covered $86 billion of imports from developing countries and $79 billion of imports from industrial economies. Particularly significant is the higher coverage of the exports of developing country major borrowers, In relative terms developing countries face more barriers than industrial countries in manufactured trade and less in agricultural trade. However, developing countries still generally encounter more barriers on agricultural exports than on manufactures, and since agriculture accounts for a higher share of their exports than of industrial countries' exports9 - 34 - protection in this sector contributes to the differential incidence observed at the aggregate level. Finally, the results provide evidence that NTBs are encroaching progressively further on international trade and at a significant pace. In the period 1981-1983, a net increase of 2,486 NTBs, covering $12.8 billion of 1981 imports was observed. Since this increase does not reflect the tightening or reinforcement of already existing measures, the growth of NTBs should be taken very seriously. - 35 - APPENDIX 1 World Trade Weights for the Weighted Coverage Ratio Index Iw, the Weighted coverage ratio, is based on world trade weights, but naturally the data for such weights are not available on each country's own detailed trade classification. We derived them as follows. First 1981 import data from the World Bank System at the 4-digit level of the SITC(R) were summed across the 102 importers for which they existed ("the world" - see table A.1). These were converted to a 5-digit SITC(R) basis by pro-rating each 4-digit total over its component 5-digit groups according to shares derived from the sample of countries reporting 5-digit data for that category. (This sample varied by 4-digit groups, but its trade invariably covered at least 75% of the 4-digit world total). These 5-digit SITC(R) data were then converted to a 4-digit CCCN basis (Z.) using a converter supplied by UNCTAD, and then used to update each country's own tariff-line data as follows: X.. Xik ijk ijx Xijk where XiJkx is i's imports from x of tariff item k within CCCN sub-group j, and Xijkx is the updated 'world' version of this. In the notation of the text, Wqx for country i is set to Xir'x where tariff index q corresponds to tariff item s within CCCN sub-group r. Thus we are weighting CCCN sub-groups together by world trade weights (UEE X. = Z.), while using a country's own trade weights for both the imn ijmn i composition and direction of trade with the sub-group. Thus while the world - 36 - index Iw makes allowances for differences in the restrictiveness of barriers on broad groups of goods, it makes no such allowance for differences in the restrictiveness of barriers on different tariff-items or sources within the broader groups. In particular, this approach implies that if some Xijkx were zero, so too would be the corresponding "world" weight Xijkx. Thus prohibitions still receive zero wieghts in Iw. The total of Xijkx is world imports and is the same for each of the countries treated above. For very small proportions of each country's trade the classification convertions from CCCN to tariff-line were not straight-forward. They were treated as follows. (A) Non-USA Data Several headings in each of the non-USA national trade statistics were not matched in our SITC-CCCN converter. CCCN 0407 equated to UN Special Code SITC(R) 0990 (edible animal products n.e.s.) CCCN 3507 received half of SITC(R) 51291 the other half going to CCCN 2940 CCCN 7107, 7108 gold - no corresponding SITC(R) world data. Their share in total imports was kept the same in the adjusted (world weighted) and the unadjusted (national) trade data-sets. (B) EEC Data For EEC countries further difficulties comprised: NIMEXE 736n and 737n n= 01....9. These are a subdivision of CCCN 7315 (iron and steel). Trade allocated by the converter to CCCN 7315 was spread over 7315, 736n and 737n using national shares. NIMEXE nn97 postal trade Shares in total imports were nn98 ships stores kept the same in the adjusted NIMEXE nn99 unidentified (world weighted) series as 0090 unidentified in the unadjusted (national) series. - 37 - (C) USA Data The USA classifies trade data by the TSUS and TSUSA which relate directly to neither the CCCN nor the SITC(R). Using a converter provided by the Special Trade Representative's Office, the world trade data were converted from SITC(R) to TSUSA 7-digit groups. When one SITC(R) category fed n TSUSA category each of the latter was allocated 1/n of the former. The 7-digit data were then aggregated to a 5-digit (TSUS) basis comparable to the US trade data received from the CATT. The whole of this process resulted in around 7% of headings and trade being unmatchable. These headings were given the same weight in the adjusted (world) trade series as in the national (USA) statistics. The mismatches were fairly evenly spread except for a concentration in iron and steel. Current research is trying to resolve these difficulties. Overall it is likely that our world weighted coverage ratios for the USA are less accurate than those for other countries, and that our results for all countries' iron and steel sectors are less accurate than those for other sectors. - 38 - Table A.1: THE "WORLD" WEIGHTS - COUNTRY COVERAGE Algeria Madagascar Argentina Malawi Australia Malaysia Austria Malta Bahrain Martinique Bangladesh Morocco Belgium-Luxembourg Netherlands Antiles Bermuda Netherlands Brazil New Caledonia Brunei New Zealand Canada Nicaragua Chile Niger Columbia Norway Costa Rica Oman Cyprus Pakistan Denmark Panama Dominican Republic Peru Ecuador Philippines Egypt Poland El Salvador Portugal Ethiopia Qatar Faeroe Islands Reunion Fiji Samoa Finland Saudi Arabia French Guiana Senegal French Polenesia Seychel. 9.s France South Africa Germany, F.R. Spain Greece Sri Lanka Greenland St. Pierre & Miquelon Guadeloupe Sudan Guatemala Sweden Honduras Switzerland Hong Kong Thailand Hungry Togo Iceland Tonga Indonesia Trinidad Ireland Tunisia Israel Turkey Italy Tuvalu Ivory Coast United Arab Emirates Jamaica United Kingdom Japan Tanzania Jordan Upper Volta Kenya Uruguay Korea, Republic of USA Kuwait Vanuatu Liberia Venezuela Libya Yeman Macau Yugoslavia - 39 - APPENDIX 2 Definitions of Product and Country Groups Product TSUSA Headings CCCN 4-digit headings All 10001-87045 0101-9906 All, less fuels 10001-47462, 48005-52121 0101-2604, 2801-9906 52141-87045 Agricultural Goods 10001-19324 0101-2402 Manufactured Goods 20003-47462, 48005-49520, 2801-9906 53101-54805, 60502-87045 of which textiles 30010-39060 5001-6302 footwear 70005-70095 6401-6406 iron and steel 60600-61081 7300-7399 electrical machinery 68205-68847 8501-8528 vehicles 69202-69260 8701-8714 Major Exporters of Manufacturers: Argentina, Brazil, Hong Kong, Israel, Korea, Philippines, Portugal, Singapore, South Africa, Thailand, Yugoslavia Major Borrowers: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Egypt, India, Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Mexico, Turkey, Venezuela, Yugoslavia (all had over $15 billion of long-term debt at the end of 1983). Industrial Countries and Developing Countries: World Bank definitions (WDR 1984), except that Greece is transferred from developing to industrial countries, because its trade policy is determined with that of other industrial countries in the EEC. - 40 - References Balassa, B. and Balassa, C. "Industrial protection in the developed countries", The World Economy, June 1984, ppl79-96. Bale, Malcolm D. & Ulrich Koester. "Maginot Line of European Farm Policies", The World Economy, vol. 6, No. 4, Dec. 1983, pp 373-92. Cline, W. Imports of Manufactures from Developing Countries: Performance and Prospects for Market Access, Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C. ,1985. Dickey, William L. "The Pricing of Imports into the United States", Journal of World Trade Law, vol. 13, May-June 1979, pp 238-56. Finger, J. M., H.K. Hall and D.R. Nelson. "The Political Economy of Administered Protection", The American Economic Review, vol. 72, 1982, pp. 452-66. Finger, J. M. "The Industry-Country Incidence of 'Less than Fair Value' Cases in U.S. Import Trade", Quarterly Review of Economics and Business, Summer 1981, pp. 260-79. GATT. The Tokyo Round of Mutilateral Trade Negotiations, Geneva, 1979. GATT. Reply to the questionaire on licensing: USA, L/5131, Geneva, 1983. GATT. Report of the Group on Quantitative Restrictions and other Non-Tariff Measures, L/5713, Geneva, 1984. GATT. Developments in the Trading System, C/W/448, April 1984-September 1984, Geneva, 1984a. IMF. Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions, Annual Report, Washington, D. C., 1984. Industries Assistance Commission. Annual Report, Canberra, 1983-84. Jones, C.D. "Visible Imports Subject to Restraint", Government Economic Service Working Paper No. 62, HMSO, London, 1983. Natural Gas Act. Act of 21 June 1938, C.556, 52 Start. 821-833, 15 U.S.C. 717-717w. Nogues, J., Olechowski, A. and Winters, L. A. "The Extent of Non-Tariff Barriers to Industrial Countries' Imports", Development Research Department Discussion Paper 115, The World Bank, 1985. Olechowski, A. and Yeats, A. "Implications of the Tokyo Round for East-West Trade Relations", Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, February 1982, pp. 79-96. - 41 - UNCTAD. Non-tariff barriers affecting the trade of developing countries and transparency in world trading conditions: the inventory of non-tariff barriers, TD/B/940, Geneva, 1983. UNCTAD. Protectionism, trade relations and standard adjustment, TD/274, Belgrade, 1983a. UNCTAD. Protectionism and standard adjustment in the world economy, Part I: Analysis of major issues and policy requirements, TD/B/981, Geneva, 1984. UNCTAD. Problems of protectionism and structural adjustment, Part I: Restrictions to trade and structural adjustment, TD/B/1039, Geneva, 1985. - 42 - ANNEX List of Tables Table 1 NTBs by Product Category, 1983 Table 2 Types of NTB, 1983 Table 3 The differential impact of NTBs Table 4 Differential impact of NTBs by product category, 1983 Table 5 Differential impact of NTBs by type, agriculture, 1983 Table 6 Differential impact of NTBs by type, manufacturing, 1983 Table 7 Change in the Prevalence of NTBs; 1981-1983 Table 8 Balassa and Balassa's Results for Manufactures Table 9 Cline's Results for Manufactures Table 10 Jones' Results for the UK Table 11 Industrial Countries' Trade, 1981 -43- TA8LE 1S Extent of Industrial Countries' NIBs by Product Category, by Country, 1983 own imports couerage ratio: all exporters Industrial Country All Rll, less Rgri- llanufac- Iron & Electrical Rest of Market Products Fuels fuels, culture turing Textiles rootuear Steel Machinery Uehicles Ianuf. EEC Z2.3 21.1 24.1 36.4 18.7 52.0 9.5 52.6 13.t 45.3 10.3 Belgium-Lux Z6.0 33.9 10.0 55.9 33.6 38.3 12.3 47.4 19.5 54.3 30.6 Oenmark 11.7 15.9 0.0 28.5 13.2 16.5 13.6 49.9 6.7 35.0 5.4 France 57.1 28.1 91.0 37.8 27.t 18.4 6.6 73.9 41.7 S2.9 19.4 Uest Gernany 12.4 18.3 0.0 22.3 18.5 57.0 9.7 53.5 6.8 52.0 6.6 6reece 13.4 23.2 0.0 46.1 20.1 21.8 22.8 54.5 13.5 65.5 8.5 Ireland 13.1 1S.0 0.0 24.8 13.8 31.7 8.8 23.0 O.S 65.8 6.6 Italy 6.9 11.6 0.0 39.9 9.3 37.2 0.2 18.6 7.1 10.2 2.6 Netherlands 25.5 28.0 22.0 51.9 17.8 57.3 12.0 3S.S 4.0 49.7 10.7 UK 14.3 17.5 0.0 34.9 14.8 59.6 12.2 42.1 12.7 44.3 6.7 Australia 34.1 24.1 98.0 36.1 23.6 30.9 50.0 55.6 48.7 0.7 21.6 Rustria 4.9 6.0 1.0 11.7 2.4 2.2 0.1 0.0 0.0 2.9 3.0 Finland 34.9 9.2 91.0 31.5 6.7 31.0 68.8 13.9 0.0 0.0 0.4 Japan 11.9 16.9 7.0 i2.9 7.7 11.8 34.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 7.7 Noruay 5.7 5.8 S.0 21.2 4.1 42.9 5.1 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.4 Switzerland 32.2 23.6- 91.0 73.4 17.6 57.4 0.0 3.9 28.1 1.1 14.6 USR 43.0 17.3 100.0 21.2 17.1 57.0 11.5 37.7 5.2 31.2 6.1 Rll 16 Markets 27.1 18.6 43.0 36.1 16.1 11.8 12.6 35.4 10.0 30.4 8.8 -44- TROBLE IU Extent of Industrial Countries' iT8s by Product Category, by Country, 1983 Uorld imports coverage ratio; all exporters Industrial Country RIll Rll, less figri- Manu- Iron S Electrical Rest of narket Products fuels Fuels culture facturing Textiles Footwear Steel Machinery Uehicles Mlanuf. EEC 18.9 21.0 13.0 39.5 18.3 41.2 10.7 98.6 10.9 12.3 7.1 Belgium-Lux 21.0 22.0 18.0 41.5 19.1 36.3 10.4 45.2 11.2 55.8 7.6 Denmark 13.3 18.0 0.0 40.8 14.5 38.7 16.8 96.8 5.7 35.9 3.4 France i1.2 31.2 81.0 17.9 29.1 52.8 8.0 70.9 10.6 l.0 16.7 llest Gerrany 14.7 19.9 0.0 35.6 17.7 48.3 9.5 48.0 5.6 47.5 5.1 Greece 19.0 25.8 0.0 44.2 23.3 V2.1 19.5 19.7 16.1 56.8 11.1 Ireland 13.0 17.8 O.0 32.3 16.1 34.5 8.5 12.4 0.9 51.6 4.8 Italy 10.0 13.3 0.0 36.5 9.6 42.0 0.7 44.8 4.4 1.9 2.6 Netherlands 21.4 22.6 18.0 11.4 19.8 49. 11.6 45.2 3.6 50.1 8.4 UK 13.9 18.8 0.0 31.5 16.5 53.9 11.1 15.6 9.8 36.9 4.3 Rustralia 44.4 26.6 95.0 31.1 24.8 27.3 54.4 49.2 49.2 0.4 21.9 Rustria 7.5 10.1 0.0 53.9 2.1 2.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 3.5 2.9 Finland 34.3 14.3 90.0 48.7 8.8 43.1 75.0 43.7 0.0 0.0 0.8 Japan 9.0 9.6 7.0 33.8 5.4 11.0 39.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 6.0 Noruay 6.1 7.1 3.0 32.5 2.9 27.2 4.9 0.1 0.0 0.5 0.5 Suitzerland 12.9 26.0 91.0 77.5 16.1 15.7 0.0 5.9 23.8 0.9 15.2 USR 34.3 12.3 96.0 14.5 12.3 48.1 12.6 36.2 2.5 28.2 3.8 Rll 16 Markets 21.8 18.5 31.0 10.4 14.9 37.8 17.7 35.8 10.8 25.9 7.2 -45- TRBLE If Extent of Industrial Countries' NTBs by Product Category, by Country, 1983 Frequency ratio; all exporters Industrial Country Rll Rll, less Rgri- Mlanu- Iron 8 Electrical Rest of itarket Products Fuels fuels culture facturing Textiles Footwear Steel llachinery Uehicles lManuf. EEC 13.8 13.8 11.8 30.3 12.0 45.2 7.7 23.4 5.6 9.8 2.6 Belgiumi-Lux 11.6 11.4 42.0 31.1 8.9 32.7 13.8 17.8 1.0 2.8 2.9 Benmark 11.4 11.4 0.0 29.7 9.6 35.9 12.1 18.2 1.1 2.,2 1.5 rrance 21.0 23.9 32.0 41.8 21.9 56.0 2.2 56.6 31.7 11.2 7.0 Uest Germany 12.5 12.6 1.0 25.1 11.1 43.9 11.0 19.5 0.7 1.4 1.5 Greece 13.6 13.7 0.0 32.7 12.3 37.5 6.7 24. 7.6 19.8 6.7 Ireland 9.1 9.2 0.0 35.0 7.6 32.4 7.8 9.6 0.7 3.9 1.6 Italy 9.7 9.8 0.0 25.6 8.4 38., 2.7 21.2 1.0 3.6 1.0 Netherlands 13.1 12.8 45.0 30.1 -1A0.2 41.9 10.8 16.2 1.0 3.0 2.4 UK 13.8 13.8 0.0 27.7 12.3 59.8 4.5 16.9 1.6 1.7 0.9 Australia 18.3 18.1 56.0 21.4 17.9 25.9 43.6 14.4 25. 6.1 15.1 Austria 5.4 5.5 1.0 33.0 0.9 i.8 .1,0 0.0 0.0 9.0 0.5 Finland 13.1 13.2 50.0 30.2 11.9 37.3 58.8 39.2 0.0 0.0 0.6 Japan 9.3 9.3 10.0 36.2 5.1 14.8 32.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.8 loryag 9.7 9.8 3.0 30.3 7.9 33.2 4.1 0.7 0.0 - 1.0 1.5 Suitzerland 19.4 19.1 56.0 58.1 13.2 37.1 0.0 4.6 15.8 2.9 8.0 USR 7.0 6.6 91.0 6.1 6.9 30.8 5.4 22.8 0.6 1.3 1.6 fill 16tlarkets 12.8 12.7 23.9 29.5 10.8 38.1 13.5 19.3 5.4 7.1 3.2 -46- TRBLE ZC Extent of Industrial Countries' NTBs by Iype of Measure, by Country, 1983 Own inports coverage ratio; all products; all exporters quantitative Uoluntary Rll WT8s: - Industrial Country inport export Decreed Tariff- Monitoring Union of Market restriction restriction prices type neasures (1) thru (5) (1 ) (2) (3) 0t) (S) (6) EEC 11.8 2.2 3.3 1.9 7.8 22.3 Belgiut-Lux 12.8 0.8 t.1 1.6 19.0 26.0 Deoark 3.0 2.1 3.3 2.t t.0 11.7 France t7.2 1.2 2.2 1.3 10.1 57.1 Uest Bermny 1.7 3.9 3.1 1.8 5.1 12.t Breece 5.1 1.0 3.2 1.6 6.5 13. Ireland 2.1 1.t 2.0 2.6 7.3 13.1 Italy 1.8 1.0 3.7 1.1 1.9 6.9 Netherlands 6.6 2.0 4.6 1.9 11.0 25.5 UK 3.5 2.8 3.t 3. 7.1 14.3 Rustralia 27.0 0.0 0.7 3.3 t.6 3t.1 Rustria 2.5 0.2 1.t 0.8 0.6 1.9 rinland 30.? 0.2 0.7 1.0 3.8 34.9 Japan 9.8 0.0 0.0 2.2 0.0 11.9 Noruay 5.5 0.0 0.4 0.3 0°0 5.7 Switzerland 11.8 0.0 0.6 0.2 21.6 32.2 USR 1.3 6.8 0.9 0.2 31.9 43.0 All 16 Markets 8.6 3.0 1.7 1.3 14.8 27.1 -47- TABLE 2U Extent of Industrial Countries' NTBs by Type of Measure, by Country, 1983 Uorld iAports couerage ratio; all exporters Ouantitative Uoluntary Rll RIBs: Industrial Country inport export Decreed lariff- Monitoring Union of Market restrictions restriction prices type neasures (1) thru (5) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) [EC 6.0 i.8 4.9 1.9 9.6 18.9 Belgium-Lux 1.1 1.5 5.2 1.8 14.1 21.0 Derwark 2.3 1.8 4.8 2.3 6.0 13.3 France 28.3 1.8 5.0 1.1 15.2 41.2 Uest 6ernany 2.2 2.1 5.4 2.2 7.1 14.7 Greece- 7.2 1.8 4.S 1.9 9.2 19.0 Ireland 1.1 1. 4.7 1.6 8.0 13.0 Italy 2.1 1.9 5.2 1.4 3.7 10.0 Netherlands 1.3 2.3 5.0 1.9 14.4 21.4 UK 2.5 2.1 4.6 2.2 8.5 13.9 Rustralia 38.2 0.0 0.7 3.7 3.3 44.4 Rustria 1.6 0.2 3.9 1.3 0.7 7.5 Finland 29.0 0.2 2.4 0.8 5.0 31.3 Japan 7.2 0.0 0.0 1.8 0.0 9.0 Noruay 6.0 0.0 1.1 0.2 0.0 6.1 Switzerland 10.6 0.0 0.7 0.1 33.2 4.9 USR 1.6 4.9 O.1 0.5 27.7 34.3 Rll 16 Markets 9.S 1.4 3. 1.6 9.8 21.8 -48- TA8LE 2F Extent of Industrial Countries' HT8s by Type of tMeasure, by Country, 1983 frequency ratio; all products; all exporters Quantitative Uoluntary Rll NT8s: Industrial Country inport export Decreed Tariff- Monitoring Union of Mlarket restriction restriction prices type neasures (1) thru (5) (1) (2) (3) (e) (5) (6) EEC 4.2 S.0 2.5 1.8 SA 13.8 Belgium-Lux 4.2 3.9 2.8 1.9 3.8 11.6 eniarlk 2.1 5,6 2.4 1.7 .2.0 11.4 rrance 9.6 4.6 2.4 1.8 13.7 24.0 Uest 6ernany 2.2 6.4 2.5 2.0 2.6 12.5 6reece 5.0 3.2 2.9 1.4 4.8 13.6 Ireland 2.4 4.1 2.0 1.4 3.7 9.1 Italy 1.5 1.4 2.4 1.9 2.2 9.7 Netherlands 4.3 S.5 2.6 2.0 1.4 13.1 UK 5.0 5.0 2.5 1.7 7.4 13.8 Australia 12.8 0.0 0.1 4.2 1.8 18.3 Rustria 2.3 0.3 2.2 1.8 0.1 5.4 Rinland 2.4 0.5 0.2 0.6 10.6 13.4 Japan 8.9 0.0 0.1 0.4 0.0 9.3 Noruay 9.6 0.0 0.4 0.2 0.1 9.7 Switzerland 8.1 0.0 1.7 0.2 11.0 19.4 USR 0.9 4.8 0.1 0.1 1.2 7.0 Rll 16 Markets 5.0 3.4 1.7 1.4 4.6 12.8 -49- IRBLE 3C Extent of Industrial Countries NT6s on Inports fron Industrial and Developing Countries Own imports coverage ratio; all products Imports from: Deueloping Countries Industrial ----------------------------------- Countries Total llajor Exporters Major Inporter of Manufactures Borrouers nnm.n-CuccflSnusfs:,snamcnnnsss=-svuuuu...-uufln.a,anu.c=:- EEC 10.6 25.1 32.0 25.3 Belgium Aux 25.7 38.1 61.7 33.1 Deumark 9.5 29.5 37.1 32.7 rranee 31.3 50.1 30.2 43.0 Uest Gernany 13.7 18.1 29.1 25.9 Greece 26.1 6.2 18.7 1.9 Ireland 13.1 19.6 21.8 25.5 Italy 11.0 7.3 13.3 8.6 Netherlands 25.8 29.3 45.3 37.1 United Kingdon 15.1 23.3 36.0 26.t Australia 23.6 13.7 39.6 61.1 Rustria t.5 13.8 17.9 24.1 Finland 10.9 38.1 35.2 27.6 Japan 21. 12.1 21.2 11.3 Horway 1.3 16.8 26.8 H1A. Switzerland 27.2 43.4 36.7 39.9 USR 26.0 54.0 21.3 56.6 Rll 16 iarkets 21.0 3t.3 26.5 35.A -50- IRBLE 3J Extent of Industrial Countries' NI8s on Inports frm Industrial and Developing Countries Uorld inports coVerage ratio; all products Inports from: Developing Countries Industrial ------------------------------- Countries llajor Exporters lMajor Inporter Total of Manufactures 8Brrouers EEC 18.6 20.7 25.4 22.7 Begiln-Lux 20.5 22.0 27.8 24.8 Oewnark 14.1 20.3 36.5 31.9 France A.4 i1.7 33.7 41.6 UIst ernawny 17.4 15.6 24.3 23.4 Greece 22.8 17.0 25.1 14.1 Ireland 15.9 16.2 17.3 23.2 Italy 9.8 11.6 13.9 12.8 Netherlands 20.8 23.4 30.5 32.5 United Kingdon 16.3 18.1 29.6 20.6 Rustralia 26.6 52.8 39.1 72.1 Rustria 8.6 9.8 14.5 18.6 Finland 14.2 37.0 31.6 22.4 Japan 10.2 10.7 12.9 10.5 Norway 5.3 15.2 22.9 14.4 Switzerland 27.7 67.2 49.2 52.1 USR 17.6 51.7 16.0 55.6 Rll 16 tIriets 17.1 27.0 24.6 29.4 IRBLE 3F Extent of Industrial Countries' NT8s on Imports from Industrial and Dcueloping Countries rrerency ratio; all products lports .fron: Developing Countries Industrial --------------------------- - Countries Major Exporters Major Importer Total of Manufactures Borrowers D--"FCcftUEUStDS*C-11kE-"XtSU bUa 88- tR1lCSU3 SU.unZg2.asnX.......s. EEC 7.7 20.9 20.7 22.1 Belgiwu-Lux 5.9 20.0 19.2 2Z.1 Oermak 1.6 24.6 22.5 26.t Frre 17.9 30.0 30.1 31.5 Uest Serny 5.1 15.1 19.7 19.8 Greece 9.5 17.0 17.3 19.3 Ireland 3.9 22.0 19.9 24.5 Italy 1.6 14.9 11.0 15.9 Netherlands 5.5 21.3 21.1 23.3 United Kingdom 9.0 19.7 20.1 21.7 Rustralia 17.5 19.7 18.9 21.1 Rustria 1.8 6.3 5.9 8.6 Finland 11.9 21.0 20.6 17.1 Japan 8.2 11. 9.8 11.2 Neruay 8.0 18.5 19.2 15.5 Switzerland 17.1 21.8 21.9 26.0 USR 3.9 10.8 9.5 11.5 RI1 16 Markets 8.8 18.6 18.1 19.1 -52- TABLE tC Extent of Industrial Countries' HTOs on Imports from Developing and Industrial Countries, by Product Category, 1983 Oun inports couerage ratio; developing (aboue), industrial (below) *. .......... .....u . ............... ..tS....= ........ttSutS= ttsua=t :tett==rtnS: All Rll, less Rgricul- Mlanufac- Iron 6 Electrical Rest of products fuels Fuels ture turing Textiles footwear Steel Machinery Uehicles nanuf. z%=:zza-was:=v:z>=::==So====--===sc:t:R*z::t2t:t:;::R:2c:2t:tc:: .an,=.gSuc.r=2R:uuucc:.R ,=,cmu=z .= = =.,= == n EEC 25.4 26.9 22.3 26.9 29.9 68.0 9,9 31.9 7.0 8.4 14.7 18.6 18.9 14.7 47.7 15.2 15.6 0.6 S1.8 15.8 49.9 9.3 Belgium-Lux 38.1 45.1 11.2 35.1 54.7 43.5 5.6 40.2 0.2 0.1 58.1 25.7 27.1 9.7 72.0 22.5 30.4 6.5 43.4 21.4 56.5 13.5 Deruark 29.5 35.8 0.0 36.3 36.7 72.3 16.3 34.4 0.a. 0.5 5. 9.5 10.9 0.0 20.9 9.8 11.1 0.2 48.5 5.9 38.0 5.0 France 50.1 28.6 78.1 28.1 33.0 64.6 11.3 35.1 35.5 29.0 21.3 31.3 27.4 78.2 53.3 25.0 21.9 0.3 78.1 42.8 45.6 18.3 Uest 6ernany 18.1 23.9 0.0 16.6 30.2 71.9 2.9 32.2 0.2 0.0 3.5 13.7 14.5 0.0 28.5 13.3 8.8 0.5 51.6 8.8 56.2 7.2 Greece 6.2 12.9 0.0 20.1 11.8 33.5 41.2 43.6 6.9 41.9 2.9 26.1 26.4 0.0' 61.8 22.6 4.4 0.1 50.4 16.5 71.9 10.2 Ireland 19.6 19.9 0.0 21.2 19.5 55.5 10.5 4.4 0.0 0.0 9.3 13.4 .13.8 0.0 29.1 12.8 17.6 0.0 19.2 0.3 67.9 6.3 Italy 7.3 16.2 0.0 32.1 12.0 49.0 0.3 33.8 0.1 0.0 1.0 11.0 11.9 0.0 47.6 6.0 4.4 0.2 47.0 6.9 16.8 3.1 Netherlands 29.3 32.3 23.9 38.3 28.0 72.4 8.9 15.9 0.0 0.2 8.7 25.8 27.1 13.5 68.8 15.3 6.7 1.7 35.7 6.8 53.3 11.6 United Kingdom 23.3 27.4 0.0 24.4 30.4 78.6 18.0 26.8 5.8 0.0 5.0 15.4 17.0 0.0 tt,S 13.2 26.0 0.6 40.4 16.7 46.7 6.8 Australia 43.7 27.9 99.7 21.6 28.6 29.1 48.5 42.5 62.5 0.0 22.3 23.6 23.4 48.9 47.7 22.7 28.1 51.6 57.8 46.8 0.7 21.7 flustria 13.8 19.2 3.6 40.5 6.1 15.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.9 0.0 4.5 t.7 0.0 39.9 2.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 3.0 3.3 Finland 38.4 26.9 99.3 28.7 27.5 63.0 56.2 15.8 0.0 0.0 0.6 10.9 7.4 80.8 32.6 5.5 23.5 72.0 42.8 0.0 0.0 0.5 Japan 12.1 17.5 6.7 53.3 4.4 13.0 36.3 0.0 0.0 0,0 1.3 21.4 16.9 52.8 36.8 9.7 11.0 27.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 10.6 Horway 16.8 18.2 0.0 15.4 20.9 59.5 20.5 20.6 0.0 43.9 5.0 4.3 4,9 0,0 27.0 3.2 39.5 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.2 Switzerland 43.4 34,5 100,0 67.3 19.5 45.8 0.0 7.7 10.1 0.0 3.6 27.2 22.4 87.9 7i.9 17.4 60.8 0.0 3.8 28.9 1.1 15.1 USR S.0 18.9 99.9 25.1 18.6 64.0 16.7 48.9 5.3 0.0 5.4 26.0 16.6 99.8 23.5 16.5 31.1 0.0 35.6 5.2 34.7 6.4 All 16 Markets 34A3 22.5 51.9 31.2 21.3 57.2 17.3 31.1 6.1 5.0 11.0 21.0 17.1 S9.5 18.5 14.5 23.3 3.5 34.3 11.8 31.4 9.8 TA8LS{T' Extent of Industrial Countries' HTBs on Imports fron Developing and Industrial Countries by Product Category, 1983 Uorld inports couerage ratio; deueloping (aboue), industrial (below) Rll Rll, less Rgricul- Manufac- Iron a Electrical Rest of products fuels ruels ture turing Textiles Footuear Steel Machinery Uehicles manuf. EEC 20.7 23.6 6.5 29.3 23.3 66.4 12.7 32.7 6.5 9.1 7.4 18.6 19.t 13.0 47.4 16.3 16.0 1.4 S5.S l1.2 47.0 6.5 Belgiun-Lux 22.0 22.1 22.0 24.6 22.9 51.1 4.8 50.6 0.3 0.1 12.0 20.5 21.0 14.0 55.6 17.3 16.6 2.1 39.1 12.0 58.5 5.9 Dennark 20.3 29.6 0.0 38,2 27.8 64.9 20.5 25.3 0.0 0.1 2.3 14.1 15.6 0.0 43A4 12.3 11.1 1.9 46.1 5.1 38.8 3.2 France 41.7 33.8 58.0 36.7 36.0 71.5 13.2 34.7 34.7 29.2 20.6 30.4 29.1 66.0 56.3 26.2 26.3 1.6 70.0 41.4 +3.2 15.2 Uest 6ermany 15.6 21.9 0.0 27.5 21.2 70.2 2.8 32.2 0.2 0.0 2.8 17.4 18.2 0.0 41.6 15.7 13.4 1.1 45.2 7.2 51.6 4.8 6reece 17.0 26.2 0.0 34.9 25.6 68.2 36.5 37.9 7.9 39.7 10.0 22.8 24.1 0.0 47.0 21.2 14.3 0.4 46.5 16.5 61.1 10.7 Ireland 16.2 16.6 0.0 16.4 20.1 58.8 9.2 17.6 0.0 0.0 4.2 15.9 16.9 0.0 45.9 14.3 15.7 0.0 34.3 0.5 54.5 4.5 Italy 11.6 16.7 0.0 35.9 11.9 58.6 0.5 30.0 0.1 0.0 1.3 9.8 10.1 0.0 38.3 6.8 7.3 1.2 42.2 3.3 7.6 2.9 Netherlands 23.4 24.5 21.0 27.5 24.3 74.0 8.0 15.6 0.0 0.1 9.2 20.8 21.4 10.0 52.0 18.2 16.2 3. 43.4 4.5 54.0 8.0 United Kingdom 18.1 23.6 0.0 21.7 26.2 78.0 15.9 36.5 4.2 0.0 2.7 16.3 18.4 0.0 45.6 15.1 25.1 2.4 44.4 12.1 39.2 3.9 Rustralia 52.8 32.6 96.0 33.4 26.5 26.0 53.9 35.3 58.9 0.0 19.1 26.6 24.9 61.0 29.7 24.2 25.5 52.7 52.0 V7.7 0.4 22.i Rustria 9.8 16.8 0.0 40.1 3. 11.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.3 0.0 8.6 9.2 0.0 59.3 2.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 3.5 3.2 Finland 37.0 28.8 99.0 35.2 26.2 67.2 65.8 18.8 0.0 0.0 0.1 14.2 12.1 78.0 51.6 7.0 34.3 7?.0 43.1 0.0 0.0 0.9 Japan 10.7 10.5 11.0 30.2 5.4 14.2 42.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.9 10.2 9.3 39.0 35.6 5.4 14.0 33.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 7.1 Noruay. 15.2 17.1 0.0 19.1 19.3 42.4 17.3 8.2 0.0 34.6 7.1 5.3 6.8 0.0 36.1 2.1 23.7 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.5 0.2 Switzerland 67.2 42.4 100.0 72.7 17.9 40.8 0.0 18.3 8.0 0.0 3.6 27.7 24.0 64.0 78.4 16.0 46.9 0.0 5.8 24.7 0.9 15.8 USR 51.7 15.9 97.0 14.3 17.8 65.7 19.1 34.6 0.1 0.0 5.6 17.6 10.9 90.0 15.1 10.5 25.7 0.0 36.5 4.4 29.0 3. ll 16 Markets 27.0 22.7 36.9 30.S 20.5 55.5 21.5 21.5 6.6 7.9 7.1 17.1 16.8 20.6 46.1 13.2 20.5 10.3 33.7 11.3 27.4 7.2 -54- TRBLE if Extent of Industrial Countries' NT8s on Inports fron Developing and Industrial Countries by Product Category, 1983 frequency ratio; developing (above), industrial (below) all Rll less Agricul- flanu- Iron & Electrical Rest of products fuels ruels ture facturing Textiles footwear Steel Mlachinery Uehicles nanuf. EEC 20.9 20.9 16.1 27.2 20.0 64.7 5.0 17.0 6.1 8.1 2.5 7.7 7.6 11.4 32.6 5.7 16.6 1.7 22.6 1.3 9.8 1.8 Belgiur-Lux 20.0 19.9 45.8 27.4 18.3 52.3 7.1 9.5 0.7 0.9 C.5 5.9 5.7 37.7 33.9 3.1 7.7 2.5 17.6 0.3 3.1 1.6 Dennark 24.6 24.6 0.0 26.7 24.4 65.5 7.3 8.7 0.2 1.2 1.5 4.6 4.6 0.0 30.0 2.6 6.4 0.9 15.7 0.4 2.3 0.7 trance 30.0 30.0 29.5 37.3 28.9 70.4 3.2 50.1 36.3 38.3 7.1 17,9 17.9 17.5 45.1 15.7 34.2 1.7 57.6 27.4 40t. 5.3 Uest 6ernany 18.4 18.5 0.0 21.7 18.2 59.5 3.6 15.2 0.1 0.0 0.9 5.4 5.4 0.0 28.5 3.3 10.2 1.7 17.4 0.3 1.9 0.8 Greece 17.0 17.1 0.0 26.3 16.1 60.2 11.1 17.5 8.3 17.0 6.6 9.5 9.S 0.0 32.0 8.1 12.1 4.3 21.7 7.1 20.5 5.9 Ireland 22.0 22.1 0.0 35.3 20.6 61.7 5.2 3.9 0.0 0.0 1.8 3.9 3.9 0.0 33.2 2.6 7.8 0.0 9.0 O.1 6.0 1.2 Italy 11.9 15.0 0.0 21.2 14.4 59.2 4.0 13.1 0.1 0.0 0.8 t.6 4,6 0.0 28.9 3.2 8.3 1.6 20.5 0.6 1.8 0.9 Netherlands 21.3 21.1 58.1 28.5 19.1 62.8 5.0 7.t 0.0 0.6 2.3 5.5 5.3 37.1 31.9 2.9 5.8 2.4 16.3 0.2 2.9 1.4 United Kingdmi 19.7 19.8 0.0 25.2 19.1 76.9 5.7 9.5 1.2 0.0 0.6 9.0 9.0 0.0 30.2 7.3 36.4 1.3 18.5 0.8 3.2 0.7 Rustralia 19.7 19.5 67.5- 19.6 19.5 27.2 40.3 12.6 26,7 0.8 16.5 17.5 17.3 50.6 22.8 17.0 25.0 46.2 15.2 24.5 7.4 14.8 Rustria 6.3 6.3 3.8 22.3 1.9 6.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 12.9 0.4 4.8 4.8 0.4 36.0 0.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 9.1 0.5 Finland 21.0 21.0 50.0 27.3 20.1 55.1 59.4 15.8 0.0 0.0 1.0 11.9 i!.? 48.9 30.2 10.5 32.1 56.2 1O.3 0.0 0.0 0.5 Japan 11.4 11.3 16.0 39.4 4.1 9.8 28.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.3 8.2 8.2 5.7 32.5 5.5 18.1 34.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 3.0 Norway 18.5 13.6 0.0 28.4 17.2 i1.3 13.0 13.3 0.0 11.6 5.7 8.0 8.1 0.0 30.2 6.3 29.9 1.6 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.9 Switzerland 24.8 24.7 71.4 51.0 18.5 46.2 0.0 13.1 21.5 0.0 8.8 17.4 17.2 50.7 60.5 11.5 32.8 0.0 3.8 13.8 3.9 7.4 USR 10.8 10.3 95.6 5.7 11.8 52.1 9.5 13.7 0.4 0.0 2.4 3.9 3.6 91.4 7.2 3.2 10.1 0.9 26.1 0.9 2.4 1.0 All 16 lbrkets 18.6 18.5 29.5 25.6 17.4 55.8 10.3 14,6 6.1 6.6 3.6 8.8 8.7 20.5 31.9 6.7 20.1 11.5 18.7 1.3 7.2 2.9 -55- TABLE SC Extent of Industrial Countries' NlBs on Agricultural Products on Imports from Developing and Industrial Countries by Type of Iteasure, 1983 Own imports coverage ratio; developing (above), industrial (belou) Quantitatiue Uoluntary Rli IT8s: import export Decreed Tariff- MIonitoring Union of restriction restraints prices type neasures (1) thru (5) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) EEC 14.1 0.0 13,4 6.6 2.7 26.9 21.3 0.0 27.2 8.0 2.2 4?.7 Belgium-Lux 15.? 0.0 23.5 S.3 0.1 35.1 28.9 0.0 42.6 5.4 0.0 72.0 Oenmark 33.6 0.2 7.9 1.A 0.1 36.3 8.3 0.0 12.1 10.8 0.1 20.9 France 15.1 0.0 10.0 5.4 7.7 28.1 19.7 0.0 23.0 11.2 15.3 53.3 Uest Germany 7.4 0.0 9.0 7.3 1.0 16.6 12.2 0.0 18.7 6.2 0.1 28.5 6reece 13.8 0.0 6.2 6.9 5.1 20.1 33.5 0.0 27.7 11.6 2.1 61.8 Ireland 17.0 0.0 7.4 2.7 0.5 21.2 17.4 0.0 19.8 2.1 0.2 29.1 Italy 17.9 0.0 20.9 6.6 1.0 32.1 5.1 0.0 45.8 4.0 0.1 47.6 Netherlands 16.4 0.0 21.2 6.2 0.7 38.3 50.2 0.0 21.1 2.9 O.1 68.8 United Kingdon 15.0 0.2 10.8 8.3 2.2 24.4 19.5 0.0 29.0 14.4 0.3 44.5 Rustralia 21.4 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 21.6 44.8 0.0 1.7 0.0 3.0 47.7 Rustria 37.8 0.0 3.0 1.2 0.0 0.S 14.3 1.2 24.6 9.1 0.0 39.9 Finland 18.3 0.0 0.0 17.3 0.0 28.7 31.2 0.0 15.3 10.3 0.0 32.6 Japan i6.0 0.0 0.0 7.9 0.0 53.3 31.4 0.0 0.1 6.2 0.0 36.8 Noruay 14.4 0.0 5.2 5.6 0.2 15.4 24.9 0.0 5.0 3.6 0.5 27.0 Switzerland 19.4 0.0 0.2 0.9 50.3 67.3 17.0 0.0 8.8 2.6 26.7 74.9 USR 18.1 0.0 15.2 3.8 3.3 25.1 8.7 0.0 4.1 2.2 13.0 23.5 All 16 Mlarkets 20.8 0.0 11.1 5.9 3.1 31.2 23.5 0.0 13.0 S.9 4.8 4O.5 -56- TRBLE SU Extent of Industrial Countries' HT8s on Rgricultural Products on Inports from Developing and Industrial Countries, by Type of Measure, 1983 Uorld imports coverage ratio; deueloping (above), industrial (belo) Quantitative Uoluntary fill NMIs: import export Decreed Tariff- Monitoring Union of restriction restraint prices type measures (1) thru (5) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) EEC 16.0 0.2 15.2 8.1 3.4 29.3 iS.S 0.0 3i.1 8.5 2.1 47.4 Belgium-Lux 18.2 0.1 13.7 6.9 0.7 24.6 23.4 0.0 36.7 7.5 0.1 55.6 Denmark 21.3 0.6 16.9 4.9 1.4 38.2 17.4 0D0 30.9 17.3 0.1 43.4 France 18.1 0.0 14.5 5.4 14.0 36.7 14.4 0.0 33.7 6.1 14.3 56.3 Uest Germany 16.2 0.0 17.9 14.7 1.0 27.5 9.7 0.0 36.6 7.9 0.1 41.6 Greece 14.2 0.0 16.4 10.6 5.4 34.9 Z0.8 0.0 Z6.4 6.5 3.1 47.0 Ireland 6.6 0.3 6.9 6.1 1.8 16.4 7.0 0.0 40.6 3.9 0.1 45.9 Italy 20.7 0.0 23.8 8.8 2.8 35.9 7.1 0.0 35.3 5.5 0.1 38.3 Netherlands 17.2 0.2 13.0 8.2 0.8 27.5 23.0 0.0 34.9 5.4 0.3 52.0 United Kingdom 10.1 0.5 12.3 7.1 2.1 21.7 14.5 0.0 33.5 13.9 0.1 45.6 Australia 32.9 0.0 0.5 0.0 0.0 33.4 28.4 0.0 0.9 0.0 1.4 29.7 Austria 34.5 0°0 11.7 0.9 0.0 40.1 39.4 0.8 42.2 11.5 0.2 59.3 Finland 26.8 0.0 0.9 14.0 0.0 35.2 50.6 0.0 29.6 5.3 0.0 51.6 Japan 25.4 0.0 0.0 5.3 0.0 30.2 31.9 0.0 0.5 4.7 0.0 35.6 Noruay 18.6 0.0 3.9 2.3 1.1 19.1 34.7 0.0 11.0 1.2 0.1 36.1 Switzerland 28.2 0.0 0.1 0.4 48.3 72.7 45.9 0.0 8.7 1. 35.5 78.4 USA 7.1 0.0 5.0 4.6 2.S 14.3 9.5 0.1 0.8 4.1 4.2 15.1 Rll 16 larkets 18.6 0.1 10.7 6.6 4.4 30.5 25.4 0.1 23.8 6.2 4.3 46.1 -57- Extent of Industrial Countries' HT8s on Rgricultural Products on Imports from Deueloping and Industrial Countries by Type of feasure, 1983 frequency ratio: developing (above), industrial (below) Quantitative Uoluntary Rll NIBs: import export Decreed Tariff- Mlonitoring Union of restriction restraints prices type neasures (1) thru (S) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) ==, ====== =2,=====22,,= = 22==2== 222====,================= 222========,2...=,,.===2,,...., ...==, 22...,,== ,,,. Z..=== (EC 12.7 0.0 12.9 7.5 3.6 27.2 13.4 0.0 18.8 7,9 3.5 32.6 Belgium-Lux 18.9 0.1 13.5 6.3 0.3 27.4 21.1 0.0 19.9 7.3 0.2 33.9 Oenmark 14.7 0.5 10.8 7.8 0.6 26.7 10.8 0.0 19.2 7.7 0.2 30.0 france 12.9 0.1 11.9 7.0 18.4 37.3 15.6 0.1 17.2 8.1 21.1 45.1 Uest Germany 8.8 0.0 11.6 7.8 0.3 21.7 9.5 0.0 18.3 8.2 0.1 28.5 6reece 14.6 0.0 10.8 6.9 1.0 26.3 12.7 0.0 19.9 6.0 3.5 32.0 Ireland 22.5 0.2 18.8 9.9 1.9 35.3 15.3 0.0 23.4 5.9 0.6 33.2 Italy 7.3 0.0 11.8 7.1 1.5 21.2 8.2 0.0 20.7 7.2 0.6 28.9 Netherlands 17.1 0.0 12.0 8.6 0.6 28.5 19.3 0.0 16.0 9.5 0.5 31.9 United Kingdom 10.2 0.1 16.4 7.4 0.5 25.2 10.s 0.0 19.9 7.8 0.3 30.2 Rustralia 19.5 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 19.6 21.6 0.0 0.2 0.0 1.6 22.8 Rustria 10.6 0.6 9.2 6.0 0.0 22.3 15.6 1.2 17.4 12.2 0.0 36.0 finland 21.0 0.0 0.5 11.2 0.0 27.3 28.0 0.0 3.9 6.9 0.0 30.2 Japan 38.5 0.0 0.0 1.2 0.0 39.4 30.1 0.0 1.2 1,9 0.0 32.5 lorway 26.0 0.0. 2.8 2.4 1.3 28.4 29.0 0.0 5.6 2.5 0.6 30.2 Suitzerland 27.6 0.0 5.2 2.1 U.6 S1.0 26.5 0.0 17.4 0.9 25.2 60.5 USA 2.7 0.0 0.7 2.6 0,1 5.7 4.9 0.0 0.3 2.5 0.7 7.2 Rll 16 Markets 14.5 0.1 8.7 5.7 3,3 25.6 17.5 0.1 12.5 5.7 4.2 31.9 -58- TR8LE 6C Extent of Industrial Countries' HT8s on Manufactured Products on Inoorts from Deueloping and Industrial Countries, by Type of neasure, 1983 Own inports coverage ratio; developing (above). industrial (belou) Duantitative Uoluntarv Rll NT8s: in,port export Decreed Tariff- Monitoring Union of restriction restraints prices type Mleasures (1) thru (5) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) EEC 10.7 17.0 0.9 2.0 14.7 29.9 1.9 0.1 2.1 1.l 12.9 1S.2 Belgium-Lux 48.3 4.7 0.5 1.8 50.8 54.7 5.5 0.0 1.6 2.3 20.0 22.5 Dernark 0.8 32.5 1.t 2.1 0.5 36.7 0.0 0.0 3.0 2.8 7.0 9.8 rrance 15.5 10.4 0.5 1.6 21.t 33.0 6.3 0.0 1.7 1.3 21.0 25.0 Uest Gernany 2.1 25.8 1.0 1.6 1.8 30.2 0.1 0.0 2.9 2.2 11.0 13.3 Greece 3.2 6.0 1.0 1.3 1.7 11.8 8.2 0.1 2.5 2.0 16.9 22.6 Ireland 3.7 13.5 0.8 5.1 7.3 19.5 0.0 0.2 1.7 2.9 9.3 12.8 Italy 2.5 7.7 0.9 2.5 1.t 12.0 0.7 0.0 1.8 0.8 5.2 6.0 Hetherlands 3.9 22.4 0.9 2.3 14.9 29.0 0.7 0.0 1.6 2.6 12.5 15.3 United Kingdun 10.0 22.0 1.3 2.6 22.3 30.A 0.S 0.1 1.7 0.9 11.8 13.2 Rustralia 14.9 0.0 0.7 8.1 6.0 28.6 15.0 0.0 0.9 3.1 5.7 22.7 Rustria 0.0 6.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 6.1 1.0 0.0 0.0 0.4 1.0 2.4 Finland 0.0 6.5 0.0 0.0 25.4 27.5 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 5.2 5.5 Japan- 1.2 0.O 0.0 0.2 0.0 4.4 9.4 0.0 0.0 0.3 0.0 9.7 Nornay 20.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 20.9 3.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 3.2 Switzerland 2.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 18.2 19.5 10.5 0.0 RO 0.0 8.t 17.1 USR 0.1 13.0 0.5 0.0 5.6 18.6 0.4 11.1 0.0 0.0 5.6 16.5 Rll 16 Countries 5.4 12.1 0.6 1.0 8.6 21.3 3.2 3.9 0.8 0.8 7.5 14.5 -59- TOBLE 6U Extent of Industrial Countries' HT8s on Manufactured Products on Inports from Developing and Industrial Countries, by Type of Measure. 1983 Uorld imports coverage ratio; developing (above), industrial (belou) guantitative Uoluntary Rll NT8a: import export Decreed Tariff- Monitoring Union of restriction restraint prices type measures (1) thru (5) (1 ) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) [EC 6.2 14.8 1.3 1.7 10.2 23.3 2.0 0.0 2.9 1.3 14.0 16.3 Belgium-Lux 7.0 13.0 1.8 1.7 14.4 22.9 1.0 0.0 2.9 1.4 15.7 17.3 Oennark 0.8 24.0 1.5 1.5 0.1 27.8 0.0 0.0 3.2 1.5 10.7 12.3 France 2g 70 1 1:2 21° 9 Uest 6ernany 1.9 16.? 1.1 1.4 2.0 21.2 0.2 0.0 3.1 1.4 14,1 15.7 Greece 5.9 12.6 1.5 2.6 10.4 25.6 8.5 0.0 2.1 1.3 15.0 21.2 Ireland 5.7 16.1 0.9 2.1 10.2 20.1 0.2 0.2 2.8 1.7 12.1 14.3 Italy 0.7 9.5 1.0 1.1 1.5 11.9 0.7 0.0 2.8 0.8 6.0 6.8 Hetherlands 5.5 17.1 1.1 1.6 13.5 24.3 1.8 0.0 3.1 1.6 16.4 18.2 United Kingdon 8.6 18.8 2.1 1.9 19.2 26.2 0.4 0.1 3.3 0.7 14.1 15.1 Australia 12.0 0.0 0.9 12.1 3.4 26.5 15.4 0.0 1.0 .8 5.8 24.2 Rustria 0,0 3.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 3.4 0.6 0.0 0.1 0.5 1.3 2.4 Finland 0.0 5.7 0.0 0.0 25.2 26.2 0.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 6.5 7.0 Japan 5.3 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 S. 5.3 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 5.4 Koruay 19.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 19.3 2.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.1 Switzerland 2.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 16.1 17.9 10.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 6.9 16.0 USA 2.0 12.3 0.1 0.0 3.8 17.8 0.7 7.1 .0 0.0 3.4 10.5 Rll 16 Markets 6.0 10.9 0.9 1.9 8.2 20.5 3.4 0. 1.6 1.0 9.1 13.2 -60- TRBLE 6F Extent of Industrial Countries' HTBs on Manufactured Products on Imports from Developing and Industrial Countries, by Type of Measure, 1983 frequency ratio; developing (above), industrial (below) Quantitatiue Uoluntary Rll'NTBs: import export - Decreed Tariff- Monitorin Union of restriction restraints prices type neasure (1) thru (5) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) EEC 4.7 14.1 0.9 1.3 6.8 20.0 1.4 0.1 0.9 1.1 3.5 5.7 Belgium-Lux 3.1 13.9 0.4 2.0 6.6 18.3 0.6 0.1 1.0 1.1 2.0 3.i Dennark 0.6 22.2 0.3 1.3 0.2 2t.4 0.0 0.1 0.8 1.1 1.3 2.6 france 14.4 12.0 0.3 1.2 15.1 28.9 i.4 0.2 0.9 1.2 10.6 15.7 Uest Germany 1.4 15.3 0.5 1.3 1.0 18.2 0.4 0.1 1.0 1.2 1.6 3.3 Greece 3.8 8.2 1.1 1.4 - .t 16.1 3.8 0.0 1.2 0.8 3.6 8.1 Ireland t.9 18.1 0.4 1.5 9.5 20.6 0.1 0.1 0.7 0.9 1.3 2.6 Italy 0.8 12.0 0.5 1.8 1.0 14.4 0.2 0.1 1.1 1.3 1.7 3.2 Netherlands 1.9 16.6 0.3 1.0 6.6 19.1 0.5 0.1 0.9 0.8 1.8 2.9 United Kingdon 6.7 12.7 0.3 1.1 12.3 19.1 2.7 0.1 0.9 1.2 5.2 7.3 Australia i2.1 0.0 0.1 6.t 1.6 19.5 11.4 0.0 0.1 4.1 1.9 17.0 Rustria 0.3 1.4 0.0 0.2 0.0 1.9 0.2 0.0 0.1 0.3 0.1 0.7 Finland 0.0 4.2 0.0 o.o. 19.4 20.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 10.3 10.5 Japan i.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 t.1 5.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 5.5 Norway 17.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 17.2 6.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 6.i Switzerland 6.3 1).0 0.0 0.0 12.9 13.5 i.6 0.0 0.0 0.U 7.5 11.5 USR, 0.2 10.6 6. 0 i.0 1.1 1.8 0.6 2.2.0 d.0 0.8 3.2 R11 16 Markets 4.7 0.6 0.3 1.2 5.6 17.4 2.6 0.2 0.5 0.e 3.3 6. - 61 - TABLE 7 Change In the Extent of Industrial Countries' NTBs for All Products, All NTB Types Percentage Point Increase, 1981-1983 Own Imports World Imports Coverage Ratio Coverage Ratio Frequency Ratio Exporters Markets all industrial developing all industrial developing all industrial developing EEC 2.5 4.5 1.2 2.8 4.1 1.3 1.5 1.6 1.5 Belgium-Luxembourg 1.9 3.5 0.8 2.1 3.0 0.8 1.5 1.5 1.4 Denmark 2.9 3.8 1.0 2.7 3.7 0.7 1.8 1.5 1.4 France 2.7 5.1 2.1 2.8 3.8 2.3 2.0 1.9 2.3 West Germany 2.8 5.5 0.8 2.6 3.9 0.8 1.5 1.6 1.3 Greece 4.0 10.2 0.9 5.9 8.7 3.4 2.9 3.0 3.3 Ireland 3.8 4.5 2.3 2.8 4.3 0.7 1.1 1.2 1.1 Italy 1.0 2.6 0.7 1.5 2.3 0.6 1.6 1.6 1.7 Netherlands 2.0 4.3 0.8 2.6 4.2 1.0 1.2 1.2 1.0 United Kingdom 3.6 4.2 1.4 2.4 3.1 0.8 1.2 1.5 0.8 Australia 2.5 2.7 2.7 2.8 3.7 2.6 0.3 0.4 0.2 Austria 0.1 0.0 2.1 0.2 0.0 1.1 0.1 0.0 1.0 Finland -3.8 -5.5 -1.4 -3.1 -4.2 -2.0 -11.5 -11.5 -10.6 Japan 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.1 Norway -0.3 -0.4 1.0 -0.2 -0.3 1.7 0.1 -0.1 1.7 Switzerland 2.5 2.7 1.2 2.5 3.1 1.6 1.4 0.9 2.5 USA 1.3 1.6 1.4 0.5 0.6 0.4 0.1 0.1 0.1 All 16 Markets 1.5 2.2 1.1 1.8 2.3 1.1 0.3 0.1 0.9 - 62 - Table 8: Balassa and Balassa's Results for Manufactures Own imports coverage ratio Nogues Olechowski and Winters Balassa and Balassa (a) (b) USA 1981 16.4 11.7 11.7 1983 17.1 11.9 12.7 Japan 1981 7.6 7.3 7.2 1983 7.5 7.4 7.2 EEC 1981 13.9 8.1 10.8 1983 18.7 8.5 (c) 14.9 Memorandum data-level tariff-line 4-digit SITC(R) NTB year 1983 1983 trade year 1981 1980 NTB definition (a) (1)-) (1)-(2) (1)-(2) plus standards (b) (a) In terms of groups defined in the text (b) "The restrictive application of standards" (c) At least part of the reason for this figure being below the Balassas' is the treatment of voluntary export restrictions on the EEC's vehicle imports from Japan. The Balassas include these, but in general we do not, because the VERs have never been officially reported by national sources or GATT, and thus are excluded from the UNCTAD data. In fact the EEC uses surveillance to "implicitly enforce" unofficial (in Britain's case explicitly private) VERs. If we include EEC surveillance on vehicles the figure comparable to the Balassas' rises to 11.1. Of course the surveillance practices are included in column (a) of this table. - 63 - Table 9: Cline's Results for Manufactures Own imports coverage ratios Nogues Olechowski and Winters Cline (a) (b) Importer Exporter USA all 16.4 12.2 45.1 developing 20.2 17.5 43.0 W. Germany all 13.4 10.4 27.5 developing 28.5 28.1 30.8 France all 21.8 9.5 40.4 developing 28.3 17.9 29.4 Italy all 6.7 5.9 32.4 developing 10.6 10.4 29.4 U.K. all 9.4 5.6 25.7 developing 27.9 25.1 23.8 Japan all 7.6 7.3 22.1 developing 4.4 4.2 27.5 Memorandum: data-level tariff-line 4-digit ISIC NTB year 1981 mid-1970's to 1981 Trade year 1981 1981 NTB definition (a) (1)-(5) (1)-(3) (1)-(3) (a) In terms of groups defined in the text - 64 - Table 10: Jones' Results for the UK Own imports coverage ratio Nogues Olechowski and Winters Jones Category Coverage Category Coverage of imports ratio of imports ratio of: manufactures 5.6 of: industrial products 6.0 agricultural 34.6 agricultural 44.0 from: developing countries 20.4 from: developing countries 14.8 industrial countries 6.6 other developed countries 7.9 Memorandum: data-level tariff-line tariff-line NTB year 19811980 trade year 1981 1980 NTB definition (a) (101 f4O4) (a) In terms of groups defined in the text. -65- Table 11 Industrial Countries' Trade, 1981 (A) All Products in US S billion Total Imports from Imports from Imports Developing Countries (b) Industrial Countries (b) EEC (a) Belgium-Luxembourg 24.7 2.1 10.2 Denmark 9.1 1.4 3.9 France 62.6 18.8 21.5 Germany, Fed. Rep. 87.3 23.4 34.4 Greece 4.5 1.5 1.4 Ireland 2.6 0.4 1.8 Italy 53.9 20.3 14.8 Netherlands 31.8 9.1 11.2 United Kingdom 64.4 13.9 28.8 Australia 20.9 3.7 14.5 Austria 19.0 1.6 13.7 Finland 14.3 1.0 7.1 Japan 141.7 48.4. 48.8 Norway 15.6 1.0 11.2 Switzerland 30.5 2.4 25.5 USA 258.6 97.7 135.2 Total 841.5 251.7 384.0 (B) Product Structure in percentage Total Imports from Imports from Imports Developing Countries (b) Industrial Countries (b) All 100.0 100.0 100.0 Fuels 34.8 40.1 9.6 Agricultural 10.2 16.3 10.8 Manufactures 52.1 38.9 76.9 Textiles 4.8 9.4 3.9 Footwear 0.7 1.4 0.6 Iron & Steel 2.8 1.3 4.6 Electrical Machinery 4.6 4.8 6.3 Vehicles 5.6 0.6 11.2 Other Manufactures 33.6 21.4 50.3 (a) Excluding intra-comnunity trade. (b) For definition of country and product grouping see Annex 2. The World Bank Headquarters European Office Tokyo Office 1818 H Street, N.W. 66, avenue d'Ina Kokusai Building Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A. 75116 Paris, France 1-1 Marunouchi 3-chome Telephone: (202) 477-1234 Telephone: (1) 47.23.54.21 Chiyoda-ku, Tokyo 100, Japan Telex: WUI 64145 WORLDBANK Telex: 842-620628 Telephone: (03) 214-5001 RCA 248423 WORLDBK Telex: 781-26838 Cable Address: INTBAFRAD WASHINGTONDC ISSN 0253-2115/ISBN 0-8213-0691-X