WPS5733 Policy Research Working Paper 5733 Civil Society, Public Action and Accountability in Africa Shantayanan Devarajan Stuti Khemani Michael Walton The World Bank Development Research Group Human Development and Public Services Team July 2011 Policy Research Working Paper 5733 Abstract This paper examines the potential role of civil society within-state agencies or frontline providers accountable, action in increasing state accountability for development there is frequently positive impact on outcomes. in Sub-Saharan Africa. It further develops the analytical However, the big question remaining for such types framework of the World Development Report 2004 of interventions is how to improve the incentives of on accountability relationships, to emphasize the higher-level leadership to pursue appropriate policy underlying political economy drivers of accountability design and implementation. The paper argues that there and implications for how civil society is constituted and is substantial scope for greater efforts in this domain, functions. It argues on this basis that the most important including through the support of external aid agencies. domain for improving accountability is through the Such efforts and support should, however, build on political relations between citizens, civil society, and state existing political and civil society structures (rather than leadership. The evidence broadly suggests that when transplanting “best practice” initiatives from elsewhere), higher-level political leadership provides sufficient or and be structured for careful monitoring and assessment appropriate powers for citizen participation in holding of impact. This paper is a product of the Human Development and Public Services Team, Development Research Group. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted at skhemani@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team Civil Society, Public Action and Accountability in Africa Shantayanan Devarajan1 Stuti Khemani Michael Walton World Bank World Bank Harvard University and Centre for Policy Research, New Delhi 1 Shantayanan Devarajan is Chief Economist of the Africa Region of The World Bank. Stuti Khemani is Senior Economist in the Development Research Group of the World Bank. Michael Walton is Lecturer in International Development at the Harvard Kennedy School of Government, and Senior Visiting Fellow at the Centre for Policy Research, New Delhi. We are grateful to Avnish Gungadurdoss for excellent research assistance, and the preparation of a literature review that is appended to this paper. Corresponding author: Stuti Khemani, Development Research Group, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433, skhemani@worldbank.org. Disclaimer: The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the author, and do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. 2 1. Introduction Consider the following facts:  Teachers in public primary schools in Uganda are absent 20 percent of the time; when present, they are in class teaching 18 percent of the time (Chaudhury et al, 2006, World Bank, 2007).  Only 1 percent of non-salary expenditures allocated to primary health clinics in Chad actually reach the clinics (Gauthier and Wane, 2005).  There are huge leakages from fertilizer subsidies in Tanzania, with elected officials receiving 60 percent of the vouchers (Pan and Christiansen, 2011).  Efforts to hire workers below the minimum wage in South Africa—a country whose unemployment rate is 25 percent—are met with widespread, sometimes violent, protest.  Thanks to regulations that prohibit entry, monopoly rents to trucking companies cause Africa to have the highest transport prices in the world (Teranavithorn and Raballand, 2009). In addition to being emblematic of problems facing poor people in Africa, these facts have one more thing in common: they can be explained by failures of “accountability” at various points in the chain of relationships in the implementation of public sector policies. This chain goes from the preferences and needs of citizens, through the political process, and then passes to the bureaucracies and front-line actors charged with delivering services, or to the regulators, judges and others with responsibility for monitoring and enforcing economic and social behavior. Teacher absenteeism or leakage of public funds are examples of politicians or central-level bureaucrats being unable (or unwilling) to hold lower-level bureaucrats and service providers accountable. Capture of fertilizer subsidies or wage premiums by politically powerful groups are instances of citizens’ inability to hold politicians accountable.2 An approach to improving state accountability through public action by civil society, that has long been advocated and practiced by local and international non- governmental organizations, has more recently become of interest to the development financing community of bilateral and multilateral donors, including the World Bank. 2 It is important to note that these are not problems that can be solved by rolling back the state. For a wide range of goods and policies, the state has an important role to play in facilitating markets, growth poverty reduction, and human development. The concern is how to make the state more accountable for better development policies. 3 Does a substantially strengthened role for civil society have a sound conceptual and empirical basis, or is it just another fad? Where civil society influences state action, is it always in the direction of better provision of public goods, equitable human development and dynamic capitalist advance? Or does civil society also reflect the inequalities in wealth, organization and influence in the political process? What is the relationship between civil society action to make the state work better for all citizens, and formal political and governmental mechanisms of accountability? And even if there is a sound, substantiated case for some forms of strengthening of civil society, can external actors play a useful role in supporting it, or will they just add a new set of distortions? This paper seeks to provide answers to these questions, drawing on a structured review of the available literature and development experience in these areas. First, it reviews the analytics of accountability relationships, linking the core accountability relationship to the broader political economy of African societies, the democratization process, and the potential role of civil society. Second, against that analytical framework, the paper reviews the available evidence from current attempts to improve accountability through civil society-related interventions, focusing on empirically rigorous and carefully documented studies. The theme here is civil society action as a means to the pragmatic ends of development—growth, poverty reduction, health, education—rather than an objective in and of itself. The analytics and evidence support a common conclusion. There is indeed a strong prima facie case for a strengthened role for civil society, to differing degrees and forms in both democratic and at least semi-authoritarian regimes. However, strategies and interventions in this regard need to be cognizant of underlying political economy drivers of failures in accountability. In political economy environments characterized by high degrees of clientelism and rent-seeking, such as are widespread in the Africa region, an unqualified faith in civil society as a force for good is more likely to be misplaced. The evidence base on the organization of civil society suggests that historic institutions of poverty and inequality, or of ethnic identity, can inhibit collective action in the broader public interest, promote more narrow sectarian interests, and nourish clientelist political competition. Furthermore, broad collective or public-interest action by civil society is heavily constrained by existing systems and institutions of the state. However, there is also substantial potential for civil society action to achieve success in addressing accountability failures, incremental and transformational, with the focus here on conditions under which incremental changes can emerge. 4 What does this mean for domestic, and especially external, actors? It implies that support for civil society should follow an approach that is both organic and experimental: organic in the sense that interventions contribute to change in existing political and societal structures, and not seek to bring “best practice” ideas from outside; experimental in the sense of that there be structured monitoring, information generation and evaluation in the process—with the techniques depending on the nature of the intervention. In the next section, we unbundle the different accountability relationships and explore how, depending on the nature of the “failure,” civil society action may or may not help. The following section summarizes our review of the existing evidence on the impact of civil society related initiatives to improve accountability. A final section discusses the implications for external actors. 2. The analytics of accountability and civil society action in a Sub-Saharan context 2.1 The long and short routes of accountability The 2004 World Development Report (WDR), Making Services Work for Poor People, postulated that problems in the delivery of basic services—such as the teacher absenteeism, leakage of public funds or poorly targeted fertilizer subsidies described above—could be interpreted as breaks in the “long route of accountability.” The argument was as follows. In a private market transaction— such as buying a sandwich from a vendor—there is direct accountability of the sandwich provider to the client or consumer. The client pays the vendor directly; she can observe whether or not she received the sandwich; and, if the market is reasonably competitive, the client can go elsewhere if she doesn’t like the sandwich—and the vendor knows that. The WDR called this relationship the “short route of accountability.” When public action is involved, the relationship between the client and the service provider is no longer a direct one, but an indirect one, intermediated by the state. In the case of education, for instance, citizens as voters hold politicians accountable for allocating resources and regulating the education system. In turn, politicians or policymakers hold teachers accountable for delivering the service. This is the long route of accountability (Figure 1). Viewed in this light, it is easy to see how service delivery failures can be interpreted as a breakdown in one or both of the links in the long route of accountability. Teacher absenteeism is the result of policymakers’ inability (or unwillingness) to monitor teachers’ performance in the classroom. 5 Even if they can monitor performance, they may not be able to enforce penalties for non-performance because of the nature of the contract between teachers and the state (most teachers’ salaries are fixed, independent of attendance). Figure 1: The Long and Short Routes of Accountability The state Politicians Policymakers Long route of accountability Short route Citizens/Clients Providers Coalition/Inclusion Client Power Management Organized Unorganized Frontline organizations However, in the case of teacher absenteeism, there is the further question of how the contracts get determined in the first place, and why it is so difficult to change them, to make them more sensitive to performance. The answer lies in the first link in the long route—the relationship between citizens and politicians. Even if a majority of voters would prefer less absenteeism, there are significant failures in the political process that result in politicians who favor the status quo getting elected, and those attempting to address the problem of teacher accountability losing elections. These political failures take on many forms, and in the case of education, there are some specific causes. In many rural areas, teachers are also political organizers, so that politicians rely on them to deliver votes. The South African Democratic Teachers Union (SADTU), part of the governing coalition, is one of the most powerful trade unions in the country. In the state legislature of the Indian state of Uttar Pradesh, teachers constitute 20 percent of the assembly in the early 2000s, and former teachers another 20 percent (Kingdon and Muzammil, 2001). 6 The relationships of accountability—the politics between citizens and policymakers, the compact between policymakers and providers, and the client power of citizens over providers—are determined by the behavior, incentives and organization of each set of actors in the “nodes”. There can be considerable heterogeneity within each of these nodes. Citizens can become organized as interest groups, to service the objectives of their group, even at the expense of broad public interest; formally unorganized citizens can demand broad public interest policies (or not) through the aggregate effect of their individual participation in elections. Politicians and providers (a variety of state agents) can similarly be heterogeneous in their motivations, incentives and organization, with some having more intrinsic motivation and stronger incentives for development objectives, while that of others is inclined to extraction of private benefits. The central question of this paper is how citizen behavior, incentives and organization can be influenced to improve the functioning of politics, compact, and client power? How can citizen action contribute to the selection of better quality political and state agents, and strengthen incentives of all types of agents to deliver effective development policies? We re-interpret the WDR accountability triangle here by emphasizing the underlying political economy drivers of accountability. The politics between citizens and policymakers, previously characterized in the WDR 2004 as the “voice” relationship, is argued to be the more fundamental relationship of accountability in that it shapes the nature of the compact and client power. Civil society action can help to the degree that it can fix failures in political incentives for development policies; or in cases when the political leadership has incentives to use civil society input to address failures in the compact and client power. Even when political incentives allow interventions that enable civil society action to improve the compact and/or client power, the question has to be asked whether there are other mechanisms that political agents could have used to improve the performance of state agents and providers which rely less on citizen effort and time and more on political agent effort and time, or by reducing political rents. Accountability solutions, and associated failures, relate to three mechanisms, with strong complementarities between them:  Information  Collective action  Sanctions Political accountability failures could be attributed to asymmetric information about the performance of public policies; lack of coordination or collective action among citizens in evaluating politicians on the basis of broad public interest policies (as opposed to the basis of ethnic identity, or narrowly targeted clientelist transfers); 7 and lack of effective sanctioning mechanisms such as through an independent election commission, that monitors free and fair elections. Weak compacts can be derived from weak politics, when policymakers do not use instruments at their disposal to address information constraints in monitoring providers or to strengthen organizational incentives and sanctioning mechanisms within public agencies. A highly committed senior education officer will be able to do little if teachers are hired as political patronage and not to teach; a mining official determined to meet citizen complaints of flouting environmental standards will not be tolerated if politicians are party to rent-sharing deals with the mining companies. However, even in cases where higher tier political authorities have incentives to reduce rent-seeking at lower levels, lack of information and managerial constraints on enforcing sanctions can lead to failures in the compact. Weak client power can also be derived from weak politics, such as when states provide weak grievance mechanisms (sanctions) and limit choice among providers through state policies. Furthermore, very local institutions of inequality can make poor citizens powerless against local social and economic elite who can be the providers of most state and private services. That is, client power is hobbled by asymmetric information and institutional constraints to collective action and sanctions. Civil society action in Africa and elsewhere has focused on ways in which information provision and other activities mobilize citizens for collective action and demands for redress. These may be localized islands, where social pressures improve the performance of frontline providers. Or there can be particular sectors or agencies that are effective and responsive, and use citizen inputs to monitor the performance of providers and sanction poor behaviors. These islands of collective and effective action can be of great interest as to what can be done, and may be signs of potential for broader change. But they can also be deceptive if they do not reflect overall political strategies, making scaling of development results (even if not the specific interventions) problematic. Civil society’s effectiveness will almost always depend on incentives, and in particular the activation of sanctioning mechanisms, within the state. These may take the form of internal bureaucratic structures within implementing agencies, or formally independent institutions of accountability within the state, including the legislature, judiciary, auditing departments etc. In practice, however, such institutions are often either weak or not substantively independent. The effectiveness of such internal mechanisms will depend on their being aligned with 8 political strategies, especially over the medium to long term. It is in this sense, that we regard the relationship of politics, that reflects underlying structures of power in a society, as being the primary influence on overall accountability relations. 2.2 Political economy drivers of accountability relations Recent theoretical advances in understanding development, or the persistent lack of it, have emphasized the role of long-term institutions that continue to shape the current political economy of countries. Institutions are interpreted as products of long-term interactions among elite groups and between elites and middle and poorer groups (North et al, 2009; Acemoglu et al, 2001, 2005; Engerman and Sokoloff, 1997; Rajan, 2009). Important themes are of state formation as a response to the threat of violence between competing groups, and of institutional resolutions that often reflect the interests of elites, in environments of highly unequal distribution of endowments. Institutional resolutions, involving “extractive” economic institutions (Acemoglu and Robinson, Forthcoming) can be good for political and economic elites, while also sustaining inequalities and inhibiting the innovation, entry and investment that is necessary for long-term growth. Related strands examine the role of historical colonial institutions in creating or sustaining inequality, which then leads to persistence of elites and poor institutions that inhibit development (Acemoglu et al, 2001). Two kinds of rent-sharing arrangements are of importance to the functioning of the polity and the economy. First, there are bargains between competing elites, and between political and economic elites. Effective bargains with strong incentives against reneging are necessary for overall political stability, since excluded elite groups will otherwise mobilize to topple rulers to capture the rents. In particular a credible commitment by political elites not to expropriate economic elites is crucial to the investment and innovation that drive aggregate growth.3 In mature, consolidated democracies credible commitment against such expropriation is provided by the array of institutions that guarantee the rule of law, and protect businesses and individuals from opportunistic behavior of agents of the state. Under authoritarian polities, political elites in control of the state also use force—despotic power4—to prevent 3 See Haber et al (2003) for a historically based development of this argument for Mexico in the 20 th century. 4 By despotic power, we mean the capacity of the state elite to coerce and dominate civil society classes, including other social and economic elites and middle and subordinate groups. Mann (1986) contrasts this with “infrastructural power” that involves provision of public goods and services, 9 competing groups from taking over the state. However, for economic investment to occur, there must also be mechanisms that make it costly for the political elites to expropriate productive investments. One mechanism is the mingling of political and economic elites by social, marital and cultural ties.5 Sharing of rents among different elite groups is a pervasive institutional form in Africa (van de Walle, 2001). Cote d’Ivoire is an example of a case in which the credible management of such a sharing system by then President Houphouet-Boigny was central to the country’s stability; this lost credibility and spilled over into conflict on his death (Azam, 2001). In post-apartheid, democratic South Africa, the Black Economic Empowerment policy is effectively a mechanism to share rents with the emerging black elite (Andrews, 2008; Acemoglu et al, 2007). Second, there is rent-sharing with middle and poorer groups—that may include formal sector workers, slum-dwellers, large and small farmers, landless rural workers and so on—in return for their political support. The extent to which this is necessary again depends on the nature and power of the regime: regimes with high levels of despotic power will be able to use repression to maintain order under conditions of high inequality and political or social exclusion. However, this is sustainable only with substantial resources to maintain the repressive apparatus (including rent-sharing with the army and police). Some redistribution is necessary to subordinate groups to avert social revolt even in authoritarian societies. Under democratic auspices this is clearly even more relevant. Moreover, where subordinate groups are sufficiently organized to threaten an authoritarian regime, a democratic transition will be demanded to ensure that any concessions (economic, social or political) are credible—otherwise the elites will have every incentive to reverse the concessions if they can restore their organizational capacity and associated despotic power.6 These two sets of rent-sharing political arrangements provide the underlying structure to the politics relationship. In each domain, the rent-sharing arrangements are functional to both the stability of the polity and to the economic investment and the expansion of employment and services. But each also brings with it intrinsic state maladies—problematic aspects of state functioning with regulation of private activity and raising taxes over the whole of a nation’s territory; this intrinsically depends on the behavior of households, firms and civil society. 5 Haber et al (2003) explore the systematic role of third party enforcement, even in Mexico’s turbulent revolutionary period, by many mechanisms, including the one referred to in the text. 6 Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) build a theory of democratic transitions around this insight: arguing that a transition to democracy is more likely the more unequal is a society and the greater the costs of repression 10 respect to both efficiency and equity. In particular, in both domains they are associated with under-provision of public goods and the perpetuation of economic, political and social inequalities. With respect to inter-elite bargains, the main maladies are the failure to deliver the general public goods of credible commitment to investors (including small, informal firms), the rule of law and market institutions that support entry and competition. This is the flipside of the extraction and appropriation of rents by elite groups— whether through creation of monopolies, extraction of surpluses from the population (e.g. through state agricultural boards) or mining and other natural resources. This is typically associated with a tight nexus between political influence and economic resources. With respect to rent-sharing with middle and poorer groups, the dominant political strategy is of clientelism: the provision, via state resources, of private benefits to particular groups in return for their political loyalty. The literature on clientelism suggests it comes in two different forms (e.g. Kitschelt and Wilkinson, 2007; Vicente and Wantchekon, 2008): targeted benefits to citizens that depend on the holding of political power, such as jobs in the public sector (Robinson and Verdier, 2003; Keefer and Vlaicu, 2008), or “club” goods to particular localities or groups; and petty benefits to less organized supporters, through vote buying, which can also be offered by competitors who are not current incumbents. A more extreme malady comes in the form of use of the state apparatus to predate on the population and the country’s resources by the political elite in power. This is typically associated with extensive use of despotic power. In the African context, both rent-sharing among elite groups, and clientelism are often linked to identity-based groups, of ethnicity, religion or region (or all three overlapping, as they do in Nigeria and Sudan). However, this is by no means necessarily the case: in Tanzania, ethnicity is not salient in politics, in part due to a concerted nation-building strategy. Yet clientelism is still rampant (Kelsall, 2002). Nor are such identity-based links peculiar to Africa: India is a consolidated democracy in which identity of caste and religion is highly politically salient: Chandra (2004) develops the case that patronage on identity-lines is a rational response to the overall clientelistic character of the polity. While these rent-sharing arrangements are most directly part of the basic political structuring of the politics relationship, they also profoundly influence the compact 11 and client power relationships, and bring associated maladies. This is for three reasons:  Bureaucracies and other un-elected positions are in most of Sub-Saharan Africa thoroughly embedded in political and social relations (South Africa is the most important exception of a country with something close to a Weberian bureaucracy). Indeed, far from “seeing like a state”, in James Scott’s characterization of high modernist state functioning, for many African states it is more a question of “looking like a state”7. Elite bargains and clientelism are effected through the behavior of bureaucracies, and sometimes judiciaries and other state actors, as much as through the political process.  Where bureaucratic, judicial and other “compact” positions are allocated as a form of patronage (to family, friends, co-ethnics, etc), the incentive structure is intrinsically about the reciprocal provision of political loyalty, on an individual or group basis, as opposed to delivery of a service. This is consistent with the malady of low effort, such as teacher absenteeism, that was highlighted in the examples in the introduction to this paper.  A structurally ineffective state can be part of a self-perpetuating equilibrium. Even if shifts in the politics relation lead to a politician wanting to deliver public goods, he or she may be unable to do so, given the weakness of the state as a lever to do precisely this. A clientelistic political strategy may be forced upon him or her. These issues apply throughout the state compact system, all the way to the front- line of service delivery. It thus also pervades the client power relation, though street-level workers are even more likely to be embedded in local political and social structures. Sometimes this can lead to direct social pressures for better services, but it can also lead to reinforcing of the generic maladies of the state (see discussion of evidence below). The two rent-sharing relations are also central to the creation and reproduction of inequalities. The extraction and appropriation of rents by elites is a primary source of inequality, while clientelistic strategies are a classic political strategy for sustaining sufficient support from middle and poorer groups under unequal terms. Clientelism also tends to favor those groups with greater capacity to organize (e.g. 7 This phrase is due to anthropologist Steven Pierce in his work on Nigeria [Pierce, 2006]; the theme is also emphasized in the neo-patrimonial and other literatures on the African state (e.g. van de Walle, 2001) 12 unions, organized special interest groups) or with ethnic, geographic or other identity-based ties to elites in power. Finally, corruption is intricately linked to these systems. It is facilitated by the combination of creation of rents that are controlled by state (or sometimes non- state) actors. It is also linked to both forms of rent-sharing, manifest in high-level corruption in major business deals, and the widespread petty corruption faced by citizens in their daily lives. It is also linked to patterns of inequality, since it typically benefits political and business elites in the sharing of rents, and, at a lower level, officials in public sector jobs. These deeply embedded political economy and institutional drivers of accountability are being subject to incremental changes through at least two powerful forces developing in Africa—increasing political competitiveness, and greater organization and communication among citizens. We discuss each of these trends in turn, to examine how they might be leveraged for greater civil society action for accountability. 2.3 Accountability and democratization in Africa Data from the Polity IV effort, which uses expert opinion of political scientists to categorize the extent of autocracy and democracy of a regime, can be used to illustrate the nature of the democratic change moving across Africa over the past 20 years. There is a continuum of regimes, from completely autocratic to a fully consolidated democracy, with a large range of intermediate types (that they refer to as “anocracies”) that have elements of both autocratic and democratic processes. Their synthetic classification uses a numerical system, in which -10 to -7 are classified as autocratic, -6 to +6 as intermediate, and +7 to +10 as democratic. Figure 2 illustrates both the size of the change between 1985 and 2009, and the current classification for most of the countries. In the mid-1980s, 31 out of a total of 40 in the data base were fully autocratic, with only two full-fledged democracies (Gambia and Mauritius), and 6 intermediate regimes, most of which had a heavy weight of autocracy. By end-2009, the Polity IV classification has 12 fully democratic regimes (Benin, Botswana, Comoros, Ghana, Kenya, Lesotho, Mali, Mauritius, Senegal, Sierra Leone, South Africa and Zambia) and only 3 fully autocratic (Eritrea, Somalia and Swaziland8) with a majority being classified as 8Eritrea and Somalia are not included in the figure, as data was not available for the earlier year. 13 intermediate, or “anocratic”, regimes, most with significant democratic elements (including, for example, Burkina Faso, Côte d’Ivoire, the Democratic Republic of Congo, Ethiopia, Mozambique, Nigeria, Rwanda, Uganda, Tanzania and Zimbabwe). Figure 2: Democratic and autocratic regimes in SubSaharan Africa, 1985 and 2009 Source: Polity IV data base The democratic wave has been shown to have large consequences for public policies. Harding and Stasavage (2011), for example, show that the transition to competitive elections in African countries is associated with the abolition of school fees, which in turn is associated with higher rates of school attendance than in non- democracies. Kudamatsu (2011) finds in a sample of 28 African countries that infant mortality falls by 1.2 percentage points, which is 12 percent of the sample mean, after a country has experienced a change in political leadership through the winning of multiparty elections. However, this latter example also illustrates the limits of elections per se in addressing accountability failures—there is no evidence of systematic reduction in infant mortality in countries where an autocrat holds multiparty elections and stays in power by winning them. 14 Even competitive elections can be influenced by violence, allegations of fraud, contestation of results, and are typically dominated by clientelistic practices of winning political support through promises of provision of private or group benefits (Keefer and Khemani, 2004). Such clientelist practices can have deep roots in historical institutions, as discussed in the previous section. Furthermore, there is also substantial variation in performance in growth and human development across autocratic regimes, which to a large extent overlaps the variation among democratic regimes (Besley and Kudamatsu, 2007). Autocratic and intermediate regimes can still be under political pressures to deliver on development to middle and poorer groups—as exemplified by countries such as Ethiopia and Rwanda that fall into this intermediate category. A growing body of evidence on citizen participation in elections and other political processes in Africa is being generated through the use of the Afrobarometer surveys.9 Broad arguments are made on the basis of this data that citizen political behavior in Africa cannot be reduced only to responding to clientelist appeals and ethnic identity, but that performance of governments in managing the economy and delivering development matters as well (see for example, Bratton et al, 2011, and Young, 2009). Average self-reported voter-turnout in the 2008 round of the Afrobarometer survey for both “full democracies” and even intermediate cases, as rated by Polity IV, is higher than 70 percent (see Table 1, below). Such widespread intentions to participate in political processes likely encompass a variety of citizens, some of whom demand broad public services and economic development. In section 3 below we report evidence from experiments undertaken by civil society organizations in Africa to shift citizen demands away from clientelism and towards broad public goods. 2.4 Accountability and civil society organization There also appears to be a large shift in Africa in organization among citizens. Village-level group formation in Africa increased dramatically over the 1990s when participatory approaches were emphasized in international development paradigms, promoted through aid, and adopted deliberately by country governments to deliver projects to communities.10 Bernard et al (2008), for example, show a rapid proliferation of village organizations (VOs) in a sample of 9 Working papers using the Afrobarometer data can be found at http://www.afrobarometer.org/index.php?option=com_docman&Itemid=39 10 Here, we focus on community organizations intended to solve failures in the delivery of local public goods; instead of marketed-oriented organizations that have existed primarily in agriculture (Bernard et al, 2008). 15 villages in Senegal and Burkina Faso between 1980 and 2002; in Senegal, by 2002, 65% of the sample villages had at least one VO (from 10% in 1982); in Burkina Faso, 91% had one VO by 2002 (from 22% in 1982). By 2002, 69% of households in Senegal and 57% in Burkina Faso were participating in some VO. One of the concerns with donor-driven creation or funding of local groups is that it changes the nature of who participates most actively in these groups and to what ends. Arcand and Fafchamps (2008) find that members of externally funded organizations are more likely to be older and to have more land wealth. In a program in rural Kenya which provided leadership training and agricultural inputs to small self-help organizations, with mainly women members, Gugerty and Kremer (2006) find that membership in the groups selected for the program changed, with greater representation of the more educated, and those more likely to have formal sector income. That is, group membership and leadership moved into the hands of younger and better educated women, following the injection of external donor funding and programs. At the same time, perhaps surprisingly, the program showed unimpressive results in terms of productivity gains. General theoretical treatments of civil society range from a “romantic” view of equitable participation in deliberative processes, in which rational argument resolves differing views and interest, to one in which civil society is viewed as essentially incorporating and perpetuating the unequal patterns of wealth, status, power and associated cultural practices within the overall society.11 Indeed, in the theory of public choice, the power of organized “special interests”, that pursue their partisan objectives, has been blamed for distortions to growth-promoting or efficient or equitable fiscal policies even in the context of advanced industrial democracies, like the United States, (Tullock, 1959; Becker, 1985). An extreme and tragic example of conflict of interests within civil society in Africa is the Hutu mobilization (and the use of radio within this) in the Rwandan genocide. The capacity for voluntary collective action, that is, the organization and exercise of action by civil society, is typically unequally distributed in a society. The issue is not simply one of whether the more poor and less educated are less likely to participate in organized groups (although a review of evidence from various countries by Mansuri and Rao, Forthcoming, suggests that can be the case), but a more complex one of how broader conditions of inequality influence how groups are organized and for what objectives. La Ferrara (2002) provides evidence from Tanzanian villages of 11 See Baiocchi, Heller and Silva (Forthcoming, Chapter 1) for a review. The deliberative perspective is associated in particular with Jurgen Habermas, the view of civil society as reflecting and perpetuating inequalities with Pierre Bourdieu. 16 such complex interaction between village-level inequality and group organization; perhaps most interestingly for our current discussion, in more unequal villages, individuals are less likely to report trust in the community, and more likely to report conflict of interest. There is more rigorous and detailed evidence from India on the role of historic institutions of inequality in influencing breakdowns in collective action for broad public goods (Banerjee and Iyer, 2005; Andersen, 2011), dissolution of social cooperation (Fehr, Hoff, et al, 2008), and weak performance of government poverty alleviation programs (Besley et al, 2004). Ethnic fragmentation and polarization in many parts of Africa have been blamed for the lack of organization by civil society to generate political institutions in the public interest (Easterly and Levine, 1997; Alesina, Baqir and Easterly, 1999; Montalvo and Reynal-Querol, 2010). Miguel and Gugerty (2005) find that community contributions to public schools and quality of school infrastructure are lower in communities with greater ethnic diversity. In experimental work to examine why ethnicity matters in lowering contribution to public goods, Habyarimana et al (2007) conclude that it is not because of greater altruism towards co-ethnics, or greater sharing of common preferences, but rather because of greater power of social sanctions within ethnic networks. That is, social networks among co-ethnics make reciprocal exchanges easier to achieve. Perhaps because it facilitates such reciprocal exchange, ethnic identity in Africa may be used to sustain clientelist political competition, enabling the type of quid-pro-quo interactions of provision of private benefits for political support that allow politicians to get away with larger rents and lower public goods. Consistent with this view of ethnicity as an instrument of clientelist strategies, Eifert et al (2010) find that self-reported ethnic attachment in the Afrobarometer surveys is greater when the question is asked nearer to elections. Table 1 provides further data on reported participation in groups for 18 African countries covered by the most recent round of the Afrobarometer survey around 2008. On average, across all countries, 26 percent report being active members of a group, and 52 percent report frequently attending group meetings. Reported participation does not appear to be strikingly different across the countries classified as “full democracies” by Polity IV, versus those classified as “anocratic”. Indeed, there is significant variation in group participation within these categories across countries. Among the full democracies, the highest ranking (South Africa and Botswana) have active group membership reported by only 16 and 17 percent, compared to a Kenya and a Liberia lower down the “democracy” scale, with 17 43 and 45 percent respectively. Among the “anocracies”, group membership and attendance in meetings is particularly high for Tanzania.12 The Afrobarometer data suggest that local-level organization of civil society into groups does not exclude the poor. For six countries—Benin, Botswana, Ghana, Senegal, South Africa, and Zimbabwe—an indicator of poverty in the Afrobarometer (when a respondent mentions that the household has gone without adequate food many times in the recent past) is significantly associated with greater attendance of group meetings (after controlling for respondent age, gender, education, media access, household size, and neighborhood availability of infrastructure). However, the extent to which these groups indeed represent the interests of the poor, or have impact on improved accountability for development outcomes are questions on which the evidence is patchy. This will be discussed in the following section. However, what can also be seen in the Afrobarometer data for seven countries-- Benin, Lesotho, Mozambique, South Africa, Tanzania, Uganda, Zimbabwe—is that respondents that report going without food many times (an indicator of poverty) are significantly more likely to report fear of punishment or reprisals should they complain about poor quality of government services or misuse of government funds. In five countries—Benin, Ghana, Senegal, Zambia, and Zimbabwe—respondents that report frequent attendance in group meetings are also more likely to be those with ethnic grievances. In these countries, ethnic grievance is also correlated with respondents reporting any instances of joining with others to raise an issue. Whether their participation in group and organized activities is geared towards broad collective action or narrower redress of ethnic grievances is an important concern for the efficacy of civil society action in addressing broad accountability failures. These insights from research and evidence into local-level groups, and how their membership and leadership changes in response to the availability of external funding is pertinent for other donor initiatives to promote transparency and accountability through national groups and associations. We are not able to uncover any systematic evidence on the organization and incentives of such national civil society organizations. However, some types of activities undertaken by these groups have been subjected to rigorous impact evaluation in collaboration with independent researchers. The next section will discuss the state of evidence on 12This is, in fact, quite visible during field visits to Tanzanian villages by one of the authors (Khemani) with posters listing village groups and their membership being plastered all over the walls of the village government office. 18 particular types of interventions that could be undertaken by national groups to influence civil society organization to extract greater accountability. Another interesting type of organization which could play a role, but again one on which we are not able to find systematic evidence in Africa, are business associations. As already emphasized, firms need a variety of public goods—most fundamentally the public good of credible commitments not to expropriate profits or assets once investments have been made—but also the provision of law and order, the underpinnings of contracts, a framework for labor relations and “real” public goods such as roads, ports, electricity networks and an education and training system that generates adequate skills. But both the general public good of credible policy commitment and specific public goods are hard to deliver (Haber et al, 2003). Where these dilemmas are not resolved, the result is low levels of private investment and so low growth. This can also make a predatory policy, as opposed to a pro-development one, a more attractive political strategy. As discussed above, rent-sharing arrangements between political and business elites, with credible punishment for political elites in the event of reneging, are a solution to the commitment problem, but an imperfect one. And specific deals, for construction contracts, forestry concessions, mining production, the array of specific licenses needed for production and so on, are often obtained through personalized, corrupt transactions. Longer-term relations are based on the various forms of legal and illegal political finance. This is where there is a potential role for business associations. On the one hand their function is to represent the interests of capital—and for society as a whole, there is a need for countervailing structures, such as trade unions, civil society groups or political representatives—to ensure that overall accountability is not skewed toward these interests. But they can also play a role in solving collective action problems within the business sector, both among large and small firms, and in pressing for states to deliver the general public goods for capitalist production as opposed to particularistic (and often corrupt) deals. 3. Evidence on the impact of specific interventions Specific types of interventions have been pursued by civil society organizations, and supported by donors, to achieve incremental change within the broader systemic failures in accountability, both through addressing citizen participation in political processes and through citizen participation in monitoring and managing state- funded programs. This section focuses on assessing what the evidence tells us from 19 interventions that have been rigorously evaluated, and identifying where there are large knowledge gaps compared to the theoretical potential examined in the analytical section. It makes selective use of some studies as examples, while referring to other comprehensive reviews that are available for broader conclusions. A literature review was also undertaken specifically for this paper, focusing on evidence generated through randomized control trials and other econometric methods for rigorous identification of impact, and classifying the interventions according to the arm of the accountability triangle at which they were aimed.13 This is appended to the paper. Most of the interventions that have been carefully evaluated use some form of “information and transparency”, not only to address information gaps among citizens, but rather to use more strategic packaging of evidence and advocacy to mobilize and persuade citizens to address accountability failures. That is, the interventions typically rely on a combination of all three types of mechanisms— addressing information gaps, mobilizing or coordinating citizens for collective action, and redressing weak sanctioning power.  Solving accountability failures in politics: “Open budget” initiatives. Making greater information available about government budgets has been at the center of many donor-supported civil society initiatives. Citizen action, and donor pressure on governments has contributed to the adoption of legislation for citizens’ “Right to Information”, and to various initiatives to facilitate citizen ability to monitor public budgets and allocation of public resources, such as the Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative, and the Open Budget Index. Descriptions of these initiatives, and reviews of evidence of their impact are provided by McGee and Gaventa (2010) and Gaventa and Barrett (2010). We classify these initiatives as addressing the “politics” arm of accountability between citizens and political leadership of states, geared as they are towards improving general accountability of overall state resource allocation. Much of the evidence on how these initiatives work and what impact they have appears to be qualitative, and focuses on intermediate outcomes such as whether citizens indeed became more informed and engaged in budget processes. There are also some quantitative studies reviewed specifically in a background paper prepared by Carlitz (2010) for the synthesis report prepared by McGee and Gaventa (2010), that provide mostly cross-country correlations of indicators of greater budget transparency with indicators of governance, corruption, socio- economic and human development, and even political participation. As with all such types of cross-country correlations, however, there is an important concern about causality—it is not possible to draw strong conclusions about whether specific budget transparency initiatives in fact lead to the better outcomes, or whether other underlying changes in government accountability to citizens drive the outcomes together. Micro-quantitative evidence of impact on budget allocations (which areas 13This literature review was prepared by Avnish Gungadurdoss of the Harvard Kennedy School of Government. 20 get more or less allocations), and budget implementation (whether the allocations translated into better services or outcomes) appears to be almost entirely missing. There is evidence on a specific type of budget information which was pioneered in the education sector in Uganda. Purposefully designed survey instruments—named the Public Expenditure Tracking Surveys (PETS)—were used to measure discrepancies between budget allocations to schools in Uganda, and what actually reached the schools (Reinikka and Svensson, 2004). One study argues that the publication in mass media of estimated “leakage” in the flow of funds led to dramatic improvements, with most of the intended funds reaching the schools subsequent to the information campaign (Reinikka and Svensson, 2005). In this argument, accountability for the flow of funds improved because of addressing information gaps among parents in schools, and thus enabling them to exercise their client power vis a vis district authorities responsible for transferring funds to schools. Following the celebrated success of the Uganda case there has been a proliferation of PETS activities, and external investments in strengthening the capacity of civil society organizations to undertake such surveys to uncover and publicize “leakage” and thereby stem it. More qualitative evaluations of these efforts suggest that they can be frequently successful in getting the funds to reach the intended destinations, although to a lesser degree than the estimates in Uganda (McGee and Gaventa, 2010). However, alternate arguments about the drivers of success in the Uganda case indicate that the client-power channel was only part of the story. Hubbard (2007) examines larger changes in school funding policies in the Ugandan Ministry of Education, and suggests that the information that activated client-power may have been only one element in increasing the amount of resources available in schools; that other, perhaps larger, elements consisted of strengthening of the compact between the Ministry and the districts following President Museveni’s 1996 election campaign in which free and universal primary education was a prominent agenda. This argument thus suggests that pressures working through the politics relationship led to a greater focus on education funding and to a better compact for education services. The role played by client power was a complement to changing political incentives within the state. Are there other interventions that could enable civil society to influence the politics relationship to demand stronger changes in the compact? For example, the school grants covered by the PETS in Uganda are estimated to be a much smaller proportion of total government spending on education compared to teacher salaries (Hubbard, 2007). Other work on public education spending, and on the political economy of teacher management as a manifestation of clientelism, suggests that the compact with teachers is especially weak because citizens’ demand from politicians for quality education services is not sufficiently strong. This takes us to evidence on information and communication campaigns to mobilize voters around broad public interest policies. 21 Voter education: Can civil society engagement undercut clientelist politics, and better coordinate citizen demand for quality public services? A series of voter education experiments have been undertaken between CSOs and researchers in Benin, São Tomé and Príncipe, Mozambique, and Nigeria to reduce clientelism and violence in elections (Vicente and Wantchekon, 2008; Aker et al, 2010; Collier and Vicente, 2010). In Benin, a civil society group organized town-hall meetings with real political candidates in the first round of the 2006 Presidential elections, to discuss specific policy proposals informed by empirical evidence (Wantchekon, 2009). The results of the impact evaluation suggest that where such town-halls were held, voter turnout was higher and support for clientelist political platforms was lower. In São Tomé and Príncipe and Mozambique voter education campaigns were undertaken to persuade voters not to “sell” their vote. Previous work in São Tomé and Príncipe had documented that vote-buying practices increased dramatically in the late 1990s, after the discovery of oil (Vicente, 2010). Such practices have been analyzed as enabling political leaders to get away with large rents from public resources, while providing low quality and quantity of public services. In Nigeria, community campaigns were undertaken by civil society groups to encourage voters to oppose political intimidation or violence (Collier and Vicente, 2010). This body of work focuses on measuring impact on explicit political outcomes, such as voter turnout and use of different electoral strategies by incumbents and challengers. There is also evidence from other regions, relevant for Africa, on voter education campaigns to reduce the extent to which citizens vote on the basis of ethnic identity (India) or gifts (vote-buying in the Philippines). Banerjee et al (2010) evaluate the impact of interventions by a CSO in India to persuade voters not to vote on the basis of caste identity of candidates; the results show that these were effective in increasing voter turnout and reducing the votes of caste-preferred candidates with criminal records. Schaffer (2005) provides qualitative evidence from the Philippines that voter education campaigns to reduce vote-buying practices may have unintended effects; that such campaigns may offend target groups and intensify “class divides” between the middle or upper classes that are the sponsors of the campaigns, and the poor, who are convinced of the legitimacy of receiving benefits from politicians in exchange for their vote. While these are important examples of the engagement of civil society in strengthening political accountability by making elections more effective mechanisms for evaluating the policy performance of candidates, this body of work is not designed to examine the ultimate impact on policies and development outcomes. It is therefore not immediately clear whether even significant electoral effects of voter education campaigns would effectively translate into different or better policy choices. For example, if the campaigns primarily strengthen the hands of incumbent politicians (by reducing the efficacy of vote-buying tactics employed by political challengers), they may be further protected from the risks of losing office and able to continue rent-extraction policies. 22 The example from the Philippines also suggests that tackling the proximate symptoms of clientelist political competition directly may not be effective. An alternate strategy, akin to the Benin town halls, could use information on policy performance to coordinate voters better on public goods platforms. Can policy- based information and mobilization interventions overcome collective action problems (such as social polarization, ethnic fragmentation, and vote-selling), and weak sanctioning power (such as through state-led coercion and violence in elections)? Politician and Constituency Report Cards: Civil society organizations in some countries have attempted to garner and provide information on performance of politicians in delivering benefits to their constituents. Banerjee et al (2010) evaluate the impact in India of providing information on the performance of state legislators in delivering constituency development projects and subsidized food rations to the poor. They find that greater information enabled voters to punish incumbents who performed poorly by voting against them in local elections. However, a similar experiment in Uganda with the African Leadership Initiative, providing information about the legislative activities of their MPs, and efforts towards spending their constituency development funds, seems to have had little or no impact on election outcomes (Humphreys and Weinstein, Forthcoming). Full results from Uganda are not currently available to assess whether greater performance information may nevertheless have contributed to improvements in legislator use of their funds, with the politicians changing their behavior in anticipation of electoral punishment. Keefer and Khemani (2009) find more qualitative evidence from India that a surge in media reporting about the lack of effort among MPs in using their constituency development funds was associated with dramatic increases in legislator effort and utilization of funds. There is a new civil society effort underway in Africa, called Uwezo14, to measure education service delivery and learning outcomes on a large scale, enabling performance measures to be computed at disaggregated jurisdictional levels such as districts. Such disaggregated measurement could potentially enable attribution of performance in delivering education services to specific government agents and politicians. The Uwezo effort was partly inspired by a similar effort in India, called ASER (Annual Status of Education Report), run by the organization Pratham15. Although media stories would suggest that such initiatives contribute to strengthening political accountability for education outcomes, because of the information generated and collective pressure exerted by CSOs, there is as yet no rigorous evidence of how this changes key politically motivated distortions in education allocations. In the case of India, five years of ASER reports has played an important role in raising public awareness of the education quality, but has essentially found no overall increase in test scores for rural children in the period to 2010 (ASER 2011). There remains substantial untapped potential for examining whether such disaggregated information can indeed generate sufficient political 14 http://www.uwezo.net/ 15 http://www.pratham.org/M-20-3-ASER.aspx 23 pressure and yardstick competition across jurisdictions to improve performance (Khemani, 2007). Brazil provides a qualitative example of successful experience with this type of information intervention, albeit one that was led by a “reformist” leader rather than by civil society organizations (Tendler, 1997). The Governor of the state of Ceará in Brazil, who took office in 1987, supported a strategy of creating a new class of public health workers through a publicized recruitment effort that conveyed information to communities about the valuable role the workers could play in improving public health through community-wide effort. The strategy also included extensive use of radio with messages about how infant and child mortality could be drastically reduced through particular programs of municipal governments, thus bringing political pressure to bear upon the mayors to actually deliver basic health services. In only a few years coverage of measles and polio vaccination in Ceará tripled to 90 percent of the child population, and infant deaths fell from 102 to 65 per thousand births. In addition to the specific health example, the state government leadership has been generally credited with using various means to bringing a remarkable turnaround in the municipal politics of the state—from clientelist and patronage-based to more service-oriented. More recently, Brazil has been the source of another example of higher-tier government efforts to reduce local political rent-seeking by generating and providing credible information to citizens. In May 2003 the national government of Brazil launched an anti-corruption program based on the random auditing of municipal government expenditures by an independent public agency, and then publicly releasing audit findings on the internet and to media sources.16 New evidence from more than 600 municipalities covered by the audit suggests that the disclosure of information significantly and substantially reduced the re-election rates of mayors who were found to be corrupt (Ferraz and Finan, 2006). Furthermore, this impact was significantly more pronounced in municipalities with greater access to radio stations. What these examples suggest is the potential of particular types of information interventions that not only address information gaps, but also enable voter collective action and sanctions through greater coordination around the information. However, it is not clear that civil society organizations would be able to replicate the Brazilian success in the absence of leadership in some part within Government or through institutionalized state agencies. An important question suggested by this for external donor assistance to civil society in Africa is whether performance information can be credibly generated and communicated in the way it was by the government of Brazil, and in ways that sustains the effects in between elections. Again, how would such information overcome the collective action problems posed by social polarization, ethnic 16In Portuguese, this program is called Programa de Fiscaliza¸cão a partir de Sorteios Públicos, details of which is available from the following website: www.presidencia.gov.br/cgu. 24 fragmentation and vote-selling? Or of problems of weak sanctioning power of voters because of state-led violence and coercion in elections? Mass media: The potential role of media organizations, such as radio, seems obvious as purveyors of information to large numbers of citizens, especially the poor. Indeed, donors have been engaged in setting-up and supporting community radio in various parts of Africa to broadcast public-interest programming for democratic values, human rights, and the importance of health and education. Yet, there is little rigorous evidence of their impact; recent work using new and unique data from Benin yields surprising conclusions for the advocates of community radio. Keefer and Khemani (2011a, 2011b) find that greater access to community radio in Benin is not associated with the ability of citizens to extract greater benefits from their government; instead, the impact of radio programming seems to be to persuade people to invest more of their own private resources into the education of their children and the health of their family. While this is a useful role for mass media to play in development, it is unrelated to the accountability challenge. This contrasts with evidence from the post-Depression-era USA, when radio had just begun to spread, that greater access to radio enabled citizens to receive greater benefits from government welfare spending (Stromberg, 2004). It also contrasts with the experience from Uganda and elsewhere when media were used purposefully to disseminate information about leakage in public resources; in such cases they were instrumental in stimulating public opinion and action to reduce such leakage (Reinikka and Svensson, 2005, as discussed above). This suggests that investments in building capacity of media alone, and advocating their independence from the state, may not be sufficient to achieve greater accountability—investing further in well-designed messages, either those that can enable voters to coordinate on policy performance, or those that are endorsed by the state in an effort to improve efficiency in its public spending (as in the Brazil examples discussed above) is needed. Although theory suggests an accountability role for mass media, it also suggests that media could be used for political “posturing” and “pandering”, reducing incentives to pursue actions that contribute to broad public goods. (Prat, 2005; Besley and Prat, 2006; Mullainathan and Shleifer, 2002; Maskin and Tirole, 2004). For example, when there is uncertainty about the effects of different policies, and policymakers/politicians as “experts” have access to greater private information about these different effects than do voters, media coverage may induce politicians to take positions that cater to voter beliefs, ignoring their private information that could lead to better policy decisions. The policy mantra for media development for accountability seems to be to pursue laws and regulations for media independence from state control, which while probably necessary doesn't address other incentive issues in competitive media markets. First, even independent media may be manipulated by governments seeking to broadcast propaganda messages, or because politicians service the partisan interests of media owners—that is, independent media can be "lapdogs" rather than "watchdogs"(Qian and Yanagizawa, 2010). Second, media have 25 incentives to “slant” the news to cater to people's priors, instead of reporting unbiased information. Recent empirical estimates of the large effects of radio on violence in Rwanda, concluding that “hate radio” may explain as much as 9 percent of the genocide (Yanagizawa, 2010), is a singularly dramatic demonstration of a general proposition that media effects are contingent upon the messages and programming broadcast, which depend on larger political incentives and biases and prejudices among citizens. The conventional wisdom on the drivers of the recent Arab Spring indicates that citizen collective action on such a large scale was facilitated by social media and information and communication technology (ICT). Indeed, pioneering efforts such as Ushahidi17, to develop platforms for “crowd-sourced” information have their roots in Africa, with much enthusiasm that such technological advances can have far reaching accountability effects by spurring collective action among citizens. Again, however, there is little rigorous research on whether or how ICTs enable greater public accountability. Most of the work on ICT, accountability and transparency, remains at the level of assuming that greater use of and investment in such technology are both necessary and sufficient, with little or no work investigating what kinds of accountability messages or interventions, delivered through ICT, do or don’t achieve impact on development effectiveness. There is substantial scope for pursuing such a research program, which may have especially large returns in terms of reaching the pivotal “youth” group for democratic political stability that is conducive to good economic policies. The question for external support to citizen media and ICT organizations, once again, is whether such support can promote information for development and public interest accountability. There is little knowledge of what does or does not work in using media and ICT to promote accountability for development effectiveness. Addressing this knowledge gap requires a program of rigorous, data- based impact evaluation, rather than simply greater advocacy for greater media independence and transparency. What accountability or governance interventions facilitated by media can improve the quality of public services? Do media help to make public-payroll teachers show-up and teach in schools? Do they improve the implementation of public health programs? Can media do this only through the strengthening of compact and client power by “willing” state agencies; or, can it address the more fundamental political constraints to weak compacts and client power in the first place? What types of intervention design can overcome potentially harmful civil society action along ethnic lines?  Solving accountability failures in compact and client power: A wide range of interventions have been pursued by governments and donors in engaging civil society in local communities to monitor and directly participate in the delivery of public services. Some of the initiatives of civil society organizations, such as Uwezo and ASER, discussed above as information interventions that potentially influence politically accountability, may indeed not be 17 http://www.ushahidi.com/ 26 primarily described by their organizations as such, but rather more about community mobilization and engagement to take direct action to improve public services. Citizen Report Cards: The experience of a CSO based in Bangalore, India, the Public Affairs Centre, in pioneering the use of “citizen report cards” as a tool for client power has been celebrated in much of the development policy literature. In the anecdotal evidence provided by Paul (2002), this initiative aggregated citizen perceptions of the quality of urban services provided by various agencies in the city of Bangalore, then publicized these through local media, serving as a massive, collective complaint mechanism. This either “shamed” the agencies into improving services, or sent a strong signal to local municipal politicians that citizens care about service delivery and the politicians in turn put pressure on the providers to improve performance. Subsequent surveys by the same CSO report substantial improvements in perceptions of service over time. However, there are diverging results from more rigorous evaluation of such initiatives in rural areas of India and Africa (Uganda). In Uganda, Bjorkman and Svensson (2006) report on interventions in 25 communities where local CSOs organized meetings between community members and health service providers of public clinics around citizen report cards on the quality of care provided at these clinics. Compared to “control” communities where no such discussion took place, in intervention communities both provider attendance and quality of service measures (including wait time and quality of care) improved. The final result was an increase in the immunization rate and a substantial drop in child mortality in the communities where the mobilization interventions occurred. The evidence suggests that these improvements in health services resulted from greater activism by the community in monitoring health clinics and demanding improvements, most likely through existing beneficiary-control institutions called Health Users Management Committees (HUMCs). This is a case in which information, and possibly complementary mobilization, activated a client power mechanism that the state has already set up. However, similar meetings that were organized by a CSO (Pratham, mentioned earlier) in India around citizen report cards on the quality of education services in 195 intervention villages had no impact on teacher effort, or on learning outcomes in public schools (Banerjee et al, 2010). The intervention also had no impact on a beneficiary-control institution existing in the state (Uttar Pradesh) where the study was conducted—the Village Education Committee (VEC), which is authorized by the state and in principle operates much like the HUMCs for health services in Uganda. In both UP and Uganda these existing institutions were found to be inactive at the baseline. Yet, perhaps the most striking finding of the India study is that in one set of intervention villages, where the citizen report card was combined with an offer by Pratham to train village volunteers to hold remedial classes outside school, a large number of local youths volunteered to hold such classes, completely bypassing the public school system. In these villages, the children who attended the volunteer-led 27 remedial classes made dramatic improvements in learning. Better information here induced greater private efforts, by the volunteers and the families of the children. Such instances of direct citizen participation are of course inspiring, but leave open a billion-dollar question (in the context of public spending on education in India)— how to make the substantial allocation of public resources to education less wasteful and more effective in delivering development ? These villages in north India were able to take private collective action to help themselves, facilitated by the CSO Pratham, but were not able to overcome the barriers to holding local politicians and bureaucrats to account for the large amounts of state resources going to salaries of absent teachers and captured school construction. Furthermore, the results of the participatory interventions documented in Banerjee et al (2010) contrasts with those of another information intervention in similar villages in the same part of north India which was not as participatory but rather carried the seal of the state department of education, and was delivered through a savvy video played to village gatherings (Pandey et al, 2009). This resulted in the village public school teacher reducing absenteeism, with some discernable effects on improvements in learning among children. Such large variation both within and across different information interventions to mobilize citizens to increase their client power suggests that local context and the larger political economy environment matter significantly for success, especially in supporting (or not) citizen engagement in strengthening compacts or authorized client-power structures with public providers. A rigorous impact evaluation of another type of client-power initiative to combat corruption in local infrastructure construction projects was able to directly contrast the efficiency of citizen-led initiatives with other technocratic means of strengthening the compact between the state and local providers. In Indonesia, Olken (2005) compared the impact of information provision to local citizens about corruption in local roads projects against that of a technocratic government-led initiative—credible audits of local projects by higher tier authorities. He finds that the state-led audits were substantially more effective at reducing corruption than the intervention based on information and local collective action. Another study, in Madagascar, contrasting interventions designed to encourage district education bureaucrats to improve their monitoring of schools, versus directly engaging school communities to do so, instead finds that local-level monitoring was more effective (Nguyen and Lassibille, 2008). However, in contrast to the certain-audit intervention in Indonesia, the Madagascar intervention did not require district officials to improve their monitoring. Community “management” committees: There are a large number of initiatives pursued by governments and donors to organize citizens in local communities into committees to manage environmental resources, targeting of benefits of poverty alleviation schemes, infrastructure projects, health and education services (as in the cases of HUMCs in Uganda and VECs in India described above). In an extensive 28 review of the evidence of the impact of such initiatives, Mansuri and Rao (Forthcoming), conclude that there is variation in the success of such initiatives which depends on the nature of social organization across communities (the degree of inequality, in particular), the technical complexity of projects, and importantly, on whether higher-tier state agencies indeed provide the powers and resources to local committees to be effective. That is, these initiatives can serve to strengthen client- power and/or compact, as long as they are appropriately designed and supported to do so by higher state agencies, and as long as collective action processes within communities can work. Participatory budgeting: Participatory budgeting, another initiative popular with donors and some governments to engage civil society to address accountability problems, where citizens directly participate in formulating budgets of local governments, was pioneered in the city of Porto Allegre in Brazil, where the city council devolved decision making over new capital investments to citizen councils. This devolution has been credited in qualitative analysis with substantial improvements in local governance and responsiveness to the needs of the poor, although there is a problem in attributing gains to the institution of participatory budgeting. The introduction of participatory budgeting in Porto Allegre went hand- in-hand with the election of a particular political party (the Partido dos Trabalhadores, or Workers Party) which catered to a particular constituency of citizen activists (and therefore adopted a specific mode of participatory institutions to implement its compact) and had broader incentives to service the poor. Baiocchi et al (2011) use a regression discontinuity empirical design to address the possible conflation of the political effects of voter support for the Partido dos Trabalhadores with the use of the institution of participatory budgeting—they compare outcomes across municipalities where the party won or lost the elections by a narrow margin. These municipalities are therefore similar in voter support for the party, but in only one set, where the party won narrowly, was participatory budgeting adopted by the municipality. They report differences in the process of citizen engagement with the local government, but do not examine impact on outcomes of service delivery or poverty reduction. Further, they conclude that even the impact on greater inclusion of citizens in government decision-making is conditional on pre-existing state-citizen relationships, that is, on the political relationship. Community-driven-development (CDD) projects. Several community- driven-development (CDD) projects "bundle" different interventions that potentially impact each arm of accountability: they change the compact by transferring funds/project management from line ministries to local governments or to newly created local agencies with direct citizen representation (such as school committees); they change client power by allowing such agencies of citizen representation some power over service providers; they change politics by increasing the representation of some groups (women, youth, traditionally marginalized social groups) whose participation in political processes could impact 29 broader political incentives; they also change politics by attempting to increase social cohesion for greater collective action. Again, drawing upon the extensive review of such projects in Mansuri and Rao (Forthcoming), the broad conclusion is that while citizen participation in project design and implementation can have beneficial effects on project outcomes (better design, better quality, better targeting of benefits to the poorest), this varies across communities with variation in characteristics of initial inequality, social cohesion, and state-citizen relations (politics). Furthermore, in the available evidence, there has been little scope to test whether there is any impact on political inclusion of marginalized groups and social cohesion, leading to effects on the politics relationship that could extend beyond the project. Two more recent pieces of work that have attempted to examine impact on political accountability, through broader political inclusion and social cohesion, reach different conclusions. Casey et al (2011) conclude from the detailed examination of a CDD program in Sierra Leone that although it improved local public goods provision and household welfare in the short-run (which could be because of the increased funds provided), there was no long-term or durable impact on local institutions of decision-making, inclusion, and collective action. In contrast, Fearon et al (2009) find in Liberia that a CDD project did not have significant impact on local household welfare measures, but that in project villages the results of behavioral games played with community members indicates greater social cohesion and willingness to contribute to public goods. Community-driven reconstruction in post-conflict settings. The two studies just referenced are examples of particular types of CDD projects with the broader aim of providing benefits to the poor and building social cohesion in post- conflict environments. Once again, a broader review of the evidence of such forms of engaging civil society, both to deliver project benefits and to address the root causes, perhaps, of conflict, concludes with strikingly mixed messages (Mansuri and Rao, Forthcoming). While there are some qualitative cases of success in both delivering benefits to the poor and to ex-combatants, and in engaging civil society to confront violent actors, others find that the poor and marginalized find it even harder to access project benefits in conflict areas, and that governments only selectively scale-up such projects in areas where they command political support. The authors of the positive outcomes measured in Liberia, Fearon et al (2011), point out that their results may not speak to addressing conflict per se, because conflict usually occurs at higher levels than that of the local “community” targeted by CDD/CDR projects. It is even possible that strengthening cohesion within communities may worsen conflict across communities. In sum. Interventions that organize civil society to improve the compact and client-power can be effective; however, much depends on project design and initial conditions of inequality and social cohesion that vary across communities. This does not imply that community participation in projects involving public goods will always fail in communities with high levels of inequality or weak social cohesion (low “social capital). Khwaja (Forthcoming) finds that modifying project design can 30 compensate for such features of local communities in his analysis of community- maintained infrastructure in Northern Pakistan. In particular, reducing project complexity and confining community participation to non-technical aspects of maintenance improved outcomes in “social adverse” settings; moreover, projects initiated by communities and NGOs had much greater success than those started by governments. That is, much depends on whether political relations are sufficiently strong to give incentives to governments to select good project design, tailored to community conditions. More broadly, however, it is almost never possible to make a general statement that civil society engagement is more effective than technocratic changes to the compact between governments and their local agents, bureaucrats and public providers. Even when governments allow (driven by donor or NGO pressure) or elect to undertake projects that engage civil society, they may continue to let their bureaucrats and providers get away with high salaries and low effort in servicing citizens, especially the poor. There has been little scope to test whether participatory interventions at the local level have impact on civil society capacity for demanding accountability outside the narrow scope of specific projects; in the few cases where such testing is possible, there is no evidence of impact outside the project. This pattern of evidence lends itself to a general concern with community participation, that is also expressed in Banerjee and Duflo (2008), that the responsibility for managing successful projects is being palmed-off to largely poor communities, and could be viewed as a tax on their time and efforts; as opposed to other modalities of improving accountability of government agents to work harder and better for the poor. Evidence is particularly lagging on the potentially central domain of how civil society could solve accountability problems in politics and thereby strengthen incentives of higher-tier governments to pursue appropriate interventions for improved compact and client power. For example, there is little rigorous impact evaluation of the role of mass media and cutting-edge communication technologies, that are proliferating across Africa, and being credited in the conventional wisdom with strengthening political accountability; on the contrary, available evidence provides sobering conclusions that media can be either ineffective or even tragically misused. Such large evidence gaps have implications for external aid strategies in supporting civil society in Africa to address accountability failures. 4. Accountability, civil society and external donors Should external donors support civil society to tackle accountability problems in African states? Is this a route to improving delivery of public goods, whether for poverty reduction, human development or dynamic business investment? The analysis of this paper indicates that such action, while surely desirable, is fraught with both difficulties and uncertainties—difficulties because of the intrinsic problem of an external actor seeking to change a socio-political system, and uncertainties because of the weak information on what does and does not work. 31 There is a case for external action, but the intervention needs to be designed in ways that takes account of these constraints, with a particular emphasis on a process of discovery and experimentation of what works. In the core aid community there has been extensive interest in areas related to accountability since the mid-1990s, with activities supporting “governance” and community-driven development (CDD), as well as a longer tradition of support for various aspects of institutional development. The history is cautionary with respect to actual results. For example, reviews of the impact of World Bank support for public sector reform suggest mixed results at best. While there have been some highly celebrated CDD programs (e.g. the Self-help group movement in India), actual evidence of major change is also weak, as indicated in the review of evidence above and other more extensive reviews (Mansuri and Rao, Forthcoming). In this paper we suggest that ignoring the underlying political economy drivers of accountability may have been a principal factor accounting for cases where results were less than satisfactory. First, aid for improved accountability improvements will get lost within a generalized clientelistic or predatory state system, whether the aid is attempting to improve public administration against the grain of the underlying incentives and organizational culture, or supporting small local islands of client power. Second, aid can often be a source of distortions within the system, especially when it is large in scale (as it is in many African countries). Of course, aid is generally trying to change parts of the system, but it all too often has an inadequate theory of change, and becomes a source of unintended, adverse consequences. Support for “civil society” is just as likely to be distortive as accountability-improving, if it is ill- designed. Third, aid for civil society can become a basis for new breeds of rent-seeking NGOs complete with mutually agreeable new narratives, just as African counterparts in the 1980s and 1990s learnt the language of structural adjustment, even while the aid was going into a still highly clientelistic system. Our review of the evidence—that includes a significant proportion of aid-supported initiatives—shows that our current state of knowledge of just how externally supported action interacts with civil society initiatives is very weak, both because many results are limited and ambiguous, and also because most results are for local islands of action, with unusually large uncertainties over scalability. Some practical implications The analysis of this paper presents a difficult challenge: it develops the case for systemic change, while showing the difficulty of external aid initiatives’ doing this successfully (and not making things worse) and the lack of clear evidence on what does work. To resolve this challenge, we suggest some principles that external 32 donors can apply in ensuring that their interventions in supporting civil society to strengthen accountability will lead to an improvement. In general, aid is most likely to be effective if it essentially organic, in the sense of (a) supporting existing domestic initiatives and pressures for change, and (b) in ways that are consistent with the initial state of the polity. The latter is likely to vary significantly across countries. This suggests a procedural case for linking external support with diagnosis of the institutional functioning of a country, sector, region or wherever the focus of desired action is. In addition there are a number of areas where there is a good prima facie case for support, provided the general conditions apply. This will typically be a function of the nature of overall polity. For example, there is the largest range of potential action for democracies with real political competition, albeit of a competitive clientelistic form, whether the regime is consolidated or fragile. Here are some categories.  There is a strong case for general support on information-related initiatives—from information on politician performance, to school test results, procurement processes and so on.  There is also a contingent case for support for local organizational initiatives that are working with and processing information that the evidence base suggests has potential in solving accountability problems. This is related to the broad point that citizens and state actors do not need full information, but information salient to specific aspects of performance assessment. This domain can include NGOs working with right-to-information laws, think tanks analyzing budgets or regulator behavior, or service delivery outcomes, etc.  A related area concerns support for information for benchmarking of performance of local levels of government, e.g. municipalities; or across local service providers (schools; electricity and water supply), where service quality can be measured and compared  It often makes sense to support local client-power-related initiatives, but these are only likely to be fruitful if linked to broader change over the long route.  Support for the strengthening of compact mechanisms is highly desirable if this has domestic political and technical support.  There are two kinds of roles for civil society in the business sector. 33 o Support for processes that provide mechanisms for both identifying and resolving conflicts between business investment and social and environmental concerns, especially in mining and urban development. o Support for business associations working for public goods for business, e.g. agencies such as IFC that are concerned with private business, with the important concern that this needs to take account of conflicts of interest in aid, since such agencies are also often engaged with particular investment projects and firms. Finally, in all cases, there is a need to base any support in an analysis of the nature and functioning of civil society. As has been emphasized here, and as sociologists have also argued, civil society can be a force for pressuring the state to be more responsive to citizens and more equitable, or can be a source of exclusion and the reproduction of inequalities (Baiocchi, Heller and Silva, 2011). Civil society will also typically work very differently under more and less democratic regimes. In general, aid should not be focused on “money”. This can be counter-productive (for reasons mentioned above). Rather, external partners can provide technical assistance in designing locally-grown interventions; they can play a role in financing information-gathering by local NGOs (e.g. Pratham and ASER); and can finance experimental interventions (and their learning). Most valuable is likely to be support for a domestic process of innovation and learning involving a generalized approach of experimentation—of which RCTs are one, but only one, component. Can aid ever lead to transformational changes in accountability relations? Almost certainly not, if designs are hatched and brought in from outside. However, aid can potentially provide a supporting role if it is aligned with the flow of internal initiatives, is consistent with domestic political strategy, and supports greater accountability at the margins of major projects. Our analysis supports the view that recognition of the systemic features of state behavior is fundamental to interpreting the development process. An aspiration to effect some form of system change is admirable, for both internal and external actors. But for donors this needs to be blended with humility over the limits and unintended consequences of external action, and a central focus on helping domestic actors learn by doing. 5. Conclusion This paper has reviewed the potential role of civil society action in increasing the accountability of the state for development in Sub-Saharan Africa. It has focused in particular on the question of whether states can be induced to more effectively deliver the broad range of public goods needed for development, from credible policy commitments for business to universal quality education. It has argued that this question has to be understood in the context of the overall political economy of African societies, and the way in which civil society is constituted and functions. 34 There has been substantial change in African polities in the past two decades, with fewer totally despotic states, a remarkable expansion in democracy, and fewer countries mired in internal conflict. But most states remain deeply clientelistic, or personalistic, or riven along identity lines. State apparatuses typically have weak internal accountability mechanisms, and are sometimes predatory on the citizens. Democratic countries are typically characterized by “competitive clientelism”. Many countries hold elections but are still intermediate, semi-authoritarian regimes. Africa is by no means unique in these respects. We have argued that there is a potential role for civil society action in these contexts. The most important domain for greater accountability is via power and politics. If politicians, and especially leaders, do not have the incentives to deliver on development, putting extra pressure on bureaucratic state agencies is likely to have limited, or local effects. When the political leadership has some commitment to development, civil society may have a role to play in how internal state mechanisms work, including in front-line interactions. However, civil society actors are themselves part of unequal societal structures, in terms of the capacity for collective action, the potential to influence the state, and the extent to which they seek to further general development goals. The variation in civil society is important to both understanding and designing its role in increasing accountability. Moreover, whether civil society engagement will be effective will also depend on whether there is salient information on state performance, resolution of collective action issues among citizens, and on the existence of effective sanctions. With the partial exception of very local interactions (and violent or peaceful revolutionary changes), immediate sanctions will depend on the activation of complementary within-state accountability mechanisms. The review of evidence on specific civil society interventions further underlines the conclusion that effects will be uncertain and contingent. While there are a large number of potentially valuable initiatives underway, only relatively few have been carefully evaluated, especially in the domain of politics, and results have been mixed. The implication is that generalized, “best practice” initiatives for greater civil society engagement are likely to fail. There is a strong prima facie case for greater action, but it is important that this be both organic—building on existing political and civil society structures—and experimental—structured for careful monitoring and assessment of how interventions work in practice and their impact. This applies with particular force to the strategies and support provided by external actors. 35 References: Acemoglu, Daron, Stephen Gelb and James A. Robinson. 2007. “Black Economic Empowerment and Economic Performance in South Africa.” Cambridge, MA: Center for Economic Development, Working Paper. Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Cambridge, UK and New York: Cambridge University Press. Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson. Forthcoming. Why Nations Fail. Book manuscript. Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson. 2001. "The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation." American Economic Review 91 (2001): 1369-1401 _______. 2005. "Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth." Handbook of Economic Growth 1A : 386-472. Aker, Jenny, Paul Collier and Pedro Vicente, 2010. “Is Information Power? Using cell phones during an election in Mozambique,” Working Paper, Department of Economics, Oxford University Alesina, Alberto, Reza Baqir and William Easterly 1999. “Public Goods and Ethnic Divisions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 114(4): 1243-1284 Anderson, Siwan. 2011. “Caste as an impediment to trade,” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 3(1): 239-263. Andrews, Matthew. 2008. "Is Black Economic Empowerment a South African Growth Catalyst? (Or Could it Be?)." Center for International Development Working Papers and HKS Faculty Research Working Paper Series (170 and RWP08-033), June 2008. Arcand, Jean-Louis and Marcel Fafchamps. 2008. “Matching in Community-based Organizations,” Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of Oxford Azam, Jean-Paul. 2001. The Redistributive State and Conflicts in Africa Journal of Peace Research, 38(4): 429-444 Baiocchi, Gianpaolo, Patrick Heller, and Marcelo K. Silva. 2011. “Bootstrapping Democracy: Transforming Local Governance and Civil Society in Brazil” Stanford: Stanford University Press. Banerjee, A., R. Banerji, E. Duflo, R. Glennerster, and S. Khemani, 2010. “Pitfalls of Participatory Programs: Evidence from a randomized evaluation in education in India,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2(1): 1-30. 36 Banerjee, A., D. Green, J. Green, R. Pande. 2010. “Can voters be primed to choose better legislators? Experimental evidence from rural India,” Working Paper, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University Banerjee, A., S. Kumar, R. Pande and F. Su. 2010. “Do informed voters make better choices? Experimental evidence from urban India,” Working Paper, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University Banerjee, Abhijit, and Lakshmi Iyer. 2005. “History, Institutions and Economic Performance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India,” American Economic Review, 95. 1190–1213. Becker, G. S. 1985. “Public policies, pressure groups and deadweight costs,” Journal of Public Economics, 28: 330-47. Bernard, T., M. Collion, A. de Janvry, P. Rondot, and E. Sadoulet. 2008. “Do village organizations make a difference in African rural development? A study for Senegal and Burkina Faso,” World Development, 36(11): 2188-2204. Besley, Timothy and Masayuki Kudamatsu, 2008. "Making Autocracy Work" in Elhanan Helpman (ed.) Institutions and Economic Performance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Besley, Timothy, Rohini Pande, and VijayendraRao. 2004. “The Politics of Public Good Provision: Evidence from Indian Local Governments.” Journal of the European Economic Association 2 (2–3): 416–26. Besley, T. and A. Prat, 2006, Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability. American Economic Review 96, 720-720. Bjorkman, M. and J, Svensson. 2006. “Power to the People: Evidence from a Randomized Experiment of a Community Based Monitoring Project in Uganda.” Mimeo. IIES, Stockholm University Bratton, Michael, Robert Mattes and E. Gyimah-Boadi, 2005. Public Opinion, Democracy and Market Reform in Africa. Cambridge, UK and New York: Cambridge University Press. Bratton, Michael, Ravi Bhavnani and Tse-Hsin Chen, 2011. “Voting Intentions in Africa: Ethnic, Economic or Partisan?” Afrobarometer Working Paper No. 127 Carlitz, R. 2010. “Background paper on budget processes,” Prepared for the Review of Impact and Effectiveness of Transparency and Accountability Initiatives. Brighton, UK: Institute of Development Studies. Casey, K., R. Glennerster, and E, Miguel. 2011. “Re-shaping Institutions: Evidence on external aid and local collective action,” Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of California-Berkeley 37 Chandra, Kanchan. 2004. Why Ethnic Parties Succeed: Patronage and Ethnic Headcounts in India. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. Chaudhury, Nazmul; Jeffrey Hammer, Michael Kremer, Karthik Muralidharan, and F. Halsey Rogers. 2006. “Missing in Action: Teacher and Health Worker Absence in Developing Countries,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Winter 2006, pp 91- 116. Collier, Paul and Pedro Vicente, 2010. “Votes and Violence: Evidence from a field experiment in Nigeria,” Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of Oxford Easterly, William and Ross Levine. 1997. “Africa’s Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4): 1203-1250. Eifert, B., E. Miguel, and D. Posner. 2010. “Political competition and ethnic identification in Africa,” American Journal of Political Science, 54(2): 494- 510. Engerman, Stanley L., and Kenneth L. Sokoloff, 1997. “Factor Endowments, Institutions, and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies: A View from Economic Historians of the United States,” in Stephen Haber, ed., How Latin America Fell Behind 260–304. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 260–304. Fearon, James, Macartan Humphries, and Jeremy Weinstein. 2009. “Can development aid contribute to social cohesion after civil war? Evidence from a field experiment in post-conflict Liberia,” American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 99(2): 287-291. Fehr, Ernst, Karla Hoff and Mayuresh Kshetramade. 2008. “Spite and Development,” American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 98(2): 494-499. Ferraz, C. and F. Finan. 2008. “Exposing Corrupt Politicians: the effect of Brazil’s publicly released audits on electoral outcomes,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(2): 703-745. Gauthier, Bernard and Waly Wane. 2008. “Leakage of Public Resources in the Health Sector: An Empirical Investigation of Chad,” Journal of African Economies, July, 10.1093. Gaventa, John and Gregory Barrett. 2010. “So what difference does it make? Mapping the outcomes of citizen engagement,” IDS Working Paper 347, Institute of Development Studies, Sussex Gugerty, Mary Kay and Michael Kremer. 2008. “Outside Funding and the Dynamics of Participation in Community Associations.” American Journal of Political Science 52(3):585-602 38 Haber, Stephen H., Armando Razo and Noel Maurer. 2003. The Politics of Property Rights: Political Instability, Credible Commitments and Economic Growth in Mexico, 1876-1929. New York: Cambridge University Press. Habyarimana, James, Macartan Humphreys, Daniel N. Posner and Jeremy M. Weinstein. 2007. “Why does ethnic diversity undermine public goods provision?” American Political Science Review, 101(04): 709-725. Harding, Robin and David Stasavage. 2011. “What Democracy Does (and Doesn’t) Do for Basic Services: School Fees, School Quality and African Elections,” Working Paper, Department of Politics, New York University Hubbard, P. 2007. “Putting the power of transparency in context: Information’s role in reducing corruption in Uganda’s education sector,” Working Paper No. 136, Center for Global Development, Washington DC Humphreys, M. and J, Weinstein. 2010. Policing politicians: citizen empowerment and political accountability in Uganda. Mimeo. Columbia University, Department of Political Science Keefer, P. and S. Khemani, 2011a. “Mass Media and Public Services: The Effects of Radio Access on Public Education in Benin,” Policy Research Working Paper Number 5559, Development Research Group, The World Bank Keefer, P. and S. Khemani, 2011b. “The Role of Mass Media in Poor Democracies: Impact of Radio on the Distribution of Anti-Malaria Bed-nets in Benin,” Mimeo, Development Research Group, The World Bank Keefer, P. and S. Khemani, 2009. “Why do some legislators pass on “pork”? The role of political parties in determining legislator effort,” American Political Science Review, 103(1): 99-112. Keefer, Philip and Stuti Khemani. 2005. “Democracy, Public Expenditures, and the Poor: Understanding Political Incentives for Providing Public Services.” World Bank Research Observer. 20 (1): 1–28. Keefer Philip and Razvan Vlaicu. 2008. “Democracy, Credibility and Clientelism,” The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization,” 24(2): 371-406. Kelsall, Tim. 2002. Shop windows and smoke-filled rooms: governance and the re- politicisation of Tanzania. Journal of Modern African Studies 40 (4):597-620. Khemani, Stuti. 2007. “Can Information Campaigns Overcome Political Obstacles to Serving the Poor?” In The Politics of Service Delivery in Democracies: Better Access for the Poor, Shanta Devarajan and Ingrid Widlund (Eds.), Expert Group on Development Issues, Ministry for Foreign Affairs, Sweden, 2007 39 Khwaja, Asim Ijaz. Forthcoming. Can Good Projects Succeed in Bad Communities? Forthcoming, Journal of Public Economics. Kingdon, G. and M. Muzammil. 2001. “A Political Economy of Education in India,” Economic and Political Weekly, 36(32): 3052-3063 Kitschelt, Herbert and Steven I. Wilkinson. 2008. Patrons, Clients and Policies. Patterns of Democratic Accountability and Political Competition. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. Kudamatsu, Masayuki. 2011. “Has Democratization Reduced Infant Mortality in Sub- Saharan Africa? Evidence from Micro Data.” Forthcoming in Journal of the European Economic Association La Ferrara, Eliana. 2002. “Inequality and group participation: theory and evidence from rural Tanzania,” Journal of Public Economics, 85(2): 235-73. Maskin, Eric, and Jean Tirole. 2004. “The Politician and the Judge: Accountability in Government”, American Economic Review, 94(4): 1034-1054 Mann, Michael. 1986. The Sources of Social Power: A History of Power from the Beginning to AD 1760. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Mansuri, Ghazala and Vijayendra Rao, Forthcoming. “Localizing Development: Does Participation Work?” Policy Research Report, Development Research Group, The World Bank McGee, R. and J. Gaventa. 2010. Synthesis Report: Review of impact and effectiveness of transparency and accountability initiatives. Transparency and Accountability Initiative, Open Society Foundation, London, UK Montalvo, José G. and Marta Reynal-Querol. 2010. “Ethnic Polarization and the Duration of Civil Wars.” Economics of Governance 11(2). Mullainathan, S. and A. Shleifer, 2002, Media Bias, (National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, NBER Working Papers: 9295). Nguyen, Trang and Gerard Lassibille. 2008. “Improving management in education: Evidence from a randomized experiment in Madagascar,” MIT Poverty Action Lab Working Paper, Cambridge, MA North, Douglass C., John Wallis and Barry Weingast. 2009. Violence and Social Orders New York: Cambridge University Press Olken, B. A., 2007, Monitoring Corruption: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Indonesia. Journal of Political Economy 115, 200-249. 40 Pan, Lei and Luc Christiansen. 2011. “Who is vouching for the input voucher: Decentralized Targeting and Elite Capture in Tanzania,” mimeo, World Bank. Pandey, Priyanka, Sangeeta Goyal and Venkatesh Sundararaman, 2009. “Community participation in public schools: impact of information campaigns in three Indian states.” Education Economics 13(3): 355-375 Paul, Samuel, 2002. Holding the State to Account: Citizen Monitoring in Action. Bangalore, Books for Change Pierce, Steven. 2006. "Looking Like a State: Colonialism and the Discourse of Corruption in Northern Nigeria." Comparative Studies in Society and History 48(4): 887-914 Polity IV. http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.htm Downloaded June 1, 2011 Prat, Andrea. 2005. “The Wrong Kind of Transparency”, American Economic Review, 95(3): 862-877 Qian, Nancy and David Yanagizawa-Drott. 2010. “Watchdog or Lapdog? The Effect of U.S. Strategic Objectives on Human Rights News Coverage during the Cold War,” NBER Working Paper No. 15738. Rajan, Raghuram. 2009. “Rent Preservation and the Persistence of Underdevelopment”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1(1): 178-218 Reinikka, R. and J. Svensson, 2004, Local Capture: Evidence from a Central Government Transfer Program in Uganda. Quarterly Journal of Economics 119, 679-705. Reinikka, R. and J. Svensson, 2005. “Fighting Corruption to Improve Schooling: Evidence from a Newspaper Campaign in Uganda”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 2005, vol. 3 (2-3): 259-267 Robinson, James A. and Thierry Verdier. 2002. “The Political Economy of Clientelism” CEPR, Working Paper 3205; Schaffer, F. 2005. “Clean Elections and the Great Unwashed: Vote Buying and Voter Education in the Philippines,” Paper Number 21, School of Social Science, Institute of Advanced Study, Princeton NJ Stromberg, D. 2004a. “Radio's Impact on Public Spending,”Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(1): 189-221. Tendler, J. 1997. Good Government in the Tropics, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, MD 41 Teranavithorn, Supee and Gael Raballand. 2009. Transport Prices and Costs in Africa¸ World Bank. Tullock, G. 1959. “Some problems of majority voting,” Journal of Political Economy, 67: 571-79. van de Walle, Nicolas. 2001. African Economies and the Politics of Permanent Crisis, 1979-1999. New York: Cambridge University Press. Vicente, Pedro C. 2010. “Is Vote-buying Effective? Evidence from a field experiment in West Africa,” Working Paper, Trinity College, Dublin Vicente, Pedro C. and Leonard Wantchekon. 2009 “Clientelism and Vote Buying: Lessons from Field Experiments in African Elections”. Oxford Review of Economic Policy Wantchekon, Leonard. 2009. “Can Informed Public Deliberation Overcome Clientelism? Experimental evidence from Benin,” Working Paper, Department of Politics, New York University Wantchekon, Leonard. 2003. “Clientelism and Voting Behavior: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Benin” World Politics 55: 399-422 World Bank. 2003. World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for Poor People, Washington DC World Bank. 2007. Uganda: Public Expenditure Review, Report number 40161-UG, Washington, DC Yanagizawa-Drott, David. 2010. “Propaganda and Conflict: Theory and Evidence from the Rwandan Genocide,” Working Paper, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University Young, Daniel J. 2009. “Support you can count on? Ethnicity, partisanship, and retrospective voting in Africa,” Afrobarometer Working Paper No. 115. 42 Table 1: Civil Society Activity Across Countries: Afrobarometer Round 4, 2008 Country Percentage of Respondents Answering “Yes” to: Often Often Punishment Voted in Active joined Willing to attended likely if last member of others demonstrate group people elections a group to raise or protest meetings complain an issue Polity IV Score Between 10 and 6 (“full democracies”) South Africa 65 16 29 20 45 46 Botswana 59 17 55 39 52 19 Lesotho 61 28 67 50 52 74 Ghana 81 35 40 38 30 32 Senegal 79 28 60 55 62 60 Mali 77 29 57 55 59 46 Kenya 79 43 44 35 40 37 Benin 91 23 53 50 65 25 Zambia 59 24 45 33 45 47 Liberia 78 45 50 42 24 40 Malawi 75 22 60 54 50 27 Avg: 73.09 28.18 50.91 42.82 47.64 41.18 Polity IV Score Between 6 and 2: Mozambique 60 18 49 45 57 47 Nigeria 60 27 30 26 43 57 Avg: 60 22.5 39.5 35.5 50 52 Polity IV Score Between 2 and -2: Zimbabwe 61 16 51 38 42 44 Madagascar 70 4 75 29 20 61 Burkina 72 18 59 52 63 53 Uganda 70 31 44 33 35 41 Tanzania 82 35 64 51 65 57 Avg: 71 20.80 58.6 40.6 45 51.2 Appendix Literature Review (Prepared by Avnish Gungadurdoss) Paper Title Country/ Leg of Mechanism How Role played by Nature of Category Measured Abstract Region Triangle civil society Analysis of Impacts actors findings Abstract: Institutional performance is thought to be a key determinant of economic success, however there is little evidence on how best to reform existing institutions. Foreign aid donors spend substantial resources on ―community driven development programs that combine the provision of public goods with intensive long term facilitation designed to strengthen local 1) Improved institutions; make them more democratic and Provided an service delivery inclusive of marginalized social groups; and opportunitiy (public goods) enhance the capacity of communities to for collective but no This was a engage in collective action. This paper enterprise, distinction are government evaluates the effectiveness of one such Katherine Casey, founded on made regarding initiative in line program in post-war Sierra Leone using a Rachel democratic the channels with the post- randomized methodology. Data collection Glennerster, institutions (addressing conflict combined rich survey instruments with a set Edward Miguel, meant to accountability Compact, Solving decentralization of novel structured community activities Experimental empower the Improved or simply Sierra Client collective strategy: designed to measure how real world Evidence on marginalized. RCT Service higher input of Leone Power, action Facilitators collective action and participation changed External Aid and The hope Delivery resources) Politics problems introduced over the four year program (2005-2009). We Community then is that 2) No impact on practices aimed find positive impacts on the establishment of Institutions in those village-level at making local local development committees, local public Sierra Leone, JPAL artificial institutions decision- goods provision, links between communities working papers institutions (inclusiveness making more and local government officials, household would spill in decision- democratic. economic welfare, and village-level market over onto making, better activity. However, we do not find any existing collective program impacts on community social norms. action ability, norms, the role of women and youths in local etc..) affairs, more egalitarian decision making or the capacity for collective action beyond the immediate project sphere. Overall, these findings suggest that community driven development programs and related donor projects may leave communities materially better off but may be less effective in fundamentally transforming local institutions or power dynamics. Abhijit Banerjee, Esther Duflo, “Addressing THIS PAPER REVIEWS THE NEXT 3 STUDIES DESCRIBED IN GREATER DETAIL BELOW: Absence” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 20, No. 1 (Winter, 2006), pp. 117-132 The RCT’s treatment was to link teacher’s bonuses and penalties to their attendance levels. Using cameras with tamper-proof date NGO (Seva and time function to monitor daily Duflo, Esther and Mandir) attendance, the experiment decreased Linking Rema Hanna. monitored absence rate by half. When in school, bonus and 2005. "Monitoring teacher teachers were as likely to teach in both penalties to Increased Works: Getting Financial attendance with Improved control and treatment groups. Despite that, attendance teacher Teachers to Come India Compact sanctions the help of RCT Service given increases in teacher attendance, the rate, recorded attendance and to School." Mimeo, and benefits clients - Delivery number of children-days taught in treatment using tamper- children-days Massachusetts children in increased by one third. In addition, given proof Institute of school in charge structure of the pay, the average salary in the cameras Technology of taking two groups was almost equal. The cost of the pictures cameras and administration of the program amounted to $6 per child per year for an increase of over 30 percent in the number of days the child is taught, This experiment explored the idea of boosting teacher attendance with a prize (a bicycle). The allocation of the prize was to be determined by the headmaster. In all treatment schools, the headmasters marked the preschool teachers present a sufficient number of times for them to receive the prize (and they therefore all got it). However, Kremer, Michael Linking when the research team independently and Daniel Chen. bonus to verified absence through unannounced visits NGO (ICS 2001. "An Interim attendence in both treatment and comparison schools, Africa) funded Report on a Financial rate - they found that the absence rate was actually and Teacher Kenya Compact sanctions monitoring RCT None No effect at exactly the same high level in treatment implemented Attendance and benefits and and in comparison schools. Either to avoid the incentive Incentive Program distribution the unpleasantness of a personal system in Kenya." Mimeo, done by confrontation, or out of compassion for the Harvard University headmaster preschool teachers, headmasters apparently cheated to make sure that the preschool teachers could get the prizes. This outcome suggests that when human judgment is involved in a system where rules are often bent, incentives may easily be perverted, either as in this case in an equitable direction or to favor some specific individuals or groups. The Kenyan experiment provides incentives to teachers based on the test scores of students in their class. ICS Africa (NGO) provided prizes to teachers in grades 4 to 8 based on the performance of the school as a whole on the district exams in each year. All teachers who taught these grades were eligible for the prize. Prizes were awarded in two categories: "Top-scoring schools" and "Most-improved schools." Schools could not win in more than one category. Improvements were calculated relative to performance in the base-line year. In each category, three first, second, third and fourth prizes were awarded. Out of the 50 schools participating in the program, 24 received prizes of some type, and teachers in most schools should have felt that they had a chance of winning a prize. Prizes ranged in Improved value from 21 to 43 percent of typical service delivery teacher monthly salaries. Glewwe, Paul, NGO (ICS as measured by The comparison of the 50 treatment and 50 Nauman Ilias and Linking Africa) funded short-term control schools suggested that this program Michael Kremer. Financial bonus to Improved and outcomes (test did improve performance in the district 2003. "Teacher Kenya Compact sanctions objective RCT Service implemented scores) but no exams (by about 0.14 standard deviations), Incentives." and benefits performance Delivery the incentive effect on long- but had no effect on teacher attendance. Mimeo, Harvard measures system term Instead, the teachers held more test University educational preparation sessions. This, the authors outcomes. conclude, was rational based on the (limited) evidence on what is most effective in improving test scores over the short horizon. However, these preparation sessions are probably poor substitutes for regular classes. This method of pushing up test scores did little for long-term learning, as evidenced by the fact that once the program ended, students who had been in the program schools did not out-perform those in control schools. The lesson from this experiment seems to be that if we want to boost teacher attendance by providing incentives for teachers, the incentive must be tied directly to attendance. Incentives help teachers get a better sense of what their objectives are and will lead them to focus on the most painless way to achieve this particular objective The experiment explores if and how villagers organize themselves to discipline service providers upon provision of monitoring information regarding the attendance rates of the service providers. A member of the community was paid to check once a week, on unannounced days, whether the auxiliary nurse-midwife assigned to the health sub- center was present in the center, and if she was not there, whether she could be found in Community Banerjee, Abhijit, the village. A parallel system (a monthly member Angus Deaton and visit by a member of the survey team, on the individually Esther Duflo. 1) Improved Disseminatin same day) confirmed that this system of local monitored 2004a. "Health information g information monitoring was properly implemented: Client health Care Delivery in India 2) Financial on attendance RCT None No effect external monitors and community members Power employees and Rural Rajasthan." sanctions on weekly found similar absence rates. However, no reporting to Economic and and benefits basis attempt was made to impose an external other Political Weekly. reward system for the nurse-midwives based community 39:9, pp. 944-49. on the monitoring information. The idea members behind this experiment was to let the villagers choose how they would use the monitoring information they were generating. For example, the villagers could choose to put explicit pressure on the nurse- midwife or try to shame her by exposing her absences. They could even promise her some explicit rewards. In this case, the collective action problem in monitoring stood in the way of effective local control. Disseminate Strengthening the relationship of information accountability between health service Community- on providers and citizens is by many people based community’s viewed as critical for improving access to organizations Martina Björkman, entitlements, and quality of health care. How this is to be facilitated Jakob Svensson aggregate achieved, and whether it works, however, initial (2007) “Power to outcomes, remain open questions. This paper presents a dessemination the People: status of randomized field experiment on increasing 1) Solving of report cards Evidence from a health service community-based monitoring. As collective at community The quantity of Randomized Field delivery Improved communities began to more extensively Client action meetings. They services Experiment of a Uganda compared to RCT Service monitor the provider, both the quality and Power problems also guided delivered Community-Based other Delivery quantity of health service provision 2) Improved community increases Monitoring Project communities improved. One year into the program, we information members in in Uganda” Policy & external find large increases in utilization, significant designing a Research Working support by weight-for-age z-score gains of infants, and monitoring plan Paper Series 4268, local NGO in markedly lower deaths among children. The and revising it The World Bank addressing findings on state’s behavior suggest that the midway the free-rider improvements in quality and quantity of through the problem of health service delivery resulted from an program monitoring increased effort by the state to serve the by increasing community. Overall, the results suggest that organizationa community monitoring can play an important l capacity and role in improving service delivery when encouraging traditional top-down supervision is communities ineffective. to develop their own monitoring strategy that they could manage and sustain Martina Björkman The & Jakob Svensson This is a follow-up examination of the above improvement in (2010) "When Is experiment (Bjorkman, Svensson 2009) services is Community-Based focusing on the effect of communities’ social largest for the Monitoring heterogeneity on their ability to address the most Effective? Evidence collective action problem. Evidence reveals homogenous from a Randomized substantial heterogeneous treatment effects communities, Experiment in 1) Solving within the treated group. Using data from the Improved signifying that Primary Health in Client collection same as randomized experiment in primary health in Uganda same as above RCT Service there is a Uganda," Journal Power action above Uganda (described above), the authors test Delivery greater ability of the European problem whether social heterogeneity can explain to coordinate Economic why some treated communities managed to collective Association, MIT push for better health service delivery while action within Press, vol. 8(2-3), others did not. The results suggest that ethnic groups as pages 571-581, 04- income inequality, and particularly ethnic compared to 05. fractionalization, adversely impact collective across ethnic Follow up on action for improved service provision. groups. above study The poor and disadvantaged are widely seen International as having weak organizations and low rates NGO of participation in community associations, (International 1) Outside impeding their political representation and Mary Kay Gugerty Child Support) funding did not economic advancement. Many policy and Michael provided expand initiatives aim to build civic participation Kremer, “Outside assistance in the organizational among the disadvantaged by funding local Funding and the form of strength, community associations. Taking advantage Dynamics of External agricultural Shifts in 2) of random assignment in a program Group 1) Solving Participation in funding for inputs, inequalitie Substantial evid supporting women's community associations Formation collection Community Kenya local organizational RCT s of ence that in Kenya, we find little evidence that outside Client action Associations”, women's and group access/infl funding funding expanded organizational strength, power problem American Journal associations management uence changed group but substantial evidence that funding of Political training and membership changed group membership and leadership, Science, Vol. 52, agricultural and leadership, weakening the role of the disadvantaged. The No. 3 (Jul., 2008), training in the weakening the program led younger, more educated, and pp. 585-602 hope of role of the better-off women to enter the groups. New strengthening disadvantaged. entrants, men, and more educated women the group assumed leadership positions. The departure membership of older women, the most socially marginalized demographic group, increased substantially. The results are generalized through a formal model showing how democratic decision making by existing members of community associations can generate long-run outcomes in which the poor and disadvantaged either do not belong to any associations or belong to weak organizations. In Tanzania, corruption posed a threat to successful implementation of poverty reduction strategies. To tackle this problem, the government undertook public expenditure reviews (PER) in priority areas such as education and health. Given the highly participatory environment under which the country had undertaken its strategy and reform process, in 2004 a local NGO— the Rural Initiatives and Relief Agency (RIRA)—undertook a pilot funded by the Partnership for Transparency Fund to track public expenditures. Without public access to information on local government budgets and NGO REPORT spending, officials cannot be held (2004) “Rural 1) The project accountable. The NGO saw a need in Initiatives and was effective in Tanzania—where local government Relief Agency Local NGO those villages in authorities must disseminate information on (RIRA) – Report RIRA External Improved ensuring that revenues and expenditures—to develop a for a Pilot Public Client 1) Improved undertook Qualitativ Tanzania support by Service commitments to model for effective monitoring and Expenditure Power information public e NGO Delivery deliver funds evaluation in villages. There was particular Tracking in 10 expenditure for health and emphasis on education, which represents the Villages of Magu tracking education were largest disbursement to villages. District”. met. • According to a RIRA survey, only 10 Partnership for percent of villagers had seen information on Transparency. education or health spending, required by law. The project found that communities were not involved in decision-making, received little information, and cannot easily lodge grievances. • In 2004, the pilot-program assisted communities in track government disbursements for health and education development for ten villages in the Magu district. • A replicable model for public expenditure tracking was built. • The project mobilized community participation in public expenditure tracking. This paper evaluates several interventions in Madagascar that sought to promote top-down and local monitoring of the school to improve education quality. Randomly 1) Top-down selected school districts and subdistricts monitoring by received operational tools to facilitate the district and sub- administrators’ supervision tasks. Randomly district selected schools in these treated districts administrators were reinforced with teacher tools and had no parent-teacher meetings centered around a significant school report card. The other schools in impacts treated districts did not receive any direct Group of 2) Beneficiary intervention; it was up to the administrators 1) External parents 1) Improved monitoring to distribute the report cards and tools, and Trang Nguyen, support by (beneficiaries) information improved test implement effective monitoring in those Gerard Lassibille, Government, attended 2) scores by 0.1 places. We find little impact of targeting Improving in terms of meetings where Leveraging standard district and subdistrict administrators on their Management in training for report cards of social deviations after behavior and on the performance of the Education: district and teacher Compact sanctions Improved 2 years and schools under their jurisdiction. Meanwhile, Evidence from a Madagas sub-district performance v/s Client through RCT Service teacher's the intervention implemented at the school Randomized car administrator were Power regular Delivery behavior level led to an improvement in various Experiment in s and teachers distributed, meetings improved in observable performance measures. Teachers Madagascar, MIT as well as to giving between lesson planning prepared lesson plans and evaluated their Poverty Action Lab structure credibility to school and giving students more frequently. Teacher attendance Working Paper, parents- the social teachers and evaluations. and communication with parents did not June 2008 teachers sanction parents Tasks that did improve, consistent with predictions of the meetings mechanism at were not multitasking principal-agent problem. On play. specifically balance, the effect of the school intervention measured, such on student attendance was positive: 4.3 as teacher percentage point increase from 87% mean attendance or attendance. Test scores also improved by 0.1 communication standard deviations after two years, with parents, particularly in math and Malagasy. These did not results suggest that improving management improve. via mediated control in the hands of government bureaucrats does not do much in this context, while beneficiary monitoring leads to an improvement in teaching activities and student achievement. Reinikka, R. and 1) Public This paper demonstrates that public service Svensson, J. 2005. Information Expenditure capture of government funds should increase “Fighting on central Economet Tracking as information regarding funding becomes Corruption to grant ric - IV surveys, when more available to the public. The author Improve Schooling: disbursal estimation Improved made public studied central government funding received Client 1) Improved Evidence from a Uganda published and Service and linked to by public schools in Uganda after a 1996 Power information Newspaper monthly by difference Delivery public newspaper campaign to provide grant Campaign in the -in- information information to schools and parents. Average Uganda.” Journal government difference campaigns, can school capture of central government grants of the European to increase contribute to increased from 20% before the campaign to Economic awareness of reducing 80% in 2001. As teachers demonstrated more Association 3 (2- parents and leakages in knowledge of grant capture in a survey 3): 259-267. schools delivery of conducted during the study and as the service sector distance to a newspaper stand from the budgets locally school decreased, the percent of grant money captured by the school increased. "It is a mistake to attribute the entire reduction in corruption to a single publication policy. Reinikka and Svennson's research focuses on a Hubbard, P. (2007) small but ‘Putting the Power significant One of the popular stories told (and taught) of Transparency in element - in development circles is how corruption was Context: information slashed in Uganda simply by publishing the Information’s Role provided amount of monthly grants to schools. This in Reducing through paper takes a deeper look at the facts behind Corruption in newspapers to the Uganda story and finds that while Uganda’s THIS PAPER OFFERS A DIRECT CRITICISM OF THE RENIKKA AND local schools. information did indeed play a critical role, Education Sector.’ Uganda SVENSSON PAPER DESCRIBED ABOVE --> More specifically it claims that But their the story is much more complicated than we Working Paper there were concurring changes in Politics and Compact as well. research is best have been led to believe. A dramatic drop did Number 136. understood in occur in the percentage of funds being Washington, DC: terms of diverted from Uganda’s capitation grant. But Center for Global concurrent to attribute this leakage solely to the monthly Development. reforms in release of grant data by the government risks Available at Uganda's ignoring the major funding in which this http://www.cgdev.o education and transparency campaign was imbedded rg/content/publicati fiscal systems. ons/detail/15050/ This paper examines a number of other policies and reforms that help explain the reported decline in corruption to Ugandan education in the 1990s." Why would government officials in This is a In the absence authoritarian and transitional systems where model of of strong formal democratic and bureaucratic informal institutions and institutions of accountability are often weak government Villagers create in the presence ever provide more than the minimum level of accountability and leverage of weak formal public goods needed to maintain social Tsai, L. L, whereby encompassing accountability stability? Findings from a unique “Solidary groups, citizens and powerful systems, combination of in-depth case study research informal Client award public social networks embedding and an original survey of 316 accountability, and Power Social official with (such as Improved public officials villages in rural China indicate that even local public goods China and/or Sanctions / valuable religious Service or elected when formal accountability is weak., local provision in rural Local Benefits 'moral groups) to Delivery representatives officials can be subject to unofficial rules and china”, 2007, Politics standing' for sanction/ in norms that establish and enforce their public American Political above incentivize encompassing obligations. These informal institutions of Science Review average local officials social groups accountability can be provided by 101, (02): 355-72. performance and elected (solidary encompassing and embedding solidary and hence representatives groups) lead to groups. Villages where these types of groups incentivize higher levels of exist are more likely to have better local public good public good governmental public goods provision than provision provision. villages without these solidary groups, all other things being equal Pay for Paying for performance (P4P) provides performance financial incentives for providers to increase incentivizes the use and quality of care. P4P can affect providers to health care by providing incentives for increase service providers to put more effort into specific delivery (where activities, and by increasing the amount of possible) and resources available to finance the delivery of also increase services. This paper evaluates the impact of quality of P4P on the use and quality of prenatal, services. In institutional delivery, and child preventive addition, when care using data produced from a prospective WORLD BANK Linking particular quasi-experimental evaluation nested into the REPORT: "Paying payment to services (such national rollout of P4P in Rwanda. Treatment Primary Health Increased performance, Difference Improved as deliveries) facilities were enrolled in the P4P scheme in Care Centers for Monitoring/ Rwanda Compact measured by n/a -in- service are rewarded 2006 and comparison facilities were enrolled Performance in Incentive quantity and difference delivery better than two years later. The incentive effect is Rwanda", Policy systems quality others, there is isolated from the resource effect by Research Working indicators evidence of increasing comparison facilities’ input-based Paper 5190. greater effort to budgets by the average P4P payments to the increase quality treatment facilities. The data were collected and also from 166 facilities and a random sample of outreach in 2158 households. P4P had a large and those services, significant positive impact on institutional through health deliveries and preventive care visits by care providers. young children, and improved quality of Thus, if prenatal care. The authors find no effect on designed the number of prenatal care visits or on properly, P4P immunization rates. P4P had the greatest can be targeted effect on those services that had the highest to improve payment rates and needed the lowest specific provider effort. P4P financial performance services. incentives can improve both the use of and the quality of health services. Because the analysis isolates the incentive effect from the resource effect in P4P, the results indicate that an equal amount of financial resources without the incentives would not have achieved the same gain in outcomes. In this paper, we report on a meta-case study analysis of a ten-year research programme on citizenship, participation and accountability, which analysed a nonrandomized sample of 100 research studies of four types of citizen Maps positive engagement in 20 countries. By mapping the and negative observable effects of citizen participation outcomes of through a close reading of these studies, we citizenship Barret Gregory created a typology of four democratic and engagement and Gaventa John, developmental outcomes, including (a) the initiatives into 4 "So what difference construction of citizenship, (b) the Qualitativ different does it make? Various strengthening of practices of participation, e- categories and Mapping the types of (c) the strengthening of responsive and Various Various n/a n/a Synthesis n/a offers an insight outcomes of Citizen citizen accountable states, and (d) the development of 100 on future Engagement", IDS engagement of inclusive and cohesive societies. We find studies approach to Working Paper that citizen participation produces positive citizen Volume 2010 effects across these outcome types, though in engagement - Number 347 each category there are also examples of Very good negative outcomes of citizen participation. summary of We also find that these outcomes vary qualitative according to the type of citizen engagement literature and to political context. These findings have important implications for the design of and support for participatory programmes meant to improve state responsiveness and effectiveness. Mcgee, Rosemary, Gaventa John (2010) “Review of Impact and Effectiveness of Transparency and ALL STUDIES LISTED BELOW ARE DRAWN FROM THE MCGEE, GAVENTA Synthesis Report Accountability Initiatives: Synthesis Report”, Institute of Development Studies Ravindra, A. (2004) ‘An This review finds that citizen report cards Assessment of the Citizens report Improved have been an important vehicle for civil Impact of grievances and quality of society action in Bangalore, and that they Bangalore Citizen civil societies services have had a significant impact on the quality Report Cards on User and NGOs through of public services. The review identifies the Performance of feedback in increase their increased civic success factors and considers the replicability Public Agencies.’ Report cards level of Improved activism, Client 1) Improved Qualitativ of the report card approach. 2 citizen Report Evaluation India can be used activism using Service increased public Power information e Cards, in 1994 and 1999, collected citizen's Capacity to hold public grievances to Delivery awareness and feedback on the performance of 8 major Development officials hold public increased client Public Service Agencies in Bangalore. The Working Paper accountable officials and orientation on study conducts targeted interviews with no.12, Operations local the part of NGOs and to assess the role of and extent to Evaluation government Public Service which report cards align public officials' Department. accountable Agencies performance with public needs. Washington, DC: World Bank. How can public sector service providers deliver improved services to citizens within environments where inefficient and often corrupt service delivery is the norm? The 1) Senior following paper provides some answers to Managers and this question through examining the impact front-line of a series of customer-focused service providers delivery reforms undertaken at the organize Hyderabad Metropolitan Water Supply and Caseley, J. (2003) meetings with Sewerage Board (Metro Water) in ‘Blocked Drains citizens to Hyderabad City, Andhra Pradesh state, 1) Improved and Open Minds: identify needs Complaint Southern India at the end of the 1990s. The information Multiple 2) Citizens mechanisms Metro Water case is interesting, as it shows 2) Providing Accountability also lodge can contribute how a semi-autonomous service provider can a compact Relationships and complaints to reduction of undertake organisational change and realise with greater Improved Service Client through Improved corruption, by sustained improvements in service delivery independenc Case- Delivery India Power and formal n/a Service linking citizens performance. If this process is deepened over e from study Performance in an Compact system to Delivery directly to time there is a greater opportunity to attract, politicians Indian City.’ IDS increase managers who and provide security for, larger state or and better Working Paper information can then hold private sector investments that can impact performance 211. Brighton, UK: flow managers to water supply and sewerage service delivery measuremen Institute of 3) The extent account over the long-term. This is the scenario that t Development to which emerges in the following case. A key finding Studies. complaints in this research is that multiple accountability are addressed relationships, operating between external is used as a actors and Metro Water staff, have measurement collectively contributed to sustained of organisational change and improved service performance delivery performance. The most critical of these relationships are those that triangulate between citizens, senior managers, and ìfront-lineî workers. In the Metro Water case active citizen engagement through formal accountability mechanisms has been the key to the organisationís overall success in delivering improved services to citizens (both middle class and urban poor) throughout Hyderabad City. Participation of beneficiaries in the monitoring of public services is increasingly seen as a key to improving their efficiency. In India, the current government flagship Information program on universal primary education provision has organizes both locally elected leaders and been found to parents of children enrolled in public schools have little into committees and gives these groups impact by itself powers over resource allocation, and on the level of monitoring and management of school engagement by performance. However, in a baseline survey Banerjee, A., citizens in we found that people were not aware of the Duflo, E., Provision of engaging for existence of these committees and their Glennerster, R., information, accountability potential for improving education. This paper Banerji, R. and training of with school evaluates three different interventions to Khemani, S. (2010) community systems in one encourage beneficiaries’ participation ‘Pitfalls of members and study. There is through these committees: providing Participatory External supplementin evidence that information, training community members in Programs: Client 1) Improved support in India g public RCT None citizens are a new testing tool, and training and Evidence from a Power information experimental education constrained and organizing volunteers to hold remedial Randomized setting system with a cannot reading camps for illiterate children. We find Evaluation of parallel participate in that these interventions had no impact on Education in remedial one improving the community involvement in public schools, India.’ American motored by education and no impact on teacher effort or learning Economic Journal: volunteers. system. This outcomes in those schools. However, we do Economic Policy highlights the find that the intervention that trained 2(1): 1-30. regressive volunteers to teach children to read had a nature of large impact on activity outside public participatory schools—local youths volunteered to be approaches and trained to teach, and children who attended also may reflect these camps substantially improved their the free rider reading skills. These results suggest that problem citizens face substantial constraints in participating to improve the public education system, even when they care about education and are willing to do something to improve it. This study evaluates the impact of a community-based information campaign on school performance from a cluster randomized control trial in 610 villages. The Information campaign consisted of eight or nine public was given to meetings in each of 340 treatment villages increase the across three Indian states to disseminate awareness of When information to the community about its state- parents and information mandated roles and responsibilities in school community provision is tied management. No intervention took place in Pandey, P., Goyal, members on to a control villages. At baseline there are no S. and important community– significant differences in school outcomes. Sundararaman, V. processes that based This paper reports on the first follow up (2009) 'Community influence the information survey that took place two to four months Participation in Citizens act quality of campaign, after the intervention. We find that providing Public Schools: upon Improved Client 1) Improved schools. Thus positive impacts information through a structured campaign to Impact of India information to RCT Service Power information parents were were found on communities had a positive impact in all Information pressurize Delivery empowered citizen three states. However, there are differences Campaigns in school system to engage engagement, across states in where the impact occurs. The Three Indian with the teacher most notable impacts occurred on teacher States', Education school system engagement and effort, while impacts on learning were more Economics 17(3): (with scholastic modest. Some improvements also occurred 287-89. teachers, outcomes in in the delivery of benefits entitled to students committees, UP, MP and (stipend, uniform and mid-day meal) and in funding Karnataka process variables such as community process, etc..) participation in each of the three states. and hold it Future research needs to examine whether accountable. there is a systematic increase in learning when the impact is measured over a longer time period and whether a campaign sustained over longer duration generates greater impact on school outcomes. Whether this diffusion of Participatory Budgeting (PB) is seen as cause for celebration or cause for alarm should depend on both how PB is interpreted and how it is being implemented in its new environs. Interpretations of PB, especially as practiced in Porto Alegre, the Brazilian city that named and publicized it, abound. Yet studies of how PB is practiced, especially outside of Brazil, Participatory are only beginning to emerge. Most budgeting importantly, systematic comparisons of the initiatives can variety of ways in which PB is designed and Goldfrank, B. contribute to implemented in practice remain exceptional. (2006) ‘Lessons multiple With the aim of contributing to this emerging from Latin outcomes, area of scholarship, this chapter attempts a American including preliminary analysis of the more recent Experience in improved Citizens efforts at introducing participatory Participatory public services, participate in mechanisms into local government budget Budgeting.’ Paper Multiple, re-direction of Involve decision- processes. After a brief section defining PB Presented at the but resources to Politics, clients in making of Improved and outlining its history, I present the major Latin American largely Case- poor Client decision- municipalities Service normative perspectives on PB as well as a Studies Association Brazil or study communities, Power making on and other Delivery number of sometimes corresponding Meeting, San Juan, Latin new civic budgets government analytical perspectives. Combining Puerto Rico, America associations, units on arguments made in earlier work, the broad March. etc., budgets. hypothesis I advance is that the design and, Available at strengthened partially in turn, the results of PB depend on http://www.internat democratic both the designing actors’ intentions and the ionalbudget.org/the processes, etc., preexisting conditions in the particular mes/PB/LatinAmer but there are locale. This translates into a number of ica.pdf also specific suggestions. The most important of contradictory these are that introducing PB is never a findings in neutral political act but rather always a form some settings of “competitive institution building” (Goldfrank and Schneider, forthcoming), and that the results of PB will vary tremendously. The next section examines these hypotheses through a broad comparison of national experiences in Brazil, Bolivia, Guatemala, Nicaragua, and Peru. This is followed by analysis of case studies in fourteen non- Brazilian municipalities. This paper examines the impact and significance of independent budget analysis and advocacy initiatives that are designed to improve budget transparency and the poverty focus of government expenditure priorities. It draws on case study research of six budget groups in Brazil, Croatia, India, Mexico, South Africa, and Uganda, which include non-governmental organisations, research institutions and social movements. The findings demonstrate that civil society budget Budget initiatives contribute to improvements in the Robinson, M. monitoring transparency of budgetary decisions and the (2006) ‘Budget initiatives can budget process, increased budget awareness Analysis and Policy contribute to and literacy, and deeper engagement in the Advocacy: The Improved improved budget process on the part of legislators, the Role of Non- Multi- Case- Service budget media and civil society organisations. While governmental country Client 1) Improved study/ Delivery transparency various various the structure of the budget process makes Public Action.” case Power information Qualitativ and and awareness, substantial changes in expenditure priorities IDS Working Paper studies e redistribut as well as difficult to achieve, budget groups directly 279. Brighton, UK: ion enhanced contribute to positive impacts on budget Institute of resources and allocations and improved implementation, Development efficiency in thereby increasing the accountability of Studies. expenditure decision-makers. Tracking of budgetary utilization expenditures and impacts was also found to be effective in ensuring effective utilisation of education and health expenditures. Increased budget allocations and improved utilisation of public funds that benefit poor and disadvantaged groups can ensure greater equity in budget priorities and further social justice objectives. The activities of budget groups strengthen democracy by fostering accountability, enhancing transparency and deepening participation. Freedom of This report records and analyzes the results information of a study in which partners of the Justice requests can Initiative in 14 countries filed a total of 1,926 Open Society contribute to requests for information. In each country, Justice Initiative, System responsiveness seven different requesters twice submitted up 'Transparency and Test of public to 70 questions to 18 public institutions. Citizens file Silence: A Survey 14 Freedom of (Lodging officials, though Requesters included NGOs, journalists, Client 1) Improved requests to of Access to country Information complaint n/a not always, and businesspersons, non-affiliated persons, and Power information access Information Laws study laws s and highly members of excluded groups, such as information and Practices in 14 analyzing dependent on illiterate or disabled persons or those from Countries', OSJI responses) status of person vulnerable minorities. The requests were for 2006 submitting the types of information that public bodies request and hold—or should hold. As far as possible, no civil society requests were made for classified pressure information and other information that would ordinarily be exempted under standard access to information legislation. Summary of findings: 1) Access to Information laws increase responsiveness 2) Mute refusals are still a significant problem with 38% of requests made in countries with FOI laws going unanswered. 3) Regional variations exist 4) Civil society involvement helps 5) Discrimination affected response rates. Requesters participating in the study who were journalists or representatives of NGOs and who identified themselves as such when making their requests tended to receive responses more often than individuals who identified themselves as members of an excluded or vulnerable group 6) Results Inconsistent, Even in the Most Responsive Countries suggesting a lack of training of government officials The Right to information Jenkins, R. (2007) campaign in This paper provides a historical overview of ‘India’s Unlikely Civil societies India led to new the two anti-corruption waves in India during Democracy: Civil (like MKSS) legislation and Freedom of the 90s and 2000s. It describes the concerted Society versus Client 1) Improved spearheaded Qualitativ Reduced widely India Information political and civil society efforts that led up Corruption.’ Power information movement e corruption mobilised laws to the 2003 Right to Information Act in an Journal of leading to RTI constituencies effort to reduce corruption in government Democracy 18(2): Act. to use programs targeted to the poor. 55-69. information for developmental purposes. Community- The lack of “social capital” is increasingly managed forwarded as an explanation for why projects are communities perform poorly. Yet, to what better extent can these community-specific maintained than constraints be compensated? I address this projects question by examining determinants of Citizens are managed by the collective success in a costly problem in involved in local developing economies - the upkeep of local Quantitati Kwaja, Asim Ijaz. Compact, Community prioritizing Public government. public goods. A difficulty is obtaining ve (fixed (2001), 'Can good India Client Participation and planning good Also, reliable outcome measures for comparable effects, projects succeed in Power (CDD) the delivery provision community collective tasks across well-defined with IV) Bad Communities? of public participation in communities. In order to resolve this I Collective Action in goods tehchnical conduct detailed surveys of community- the Himalayas', decisions maintained infrastructure projects in Harvard reduced the Northern Pakistan. The findings show that University, quality of while community-specific constraints do Department of maintenance, matter, they can be compensated by better Economics , whereas project design. Inequality, social Cambridge, Mass community fragmentation, and lack of leadership in the participation in community do have adverse consequences non-technical but these can be overcome by changes in decisions project complexity, community participation significantly and return distribution. Using community improved fixed effects and instrumental variables maintenance. offers a significant improvement in empirical identification over previous studies. Moreover, the evidence suggests that better design matters even more for communities with poorer attributes. Projects can be designed to succeed even in “bad” communities. Community-based and driven development projects have become an important form of development assistance, with the World Bank’s portfolio alone approximating $7 billion. A review of their conceptual foundations and evidence on their The review effectiveness shows that projects rely on reveals lack of community participation have not been rigorous particularly effective at targeting the poor. evaluations of There is some evidence that such projects the CDD create effective community infrastructure but approach and not a single study establishes causal the few rigorous relationship between any outcome and evaluations participatory elements of a community-based (with the except development project. Most such projects are Mansuri, G. and V. of the above dominated by elites, and both targeting and Rao, Citizens are study by Asim project quality tend to be markedly worse in ―Community- involved in Compact, Kwaja), reveal more unequal communities. A distinction Based and –Driven Community prioritizing Public Various / Client that CDD is between potentially ‘benevolent’ forms of Development: A Participation and planning good lit review Power, ineffective in elite domination and more pernicious types Critical Review,‖ (CDD) the delivery provision Politics most cases and of capture is likely to be important for The World Bank of public the success understanding project dynamics and Research Observer, goods depends largely outcomes. Several qualitative studies indicate 19:1(2004), 1-39. on the ability of that the sustainability of community-based implementers to initiatives depends crucially on an enabling 'contextualize'. institutional environment, which requires Therefore, the government commitment, and on author accountability of leaders to their community condones to avoid ‘supply-driven demand driven wholesale development. External agents strongly application of influence project success, but facilitators are best practices. often poorly trained, particularly in rapidly scaled-up programs. The naïve application of complex contextual concepts like participation, social capital, and empowerment is endemic among project implementers and contributes to poor design and implementation. The evidence suggests that community-based and –driven development projects are best undertaken in a context-specific manner, with a long time horizon and with careful and well-designed monitoring and evaluation systems. I conducted a field experiment in Benin to investigate the impact of clientelism on voting behavior. In collaboration with four political parties involved in the 2001 The results indicate that presidential elections, clientelist and women voters programmatic platforms were designed and Wantcheckon L. run in twenty randomly selected villages of have stronger (2002), an average of 756 registered voters. Even preference for "Clientelism and after controlling for ethnic affiliation, I find public goods Voting Behavior: A Benin Politics n/a n/a n/a RCT that clientelist platforms have significant than men, and field Experiment in effect on voting behavior. The effect was that younger Benin", New York strongest for incumbent and for “local” and older voters University candidates. The evidence indicates that have similar “national” candidates have comparative policy advantage over “local” candidates on preferences programme. In addition, the less clientelist is the platform of the “national” opposition candidate, the better is his electoral prospect among female voters. Government provision of free or subsidized bed nets to combat malaria in Africa is an important policy context to examine unanswered questions regarding the Increased influence of mass media on household information political behavior and health practices in resulted in an poor democracies. Does radio access enable Khemani, S and Radios greater usage of It is usually citizens to receive greater private benefits Kheefer, P "The disseminate Natural bed nets. hypothesized from government programs (in this case, free Role of Mass information Experime However, this that increased bed nets), as it does in richer countries? Does Media in on the nt - was the result information it persuade households to invest more of their Developing Compact, availabitliy of Exploiting of individual could improve Public own resources to acquire bed nets? Using a Democracies:Impa Client 1) Improved free bed nets quasi- households Benin collective good “natural experiment” in radio markets in ct of Radio on the Power. information and of their random investing more action capacity provision northern Benin, which provide for exogenous Distribution of Politics importance in radio of their own of clients to variation in village access to community Anti-malaria Bed reducing the coverage resources in increase radio, we find that households in villages Nets in Benin", contraction within acquiring bed government with greater radio access are more likely to World Bank Draft and spread of commune nets as opposed accountability. acquire bed nets using their own resources; (May 2011) Malaria to higher levels they are not more likely to receive them for of provision of free from government sources. This free bed nets by evidence, consistent with other evidence on government education in Benin, suggests that in poor democracies mass media are more likely to be persuasive in changing the private behavior of poor citizens—in this case, to invest more of their own resources on a good with large positive externalities (bed nets)— rather than enabling citizens to extract greater benefits from government. In areas where voters display strong attachement to A central challenge in political economy is to party, identify the conditions under which legislators exert legislators seek lower effort in to “bring home the pork” to constituents. We using their conduct the first systematic analysis of one discretionary determinant funds to of constituency service, voter attachment to implement political parties, holding constant electoral 1) Compact Khemani, S and projects. The and political institutions. Our analysis takes between Kheefer, P "When authors advantage of data from a unique type of party leaders Do Legislators interpret this public spending and Through Pass on Pork? The finding as an program that is proliferating across legislators is seleciton of Role of Political Public indication that developing countries, the constituency linked to legislators Quantitati Parties in India Compact n/a good party leaders development fund (CDF), level of with the ve Determining provision can afford to which offers more precise measures of party correct Legislator Effort", select legislator effort than are common in the attachement preferences American Political legislators literature. Examining in the Science Review, whose the CDF in India, we find that legislator legislator's Vol. 103, No. 1 preferences are effort is significantly lower in constituencies constituency more aligned to that are party party strongholds. This result, which is robust to preferences controls for alternate explanations, implies rather than that legislators concerned with pass on pork when voters are more attached their to political parties. It has implications not constituents in only for understanding those areas political incentives and the dynamics of party where there is formation, but also for evaluating the impact strong party of attachment. CDFs. Does radio access improve public service provision? And if so, does it do so by increasing government accountability to citizens, or by persuading households to take advantage of publicly-provided services? Prior research has argued that citizens with Increased greater access to mass media receive greater information benefits from targeted government welfare resulted in an programs, but has not addressed these increase in questions for public services such as in Khemani, S and It is usually Natural access and education and health. Using unique data from Kheefer, P "Mass hypothesized Radios Experime usage of Benin, this paper finds that literacy rates Media and Public that increased disseminate nt - education among school children are higher in villages Services: The information Compact, information Exploiting facilities but the exposed to signals from a larger number of Effects of Radio could improve Public Client 1) Improved on school quasi- change came community radio stations. The effect is Access on Public Benin collective good Power, information infrastructure random from changes in identified based on a “natural experiment” in Education in action capacity provision Politics and radio household the northern communes of Benin where Benin", World of clients to educational coverage behavior within-commune variation in village access Bank Policy increase services within (greater demand to radio stations is exogenous to observed Research Working government commune for education) and unobserved village characteristics. In Paper, WPS5559 accountability. rather than contrast to prior research, the authors find better that this media effect does not operate government through government accountability: accountability government inputs into village schools and household knowledge of government education policies are no different in villages with greater access to community radio. Instead, households with greater access are more likely to make financial investments in the education of their children. Theoretical This analysis has had to leave many conclusions important issues and questions unaddressed. described in With regard to the Philippine case alone, it abstract -->. has little to say about how rural voters view The main take- vote buying and efforts to reform it, or the away is that distinctive contribution of upper class Schaffer, F electoral reformers to the misrepresentation of the "Disciplinary reforms that urban poor. It has not discussed the views of Implementing Reactions: 1) address vote- vote-buying politicians, those who bankroll electoral Alienation and the Philippin Regulating Qualitativ buying can them, or members of the higher classes who Politics reforms to n/a Reform of Vote es the electoral e sometimes have distance themselves from reformist groups. fight vote- Buying in the system unintended Nor has this analysis delved into the question buying Philippines", MIT second-hang of whether vote buying is really a serious 2002 complications defect of the Philippine and Thai electoral and costs that systems, or whether efforts to discipline vote do not justify sellers reflect instead middle class fantasies these reforms. and anxieties blown out of proportion. Through the Callahan (2002, 24) goes so far as to argue case study of that in Thailand “vote-buying is not as big a the Philippines, problem as is our obsession with it.” It could Schaffer shows thus be asked why reformers in both the important of countries have not tried to change more context in earnestly the deeper political and economic assessing the structures which have given rise to a host of viability of such extra-legal political practices, of which vote reforms. buying is but one. Or it might be asked why reformers have not focused more intensively on other, more clearly nefarious, practices such as the use of violence as an election strategy. In the May 2001 Philippine elections there were 100 election related deaths, with another 141 people wounded. When 76 people were killed and 26 injured in the 2002 barangay elections, the COMELEC chairman expressed satisfaction that it was “generally peaceful,” while the PPCRV charmain chairman described the violent incidents,- which included 42 shootings, 9 liquidations, 7 gunfights, 6 ambushes, 3 cases of harassment, 3 strafings, 3 abductions, and 2 bombings - as “isolated". Improved Vote-buying, i.e., cash-for-votes, is a information on frequent practice during election time in illegality on many parts of the world, namely in West vote-buying Africa. However, in the presence of secret reduced the ballots, it is not clear whether vote-buying influence of drives voting behavior. In order to infer Improving money on effects of vote-buying on electoral behavior, Vincente, P (2010) information outcomes we designed and conducted a randomized Voters attended "Is Vote-buying on the legal (although we field experiment during an election in newly voter education Effective? Evidence Sao structure of are not sure oil-rich Sao Tome and Principe. We follow a campaign from a Field Tome 1) Improved the electoral Electoral whether the voter education campaign against votebuying Politics organized by RCT Experiment in West and information system, outcomes information sponsored by the Electoral Commission, the National Africa" , Oxford Principe namely, on itself or rather using panel-survey measurements as well as Electoral University and the illegal the perception actual electoral data per ballot station. Our Commission BREAD nature of of greater results show that the campaign reduced the vote-buying monitoring by influence of money offered on voting, the electoral decreased electoral participation, and favored commission is the incumbent. This evidence suggests that driving the vote-buying increases voter turnout and that result) and the challenger drives relatively more votes favored the through vote-buying - i.e., vote-buying incumbent counteracts the incumbency advantage. 1) Providing information on politician's performance This article evaluates a body of recent work and which uses field and natural experiments to characteristic answer this question. A common finding in Better- sand the literature is that voter behavior is Pande, R (2011) performing exposing malleable and that information about the "Can Informed politicians are voters to NGOs and civil political process and politician performance Voters Enforce elected and politicians societies improves electoral accountability. Limited Better there is a from under- organize availability of information thus provides one Governance? 1) Improved Electoral decrease in the India Politics represented awareness RCT explanation for the persistence of low quality Experiments in information outcomes extent of groups campaigns to politicians and the existence of identity Low Income electoral 2) Educating educate and politics and electoral malpractices in low- Democracies", malpractice and voters about inform voters income democracies. Understanding how Annual Review of the level of importance of voters can gain access to credible sources of Economics identity politics politics and information and how politicians react to (caste) the potential improved information about their costs of performance are promising avenues for electoral future research. malpractice and identity politics Ethnic politics and political corruption are important concerns in many developing country democracies. We conducted eld experiments in rural India to examine the Ethnic responsiveness of voter preferences to 2 voter preferences can priming about the relevance of ethnicity and awareness be altered by Banerjee, A, politician quality for service delivery. We campaigns to disseminating Green, D & Pande, used vignette experiments to examine how priming 2 prominent information on R "Can Voters be voter preferences vary with information voters to not NGOs the quality of Primed to Choose about politician quality. We nd strong vote for organized politicians, Better Legislators? 1) Improved Electoral evidence that ethnic preferences are India Politics corrupt awareness RCT providing a Experimental information outcomes malleable. The vignette experiments show candidates campaigns to means to move Evidence from that ethnic preferences respond to politician and to not educate and away from Rural India", quality and the field experiment shows that vote for inform voters identity politics Preliminary and reductions in ethnic voting reduce the vote candidates and also select Incomplete share of criminal politicians. In contrast, based only on better and less priming voters on the relevance of corruption caste corrupt left electoral outcomes una ected (in the field politicians experiment). We interpret these results in the context of a model where a voter's use of specific evaluative criteria is influenced by available information. As part of a recent anti-corruption campaign, the Brazilian government began to audit the municipal expenditure of federally- transferred funds. Using these audit reports, Ferraz, C and we construct a unique data set of political Finan, F corruption to test whether reelection "Reelection incentives affect the level of corruption in a Incentives and municipality. Consistent with a political Political economy agency model, we find that mayors Corruption:Eviden who are in their second and final term are ce from Brazilian significantly more corrupt than first-term Re-election Audit Reports", This paper uses audit data from Brazil to test political agency mayors. In particular, second-term mayors on incentives can 2005 Annual models on corruption that predict that 2nd and 3rd term average divert, R$188,431.4 more than first- Electoral influence the meeting, July 24- Brazil Politics politicians will tend to be more corrupt than 1st term term mayors, which is approximately 4 outcomes level of 27, Providence, RI, politician. Their unique dataset confirms the model's percent of the total amount transferred to corruption in American predictions. municipalities. We also find much more politicians. Agricultural pronounced effects among municipalities Economics where the costs of rent-extraction are lower, Association (New and the density of pivotal voters is higher. Name 2008: Our results also illustrate an important trade- Agricultural and off: second-term mayors, while more corrupt, Applied Economics provide a higher level of public goods. As Association) Brazil and other countries continue their decentralization process, our findings promote the need for a better understanding of how local institutions can help reduce the incentives for corruption. Does the disclosure of information about While political corrupt activities induce a sustained agency models reduction in corruption? We use publicly may predict that released routine audits of municipal politicians who Bobonis, G, governments in Puerto Rico to answer this benefit whose Fuertes, C, question. We first develop a political agency reputation goes Schwabe, R (2011) model where voters re-elect incumbents up will tend to "The Dynamic based on their performance while in office. exploit the Effects of We show that, because voters cannot directly Naturally 'slack' they Information on Providing observe incumbents’ actions, an incumbent random receive by Political information whose reputation improved in the previous Puerto 1) Improved auditing Electoral seeking more Corruption:Theory Politics on corruption term is likely to engage in more rent-seeking Rico information of outcomes rents in the and Evidence from level of activities in a future term. Guided by this municipali future, the Puerto Rico", politicians model, we use longitudinal data on audit ties authors show Working Papers results to examine the long-term that this is not from University of consequences of providing information to the case. Toronto, voters on levels of political corruption. We Corruption Department of find that municipal corruption levels in levels before Economics subsequent audits are on average the same in and after the municipalities audited preceding the previous audit stay the election and those not audited then. In spite same in audited of this, mayors in municipalities audited areas preceding the previous election have higher re-election rates, suggesting that audits enable voters to select more competent politicians. We conclude that short-term information dissemination policies do not necessarily align politicians’ long-term actions with voter preferences as politicians exploit their reputational gains by extracting more rents from office.