Policy, Research, nd External Affairs |ZI) F§ - _ 52 WORKING PAPERS K Publh Economics Country Economics Department The World Bank September 1990 WPS 425 Earmarking Government Revenues in Colombia William A. McCleary and Evamaria Uribe Tobon Reducing and rationalizing the earmarking of government funds will give Colombia's govemment budget more flexibility. Tbe extent of earmarking could be sharply reduced by limiting its application to revenue-sharing between levels of government and to cases where the beneft principle applies. The Prrhcy. Reearch, and Extema I Arfairs Comnplex distnhutes I'RI 'Working Paperns to dissemninaLe the rindings of work in progres and to anonursge the exchange of ideas among Hank suff and all oxhen interested in deve!oprecrt issues l'hese par.r carry the names of the authors. neflec rnly their vIeW%. and nhiu;d he wend and taed aIcordrnglh Iiw rinding., inerTrewuoin, and conclusons are th, aulthors' own They shmald not he aunhwed ii the A or!d Hankk :ir H,ard of IDr:,:ci. iLs managemnen. ow ary of is, memher coinrexs Policy, Research, arnd External Affairs Public Economics WPS 425 This paper- a pro(duct of the Public Economics Division, Country Economics Department -is part of a larger effort in PRE to improve the evaluation of government expenditure programs and the rationaliza- tion ofpublic expenditurcs. Copies are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H StrectNW, Washington DC 20433. Please contact Ann Bhalla, room N 10-059, extension 37699 (88 pages with tables). About 55 percent of total public income in (exporters or foreign consumers). The level of Colombia is earmarked for specific areas of duty is arbitrary so it is questionable whether the government activity. McCleary and Tobon correct amount of export financing is provided, recommend reducing the proportion and amount and the large subsidy differences among sectors of carmarked funds to give the govemment distort te allocation of resources. budget morc flexibility. Their recommendations would eliminate one quarter of existing earmark- The carmarking of departmental taxes on ing and introduce greater flexibility for an alcohol, tobacco, and gambling for health, additional one quarter. They funher conclude welfare, and spons are particuiarly strong that: candidates for elimination. Therc is no connec- tion between taxpayers and beneficiaries in these Earmarking should be limited to revenuc- arrangements and hence no indication of whether sharing and to situations wherc there is a clear appropriate amounts of funding for these activi- connection between the source of revenue and ties is being provided. the benefits of earmarked spending (for example, between payroll taxes and pension/disability lThe relativcly new tax allowance and sales benefits or between gaisoline taxes and highway tax transfe'r have played important rolcs in the funding). government's ef'l'ort to dccentralizc, the former for dcpartmnents, thc latter mainly lor inunicipali- Even then the commitmcnt to carmark iig ties. T'hcse revenuc-sharing arrangements need should not be openi-enicd. The autormatic to be strengthened by climinating anomalies ii 1inancinig arrangement should hb rcviewed the sharing formnulas, introducing morc incen- regularly and terminated automatically unILss tives for local rcsource mobilization, and expressly renewed. 'rThis would force a review of' strengthelning municipal capacity to absorb the pricing arrangeme,its, ol' the quality of invest- additional resources. ments financed, aLnd of the past and f'uture growth of sector infrastructure relative to needs. Earmarking that follows thc benefit principle closely (thc cot'lec lund, the gasolinc tax, and the Payroll taxcs should cover only social nI unicipal valori/ation tax) can be continued, but security. Colombia's pay'rol: taxes adcd 24-2') in cacti case, modificationis are suggestcd to percent to the cost of, lakbr. Eliminating payroll make the arrangement Aork hntctr. taxes for non-social-security purpxses \Aould lower labor cosLs and prohably take 0.5- l.() Certain parts of the ncw Organic Law of the percentage poirits ol'' thte employment rate. Budget relatcd to carmarkinig should be imple- mcnted quickly - the limits on minibudgets, the Earmarking for PROEXPO, which finances prohibition of new earmarking from existing subsidized loans for exporters, should be elimi- public resources, and the claim of the central nated. There is little connection between those budgct on public enterpriscs' operating surpluses. who pay import duties and those \kho hbnctfit The f'RE Working Paper Senies disseminates the Fildings (f 'A Trk unrider A a! in the Bank's Policsj. Research, and External Affairs Complex. An ohjectls e of the scries is to gel these fikillJg: out qui] kl]\, cs en if presentations are less than fully txolished. The finding-s. interpretations, and coMn hLii1ins in the. po;pers do1 not nec ssaril\ represent offii Bank pohlcy. 'rtoduccd h! t'. P'RI. I-)CII.'entinjt, (ctri.r THE EARMARKING OF GOVERNMENT REVENUES IN COLOMBIA Table of Contents I. INTRODUCTION ........................................................ 1 A. Definition of Earmarking ......................................... 1 B. Types of Earmarking Found in Colombia ............................ 2 II. TRENDS IN THE SIZE AND STRUCTURE OF EARMARKING, 1970-87 . . 6 A. Size and Structure of Earmarking ................................. 6 B. The Effects of Law 55 (1985) ..................................... 8 C. Consideration of Social Security and Public Enterprise Profits ............................................ 13 III. THE EXPERIENCE OF EARffARKING .17 A. The Origins of Earmarking .17 B. Recommendations of Previous Government Commissions .19 IV. AN EVALUATION OF EARHARKING .22 A. Revenue Sharing .22 1. The Tax Allowance (Situado Fiscal) .23 2. Sales Tax Transfer (Cesion a las Ventas) .29 B. National Government Level Earmarking .37 1. Coffee Fund .37 2. National Highways Fund (Gasoline Tax) .41 3. PROEXPO .45 C. Departmental Earmarking .48 D. Municipal Level Earmarking .50 E. Payroll Taxes .54 1. Funds for Social Welfare Objectives .54 2. Social Security .58 3. Employment Effects of Payroll Taxes .60 V. SUMHARY AND RECOMMENDATIONS .............................. 62 BIBLIOGRAPHY .69 STATISTICAL APPENDIX THE EARMARKING OF GOVERNMENT REVENUES IN COLOMBIA I. INTRODUCTION A. Definition of Earmarking 1. Earmarking is the term given to the practice of assigning revenues from specific taxes or groups of taxes to certain government activities which may be broadly or narrowly defined. As such, it contrasts with general fund financing where revenues frcm various sources are pooled together to be used for various government purposes; under genera± fund financing the connection between any particular government activity and any specific revenue source is remote or non-existent. In practice, earmarked revenues may be the sole source of financing for the specified activity or they may be supplemented by general transfers from the government budget or by borrowing. Lastly, earmarking may or may not have a benefit connection, with the persons paying the taxes or fees overlapping substantially with the group receiving the benefits of the public goods or services being provided.1 2. Broadly defined as the setting aside of government revenues for certain activities, earmarking can pertain to a wide range of public sector activities. At one end of the spectrum would be a fairly specific set of taxes set aside to be used for certain quite specific purposes. Examples would be gasoline taxes or tolls used for highway maintenance and construction, payroll taxes used to finance pensions and medical payments, 1/ Conversely benefit taxation may or may not involve earmarking since revenues may be added to the general pool. - 2 - and the after-tax profits of public commercial and industrial enterprises, the latter being included as earmarking to the extent that profits ere government purposes. Ac the opposite end of the spectrum would be earmarking in the broadest sense--the unconditional sharing of revenues between levels of government. Between these two ends of the spectrum lie a variety of earmarking varying in the specifieity of revenue sources, the specificity of government expenditures, the degree to which the benefit principle applies, and the mix of financing between earmarked and non- earmarked sources. B. TY1es of Earmarking Found in Colombia 3. Among free-market LDCs, Colombia--together with some other South American countries--have long been known for extensive earmarking. Table 1--which cites the major instances of earmarking in existence today with the agencies involved, the tax bases and rates, and the purposes to which revenues are put--gives some notion of the breadth of earmarking as currently practiced. It should be clear from the outset that earmarking in Colombia runs the full spectrum of experience. It has earmarking which follows the benefit principle (e.g., the highway funds, the airport funds, the valorization tax). It also has taxes with no clear benefit rationale (e.g., taxes on alcohol, gambling and tobacco used for health, sport6, and neighborhood roads). It has payroll taxes used for traditiona'. social security purposes (pensions and medical payments) and also for other purposes-vocational training, family welfare and nutrition. It also has revenue sharing between levels of government and an extensive set of decentralized agencies and enterprises at all the levels of government. 4. This paper has two broad objectives. The first is the examination of the trends in the size and structure of earmarking sincr 1970, -3- Table 1 Waler Sources of Earmarkit In Colmba armarkd PuAld/ Agency Lgal !nstrmseot Tax/l2venu Sees Tea at e Purpose. A. Revenue Soaring Tax Alseance Law 46/1971 ( lementing 94ational CurreAt SevenUe 132 (1975) Of transfer, 702 - basis of (Stuado Fiscal) Article IU of 1949 Kilu armarked &avomes 142 (1974) popul_tion s 1d j02 ared equally Conetitution) 152 (tbereafter) _ departents territories ad tbh Sp ecil Distriet of logota. Of amont received by each juris- diction, 742 ftr Reional Education Fuads (F;R) ..n *05 .r Sectioal Nesltb Servicee (SS). Salee Tax tranfer L_ 331548 gales tax revestu 10t (1949) Mulcipal activitils. secondary (Ceeoen a las vent..) 202 (1970) educetioo ed the 'ectionol pension 302 (1971) fund. The varieos a",area allocated to saeb were altoree b) LAw 22/1973, ta 43/1975 -.s Deers. 132/1993. LW 12,1196 Value added toa rv ees 30.3(1994) Por micipal activites. .*p. s"all 32.0 (1997) somnicipalities. Amounts also for 34.5(1948) uationl territories, sectioal socisl 37.5 (1999) security fund, and tl Itnatituro 41.0 (1990) beografico Agu,tia Codazsi (IGlC) sand 45.0 (1991) Ecula Suerlior de A6vinistracion 50.0 (1992) Publie (gI). 9. Mat %al Level 3. P?OE (Pood d4 Dt. 444/1967 (Arttele 229) CI? value c aerchandise 1.52 Encourage and prmote diversification Priton de iports of sxorts. sortesorioe) Dt. 2366/1974 (Article 6) CIF value of merchandise 3.72 imports (5t fron 1991) LW 75/1994 Ctr value of merchandise 62 imports 4. Eixlvy Fund (rondo Lw 43 (1947) ltfinery price per gallon 1142 and 53.52 Highway inveooetnt program vith 102 vial Eacional) arnd Decree of gasoline sod ACP respectively golng to Rational Fund for Neighborhood 2962 (1968) 2oads (Fonda NaCiOnal de Casinos Yecinales or FnCV); 102 for national railways (Forrocarriles Nacion al Law 30 (1982) Rsfin ry price per gallon Ccl.S13.S0 de Colombia)l and 52 for urban of gasoline and ACPR per gallon transport operatious (Corporacion Financiers de Transports or CFT) 5. 9UA (Servicio Nacional Decree 11/1957 Payroll of private 12 &au.ally Progrms of technical skills training. Aprendisij) (Article 9) enterprises Lw 53/1963 (Articles 2 Payrolls of public and 5) industrial sod commercial 22 anally *tterpriees end dixe4 enterprises Private Enterpris*e 22 a=ually Payrolls of central. 0.52 &otmally department. territories, unicipalities and Bogota Dt goverrAmets. ICIU (tnetituto Colonbiano LW 75/1968 (Article 63) Sale price of salt 122 Programs of protection of de Nienetar Fmiliar) children and the foaily LW 7/1979 (Article 39) Payrolle of Public enterprises 22 anusally Payrolls of Privet. enterprise 22 annAually LW 89/1999 P*yrolls of Private and Public enterpriss 32 ans lly eemeesation Funds (Csjas de Comeneecism FPmili n.*. Payrolls of Private sLterprises 42 Pmily allowaces and *oci' investmantel varioue private ivstm nt t. AM (Podo haronmtit al LW 3/1977 end Isolutlon Internatonal Peeseagers 9$15 per Coetruction. Lehabilitetion Iacimoal) 9042/1192 passenger nd ^larginnt of Airports ta, ,lution 1510/1995 International Passengers Col.$500 per pasenger -4- (Continued) Table I Halor 8 i,rce of Karmarkint in ColombiS Earmarked Fund/ Agency Legal Instruments Ta'/.(venuo Save Tax Rate Purpes*. 9. IFI (Inatituto de Fomento Law 6311983 and Decree C.I.F value of Lports 0.8$ (400 of Capitalization of IFI (for Industrial) 28/1985 21) conversion of investments and dobt mrvice) 10. Caje Agraria Law 68/1t83 and Decree CAI.. F alue of leporte 0.85 (400 of Capitalisatton of the fund 628/1985 2S) secording to the lws iJ/1971 and 66/1982 and for the Fund for Rural dwellings (Law 2011976 11. Corporatioal Hacionsl Law 20/1979 (Article 24) Tariff on .otel lodging, 5t Planning, promotion and finauci- de, Turieso of the tourist industry 12. Fondo Nacional del Carbon Law 61/1979 (Article 4) Value of the production of 2.80 (565 of Financing progrms of exploration, of coal at the mim site 52) exploitation. tranport. and coercialixation of coal. 13. FOCIlE (Companti d Fomento Law 551985 (Article 15) Not value of cinem tickets 161 Encouragement and development of Cin atografico) of the cineamaraphic industry in Colombia (8.5Z for the lund to encourage film making and 7.5X for producers. distribution and exhibitions of national wrks). 14. Caje Hacional de Law 4/196' (Article 1) Value of payrolls for the Col.S0.10 per For social services Prevision Social governent (national, each $100 departmental, municipal, or fraction territorial and special thereof district), police offices. and decontralited institutione 15. Superintendencia de Law 50/1984 (Art:cle 8) Public documents and deeds Fixed amount in As of 1986, 207 to be used for Notoriado * Registro Decree 3140/1984 and peso construction, adaptation and Low 65/1985 (Article 13) endowment of judicial courte and jails. 16. Pondo NHcional de Cafe 1940 F.O.8. value of coffea exports 40 uf expozc Stabiltoation of producer incomes, value, investments in economic end social pr.jactt in coffee growing arease Retention on financial end equity investments; export volume variou Fund activities (e.g. quality control, export promotion), 61 on inferior &rades C. Denartmental 17. Fondo de Casino. Decree 190/1969 Consumption of beer in all Col. $0.02 per Construction, maintenance and Vecinales (Article 9) departmet except Cundinamrca bottle repair of 1ucsl roads. 18. Sectional Health Services ns. beer, liquor, wine Beer - 8U Health expenditures Liquor 353 Wim - 15% 19. Seet'oa.1 Health Services n.e. Varioums gabling profits Health expenditures and Walfare Agencies and taxes and welfare assistance (beneficirLcias) 20. Sectional Sports n.e. Cigarettes 101 ad velores Assistance to sports. Of Co_istions (Juntas plus Col50.S 10 ad valore. revenues, 300 Adainistradores de per pack (domos- goes to Colombian Institute Deportee) tic *nd Col.$0.20 of Youth and Sports per pack (imports) (COLDEPCRTES) which in turn must transfer 100 to Colombion Institute of Culture (COLCvLTURA) 21. Schools for :bo Blind/ na. Lottery prizes 1exeeding 21 Assistance for the blind National leder.tion 100 peaso for the blind D. Municipal 22. Valorization tax for Law 25/1921 Increase in site value Amount equal to Investmnt in v&rioue variou municipal cost of invest- municipal improvemnts activi' lee sent and sea"c- (e.g. roa4s water, iated expenl se swere). -5- illuminating the major changes and their causes. To examine these trends, we cre4te what is--to our knowledge--the first comprehunsive time series on earmarking at all levels of government in Colombia. The second is an evaluation of the major examples of earmarking--what are their objectives and how well do they work in practice--with a view toward making recommendation3 for change. In making recommendations for reducing the scope of earmarking ir Colombia, we will be guided by several principles: (a) is there a substantial overlap between the beneficiaries and the tax/price payers for any given government service; (b) do the ta;L/price arrangements appear to be leading to appropriate levels or the service over time; and (c) are resources being utilized effectively for the purpose intended. The remainder of the paper is divided into four parts. Part II p:esents time series data on the size and structure of earmarking during the last two decades, which shed light on the factors behind the trends in earmarking. Prart III outlines some of the factors 'ehind the popularity of earmarking in Colombia and reviews the findings and recommendations of two major government commissions which have examined the subject--the Mission on Intergovernmental Finance of 1981 (or Bird-Wiesner Commission) and the Public Expenditures Commission of 1986 (Comision del Gasto Publico). Part IV undertakes a critical review of the major examples which make up over 902 of total earmarking. Part V summarizes our major findings and makes some recommendations for changes. -6- II. TRENDS IN THE SIZE AND STRUCTURE OF EARMARKING (1970-87) A. Size and Structure of Earmarking 5. Earmarking (rentas de destinacion especifica or RDEs) has long been a prominent feature of Colombian public finances.2 During the past two decades, the proportion of government revenues earmarked has increased by about one half and the sources of earmarking have become more varied. In 1970, RDEs consticuted just 11% of national government revenues and were equally large in size at the departmental level where they formed a much larger proportion of revenues (see Table 2). The most prominent sources of earmarking were beer, alcohol, and lottery revenues at the departmental level followed by the coffee expozt tax and gasolir.e tax at the national level, and the valorization tax for local improvements. Together, these four sources accounted for about 89% of all earmarking (see Table 3). In total, RDEs constituted 21Z of revenues at all levels of government. 6. The upward trend in earmarking since 1970 has been the product mainly of greater earmarking at the central government level; over the period, the proportion of national government revenues earma.ked tripled from 11% to a peak of 34% in 1984 before falling off slightly in the past three years (Table 2). The shares of earmarking in departmental and 2/ At first, our discussion will be confined to traditional sources of earmarking--i.e. those funds and revenue sharing arrangements that are usually listed as earmarking in Colombia. La' r, nontraditional sources of earmarking--payroll taxes and the operating profits of nonfinancial enterprises--will also be considered. There are two reasons for splitting the discussion in this fashion. Firet, the traditional sources are what is more commonly -hought of as earmarking. Secondly, longer time series were available for the traditional earmarking sources. Table 2 Shares of Earmarked Revenues in Government Ravenuesa (percentages) 1970 1975 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 Share in National Government Revenues 11.3 17.5 27.8 27.0 28.3 27.9 34.4 31.3 27.7 27.7 Share in Departmental Government Revenues 93.9 82.5 88.6 85.8 86.6 85.5 78.3 76.6 76.5 Share in Municipal Government Revenues 30.1 30.2 31.3 30.5 29.3 33.9 27.0 22.9 16.3b Share in Government Revenues All Levels 21.i 23.5 33.4 32.3 31.1 33.5 39.1 35.5 32.0 Source: Estimates based on Tables Al and A2 in Statistical Appendix. a. Earmarked revenues are listed in Statistical ADpendix Table A2, excluding payroll taxes, the operating profits of nonfinancial public enterprises and, at the national level, "other" sources of earmarking. Revenues are total tax and non-tax revenues at each level of government; at the national level, revenues from the 4% ad valorem tax on coffee exports are added 1970-1983, because the:e monies did not pass through the budget in those years. b. Likely to be an underestimate due to missing data. municipal incomes have been generally trending downward over the period. Between 1970 and 1986 the share of the central government's RDEs ir. the total rose from 44% to 75%, while the shares of the departmental and municipal governments fell from /-. to 23% and 9% to 2% respectively. 7. By far the biggest contr:ibuting factor to the increase was the rise in revenue sharing between levels of government. "Situado fiscal" and "cesion a las ventis" contributed about 39% of the total increase in earmirking over the period. Other major contributors were: departmental alcohol/tobacco/gambling taxes (23%), the gasoline tax (14%), import duties to support PROEXPO, IFI and Caja Agraria (11%) and the coffee export tax (5%).3 In addition, there wao a proliferation of relativuly minor RDEs--e.g. hotel taxes to support tourism, taxes on movie tickets to support movie making and culture, taxes on coal producticoln t-o *upport exploration and development, and a variety of others. 8. By the mid-1980s, the following six were the major sources of earmarking in descending order of importance: revenue sharing (situado fiscal and cesion a las ventas), departmental alcohol/tobacco/gambling taxes, the gasoline tax, the import tax (PROEXPO, etc.), the coffee export tax, and the valorizaticn tax. Together they constituted about 94% of total earmarking (see Table 3). Ihe remaining funds (about 20 in number) individually and even together contribute very little to total earmarking. B, The Effects of Law 55 (1985) 9. Since Lle mid-1980s there has been a deliberate governuent effort to curtail the extent of earmarking, most particularly as the result of recommendat.ic !l v the Ccrmission on Public Expenditurec. However, resi,stance, to re.i(lt1ions in earmarking has been strong and the impact of measures taKewn t.O date has been limited. Specifically Law 55 stipulated that the NCtOUT10l Conc il. of Economics and Sorial Policy (CONPES) would decide cn the reassignment of funds from recipients of earmarkinlg to 3/ While the taxes listed made significant contributicns to increases in earmarking over the period, not all grew as fast as total government revenues. We have already seen how departmental and municipal earmarking failed to keep pace with own sources of revenue at those levels of government. The rising share of earmarkirng in national government revenues is explained by rising shares for revenue sharing, PROEXPO (plus IFI and Caja Agraria), and (to a small extent) a variety of minor funds making up for falling shares for the coffee export tax and gasoline tax. Together, the former three rose from 2.9% to 21.7% of national government revenues between 1970 and 1987 while the latter two fell from 'lZ to 5.9%. -9- complementary or re'ated activities. The RDEs affected by Law 55 and the activities to which funds could be reassigned are spelled out in Table 4. The upper bounds or reassignments were set at 10% of earmarked revenues in 1985,4 20S in 1986, and rising in 101 increments to a maximum of 502 in 1989. In implementing Law 55, proposals would be made by the relevant minister and the Chief of the National Planning Department based on programs submitted by the agencies receiving earmarking funds and related agencies and the final allocation would be made by CONPES on a case by case basis. The reassignment could be effected by the earmarking recipient agency itself carrying out the activ4t' or, if it was unable, by contractual agreements with the government or with its various public crganization or enterprises. 10. Law 55 resulted in the reallocation of Col.$30 billion and 52 billion in 1986 and 1987 (Table 5), the equival.ent of 11.9% and 15.2% of total earmarking at the national leval in the two years respectively. If these amounts were r-moved the remaining earmarking at the natioral level would have constituted 24% of national revenues in the two years (in contrast to the 28% figures repcrted in Table 2). Particularly significant amounts--both absolutely and relative to total earmarking--were involved in the cases of PROEXPO, the gasoline tax, ICBF and SENA. 4/ The limit for PROEXPO was set at 20% for 1985 after which it would follow the same schedule as other funds. - 10 - Table 3 Share of Various Traditional Earmarked Funds in Total Earmarked lundsa 1970-86 a/ (percentages) 1970 1975 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 Ltional Level 44.7 65.2 72.2 72.4 74.7 70.8 71.9 73.5 74.7 Tax on Impo.ts C.I.F. 1.3 4.1 8.1 7.5 8.4 6.8 8.5 8.5 10.5 Caja Agraria 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.1 1.1 1.2 IFI 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.1 1.1 1.2 PROEXPO 1.3 4.0 7.3 6.7 7.5 6.0 6.3 6.3 8.1 Gasoline Tax 14.2 8.9 20.8 21.1 18.1 15.3 13.5 14.8 13.8 Fondo Vial Nacional (FVN) 752 1C.7 6.7 15.6 15.8 13.5 11.5 10.5 9.9 9.7 Fondo de Caminos Vec!nalea (FCN) 102 1.4 0.9 2.1 2.1 1.8 1.5 1.2 2.0 1.6 Ferrocarrilea Nacional 102 1.4 0.9 2.1 2.1 1.8 1.5 1.2 2.0 1.6 Corp. Fin de Tranaporte 52 0.7 0.4 1.0 1.1 0.9 0.8 0.6 0.9 0.8 Tax on International Travel 0.7 n.a. 1.1 1.5 1.9 1.7 1.5 1.4 1.0 42 Tax Coffee Exports 19.1 12.9 4.4 3.2 2.7 2.6 2.8 3.3 5.3 Fondo Nacional del Cafe n.a. n.a. 3.7 2.7 ,.3 2.2 2.3 2.8 4.4 Fedecafe, zonas cafeterias n.a. n.a. 0.7 0.5 0.4 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.9 2 Tax on Tourism 0.0 0.7 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.1 0.1 0.1 6I Tax on Movie Theater Tickets 0.0 0.0 0 0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 ontributions and Participations 2.8 2.2 1.5 1.0 1.6 1.9 1.9 3.0 2.1 pecial Funds 0.1 0.5 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.4 0.6 1.2 2.4 b/ Revenue Sharing 6.4 35.9 35.7 37.7 41.4 41.7 43.1 41.2 38.9 Tax Transfer 0.0 23.4 23.8 27.4 28.3 29.9 28.7 25.9 22.5 Sales Tax Allowance 6.4 12.5 11.9 10.3 13.1 11.8 14.3 15.3 16.5 mnartment Level 46.7 29.5 23.4 23.1 21.0 23.8 23.5 22.7 23.2 inicival Level 8.6 5.3 4.4 4.5 4.3 5.4 4.6 3.8 2.1 c/ See footnote to Table 2 for definitions. Includes some miscellaneous reallocations under Law 55. Understated because of missing data. Durce: Estimates based on Table A2 in Statistical Appendix. - 11 - 11. There are a number of reasons why the foregoing overstates the reduction in earmarking actually achieved by Law 55. First, Law 55 did not--and was nout intended to--tree up earmarked money t:o be isod entirely at the central government's discretion. The alternatives fcr wh;i.;h monies could be used were carefully spelled out and narrowly limitea tc activities in the same sector. Secondly, while intending to free up budgetary resources, Law 55 actually created two new (relatively small) earmarked funds--the tax on cinema tickets and the fees on registration of public documents. Moreover, in subsequent years, still further RDEs have been established e.g., the allocation of the VAT on cement for housing and water/sewerage and the national valorization tax on public works to be allocated for municipalities. Lastly, in numerous cases, the earmarkir.g recipient agen.cies have ended up carrying out the activities mandated by Law 55 the-seives. AD examples, the Law 55 stipulation that a port.ion of gascii4no t ax re'enues be used for road maintenance and repo-ale tirvely keeps the _:-Fs with'n the highway fund (Fondo Vial Nacioni.). M;n-v of Law 55 pro4e½ts irtle-rated rural development or in trainng -.r he Ministry of Education are carried cut by SENA itself on a cont.rac basis; since other agencies are n-. pre par&-d to carry out the work. While son-.o of lCBFs mc..es eore rea! ^ccated tc Ministry of HealLh programs (e.sg. Va7ciations, chldren 's h* s.p.tals, mal.aria control) in 1985-87, thereafter ICBFs Law 55 money will We `edicated tc its own "hogares" (hcusehoid) progran .9f nutrition and daycare support (see paragraph 62). In sum, the reallocation of resources under Law 55 is in reality much smaller than appears on the surface; only in the case of PROEXPO has there been a significant shift of resources (i4n this case, out of subsidized export credit toward a separate program c t expert subsidies). - 12 - Table 4 Potential Reallocations Under Law 55 (1985) Organization or Recipients of or Agency Earmarked Source Reallocation 1. National Highway Fund Tax on gasoline Construction; maintenance and National Fund for and valorization and repair of national Neighborhood Roads tax on national niighways and local roads; public works and improvements in river navigation. 2. National Aeronautical Stamp tax on sales Ai-port activities and those Funds aboard and airport tax, activities listed in 1 above. 3. PROEXPO 62 tax on CIF value Funding of CERTS (tax refund of imports certificates and other instrmnents to promote exports) 4. IFI Tax on cif value Small-scale industry, timber of imports industry, and fisheries. 5. National Tourism Tourism tax Preservation and restoration Corporation of national monuments and parks; prcmotion of cottage industry; and the financing of tourism development certificatee. 6. National Coal Fund Coal production tax Finance of mining investi- gation and exploration activities. 7. Notary and Registration Duties on the registration Finance of investments for Superintendency of public instruments conatruction; irnprovement and issuance of notary and equipping of judicial certificates offices and priscn faci- lities. 8. Hotion Picture Promotion A new 162 tax on cinema 8.52 of the tax amount to ticket prices be paid into the Motion Picture Promotion Fund to be managed by the Motion Picture Development Company and used to finance cultural and artistic programs. The remaining 7.52 shall be paid to producers, distributors, and exhibitors of Colombian films in proportions esta- blished by government with greater amounts going for full length features. 9. SENA (National Apprentice- Payroll tax Training geared to jobs, ship Service) technical and small industry and agriculture extension. SENA to assume responsibility for financing, in full or in part, industrial schools and technical institutes, colleges, agricultural training schools, and computer and telemetrics programs. 10. ICBF (Colombia Family Payroll Taxes Child and Family protection Welfare Institute) programs; vaccination and prevention health programs; food assistance programs for India communities; public nursing homes; and also the maintenance of children's hospitals and construction of water supply infrastructure in comnunity with less the 60,000 inhabitants (based on 1973 census) Source: LEY 55 Por medio de la cual se dictan normas tendientes ai ordenamiento de las Finanzas del Estado y se dictan otras disposiciones; June 18, 1985. - 13 - Table 5 Reallocation of Earmarked Funds Under Law 55/85, 1986-89 (millions of Colombian current pesos) 1986 1987 1988 1989 Donor Budget Actual Budget Actual Budget Budget PROEXPO 6,651.0 5,408.0 10,503.0 20,744.0 31,120.0 42,000.0 ICBF 3,100.0 2,635.0 3,300.0 1,145.0 0.0 19,315.0a SENA 2,286.0 2,449.0 2,980.0 2,984.0 0.0 19,500o0a FAN 990.0 500.0 1,000.0 332.0 696.0 850.0 Supernotariado Y Registro 910.0 677.0 1,510.0 1,315.0 1,750.0 1,750.0 Fondo Rotatorio De Aduanas 0.0 56.0 359.0 70.0 350.0 570.0 Corturismo 278.0 242.0 643.0 643.0 404.0 582.8 Focine 35.0 146.0 32.0 164.0 185.1 Fondo Nacional Del Carbon 556.0 139.0 775.0 297.0 649.0 926.2 Gasolina ACPHb 9,683.0 9,937.0 17,556.0 17,880.0 25,492.0 40,324.0 Reallocations among various agencies (LEY 55/85)C 3,453.0 3,164.0 1,245.0 1,157.0 1,555.0 2,969.0 Ecopetrol (Decree 399/86) 5,120.0 5,120.0 5,500.0 5,500.0 5,500.0 Instituto De Fomento Industrial 970.0 TOTAL 33,027.0 30,362.0 45,517.0 52,099.0 67,680.0 129,942.1 a. ICBF will reallocate this amount within its budget to a program that is a government priority (Children's Welfare Homes). SENA will reallocate this within its budget to special government programs. b. Estimates based on Law 55/85 percentages. c. Several agencies included. Source: Contraloria General de la Republica for actual figures and Departmento Nacional de Planeacion for budget figures. C. Consideration of Social Security and Public Enterprise Profits 12. Focussing on the traditional sources of earmarking--as in Tables 2 and 3 above--understates the true extent of the earmarking of public funds in Colombia.5 Public enterprise profits and the payroll tax for social security and SENA, ICBF, etc. are the major reasons for th- understatement. Net profits of public enterprises (i.e. gross receipts net of operating 5/ Qu!2"e apart f.om the fact that some relatively minor funds are not included in our data. - 14 - expenses and taxes paid to government) may be considered earmarking because they are left to the control of the enterprises despite the fact that they are owned in whole or in part by the government; that is, the government cannot or in practice does not attempt to allocate such resources at irt discretion. Similarly, payroll taxes for social security imply an obligation to pay pensions and medical expenses now and in the future and the government has no discretion about how payroll tax receipts are to be used. Depending on the rates charged relative to the mortality and morbidity problems faced by the population, present revenues may be greater or less than the present payment obligations. That part of the payroll tax that is allocated to SENA and ICBF commits the public monies to funding a variety of activities in training, nutrition, daycare, and social welfare. In reality, therefore, such profits and payroll taxes are little different than the traditional cases of earmarking. Table 6 Shares of Traditional and Non-Traditional Earmarkina in PublIc Incomea (incl. social security and public enterprises profits) (percentages) 1970 1975 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 Share in national public income 28.6 31.8 39.3 38.2 43.3 43.0 54.2 49.9 44.9 46.0 Share in departmental public income 90.9 88.5 89.3 88.4 82.0 80.8 Share in municipal public income 61.4 65 0 65.9 67.9 63.4 67.2 Share in Public Income All levels 45.5 44.6 48.7 49.1 57.8 54.6 a. Public income is the sum of tax and non-tax revenues, operating profits of public non-financial enterprises, and payroll taxes for social security and for SENA, ICBF, etc. The ad valorem coffee export tax is added to national public income 1970-83 since these revenues did not pass through the budget in those years. The earmarking considered here is traditional earmarking plus non-traditional earmarking which includes non-financial public enterprise profits and payroll taxes for social security and SENA, ICJF, etc. Source: Estimates based on Tables Al and A2 in Statistical Appendix. - 15 - 13. The result of adding these non-traditional sources of earmarking to the traditional sources is shown in Tables 6 and 7 for the period 1980 to 1985. The extent of earmarking in public income6 is, of course larger at all levels of government but, most particularly, at the national and municipal levels. The upward trend in earmarking is still also clear, most particularly at the national level where data is available for 1970-87. Earmarking in total public income was 462 in 1980 and rose to 55Z or more in 1984 and 1985. Over the period, the share of earmarking contributed by payroll taxes and public enterprise operating profits has been increasing while the share contributed by traditional RDEs has been falling; by the end of the period the split between traditional and non-traditional sources of earmarking was roughly fifty-fifty. Increasing public enterprise profits at the national and municipal level have been the major cause of this trend. In 1985, the major contributors to traditional plus non-traditional earmarking were in descending order of importance: public enterprise profits (27Z), payroll taxes for social security and SENA/ICBF (24Z), revenue sharing (20%), departmental alcohol/tobacco/gambling taxes (11%), gasoline tax (71), import duties for PROEXPO, etc (41), the municipal valorization tax (2Z)7 and the ad valorem tax on coffee exports (2%). Together these eight sources account for about 97% of total earmarking. Out of the large number of other cases of earmarking, no single source contributes as much as one percent to the total. 6/ Public income is derived by adding to the tax and non-tax revenues used in Table 2 the net operating profits of non-financial enterprises and payroll taxes. 7/ Also includes Bogota's taxes on beer and tobacco. - 16 - Table 7 Share of Various Traditional and Non-traditonal Earmarkina Sources in Total Earmarking. 1980-85 a/ 1980 '981 1982 1983 1984 1985 Natianal 72.5 71.6 75.2 72.5 75.4 73.3 Traditional Earmarking 44.6 43.7 40.6 37.6 35.4 36.3 Tax on Imports C.I.F. 4.9 4.4 4.5 3.5 4.1 4.1 Gasoline Tax 12.5 12.3 9.6 7.9 6.5 7.2 Tax on International Travel 0.7 0.9 1.0 0.9 0.7 0.7 Coffee Export Tax 2.7 1.9 1.4 1.3 1.3 1.6 Tax on Tourism 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.1 0.0 Tax on Movie Tickets 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Contributions and Participation 0.9 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.9 1.5 Special Funds 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.3 0.6 Revenue Sharing 21.6 22.1 21.9 21.6 20.7 19.9 Tax Allowance 14.3 16.1 15.0 15.5 13.8 12.5 Sales Tax 7.3 6.0 6.9 6.1 6.9 7.4 Other 1.1 1.2 1.0 1.1 0.9 0.8 Non-Traditional Earmarking 27.9 27.9 34.6 34.9 40.0 37.0 Payroll Taxes 22.0 23.2 21.6 25.3 23.4 22.2 Social Security 16.4 17.6 16.0 19.5 17.9 17.1 SENA, ICBF, etc. 5.6 5.6 5.6 5.8 5.5 5.1 Operating Profits of Non-Financial Public Enterprises 5.9 4.7 13.0 9.6 16.6 14.8 Departments 18.2 17.3 14.4 15.9 14.2 14.1 Traditional Earmarking '4.1 13.5 11.1 12.3 11.3 11.0 Non-Traditonal Earmarkin& Social Security 1.1 1.2 1.0 1.1 0.7 1.1 Operating Profits of Non-Financial Public Enterprises 3.0 2.6 2.3 2.5 2.2 2.0 Municipal 9.4 11.1 10.4 11.5 10.4 12.6 Traditional Earmarking 2.7 2.6 2.2 2.8 2.2 1.8 Non-Traditional Earmarking Social Security 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.7 0.6 0.6 Operating Profits of Non-Financial Public Enterprises 6.2 8.0 7.7 8.0 7.6 10.2 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Traditional Earmarking (All Levels) 61.4 59.8 53.9 52.7 49.0 49.1 Non-Traditional Earmarking (All Levels) 38.6 40.2 46.1 47.3 51.0 50.9 a. See footnote to Table 6 for definitions. Source: Estimates based on data in Table A2 in Statistical Appendix. - 17 - III. THE EXPERIENCE OF EARMARKING A. The Orizins of Earmarking 14. The extent of earmarking found in Colombia is the product of several important features of its politics--decentralization, political instability, and an elaborate budgetary process. Since Independence, its politics have been dominated by powerful and opposing political forces favoring centralization and decentralization of power. Over the long sweep of one hundred or more years, centralization has been the dominant tendency, producing a central government that carries out the majority of public activities, collects an even larger share of public incomes, and dominates the decisionmaking process on economic and social questions. In the last two decades, however, there have been greater efforts at decentralization, the hiving off of government activities to special agencies and to lower levels of government. This has necessitated a shift in public revenues--partly on a discretionary basis and partly on a more automatic basis through the sharing of government revenues or the setting aside of particular revenue sources for particular activities. 15. Colombia's political history has also been dominated by strong opposing forces, producing periods of extreme tension and often violence. In a climate of uncertainty--where the political situation can shift abruptly and sharply, earmarking provides a means for providing somewhat greater certainty that certain important activities will be carried out. The wishes of one administration or congress will be carried on to the next unless explicit measures are taken to stop the activity. 16. Last, but very important, is the budgetary process. The process has been designed on the premise that carelessness and outright dishonesty - 18 - are prevalent; unless checked, monies are likely to be mismanaged and/or diverted to personal use or uses not intended by the executive or congress. Elaborate procedures have been set up to assure that this does not occur. 17. Sevetal aspects of the budget process have been relevant to explaining the popularity of earmarking.8 First is that initial budgets bear little relation to final budgets. While initial budgets may have been carefully prepared in line with the government's medium-term objectives, they are constrained by artificial limits on estimates of revenue increases and the requirement of budget balance, necessitating several additional budgets each year. During the additions, political pressures, short-term emergencies (e.g. unforeseen losses in public agencies), and lack of time appear to overwhelm the planning process leading to a final budget that is different in total (often 251 or more) and composition than the original. Second, the authorization process by which monthly allocations of allowable expenditures are made leads to considerable uncertainty. "Authorizations" are based on estimates of monthly available resources by the Ministry of Finance, the resulting giros issued by ministries and agencies become payment orders only when countersigned by the Inspector-General (Contraloria) which checks to see whether resources exist, and payment is actually made by Treasury only if resources are in fact available. Since there is considerab- pressure to pay government salaries, debt service obligations, transfer payments ard other seeming essentials (defense, security), the investment program bears the brunt of short-term adjustments. Lastly, recipients of budgetary resources have to pass through elaborate and time-consuming controls designed to prevent the 8/ The following statements would have to be modified somewhat in light of the new budget law. See paragraph 71. - 19 - diversion of funds. Through pre-audit (control previo), Contraloria attempts to check each item of expenditure to ensure that it is in accordance with the government's intentions, but it is not clear that these procedures do prevent the misuse of funds or, more importantly, ensure that on balance the funds are being used effectively to forward the government's objectives. 18. For agencies faced with this process, earmarking has a number of advantages.9 It gives them greater certainty about the amount and timing of resources they will receive during the year. It is easier for them to forecast the amounte of the earmarked tax (even acknowledging possible errors in those forecasts) than to forecast the outcome of the budgetary process during the year. Moreover, procedures are easier for earmarked funds. Earmarked taxes may be collected by the Division of National Taxes and distributed to the relevant agency or, in some cases collected directly by the agency itself. In either case, earmarked monies are subject to far less detailed controls th i general budgetary resources. In sum, earmarking gives recipients more certainty about available resources, allowing them to plan their spending programs more effectively and to enter into longer-term contractual arrangements. B. Recommendations of Previous Government Commissions 19. The Commission on Intergovernmental Finances of 1981 (the Bird- Wiesner Report)10 took a generally skeptical view of the earmarking of taxes, but recognized that such earmarking had its origins in the weakness of Colombian budgetary processes and could be justified--in some cases--by 9/ These points were cited in numerous interviews with officials from agencies that are recipients of earmarked fund. 10/ Interaovernmental Finance in Colombia - Final ReDort of the Mission on Intertovernmental Finance (International Tax Program: Harvard Law School; Cambridge, Massachusetts; 1984). - 20 - appeal to public finance principles. Budgetary processes are designed to curb deviations and dishonesty and the result is bothersome, time-consuming and uncertain. Earmarking provides sim,pler and clearer procedures and more certain outcomes. The Bird-Wiesner Report took the pragmatic view that a more perfect world of rational budget processes moving resources to their highest-priority uses is not readily obtainable and earmarking may be justified because it works and because it protects priorities. Thus Bird- Wiesner approached earmarking on a case-by-case basis asking whether the following criteria were fulfilled: (a) is the benefit principle involved with a clear identity of tax/price payers and beneficiaries (i.e. it is not appropriate to use earmarking where benefits are not easily assigned or where income redistribution objective- are involved); (b) does earmarking provide the sole source of financing (or, at least the preponderance of funds) for the entity involved; where large amounts of funds from the general budget are involved, earmarking may not be doing any harm but it is also not clear that it is having any impact on the allocation of resources; and (c) is there a match between the revenues generated and requirements of the recipient agency or is there a systematic tendency for the tax/pricing procedures to under- or over-fund activities. 20. With these criteria in mind, the Bird-Wiesner Report made a nunber of recoummendations:11 o Earmarking which takes the form of allocating a fixed percentage of total government expenditures (or total government revenues) to a specified activity (e.g. justice or education in Colombia's national budget) serves no justifiable purpose and should be eliminated. 11/ Ibid, pp. 111-114 and pp. 379-380. - 21 - o Revenue sharing arrangements between levele of government may be justified but the sharing formulas need to be modified to assure that no jurisdiction obtains amounts in excess of its needs. O Some uses of the payroll tax can be clearly justified on benefit principle grounds (e.g., SENA) but others (e.g. ICBF and the Cajas de Compensacion) clearly cannot and in no case was it clear that the payroll taxes were generating the appropriate amount of resources for the sector. O Earmarking of taxes with no clear benefit rationale ought to be abolished; this would eliminate, for example, the use of departmental taxes on beer and alcohol for the health sector or the use of tobacco and amusement taxes to support sports. O There is no justification for leaving public enterprise sector profits at the disposition of the enterprise and public enterprises should be subject to income taxes. 21. Since the Bird-Wiesner Report, there appears to be growing pressure to eliminate or at least substantially reduce the role of earmarking in Colombia. Starting from the same set of criteria as Bird-Wiesner, the Comision del Gasto Publico (1986) comes to a much harsher conclusion. Having examined most of the prominent cases of earmarking, it finds that cases of identity between payers and beneficiaries are in fact the exception (only the funds for highways and aviation seem to fit this criterion very closely); cases of extremely tenuous or non-existent connections predomainate (even SENA and PROEXPO fail to produce a significant overlap). Moreover, the Commission is very skeptical of the argument justifying earmarking by reference to Colombia's inefficient budget processes. Given these inefficiencies it may be desirable, from any - 22 - agency's point of view to obtain earmarked resources, but there is no evidence chat recipients of earmarked resources are more efficient than other agencies or that--given the lack of identity between payozs and beneficiaries--the appropriate amount of resources is being allocated to these sectors. Hence, it is not clear that earmarking leads to an efficiency gain from the point of view of the country. 22. On the basis of the above arguments, the Commission concludes: (3) earmarking should be eliminated;12 (b) the budgets of all agencies ought to be subject to the same budgetary process; (c) improvements in the administration of the revenue sharing arrangements appear to be desirable. While not pursuing this matter further, the Commission also expressed concern over the effects of payroll taxes on the cost of labor and hence upon employment. IV. AN EVALUATION OF EARMARKING A. Revenue Sharing 23. One of the prominent characteristics of Colombian pubiic finance is the significant transfer of revenues between levels of government and from the various levels to a number of decentralized agencios. In the main, the flow is from the central government proper to its own decentralized agencies and to lower levels of government and their decentralized agencies. Part of the transfers are discretionary, the amounts being decided each year as part of the budgetary process, but a growing proportion of transfers are automatic, the result of turning over revenues from specified taxes or fees to decentralized agencies and the sharing of 12/ Reference hers seems to be to a subset of earmarking that excludes revenue sharing, payroll taxes (except for SENA, ICBF, and the Cajas de Compensacion Familiar), and the profits of public enterprises. - 23 - revenies between levels of government according to predetermined rules. The dominant factors in the latter have been the tax allowance (situado fiscal) and the sales tax transfer (cesion de ventas or IVA). Together, their share in central government RDEs and in central government current revenues grow from 14 to 56Z and 2? to 15Z between 1970 and 1987. The tax allowance is roughly a third larger than the sales tax t-:ansfer, but the latter has been growing more rapidly in recent years. 1. The Tax Allowance (Situado Fiscal) 24. The tax allowance was implemented through Law 46 of 1971 which followed from Article 182 of the Colombia Constitution of 1968 which provided that a portion of annual ordinary revenues13 be allocated among departmenti, national territories, and the Special District of Bogota with 30% to be shared equally among 33 jurisdictions and 70% to be divided on the basis of population shares as they appeared in the 1964 census. Law 46 called for the share to be 13Z, 14%, and 15% in 1973, 1974 and 1975, thereafter increasing by 2% per annum to a maximum of 25% provided that ordinary revenues were rising by at least 15% per year. These 2% increases were never formally implemented and so the sharing formula remains at 15%; as will be shown below, the amounts actually shared have fluctuated around that limit. 25. Law 46 also stipulates that 74% of the amount transferred each year shall be used to fund the operating costs of primary education and 26% to finance those of the health sector. These funds are a major source of finance for primary education and make a significant contribution to the financing of health. The national government retains the right to alter 13/ Ordinary revenues are defined as current revenues not earmarked by legislation for any specific purpose or use. - 24 - the split between education and health, but has not done so specifically. The departmental and territorial government have a legal obligation to provide, in addition to the tax allowance, the same share of their ordinary income to finance primary education and health operating costs as they provided in 1972. According to the law, the funds provided through the tax allowance are to be administered through the Regional Education Funds (Fondos Educativos Regionales or "FERs") and Section Health Services (Servicios Seccionales de Salud or "SSSs"). Despite the seeming tightness of the legal provisions for implementing the tax allowance, there has been considerable room for flexibility in how they have been interpreted. There are a number of reasons for this: first the 7 -uirements of individual FERs and SSSs are considered and the amounts are totalled to make sure that they do not exceed the amount available to be distributed. Second, where the sum of the tax allowance and local resources in any jurisdiction is not sufficient to meet requirements, supplements can be added. Similarly where th?re are excesses, the excess may be diverted to the finance of investment with the apprcval of the Ministry of Finance. Third, the process of additions to the initial budget distorts the process still further since the additions do not follow the sharing formula precisely. 26. As a result, there is considerable variation in the proportion shared, the share going to each jurisdiction, and the split between education and health by jurisdiction or in total. These results show up clearly in statistical Appendix Tables A3 through A5. Table A3 shows that the share of the tax allowance in ordinary revenues (current revenues minus earmarked taxes) has mostly been above the 15Z level in the last decade. Starting from about 12% in 1975 it rose to a peak of 242 by 1984 before falling back sharply. While according to a strict interpretation of the sharing formula, each jurisdiction would obtain a constant share of the - 25 - total tax allowance each year (since the numb.r of jurisdictions is fixed and each jurisdiction's share in the 1964 population is fixed), Table A4 shows that jurisdictional shares exhibit considerable year to year fluctuations. Moreover, there appear to be a number of patterns in the data: o Departments consistently receiving more than implied by the sharing formula: Antioquia, Bogota, Choco, Cordoba, Cundinamarca, Norte Santander, Santander. o Departments consistently receiving less than implied by the sharing formula: Atlantico, Bolivar, Boyaca, Caldas, Cauca, Magdalena, Narino, Quindio, Risaralda, Sucre, Valle de Cauca. 0 The territories' share in the tax allowance is always greater than their share in population but they consistently (approximately 85Z of cases) obtain less than implied by the sharing formula. The remaining departments have had a more mixed experience of positive and negative differences from amounts implied by the sharing formula. Lastly, Table P5 shows that the shares devoted to education and health in the tax allowance have deviated--quite often substantially--from the formula. For the total, education shares have varied from a low of 71% (1986) to a high of 802 (1980) with health shares, of course, varying conversely. For individual jurisdict4ons, the variations have been even wider. 27. While the flexibility with which the situado fiscal sharing formula has been applied is welcome, the formula contains a number of flaws --regarding its treatment of small versus large population areas and its failure to provide incentives for devartmental resource mobilization--which should be corrected. First, the sharing formula for the tax allowance favors less populated jurisdictions at the expense of more populated areas as compared with a formula based on population alone. The full dimensions - 26 - of the bias toward areas with smaller popLtations may not be appreciated, however. Given the shares to be allocated on population and non-population bases, the formula says that all jurisdictions whose population is greater than 3.03% of Colombia's population will share in the tax allowance in a lower proportion than their share in total population while all those with populations less than 3.03% will obtain shares in the tax allowance that are higher than their share in total population.14 Thus Antioquia with 14.2% of the population gets 10.85Z of the tax allowance and Boyaca with 6.1% gets 5.18% while Sucre with 1.8% gets 2.17% and San Andres with 0.1% gets 0.98%. Put another way, according to the sharing formula, the per capita transfer th.:t a jurisdiction receives varies inversely with its share in the total population. The potential variance will be larger, the larger is the non-population based factor in the sharing formula. Thus, the per capita amount received can be ranked with the highly populated areas (e.g. Antioquia, Bogota) at the bottom and the small territories at the top. As compared with Antioquia (14.2' of the 1964 population) residents of Norte de Santander (3.1% of the population) would receive 30% more; Sucre (1.8% of population) 58% more; Caqueta (0.6% of population) 190% more; and San Andres 1180% more. However desirable it might be to 14/ Given that 30% of the tax allowance formula is shared equally by jurisdictions and 70% is allocated on the basis of population and that there are 33 jurisdictions, the difference between a formula based on population and the present tax allowance formula is Pi _ 3 + .7 Pi Pop 33 Pop _.3 Pi _ 3 , when Pi is the population of the ith Pop 33 jurisdiction and Pop is total population. This expression is zero when the population share of the ith district is 3.03%, positive for greater population shares, and negative for smaller. Note that the point at which the expression is zero depends solely on the number of jurisdictions and is independent of the shares allocated on a population and non-population basis. - 27 - make some additional resources available for smaller areas (say to create and maintain a critical minimum level of public education and health services or to compensate for the dispersion of population), it would be better to do so on the basis of estimated costs of compensating for smallness. The differential gains and losses for various jurisdictions cited above is not related to wealth or poverty in any systematic way and cannot be justified on any rational basis.15 28. A second flaw in the application of the formula is the continued use of the 1964 census for the population-based part of the formula. This would favor those jurisdictions whose populations have grown relatively slowly at the expense of rapidly growing areas. It would be desirable to use the 1985 census when applying the formula. 29. The third flaw in the sharing formula is that it fails to encourage greater resource mobilization efforts at the local level. The formula needs to be altered such that the amount of transfer received by any jurisdiction dependa in some degree on the amount of resource it contributes. As it stands, the tax allowance is a conditional, close- ended, non-matching grant.16 Conditional because the funds must be used for education and health. Close-ended because the total amount to be 15/ Some acditional noticr. of the arbitrariness of the formula may be obtained from recognition of the fact that the cutoff population share--separating jurisdictions receiving above- and below-average per capita transfers--depends solely on the number of jurisdictions. The number presently stands at 3.03: because there are 33 jurisdictions, but if--for whatever reason--Colombia should decide to consolidate to (say) 16 jurisdictions, the cutoff population would become 6.251 and areas would begin receiving higher or lower per capita amounts for no reason other than a change in the number of departments/territories. 16/ See R.M. Bird, Intergovernmental Finance in Colombia--Final Report of the Mission on Interaovernment Finance (International Tax Program, Law School of Harvard University, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1984), pp. 148-153 and N.E. Slack and R.M. Bird "Local Response to Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers--The Case of Colombia" Public Finance (No. 3, 1983), pp. 429-437. - 28 - shared is fixed even though the shares of individual jurisdictions may vary. Non-matching because the amount received by any jurisdiction is set independently, unrelated to its revenues or expenditures. That is, the requirement that jurisdictions spend the same proportion of their income on education and health as in 1972 has never really been enfotced and while jurisdictions are expected to contribute to educatior. and health expenditures there is no formula relating these to the size of the transfer received from the national government. As constituted, the sharing formula does not further resource allocation or income distribution objectives in any systematic fashion. If the objective were to encourage increased resources in education and health, the appropriate formula would be conditional, open-ended and matching. On the other hand, if the objective were to reallocate resources to poorer jurisdictions or jurisdictions with lower tax bases, the formula should be unconditional not conditional. Moreover, as was shown above, the formula favors jurisdictions with smaller populations in a rather capricious fashion unrelated in any systematic way to needs or to poverty. Lastly, it is clear that the formula does not encourage greater tax effort on the part of departments and available evidence suggests that tax effort has been reduced. For exa'mple, a 1978 study by the Foundation for Higher Education and Development (FEDESARROLLO) found that the non-matching nature of the formula would in general tend to discourage local effort and that the tax allowance has had no effect on the level of department expenditures in education and health.17 A study done by Slack and Bird, as part of their background work for the 1981 Mission on 17/ Fundaci6n Para la Educaci6n Superior y el Desarrollo "El Efecto del Situado Fiscal y la Cesion del Impoventas Sobre los Ingresos y la Estructura del Gasto Departmental y Municipal" (unpublished, Bogota, October 1978). - 29 - Intergovernmental Finance, shows that a one peso increase in the tax allowance leads to an increase in expenditures less than one third of 1% as large, suggesting that the tax allowance substitutes for local resources.18 2. Sales Tax Transfer (Cesion a las ventas) 30. The sales tax transfer was created by Law 33 of 1968 which provided that the departments and Special District of Bogota would share in the revenues from the national sales tax starting at 10% in 1969 and rising to 202 in 1970 and 302 in 1971 and thereafter. Through a series of laws during the 1970s, the uses to which the monies could be put and :he proportions devoted to each were altered but basically these resources were devoted to social security pensions (departmental), secondary education, and most importantly, the municipalities.19 As it stood before the change introduced by Law 12 of 1986, the transfer had a number of points of similarity and difference with the tax allowance. Both were based on a 30-702 sharing formula, that is partly by department and partly by popuilation, but in the latter case the national territories were excluded. Neither tax provided any incentive for increased fiscal effort by lower levels of government. The main differences were that under the sales tax allowance municipal and not departmental activities were the main beneficiaries and that the population basis for the allocation was 18/ N.E. Slack and R.M. Bird, Op. cit. 19/ In 1983, the sales tax was expanded to a value-added tax (IVA). Via Decree 232 in that same year, 302 of IVA revenues were allocated as follows: 25% to departmental municipalities via the 30-70% sharing formula, 1.5% for the national territories to be invested in local government, and 3.5% for the social security funds of departmental governments. In addition part of the revenues tL.at were to have gone to municipalities were diverted to departmental FERs in the following proportions: 302 for municipalities of 100,000-500,000 population and 502 for those over 500,000. - 30 - Table 8 The Distribution of Sales Tax Revenues. 1985-92 (As Z of IVA collection) Recipient 1985a 1986b 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 All municipalitiesC 25.0 25.8 25.9 26.4 27.0 27.5 28.0 28.5 Small municipalitiesd 0.4 1.8 3.8 6.0 9.0 12.5 16.8 National territoriese 1.5 0.7 0.6 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 Social Securityf 3.5 3.5 3.5 3.5 3.8 3.8 3.8 4.0 IGAC8 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 ESAPh 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 Total: 30.0 30.5 32.0 34.5 37.5 41.0 45.k, 50.0 Notes: a. As set out in Decree 232 of 1983 (with the distribution in part based on 1973 population). b. Thus allocation actually only takes effect only as of July 1, for the first six months, 1985 formula applies. c. Includes Bogota, and after mid-1986, municipalities in national territories. Note however, that 302 of allocation to cities between 100,000 and 500,000 population and 502 of allocation to cities over 500,000 in fact goes directly to FERs. d. To be allocated in accordance with fiscal effort formula among municipalities of less than 100,000 inhabitants. *. After mid-1986, this amount goes directly to national territories for their own use, without restriction. f. This share goes to the sectional social security funds (including those in the territories) and is intended mainly to cover social security payments for teachers. g. Instituto Geografica Agustin Coddazi. To be used for revaluation in smaller municipalities. h. Escuela Superior de Administracion Publica. To commence as of 1987. Source: "IBRD Colombia - A Revie- of Recent Decentralization Measures", Washington, D.C.; April 6, 1987, p. 36. quickly adjusted from the census of 1964 to those of 1973 and then 1985. Because of the size and elasticity of the sales tax, the transfer became an important source of municipal finance. It was the most important transfer to Colombian municipalities and, most particularly, to those cities other than Bogota and the departmental capitals for whom it was the equivalent of twice the level of municipal tax collections in the late 1970s. Because there were no incentives to raise local resources, there is some evidence that the sales tax transfer mainly substituted for local resources. - 31 - 31. Law 12 of 1986 is designed to bring about improvements in the finances of smaller cities and brought major changes in the sales tax transfer.20 Law 12 has three important objectives: o To strengthen the smaller municipalities, both by giving them more resources and by encouraging their own fiscal efforts. O To transfer to municipalities certain national responsibilities equal in amount to the amolnt of additional revenues transferred. O To increase the efficiency of the local sector; by reducing the number of agencies working at the level and by increasing the capacity of local institutions. 32. The major changes introduced by Law 12 were: (a) the increase in the proportion shared of the value-added tax from 30Z to 50% by 1992 and especially the share going to small cities (see Table 8);21 (b) the introduction of a "tax effort" formula for small municipalities; (c) the use of population as reflected in the 1985 census as the sole basis for sharing (modified by "effort" in small municipalities)--i.e. the elimination of the 30% share that formerly was divided equally among departments; (d) the additional funds for municipalities in excess of 25.8Z (1986 share) to be spent on investments (including maintenance, debt service and investment in FFDU bonds); (e) new shares for the Public 20/ The discussion of Law 12 (1986)--its content and effects and the issues it raises--closely follows IBRD Colombia - A Review of Recent Decentralization Measures (Washington, D.C.; April 6, 1987), pp. 33-46. 21/ Note that Luw 12 maintains the retention feature of the previous allocation system in that for cities with population of 100,000-500,000, 302 of their potential transfers will be redirected to department FERs while for cities over 500,000, the amount would be 50%. - 32 - Administration Institute (ESAP) and National Cadastre Agency (IGAC), agencies which provide training for local level officials and revised estimates of property values respectively; (f) and a timetable for the national government to reorganize and transfer functions toward the 1992 deadline. 33. The full implementation of Law 12 will have a major impact on the finances of municipalities. By 1992, municipalities in the aggregate will receive 852 more resources than they would have under the old sharing formula.22 For small municipalities, the increase is due to an increase in their share and to an assumed greater fiscal effort since, due to relatively slow growth, they would have lost revenues on a population basis alone. For larger cities, the increase is due mainly to their increase in population share and to a lesser extent to the rising proportion of the IVA (impuesto al valor agregado or VAT) being shared. These changes will have a major impact on the finances of municipalities. The dependence of municipalities on transfers will rise dramatically--for all municipalities from 382 to 58% of current revenues and especially for small municipalities from 67 to 83% of current revenues.23 Without these transfers it is estimated that municipalities in general--and small municipalities in particular--would not be able to finance their current expenditures out of their own revenues. 34. Law 12 represents a welcome attempt to transfer greater resources to municipalities, give them incentives to raise their own resources (at least for smaller municipalities), and initiate some measures to increase 22/ See IBRD (1987), 2D. cit, p. 39 23/ Ibid, p. 40. - 33 - municipal absorptive capacity. As such, however, the Law raises a number of issues about: (a) the form of the sharing formula for small municipalities; (b) the restriction of tax effort just to those municipalities; and (c) the speed with which municipal absorptive capacity can be increased. 35. First, the elimination of the 30% portion of IVA shared equally by departments and the introduction of a "fiscal effort" factor for small municipalities are both improvements. However, the formulas that have been used raise questions. The formulas suggested by the Government and by the World Bank account for fiscal effort adding a factor to the population share which reflects a community's efforts relative to average efforts. The Government's formula is:24 CAMi '_- . CAT -ACi - -Pi r Ri Ri Pop i EACi Aci and the World Bank's recommended reformulation is:25 CAMi -CAT Pi _ Pi [ACi + Pi 1 [ti ACi [Pop Pop j ACi Pop EACi J where CAT is total transfer to be divided among . municipalities; CAHi is the transfer received by the ith municipality; P1 is its population and Pop is the total population of small municipalities; AC1 is the total cadastral value (less tax exempt properties) in the ith municipality and 24/ See DNP Proveccion de la ParticiDacion de los Hunicipios en la Cesion del ImDuesto al Valor Aaretado (Bogota; Septiembre 1988), p. 6 25/ See IBRD (1987), Op. cit., p. 42. - 34 - Ri is property taxes (plus surcharges) collected and ti is the effective tax rate in the ith municipality or its property tax revenues divided by its cadastral values and t is the average tax rate across ail small muni ipalities. As o.riginally conceived the formula was to be applied separately to each department, and so the relevant comparator group would be all small municipalities in the same department. The formulas intend to say that the amount that any municipality receives will be larger, the higher are its tax rates and the greater are its cadastral values.26 However, both formulas are also flawed. in that municipalities are encouraged to increase the cadastral assessments only if their tax rates exceed the department average; otherwise such an increase would reduce the amount of transfer received. This flaw can be corrected by redefining the formula to eliminate the direct connection between cadastral assessments and the transfer received, thus; i-.Mi - CAT -Pi [ t + t*i .-op where ti is actual property tax receipts in the ith district divided by the cadastral values of the ith municipality that would be obtained if assessment practices in all small municipalities were the same (t* being equivalently defined as the average for all relevant small municipalities). Thus defined, this cadastral value is outside the control of the ith municipality but it can always increase the transfer received by raising 26/ Both the formula contained in Law 12 (1986) and the Bank's proposed revision leave open the question of what to do with municipalities whose reduction in share because of poor fiscal effort exceeds their population share. The intention appears to be that such jurisdictions would get zero and the amount to be shared would be divided up among the remaining qualifying jurisdictions. - 35 _ its tax rates or raising its cadastral assessment since either would incre.se its revenues relative to the equivalently assessed cadastral base.27 28 36. Secondly, the "fiscal effect" formula is too narrowly focussed both as to the taxes covered and the types of municipalities. By focusing on property taxes, it not only fails to encourage the development of other tax bases but may actually encourage tbe substitution of property taxes for other types of taxes with little overall gain in local resource mobilization. To forestall this probletm, consideration should be given to including all municipal revenue sources in the formula, even while continuing to use cadastral values as tne (actual or potential) tax base. Moreover the application of "fiscal effort" to small municipalities alone is undoubtedly undesirable. Large municipalities (above 100,000 inhabitants) bulk large in total local government finance and the lack of an incentive for effort invites them to substitute national resources for local resources. 27/ By using uniform assessments (or uniform relations between assessed values and market values) across different (small) municipalities, no municipality would stand to gain from undervaluing its property or lose from increasing assessed values. In fact, communities would only stand to gain from increasing assessments both because their owni revenues would rise as would the transfer received. The recommended sharing formula would necessitate some agency--such as the Instituto Geografico Agustin Codazzi (IGAC)--provide information so that the uniform or equivalent assessed value of property in each municipality could be calculated. 28/ Note that as they stand all three formulas take into account factors of "need" (as represented by population share) and "fiscal effort" (each community's tax performance relative to some average performance) but all ignore the question of "taxable capacity" (i.e. differential per capita tax bases) and hence make no attempt to compensate for differences in capacity. In addition, regardless of which of these sharing formulas were used, the problem would remain that each municipality was to be compared with other municipalities in the same department, thus raisin8 the possibility of unequal treatment of municipalities across departments. This potential anomaly in the application of the formula was corrected in 1987 and now small municipalities are being compared nationwide. - 36 - 37. Thirdly, Law 12 and its follow-up Decree 77 (1987) which identified those public services to be transferred to local government,29 reassigned responsibilities among various levels of government and presented timetables for the alteration/liquidation of a number of government agencies, have mandated a major shift in responsibilities and in available resources among levels of government. At this stage it is not yet clear whether local governments are well prepared to handle the additional responsibilities, especially within the short timeframe available. To date, there has been no thorough analysis of the capacity of local government to deliver the additional services. Nor have many jurisdictions complied with the requirement of Law 12 that annual reports be submitted on the use of IVA resources. Nor has there been a serious attempt to match the cost of the activities transferred with the additional resources being made available by Law 12. There is considerable skepticism at the local level about the sufficiency of resources. A number of steps appear 4esirable to assure that the added resources are put to good use. Municipalities should be required to submit annual investment plans as a preconditioni for receiving IVA transfers. While such plans are likely to be crude at first until local planning capacity can be improved and better coordination between planning units at all levels of government can be achieved, it would encourage better planning and at least rudimentary justification for projects being undertaken. In addition, to assure local 29/ Among the public services to be transferred to the local level are: provision of drinking water, sanitation, garbage disposal; management of markets and slaughter houses; construction, operation and maintenance of health posts and centers and regional hospitals; construction and maintenance of schools and athletic facilities; provision of agricultural extension and technical assistance; construction and maintenance of feeder roads, bridges, and river ports; extension of electricity services; construction and up graditLg of low income shelters; and cofinancing (with central agencies) for rural development projects. - 37 - resources are put to good use, cofinancing or matching local counterpart funds for projects with largely localized benefits undertaken by national agencies should be required. The required matching rate could vary according to sector (according to the priority the national government might wish to assign to the activity) and according to the fiscal capacity of the local government. Such matching programs would help to compensate for weak local institutional capacity in some areas, give the national government a means by which to encourage investment in priorit zeas, and provide local finance for national activities. B. National Government Level Earmarking 1. Coffee Fund 38. The Fondo Nacional del Cafe (FNC) was created in 1940 in response to the new "Quotas Agreement" of the International Coffee Organization which called upon signatories to establish mechanisms for withholding surpluses above quota limits. Management of the Fund is by the National Federation of Coffee Growers, a private non-profit association representing almost all coffee producers. The Federation is responsible for the domestic and external marketing of Colombia's coffee. Its activities include technical assistance to the industry, enforcement of quality control, provision of storage, promotion of external coffee sales, representation of Colombia in the International Coffee Organization, and management of the FNC.30 The Coffee Fund intervenes in markets, promotas 30/ For useful discussions of FNC activities, see Contraloria General de la Republica El Fondo Nacional del Cafe - Evaluaci6n Institutional v Financiera (Bogota, Colombia; December, 1988); R.M. Bird, Taxation and Development - Lessons from the Colombian ExDerience (Harvard University Press, Cambridge; 1970) Appendix B on Coffee Tax Policy; and V. Thomas, Linking Macroeconomic and ARricultural Policies for Adjustment with Growth - The Colombian Experience (Johns Hopkins University Press; 1985), Chapter 6 and Appendix F. - 38 - stabilization objectives, and engages in activities to assist the growers and promote economic and social welfare in the coffee growing areas. The nature of its activities and its relationship with government are spelled out in ten-year contracts with government, the latest of which covering 1989-99, was just signed in December 1988. 39. A major objective of coffee policy is the stabilization of growers' real incomes at levels consistent with long-run equilibrium international prices. The major stabilization instruments--the ad valorem export tax and the retention quota--also generate important sources of income for the Fund.31 32 Of the 6.5% tax on the value of coffee exports, 2.5% goes to the central government general budget and 4% to the Coffee Fund, the latter thus representing an earmarked tax.33 In line with government policy, the ad valorem tax share going to the central government has beeii falling--from 22% at the inception of the tax in 1967 to 8% in 1980 to 2.5. in 1983. The 4% tax rate, 0,8Z (or 20%) of which is reallocated to Departmen: Growers Committees to be used for economic and social projects in the growing areas, has been coinstant since 1967. The retention quota is a fixed 31/ The major source of the FNC's current income is its own sales of coffee in foreign and domestic markets. It also obtains income from the ad valorem and retention taxes and oiom sales of intermediate inputs (e.g. fertilizer at subsidized prices) and from financial and equity investments. 32/ T-io other instruments of stabilization policy do not have such obvious fiscal implications--the domestic support price and the minimum exchange surrender requirement. The minimum guarantee pric- is set by the government, in consultation with the Federation, taking into account such factors as production cost, inflation, the exchange rate, trends in production and stock holdings, and international prices. The Federation stands ready to buy unlimited amounts of coffee at the minimum price. The minimum exchange surrender requirement is the minimum amount of foreign exchange to be surrendered by exporters to the Banco de la Republica for each bag of coffee exported and forms the basis for the ad valorem tax. 33/ There is an additional min, - tax--the "pasilla"--of 62 of the volume of exports of inferior grades of coffee. - 39 - proportional amount of coffee--in volume or equivalent value--which exporters must give to the Coffee Fund for every 100 bags of coffee exported. The proportion is set taking into account the present and expected volume and value of coffee exports, exchange rates, and export taxes. To finance an accumulation of stocks and to improve the Coffee Fund's finances, the retention quota was reised from 15% in 1981 to a peak of 68% 1985-87 before being reduced to 35% in December 1987. The retention tax acts like a tax on exports and because its proceeds are directed to the coffee fund it should be viewed as an earmarked tax. 40. Table 9 shows the amount of revenues the Coffee Fund obtained from its 4% share of the ad valorem export tax and the retention quota.34 The former is usually listed in any accounting of central government earmarked taxes, but the latter is not. Because of discounts and bonuses the Fund gives on private exports and because a significant share of exports in any year comes from the Coffee Fund itself, the retention figures in the table are likely to exaggerate the net income accruing to the Fund. Bearing in mind, therefore, that these are upper bound figures,35 they would represent Table 9 Earmarked Taxes for the Coffee Sector. 1980-1987 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 Ad Valorem Export Tax 3,005.0 2,823.0 3,112.6 3,377.0 4,698.5 7,298.7 14,905.2 11,671.1 Retention Quotas 31,116.2 9,596.9 23,531.2 29,262.1 61,742.0 81,607.4 174,143.8 194,199.4 In Kind 31,098.2 9,588.8 23,510.5 29,146.5 61,539.9 80,821.1 172,567.8 n.a. In Value 18.0 8.1 20.7 115.6 202.1 786.3 1576.0 n.a. Total 34,121.2 12,419.9 26,643.8 32,639.1 66,440.5 88,906.1 189,049.0 205,870.5 Source: Statistical Appendix Table A7. 34/ For a morc complete picture of the Coffee Funds' revenues and expenditures, see Statistical Appendix, Table A7. 35/ They are also an exaggeration of retenticn's contribution to earmarking because at times the Coffee Fund has loaned substantial sums of money to the central government. - 40 - an amount equivalent on average to over 45% of total national government earmarked revenues 1980-87. 41. The Fund engages in a number of activities beyond its stabilization function. Through the Departmental Growers Committees, it channels resources to health, education, rural electrification, and infrastructure in the coffee growing areas. Investments are decided upon in consultation with the national government. Whatever assets are created in this process are owned by the government and operated and maintained, using the government's resources, as part of the normal public system. Through loans and equity investment, the Fund has interests in a wider variety of activities beyond the coffee sector:36 e.g. transportation (Flota Mercante GranColombiana--the largest maritime fleet), sugar, steel, meat processing and banks, insurance companies, savings/mortgage corporations. In addition, it carries out activities directed at promoting the production and conpumption of coffee- two of which are direct subsidies to the domestic consumption of coffee and the provision of subsidized inputs (mainly fertilizers) to coffee growers. 42. It is clear that the Fund's activities have taken it far beyond the stabilization objectives envisaged some 50 years ago. Movement back toward stabilization and other coffee-sector related activities would be desirable. The recently signed contract with government (covering 1989-1999) is an important attempt to refocus the Fund's activities and to increase the government's influence on its operations. The outstanding features of that agreement are: (a) the Fund's budget is to be approved by the National Coffee Committee (which has as many government represent- atives as industry representatives) and the Minister of Finance; (b) the Fund's different activities will be accounted for more explicitly 36/ For a useful umm-ary of FNC's holdings see Contraloria General de la Republica, op.cit., pp. 114-117. - 41 - by the objectives they serve; (c) its investments will be restricted to those which directly benefit the coffee areas and a liet of non-related holdings and a schedule for their sale by a target date (end-1993) will be prepared; and (d) the Minister of Finance will exercise veto power over commercial policies related to coffee. These are important steps to returning the use of public money toward legitimate public sector activities such as stabilization and economic and social welfare projects together with trade association type functions (e.g. quality control, export promotion). One might still wish to question the use of export taxes to finance public investment in coffee areas. While there is a general feeling in Colombia that the monies for such investments have been utilized effectively, there is no reason to suppose that coffee taxes will generate the right amount of economic and sociA.l infrastructure in these areas. It will be important to monitor such investments to see that they don't result in overbuilding or a maldistribution of infrastructure between regions. Lastly, subsidies for the domestic consumption of coffee remain a questionable use of public money and the provision of subsidized fertilizer has been shown in many other cot.ntries to lead to wasteful use. Continued progress toward the elimination of both these subsidies would be desirable. 2. National Highways Fund (Gasoline Tax) 43. The Fondo Vial Nacional (FVN) was created by Law 64 of 1967 in response to a sharp decline in road infrastructure investment due to a fragmented public works budget and lack of continuity in budget resources. Its mandate was to provide funding for the planning, construction, and maintenance of the nAtional highways and inland waterways networks. Its expenditures are mainly on construction/rehabilitation/maintenance and - 42 - debt servicing (see Tables A7 and A8 in the statistical appendix). Operational expenditures, such as payroll and other general expenses, are financed by the Ministry of Public Works and Transport which is responsible for implementing the investment and maintenance program. FVN's major sources of funds are earmarked taxes on gasoline (about 70% of revenues) tolls and sales of services (10%), budget transfers (about 6%) and (mainly foreign) borrowing (about 9%). Under Law 64 of 1967, as modified by Law 30 of 1982, FVN receives 75% of the earmarked tax on petroleum automotive fuel while 10% goes to the National Fund for Neighborhood Roads (Fondo Nacional de Caminos Vecinales or FNCV), 10% for the national railways (Ferrocarriles Nacionales de Colombia or FNC), and 5% for the Corporacion Financiera de Transporte (CFT) to fund urban transport operations. 44. During the 1980s, expenditures on the construction and maintenance of national highways have not expanded in real terms and hence have not kept pace with the expansion of general economic activity (see Table 10). The failure of gasoline taxes to raise sufficient revenues and the diversion of increasing amounts of FVN resources to debt service appear to be the major reasons. Article 2 of Law 30 (1982) modified the gasoline tax from a 5% rate based on the retail price to a specific amount equivalent to Colombian $13.50 per gallon of regular motor gasoline and diesel fuel (gasoline for aircraft and marine diesel were exempted). The amount of the tax is to be adjusted each time the gasoline price changes by an amount which takes into account the percentage change in the prices of gasoline and diesel and the percentage change in the heavy construction price index. Prices and taxes have in fact been adjusted annually but not enough to keep up with inflation generally and revenues from the gasoline tax have been falling in real terms (see Table 10). The rise of debt - 43 - Table 10 Real Outlays in the Hithway Sector - Fondo Vial (millione of Colombia $ in 1975 prices) 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 Total Expenditure 5267.4 6093.9 5868.6 5317.0 5214.6 5286.3 4862.6 6335.3 Construction, Rehabilitation and Maintenance Expenditures 3624.4 3975.1 2853.4 2415.6 2338.3 2657.8 2403.1 3179.2 Memorandum Item Real Gasoline Tax Revenue 4239.1 4386.5 4044.4 3260.7 3197.7 3156.1 3021.7 3243.3 Gasoline Tax in current prices) (Col. $/gal.) 8.71 12.50 13.50 16.45 19.64 22.06 26.49 32.58 Gasoline Tax Adjusted for Inflation (Col. $/gal. e 1975 prices) 2.90 3.29 2.93 2.97 2.94 2.61 2.44 2.41 Source: Data from statistical appendix Tables AS and A9 deflated by the GDP deflator. service (mainly on external debt) has been a recent phenomenon. From merely 0.7% of FVN's expenditures in 1980 it rose to 10.4% in 1986 and 17.40% in 1987 (see Table A8 in statistical appendix). While transfers from the central government budget have been rising, they have not been sufficient to offset the squeeze from falling gasoline revenues and rising debt service and FVN expenditures on construction and maintenance were lower than in 1980 in all years but one (1981); even a major expansion in 1987--financed mainly by external borrowing--left expenditures some 12% lower than in 1980.37 37/ See Table 10 where data is current prices have been converted to constant (1975) prices by use of the GDP deflator. Similar results would be obt.ined if the deflator for heavy construction activities were used instead. - 44 - 45. The general impression is that the resources of FVN are fairly well managed. Projects are subject to feasibility studies and, while there is room for improvement, there is no reason to suspect that a significant proportion of projects fail to meet economic criteria. The investment program of FVN--and any significant changes during the year--are subject to approval by National Planning Department and by Congress. The amounts of expenditures devoted to road maintenance and rehabilitation appear to have been appropriate. The Ministry of Public Works and Transport has been guilty in the past of starting up too many projects and spreading its resources too thinly. As a consequence, completions have been delayed and cost overruns and commitments fees on external loans have consumed more resources than expected. These problems are being corrected in the past couple of years by conscious efforts to speed the completion of ongoing projects and to delay the start up of major prcgrams. Moreover, highway officials are convinced that the existence of earmarked funds protects them from the complexities of the budget process and allows them to engage in long-term contracts with the private sector that would not otherwise be possible. However, FVN (and FNCV) have fallen victim to the same problems highway funds in many LDCs have faced--the failure of the automatic tax arrangements to generate the appropriate level of revenues to carry out the long-term construction and maintenance program. In the late 1970s, it appeared that the gasoline tax was generating too much resources;39 in the 1980s, falling zeal gas taxes--and rising debt service--appear to be leading to a shortage of resources. 46. In principle, gasoline taxes are a legitimate application of the benefit principle of taxation. There is normally a strong link between 38/ See Bird-Wiesner Report, Op. ctt., p. 113. - 45 - the tax base and service received from the highway system because road users must buy gasoline and the costs they impose can be captured in the higher price of gasoline stemming from taxation. Gasoline taxes, therefore, could be used in lieu of direct user charges. While it is difficult to calibrate taxes paid to the exact amount of damage done by different types of uses (trucks causing much greater damage than private passenger vehicles), reasonable approximations can be established and a significant proportion of the cost of constructing and operating the system recovered from the users. In Colombia, however, the link between the consumers of road services and road expenditures has been broken. Since the price paid by consumers is roughly equivalent to the c.i.f. import price, road users are not being taxed. Instead, it is evident that Ecopetrol (the domestic gasoline producer) is being taxed since the price it receives is lower than the c.i.f. prices by an amount approximating the gasoline tax. If earmarking of gasoline taxes for highway expenditures is to be retained in Colombia, it is the consumer who should be taxed--i.e., retail prices should exceed c.i.f. prices. Moreover, it would be desirable to set gasoline taxes (and other road user taxes such as tolls, licenses and registration fees), such that the required a:ghway construction and maintenance program can be carried out. 3. PROEXPO 47. PROEXPO is one of a three part set of export incentives which has been in existence for more than twenty years and which includea Plan Vallejo, which provides registered exporters with access to duty free imports; the CERT system which provides rebates for domestic indirect taxes (and tariffs as well for unregistered exporters); and PROEXPO itself which provides subsidized credit for exports. PROEXPO is a financial institution - 46 - with clear links to the central bank (Banco de la Republica).39 It offers 33 distinct lines of credit for: pre- and post-shipment financing; long- term investment, working capital, promotion of exports, and technical assistance for quality control. A relatively minor share of PROEXPO's portfolio is in equity investments (about 20%) and for the past two years policy has been to discourage such investments. PROEXPO does not raise money in capital markets to any extent but instead relies on rollover of existing loans (60-70%), interest earnings (7-10%) and earmarked taxes (15-20%) to provide funding for its loans (see Table All in statistical appendix). The earmarked tax is its share of a general 18% tax on c.i.f. imports which is divided in the following way: National Treasury - 10.4%; PROEXPO - 6%; IFI - 0.8%; and Caja Agraria - 0.8%. 48. Overtime, PROEXPO has reduced the extent of the subsidy in its credit lines, but the subsidies still remain sizable. Most of its credit carried a 19% rate 1980-83 and 22% 1984-86, compared to commercial bank rates which averaged 44%.40 During the past two years, PROEXPO has sought to increase its financing of fixed investment by offering rates of 18% for terms up to 8 years while raising the rates on pre and post-shipment finance to about 35%. During the 1980s, PROEXPO credit has averaged the equivalent of 5.6% of domestic credit outstanding and the loans made each 39/ The General Manager of the Banco de la Republica is the Director of PROEXPO, which has two executive directors in charge of Export Promotion and Financial Operations. PROEXPO's employees are central bank officials but the fund has a separate salary structure. PROEXPO's Board of Directors consists of: Minister of Economic Development (President); Minister of Foreign Relations; Director of INCOMEX; Manager of Banco de la Republica; and three private sector representatives appointed by the President of Colombia. 40/ See I.B.R.D. Colombia - Trade Policy Survey (1988), pp. 42-43. - 47 - year relative to total minor exports (i.e. non-coffee) have been a sharply declining trend from 39Z in 1981 to 10% in 1986. 49. PROEXPO is one of the earmarked funds covered by Law 55 (1985), but part of the intended reallocation appears to have been offset through increases in resources that it has been able to obtain. According to Law 55, 20% of PROEXPO's earmarked tax proceeds are to be reallocated to the financing of the CERT (or other financial incentives for exports) in 1985 and 1986 rising by 10% per year to a ceiling of 50% in 1989. And transfers have indeed taken place in line with this schedule. At the same time, however, PROEXPO has received a major increase in resources through a rise in its share of the tax on imports c.i.f., an expansion in the proportion of imports covered by tariffs, and a surge in imports. As a consequence, the amount of earmarked resources--even after subtracting out transfers under Law 55 was no lower in real terms in 1986 than in 1985 and was only 15% lower in 1987 than in 1985. 50. The logic of financing PROEXPO with an earmarked tax on imports is highly questionable. There is no connection between those who must bear the cost (consumers and producers using imported products) and those who are obtaining the benefits (domestic producers obtaining higher profits and/or foreign consumers receiving cheaper goods). Hence, shielded from the budget process where these allocations would be evaluated against other priorities and from capital markets where the ability of PROEXPO's loans to cover its cost of raising funds and its administration costs would be considered, there is no rea&on to suppose that the amount of subsidized loans is in any sense efficient or desirable from Colombia's point of view. The realization thAt resources d pend on total imports and infrequent changes on the duty on imports c.i.f. rate allocated to PROEXPO (1.5% 1968-75, 5% 1975-86; 6%, 1986) only enhances our suspicicn that it is - 48 - unlikely that the appropriate level of resources is being provided for this activity. Moreover, while at first glance PROEXPO appears to be an attempt to offset the bias against exports inherent in the protection given to import substituting activities, it is not evident that this is so. The subsidies to exports in PROEXPO loans are made possible by taxes on imports which in themselves would discourage exports.41 At best then, PROEXPO loans and their financing would encourage the production of traded goods at the expense of non-traded goods. But, since not all of PROEXPO's loans are directly related to exports and since the subsidies to export vary sharply across sectors,42 the offset to greater protection is incomplete and introduces distortions into economic activities. The financing of PROEXPO with earmarked taxes should, therefore, be ended and the question of subsidizing credit for exports--regardless of source of finance--should be re-examined. C. Departmental Earmarking 51. The principal sources of departmental income are from earmarked revenues. Three of the major revenue earners aze earmarked for health: beer for the Sectional Health Services, SSS (with a minor part for the 41/ There are two arguments why the financing of PROEXPO may not be biased against exports. The first is that quantitative restrictions, not tariffs, are the binding constraint and hence raising tariffs enables the government to share in rents without raising the level of protection. This argument's validity is dissipating, however, as Colombia dismantles its QR system, relying more heavily on tariffs for protection. The second argument is that the tariff rate has been set independently of PROEXPO's requirements and the government is merely allowing PROEXPO to share in this revenue. This reasoning is questionable since it strengthens the suspicion that the funding of PROEXPO is arbitrary and unrelated to legitimate needs for export financing and since the government always has the option of lowering the tariff if it did not want these funds to go to PROEXPO. 42/ See IBRD, Colombia - Trade Policy Survey, op. cit., p. 44. - 49 - National Fund for Neighborhood Roads); liquor for the SSS; and profits :-d taxes from lotteries (and race course betting) which go mainly to the SSS with a minor portion going to schools for the blind and the National Federation for the Blind. A fourth major source of departmental revenue --cigarette taxes--is also earmarked for Sectional Sports Commission, of which 30% must be passed on to the Colombian Institute of Youth and Sports (COLDESPORTES) which in turn is required to pass on 10% to Colombia Institute of Culture (COLCULTURA). The remaining sources of departmental current revenues--mainly a small specific tax on gasoline, taxes on animal slaughter, and taxes and fees on the ownership of automobiles--and a number of non-tax revenues are quite small but because they have proven to be somewhat more elastic (or less unelastic) than the earmarked sources, their share in departmental revenues actually rose from 11% to 24% 1980-86. 52. The type of tax (and lottery earnings) earmarking found at the departmentai level has no rational basis whatever. There is virtually no link between taxpayers and the beneficiaries of government services provided. Hence, there is no reason to believe that tax revenues are generating an appropriate amount of resources for the activities in question. Moreover, there is no reason to believe that the tying of revenues to expenditures enables the government to raise more revenues because taxpayers see the proceeds going for a worthy cause. Taxes on alcohol and tobacco raise considerable sums in most countries regardless of how the proceeds are used. This leaves us with a final argument that the bulk of the earmarking is for worthy decentralized agencies (such as SSS) which are growing rapidly and are in need of transfers from both central and departmental governments. However much cuch transfers may be needed, the question is still open as to the appropriate level of resources for - 50 - such activities and the division of responsibilities of the central and departmental governments. The answer is not in the arbitrary earmarking of such taxes which apparently has not been sufficient to prevent the virtually complete substitution of national for departmental resources, but in the reform of the sharing formula for the tax allowance to take account of departmental needs and to induce greater local fiscal efforts.43 D. MuniciDal Level Earmarking 53. The major sources of revenue for Colombia's municipalities are the property tax, the industry and commerce tax, and transfers from higher levels of government (esp. the central government). Other taxes (e.g. on billboards, vehicles, gambling, and public sFectacles) generate relatively minor amounts of revenues. Of these sources, the major contribution to municipal level earmarking is the valorization tax, a betterment tax levied on real propertv that has benefitted from the construction of local public works.44 54. Valorization represents one of the purest forms of earmarking. This purity results from several characteristics: o the fact that taxpayers and beneficiaries overlap to a substantial degree; o the use of benefit-cost type considerations in making investment decisions ("appraisal" or "analysis" might be too 43/ See our discussion of the "tax allowance" in para. 29. 44/ For an evaluation of the practice of valorization in Colombia see W.G. Rhoads and R.M. Bird. "Financing Urbanization by Benefit Taxation" Land Economics 43 (November 1967), pp. 403-12; IBRD Valorization CharQes as a Method for Financing Urban Public Works: The Example of Bogota. Colombia Staff Working Paper No. 254 (March 1977); and International Tax Program, Intergovernmental Finance in Colombia: Final Report of the Mission on Intergovernmental Finance (The Law School of Harvard University; Cambridge, 1984), pp. 280-282. - 51 - strong a word) and the conscious and conscientious attempt to allocate tax assessments proportionally according to how people benefit from the project; and o the strong link between valorization revenues and expenditures (i.e. no supplements from or diversions to general fund financing, at least in principle). In addition, valorization appears to reverse the usual sequence of earmarking whereby available revenues drive expenditure levels: instead, the identification of desirable projects, often within the scope of prepared investment programs, appears to call forth efforts to raise financing from prospective beneficiaries. 55. Valorization--as practiced in Colombia--is a system by which the costs of public investments are apportioned and recovered according to the distribution of the benefits received. While practice has evolved over time, Colombian municipalities, as well as some specialized agencies, have been given the right to recover costs and considerable flexibility in determining how to measure and allocate benefits. Over time the scope of valorization has been extended to include street construction, local paving, parking facilities, urban development, and what are called "green spaces" and "zones of historical interest". 56. Upon a project's selection, a "zone of influence" is demarcated, the area over which benefits are expected to be felt. Benefits are estimated--as the total resulting rise of site values--and allocated across the properties within the zone according to formulas which take into account a number of characteristics such as size, shape, topography, frontage, distance from project, and a number of economic factors. This allocation then determines how the project costs are allocated across properties. Costs eligible for inclusion are: (a) cost of land; (b) cost - 52 - of construction; (c) cost of administration, estimated at 20% of (a); (d) contingencies, estimated at 5-10% of (a) plus (b); (e) interest on the value of (a) and (b) during the construction period; and (f) honoraria for representatives. 57. In principle, there is notning to stop authorities from attempting to recapture some or all of the project (net) benefits, but in practice only full recovery of the costs lit ted above is sought. Care in selection is exercised to make sure that projects yield benefits in excess of costs; in practice the rapid development of most cities plus inflation has left a sizable margin for error. In addition, consideration is given to problems that the ;oor or persons with few liquid assets might have in paying the tax. Low income persons can be exempted altogether and others are allowed to stretch out the valorization tax payments over several years if otherwise it would absorb a significant fraction of their annual income. 58. The valorization tax as practiced obviously has a number of desirable features--the benefit connection; the efforts to select economically desirable projects, and the flexibility with which it has been adopted in differing circumstances. As a tax on the unimproved value of land, the tax would have no adverse incentive effects, and in fact the combination of the tax and the improvement serve to raise income and increase tht potential profitability of investments which should have a desirable incentive effect. 59. On the other hand, valorization does have some drawbacks, primarily centered around collections problems.45 Firse, quite aside from 45/ See World Bank, World Development ReRort 1988 (Oxford University Press; June 1988), p. 160. - 53 - the fact that authorities attempt to recover only project costs, collections fall far short of 100Z.46 The reasons appear to be cost overruns, generous exemptions (e.g. the Catholic Church, charitable institutions, and public enterprises), and generous exceptions/payment schedules given to the poor and those with liquidity problems. Problems have particularly arisen when projects have been designed to improve conditions in low income areas. Second, the concept of the "zone of influence" has its limitations: in a number of cases, a sizable fraction of beneficiaries fall outside the zone, and this has led to collection problems because persons within the zone were reluctant to pick up the added burden. It is also hard to implement with a number of projects simultaneously affecting a number of overlapping zones. Lastly, valorization revenues have proven to be quite unstable in part because of collection problems and in part due to administrative deficiencies in planning and implementing projects; thus revenue growth seems to be characterized by periods of stagnation followed by sizable increases. 60. Despite its imperfections, valorization deserves a favorable rating. Its popularity and its ability to raise revenues would justify its continuation and extension into cities which have not taken full advantage of it. Its weaknesses could be reduced by cutting back on exemptions and the introduction of interest payments and penalties on arrears (the former was introduced in 1981). Further, where subsidization of low income groups is a key project objective, the naed for trar3fers should be made explicit and financed from general budget revenues. 46/ Apparently this has been the experience with betterment taxes around the world. - 54 - E. Payroll Taxes 61. Payroll taxes in Colombia are earmarked to provide financing for two broad sets of activities--social welfare type activities and traditional social security. Included in the former are programs of technical skills and labor training (Servicio Nacional Aprendizaje or SENA), programs of preschool education and nutrition for children and family protection (Instituto Colombiano Bienestar Familiar or ICBF) and family allowances and various private sector activities (Cajas de Compensacion Familiar). Included in the latter are a variety of programs for pensions, health-maternity care, and occupational risk covering employees in the private and public sectors. These are financed through payroll taxes and transfers from the government budget (the latter are especially needed to cover the deficits of the various public sector social security programs). Table 11 shows the contribution of employees and employers (as I of wages) for the various programs. Several features of the contribution system stand out. The range of contribution is large, being quite high in the private sector and lower in the public sector, especially in the programs for the military and police. The combined employer/employee contribution of 15-20% for social security is already quite high--seventh highest in Latin America in 1986--and when the 9% tax is added to cover Cajas de Compensacion (4%), SENA (2%) and ICEF (3%), total payroll taxes are adding 24-29% to the cost of Colombian labor. 1. Funds for Social Welfare Objectives 62. ICBF is a public agency responsible for matters pertaining to nutrition and family welfare. Its program covers such activities as foodprograms for children, assistance to families and children with legal problems, aid for orphans and children with behavioral problems, and - 55 - Table 11 Legal Contributions to Social Security by Program. Source and Fund in Colombia: 1988 (as a percentage of wages) Fund/ Active Program Insured (a) Employer State Total ISS (private sector) Pensions 2.17 4.33 d r.5 Health-Maternity 2.33/4.0 (b) 4.67/8.0 (b) 7.0/12.0 (b) Occupational Risks 0 1.5 (c) 1.5 TOTAL 4.5/6.17 10.5/13.83 15.0/20.0 CAJANAL (public sector) Pensions (e) 0 3.0 f 3.0 Health-Maternity 5.0 5.0 10.0 TOTAL 5.0 8.0 13.0 CAPRESUB/CAPRECOM (public sector) Pensions (e) 0 g g Health-Maternity 5.0 g g 5.0 TOTAL 5.0 5.0 MILITARY Pensions (e) 8.0 h h 8.0 Health-Maternity 0 i i 0 TOTAL 8.0 8.0 POLICE Pensions 5.0 h h 5.0 Health-Maternity 0 i i 0 TOTAL 5.0 5.0 OTHER PAYROLL TAXES 0 9.0 (j) 0 9.0 (a) In ISS, the voluntarily insured self-employed pays a percentage over income equivalent to the combined percentage paid by the salaried insured and his employer. (b) Among those covered by family health program. (c) Avcrage premium; the premium should vary from 0.28 to 72 according to risk but the classification of risks is not yet in effect. (d) Initially the state had to contribute but never actually did and such obligation was abolished in 1971. (e) There is no distinction between treatment of comon and occupational risks and the contribution to pension and health cover such risks. In any case the employer is considered directly responsible. (f) The state is responsible for absorbing most of the resulting deficit. (g) The employer (state) pays the rest. (h) The state pays all the resulting deficit. (i) The employer (state) pays all costs. (j) 4% goes for Family Allowances (Cajas de Compensacion), 22 for SENA, and 32 for ICBF. Source: Current Legislation. - 56 - special projects for Indian minorities.47 In particular, its traditional program (CAIP) of daycare and supplemental feeding for children under 6 years involved supervised programs in well-equipped day centers with trained personnel. The program suffered from high administrative costs, lack of targeting for the poorest, and lack of access. To increase replicability, IBCF launched a new "programa de hogares de bienestar familiar" (HBI) which involves nutritional support, daycare facilities run in the homes of volunteer mothers who are provided training and loans for home upgrading, and the targeting of the poor through the location of the facilities.48 The "hogares" program is supposed to expand from 45% to 85% of ICBF's budget by 1990 and its coverage from 400,000 to 1.5 million children by 1992. The increased resources to pay for this expansion is to ccme from an increase in the payroll tax for ICBF from 2% and 3% and from foreign borrowing. Law 89/1989, approving that increase, was recently passed. Quite apart from unfavorable employment effect (see below), this is a questionable use of earmarked resources. There is no connection between the beneficiaries and the payors of the payroll tax. There is therefore no assurance that the amount of taxes generated are appropriate for the activities involved. If the "hogares program" is justified--and it appears to have many attractive features--its redistributional intentions should be financed from general revenues where the matching of needs and resources can be more continually assessed. 47/ See statistical appendix Table A14. 48/ ICBF was one of the agencies called upon to reallocate earmarked services to other activities in the health sector under Law 55 (1985) and actually reallocated about 8% of its 1986 and 1987 budgets to children's hospitals, vaccinations, and malaria control. From 1988, the reallocations that would have been required under Law 55 will be directed to the "hogares" program. - 57 - 63. SENA is a public sector agency responsible for the training of various labor skills. It has a decentralized structure to better enable it to tailor its programs to local labor market conditions. Financed from a payroll tax (2% per annum on the payroll of public, private, and mixed enterprises and 0.5: per annum on all government departments at the national, department and municipal levels) which has provided about 80% of its resources in the 1980s, it at first confined the bulk of its training activities to the needs of the entities paying the payroll tax.49 However, it has gradually expanded into construction, agriculture, and self- employment areas, areas which are only thinly covered by the payroll tax. This process has been accelerated by Law 55 which has moved SENA into broader areas of education--agricultural research and extension, artisans and handicrafts, rural development and rehabilitation projects in guerilla infested areas. At first, SENA would appear to have a benefit rationale in that employers obtain trained workers, but at best the link is not strong since employers have no options about whether or not to pay the payroll tax or how much to pay and hence there is no reason to suppose that the payroll tax generates the right amount of resources for training. The likelihood grows less with SENA expanding into activities that are more remote from those that pay payroll taxes. There are a number of indications that the amount of resources going to SENA has been excessive: its training facilities are operating substantially below capacity; its agriculture 49/ The use of payroll taxes to finance training is popular among Latin American and Caribbean countries, particularly in the lower-middle per capita income bracket (US$401-1635 GNP per capita). These countries charge payroll tax rates of 0.05-3.0% per year; among them only Jamaica and Venezuela have rates as high or higher than Colombia. See J. Whall y and A. Ziderman "Payroll Taxes for Financing Training in Developing Countries" (World Bank, Policy, Planning, and Research Working Paper No. 141; January 1989). - 58 - centers have been overbuilt; and it has been unable to utilize its budget in most years in the 1980s.50 Thus, it would be desirable to cut SENA off from automatic sources of financing and force it to compete for budgetary resources with other governmental departments and agencies. 64. The Family Compensation Funds (Cajas de Compensacion Familiar) are private non-profit institutions, relying heavily on a 42 payroll tax for financing. The bulk of the monies are supposed to be paid out as "family subsidies" to workers in participating firms and the remainder is to be used for various social programs directed at assisting the same group of workers. There are several questionable aspects of Caja activities. Their coverage is very narrow, reaching only about one-fifth of the employed population. While cash and in-kind allowances have been paid out, a large proportion of resources have gone into investment--e.g. supermarkets, theaters, and recreational facilities--which are luxurious and beyond the reach of ordinary workers. The use of public monies for luxury investments is quite simply undesirable and the use of an earmarked tax for this purpose is again questionable. The Cajas should be cut off from earmarked taxes and forced to rely on their own resources. 2. Social Security 65. The social security system in Colombia consists of the Institute of Social Insurance (ISS) covering the private sector and almost two 50/ This is not to argue that SENA's investments generally have not had positive payoffs, but rather that at the margin there may have excessive investments and that some of the movement away from modern sector activities may have been of questionable value. A recent study by Jimenez and Kugler found that the rate of return to SENA's investments was 142 and that the payoffs were higher the greater were worker's formal schooling or previous work experience. See E. Jimenez and B. Kugler, An Economic Evaluation of a National Job Training System: Colombia's Servicio Nacional de Aprendizaje (SENA); IBRD Education and Training Series Report No. EDT 24 (April 1986). - 59 - hundred funds covering civil servants at all levels and employees of public decentralized agencies. Although not commonly thought of in this fashion, the payroll taxes that fund these various private and public funds represent earmarked taxes in that they are the result of a contractual obligation to pay pension, death and medical benefits and there is no alternative use to which these monies may be put (except financial investments toward the future payment of these obligations). To the extent that the funds are being run on an actuarially sound basis--i.e. that premiums charged (payroll taxes) plus interest accumulations are sufficient to cover the expected payments to beneficiaries based on age distribution, mortality, and morbidity characteristics of population, payroll taxes would be a good indication of the trend in obligations of these funds. Differentials between payments and premiums (payroll taxes) in any year could be regarded as temporary deviations. However, there are a number of reasons that this is not the case in Colombia. Firstly, a number of funds rely explicitly on the government budget for funding (the tax on the employee is small and there is no tax on the employer forcing continued reliance on general budget financing). Second a number of public funds--most notably CAJANAL which covers the majority of civil servants, at least at the national level--have been running continuous deficits. The public programs--most importantly CAJANAL--have no actuarial base and no financing program other than an ad hoc and open ended reliance on the budget. Thirdly, even in ISS, which has run surpluses in all years but one in the 1980s, premiums have not been increased in line with actuarial needs and pension funds have been depleted by transfers to cover the costs of medical programs. For these reasons, payroll taxes are an understatement of present as well as potential future obligations the Government of - 60 - Colombia may face. Nonetheless payroll tax revenues for social security are the appropriate indicator of their contribution to total earmarking. They represented 18% of total earmarking at all levels of government in 1980 and 19% in 1985 (see Table 7). 3. Emvloyment Effects of Payroll Taxes 66. Questions of employment and poverty in Colombia appear to be intimately related to formal sector wage determination. According to two recent reports--by the Employment Mission (Chenery Report) and the World Bank, the Colombian labor market has a number of prominent characteristics: o Employment is sensitive to changes in real wages both in the short and long-runs (i.e. higher wages induce substitution of capital for labor and also undermine the profitability of investment). O Employment is provided by formal and informal sectors, with the latter accounting for about 70% of urban employment. O Wage differentials between the formal and informal sector can partly be explained by skill mix differences but are greater than can be explained by this factor alone, and o Poverty appears to be associated with employment at low wages in the informal sector rather than unemployment (i.e. the payoffs to job search for formal sector employment are high and many of the unemployed appear to be financed by their families or from savings). O Real wage growth for formal sector workers--and especially the non-wage component of compensation--appears to be quite independent of supply/demand factors.51 51/ See El Problema Laboral Colombiano: Diafnostico. Perspectivas v Politicas -Informe Final de la Mision de EmDleo (Economia Colombiano - Revista de la Contraloria General de la Republica: Agosto - Septiembre de 1986) and IBRD Colombia - Country Economic Memorandum (October 15, 1987), Ch. III. - 61 - 67. Since the mid-1970s, total labor compensation in Colombia has risen by more than 50Z in real terms--a large increase both absolutely and relative to the cost of capital which has scarcely changed. Non-wage compensation (e.g., leave arrangements, dismissal payments, and payroll taxes) has been rising faster than wage components. As a consequence mainly of rising real wages and slower real growth in the 1980s, the open unemployment rate has risen to 12-14% (as compared with the 1958-79 average rate of 9.5%) and the gap between formal and informal sector wages has widened from 672 to 73%. Urban poverty, which has been shown to be more a question of employment in low productivity jobs in the informal sector rather than open employment, is likely to have increased in the process. 68. The adverse effects of payroll taxes on employment are an important consideration. Both because of the relatively high unemployment rate and because future increases in payroll taxes may become necessary to put the social security system on a sound financial and/or actuarial basis, some present reduction in the number of activities financed by payroll taxes would appear to be desirable. Payroll taxes have unfavorable effects on employment by raising the cost of labor, penalizing labor intensive sectors and making it economic to substitute machinery for labor. The effects on employment will be greater the higher is the tax, the greater is labor's share in the cost of factors of production, and the greater is the elasticity of -.bstitution. Two recent studies enable us to get some idea of the amount of employment that would be generated by reducing payroll taxes. In a study prepared for the Chenery employment mission, Gom6z Buendia and Cifuentes projected that eliminating the payroll taxes supporting SENA, ICBEF and the Cajas de Compensacion would add about 33,000 or the equivalent of about 0.5% of the urban labor force to total urban - 62 - employment. Using estimates from the World Bank's later study of the demand and supply of labor in Colombia's formal and informal sectors suggests that the addition could be in the order of 70-75,000 jobs. The reduction of 0.5-1.1 percentage points on a 13% unemployment rate implied by these studies is not trivial and suggests that finding different ways of financing these activities merits serious consideration.52 V. SUMMARY AND RECOMMENDATIONS 69. Over the past two decades, earmarking in Colombia has trended upward and the sources of earmarking have become more varied. The rise in overall earmarking (in the "traditional" sense) from 21% to about 35% of revenues at all levels of government is the product of a substantial rise in national government revenues earmarked from 11% to 28% and falling proportions of revenues earmarked at the departmental and municipal levels from 94% to 77% and 30% to about 20% respectively. During this period the share of the national government in earmarking at all levels rose from under one half to over three quarters. In 1970, departmental taxes on alcohol/tobacco/gambling were the largest source of earmarking followed by the coffee export tax and gasoline tax at the naticnal level and the valorization tax at the municipal level. During the past two aecades, revenue sharing (the tax allowance and sales tax transfer), import duties for PROEXPO (et. al.), and, to a lesser extent, a number of new minor funds have increased the variety of earmarking. 52/ See H. Gom6z Buendia and A. Cifuentes Noyes "Seguridad Social Y Empleo" in El Problema Laboral Colombiano, Tomo 2, J. Antonio Ocampo y M. Ramirez (eds.), (Servicio Nacional de Aprendizaje, Departmento Nacional de Planeacion, Contraloria General de la Republica; Bogota, 1987), pp. 115-139; and IBRD op. cit., Annex 3. - 63 - 70. Concentration on traditional sources of earmarking, however, understates the extent to which government monies are tied up. "Non-traditional" sources--public enterprises net operating profits and payroll taxes for social security and SENA/ICBF also represent earmarking in that they are public incomes which cannot be used flexibly for whatever purposes the government might deem necessary. Including non-traditional sources raises the share of earmarking in total public incomes to about 55Z today. About 971 of earmarking comes from just eight sources: public enterprise profits (27X); payroll taxes for social security and SENA/ICBF (24x); revenue sharing (201); departmental alcohol/tobacco/ gambling taxes (111); the gasoline tax (7%); import duties for PROEXPO et. al. (4x); and the ad valorem coffee export tax and municipal valorization tax (21 each). The remainder comes from about 20 relatively minor sources (e.g. tourism, cinema, coal), no one of which contributes as much as one percent to the total. 71. The key measures taken by the government in the 1980s to reduce the extent of earmarking are Law 55 of 1986 and the recently passed Organic Law of the Budget of 1988. The former is an attempt to reallocate specified proportions of earmarked money to different activities in the same field. Because of this limitation, a significant increase in flexibility in the use of earmarked monies was not to be expected and in practice Law 55 activities have mostly been carried out by the original earmarking recipient agencies themselves because they were best qualified to carry out the activity or because changing government priorities meant that reallocations should not take place (as for example with ICBF's "hogares program"). Thus, Law 55 has increased the variety of activities that can be financed with earmarked money, but has not significantly - 64 - increased the flexibility of the budget. The new Organic Law is likely to impact on earmarking both directly ard indirectly. It prohibits the creation of new earmarked funds from existing sources of revenue and it also states that the operating profits of public enterprises belong to the central budget until (or unless) the enterprise justifies their use with an appropriate investment program. The latter should help to foster better medium-term enterprise planning and introduce some flexibility into the major source of earmarking. In addition, by greatly restricting the number of mini budgets within one year, the new Organic Law would sharply reduce variance between original and final budgets, greatly reducing uncertainty about allocations each year. If cumbersome budget procedures were also reduced, these reforms of the budgetary process could substantially reduce the pressure for earmarking. Thus despite the New Organic Law, further measures are likely to be necessary to improve budgetary processes. 72. Earmarking in Colombia is too complex to allow blanket recommendations for reform. Instead we content ourselves with piecemeal suggestions based on assessments of whether the automatic funding arrangements involved in each case are likely in principle to bring about desirable results and whether they are working in practice. Our assessment in each case involves considerations of whether there is a substantial overlap between beneficiaries and tax/price payers, whether the tax/price mechanism appears to generating an appropriate level of resouirces, and whether these resources are being utilized effectively for the purposes intended. With these considerations in mind, there are five broad recommendations some of which will be elaborated upon in subsequent paragraphs. If recommendations (a)-(c) below were to be implemented in full, approximately one quarter of earmarking would be eliminated and - 65 - greater flexibility in use of resources imparted to an additional one quarter. The recommendations are: a. There are a number of earmarking arrangements which have no strong benefit rationale and which are prime candidates for elimination; i.e. those for PROEXPO (plus IFI and Caja Agraria); SENA/ICBF/Cajas de Compensacion; and the departmental taxes on alcohol/tobacco/gambling for health, welfare, and sports. b. Further potential candidates for elimination should be sought in the large number of very small funds which ma1le up about 31 of total earmarking (see Statisticv Appendix Table A2, esp., the categories "Special Funds", "Cont butions and Participations", and "Other" at the national level). While this Report has not had the time to review thise cases, only a small number (e.g. the taxes on tourism, cinema tickets, coal) appear to be benefit related and, in all cases, questions should be raised about whether appropriate levels of funds are being raised and whether the activities being financed are indeed a desirable use of public funds. c. Those parts of the new Organic Law of tha Budget pertaining to earmarking--namely, the limitations on mini-budgets, the prohibition of new earmarking from existing revenue sources, and the claim of the central budget on public enterprises' operating surpluses--should be implemented expeditiously. d. Existing revenue sharing arrangements between the central government and the department or municipalities need to be strengthened since they are an important part of the decentralization effort. - 66 - e. There are a number of earmarking cases which follow the benefit principle quite closely (e.g. coffee fund, gasoline tax, and the municipal valorization tax) and which--with some adjustments--could suitably be continued. 73. EArmarking arrangements for PROEXPO are a prime candidate for elim.'.nation. There is little connection between those who pay the import duties and those who bene.it (exporters or foreign consumers); the arbitrary level of the duty makes it problematic whether an appropriate amount of export financing is being provided; and the differential credit subsidies across sectors has introduced an additional distortion into the allocation of esources. Payroll taxes for SENA/ICBF/Cajas de Compensacion Familiar are also questionable.53 The benefit connectico. is virtually absent in the case of ICBF and is not strong in the cases of the Cajas or SENA which have ventured into activities which have little impact on the payors of payroll taxes. The result is that any rate cf payroll tax would end up being arbitrary and there is no assurance that the automatic funding arrangements that earmarking entails are generating an appropriate level of resources. In addition, Colombia's payroll taxes (including those for social security) are at the upper end of the spectrum among Latin Americ n countries and add 24-29Z to the cost of labor. Eliminating the pavroll taxes for non-social security purposes would lower labor costs and would likely take 0.5-1.0 percentage points off the unemployment rate. Lastly, on the same grounds as above, the earmarking of departmental taxes on beer/alcohol/tobacco/gambling for welfare, health and sports has no 53/ The recommendation on ths payroll tax is conststent with that of the Chenery employment mission. See op. cit., p. 123. - 67 - rational basis; such arrangements should be terminated and these activities made to rely on general budget resources. 74. The tax allowance and sales tax transfer--neither of which existed 20 years ago--have played important roles in the government's effort to decentralize, the former for che departments and the latter (mainly) for municipalities. The government is committed to continue in this direction and our recommendations here are intended to assist in this process. First, certain anomalies in the sharing formulas ought to be corrected, in particular the undue favoritism to small iurisdictions offered by the non-population part of the tax allowance and disincentive to increase cadastral values contained in the present sales tax transfer. Second, all revenue sharing formulas ought to contain incentives for greater local resource mobilization (as the formula for small municipalities presently does) to prevent national resources from substituting for local resources and encourage greater efforts in priority areas. And lastly, it is essential that efforts be intensified to ensure that municipalities- -especially small ones--have the capacity to utilize additional resources effectively. 75. Even for those earmarking cases where the benefit principle seems to fit and where price tax arrangements offer the possibility of generating an appropriate level of resources for the sector; a number of improvements are necessary. The coffee fund. which has strayed into a number of ao.tivities beyond its mandate of income stabilization and assistance to coffee growing areas, needs increased government surveillance. The new coffee contract 1989-1999 makes this possible, but very determined government efforts will be needed to ensure that activities are refocussed back toward the original mandate. As for earmarking in highways, it - 68 - appears that it is the producer of gasoline (Ecopetrol) and not consumer who is paying the gasoline tax. Earmarking is only justified where the benefit principle applies and consumers face a retail price that is above the import c.i.f. price. In addition, while gasoline prices and taxes have been adjusted annually, they still have not kept pace with inflation and the amount of resources devoted to maintenance and construction has been failing in real terms. If earmarking for highways is to continue, gasoline prices/taxes (and tolls, license, and registraticn fees) should be set that they can cover an appropriate expenditure program and debt service for the sector. Lastly, municipal level valorization taxes represent a quite pure form of earmarking with considerable reliance on benefit-cost considerations in investment decisions. Valorization appears to be popular and--in some instances--offers a way round resistance to property tax increases. Its extension to cities which have yet to make substantial use of it (i.e., beyond the major cities) merits consideration. 76. The recommendations made above would substantially xduce the number of earmarked funds and the extent of government monies earmarked, thus imparting greater flexibility to the government budget at all levels. Earmarking would be limited to revenue sharing, payroll taxes for so_ial security, and those few cases where benefit connections are clear and pricing arrangements appear to generate appropriate levels of resources. Even in these cases (especially the first and third), the commitment to earmarking ought not to be open-ended. In each case, a date should be set when the automatic financing arrangement would be reviewed, or better, when the arrangement would be terminated unless expressly renewed. This would permit adjustments to changing circumstances and force a review of the pricing arrangements, the quality of investments financed, and the past and future growth of infrastructure in the sector relative to needs. - 69 - BIBLIOGRAPHY Bird, R.M. 1970. Taxation and Development - Lessons from the Colombia Experience. Cambridge: Harvard University PreFs. Bird, R.M. 1984. Interaovernmental Finance in Colombia - Final Retort of the Mission on Interzovernmental Finance. International Tax Program. Cambridge: Harvard Law School. Chenery, H. 1986. El. Problema Laboral Colombiano: DiaRnostico. Perspectivas v Politicas - Informe Final de la Mision de Empleo. Economica Colombiano - Revista de la Contraloria General de la Republica (August-September). Contraloria General de la Republica. 1988. El Fondo Nacional del Cafe - Evaluacion Institutional v Financiera (December). Colombia: Bogota. Departmento Nacional de Planeacion. 1988. Proveccion de la ParticiRacion de los Municipios en la Cesion del Impuesto al Valor Agreaado. (September). Colombia: Bogota. Fedesarrollo. 1978. "El Efecto del Situado Fiscal y la Cesion del Impoventas Sobre los Ingrescs y la Estructura del Gasto Departmental y Municipal". Unpublished, Bogota (October). Gomez Buendia, H. and A. Cifuentes Noyes. 1987. "Seguridad Social y Empleo". In El Problema Laboral Colombiano, Tomo 2, J. Antonio Ocampo y M. Ramirez (eds.). Servico Nacional de Aprendizaje, Departmento Nacional de Planeacion, Contraloria General de la Republica, pp. 115-139. Colombia: Bogota. IBRD. 1977. "Valorization Charges as a Method for Financing Urban Public Works: The Example of Bogota, Colombia". Staff Working Paper No. 254. - 70 - IBRD. 1987. Colombia - A Review of Recent Decentralization Measure. (April). Washington, D.C. IBRD. 1987. "Colombia - Country Economic Memorandum". (October). Washington, D.C. IBRD. 1988. "Colombia - Trade Policy Survey". Washington, D.C. Jimenez, E. and B. Kugler. 1986. "An Economic Evaluation of a National Job Training System: Colombia's Servicio Nacional do Aprendizaje (SENA)". IBRD, Education and Training Series Report No. EDT 24 (April). Rhoads, W.G. and R.M. Bird 1967. "Financing Urbanization by Benefit Taxation". Land Economics, 43:403-12 (November). Slack, N.E. and R.M. Bird. 1983. "Local Response to Intergovernmental Transfers - The Case of Colombia". Public Finance, No. 3, pp. 429-437. Thomas, V. 1985. Linking Macroeconomic and Agricultural Policies for Adiustment with Growth - The Colombian Experience. Johns Hopkins University Press. Whalley, J. and A. Ziderman. 1989. "Payroll Taxes for Financing Training in Developing Countries". Policy, Planning and Research Working Paper Series, WPS No. 141 (January). World Bank: Washington, D.C. World Bank. 1988. World Development ReRort. Oxford University Press. - 71 - STATISTICA1 APPENDIX Earmarking in Colombia Al. Total Public Revenue and Incomes: National, Departmental, Municipal Levels, 1970-87. A2. Earmarking of Revenue: National, Departmental, and Municipal, 1970-87. A3. Situado Fiscal: Share of Tax Allowance in National Government's Revenues A4. Situado Fiscal: Jurisdictional Shares in the Tax Allowance, 1980-87. A5. Situado Fiscal: Share of Education and Health in Divisional/ Territorial Tax Allowances, 1980-87. A6. Distribution of Situado Fiscal, 1980-87. A7. Fondo Nacional del Cafe: Income and Expenditures, 1979-87. A8. Fondo Vial Nacional (F.V.N): Total Expenditures, 1980-87. A9. Fondo Vial Nacional (F.V.N.): Total Revenues, 1980-87. A10. Fondo de Promocion de Exportaciones (PROEXPO): Total Expenditures, 1980-87. All. Fondo de Promocion de Exportaciones (PROEXPO): Total Revenues, 1980-87. A12. Servicio Nacional de Aprendizaje (SENA): Total Expenditures, 1980-87. A13. Servicio Nacional de Aprendizaje (SENA): Total Revenues, 1980-87. A14. Instituto Colombiano de Bienestar Familiar (1CBF): Total Expenditure, 1980-87. A15. Instituto Colombiano de Bienestar Familiar (ICBF): Total Revenues, 1980-87. A16. Cajas de Compensacion Familiar: Revenues and Expenditures, 1980-87. - 72 - Table Al Totel Public Revenue and Income, National, Depaertmntal and Municipal Level, 1970-87 (Million, of Colombian Current Peace) 1970 1975 1940 19l1 1982 1963 1964 1985 1964 1997 National L*vel Revenues A. Central GOwerment (- 1+3) 20,361 66,009 206.205 279.627 356,592 396,367 426.550 631,666 911.553 1.234.950 1. Current Revenue 12,139 *1,619 168,247 221,792 279.955 296,960 300,U64 464,674 690,435 964.174 s. Tax Revenues 11.624 39,745 143,332 212.566 266,811 273,560 263.636 421,695 606,803 M11.766 b. Non-Uas Revenues 765 2,074 4.915 9.224 13.144 23,400 17,248 42.781 83,632 150.406 2. Transfers Notional Docentralitzed Agencis 3.23J 1.056 55,846 70.564 66,856 99,823 114,241 134,046 165,056 255,565 3. Other Incoe Natioual Public 4encie. 7,992 24.190 39,956 38.035 78.637 99,407 125,.66 167,212 221.1i8 270.77% a. Tax Uevenues 414 1.699 1,447 2,160 2,136 3.627 5.111 7,448 ,566 8.638 b. Other Transfers 443 606 3,996 7.436 6,744 8,093 7.162 7,666 13,294 13.053 c. Cross Operating Incmee 1/ 7,135 21,663 34,493 46.419 67,757 67.687 113,393 1 2.078 199,256 249,079 6. Operating Surplue Non-Financial Decentralized Agencies 3,372 7,850 6.525 12,426 31,956 36.669 65,416 61.633 50,081 139.944 C. Socia Security Contributions 2/ 2,269 7.,22 29.799 41.857 56,213 77.161 99,215 123,435 166.624 210,604 1. Retire"nt and Severanc. Contributions n.a. n.m. 22,277 31,69.4 41,675 59,439 76,102 95.00: 131.658 162.921 2. Payroll Taxes armarked for Decentralized Agenci4s na. na. 7,522 10,163 14.538 17,722 23.113 26.433 37.166 47.663 a. for the SOtA na.. n .. 3,616 5,193 7,936 9,088 12.16' 14,423 16.255 23.195 b. fcr tck ICIF n.a. n.e. 3.564 4,872 6.464 8,531 10,766 13.867 17,831 23.534 e CAJANAL n.. n.. 122 96 136 103 156 143 1,079 954 D. Total Current Revenu9 - Notional 26,042 61,661 246,529 334,112 446.761 510,197 591,151 *16,956 1,130,458 1.565,496 1. Departental Level avenues 3/ A. Departmnt Central Level 2,697 6,589 21,601 26,436 33.354 43,935 61,185 79.682 102.605 n.e. 1. Tax tevenues 2.535 S,638 20,166 25,627 30,444 39.690 54.018 66,564 67,471 n.e. a. Liquor *i 1,086 2,563 10,174 12.!50 14,866 18,612 23,766 30.123 361939 n.a. b. Tobacco 607 1,537 4.606 6,069 6.353 9,218 12,.93 15,680 20.26' n.o. c. Beer 562 1,269 4.353 6,171 7.656 9,731 11,856 15,013 19,238 n.s. d. Other 260 249 1,033 1 437 1,566 2.129 6,103 7,546 9.010 n.s. 2. Non-Tax ?.venues 162 95. 1,405 2,609 1I/ 2,910 4,245 7,147 11,116 15,134 na.. S. Social Security n.S. n.e. 1,475 2,233 2,721 3,468 2,960 S/ 6.216 n.s. n.*. C. Opereting Surplus In.. financial Departmental Enterpris 5/ n .S. 2.600 10/ 4,043 4,529 5,750 7,492 9,469 7/ 11,067 7/ 10,224 14/ n.e. D. Total Current Revemnue - Departmental n.e. nU.. 27,119 35,198 41,825 54.695 73,614 96,97 112.8;9 - 73 - (Continued) Table Al Total Public Revenue and Income., National Deoartmental and Municipal Level. 1970.d7 (Hillions of Colombian Current Pesos) 1970 1975 150 1961 1962 19$3 1984 1965 1966 1967 lIl. Capital Cities Municipal Incms I/ A. Central AdmimLetretion Municipal Level 1.550 3.236 11.59 15.504 19.d26 25.006 34.695 44.402 42.623 n.e. 1. Tea Uevenue 1,179 2.458 *.750 11,644 15.211 20,100 29,063 37.062 *2.623 na. a. Industry and Co_merce 193 624 2.968 4*105 5.551 7.026 12,533 16,616 16t261 na. b. Land Tax 369 660 2.567 3,426 4.502 5.772 7,310 10,011 12,399 na. c. Valorization Tax 9/ 261 461 2.067 2,563 3.291 5.309 5.937 14/ 6.063 14/ 6,967 14/ n.e. d. Other 356 513 1,146 1.530 1 .U7 1,993 5,263 4,350 4,976 n.e. 2. Von-Tax Revenues 371 760 2.S39 3,662 4,617 4.994 S.632 7,340 n.a. na. a. Total except Bogota 166 264 1.276 1.717 2,095 1.d07 2,348 3.254 n.e. n.a. b. Bogota _/ 205 516 1.563 2.145 2.522 3.169 3.464 4.06d n.D. n.a. S. Social Security n. n.n. 679 9S6 1.269 2.096 2.61S 3,716 n.a. n.a. C. Operating Surplus Departmental Laterpriae. 11/ n.e 2.220 6.370 14,374 20.012 24,539 32.064 56,517 12/ 77.700 13/ D. Total Currant levenAe Municipal na n.. 20,436 30.866 41,129 51,733 69,577 104,635 n.a. n.a. IV. Total Geormant x veouas Ail Levels n.a. n.e. 294.266 400.176 529,715 616* 825 734,372 1.016,556 n.e. n.a. Potesi I. Gross operating income of national decentralized agencies such as ICEL (electricity), TELECOM (tel.co.unications), end ICT (housing) and the sociel security agencies. 2. tSS. CAJAIIAL, Pondo Nacional del Ahorro (National Sevings Fund)k. CAPRZCO(. Militery Force Retiresent Pund. National Police Ketira*ent F_nd. 3. Excludee transfers from central goveroment and interdepartmntal tranefera. Includes oil royalties. 4. Includes transfere from tho distilleries. 5. Social welfare agsncieas lotteries, distillaries net operating income. 6. Some departsental information missing. 7. Som transfers to other departmental egencels included. S. Transfers from higher levels of goverment excluded. 9. Tsxes collected directly by the agencies. 10. Ieer and tobaeco taxes in Bogota. (1. Public utilities and Bogota lottery. !2. Bogota. hdelline, nd Cal. 12. Bogotc and Hedellin. 14. Estimate. - 74 - Eamna'imof e,maea U1i.al, Ve,rtlebtlal, Masteiogl 1970-07 ,tLit Cele _i Curwo_t Poo) 1070 1675 1960 1961 1908 1061 1064 1065 1964 1967 1. Kerueke Ftm. U.ia Leve A. Tan o C..V. aWL of l7_erts 72 736 6.641 7,004 11,595 10,657 17.395 22,S25 35,337 54.647 1. 12 tea fort 0 a 0 a 0 0 4.645 6.0S 5 *.290 11.647 a. Caja 4nrarU (402) 0 0 0 0 0 0 2,340 3,01 4,147 5,672 b. Induatrial (111) (402) 0 0 0 0 0 0 2,305 3,047 4,152 5,975 c2 2 e fo Proea 72 754 4.U61 7.904 11,595 10.S57 12.749 16,740 27.030 43,200 S. Pyroll taea 146 147 29,799 41.057 56,213 77,141 99,215 123,435 16.824 210.604 1. am 0 0 35,16 5.193 7.936 9*0O 12,167 14,423 18,256 23,195 2. 7CI.?. 140 112 *5,4 4,672 4,44 6,531 10. 7U 13,667 17,631 23.534 3. Cajema 6 15 122 9O 134 103 156 143 1,079 954 4. letiremat *Nd Swerenee payute U.S. S.&. 22,277 31,494 41,675 59,456 74,102 95,002 131,456 162.921 C. Ocoeline Taa 771 1.637 14,973 22,234 24,06 24.041 27,499 39,640 44,495 59,600 1. liahya fuad (752) 579 1.226 12,750 16.476 186404 16,061 21,354 24,474 32,792 42,765 2. S6.l lOad. Yu" (102) 77 1I4 1.497 2,223 2.4u1 2,406 2.456 5,264 5,u40 6,334 3. Utsiosl lilveys (102) 77 164 1,697 2,223 2,461 2.406 2,456 5,244 5.480 6,334 4. Transport fund (52) 39 62 $49 1,112 1,240 1,204 1,229 2.632 2.741 3.167 D. Tea an Internatial travel 40 n.S. 697 1.531 2,463 2,424 3.117 3.SO 3,425 4,426 S. 42 Coffee eaport tax 1,034 2.369 3,606 5.367 3,735 4,032 5,63S 6.756 17,664 14,005 1, Coffee fund (602) n.e. c .o. 601 SO4 422 673 939 1.459 2.961 2.334 2. Coffee Private Federation, Rural Sono (202) ua. c e.. 3,005 2,623 3,113 3,377 4*699 7,299 14,905 11,671 F. s5 Tourim Tra a 132 345 512 736 623 241 213 327 542 G. Movie Ta 0 0 a 0 0 0 0 0 221 505 H. Participations and Cootributioem 151 405 1,225 1,01S 2,163 353,4 3643 6,SS0 9,04 1.1063 1. Banks Legultory Cmilasioo 41 164 550 129 974 1.242 1.564 2,461 3.471 2.940 2. Privat. firt Re gulatory CormisesLo 35 64 290 394 552 743 943 1.410 1.572 2.736 3. Contribution Contraloris General 55 151 330 463 439 775 1,069 1,690 2,312 3,096 4. fasily funds Laguatory Coerniest 0 0 0 0 0 0 217 172 190 348 5. Industry en Cnemre l2eo atory Cimnissio 0 0 6 15 11 0 0 0 96 140 6. 1even Shbrin AeronauticS Funed 0 0 49 17 9 275 10 105 106 51 7. Superintetnmncia de Wotariad y lagietro 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 2.264 13'5 1,750 1. Spcl* FPunec 5 90 66 t0 74 573 1,127 3.206 4,956 6.212 1. Natinal D.tes" fund 5 72 1 0 1 438 $76 933 1,145 1.327 2. CoaWnicatio. fund a 0 1 49 25 69 196 227 367 404 5 UgucetioUel Srvte..row 0 0 0 0 0 0 a 0 0 a 4. Tea Education fP 0 16 4U 41 49 46 55 is 71 65 5. C,il Fund 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 632 1,966 2,995 6. Agricultural moetion Fimd 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 350 274 67 7.lioefund 0 a 0 0 0 0 0 171 251 240 S Cocoaeued 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 300 416 557 9. CerealFud 0 0 0 0 a 0 0 1$7 211 354 10. 6tec* rkLt* legulatory Cemissit 0 0 0 0 0 0 a 50 35 23 11. Food letaterti do Advmee 0 0 0 0 0 0 a 70 160 140 J. Tranefere en levern. S*arbin 3149 4,40 29,206 39,744 53.671 U3.794 87,941 110,765 131,426 190,29' 1. Tea Allaenee (dugatio. lcaltb) 0 4,503 19.43U 26.912 93.646 47.219 56,626 69.400 753616 109,862 2. Sae Ta 349 2,305 9,766 10,632 17,965 16.575 29.313 41,165 55,560 60,432 lable A3 Share of Tax Allowance in National Government's Revenues (millions of pesos; percentages) 1975 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 Current Revenues 41,819 168,247 221,792 279,955 296,960 330,884 464,676 690,435 964,176 Less: Earmarked Revenuesa 5,325 35,935 44,120 60,051 60,371 88,174 127,761 173,302 231,634 Equals: Ordinary Revenues 36,494 132,312 177,672 219,904 236,589 242,710 336,738 517,133 732,542 Tax Allowance 4,303 19,438 28,912 38,886 47,219 58,628 69,600 75,838 109,862 Tax Allowance + Ordinary Revenues X100 11.8 14.7 16.3 17.7 20.0 24.2 20.7 14.7 15.0 a. Included in earmarked revenues are the taxes on imports C.I.F., gasoline, international travel, tourism, cinema tickets, and after 1984 the ad valorem tax on coffee exports; also included are contributions and participations, the special funds, and the salea tax (or IVA) transfer. Source: Information supplied by Contraloria General de la Republica. - 76 - Table A4 Jurliedictional Shares in the Tax Allowance. 1980-87 (percentages) Formula 1964 Share Division/ Population in Tax Territory Share Allowance& 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 Antioqula 14.2 10.85 11.61 10.92 11.33 11.08 11.08 11.20 11.06 11.10 Atlantico 4.1 3.78 3.13 3.70 3.45 3.74 3.76 3.41 3.45 3.36 Bogota 9.7 7.70 8.51 10.32 9.47 8.36 0,37 9.04 8.83 9.32 Bolivar 4.0 3.71 3.26 3.47 3.30 3.59 Z.31 3.25 3.41 3.44 Boyaca 6.1 5.18 4.77 4.44 4.96 4.84 4.99 5.17 5.11 5.28 Caldas 4.1 3.78 3.66 3.77 3.89 3.76 3.60 3.56 3.77 3.41 Cauca 3.5 3.36 3.16 2.99 2.98 3.08 2.87 2.73 2.85 2.88 Cesar 1.5 1.96 1.89 1.78 1.95 2.17 1.99 1.92 1.96 1.85 Choco 1.0 1.61 1.67 1.73 1.72 1.90 1.92 1.82 1.79 1.88 Cordoba 3.4 3.29 3.58 3.65 3.62 3.68 3.18 3.53 3.61 3.43 Cundinamarca 6.4 5.39 7.12 6.67 6.67 6.37 6.57 6.84 6.85 6.91 Guajira 0.8 1.47 1.23 2.21 1.42 1.44 1.34 1.34 2.51 2.58 Hulla 2.4 2.59 2.85 1.55 2.76 2.73 2.94 2.76 1.48 1.44 Magdalena 3.0 3.01 2.82 2.97 3.05 2.98 2.75 2.97 2.86 2.98 Meta 1.0 1.61 1.48 1.49 1.34 1.64 1.61 1.46 1.61 1.56 Narina 4.0 3.71 3.91 3.39 3.68 3.77 3.95 3.70 3.61 3.70 Norte de Santander 3.1 3.08 3.42 3.14 3.53 3.04 3.36 3.74 3.59 3.55 Quindio 1.8 2.17 2.15 1.91 1.89 2.04 1.83 !.75 1.69 1.74 Risaralda 2.5 2.66 2.45 2.40 2.38 2.70 2.46 2.50 2.46 2.54 Santander 5.8 4.97 5.19 6.06 5.47 4.96 5.22 5.98 5.84 6.04 Sucre 1.8 2.17 1.97 2.02 1.94 2.27 2.00 2.01 1.97 1.94 Tolima 4.9 4.34 4.59 4.18 4.44 4.34 4.88 4.09 4.29 4.18 Valle del Cauca 10.0 7.91 7.31 6.97 6.71 7.62 6.79 6.95 6.78 6.82 Arauca 0.1 0.98 0.79 0.79 0.79 0.82 0.82 0.81 0.91 0.81 Caqueta 0.6 1.33 1.15 1.16 1.06 1.36 1.07 1.33 1.38 1.43 Casanare n.a. 0.912 0.93 0.92 0.92 0.80 0.98 1.12 1.29 1.17 Putumayo 0.3 1.12 0.95 0.98 0.88 1.06 0.95 0.99 1.16 0.98 San Andres 0.1 0.98 0.77 0.76 0.75 0.73 0.75 0.71 0.82 0.69 Amazonas 0.1 0.98 0.74 0.74 0.74 0.73 0.74 0.65 0.57 0.53 Guainia 0.0 o.91b 0.73 0.73 0.71 0.69 0.71 0.63 0.66 0.61 Guaviare n.a. O.91b 0.70 0.72 0.71 0.69 0.72 0.63 0.64 0.76 Vaupae 0.1 0.98 0.75 0.74 0.73 0.71 0.75 0.68 0.49 0.47 Vichada 0.1 0.98 0.75 0.74 0.73 0.62 0.72 0.69 0.71 0.63 TOTAL 100.0 100.0 100.0 ICO.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 a/ According to the sharing formula, the 1th jurisdictions share in "situado fiscal" is equal to .3/33 + .7 Pi/Pop where Pi/Pop is a constant since it is based on the 1964 census. b/ Jurisdictions with virtually no population in 1964 or which did not exist in 1964 are entered as sharing in the non-population component--i.e. 1/33 of 302. Source: Data supplied by Contraloria General de la Republica and mission estimates. - 77 - Table A5 Share of Iducetio eand selth in Divtetont.l/Territorl Tra AU4lwencee. 1960-87 (percentages DivitSon/ 1960 It61 1962 1963 194 1965 1966 1967 Territory I I I I a I I * d a I R I I I i Antioquis 60.96 19.04 76.30 21.70 77.59 22.41 76.49 11.51 7t.27 21.13 75.S0 24.20 71.63 26.15 76.34 ;1.66 Atjantico 75.41 24.59 73.31 24.64 77.03 22.97 75.17 24.63 75.46 24.52 70.01 29.99 6C.13 31.67 72.55 27.45 Bogota 61.50 16.50 76.94 21.06 51.91 16.09 77.61 22.19 71.47 21.53 71.S6 26.12 72.S3 27.47 75.76 24.24 Bolivar 74.97 23.03 72.13 27.67 72.45 27.55 74.01 25.99 72.22 27.76 46.37 31.43 67.23 32.77 69.39 30.61 Soysce 79.20 20.60 77.1$ 22.42 60.03 19.97 76.40 21.40 79.17 20.83 76.74 23.26 73.93 26.07 77.21 22.79 Caldas 79.07 20.93 78.97 21.03 76.76 21.22 76.53 21.45 76.76 21.22 76.30 23.42 71.60 28.20 75.49 24.51 Cauca 78.50 21.50 75.20 24.60 73.44 26.34 77.62 22.38 70.72 29.26 47.86 32.12 43.75 24.25 49.06 30.92 Ceesr 76.$5 21.15 73.93 24.07 74.44 25.34 71.73 26.17 74.42 23.S 49.34 30.44 49.52 30.48 72.36 27.44 Choco 79.94 20.06 76.25 23.75 49.61 30.39 77.49 27.51 77.39 22.41 71.74 28.26 72.27 27.73 78.50 21.50 Cordoba 61.47 10.53 73.513 24.47 76.46 21.52 77.14 22.64 76.41 21.59 73.95 24.05 72.24 27.74 74.00 26.00 Cundinarea 64.54 15.46 61.73 1S.27 61.66 16.12 87.63 12.17 61.45 18.55 79.62 20.18 77.32 22.6S 61.45 16.55 Guajire 75.42 24.56 64.64 15.16 46.24 33.76 44.$4 33.14 45.44 34.34 40.41 39.57 62.31 17.49 65.54 14.46 Huila 61.59 16.14 63.25 34.75 79.20 20.60 72.77 27.33 76.14 21.84 74.64 23.36 53.93 46.07 56.50 43.47 Megdeleaa 76.14 21.S6 46.06 33.92 47.99 32.01 73.31 26.69 69.98 30.02 70.22 29.76 70.16 29.82 70.94 29.06 oats 76.40 21.60 74.25 25.75 73.51 24.49 73.64 24.16 71.66 26.12 47.55 32.45 70.03 29.97 75.95 24.05 Narinc 60.53 19.47 76.02 23.96 73.39 26.61 73.43 24.57 75.72 26.26 67.93 32.07 68.77 31.23 70.71 29.2t Norte de Santander 61.83 16.17 75.14 24.64 61.20 16.dO 77.55 22.45 77.46 22.54 71.67 29.13 72.03 27.97 75.06 24.94 quindio 79.67 20.33 75.77 24.23 75.37 24.43 75.78 24.22 72.93 27.07 45.11 34.89 65.29 34.71 71.31 28.69 Risaralde 77.73 22.27 76.77 23.23 76.30 23.70 75.60 24.20 73.70 26.30 69.50 30.50 68.76 31.22 71.61 26.39 Sent:sd.r 60.65 19.35 60.66 19.34 76.53 21.47 76.56 23.44 77.17 22.83 73.13 26.87 74.46 25.54 74.78 25.22 Sucre 77.5. 22.45 71.53 26.47 72.75 27.25 73.35 24.45 73.93 26.07 *7.12 32.66 47.76 32.22 73.06 26.94 Tolime $0.96 190.4 78.15 21.8 74.62 25.38 76.67 21.33 79.92 20.06 74.03 25.97 49.16 30.64 75.37 24.63 VUell del Cauc, 76.10 21.90 76.14 23.$6 75.17 24.63 76.83 23.17 72.47 27.53 66.45 33.35 45.36 34.62 70.19 29.81 Arauce 74.51 25.49 73.57 26.43 73.14 26.56 75.62 24.16 71.61 28.39 73.49 26.51 72.94 27.06 71.83 28.17 Caqust& 76.79 23.21 76.12 23.$$ 75.16 24.62 70.45 29.35 72.16 27.64 74.30 25.70 72.93 27.07 79.47 20.53 Casasare 74.03 25.97 73.6S 26.32 73.54 26.46 64.13 15.87 75.22 24.76 79.92 20.08 77.16 22.62 78.08 21.92 Putuuayo 75*54 24.46 74.65 25.35 72.97 27.03 69.50 30.50 73.17 26.83 70.74 29.26 74.17 23.83 73.17 26.83 Son Andrea 74.00 26.00 73.30 26.70 74.04 25.94 71.16 28.82 72.44 27.56 72.23 27.77 45.76 34.24 68.68 21.32 A:azonae 73.43 26.57 73.63 26.17 73.96 26.04 70.14 29.86 73.32 26.68 70.64 29.36 57.97 42.03 59.86 40.14 Guainia 73.76 26.24 72.86 27.14 74.01 25.99 71.69 26.31 73.25 26.75 71.30 29.70 65.59 34.41 66.17 33.83 Gu&viere 70.60 29.20 73.91 26.09 74.01 25.99 71.04 28.96 71.53 26.47 70.34 29.66 64.32 35.46 73.18 26.82 Veup.z 73.79 26.21 73.71 24.29 74.04 25.64 71.64 26.36 70.64 29.16 72.21 27.79 51.35 46.45 54.86 45.14 tichads 73.79 24.21 73.71 26.29 73.94 26.06 82.19 17.61 73.12 26.62 72.56 27.44 67.22 32.78 6 6.57 33.43 TOTAL 79.56 20.42 76.51 23.49 76.79 23.21 76.45 23.55 74.16 23.84 72.37 27.63 70.60 29.70 74.52 25.48 Soureess From data supplied by Contraloria Genral d. is Republics. .0bflAS*S*SO....0, A *.  1. * * * Ri -- * ,.4...'.4. Wa ** - - -' 03 - * - - 0 * I 5 0 S '4-. o . --.-. F @0 *00  ..o. * 0 0 I - - A V 3 0 0 0 S 0 OO*NOO AO 3'… o01 F - *4 * N000 0   0040 NO CON 00.- 00 0. - - .- - 0 0 - - *0,F0NN00N 0 .N000.00.0 2 -.I - V 0 a 00CN0 20*0  gNO NO 2 * z-  0 .4 0 .. 2 - V -*000 0 00N I ,0 - 0 - *0.0 3 C - *O N 0 N - C A - 0 - 0 O -.  . ZN 0 - * 0-- 0 ON 4 …0 - - - - - - I ON NO - ONO . . I V …:-3V:.e 0…N 2 ZR o..o.o.C 2O- - N - NO N - .0 - 00 ,00 00 0…000 000 - -  00 N 0 N - - - - I .0 0 …0 O000NON 0 V .   VNNON 2 2200N0ON2±*O . - 79- TaIble 8, rondo Kaclonal 4.1 Cate; Oncog. and Waendliurso. 1979.87 1979 1980 1981 I82s]8 1993 1964os 9188 It87 .I 1. e-nses 109846.3. 153,827.2 87,94l.4 92. 777.4 108,967.8 I90.21l,2 284,049.9 827,981.4 312,246.8 A. Operational 78,809.3 118,792.4 89,371.2 37,094,0 47.619,8 118,2)0.3 1351,90.I 409,139.9 220,032.0 Coffee Sa..4 74.400,5 118,792.8 89,371.2 57.098,0 47.818,8 114,220.3 133.190.I 809,139.. n1.6. I. Goff.. fo, eaorr ',25. 114.05222 47,000.4 34,379 39397 102,399.2I I23,3I7.8: 228:,908.9 s 2.Cffee for:apo 936. 89.7 919,2 923 ,383, 2,139. 3,33. ,99, n.. 2. Coffee: ffor, 10 Retentoa 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 ni.e. Consornprton 1.524.8 2,121.3 1.851.8 1.78394 2,093.8 2,433.3 3,157.1 3,802.9 U.S. 1. Other operating rev. 1,430.7 2.393,3 232.83. 2,138.2 2,939.3 4,230.9 8,327.3 10,399.8 10,293.2 I. 2713cr 1!oo:8s sales 1,210.8 4,082.9 3,102.9 2,802,9 2,302.1 2,870,8 3.892,7 8.938,8 10,293.2 2. Fege reat ee. t (Freights) 020.1 2108 822.9 5323.4 437.8 780.3 03. 1,433.4 n.e. C. Trea,,fere 32.318,6 34.121,2 12,419.9 24.643,9 22,839.1 86,440.3 89.908,1 199,049.0 203,870.3 I. from the Central Government 2.489,4 3,003.0 2,822.0 3,112.8 2,377.0 4,899.3 7,299.7 14,903.2 11.871,1 A5 valorem Tea 2,488.8 3,003.0 2,923.0 3,l12.8 3,377.0 4.898,5 7,298,7 14,903.2 11,871.1 2. Froqa the Privet. Sector 45,848.2 31,l18.2 9,398.9 23,331.2 29,282.1 81,782.0 81,807.8 174.142,8 194,199.4 a, Setention-in.kind 29,4532.7 31,099,2 9,368.6 223,l0.3 29 148.3 81,339,9 80,621.1 172.387.8 n.e. b. Ret.ntLon-in-oalue 292.3 19.0 8.1 20.7 113.8 202.1 788.3 1,378.0 a.m. D. rinancIal Reve..noe 1,433.8 2,447,2 2,334.9 2,321,9 2,729.9 2,880.9 12,820,0 17,806.0 31, 108.4 C. Other R.ven-s 34.6 83.2 39.7 8.379,3 21.3 328.3 1,008.4 1,873.2 241.90.? Ex lpendituree 97.221,1 130,340.2 74,5336.8 92,237.0 100,827.3 138,902.2 173.800,9 407.230,7 483414.0 A. OporationaI expenditures 39,757.3 83,304.2 38,911.2 83,190.2 83.284,7 73,887.9 64,214.4 142.214,4 288,700.9 1. Coffee Purchases 39,737.3 65.304,2 38,911.2 43.190,2 4536.4,7 72.897,9 84,218.4 142.214,4 248,700.9 S. Other Rcoendltoree 4,923,4 3,999.1 8,800.2 8,137.0 9,942.2 1,3952.9 17,123.2 23,289.3 208,130.0 1. Coinerciall expenditures 3,81.8AI4 4,279.7 4,132.9 8,810.3 3,904.3 8,288.0 11,137,8 17,723.1 138,089.0 a.Co"'.eei"n 497.8 998,0 919,9 1,189.3 1,290.3 1,293.9 23283.3 2,838.9 n.e. 4.FrIht cha s 2347 2,75333 1,932.3 2,178.7 2,827.4 2,981.3 3,284.8 4,731.3 n.e. c. Ad"ertiaing 142.7 123,4 723.4 933,7 1,094.3 2,081.5 2,042.3 5,988,1 n.e. 4.Foreign promotion 0 0 0 0 727,4 988.0 243.0 1,744.0 ne e c kereg ing 50,9 703.0 537.1 508.4 836.i 1,034.8 1,187.4 1,788.35.e f.Quality changee (38.3) 0 0 0.2 (681.41 4.7 792.3 n.a. 2. Coffee Handling 1.321,.0 1, 718.8 2,847.3 3,348.3 2,937.9 5,238,9 3,967.4 7,848.4 54,723,35 a. Trashing expenditu.res 502.6 499.0 883,0 692.6 794 3 870.9 1,288.7 1,303,7 ne 3. Storafe 928.9 1,033.8 1.330.0 2,247.2 2,878.8 2,743.1 4,401.8 5,901.7 nr.a c. Forte expenditures 12 8 .7 1603 .4 117.8 138.9 131.1 145.5 1 52,.7 170.5 n.a. 0. Ttereet peymente 0 0 '46.7 271.8 133.7 477.9 124.2 8.3 n.s. elns.r-nco 0,9 2.2 J0 0 0 0 0 4 3. 0rh., Goode ,.3$0.9 2,427.8 3,460.6 3,077.1 3.917,4 4,298.0 8,848.3 12,371,1 13,307.8 a, 0ther Goods P.,,cha..s 1,019.9 1,776.6 2,946.8 2,301.1 3.224,3 3.483,0 3,225.7 10,086.0 11,894.l b. Other G-ood Enperrditures 361,0 831.2 514.0 576.0 892,1 833.0 1,820.8 2,543.1 3,613.3 C.Price differentials Adj,..toents 6,318.1 13,773.2 3,860,4 3,378.1 8.900.l 3,002.6 4,943.1 49.814,8 n.e. D. Transfers 37,003.3 43,647,2 132359,8 22,103.3 21,233.1 40,939.0 33,048.1 146,283.9 n.e. E. Ads,init ti.nn 4,817.8 6,620.3 3,G11.9 3,909,9 4,911.' 7.761.2 10,922.3 13,423.0 17,824.7 I. Fad, to Administration 1,393.9 2 , '70 .7 2,810.1 3.919,8 4,903.3 7,671.3 10,928.7 13,397.2 17,183.8 2. Conr,sioris 3.8 31,4 56,7 70.5 9.2 89.7 8.9 225.8 280.9 3. Exchange rate 10ees. (certificetes) 3,028.4 4,098,8 145.1 0 0 0 0 0 0 F. Intereat payments 2,746.7 2,259.0 2,894,0 5,482,9 9,972.1 18,082,9 11,029.3 '.019.7 17,785.4 G. Other expenditurtes 443.2 6.31lT.2 4383 a48562.3 418.4 1,367.8 3,432.3 10.354.5 5,373.1 A. tnf los minue outflone totel (t - 1II 12.642,1 5,497.1 (6.613.2) 1,340.4 8,109.9 31,279.0 98,849.1 220,820.7 16,832.8 Minu.- Exchange Losese 0 0 0 908.1 9.424,1 3,317.7 11,74,0.3 9,047.2 0 B. Surpluse or Deficit 12,642,1 5,497.1 (6.615.2) 836.3 1,883.8 22,881.2 78,909.8 229,877.9 l8,832.8 Minuet Roesorve 0 203.4 0 0 0 9 0 0 2,9381.9 C.Surplue or Oefictt 12,882.1 5,291.7 (8.813.2) 828.3 1,893.8 25,841.3 74,908.8 229,877.9 18,832.8 D. Internal cash flow 31,247.3 47,882.4 7,596.8 4,883.0 16,351.0 31,990.8 80,377.8 231,9853. (224.3027 1917, Io,e. of the dAts are not available. The source ts F9C hut differs frog 1880.98. 5o-ce- Fond. Nacional del Cafe. Actual dote, Table A8 fondo Vial Nacional (F.V.N.): Total Expenditures. 1979-87 (Milliois of Colotabin S) Progr and Projects 1. (S) 1981 (S) 1982 (CL 1983 C) 1984 () 1985 (S) 1986 (X) 1987 (S) 1. Highway construction, repairing and mintenance 10,' .0 68.8 15,112.0 65.2 13,127.0 48.6 13,380.0 45.4 15,615.0 44.8 22,463.5 50.3 26,078.0 49.4 42,900.9 50.2 II. Technical Services an Special Studies C .0 1.8 524.0 2.3 581.0 2.2 362.0 1.2 892.0 2.6 2,022.9 4.5 2,467.5 4.7 3,631.2 4.2 Ill. Equipment Investment ?.0 1.9 509.0 2.2 2,957.0 11.0 1,682.0 5.7 842.C 2.4 1,517.8 3.4 909.7 1.7 634.3 0.7 IV. Highways Safety Control .0 0.3 49.0 0.2 60.0 0.2 94.0 0.3 483.0 1.4 945.4 2.1 341.2 0.6 602.4 0.7 V. Other Roads Maintenance and District Admini- stration 3,+- .0 23.2 5,552.0 24.0 8,185.0 30.3 10,734.0 36.4 11,363.0 32.6 11,895.4 26.6 13,598.9 25.8 18,933.1 22.1 1 VI. Maritime ard Riverways Co Transportation --0 3.3 1,342.0 5.8 2,019.0 7.5 2,194.0 7.4 4,271.0 12.3 3,143.7 7.0 3,871.2 7.3 3,918.0 4.6 Vil. Debt Servicing .0 0.7 79.0 0.3 69.0 0.3 1,005.0 3.4 1,357.0 3.9 2,691.1 6.0 5,502.2 10.4 14,868.1 17.4 1. ExternaLt .0 0.0 0.0 0.0 17.0 0.1 767.0 2.6 1,146.0 3.3 2,290.1 5.1 4,727.1 9.0 10,807.4 12.6 2. Internal 113.0 0.7 79.0 0.3 52.U 0.2 236.0 0.8 211.0 0.6 401.0 0.9 775.1 1.5 4,060.8 4.8 Total Gastos 15,818.0 100.0 .!,167.0 100.0 26,998.0 100.0 29,451.0 100.0 34,823.0 100.0 44,679.7 100.0 52,768.8 100.0 85,488.0 100.0 Source: NOPT - Oficins de Planeacion y 0Wreccion Comercial y Financiera (Estados Financieros). Inforues Financieros de Contraloria Generat de la Republica. Table A9 Fondo Vial Nacional (F.V.N.) Total Revenues, 1980-87 I/ (Mlltions of Coloabian S) Description 1968 (t) 1981 (X) 1982 (X) 1983 (X) 1984 MX) 1985 (S) 1986 (X) 1987 1. Current Revenues 14,296. 88.7 18,758.6 91.7 22,281.$ 99.2 24,411.2 83.6 26,2'5.5 82.7 32,648.5 87.7 40,393.3 92.5 62,701.9 A. Operatioatl :ncome 563. 3.5 8 .0 4.1 1,377.1 6.1 1,885.3 6.5 3,044.0 9.6 4,986.0 .3.4 6,571.4 15.0 12,362.1 1. Sale of Ser,ices 2. 0.0 2.7 0.0 3.8 0.0 17.2 0.1 84.1 ..3 27.2 0.1 38.6 0.1 70.5 2. Other 27 560. 3.5 833.3 4.1 1,373.3 6.1 1,868. 1 6.4 2,959.9 9.3 4,958.8 13.3 6,532.8 15.0 12,291.6 B. Transfers, Revenue Sharing, Taxes 13,733. 8B.2 17,9,2.6 BF.6 20,904.8 93.1 22,525.9 77.2 23,251.- 73.2 27,662.5 74 33,821.9 77.4 50,339.8 I 1. R.D.E. 3/ 12,730. 79.0 16,616.0 h1.5 18,606.0 82.8 18,061.0 61.9 21,354.0 67.2 26,675.7 71.7 32,791.6 75.1 43,765.1 ao 2. .,udget transfers _j 1,003. 6.2 1,246.6 S.1 2,298.8 10.2 4,464.9 15.3 1,897.3 6.0 986.8 2.7 1,030.4 2.4 6,574.7 II. Capital Incom 1,826.f- 11.3 1,707.7 3.3 179.3 0.8 4,773.6 16.4 5,484.8 17.3 4,569.8 12.3 3,293.2 7.5 18,190.4 Total Revenues 1i 123.2 100.0 20,466.3 100.0 22,461.2 100.0 29,184.8 100.0 31,780.1 100.0 37,218.3 100.0 43,686.5 100.0 80,892.3 X R.D.E./Current Income 89.0 89.0 83.5 74.0 81.2 81.7 81.2 1/ Actual Figures. 2/ It includes toll revenues and revenues from agreements with other agencies / Gasotine and ACPH tax. Proceeds are used for debt servicing and investmenit. I/ Other budget transfers for investment. Source: Contraloria General de ta Aexklica, Informes Financieros. FvII financiat reports. TabI. 610 Fo-d. d. P.olnd. E.Portal6n. PREKO . Tot.1 £g.-ditur.a. 1860.8? D.attlptioo '0~~~~-F CU 1981 (2) 1982 (Il 1983 (12 1984 (0) 3985 (U 1988 CI) 3887 (1) Op.,,*Ltoaj £xZp*ndituT*o 1. Pot.oo.1 S.rIoi. i),.I 0.? 244.4 0.6 299.6 0.3 463.8 0.6 663.8 0.3 839.8 0.8 3.M9.2 1.1 C.438.2 0.8 It. G*-ata Expandlt.... 1'. 0.4 135.3 0.3 168.0 0.3 269.7 0.4 373.9 0.4 492.8 0.3 849.? 0.8 864.0 0.3 11.Tr...(... (I 0.8 117.7 0.3 127.S 0.2 1.374.8 2.1 700.0 0.8 4,641.8 4.6 7,809.3 7.3 379.7 0.2 S.btotai 3.2 2.0 491.6 1.2 393.1 (.0 2.308.3 3.0 3,739.7 (.9 3,274.6 6.0 9,871.2 8.9 2.041.9 3.3 IV. D.bt S.-.ictsi . (. 4.5 1.349.8 1.8 2.243.1 I .7 1.770.9 2.3 1.9(6.6 2.1 L.911.2 2.0 2.527.5 2.3 3.372.9 1.6 Total Op-rtta-a Eap.n4itur., W34.13. 6.5 2.067.4 3.0 2,838.2 4.7 4,079.2 5.3 3,436.3 3.5 7,943.8 1.8 (2.398.7 11.1 5,834.8 3.3 la.-It".o Exy.aditure. 1. T,;d Fir PaotTclpatloo ~~41.9 0.2 68.4 0.2 40.0 0.1 105.7 0.3 131.3 0.1 (23.9 0.1 270.2 0.2 304.0 0.2 It. Po5nt 31.4 3.2 (.311.9 3.6 38681.0 4.5 2,805.3 3.7 4,106.3 4.4 33,037.9 13.0 6,743.9 6.1 324.5 0.2 Ill. Fap-rt C-adit L-as. 23,11!.1 97.8 16.8(1.7 1,8.6 51,774.7 84.2 68.9(4.8 89.9 82,121.1 88.3 75,603.2 73.4 64.140,7 71.4 329,373.0 72.3 IV. B.IlIdtog a~d Otban 00 A .. to (..'93.O 4.4 (.068.3 Y.6 3,330.2 -. 726.7 0.9 2.806,4 3.0 627.2 0.6 383.4 0.3 22,243.2 32.4 N V. L. 53313883 1 ). 0 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 2.996.,- 3.0 3,408.0 4.9 20,744.2 31.4 Total I-vaat-nt E p-nditn.I. 27 9.4 93.3 39 .46 0. 3 13.0 57.255.9 93.) 72,3354.3 94.7 99,163.1 94.1 92,368.4 92.1 96,948.3 88.9 172,990.9 94.7 Tota1 .p-odit.r.a 29.-94.3 100.0 41,327.9 ('A. 60,064.1 100.0 76,633.3 100.0 92,823.4 100.0 i00,33'.2 300.0 3111,347.0 100.0 178.823.7 300.0 lnv.at.anr ~~~~93.y 93.3 90.3 93.0 92.1 81.8 87.1 74.6 In 3981 CERr paysnta i.c1od- (lbh. C).ET a. aPoot PI -ot1on ta.. ....Ptl- onnt-... La.. 33 ,allca 11a.al ba ...o(vI for CERT and oth.t axp-t 1-atl-. ad.auptlo. Sourcv: Gotaol ..nara. d. .. RaP.b1iCs. I.f.r... Ft....laI-- Tf.bl All Fonlo do Pro,octan do Expo:taclones (PROEXPO). Total R*ever*e. 1960-87 (Mill'ons of Colombian ) DescriptIon 1960 C r)t) 1982 (2) 1963 (1) 19894 (1 1985 (1 1986 (2) 161 (2) 1. Curr*n. ltveen.* 29.452.1 91 C 664- 1 ) S .6831.8 9'.6 73.080.0 95.4 92.821.4 100.0 97.338.0 100.0 117.604.2 100.0 150.921.C 100.0 A. Operational Income 22.791.3 1' i i60. 76.5 4A.2 7.3 15.3 62.423.3 81.5 80.072.3 86.3 60.517.t 62.6 90.566.5 17.0 107.721.0 71.9 1. Loan Ropsysents a. Principal 20.193.4 64 i.6.Cl. 66.9 4).900.0 68.1 s6.928.7 74.3 713.07B.8 76.Z 70.972.0 72.9 71.846.5 63.6 92.8-9.0 61.5 b. Interest 2.498.5 1 :4 I a 8.6 *.280.9 7.1 5.290.9 6.9 6.636.9 7.2 7.997.9 8.2 11.027.0 9.4 13.675.0 9.2 c. Other 99.6 316.8i 0.9 56.9 0.1 203.1 0.3 356.6 0.4 1.606.) 1.7 4.693.0 6.0 967.0 0.1 *. Earmarked Revenueo 6.660.6 2 ,.9 6.4 :9.C 11.,94.5 19.3 10.65S.7 13.9 12.749.1 13.7 16.760.3 17.2 27.0317.7 23.0 43.200.0 28.6 11. Capitol Incom4 1.1-3.0 3 j,6 9. 4 3.132.5 5 . 3.954.2 *.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0 Total Revenues 30.595.1 100.0 ( s.1.i9 r 60.064.3 100.0 76.634.2 100.0 92.621.4 100.0 97.338.0 100.0 117.604.2 100.0 150.921.0 0.0 W 2 R.D.E.ICurrent Income 22.6 49.9 20.4 14.6 13.7 17.2 23.0 2U.6 Soure,4 Contralort Geneeral de Is Rapublica. Info." FIt-.rcl.ros. rabl._ ^12 S-r-.clo Naclo.sl de APrandlsale (SA)t Total Ezpenditures. 1960-87 (Millions of Colombian Sl Deecziption 19MI 1) 1961 (11 1962 (2) 1983 (2) 1964 (2) 1965 (I) 1966 (I) 1987 (2) Operat loal EapnXs bad Debt S"ervicln 1. Personal Services 2,164.4 !.1 2.623.3 43.5 3,276.9 44.6 3,910.1 37.7 1.617.1 10.5 1,670.9 9.6 2,167.4 11.1 2.756.6 10.1 It. Genral Expenses 9or4.9 1.3 1.094.6 16.2 1.634.1 22.2 2,031.9 19.6 999.2 6.5 1.165.3 6.2 1,223.0 6.3 1,657.3 6.0 111. Transfers 39 .3 !.7 959.0 15.9 1,484.2 20.2 1.896.3 16.3 2.207.7 14.3 1,053.7 5.5 1,379.3 7.1 1.871.3 6.6 Subtotal 3,529.3 .4 4.677.1 77.6 6,397.2 87.1 7,636.3 75.6 4,624.0 31.3 6,109.9 21.5 4,710.5 24.4 6,265.4 22.9 IV. Debt ServiLeing 19.5 1.4 17.6 0.3 16.6 0.2 15.6 0.2 14.5 0.1 7.8 0.0 6.9 0.0 t.0 0.0 Total Operational Ezpenses and Debt Servicing 3,548.5 .1 4.6*6.' 77.9 E.413.S 87.3 7,654.1 75.7 4,838.5 31.4 4,117.7 21.6 4,777.4 24.5 6,293.4 23.0 InvstmntlProexma_ I. Educational Buildings Construction and Maintenance 612.9 1.4 950 .. 15.6 612.2 8.3 2.025.5 19.5 3,492.4 22.6 2,160.6 11.3 697.5 3.6 1,tl7.2 6.7 11. Rlural Development Program 197.5 4.1 235. 3.4 204.5 2.8 351.6 3.4 567.0 3.7 407.3 2.1 647.2 3.3 767.0 2.9 111. Comunity Participatlon Program 64.8 1.9 70.1 1.2 66.4 1.2 125.9 1.2 135.3 0.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 13.5 0.0 IT. food Prograe 10.0 0.2 106.1 1.8 24.2 0.3 12.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0> V. bNuan Resources lInrs. structure and Rese ch 0.0 0.0 0. 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 1,242.1 8.1 2,316.1 12.1 2,135.6 10.9 2,970.5 10.6 VI. ScientiLic a" T_.cbnology esearchb and Protion 0.0 0.0 0.J 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 4,782.1 31.0 6,246.3 32.7 7,474.5 38.3 10.666.9 3t.9 VI*. Educational Material and uipment 0.0 0.0 0. ) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 65.5 0.6 1,026.1 5.4 657.4 4.4 1,032.7 3.6 VII. Eployees Social Velsfre 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 1,209.9 6.3 642.1 3.3 1,226.0 4.5 IX. Industrial Sector Promotion 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 216.48 1.1 266.8a 1.4 200.0' 0.7 f. Vinancial !2westment 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 505.3 1.6 XI. Tecbnical Assistance and Plareidg 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 500.0b 2.6 460.0 2.4 200.3b 0.7 XII. L4w 5511965 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 804.0c 4.6 *.565.0c 6.0 1.581.64 5.8 1111. Otbhrs 113.4 2.5 0.0 0.0 4.4 0.1. 0.0 0.0 263.0 1.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 60.1 0.3 Total Investment TZplndituret 1.006.6 2.1 1.I34.8 22.1 931.7 12.1 2.515.0 24.3 *0.567.4 66.6 14.966.6 76.4 14.748.7 75.5 21.104.9 77.0 Total Expenditures 4.557.1 0. 0 6..14. 100.0 7.345.5 100.0 10.369.1 100.0 15,425.9 100.0 19,064.3 100.0 19,526.1 100.0 27,398.3 100.0 a. It I,cluded In 1965 $130 millIons . vr165 Iet.-n, !,n -Ar,rte.anias d. Colombt.1 1966, $161 mtilions1 1987s $200 millions. b. La 55, 555 millions and 1967, S2: .JIII-, . . . I saI c:-sd Sane-C-rtrol L.tInnoserric&no de Informstics agreement. C. L"v 55 reallocated funds are placs t-lrph .6r-Is.tL .i:t lifforent agencies. d. Las, 55 agreF enL9, Pacific Coast . .n d -. I.s Fl.nao Fn; ,1.001.6 millions for S.n.-For.do KEIN (L.y 55165). e. In 1967 It belongs to Coiw,nity D.- cwa.,t . (Te.I.ing and coeunily organloatn Source, Contralorla Ge.nral do la Re 7a.. I.. ..c..e Flnrc. er,. Tabie A3 Ssrvlclo Nacional do Aprendizal. (SINA), TotalP.evenues. 1980-.7 !1 (Hillilon of Colobilan 6) DOscrlption 1960 (11 15181 () 1982 (2) 1983 (2) 1964 (2) 3965 (Z) 196 (2) 1o67 (2) 1. Current leyies 4,'- A 9f6..1 64(N.5 130.0 8,679.5 97.4 11,056.6 87.4 14,319.7 53.0 16.662.7 67.1 20.353.9 99.6 26.435.3 93.4 A. Operational IJ 7. 426.9 6.5 376.9 4.2 1,040.6 8.2 1,771.9 10.3 2.094.5 10.9 1.561.5 7.7 2.709.7 9.6 1. Sale of Services ! I.Z 16.6 1.5 106.1 1.2 119.5 0.9 149.9 0.9 172.5 0.9 197.5 1.0 4.7 0.0 2. A4r5emmte 0.2 4.6 0.1 2.0 0.0 15.6 0.1 14.2 0.1 157.9 0.9 162.1 0.9 23.6 0.6 3. InanLetl e remes : .4 2.1 290.0 4.4 235.8 2.6 665.0 6.6 1.536.4 .9 1.617.0 6.5 990.6 4.9 1.429.6 5.1 4. Otbher ;. 3.8 :35.I 0.3 31.0 0.3 40.5 0.3 69.4 0.4 146.3 0.6 391.0 0.9 1.05.6 3.7 R. Trassfers 7ad 7.2. 4. i69.D l. &. 3.5 9.302.6 93.1 10.016.2 79.2 12.547.8 72.8 14.566.2 76. 167.92.4 92.1 23.725.6 63.8 1. Budget traefore 21 r 6.2 210s.9 4.3 125.6 1.4 325.6 2.6 380.6 2.2 145.6 0.6 253.5 1.4 316.2 3.3 2. (FTC) Industry Coetruction tlun O. D 0. 9. l C.6 241.5 2.7 602.7 4.6 645.9 4.9 484.6 2.5 263.5 1.4 316.2 I.1 3. I.3.3. 31 OD (UK tea.) 3. . 1.. 62.3 - 1!3.4 7e.6 7,935.5 69.0 9.087.7 71.9 11,321.1 65.6 13.936.0 72.6 16.255.6 69.5 23,194.6 92.0 Vl tl. C.it.l Imome L 3.1 O..) (.0 234.9 2.6 1.567.1 12.6 2.926.1 37.0 2.474.5 12.9 60.0 0.2 1.666.6 6.6 A. llsac Surplus 3.wm e4I 4.! 3.1 0.0 Oi.ui 234.9 2.6 1.567.1 12.6 2,920.9 16.9 2,469.4 12.9 20.9 0.1 I1,6.6 6.6 A. Other Capital evenues 5 ( 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 7.2 0.0 5.1 0.0 19.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 Tota leveue .; 100.0 ., 636.5 (0.0 8.914.4 100.0 12,643.9 100.0 17.247.6 100.0 .9137.2 300.0 20.393.9 100.0 26.302.1 100.6 I S6lUCurret Incme .0 65.0 0.0 76.6 0.0 91.4 0.0 82.2 0.0 79.1 0.0 63.6 0.0 69.7 0.0 67.? 1. Actual *Vigr.e 2. Covernmet special prwogramm ;1 P3.. IPC. (Inral 4eve.opo_nt, foods programs. Commuity programs) J. It locluds Le 55165 r*sl1oea:,r s*tevue. 4. Th. 1960 surplus for $375.6 nil . is not licl.,ded in 1661. 5. rized &._te sales proceedm &nS v,;,w Funds surplases (Eployee Funds). Sources Costralorla Genierl do I 1 . utlica Infors.. Fin.n, lroa. rbl.- A14 Instituto Colooblno do Slteastar Familiar 11CSF)v Total Ezpeaditures. 1900-S7 (tlillions of Colombian S5 Deacription (2) l98I ( 1 1982 (2) 1963 (1) 1964 (2) 19S5 CZ) 196S tP) 191 (it) Operat loal Perrmal Services 2 5.0 176.7 5.7 529.6 7.1 190.0 2.1 327.9 2.9 376.0 2.7 840.8 2.1 536.5 2.1 GCniral xpenes 1 - 2.9 19.0 2.7 229.2 3.1 87.1 1.0 112.6 1.0 166.6 1.2 233.4 1.1 243.6 1.0 Traf-era 1.8 10.8 1.6 152.6 2.0 629.7 9.1 2,739.9 24.2 3.027.6 21.6 3,639.0 1.3 4,77f.1 19.0 Total General 9xpendituree 51 h 9.8 06J.3 10.0 911.4 12.2 1,106.8 12.1 3,IOS.4 2S.0 3,570.2 25.5 4,513.2 21.5 5.556.2 22.1 lnI etmnt Sen.IWures Children £aecstasne, Programs 3.61 I; 87.6 4. 4 72.5 4.995.6 66.9 5.992.3 65.5 U.S. 0.0 10,123.0 72.2 13,593.6 64.6 16,071.0 71.0 Adults hAaIstane Program 79 1 1 14.3 .21.7 12.4 1,160.1 15.8 1,493.0 16.3 n.e. 0.0 0.0 1,460.0 7.0 221.0 0.9 Pbysical Infrastructure - Healtb SlI 1.6 ; 1.. 3.2 65.3 1.1 114.7 1.3 n.S. 0.0 d 9.2 0.6 1.273.7 6.1 1,198.0 4.S Mhuss Resources Training and Researeb 0.0 0.0 ;7. 2 t . 15.6 0.2 31.6 0.3 n.e. 0.0 222.9 1.6 138.7 0.6 104.5 0.4 Global Planing. Social Devlopmant 4.3 0.1 4. O 0.0 0.1 0.0 n.a. 0.0 0.0 11.6 0.1 10.0 0.0 food an Rural Developmant Program 343.0 8.4 t.0 263.9 3.S 403.0 4.4 a.S. 0.0 17.0 0.1 0.0 7.3 0.0 Total Inest_st lupeaitures 4,871.2 90.4 S. V8 8 90.0 8,580.7 67.6 5,034.9 67.9 6C15S6.9 1 72.0 10,452.1 74.5 16,457.6 76.5 19.610.1 77.9 Total Gasto. 5,369.6 I0C.0 6.411.9 IN0.u0 7,472.1 100.0 9,143.7 100.0 11 .39.3 100.0 14,022.3 100.0 20,970.6 100.0 25,166.3 100.0 1. Budget estimates. Actual data rit found. Sources Contraloria Goniral de Is -9.blica. lntor,-s Fiancl sros. Table r15 Ins:ituto Colodbiano de BieneStar Ftitier (ICOF): Totol RevemeS. 190D-87 (Millions o Co cb) n ) Description 1980 f . 198 ({ 1982 (M) 1983 (X) 1984 (1' M CX) 1986 1S) 1987 (1) 1. Current Revewsws 4,740.4 57.5 5,83'.9 7. 6,763.4 83.8 8,737.6 89.0 11,164.0 89.3 14,210.6 89.7 18,524.0 82.5 24,095.1 87.4 A. Operationml 35.2 0. a. 7.7 1.l 32.6 0.4 39.0 0.4 31.7 0.3 186.2 1.2 380.9 1.7 111.3 0.4 D. Budget Trwa.fers, Texes 4,7M0.2 57.1 5,76'.2 '5.5, 5,730.8 83.4 8,698.6 88.6 11,132.3 89.0 14,024.4 88.5 18,143.1 80.8 23,963.8 87.0 1. Transfers 1,121.2 13.6 891.2 11. 266.5 3.3 167.9 1.7 344.8 2.8 17.0 0.1 28.5 0.1 160.0 0.6 2. R.0.E. 3,584.0 43.5 4,87.'.0 O.Ai 6,464.3 80.1 8,530.7 86.9 10,787.5 86.3 14,007.4 88.4 18,114.6 80.7 23,823.8 86.4 1 00 11. CapitaL Incom. 3,500.1 42.5 1,791.8 23.t. 1,305.2 16.2 1,076.1 11.0 1,341.3 10.7 1,638.6 10.3 3,918.6 17.5 3,484.3 12.6 -4 Total Revenues 8,240.5 00.0 r,63'.7 100.(1 8,068.6 100.0 9,815.7 100.0 12,505.3 100.0 15,849.2 100.0 22,442.6 100.0 27,579.4 100.0 I X R.D.E./Current Incom 75.6 81.5 95.6 97.6 96.6 98.6 97.8 98.9 Sjuc : Contralorla Generat de La '!Vublica. Inf,m,s Financieros. - 88 - Table A16 Calas de Compensacion Familiar: Revenues and Exwenditures. 1980-87 Revenues 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 Revenues Total .. .. 47,680 61,445 75,586 .. 171,770 Taxes 6,979 9,348 12,457 17,048 21,866 29,080 na. 51,258 I/ Coamercial Operation n.a. n.a. 35,223 44,397 53,720 n.a. 93,073 2/ 120,512 2/ ExDenditures Total 6,979 9,348 12,457 17,048 21,866 n.a. n.a. n.a. Subsidy in Cash 3,278 4,664 6,204 8,828 11,196 Subsidy in Kind n.a. .. 152 246 358 n.a. n.e. n.e. Subsidy in Services n.a. 1,702 2,439 3,270 4,021 n.a. n.e. n.a. Other 3/ n.e. 2,981 3,662 4,704 6,290 n.a. n.a. n.a. Notes: 1. Sixty-nine Family Funds. 2. Forty-Five Funds. 3. Administrative expenses. Source: Hanrique and Associates, Years 1980-84. Magazine 'Negocios" (Business), No. 59, 1988. PRE Working PaQer Series Contact vsw Author ZtDA WPS402 The GATT as intemnational Discipline J. Michael Finger March 1990 N. Artis Over Trade Restrictions: A Public 38010 Choice Approach WPS403 Innovative Agricultural Extension S. Tjip Walker June 1990 M. Villar for Women: A Case Study of 33752 Cameroon WPS404 Chile's Labor Markets in an Era of Luis A. Riveros April 1990 R. Luz Adjustment 34303 WPS405 Investments in Solid Waste Carl Bartone April 1990 S. Cumine Management: Opportunities for Janis Bernstein 33735 Environmental Improvement Frederick Wright WPS406 Township, Village, and Private William Byrd April 1990 K. Chen Industry in China's Economic Alan Gelb 38966 Reform WPS407 Public Enterprise Reform: Ahmed Galal April 1990 G. Orraca-Tetteh A Challenge for the World Bank 37646 WPS408 Methodological Issues in Evaluating Stiin Claessens May 1990 S. King-Watson Debt-Reducing Deals Ishac Diwan 33730 WPS409 Financial Policy and Corporate Mansoor Dailami April 1990 M. Raggambi Investment in Imperfect Capital 37657 Markets: The Case of Korea WPS410 The Cost of Capital and Investment Alan Auerbach April 1990 A. Bhalla in D:vc!c C.ntries 37 i9Q WPC411 ncnftiuionn! Mm-sions of Poverty La;fence F. Sa!;i2cn A ay ,199 E. Madrn - 7t i. ,9C WPS412 Exchange Rate Policy in Developing W. Max Corden May 1990 M. Corden Countries 39175 vvr;-. .;t A.af*iy .. M. Howard May 1990 S. Alizi,ii A Review of Financial Trends 31091 Full Report WPS414 Supporting Safe Motherhood: L. M. Howard May 1990 S. Ainsworth A Review of Financial Trends 31091 Summary WPS415 How Good (or Bad) are Countrv Norman Hicks April 1990 M. Berg Projections? Michel Vaugeois 31058 PRE Working Pager Series Contact vl Anhor DIor paper WPS416 Improving Data on Poverty in the Paul Glewwe May 1990 A. Murphy Third World: The World Bank's 33750 Living Standards Measurement Study WPS417 Modeling the Macroeconomic William Easterly May 1990 R. Luz Requirements of Policy Reform E. C. Hwa 34303 Piyabha Kongsamut Jan Zizek WPS418 Does Devaluation Hurt Private Ajay Chhibber May 1990 M. Colinet Investment? The Indonesian Case Nemat Shafik 33490 WPS419 The Design and Sequencing of Brian Levy May 1990 B. Levy Trade and Investment Policy Reform: 37488 An Institutional Analysis WPS420 Making Bank Irrigation Investments Gerald T. O'Mara May 1990 C. Spooner More Sustainable 30464 WPS421 Taxation of Financial Intermediation: Christophe Chamley May 1990 W. Pitayato- Measurement Principles and Patrick Honohan nakarn Application to Five African Countries 37666 WPS422 Civil Service Reform and the World Barbara Nunberg May 1990 R. Malcolm Bank John Nellis 37495 WPS423 Relative Price Changes and the M. Shahbaz Khan May 1990 WDR Office Growth of the Public Sector 31393 WPS424 Mexico's External Debt Sweder van Wijnbergen June 1990 M. Stroude rlestrucru rui g in I 90 U WPS425 Earmarking Governmreni vvdiiiirTi A M.Cioeav Seutembei 1990 A. Gha.ia Revenues in Goiomoia Evamaria u oe iowon 37699 WPS426 Growth-Oriented AdJustment Riccardo Faini June 1990 M. Ameal Prograrms A Statistical Ana!vsis Jaime de Melo 37947 Julie Stanton WPS427 Exchange Reform, Parallel Markets Ajay Chhibber May 1990 M. Colinet and Inflation in Africa: The Case Nemat Shafik 33490 of Ghana WPS428 Perestroyka end Its Implications Bela Balassa May 1990 N. Campbell ,or European Socialist Countries 33769