WPS7346 Policy Research Working Paper 7346 The Economics of Policy Instruments to Stimulate Wind Power in Brazil Florian Landis Govinda R. Timilsina Development Research Group Environment and Energy Team June 2015 Policy Research Working Paper 7346 Abstract Large-scale deployment of renewable energy technologies, absence of the 10 percent wind power expansion. The study such as wind power and solar energy, has been taking place also finds that, in the case of Brazil, production subsidies in industrialized and developing economics mainly because financed through increased value-added tax would have of various fiscal and regulatory policies. An understand- superior impacts on welfare and greenhouse gas mitigation, ing of the economy-wide impacts of those policies is an compared with a consumption mandate where electricity important part of an overall analysis of them. Using a utilities are allowed to pass the increased electricity supply perfect foresight computable general equilibrium model, costs directly to consumers. These two policies would this study analyzes the economy-wide costs of achieving impact various production sectors differently to achieve a 10 percent share of wind power in Brazil’s electricity the wind power expansion targets: the burden of the man- supply mix by 2030. Brazil is in the midst of an active date falls mostly on electricity-intensive production and program of wind capacity expansion. The welfare loss consumption, whereas the burden of the subsidy is distrib- would be small, 0.1 percent of total baseline welfare in the uted toward goods and services with higher value added. This paper is a product of the Environment and Energy Team, Development Research Group. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted at gtimilsina@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team The Economics of Policy Instruments to Stimulate Wind Power in Brazil§ Florian Landis and∗ Govinda R. Timilsina† Key Words: wind power, energy supply, climate change, CGE modeling, Brazil JEL Codes: Q27, D58 § The authors would like to thank Mun Ho, Christophe de Gouvello and Mike Toman for very helpful comments and suggestions. We also acknowledge the financial support of the World Bank’s Knowledge for Change Program (KCP). The views and interpretations are of authors and should not be attributed to the World Bank Group and the organizations they are affiliated with. ∗ Researcher, ETH, Zurich, Switzerland, e-mail: landisf@ethz.ch. † Senior Economist and corresponding author, Development Research Group, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington D.C. 20433, USA, e-mail: gtimilsina@worldbank.org The Economics of Policy Instruments to Stimulate Wind Power in Brazil 1 Introduction In addition to large hydropower potential, Brazil is endowed with good wind power potential, mostly in the northeast and southern parts of the country, especially across the states of Bahia, Rio Grande do Norte and Ceara. A large portion of the economic potential of hydropower has already been exploited in Brazil and further expansion is increasingly constrained by environmental sensitivity and the remoteness of much of the remaining resource (REN21, 2014). On the other hand, emissions of greenhouse gas (GHG) from the power sector is rapidly increasing due to the increasing share of thermal power generation in the power supply mix (IEA, 2014b). Therefore, the government is planning to expand wind power and expects wind power to contribute 9% of total electricity consumption in the country by 2021.1 Moreover, wind power provides an excellent complementarity to hydropower in Brazil, as the high wind seasons coincide with low rainfall seasons. Currently, Brazil is the leader in Latin America in developing wind power; total installed capacity for wind power generation increased by more than -fold in just four years since 2010 (GWEC, 2014).2 Brazil has introduced a number of policies and programs to promote large- scale deployment of wind energy. Existing policies aimed at wind power development include market (or purchase) guarantee, where the government procures wind power through competitive bidding or auctions (Franca, 2011). In addition, the government has launched specific programs to facilitate a large-scale deployment of renewable energy, including wind power (REN21, 2014). Although Brazil and many other countries have introduced policies to promote renewable energy, including wind energy, the implications of such policies from a broader economic perspective are often not addressed. This clouds an already complex debate over whether or not a large-scale deployment of energy technologies that are yet to gain economic competitiveness should be promoted through government support policies rather than being left to markets. 1 The Brazilian government’s Decennial Energy Plan (PDE 2021) sets a goal of 16 GW of installed wind capacity by 2021, accounting for 9 % of national electricity consumption (GWEC, 2014). 2 By the end of 2010, total wind power capacity was 927 MW, it increased to more than 5000 MW by the end of 2014 (GWEC, 2014). 2 Economy-wide macroeconomic models, particularly computable general equilibrium (CGE) models, are used to assess the economy-wide impacts of a policy. However, only a limited number of studies are available in the literature that assess renewable energy policies using a CGE framework (Timilsina and Landis, 2014; Böhringer and Löschel, 2006; Rana, 2003). The main obstacle to the use of CGE modeling approach to assess renewable energy is that the share of renewable energy in the total energy mix is very small. Therefore, renewable energy technologies are not treated as a separate economic activity or sector in input-output tables or social accounting matrix, the main database for a CGE modeling exercise. Moreover, most CGE models represent electricity generation technologies as a single technology thereby ignoring the heterogeneity among various technologies to generate electricity.3 The existing literature also diverges on techniques for representing renewable energy policy instruments in a CGE framework, particularly modeling renewable energy mandates. Some studies represent a renewable energy mandate, such as a biofuel blending mandate (a regulatory policy), through an equivalent fiscal policy, such as a subsidy to biofuels to the level that increases its consumption to satisfy a mandate or target (see. Hertel et al. 2010; Sorda and Banse, 2011 and Timilsina et al. 2012b). This approach is easier to incorporate in a CGE model. However, the general equilibrium effects derived through this approach might be different from the actual effects of a mandate because a mandate has a significant, direct effect on energy prices and thus the behavior of consumers, whereas consumer behavior is more indirectly affected by the energy price impacts of a renewable subsidy financed by the government through increases in other taxes. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. In section 2, a brief description of the CGE model is given. In section 3, the results of our simulations are presented. Finally, section 4 contains a summary and the conclusions of this study. 2 Model Description We model Brazil’s efforts to promote wind power generation in a perfect foresight intertemporal computable general equilibrium model. Base year data about the economy are 3 However, recognizing the role of power sector on climate change mitigation policies, CGE models developed for climate change mitigation polices started to represent different electricity generation technologies separately instead of lumping them in a single technology (see e.g., Rana 2003; Paltsev et al. 2005; Timilsina and Shrestha, 2006). 3 according to a social accounting matrix (SAM) by Chen and Timilsina (2012). We have considered 31 production sectors and 27 goods and services. While the oil refinery industry produces three commodities, gasoline, diesel and other petroleum products, electricity is produced from seven different types of technologies (i.e., hydro, wind, biomass, coal, oil, natural gas and nuclear). The disaggregation of the electricity sector to various power generation technologies is crucial, as without this disaggregation, simulations of policies to promote renewable energy-based electricity generation is not feasible. Table 1. Production sectors and consumption goods considered in the model Industry/sectors for production Goods and services for consumption 1. Sugarcane industry 1. Sugarcane 2. Soybeans industry 2. Soybeans 3. Other agriculture industry 3. Other agricultural products 4. Livestock 4. Livestock 5. Forestry 5. Forest products 6. Crude oil & natural gas 6. Crude oil & natural gas 7. Coal mining 7. Coal 8. Metals and mineral mining 8. Metals and minerals 9. Food & beverages 9. Food & beverages 10. Textile & leather 10. Textile & leather 11. Wood industry 11. Wood 12. Pulp, paper & furniture 12. Pulp, paper & furniture 13. Oil refining 13. Gasoline 14. Diesel 15. Other petroleum products 14. Biofuels 16. Biofuels 15. Chemicals 17. Chemicals 16. Metal industry 18. Metals 17. Non-metallic minerals industry 19. Non- metals (e.g., cement, lime, glass) 18. Machinery & equipment 20. Machinery & equipment 19. Other manufacturing 21. Other manufacturing goods 20. Hydropower 22. Electricity 21. Coal fired electricity generation 22. Natural gas fired electricity generation 23. Oil fired electricity generation 24. Windpower 25. Biomass fired electricity generation 26. Nuclear power generation 27. Gas processing industry 23. Process gas 28. Construction sector 24. Construction goods/services 29. Commercial sector 25. Commercial services 30. Transport sector 26. Transport services 31. Service sector 27. Other services 4 All production sectors, except the sub-sectors with various electricity generation technologies, are assumed to follow the 4-tier nested production structure as illustrated in Figure 1. Figure 1. Production Structure of industries except electricity At the bottom tier, a CES function combines coal and petroleum products to have a fuel aggregate. The fuel aggregate is then combined with electricity to have an energy aggregate. Energy is combined with land and value added (capital and labor) inputs, and this energy-value added & land composite is then combined through a CES function with intermediate goods and services to produce outputs. The output is distributed to domestic and foreign consumption (i.e., exports) through a constant elasticity of transformation (CET) functional form. On the domestic market, a domestically produced good is aggregated with its imported counterpart using a CES functional form; all internationally tradable goods and services follow this assumption. For the electricity-generating industries, the production 5 structure is different from that in other sectors (see Figure 2). The main difference is that the electricity production structure allows direct substitution between capital and fuel. This is necessary to portray the substitution potential between fossil fuel-based carbon-intensive electricity generation technologies with carbon free but capital intensive renewable energy technologies. Figure 2: Nesting structure for electricity generation sectors Following Timilsina and Landis (2014), we used a nested multinomial logit choice model to distribute investment to various types of electricity generation technologies. The multinomial logit model assumes that investment in generation capacity—unlike the more aggregated investment in the other production sectors—implicitly entails additional technology and site specific investments needed to provide the generated power to consumers (see Figure 3). The nature of those additional costs determines what technologies are most profitable to invest in and how costly the overall investment is. We also account for the investments needed for transmission facilities, which is important as wind power resources 6 are often located in remote areas away from load centers and access to national transmission grids needs to be built. We assume that at each point in time a certain number of building sites for power plants become available. In order to invest into electricity generation capacity of a technology at a specific site, a technology specific investment into transmission capacity and an additional site specific investment has to be made. The site specific investment need is calibrated with levelized cost of electricity generation technologies from various sources. Figure 3: The nested multinomial logit choice model for investment decision in the electricity sector Our study follows a standard approach used in the literature to model household behavior. Under the perfect foresight framework, a representative household maximizes a Ramsey type welfare function, where the household maximizes the present value of its consumptions over time. The overall household consumption is a nested CES aggregate of leisure and consumption of aggregated final goods and services. The final goods and services are a CES aggregate of energy and non-energy goods and services. The aggregated energy good is, like in the production sector, a CES combination of electricity and fossil fuels (Figure 4). The model assumes that labor is perfectly mobile between sectors, capital is sector specific, and land can be transformed between its sector specific states according to a nested constant elasticity of transformation CET function as in Figure 5. While land is not an input to production for many sectors, it is an inpub, especially in agricultural and mining sectors. 7 Figure 4: Representation of household behavior Figure 5. CET nesting structure for allocation of land to different uses Note: Demand for protected forest is assumed to be exogenous. We considered two types of policy instruments to promote renewable energy: a production subsidy, and a renewable energy portfolio standard. While the subsidy is designed to pass the financial burden to all consumers indirectly, through increased taxation in other 8 goods and services to finance the subsidy, the mandate passes the burden to electricity consumers directly through increased electricity prices. 3. Results and Discussion As of year 2012, Brazil has installed 121,000 MW of electricity generation capacity, of which wind power accounts for around 1%, nuclear power accounts for 2%, thermal power (coal, gas and oil) accounts for 27% and hydropower accounts for the remaining 70% (EPE, 2013). In 2012, total electricity generation in Brazil was 552.5 TWh, of which wind power plants generated 5.3TWh or less than 1% (IEA, 2014a). In this study we are analyzing policies to increase the share of wind power in total generation to 10% by 2030. In fact, Brazilian government’s Decennial Energy Plan (PDE 2021) aims to increase the share of wind power in the total electricity production to 9% by 2021 (GWEC, 2014). We stayed a bit conservative, considering the growth of total electricity demand in the country and assumed that the country would achieve the wind power target by 2030. If a production subsidy from the government is used to achieve the target, the subsidy would need to be equivalent to 65% of electricity supply cost of wind power to achieve the 10% target. Since the government needs additional revenue to finance the wind power subsidy, we assumed that it would increase the value added tax (VAT). However, the increase in VAT would be very small. When a consumption mandate is implemented to promote wind power, the electric utility is allowed to increase its tariff so that it can pass the incremental system cost caused by wind power addition to consumers. Meeting the 10% wind power target by 2030 through the consumption mandate would increase the average electricity bill by 6.2%.4 The model simulation results under subsidy and mandate scenarios are presented below. We first present impacts of the policies on electricity system followed by the impacts on the national economy and GHG emissions. 4 The subsidy policy averages the premium for wind power into a relatively large base of total consumptions of goods and services in the country whereas the mandate policy averages the premium into relatively smaller base of consumption of electricity only. 9 3.1 Impacts on the electricity sector The impacts of the wind power subsidy and mandate on total electricity generation in Brazil are presented in Figure 6. In the case of the subsidy, the policy basically increases the amount of electricity available at any price (an outward shift of the electricity supply curve). This causes the aggregate price of electricity to drop, thereby increasing electricity demand.5 To meet the increased demand more electricity would be generated. As can be seen from Figure 6, the subsidy to cause 10% penetration of wind power in Brazilian electricity system would lead to a 1% increase in total electricity generation. In the case of the mandate, the increased electricity cost, thereby increased electricity price due to expanded wind power is directly transferred to households. The increase in electricity price would decrease its demand. Figure 6 indicates that the expansion of wind power to meet 10% of the total electricity generation, would decrease total electricity demand by 1.5%. Figure 6: Impacts of wind power subsidy and mandate on total electricity generation 1.50 1.00 Change from BAU [%] 0.50 0.00 ‐0.50 ‐1.00 Subsidy ‐1.50 Mandate ‐2.00 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 Year Pushing wind power into the electricity generation mix through policy instruments means replacing electricity that would have been generated from other technologies, such as 5 There would be real income drop due to increased VAT to finance the subsidy, however this drop is distributed across the savings, and consumption of various goods and services. It could reduce the demand for electricity as well, but the effect of net drop in relative price of electricity is more than offsetting the demand loss due to increased VAT. 10 hydro, nuclear, coal, oil etc. Table 2 shows how the 10% penetration of wind power replaces other electricity generation from other technologies. The wind replaces 6.6% and 7.2% hydropower respectively under subsidy and mandate policy. The replacement rates are different between these two policy cases because the subsidy policy increases the total electricity generation, whereas the mandate policy decreases the total electricity generation. Similarly, the corresponding replacements of natural gas based generations are 1.8% and 1.4%. Table 2: Impacts of 10% penetration of wind power on electricity generation mix in 2030 Generation type Generation mix (% share of technologies on total generation) Baseline Subsidy Case Mandate Case Hydro  80.0  73.4  72.8  Coal  1.8  1.5  1.5  Natural gas  6.9  5.2  5.5  Oil  4.2  3.3  3.4  Wind  0.2  10.0  10.0  Biomass  4.1  4.1  4.2  Nuclear  2.8  2.5  2.5  3.2 Impacts on economic welfare Figure 7 illustrates the welfare impacts of meeting wind power targets in Brazil. Higher penetration of wind power causes a loss in economic welfare no matter whether a subsidy or mandate is used as policy instrument. This is because to reach the high share of wind power, it is necessary to realize wind projects that would not be economically viable without policy supports, and the policy supports are not cost free. The adverse welfare impacts of wind power expansion increases along with the share of wind power in the total electricity generation over time. Figure 7 illustrates that the welfare loss would higher in the case of consumption mandate. This is because the mandate directly impacts consumers through a notably increase in the electricity price. Consumers reduce their electricity consumption due to the price increase caused by higher penetration of wind power into the national electricity supply system under the mandate. In the case of production subsidy, in contrast, the adverse welfare impacts are smaller compared to that in the case of consumption mandate because the cost of the policy is covered by very small increases in the prices of goods and services in general through the 11 increase in VAT, rather than through a more significant increase in the price of one commodity (electricity).6 Figure 7: Impacts of expansion of wind power on economic welfare (% change from the baseline) 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 ‐0.07 Change from BAU [%] ‐0.08 Subsidy ‐0.09 Mandate ‐0.10 3.3 Impacts on GDP and sectoral value added Figure 8 presents impacts of 10% wind penetration to sectoral value added and GDP.7 The results vary significantly across the sectors. Moreover the sectoral impacts are much different between subsidy and mandate cases. A mandate to promote wind power expansion would reduce sectoral value added of energy sectors, most notably electricity and oil and gas. This is because the mandate makes electricity expensive thereby reducing its demand. In response electricity generation to meet the demand also drops. Fuel demand for electricity also decreases thereby lowering their production and thus value added. Although a production subsidy to wind power does not raise electricity price, it would still have regressive impacts in certain sectors. This is because, the wind power production subsidy is financed through an increase in value added tax in all other sectors. The value added tax would have negative implications in outputs of sectors which produce relatively higher value added per unit of 6 This finding recalls the general point from public finance theory that for a given level of total expenditure, deadweight loss is higher if the expenditure is financed with significant increases in taxes on a small number of goods versus smaller per-unit taxes on a larger number of goods (taking into account also the relative elasticities of demand of the various goods). See Parry (2003) for a discussion of this in the context of greenhouse gas mitigation instruments. 7 Like in any CGE study, we have presented the impacts as percentage change from the baseline. However, if any reader is interested to know the actual dollar value of the impacts, they are available upon request to authors. 12 output (i.e., capital and labor intensive sectors). As expected, sectors which supply goods and services to wind power industry would experience increased value added under both policy scenarios. Examples are construction, machinery industries, commercial services, wood and lumber, forestry. Figure 8: Change of sectoral activity and GDP relative to BAU in the year 2030 (%) GDP Other  service   mandate subsidy Transport service Commercial service Construction  Processed gas Electricity Other  manuf.  industry Machinery  Metal  Non metalic   Chemical  Biofuel  Other  petro products Diesel Gasoline Pulp paper  & furniture   Wood and lumber Textile  & leather   Coal mining Non energy mining  oil & gas Food & beverage   Livestock  Forestry Soybeans  Sugar  cane   Agricultural  ‐1.5 ‐1.2 ‐0.9 ‐0.6 ‐0.3 0 0.3 0.6 0.9 1.2 While aggregate consumption in the Brazilian economy goes down due to wind power policy, investment goes up. And policy induced changes in GDP, the sum of values of consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports, turn out to be driven mainly by changes in value of consumption and investment. On the one hand, the increase in the value of investments is bigger than the decrease in the value of consumption, leading to an increase in GDP for both policies in by 2030. On the other hand, we argued above that both the reduction 13 in consumption is smaller and the increase in investment bigger under a subsidy than under a mandate and thus the increase in GDP turns out to be bigger for the subsidy than for the mandate (see Figure 8). 3.4 Impacts on GHG emissions A 10% penetration of wind power in Brazil’s electricity generation mix would reduce 1.2% and 1.4% of total energy sector GHG emissions in the country in 2030 if the penetration was caused by mandate and subsidy policies, respectively. The mandate causes lower mitigation of GHG compared to the subsidy, as the mandate causes more replacement of hydro and less replacement of natural gas based electricity generation compared to the subsidy policy. Figure 9: Economy wide CO2 emissions reduction (percentage deviation from the baseline). 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 ‐0.7 ‐0.8 Subsidy Change from BAU [%] ‐0.9 Mandate ‐1.0 ‐1.1 ‐1.2 ‐1.3 ‐1.4 4. Conclusions Fiscal policies (subsidies in particular) and regulatory policies (particularly mandates) are the main instruments introduced in both developing and developed countries to encourage a large-scale deployment of renewable energy, such as wind power. Which policy instrument would be attractive from the broader economic perspective, however, has not been clearly 14 answered yet. This study aims to address this question in the case of wind power in the Brazilian electricity mix. The study shows that expansion of wind power would reduce economic welfare no matter whether a subsidy or a mandate is used to drive the expansion. This is because the cost of wind power generation is still expensive compared to most traditional sources of electricity generation in Brazil. However, we found that in Brazil, a subsidy causes lower welfare loss compared to the mandate to achieve the same level of wind power penetration. This is because the subsidy did not raise electricity prices but financed wind expansion through very small increases in consumer prices throughout the economy, whereas the mandate did lead to a considerable increase in the price of electricity. Since the subsidy causes less welfare loss compared to the mandate and it also causes higher reduction of GHG emissions than a mandate does, the study concludes that subsidy policy is superior to mandate for Brazil’s efforts in promoting renewable energy. Although this finding is consistent with general principles in public finance and with findings in other studies of renewable energy policy (e.g., McCullough et al. 2011; Timilsina and Landis, 2014), it should not be generalized because the results from CGE models are country specific: particular parameters, such as those reflecting electricity supply mix, and elasticity of substitution, can be significantly different across countries. The sectoral results are different not only between the two policy instruments but across the sectors for a given policy instrument. Sectoral value added of fossil fuel industries decreased under both policy instruments whereas the value added of industries providing goods and services to wind power industry increased. The decrease in value added of fossil fuel industries is higher under subsidies compared to those with the mandate due to tax imposed on fossil fuels to generate a fund to finance the subsidy. The analysis is carried out based on present (2012) data on electricity supply costs of various technologies to generate electricity. The capital costs of renewable energy technologies, including wind power technologies, have declined over time in the past. However, it is difficult to predict how far the cost reduction will go and when wind power technologies would be economically competitive with traditional sources of electricity generation. Even if they are competitive in terms of the levelized costs of electricity generation, utility planners still discount wind and solar because these are intermittent 15 resources to generate electricity and do not provide a firm power or capacity guarantee, which is essential to have a reliable electricity supply system. References Böhringer, C. and A. Löschel (2006). Promoting Renewable Energy in Europe: A Hybrid Computable General Equilibrium Approach, The Energy Journal, Vol. 27, Special Issue: Hybrid Modeling of Energy-Environment Policies: Reconciling Bottom-up and Top-down, pp. 135-150. Chen, H. and G. R. Timilsina (2012). Economic implications of reducing carbon emissions from energy use and industrial processes in Brazil. Policy Research Working Paper, World Bank, (WPS6135), World Bank, Washington, DC. França, V.C.L (2011). Challenges for the optimal uses of wind power in Brazil, Joint Report of George Washington University and Institute of Brazilian Business and Public Management, available at http://www.aneel.gov.br/biblioteca/trabalhos/trabalhos/Artigo_Vitor_Franca.pdf Global Wind Energy Council (GWEC), 2014. Annual market update 2013: Global Wind Report, GWEC, Brussels. Hertel, Thomas W.; Tyner, Wallace E.; Birur, Dileep K. (2010). The Global Impacts of Biofuel Mandates. Energy Journal 31 (1): 75-100. International Energy Agency (IEA). 2014a. Electricity Information 2014. IEA, Paris. International Energy Agency (IEA). 2014b. CO2 Emissions from Fossil Fuel Consumption. IEA, Paris. International Energy Agency, OECD, and Nuclear Energy Agency. 2010. Projected Costs of Generating Electricity, OECD, Paris. McCullough, M., D. Holland, K. Painter, L. Stodick, and J. Yoder (2011). Economic and Environmental Impacts of Washington State Biofuel Policy Alternatives, Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 36(3):615–629 Paltsev, S., J. M. Reilly, H. D. Jacoby, R. S. Eckaus, J. McFarland, M. Sarofim, M. Asadoorian and M. Babiker (2005). The MIT Emissions Prediction and Policy Analysis (EPPA) Model: Version 4. Report No. 125, MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change, Cambridge MA, USA. Parry, I. (2003). Fiscal interactions and the case for carbon taxes over grandfathered carbon permits, Oxford Review of Economic Policy 19 (3): 385-399. Rana, A. (2003). Evaluation of a renewable energy scenario for economic and CO2 mitigation effects, RURDS 15(1): 45-54. Renewable Energy Network for 21st Century (REN21), 2014. Renewables 2014: Global Status Report, REN21, Paris. 16 Sorda, G. and M. Banse (2011). The Response of the German Agricultural Sector to the Envisaged Biofuel Targets in Germany and Abroad: A CGE Simulation. German Journal of Agricultural Economics 60 (4): 243-58. Timilsina, G. R., and Landis, F. 2014. Economics of transiting to renewable energy in Morocco: a general equilibrium analysis. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 6940. Timilsina, Govinda R.; Beghin, John C.; van der Mensbrugghe, Dominique; Mevel, Simon (2012), The Impacts of Biofuels Targets on Land-Use Change and Food Supply: A Global CGE Assessment, Agricultural Economics 43 (3): 315-32. 17