WAP'S 250 1 POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 2501 Anti-Corruption Policies In a largely corruption-free environment, anti-corruption and Program s agencies, ethics offices, and ombudsmen strengthen the A Framework for Evaluation standards of accountability In A Framework for Evaluation ~~~~~~countries with endemic corruption, however, the Jeff Huther same institutions function in Anwar Shah form but not in substance; under a best-case scenario such institutions might be helpful, but the more likely outcome is that they help to preserve social injustice. The World Bank Operations Evaluation Department Country Evaluation and Regional Relations Division H December 2000 PoI i y RFSEARCH WORKING PAPER 2501 Summary findings The anti-corruption strategy the World Bank announced * The expected gains from undertaking a corrupt act in September 1997 defined corruption as the "use of exceed the expected costs. public office for private gain" and called for the Bank to * Little weight is placed on the cost that corruption address corruption along four dimensions: imposes on others. * Preventing fraud and corruption in Bank projects. In a country with heavy corruption and poor * Helping countries that request Bank assistance for governance, the priorities in anti-corruption efforts fighting corruption. would then be to establish rule of law, strengthen * Mainstreaming a concern about corruption in Bank institutions of participation and accountability, and limit work. government interventions to focus on core mandates. * Lending active support to international efforts to In a country with moderate corruption and fair address corruption. governance, the priorities would be decentralization and The menu of possible actions to contain corruption (in economic reform, results-oriented management and both countries and Bank projects) is very large, so evaluation, and the introduction of incentives for Huther and Shah develop a framework to help assign competitive delivery of public services. priorities, depending on views of what does and does not In a country with little corruption and strong work in specific countries. Their framework, based on governance, the priorities might be explicit anti- public officials' incentives for opportunistic behavior, corruption agencies and programs, stronger financial distinguishes between highly corrupt and largely management, increased public and government corruption-free societies. Certain conditions encourage awareness, no-bribery pledges, efforts to fry the "big public officials to seek or accept corruption: fish," and so on. This paper-a product of the Country Evaluation and Regional Relations Division, Operations Evaluation Department- is part of a larger effort in the department to improve the development effectiveness of external assistance. Copies of the paper are available free from the World Bank, 18 18 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Please contact Agnes Santos, room H3-425, telephone 202-473-1675, fax 202-522-3124, email address asantos@worldbank.org. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at www.worldbank.org/research/workingpapers. Anwar Shah may be contacted at ashah@qworldbank.org. December 2000. (17 pages) The Policy Research Working Paper Sees disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even itfthe presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and sbould be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessaril) represent the view of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. Produced by the Policy Research Dissemination Center Anti-corruption Policies and Programs: A Framework for Evaluation Jeff Huther and Anwar Shah I Anti-corruption Policies and Programs: A Framework for Evaluation By Jeff Huther and Anwar ShahI The Executive Board of the World Bank approved its anti-corruption strategy in September 1997. The strategy defined corruption as the "use of public office for private gain"2 and called for the Bank to address corruption along four dimensions: * Preventing fraud and corruption in Bank projects; * Helping countries that request Bank assistance for corruption; * Mainstreaming a concern for corruption in Bank's work; and * Lending active support to international efforts to address corruption. Following the adoption of this strategy, concrete steps to prevent fraud and corruption in Bank projects have included: the introduction of a confidential hotline, tightening of procurement guidelines, intensive audits of projects, and support for improving procurement systems in client countries. Mainstreaming a concern for corruption has taken place through the Bank's economic and sector work which provides the analytic basis for country assistance strategy documents which, in turn, underlie the Bank's lending programs. Of the analytical tools used in economic and sector work, institutional reviews (IRs), country financial accountability assessments (CFAAs) and public expenditure reviews (PERs) offer substantial scope for addressing the governance failures that permit wide spread corruption, country procurement assessment reports (CPARs) identify sources of corruption in procurement and recommend remedies, country economic memoranda (CEMs) can be used for relatively quick assessments of corruption sources, and country assistance evaluations (CAEs) may highlight areas where corruption concerns are undermining Bank work. In addition to economic and sector work, all country assistance I The authors are with the US Treasury and World Bank respectively. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors' alone and should not be attributed to these institutions. The paper has benefited from comments by Gregor Binkert, Gregory Ingram, Cheryl Gray, Daniel Kaufmann, Robert Klitgaard, Ruben Lamdany, Mita Marra, Robert Picciotto, Susan Rose-Ackerman, Mark Schacter, Rick Stapenhurst, Michael Stevens, P. Sharafudheen, Gerolf Weigel, and Alexandre Widmer. The authors are particularly grateful to Mark Schacter for substantive contributions. Please address comments to: ashah@worldbank.org 2 Schacter and Shah (2000) list three broad varieties of corruption consistent with this definition: (a) bureaucratic or "petty" corruption - vast number of public officials (bureaucrats and politicians) abusing public office often extracting small bribes or favors; (b) grand corruption - theft or misuse of vast amount of public funds by a relatively small number of officials; and (c) "state capture" or "regulatory capture" - collusion among public and private agents for private benefit. strategy (CAS) documents are now required to diagnose the state of governance and the risks that corruption poses to Bank projects. The Comprehensive Development Framework unveiled in 1999 underscores the importance of governance and public sector institutional reform issues in the Bank's development assistance dialogue. The World Bank Institute has initiated courses on corruption for developing country officials and conducted surveys on service delivery. The Bank has also put a greater emphasis on institutional reform and capacity building through its lending program. Bank assistance for intemational efforts to curtail corruption has been mainly in the form of sponsorship of major conferences, dissemination notes and support for the adoption of the 1999 OECD Convention on Combating Bribery of Foreign Public Officials in International Business Transactions. The impact of corruption on public service delivery performance and poverty alleviation is widely recognized (see e.g. Tomaszewska and Shah, 2000 for empirical evidence). A wide consensus has also recently emerged that corruption is a symptom of failed governance (see World Bank 2000) and hence curtailing corruption requires addressing the causes of mis-governance. Nevertheless, the menu of potential actions to curtail corruption is very large so a framework is needed that provides guidance on ordering potential actions. Prioritization of various actions depends on both the conceptual and empirical views of what works and what does not work in the context of particular countries. Such a framework is also needed for evaluating both Bank and country anti- corruption programs. This note proposes a framework for such evaluations. A Simple Evaluation Framework To focus attention on the corruption aspects of development programs, we use a framework based on the incentives for opportunistic behavior by public officials.3 To distinguish between highly corrupt and largely corruption-free societies, consider the conditions that encourage public officials to seek out or accept corruption: * The expected gains exceed the expected costs of undertaking a corrupt act. * Little weight is placed on the cost that corruption imposes on others. The first point is based on pure self-interest: corruption will only take place when officials expect to derive net positive benefit from the transaction. Successful anti- corruption programs will lower the expected gains and raise the expected penalties of corrupt behavior. That is, anti-corruption programs must change the cost-benefit calculations of public officials who believe that the expected net benefits of corruption 3 A suggestion we received, based on an earlier version of this paper, was that we include the actions of private agents as well as public officials (the "demand side" for corruption in the case of bribery). We focus on the supply of corruption by public officials because a government that is unable to improve the incentives of its own employees is unlikely to affect private sector agents (i.e. demand can safely be thought of as constant in highly corrupt societies) since a government has significantly fewer policy actions for discouraging corruption by private agents than for discouraging corruption among public officials. 2 are positive. A self-interested individual will seek out or accept corruption if the expected gains outweigh the costs, i.e. when: E[B] = nxE[G] - prob [P] x [P] > 0 where E is the expectations operator n is number of corrupt transactions G is the gain from the corrupt transaction prob [P] is the probability of paying a penalty P is the penalty for the corrupt activity Based on cost-benefit considerations, anti-corruption programs can influence corruption through four mechanisms - reducing the number of transactions involving public officials, reducing the scope for gains from each transaction, increasing the probability of paying a penalty, or increasing the penalty from corrupt behavior. The factors influencing each element of a public official's cost-benefit analysis are described in the following paragraphs and listed in Table 1. Reducing expected gross benefits:4 The expected net benefit derived from corruption is context-dependent on the factors that influence a public official's expectations - a country's historical treatment of corrupt activities, the quality of the judicial framework, the strength and scope of enforcement institutions, and the potential for changes in these characteristics for escaping the procedures of legal recourse with illegal maneuvers. Thus relevant anti-corruption policies geared towards reducing the gross gains will vary with the institutional environment of each country. Transaction value can be reduced by scaling down of individual projects, requiring popular referenda for large projects with votes both on tax and expenditure allocation choices, de-monopolizing public services, promoting competition in the private sector, increasing the share of financing from domestic taxes or user charges,5 and bringing a culture of new contractualism to the public sector. Reducing the number of transactions: Policies which reduce the number of transactions that create opportunities for graft and private capture of public programs can include streamlining bureaucracy, economic or financial liberalization (e.g. deregulation, freer trade, etc.), improving service standards, and decentralizing government services. Privatization can reduce the number of transactions but, as recent experience in Eastern Europe shows, the privatization process itself involves transactions which may strengthen the hold of vested and sometimes corrupt interests so businesses operating in a 4 A large subset of expected benefits is captured in the commonly cited formula, Monopoly + Discretion - Accountability (Klitgaard, 1988). By focusing on the actions of individual officials, we hope to highlight the difficulties in improving accountability and the implications of greater accountability on a country's institutional framework. In addition, in a country with adequate governance arrangements, discretion by public officials may be welfare-enhancing - it is discretion, after all, that is likely to provide efficiency gains in the public sector (even for public services that are not highly contestable). ' Domestic finance is important because it forces deliberate choices on the trade-off between the pain of taxation and the pleasure of spending by the government and the citizenry. 3 competitive environment, free of state financing, and with adequate governance safeguards may or may not emerge from privatization. Increasing the Probability of Paying Penalties:6 Increasing the probability of penalties is a three step process: detection, prosecution, and exacting the penalty. In cases where corruption is extortion for jobs that should be done as a matter of public service, improved detection is straight-forward - increase citizen participation in the electoral process, establish citizens' charters specifying expected service standards, allow media independence, make interactions between the public and private sectors more transparent, and strengthen the rule of law so that both individuals and the media do not fear reprisals. Increasing the Magnitude of Penalties: There are corrupt societies which have stiff penalties for corruption, suggesting the magnitude of penalties may not be a strong deterrent to corruption. In general, people may not respond much differently to, say, an increase in penalties from five to ten years in prison, as Malaysia did in 1997 with no discernible change in perceptions of corruption (as measured by Transparency International). In some countries, however, the legislation setting penalties may be ambiguous or penalties may be set at the discretion of judges. In either case, a country may discourage corruption by clarifying corruption penalties. While the Bank may provide assistance in clarifying legislation, setting criminal penalties is outside the scope of its work. In cases where corruption is in the form of bribes to alter the normal course of government, increased transparency of government operations reduces the opportunity for undetected corruption (e.g. clearly defined bidding processes, open judicial proceedings, strict rules on gift-giving) and increasing the number of competitors reduces the potential gains while increasing scrutiny of bidding processes. Prosecution requires judicial independence and transparency. For the judicial system to exact penalties, it must have sufficient resources and independence. To the extent that penalties are reputational, media independence is a crucial element to deterrence. While a more complete treatment would include the incentives of private sector agents who interact with public officials, policies affecting private sector incentives are largely outside the scope of Bank work. Policies which increase the magnitude of penalties or the expected probability of paying penalties, however, are likely to have similar effects on the private sector as they do on the public sector. The focus on public officials excludes consideration of policies, typically in countries with low levels of corruption, that penalize private sector efforts to participate in corruption in other countries. These policies are potentially relevant to anti-corruption efforts, but are outside the scope of our framework (and most Bank work). In terms of domestic policies, we believe that the 6 There may also be losses that occur.with certainty, for example, if an official has to "buy" a position that offers potentially large gains from corrupt actitivities. While this type of situation should not affect the officials cost-benefit analysis (since the price paid for the position is a sunk cost), it does raise an equity issue. In cases where endemic corruption has led to a traditional of buying public positions, serious anti- corruption efforts could, conceivably, include partial compensation for current office holders (declining in value with tenure). In practice, such a system is likely to be too prone to abuse to be feasible. ' For example, countries such as China and Vietnam, which are perceived to have relatively high levels of corruption, have sentenced people to death for graft. 4 focus on public officials is appropriate even if well-designed policies may reduce the incentives of the private sector to engage in corruption. The argument is that a goverunent which cannot influence the incentives of its own officials is unlikely to be able to reduce private sector incentives to engage in corruption. In the formulation above, an official's income does not have an effect on whether or not to engage in corrupt activities. Two concerns have been raised with this approach. One is that officials paid less than subsistence income are forced to undertake corrupt activities to survive, the second is that, at some high level of income, officials should be unwilling to risk that income to gain more through corrupt activities. Both arguments require an assumption that officials are motivated to follow the rule of law regardless of whether they see it as a threat to their income from corrupt activities. The argument put forward in this paper is that officials are not so motivated in countries in which the rule of law is weak.8 Table 1: The Influence of Anti-Corruption Programs on Officials' Cost-Benefit Analysis Number Of Gross Gains From Probability Of Magnitude Actions Not Corrupt Corruption Paying Of Penalty Influencing Cost Transactions Penalty Benefit Analysis Bureaucratic Economic Reform - Anti- Rational- Raising Culture - Improving Corruption ization of Awareness of Streamlining Competitive Agencies laws Public Through Services Environment Seminars Creating or Raising Scaling Down Parliamentary Public Opinion Public Service Individual Public Oversight Surveys Standards Projects Reducing Public Bureaucratic Culture Ombudsman Raising Public Employment Sector Wages Reducing Public Referenda on Large Financial Reducing Wage Sector Size Public Projects Accountability Compression Financial Media Liberalization Independence Increasing Judicial Transparency Independence Decentralization of Citizen Public Services Participation Economic Reform Rule Of Law - Privatization Ethics Office A similar argument applies on the penalties side. The alternatives to public sector employment tend to be worse in countries with high levels of corruption. Given poor alternatives, we would expect public officials to be unwilling to risk their careers for small temporary gains. While in some cases an argument can be made for desperation on the part of public officials, more generally it seems likely that officials in highly corrupt societies do not see the rule of law as a risk to their careers. 5 The large number of potential incentive targets and anti-corruption actions listed in Table I raise two questions: * how to establish the priorities of anti-corruption campaign, and * which actions should be used to meet those targets. Economic theory suggests that high priority programs are those that address large welfare losses caused by corruption. Two practical considerations make prioritization based on welfare losses difficult: quantifying corruption losses is often not possible and large losses are often the result of multiple governance failures. The result is that prioritization of anti-corruption campaigns must rely on analysis of an individual country's economic, political and bureaucratic conditions. Prioritization based on welfare losses highlights one of the problems with using survey data to construct an anti-corruption program. High visibility corruption, which is likely to be identified by surveys, may have significantly lower welfare costs than less visible corruption. It is possible, for example, that the public is highly aware of corruption causing marginal losses in traffic enforcement, utility hook-ups, or business permits but largely ignorant of the economic distortions caused by revenue losses through tax evasion by wealthy individuals and large corporations. In determining which actions should be used, Table I suggests actions which vary depending on the weaknesses of a specific government. For a country in which the government that is disproportionally large, actions which reduce the size of government are likely to reduce the scope for corruption. For a country in which a few officials appear to have become very wealthy in public service, actions should aim to reduce the gross gains from corruption. For a country in which few are held accountable for corrupt activities, anti-corruption efforts should focus on judicial independence resources. Empirical evidence for individual anti-corruption efforts is listed in Table 2. Wide- spread corruption, however, is likely to be the result of multiple governance failures so successful anti-corruption campaigns are likely to be multi-pronged. For example, an official's cost-benefit analysis suggests that raising public sector wages, by itself, is unlikely to lead to lower corruption.9 A program that ties wage increases to increases in satisfaction with public services, however, may encourage public officials to trade income from corrupt sources for legitimate income. The effectiveness of such a program may be further enhanced if it is jointly undertaken with efforts to increase the probability of paying penalties, say through efforts to increase judicial independence. 9 This assertion is supported indirectly by observation in countries facing wide spread corruption that wealthy officials are at least as susceptible to corrupt activities as poor ones (among examples of wealthy officials convicted of corruption are two former South Korean presidents, a former Pakistani prime minister and a former mayor of Beijing. In economic terms, we are arguing that, for an average individual, the utility of wealth function is not highly concave. Evidence directly supporting this assertions difficult to obtain, given the need to make inter-personal comparisons of utility. 6 Table 2. Empirical Evidence on Selected Anti-corruption Programs Program Empirical Evidence Anti-Corruption Anti-corruption agencies have been successful in Chile, Hong Kong, New South Agencies Wales, Australia and Singapore (Allan; 1992, Clark; 1987, Holm; 2000; Doig; 1995; Klitgaard; 1998; Segal; 1999 and World Bank, 1999). Developing country officials however do not see these as effective anti-corruption tools in countries with endemic corruption (see Kaufmnann, 1997). Public Opinion Public opinion surveys have served as a useful tool in articulating more precisely Surveys citizens' concerns (e.g. Bangalore scorecard and a "corruptometer" by an Argentine NGO). International surveys, such as those compiled by Transparency International, highlight countries in which corruption is perceived to be endemic. Raising Public Rijckeghem and Weder (1997) find no short run impact (as the income from Sector Wages bribery dominates total income). Gurgur and Shah (1999, 2000) find negative yet insignificant effect. Treisman (1999) and Swamy et al. (1999) find no relationship. The SDC experience in the forestry sector in Pakistan also confirms this. In corrupt societies public positions are often purchased by borrowing money from family and friends. Raising public sector wages simply raises the purchase price and subsequent corruption efforts to repay loans. Of course raising public sector wages which do not allow the employee to satisfy basic needs of his/her family, are likely to reduce petty corruption. Reducing Public Tanzi and Davoodi (1998), LaPalombara (1994), La Porta et al (1999) find that Sector Size reduction in public sector size leads to less corruption. Gurgur and Shah (1999) find that this result only holds when important variables such as judiciary, democratic institutions, colonial heritage, decentralization, and bureaucratic culture are omitted. Elliot (1997) finds an inverse relationship between the budget size and corruption. Privatization in some countries (e.g. Russia) has led to increased corruption and exploitation. Thus appropriate role of the __government is the critical element for discussion on corruption. Financial Gurgur and Shah (1999, 2000) find a negative yet insignificant association. Accountability Media Freedom of press is negatively correlated with the level of corruption (see Independence Brunetti and Weder, 1998) Judicial Judicial independence reduces corruption as confirmed by Ades and Di Tella Independence (1996), Goel and Nelson (1998) and Gurgur and Shah (1999, 2000). Citizen Citizen participation leads to reduced corruption as confirmed by Kaufman and Participation Sachs (1998) and Gurgur and Shah (1999, 2000). Decentralization Huther and Shah (1998), Gurgur and Shah (2000) and Fisman and Gatti (2000) find a negative relationship between decentralization and corruption. Bureaucratic Gurgur and Shah (1999, 2000) find a positive relationship between command Culture and control type civil service orientation and corruption. Corruption in the Presence ofAltruism While the presence of wide-spread corruption suggests a lack of altruism among public officials, some may be motivated, in part, by a desire to perform civic duties or a desire to 7 help others. In corrupt societies, however, otherwise altruistically motivated officials may participate in corruption because: * Officials believe that their careers can be advanced by corrupt practices. * Corruption acts as an insurance against risk in an unstable and uncertain political environment. * Officials may believe that their marginal contributions to the burden of corruption are insignificant. * Corruption may be reinforced by prejudice or tradition. • Officials may believe that their actions are an appropriate "fend for yourself' response in an inhospitable environment with large income inequalities. Policies which promote altruistic behavior face significant hurdles. Wide spread corruption is likely to be influenced by multiple factors. Consequently, an anti- corruption program which focuses on officials' concerns for others is unlikely to be effective unless it simultaneously addresses these factors -- awareness or selective enforcement campaigns may fail if officials do not believe most other officials will not change their ways, creation of ethics offices and ombudsmen may actually lead to greater entrenchment of underlying prejudices or traditions, and public opinion surveys may confirm officials' views of their clients. While policies that promote altruism seem unlikely to be successful by themselves, programs which influence officials' cost-benefit analysis may also reinforce altruistic motivations. Efforts to improve service delivery or policies which reward performnance should be effective from either a cost-benefit or altruistic perspective. Adapting OED Methodology to the Evaluation of Anti-corruption programs The above discussion provides us with some background to apply the OED methodology in evaluating anti-corruption programs. In the following, the key criteria used in OED methodology are discussedl'. Relevance. OED defines relevance as to "the extent which the project's objectives are consistent with the country's current development priorities and with current Bank country and sectoral assistance strategies and corporate goals."'"1 Thus anti-corruption programs are judged to be relevant if they have the potential to achieve their objectives given a country's existing institutional and policy environment. Schacter and Shah (2000) argue that judgement about relevance combine two distinct factors: technical relevance and welfare relevance. Technical relevance refers to the imapct of specific activities on the incidence of corruption and the welfare relevance relates to the relative importance, for growth and poverty reduction of a particular type of corruption. 10 This section draws heavily upon Mark Schacter's comments on an earlier version of this note. Several of his comments have been added verbatim. For details on the definitions in this section and OED methodology more generally, see OED (2000). Highly relevant Bank-supported interventions target (a) the known causes of given types of corruption and (b) the forms of corruption that are believed to have a strong negative effect on growth and poverty reduction. As a first step, Bank-supported intervention is assessed on whether it is likely to have an impact on a given form of corruption by changing the incentives of public officials (technical relevance). This requires identification of the particular causes of corruption in the particular country setting. The intervention then must be assessed on how that particular type of corruption is likely to be affecting growth and poverty-reduction. This requires a view on the link between a particular fonn of corruption and development within a specific country (welfare relevance). So evaluation of the relevance of a Bank-supported interventions combines judgments about both the suitability of any particular intervention (targeting) and the importance of one particular form of corruption relative to any other (potential for welfare gains). For example, one could imagine a case where an intervention was well suited to the form of corruption in question, but where the particular form of corruption had relatively little negative impact on growth and poverty-reduction. Explicit anti-corruption efforts such as setting up of anti-corruption agency, ethics office and requiring no bribery pledge, for example, are likely to be less effective in countries lacking a functioning legal system, without accountability of govenmuent, or inadequate financial transparency. Given this breadth of issues, we have used a stylized view of countries based on broad categories of "Poor," "Fair" and "Good" governance to classify countries by incidence of corruption and the likely consequences of anti-corruption efforts (see Table 3). 12 Table 3. Ratings on Relevance of a Menu of Anti-corruption Programs Program Country's Quaity of ernance Comments Weak Fair Good Raising public Not Low Medium In countries with weak governance, corrupt awareness of relevant practices and agents are generally well corruption through known. seminars _ Raising awareness of Not Low Medium Public officials may be aware of corruption public officials relevant but unwilling and/or unable to take action through seminars due to incentive problems in countries with weak governance. Anti-corruption Not Low Medium With endemic corruption, anti-corruption agencies / relevant agencies or ombudsman may actually Ombudsman extort rents. Positive influence if pre- conditions for good governance exist. Ethics office Not Low Medium Positive influence may be limited to relevant societies with good governance. Raising Public Sector Negligible Low Medium May have positive impact on petty wages corruption but little impact on grand corruption. Negative impact if part of Iproblem is excessive public employment. 12 For a discussion of the measurement of quality of governance and country rankings, see Huther and Shah, 1998 or Kaufmann, Kraay, and Zoido-Lobaton, 1999. 9 Program Country's Quality of Governance Comments Weak Fair Good Reducing Wage Negligible Negl. Negligible More relevant as an incentive mechanism Compression for career development. May increase corruption if the public sector viewed as lucrative career option by greedy elements __________ of society. Merit based civil Low Medium High May be derailed by bureaucratic processes service in highly corru pt societies. Public Opinion Low Medium Medium Public opinion surveys have served as a Surveys useful tool in articulating citizens' concerns (e.g. Bangalore scorecard). Financial Low Low Medium Appropriate when democratic accountability accountability and a substantial accounting/bookkeeping infrastructure I_________ with some integrity are in place. Parliamentary Low Medium Medium Parliamentary oversight can be helpful but oversight parliamentary micro-management not an ____________________ _________ __________ effective form of governance. Reducing Public Medium Low Low May reduce opportunities for corruption. Employment Decentralization Medium Low Low May improve accountability and may increase sense of social purpose for public officials. Client-based civil Medium Medium Low Success depends upon service delivery service / Bureaucratic orientation of public service, reinforced by culture _____ accountability for results. Economic policy High Medium Low Reduces potential corruption by shifting reform __I _ l= decision-making to the private sector. Media and judicial High Medium Low Allows for detection, followed by independence, citizen accountability. participation _ Reducing Public High Medium Low By reducing the number of govemment Sector Size activities, officials can focus on primary ____________________ ________ I objectives of the state. Rule of law High Medium Low I Essential for any progress. Efficacy. OED defines efficacy as to "the extent to which the project's objectives were achieved, or expected to be achieved, taking into account their relative importance." This requires measurement of the effect of a given set of anti-corruption activities on levels of corruption or corrupt activities. Of interest is the measurement of changes in levels of corruption as well as the degree to which observed changes can credibly be attributed to the anti-corruption interventions. Both these issues are subject to large measurement errors. Judgments need to be made about the degree to which Bank-supported interventions have (i) reduced, (ii) had no impact upon, or (iii) led to an increase in, levels of various forms of corruption in the country. For practical purposes, efficacy evaluation will need to focus on the relationship between Bank-supported interventions and changes in key corruption drivers. Efficiency. OED defines efficiency as "the extent to which the project achieved or is expected to achieve, a return higher than the opportunity cost of capital and benefits at least compared to alternatives" (see OED 2000, p.3). An anti-corruption program is 10 considered efficient if it generates maximum reduction in the incidence of corruption (good targeting) and associated welfare gains at the least cost. The same data constraints noted above apply here. Efficiency would ideally be based on the cost of Bank-supported interventions in relation to outcomes at the level of corruption. In the absence of direct measures of levels of corruption, assumptions about changes in levels of corruption have to be based on changes in proxy measures. Therefore, the evaluation will focus on the relationship between the cost of anti-corruption interventions and changes in incentives. Sustainability. OED defines sustainability as "the resilience to risk of net benefit flows over time" (see OED 2000, p.4). Assessment of sustainability would take into account political, economic, financial, social and external factors. In terms of anti-corruption activities, sustainable actions are likely to be those which change the expectations of accountability of public officials. Risk reduction in anti-corruption efforts, like risk reduction in financial management, is likely to be aided by diversification. In countries with limited restraints on corruption, anti-corruption activities which rely on a single office, official, or regulation face a high risk that benefits will be lost over time. Conversely, broad-based efforts to improve accountability, reduce the monopoly power of government, or create judicial independence are likely to create sustainable reductions in corruption. Table 4: Summary of Proposed Rating Factors for Anti-Corruption Programs Relevance * Program objectives consistent with country's development priorities, with Bank strategy a Program design underpinned by analytical work that recognizes country specific public sector mission and values, opportunities and constraints and an informed view of potential impacts of alternative actions * Judgments as to (a) the degree to which the anti-corruption programs were targeted to corruption drivers; (b) the relationship between those drivers, corruption and welfare outcomes. Efficacy * The extent to which the project's objectives were achieved, or expected to be achieved, taking into account their relative importance in curtailing corruption. * Judgments to be made about the degree to which Bank supported interventions have (i) reduced, (ii) had no impact, or (iii) led to an increase in, levels of various forms of corruption in the country. As a proxy focus on the relationship between Bank supported interventions and changes in key corruption drivers. Efficiency * generates most reductions in corruption and associated welfare gains for the least cost * targets corruption that has large costs Sustainability * the resilience to risk of net benefit flows over time based upon an assessment of political, economic, financiaf, social and external influences This framework highlights the difficulty of an anti-corruption campaign - successful campaigns reduce the welfare of some public officials. In this environment, Bank staff have to operate opportunistically in pursuing anti-corruption policies. The implication is that anti-corruption campaigns cannot be applied uniformly in terms of either timeframe 11 or policy reach. As a result, some evaluations may show that in some countries, at some times, anti-corruption efforts are not worthwhile either because the political opportunities do not exist or because the welfare gains are not likely to be significant. Conclusion As noted earlier, path dependency is critical in determining the relative efficacy of various anti-corruption programs. For example in a largely corruption-free environment, anti-corruption agencies, ethics offices, and ombudsman serve to enhance the standards of accountability. In countries with endemic corruption, the same institutions serve a function in form only and not in substance. Under a best case scenario, these institutions might be helpful but the more likely outcome is that they help to preserve the existing system of social injustice. Successful anti-corruption programs are those which address the underlying governance failures, resulting in lower opportunities for gain and a greater likelihood of sanctions.'3 Thus, programs have to be targeted to a country's existing quality of governance. Past experiences of industrialized world confirm these conclusions since, without exception, these countries did not achieve reduction in corruption by introducing technocratic solutions but, rather, by encouraging a sense of public duty among officials though accountability for results. Such an accountability culture came about by empowering people and decentralizing decision making (see Shah, 1999). These conclusions suggest the following stylized presentation of anti-corruption measures based on the existing quality of governance. Table 5: Effective Anti-Corruption Programs Based on Governance Quality Incidence of Governance Priorities of Anti-Corruption Efforts Corruption Quality (Based on Drivers of corruption) High Poor Establish rule of law, strengthen institutions of participation and accountability; limit government interventions to focus on core mandate Medium Fair Decentralization and economic policy reforms; results-oriented management and evaluation; introduction of incentives for competitive public service delivery Low Good Explicit anti-corruption programs such as anti-corruption agencies; strengthen financial management; raising public and officials awareness; no bribery pledges, fry big fish, etc. 1' The SDC experience supports this point. The SDC finds (personal communications with Gerolf Weigel and Alexandre Widmer) that in highly corrupt societies, three forces are essential for a fight against corruption: - a well organized and motivated community in the directly concerned area, ready to defend its interests, combined with; - well targeted institutional development and reforms at the higher levels; - an organized group of "activists" from the media can be very helpful to support the government reform process through well timed and coordinated newspaper, radio or TV publications for increasing the pressure on parliament and politicians to support reforms. 12 Addressing the governance failures which distort officials' cost-benefit assessment is likely to be the only route to success in countries with high levels of corruption and poor governance since direct dialogue on corruption is likely to be counter-productive (resulting in simply another level of corrupt officials under the name of anti-corruption offices). In countries with poor governance quality, Bank staff can promote economic liberalization, judicial reform and greater public participation in public expenditure decisions without explicitly raising contentious issues of corruption and, one hopes, without threatening their existing relationships. In countries with modest levels of corruption and governance quality, where the existing governance structure has the capacity to reform, Bank staff can focus on improvements in readily identifiable output indicators rather than uncertain measures of corruption as measures of success. In countries with high governance quality, explicit efforts to reduce corruption are likely to be successful - commissions on corruption, ombudsmen, ethics offices, and the like can rely on an infrastructure of public accountability and transparency to ensure that their findings result in lower incentives to commit corrupt acts. 13 References: Ades, A. and R. Di Tella (1995), "Competition and Corruption", Oxford Applied Economics Discussion Paper, Series. 169 April: 18. Ades, A. and R. Di Tella (1996), "The Causes and Consequences of Competition: A Review of Recent Empirical Contributions". In B Harris-White and G White (Ed), Liberalization and the new corruption, Institute of Development Studies Bulletin 27(2):6-11. Ades, A and R. Di Tella (1997), "The New Economics of Corruption: a Survey and Some New Results" in Political Corruption, (ed) Paul Heywood, Blackwell Publishers. Arvind K. Jain (1998), "Economics of Corruption", Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston/Dordrecht/London. Brunetti, A.G. Kisunko, and B. Welder (1997), "Credibility of Rules and Economic Growth: Evidence from World Wide Private Sector Survey", Background paper for the World Development Report 1997, Washington: The World Bank. Brunetti, A and B. Weder (1998a), "A Free Press is Bad News for Corruption", Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Zentrum der Universitat Basel Discussion Paper, No 9809 Brunetti, A and B. Weder (1 998b), "Explaining Corruption", Draft version, University of Saarland and University of Basel. Clements, B., R. Hugouneng and G. Schwartz (1995), "Government Subsidies: Concepts, International Trends and Reform Options", IMF Working Paper, 95/91, Washington, International Monetary Fund. Elliott, KA. (1997), "Corruption as an International Policy Problem: Overview and Recommendations ", Corruption and Global Economy, ed. by K.A. Elliott, Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C. Evans, P.B. and J.E. Rauch (1996), " Bureaucratic Structures and Economic Performances in Less Developed Countries", Mimeograph, San Diego: University of California, San Diego. Gaultung, F (1997), "The Social and Economic Implications of Corruption", Transparency International) Report 1997, Berlin Transparency International, 76-8. Goel, R.K., and M.A. Nelson (1998), "Corruption and Government Size: A Disaggregated Analysis", Public Choice, XCVII, 107-20. 14 Gurgur, Tugrul and Anwar Shah (2000). Localization and Corruption: Panacea or a Pandora's Box. Presented at the IMF Conference on Fiscal Decentralization, Washington, DC, November 21, 2000. Gurgur, Tugrul and Anwar Shah (1999). Major Causes of Corruption. World Bank, Processed. Henderson, D.R. (1999), "Power Corrupts - Editorial Comment", The Wall Street Journal, April 19. Hofstede, G., (1997), "Cultures and Organizations: Software of the Mind", McGraw Hill, New York. Husted, B. (1999), "Wealth, Culture, and Corruption", Journal of International Business Studies, XXX (2): 339-60 Huther, J and A. Shah (1998), "A Simple Measure of Good Govemance and its Application to the Debate on the Appropriate Level of Fiscal Decentralization", World Bank Working Paper, Series No. 1894, Washington D.C. Kaufmann, D. (1997), "Listening to Stakeholders' Views about Corruption in Their Countries", Harvard Institute of International Development" Kaufmann, D. (1998), "Challenges in the next Stage of Anticorruption", in New Perspectives on Combating Corruption, Transparency International and the World Bank. Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay, and P. Zoido-Lobaton (1999), "Governance Matters," World Bank Working Paper, Series No. 2196, Washington D.C. Kaufmann, D. and J. Sachs (1998), "Determinants of Corruption", Harvard University (forthcoming). Klitgaard, R. (1988), "Controlling Corruption". Knack and Keefer (1995), "The Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross Country Tests Using Altemative Institutional Measures", Economics and Politics, 7(3), 207- 27. Krueger, A (1974), "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society", American Economic Review 64, No.3, June 291-303. La Porta, R. and F. Lopez-De-Silanes, A. Shleifer and R.W. Vishny (1997), "Trust in Large Organizations", American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, CXXXVII (2), 333-8. 15 Leite, C. and J. Weidman (1999), "Does Mother Nature Corrupt? Natural Resources, Corruption and Economic Growth" International Monetary Fund Working Paper, 99-85, July. Mauro, Paolo (1995), "Corruption and Growth", Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 681-712. OECD (1999), "Public Sector Corruption: An International Survey of Prevention Measures, OECD, Paris. Operations Evaluation Department (OED), World Bank (2000), OED Methodology Syndicate - Evaluation Criteria Review. Draft, June 30, 2000. Paldam, M (1999), "The Big Pattern of Corruption, Economics, Culture and the Seesaw Dynamics", Unpublished Manuscript, Aarhus University, Denmark, June. Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1997). "The Political Economy of Corruption," in Kimberly Ann Elliot (ed), Corruption and the Global Economy, Washington DC: Institute for International Economics Sachs, J and A.Warner (1995), "Economic Reforms and Process of Globalization", Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1- 118. Schacter, Mark and Anwar Shah (2000). Anti-corruption Programs: Look Before You Leap. Prepared for the International Conference on Corruption, Seoul, South Korea, December 2000. Segal, P (1999), "Dealing with Devil: The Hell of Corruption", Impact, International Finance Corporation, Spring. Shah, Anwar (1999). Governing for Results in a Globalized and Localized World. Mahbub ul Haq lecture at the Pakistan Society for Development Economics, Islamabad, Pakistan, December 1999. Stapenhurst, R and K. Dye (1998), "Pillars of Integrity: The Importance of Supreme Audit Institutions in Curbing Corruption", in New Perspectives on Combating Corruption, Transparency International and the World Bank. Swamy, A., S. Knack, Y. Lee and 0. Azfar (1999), "Gender and Corruption", IRIS Center, University of Maryland, July. Tanzi, V and H Davoodi (1998), "Roads to Nowhere: How Corruption in Public Investment Hurts Growth", in New Perspectives on Combating Corruption, Transparency International and the World Bank. Tomaszewska, Eva and Anwar Shah (2000). Phantom Hospitals, Ghost Schools and Roads to Nowhere: The Impact of Corruption on Public Service Delivery Performance in Developing Countries. Processed. 16 Treisman, D (1999a)," The Causes of Corruption: A Cross National Study", Unpublished manuscript, University of California, Los Angeles, June. Treisman, D (1999b), "Decentralization and Corruption: Why are Federal States Perceived to be More Corrupt", Paper prepared for the presentation at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta, September 1999, University of California, Los Angeles, August Van Rijckeghem, C, and B Weder (1997), "Corruption and the Role of Temptation: Do Low Wages in Civil Service Cause Corruption?", IMF Working Paper, WP/97/73. World Bank (1997). World Development Report 1997, The World Bank, Washington DC. World Bank (2000). Reforming Public Institutions and Strengthening Governance. A World Bank Strategy, November 2000. 17 Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS2480 Productivity Growth and Resource Mubarik Ali November 2000 D. Byerlee Degradation in Pakistan's Punjab: Derek Byerlee 87287 A Decomposition Analysis WPS2481 Foreign Direct Investment in Africa: Jacques Morisset November 2000 N. Busjeet Policies Also Matter 33997 WPS2482 Can Institutions Resolve Ethnic William Easterly November 2000 K. Labrie Conflict? 31001 WPS2483 The Credit Crunch in East Asia: Pierre-Richard Ag6nor November 2000 M. Gosiengfiao What Can Bank Excess Liquid Joshua Aizenman 33363 Assets Tell Us? Alexander Hoffmaister WPS2484 Banking Crises in Transition Helena Tang November 2000 A. Carcani Economies: Fiscal Costs and Edda Zoli 30241 Related Issues Irina Klytchnikova WPS2485 Are Corruption and Taxation Really Raymond Fisman November 2000 R. Bonfield Harmful to Growth? Firm-Level Jakob Svensson 31248 Evidence WPS2486 Who Must Pay Bribes and How Much? Jakob Svensson November 2000 R. Bonfield Evidence from a Cross-Section of 31248 Firms WPS2487 Finance and Macroeconomic Volatility Cevdet Denizer November 2000 I. Partola Murat F. lyigun 35759 Ann L. Owen WPS2488 Revisiting the Link between Poverty Niels-Hugo Blunch November 2000 H. Vargas and Child Labor: The Ghanaian Dorte Verner 37871 Experience WPS2489 Banking Crises and Exchange Rate Ilker Domac November 2000 A. Carcani Regimes: Is There a Link? Maria Soledad Martinez 30241 Peria WPS2490 Contractual Savings, Stock, and Gregorio Impavido November 2000 P. Braxton Asset Markets Alberto R. Musalem 32720 WPS2491 Labor Demand and Trade Reform Pablo Fajnzylber November 2000 T. Gomez in Latin America William F. Maloney 32127 WPS2492 Health Insurance Reform in Four William Jack November 2000 H. Sladovich Latin American Countries: Theory 37698 and Practice Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS2493 Annuity Markets in Comparative Estelle James November 2000 A. Yaptenco Perspective: Do Consumers Get Dimitri Vittas 31823 Their Money's Worth? WPS2494 The Relevance ot Index Funds for Ajay Shah November 2000 A. Yaptenco Pension Investment in Equities Kshama Fernandes 31823 WPS2495 The Australian Annuity Market David M. Knox November 2000 A. Yaptenco 31823 WPS2496 Perspectives on the Sources of Somik V. Lall November 2000 R. Yazigi Heterogeneity in Indian Industry G. Chris Rodrigo 37176 WPS2497 State Policies and Women's Monica Das Gupta November 2000 M. Das Gupta Autonomy in China, India, and the Sunhwa Lee 31983 Republic of Korea, 1950-2000: Patricia Uberoi Lessons from Contrasting Danning Wang Experiences Lihong Wang Xiaodan Zhang WPS2498 Sustaining Economic Welfare: Kirk Hamilton November 2000 L. Rivera Estimating Changes in Per Capita 82819 Wealth WPS2499 The Treatment of Non-Essential Isidro Soloaga December 2000 L. Tabada Inputs in a Cobb-Douglas Technology: 36896 An Application to Mexican Rural Household-Level Data WPS2500 Investigating Corruption Canice Prendergast December 2000 H. Sladovich 37698