The Economic Effects of Counterfeiting
                     and Piracy: A Review and Implications
                            for Developing Countries


                                             Carsten Fink, Keith E. Maskus, and Yi Qian


                 Policy makers around the world recognize the potentially harmful consequences of trade-
                 mark counterfeiting and copyright piracy. Indeed, many countries have recently initiated
                 policy reforms to strengthen the enforcement of intellectual property rights (IPR).
                 Further, minimum standards of enforcement have been incorporated in many international
                 treaties, especially trade agreements. This emphasis on enforcement raises basic questions
                 about the actual impacts of IP rights infringement, which differ across the types of IPR
                 and economic sectors. We review the academic literature and other studies in the public
                 domain to evaluate what has been learned about these socioeconomic effects, with an empha-
                 sis on developing countries where possible. We also identify important gaps in our understand-
                 ing of the consequences of counterfeiting and piracy and develop recommendations on how
                 governments might collect data and conduct studies to better inform IPR enforcement policy.
                 Counterfeiting, Piracy, Intellectual property rights . JEL codes: L14, O31, O34



                 Intellectual property rights (IPR) cover a broad array of legal rules affording individ-
                 uals and enterprises, or their licensees, exclusive opportunities to make, copy, and
                 sell products and technologies arising from their inventive and creative work. These
                 rules range from patents on new inventions to trademarks and geographical indica-
                 tions certifying the origin of goods. These rules also include copyright on creative
                 and literary works, including software and digital transmissions. Because these
                 rights are national in scope, how they are defined and protected varies considerably
                 across countries for a variety of reasons (Maskus 2012).
                    Despite their broad similarity as a means of supporting markets for knowledge,
                 various forms of IPR embody different economic and social objectives. It follows

                 The World Bank Research Observer
                 # The Author 2015. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the International Bank for Reconstruction and
                 Development / THE WORLD BANK. All rights reserved. For permissions, please e-mail: journals.permissions@oup.com
                 doi:10.1093/wbro/lkv010           Advance Access publication May 7, 2015                                        31:1–28




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
              that their infringement, or actions taken by third parties in violation of exclusive
              rights, interferes in varying degrees with attaining these objectives. Producing an
              imitative good that infringes on one’s patent rights may diminish dynamic incen-
              tives to invest in R&D, for example, though it can also bolster market competition
              in a static sense. Moreover, there is an important international element: if IPR
              infringement weakens the profitability of largely foreign enterprises, why would
              governments choose to invest in costly enforcement activities?
                 The particular forms of IPR infringement that have attracted the greatest global
              policy interest are counterfeiting, which is the illegal use of trademarks to sell unau-
              thorized goods, and piracy, which is the duplication and sale of copyrighted goods
              without the copyright holder’s permission. Policy makers around the world recog-
              nize the potentially harmful consequences of trademark counterfeiting and copy-
              right piracy. First, infringements of intellectual property (IP) rights undermine trust
              in rules-based systems that are at the core of modern market-based economies.
              Second, counterfeit products can confuse consumers and may be ineffective or even
              dangerous, as with adulterated medicines and foodstuffs or non-certified engine re-
              placement parts. Third, extensive counterfeiting can significantly deter the emer-
              gence of new products and firms, and piracy can block the development of creative
              industries, especially in poor countries where entry conditions are already weak.
                 Over the past two decades, many governments—including those of developing
              countries—have initiated policy reforms to strengthen the enforcement of IPR
              (Maskus 2012). In addition, minimum standards of enforcement have also been
              incorporated in many international treaties, especially trade agreements, as IPR
              owners in wealthier economies push for stronger global protection. For example,
              the terms of the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), while still under negotiation,
              embody extensive expectations for stronger border and domestic enforcement.
                 However, instituting a policy framework for combating counterfeiting and piracy
              poses substantial challenges. The economic effects of infringements differ across dif-
              ferent IPR and economic sectors (Fink 2009), and it is important to understand
              these differences at the theoretical and empirical levels to set priorities for IPR en-
              forcement policy. Governments are invariably resource-constrained, and completely
              eradicating violations of IP law—similar to violations of other types of law—is out
              of reach for even the best-resourced states. This is especially true for developing
              countries, where many public goods are underprovided and enforcement challenges
              exist in many areas of law.
                 Thus, in this article we review the academic literature and other studies in the
              public domain to evaluate what is known about the socioeconomic effects of coun-
              terfeiting and piracy.1 We also identify important gaps in the understanding of these
              effects and develop recommendations on how governments might collect data and
              conduct studies as inputs into the formulation of IPR enforcement policy. For the
              most part, we ignore differences and limitations in the effectiveness of IPR

              2                                               The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 enforcement measures, which are equally important but warrant a separate discus-
                 sion. Where relevant, we draw inferences from these studies about important impli-
                 cations for economic development and policy making in developing countries. In
                 particular, we highlight the importance of collecting better and more consistent
                 data, conducting microeconomic studies of the impacts of infringements on local
                 firms, and raising consumer awareness of the potential externalities they impose on
                 domestic producers and the potential risks consumers face with sub-standard
                 products. Governments may also wish to develop an impact evaluation framework
                 to assess their strategic investments in enforcement activities. This could be particu-
                 larly important in light of growing external pressures for stronger efforts in the
                 context of regional trade agreements.
                    The paper is structured as follows. In the next section, we approach the topic
                 from a theoretical perspective, first reviewing the different market failures under-
                 lying trademark and copyright protection, and then exploring what happens
                 when these rights are violated. The discussion concludes with brief suggestions
                 for future theoretical research. In the next section we review existing empirical ev-
                 idence, including aggregate estimates of levels of counterfeiting and piracy, studies
                 of the effects of IPR infringements in particular industries, and anecdotal evidence
                 from selected case studies. In the final section we explore what the findings of the
                 literature imply for policymaking in developing countries, and develop recommen-
                 dations for data collection and the conduct of future studies on counterfeiting and
                 piracy.



                 Theoretical Considerations
                 In general, intellectual property rights aim to remedy the failure of markets to
                 provide an efficient allocation of resources. The relevant market failures that give
                 rise to copyright and trademark protection vary. Accordingly, the effects of trade-
                 mark counterfeiting and copyright piracy vary and warrant separate treatments.


                 Economics of Trademark Counterfeiting
                 The primary welfare effects of counterfeiting depend crucially on whether consum-
                 ers are deceived into believing that a fake good is produced by the owner of the
                 trademark. The likelihood of this deception depends on product characteristics and
                 the nature of distribution channels. For example, consumers are usually unable to
                 ascertain whether a pharmaceutical product contains the desired chemical ingredi-
                 ent, whereas most fashion shoppers can distinguish an original handbag from its
                 fake clone. We discuss the implications of deceptive and non-deceptive counterfeit-
                 ing in turn.

                 Fink et al.                                                                                              3




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
              Deceptive Counterfeiting. The most relevant market failure giving rise to trademark
              protection arises from asymmetric information. For many goods, consumers do not
              have enough information to ascertain the quality of a potential purchase. A trade-
              mark guarantees that a product or a service originated with a particular producer.
              This is valuable information to consumers because it reduces both uncertainty and
              the costs of searching for particular quality levels. Indeed, producers compete by es-
              tablishing a reputation for different levels of quality. In turn, trademarks serve as an
              indication of product quality, a crucial support for functioning markets. Thus,
              trademarks, geographical indications, and similar rights enable high-quality pro-
              ducers to distinguish themselves in the market, supporting investments in improved
              product or service quality.
                 Deceptive counterfeiters copy trademarks, logos, and designs to confuse consumers
              into believing they are buying the legitimate product. In the presence of information
              asymmetries, deceptive counterfeiting is virtually certain to reduce economic welfare
              (Grossman and Shapiro 1988a). Those who discover they bought a fake good realize
              less consumption value than the price they paid for it (Liu et al. 2005). Rational
              consumers, aware that fake goods are on the market but are indistinguishable from
              originals, are unwilling to pay the full price of a high-quality good. This problem un-
              dermines the incentive for producers to invest in higher quality and may destroy
              markets for high-quality goods (Akerlof 1970; Qian et al. 2013).
                 For developing countries, where deceptive counterfeiting sometimes reaches high
              levels, at least two significant costs arise (Maskus 2012). First, extensive anecdotal
              evidence suggests that the likelihood of infringement deters market entry by local
              enterprises, thus limiting the growth of small and medium-sized enterprises. In this
              context, counterfeiting can be anti-competitive in a dynamic sense, even in poor
              countries.
                 Second, for certain products, the consumption of deceptive fakes can generate
              negative externalities. Examples would be an increased risk of disease transmission
              in the case of pharmaceuticals, or environmental degradation in the case of indus-
              trial chemicals. Indeed, the distribution of counterfeit drugs poses a significant
              public health challenge in many developing countries, especially in Africa.2 The
              presence of negative externalities calls for public action against counterfeit prod-
              ucts, independent of any private incentive for enforcing trademark rights.

              Non-deceptive Counterfeiting. A more complex situation arises where consumers are
              perfectly able to ascertain the quality attributes of goods at the moment of purchase
              and therefore know whether they are buying a counterfeit. Because no information
              asymmetry prevails, trademarks, at first sight, seem irrelevant. However, for so-
              called status goods the display of the producer’s name confers prestige on the pur-
              chaser, yielding utility beyond that from the goods’ functional characteristics.
              Counterfeiting of status goods can reduce the prestige value of genuine versions.

              4                                               The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 Such value is real, as is manifested by the substantial marketing outlays of produc-
                 ers of luxury goods and the prevalence of counterfeits.
                    Grossman and Shapiro (1988b) analyze the effects of non-deceptive product
                 counterfeiting. In their simplified model, status value depends negatively on the
                 number of consumers who purchase a product bearing the same brand name,
                 whether genuine or fake. In this setting, the social welfare consequences of product
                 counterfeiting become theoretically ambiguous. Producers and consumers of the
                 genuine product are made worse off by counterfeits because their presence reduces
                 the status value, and therefore the price, of the genuine product. However, produc-
                 ers and consumers of the counterfeit product are better off. In particular, consum-
                 ers of fake products gain status value without paying the full price of the genuine
                 product. The overall effect on social welfare is an empirical question.

                 Strategic Responses to Counterfeiting. More recent analysis has identified further in-
                 teresting features of markets with fake goods. For example, Qian (2014a) models
                 the impacts of entry by counterfeiters on the subsequent responses of genuine pro-
                 ducers. Because counterfeits are usually an inferior imitation of the authentic
                 product, the theory adopts a vertical differentiation setup. In particular, the theory
                 incorporates two layers of asymmetric information potentially generated by coun-
                 terfeits: (1) counterfeiters fool buyers, and (2) buyers of counterfeits fool their peer
                 consumers by pretending to have high-status goods. One key prediction is that
                 entry by counterfeiters would induce a genuine producer to upgrade product
                 quality and raise the product’s price if and only if the entrant’s quality is lower than
                 a threshold level. In essence, genuine trademark owners must raise quality and
                 price (and reduce sales) to attract demand in the market, which is consistent with
                 evidence from China discussed in the next section. Note, however, that the possibili-
                 ty that original producers may invest in higher quality versions to compete with
                 counterfeiters does not imply higher economic welfare, or that the induced innova-
                 tion is efficient. Qian et al. (2013) further show that competition from counterfeiting
                 induces branded firms to invest more in improving searchable quality attributes such
                 as appearance, and less in enhancing experiential attributes, such as functionality.
                    Competition from counterfeit products can either lower the prices of genuine
                 goods due to substitution in demand or raise their prices and production costs in
                 order to move up-market. In addition, Qian (2014a) demonstrates how authentic
                 producers could invest in “self-enforcement” strategies to limit the competition from
                 counterfeit goods. Such strategies include conspicuous packaging of products and
                 specially licensed company stores.3

                 Longer-term Welfare Considerations. Counterfeiting can encourage certain forms of
                 innovation among genuine producers in an attempt to differentiate their products
                 from imitations. This process is costly, however, perhaps especially in poor countries

                 Fink et al.                                                                                              5




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
              where the margin of high-income consumers seeking high-quality genuine goods is
              relatively small. More fundamentally, under both deceptive and non-deceptive coun-
              terfeiting, producers of genuine products realize lower profits. Facing this problem,
              original trademark owners become less willing to invest in developing new goods,
              ultimately reducing the rate of new product development and lowering both entry
              of new firms and consumer welfare (Aghion et al. 2005; Scherer 1967). We con-
              clude that on balance, extensive counterfeiting is likely to harm consumers and
              impede growth in poor and emerging economies.



              Economics of Copyright Piracy
              The need for copyright protection comes from three characteristics associated with
              creative works such as books, music, films, and software. First, these products can
              be reproduced at low marginal cost; in the case of the Internet, reproduction occurs
              at virtually zero marginal cost. The second characteristic is that their consumption
              is non-rival; many people can enjoy them without diminishing availability for
              others. The third characteristic of such works is that the creative process may
              require costly sunk investments. If competitive market forces were to provide crea-
              tive works at marginal cost, actors, artists, authors, producers, and publishers
              would have little financial incentive to undertake those investments. The copyright
              offers a solution to this problem by affording producers of creative works the exclu-
              sive rights to authorize and control their reproduction. In turn, genuine copies may
              be sold at a profit, allowing for the financing of creative investments.4
                 In light of this essential economic rationale for protection, what are the implica-
              tions of copyright piracy? The basic answer is that high levels of copyright infringe-
              ments undermine the incentives for creating and licensing new works, ultimately
              lowering social welfare. Unauthorized copying tends to flourish where originals
              command a high price, copying is cheap (as with digital goods and internet trans-
              missions), and the likelihood of detection or meaningful punishment is low. In such
              circumstances, widespread copying can significantly diminish the incentives to
              develop and produce new creative and literary works. This barrier seems particular-
              ly relevant for indigenous music and software industries in developing countries
              with high rates of piracy, where copiers pervasively target local performers and
              emerging enterprises (Maskus 2000; Penna et al. 2004).
                 Beyond this basic framework a number of theoretical nuances should be men-
              tioned. For example, theory suggests that piracy can raise or lower the price of origi-
              nal works (Besen and Kirby 1989; Takeyama 1997). If consumers who prefer to
              buy originals have sufficiently inelastic demand, it is possible for the prices they pay
              to be higher in the presence of pirated copies. The reason is that copying would
              induce original producers to concentrate their sales on this group, which pushes up

              6                                               The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 price. Overall sales of legitimate copies are likely to be lower, however, because copy-
                 right owners would choose not to sell to the remaining market segment.
                     An example is the model by Harbaugh and Khemka (2010), who point out that
                 if copyright enforcement efforts are focused on larger users with higher valuations
                 for software, such as public enterprises, universities, and government agencies, the
                 original IP owners can charge higher-than-monopoly prices to those users. The re-
                 maining users in the market then purchase pirated copies. When enforcement is
                 spread more broadly throughout the market, however, original producers will sell
                 more legitimate copies and prices will fall, even as the volume of pirated goods di-
                 minishes. In this situation, it is possible to observe more genuine goods on the
                 market and an increase in overall consumer benefits.5
                     Another reason prices may rise in the face of piracy is that unauthorized copying
                 may induce copyright holders to add features and functionality to genuine copies to
                 distinguish them in the marketplace. In turn, these features support higher prices,
                 which consumers of originals are willing to pay, whereas pirated copies command
                 lower prices (Varian 2000). An early variant of this concept is detailed by Liebowitz
                 (1985), who presents empirical evidence that academic journals raised their prices
                 after the introduction of photocopying because they had become more valuable to
                 consumers. A similar process is underway in academic publishing in the digital age,
                 with dramatic increases in subscription prices for paper copies (Maskus 2012).
                     Finally, note that books, journals, music, and videos are “information goods”
                 that can be shared across multiple uses through copying, rentals, and literal
                 sharing. This fact affects strategies of the content producers and copyright owners,
                 who must decide the formats, timing of releases, functionality, and prices of such
                 goods. According to Varian (2000), copyright owners are likely to sell fewer copies
                 at higher prices to manage the sharing problem. This strategy is likely to be profit-
                 able when there are low transaction costs in sharing (e.g., movie rentals) and when
                 sharing markets permits separation of higher-valuation and lower-valuation users.
                 The former will receive goods faster at higher prices, and the latter will have delayed
                 access at lower prices or will enter lower-quality and, perhaps, pirated markets.

                 Network Effects. Piracy takes on interesting features in the presence of goods with
                 network externalities, in which one consumer’s valuation of a creative work in-
                 creases with the number of other consumers owning the same product. Computer
                 programs are an example, as the ability to share files with other users increases the
                 attractiveness of a particular software package.
                    What happens if creative works subject to network externalities are pirated?
                 Suppose that original and pirated copies are perfect substitutes, or at least highly in-
                 teroperable as in the case of software. Consumers of original copies gain because the
                 presence of pirated copies enlarges the network with which they can interact. In addi-
                 tion, sonsumers of pirated copies will benefit from inexpensive access to the work.

                 Fink et al.                                                                                              7




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 The effects of copyright piracy on the producer of the creative work and overall
              welfare are ambiguous. As Conner and Rumelt (1991) and Takeyama (1994) show,
              it is theoretically possible for the copyright owner to reap higher profits from
              certain levels of piracy. The intuition is that the enhanced network value of the
              product may allow producers to charge a higher price for originals. Here, copyrights
              support profitable price discrimination. In theory, the copyright owner could
              achieve the same outcome by simply giving away a certain number of original
              works. In practice, this would not work because all consumers would expect a free
              legitimate copy. However, consumers differ in their willingness to use pirated copies,
              as determined, for example, by income levels. This difference allows the producer to
              segment the market and choose the profit-maximizing combination of price and
              network size.6


              Effects on Tax Revenue and Employment
              In policy discussions on trademark counterfeiting and copyright piracy, effects on
              tax revenue and employment have gained in importance, especially in richer coun-
              tries where firms see their IPR infringed on abroad. From an economic perspective,
              these effects can be evaluated either in a shorter-term partial-equilibrium setting or
              a longer-term general-equilibrium setting.
                 The overall partial-equilibrium employment effects are theoretically straightfor-
              ward and depend on how output shifts between genuine and illicit producers and
              the labor intensities of original and pirated copies. The same holds for tax revenues,
              which are nearly certain to fall because sales of pirated and counterfeit products
              occur in informal markets where taxes and import tariffs are usually not collected,
              and because sales of legitimate producers likely decline. No existing theoretical re-
              search examines the tradeoffs between employment in the formal and illicit infor-
              mal sectors, including the setting of wages, the existence and impact of social safety
              nets, and the nature and length of possible unemployment spells.
                 The long-term general-equilibrium effects of IPR infringement are often ignored
              in policy discussions, but understanding them better is crucial. Again, direct im-
              pacts in affected sectors are surely negative. However, workers losing employment
              likely find other jobs, and governments facing a revenue shortfall likely adjust their
              tax structure to finance public spending. The key question is how workers and the
              efficiency of the tax system fare in the counterfactual equilibrium. No formal model-
              ing work seems to exist in the literature that would offer conceptual guidance.


              Impacts on Trade, Foreign Direct Investment, and Licensing
              The theoretical literature on the relationships between IPR protection and inter-
              national trade, FDI, and licensing is deep and sophisticated.7 These linkages

              8                                               The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 are important because they govern how policy reforms and enforcement affect
                 market-based inward technology transfer (ITT) into developing economies.
                 However, economic theory in this area focuses almost exclusively on IPR as technol-
                 ogy protection, for example patents and trade secrets, and has ignored trademark
                 counterfeiting and copyright piracy. Further, no models have considered the role of
                 stronger enforcement as being distinct from basic legal reforms.
                    Thus, a comprehensive review lies beyond the scope of this paper and we simply
                 state the primary theoretical findings. Because multiple channels exist for transfer-
                 ring technology, IPR in the recipient country has both scale effects and composition
                 effects. Regarding scale, multinational enterprises (MNEs) seeking to deploy a new
                 technology or sell a new good face a basic tradeoff when local IPR is enhanced
                 (Maskus and Penubarti 1995). Because local firms face higher imitation costs, their
                 outputs are reduced and MNEs sell more, whether through trade or FDI. At the same
                 time, MNEs face less elastic demand from consumers who continue to buy their
                 goods, thus permitting higher prices at reduced (monopolistic) volumes. This tradeoff
                 between market expansion and market power is fundamental to the theory of intellec-
                 tual property and ITT. This tradeoff extends to licensing as well: MNEs can expand the
                 number of contracts for technology use and production rights but they can also raise
                 royalty rates (Branstetter et al. 2006). The key point is that IPR reforms have ambigu-
                 ous impacts on ITT, at least in theory, making it an empirical question.
                    As for the composition of ITT, economic theory suggests that MNEs shift their em-
                 phasis from exports at weak IPR levels to FDI and then licensing as protection im-
                 proves (Markusen 2001; Javorcik 2004). This theory assumes (with little evidence)
                 that imported high-technology goods are relatively difficult to imitate and thus
                 carry their own protection. As IPR is strengthened, MNEs gain more confidence
                 that local affiliate production cannot readily be copied, and become more willing to
                 take advantage of cost reductions through FDI. However, technology remains inter-
                 nal to the firm for purposes of control. At yet higher protection levels, MNEs become
                 willing to license their technologies to local partners, thereby externalizing their
                 knowledge assets. A related factor is that stronger patents and trademarks increase
                 the confidence that contracts are enforceable, making arm’s-length licensing more
                 attractive.
                    One additional strategic response (among many) is worth mentioning here.
                 Specifically, where MNEs fear losing their technological advantages to imitation
                 and their trademark reputations to counterfeiting, they may fragment their produc-
                 tion among multiple local plants at various locations to diminish information flows
                 among them and gain more ability to deter infringement. This approach, which has
                 been common among MNEs operating in China (Maskus 2000), is inefficient and
                 likely reduces net technology transfer. For example, Sun et al. (2010) demonstrate
                 theoretically that an MNE worried about imitation in an emerging market may
                 limit the range of technologies it offers to deter entry by local imitators.

                 Fink et al.                                                                                              9




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 As mentioned, there are no theoretical studies focusing on FDI, licensing, and
              ITT with respect to counterfeiting and piracy, our focus here. However, many of the
              tradeoffs above surely apply. For example, reducing trademark infringement can
              lower the local selling costs of MNEs and expand their markets, whether through
              trade or FDI. Regional fragmentation of production is a costly reaction to counter-
              feiting, as is the need to engage in private enforcement. And, because of weak copy-
              rights, MNEs may deploy expensive software to deter copying or pay more for
              programs on the market, as noted above. Presumably, these factors are deterrents
              that companies take into account when deciding on investment locations.
                 It is important to note that high-technology imports and FDI support localized
              learning and productivity gains in developing countries (Keller 2004; Branstetter
              et al. 2006), which are important for supporting productivity growth. To the extent
              that weak IPR diminishes such prospects, they have a negative dynamic impact on
              development.


              Recommendations for Future Theoretical Research
              While the economic literature offers useful theoretical guidance on the economic
              effects of counterfeiting and piracy, several issues deserve further exploration. We
              highlight three such issues here. First, as we described previously, the presence of
              (non-deceptive) counterfeit goods exerts an externality on consumers of originals.
              In their analysis, Grossman and Shapiro (1988b) assume that this externality is
              negative and takes the form of counterfeits diluting the exclusivity value of status
              goods. This assumption is appropriate for some classes of goods but not for others,
              and survey evidence suggests there is substantial heterogeneity in consumers’
              decisions to purchase counterfeit versus authentic products Wilcox et al. (2009).
              Other types of externalities are conceivable, and it would be important to analyze
              how their presence affects consumers, the strategic reactions of producers, and
              overall welfare.
                 Second, hardly any theoretical study has formally analyzed the short- and long-
              term employment effects of counterfeiting and piracy. It would be especially
              important to obtain conceptual guidance on how the different nature of formal and
              informal labor markets affects the welfare of different types of workers. Such guid-
              ance would seem especially important for developing countries, where informal
              employment often accounts for a larger share of total employment. Developing a
              better understanding of broader labor-market linkages may also be important for
              designing effective IP enforcement policies Fink (2009).
                 Finally, it would be interesting to focus theoretical attention specifically on coun-
              terfeiting and piracy in terms of their potential impacts on technology transfer and
              localized learning. Little is known, for example, about how the enforceability of IPR
              affects relationships between MNEs and local suppliers and distributors. Nor is there

              10                                              The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 much analysis of how piracy and counterfeiting influence global franchising deci-
                 sions, which often embody considerable knowhow regarding market organization.



                 Review of Empirical Evidence
                 Economic theory is helpful for rigorously examining the likely effects of trademark
                 counterfeiting and copyright piracy. However, as we noted previously, some effects
                 are theoretically ambiguous and require empirical investigation. In addition, even
                 when the overall direction of effects is conceptually clear, empirical insights into the
                 scale of effects are needed for policy makers to set priorities for public policy.
                    Notwithstanding the need, generating credible empirical evidence poses a signifi-
                 cant challenge. Counterfeiting and piracy, by their very nature, are illegal activities
                 and thus largely escape official statistical recording. The basis for empirical research
                 is thus weak, and studies must rely on indirect official data, selected information
                 supplied by rights holders, and original surveys to gather evidence. In addition,
                 welfare impacts such as producer and consumer surplus gains or losses are difficult
                 to measure at both the individual and the aggregate societal level. Finally, the
                 limited empirical evidence that is available comes mostly from developed countries.
                 While this evidence can still inform policy makers in developing countries, there are
                 special characteristics of poorer economies that caution against the direct applica-
                 bility of this evidence—notably, different parameters of consumer demand and dif-
                 ferent legal and institutional frameworks.
                    In what follows we critically review relevant empirical studies, and focus on the
                 extent to which the underlying methodologies produce credible results. We begin
                 with a review of aggregate estimates of the level of counterfeiting and piracy. We
                 then examine studies that have evaluated the welfare impact of these activities at
                 the micro level, and review the studies that have specifically focused on the effects of
                 Internet file sharing. We conclude by evaluating the advantages and disadvantages
                 of alternative empirical approaches.


                 Aggregate Estimates of Levels of Counterfeiting and Piracy
                 We begin the review of aggregate estimates by considering efforts to ascertain the
                 incidence of piracy and counterfeiting in international trade. Focusing on trade
                 seems promising, because goods undergo processing when they cross borders. In
                 particular, customs authorities investigate suspected infringements of IP rights,
                 thereby generating indirect data on the incidence of pirated and counterfeit goods
                 in different product categories and for different exporting and importing economies.
                    The most comprehensive study attempting to quantify the importance of coun-
                 terfeit and pirated goods in international trade was conducted by the OECD (2008).

                 Fink et al.                                                                                             11




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
              This study estimated the value of pirated and counterfeit goods in international
              trade at U.S. $200 billion, or approximately 2% of global merchandise trade in
              2005. In an update of this study, the OECD (2009) estimated the value of illicit
              goods in international trade as having grown to $250 billion in 2007 (largely re-
              flecting the growth in worldwide trade). These estimates do not include the value of
              Internet-related piracy of digital goods, which easily cross borders but are almost
              impossible to measure and, in any case, cannot be counted in any merchandise
              trade categories.
                 The OECD (2008) report recognizes that its estimates are only “a crude indicator”
              of the value of counterfeit and pirated products in international trade. This caution
              is warranted. For instance, the OECD estimate employs data on interceptions and
              seizures by customs authorities in selected countries to estimate the proportion
              of counterfeit and pirated goods in different product groups and across exporting
              economies. However, these values only provide information about the relative inci-
              dence of pirated and counterfeit goods across product groups or across exporting
              economies. To arrive at their estimates, OECD staff use a value of the absolute inci-
              dence of counterfeit and pirated goods in one particular “fix-point” product group
              (e.g., apparel, leather articles, tobacco products). The value in question is not based
              on any hard data, but rather seems to reflect the best guess of OECD staff.8
                 Notwithstanding these methodological caveats, the evidence on the relative
              incidence of counterfeit and pirated goods across product groups is insightful. It
              shows, for example, that trade in illicit goods is concentrated in a small number of
              “sensitive” product categories; the top five product groups (at the two-digit Harmonized
              System level) account for more than three-quarters of all customs seizures.

              Industry Studies. Moving beyond trade, a large number of studies—often sponsored
              by affected industries—attempt to quantify the incidence of pirated and counterfeit
              goods at the level of specific sectors and to estimate their effects on certain economic
              performance variables. The methodological approaches and quality of the data in
              these studies vary substantially. A detailed review of each of these studies would go
              beyond the scope of this article, but it is worth highlighting several common issues.
                 First, given the inherent difficulty of accurately measuring the prevailing levels of
              counterfeiting and piracy, the reliability of any underlying estimate is in many cases
              questionable. This difficulty applies to the results of original survey work. For
              example, industry associations in the major copyright-intensive industries publish
              annual surveys of piracy rates in major countries around the world. These question-
              naires may collect useful information about attitudes toward piracy and means of
              unauthorized copying, but the resulting estimates of illegitimate use need to be
              treated with caution.
                 As a specific example, the Business Software Alliance (BSA) released their ninth
              study in May 2012, in which they argued that the global piracy rate for PC software

              12                                              The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 stood at around 42% in 2011, representing more than $60 billion (BSA 2012).
                 This finding came from a study of more than 110 countries, with piracy rates
                 ranging from approximately 19% (United States and Japan) to over 90% (Georgia
                 and Zimbabwe). To compute these rates, the study relied on surveys of sampled con-
                 sumers and businesses in a smaller set of 28 countries to determine the number of
                 computers in use and the share of legitimately procured software.9 The study then
                 estimated piracy rates for countries not in the sample surveys by means of a correla-
                 tion between software usage and an “information development index” published by
                 the International Telecommunications Union. The extent of bias in the estimates for
                 these non-sampled countries arising from both the underlying approach and the
                 application of the index is unknown. Regarding the latter, considerable variation is
                 likely to exist in its applicability to countries of differing economic and social charac-
                 teristics, as is the case for most such “development” indexes.
                    Second, estimates of the economic effects of counterfeiting and piracy often do
                 not account for demand responses—the possibility that not all consumers would
                 switch to the original product if the counterfeit or pirated version were unavailable.
                 Again, the BSA (2010) piracy estimates illustrate this point. Based on estimates of
                 the volume of unlicensed software, the BSA computes its commercial value by
                 applying a vector of prices for various kinds of computer programs including retail,
                 licensed, and open-source. This total value is then taken as a measure of lost sales
                 for legitimate software producers in each country. This approach assumes that each
                 unit of pirated software would be fully replaced by a purchased version if copying
                 were eliminated. That the BSA’s estimates of volumes and values foregone are likely
                 substantially overstated emerges from a recent study estimating demand responses
                 for one popular software product, Microsoft Office. Relying on original conjoint
                 survey data from college students in Hong Kong, Leung (2013) estimated a discrete
                 choice demand system for Microsoft Office from both legal and illegal sources; he
                 concludes that the true gain from eliminating all sources of piracy is only 15% of
                 the BSA’s estimated cost of piracy.
                    Third, the counterfactual market equilibrium analyzed is often not clearly spelled
                 out, nor does it seem realistic. In particular, studies provide estimates of the eco-
                 nomic implications of certain levels of counterfeiting and piracy, and associate those
                 levels with employment and tax losses without considering the longer-term general
                 equilibrium responses outlined previously. Possible employment effects in the infor-
                 mal sector are almost always ignored.10
                    Some studies attempt to consider cross-economy impacts, at least in an input-
                 output framework. Consider, for example, a widely-cited calculation of U.S. copy-
                 right industry sales, employment, and tax revenue losses (see Siwek 2007). The
                 author employed industry-generated measures, such as those from BSA and LEK, of
                 global sales losses in motion pictures, recorded music, software, and video games.
                 Siwek considered the sum of these losses to be an underestimate because not all

                 Fink et al.                                                                                             13




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
              countries are covered in all industry estimates. Making some adjustments for substi-
              tution between pirated and legitimate copies, and valuing all lost sales at legitimate
              prices, the study suggested a direct total loss of $25.6 billion for U.S. industries (in-
              cluding retailers).
                 Siwek (2007) then applied “multipliers” available from the U.S. Department of
              Commerce, derived from its input-output model of the U.S. economy, to determine
              how this lost sales figure translates into total (direct plus indirect) losses in economic
              activity and total employment lost. These basic calculations resulted in a total sales
              loss for the U.S. economy of $58 billion per year, along with 373,000 jobs lost as a
              result of global piracy. All of that translated further into an earnings loss of $16.3
              billion and reduced tax collections of $2.6 billion. These are large figures but must be
              kept in context.
                 Although the multipliers account for cross-industry impacts in a static sense, the
              basic input-output approach again does not consider general-equilibrium linkages
              in the economy. If there really were $25.6 billion in reduced demand for U.S. copy-
              right goods, consumers would focus their expenditures elsewhere in the domestic
              and international economies, while workers would move to alternative employment
              and output and tax payments would rise there. Thus, Siwek’s (2007) study offers
              an assessment of the gross losses in sales and employment but greatly overstates the
              net losses. As we described previously, analysts would need to develop a general-
              equilibrium model for the latter calculations with endogenous changes in sectoral
              demands, output, and trade, while computing earnings losses at the difference
              between with-piracy and without-piracy wage rates.

              The United States International Trade Commission Analysis. Because of the methodo-
              logical shortcomings outlined above, we are skeptical that the results of the studies
              reviewed to this point offer useful guidance to policy makers. A more careful study
              was performed by the United States International Trade Commission (USITC:
              2011); this project focused exclusively on the effects of IPR infringement in China,
              where concerns among major technology, fashion and content creators in the
              United States, the EU, and other rich countries are primarily focused.
                 The USITC’s figures on gross sales lost due to Chinese infringement were taken
              largely from surveys of American firms. These firms claimed sizable damages,
              largely due to copyright piracy and trademark counterfeiting, though issues of in-
              digenous innovation and industrial espionage were also considered. Analysts at the
              USITC applied these reported reductions in demand to their well-regarded computa-
              tional general-equilibrium model. Such models are more flexible and more in-
              formative than simple computations with input-output tables, for they permit
              endogenous responses in prices, outputs, factor use, trade, and product demands.
              At any rate, the USITC model computed losses of nearly one million jobs in the
              United States in the sectors most affected by Chinese infringement. There was,

              14                                              The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 however, considerable uncertainty about this estimate depending on the scenarios
                 considered.
                    After having conducted this review, we observe that capturing the impacts of
                 global infringement of IPR is a complex and uncertain problem that could use far
                 more analytical and data attention. Moreover, there are no reliable computational
                 general-equilibrium studies on how infringement affects the economies of develop-
                 ing countries.11 This is not to say that the economy-wide effects are negligible and
                 do not deserve the attention of policy makers in both developed and developing
                 countries. We merely emphasize the challenge those policy makers face in address-
                 ing counterfeiting and piracy problems with limited empirical guidance on offer.


                 Micro-data Studies on the Effects of Counterfeiting and Piracy
                 Although obtaining aggregate estimates of the levels of counterfeiting and piracy is
                 important for understanding the scale of the problem, effective policy cannot be
                 devised without considering the micro level of firms and consumers.


                 Marketing Analyses and Consumer Surveys. Several marketing studies have been con-
                 ducted to help understand consumer psychology and behavior that characterize the
                 demand-side origin of counterfeiting. Although many of these are surveys or case
                 studies, a few are experiments. Generally, experiments—whether in the field or in
                 the lab—generate more credible evidence, but they also face methodological limita-
                 tions. Field experiments that randomly assign people to control and treatment
                 groups potentially have higher external validity because participants are real-world
                 consumers making statements or decisions about the products of interest in (close
                 to) real-world settings. However, compared with a lab experiment, in a field study it
                 is more difficult to avoid interferences among participants and to exert tight control
                 over the randomized treatment manipulations. Field experiments therefore generate
                 results that are more susceptible to these “internal validity” concerns.
                    As an early study in this literature strand, Bloch et al. (1993) examined the
                 consumer’s role as an “accomplice” in the proliferation of product counterfeiting.
                 These authors presented results from a field experiment showing that a surprisingly
                 large proportion of adult consumers will select a counterfeit garment over the
                 genuine good when there is a price advantage. The researchers also found that a
                 significant price gap and negative attitudes toward large branded companies were
                 the main factors driving counterfeit demand.
                    In more recent work, Wilcox et al. (2009) conducted lab experiments and found
                 that products with branded logos were more likely to be valued for their ability to
                 help consumers gain social approval and status. In turn, this characteristic makes
                 consumers more willing to buy such products from counterfeiters.12

                 Fink et al.                                                                                             15




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 Looking further into the determinants of why consumers purchase non-deceptive
              counterfeit products, Vida (2007) reports on a consumer survey conducted in
              Slovenia. The results suggested that personal religiosity and education tend to
              reduce one’s willingness to buy fake goods. Such was not the case in Kwong et al.
              (2003), who studied consumer attitudes toward pirated CDs in Hong Kong. These
              researchers found that approximately 70% of the respondents stated that they
              bought pirated CDs and that they thought this generated high social benefit and
              low social cost. However, both studies concluded that gender matters, in that men
              are more willing to buy counterfeits than women. Bian and Veloutsou (2008) sur-
              veyed consumers in China and the United Kingdom, and found that perceived finan-
              cial, physical, and performance risks from consuming counterfeits were moderate.
              Still, consumer willingness to buy fakes varied with each product and each country,
              which makes it difficult to draw general conclusions.
                 Finally, Casola et al. (2008) conducted three studies of consumer behavior in
              hypothetical situations. All three studies revealed that consumers were less willing
              to buy counterfeits when the victim was an individual rather than an organization.
              The average consumer would buy fakes if they cost about one-third of the genuine
              price. Finally, consumers’ willingness to buy counterfeit goods decreased if they
              were informed of the harmful impacts imposed on others. Thus, spreading aware-
              ness about the negative consequences of counterfeiting may be effective at deterring
              demand.


              Field Studies. Overall, studying consumer psychology is perhaps more useful for un-
              derstanding why there is a demand for counterfeits than for estimating the econom-
              ic impacts of counterfeiting. For the latter, it is more fruitful to collect field data over
              time to generate a sample panel on actual branded firms and their infringers. This
              is a challenging task because of the illicit nature of counterfeiting and the confiden-
              tiality concerns of both genuine and infringing companies. Nonetheless, a series of
              recent studies have been carried out in this direction.
                  Qian (2008) offers the most comprehensive empirical investigation on the eco-
              nomic impacts of counterfeits. This study also stands out in that it is one of a rela-
              tively few studies that focus on a developing country. Qian collected original panel
              data from Chinese shoe companies from 1993 to 2004 (after government enforce-
              ment efforts were reduced in the footwear sector) through stratified random sam-
              pling to identify and measure the effects of competition from counterfeit goods on
              the prices, qualities, and other market outcomes of authentic footwear. The results
              show that brands experiencing less government enforcement action differentiated
              their products by introducing higher visible quality. These brands also engaged in
              forms of self-enforcement by establishing vertical relationships with licensed down-
              stream retailers (“company stores”) to control their sales, and setting higher prices

              16                                              The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 to signal their legitimacy in the marketplace. All these reactions helped reduce
                 counterfeit sales in the period studied.
                    It should be clearly noted that all the innovation and differentiation strategies
                 mentioned above are costly. Although the authentic prices dropped initially under
                 competitive pressure from counterfeits, the long-term effects on driving up authen-
                 tic-product prices kicked in at various times for different firms. Larger firms with
                 more human capital and research-and-development resources were faster in re-
                 sponding and differentiating their products from counterfeits. Firms with more
                 exports responded slower, perhaps because they were more diversified and less influ-
                 enced by domestic counterfeits (Qian and Xie 2010).
                    Field panel data of the kind used in the Chinese footwear study provide direct
                 measures of how various economic variables change over time within each brand,
                 but there are limitations that mean the results should be treated with caution. For
                 example, even when field panel data are available for estimating how economic per-
                 formance changes in response to counterfeiting, the underlying mechanism may be
                 difficult to identify. Qian (2014b) explored the sales impacts of counterfeiting based
                 on a combination of field data and lab experiments, and found that counterfeits
                 have both a positive advertising effect (inducing more awareness of the brand) and
                 a negative substitution effect on authentic products (reducing their sales). The ad-
                 vertising effect dominates the substitution effect for high-end authentic product
                 sales, and the substitution effect outweighs the advertising effect for low-end
                 product sales. The advertising effect is found to be larger for fashion products and
                 for brands that were less well-known at the time of infringement. Another impor-
                 tant observation about consumer attitudes toward counterfeiting is that a high
                 degree of income inequality seems to cause a greater demand for fake goods (Qian
                 and Rucker 2013).
                    Finally, several micro-data studies examine the economic effects of copyright
                 piracy Notably, Hui and Png (2003) estimated the effects of physical CD piracy on the
                 legitimate demand for recorded music in an econometric setting. These authors’
                 model expressly accounts for the demand linkages outlined in the previous section
                 (sales of pirated copies could stimulate more demand for originals). Their econometric
                 results showed that piracy had a negative net effect on the demand for legitimate
                 music, though Hui and Png’s estimate of foregone sales by copyright holders was
                 58% lower than the music industry’s estimate (see International Federation of the
                 Phonographic Industry 2003). The latter assumed a one-to-one substitution of
                 pirated with legitimate purchases, whereas Hui and Png’s model allowed for a share
                 of price-sensitive consumers to choose not to switch to legitimate goods in the coun-
                 terfactual scenario. The Hui and Png analysis is limited, however, by an assumption
                 that copyright holders do not adjust prices in response to lower piracy.
                    That demand is responsive to prices charged for pirated and original copies also
                 emerges from an experimental study of the music consumption behavior of

                 Fink et al.                                                                                             17




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
              university students. Maffioletti and Ramello (2004) found that in general, students’
              willingness to pay for a CD is lower than the market price of a legitimate copy. Thus,
              the hypothetical elimination of piracy would not expand sales of legitimate copies
              on a one-to-one basis at existing prices. At the same time, the study reveals that stu-
              dents’ willingness to pay for a pirated CD was substantially greater than its margin-
              al cost. This finding clearly points to the possibility that copyright holders might
              respond to stronger copyright enforcement by lowering their prices to capture a
              larger number of consumers.13


              The Effects of File Sharing on the Internet
              One of the most frequently studied aspects of copyright infringement is how unau-
              thorized downloading and file sharing have affected sales of recorded music offered
              by major music publishers. It should be noted that this “end-user piracy” is some-
              times different in intent from commercial piracy. In particular, many people who
              download music for free and put music files on their computers in forms that can be
              readily shared by others rarely attempt to make money from these actions.
                  Furthermore, some surveys suggest that many such users see little wrong with
              freely taking and sharing digital information products. For example, a recent survey
              of 1,607 people in the United Kingdom found that more than 80% admitted to
              having downloaded at least one file without authorization, and 47% said they did
              not think it was a crime (Bonnett 2010). In a survey of 1,000 U.S. college students
              in 2003, 69% said they had downloaded music, and 75% of those indicated they
              never paid for it (IPSOS Public Affairs 2003). Moreover, 76% responded that they
              would download even if they suspected the music file was illegal. These perceptions
              are among the reasons this form of unauthorized use is exceptionally difficult to
              control by copyright owners.
                  Regardless of the motivation, downloading and file sharing through peer-to-peer
              (P2P) networks is common. The OECD (2005) calculated that one-third of Internet
              users in its member nations have downloaded files from P2P networks. Regarding
              the effects of downloading and file sharing, U.S. shipments of recorded music on
              CDs fell by 25% between 2000 and 2005 (Recording Industry Association of
              America 2006), and representatives of the music publishers blamed this trend on
              illegal downloads and P2P file sharing. Most recently, a global music industry asso-
              ciation noted a 7% drop in music sales in 2009, though it was unclear how much
              was due to unauthorized activity (International Federation of the Phonographic
              Industry 2010). That report claims that P2P piracy accounted for more than 20%
              of global Internet traffic, with higher shares in Latin America and Europe.
                  This proliferation of file sharing has negatively affected authorized music sales.
              For example, Rob and Waldfogel (2006) collected data on albums obtained through
              downloading or purchase and used surveys among students at the University of

              18                                              The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 Pennsylvania to measure their valuation of this music. Using changes in Internet
                 access as an instrumental variable, they found that downloading reduced the per-
                 capita student expenditure on hit albums from 1999 to 2003 from $126 to $100,
                 though it raised per-student welfare by $70.
                    The most widely debated analysis surrounds the work of Oberholzer-Gee and
                 Strumpf (2007), who suggest that downloading could, in theory, increase or
                 decrease album sales due to the peering effects we outlined previously. These
                 authors regressed the volume of sales by album on the number of downloads of
                 songs on the album and other factors. To control for a possible simultaneity bias,
                 they used as a primary instrumental variable the number of German secondary
                 school children on holiday when they had more time to wait for downloads. Their
                 results were striking; in a basic ordinary least squares regression, the coefficient of
                 sales on downloads was 1.09 and highly significant, suggesting a large positive
                 impact. However, after adding album fixed effects and first-stage instrumentation,
                 they could find no evidence that the number of times an album was downloaded
                 had a statistical impact on music sales, while the implied economic effects were
                 small.
                    This finding has been criticized on several grounds, primarily by Liebowitz
                 (2005; 2006; 2007). In their more recent study, Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf
                 (2010) acknowledged that file sharing has reduced music sales, but by more
                 modest amounts than generally supposed. Furthermore, they argue that offsetting
                 increases in demand for complementary music services have increased incentives
                 for the creation of new music, books, and movies. In other words, file sharing may
                 be damaging to music publishers but not necessarily to artists themselves, especial-
                 ly those who are younger and less well-known. However, this possibility deserves
                 further study. Unfortunately, empirical studies on the effects of copyright piracy—
                 whether physical or online—are almost exclusively confined to developed countries.
                 To a good extent, this reflects the availability of data and the “home bias” of re-
                 searchers in developed economies. However, there are reasons to believe that copy-
                 right piracy is more widespread in poorer countries. For example, across a wide
                 range of countries, Fink (2009) reported a correlation coefficient between software
                 piracy rates and per capita GDP in 2004 of 2 0.89. This likely reflects poorer
                 consumers turning more frequently to pirated goods, the greater importance of the
                 informal economy as a source of employment, and less developed and more
                 resource-constrained legal systems.
                    Copyright-based industries exist in most developing countries. In some—such as
                 the Philippines, Malaysia, and Mexico—these industries account for larger employ-
                 ment shares than in developed economies.14 Copyright piracy is bound to affect the
                 prospects of earning a livelihood from creative and artistic activities in poorer coun-
                 tries. One study on the music industry in West Africa reported anecdotal evidence
                 confirming both the high incidence of piracy and its negative effect on musicians’

                 Fink et al.                                                                                             19




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
              incomes (Penna et al 2004). However, this study also pointed to a large number of
              other barriers—from ineffective collection societies to tax policies—that render the
              recording activities unprofitable for most musicians. How a reduction in piracy
              levels alone would affect artists and those involved in the distribution of creative
              works remains an open question.

              Conclusions
              We conclude this review with some observations on what the literature suggests
              about the importance of policy initiatives for dealing with counterfeiting and piracy
              in developing nations. We then discuss the need for further work to improve data
              collection and analysis.

              Implications for Policymaking in Developing Countries. As we have noted, most of the
              studies we reviewed above offer evidence about the impacts of counterfeiting and
              piracy in more developed economies, with the notable exception of Qian (2008;
              2014b). Thus, readers may question their applicability to developing countries and
              policy authorities. Indeed, there are important differences to note. First, the classic
              “intellectual property industries” (high-end fashion, digital content, publishing,
              software, and research-based pharmaceuticals, food products, and plant varieties)
              play a smaller role in the production structures of poor countries. Rather, local
              firms may be more focused on imitation and copying, while consumers may be
              more open to buying fake goods. In this context, the immediate gains from stronger
              IPR enforcement are likely to accrue to foreign content providers and multinational
              enterprises, most of which develop the bulk of their intellectual property in rich
              economies. It is thus not surprising that many developing countries face demands
              for more stringent IP enforcement in bilateral and regional free trade agreements
              they negotiate with developed countries.15 Notwithstanding the broader welfare
              gains that such agreements could offer, policymakers in developing countries rea-
              sonably wonder whether it makes sense to devote scarce development resources to
              IPR enforcement.
                 However, it is important to point out that there is considerable and growing
              heterogeneity among developing countries. Rapidly emerging economies such as
              Brazil, Mexico, China, and Turkey see increasing interest among growing middle
              classes for higher quality goods protected by recognizable brands. There is also a
              rapid trend among innovative local firms toward brand development, investments
              in product variety and quality, and R&D expenditures in numerous industries,
              including software and digital content (Maskus 2012). In this regard, domestic
              interests in stronger IPR protection and enforcement are rapidly emerging and chal-
              lenging the political-economy equilibrium that favors weaker enforcement. These
              countries presumably can learn from the experience of developed countries.

              20                                              The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                    Second, even poorer countries have significant interests in stronger enforcement
                 for at least two reasons. One is that their citizens disproportionately suffer from adul-
                 terated counterfeit medicines and ineffective or dangerous foods and beverages. Basic
                 calculations suggest that this can be a major problem for sustaining public health in
                 poor countries and that there is a positive payoff from working to reduce such risks
                 (Maskus 2007). Another reason is that weak trademark enforcement can sharply
                 diminish prospects for effective brand development, firm entry, and national market-
                 ing success among potentially innovative companies in poor countries. Indeed, local
                 counterfeiting often targets domestic enterprises at least as much as foreign brands
                 (Mertha 2005). Similarly, extensive unauthorized copying of music, designs, and
                 other creative activities limits opportunities for artists and artisans to build local
                 markets, ultimately harming their ability to sell globally as well. Thus, public invest-
                 ments in enforcement and creative infrastructures, perhaps in partnership with
                 private entities, could help remove such barriers to entry. As a strategic matter, invari-
                 ably scarce enforcement resources could focus on reducing deceptive counterfeiting
                 (to deal with dangerous fakes) and educational campaigns on expanding consumer
                 awareness of how unauthorized copying negatively affects local artists.


                 Recommendations for Data Collection and Future Empirical Work. Policy makers in
                 countries at different stages of development are interested in better understanding
                 the economic effects of trademark counterfeiting and copyright piracy. So what di-
                 rection should future analytical work take? As discussed previously, many studies
                 exist that aim to quantify the extent of counterfeiting or piracy at the aggregate
                 level, be it sectoral or economy-wide. Most of these studies have serious shortcom-
                 ings, both in the data employed and in the adopted methodologies. More important,
                 aggregate estimates of the incidence of piracy and counterfeiting by themselves
                 offer policy makers little guidance on appropriate IP enforcement policies.
                     More useful guidance emerges from micro studies that take into account the spe-
                 cific characteristics of different industries and comprehensively assess the effects of
                 illicit activities on prices, consumer demand, company revenues, innovative behav-
                 ior, and overall welfare. Such studies are still scarce. Finding reliable and representa-
                 tive data is challenging and creative approaches are needed to establish causality
                 and derive credible estimates. Experimental studies offer one way forward, particu-
                 larly in combination with broader empirical investigations. For example, research-
                 ers could gather field panel data to analyze the overall impacts of counterfeiting,
                 and supplement them with lab experiments to understand the underlying mecha-
                 nisms (see Qian 2014a; Qian and Rucker 2013).
                     The quality of any future empirical work will largely depend on the quality of the
                 underlying data, however. Given the illegal nature of counterfeiting and piracy, col-
                 lecting representative and systematic data on all relevant economic variables will

                 Fink et al.                                                                                             21




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
              continue to be a challenge, and progress will only be gradual. Nonetheless, several
              promising avenues exist.
                 For example, more could be done to improve and harmonize data collection in
              the course of IP enforcement activities. Customs statistics are an obvious place to
              start because they are generally the most direct source of information about the
              extent of piracy and counterfeiting flows that cross international borders. Many
              customs offices already compile and publish data on seizures of counterfeit and
              pirated goods. Although the World Customs Organization has developed interna-
              tional guidelines for reporting on seized products, actual reporting practices differ
              substantially across countries. For example, some countries report the number of
              seizures, whereas others focus on the quantity of seized goods, or the number of
              consignments. Substantial differences also exist regarding the valuation of seized
              goods (World Customs Organization 2009).
                 From an analytical point of view, it would be important to achieve as much consis-
              tency as possible in the treatment of firms, products, and sectors. Data collection needs
              to be done consistently over time to track trends and analyze the impacts of changes in
              enforcement policy. Sampling interceptions data could be extended to detailed subcate-
              gories of goods to gain a better understanding of the scope of counterfeit trade.
                 Beyond customs statistics, there is scope for collecting more comprehensive data
              associated with domestic law enforcement activities, notably through the judicial
              system. To our knowledge, no systemic effort exists at the international level to
              promote and harmonize the collection of such data. Intergovernmental organiza-
              tions can play a more active role in coordinating data collection initiatives, promot-
              ing the harmonization of reporting standards, and offering technical assistance to
              developing country governments.
                 At the domestic level, governments may want to consider adopting an impact
              evaluation framework, especially when new IP enforcement policies and measures are
              introduced. Continuous data gathering would be an essential component of such a
              framework. Finding appropriate control groups against which enforcement activities
              could be evaluated may prove challenging but is possible in certain circumstances—
              especially when new initiatives are first implemented on a pilot basis.
                 In addition, there is scope for conducting original surveys to support targeted ana-
              lytical work. Surveys of rights holders on key performance characteristics as they
              relate to counterfeiting activity could usefully complement firm-level data available
              through industry or official sources. Depending on the industry, rights holders may
              also possess valuable information on the nature of, and markets for, counterfeit and
              pirated goods that was gathered in the course of their own market intelligence
              and enforcement activities. Surveys of rights holders could take place within existing
              cooperation programs between the public and private sectors. Such firm surveys
              should be designed to collect as detailed and comprehensive data as possible while



              22                                              The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 guaranteeing the anonymity of respondents when submitting sensitive business
                 information.16
                     In the longer term, as information from these surveys—especially across countries—
                 becomes more standardized and comprehensive, econometric models could be de-
                 veloped to estimate important market parameters about which limited information
                 exists. Most prominently, the demand characteristics and substitution parameters
                 between legitimate goods and counterfeit goods are important to estimate to gain
                 an accurate picture of damages imposed on rights holders and the associated effects
                 on employment and research-and-development spending. Such estimates need to
                 be subjected to significant sensitivity and robustness analysis to ensure that they
                 can be deployed with confidence.
                     After these parameters are estimated, it would be feasible to develop computational
                 general equilibrium models to assess the country-specific and international impacts
                 of counterfeiting and piracy, particularly accounting for cross-industry effects and em-
                 ployment channels. Models of this sort would be particularly useful for assessing the
                 potential impacts of additional policy efforts to counteract illicit trade and production.
                 It is important to emphasize, however, that such models necessarily rely on strong as-
                 sumptions that could be misleading in this context. For example, employment in the
                 counterfeiting and piracy sector is largely informal, and few models can manage the
                 linkages between informal sector and formal sector employment. Still, with appropri-
                 ate caveats, these models should be an improvement over existing estimates of
                 economy-wide losses in employment and tax revenues because those estimates do
                 not account for aggregate relationships in the economy.




                 Notes
                 Carsten Fink is the Chief Economist, World Intellectual Property Organization; carsten.fink@wipo.int.
                 Keith Maskus is a Professor of Economics, University of Colorado Boulder. Yi Qian is an Associate
                 Professor of Marketing and Behavioral Science, Sauder School of Business, University of British
                 Columbia. The authors contributed equally and are listed in alphabetical order. Helpful comments
                 from Intan Hamdan-Livramento, Sacha Wunsch-Vincent, and two anonymous referees are gratefully
                 acknowledged. The opinions expressed herein are those of the authors and should not be attributed to
                 any of the institutions with which they are affiliated.
                    1. The literature on counterfeiting and piracy is large and cannot be fully reviewed here. Instead,
                 we focus on widely-cited studies of counterfeiting and piracy and offer an overview of the various ap-
                 proaches that researchers have adopted.
                    2. See, for example, Newton et al. (2010). Counterfeit drugs are part of the broader challenge of
                 substandard pharmaceuticals, which also extends to generic medicines.
                    3. Taylor (1993) analyzed such “masking” strategies, which are costly in welfare terms. Again,
                 Maskus (2000; 2012) offers anecdotal evidence of such responses in developing countries.
                    4. Copyright protection is limited to strike a balance between incentives for creating new works
                 and the desirability of making them widely available. Thus, copyright has a limited term and certain


                 Fink et al.                                                                                             23




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
              exceptions and limitations to exclusive rights exist in areas in which society reaps special benefits from
              the rapid dissemination of creative works.
                  5. Maskus (2000) relates anecdotal evidence that this price moderation occurred in the software
              industry when Taiwan improved its enforcement activities in the 1990s.
                  6. Conner (1995) offers a broader set of circumstances in which it might be profitable for copyright
              owners to accommodate copying in the presence of network effects and quality differences.
                  7. Maskus (2012) offers a full review, while Arora et al. (2001) set out comprehensive models.
                  8. Another problem is that the analysis takes place at the highly aggregated two-digit Harmonized
              System categorization of traded goods. Within each such category, typically hundreds of goods subcate-
              gories may or may not be subject to much counterfeiting. The OECD (2008) analysis assumes that its
              average rates computed at the aggregate level apply to each subcategory. This list of methodological
              problems is not exhaustive. The OECD (2008) report describes several other important problems that
              likely bias the resulting estimates.
                  9. The difference between the total installed software and legitimately purchased software is the
              amount of piracy. Although this approach is sensible in that it relies on reported measures of legitimate
              usage in relation to overall computer capacity, both of which may be reliable, the BSA report does not
              indicate what the underlying sampling biases may be. This approach also ascribes some use of open-
              source software and freeware to piracy.
                  10. See, for example, Siwek (2007) and Frontier Economics (2009). The latter study considers the
              reemployment of workers “losing” their jobs as a result of counterfeiting and piracy but does not con-
              sider the effects of revenue-compensating tax policies. In addition, the assumption of a certain share of
              workers not finding reemployment implicitly assumes some form of historical shock that led to actual
              job losses. The latter assumption is difficult to reconcile with the more gradual evolution of counterfeit-
              ing and piracy activity observed in most sectors.
                  11. Maskus (2005) offers a simple partial-equilibrium model of the effects on employment and
              sales in several key sectors in Lebanon, using data for 1996. However, this approach cannot determine
              cross-industry equilibrium impacts and is only suggestive at best.
                  12. Bian and Moutinho (2009) find a similar result from surveying consumer attitudes in
              Scotland toward buying fake luxury watches.
                  13. This outcome was noted in survey evidence of the pricing strategy of legitimate software
              producers in Asian countries as copyright enforcement improved (Maskus 2000).
                  14. See WIPO (2013).
                  15. See Fink (2013) for a discussion of how trade agreements treat intellectual property rights and
              how they may affect economic welfare.
                  16. There are also recent attempts to employ surveys to estimate the incidence and characteristics
              of counterfeit and substandard drugs. For example, Bate et al. (forthcoming) studied 1,437 samples
              of Ciprofloxacin in 18 low-to-middle-income countries. These authors found that 9.88% of
              samples contained less than 80% of the correct active ingredient, and 41.5% of these failures are coun-
              terfeits. Counterfeit and substandard drugs tend to differ in two observable attributes: first, counterfeit
              drugs are more likely to mimic drugs registered with local drug safety regulators than substandard
              drugs. Second, after controlling for other factors, substandard drugs are on average cheaper than
              generics, whereas counterfeit drugs do not show any significant price difference.




              References
              Aghion, P., N. Bloom, R. Blundell, R. Griffith, and P . Howitt. 2005. “Competition and Innovation: An
                Inverted-U Relationship.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 120 (2): 701–28.
              Akerlof, G. A. 1970. “The Market for ‘Lemons’: Qualitative Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.”
                Quarterly Journal of Economics 84 (3): 488 –500.


              24                                              The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 Anderson, E. T., Y. Qian, and D. Simester. 2010. “Spillover Effects of a Low-quality Entrant.”
                   Northwestern University and Massachusetts Institute of Technology Working Paper.
                 Arora, A., A. Fosfuri, and A. Gambardella. 2001. Markets for Technology: The Economics of Innovation
                    and Corporate Strategy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
                 Bakos, Y., E. Brynjolfsson, and D. G. Lichtman. 1999. “Shared Information Goods.” Journal of Law and
                    Economics 42 (1): 117 –55.
                 Bate, R., G. Jin, and A. Mathur. “Falsified or Substandard? Assessing Price and Non-Price Signals of
                    Drug Quality.” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy. In press.
                 Besen, S. M., and S. N. Kirby. 1989. “Private Copying, Appropriability, and Optimal Copying
                    Royalties.” Journal of Law and Economics 32 (2): 255–80.
                 Bhattacharjee, S., R. D. Gopal, K. Lertwachara, and J. R. Marsden. 2007. “The Effect of P2P File-
                   Sharing on Music Markets: A Survival Analysis of Albums on Ranking Charts.” Management
                   Science 53 (9): 1359– 74.
                 Bian, X., and L. Moutinho. 2009. “An Investigation of Determinants of Counterfeit Purchase
                    Consideration.” Journal of Business Research 62 (3): 368–79.
                 Bian, X., L. Moutinho, and C. Veloutsou. 2008. “A Cross-National Examination of Consumer
                    Perceived Risk in the Context of Non-Deceptive Counterfeit Brands.” Journal of Consumer Behaviour
                    7 (1): 3–20.
                 Blackburn, D. 2004. “Does File Sharing Affect Record Sales?” Working paper, Department of
                    Economics, Harvard University.
                 Bloch, P. H., R. F. Bush, and L. Campbell. (1993). “Consumer ‘Accomplices’ in Product Counterfeiting:
                    A Demand Side Investigation.” Journal of Consumer Marketing 10 (4): 27 –36.
                 Bonnett, T. (2010). “Four in Five People Download Illegally.” Sky News Online, March 19. Available at
                   http://news.sky.com/home/technology/article/15576542.
                 Branstetter, L., R. Fisman, and C. F. Foley. 2006. “Do Stronger Intellectual Property Rights Increase
                    International Technology Transfer?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 121 (1): 321– 49.
                 Business Software Alliance (BSA). 2012. “2011 BSA Global Software Piracy Study.” May. Available at
                   http://globalstudy.bsa.org/2011/downloads/study_pdf/2011_BSA_Piracy_Study-Standard.pdf.
                 Burnkrant, R. E., and A. Cousineau. 1975. “Informational and Normative Social Influence in Buyer
                   Behavior.” Journal of Consumer Research 2 (3): 206 –14.
                 Casola, L., S. Kemp, and A. Mackenzie. 2008. “Consumer Decisions in the Black Market for Stolen or
                    Counterfeit Goods.” Journal of Economic Psychology 30 (2): 162–71.
                 Conner, K. R. 1995. “Obtaining Strategic Advantage from Being Imitated: When Can Encouraging
                   ‘Clones’ Pay?” Management Science 41 (2): 209– 25.
                 Conner, K. R., and R. P. Rumelt. 1991. “Software Piracy: An Analysis of Protection Strategies.”
                   Management Science 37 (2): 125 –39.
                 Fink, C. 2009. “Enforcing Intellectual Property Rights: An Economic Perspective.” World Intellectual
                    Property Organization WIPO/ACE/5/6, August 26. Available at http://www.wipo.int/edocs/mdocs/
                    enforcement/en/wipo_ace_5/wipo_ace_5_6.pdf.
                 Fink, C. 2013. “Intellectual Property Rights: Economic Principles and Trade Rules.” In A. Lukauskas,
                    R. M. Stern, and G. Zanini, eds., Handbook of Trade Policy for Development. Oxford: Oxford University
                    Press.
                 Frontier Economics. 2009. “The Impact of Counterfeiting on Governments and Consumers.”
                    Report commissioned by BASCAP. May. Available at http://www.icc.se/policy/statements/2009/
                    BASCAP .pdf.


                 Fink et al.                                                                                             25




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
              Grossman, G. M., and C. Shapiro. 1988a. “Counterfeit-Product Trade.” American Economic Review 78
                 (1): 59 –75.
                       . 1988b. “Foreign Counterfeiting of Status Goods.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 103 (1):
                   79 –100.
              Harbaugh, R., and R. Khemka. 2010. “Does Copyright Enforcement Encourage Piracy?” Journal of
                Industrial Economics 58 (2): 306 –23.
              Hui, K.-L., and I. Png. 2003. “Piracy and the Legitimate Demand for Recorded Music.” Contributions to
                Economic Analysis and Policy 2 (1): Article 11.
              International Federation of the Phonographic Industry. 2003. The Recording Industry Commercial Piracy
                 Report 2003. Available at http://www.ifpi.org/content/library/Piracy2003.pdf.
                       . 2010. Recording Industries in Numbers 2010. Available at http://www.ifpi.org/content/
                   section_news/20100428.html.
              IPSOS Public Affairs. 2003. Internet Piracy on Campus. Research report.
              Javorcik, B. S. 2004. “The Composition of Foreign Direct Investment and Protection of Intellectual
                 Property Rights: Evidence from Transition Economies.” European Economic Review 48 (1): 39– 62.
              Johnson, W. R. 1985. “The Economics of Copying.” Journal of Political Economy 93 (1): 158–74.
              Keller, W. 2004. “International Diffusion of Technology.” Journal of Economic Literature 42 (3):
                 752 –82.
              Kwong, K., O. H. M. Yau, J. S. Lee, L. Y. M. Sin, and A. C. B. Tse. 2003. “The Effects of Attitudinal and
                Demographic Factors on Intention to Buy Pirated CDs: The Case of Chinese Consumers.” Journal of
                Business Ethics 47 (3): 223– 35.
              Consulting, L. E. K. 2005. The Cost of Movie Piracy: An Analysis Prepared by LEK for the Motion Picture
                Association. Available at http://www.archive.org/details/MpaaPiracyReort.
              Leung, T. C. 2013. “What is the True Loss Due to Piracy? Evidence from Microsoft Office in Hong
                 Kong.” Review of Economics and Statistics 95 (3): 1018–29.
              Liebowitz, S. J. 1985. “Copying and Indirect Appropriability: Photocopying of Journals.” Journal of
                 Political Economy 93 (5): 945 –57.
                       2005. “Pitfalls in Measuring the Impact of File-Sharing on the Sound Recording Market.”
                   CESIfo Economic Studies 51 (2 –3): 435–73.
              Liu, K., J.-A. Li, Y. Wu, and K. K. Lai. 2005. “Analysis of Monitoring and Limiting of Commercial
                 Cheating: A Newsvendor Model.” Journal of the Operational Research Society 56 (7): 844–54.
              Maffioletti, A., and G. B. Ramello. 2004. “Should We Put Them in Jail? Copyright Infringement,
                Penalties and Consumer Behaviour: Insights from Experimental Data.” Review of Economic Research
                on Copyright Issues 1 (2): 81 – 95.
              Markusen, J. R. 2001. “Contracts, Intellectual Property Rights, and Multinational Investment in
                Developing Countries.” Journal of International Economics 53 (1): 189– 204.
              Maskus, K. E. 2000. Intellectual Property Rights in the Global Economy. Washington DC: Institute for
                International Economics.
                       . 2005. “Strengthening Intellectual Property Rights in Lebanon.” In C. Fink, and K. E. Maskus,
                   eds., Intellectual Property and Development: Lessons from Recent Economic Research. New York: World
                   Bank and Oxford University Press.
                       . 2007. “Lack of Intellectual Property Rights.” In B. Lomborg, ed., Solutions for the World’s
                   Biggest Problems: Costs and Benefits. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
                      . 2012. Private Rights and Public Problems: The Global Economics of Intellectual Property in the
                   21st Century. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.


              26                                              The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
                 Maskus, K. E., and M. Penubarti. 1995. “How Trade-Related are Intellectual Property Rights?” Journal
                   of International Economics 39 (3/4): 227 –48.
                 Mertha, A. C. 2005. The Politics of Piracy: Intellectual Property in Contemporary China. Ithaca, NY:
                   Cornell University Press.
                 Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer Studios Inc., et al. v. Grokster, Ltd. et al. 2005. 545 U.S. 913. Available at
                   http://w2.eff.org/IP/P2P/MGM_v_Grokster/04-480.pdf.
                 Newton, P. N., M. D. Green, and F. M. Ferna ´ ndez. 2010. “Impact of Poor-Quality Medicines in the
                   ‘Developing’ World.” Trends in Pharmacological Sciences 31 (3–3): 99 –101.
                 Oberholzer-Gee, F., and K. Strumpf. 2007. “The Effect of File-Sharing on Record Sales: An Empirical
                   Analysis.” Journal of Political Economy 115 (1): 1– 42.
                        . 2010. “File-Sharing and Copyright.” Working paper, Harvard Business School, Harvard
                     University.
                 Organisation for Co-operation and Economic Development. 2005. OECD Report on Digital Music:
                    Opportunities and Challenges. Paris: OECD. Available at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/13/2/
                    34995041.pdf.
                         . 2008. The Economic Impact of Counterfeiting and Piracy. Paris: OECD. Available at http://www.
                     oecd.org/document/4/0,3343,en_2649_34173_40876868_1_1_1_1,00.html.
                         . 2009. “Magnitude of Counterfeiting and Piracy of Tangible Products: An Update.” Research
                     report. Available at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/57/27/44088872.pdf.
                 Peitz, M., and P. Waelbroeck. 2004. “The Effect of Internet Piracy on Music Sales: Cross-Section
                    Evidence.” Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues 1 (2): 71 –79.
                 Penna, F. J., M. Thormann, and J. M. Finger. 2004. “The Africa Music Project.” In J. M. Finger, and P     .
                    Schuler, eds., Poor People’s Knowledge: Promoting Intellectual Property in Developing Countries. Oxford:
                    Oxford University Press.
                 Qian, Y. 2008. “Impacts of Entry by Counterfeiters.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 (4):
                    1577–1609.
                        2014a. “Brand Management and Strategies against Counterfeits.” Journal of Economics and
                     Management Strategy 23 (2): 317 –343.
                          2014b. “Counterfeiters: Foes or Friends? How Counterfeits Affect Sales by Product Quality
                     Tier.” Management Science 60 (10): 2381–2400.
                 Qian, Y., Q. Gong, and Y. Chen. 2013. “Untangling Searchable and Experiential Quality Responses to
                    Counterfeiting.” Working paper, Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University.
                 Qian, Y., and D. Rucker. 2010. “Income Inequality and Counterfeiting.” Working paper, Kellogg
                    School of Management, Northwestern University.
                 Qian, Y., and H. Xie. 2010. “Bayesian SEM with Random Changepoints in Analyzing the Timing
                    of Responses to Counterfeits.” Working paper, Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern
                    University.
                 Recording Industry Association of America. 2006. “The Recording Industry Association of America’s
                    2005 Year-end Statistics.” Available at http://www.riaa.com.
                 Rob, R., and J. Waldfogel. 2006. “Piracy on the High C’s: Music Downloading, Sales Displacement, and
                   Social Welfare in a Sample of College Students.” Journal of Law and Economics 49 (1): 29 – 62.
                 Scherer, F. M. 1967. “Market Structure and the Employment of Scientists and Engineers.” American
                    Economic Review 57 (3): 524 –31.
                 Siwek, S. E. 2007. “The True Cost of Copyright Industry Piracy to the U.S. Economy.” Institute for
                    Policy Innovation Policy Report #189.


                 Fink et al.                                                                                             27




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017
              Sun, J., L. Debo, S. Kekre, and J. Sun. 2010. “Component-based Technology Transfer in the Presence of
                Potential Imitators.” Management Science 56 (3): 536–52.
              Takeyama, L. N. 1994. “The Welfare Implications of Unauthorized Reproduction of Intellectual
                 Property in the Presence of Demand Network Externalities.” Journal of Industrial Economics 42 (2):
                 155 –66.
              Takayama, L. N. 1997. “The Intertemporal Consequences of Unauthorized Reproduction of
                 Intellectual Property.” Journal of Law and Economics 40 (2): 511 –22.
              Taylor, M. S. 1994. “TRIPS, Trade, and Growth.” International Economic Review 35 (2): 361 –82.
              Tirole, J. 1988. The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
              United States International Trade Commission (USITC). 2011. China: Effects of Intellectual Property
                Infringement and Indigenous Innovation Policies on the U.S. Economy. Investigation No. 332–519,
                USITC Publication 4226.
              Varian, H. R. 2000. “Copying and Copyright.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 19 (2): 121 –38.
              Vida, I. 2007. “Determinants of Consumer Willingness to Purchase Non-deceptive Counterfeit
                 Products.” Managing Global Transitions 5 (3): 253 –70.
              Wilcox, K., H. M. Kim, and S. Sen. 2009. “Why Do Consumers Buy Counterfeit Luxury Brands?”
                 Journal of Marketing Research 46 (April): 247–59.
              World Intellectual Property Organization. 2013. “WIPO Studies on the Economic Contribution of
                the Copyright Industries.” Available at http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/copyright/en/
                performance/pdf/economic_contribution_analysis_2013.pdf.
              World Customs Organization. 2009. “Customs and IPR Report 2009.” Available at http://www.
                wcoomd.org/files/1.%20Public%20files/PDFandDocuments/Reports/Extract_IPRReport2009.pdf.
              Zentner, A. 2006. “Measuring the Effect of Music Downloads on Music Purchases” Journal of Law and
                 Economics 49 (1): 63– 90.




              28                                              The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 31, no. 1 (February 2016)




Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/31/1/1/2461705/The-Economic-Effects-of-Counterfeiting-and-Piracy
by Joint Bank-Fund Library user
on 06 October 2017