76603 Cofinanced Public Extension in Nicaragua Gabriel Keynan • Manuel Olln • Ariel Dinar How effective is agricultural extension? Is it worth the vast sums governments spend to provide it, mostly as a free service, to farmers worldwide? Relatively Jew studies exist that measure and compare the benefits of extension activities against their costs. In the absence of such data, this pilot activity concentrated instead on demand 'Would demand far extension services be high if they were no longer free? The exis- tence of solid demand would presuppose some benefits from the service. Further, might chargingfarthe service actually improve its quality and sustainability? The pilot program in Nicaragua described here set out to test whether a truly demand-driven extension system aimed at farmers with small- and medium-size holdings could be developed The principal mechanism was a contribution by the fanner paid as a bonus to the extensionist: the aim was to introduce incentives for providers to improve the service through rewards linked to the quality oftheir work and to establish direct accountability ofextensionist to client. The outcomes showed that the cofinancing concept can be successful The article describes the design, imple- mentation, and results in the expectation that the lessons learned may be ofinterest elsewhere. Governments have spent large sums providing agricultural extension as a free service to farmers—some US$6 billion worldwide in 1988 alone, according to estimates from the Food and Agriculture Organization (1990). Is expenditure on that scale justified by commensurate benefits? Evidence does exist that extension has increased productivity and income (Birkhaeuser, Evenson, and Feder 1991; Bindlish and Evenson 1993; Bindlish, Evenson, and Gbetibouo 1993), but it is not dear diat die investigated cases are typical. Evaluation of die cost-benefit relationships has been surprisingly thin. As Birkhaeuser, Evenson, and Feder (1991, p. 643) observe: "Given diat an extension organization exists in almost every country and in view of die large volumes of public funds directed to extension, diere is scope for much more Tie WerU Btnk Raatnh Oherver, POL 12, no. 2 (August 1997). pp. 225-47 O 1997 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / THE WORLD BANK HI empirical work on this issue." In the same vein, Purcell (1994, p. 10) notes (of World Bank—financed projects) diat "quantification of the impact of extension investments in economic terms is normally not undertaken in either ex-ante or ex-post analysis." In the absence of data, unsatisfactory results are frequently assumed: °.. . die poor performance of many public extension programs..." (Umali 1996, p. 2), and "the public sector extension services in which developing countries often at the behest of donors have invested large sums are achieving only limited im- pact . . . " (Farrington 1994, p. 1). Nonetheless, diere is a common conviction dial, whether universally successful or not, extension is the only means avail- ableforincreasing production "given the limits on land and irrigation and likely breakthroughs in technology, future increases are apt to . . . come from techno- logical improvements derived from identifying, developing and applying more efficient practices" (Antholt 1994, p. 4). Anodier way of deducing the value of extension services would be to find out whether farmers have expressed demand for them. Pressure from interest groups in the form of petitions or strikes when die service has been discontinued would be a fair indicator of demand (Guttman 1980; Rose-Ackerman and Evenson 1985). It is instructive, for example, diat no strike took place in Nicaragua in December 1995 when die government announced a substantial cut in public expenditures that would affect the extension budget, whereas the concurrent announcement of a corresponding cut in financial support to universities was met widi a very violent strike. The farmers' lack of reaction suggests limited interest, even apathy toward the service and obviously dierefore calls into question its impact on farmers' economic condition. Because failure to react to removal or reduction of exten- sion is common to most extension services in die developing world, it is likely that die services provided often leave farmers' indifferent to diem. An extension service should be designed to make the outcome of its actions advantageous to both the farmer and the extension institution. Without a stake in die outcome, the extensionist will make litde effort: "The amount of effort . . . depends on the value of a reward and the probability of receiving die re- ward. The perceived effort and probability of actually getting a reward are, in turn, also influenced by the record of actual performance" according to die Porter and Lawler model of motivation (Koontz and Weihrich 1990, p. 326). Accountability, which Kessides (1993, p. 17) defines as "die ability of service providers to serve die interests of users and odier financiers," also needs to be built into the design of the service. "Competitive markets meet this criterion of accountability in diat the profit-oriented suppliers have an incentive to satisfy the demands of dieir customers" (Kessides 1993, p. 17). In standard extension organizations, diese incentives are lacking. Data on performance are rarely col- 1*6 The WorUBtnk Research Observer. voL 12. IU. 2 (August 1997) lected, so potential reward cannot be related to any record of performance, and public institutions in any case rarely offer performance-based incentives to their employees. Consequendy, little effort is likely to be expended toward satisfying clients' needs. This article describes die methodology applied in establishing and delivering a demand-