39250 Caucasian The Tiger S U S TA I N I N G E C O N O M I C G R O W T H I N A R M E N I A Saumya Mitra Douglas Andrew Gohar Gyulumyan Paul Holden Bart Kaminski Yevgeny Kuznetsov EkaterineVashakmadze The Caucasian Tiger Sustaining Economic Growth in Armenia The Caucasian Tiger Sustaining Economic Growth in Armenia Saumya Mitra Douglas Andrew Gohar Gyulumyan Paul Holden Bart Kaminski Yevgeny Kuznetsov Ekaterine Vashakmadze © 2007 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street, NW Washington, DC 20433 Telephone 202-473-1000 Internet www.worldbank.org E-mail feedback@worldbank.org All rights reserved. 1 2 3 4 5 10 09 08 07 The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Board of Executive Direc- tors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of the World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Rights and Permissions The material in this work is copyrighted. Copying and/or transmitting portions or all of this work without permission may be a violation of applicable law. The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and will normally grant per- mission promptly. For permission to photocopy or reprint any part of this work, please send a request with complete information to the Copyright Clearance Center, Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA, telephone 978-750-8400, fax 978-750- 4470, www.copyright.com. All other queries on rights and licenses, including subsidiary rights, should be addressed to the Office of the Publisher, World Bank, 1818 H Street, NW, Washing- ton, DC 20433, USA; fax 202-522-2422; e-mail pubrights@worldbank.org. Cover design: Drew Fasick, Serif Design Group Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data The Caucasian tiger : sustaining economic growth in Armenia / Saumya Mitra . . . [et al.]. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN-13: 978-0-8213-6811-4 ISBN-10: 0-8213-6811-7 ISBN-13: 978-0-8213-6812-1 (electronic) 1. Armenia (Republic)--Economic conditions--1991- 2. Armenia (Republic)--Economic policy--1991- 3. Investments--Armenia (Republic) 4. Industrial policy--Armenia (Republic) I. Mitra, Saumya, 1951- HC415.17.C28 2007 330.94756--dc22 2007007772 Contents Preface xvii Introduction xix Acronyms and Abbreviations xxxi Part I Policies to Sustain Economic Growth 1 Chapter 1 The Pattern of Growth 3 Chapter 2 Constraints to Sustained Growth 33 Chapter 3 The Framework for Competition 47 Chapter 4 Finance as a Barrier to Accumulation 75 Chapter 5 Impediments to International Integration 93 Chapter 6 Knowledge and Innovation 117 Part II Detailed Analysis 145 Chapter 7 Growth Analysis from the Perspective of Employment Generation and Poverty Reduction 147 Chapter 8 A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 193 Chapter 9 Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 243 Chapter 10 Strengthening Competition 283 Chapter 11 Real and Formal Ease of Doing Business in Armenia in Comparative Perspective: Implications for Regulatory Reforms 329 vi Contents Chapter 12 Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 349 Chapter 13 Civil Aviation Policy 413 Chapter 14 Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 489 References 581 Tables Table 1 Key Policy Recommendations xxvi Table 1.1 Armenia's External Debt Burden Indicators 17 Table 1.2 Armenia's Poverty Indicators, 1999­2004 21 Table 1.3 Armenia: Growth and Inequality Decomposition of Changes in Poverty Incidence between 1998­99 and 2004 24 Table 2.1 Progress with Second-Generation Reform, 1994­2004 43 Table 3.1 Selected Indicators of the Quality of Governance, 1998­2004 48 Table 3.2 Values of CPIs for Selected Countries and Groups, 1999­2000 and 2002­04 51 Table 3.3 Relative Ease of Doing Business in CIS and CEEC-10 Economies, 2005 53 Table 3.4 The Size of the Informal Economy and the "Revealed" Ease of Doing Business 56 Table 3.5 Doing Business in Armenia and Selected Comparators in 2004 58 Table 4.1 Financial Indicators in Selected Countries 76 Table 4.2 Bank Concentration Indicator, 2000­04 77 Table 4.3 Decomposition of Interest Rate Spreads, 1999­2004 78 Table 5.1 Average Applied and Bond MFN Tariff Rates in Selected Countries 96 Table 5.2 Telecommunications Sector Overview 104 Table 5.3 Percentage of Households with Access to a Telephone 105 Table 5.4 Basic Telecommunications Infrastructure Benchmarks 106 Table 5.5 Internet Benchmarks 107 Table 5.6 Phased Civil Aviation Reform 113 Table 6.1 The Size of the Shadow Economy 124 Table 6.2 Sequencing of the Armenia KE Policy Agenda 131 Contents vii Table 6.3 Specific Policy Initiatives as Entry Points to Address Systemic Constraints 135 Table 6.4 Matching Policies to Capabilities: A Range of Instruments to Support Innovation 137 Table 7.1 Sources of GDP Growth in Armenia by Sector 148 Table 7.2 Sources of Exports in Armenia, 2002, by Sector 151 Table 7.3 Armenia: Revealed Comparative Advantage, 2003 152 Table 7.4 Direct and Indirect Multipliers 166 Table 7.5 Armenian Economy, Sectoral Structure Depicted by SAM 168 Table 7.6 Sources of Employment in Armenia: Distribution by Sector, 2002 170 Table 7.7 Tables Generated Using the 2002 SAM-based Model for Armenia 176 Table 7.8 Simulation Assuming Export Diversification 178 Table 7.9 An Alternate Approach That Does Not Rely on Export Growth 179 Table 7A.1.1 Effect of a (­50%) Shock on Diamonds 183 Table 7A.1.2 Effect of a (­30%) Shock on Construction 183 Table 7A.1.3 Effect of a (­5.5%) Shock on Remittances 184 Table 7A.1.4 Effect of a (+US$135 million) Combined Shock Based on Relative Export Shares 184 Table 7A.1.5 Effect of a (+10% = US$91 million) Positive Shock in Agriculture 184 Table 7A.1.6 Effect of a (+10% = US$241 million) Positive Shock in Manufacturing and Industry, except Minerals and Mining 185 Table 7A.3.1 Selected Labor Indicator Definitions 191 Table 8.1 Aggregate Social Accounts for Armenia, 2002 196 Table 8.2 Replication of Selected National Accounts Measures by the Macro SAM 197 Table 8.3 Structure of the Disaggregated (micro) SAM for Armenia, 2002 198 Table 8.4 Detailed Sector Descriptions for Each Industry in the 2002 Armenian micro SAM 199 Table 8.5 Armenian Production Statistics by Sector, 2002 202 Table 8.6 Value Added in Production for Armenia, 2002 203 Table 8.7 Tax Payments by Sector in Armenia, 2002 204 Table 8.8 Total Commodity Supply and Component Demand by Consumer, 2002 206 Table 8.9 Household Income by Factor, 2002 209 Table 8.10 Final Demand Disaggregated by Household Type and Commodity, 2002 210 viii Contents Table 8.11 Consumption and Income for Rural Household Decile No. 4 213 Table 8A.1.1 Input Tables Required for the Structured Approach to SAM Development 223 Table 8A.1.2 Input Table #1: Sectoral Production and Trade Values for Armenia, 2002 224 Table 8A.1.3 Input Table #2: 2002 Collected Taxes by Sector and Tax Stream 225 Table 8A.1.4 Input Table #3: Production Technology Structure for Armenia 226 Table 8A.1.5 Input Table #4: Value Added and Consumption Shares 227 Table 8A.1.6 Symbol Table 228 Table 8A.1.7 Mapping GTAP V5 Sectors onto 2002 Armenian SAM Sectors 232 Table 8A.1.8 Mapping of Armenian Output Statistics to SAM Sectors 236 Table 8A.1.9 Mapping GTAP V5 Sectors onto 2002 Armenian SAM Sectors 237 Table 9.1 Economic Sectors in the Armenian Model 255 Table 9.2 Base-Year Production and Trade Statistics by Sector for Armenia, 2002 256 Table 9.3 Benchmark Import Statistics for Armenia, 2002 257 Table 9.4 Export Statistics for Armenia, 2002 258 Table 9.5 Sectoral Value Added, Ranked by Labor Intensity 259 Table 9.6 Estimated Level of Underground and Informal Activity 260 Table 9.7 Armenian Tax Collections, 2002 (by source) 262 Table 9.8 Benchmark Tax Collections, 2002 by Production Sector 263 Table 9.9 Cost of Raising 0.5% GDP (US$15 million) in Tax Revenues: A Comparison of Tax Bases 264 Table 9.10 Indices of Informality and the Average Cost of Funds 265 Table 9.11 Revenue and Welfare Impacts of Selected Tax Reforms 266 Table 9.12 Sensitivity Analysis for the Cost of Raising 0.5% of GDP 268 Table 9A.1.1 Origin of Each Variable 274 Table 9A.1.2 External Data Sources 275 Table 9A.1.3 Production Technology Structure for Armenia 276 Table 10.1 Business Formation Indicators, 2001­04 285 Table 10.2 Employment Indicators, 2001­04 286 Contents ix Table 10.3 Average Earnings Indicators, 2001­04 286 Table 10.4 Gross Value Added Indicators, 2001­04 287 Table 10.5 Foreign Exchange Rate Comparisons, 2001­04 288 Table 10.6 Percentage Share of Different Modes of Transportation, 1999­2003 295 Table 10.7 Internal Freight in Volumes and Percentage Shares, 1999­2003 296 Table 10.8 Welfare Calculations in the Petroleum Market, 1999­2001 302 Table 10.9 Sugar Market Data, 1999­2002 304 Table 11.1 Ranking of CIS and CEEC-10 Economies by Ease of Doing Business in 2005 333 Table 11.2 Size of the Informal Economy and "Revealed" Ease of Doing Business 337 Table 11.3 Doing Business in Armenia and Selected Comparators, 2004 340 Table 12.1 CIS: Total Exports, Export Growth, and Share of Exports in GDP, 1999­2003 353 Table 12.2 Trade in Services by Mode of Supply, 1999­2003 358 Table 12.3 Recipients of Armenia's Exports, 2000­04 364 Table 12.4 Sector Concentration of Exports in Selected Transition Economies, 2003 365 Table 12.5 Factor Intensities of Armenian Trade in 1997, 2000, and 2003 366 Table 12.6 FDI Inflows Compared, 1995­2003 370 Table 12.7 Receipt of FDI Inflows by Sector, 1998­2003 373 Table 12.8 Progress of Structural Reform in Armenia and Lithuania, 1994­2004 378 Table 12.9 Correlation of FDI (1990­2003) and SRI (1999­2003) 382 Table 12.10 Formal Barriers to Doing Business in Armenia, 2003 and 2005 386 Table 12.11 Average Applied and Bound MFN Tariff Rates in Selected Countries 388 Table 12.12 Indicators of Telecommunications Penetration in Armenia and Other CIS Countries, 1998­2003 394 Table 12.13 Ratio of Transportation Costs to Trade, 1998­2003 397 Table 13.1 Zvartnots' Airport Freight Volumes, 1997­2004 418 Table 13.2 Comparative Yerevan-EU Air Fares 421 Table 13.3 Passenger Throughput, Riga Airport, 1990­2005 465 Table 13.4 Czech Airline Data, 1999­2003 467 x Contents Table 13.5 Weekly Frequencies of Air Services Offered 471 Table 13.6 Market Shares 472 Table 13A.1.1 Key Findings, LHR Only 483 Table 13A.1.2 Key Findings, 8 EU Cities 483 Table 14.1 Sequencing of the Armenia KE Policy Agenda 493 Table 14.2 Specific Policy Initiatives as Entry Points to Address Systemic Constraints 495 Table 14.3 Gross Domestic Product by Sector, 1998­2003 500 Table 14.4 Sector Contributions to Export Growth, 2000­02 500 Table 14.5 Countries That Have Successfully Aligned Key Drivers of Growth and Developed Innovation Clusters 503 Table 14.6 Countries with Obstacles to Aligning Key Drivers of Growth 504 Table 14.7 Exports of Goods and Services, 1995­2002 515 Table 14.8 The Size of the Shadow Economy 515 Table 14.9 Key Innovation Indicators, 1997­2002 519 Table 14.10 Interest Rate Spread, 1996­2002: Armenia and Comparators 520 Table 14.11 Sequencing of the Armenia KE Policy Agenda 528 Table 14.12 Specific Policy Initiatives as Entry Points to Address Systemic Constraints 530 Table 14.13 Matching Policies to Capabilities: A Range of Instruments to Support Innovation 533 Table 14.14 FDI Incentives in Armenia versus Comparator Countries 557 Table 14A.1.1 Annual Growth Rates of Total Factor Productivity 564 Table 14A.3.1 Gross Capital Formation, 1995­2002 569 Table 14A.3.2 Performance--Economic Regime Variables 570 Table 14A.3.3 Governance Variables 571 Table 14A.3.4 Innovation Systems Variables 572 Table 14A.3.5 Education Variables 573 Table 14A.3.6 ICT Variables 574 Figures Figure 1.1 Official Development Assistance, Cumulative, 1992­2003 4 Figure 1.2 ECA Countries, Income per Capita and Employment in Agriculture, 2003 5 Figure 1.3 Index of Real GDP, 1990­2005 7 Figure 1.4 GDP Growth Rate, 1996­2006 7 Contents xi Figure 1.5 GDP Growth and Contribution of Expenditure to GDP, 1996­2005 8 Figure 1.6 Evolution of REER, Trade Balance, and Current Account Balance, 1999­2005 8 Figure 1.7 Relative Productivity Level and Productivity Growth Rate, Latest Data 9 Figure 1.8 Relative Unit Labor Cost Index, 1997­2004 10 Figure 1.9 REER Quarterly Increase, Indicating Appreciation 12 Figure 1.10 Key Economic Indicators of External Performance, 1998­2005 13 Figure 1.11 Savings and Investment Balance, 1994­2005 14 Figure 1.12 Gross Domestic Savings and Gross National Savings, 2004 15 Figure 1.13 Sectoral Shares in GDP and Investment by Sectors, Average, 1999­2005 16 Figure 1.14 Indicators of Public and Publicly Guaranteed External Debt under Alternative Scenarios, 2005­25 18 Figure 1.15 Growth Incidence Curves, 1998/99­2004 22 Figure 1.16 Participation, Employment, and Unemployment Rates in Urban and Rural Areas (population aged 15 and older) 26 Figure 1.17 Change in Sector Prices, Nominal Value- Added Deflator 27 Figure 1.18 Nonagricultural Jobs in the Productive State and Private Sectors, 1998­2003 28 Figure 1.19 Relative Labor Productivity by Sector 30 Figure 2.1 Progress in First-Generation Reforms as Revealed in Values of the EBRD-Based Aggregate Index in 1992­2004 in Selected Transition Economies 38 Figure 2.2 Challenge of Sustaining and Diversifying Sources of Growth toward Those with Stronger Spillover Effects 39 Figure 2.3 Progress in Structural Reforms: Values of SRI, 1994­2004 41 Figure 3.1 Aggregate Quality of Governance, 1998­2004 49 Figure 3.2 The Average of Government Effectiveness and Regulatory Quality, 1998­2004 50 Figure 3.3 Gasoline Price Structure for the Period 1999­2001 68 Figure 5.1 Armenian Exports, 1997­2004 94 xii Contents Figure 6.1 Armenia and the World: Knowledge Economy Index 119 Figure 6.2 Armenia: Performance in the Four Knowledge Economy Pillars, 1995­Most Recent 121 Figure 6.3 Armenia Knowledge Economy Index Scorecard 121 Figure 6.4 Economic Incentive Regime: Armenia and the World 122 Figure 6.5 Armenia's Scorecard in the Economic Incentive Regime 123 Figure 6.6 Education: Armenia and the World 125 Figure 6.7 Armenia's Scorecard on Education 125 Figure 6.8 Innovation: Armenia and the World 126 Figure 6.9 Armenia's Scorecard in Innovation 127 Figure 6.10 ICT: Armenia and the World 127 Figure 6.11 Armenia's Scorecard in ICT Variables 128 Figure 6.12 Virtuous Circle of Growth and Reforms 133 Figure 6.13 The Pyramid of Learning Capabilities of Firms 136 Figure 7.1 Armenia and the Slovak Republic, Employment by Sectors, 1994­2004 148 Figure 7.2 Sectoral Shares in GDP and Investments 149 Figure 7.3 Matrix: Classification of Armenian Exports by Composition and Destination, 2003 153 Figure 7.4 Real Growth and Factors of Production, 1997­2004 157 Figure 7.5 Real Wage Growth and Productivity Growth, Unit Labor Cost, 1998­2004 158 Figure 7.6 Labor Productivity by Sector 159 Figure 8.1 Expansion from a Single RA to Multiple Households 208 Figure 8.2 Impact of Increased Wages or Lower Food Prices on Poverty for Rural Decile No. 4 214 Figure 8A.1 Simplified Structure of SAM Development Process 223 Figure 9.1 Armenian Production Structure for Formal and Informal Activities 249 Figure 9.2 Demand for Formal and Informal Goods 252 Figure 9A.1.1 Armenian Agricultural Accounts for 2002 278 Figure 9A.1.2 Industrial Production Shares According to the National Statistical Service 279 Figure 9A.1.3 Official Armenian National Production Statistics for 2002 280 Figure 10.1 Business Competitiveness Indicators for Selected Sectors 287 Contents xiii Figure 10.2 Gasoline Price Structure, 1999­2001 303 Figure 10.3 Sugar Price Decomposition 303 Figure 10.4 Interest Rate Spreads 310 Figure 10.5 Domestic Credit to the Private Sector 311 Figure 12.1 Dynamics of Exports of Goods and Services and GDP and Change in Exports and Imports as Percent of GDP, 1998­2003 355 Figure 12.2 Exports of Diamonds and Other Products, 1997­2004 361 Figure 12.3 Privatization and FDI Inflows, 1998­2004 372 Figure 12.4 Progress in Structural Reforms: Values of SRI, 1994­2004 377 Figure 12.5 Total FDI Inflows per Capita and SRI, 1999­2003 381 Figure 12.6 Quality of Infrastructure in Armenia against Georgia, the CEEC-8, and Highly Developed Countries 391 Figure 13.1 Zvartnots' Airport Passenger Volumes, 1990­2005 419 Figure 13A.1.1 Average Fare 485 Figure 13A.1.2 Yield by Distance 485 Figure 14.1 Armenia and the World: KEI 509 Figure 14.2 Armenia and Comparators: Disaggregated Performance in the KE 511 Figure 14.3 Armenia: Performance in the Four KE Pillars 511 Figure 14.4 Armenia KE Index Variables, Basic Scorecard 512 Figure 14.5 Economic Incentive Regime: Armenia and the World 513 Figure 14.6 Armenia's Scorecard in the EIR 514 Figure 14.7 Education: Armenia and the World 516 Figure 14.8 Armenia's Scorecard on Education 517 Figure 14.9 Innovation: Armenia and the World 517 Figure 14.10 Armenia's Scorecard on Innovation 518 Figure 14.11 ICT: Armenia and the World 520 Figure 14.12 Armenia's Scorecard on ICT Variables 521 Figure 14.13 Armenia: Real GDP per Capita: Alternative Projections, 2003­20 522 Figure 14.14 Virtuous Circle of Growth and Reforms 529 Figure 14.15 The Pyramid of the Learning Capabilities of Firms 532 Figure 14.16 Comparative Performance of Armenia's ICT Infrastructure 535 Figure 14A.4.1 Armenia and ECA 575 xiv Contents Figure 14A.4.2 Armenia and Latvia 575 Figure 14A.4.3 Armenia and Slovenia 576 Figure 14A.4.4 Armenia and Russia 576 Figure 14A.4.5 Armenia and Israel 577 Figure 14A.4.6 Armenia and Chile 577 Figure 14A.4.7 Armenia and Costa Rica 578 Figure 14A.4.8 Armenia and Ireland 578 Boxes Box 2.1 Armenia--Production Statistics by Sector 36 Box 2.2 Gains from the Liberalization of the Services Sectors 44 Box 3.1 The Petroleum Distribution Market 69 Box 4.1 Priorities in Reform of Financial and Capital Markets 80 Box 6.1 Korea's Transition to a KE: Bottom-up Initiative Leads to Government Action 130 Box 6.2 Distance Learning as a Potential Pilot Project to Enhance Education-Industry Linkages 142 Box 7.1 Reconciliation of National Accounts and the Household Survey Data 155 Box 7.2 Linkages in the Model Based on the Social Accounting Matrix 163 Box 7.3 Information and Communications Technology Sector 180 Box 10.1 Noncompetitive Behavior in the Gasoline Market 301 Box 10.2 Anti-Competitive Practices of the Customs Office 306 Box 12.1 Lycos Armenia on the Move 359 Box 13.1 Armenian Aviation Market Entry Restrictions 415 Box 13.2 Case Studies: Additional Liberalization Experiences 428 Box 13.3 Economic Benefits of Liberalization: An Illustrative Calculation 429 Box 13A.1.1 Sequence of Data in Excel File 481 Box 13A.1.2 Impact of Ryanair on the Market 484 Box 14.1 The Growing Importance of Knowledge: Global Trends 505 Box 14.2 The Four Pillars of the KE 508 Box 14.3 Armenia' Growth Paradox, Illustrated by Private Companies 523 Contents xv Box 14.4 Korea's Transition to a KE: Bottom-up Initiative Leads to Government Action 526 Box 14.5 Distance Learning as a Potential Pilot Project to Enhance Education-Industry Linkages 539 Box 14.6 Toward a National System of Support for Continuous Vocational Training 540 Box 14.7 The Fundación Chile Model and Its Relevance for Armenia 541 Box 14.8 Clusters and Value Chains 543 Box 14.9 Private Universities in Turkey and the Turkish Diaspora of the Highly Skilled 552 Box 14.10 Toward a New Type of Diaspora Involvement in Armenia's Economy: Lessons of the University Alumni Model 553 Preface This book is the result of work carried out by the World Bank's eco- nomic team charged with providing analysis and policy advice to the Armenian government in the years 2005­6. These were years in which Armenia had established a decade-long solid record of sustained eco- nomic growth amid conditions of economic stability, low inflation, and modest fiscal deficits and external debt. For an economy that had endured a collapse of economic output and hyperinflation in its imme- diate post-Soviet period, this was a signal achievement, particularly when it is noted that the country is poorly endowed with natural resources, and its two major borders have been closed by its neighbors to trade and labor movement since its independence. The attribution for the emergence of Armenia as the Caucasian Tiger lies in the creation of an environment of macroeconomic stability and the determined pursuit of reforms aimed at establishing a market economy that was integrated with the world. This book describes that story. But the central focus of the book remains the reform agenda for the future. It is argued that the continuation of high rates of growth would require building defenses against economic shocks the country may face, and this would entail addressing the key vulnerabilities in today's economy. Thus the book is intended not only as a case study of success in post-Soviet economic transition, but also as a candid piece of policy advice for the Armenian authorities. This book was written by a team headed by Saumya Mitra and consisting of Doug Andrew, Gohar Gyulumyan, Paul Holden, Bart Kaminski, Yevgeny Kuznetsov, and Ekaterine Vashakmadze. It utilizes the contributions of Reza Ghasimi, Karen Grigorian, Armine Khacha- tryan, Artsvi Khachatryan, Matin Kholmatov, Miles Light, Gareth Locksley, Stephen Miller, Thomas Rutherford, Sue Rutledge, Vahe Sahakyan, Eduardo Siandra, and Michel Zarnowiecki. Comments from Shahrokh Fardoust, Felipe Jaramillo, Samuel Otoo, Christian Petersen, Roger Robinson, and Roberto Zagha are gratefully acknowledged. The xvii xviii Preface book has benefited from close cooperation with the IMF team, headed by Hassan Al-Atrash, working on Armenia. It was processed by Zakia Nekaien-Nowrouz. The authors are particularly grateful to Donna Dowsett-Coirolo and Cheryl Gray for their judicious guidance and steadfast support for this work. The authors are also indebted to the Armenian economic team headed by Vardan Khachatryan, minister of finance, for its many valuable observations on the analysis contained in this book. The book draws on sector-specific studies that have been carried out by colleagues at the World Bank; in particular, the study on pov- erty assessment (World Bank 2006), prepared by a team headed by Alexandra Posarac, and the study on the financial sector assessment program (World Bank and International Monetary Fund 2005c), pre- pared by a team headed by Hormoz Aghdaey. The responsibility for the text is entirely that of the authors. Introduction T his book is intended to explain the factors underlying the stellar growth record that has led to Armenia's emergence as the Cauca- sian Tiger and to provide policy advice to the Armenian authorities to ensure the continuation of this growth. The book is presented in two parts, with Part I containing the analysis and the policy advice and Part II containing detailed background papers. In Part I, Chapter 1 sketches the pattern of growth, indicates the opportunities for broad- ening growth and establishes linkages to employment and poverty. Chapter 2 examines the record of reform and the principal constraints to growth in the future, using a growth diagnostics framework being piloted in the World Bank and making use of comparisons with the experiences of more advanced post-transition reformers. Chapters 3­6 investigate the key opportunities for reform: strengthening the framework for competition, lowering the costs of financial interme- diation, developing policies that will deepen the integration of the economy into global markets, and creating the conditions for building on knowledge assets and promoting innovation. GROWTH, POVERTY, AND EMPLOYMENT Over the past half-decade the Armenian economy has grown by double- digit rates annually on average--reminiscent of the east Asian tiger economies--and high growth rates have been registered for over a dec- ade. This impressively consistent performance can be attributed to the steadfast pursuit of market-oriented reforms, assisted by large external inflows on grant or soft terms. Nevertheless, Armenia remains poor, with income per head at around US$2,100 today or about a third of that in the Baltics. Growth has now begun to make a significant dent in poverty, but its impact on employment has been muted. This book will examine the reasons for the weak transmission link to employment and xix xx Introduction will suggest policy reforms. It will discuss the major sources of risk to the continuation of high growth and will outline the policy adaptations necessary to place growth on firmer foundations. To meet the aspira- tions of the public, economic policies will have to be designed to max- imize the prospects for growth; and, thus, impediments to growth will have to be addressed early and vigorously. Armenia was quick to recover from the output shock experienced by transition economies: its upturn in output, dating from 1994, cor- responds to the experience of Central Europe and the Baltic States and predates by four to five years the recovery in the rest of the former Soviet Union (FSU). Growth has been driven by productivity gains in the private sector as macroeconomic stability took hold; the role of private markets was rapidly expanded; the public sector remained small as a share of the total economy; and important institutional measures were adopted to ensure free price formation, liberal trade in goods services and investment, private ownership of assets (including land), and industrial restructuring. Moreover, the adoption of respon- sible fiscal and monetary policies in the late 1990s led to the defeat of inflation and to predictability in the stance of financial policies. Thus, first-generation structural and institutional reforms were achieved and have laid the foundations of the impressive growth performance. The recent period of growth has resulted in a sharp rise in the consumption of the poor. The poorer quintiles of the income distri- bution have gained more from growth than the richer quintiles, with the extremely poor showing the greatest gain. Overall poverty fell from over half to one-third of the population between 1998 and 2004 and extreme poverty fell from over 20 percent to just 6 percent of the population over the same period. The reduction in poverty has been driven by consumption growth rather than by redistribution effects. The capital city of Yerevan has reaped large dividends from the fall in poverty, with other urban areas benefiting to a much lesser degree. Despite the impressive GDP growth, unemployment, according to survey data, stands at around one-fifth of the labor force; and a dual labor market has emerged with large underemployment or subsist- ence employment coexisting with a more skilled labor force that has enjoyed large real wage gains in expanding sectors of the economy. The causes of the weak response of employment to investment and growth lie in a business climate that has discouraged the flexible use of labor and in inadequate skills among the unemployed. Address- ing the binding constraints to the formation and expansion of firms remains central to raising employment. More broadly, this book argues that the incompleteness of structural reforms and inadequacies in the development of institutions and practices that encourage competition are factors leading to the persistence of unemployment. Introduction xxi This book suggests that the continuation of high rates of productiv- ity gains in the economy requires Armenia to make use of new oppor- tunities in reforms directed at sharpening the competition framework of the economy, achieving closer integration with international trade and capital markets, deepening financial markets, and creating the conditions for the absorption of knowledge leading to higher tech- nological sophistication. Should the country fail to seize the oppor- tunities to advance in this second generation of reforms and to over- come the associated institutional and political difficulties, high rates of growth over the next decade would be put at risk. Growth remains narrowly based, despite some widening of the base in recent years, exports remain concentrated by product and markets, significant bar- riers to domestic and private investment remain within a context of a weak competition framework and high policy-induced costs, and the country has made poor use of opportunities for knowledge and innovation. All these factors make up constraints to growth over the medium term. The challenge to policy makers now lies in seizing the opportunities for reform by breaking through these constraints and capitalizing on the solid reform achievements thus far. SEIZING NEW OPPORTUNITIES FOR REFORM As experience has repeatedly shown--not least among the south- east Asian tigers--rapid growth over prolonged periods can conceal underlying weaknesses in an economy and can lull policy makers into complacency. Armenia has begun to address the second generation of reforms somewhat fitfully. Utility reform and privatization have proceeded, and some improvements to the business environment have been made; however, a primitive state of corporate governance, poor property rights enforcement, arbitrary practices in the tax and cus- toms administrations, the distortions associated with corruption, and stunted financial markets all act to impose a large risk premium on investment. Surveys conducted over a number of years and using varying methodologies provide robust evidence of the importance of these factors in inhibiting business. Policy shortcomings in the tele- communications and civil aviation regimes in particular effectively levy a large tax on all economic activities. This environment of weak second-generation reforms has resulted in a dualistic output market (parallel to the dual labor markets), in which entrepreneurs enjoying property rights protection, benefiting from distortions in tax and cus- toms practices, and having recourse to internal financing, gain from being incumbents, while potential entrants to the market are placed at a disadvantage. xxii Introduction The policy adaptations discussed above are also essential to deal- ing with the weak response of employment to high rates of economic growth in Armenia. The initial output and price shocks of transition led to a shift of labor to subsistence agriculture and to the develop- ment of a large informal economy. Macroeconomic stability, privatiza- tion, and enterprise restructuring have promoted flexibility in labor markets, but deficiencies in the business environment, some rigidities in the employment regime, and inadequate financial markets have led to a dual labor market: there is a market of real wages that are rising on the strength of impressive productivity gains, and another market (a larger one) which is informal, stagnant, and immobile. This book can be seen as an attempt to analyze the policy responses necessary to make the growth in rates of employment commensurate with output growth. Investment has been financed to a disproportionate degree from external sources, though the domestic share of investment financing has been rising in recent years. The opportunity offered by a further bout of external grant financing over the medium term, with Armenia qualifying for a large increase in U.S. bilateral assistance in the form of the Millennium Challenge Corporation, can prove a prize if the policy environment is reformed so as to deal with the weaknesses outlined above; or it can be a curse if, in a weak policy setting, private invest- ment is crowded out and excessive consumption or nonsustainable public investment is encouraged. Again, as experience shows, under conditions of grant inflows, the pursuit of reforms can become more difficult and the quality of growth can often be sacrificed. This under- scores the importance of redoubling reform efforts in a farsighted manner in order to position the economy for the time when external support will dwindle. The rest of the book focuses on how to make the best use of this window of plentiful external funds. SHARPENING COMPETITION Within the Armenian economy, competition is hobbled by weaknesses in the law and its application (as with the competition law and the law on contracts) in formal and informal institutions and their workings (such as corporate governance arrangements); by business regulations and governance rules and practices (such as arbitrary and unpredict- able behavior of the tax and customs administrations); and by policy- induced high costs that fall on the shoulders of all enterprises (such as telecommunications and transport costs). The competition law, a recent innovation, needs to be strengthened in both structure and implemen- tation, notably by clarifying what is meant by collusive behavior and Introduction xxiii dominant market practices, and by modernizing the basis for judging pricing practices. Implementation is bedeviled by a weak commission and by the inadequate legal powers of the commission. The commer- cial transactions law offers insufficient safeguards, with the result that contracts tend to be informal. Equally worrisome is the state of corporate governance, where laws, regulations, and institutions are particularly weak. Regarding several key transparency issues--notably public access to company registries and lists of founders and shareholders--Armenia is among the weak- est of the CIS countries. The quality of corporate financial reporting also remains deficient. Moreover, while the securities law has some weaknesses, the greatest corporate governance deficiencies are found in the company law and other basic legislation affecting the corporate sector. Weak corporate governance practices reinforce the dominant position of a limited number of businessmen and undermine investor confidence. Furthermore, informal barriers to competition--such as the system of interlocking obligations arising from favors and inter- ventions among businessmen--act as a substantial barrier to entry for foreign investors as well as for new local businesses. Despite satisfactory indicators in a number of categories measuring the ease of doing business (such as ease of formal entry, hiring employ- ees, and business exit), Armenia falls short in other areas, the weakest of which are the registration of property, access to credit, property rights, and large severance payments (at least until the recent reform of the Labor Code, now being put into effect). Overall, however, even in the most streamlined and reformed areas, the level is well below the best practices in transition economies. In addition, Armenia has a large informal economy, with the main incentives to informality being the arbitrary behavior of public servants, the burden of administrative regulation, and a poor record in establishing the rule of law. Absent in Armenia is a major attraction of formality--the access to credit for which formal registration is a precondition. Such constraints to enterprise activity have implications for effi- ciency and also carry growth costs. The weaknesses in market insti- tutions act as a barrier to the development of financial markets, and, in turn, this leads to the dominance of the incumbent in markets. Financial intermediation is shallow, and the cost of funds is high. DEEPENING FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION Confidence in banks is affected by the shortcomings in corporate gov- ernance, notably the lack of transparency regarding the ownership and control of banks. Moreover, the opaque ownership structure of xxiv Introduction the corporate sector makes it more difficult for the banking sector to assess risks concerning corporate sector exposures. Official dis- closures of direct and indirect ownership are substantially weaker than in other transition economies. No disclosure of beneficial owners is required under Armenian law. This limits the ability of banks to ensure compliance with prudent limits on loan portfolio concentra- tions and related party transactions. These shortcomings in corpo- rate governance can be addressed through legal, institutional, and supervisory reforms. The Central Bank of Armenia has developed a proposal to accelerate improvements in corporate governance in the banking sector through legislative and supervisory means and by introducing upward-consolidated supervision. The protection of creditor rights is one of the main legal problems hindering the growth of bank lending. The enforcement of collateral is difficult for banks, and this translates into high lending rates. In Armenia, movable property cannot be used effectively as collateral to secure loans. There are numerous problems with the secured transac- tions framework. Floating pledges are not allowed, and there are no registries that allow pledges to be perfected. Repossession is time- consuming and costly. A particular problem with financing exports is that there is no provision that allows the use of future produc- tion as collateral, so financing against export orders is not feasible. A similar problem arises with imports because there is no provision for pledging goods that are not in the possession of the borrower; goods that are being imported, even though they have been paid for by letter of credit, cannot be seized in the event of default. The effect of the inadequacies of the collateral framework extends throughout the economy, with the result that banks correctly perceive lending as extremely risky. Overall, Armenia lacks a regularized system of credit that should be stimulated by mechanisms providing efficient, transparent, and reli- able methods for recovering debt. Armenia's financial sector (possibly with help from the Central Bank and the Ministries of Finance and Justice) should promote an informal, out-of-court process for dealing with cases of enterprises with financial difficulties in which banks have a significant exposure. Finally, given the vital role played by the generation and transmis- sion of information on creditworthiness in ensuring low intermedia- tion costs, it is suggested that the Central Bank adopt an active role in facilitating private credit bureau development by making credit bureau reports a requirement for lending. This requirement should be coupled with mechanisms that ensure efficient entry and exit by credit bureaus, thereby avoiding abuse of their exclusive rights; and, in order to ensure greater privacy protection, there should be a requirement Introduction xxv that borrowers must give explicit consent prior to any access to their files. In addition, improving governance in credit bureaus and raising the quality of information disseminated remain important. REMOVING BARRIERS TO INTERNATIONAL INTEGRATION Armenia enjoys an admirably open regime in trade in goods and services and in capital and investment flows. No legal restrictions are in place for foreign capital inflows; the foreign investment regime provides for national treatment, most favored nation (MFN), and full repatriation of capital and earnings. Access to Armenian mar- kets of goods is liberal in terms of official border and behind-the- border arrangements. Tariffs are low not only by CIS standards but by international standards as well. Although both its weighted and unweighted average MFN tariff rates are twice as high as in the Euro- pean Union (EU), they are still well below 5 percent. Furthermore, commitments made upon accession to the World Trade Organization (WTO) have infused a considerable degree of stability and predict- ability into Armenia's foreign trade policy and have also reduced the potential for the capture of foreign trade decisions by narrow interest groups by providing the government with tools for taming the rent- seekers. Armenia's two-band tariff regime, with applied MFN tariff rates at zero or 10 percent ad valorem, has been locked. Armenia has made highly liberal commitments under the WTO General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS). Except for telecom- munications, Armenia's bound sectoral commitments are extensive in terms of both coverage and market access across different modes of supply of services. The number of subsectors in which exceptions are placed on a mode of supply (that is, unbound) is very small in Armenia's schedule. Yet neither commitments under the WTO agreements nor legal provisions protecting private property rights and enforcing contracts alone have ensured the high contestability of Armenia's domestic markets. First, the capacity of courts remains weak, as they operate slowly in enforcing contracts and mediating commercial disputes. Sec- ond, the computerization of customs has not to date much improved the quality of customs services, and customs procedures have yet to achieve WTO standards of transparency. The time needed to complete customs clearance is grossly excessive. Value added tax (VAT) reim- bursements do not occur quickly enough and are underpaid by the government, though there was a substantial improvement in 2005. Weaknesses in the provision of backbone services add greatly to the cost of participating in the emerging division of labor. Falling xxvi Introduction transportation and communications costs create opportunities for out- sourcing, just-in-time production, and supply-chain management. The high transportation and communications costs in Armenia are barriers to participation in the division of labor based on production fragmenta- tion. This is illustrated particularly by services in telecommunications and civil air transport. The government's decision to grant a legal monopoly (originally until 2013) to ArmenTel, the local telecommunica- tions company owned by a foreign investor, has led to greatly increased costs and to a considerably lowered quality of service in this key eco- nomic activity. The cost of using the Internet in Armenia was 41 percent higher than the average for the CIS. The prices charged by ArmenTel for high-speed connections are 30 times those of countries with competition in telecommunications. Armenia has a surprisingly low number of Inter- net users, well below the CIS average. The poor quality of the information technology infrastructure is a barrier to the development of the economy, and the very high telecom- munications costs severely exacerbate the disadvantage associated with Armenia's geographical location. ArmenTel's dominant position has been reduced by the introduction of a cellular competitor in 2005, and provision has been made for a second cellular operator in 2009. However, the new mobile operator was licensed in a process that was not transparent and fell far short of international good practice; it is unlikely that a competitive regime will emerge. Duopolies can pro- duce outcomes close to monopolies unless competition law is actively applied to prevent tacit collusion. The analysis of this book suggests that the regulator should be given enhanced powers in an attempt to countervail the adverse effects of ArmenTel's continuing dominant market position. Further- more, future policy should be developed and announced now. This policy should stipulate that all government-imposed economic entry barriers would be removed at the same time that the regulator is given enhanced powers; in addition, the available and necessary radio fre- quency spectrum should be auctioned off well before 2009 so that further mobile operators, to the extent that they consider they would be commercially viable, would be able to enter the market as soon as restrictions are lifted. After 2013, with the termination of ArmenTel's right to exclusivity, the market at that point should be regulated only by competition law. Freight shipped by air from Yerevan fell by more than two-thirds between 1997 and 2005--a dramatic development considering that the value of exports of goods rose 4 times in dollar terms. The fall in the share of the most dynamic worldwide mode of transport--air trans- port--can be attributed to the fall in the competitiveness of air trans- port services, largely because of a restrictive aviation policy. Armenia Introduction xxvii has operated a bilateral system of air transport regulations that is based on a restrictive positive list approach, which limits the provision of services to those services that are explicitly permitted. The empirical evidence from countries that have deregulated the domestic aviation sector (for example, the United States and the EU countries) is robust: passengers and air freight shippers in both the EU and the United States have experienced a dramatic and continu- ing decline in airfares. The costs of bilateral aviation agreements are not confined simply to the higher prices of air transport but include more difficult-to-estimate costs of forgone opportunities. These costs are potentially large, as lower airfares boost tourism, stimulate impor- tant flows of ideas and human capital, and deepen networks. For a small, land-locked economy aiming to maximize its long-term eco- nomic growth rate, the best aviation policy would be to eliminate government-imposed entry barriers to air transport. Armenia could gain considerably from following Open Skies arrangements among CIS countries modeled on the EU European Civil Aviation Area Model as well as joining the many countries that have signed Open Skies agreements with countries such as the United States. Because of the limited contestability of markets and deficiencies in backbone services, information, communications, and technology (ICT) firms have not been able to crest the recent change in the ICT sector worldwide. Armenian firms have successfully entered software and imaging technology niches, but they have failed to enter other stages of the production and delivery processes--in particular as pro- viders of front-end customer contact/support services or suppliers of components. CAPITALIZING ON INNOVATION AND KNOWLEDGE The generation and diffusion of knowledge and the use of innova- tive technology are important factors behind growth, in general, and the raising of labor productivity, in particular. Information technology externalities that promote the expansion of producer services (such as communications, sophisticated financial and insurance products, and marketing) explain a significant portion of the total factor pro- ductivity growth. Armenia has the advantage of a large proportion of highly educated population; however, this educated segment has largely obsolete specialized skills and has eroded through emigration, low public spending on education, and delayed reforms in university education. The country has experienced an entrepreneurial diaspora; and it also suffers from weak local entrepreneurship, in which clus- ters and value chains are not developing. Entrepreneurs and policy xxviii Table 1 Key Policy Recommendations Matching Reform Priorities to Policies and Instruments Reform priorities Policy objectives Instruments and interventions Intr Create Raise the domestic investment · Improve the business climate, simplify regulations and tax code, and create oduction macroeconomic ratio, raise public investment, and measures to fight corruption. policies to foster increase the effectiveness of public · Redirect budget resources to public investment, particularly to enhance human growth. spending. capital and build rural infrastructure. Sharpen Foster competition and encourage · Strengthen the competition law by clarifying collusive behavior and dominant competition. private sector development by market practices and by modernizing the basis for judging pricing practices. lowering cost of doing business. · Enhance the administrative capacity of the competition commission to review cases and enforce its rulings. · Modify the commercial transactions law to strengthen safeguards. Integrate into Create infrastructure that facilitates · Establish a "white list" of firms eligible for special treatment by Customs and VAT global markets and encourages firms to engage in Administration, including quick customs clearance. for goods and international trade. · Use provisions of the WTO Agreement on Customs Valuation instead of using services. reference prices. · Create an effective scheme that provides duty waivers and exemptions from other restrictions on imported inputs. · Give rebates of VAT as soon as exports are cleared by customs. · Extend direct transfer input to all customs houses. · Bring customs-related documents in line with what is really required under a computerized system such as the Automated System for Customs Data (ASYCUDA). · Simplify customs clearance procedures for exports with a strict time limit on releasing a shipment; if it is exceeded, a shipment should be immediately released. · Support participation in international R&D networks (such as the EU 6th Framework Program). · Sign the WTO Information Technology Agreement. Support Liberalize air services markets. · Deepen implementation of liberalised government civil aviation policy. international Maximize the contribution of ICT. · Increase and add new services under "open skies" type arrangements. integration. · Pass the new telecommunications law and pass to the Public Services Regulatory Commission (PSRC) responsibility for implementation, including the ArmenTel license. · Promote cellular competition. · Have the PSRC prepare a regulatory policy statement that, among other things, lays out an implementation plan for the entry of a third service provider by 2009. Deepen financial Strengthen corporate governance · Implement new law on corporate governance of banks. markets. standards and practices. · Strengthen official disclosures of direct and indirect ownership. Build legal foundations for · Make disclosure of beneficial owners required by Armenian law. protection of creditor rights. · Ensure public access to the company registry and lists of founders and shareholders. Improve information flows and · Implement law on creditor rights and secured transactions with streamlining of promote capital markets. judicial procedures. Foster investment activity through · Strengthen supervision of capital markets. expanding access to bank credit to · Implement unified supervision of financial and capital markets, with new standards small and medium firms. for supervision of insurance, pensions, and housing finance institutions. · Promote the development of a credit bureau. Capitalize on Foster competitiveness by · Provide business advisory and support services, such as SME and microenterprise innovation and introducing basic innovation skills support agencies. technology. and encouraging adoption and · Facilitate access to finance (including microfinance). application of new ideas. · Develop management and skills. Intr Support market development and · Develop internet-based information services. oduction entry into global value chains · Support technology adoption and adaptation projects. by fostering strategic alliances · Adopt cluster-based approaches to stimulating innovation. and certain in-house innovation · Support participation in international R&D networks (such as the EU 6th capabilities. Framework Program). Diffuse experience of innovation · Encourage participation of national innovation leaders in national advisory bodies, xxix leaders as role models for the rest technology foresight, and cluster processes. of the economy. xxx Introduction makers alike do not appreciate (and hence do not seek to improve) the value of intangibles (such as brand names, business reputations, marketing and managerial skills, and networks). The policy challenge lies in the mobilization and recombination of the existing human capital, triggered by an initially modest invest- ment in intangibles, such as mechanisms of knowledge and skill trans- fer from the diaspora to Armenia. International experience suggests that, although major reform efforts from the top are vital, bottom-up experiments in Armenia, some of which are already under way, need to mature. Central to the policy task are improvements in what may be called the innovation system (that is, the network of organizations, rules, and procedures that affect how a country acquires, creates, dis- seminates, and uses knowledge). Traditional measurements for an innovation system include indicators of expenditure on R&D, activ- ity in high-technology sectors (biotechnology, ICT), patenting activity (numbers, intensity), and number of researchers per 10,000 population. These indicators proxy the ability to generate new knowledge. Key organizations for the creation of knowledge include universities, pub- lic and private research centers, and policy think tanks. Private firms are at the center of the innovation system. If the private sector has little demand for knowledge, the innovation system cannot be effec- tive. Effective R&D-industry linkages are vital to transform knowl- edge into wealth. Therefore, networking and interactions among the different organizations, firms, and individuals are critically important. The intensity of these networks, as well as the incentives for acquir- ing, creating, and sharing knowledge, are influenced by the economic incentive regime in general. Acronyms and Abbreviations ACF Average Cost of Funds ADA Armenia Development Agency AIA Armenian International Airlines ASA Air Service Agreements ASYCUDA Automated System for Customs Data ATC Air Traffic Control BA British Airways BEEPS Business Environment and Enterprise Performance Survey CAA Civil Aviation Administration CEEC Central and Eastern European Countries CEM Country Economic Memorandum CES Constant Elasticity of Substitution CGE Computable General Equilibrium CIF Cost, Insurance, and Freight CIS Commonwealth of Independent States CMEA Council for Mutual Economic Assistance CNC Computer Numerical Control CPEC Commission for the Protection of Economic Competition CPI Corruption Perception Index CRS Computer Reservation Services DSA Debt Sustainability Analysis EASA European Aviation Safety Agency EBRD European Bank for Reconstruction and Development EC European Commission ECA Europe and Central Asia EDC Electricity Distribution Company EIF Enterprise Incubator Foundation EIR Economic and Institutional Regime/Economic Incentive Regime xxxi xxxii Acronyms and Abbreviations EQ&R Education Quality and Relevance ERC Energy Regulatory Commission EU European Union FAT Foreign Affiliate Transfers FDI Foreign Direct Investment FIAS Foreign Investment Advisory Service FSU Former Soviet Union GAMS General Algebraic Modeling System GATS General Agreement on Trade in Services GATT General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade GDCA Director General of Civil Aviation GDP Gross Domestic Product GDS Gross Domestic Savings GERD General Expenditures on Research and Development GNI Gross National Income GNS Gross National Savings GSM Global System for Mobile Communications GTAP Global Trade Analysis Project GVA Gross Value Added HDI Human Development Index HH Household HSBC Hong Kong and Shanghai Banking Corporation IAP International Aviation Policy ICAO International Civil Aviation Organization ICT Information Communication Technology IDA International Development Association IEF International Enterprise Foundation IFC International Finance Corporation IFRP Integrated Financial Rehabilitation Plan ILCS Integrated Living Conditions Survey ILO International Labour Organization IMF International Monetary Fund IO Input-Output IP Internet Protocol IPR Intellectual Property Rights ISAM Internal Single Aviation Market ISIC International Standard Industrial Classification ISP Internet Service Provider ITA International Technology Agreement JAA Joint Aviation Authorities JAC Junta de Aeronáutica Civil de Chile KAM Knowledge Assessment Methodology KE Knowledge Economy KEI Knowledge Economy Index K4D Knowledge for Development KI Knowledge Index LCC Low-Cost Carriers Acronyms and Abbreviations xxxiii LHS Left-Hand Side LIL Learning and Innovation Loan MCA Millennium Challenge Account ME Maximum Entropy MFN Most Favored Nation MoU Memorandum of Understanding MTEF Medium-Term Expenditure Framework NBER National Bureau for Economic Research NSS National Statistical Service OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development PPORF Practical Program of Revolution in Factories and Other Organizations PPP Purchasing Power Parity PRSP Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper PSRC Public Services Regulatory Commission R&D Research and Development RA Representative Agent RCA Revealed Comparative Advantage RCS Regulatory Cost Survey REER Real Effective Exchange Rate RHS Right-Hand Side S&T Science and Technology SAC Structural Adjustment Credit SAM Social Accounting Matrix SAS Scandinavian Airline Systems SEE Southeastern Europe SIMA Statistical Information Management & Analysis SITC Standard International Trade Classification SME Small and Medium Enterprises SNA System of National Accounts SOE State-Owned Enterprise SRI Structural Reform Index SWOT Strengths, Weaknesses, Opportunities, Threats TCS Teaching Company Scheme TFP Total Factor Productivity ULC Unit Labor Cost UNDP United Nations Development Programme USAID United States Agency for International Development USPTO United States Patent and Trademark Office VAT Value Added Tax VoIP Voice over Internet Protocol WBI World Bank Institute WDI World Development Indicators WITS World Integrated Trade Solution WTO World Trade Organization YBF Yerevan Brandy Factory Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Chapter 1 The Pattern of Growth A rmenia's macroeconomic performance has been a success.1 Mod- erate but robust economic growth in the initial years of the recov- ery (5 percent on average over 1994­2000) accelerated in the late 1990s, reaching an average annual rate of 11 percent since 2001. Growth has been fostered by a sound macroeconomic stance and a steady pur- suit of first-generation structural reforms, and has relied on excep- tionally high foreign assistance. Poverty began to fall at the end of the 1990s. Yet unemployment has persistently remained at double-digit levels and every third Armenian was still below the overall poverty line in 2004.2 On average, roughly one out of five economically active people is unemployed (based on survey data) and two-thirds of formal work- ers depend on incomes from low-productivity agriculture and trade. The brain drain had not been reversed as of 2005, indicating that there are limited employment opportunities across a wide range of skills. As in other transition economies, the formal labor market has seen strong gains in real wages based on rises in productivity but little increase in employment; informal labor markets have been stagnant. The impact of growth on poverty and extreme poverty has been strong. The initial phase of growth (1994­2000) had a moderate and uneven impact on poverty reduction, but, with the sharp accelera- tion in growth since 2000, poverty has fallen massively. The favora- ble effects from recent growth have been uneven across the regions, with the greatest benefit occurring in Yerevan. Urban areas outside of Yerevan, in particular, have experienced a lesser improvement. The present growth pattern rests on concentrated and volatile sources. The impact of growth on the generation of employment continues to be disappointing. 3 4 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Growth has been dependent on foreign aid. During the entire trans- formation period Armenia has benefited from exceptionally generous international assistance (Figure 1.1) and has also been aided by a high level of remittances and private transfers from diaspora Armenians. Income and investment in Armenia continue to rely heavily on for- eign savings, while gross domestic savings, although on an increasing trend, are still low at about 9 percent of GDP. Financial deepening and the economic diversification of industry, manufacturing, and services have not taken off (see Figure 1.2 for a comparison with other Europe and Central Asia [ECA] countries). Agriculture's contribution in Armenia to GDP is around 30 percent, Figure 1.1 Official Development Assistance, Cumulative 1992­2003 Albania Kyrgyz Republic Armenia Bolivia Tajikistan Georgia Moldova Azerbaijan Bulgaria Estonia Lithuania Latvia Paraguay Poland Uzbekistan country Ukraine Turkmenistan Romania Belarus Slovak Republic Kazakhstan Russian Federation Cyprus Czech Republic Hungary Thailand Croatia Slovenia Turkey 0 50 100 150 200 percent of GDP Source: World Development Indicators (WDI). The Pattern of Growth 5 Figure 1.2 ECA Countries, Income per Capita and Employment in Agriculture, 2003 60 Kyrgyz Rep. Georgia total) 50 Moldova of Armenia (% Romania 40 Azerbaijan Uzbekistan Turkey 30 agriculture Bulgaria in Kazakhstan 20 Poland Lithuania Ukraine Greece Latvia Croatia Portugal Russian Federation 10 Hungary Spain Ireland employment Estonia Norway Czech Rep. Cyprus Germany 0 7.0 7.5 8.0 8.5 9.0 9.5 10.0 10.5 11.0 GNI per capita, PPP (current international US$) Source: WDI. and to employment it is more than 45 percent, well above the levels of 4.5 percent and 20 percent, respectively, in new EU member states. The services sector, concentrated in public administration and trade, generates about 35 percent of GDP in Armenia compared to more than 60 percent in new EU member countries. As a small develop- ing economy Armenia depends critically on external markets. With a population estimated at 3.2 million and a GDP per head of about US$1,600 distributed quite unevenly, Armenia faces considerable chal- lenges in both development and poverty reduction. Armenia is a land-locked country with high transportation costs. Two important neighbors, Azerbaijan and Turkey, closed their bor- ders with Armenia for political reasons soon after Armenia's inde- pendence. Border closures have imposed costs on the economy, with the main surface trade link limited to (i) low-capacity rail and road connections with Georgia and its Black Sea ports, and (ii) Iran via a single road. High transport costs arise from border closures, but also, importantly, from policy weaknesses in the transport and communi- cations regimes. Overcoming policy-induced and structural problems such as these makes development and poverty reduction challenges even more complicated. 6 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth SUSTAINED GROWTH WITH IMPRESSIVE PRODUCTIVITY GAINS As noted, Armenia's macroeconomic performance during the transition has been very successful. A sharp 60 percent decline in output between 1991 and 1993 was reversed by a rapid recovery. Since 1994, Armenia has grown at a remarkable average annual rate of over 8.0 percent, and by 2005 its real GDP reached 120 percent of its pretransition level. This growth pattern is comparable with the Central and Eastern European (CEEC) and Baltic countries, where the resumption of growth dates from 1996­97,3 rather than with the CIS (Figure 1.3). Growth was robust for the entire past decade (Figure 1.4). It started moderately in the first years of economic recovery (1994) and accelerated toward the end of the decade in response to the strong contribution from investments. The macroeconomic impact of the regional financial crisis (1998­99) was moderate. The authorities have mitigated the negative impact by the timely implementation of pre- cautionary measures. In addition, the initiation of diamond exports and subdued imports have compensated for the temporary erosion of other sources of growth in 1999. The regional crisis, however, had a strong adverse impact on the terms of trade for agriculture, with an associated impact on pov- erty. It also dampened remittances with a painful effect on house- hold incomes. Economic growth accelerated in 2000 and was led by growth in consumption, while net exports contribution was small as both exports and imports showed strong expansion (Figure 1.5). As noted, growth has been dependent on foreign aid. During the entire transition period Armenia has benefited from exceptionally generous international assistance and has also been aided by a high level of remittances and private transfers from diaspora Armenians.4 The current account balance has seen considerable improvement as a result of steady reduction in trade deficit (Figure 1.6). The foreign trade and exchange regime was liberalized in the early 1990s and has contributed to promoting trade and investment. In addition to a pru- dent monetary policy, the large import content of the consumer price index also helped to hold down the rate of inflation when import prices fell in the late 1990s. Total factor productivity, reflecting efficiency gains from macroeco- nomic stabilization and structural changes, has driven GDP growth in Armenia. During the 1990s and early 2000s, Armenia realized much of the "catch up" potential which arose following the economic trans- formation. Labor productivity growth outperformed GDP growth and capital productivity growth was also high. As a result, the productiv- ity gap between Armenia and the industrialized countries has nar- rowed, but it remains substantial (Figure 1.7). The Pattern of Growth 7 Figure 1.3 Index of Real GDP, 1990­2005 250 Armenia 200 CEEC and Baltics 150 1994=100 100 ECA region CIS 50 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004p2005p year Source: World Bank, ECA Regional Tables. Figure 1.4 GDP Growth Rate, 1996­2006 35 gross capital formation 30 25 exports of goods and services 20 15 cent per 10 GDP 5 0 total consumption -5 imports of goods and services -10 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005p year Source: NSS. 8 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 1.5 GDP Growth and Contribution of Expenditure to GDP, 1996­2005 20 15 consumption 10 points GDP 5 investment 0 percentage -5 resource balance -10 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005p year Source: NSS. Figure 1.6 Evolution of REER, Trade Balance, and Current Account Balance, 1999­2005 120 0 real effective exchange rate 100 (left-hand side) -2 80 -4 -6 1997=100 60 -8 GDP 40 current account balance of index, (right-hand side) -10 20 -12 percent 0 GDP -14 of -20 -16 percent -40 -18 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005p trade balance (left-hand side) Source: NSS. CAB = current account balance; REER = real effective exchange rate. Figure 1.7 Relative Productivity Level and Productivity Growth Rate, Latest Data 45 8 40 6 2004=1 35 in 30 4 level 25 2 20 percent productivity 15 0 10 -2 Armenia 5 The 0 -4 Pattern de China Korea Greece ChinaChile France JapanItaly Peru R.B. ArmeniaEstonia Latvia GeorgiaSloveniaof Finland Ukraine SwedenNorwayPortugalBulgariaPakistan Turkey BoliviaSpain Mexico Moldova Romania Ecuador Azerbaijan KazakhstanCroatia PolandHungarySingapore Federation Australia AustriaDenmarkKingdom GermanyColombiaBelgium IndonesiaSalvadorUruguay Argentina Kong, Netherlands El of Republic United Russian Hong Venezuela, Gr owth relative productivity level (left-hand side) productivity growth rate (right-hand side) Source: WDI, Staff Calculations. 9 Note: Data are for 2004; 2003 data are used if 2004 data are not available. 10 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Armenia's unit labor cost (ULC) generally compares favorably to neighboring markets. This is mainly due to Armenia's comparative advantage in having an educated and skilled workforce and the coun- try's strong tradition of highly skilled craftsmen. In the mid-1990s the real wage increase outperformed the increase in labor productivity. This was partially due to the wage adjustment from a very low base. Unit labor costs did not rise during the 1990s as the real exchange rate depreciated. The early 2000s were characterized by strong productiv- ity gains and, except in 2003, outperformed the increase in real wages. The unit labor cost started to increase in late 2002, reflecting both the increase in employment compensation and the real effective exchange rate (REER) appreciation and declined again in 2005 in response to wage stability and strong productivity growth. Over the 1990s, the unit labor cost increased to about 46 percent of the U.S. level (about 44 percent of the euro-area level) from as low as less than 3 percent in the early 1990s (Figure 1.8). Figure 1.8 Relative Unit Labor Cost Index, 1997­2004 106 48 105 46 104 103 44 102 42 101 States=100 40 100 percent 99 38 United 98 36 97 34 96 95 32 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 year United States (left-hand side) Euro area vs U.S. (left-hand side) Armenia vs U.S. (right-hand side) Armenia vs Euro area (right-hand side) Source: OECD, WDI. The Pattern of Growth 11 Productivity gains have risen because of the enterprise restructur- ing and the contemporaneous macroeconomic discipline that ena- bled enterprises, through competition and trade, to realize efficiency improvements in the areas of management, marketing, and technol- ogy. They have also risen because of labor shedding from declining economic activities and sectors and the absorption of labor by new enterprises. In contrast, productivity fell in agriculture for reasons dis- cussed earlier. Armenia's exchange-rate regime has been stable since the national currency was introduced, and the REER depreciated gradually until 2004 (Figure 1.9). The strong appreciation of the dram (the Arme- nian currency) since early 2004, in response to sustained high rates of growth and productivity gains in the economy (the Balassa-Samuelson effect), has ensured the continued importation of price disinflation to the benefit of economic performance. INCREASINGLY EXPORT-LED GROWTH Following an initial prolonged period of export weakness, partly owing to adverse geopolitical conditions peculiar to Armenia, extremely strong export growth has been registered since the late 1990s. This development reflects a transition to market conditions in three ways. First, exports have been based on restructured industrial capacities. The inherited industrial capacities that were incompatible with market disciplines have been dismantled. No other CIS econ- omy recorded such a strong growth in 1999­2004. Armenian firms have also outperformed other non-oil CIS competitors in both CIS and EU markets, with their shares in respective markets increasing very significantly in the 1999­2004 period. The export share in total EU imports doubled in 2003 alone. Against the background of falling Russian imports from most CIS countries, the Armenian performance is particularly impressive, with the value of exports of goods more than doubling between 1999 and 2004. Trade with the CIS appears no longer driven by the post-Soviet hysteresis in trade patterns, with the emerging trade reflecting a comparative advantage in these increas- ingly competitive and market-oriented markets. Second, the readjustment in the geographical pattern of trade, reflecting the economic weight of regional markets, appears to be com- plete. While in 1995 Russia, together with other CIS countries, took 56 percent of Armenia's exports and supplied 49 percent of Armenia's imports of goods, these shares fell to 25 percent and 27 percent, respec- tively, in 1999 and to 19 percent and 29 percent in 2005. The shift has been largely toward the EU-15, whose share in Armenian exports rose 12 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 1.9 REER Quarterly Increase, Indicating Appreciation 115 110 105 100 95 appreciation 90 85 80 Q1-97 Q1-98 Q1-99 Q1-00 Q1-01 Q1-02 Q1-03 Q1-04 Q1-05 quarter Source: Central Bank of Armenia. from 26 percent in 1995 to 46 percent in 2005 and in imports from 15 percent to 26 percent over the same period. Third, the expansion in exports has not been confined to goods but has also included services, especially if the estimate that puts exports of ITC services at around US$100 million rather than the US$11 mil- lion reported in the balance of payments category of "computer and information services" is broadly correct. With or without a revised figure for these services, revenues from services increased more than expenditures. With a revised figure, the balance of trade in services swung to the surplus in 2003, and the overall deficit in trade in goods and services was significantly lower. Finally, Armenia's growth has become export-led, as exports growth has far outstripped GDP growth. (Figure 1.10). Moreover, a strong GDP growth performance considerably lessened an overall potentially adverse macroeconomic impact of trade imbalances. In terms of the GDP, the trade deficit fallen rather rapidly from 38 percent in 1997 to 12 percent in 2005. The Pattern of Growth 13 Figure 1.10 Key Economic Indicators of External Performance, 1998­2005 60 50 40 30 cent per 20 10 0 -10 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 year exports as percent of GDP annual rate of GDP growth imports as percent of GDP annual rate of export growth Source: NSS. The composition of exports of goods has registered some encour- aging developments, with exports diversifying toward high value­ added goods. Yet a significant weakness is that manufactures, other than diamonds, have been conspicuously absent in Armenia's exports. Although the share of manufactures increased in Armenia's total exports from 39 percent in 2000 to close to 70 percent in 2005, this was mainly due to the increase in exports of diamonds. Other manu- factured exports fell in terms of value with their share in total exports falling from 29 percent in 2000 to 10 percent in 2003 alone. CONTINUING HEAVY RELIANCE ON EXTERNAL SAVINGS Armenia's heavy reliance on foreign savings to finance its investment needs has declined over time but remains large (Figure 1.11). In 2005 about 20 percent of total investment was financed through foreign 14 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 1.11 Savings and Investment Balance, 1994­2005 30 total investment 20 net current transfers 10 foreign savings GDP GDS of 0 cent per -10 net income from abroad -20 -30 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 year Source: NSS. GDS = gross domestic savings. savings as compared to 90 percent in 1999. This reduction in reli- ance on foreign savings did not entail a decline in investments, as a commensurate rise in gross domestic savings has taken place. But the investment share in GDP has risen only modestly (growth has been driven by productivity) and the rise in investment necessary for sustained growth will require a greater domestic savings effort. Total investments averaged 19 percent of GDP during 1996­2000, increasing to 23 percent of GDP in 2001­05, but Bank projections show that the investment-to-GDP ratio will need to rise to around 28 percent by the end of the decade to sustain growth, assuming a return to a steady rate of productivity growth. Gross domestic savings remain low as shown by international com- parisons; and gross national savings fall short of those in some other CIS countries. Though the external debt and current account posi- tions are comfortable, these figures illustrate the dependence of the economy on income and transfers from abroad to finance investment needs (Figure 1.12). The Pattern of Growth 15 Figure 1.12 Gross Domestic Savings and Gross National Savings, 2004 Albania Armenia Georgia Bulgaria Kyrgyz Republic GNS Poland GDS Romania Lithuania Latvia Hungary country Croatia Ukraine Slovak Republic Estonia Slovenia Czech Republic Russian Federation Azerbaijan Kazakhstan 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 percent of GDP Source: World Bank ECA Regional Tables. GDS = gross domestic savings; GNS = gross national savings. Investment has been broad-based, but with a tilt toward housing construction. The structure of investments by sectors during 1999­2005 (Figure 1.13) shows that housing represents over 30 percent of total investment. Infrastructure has also attracted a considerable share of investment. Several profitable and competitive traditional sectors have attracted private investment during the process of economic transfor- mation (for example, gem cutting, brandy distillation, electric motors, hotels, high-technology manufacturing, and software services). A sig- nificant source of investment financing has been foreign direct invest- ment (FDI), but associated with large transactions. A large part of the 16 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 1.13 Sectoral Shares in GDP and Investment by Sectors, Average, 1999­2005 35 30 25 20 percent 15 10 5 0 industry agriculture transport trade housing other sector share in investment 1999­2003 share in GDP 1999­2005 Source: NSS. FDI, particularly in infrastructure (telecommunications through the privatization of the national telecommunications company, ArmenTel) and in industry (privatization of the gas distribution network) was the direct result of large-scale privatization. COMFORTABLE OUTLOOK FOR EXTERNAL DEBT A debt-sustainability analysis (DSA) carried out for Armenia shows that the country is considered to be at a low risk for debt distress, with all debt indicators well below the relevant country-specific debt-burden thresholds, including when subjected to stress tests (see Table 1.1). The baseline DSA has been developed on a cautious set of assump- tions, including: (i) a real GDP growth of 5 percent per year over the period 2008­12 and 4 percent thereafter; (ii) an inflation rate of 3 percent throughout the projection period; (iii) an overall fiscal deficit of 2.9 percent of GDP through the Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper The Pattern of Growth 17 Table 1.1 Armenia's External Debt Burden Indicators Armenia's Ratios Thresholda 2005 2025 NPV of debt in percent of: Exports 200 60 25 GDP 50 15 8 Debt service in percent of: Exports 25 6 2 Source: IMF-WB Staff calculations a. Threshold values are based on the guidelines for low-income country DSAs, among which Armenia is considered to be a strong performer. NPV = net present value. (PRSP) horizon of 2015 and 2.3 percent of GDP thereafter (implying a debt-stabilizing primary balance); (iv) a steady increase in the share of both exports and imports as a proportion of GDP, leading to a gradual improvement in the current account balance over the projec- tion period; and (v) a shift away from highly concessional forms of external financing. Under the baseline scenario the fiscal position remains sustainable. The net present value (NPV) of the ratio of debt to revenue and NPV of the ratio of debt service to revenue remain relatively stable through- out the projection period. In particular, the NPV of external debt falls steadily from around 15 percent of GDP in 2005 to just over 8 per- cent by 2025, the NPV of the debt-to-exports ratio falls from just over 60 percent to around 25 percent over the same period, and the debt service-to-exports ratio declines from just under 6 percent in 2005 to around 2 percent by the end of the projection period (Figure 1.14). The framework for low-income country DSAs also incorporated alternative scenarios and bound tests aimed at identifying the sensi- tivities of the baseline projection to a range of potential shocks. Based on these scenarios and tests it can be seen that Armenia's debt outlook is particularly sensitive to (i) a lasting shock to the growth outlook and (ii) a slowdown in export growth. Nevertheless, even under these scenarios, Armenia's debt outlook is likely to remain manageable. The DSA also considered the possible impact on debt sustainability of a "significant" fiscal event, such as the assumption by the govern- ment of pension liabilities. Assuming such an event was to occur in 2010, costing around 10 percent of GDP, the NPV of the public debt- to-GDP ratio in 2025 would remain manageable at about 40 percent. While the historical scenario (which can be considered as a "no-reform" 18 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 1.14 Indicators of Public and Publicly Guaranteed External Debt under Alternative Scenarios, 2005­25 30 NPV of debt-to-GDP ratio 25 20 15 percent 10 5 0 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 year 90 NPV of debt-to-exports ratio 80 70 60 50 40 percent 30 20 10 0 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 year 7 debt service-to-exports ratio 6 5 4 percent 3 2 1 0 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 year baseline historical scenario most extreme stress test Source: IMF-WB Debt Sustainability Analysis for Armenia. The Pattern of Growth 19 scenario) also projects debt ratios below the threshold indicators, the ratios generally continue on an upward trend through the projection period. This finding underlines the importance of continuing the proc- ess of structural reform and preserving macroeconomic stability in order to safeguard the debt outlook. KEY MACROECONOMIC CHALLENGES Despite the success of macroeconomic management thus far and the sustainability in medium-term fiscal and external accounts, the author- ities have to remain vigilant regarding the major sources of vulner- ability to economic performance. Economic projections to the year 2010 indicate that even with some moderation of growth to an average of 6 percent per year, external debt and debt service indicators will fall sharply, thereby creating both fiscal space and greater private sector funds for financing investment. On reasonable assumptions of produc- tivity growth and incremental capital-output ratios, the investment-to- GDP ratio will have to rise by around 4 percentage points in the rest of this decade. This rise in the investment-to-GDP ratio is projected to be financed equally by external savings (as grant inflows into the economy rise substantially) and private sector savings. Thus, the macroeconomic management challenge will lie in ensur- ing stability that leads to the generation of greater private savings and efficient use of official inflows. The task of monetary and exchange rate policies will be to bear down on inflation, which has flared up periodically in recent years. The appreciation of the dram that is under way will help to fight inflation. In an economy with rapid productivity growth such as Armenia's, a real appreciation of the currency is to be expected and is the mechanism for establishing a balance between the tradables and the nontradables sectors. The Central Bank is entirely right in permitting the nominal appreciation seen thus far: were it to seek to hold the nominal rate down, the real appreciation would be realized through higher inflation. It is particularly important to permit the exchange rate to be determined entirely through market forces, as the bank lacks the long-duration financial instruments necessary for sterilization activities. One-year bills currently being issued will help in short-term liquidity control and in operations to dampen day-to- day volatility in the exchange rate. The fiscal deficit over the medium term should be confined to a range of 2.5 to 3 percent of GDP. This will require some broadening of the fiscal base and a rise in the revenue mobilization ratio to finance priority social expenditure needs. The narrowness of the fiscal base and the insufficient reliance on direct taxes lead to a lack of balance in the tax structure and to a mobilization ratio that is too low to fund 20 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth priority social expenditure needs. Changes in tax policy to enhance the role of direct taxes5 and in tax administration to ensure minimal evasion and fair treatment of all taxpayers will go a long way to sta- bilizing the fiscal base. As labor taxes and social contributions are high, particularly given the high unemployment and the large infor- mal economy, consideration could be given to a shift toward direct taxes. Any temptation to relax on tax reforms against a background of large donor grant inflows should be resisted. Questions also arise as to the capacity of the economy to efficiently absorb the large volume of the external grant funds flowing from the Millennium Challenge Account (MCA) and other sources. Constraints to efficient absorption arise from macroeconomic factors, institutional and managerial factors, and infrastructure. Projected inflows equiva- lent to 2 percent of GDP will not be inconsistent with the macro- stability provided that the monetary and exchange rate stance is as discussed above, the import content of the counterpart to the grant financing is high (as would be the case with infrastructure capital spending), and domestic spending (for example, on salaries) is con- trolled. In this manner, the inflationary impact and the real apprecia- tion of the dram will be minimized. Macroeconomic challenges will also arise if grant financing is substituted for domestic revenue mobi- lization or if it leaks into public consumption--these situations would pose a danger to fiscal sustainability over the medium term. On the institutional side, the appropriate budgeting of inflows and the selection of projects to reflect high-priority needs as identified in the PRSP action plan, as well as careful management of the public investment program, are essential if absorption is to be efficient. More- over, infrastructure constraints to efficient absorption will be eased if priority is given--as envisaged--to addressing needs in the transport and water sectors (especially in rural areas). There is a concomitant need to ensure high quality in public expen- ditures. Over 2005­06, a large increase in teacher salaries took place as salaries were grossly inadequate to attract quality services. This increase is related to productivity increases (the pupil-teacher ratio rises). In subsequent years, expenditures must shift from wages to items that enhance service quality as envisaged in the medium-term expenditure framework, such as curricular reform and education aids, the broadening of education services, primary health care, and increasing the real rate of the poverty benefit as well as targeting the benefit more sharply. A strategic approach to capital spending based on an overall public investment plan that explicitly makes sec- tor choices is also necessary, particularly in the context of the MCA disbursements. The Pattern of Growth 21 GROWTH AND A PRONOUNCED FALL IN POVERTY The most recent period of growth has resulted in a sharp, dispropor- tionate rise in consumption by the poor (Table 1.2).6 Growth incidence curves are useful for analyzing the impact of aggregate economic growth across households, as they plot the growth rate in consump- tion for individuals ranked according to their consumption. Figure 1.15a­d presents growth incidence curves for the period from 1998­99 to 2004. The vertical axis is ordered by increasing the levels of per- adult equivalent consumption. A downward sloping incidence curve indicates that people in the poorest quintiles of the population have benefited from growth more than the average. The horizontal line parallel to the horizontal axis indicates the growth rate in mean. In 2004 per adult equivalent consumption was about 10 percent higher than consumption in 2001, while output in Armenia grew by a cumulative 30 percent during the same period. This trend was not uniform across the capital and noncapital urban and rural areas. Over- all, this pattern appears to be driven by the distribution of the growth impact in the capital city and the rural areas. In contrast, with the exception of the people below the tenth percentile, whose consump- tion increased by 10 percentage points on average, the consumption of the non-Yerevan urban population was either unchanged or declined in 2004 compared to 1998­99. The population across all deciles, with the exception of non-Yerevan urban areas, experienced consumption growth, except for the richest population above the ninetieth percentile, which experienced a nega- tive growth rate everywhere except in the capital city. The poorer quin- tiles of the income distribution gained more from economic growth than the richer quintiles. The extremely poor have gained the most Table 1.2 Armenia's Poverty Indicators, 1999­2004 (percent) Poverty incidence (%) All Urban Yerevan Other urban Rural Extreme poverty 1998/99 26.1 32.1 29.6 34.5 18.0 2004 6.4 7.5 6.1 9.2 4.4 Overall poverty 1998/99 56.3 62.7 58.7 66.5 47.7 2004 34.6 36.4 29.2 43.9 31.7 Source: Integrated Living Conditions Survey (ILCS); Armenia 1998/99­2004. 22 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 1.15 Growth Incidence Curves, 1998/99­2004 a. Armenia: Growth Incidence Curve, 1998/99-2004 50 % growth incidence curve 40 adult 04- per 30 98/99 mean of growth rates cumulative rate 20 growth rate in mean equiv. 10 consumption growth 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 consumption per adult equivalent percentiles b. Armenia: Growth Incidence Curve in Yerevan, 1998/99-2004 50 growth incidence curve % 40 mean of growth rates adult 04- per growth rate in mean 30 98/99 cumulative rate 20 equiv. 10 consumption growth 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 consumption per adult equivalent percentiles from the recent economic growth. This evidence is consistent with the evolution of inequality for the period--the Gini coefficient decreased from a value of 0.32 in 1998­99 to a value of 0.23 in 2004--and indi- cates that the growth was accompanied by a compression in the over- all structure of the consumption distribution. This favorable pattern has been driven by the increase in nonfactor income and indicates the effectiveness of the social protection policy through the improved The Pattern of Growth 23 Figure 1.15 (continued) c. Armenia: Growth Incidence Curve in Other Urban Areas, 1998/99-2004 50 % growth incidence curve 40 adult 04- per mean of growth rates 30 98/99 cumulative growth rate in mean rate 20 equiv. 10 consumption growth 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 consumption per adult equivalent percentiles d. Armenia: Growth Incidence Curve in Rural Areas, 1998/99-2004 60 % growth incidence curve 40 adult 04- per 20 mean of growth rates 98/99 cumulative rate 0 growth rate in mean equiv. consumption -20 growth -40 0 20 40 60 80 100 consumption per adult equivalent percentiles Source: ILCS; Armenia 1998/99­2004. Note: The curve refers to the period of 5 years and 9 months. targeting of the family poverty benefit system and the increased social transfers (such as pensions, family poverty benefits, and others), and also points to the effect of remittances and the multiplier effect from externally driven demand sources. The consumption figures shown above fit in well with the data on poverty indicators. The strong gains for both poverty and extreme pov- erty in Yerevan are consistent with growth rates of about 17 percent 24 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Table 1.3 Armenia: Growth and Inequality Decomposition of Changes in Poverty Incidence between 1998­99 and 2004 (average effects) Total Urban Yerevan Other urban Rural Extreme poverty Change in poverty incidence ­20.6 ­25.9 ­26.3 ­25.4 ­13.5 Growth component ­14.2 ­22.6 ­21.4 ­21.7 ­4.1 Redistribution component ­6.4 ­3.4 ­4.8 ­3.6 ­9.5 Overall poverty Change in poverty incidence ­24.3 ­32.0 ­36.7 ­26.8 ­13.8 Growth component ­22.5 ­31.1 ­33.3 ­27.4 ­7.8 Redistribution component ­1.8 ­0.9 ­3.4 0.6 ­6.0 Source: ILCS; Armenia (various years). in the mean consumption of the bottom three deciles, as compared to about 6 percent for the same deciles in the non-Yerevan urban areas and 12 percent in the rural areas. Armenia's poverty is skewed toward being an urban problem (outside of the capital). The reduction in poverty is mostly driven by consumption growth. The decomposition of poverty reduction into a growth and a distribu- tional component, developed by Datt and Ravallion (1992), gives bet- ter insight into the poverty effects of decreasing inequality (Table 1.3). Calculations for both extreme and overall poverty incidence reveal that the growth and redistribution components worked in the same directions in influencing the reduction in poverty. However, most of the observed poverty decline is attributed to the growth component (around two-thirds, on average). Changes in consumption distribution played a more important role in extreme poverty reduction than in overall poverty reduction. Decreased inequality contributed about 31 percent to extreme poverty reduction and 7 percent to overall pov- erty reduction. Thus, the importance of the inequality component in explaining changes in overall poverty in Armenia is similar to that in other CIS countries where changes in inequality explained 5 percent of the changes in poverty (Alam et al. 2005). In the capital city of Yerevan and other urban areas, consumption growth was the most important source of the reduction in poverty (extreme and overall), as its contribution was over 80 percent. For rural poverty, on the other hand, both components--the decline in inequality and consumption growth--were almost equally important. Extremely poor rural households benefited mainly from the decline in inequality, as 70 percent of the reduction in rural poverty was attribut- able to decreased inequality. The Pattern of Growth 25 GROWTH WITHOUT JOBS An analysis of the impact of growth on employment is bedeviled by the change in economic regime. First, a market-based economy has replaced the command economy directed at realizing economies of scale on a narrow range of products--such as electronics and syn- thetic rubber--for dispatch to the rest of the Soviet Union. Second, upon independence the economy experienced large external price, output, and infrastructure shocks. In the initial phase (1992­94), there occurred a massive shift of labor to subsistence agriculture in response to the initial price and output shocks, and labor hoarding took place in enterprises that continued to function at considerably shrunken levels of output. The strong growth in output seen over the past decade has not resulted in a commensurate rise in employment until very recently. Output growth has been supported by strong labor productivity increases. Though registered unemployment stands at around 10 per- cent of the labor force, survey data point to rates twice as high, and the labor force has been affected by weak participation rates (Figure 1.16) and large migration, both skilled and unskilled. Much of the work force is to be found in subsistence agriculture or in the informal economy and underemployment is endemic. The weak demand for labor has persisted for a decade, and the rapid growth in productivity in formal activities has translated into rising real wages rather than more demand for labor. The labor market is segmented and has weak geographical mobility within the country. This phenomenon, called "jobless growth," is not specific to Arme- nia but is typical of most transition economies, where initial growth is mostly based on large productivity gains due to structural changes and labor shedding in the process of labor rationalization and more efficient utilization of labor resources rather than through an increased use of the labor force. According to a recent study, Armenia has actu- ally registered a significant "job loss growth" (Kuddo 2006). Over the last 15 years since 1990, employment has declined by 34 percent from 1.63 million people to around 1.1 million in 2004. In the process of the country's search for new equilibrium, the destruction of unproductive jobs has been accompanied by the creation of new and more produc- tive jobs. Job losses usually exceed job gains, leading to a net fall in employment. Only the World Bank's (2004a) Integrated Living Condi- tions Survey (ILCS) has recorded some increase in the employment rate among the population. Recent positive trends in employment indicate that Armenia may have reached a new equilibrium, and that growth will start to rely increasingly on improved labor utilization. The cities have been most deeply affected by transition, with labor participation and employment higher in rural areas. Other key 26 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 1.16 Participation, Employment, and Unemployment Rates in Urban and Rural Areas (population aged 15 and older) 80 participation rate 70 employment rate unemployment rate 60 50 40 percent 30 20 10 0 total Yerevan other urban rural sector Source: ILCS (2004) and NSS (2006). features of labor conditions in Armenia include the high percentage of youth that are neither in work or in study; the significant gender differences in participation; the extremely long duration of unem- ployment; the considerable regional disparities in participation; and the notable shift of employment from the state sector to the private sector in recent years. In comparison to the structural changes seen in the economies of the new members of the EU, those in Armenia have been much less profound thus far. The share of agriculture in GDP is today around 30 percent and agricultural employment accounts for more than 45 percent of total employment, well above the levels of 4.5 percent and 5 percent, respectively, in new EU member states. Activity is concen- trated in low value-added agriculture (dairy, meats, and grains). The services sector, concentrated in public administration and trade, gen- erates about 35 percent of GDP in Armenia, compared to more than 60 percent in new EU member countries. Subsistence agriculture, which is susceptible to supply shocks, remains overmanned, and those who rely on subsistence agriculture remain economically vulnerable. The Pattern of Growth 27 The impact of growth on formal job creation outside the construc- tion and trade sectors has been weak. Agriculture, which had been growing more slowly than the rest of the economy during the 1990s, has absorbed a surplus of (unskilled) labor released in the process of economic transformation. Part of the decline in the share of agriculture in total output from over 30 percent to 25 percent over the 1990s was related to changes in relative sector prices (that is, a decline in agricul- ture terms of trade since the 1998 Russian crisis) (Figure 1.17). Agricul- tural prices have been declining until recently, while prices in services (led by the utility price adjustment) and industrial prices have been consistently increasing. The special conditions that drove up the price of oil recently required another round of relative price adjustment. Agricultural prices saw another considerable decline in 2005. Clearly, such price shifts benefit the urban consumer and lead to the shift in resource allocation away from agriculture. But they have not led to the expected fall in employment in agriculture. In contrast, the fastest growing sector of the economy--construction--has made a significant contribution to job creation: the share of the labor force employed in construction has risen from 4 to 9 percent over the past five years. Job creation in industry in recent years was mostly concentrated in new private enterprises. Out of 26,500 jobs created in industry during 1999­ 2003, 22,000 were established in newly created private enterprises. Recent enterprise surveys indicate that there is a potential for employment growth. Average capacity use in Armenian firms, as Figure 1.17 Change in Sector Prices, Nominal Value-Added Deflator 1.7 construction 1.6 industry 1.5 GDP 1.4 services agriculture 1.3 1997=1 1.2 index,1.1 1.0 0.9 0.8 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005p year Source: NSS. 28 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth surveyed by the 2005 Business Environment and Enterprise Perform- ance Survey (BEEPS 2005), equals 82 percent, indicating that new jobs can be generated using the available capital stock. Moreover, employers point out that the optimal employment level in their firms compared to the current level implies an expansion of the workforce by 12.1 percent. This is more than the average in the ECA region of 8.6 percent of potential new employment in existing firms. GDP growth is expected to be more employment-intensive, since the rate of production growth in service sectors is expected to rise. Public employment has been constrained by the political choice of a small public sector in the economy. Other labor-intensive sectors and sectors with a demand for skilled labor, such as banking and light manufacturing, have been growing slowly since 2003 (Figure 1.18). The share of unskilled labor in total employment rose from 50 percent in 1990 to 75 percent in 2002. This development reflects some out-migration of skilled labor and possibly a worsening of the skills mismatch in the labor force after the collapse of central planning, as skills that were in demand under a planned economy were not needed under market conditions. (Labor-market research under way will examine such factors). Figure 1.18 Nonagricultural Jobs in the Productive State and Private Sectors, 1998­2003 500 jobs in productive state sector 450 jobs in productive private sector 400 350 300 250 thousands 200 150 100 50 0 2003 2002 2001 2000 1998 year Source: NSS and authors' calculations. The Pattern of Growth 29 Strong labor productivity growth and the increases in the ULC appear to have curtailed the potential for new employment in the short term. This trend has been reversed very recently with the increased reliance of growth on labor utilization. From an international perspec- tive, the Armenian labor market is still characterized by relatively low participation (65.9 percent compared to 70 percent in EU-19 and OECD) and employment rates, along with high unemployment rates (above 20 percent in 2004). In general, growth in labor productivity, if associated with slower growth in real wages, reduces ULCs and creates room for new employment. In Armenia, rapid growth in labor productivity was accompanied by increases in hourly compensation above the productivity growth level and related increases in ULC. The benefits of recent economic growth secured stronger earnings for current workers but did not generate higher employment, and the increase in labor costs contributed in part to jobless growth during the mid-1990s. Figure 1.19 illustrates the mismatch between the rapidly expand- ing sectors and labor productivity. The contrast between the rapidly growing sectors and formal employment indicates that the majority of the labor force has benefited only modestly from rapid economic expansion. The causes of the weak employment response to investment and growth lie in a business climate that discourages the flexible use of labor (business surveys provide evidence for this statement and are discussed in detail in Part 1, Chapter 3, of this book). Thus, a central policy task is to create conditions that will lead to an expansion of jobs. Raising the rate of job creation would require addressing the binding constraints to the formation and growth of firms. The prin- cipal weaknesses in Armenia are uncertainty in property rights, poor enforcement of contracts, arbitrary and predatory behavior on the part of public authorities, restrictiveness in the formal regime governing employment, and stunted financial intermediation. Considering that the labor market situation may be aggravated due to the fact that during the decade the labor supply will increase sig- nificantly, while the generation born at the birthrate peak in the 1980s will enter the labor force, Armenia will need to create more and better jobs. Thus, in addition to improving the business climate, Armenia will need to reform labor market institutions to create an adaptive labor market--that is, a market in which employers have the incentives to hire and workers have the incentives and required skills to take up available jobs. The upgrading of the labor force, or vertical mobility, is a precondition for rapid structural and technological change, for com- petitiveness, and for raising the share of high value-added products and services. The new role of employment services should be specified 30 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 1.19 Relative Labor Productivity by Sector 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 index 1.0 0.5 0.0 services industry average agriculture economic construction manufacturing sector 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 index 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 & stones power products banking economic average processing beverages mining quarrying & construction mineralprecious transportation food communication & & Source: NSS and authors' calculations. and the overall state of the labor market should be thoroughly ana- lyzed, including new forms of employment, underemployment, and unemployment; the components of labor force growth; age structure; industry and occupation structure; labor market segregation (for exam- ple, by age or gender); and regional imbalances. In contrast to some other CIS countries, the long record of stable macroeconomic management in Armenia reduces policy uncertainties. Moreover, with privatizations and enterprise restructuring being com- pleted, labor hoarding has practically been eliminated. In addition, wage-setting mechanisms are market-based and are decentralized to the firm level. However, employment protection legislation is restric- The Pattern of Growth 31 tive and dismissal costs are high in terms of severance pay, though enforcement is erratic (see Chapter 3 and Table 3.5). Thus, the muted employment response to growth reflects the incom- pleteness of structural reforms and of the development of institutions and practices that would encourage competition and enterprise activ- ity. To encourage employment growth, policy makers need to focus on property rights and all aspects of the rule of law, including rules- based regulation and regulatory behavior, bureaucratic arbitrariness and corruption, and the creation of a framework for bank and capital markets development. The persistent, very high rates of unemployment and the associated large, informal economy entail risks for the continuation of "tigerish" rates of growth. At a time when the memory of Soviet full employ- ment (even if of the "we pretend to work and they pretend to pay us" variety) and the adequate provision of very basic goods is still strong, the creation of haves and have-nots in the employment world--with large increases in real wages for a minority and with no clear prospect of a strong generalized growth in employment--diminishes support for the reform agenda still to be addressed. The strong association between unemployment and poverty makes reform even harder to promote. The worst affected by unemployment and poverty are middle- aged workers who may be less attuned by attitude and skills to the new economy. The remainder of this book is structured as an analysis of the policy response necessary to raise employment growth to the rates in com- parable tiger economies. Such an analysis will deal with questions of competition, the impediments to enterprise activity, the absorption of knowledge, the use of finance for investment, and the benefits of the international division of labor. SUMMARY Armenia's growth performance has been impressive and has had a sharp impact on poverty reduction. But growth has been depend- ent on foreign inflows (although the share of national savings has risen substantially), and growth has had a muted impact on lower- ing unemployment until very recently. The economy is insufficiently diversified; the export base remains narrow. The economy can be characterized as having a dual labor market: one formal, with rising productivity and real wages; the other, informal and stagnant. Thus, growth has been based on rising investment and productivity gains rather than on higher employment--a phenomenon seen in other CIS states. Broadening the base of growth and generating new jobs will 32 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth require changes in the business climate, sharper competition condi- tions, and a shift in taxation away from labor and social security taxes and charges and toward direct income taxation. NOTES 1. A background analysis for the pattern of growth can be found in Chap- ters 7 to 9 of Part II of this book. 2. Survey-based data show unemployment rates of around one-third; reg- istered unemployment is around 10 percent. In the EU-15 (the 15 EU mem- bers prior to the most recent enlargement of membership) and EU-10 (the 10 most recent members) less than 0.5 percent and 5.4 percent of the population, respectively, live below the poverty threshold of US$2 a day. 3. For a more detailed cross-country comparison see Loukoianova and Unigovskaia (2004). 4. Armenia has a very large diaspora of about 5 million compared to the country's population of about 3.2 million people. The diaspora is spread over the world and is large in the Middle East, the United States, Russia, and Western Europe. 5. Indirect tax rates are high (VAT [value-added tax] is levied at 20 percent) and the tax base is commendably broad; thus the scope for further action on indirect taxes is small. The tax system is discussed in Part 2 of this book. 6. A detailed study of developments in poverty can be found in ILCS; Armenia (various years). Chapter 2 Constraints to Sustained Growth THE RECORD As has been noted, Armenia has an impressive decade-long record of double-digit rates of growth on average, although incomes remain well below those in countries such as Lithuania. Armenia's strong growth record has been fostered by sound macroeconomic per- formance: namely, modest fiscal deficits, low inflation, and a stable (recently appreciating) currency. Exports have accelerated and the cur- rent account deficit has declined from over 20 percent of GDP in the mid-1990s to less than 5 percent in 2005. Gross international reserves remained at about four months of imports. Armenia has pursued a prudent debt management strategy. By now, almost all nonconces- sional debt, accumulated during the first years of independence, has been settled1 and the debt burden has been kept under control. Macroeconomic projections, on the assumption of continued stabil- ity-oriented policies, indicate a comfortable fiscal sustainability and plunging indicators for debt service and debt burden (as discussed in Chapter 1 of this book). Armenia has already implemented an impressive range of market- oriented reforms, including free price formation in a highly open market with a liberal regime for trade and investment, a liberal finan- cial system, total private ownership of land, and privatization of both small and medium enterprises (SMEs) and large enterprises.Acces- sion to the WTO in December 2002 has locked Armenia into a liberal foreign trade regime. The early and swift privatization of land was particularly impressive and stands in contrast to all other CIS coun- tries. Land ownership reforms have continued with an acceleration of land registration processes and streamlined titles issuance to farmers. These actions have been followed by the development of rural land 33 34 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth markets. The government adopted a privatization program in 2000 that resulted in privatization of 75 percent of the large public enter- prises and almost all of the SMEs. For those enterprises that were not sold following three attempts at privatization, the government established appropriate exit strategies for public enterprise reorgani- zation or liquidation. The government implemented several structural reforms in the energy sector, which included undertaking the financial and technical restructuring of the sector, increasing tariffs, establishing a regulatory framework, improving the collection of electricity bills, and reduc- ing cross-subsidization. The price of electricity reflects cost recovery. In addition, the government mitigated the adverse impact of tariff increases on the poor through increasing the well-targeted family benefits. Furthermore, the government privatized the Electricity Dis- tribution Company (EDC) in 2002. Since its privatization, the EDC has improved its financial performance significantly. The government has ensured that the privatized electricity distribution company will comply with its license. The government also carried out a wide range of reforms to improve the regulatory framework for utilities and infrastructure, especially for the power sector. The role and the independence of the Energy Regulatory Commission (ERC) were strengthened and a strategy was developed to improve the efficiency of the nonprivatized parts of the power sector. In addition, the government established a single utility regulator based on the ERC; adopted the necessary legal framework to ensure its financial autonomy; and transferred the economic regula- tions of the energy, drinking water, and telecommunications sectors to the single Public Services Regulatory Commission (PSRC). The gov- ernment also carried out performance monitoring and a public infor- mation program to ensure that people are made aware of the power sector's performance in a timely and credible manner. Other utilities also underwent deep reforms and experienced a gradual increase in private sector participation. The government adopted the Integrated Financial Rehabilitation Plan (IFRP) for pub- lic utilities--covering electricity, drinking water, irrigation, and urban electric transport--to guide the policy reforms and to ensure the ultimate commercialization of the utilities. The government made adequate provisions in the annual budgets to support the financial recovery plan of the transport and water sectors in order to ensure that full payments are made to the energy sector. Reforms in the water sector included the financial restructuring of drinking water compa- nies, tariff increases, the adoption of a new water code, and improved collections. In addition, the government adopted a schedule for irriga- tion tariff increases in 2002­07 to provide full cost recovery tariffs for the irrigation system by 2007. Constraints to Sustained Growth 35 The government undertook several reform measures in the banking sector to improve the lending environment. The government restruc- tured two weak and failing banks, adopted the law on the bankruptcy of banks, increased the minimum capital requirements of the banks, and modernized the loan classification system. In the area of banking supervision, the Central Bank developed manuals both on- and offsite, started on-site supervision, and introduced regulations for the inter- nal control of banks. The payments system was improved, diagnostic studies were completed that resulted in the revoking of the licenses of six banks, a credit registry at the Central Bank was introduced, and confidence in the banking system was enhanced by the introduction of a deposit guarantee system and a series of accounting standards. The government also adopted the law on insurance, took initial steps to strengthen creditor rights and corporate governance for banks, estab- lished a regulatory and supervisory environment for insurance, and adopted regulations and procedures for the Securities Commission. These reforms contributed to enhancing confidence in the banking system and accelerating credit growth. THE RECORD IN A COMPARATIVE CONTEXT Some interesting comparative insights can be gleaned from the exami- nation of European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) transition indicators of progress (normalized for the purpose of this analysis) in the liberalization of prices, small-scale privatization, and foreign trade and exchange rate regimes (EBRD, various years).2 They all comprise measures at the core of the first-generation reforms (see Figure 2.1). Armenia and Lithuania began their journey toward a market-based economy from the same level, estimated at around 35 percent of the "desired" level. Nevertheless, while Lithuania made a big leap in 1993­94, Armenia initially lagged behind. However, both countries had largely completed first-generation reforms by 1998. It is interesting to note that the SEE-4 economies, although at the same starting point in terms of EBRD scores, have lagged behind Armenia in implementing first-generation reforms. CONSTRAINTS TO FUTURE GROWTH The preceding section of this chapter has argued that the factors under- pinning Armenia's impressive growth performance are durable stabil- ity in macroeconomic stance and the pursuit of first-generation struc- tural reforms, price and trade liberalization, a liberal foreign exchange regime, the privatization of all small enterprises and some medium Box 2.1 Armenia--Production Statistics by Sector Output Value added Sector Sector share share Sector US$ in total US$ in total Wheat, potatoes, and legumes 155.5 3.6 98.7 4.6 Vegetables and fruits including grapes and dried fruits 132.5 3.1 115.4 5.4 Vegetable oils and fats 15.8 0.4 1.0 0.0 Crops not elsewhere classified 103.1 2.4 81.1 3.8 Diary products including eggs and milk 342.6 7.9 168.2 7.8 Beef, pork, mutton, and poultry meat 159.0 3.7 66.9 3.1 Energy--oil and natural gas 75.7 1.7 0.0 0.0 Mining and quarrying 65.9 1.5 39.4 1.8 Food processing and beverages 430.7 9.9 158.1 7.4 Tobacco products 80.9 1.9 13.7 0.6 Light manufacturing and textiles 52.6 1.2 5.3 0.2 Chemicals, rubbers, and plastics 53.0 1.2 10.4 0.5 Mineral products and precious stones 269.3 6.2 40.7 1.9 Metals and metal products 109.9 2.5 43.6 2.0 Machinery, equipment, and motor vehicles and precision optical equipment 88.7 2.0 5.8 0.3 Other manufacturing 61.2 1.4 17.9 0.8 Electricity, gas, and water supply 152.0 3.5 111.6 5.2 Electricity supply and distribution 163.2 3.8 102.1 4.8 Construction 518.3 11.9 298.6 13.9 Transport and communications 259.9 6.0 153.1 7.1 Retail and wholesale trade and public catering 447.2 10.3 288.6 13.5 Banking, lending, and insurance 51.6 1.2 35.7 1.7 Governance, defense, and public procurements 362.5 8.4 197.7 9.2 Other services not elsewhere classified 93.7 2.2 23.6 1.1 Housing and dwellings 92.6 2.1 68.2 3.2 Total agriculture 908.6 20.9 531.3 24.8 Total manufacturing 1,036.4 23.9 251.9 11.7 Total industry 403.5 9.3 194.7 9.1 Total construction 518.3 11.9 298.6 13.9 Total services 1,470.8 33.9 869.0 40.5 Total 4,337.6 100.0 2145.5 100.0 Source: Armenia Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) 2002. See Part 2 of this book. Note: The above table displays Armenia's production and trade statistics for 2002. The larg- est single output sectors were construction, trade, and processed foods. Other large activities include the public sector, cut gems, transportation services, and electricity output. Food is probably more important to the Armenian economy than it appears in this table. If we com- bined the three largest food industries (processed foods, dairy, and meats and grains), then consumable food would be the largest single industry in Armenia. The total combined output for these four industries accounts for 25.1 percent of total production. If we reorganize these statistics according to value added, a different story emerges. Value added is generally high in the nontradable sectors such as construction, trade, banking, and public services. Food and food products (crops, vegetables, and fruits) are the leading tradable sectors in the economy. Growth in these sectors is more likely to contribute to higher personal income for Armenians in the short term. Other manufacturing sectors such as machinery and gem cutting have Supply to domestic market Exports Import Share in Share in Share in US$ output US$ output US$ Armington supply 155.2 99.8 0.3 0.2 50.7 24.6 126. 9 95.8 5.6 4.2 24.0 15.9 15.8 100.0 0.0 0.0 14.7 48.1 98.1 95.2 5.0 4.8 19.9 16.9 342.1 99.9 0.5 0.1 6.8 2.0 158.9 99.9 0.1 0.1 23.1 12.7 75.7 100.0 -- -- 156.7 67.4 27.2 41.3 38.7 58.7 1.1 4.0 379.6 88.1 51.1 11.9 46.7 11.0 77.3 95.6 3.6 4.4 30.0 28.0 23.5 44.7 29.1 55.3 40.2 63.1 44.7 84.4 8.3 15.6 81.8 64.6 11.3 4.2 258.0 95.8 206.4 94.8 65.3 59.4 44.7 40.6 55.3 45.9 33.0 37.2 55.7 62.8 185.7 84.9 56.1 91.8 5.0 8.2 52.1 48.2 152.0 100.0 -- -- 0.0 0.0 149.8 91.8 13.4 8.2 5.6 3.6 512.1 98.8 6.2 1.2 2.8 0.5 172.2 66.3 87.7 33.7 24.0 12.2 447.2 100.0 -- -- 0.0 0.0 44.9 87.0 6.7 13.0 11.3 20.1 354.8 97.9 7.7 2.1 7.8 2.2 23.1 24.6 70.6 75.4 60.5 72.4 92.6 100.0 -- -- 0.0 0.0 897.0 98.7 11.5 1.3 139.3 13.4 690.9 66.7 455.5 43.9 698.3 50.3 254.9 63.2 38.7 9.6 157.8 38.2 512.1 98.8 6.2 1.2 2.8 0.5 1,284.7 87.3 186.1 12.7 109.2 7.8 3,639.6 83.9 698.0 16.1 1,107.4 23.3 the lowest share of value added in production, which implies that these industries comprise mostly intermediate inputs and that the short-term spillover effects from these sectors are insignificant. These sectors have, however, the highest export potential and have considerable implications for the medium-term and long-term growth of the Armenian economy. Some industries, such as cellular telecommunications, mining, or utilities, may exhibit a high degree of value added in production, but since those industries are capital-intensive, their contribu- tion to personal income will depend upon who collects the capital rents. For example, a for- eign-owned mine may capture significant rents, but most of this income could be forwarded offshore. The table above also displays exports, imports, and total domestic supply for each sector. Import and export volume is dominated by a single sector: uncut and cut gems. This sector alone represents about one-fourth of total trade volume for Armenia. Export potential is highest in the manufacturing sector, as most of the manufacturing subsectors show high export/output shares. 38 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 2.1 Progress in First-Generation Reforms as Revealed in Values of the EBRD-Based Aggregate Index in 1992­2004 in Selected Transition Economies 100 90 80 70 60 50 percent 40 30 20 10 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 year Lithuania CEEC-8 median Armenia SEE-4 median Source: Authors' calculations based on data from EBRD Annual Transition Reports. Note: The aggregate is the average of scores ranging between 1 (no liberalization) and 4.5 (liberalization at the levels of highly developed market economies) for prices, for- eign trade and exchange rate regime, and small privatization. It has been normalized with 1=0 and 4.5=100. SEE-4 includes Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Macedonia, and Serbia and Montenegro. and large enterprises, and the reversion of land to private ownership. The experience of advanced transition countries (CEEC and the Baltics) suggests that the following factors are important for sustained rates of growth: undertaking deep structural and institutional reforms cen- tered on creating contestable and competitive conditions for economic activity, entrenching property rights, facilitating banking and capital markets to provide low-cost intermediation, fostering an environment for innovation and product diversification, and locking in integration with international services and factor markets. Constraints to Sustained Growth 39 In identifying the constraints to the maintenance of high growth rates, the framework building on the idea of growth diagnostics3 can be useful. This permits a focus on the country-specific constraints to growth as the first step toward identifying a growth strategy for the country. The question to be answered is not so much, "What creates success?" but rather, "What are the constraints to better performance?" The work on growth diagnostics suggests that constraints could be shown as a tree diagram (see Figure 2.2). The driving factors of growth are seen as the private return to accumulation (that portion of the social return which is subject to private appropriability) less the cost of financing accumulation. In Armenia, observation indicates that social Figure 2.2 Challenge of Sustaining and Diversifying Sources of Growth toward Those with Stronger Spillover Effects Macroeconomic stability (good progress) High social Low private High cost returns appropriability of finances Productivity gains Competition framework Low domestic savings (satisfactory progress) weak (underlying vulnerability) (binding constraint) Investment in Weak bank corporate infrastructure Poor contract governance (satisfactory progress) enforcement (structural weakness) (binding constraint) Stable price, fiscal, trade Insecure regime for regimes Corruption and arbitrary secured loans (good progress) state behavior (structural weakness) (structural weakness) Scientific and entrepreneurial Burdensome cost of endowment backbone services (satisfactory progress) (telecom, transport) (binding constraint) Diaspora and emigrant support Outmoded investment in (good progress) human capital (structural weakness) Source: World Bank staff. 40 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth returns are high, based on the rising productivity of factor use, but pri- vate appropriability is compromised by poor property rights protection and enforcement, inflexible labor regimes, and arbitrary customs and tax administration. The cost of finance remains high, partly because of low domestic savings rates but more fundamentally because of barriers to intermediation related to secured transactions and extremely weak corporate governance. The evidence suggests that the high growth rates of the past decade have resulted from productivity gains in the use of labor, with little additional labor use. Evidence for weaknesses in private appropri- ability and inadequacies in the competition framework comes from the large degree of informality in the economy (discussed in detail in Chapter 3), the use of informal mechanisms for the protection of prop- erty rights, and the perpetuation of monopoly positions in produc- tion and distribution. Evidence for the intermediation constraint arises from the internalization of finance through firms and business groups, the high shadow price of capital, and the dependence of investment on external financing. EVALUATING THE STATE OF THE BINDING CONSTRAINTS While progress in first-generation reforms (such as free price forma- tion, the convertibility of domestic currency for current account trans- actions, liberal trade and investment regimes, and private ownership) can be readily assessed, this is not so with second-generation reforms covering, as a rule, actions, policies, and institutions where progress can be gauged, at times, only indirectly. Moreover, the binding con- straints are usually highly intertwined. Progress in one area can be neutralized by the lack of progress in another area. For example, large- scale privatization may be completed, but its benefits may not materi- alize if privatized companies are subsidized by still state-owned banks (the situation in the Czech Republic in the mid-1990s), or if competi- tion policy is too weak. Excessive minimum capital requirements or instabilities in tax or customs policy or administration may offset the benefits for business formation and growth offered by the simplicity of procedures for business entry. Figure 2.3 compares structural reform progress in Armenia to three other country groupings. The figure uses a structural reform index (SRI), which was derived from EBRD transition indicators for com- petition policy, government and enterprise restructuring, large-scale privatization, banking reform and interest rate liberalization, and policy and regulations for security markets and nonbank financial institutions.4 Constraints to Sustained Growth 41 Figure 2.3 Progress in Structural Reforms: Values of SRI, 1994­2004 70 60 50 40 percent 30 20 10 0 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 year Lithuania CEEC-8 median Armenia SEE-4 Source: Authors' calculations based on data from EBRD Annual Transition Reports. Note: The aggregate is the average of scores ranging between 1 (no liberalization) and 4.5 (liberalization at the levels of highly developed market economies) for govern- ment and enterprise restructuring, competition policy, banking reform and interest rate liberalization, security markets and nonbank financial institutions, and large-scale privatization. It has been normalized with 1=0 and 4.5=100. SEE-4 includes Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Macedonia, and Serbia and Montenegro. The results presented in Figure 2.3 show that moving to the insti- tutional environment of highly developed countries takes time. The median value of an SRI for new EU CEEC-85 member states stood in 2004 at 66 percent of the level of mature market economies. While this figure is above the level of institutional maturity achieved by Armenia (40 percent), the CEEC-8 countries have a long way to go to catch up with the highly developed countries. So does Armenia. The greatest "distance" (Table 2.1) separating it from institutions in Lithuania is in competition policy (at 29 percent of the "normal" desired level) and in security markets and nonbank financial institutions (29 percent). Competition policy and financial 42 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth intermediation are key binding constraints. Other institutional areas where the SRI index is below average for second-generation reforms are government and enterprise restructuring (38 percent) and banking reform and interest rate liberalization (38 percent). The most advanced area of structural reforms is large-scale privatization (67 percent). Another interesting observation that can be derived from data in Figure 2.3 is that Armenia's reforms have moved in leaps that extended over three to four years and that they appear to have slowed in the areas of competition policy, financial sector reforms, and governance over the past three years. The critical weaknesses in competition deserve particular attention. Although reforms and large investments in infrastructure have gen- erated a strong short-term growth response, the creation of a strong monopoly in the area of communications--a strategic sector--damages competitiveness and future growth. Telecommunications infrastructure in Armenia is currently one of the least developed in the CIS, despite the fact that it was among the earliest of the CIS to privatize. The 15- year monopoly granted to a private investor has led to the extremely high cost and poor quality of telecommunications services. Research shows the large and often economy-wide impact of the cost and diver- sity of telecommunications services on investment, international inte- gration, and growth. Competition in the backbone sectors remains restricted. Competi- tion forces tariffs down and boosts the quality of services, thus facili- tating progress in all other sectors. It also encourages utilization of a skilled, technically qualified labor force, which has traditionally been a comparative advantage for Armenia. Competition in back- bone services has strong spillover effects on household welfare and employment through multiple channels. Competition and transpar- ency in backbone services can also stimulate private investment (both domestic and foreign) and can entail technology transfer and techno- logical capacity building, as well as human resources development. (Box 2.2 discusses gains to be made from the liberalization of the service sectors.) The quality of service links is critical in the location decisions of multinational corporations and in a country's capacity to attract out- sourcing activities. Services linking production operations include procedures for the simplification and harmonization of international trade; the state of infrastructure and its management; and the provi- sion of such backbone services as telecommunications, banking, insur- ance, transportation, and business services. Together with customs, related border clearance regulatory procedures, technical standards regulations, and port efficiency, service links shape the ease and speed with which goods and services move across national borders and, Table 2.1 Progress with Second-Generation Reform, 1994­2004 Country 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Large-scale privatization Armenia 0 29 57 57 57 57 57 57 67 67 67 Lithuania 57 57 57 57 57 57 57 67 76 76 76 Government and enterprise restructuring Armenia 0 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 38 38 38 Lithuania 29 29 57 48 48 48 48 48 57 57 57 Banking reform and interest rate liberalization Armenia 0 29 29 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 Constraints Lithuania 29 57 57 57 57 57 57 57 57 57 57 Security markets and nonbank financial institutions Armenia 0 0 0 0 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 Lithuania 29 29 29 38 38 48 57 57 57 57 57 to Competition policy Sustained Armenia 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 29 29 29 29 Lithuania 29 29 29 38 38 38 48 57 57 57 57 Note: The EBRD transition scores ranging between 1 (absence of institutions supporting competitive markets) and 4.5 (presence of institutions at Gr the levels of highly developed market economies) are normalized with 1 = 0 and 4.5 = 100. The difference between 100 and the actual value repre- owth sents the distance to the level prevailing in highly developed market economies. Source: EBRD (various years). 43 44 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Box 2.2 Gains from the Liberalization of the Services Sectors The importance of backbone services such as finance, telecommunications, and transport is threefold. First, these services constitute major inputs into the production of goods and services--including agriculture--and their cost often accounts for a major share of the total cost of production. Con- sidering that services contribute on average around 10­20 percent to the production cost of a product and account for all trading costs (includ- ing transport, trade finance, insurance, communications, and distribution services), the savings from liberalization of the services sector can be sub- stantial (Hodge, 2002). Second, services related to education, training, and health influence the productivity and quality of human capital. Thanks to lower input costs and higher quality inputs, these services help industries and agri- culture improve their capacity to compete with imports. Last but not least, cheap backbone services combined with efficient and unobtrusive customs is necessary for domestic firms to participate in the emerging division of labor based on international outsourcing, just-in-time production, and supply-chain management. The poor qual- ity of backbone services and trade facilitation deters foreign firms from incorporating domestic firms into their supply chains and also acts as a barrier to other types of trade. This so-called supply chain network has been the fastest growing component of world trade over the last two decades, generating employment and assuring access to most dynamic markets. The liberalization of the services sector and its opening to external competition will improve the quality of these services and reduce their prices. Empirical research suggests that liberalization may generate gains that substantially exceed those that come from merchandise trade liber- alization undertaken in isolation. Cross-country growth regressions for ECA economies, juxtaposing EBRD transition indicators and per capita GDP growth, point to a strong, linear, positive relationship between service sector policy reform and per capita GDP growth (World Bank, 2005b). The econometric study of the impact of liberalization in basic telecommunications on sectoral performance in 86 countries has found that complete liberalization has paid off in terms of higher teledensity (8 percent higher than in countries following the route of partial liberaliza- tion) and labor productivity. See Fink, Mattoo, and Rathindran (2002). therefore, are crucial to trade in goods. The weakest link in the "serv- ice chain" in a country may tip the balance against including a firm in the global supply chain. As a consequence, improvements in the domestic business climate may limit positive economic effects if they are not accompanied by similar improvements in trade facilitation. In Constraints to Sustained Growth 45 short, weaknesses in any of these services may lead to the exclusion of a country by firms searching to outsource activities abroad. Finally, it may be noted that the indicator of progress in structural reforms appears also to provide a good measure of the quality of governance and the incidence of corruption. The value of the correla- tion coefficient for the values of the SRI for 27 transition economies in Europe and Central Asia and the Corruption Perception Index (CPI) compiled by Transparency International was 73 percent in 2004. The positive correlation is higher for governance indicators (which are an average of political stability, government effectiveness, and regu- latory quality)6 as compiled by the World Bank. For the 1998­2002 averages, its value was 93 percent. In other words, countries with higher values for the structural progress indicator are better governed and are less corrupt. SUMMARY Armenia's strong growth performance is due to the completion of first-generation structural reforms and the persistence of the condi- tions for macro-stability. In these respects, Armenia's growth perform- ance is much closer to the record of the CEEC-8 countries than to the CIS countries or the Balkan nations. Future opportunities for growth will depend on the pursuit of second-generation reforms: competition policy, banking and capital markets, deeper international integration, and the laying of the base for innovation and knowledge. The chief binding constraints to growth are the weak conditions for fair com- petition and the shallow nature of financial intermediation. A strong monopoly in telecommunications raises costs, and restrictive air trans- port policies also handicap the landlocked and blockaded economy; these are policy-induced failures. Such weaknesses prevent the emer- gence of strong supply chains, to the detriment of future growth. NOTES 1. Armenia's external debt management has improved over time. Bilateral debt to Russia has been settled through a number of debt-to-equity swap oper- ations, which improved Armenia's financial position but increased its depend- ence on Russia through the monopoly gas suppliers Gasprom and Itera. 2. These three policy areas constitute the core of the first-generation reforms. Scores for each area range between 1 for no reforms and 4.5 for reaching the average conditions in highly developed economies. These scores have been nor- malized for this analysis, with 1 = 0 and 4.5 = 100. The average of these three indicators amounts to the achieved progress in first-generation reforms. 46 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth 3. Hausman, Rodrik, and Velasco (2004). 4. The average of scores in each of these areas--normalized for a minimum score of 1 = 0 and a maximum score 4.5 = 100--is the indicator of progress in structural reforms. For countries that achieved institutional maturity in terms of establishing institutions supporting competitive markets, the indicator is equal to 100, whereas for those that have not started the process it equals zero. 5. The CEEC-8 are the Czech Republic, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Hungary, Poland, Slovenia, and the Slovak Republic. 6. There are two arguments in favor of focusing solely on these indicators: First, these indicators are critical dimensions of a business climate. Political stability affects investment decisions and, in extreme situations, its absence may disrupt economic activities. The quality of regulation is of little relevance unless supported by the government's capacity to enforce regulations. Second, three other indicators pertinent to such dimensions of governance--the rule of law, the control of corruption, and voice and accountability--are not taken into account because they do not yield extra information. For all transition economies, they are strongly correlated with the selected three indicators, with the values of correlation coefficients equal to or above 0.9. For the expla- nation and data, see www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/gov_data.htm. Chapter 3 The Framework for Competition W ithin the Armenian economy, competition is hobbled by weak- nesses in the law such as the competition law and the law on contracts. Moreover, the implementation of laws is undermined by the prevalence of informal institutions, such as in corporate govern- ance arrangements, by business regulation and governance rules and practices, such as arbitrary and unpredictable behavior of tax and cus- toms administrations, and by policy-induced high costs, such as tel- ecommunications and transport costs, that fall on the shoulders of all enterprises. The conditions for competition in Armenia diverge from the ideal of a level playing field, particularly in sectors related to trade and distribution, where monopoly profits are being earned and wel- fare losses are being imposed on the public. This chapter examines the interplay of these factors on the state of competition and the prospects for sustained growth.1 GOVERNANCE THAT HINDERS COMPETITIVENESS Given the intimate link between the governance standards and the level playing field essential for fair competition, this section provides an analysis based on tools developed by the World Bank to measure the quality of governance (Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi 2003). As international experience shows, FDI inflows and competition move up with improvements in the quality of governance. Table 3.1 reports the values of three indicators of governance (political stability, government effectiveness, and regulatory quality).2 A single aggregate index of gov- ernance is a simple average of the values of these three governance indicators. Their values range between ­2.5 (the worst case) and +2.5 (the best case). 47 48 Part I: Policies to Table 3.1 Selected Indicators of the Quality of Governance, 1998­2004 Sustain Political stability Government effectiveness Regulatory quality Aggregate (average) Economic Countries 1998 2000 2002 2004 1998 2000 2002 2004 1998 2000 2002 2004 1998 2000 2002 2004 Armenia ­0.5 ­0.7 ­0.5 ­0.5 ­0.5 ­0.9 ­0.4 ­0.3 ­0.5 ­0.4 0.1 0.1 ­0.5 ­0.7 ­0.3 ­0.3 Lithuania 0.4 0.4 0.9 0.9 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.7 0.2 0.5 1.0 1.2 0.3 0.4 0.8 0.9 Gr CEEC-8 median 0.9 0.8 1.0 0.9 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.7 0.8 0.6 0.9 1.1 0.7 0.7 0.9 0.9 owth CIS-11 median ­0.2 ­0.5 ­0.4 ­0.9 ­0.7 ­0.9 ­0.8 ­0.8 ­0.9 ­1.2 ­0.8 ­0.6 ­0.6 ­0.9 ­0.7 ­0.8 Source: Derived from data available at www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/gov_data.htm. The Framework for Competition 49 The quality of governance in Armenia has improved significantly since 1998, although the pace slowed down somewhat in 2002­04. The value of the aggregate indicator of governance, after a significant dete- rioration in 2000 triggered by both political instability and a contraction in the state's capacity to govern, improved considerably in 2000­02 and registered a less pronounced improvement in 2002­04 (see Figure 3.1). The improvement over 2000­02 coincided with progress made in second-generation reforms as captured in EBRD structural indicators, where the largest push came during this period. Armenia scores high among transition economies in terms of the overall quality of governance. Only the CEEC-8, new members of the EU, and three other countries in the EU-accession pipeline had, in 2004, higher values in the aggregate quality of governance. Further- more, Armenia's lead over other CIS economies increased significantly in 2002­04. While the median value of the aggregate quality of govern- ance in CIS-11 also increased in 2000­02, trends diverged in 2002­04, albeit with Armenia recording a limited improvement (Figure 3.2). Figure 3.1 Aggregate Quality of Governance, 1998­2004 1.00 0.80 ­2.5 0.60 and 0.40 +2.5 0.20 0.00 between -0.20 -0.40 ranging -0.60 Index, -0.80 -1.00 1998 2000 2002 2004 year Lithuania Armenia CEEC-8 median CIS-11 median Source: Derived from data available at www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/ gov_data.htm. Note: CIS-11 countries do not include Armenia. 50 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 3.2 The Average of Government Effectiveness and Regulatory Quality, 1998­2004 1.00 ­2.5 1.00 and 0.50 +2.5 0.00 between -0.50 ranging -1.00 Index, -1.50 1998 2000 2002 2004 year Lithuania Armenia CEEC-8 median CIS-11 median Source: Derived from data available at www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/ gov_data.htm. Note: CIS-11 countries do not include Armenia. But much remains to be done. Although the quality of governance is higher in Armenia than in other CIS economies, it is significantly lower than in Lithuania or in a "median CEEC-8" economy. It is also significantly lower than in Bulgaria, Romania, and Croatia. In areas directly relevant to setting the level playing field essential for fair competition (government effectiveness and the quality of regula- tions), the average of these indicators is higher than the overall quality of governance. The greatest progress Armenia has achieved is in regulatory quality, the only area in which the value of the indicator is in a "positive" domain. However, decent levels in terms of regulatory quality, in the presence of a low capacity of the state to effectively implement policies and regulation, will not lead to significant welfare gains. Since better governance usually implies a lower level of corruption, the question is whether international investors--surveyed by Trans- parency International--have noticed the improvement. The point to The Framework for Competition 51 Table 3.2 Values of CPIs for Selected Countries and Groups, 1999­2000 and 2002­04 Index, 2004 Countries 1999 2000 2002 2003 2004 1999=100 Armenia 2.5 2.5 3.0 3.0 3.1 124 Lithuania 3.8 4.1 4.8 4.8 4.6 121 Median CEEC-8 4.4 4.2 4.4 4.4 4.6 105 Median SEE-5 2.5 n.a. 2.5 2.7 2.7 108 Median EU-15 7.7 7.6 7.3 7.7 8.4 109 Armenia in percent of CEEC-8 median 57 60 68 68 67 118 Source: Derived from data available at the website of Transparency International: http://www.transparency.org. n.a. Not applicable. be borne in mind is that the two conditions, although significantly correlated, are different, as governance also embraces the supply of public goods and services and their quality. The values of the CPIs provide information on international investors' judgment of corrup- tion in a country in a comparative context. International investors' perception of the Armenian investment climate has improved sub- stantially since 1998 (Table 3.2). While progress in reducing opportunities for rent seeking has not been impressive, Armenia has maintained its edge over other CIS economies. However, while the values of the CPI for Armenia in relation to CEEC-8 increased between 1999 and 2002, no perceptible improvement has occurred since then. Since the values of the CPI are low, indicating high levels of graft, the challenge is to introduce measures that will enhance transparency and simplify regulations. Considering fairly low levels of government capacity (as indicated by the value of government effectiveness indicator) in the implemen- tation and enforcement of laws and regulations, simplicity and clarity in the design of regulations is of importance. REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT WEAKNESSES THAT IMPEDE COMPETITION While the Transparency International CPI scores and the World Bank governance indicators capture either the perception of investors of the extent of graft in a country or an overall assessment of a country's 52 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth capacity to govern, the World Bank's Doing Business Survey captures tangible "legal" components of the investment climate together with the cost burden and time burden imposed on businesses across 145 countries (Djankov, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer 2000).3 The survey is a useful diagnostic tool for conducting an initial assessment of the quality of the business environment, identifying most binding constraints, and assessing the overall ease/difficulty of doing business in Armenia in comparison with a selected group of countries (CIS and CEEC-10 economies). Armenia performs strikingly well in many meas- ures of regulation and the business environment, but nevertheless has a large informal economy, estimated to be in the range of one-third to nearly one-half of the size of the registered economy (Tunyan 2005). The next section of this chapter considers why this might be so, and attempts to drill down into the specific factors in the regulatory regime that constitute the binding constraints to fair competition. In particular, attention is paid to the interactions between the various characteristics of the business climate. Thus, for example, strong foreign trade facilita- tion measures will be of little relevance if the domestic environment discourages the entry of new businesses and encourages the exit of firms either for good or to the informal economy. Similarly, the limited capacity of firms to recover due payments from other firms discour- ages increased ties and limits the intensity of business activity, with negative consequences for domestic production and exports. THE EASE OF DOING BUSINESS IN TRANSITION COUNTRIES Table 3.3 presents the ranking of CIS and CEEC-10 economies in terms of the formal ease of doing business.4 Armenia ranks sixth among 20 transition economies. Doing business across all areas is on aver- age easier than in three new EU member states--Hungary, Poland, and Slovenia--and in all other CIS countries as well as Bulgaria and Romania. Only the Baltic states, the Czech Republic, and the Slovak Republic--all of them with strong reform credentials--score higher than Armenia. Armenia owes its high ranking to the procedural ease in hiring and firing employees, the simplicity and effectiveness of enforcing contracts, and effective procedures for closing a business. Its weakest areas are the registering of property, access to credit, and the large severance pay- ments that must be made when staff is fired.5 Overall, however, even in the most streamlined and reformed areas, the level is well below the best practice in transition economies. The gap is particularly large for labor market flexibility and registering property for Armenia. Table 3.3 Relative Ease of Doing Business in CIS and CEEC-10 Economies, 2005 Starting Flexibility of Registering Enforcing Closing Protecting Getting Ease of Country business employment property contracts business investors credit doing business Armenia 47 64 38 65 68 50 37 53 Azerbaijan 44 33 29 56 43 33 24 38 Belarus 18 50 48 54 44 17 44 39 Bulgaria 35 46 19 48 41 33 69 42 Czech Republic 33 56 28 72 18 100 89 57 Estonia 40 37 40 83 45 67 63 53 Georgia 39 51 18 54 53 83 56 50 Hungary 34 38 27 76 36 83 40 48 Kazakhstan 41 69 18 60 24 83 23 45 The Kyrgyz Republic 70 54 22 28 53 50 31 44 Latvia 48 30 15 77 100 83 70 61 Framework Lithuania 58 37 74 86 68 100 40 66 Moldova 33 50 26 51 41 50 36 41 Poland 32 49 19 51 60 67 57 48 Romania 79 17 17 51 27 33 53 39 for Russian Federation 43 69 21 62 77 50 13 48 Competition Slovak Republic 39 100 27 49 31 100 54 57 Slovenia 28 28 20 45 27 67 48 38 Ukraine 27 17 14 65 32 50 28 33 Uzbekistan 33 39 10 45 47 67 39 40 Worldwide 52 0 10 77 58 86 54 48 Source: Authors' calculations based on data in World Bank Doing Business database. 53 54 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth "REVEALED" EASE OF DOING BUSINESS The Doing Business Survey indicators measure the extent to which a country deviates from the best practice on each indicator within each area; they do not provide information on the comparative restrictive- ness of indicators within a country. An examination of the size of the informal economy throws light on such restrictiveness. Three causes of informality are important: the chances of getting credit, the fear of predatory administration, and a lack of trust in the state capacity to enforce contracts. While the survey captures both getting credit and contract enforcement, it does not capture informal administrative inter- ventions. Furthermore, the overall ranking procedure assigns the same weight to all areas of doing business. This book takes the average of the performance in terms of the informal economy and the ease of doing business as an indicator of the quality of the business environment. This indicator is referred to as the "revealed" ease of doing business. The large size of the informal sector, as is the case in Armenia, suggests that the hassle cost of doing business is higher than its high score would indicate. This observation applies also to other transition countries, as the value of a correlation coefficient between the values of the overall ease of doing business indicators and the respective size of the informal economy, though negative, is very low at 38 percent. This runs counter to the expectation that in countries with higher values of the aggregate "ease of doing business" indicator, the infor- mal economy should be smaller. In other words, the ranking in terms of formal overall ease of doing business diverges rather significantly from the ranking based on the size of the informal sphere. Further- more, while the ranking in terms of the size of the informal sector in transition countries is highly correlated with the incidence of cor- ruption as measured by Transparency International's CPI (correlation coefficient of 79 percent), the ranking in terms of formal ease of doing business is not so correlated; the value of the correlation coefficient is only plus 33 percent. None of the above comes as surprise. The ease of doing business indicators for CIS and CEEC countries cannot capture all of the factors determining the quality of the business environment. First, they have not been designed to do so, as they do not capture all variables rel- evant to the cost of doing business. For example, they do not take into account the fact that predatory tax administration operating according to ad hoc rules may dramatically increase the hassle cost of doing business, discouraging start-ups and encouraging exit from business activity. Second, the procedure used here to rank transition economies gives equal weights to all variables describing the formal regime of doing business. Countries with best practices on most counts may The Framework for Competition 55 rank relatively high in rankings despite weaknesses on other counts. For example, a small number of procedures, speed, and low admin- istrative fees to start a business would matter little in the presence of a huge minimum capital requirement. Since the size of the informal sector, which for transition economies happens to go in hand with the increase in the incidence of corruption, appears to be negatively linked to the friendliness of a business envi- ronment, a comprehensive assessment of the quality of the business climate should take into account both the formal ease of doing busi- ness and the size of the informal sector. One way of doing this is sim- ply to normalize the size of the informal sector in terms of its lowest level among transition economies (that is, the Slovak Republic with 18.9 percent, would be 100) and incorporate it into the final measure referred to as "revealed" overall ease of doing business.6 Table 3.4 presents the ranking in terms of revealed ease of doing business. The "fall" in Armenia's position, as well as in the position of other CIS economies, is a reminder that not only do other factors (not covered in the Doing Business Survey) determine the quality of the business environment but also that, within various areas, binding constraints exist that neutralize the positive impact of other changes. The ranking approximates well the progress achieved by the countries in building an institutional environment to support private business activity. It illustrates that in Armenia (as in Georgia and Russia), an apparently friendly regime is not sufficient to curb informality, an outcome that is detrimental to economic growth and productivity. The factors that countervail the strengths of the regime are discussed next. WEAKNESSES AND STRENGTHS OF FORMAL REGULATORY REGIME The formal regulatory burden of conducting business in Armenia is relatively low, especially when benchmarked against the CIS and CEEC-8 economies. Table 3.5 presents values of respective indicators for Armenia, the CIS economies, Russia, the CEEC-8, and New Zea- land. It also provides information on the best practice across the globe for each indicator. Indicators describe formal arrangements in terms of time and complexity in the following seven areas: starting a business, hiring and firing workers, registering property, enforcing contracts, closing a business, protecting investors, and getting credit. Armenia outperforms Russia in all indicators except the following: it is more difficult to hire in Armenia, it costs more to enforce a contract, and creditors recover less in terms of the value of a loan. Armenia rep- resents the best practice in the CEEC and CIS in two indicators: the 56 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Table 3.4 The Size of the Informal Economy and the "Revealed" Ease of Doing Business Informal "Revealed" Difference economy, ease between percent of doing current of 2003 business Previous and Memorandum: GNI indicator ranking previous CPI, 2000­04 Armenia 46.3 46.8 6 5 3.0 Azerbaijan 60.1 34.5 18 2 1.9 Belarus 48.1 39.2 17 1 4.1 Bulgaria 36.9 46.4 13 ­1 4.0 Czech Republic 19.1 77.8 4 ­2 3.9 Estonia n/a 74.0 5 ­2 5.7 Georgia 67.3 39.3 7 10 2.1 Hungary 25.1 61.5 10 ­5 4.9 Kazakhstan 43.2 44.6 11 3 2.3 Kyrgyz Republic 39.8 45.8 12 1 2.2 Latvia 39.9 53.9 2 5 3.8 Lithuania 30.3 64.2 1 3 4.7 Moldova 45.1 41.4 14 2 2.3 Poland 27.6 58.2 8 ­2 3.8 Romania 34.4 47.2 16 ­6 2.7 Russian Federation 46.1 44.4 9 6 2.7 Slovak Republic 18.9 78.5 3 ­2 3.8 Slovenia 27.1 53.7 19 ­11 6.0 Ukraine 52.2 34.6 20 ­1 2.3 Uzbekistan 34.1 47.7 15 ­6 2.5 Source: Authors' calculations based on data in World Bank's Doing Business database and data from Web site of Transparency International. Note: CPI is the average for 2000­04. It assumes values between 1 (maximum incidence of corruption) and 10 (minimum). difficulty of firing index and the cost of closing a business (Table 3.5). However, neither indicator is necessarily an indication of the superior quality of the formal arrangements in the corresponding areas of hir- ing and firing workers and closing a business. Since the worst indicator does the most to discourage business activ- ity and thus contributes to the higher size of the informal sector under most circumstances, the following question is pertinent to an over- all assessment of the regulatory and policy hassle felt by businesses: which aspects of Armenia's regulatory environment are the most burdensome for private firms? While in each area Armenia's overall The Framework for Competition 57 score is high compared to its peers in the CIS and CEEC-8 countries, within some areas indicators point to weaknesses. These areas are labor markets (firing and hiring), getting credit, and contract enforce- ment. Contract enforcement takes more money than in CIS and CEEC- 8 countries (18 percent of the debt as compared with 14 percent), but other indicators favor Armenia. Despite its importance as a dimension of labor markets, Armenia's business environment has significant weaknesses even when bench- marked only against other CIS countries. The high value of the "dif- ficulty of hiring" index combined with an obligation to pay the wages of a fired worker over a period of 30 weeks reduces the flexibility of Armenia's labor market significantly. More favorable values for the remaining two indicators do little to lessen the constraints on busi- nesses in hiring when the demand for their product goes up and in firing when conditions deteriorate. Considering that research shows the crucial importance of labor market flexibility for both reducing unemployment and boosting investment, Armenia's poor performance in this area is a serious shortcoming. While the relationship between low unemployment rates and high flexibility is empirically firmly established, the impact of labor market flexibility on FDI appears to be significant as well. A recent study (Javorcik and Spatareanu 2004b) using the labor market indicators from the Doing Business database for 2002 shows that, all else being equal, flexibility in labor markets has a significant impact on FDI flows. For example, if the flexibility of the host country's labor market increases from the level of the Slovak Republic (inflexible prior to reforms in 2003) to the level of Hungary (flexible), the volume of investment goes up by between 14 and 18 percent. Moreover, FDI in the services sectors appears to be more sensitive to labor regulations than investments in manufacturing. Armenia also scores relatively low in terms of protection of inves- tors, with the disclosure index of 3 putting it on a par with Russia. The absence of regulations compelling disclosure has several nega- tive consequences: investments are lower as potential investors fear expropriation, the stock market is undercapitalized, economic growth is lower than under full disclosure, and returns from investment are lower. (World Bank 2005a, pp. 56­57). But more powerful financial constraints to doing business relate to other legal underpinnings of financial markets in Armenia. Although the cost of creating collateral is very low by both regional and inter- national standards, and the legal rights index is within a median range, there are countervailing deficiencies. The lack of market infor- mation on the quality of borrowers, combined with the absence of a 58 Table 3.5 Doing Business in Armenia and Selected Comparators in 2004 Best practice Part CIS CEEC-8 in CEEC New Best Area Indicator Armenia median Russia median and CIS Zealand practice I: Policies Starting a business Number of procedures 10 10 9 9 5 2 2 Time (days) 25 32 36 46 18 12 2 Cost (% of income per capita) 7.0 14.2 6.7 12.0 3.7 0.2 0.0 to Minimum capital Sustain (% of income per capita) 4.5 23.3 5.6 47.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 Hiring and Difficulty of hiring index firing workers (0­100) 33 33 0 33 0 11 0 Economic Rigidity of hours index (0­100) 40 60 60 60 20 0 0 Difficulty of firing index (0­100) 10 60 20 60 10 10 0 Gr Rigidity of employment owth index (0­100) 28 44 27 44 10 7 0 Firing costs: severance payments in weeks of wages)a 30 21 17 21 17 0 0 Registering property Number of procedures 4 7 5 5 3 2 1 Time (days) 18 71 354 72 3 2 1 Cost (% of property value) 0.9 2.2 9.5 2.1 0.5 0.2 0.0 Enforcing contracts Number of procedures 24 29 29 24 17 19 11 Time (days) 195 324 395 333 150 50 27 Cost (% of debt) 17.8 18.0 9.5 10.8 8.1 4.8 4.2 Table 3.5 (continued) Best practice CIS CEEC-8 in CEEC New Best Area Indicator Armenia median Russia median and CIS Zealand practice Closing a business Time of insolvency (years) 1.9 3.8 1.5 2.5 1.1 2.0 0.41 Cost (% of estate) 4.0 7.4 4.0 18 4.0 4.0 1.0 Recovery rate (cents on the US$) 39.6 5.3 48.4 39.8 85.0 71.4 92.0 Protecting investors Investors disclosure index (0­7) 3 3 3 5 6 5 7 The Getting credit Cost to create collateral Framework (% income per capita) 0.9 3.6 11.6 3.7 0.6 0.0 0.0 Legal rights index 0­10 4 5.0 3 6 9 9 10 Credit information index (0­6) .. 0.0 0 4 5 5 6 Public registry coverage (per 1,000 adults) .. 0.0 0 6 44 0 637 for Private bureau coverage Competition (per 1,000 adults) 0 0.0 0 17 380 978 1,000 Source: Data from World Bank (2005a). a. As noted, this cost will be greatly eased once the new labor code is put into effect. .. Negligible. 59 60 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth secured transactions framework, is a binding constraint on lending in Armenia. Movable property cannot be used effectively as collateral to secure loans, as repossession is time-consuming and costly. Neither can collateral-based lending function effectively in the absence of an effective framework for creating and enforcing claims. Banks price in the corresponding (large) risk into the lending spread. Armenia's disadvantage is lower in registering property: the number of procedures is only slightly higher (4 versus 3) but it takes signifi- cantly more time to complete the process (18 days versus 3 days). The same applies to closing a business. The time of insolvency is longer (1.9 years versus 1.2 years), although it is lower than in New Zealand (2 years), with the "best international practice" at 0.41 years. The recov- ery rate (that is, the percent of what creditors collect on their debt) of 39.6 cents on the U.S. dollar is below Lithuania's level, but similar to the CEEC-8 median of 39.8 cents. An indicator in starting a business area that is lagging behind comparator values is the cost of starting business, which is higher than in Lithuania but lower than the median value for the CEEC-8. Although Armenia appears to be a top performer among CIS coun- tries, it still has to neutralize the negative effects of being land-locked, as well as its remoteness to the centers of gravity of global markets. The frame of reference for Armenia's regulatory reforms should be at least the best practice in the CIS/CEEC-10 region, if not best inter- national practice. Compared to either reference point, the differences are huge, even though Armenia fares quite well overall compared to other former centrally planned economies. THE LINK BETWEEN THE FORMAL EASE OF DOING BUSINESS AND THE LARGE INFORMAL ECONOMY Surveys covering various areas of the business environment record a general dissatisfaction of businesses with the quality of regulations, administrative requirements, and bureaucratic behavior of state agen- cies, despite some improvements since 2002. The reasons for this assessment are manifold. The first barrier to conducting business arises from the difficulties encountered in interaction with tax administration, compounded by unstable and frequently changed rules and tax rates. This is perceived as a bigger problem than corruption by both local- and foreign-owned firms, and for the former it continues to be regarded as a significant bar- rier.7 Administrative Regulatory Cost Surveys (RCSs), which have been conducted annually in Armenia by the Foreign Investment Advisory Service (FIAS) since 2000, persistently identify tax administration as the The Framework for Competition 61 biggest obstacle. For example, in both 2003 and 2004 more than 80 per- cent of respondents identified tax administration as the largest obstacle. This view appears to be shared by foreign-owned firms to the tune of 90 percent of all respondents (FIAS 2003). Furthermore, foreign-owned businesses complained that the tax burden in 2003 increased consider- ably compared with 1999. Uncertainty associated with frequent changes in policy was flagged by around three-fourths of RCS respondents. The second barrier relates to the cost that businesses must incur in order to meet the requirements of the country's administrative regula- tions. According to the RCS, the costs remain huge and there has been no major improvement over the past several years. The costs are not related to formal and informal payments but above all to the burden in terms of time and resources that firms need to allocate to assure regulatory compliance. A corrupt bureaucracy applies regulations arbitrarily. The high level of corruption results in firms' directing activity underground in order to reduce their vulnerability to extortion by government offi- cials. Changes in legislation are only rarely announced or publicly disclosed before implementation. Bureaucratic procedures can be bur- densome and time-consuming when an investor negotiates a contract with the foreign government, as the contract may require the approval of several ministries. Widespread corruption continues to affect busi- ness and most often takes the form of bribery. According to a business climate survey carried out by the World Bank in 2004, 84 percent of companies surveyed were dissatisfied with legislative and administrative regulations in the country (World Bank 2005a). Armenia's business legislation in general is good, but imple- mentation of the laws has been poor, which has hampered business operations. The prevailing negative sentiment had worsened com- pared with previous years: the indicator stood at 63 percent in 2003 and 50 percent in 2002. The unequal treatment of companies by the authorities and unfair competition were the most widely cited impedi- ments to doing business. The third barrier is the practice by customs of extracting "irregu- lar" payments from businesses, a complaint that is corroborated by nontransparent procedures. Customs clearance procedures are applied with equal zeal not only to imports but also to exports, which further corroborates the opinions about customs erecting a nontariff trade bar- rier; generally, in other countries, customs efforts are largely directed only at imports. The time needed to complete customs clearance and the amount of effort undertaken by firms to deal with customs are shocking, especially for exports. Furthermore, the most obvious ben- efits of the computerization of customs services (that is, reducing the release time of consignments and slashing the documentation or 62 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth bureaucratic burden placed on a trader or a customs broker) have so far failed to materialize. Neither traders nor customs brokers have access to the system. The old practice of bureaucratic delays fueling corruption, combined with a lack of capacity in customs administra- tion, continues. Although Armenia is no exception to the generally poor record in most transition countries in establishing the rule of law and strength- ening the courts, the situation has improved on several important counts.8 For example, Armenia has made gains in judicial reforms. Armenia is "the only country where significantly more respondents viewed the courts as fair in 2002 than in 1999" (Anderson, Bernstein, and Gray 2005). However, considering that in 2000 only 2 percent of firms surveyed viewed judges as honest (CES 2000), the improvement should be measured from the low starting point. Fairness, however, is only one dimension of efficiently functioning courts. Other important dimensions from the point of view of conduct- ing business include the perception of the honesty or dishonesty of judges, the capacity to implement enacted commercial laws, and the ability to adjudicate disputes in an efficient and timely manner. It appears that firms regard Armenia's courts as relatively honest. In response to a question about the frequency of unofficial payments when dealing with the courts, firms surveyed under BEEPS identified the courts as not extracting bribes on a significant scale. The percent of firms negatively assessing courts in this dimension was among the lowest in the region--on a par with Slovenia, Estonia, and Lithuania. Moreover, Armenia, together with Lithuania, recorded the greatest improvement among 26 transition economies between 1999 and 2002. Although most respondents perceive courts in transition countries as neither honest nor fair, the percent of those that do not share this view is comparatively high at 30 percent, putting Armenia in the same group as Croatia and Latvia. Armenia, like most other transition economies, has experienced a growing gap between the enacted legislation setting the grounds for the market economy and the capacity of the courts to implement new commercial laws. This gap between the extent of commercial legis- lation existing in 1999 ("legal extensiveness") and the degree to which it was being implemented at that time ("legal effectiveness") was par- ticularly high for Armenia--well above the level in other transition countries (EBRD 1999). Although this "implementation gap" persisted in 2002, it has fallen sharply to levels similar to that in the Czech Republic. The ability of courts to adjudicate disputes in an efficient and timely manner reduces uncertainty in actual or potential business deals. Armenia, together with Hungary, the former Yugoslav Republic The Framework for Competition 63 of Macedonia, Latvia, Lithuania, and the Czech Republic, showed the largest improvement in the perceived speediness of courts between 1999 and 2002. While in 1999 only 10 percent of firms viewed courts as rapid in Armenia, this proportion rose in 2002 to 25 percent of respondents--the level comparable to Hungary. This proportion should rise further once the case management and court administra- tion systems currently developed are put in place. To summarize, the reasons for the large size of the informal sec- tor in Armenia include the high regulatory compliance costs due to official and unofficial payments, instabilities in state policies affecting the business sector, and predatory tax and customs administrations, rather than weaknesses in the judicial system. While efforts designed to reform the judiciary should continue, improving tax and customs administrations together with injecting stability into business regula- tions and policies stand out as major "other" ingredients accounting for the gap between the formal and revealed ease of doing business in Armenia. LAW AND INSTITUTIONS: FORMAL AND INFORMAL The state is not able to protect high levels of competition in domes- tic markets. Laws and institutions underpinning antitrust policies in Armenia provide a good illustration of the welfare and growth implications of the gap between the quality of regulations and their often opaque enforcement. Competition law is a recent innovation in Armenia. The law establishing the Commission for the Protection of Economic Competition (CPEC) was passed in 2000 and the CPEC itself began prosecuting cases in 2001. An analysis of the key aspects of the law shows the following: · The law prohibits collusion among enterprises but fails to distin- guish between vertical and horizontal collusion. Generally, econ- omists view horizontal collusion as being potentially much more damaging to consumers. Vertical agreements can also present problems, but the circumstances under which this occurs need investigation and analysis, case-by-case, within clear guidelines requiring the assessment of economic benefits and costs. Poten- tial problems could arise in Armenia because the technical capac- ity for this analysis with the CPEC is limited. · Article 4 of the law prohibits anticompetitive practices between loosely connected groups, although the criteria for determining such behavior are loosely set out and would require intensive investigation and several different levels of complexity. 64 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth · Article 6 of the law indicates that a firm may be considered hav- ing a dominant position in the market if it is not exposed to substantial competition, or if it commands a market share of more than one-third of total sales. Depending on the definition of markets, and the degree of concentration in the market under consideration, this threshold could be too low. Generally, public policy should be concerned with "conduct" and "performance" rather than with market structure as such. · The law forbids the abuse of dominant market power. In Arme- nia, the CPEC keeps a list of firms with such power and suppos- edly tracks them to ensure that their behavior does not involve abuse. Most of the cases brought by the CPEC have involved firms that are in this list. Cases have been prosecuted under Arti- cle 7 of the law, which applies to the abuse of dominant mar- ket position. FIAS has criticized this approach on the grounds that the CPEC appears to have an attitude that any firm on the list is automatically suspect, which essentially means any large company. Once a firm is on the list of dominant firms, scrutiny intensifies and transactions costs for the firm rise sharply. · The CPEC has brought a number of cases of "unjustified pric- ing" based on a methodology involving comparisons between the selling prices of the company and general price indices. This makes little analytical sense, in that there is no analysis of entry barriers or sunk costs or allowance for shifts in relative prices. Moreover, such a methodology implicitly assumes that profits or rates of return on investments should not differ between prod- ucts, companies, and sectors, regardless of differences in risk. · Article 8 of the law defines market concentration and control through mergers and acquisitions and revolves around a market share of 35 percent or more. Combined with Article 10 of the law, which prohibits concentration unless it fosters competition, Article 8 is used to justify action against such companies. · Article 9 requires that firms with substantial market power must be registered as being dominant. Consideration should be given by the government to bringing the competition law into line with the EU or U.S. model so that regula- tors and courts are better able to use well-established methodologies and precedents. Allowing private enforcement of the law can also contribute to efficiency. Implementation of the competition law presents a number of prob- lems. The weak institutional framework that exists in Armenia appears to result in some cases not being prosecuted, especially in the areas The Framework for Competition 65 outlined in later sections of this chapter, whereas there may exces- sive targeting of other firms. As in many other areas of competition in Armenia, the law itself is not the primary problem. The existing legislation, while inadequate in some areas, could be used to prosecute anticompetitive behavior. Rather, the problems lie in the application of the law, the protection that some groups appear to have, and the gener- ally weak private sector business environment that limits opportunities for new entrants. These issues are explored at greater length below. Arm's length contracting is a requirement of a well-functioning economic system. In Armenia, the law governing commercial transac- tions is inadequate, with the result that contracts tend to be informal and take place between people who know each other well. The effect is a barrier to entry and increased incentives for informal behavior, which is widely observed in Armenia. Problems with the law include the following: · Decisions on issues related to commercial transactions are based on an agglomeration of civil code laws, making the applicability of contract provisions uncertain. · Contractual agreements are based on "unless otherwise gov- erned by law" provisions rather than on "unless otherwise stated in the contract" provisions. Since many commercial transactions are subject to a wide range of laws rather than a more unified commercial code, this provision requires a full knowledge of all the laws and implementing regulations that may apply to an agreement, which compounds the problem of the unavailability of translations. · Not only does precedent not play a role in court decisions, but there is no record of cases being kept, although this is partly being addressed by a World Bank legal reform project. · In addition to the uncertainty arising from the commercial code, judges are widely viewed as less than competent or honest. As a result, businesses have little recourse if they are the victims of anticompetitive behavior. Laws, regulations, and formal institutions in corporate governance are particularly weak in Armenia. The EBRD ratings on corporate gov- ernance and enterprise restructuring place Armenia at the same level as Russia, but behind the Baltics and the Balkans. On several basic issues related to transparency, notably public access to the company registry and lists of founders and shareholders, Armenia is among the weakest of the CIS countries. The quality of corporate financial reporting also remains weak. 66 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Moreover, while the securities law has some weaknesses, the great- est corporate governance deficiencies are found in the company law and other basic legislation affecting the corporate sector. The extent of such weaknesses also places an undue burden on government regula- tors. In the area of financial regulation, for example, the central bank is obliged to provide for extensive guidelines and proposed legisla- tion to make up for the shortfalls. Company legislation permits state- owned enterprises to get away with weak corporate structures, as seen, for example, in railways. Such limitations in the law and institutions for corporate govern- ance have serious implications for fair competition. Particularly in emerging markets, corporate governance has become recognized as an important part of the business climate. In virtually all of the CIS countries, weak corporate governance reinforces the dominance of a limited number of businessmen. At the same time, weak corporate governance undermines investor confidence in the capital markets, which as a result fail to provide adequate financing for capital-worthy projects and new enterprises. In the CIS countries, stock markets are littered with publicly traded companies that are little traded. Informal institutions and practices play an important role in deter- mining the fairness of the framework for competition. Many private sector participants in Armenia frequently make facilitation payments to ensure that dealings with the public sector proceed without undue delay. Unlike other countries, the system has so far not degenerated into massive corruption, although undoubtedly there is corruption that extends to the highest levels. Rather, it has evolved into one in which interlocking obligations arising from favors and interventions govern much of the interaction in the business community as well as between businesses and the legal system. A person who acts to inter- cede on behalf of another becomes a roof, and the benefactor incurs an obligation to return the favor in one form or another at some point in the future. In Armenia, there appear to be few rules which can- not be modified or adjusted through the intervention of a roof even within the judicial system. In sectors where a powerful roof exists, the incumbents appear to have the power to make life extremely difficult for new entrants. Foreign investors often do not have a network that would provide them with a roof and so frequently are more likely to have difficulty navigating their way through the various bureaucracies and the judi- ciary, as noted in all the surveys on foreign investment in Armenia. In addition, companies that are only exporters claim that they are singled out for unfavorable treatment, especially with respect to VAT refunds. The Framework for Competition 67 The roof phenomenon can act as a substantial barrier to entry in the economy for both foreign investors and new local businesses that attempt to compete with well-established companies and individu- als. Although there have been improvements recently, subtle methods are used to impose severe operating constraints on new competition, ranging from problems in clearing goods through customs to inspec- tions of various types by government officials. LARGE WELFARE LOSSES FROM WEAK COMPETITION IN PETROLEUM DISTRIBUTION As the economic effects of deficiencies in the competition framework for the utility (telecommunications) and transport (civil aviation) industries are discussed in subsequent parts of this book, this sec- tion considers the welfare losses imposed by lack of competition in the distribution of petroleum products. Having no oil or natural gas resources, Armenia is totally dependent upon imports of fuel prod- ucts, which constitute about 20 percent of total imports. This import group includes two major components in terms of volume: petroleum products (including gasoline and diesel) and natural gas imports. Statistics on petroleum product imports appear to have been under- reported. In spite of very rapid growth, gasoline and diesel imports into Armenia show that in 2000 there was a sharp drop in the import volumes and only very modest growth afterwards. This occurred in spite of a very sharp increase in automobile imports, which rough statistics indicate exceeded 14,000 vehicles per year, compared with 1,200 per year in 1999. Although oil prices rose in 2000, and demand may have been depressed by the fuel efficiency of recently imported automobiles and the conversion of some motor vehicles from gasoline to natural gas, it does not seem likely that in the face of such rapid growth fuel consumption could go down. The most likely explanation for the flat fuel imports is that there is smuggling of petroleum. The structure of market concentration underwent changes in the 1999­2000 period. In 1999 there was only one gasoline importer in Armenia, so that market power was located inside the borders of the country. In 2000 and 2001 the number of importers into the country increased; therefore, looking only at the number of operators within Armenia, the market could not be defined as uncompetitive. However, an analysis of the import chain reveals that there is only one supplier that provides the bulk (88 percent) of imported gasoline to importers. While the concentration of direct importers has declined, the virtually single sourcing of supply for gasoline importers means that the supply 68 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth chain remains highly concentrated. Even though it has been reported that one more company started to supply importers with gasoline in 2002, the share of the incumbent supplier firm remained dominant. It constituted about 70 percent of the total supply to importers. What is more interesting is that, even though the large number of retail companies operating in Armenia ensures retail competition, the retail mark-up price was substantially higher than the imported (wholesale) price (which we took to be the customs clearing price). The gross profit mark-up, most of which probably occurred at the whole- sale level, constituted more than half of the retail price in 2001 (Figure 3.3). Since competition at the retail level is strong, it is unlikely that excess profits are being earned by retailers--most of the profits prob- ably accrue to the wholesalers. These calculations (see Box 3.1) indicate that there appear to be large welfare losses arising from the concentra- tion of the petroleum market that could amount to the equivalent of over 1 percent of GDP. This loss figure could be even higher if we con- sider that there is a further profit margin earned by the single-source monopoly supplier of imports. This is not included in the calculations of the deadweight loss, which can occur as a result of the monopoly power of the one supplier of importers. This loss figure could also be higher if we also consider that the same situation dominates in similar markets (such as the diesel market). Figure 3.3 Gasoline Price Structure for the Period 1999­2001 (drams per ton) 100 146,833 225,207 203,376 90 80 70 60 50 percent 40 118,300 159,200 45,100 30 20 10 0 1999 2000 2001 year margin over wholesale price customs clearing price Source: NSS. The Framework for Competition 69 Box 3.1 The Petroleum Distribution Market To stress the negative impact of noncompetitive behavior in the gaso- line market we made a simple calculation of welfare losses (Table 1). (For the explanation of the terms used in the analysis below one is referred to Tirole 1988). We assumed a linear market-specific demand curve and estimated its slope and intercept considering price-increase v.s. demand-decrease scenarios during 1999­2000 (such a decrease in demand is mainly explained by price increase in international oil prices in contrast to the observed non-price impact (such as increased imports of cars after 2000) on demand during later years). Welfare Calculations in the Petroleum Market 1999 2000 2001 Retail Price (drams per ton) 265,000 370,000 362,500 Customs Clearing Price (drams/ton) 118,300 145,100 159,200 Quantities Consumed (tons) 258,100 181,400 187,500 Total Profit (drams, billion) 37,9 40,8 38,1 Estimated Slope of the Demand Curve ­1.4 ­1.4 ­1.4 Estimated Intercept of the Demand Curve 626,000 626,000 626,000 Quantities under Customs Clearing Price (tons) 363,000 343,800 333,700 Deadweight Loss (drams, billion) 7,7 18,2 14,8 Deadweight Loss (US$, million) 14,5 33,3 26,1 GDP (in US$, million) 1,845 1,911 2,118 Deadweight Loss as a percentage of GDP 0.8 1.8 1.3 It turns out that welfare loss, as a result of non-competitive behavior in the gasoline market alone, was averaged on 1.3% of GDP. This loss figure can be even higher if we consider that there is a double mar- ginalization (we have not include in the calculations the deadweight loss, which can occur as a result of monopoly power of one supplier of importers) and that the same situation dominates in many other similar markets (such as in diesel market). Moreover, the fact that the concentrated rather high gasoline market profits (about 3.7% of GDP) have not contributed to reducing unequal distribution of income in the country accentuates the importance of lib- eralizing the petroleum oils market. Source: NSS and authors' calculations. 70 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS AND POLICY CONCLUSIONS Lack of competition can be detrimental to efficiency over the long run. In addition, the apparent concentration of wealth among incumbents could reduce political support for reform and limit the benefits of rapid growth. There is ample evidence of poverty in Armenia, even in Yerevan; outside the capital it is far worse. Poverty reduction requires that the benefits of growth are spread to a substantial number of peo- ple, because even at current growth rates it will be some time before Armenia can afford adequate social safety nets. The more competition is restricted and activities are reserved for incumbents, the less likely it is that the benefits of growth will be widespread. There are other consequences of the dominance of incumbents in some sectors. The concentration of wealth provides substantial ability to grant "favors" to government officials to subtly (and sometimes, not so subtly) hinder competitors entering the market. The phenom- enon of roofs or protection rackets is one manifestation of the way in which incumbents maintain their market power. In other cases, it appears that there are direct attempts to prevent competition. Wide- spread subversion of the "rules of the game" by the rich and powerful sends strong messages to those who are on the outside. It contributes to a general attitude that taxes should not be paid, officials should be bribed, and goods smuggled. This does nothing to develop the foundation for a modern competitive economy. In the long run, promoting competition in Armenia is inseparable from promoting private sector development in the country. The ability to restrict competition frequently arises because the institutions that underlie private sector activity are underdeveloped, providing strong incentives for informal behavior. In Armenia, the public goods that pro- vide the foundation for private sector development are weak. The court system does not function effectively and arm's length contracting is risky, so that transactions tend to take place between those who know and trust each other. This gives powerful advantages to incumbents. Similarly, the financial system remains extremely underdeveloped even by the standards of low income countries.9 Hence, those that have substantial financial resources are in an strong position to maintain and strengthen their market dominance. The development of institu- tions supporting the private sector is the only long-run solution to promoting a competitive market environment. Legal reform and the reform of the secured transactions framework are two measures that will greatly enhance private sector activity. In addition, government institutions need to support the private sector rather than being the instruments for maintaining anticompetitive behavior that they are The Framework for Competition 71 now. In particular, reform of the customs service is the key to promot- ing competition. Should the CPEC be one of the pillars of a policy to promote compe- tition in Armenia? There are concerns that it could become yet another layer of bureaucracy that leads to corrupt "inspections," harassment of entrepreneurs, and protection of the incumbency. This concern can be addressed by emphatically assigning to the CPEC as its core role, within a strengthened statutory framework, the implementation of competition laws and the duty of advising the government on regula- tory reform. Arguments in favor of strengthening the CPEC recognize that it could be one way to address the restrictions on competition that abound in several sectors of the economy. The view of this book is that in its present form the CPEC is not a significant bulwark against anticompetitive behavior.10 It does not have the necessary skills, staff, or facilities to operate effectively. Although it has been successful in a limited number of cases, it is not a force in areas where competition is obviously restricted. Its report on the petroleum market is deficient in terms of depth as well as analysis.11 This does not mean that attempts to assist the CPEC should be abandoned. Over the longer term it could be one of the instruments for promoting competition in Armenia. Modest technical assistance is warranted to help the CPEC to better implement the law and improve its ITC resources. It is unrealistic, however, to perceive it as useful in the shorter term. The CPEC needs several years to evolve into any sort of instrument against restrictions on competition. Nevertheless, its continued existence is assured and the interests of the private sec- tor lie in its improving its technical competence. SUMMARY AND KEY RECOMMENDATIONS Governance, though improving, remains a hindrance to competition, particularly in the areas of government effectiveness, quality of regu- lations, and excessive discretionary behavior in the tax and customs administrations at the expense of rules-based discipline. Armenia does well in a CIS comparison, but lags far behind good interna- tional practice in setting a fair and attractive competition framework for investors. The large informal economy is illustrative of the high costs of doing business (especially taking into account the "hassle" factors) and of high labor (payroll) taxes, as well as weak incentives to going formal, such as the possibility of being able to obtain credit from banks. Formal laws and institutions addressing competition and 72 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth corporate governance are weak, enforcement is erratic, and informal barriers to competition abound. · Strengthen the competition law by clarifying collusive behavior and dominant market practices, and by modernizing the basis for judging pricing practices. · Enhance the administrative capacity of the competition commis- sion to review cases and enforce its rulings. · Modify the commercial transactions law to strengthen safe- guards. NOTES 1. Background material supporting the analysis of this chapter can be found in Chapters 10 and 11 of Part II of this book. 2. As has been mentioned in Chapter 2 (note 13), there are two arguments that focus solely on these indicators. First, these indicators are critical dimen- sions of the business climate. Political stability affects investment decisions and, in extreme situations of its absence, may disrupt economic activities. To be relevant, the quality of regulation must be supported by government capac- ity to enforce regulations. Second, three other indicators pertinent to dimen- sions of governance--the rule of law, the control of corruption, and voice and accountability--are not taken into account and do not yield extra information. All transition economies are strongly correlated with the selected three indica- tors, with the values of correlation coefficients equal to or above 0.9. 3. It provides data on the tangible components shaping the cost of conduct- ing business in Armenia and allows casting them in a comparative perspective. The survey covers the following eight areas: starting business, flexibility of employment, registering property, contract enforcement, doing business, pro- tection of investors, getting credit, and ease of doing business. Each area has several different indicators ranging from 1 (protection of investors) to 5 (getting credit and labor market flexibility) (see http://www.doingbusiness.org/) 4. The procedure used to assess the ease of doing business in Armenia is as follows. In order to assess Armenia's relative position among transition economies in terms of overall ease of doing business, we aggregate seven areas identified in the Doing Business Survey. We identify best practice indi- cators not worldwide but among transition countries. Indicators for countries are expressed in terms of percent of the best practice set at 100. We average indicators for each area covered by the survey, which yields an overall assess- ment of the ease of doing business for each country. 5. The new labor code in effect since 2005 greatly eases the severance pay burden for enterprises. The Framework for Competition 73 6. It is "revealed" because it takes into account the extent to which busi- nesses express a preference to opt out of the official economy or to stay in it. 7. According to the 2004 Regulatory Cost Survey, 71 percent of respondents identified corruption as a persistent problem, up from 66 percent over the previous year. Interestingly, corruption appears to be much less of a problem for foreign-owned firms than for domestic companies (FIAS 2003). 8. According to the World Bank study reviewing progress in judicial reform in transition economies, this progress has been much weaker in all transition countries than in other areas of institutional reform since 1990. Furthermore, firms' perceptions of the legal and judicial systems in transition countries are worse than comparable perceptions in most other regions of the world, according to a recent world wide survey of business executives (Anderson, Bernstein, and Gray 2005). 9. Discussed in the next chapter. 10. The commission has investigated a number of recent cases, among which was the successful elimination of a monopoly granted by the airport operator to a taxicab company. There have also been several hearings concern- ing the abuse of monopoly power by ArmenTel. The company had cut off the telephone lines of some Internet service providers without prior notification, suspecting them of providing voice-over-IP service in Armenia. 11. A four-page analysis concluded that there is competition in the distri- bution of petroleum because of the fact that there are several wholesalers/ importers within Armenia. The paper does point out that there is only one sup- plier/seller to the wholesalers but appeared not to view this as a problem. Chapter 4 Finance as a Barrier to Accumulation SHALLOW FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION AND HIGH COST OF FUNDS Comparisons with CEEC and CIS countries show the shallowness of financial intermediation in Armenia (see Table 4.1). The financial system in Armenia remains small and bank domi- nated. A wave of bank failures since the end of 2000 has reduced the number of banks from 31 to 20. One foreign bank (a subsidiary of a large first-tier international bank) is a dominant player with about 18 percent of all assets and a quarter of all deposits. Total assets of the banking sector were a paltry 19 percent of GDP in 2004, substantially below the CIS average of about 30 percent in 2003. Broad money, which excludes foreign currency cash in circulation, remained flat at about 15 percent of GDP, compared with an average of about 20 percent for CIS countries. Foreign currency cash holdings are large and have been roughly estimated at one-third of GDP. The nonbank financial sector plays a negligible role in intermediation. The insurance sector is tiny, with an annual premium income of only about US$5 million. Since the savings to-GDP-ratio in Armenia is not dissimilar to those in countries with much deeper intermediation (such as the Baltics and Central Europe), the supply base of potential deposits for banks is clearly not a constraint. One explanation for the low intermedia- tion arises from the importance of remittances from abroad and the informality of the economy. The substantial inflow of remittances from abroad provides a source of funds to finance real estate and investment expenditures, which reduces reliance on the financial sector. Remittances reach a significant percentage of the population and provide individuals and small firms with funds for investment 75 76 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Table 4.1 Financial Indicators in Selected Countries M2X/GDP Credit/GDP B/GDP (percent) (percent) (percent) Countries 1995­01 2004 1995­01 2004 1995­01 2004 Armenia 8.34 15.10 5.75 7.52 5.2 6.97 Azerbaijan 11.63 17.95 12.98 10.94 7.56 8.16 Czech Republic 67.83 66.63 69.75 41.44 21.57 10.36 Estonia 28.81 41.12 27.44 65.40 11.69 11.79 Georgia 6.67 13.27 4.9 18.83 4.96 8.40 Kyrgyz Republic 13.1 20.60 5.93 6.17 9.01 13.16 Latvia 25.16 38.27 12.22 51.29 11.94 13.01 Moldova 18.12 25.43 16.29 23.13 10.65 16.61 Poland 34.85 41.02 21.83 27.46 8.72 7.83 Russian Federation 17.15 31.63 11.02 25.94 7.68 14.21 Ukraine 12.58 36.36 7.94 25.67 6.99 12.27 Source: National central banks of countries presented in table. in small businesses and real estate purchases or improvements. The large informal economy, which is unofficially estimated to be at least one-third of GDP, also does not rely on the formal financial sector. The firms and individuals in this economy rely exclusively on cash for transactions, partly to evade taxes. This significantly diminishes the potential deposit base of the banking system and the market for products offered by banks and other financial institutions. But if deposit mobilization is weak, lending is weaker still. For example, the largest bank in Armenia, Hong Kong and Shanghai Banking Corporation (HSBC), lends a much smaller proportion of its liabilities (10 percent) to private business than it does in other coun- tries in which it operates (60 to 70 percent). Moreover, commercial banks hold large and growing excess reserves at the Central Bank, indicative of their comfortable liquidity positions even at low levels of deposit mobilization. Thus, deep structural problems lie at the heart of the abysmally low rates of bank lending to enterprises. Both the high cost of loans (averaging about 20 percent) and the lack of finance for business not only act as a deterrent to formality but also are a factor behind weak competition that reflects inefficiencies in the financial system. According to the 2003 FIAS RCS, more than half of the firms that participated in the survey believe that financing is the fourth leading constraint to the expansion of firms. Potential com- petitors cannot obtain finance, either in the form of working capital or for foreign trade. The result is that incumbents' market dominance is rarely threatened by new entrants and that wealth remains concen- trated among them. Finance as a Barrier to Accumulation 77 The rapid growth (albeit from the low base described above) in credit and monetary aggregates since 2004 is encouraging. The annual rate of growth of deposits has accelerated from 15 percent on aver- age in 2001­03 to 22 percent in 2004 (exceeding 50 percent in eight banks) and 18 percent in 2005. Similarly, the annual rate of growth of gross domestic nongovernment credit (excluding loans classified as losses) has accelerated from 24 percent in 2001­03 to 37 percent in 2004 (exceeding 65 percent in six banks) and 32 percent in 2005. IMPACT OF INSTITUTIONAL WEAKNESSES ON COSTS Banks have a limited capacity to assess risks and limit their lending to the insiders and activities with guaranteed returns (such as consumer lending) and require high and liquid collaterals. Some importers do use the banking system to raise letters of credit but the practice is not widespread. There is little export financing. The practice of using irrevocable letters of credit as a basis for providing funds to fulfill export orders appears to be nonexistent. As a result, the financial sys- tem cannot be said to support the growth of trade that, in turn, is the key to promoting more competition in Armenia. The essential skills in raising letters of credit are confined to a small number of banks. Before exporting under letters of credit can occur, training in the details of the procedures will be required for most banks in Armenia. Two indicators point to the limited degree of competition within the banking industry. The bank concentration indicator--the assets of the five largest banks as a share of total assets of the banking sys- tem--is given in Table 4.2. It points to a notable increase in bank concentration over the recent past. Moreover, out of these five banks, one large bank has about one- fifth of the total banking assets and almost a quarter of the banking sector deposits. Despite the recent increase in banking intermediation, the degree of concentration and the associated lack of competition among banks do not augur well for long-term financial stability. Second, the interest rate spreads remain high, also indicating con- centration and lack of competition (see Table 4.3); with very high Table 4.2 Bank Concentration Indicator, 2000­04 (in percent) 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Share of the assets of five largest banks in total assets of the banking system 46.8 48.4 54.1 54.5 56.3 Source: Central Bank of Armenia. 78 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Table 4.3 Decomposition of Interest Rate Spreads, 1999­2004 Total bank percentages 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 1. II/L 28.32 20.70 17.24 12.96 12.30 12.29 2. IC/D 13.52 12.34 7.38 4.85 3.41 3.10 3. II/L­IC/D(spread) 14.80 10.17 11.91 9.87 10.47 10.78 4. Sum of factors below 14.65 8.87 8.46 7.21 7.95 7.76 5. NII/D(­) 5.01 3.62 4.72 6.17 6.06 5.76 6. NIC/D 10.42 8.38 8.11 8.18 7.69 7.38 7. Net prov/D 3.08 3.62 3.35 3.99 1.50 0.52 8. ROA A/D 3.89 ­1.16 0.34 0.18 3.84 4.88 9. II/L r 2.27 1.66 1.38 1.04 0.98 0.74 Residual () 3­4 ­0.15 ­1.30 ­3.44 ­2.66 ­2.52 ­3.02 Source: Central Bank of Armenia. Financial Sector Assessment Paper (FSAP), update team preliminary calculations. Note: Definitions used in the table: II--interest income of banks; L--assets ensuring interest income, IC--interest expenses of banks; D--interest-bearing liabilities of banks, II/L--derived interest income of banks, IC/D--derived interest expenses of banks, NII--noninterest income of banks; NIC--noninterest expenses of banks; Net prov.--net assignments to reserve funds on loans, securities, and receivables. ROA A/D--the ratio of total assets in cost-bearing liabilities weighted by ROA; ROA--return on assets; Residual ()--Residual emerges as we compare the statement data on income and expenditures of commercial banks (flow indicators) with the balance sheet indicators (supply indicators), and consider a simplified assumption that commercial banks invest the total nonreserved part of the attracted interest-taking liabilities into the interest- earning assets. nominal and real interest rates for loans being prevalent. The cost of interest-bearing liabilities has declined significantly and reached extremely low nominal levels that approximate to low single-digit rates in real terms in the recent past. The principal factors behind the high and rigid spread structure in Armenia are the poor state of corporate governance; weak institutions and practices that affect banking transactions, such as the availability and flow of information on borrowers; the ease with which secured transactions can take place; the costs experienced in contract enforce- ment, as well as the costs associated with the management of banks; and the high unit costs of bank activities arising from diseconomies of scale. These factors point clearly to the role that structural reforms can play in alleviating finance as a barrier to sustained economic growth. Banks' administrative and noninterest-bearing costs are very high; at the same time banks make significant earnings from noninterest- bearing transactions, which indicates heavy reliance on nonbank oper- ations. The incompetence of the bank management itself can become a risk to the system. First of all, it can support the growth of low-quality Finance as a Barrier to Accumulation 79 loans owing to the lack of capacity to implement proper credit analysis. Second, if the quality of financial services does not improve in line with the credit growth, this can "force" clients to use "nonbank alternatives" for financing. Table 4.3 substantiates the above description. The indica- tors provide evidence that the costs of the interest-bearing liabilities of banks have declined significantly over the last years. At the same time the earnings of interest-bearing assets declined at a lower speed. Analysis makes it clear that the main factors contributing to the higher interest rate spread remain the noninterest costs of banks. This indicates that the banking system suffers from inefficient bank man- agement and high administrative costs. These costs are even higher if we exclude the largest bank in Arme- nia, which perhaps indicates that the presence of this foreign-owned bank alone does not create competitive pressure on the domestic banking system to increase its efficiency and push the interest rate spreads down. Another factor contributing to the higher spread is the ratio of total assets in cost-bearing liabilities weighted by the return on assets. This indicator has high volatility due to the significant restructuring of the banking system over the last years. It shows a growing tendency over the last two years; although this indicates a profitable allocation of the low-cost resources, its rapid growth contains future risks for the banking system. It is only through greater competition, brought about by improve- ments in the lending environment, that spreads will decline sustain- ably. Since the cost of interest-bearing liabilities is very low, the fall in spreads will come through a lowering of lending rates. The key challenge for the authorities is to extend the recent deep- ening in intermediation and entrench confidence in the financial sys- tem while maintaining macroeconomic stability. Steps to be taken are summarized in Box 4.1. Rapid credit growth is a necessary element in the expansion of still shallow financial intermediation; moreover, such growth poses a limited immediate risk, as the banking system is highly liquid and well capitalized. Further steps are needed to improve the quality of financial intermediation and to increase the range and penetration of financial services. The rest of this chapter considers the policy reform tasks ahead. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE DEFICIENCIES AND THE COST OF FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION Central to weak corporate governance is lack of transparent owner- ship and control of banks. The Detailed Assessment of Compliance with the OECD Principles of Corporate Governance indicated that, 80 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Box 4.1 Priorities in Reform of Financial and Capital Markets ACTION Liquidity management Raise the stock of local currency monetary instruments. Lengthen the maturity of T-bills and bonds. Bank supervision and regulation Amend bankruptcy law for banks to extinguish bank owners' shareholder rights in case of insolvency. Revise central bank law to explicitly protect supervisors from civil liability. Strengthen bank corporate governance based on the proposal by the Central Bank. Enhance consolidated supervision, especially with respect to risk exposures of beneficial owners and affiliated companies. Insurance supervision and the insurance sector Complete regulations implementing the new insurance law. Corporate governance Strengthen coverage and enforcement of the company law, especially on fiduciary duties and accountabilities of boards. Improve accounting and auditing practices, financial reporting, and creditor rights and strengthen disclosure by beneficial owners. Pension reform Develop actuarial projections and analyze impediments to reform options before deciding on a pension reform strategy linking benefits to wages. Housing finance Focus reform on the development of a primary market for housing finance. Develop a liquidity facility to facilitate longer-maturity mortgage lending while ensuring that there are no implicit guarantees. Source: Based on Financial Sector Assessment Paper (FSAP). Finance as a Barrier to Accumulation 81 while company law governing open and closed joint stock companies is sound, implementation is weak. Only a few banks and corpora- tions choose to operate under this law, covered under the securities legislation and enforced by the exchanges and securities commis- sions. Many of the banks and corporations are closely held and have few owners, who do not see the benefits of adopting a more formal governance structure and who are not publicly traded. The enforce- ment of sound corporate governance practices through securities leg- islation and securities regulators is weak. Clearly, there is a need for a fundamental reform to enhance the coverage and enforcement of company law if corporate governance, disclosure, and accounting are to improve. Improvements in transparency and accounting are basic first-generation reforms in corporate governance. The opaque ownership structure of the corporate sector makes it more difficult for the banking sector to assess the risks of corporate- sector exposures. Official disclosures of direct and indirect ownership are substantially weaker than in other transition economies. No dis- closure of beneficial owners is required under Armenian law. This limits the ability of banks to ensure compliance with prudent lim- its on loan portfolio concentrations and related party transactions. Although legislation requires all companies to prepare their financial accounts in line with the Accounting Standards of the Republic of Armenia, in practice these standards are not observed or are imple- mented only partly due to lack of training. Steps should be taken to improve accounting and auditing practices and financial report- ing requirements and to strengthen public information; this should include beneficial owners of banks and publicly traded companies. Furthermore, the supervising boards of Armenian companies are not sufficiently effective or accountable. The company law should clearly establish the right of shareholders to decide on owner-manager rela- tions (in cases, for example, where a separation of company owners from company managers may be desirable and should be provided for), subject to the protection of the contractual rights of minority shareholders. Moreover, legislation should strengthen and clarify the fiduciary duties and accountability of boards of directors. The above-mentioned shortcomings in corporate governance can be addressed through legal, institutional, and supervisory reforms. Given the weak implementation of company law, the Central Bank has developed a proposal to accelerate improvements in corporate governance in the banking sector through legislative and supervisory means, and through the introduction of upward-consolidated supervi- sion to address exposures to beneficial owners. There are a number of specific reforms applying to the corporate sector that should be imple- mented to address the shortcomings in corporate governance. These reforms include improvements in accounting and auditing practices; 82 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth provision of financial reporting requirements; enhanced disclosure of the shareholders of corporations; improved access to information by the public, in particular by making the company registry publicly available; and the strengthening of the role of boards of directors. Such shortcomings in corporate governance detract from confidence in the banking system, lead to information gaps that raise the cost of loans through higher risk premia, and impose a "tax" that disadvan- tages local enterprises. The Central Bank has started to address gov- ernance, including the areas of accounting and audit requirements and transparency in reporting through regulations. However, a number of key weaknesses remain which, unless addressed, would add to risks and intermediation costs: Banks should reform corporate governance practices with a view to adopting the legal form of open joint stock companies to increase the transparency of ownership. The responsibilities and accountabilities of bank owners and boards of directors should be explicitly defined in law, includ- ing taking responsibility for the safe and sound operation of the institution; being informed of their banks' operating condition, in part through ensuring an adequate external and internal audit process; and providing accurate and truthful reporting to the public and the central bank. Central Bank remedial actions should extend to both boards of directors and significant participants in the case of unsafe and unsound bank operation and significant compliance breaches. In late 2005, the Central Bank adopted a plan for the strengthening of corporate governance in banks. Specifically, measures are envisaged to protect shareholder rights (especially those of minority sharehold- ers), to clearly define the powers of the boards and the executives of banks, delineate the fiduciary responsibilities of management, and publicize bank activities. Improvements in the legal and regulatory framework and proce- dures have strengthened the supervisory process, but some weak- nesses remain. It is encouraging that the Central Bank conducts a rig- orous supervisory process, with enforcement grounded in legislation, regulatory reporting, and prudential norms. But there are weaknesses. Bank corporate governance and risk management, including the eval- uation of risks in new banking products, requires further strengthen- ing. Furthermore, a framework should be established to strengthen the monitoring of the parent and affiliated companies of banks in the context of consolidated supervision. The Law on Banks and Banking should be amended to allow the Central Bank to reject bank licenses if the legal and managerial structure does not permit adequate identi- Finance as a Barrier to Accumulation 83 fication of ownership and control, thereby hindering effective supervi- sion. The dialogue between the Central Bank and the external auditors should be substantially improved, if necessary through legislation. In addition, the law should be amended to obligate external auditors to report to the Central Bank on issues of material importance arising from their audits. Communication among regulators should be estab- lished, and formal agreements for information sharing put in place. The Law on Banks and Banking should explicitly provide for protec- tion for supervisors from civil liability. CREDITOR RIGHTS AND SECURED TRANSACTIONS FRAMEWORK A recent National Bureau for Economic Research (NBER) paper used a sample of 129 countries to show that "stronger legal rights of creditors are associated with a higher level of development of private credit mar- kets" (Djankov, McLiesh, and Shliefer 2005, p. 16). The paper under- lines the fact that this is mainly true in developed countries where the legal framework and contracting rules are more developed. The protection of creditor rights is one of the main legal problems that hinder the growth of bank lending. The enforcement of collateral is difficult for banks and this, as we have already observed, translates into high lending rates. Although the legislation on allowing secured creditors to sell collateral without resort to a court is adequate, the enforcement and the infrastructures supporting the laws are very weak and underdeveloped and do not work in practice. Collateral enforcement is difficult because of the absence of a unified and digit- ally accessible registry for immovable items and title issues related to the ownership of property. The judicial capacity is weak owing to lack of experience, corruption, insufficient capacity, and the long lead time required to adapt to the new legislation. Measures are being imple- mented to improve the legal and institutional arrangements relating to secured credit, the registration of ownership, and security interests, and to reduce the inefficiencies in court systems that impede debt recovery, which should address most of the existing weaknesses in creditor rights. In Armenia, movable property cannot be used effectively as collat- eral to secure loans. There are numerous problems with the secured transactions framework. Floating pledges are not allowed, and there are no registries which allow pledges to be perfected. Repossession is time-consuming and costly. A particular problem with financing exports is that there is no provision which allows the use of future production as collateral, so that financing against export orders is not feasible. A similar problem arises with imports because there is no 84 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth provision for pledging goods that are not in the possession of the borrower; goods that are being imported, even though they have been paid for by letter of credit, cannot be seized in the event of default. The effect of the inadequacies of the collateral framework extends throughout the economy, with the result that banks correctly perceive lending as extremely risky.1 The stages necessary for establishing a framework for secured transactions are as follows: Creation. The process by which the creditor establishes a secu- rity interest in a specific property (the collateral) Priority. The process by which the lender establishes the priority of the security interest Publicity. The process that makes public the priority status of the security interest Enforcement. The process by which, upon the debtor's default, the creditor will seize and sell the collateral to satisfy his/her claim Each of these stages must function effectively for collateral-based lending to occur. Currently, in Armenia, none of them work well. In this context, efforts by the authorities to reform the framework for secured transactions are most encouraging. But a reform program is likely to require several phases, given the complexity and the multi- sectoral nature of the task involved. Comprehensive collateral reform requires that the whole process for the pledging of property be reviewed and changed. While rewriting the laws governing the ability of property to serve effectively as collateral is an integral part of this process, it is a long way from being all that is needed. Without a thorough revision of the whole system, collateral reform will remain elusive. There have been many attempts at such reform in other countries, most of them unsuccessful. Legal analysis, without corresponding analysis by economists of suggestions for reform, has failed in most countries in which it has been tried. Internationally known legal prac- tice may not represent best economic practice. In many places model laws have provided the foundation for attempts to reform the col- lateral framework. Thus, a good project requires close coordination among economists, international expert lawyers, local lawyers, and technical experts. Examples of successful reform do exist and serve as a model of what could be done in Armenia. A recent reform of the secured trans- actions framework in Romania has transformed Romania's lending environment by facilitating the use of collateral as security for lend- ing, not only from the banking system, but also from equipment sup- pliers, wholesalers, and agricultural suppliers. Before this reform there were many similarities between the Romanian financial sector and Finance as a Barrier to Accumulation 85 that in Armenia--severe financial underdevelopment, the inability of a large sector of the economy to access credit, and a distrust of banks. Furthermore, Romania is also a civil code country. Use of this model could have significant potential for the development of the Armenian financial system and could substantially reduce barriers to entry. The secured transactions reform in Romania tightly integrated diagnosis, drafting, and regulations, and this integration is one of the main rea- sons for its success. This methodology has rarely been followed in reform efforts elsewhere. Legislation before Parliament is intended to strengthen creditor rights. Specifically, measures are planned to make the seizure of col- lateral property and its disposition easier, to broaden the category of properties that may be used for collateral, and to abridge rights that may interfere with seizure of collateral. Overall, Armenia lacks a regularized system of credit that can be stimulated by mechanisms that provide efficient, transparent, and reli- able methods for recovering debt, including the seizure and sale of immovable and movable assets and the sale or collection of intangible assets, such as debt owed to the debtor by third parties. An efficient system for enforcing debt claims is crucial to an efficient functioning of the credit system in Armenia. Armenia's financial sector (possibly with help from the Central Bank and the Ministries of Finance and Justice) should promote an informal, out-of-court process for dealing with cases of enterprises with financial difficulties in which banks have a significant exposure. Armenia's credit-based economy requires predictable, transparent, and affordable enforcement of both unsecured and secured credit claims by efficient mechanisms. Although commercial transactions in Armenia have become complex as more sophisticated techniques are developed for pricing and managing risks, the basic rights govern- ing these relationships and the procedures for enforcing these rights have not changed much. Those rights that should enable parties to rely on contractual agreements, fostering confidence that fuels lend- ing, are not in place. Therefore, uncertainty about the enforceability of contractual rights increases the cost of credit to compensate for the increased risk of nonperformance. THE ROLE OF INFORMATION FLOWS IN REDUCING INTERMEDIATION COSTS The NBER study2 emphasizes that information sharing through public and private credit registries is a significant factor promoting intermediation. The authors also find that "in addition, public credit bureaus are strongly associated with private credit in the poorer, but 86 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth not the richer, countries, pointing to a possible role of government in facilitating information sharing" (Djankov, McLiesh, and Shliefer 2005, p. 26). The credit registry, which was introduced by the Central Bank in January 2003, aims to reduce credit risks by the creation of an infor- mation system on the creditworthiness of customers of banks and credit organizations operating in Armenia. However, while the credit registry has been beneficial to banks' supervisors, this information is limited to debtors of banks only. A private credit bureau began opera- tions in early 2004 and focused in its first year on obtaining infor- mation on debtors from the banks, other financial institutions, utility companies, and government offices. This information should improve creditors' ability to evaluate prospective borrowers' creditworthiness. However, the credit bureau has faced difficulties because most banks are reluctant to provide information for free and then to have to pay for services. Furthermore, based on tradition and culture, Armenian borrowers are reluctant to share their information with others, and ensuring privacy protection substantially constrains the effectiveness of the credit bureau. This credit bureau is currently revisiting its oper- ating model and expanding ownership to include banks with a view to remedying these obstacles. In countries where credit bureaus have been established success- fully, the central bank plays an important role in creating incentive mechanisms for commercial banks to share information on their cus- tomers. In Armenia, the Central Bank proved to be less than enthusias- tic, apparently because the credit bureau would compete with informa- tion that it sells. The lack of support by the Central Bank has, in turn, led to a waning of enthusiasm on the part of the commercial banks for the new credit bureau and only one has signed up for its services. In other countries in which credit bureaus have been established success- fully, it has usually been necessary for the central bank to insist that the commercial banks share information on their customers. Given the vital role played by the generation and transmission of information on creditworthiness in ensuring low intermediation costs, it is suggested that the Central Bank adopt an active role in facilitating private credit bureau development by the following means: Make credit bureau reports a requirement for lending coupled with mechanisms to ensure efficient entry and exit by bureaus to avoid the abuse of their exclusive rights. Require a borrower's explicit consent prior to anyone's gaining access to their files to ensure more privacy protection. Other actions that may prevent privacy violations include strict bank Finance as a Barrier to Accumulation 87 policies on gathering certain kinds of information, conditions on right to access, and validation of own files, and rules on the elimination of individual files after a certain period. Adhere to the following membership policies. Access to informa- tion by borrowers and credit institutions should be granted on the basis of membership. In other words, the principle of reciprocity should guide credit bureaus and should be stated in the contrac- tual agreement between the bureau and the credit institutions. Membership should not be based on fees of any form. However, credit bureau activity should be profit-oriented. In cases where a member provides inaccurate information or fails to provide data, sanctions (ranging from fines to loss of membership and hence denial to the bureau's files) should be imposed. Adopt a balanced ownership policy. Credit bureaus are exposed to potential conflicts of interest, especially if they are owned by a group of lenders: lenders want to exploit the information pro- vided by other lenders without disclosing their own. Therefore, Armenia should adopt a balanced ownership policy. For exam- ple, credit bureaus could be incorporated as private companies and owned by a consortium of lenders to create the incentive for information exchange. Alternatively, independent ownership, coupled with a proper membership policy, could provide incen- tives for lenders to exchange information. Regulate the quality of disclosed information. Apart from the efficiency debate and the coexistence of different institutional arrangements, there is concern regarding the optimal amount of information sharing and the content of the information. In contrast to relying on the general statement that information dis- semination reduces adverse selection problems (due to bad risks in the population of credit seekers) and makes the information on which the banks base their lending decision homogenous, the policy for the development of an efficient system for sharing credit information should be focused on the regulation of the quality of disclosed information. MONETARY OPERATIONS AND MONEY MARKETS While monetary policy has ensured low inflation, it has been con- strained by a low volume of securities for use in liquidity manage- ment; the stock of local-currency government debt is low at about 3 percent of GDP. As a result, the Central Bank must rely on foreign exchange operations as its primary market instrument to manage local 88 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth currency liquidity. This worsens the classic tradeoff between exchange rate volatility and a buildup of excess liquidity, which could pose an inflation risk. An increase in the supply of local currency securities would ena- ble monetary operations in local currency to concentrate on liquidity management. This would free foreign exchange operations to focus on managing large capital inflows. The recent agreement between the government and the Central Bank to increase the supply of securities will enhance the role of money markets. The monetary transmission mechanism is weak because banks are highly liquid, money market activity is low, and dollarization is high. Monetary transmission can be strengthened by the development of money markets, which should lead banks to move away from buy-and- hold investment strategies, to hold lower excess reserves, and to rely to a greater extent on money markets. Improvements in monetary trans- mission should also result from a strengthening of the broader finan- cial system infrastructure, including corporate governance and creditor rights, which would contribute to the narrowing of lending margins and lead banks to become less liquid by reducing lending risks. Finally, an increase in reserve requirements from their current level of 6 percent to reduce banking system liquidity could be considered if it would be difficult for market instruments alone to absorb the excess liquidity. But this instrument (which is effectively a tax on banks) is a blunt one, and market- or price-based instruments are preferred. INSURANCE, PENSION, AND HOUSING FINANCE REFORM The new Law on Insurance adopted in 2004 is comprehensive, but may be ambitious in light of the current level of supervisory exper- tise. The authorities should finalize and implement key regulations to improve accounting, auditing, and financial reporting, and solvency and reserves. The oversight of reinsurance also needs strengthening. The supervisory authorities should align the regulations implement- ing the new insurance law to international best practice and imple- ment them as soon as possible. Key areas include the following: Licensing. Given the very small size of the market, the existence of 24 insurers seems inefficient. The increase in minimum capital levels will help address this. Accounting, auditing, and financial reporting. Accounting, audit- ing, and financial reporting practices in the market are weak, as is monitoring of insurers' market conduct for consumer protec- tion. Regulations in these areas should move the market toward international practices. Finance as a Barrier to Accumulation 89 Solvency and technical reserve requirements. Regulations need to be in place for the industry to be able to take on and prudently manage additional risk. Reinsurance. Given that 98 percent of risks are currently rein- sured, the supervisors should make the oversight of the quality of reinsurance programs a high priority. The insurance supervisory unit has to build its credibility and staff capabilities. A major effort is needed to upgrade the institutional capacity for insurance supervision and the technical competence of the staff. In addition, it is critical to launch an education campaign to explain to the public the potential uses of insurance products. While the Insurance Association is best placed to take the lead in organizing such a campaign, the government should support its drive to do so where possible. Armenia currently has a pay-as-you-go, first pillar, defined benefit pension system. The system provides quite low pension benefits and is widely seen as unfair because it does not link the level of benefits to the level of wages (averaging a replacement value of just over 20 percent of average salaries). Pension benefits total only about 3 per- cent of GDP. The low pensions are due to (i) demographics, including an aging population and emigration by working-age Armenians; and (ii) tax evasion by employers and employees in the large informal economy. The contributor base is less than half of the working popula- tion and the ratio of contributors to pensioners is virtually 1:1. The government has formed a working group on pension reform, which is preparing a concept paper for transition to a three-pillar pension system and has already conducted actuarial projections on reform options. The concept under consideration includes replacing the current system with a compulsory funded pillar and establishing the framework for voluntary funded pension insurance while ensur- ing a minimum level of pensions for all through budget support. Con- tributions to the mandatory and voluntary pillars would be placed in individual accounts and invested in financial instruments. However, there are a significant number of considerations for the government to keep in mind in contemplating the direction, shape, and pace of pension reform, including the following: Conflicting objectives. The objectives of the plan involve signifi- cant tradeoffs among key policy objectives. In particular, during the transition period (which can last 30 years), there would be a direct tradeoff between utilizing reserves to increase current pensions or using them to fund individual accounts. Finding the appropriate balance between these objectives could be important for achieving public support for reform. 90 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Fiscal policy sustainability. During the transition period to a compulsory funded pillar, supplementary budget support may be needed to pay current pensions and fund mandated levels of contributions to individual accounts. However, budget support should be provided only within a sound fiscal policy framework and appropriate limits on the size of public debt and debt servic- ing requirements. Lack of financial instruments in Armenia's financial sector. Armenia has few financial instruments that pension funds could invest in aside from bank deposits. The government debt market and corporate securities markets are quite small. In the initial years of funded pensions, a substantial portion of assets would have to be invested in foreign assets. The need to develop regulatory capacity and expertise. Funded pension systems are usually privately managed and have to be regulated. Before such a system could be established in Armenia, the government would need to form a regulatory body and build up its expertise. An appropriate financial institution with the requisite capacity would have to be found to act as custodian for pension fund assets (an Armenian bank that intended to receive deposits from pension funds should not be eligible). Scale of contributions. Given the small size of Armenia's pension system, the size of the pool of funds that would be created in the initial years of funded pensions would probably be too small to attract interest from qualified foreign pension fund managers, or to be financially viable in light of the fees that would be charged. A transitional set of arrangements might be needed during a start-up phase before a critical mass of funds was achieved and management by private pension companies was implemented. The transitional arrangements should also cover the creation of pension plans by interested employers. Public skepticism of financial institutions. While there is discon- tent with the current pension system, the Armenian public also holds some distrust of financial institutions as a consequence of previous experience with bank failures. There could be doubts on the part of the public that contributions to pension funds would ultimately be paid. A gradual transition could be benefi- cial, under which private accounts would accumulate slowly in the initial years, allowing confidence to grow over time. The Armenian housing finance market is at a promising early stage of development, but risks and weaknesses exist that could be reduced with limited government intervention to meet the needs of the broad population. Banks lent an estimated US$7.1 million in 2003--1.5 per- Finance as a Barrier to Accumulation 91 cent of total bank assets. Most mortgage lending is to upper-income households, in U.S. dollars, at fixed interest rates ranging between 14 and 18 percent, for low loan­to-value ratios of 50 percent, at an aver- age short-term maturity of five years. The main focus of reforms to housing finance should be on the development of the primary market for moderate- and low-income households. Key areas of reform include improving the technical capac- ities of lenders, enhancing public sector processes and systems, and improving the legal and regulatory framework. The government has proposed important reforms to strengthen the legal basis for property markets and mortgage lending, including defining real estate as a com- bination of land and structures, and improving the enforceability of the mortgage pledge. These reforms should be rapidly adopted. The government should shorten and simplify the process for title transfer and the registration of the mortgage pledge. The Central Bank should adjust provisioning rules to address the mismatch between the currency denomination of mortgage loans and the denomination of borrowers' incomes. The government and banks should more systematically gather and publicly disclose data on housing prices, transactions, mortgage lending, and mortgage performance to improve transparency and liquidity. The government should promulgate consumer disclosure reg- ulations on loan terms and risks, especially for non-dram mortgages. SUMMARY AND KEY RECOMMENDATIONS Financial intermediation is shallow and the cost of funds is high. Ratios of both deposits and loans to GDP are amongst the lowest in the CIS countries, and the interest rate spread is high. The cost of intermediation is raised by weak corporate governance, where even first-generation reforms related to transparency, disclosure of owner- ship, and accounting are still to be implemented. Creditor rights are being reformed but have been weak thus far, and the framework for secured transactions has been largely missing. Moreover, institutions to support the flow of information to support credit risk analysis need strengthening. Current reforms that are in progress, if implemented with determination, would lead over time to a lowering of costs and to a greater provision of bank credit to support growth. Implement a new law on corporate governance of banks. Strengthen official disclosures of direct and indirect ownership. Require by Armenian law the disclosure of beneficial owners. Ensure public access to the company registry and lists of found- ers and shareholders. 92 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Implement a law on creditor rights and secured transactions with streamlining of judicial procedures. Strengthen the supervision of capital markets. Implement the unified supervision of financial and capital mar- kets, with new standards for the supervision of insurance, pen- sions, and housing finance institutions. Promote the development of a credit bureau. NOTES 1. Some advocate "relationship lending," in which banks make loans on the basis of the analysis of business plans and the borrower's history as an entrepreneur. This is unlikely to happen. First, most lending to businesses in the United States is secured by collateral. Second, the skills available for drawing up business plans are scarce. Third, those who have run businesses successfully are often the entrenched interests in Armenia, so that loans go to those who have tight control of the business sector. 2. Djankov, McLiesh, and Shliefer (2005), referred to in the preceding sec- tion of this chapter. Chapter 5 Impediments to International Integration I n chapter 3, the impact of the weak framework for competition on economic efficiency and growth was discussed. The deficien- cies in competition policy also affect the integration of the Armenian economy into international goods, services, and factor markets. For a small economy, the key to fast economic growth is integration into global markets. While Armenia has entered into a diamond global value chain (see Table 5.1), it has failed to exploit the opportunities offered by participation in other global networks, and other oppor- tunities for production and distribution, owing to weaknesses in the business environment. Given the country's geographic isolation, global integration depends vitally on export opportunities in the services trade, which has grown impressively. Armenian participation in the international outsourcing of ICT-related services as well as other services sectors (such as tourism and transportation) is below its potential owing to lack of competition and regulatory constraints. The composition of exports illustrates three structural weaknesses in international integration. First, exports of unskilled labor-intensive products appear low given Armenia's abundance in low-skilled labor. Moreover, other countries that are less intensive in low-skilled labor have a higher share of low-skill intensive exports than does Armenia. Thus, the share of unskilled labor-intensive products in Armenia's total exports was 1 percent in 2003, compared to 15 percent of Czech exports, 28 percent of Lithuanian exports, and 41 percent of Alba- nian exports. The deviation is smaller when set against the perform- ance of other CIS economies: Georgia has the same share as Armenia, Kazakhstan's is even lower (0.3 percent), and the Kyrgyz Republic's is 15 percent. This second group of countries (like Armenia) has yet to 93 94 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 5.1 Armenian Exports, 1997­2004 600 500 400 exports of other goods million 300 US$ 200 exports of diamonds 100 0 1997 1999 2000 2002 2003 2004 year Source: NSS. become part of the global garments value chain. Armenia has succeeded in entering the diamond value chain (characterized by skilled labor activity) but has failed to capitalize on its large reserves of cheap, unskilled labor. While garments have accounted for a huge share of manufactured exports from European transition economies, this has not been the case with Armenia. Second, Armenian firms have not become integrated into the pro- duction and distribution networks. Trade in such networks as fur- niture, the automotive industry, and the information revolution (or e-network) has driven export expansion for recent Central European entrants to the EU. Despite outstanding success in the development of the ICT sector, trade in the e-network (which includes electronics, office equipment, and telecommunications) has remained modest at best. This is also the case in the furniture sector, which is less tech- nologically demanding. Furthermore, not a single Armenian firm has become a supplier to a major producer of automobiles. Third, ICT firms have not been able to take full advantage of the recent change in the ICT sector worldwide. With the disappearance of the global "one-stop-shop" industry structures in the early 1990s,1 opportunities have emerged for new entrants. Armenian firms have Impediments to International Integration 95 successfully entered software and imaging technology niches. How- ever, they have failed to enter other stages of the production and delivery processes, such as providing front-end customer contact and support services or supplying components (such as metal, plastics, and electronics components).2 The cost of missed opportunities seems to be significant. The incor- poration of local producers into the clothing chain, production and marketing networks, and the supply of ICT consumer services usually brings new technologies and managerial know-how as well as direct access to larger markets, and thus benefits of economies of scale. Incor- poration boosts exports without local firms having to incur marketing expenses and provides for greater stability in earnings, thanks to the global reach of a "parent" company. The fragmentation of production eliminates the need to gain competency in all stages and aspects of pro- duction and allows a small country to focus on a subset of activities. At the same time, production sharing can broaden the range of final products whose components are produced in the small country and thus protect the country from a demand shock to a particular good. The reasons for failure to tap into these opportunities can be related to the unfinished agenda of demanding and complex structural reforms together with trade facilitation measures. This unfinished agenda con- stitutes a barrier to a deeper involvement of Armenian firms in a finer global division of labor based on just-in-time production, inventory management, and complex Internet-based communication links. The fundamental impediments to a deeper international integration are discussed in this chapter. CONTESTABILITY OF DOMESTIC MARKETS The major constraints to the contestability of Armenia's domestic markets for goods, services, and capital are lack of transparency and inconsistent implementation of regulations and laws.3 The legal arrangements concerning entry to these markets are liberal with one exception--telecommunications services are not open to external competition. Access to other services sectors is liberal and is locked in as a condition for accession to the WTO in 2003. Apart from the temporary exemption of telecommunications services to most-favored nation (MFN) status, other sectors have been open to most modes of supply, with the usual caveat concerning restrictions on the employ- ment of foreigners.4 No legal restrictions are in place on foreign capital inflows. The for- eign investment regime, governed by the 1994 Law on Foreign Invest- ment, provides for national treatment, MFN, and full repatriation of capital and earnings. The law banning foreigners from owning land 96 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth (they can only lease it) is not restrictive, as companies registered by foreigners in Armenia as Armenian business entities have the right to own land. The barriers in the opinion of international businesses relate to the inconsistent application of rules for taxes, customs (espe- cially valuation), and regulation, especially in the area of trade. While these may not be prohibitive for large firms with easy access to high levels of state administration, they create conditions of unfair competi- tion for medium-size businesses and other market entrants and add to uncertainty. Access to Armenian markets for goods is liberal in terms of offi- cial border and behind-the-border arrangements. Tariffs are low not only by CIS standards but also by international standards. Although Armenia's weighted and unweighted average MFN tariff rates are twice as high as those in the EU, they are still well below 5 percent (Table 5.1). Furthermore, commitments made upon accession to the WTO have infused a considerable degree of stability and predictability into Armenia's foreign trade policy. They have also reduced (but not com- pletely eliminated) the potential for capture of foreign trade decisions by narrow interest groups by providing the government with tools to tame rent-seekers. Armenia's two-band tariff regime, with applied MFN tariff rates at low levels of zero or 10 percent ad valorem, has Table 5.1 Average Applied and Bond MFN Tariff Rates in Selected Countries (in percent) European Kyrgyz Union Armenia Republic Lithuania (15) 2001 2002 2003 2002 Total goods Simple average (%) 3.3 4.5 1.3 1.5 Weighted average (%) 2.2 3.2 0.6 1.4 Agricultural goods Simple average (%) 8.3 7.1 4.7 3.2 Weighted average (%) 6.6 6.6 4.3 2.9 Industrial goods Simple average (%) 2.9 4.3 1.0 1.3 Weighted average (%) 1.1 2.7 0.3 1.3 Bound rate Simple average (%) 8.5 7.4 9.2 3.9 of all goods Weighted average (%) 9.6 6.4 9.4 3.0 Binding Coverage (%) 100.0 99.9 100.0 100.0 Memorandum: simple average tariff rate in 2004 3.0 5.2 1.5 1.5 Sources: Based on the UNCTAD TRAINS (http://www.unctad.org/Templates/Page. asp?intItemID=1907&lang=1), WTO IDB database (http://www.wto.org/english/ res_e/statis_e/its2005_e/its05_toc_e.htm), and the IMF trade information database for 2004 (http://www.imf.org/external/data.htm). Impediments to International Integration 97 been locked, thanks to accession to the WTO. Armenia's schedule of MFN "bound" tariff rates has seven ad valorem rates: 0, 4, 5, 6.5, 8, 10, and 15 percent.5 However, as a condition of accession, Armenia has been required to bind tariffs across all Harmonized System items. In addition, Armenia has committed itself, as a result of direct pressure from members of its WTO working party, to review periodically the specific tariff rates to assure that these do not exceed their equivalents of ad valorem bound tariff rates.6 Armenia has made significant commitments toward a liberal trade regime in the context of WTO membership, including commitments under the WTO General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS). Except for telecommunications, Armenia's bound sectoral commit- ments are extensive in terms of both coverage and market access across different modes of supply of services. The number of subsectors in which exceptions are placed on a mode of supply (that is, unbound) is very small in Armenia's schedule. Except for settlement and clearing services for financial assets, including securities, derivative products, and other negotiable instruments, there are no exceptions under deliv- ery mode 1 (cross-border). Consumption abroad (mode 2) is subject to no restrictions. The only restriction in market access under mode 3 (commercial presence) is the requirement that suppliers of technical testing and analysis services should be legal entities constituted under Armenian legislation. In contrast to a number of countries--including highly developed economies--that limit a maximum foreign equity stake, there is no such a limit in Armenia. Given the emphasis in national economic policy on promoting the ICT sector, and given Armenia's specialization in computer services that sets it aside from countries at a similar level of economic devel- opment, it is puzzling that Armenia did not join the Information Technology Agreement (ITA) upon accession to the WTO. The ITA, concluded by 29 participants at the Singapore Ministerial Conference in December 1996, provided for participants to completely eliminate duties on ITC products covered by the Agreement by January 1, 2000. The number of WTO members that participate in ITA has risen to 63 states, including China, India, and East Asian countries includ- ing Malaysia, Singapore, and Thailand. Participation does not assure knowledge-intensive growth but can help to create the right condi- tions for such growth. However, neither commitments under the WTO Agreements nor legal provisions protecting private property rights and enforcing con- tracts alone have ensured the high contestability of Armenia's domes- tic markets. First, the capacity of courts remains weak, as they operate slowly in the enforcement of contracts and the mediation of commer- cial disputes. Furthermore, firms do not trust the ability of courts to 98 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth act independently and enforce decisions. Neither do they trust the impartiality of the state administration, regarded by businesses as cor- rupt. Second, the computerization of customs has to date fallen well short of improving the quality of customs services, with customs pro- cedures yet to achieve the WTO standards of transparency. The lack of the bilateral harmonization of customs practices with Georgia, cor- ruption, and the limited application of ITC further exacerbate trans- action costs. Nontransparent procedures corroborate businesses' complaints about the continuing practice of customs of extracting "irregular" pay- ments from them. Corruption and the imposition of unofficial fees at the border are most frequently reported by the private sector as serious issues. The fact that customs clearance procedures are applied with equal zeal also to exports is suggestive, as, generally, in other countries, customs efforts are largely directed only at imports. For example, on the rail system from Armenia to Georgia, unofficial fees account for approximately 6­13 percent of the total costs of transport (Molnar and Ojala 2003). A typical container shipment by truck from Tbilisi to Rotterdam is subject to unofficial payment costs totaling 7 to 40 percent of the total logistics costs, with customs clearance being the most significant element. The administration of VAT rebates to exporters is an important fac- tor that deters exports. VAT reimbursements do not occur quickly enough and are underpaid by the government. A recent survey (World Bank 2004a) notes that only 44 percent of surveyed firms entitled to the refund have claimed it.7 One obvious reason for unclaimed refunds is that for the remaining 56 percent of companies it took, on average, 145 days to receive a VAT refund. Moreover, on average they received 15 percent less than the amount to which they were entitled by the law. In 2005 a significant improvement has occurred in the pace and quantity of refunds. Moreover, the most anticipated benefits of the computerization of customs services (that is, reducing the release time of consignments and slashing the documentation or bureaucratic burden put on a trader or customs broker) have so far failed to materialize. Traders and customs brokers have limited access to the system. The old prac- tice of bureaucratic delays fueling corruption, combined with a lack of capacity in customs administration, continues. Other barriers to the high contestability of Armenia's domestic markets stem from the high "hassle" cost of doing business in Arme- nia discussed earlier. Weaknesses in tax administration, the capacity of the CPEC to enforce competition laws, and the weak judicial system have been responsible for low FDI inflows and for Armenia's limited success in attracting activities outsourced by multinational corpora- tions (except for diamonds). Impediments to International Integration 99 REFORMING CUSTOMS RULES Ideally, the government should extend the same customs rules that it applies to diamond cutting to other sectors of the economy. This would entail reducing the time for customs clearance to one day, accepting the invoice value, and conducting in-house clearance, if needed. While these steps would be a dramatic improvement over the current practice, other transaction cost­raising elements would have to be addressed as well, such as the VAT refund system mentioned previously. Extending a "diamond-like" regime with an improved VAT refund mechanism to all exports would be difficult. While inputs crossing customs borders are usually subject to tariff rates and indirect taxes if sold domestically, the tariff rate on diamonds is zero and no taxes are levied. By the same token, a domestic firm has no incentive to sell the imported input and will domestically circumvent customs, thereby depriving the budget of customs and other tax revenues. In short, there is no need for duty drawback, temporary admissions, or bonded warehouse schemes, which require considerable capacity on the part of customs administration to be really effective. While compu- terization--if accompanied by administrative reforms and changes in customs procedures commensurate with the newly acquired techno- logical capacities--may significantly improve this capacity, this might take some time. Therefore, the suggested reform would be to move gradually and establish a diamond-like regime in terms of administrative efficiency for a selected group of firms. The selected firms would be put on a "white list." Firms on such a white list would be eligible for special treatment by the customs and VAT administration. Customs would be obliged to complete customs clearance within a very short period; it would also have to observe the provisions of the WTO Agreement on Customs Valuation instead of using reference prices; and it would be obliged to run an effective scheme that provides duty waivers and exemptions from other restrictions on imported inputs for estab- lished exporters that import inputs, whether for domestic production or export, or both.8 The VAT administration would be obliged to rebate the VAT to a white-listed firm on the same day that exports are cleared by customs. For any delays, a firm would be entitled to a refund plus interest. Which firms, in addition to diamond-cutting firms, should be put on a white list? While the criteria to be used may be subject to fur- ther refinement, the general guidelines are easily discernible. First, the process and the criteria should be transparent and open to the public scrutiny of press and nongovernment organizations, such as business associations. 100 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Second, foreign-owned firms publicly traded on the U.S. and EU stock exchanges should be automatically included. Their operations are subject to the highest standards of international scrutiny and they can ill afford to enter into shady business operations. This would take care of participation in the global networks of production and distri- bution, simply because their major movers are publicly traded, large, multinational corporations. Third, firms operating in the ICT sector should also be included in the white list as their use of imported inputs is limited and the value added created locally is huge. Their exports are not subject to customs clearing procedures. In fact, they are virtually impossible to monitor. However, in order to claim duty and VAT rebates, they would have to disclose some transactions to the financial authorities. The overall direct benefits to ICT firms of being included in the white list are lower than for exporters of manufactures, although firms of this sector are as vociferous in their criticism of the VAT rebate scheme as are the diamond-cutting firms. Furthermore, this would be a significant step in improving the business climate for a sector critical to Armenia's move to a knowledge-intensive economy. Fourth, for the remaining firms, one would have to identify one or two criteria related to a record of past dealings with the tax adminis- tration. One criterion might involve the number of years in existence; another might take into account the past record of dealing with tax and customs administrations. Both would have to be clearly defined. The general idea would be to reward law-abiding firms. Firms that do meet the criterion of the length of existence but are involved in inward processing (for example, of garments or footwear) might be exempted. Representatives from government and other relevant business administration would annually or semiannually update the white list. A mechanism to address the grievances of those that have not been included should be designed and implemented. However, if the crite- ria are precisely defined and transparently implemented, the number of cases handled under this mechanism would be rather limited. A white list alone would not be sufficient for improving customs efficiency. There are other areas which might be relatively quickly fixed. One quick action would be the establishment of an independent professional association of customs brokers. The association would be empowered to license and scrutinize its members. In order to assure integrity and responsibility, it would operate according to a transpar- ent code of conduct that would be obligatory for all members and it would have an institutional voice in the government bodies respon- sible for overseeing customs administration. Another quick action would be to open the customs computer sys- tem to customs brokers. Customs-related documents would be brought Impediments to International Integration 101 in line with what is really required under a computerized system such as the Automated System for Customs Data (ASYCUDA). A further action would be the simplification of customs clearance procedures. Under normal circumstances, the customs clearance of exports serves one major purpose: to assure that the shipment does not contain prod- ucts banned for exports. Once an exporter produces a certificate of origin issued by the Chamber of Commerce, the shipment should be immediately cleared. Hence, a strict time limit on releasing a shipment should be introduced; if the time limit is exceeded, a shipment should be immediately released. The above measures are relatively easy to implement. While they require the close attention of policy makers, they consume adminis- trative resources in a very moderate way. Over the long term, they would actually reduce the administrative burden. INTEGRATION IS BURDENED BY EXPENSIVE BACKBONE SERVICES The domestic elements of the business climate (that is, regulatory regimes and measures directly affecting entry, conduct, and exit for firms) also influence the external interaction of domestic firms. Ele- ments that are as important for domestic as for external activities include procedures for the simplification and harmonization of inter- national trade; the state of the infrastructure and its management; and the provision of such backbone services as telecommunications, bank- ing, insurance, transportation, and business services. Other elements are customs procedures, related regulatory procedures for border clear- ance, technical standards regulations, and airport efficiency and effec- tiveness. These elements shape the ease and speed with which goods and services move across national borders services; therefore, they are crucial to trade in goods. Consequently, improvements in the domestic business climate may produce limited positive economic effects if not accompanied by similar improvements in trade facilitation. Weaknesses in the provision of backbone services add greatly to the costs for domestic firms to participate in the emerging division of labor based on international outsourcing, just-in-time production, and supply-chain management. Increasingly, sliced value chains, with individual production stages being moved to countries with compara- tive advantages, have become trademarks of a current global economic landscape. Interaction among "production blocs" of border-spanning production networks is particularly vulnerable to delays in and disrup- tions between individual stages of the supply chain owing to weak- nesses in service links. Hence, the poor quality of backbone services and trade facilitation deters foreign firms from incorporating domestic 102 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth firms into their supply chains and also acts as a barrier to other types of trade. In a nutshell, these are the factors responsible for the emer- gence of trade within global value chains and networks. The factors responsible for the emergence of a new form of the divi- sion of labor driven by the globalization of production appear to be missing in Armenia. Falling transportation and communications costs have created opportunities for the outsourcing, just-in-time production, and supply-chain management that have been altering the competitive landscape of many countries by relocating business activities and pro- viding a new source of entry into international markets. However, high transportation and communications costs as well as high transaction costs of doing business in Armenia are barriers to participation in the division of labor based on production fragmentation. The limited presence in the global value chain and trade network of garments, and the almost complete absence of Armenian providers for some ICT customer support services, have not been the result of adverse external conditions. These conditions are mostly home made, and thus can be addressed by changes in government policies. While geographic or political constraints are difficult to overcome, contempo- rary technology combined with a right mix of policies may consider- ably ease their negative impact. Outsourcing, just-in-time production, and supply-chain management, which are all critical to transferring abroad a slice of a production process, cannot function efficiently if there are delays and disruptions because of weaknesses in the service chain. The weakest link in the service chain in a country may tip the balance against including a firm in the global supply chain. The serv- ice chain includes backbone services, namely, telecommunications, transport, financial services (banking, insurance, securities trading), distribution and business services (legal services, accounting, consult- ing), as well as customs procedures. Neither politics nor geography has affected Armenia's strong and expanding presence in the diamond value chain. This is the result of inherently low transport costs and friendly government policies that are not extended to other sectors. Potential or actual producers of parts and products for other chains and networks are not in a similarly privi- leged position. Transportation costs usually account for a large share of total production costs. Few items match diamonds or services' com- bination of a lightweight and high-value unit. Just-in-time production and supply-chain management are less important in the diamond busi- ness, as is the timeliness of the communications links. For products other than diamonds the distance from major markets clearly matters, as trade costs, including transportation, customs, and communications, may make operations noncompetitive in world mar- kets. But even though trade has expanded more rapidly in areas geo- Impediments to International Integration 103 graphically closer to the major world markets, trade in more distant regions has also grown, which demonstrates that policies that reduce transaction costs can soften the negative impact of distance. Air and telecommunications links play a crucial role in this reduction. Wilson, Mann, and Otsuki (2004) identify four indicators of the capacity to facilitate trade. These are port efficiency, the customs envi- ronment, the regulatory environment, and the ICT infrastructure. Port efficiency measures the quality of the infrastructure of maritime ports and airports. The customs environment measures the direct customs costs as well as the administrative transparency of customs and bor- der crossings. The regulatory environment measures the country's approach to regulations and their quality. The ICT infrastructure meas- ures the extent to which an economy has the necessary domestic infra- structure (such as telecommunications, transportation, financial inter- mediaries, and logistics firms) and is using networked information to improve efficiency and to transform activities to enhance economic activity. Since we have discussed regulatory environment and customs practices, and since a private operator runs the airport in Yerevan, we shall focus on ICT infrastructure and transportation services. ICT INFRASTRUCTURE: THE PRIVATE TELEPHONE MONOPOLY Rapid technological development in the electronics, computer, and telecommunications industries has eroded the previously inherent natural monopoly characteristics of telecommunications. By the same token, it has weakened somewhat the negative impacts of the govern- ment's decision to grant a legal monopoly (originally until 2013) to ArmenTel, the local telecommunications company, owned by the Hel- lenic Telecommunications Organization. The monopoly also encom- passes cellular; the local loop providing land line links to firms and households; and international sources, including, theoretically, Internet services. The only areas that have escaped the monopoly's reach, albeit not completely, are the Voice over Internet protocol (VoIP) and private international satellite communication such as that operated by Lycos, a private foreign company. These developments account for the low volume of officially captured international calls. But satellite communi- cation is not a full substitute for access through land lines, and satellite has nontrivial fixed costs and cannot be connected to the telecommu- nications network to provide backup and higher utilization. Therefore, while modern technologies offer some ways of circumventing the monopoly reach of ArmenTel, it controls the decisive "last mile" local loop access and has dominated the mobile phone market. 104 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth How has ArmenTel's monopoly affected the development of tel- ecommunications in Armenia? One way of addressing this question is to compare the costs and the use of telecommunications services in Armenia to those in other CIS countries. This may not be a very demanding benchmark, as many other CIS countries have equally poor regulatory reform and privatization and some still maintain a state monopoly for service provision. Nevertheless, the general con- clusion is that, overall, Armenia's telecommunications services com- pared with other CIS countries performed poorly over 1998­2002. Despite an increase in 2002 over 2001, in 2003 the international outgo- ing traffic from Armenia declined significantly more on average than in other CIS countries. The cost of using the Internet in Armenia was 41 percent higher than the average for the CIS. The prices for high- speed connections charged by ArmenTel are around 30 times more than those in countries where telecommunications services are not monopolized. These developments explain why Armenia had a low number of Internet users, well below the CIS average. Moreover, the number of cellular phones per 1,000 people is significantly lower than in neighboring Georgia. Tables 5.2 and 5.3 compare the telecommunications situation in Armenia with those in Azerbaijan and Georgia. Tables 5.4 and 5.5 compare benchmarks for telecommunications infrastructure and the Internet in Armenia with selected countries. The poor quality of the ICT infrastructure is a barrier to the devel- opment of the economy and to its shift toward the higher knowledge intensity and enhanced networking that technological change permits Table 5.2 Telecommunications Sector Overview Armenia Azerbaijan Georgia Population, 2003, millions 3.80 8.23 4.89 GDP per capita 2003, PPP, US$ 3,607 3,606 2,569 Telecom revenue, 2002, US$ millions 70.1 85.8 135.0 Telecom investments, 2002, US$ millions 22.7 28.7 n.a. Number of fixed lines, 2003 563,679 941,366 650,500 State ownership share in the incumbent ArmenTel 10% n.a. n.a. fixed-line operator, September 2004 (90% owned by Greece's OTE) Number of mobile subscribers, June 2004 137,530 1,317,560 779,300 Number of mobile operators, June 2004 1 2 3 Sources: World Development Indicators (WDI) (http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/ EXTERNAL/DATASTATISTICS/ 0,,contentMDK:20398986~menuPK:64133163 ~pagePK:64133150~piPK:64133175~theSitePK:239419,00.html), ITU, European Mobile Communications Report (http://www.mac.doc.gov/ceebic/countryr/Fyrm/ MARKET/ Macedonia%27s%20Information%20Technology%20Sector.pdf). Table 5.3 Percentage of Households with Access to a Telephone Income quintiles Country Total 1 2 3 4 5 Capital (Yerevan) 83.7 73.6 80.6 78.9 88.4 92.8 Armenia Other urban 64.8 46.8 59.5 67.5 76.8 79.9 Impediments (ISLS 2001) Rural 44.0 34.8 40.4 42.8 48.1 53.3 Whole country 61.8 50.4 56.4 59.4 68.1 74.5 Capital (Baku) 63.4 58.4 55.1 62.8 68.5 71.6 Azerbaijan Other urban 44.4 43.2 42.7 40.8 48.2 48.7 to (HBS 2001) Rural 18.4 18.2 17.3 18.3 17.9 20.1 International Whole country 38.6 38.4 36.9 35.8 38.9 43.1 Capital (Tbilisi) 71.7 59.1 63.7 70.9 76.9 82.1 Georgia Other urban 47.3 31.8 44.1 49.9 58.6 66.7 (HBS 2001) Rural 8.8 5.0 8.2 8.8 10.5 10.8 Integration Whole country 34.7 25.4 33.2 34.5 37.9 42.5 Source: Integrated Survey of Living Standards (ISLS); Household Budget Survey (HBS). Note: Comparisons should be made only within countries and not between them, since the surveys were conducted independently and the questions were not identical. 105 106 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Table 5.4 Basic Telecommunications Infrastructure Benchmarks GDP per Households Mobile capita with a Main lines penetration, 2003, television, per 100 August PPP 2002 inhabitants, 2004 Country (US$) (%) 2003 (%) Albania 4,571 90 8 32 Armenia 3,607 91 15 4 Azerbaijan 3,606 121 11 17 Bosnia and Herzegovina 6,029 87 24 31 Bulgaria 7,807 93a 38 59 Croatia 11,139 94d 42b 60 Czech Republic 16,448 99 36 100 FYR Macedonia 6,762 82d 27b 40 Georgia 2,569 76 13 17 Greece 19,973 98c 45 96 Hungary 14,572 96c 35 76 Moldova 1,505 -- 22 14 Romania 7,222 97 20 40 Serbia and Montenegro -- 92 24 37 Slovak Republic 13,469 100 24 75 Slovenia 19,300 91 41 95 Turkey 6,749 108 27 45 Sources: WDI, ITU, European Mobile Communications Report, Paul Budde Communication. a. Data from 2003; b. data from 2002; c. data from 2001; d. data from 2000; -- =not available. and encourages. The absence of high-quality services and the high costs of existing services affect all sectors of the economy, amounting often to the equivalent of a prohibitive tax on some potential markets. It is impossible to estimate how many transactions have not taken place because of this situation. Neither is it possible to tell how many industrial or service operations would have been transferred to Arme- nia had there been more efficient telecommunications services. It is, however, indisputable that very high telecommunications costs have severely exacerbated the disadvantage associated with Armenia's geo- graphical location. High-quality ICT infrastructure and services are crucial to the development of a contemporary economy. Impediments to International Integration 107 Table 5.5 Internet Benchmarks Internet International Internet PCs users Internet hosts per 100 per 100 bandwidth per 1000 inhabitants, inhabitants, per capita, inhabitants, Country 2002 2003 2002, bps 2003 Albania 1.2 1 3.9 0.08 Armenia 1.6 4 2.1 0.55 Azerbaijan 4a 0.3 0.07 Bosnia and Herzegovina n.a. 3a 6.6c 1.89 Bulgaria 5.2 21 10.1 6.66 Croatia 17.4 23 41.2 6.78 Czech Republic 17.7 31 2,189.1 27.44 FYR Macedonia 4.5 5a 24.2 1.73 Georgia 3.2 3 1.01 Greece 8.2 15 222.0 17.05 Hungary 10.8 23 246.3 35.78 Moldova 2.1 8 9.4 3.32 Romania 8.3 18 89.3 2.18 Serbia and Montenegro 2.7 8 0.9b 1.84 Slovak Republic 18.0 26 1,516.0 21.22 Slovenia 30.1 38a 539.6 21.48 Turkey 4.3 8 16.3 5.08 Source: ITU. Online at: http://www.mac.doc.gov/ceebic/countryr/Fyrm/MARKET/ Macedonia%27s%20Information%20Technology%20Sector.pdf a. Data from 2002; b. data from 2001; c. data from 2000; bps = bits per second; -- = not available. The ArmenTel monopoly has been reduced and further cellular competition will be allowed in 2009. A new mobile operator has been licensed, although, given the objectives pursued and the process fol- lowed, it is unlikely that a competitive regime will emerge. Duopolies can produce outcomes close to monopolies unless competition law is actively applied to prevent tacit collusion. The PSRC has been given enhanced powers in an attempt to countervail the adverse effects of ArmenTel's continuing dominant market position. There is little expec- tation that Armenia will benefit fully from the rapid fall in costs and the introduction of new services that a fully liberalized market would offer. It is understood that the government regards current policies as the best achievable until the ArmenTel license expires in 2013. It is 108 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth crucial that every opportunity be taken to maximize the possibilities for competition given the current policy and agreements. Clearly, the government faces the difficult issue of minimizing the negative impact of some of the most restrictive provisions of its con- tract with ArmenTel without endangering the credibility of Armenia's commitment to the sanctity of contracts or facing a considerable fiscal cost. The policy so far has been a combination of a strong commit- ment to respect the contract while requiring that ArmenTel meets its obligations, together with a declaration that regardless of its outcome, mobile (cellular) and data services sectors will be open to domestic and foreign companies in the future. In the meantime, the tactic is being followed of increasing the regu- latory pressure on ArmenTel by placing telecommunications under the jurisdiction of the PSRC, which deals also with power, water, and natural gas. However, as long as ArmenTel essentially has monopoly rights, the major task would be overseeing a monopoly and trying to use regulatory tools to encourage the utility to expand its out- put and lower its prices to efficient levels. The management of the license should ensure that all provisions concerning the commitments of ArmenTel are implemented. This task is different from setting the regulatory framework that facilitates entry and protecting the com- petitive process. Hence, as long as the monopoly is in place, the best intervention is to ensure that the PSRC is an efficient and effective regulator and enforcer of the modified agreement with ArmenTel. With the current duopoly likely to continue until 2009, an additional option would be for the government to develop and announce now its future policy: namely, that all government-imposed economic entry barriers would be removed when the license expires (so that, for example, the electric- ity distribution company could provide telecommunications services if technically and commercially viable). Furthermore, the available and necessary radio frequency spectrum will be auctioned off well before 2009, so that further mobile operators, to the extent that they consider they would be commercially viable, would be able to enter the market as soon as restrictions are lifted. Private networks (includ- ing those using satellite links) could prepare to interconnect and pro- vide services to other customers. The market after 2013 should be regulated only by competition law. AIR TRANSPORT: AN UNTAPPED ASSET Despite the importance of land transport, the infrastructure system in Armenia requires modernization, including adequate provisions for ongoing maintenance and management and considerable road reha- Impediments to International Integration 109 bilitation. In addition, most of its rail track and rolling stock are in need of repair or replacement. Since rail and road links from Georgia to Armenia account for 70 percent of Armenian trade, their quality is of particular importance. They are all in poor condition. The lack of direct sea access, the mismanaged state-owned railway company (Holden and Sahakyan 2004), the high freight rates, and the ongoing blockade of the borders with Azerbaijan and Turkey, all contribute heavily to the high transportation costs faced by importers and export- ers, which puts Armenian firms at a competitive disadvantage. Unless transport costs go down, the trade patterns will remain biased toward goods with high value relative to weight at the expense of the bulky low-cost products of light industry. This may explain why, unlike the situation in other transition economies, Armenia's exports of textiles, apparel, and footwear have been limited. What can the government do about transportation costs? It is important to ensure good road operation and development in order to lower vehicle operating costs and transport time, and the govern- ment may be spending too little by way of public investment in this area (note that the medium term expenditure framework for 2006­8 suggests that funding for state roads is declining as a share of GDP). Placing the state-run railway on a business footing would allow it to compete more effectively with road transport and to maximize its economic value added. The government can influence the perform- ance of infrastructure service providers through changes in incen- tives and the institutional environment. Investments in infrastructure and strengthening the regulatory structure can reduce transport costs with particularly large potential for reducing costs in air transport and railways. Overall, however, as mentioned earlier, transportation costs, both overland and by air, are well above the levels in other CIS land- locked countries, including those located further away than Armenia from their most important markets, largely in the EU. The shift away from air transport to land transport indicates that the former has become less competitive. Providers of air cargo serv- ices have been unable to retain their clients or to lure new ones with more attractive prices, as freight shipped by air from Yerevan fell between 1997 and 2003 by more than two-thirds (depending on the indicator).9 The fall has been even more dramatic considering that the value of exports of goods rose 3.3 times over this period. Volumes increased significantly in 2004, back to the level four years earlier. The re-opening of the land corridor through Georgia might have boosted land transport. But had there been more aircraft belly space available, thanks to an increase in the number of passenger flights, lower air cargo rates would have attracted a much larger portion of shipments than was the case. This clearly has not happened, as there was no significant increase in the frequency of flights until 2004. It remains 110 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth to be seen whether the resumption of growth in air services contin- ues, is sustained, and translates into better services for cargo shippers (including lower prices). The fall in the share of the most dynamic worldwide mode of transport--air transport--can be attributed to the fall in the competi- tiveness of air transport services owing to poor infrastructure and a restrictive aviation policy. The poor infrastructure component has been potentially addressed, thanks to the government's decision to sign a 30-year concession agreement with Argentina-based Corpora- cion America for the management of the Yerevan Zvartnot Interna- tional Airport in 2003. Careful management of the concession by the government, within a clear policy framework, should result in a more efficient and effective provision of airport services. The removal of the infrastructure barrier alone will not suffice to make air transport competitive. The appropriate regulatory environ- ment must be in place in order to take advantage of better infra- structure. However, recent government action is not encouraging: an agreement has been signed with the Russian airline Siberia for the establishment of a new airline (Armavia) to take over Armenian inter- national air "rights" on an exclusive basis until 2013 (with a stream of annual payments to the government for these rights).This agreement suggests that the approach to aviation policy has remained restric- tive via exclusive and restrictive route rights. Instead of moving to a less restrictive approach that emphasizes the removal of govern- ment-imposed entry barriers to air services (as pioneered by Chile and implemented by countries such as Latvia), Armenia has retained the bilateral system of air transport regulations, which is based on a positive list approach that limits the provision of services to those that are explicitly permitted.10 An existing Armenian airline, the Armenian International Airline, has been forced out of serving the Armenian air markets as a result of the government's agreement with Armavia. Leaving aside safety and aviation security issues, which need to be addressed in any future scenario, the regulatory philosophy underly- ing the restrictive approach to bilateral aviation agreements has been to protect the "national" carrier from external competition--Armavia in this case. Governments have understandably been concerned about service continuity and have often considered that only a national car- rier will ensure such continuity. Costly regulatory assistance is usually given, as in this case, although the government, unusually by interna- tional practices, is receiving explicit annual payments in return for the grant of exclusive rights. Inferior services in terms of costs and qual- ity often result. International experience shows that in a deregulated environment airlines will serve markets: concerns about service conti- nuity have been generally unfounded. Regulatory restrictions impede this process and tend to exclude the most efficient airlines. Impediments to International Integration 111 The empirical evidence from countries that have deregulated the domestic aviation sector (such as the United States and the EU) is robust: passengers and air freight shippers in both the EU and the United States have experienced a dramatic and continuing decline in airfares. Thanks to the opening of the sector to new entrants, existing carriers have come under strong competitive pressures. These in turn have reduced costs through gains in productivity. The entry of the so-called low-cost carriers (LCCs) has halved airfares and stimulated volume by at least 70 percent in both the EU and the United States. Competition has also been responsible for a faster adaptation and diffusion of new technologies. The combination of liberalization and technological progress has been behind a 3.5 percent average annual decline in real terms in prices of services over 1991­2001. The costs of bilateral aviation agreements are not just reflected in the higher prices of air transport due to the absence or limited competition. In fact, they also involve the much more important and more difficult- to-estimate costs of forgone opportunities. These costs are potentially large as lower airfares boost tourism, stimulate important flows of ideas and human capital, deepen networks, and create new opportuni- ties for firms to market their products domestically and internationally. Tourists in turn increase the demand for a range of services and goods. The empirical evidence can be supplemented by several examples. The liberalization of aviation policy, together with investment in the Emirates airline, has contributed to Dubai's impressive economic development, which is driven largely by tourism and services. The result of the relatively liberal policies pursued by the United Arab Emirates since the 1980s is that Dubai is now served by around 100 airlines flying to 145 destinations and Emirates has become a formi- dable world-class competitor. More important, Dubai it has become a tourist and business center in the Middle East. Last, but not least, one suspects that the probability for a firm to become incorporated in global production and distribution networks increasingly on the basis of just-in-time production is low in the absence of reliable, high- frequency, competitive air transport services. A second example suggests that airline liberalization has been a contributing factor to economic development in Ireland--often described as a Celtic Tiger because of its spectacular economic growth performance over the last decade or so. It is often overlooked that the measures that created a "virtuous circle" leading to the Irish economic boom included not only public expenditure cutbacks that allowed for tax reductions but also EU-driven airline deregulation that allowed Ryanair to fully develop the LCC business model following the U.S. Southwest Airlines example. Deregulation "facilitated a more than doubling of tourist numbers over the following decade" and contrib- uted significantly to FDI inflows (Barry 2003, p. 909). 112 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth For a small landlocked economy aiming to maximize its long-term economic growth rate, the best aviation policy would be along the lines of the Chilean "Open Skies" policy, which would include Armenian carriers having reciprocal rights to compete. Under this arrangement the government policy would be to eliminate government-imposed entry barriers to air transport. This should be the option that Arme- nia should adopt as quickly as possible, although the agreement of Armavia would probably be required, unless their contract with the government is renegotiated. Full implementation of such a policy is not likely in the immedi- ate future, as it would take both governments (Armenia and Russia) to agree to liberalize a bilateral agreement. Taking into account the lack of Armavia's business interests in some routes and interests of other governments to open access for their carriers, Armenia may be able to strike Open Skies agreements with the United States, the United Arab Emirates, and Bahrain, for example. Since all three are potentially important markets, and since the latter two offer relatively close outlets to a wide range of markets, these agreements would be of significant economic importance to Armenia. The reason why the United Arab Emirates and Bahrain might be interested in Open Skies agreements is that both have carriers with well-connected hubs that offer high-frequency connections throughout the Middle East and Asia. Such an agreement would also offer an extra air cargo link to European markets. The reasons why the United States might accept the offer are two- fold: one related to the Armenian diaspora and commercial relations in the United States and the other to the international aviation policy of the United States. The pressure from the diaspora might be rein- forced by U.S. carriers interested in flights to Armenia. As for the U.S. aviation policy aspect, such a reciprocal agreement would be natural, as at present, the United States has Open Skies agreements with over 70 countries, including Uzbekistan and, recently, India. The U.S. type of Open Skies agreement typically includes the fifth freedom11 code- share rights for U.S. carriers extended beyond hubs outside the United States. This would allow a U.S. carrier to add its code to any partner airline (for example, an EU carrier flight into Yerevan). To date, the EU has displayed little interest in entering into negotia- tions to achieve the major modifications that Open Skies agreements would entail with small countries with restrictive air service policies. Rather, it has been seeking to extend arrangements like the European Civil Aviation Area to other countries with the Open Sky type of poli- cies (the United States, Singapore, and New Zealand, for example). Within the parameters of this approach, the CIS might be a potential partner but not Armenia alone. Impediments to International Integration 113 Table 5.6 Phased Civil Aviation Reform Time framework Incumbent carriers New entrant carriers April 1, 2006, to April 1, 2007 Up to 3 daily flights Up to a daily freq. From April 1, 2007 Unrestricted Unrestricted Source: Bank staff. Under these circumstances, the Open Skies agreement with the EU is currently an unlikely option, and Armenia should instead announce its objective of removing restrictions on carriers and inbound flights, subject to receiving reciprocal rights. If Armenia considers that the protection this would accord Armavia would be insufficient (includ- ing taking account of the agreement with Armavia), then depending on the assessment of the agreement with Armavia (or its successor), the government could take a phased approach toward a fully liberal and unrestrictive policy. The steps could be as shown in Table 5.6. The government could also implement a liberal approach for fifth freedom rights as well as explicitly announcing that it favors a multi- airline policy. Armenia could gain considerably from Open Skies arrangements among CIS countries modeled on the EU European Civil Aviation Area. But this would take time, as Armenia would have to develop the model and convince other CIS members, perhaps building a coalition with like-minded countries. A likely increase in the number of flights connecting Yerevan with the Middle East, the United States, and the EU would exert competitive pressure on airlines that service routes to Moscow and other destina- tions in Russia, particularly as the recent survey of passengers through Yerevan airport has shown that the great bulk of passengers flying to Moscow were actually en route to Europe and the United States. SUMMARY AND KEY RECOMMENDATIONS Armenia enjoys an admirably open trade and investment regime, but firms are insufficiently linked to the international production and dis- tribution chains, and ICT firms have not been able to make good use of international opportunities. Major constraints lie in the lack of transparency and consistency in regulation and the poor customs administration. Customs rules can be reformed to make its adminis- tration more rules-based. Policy-induced high costs in telecommuni- cations and in air transport need to be fought, as current structures impose a high "tax" on competitiveness. It is suggested that the 114 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth future liberal telecommunications regulatory regime be decided and announced now, and that rapid steps be taken to remove economic restrictions on civil aviation with the aim of developing an Open Skies policy in conjunction with the EU. Customs and VAT: Establish a "white list" of firms subject to spe- cial treatment by Customs and VAT administration, including quick customs clearance; use provisions of the WTO Agreement on Customs Valuation instead of using reference prices; create an effective scheme that provides duty waivers and exemptions from other restrictions on imported inputs; and give rebates of VAT as soon as exports are cleared by customs. Extend direct transfer input to all customs houses. Bring customs-related documents in line with what is really required under a computerized system of the ASYCUDA type. Simplify customs clearance procedures for exports with a strict time limit on releasing a shipment; if the time limit is exceeded, the shipment should be immediately released. Support participation in international R&D networks (such as the EU 6th Framework Program). Sign the WTO Information Technology Agreement. Publish a statement of government civil aviation policy for con- sultation. Introduce new and increased services in 2005­6. Pass a new telecommunications law and see that the responsibil- ity for implementation, including that of the ArmenTel license, is passed to PSRC. Have a cellular competitor enter service. Have the PSRC prepare a regulatory policy statement in 2006 that, among other things, lays out an implementation plan for the entry of a third service provider by 2009. NOTES 1. A large number of firms, connected through complex and borderless supply chains made up of high-volume, multicustomer, and multinational specialists at each level, have replaced the vertically integrated firms domi- nant in the 1980s and early 1990s. 2. The front-end, customer-centric portion of the supply chain includes service providers such as contact centers, order processing, and technical sup- port. At the same level is the order fulfillment hub, which is a combination of a logistics center with order picking and configuration capabilities. Impediments to International Integration 115 3. The following sources have been used in this section: the World Bank's various country reports, the World Bank Investment Climate Survey, BEEPS and BEEPS II surveys, Economist Intelligence Unit information, the Heritage Foundation's Index of Economic Freedom, and the World Bank's Doing Busi- ness Indicators. 4. Armenia, however, has made a commitment "to provide unlimited mar- ket access for all basic and value-added telecommunications services sub- sector initially covered by the monopoly immediately upon suspension or termination of monopoly rights in that subsector on or at anytime prior to the end of the monopoly." See WTO 2002. 5. The simple average bound tariff rate for all products is 8.6 percent, with the average rate of 14.9 percent for agricultural products and 7.7 percent for industrial products (authors' calculation based on Armenia's "Bound" Sched- ule). Both averages put Armenia in the middle of transition economies. For agricultural products, Albania, the Slovak Republic, and the Czech Republic (prior to the EU accession) have lower rates of 9.4 percent and 10 percent. Estonia's and Latvia's rates are higher at 17.5 and 34.6 percent, correspond- ingly. For industrial products, Albania, the Czech Republic, the Slovak Repub- lic, Hungary, and Estonia have lower average rates of 6.6, 4.2, 4.2, 6.9, and 7.3 percent, respectively. 6. This is an extra Armenia-specific commitment to observe the provisions of the WTO Agreement. 7. Data show that a significant improvement in timeliness in VAT refunds began to take place in 2005. 8. Their design and implementation would require the attention of pol- icy makers. Some possible mechanisms are a rebate scheme on account, a deferred drawback, or a temporary admissions mechanism. 9. Freight in thousand metric tons stood at 33 percent of its 1997 level in 2003 and in million ton-kilometers at 26 percent. 10. According to this approach, a service can be provided only if it is explicitly permitted. 11. The fifth freedom refers the right of an airline from one country to land in a second country, pick up passengers, and fly to a third country where the passengers then deplane. This would allow, for example, a U.S. airline to stop en route to Armenia or fly beyond Armenia providing services at each stage. Chapter 6 Knowledge and Innovation T he creation, dissemination, and use of knowledge, together with the required strengthening of the competition and external inte- gration policies, must lie at the heart of the effort to ramp up technol- ogy in production. For the efficient use of knowledge, the four pillars that are widely accepted conditions are the following: an economic and institutional regime that provides incentives for the efficient creation, dissemination, and use of existing knowledge an educated and skilled population that can create and use knowledge a system of research centers, universities, think tanks, consult- ants, firms, and other organizations that can tap into the grow- ing stock of global knowledge, and assimilate and adapt it to local needs a dynamic information infrastructure that can facilitate the effective communication, dissemination, and processing of information Armenia is distinctive in having the following characteristics: A significant annual inflow into the labor force of energetic, moti- vated individuals who value knowledge and higher education. Armenia's private higher education (although of a predictably low quality) is one of the most vibrant sectors of the economy. A large stock of highly educated people, yet with largely obso- lete specialized skills. In the former USSR Armenia specialized in 117 118 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth R&D, and all the tribulations of the past 12 years notwithstand- ing, Armenia still boasts a critical mass of human capital that sustains a culture that values knowledge. However, this stock has been eroded recently owing to emigration, a low level of public spending on education, and delayed reforms in university education. A large and entrepreneurial diaspora which is as generous in philanthropic contributions to Armenia as (with few exceptions) it is reticent in business initiatives. Weak local entrepreneurship. Although there are some success- ful entrepreneurs (for example, in the software and jewelry sectors), they are not nearly numerous enough to change the economy. Clusters and value chains are not developing. There are of course the usual reasons of a weak investment climate and geographical isolation, but these do not appear to be the main problem. Armenian entrepreneurs and policy makers alike do not appreciate (and hence do not seek to improve) the value of intangibles (brand names, business reputations, marketing and managerial skills, networks, and so forth). This is where a large stock of educated engineers and scientists, with their attendant focus on assets that one can touch, turns to a disadvantage. Fragmentation of the policy debate. Traditions of collective action and public-private partnerships are also weak. The policy challenge lies in building on the strengths of the coun- try and addressing the critical weaknesses so that growth at higher productivity levels can be ensured. Here the major burden falls on the mobilization and recombination of the existing human capital, triggered by an initially modest investment in intangibles, such as mechanisms of knowledge and skill transfer from the diaspora to Armenia. The major contribution that policy analysis can make is to provide a fresh per- spective on problems, thereby inviting policy makers to change their mindsets and to identify and initiate knowledge-intensive initiatives. THE KNOWLEDGE ECONOMY IN THE INTERNATIONAL CONTEXT The following figures illustrate Armenia's knowledge readiness from the mid-1990s to the early years of this decade. Figure 6.1 demon- strates the relative performance of countries and regions in the Knowl- edge Economy Index (KEI), a composite index which measures the preparedness of the country for a knowledge-based development framework. The KEI is calculated by computing the average of the Knowledge and Innovation 119 Figure 6.1 Armenia and the World: Knowledge Economy Index 10 W. Europe 9 G-7 LEVEL Singapore United Rep. of Korea States Slovenia Oceania 8 Hungary Ireland G7 Poland Israel 7 ENTRY LEVEL Latvia Chile Estonia Slovak Rep. Czech Republic ecent)r 6 EAP ECA Russian Federation Belarus Costa Rica 5 COPING Armenia Argentina (most ECONOMIES LAC Romania 4 MNA Ukraine China Kazakhstan Mexico index 3 LAGGARDS Uzbekistan Turkey Georgia India 2 AFR SA 1 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 index (1995) Source: KAM, K4D, WBI, World Bank (www.worldbank.org/kam). performance scores of a country or region in all four pillars of the Knowledge Economy (KE). Overall, during the last five to seven years, Armenia improved rather marginally its performance in the KEI. In the knowledge map (Figure 6.1), as defined by countries' performance in the index, Arme- nia stands within the medium performers group, yet noticeably below the average of the ECA region. Armenia falls further behind OECD and EU members, while the performance gap between Armenia and its selected comparators is significant.1 In particular the gap with respect to Israel and Ireland is significant. These indicators should signal the sense of urgency for Armenia, which, despite its well-documented potential and impressive economic growth trends, does not seem to be maximizing the benefits from its competencies. Armenia is also falling behind other former socialist economies that have managed to com- pete better in a rapidly changing knowledge-based environment. Countries can be divided into four broad classes: Very low knowledge endowments--laggards. Relatively low endowments--coping economies. 120 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth "Accession club"--entry-level to KE--a class that is characteris- tic of upper middle­income economies starting to compete on knowledge and innovation, not on low labor costs alone. These are more advanced ECA and Asian countries. G-7 levels of knowledge endowments. While the criteria distinguishing one class from another are neces- sarily arbitrary, the messages for Armenia are quite clear: On the overall KE score, Armenia is among the coping econo- mies: it is within the same league as Russia, Ukraine, and Costa Rica and within a healthy distance from both laggards and entry- level economies. Yet Armenia's performance across the four KE pillars (economic incentive regime, education, innovation, and ICTs) is unusually unbalanced. On economic and institutional regime Armenia per- forms very well, on a par with recent EU entrants. In contrast, the ICT pillar is shockingly underdeveloped. Not only is Arme- nia squarely among laggards (the worst category, occupied by Sub-Saharan Africa, Albania, and the Central Asian republics of the FSU); its relative position has actually worsened significantly since 1995. This is all the more worrisome given its geographical isolation. Because of its landlocked status and unfriendly neigh- bors it should at least rank in the accession club on ICT. On education, Armenia still performs reasonably although lag- ging behind many Eastern European economies. However, the relatively good human capital is a heritage of Soviet times that has not translated into adequate innovation performance. The innovation pillar remains weak. Examining performance in the four KE pillars that define the aggre- gate KEI (Figure 6.2), Armenia performs poorly in the ICT pillar, an area in which it lost significant ground relative to the world. In abso- lute terms Armenia did improve its ICT indicators (explicitly shown in Figure 6.2) but the world on average--defined by the 121 countries in the Knowledge Assessment Methodology (KAM) sample--made a significantly larger improvement. Armenia's strongest pillar is its economic and institutional regime (EIR), which was the weakest in the mid-1990s; in this area the country demonstrated significant improve- ments and remains particularly competitive in the ECA region. In the education pillar, a traditionally strong area for the country, Armenia lost some ground, while in the innovation pillar the country regressed even more. Figure 6.3 illustrates how Armenia performed, over time, in each of the 12 variables that describe the four KE pillars, and therefore Knowledge and Innovation 121 Figure 6.2 Armenia: Performance in the Four Knowledge Economy Pillars, 1995­Most Recent Armenia (most recent and 1995), normalization group: all economic incentive regime 10 information innovation 0 infrastructure most recent 1995 education Source: KAM, K4D, WBI, World Bank (www.worldbank.org/kam). Figure 6.3 Armenia Knowledge Economy Index Scorecard Armenia (most recent and 1995) average annual GDP growth (%) Internet users per 10,000 10 Human Development Index computers per 1,000 tariff & nontariff barriers telephones per 1,000 regulatory quality (mainlines & mobiles) tertiary enrollment rule of law secondary enrollment researchers in R&D/mil. pop. adult literacy rate (% age 15 scientific & technical journal & above) patent articles/mil. pop. applications most recent granted by the 1995 USPTO/mil. pop. Source: KAM, K4D, WBI, World Bank (http://www.worldbank.org/kam). the aggregate KEI, plus two performance variables (GDP growth and Human Development Index [HDI]). In the EIR pillar, the country demonstrated the largest improve- ment in the ECA region, currently performing well above the regional average, behind Latvia and Hungary (Figure 6.4). Armenia signifi- 122 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 6.4 Economic Incentive Regime: Armenia and the World 10 Singapore 9 G-7 LEVEL Estonia Oceania W. Europe 8 Ireland Chile G7 United States 7 Hungary Costa Rica Israel ENTRY LEVEL Rep. of Korea Armenia Latvia Czech Rep. recent) 6 Poland Slovak Rep. Slovenia 5 COPING Mexico ECONOMIES (most EAP Turkey ECA 4 LAGGARDSGeorgia AFR MNA Romania LAC index 3 China Ukraine India 2 Russian SA Federation Argentina Kazakhstan 1 Belarus 0 Uzbekistan 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 index (1995) Source: KAM (http://www.worldbank.org/kam). Note: Armenia is an open economy with total trade representing currently 75 percent of GDP, which is still below the average of the ECA region. Armenia's exports of goods and services as a share of GDP--a solid indication of international competitiveness--is significantly lower than all comparator countries and the same income group average. In Armenia in 2002, despite the fact that exports of goods and services had significantly increased since 1995 and accounted for almost 30 percent of GDP, imports accounted for 47 percent of GDP, causing Armenia to carry over a significant trade deficit, much larger than any of its comparator countries. cantly improved its terms of trade by reducing tariff and nontariff bar- riers2 and also managed to improve significantly, relative to the world, its regulatory quality indicators by implementing policies friendly to markets and business. Rule of law indicators did not improve signifi- cantly and they are below the regional average levels, but still the country showed better improvement than the average of the KAM country sample, and therefore it demonstrates improvement relative to the world. Armenia is lagging behind all of its selected comparators in this pillar, with the exception of Russia, which is moving particu- larly slowly toward a modernized institutional phase. Figures 6.4 and 6.5 show several additional KAM indicators that describe performance in the pillar of economic incentive regime. The scorecard indicates that Armenia is characterized by low levels of gross Knowledge and Innovation 123 Figure 6.5 Armenia's Scorecard in the Economic Incentive Regime Armenia (most recent) gross capital formation (18.80) 10 5 tariff & nontariff 0 general government barriers (10.00) budget balance as % of GDP (-3.00) trade as % of GDP (75.00) Source: KAM (www.worldbank.org/kam). Note: Data for gross capital formation shown in the figure is the average of the period 1991­2001. domestic investment, the lowest among its comparators. On average for the years 1995­2002, Armenia spent around 19 percent of GDP in domestic investments--the least share along with Costa Rica--while the closest was Russia, 20 percent; and Latvia and Slovenia topped the list with 25 percent. Armenia on average for 1995­2002 spent a significantly smaller amount in domestic investments than, on aver- age, the groups of low- and middle-income countries. On governance and institutional quality variables, Armenia per- forms significantly worse than all other comparators and the average of the region, with the exception of Russia in rule of law and Israel in voice and accountability indicators. In particular, despite a national campaign against corruption, the high incidence of corruption con- tinues to affect business and the attraction of foreign investment. The Heritage Foundation (2004) states in its analysis that "bribery is wide- spread and is the most common form of corruption, especially in the areas of government procurement, all types of transfers and approvals, and such business-related services as company registration, licensing, and land or space allocation." The Bleyzer Foundation in a benchmark- ing analysis of 15 FSU countries on FDI driving conditions notes that Armenia is ranked thirteenth in the corruption level index, whereas in the overall composite index it is ranked sixth, behind Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Kazakhstan, and Russia (Bleyzer 2002).3 124 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Furthermore, the size of the shadow economy in Armenia, which is equal to 45 percent of GDP, is significantly larger than that in some of its comparator economies and the average for the region (Table 6.1). This reveals the poor institutional capacity and high incidence of corruption in Armenia, combined with the increasing tax burden and social security payments. The size of the shadow economy in Armenia is a prohibitive factor in fiscal revenue generation, which could cre- ate a vicious cycle with tax base erosion (resulting in higher taxes), the worsening of fiscal constraints (Economist 2003), and ambiguous effects on private sector development and the quality of products and services. Unless urgent and radical reforms transform the effectiveness of the governance and institutional capacity of the country, Armenia will be facing competitiveness challenges that will be hard to meet. In education, a pillar in which Armenia has a strong tradition, the country lost some ground relative to the world and remains weak rel- ative to the regional ECA average (Figure 6.6). Enrollment in second- ary education has fallen significantly in the post-transition period and remains well below the (ECA) regional average. However, enrollment in tertiary education improved significantly but still remains at very low levels by regional standards.4 The vast majority of ECA econo- mies, and all selected comparators (with the exception of Costa Rica), outperform Armenia in the KAM variables used to define aggregate performance in the education pillar. Figure 6.7 isolates Armenia and presents the available set of vari- ables used in the KAM to define performance in the education pillar. It is striking to realize, relative to the large availability and potential of educated human capital in the country, how little Armenia spends on education--less than 3 percent of GDP (2000 data). The significant Table 6.1 The Size of the Shadow Economy (as percent of GDP) Country 1990­93 2000­01 Armenia 40.1 45.3 Estonia 34.3 39.1 Ireland 15.4* 15.7** Russian Federation 27.8 45.1 Slovenia 22.9 26.7 Average Central and Eastern Europe 23.4 29.2 Average FSU 32.9 44.8 Average of 21 OECD countries 15.7* 16.7** Source: Schneider 2002. *1994­5; ** 2001­2. Knowledge and Innovation 125 Figure 6.6 Education: Armenia and the World 10 W. Europe United States Poland 9 G-7 LEVEL Slovenia Ukraine Oceania Latvia 8 Russian Federation G7 Czech Rep. Ireland Argentina 7 Rep. of Korea ENTRY LEVEL Slovak Rep. ECA Israel Estonia Romania Belarus recent) 6 Chile Hungary EAP Kazakhstan 5 Mexico Georgia (most COPING LAC Uzbekistan 4 ECONOMIES Singapore MNA Costa Rica Armenia Turkey index 3 LAGGARDS China 2 India SA AFR 1 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 index (1995) Source: KAM (http://www.worldbank.org/kam). Figure 6.7 Armenia's Scorecard on Education Armenia (most recent) adult literacy (% age 15 and above) (38.50) 10 public spending on 5 secondary enrollment education as % of (73.28) GDP (2.90) 0 life expectancy at tertiary enrollment birth, years (74.10) (20.16) primary pupil teacher ratio, pupils per teacher (18.50) Source: KAM (www.worldbank.org/kam). 126 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth gap in education spending between the ECA regional average (4.6 percent of GDP) and Armenia is particularly alarming. Based on the KAM variables that define the innovation pillar, which in the mid-1990s was the strongest pillar of the country, Armenia lost significant ground relative to the world, and its performance currently falls below the ECA regional average (Figure 6.8). It is evident that Armenia lost a significant part of its stock of researchers (brain-drain) in the diaspora, while the number of scientific and technical publica- tions has declined over the years. Patent activity is minimal and has remained rather stagnant throughout the years. Although close behind Costa Rica and Chile, Armenia lags behind all selected comparators. In Figure 6.9, basic KAM indicators using the most recent available data are presented describing the performance of Armenia in the inno- vation pillar. One of the weakest indicators for Armenia is spending on R&D (0.2 percent of GDP) whereas the average for the lower-middle- income group is close to 0.9 percent (Figure 6.9). For the ICT pillar, in the variables that describe the availability and penetration ratios of these technologies, Armenia scores dramati- cally below the world and the ECA regional average, indicating the country's weakness in keeping up with regional and global technol- ogy penetration and usage trends (Figure 6.10). ICT is the country's weakest pillar. In absolute terms, however, some improvements in Figure 6.8 Innovation: Armenia and the World 10 United States 9 G-7 LEVEL Israel Singapore G7 Rep. of Korea W. Europe 8 Oceania Slovenia Ireland Hungary Russian Federation 7 ENTRY LEVEL Czech Rep. Estonia Slovak Rep. Argentina Belarus recent) 6 Latvia ECA Ukraine Romania Poland 5 COPING Mexico Armenia ECONOMIES Georgia Turkey EAP Chile (most China Costa Rica 4 Kazakhstan MNA India Uzbekistan index 3 LAGGARDS LAC AFR 2 SA 1 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 index (1995) Source: KAM (http://www.worldbank.org/kam). Knowledge and Innovation 127 Figure 6.9 Armenia's Scorecard in Innovation Armenia (most recent) gross foreign direct investment as % of GDP (3.70) high-tech exports as % of 10 science & engineering enrollment ratio manufactured exports (4.00) (% of tertiary level students) (29.00) patent applications granted by the 5 researchers in R&D (4,971.00) USPTO/mil. pop. (0.32) 0 patent applications granted researchers in R&D/ by the USPTO (1.00) mil. pop. (1,603.55) scientific and technical journal total expenditure for R&D articles/mil. pop. (37.36) as % of GNP (0.18) scientific and technical manufacturing trade as % journal articles (142.00) of GDP (30.68) Source: KAM (www.worldbank.org/kam). Figure 6.10 ICT: Armenia and the World 10 Rep. of Korea Singapore 9 G-7 LEVEL Slovenia G7 Israel 8 Slovak Rep. Estonia Ireland United 7 Chile ENTRY LEVEL Latvia Czech Rep. States Hungary Oceania Argentina Costa Rica W. Europe recent) 6 EAP Poland COPING Belarus Romania Turkey 5 ECONOMIES MNA Russian Federation (most Mexico China LAC 4 ECA Georgia Ukraine index 3 LAGGARDS Armenia Uzbekistan Kazakhstan 2 AFR India SA 1 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 index (1995) Source: KAM (www.worldbank.org/kam). Internet usage and computer penetration ratios were achieved, but the volume of these improvements was much less significant than those occurring globally. In Armenia the current levels of Internet users per 10,000 people and computers available per 1,000 people are among the lowest in the region and globally. The availability of telephones and 128 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 6.11 Armenia's Scorecard in ICT Variables Armenia (most recent) telephones per 1,000 (mainlines & mobiles) (151.50) 10 Internet users per 10,000 (184.12) main telephone lines per 1,000 (139.80) 5 Internet hosts per 10,000 (7.50) mobile phones 1,000 (11.70) 0 daily newspapers per 1,000 (5.00) computers per 1,000 (9.20) radios per 1,000 (225.00) TV sets per 1,000 (230.00) Source: KAM (http://www.worldbank.org/kam). mobile phones per 1,000 people is also very limited--an additional element indicating the profound weaknesses and state of emergency in the telecommunications infrastructure of the country. The gap in performance between Armenia and its selected comparators is tre- mendous and is apparently widening. Armenia's lack of growth is paradoxical. There is a high potential of knowledge utilization that shows tantalizing promise (for example, in software and certain enterprises of heavy industry) yet remains largely untapped. Figure 6.11 shows Armenia's performance relative to the world in ICT variables. POLICIES TO STRENGTHEN KNOWLEDGE-BASED COMPETITIVENESS A pragmatic agenda for change will entail focusing on bottom-up entry points (immediate policy agenda), then scaling them up to assure coordination and concerted action (medium-term policy agenda), and then moving to major reforms (longer-run policy agenda). Finland, Ireland, and the Republic of Korea are the best-known, best-practice exemplars of concerted action; they have engineered successful transitions to knowledge-based economies. In all of these cases, national economic crises compelled diverse actors to define and implement a new agenda through explicit or implicit national agreements on goals and mechanisms to move forward. The crises also prompted policy makers and private sector leaders to lengthen Knowledge and Innovation 129 the time horizon of the policies adopted. Thus, Nokia--Finland's first mover toward an innovation-based economy--dramatically increased R&D investments. Finland responded by increasing public R&D and transforming the innovation system to fit business needs. Members of Parliament took courses and went on study tours demonstrating the need for the new agenda. National public innovation organizations played a crucial role by transforming technology into businesses and assuring a critical mass of demonstration cases. Ireland also exemplifies a successful combination of top-down and bottom-up policies. It made an investment in education and R&D infrastructure in the 1980s, followed by drastic policy changes begin- ning in 1987. To complement its top-down policies, Ireland instituted pragmatic bottom-up programs, including regional partnerships to mitigate high unemployment and a program to expand national- supplier linkages from FDI. Korea's powerful and shared national vision--from which impetus a private sector champion emerged-- was followed by effective government coordination (see Box 6.1). Three lessons from the discussion above are relevant for Armenia. First, simple institutional recipes do not exist for concerted action. Armenia will need to devise its own recipe for a KE. Given its great regional diversity, Armenia's regional and state-level policy initiatives would be a key entry point for a knowledge-based economy. Armenia has already advanced somewhat in that direction. Second, the experiences of Korea and Finland indicate that even when major crises call for urgent economic transitions, countries must "prepare the bases." This essential preparatory stage is seen in the ini- tial Vision Korea Report. It is seen in Finland's major effort to facilitate and accelerate business R&D. Third, although major reform efforts from the top are vital, they may not provide the all-important impetus for transformation. Con- certed effort must evolve. Bottom-up experiments in Armenia, some of which are already under way, must mature. These transitional stages then proceed to concerted efforts (the Korean knowledge strategy is one example). Drawing on a diversity of best practices, we suggest that Armenia construct and implement a strategy to move toward knowledge-based competitiveness in three stages: Immediate agenda (2007­08): Begin massive awareness-building and initiate pilot/demonstration projects. Medium-term agenda (2008­10): Create a springboard for major reforms by assuring major improvements in the investment cli- mate, strengthening stakeholders for reforms, and proceeding with a private sector-led shared vision "Armenia 2025." 130 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Box 6.1 Korea's Transition to a KE: Bottom-up Initiative Leads to Government Action In 1998, Korea officially launched a national strategy to move to a knowl- edge-based economy in the wake of a financial crisis. The initial impe- tus came from the private sector--the Maeil Business Newspaper--which concluded in 1996, even before the crisis, that there was an urgent need for a more coherent vision of the future of the Korean economy. This newspaper launched the "Vision Korea Project" as a national campaign in February of 1997, and developed the first Vision Korea Report. Eventually, the government--the Ministry of Finance and Econ- omy--became the main champion of the KE policy agenda. The Korean Development Institute was a so-called system integrator and coordi- nated the work of a dozen think tanks. A joint World Bank and OECD report provided a framework, outlining concrete steps for reforms in the various policy domains. Progress was monitored closely. This was a crucial step in identifying and addressing any inertia or resistance, as for example, with educa- tion. Korea's knowledge strategy of April 2000 evolved into a three- year action plan for five main areas: information infrastructure, human resources, knowledge-based industry, science and technology, and the elimination of the digital divide. To implement the action plan, Korea established five working groups involving 19 ministries and 17 research institutes, with the Ministry of Finance and Economy coordinating the implementation. Every quarter, each ministry submits a self-monitoring report to the Ministry of Finance and Economy, which puts out an inte- grated report detailing progress. The midterm results and adjustments to the plan are sent to the executive director of the National Economic Advisory Council, which reports on the progress of the implementa- tion and gives an appraisal of the three-year action plan to its advisory members. Source: Author's own elaboration. Long-term agenda (2008 onward): Enact major reforms that would transform and create world-class innovation capacity, education systems, and ICT infrastructure (Table 6.2). Table 6.2 outlines a medium-term agenda (establishing a spring- board for the KE) and a longer-term agenda (creating a world-class KE infrastructure). We view the decade from 1995 to 2003 as a stage of building foundations. Armenia's accession to the WTO in 2003 was an important event signaling that Armenia had a certain macroeconomic and socioeconomic stability and had created the basic institutional Table 6.2 Sequencing of the Armenia KE Policy Agenda Stages of economic reform Drivers Examples of and growth Major constraints of growth Thrust of government policy policy initiatives Benchmarks Building Sustainability of Remittances Assuring macro and social Infrastructure Signaling event: foundations macroeconomic and other stability projects Accession to WTO (2003) 1995­2003 stability and transfers Some initiatives to improve Creation of business Other indicators: Investment share market reforms from abroad innovation climate council in GDP, private investment in GDP Infrastructure (reasonably high) and services Level of knowledge-based exports (very low) Business share in innovation (practically nil) Establishing a Dearth of role Increasing Assuring a critical mass of Competitive grant Signaling events: springboard models and share of stakeholders for reforms schemes to enhance A multinational establishes for KE, stakeholders for merchandise through a two pronged business innovation knowledge-intensive operations in 2005­8 reforms (self- exports; strategy: Armenia Knowledge Creation of made start-up growing role Top-down: dramatic innovation council Elimination of ArmenTel monopoly and spin-off of services reduction of administrative entrepreneurs) Some skilled emigrants come barriers to growth back and become successful and Bottom-up: facilitation entrepreneurs of private sector-driven Rising share of business R&D and Innovation "centers of excellence" merchandise exports Major Human capital Skill-intensive Major overhaul Wide-scale Significant return migration of reforms: constraint: exports of education, ICT introduction of highly skilled creating inadequate stock infrastructure, and income-contingent Robust Robust knowledge-intensive world- and flow of innovation systems scheme to finance internal clusters are established 131 class KE technical skills private higher demand infrastructure, education Inadequate ICT 2008­15 infrastructure Source: Elaboration by the author. 132 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth foundations for a market economy. We argue that the time has come for a new stage of policy: assuring a critical mass of stakeholders for reforms. That, in turn, would imply a two-pronged strategy: a top-down approach: a dramatic reduction of the administrative barriers to growth and a dramatic improvement in the invest- ment climate a bottom-up approach: the facilitation of private sector-driven "centers of excellence" in innovation, enterprise upgrading, edu- cation, and ICT. This policy stage should be characterized by more strategic and proactive government policies to improve innovation, the education systems, and the ICT infrastructure. By proactive, we do not mean a sectoral industrial policy of "picking winners." Rather, the focus should be on functional interventions that are open to all eligible stakeholders and that are designed to accelerate existing policy trends, rather than creating policies from scratch. Examples of policy initia- tives in this vein include competitive grant schemes to enhance busi- ness innovation (more on this is given below) and the creation of an innovation council to assure linkages among higher education, R&D organizations, and the enterprise sector. Benchmarks and signaling events of the completion of this stage of reform could be as diverse as the following: A multinational establishes knowledge-intensive operations in Armenia. The ArmenTel monopoly is eliminated. Some skilled emigrants come back to Armenia and become suc- cessful entrepreneurs. This is a rising share of business R&D in the overall R&D budget and of merchandise exports in overall exports. The achievement of these benchmarks would signal the formation of a critical mass of stakeholders that would allow Armenia to engage in major and quite painful reforms in innovation, in the enterprise upgrading system, and in ICT infrastructure. We will not discuss in detail the long-run agenda for change. What follows focuses on the "what" and "how" of the medium-term agenda (establishing a spring- board for a KE). To summarize, the sequencing of the transition to a knowledge- based economy in Armenia can be conceptualized as focusing on bottom-up entry points (the immediate policy agenda), then scaling them up to ensure coordination and concerted action (the medium- Knowledge and Innovation 133 Figure 6.12 Virtuous Circle of Growth and Reforms top down momentum Intermediate agenda Medium-term agenda Longer-term agenda demonstration projects critical mass structural reform sense of urgency of changes bottom up momentum Source: World Bank staff. term policy agenda), and then moving to major reforms (the longer-run policy agenda). The art and craft of policy making is about sequencing the various horizons of a policy agenda in a virtuous circle of growth and reforms. A pragmatic agenda to get around the many institutional rigidities that Armenia faces includes the following steps: (i) create the momentum for change by fostering stakeholder awareness; (ii) attain consensus on tackling some of the key obstacles at the national level (to enhance the demand for an institutional change); and (iii) to move ahead with concrete, manageable, bottom-up approaches that can serve as demonstration projects to move the larger agenda (Figure 6.12). MEDIUM-TERM AGENDA: ALLEVIATION OF CRITICAL CONSTRAINTS The arguments about the sequencing of reforms discussed in the pre- vious section have been confirmed by experienced policy observers. For example, Dani Rodrik's paper (2004) argues that the key to growth is not getting all or most institutions right at once, but rather overcom- ing the chief bottleneck to raising growth by, say, 2 percentage points a year, and using the proceeds of this improvement to overcome the next bottleneck--and so on. There is a kind of `bootstrapping reform' strategy which provides useful insight into the "how to" of reforms. 134 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth As is evident from the analysis in Chapter 1, two major immediate constraints from the perspective of knowledge-based competitiveness are the following: an extremely weak and fragmented innovation system, includ- ing lack of linkages among the productive sector, the universi- ties, and the research institutes the low quality and high prices of ITC infrastructure From a longer-term perspective, human capital (particularly techni- cal and managerial skills) is a major constraint. Table 6.3 summarizes the critical constraints from the perspective of the KE, and also the relevant medium-term policy agenda (to be discussed below) for alleviating the constraints. INNOVATION SYSTEM: MAKING INNOVATION RELEVANT FOR BUSINESS An innovation system consists of a network of organizations, rules, and procedures that affects how a country acquires, creates, dissemi- nates, and uses knowledge. Key organizations for the creation of knowledge include universities, public and private research centers, and policy think tanks. Private firms are at the center of the innova- tion system. If the private sector has little demand for knowledge, the innovation system cannot be effective. Effective linkages between R&D and industry linkages are vital to transform knowledge into wealth. Therefore, networking and interactions among the different organiza- tions, firms, and individuals are critically important. The intensity of these networks, as well as the incentives for acquiring, creating, and sharing knowledge, are influenced by the economic incentive regime in general. The innovation system framework, as it has been applied to a vari- ety of studies of OECD countries, relies too much on innovation in the sense of the development of radical or incrementally new knowledge. Traditional measurements for an innovation system include indicators of expenditure on R&D, activity in high-technology sectors (biotech- nology, ICT), patenting activity (number, intensity), and researchers per 10,000 population. These indicators proxy the ability to generate new knowledge. However, they are not particularly helpful in under- standing how a traditional, low-tech manufacturing firm can learn to upgrade its capabilities to compete in a more knowledge-based econ- omy. Rather, these indicators are very often just the top of a pyramid (see Figure 6.13), the bulk of which comprises firms, mostly SMEs, for Table 6.3 Specific Policy Initiatives as Entry Points to Address Systemic Constraints Relevant best practices System Main objectives Specific initiatives (discussed in Chapter 3) Innovation system Enhance linkages among Competitive grant scheme to U.K. Teaching Company Scheme productive sector, universities, promote business R&D and and science organizations training Seed support to venture capital fund Education system Reform curriculum of basic, Technology/design facility on Competence center models secondary, and higher education the basis of major university (in design stage in Estonia) Distant education project Knowledge collaboration with diaspora Establish National Innovation Council to bring together and education, R&D organizations, and industry Innovation ICT infrastructure Improve quality of ICT services Institutional strengthening of Liberalization policies in ICT and reduce their costs public utility regulator infrastructure in some Central European countries Source: Elaboration by the author. 135 136 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Figure 6.13 The Pyramid of Learning Capabilities of Firms Research and technology development: advanced firms Very rarely present, mostly large firms R&D Design and engineering: technologically competent firms technology Capabilities rarely present in SMEs upgrading reverse engineering Technician and craft skills and capabilities: minimal technology firms In SMEs, strong skills sometimes present, technology acquisition though key skills often absent or weak assimilation Basic operating skills and capabilities: survival-oriented enterprises technology use In SMEs, often weak, with and operation limited and irregular upgrading Source: Adapted from Intarakumnerd et al. 2002. which the major issue is the acquisition of basic skills in marketing, design, engineering, and other operational areas rather than technol- ogy upgrading and R&D. Because of this, the traditional innovation system approach might be applicable to a very limited subset of the economy, such as firms in the export-oriented sectors. It might also be useful for setting long- term goals and objectives, in terms of creating the elements missing in the traditional approach. Table 6.4 flags a range of policy interven- tions--which should be considered as a menu of options, not all of them immediately relevant for Armenia. Armenian policy has a narrow view of technological development, which is equated with R&D. The underlying model of technology development describes firms only as the demand side, relative to the supply side that is provided in R&D institutes and universities. Policy considers that the key to reducing the technology gap is not in the technology activities of enterprises themselves but through the expansion of intermediary institutions such as technology centers Table 6.4 Matching Policies to Capabilities: A Range of Instruments to Support Innovation Type of enterprise Policy objectives Instruments and interventions Survival- To build basic competitive business advisory and support services--SME and micro-enterprise oriented capabilities by fostering support agencies enterprises awareness of scope and benefits facilitation of access to finance (including micro-finance) of innovation management and skills development Minimum To foster competitiveness by support for business development, diversifying customer base technology introducing basic innovation product diversification and quality improvement firms skills and encouraging adoption management and skills development and application of new ideas Internet-based information services technology awareness and marketing support for technology adoption and adaptation projects cluster-based approaches to stimulating innovation Technologically To support market development business development, exports market support competent and entry into global value Internet-based information services enterprises chains by fostering strategic technology transfer support Knowledge alliances and certain in-house incubators and technology parks innovation capabilities linkages with academic researchers laboratory services and metrology services consultancy and technical assistance support, such as on and commercialization, intellectual property rights, licensing, patenting supplier development and linkage promotion programs Innovation Advanced To facilitate moving up global support for participation in international R&D networks (such as the enterprises value chains by upgrading in- EU 6th Framework Program) house innovation capabilities technology and other innovation-based spin-offs and strategic alliances university-industry collaboration support for commercialization Diffuse experience of innovation 137 development of vibrant venture capital industry leaders as role models for the encourage participation of national innovation leaders in national rest of the economy advisory bodies, technology foresight, and cluster processes Source: Elaboration by the author. 138 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth and science and technology (S&T) parks. The problem of technology development is reduced to the issue of the commercialization of R&D results. Treating industry only as demand side is quite misleading because industrial firms not only generate the demand for industrial technol- ogy but they account for a very large part of the supply side as well. In fact, most of the technology-generating capabilities are located in the industry (that is, in firms themselves, not in extramural organiza- tions such as S&T parks and R&D institutes). Business enterprises fund between 50 and 60 percent of the general expenditures on research and development (GERD) in North America, the EU, and the Nordic countries, and they perform between 60 and 70 percent of the GERD. Thus, the issue for Armenia is how to increase R&D in the business sector, not outside of it. In addition, using only R&D can be misleading as a large contribution to technology development is made by types of technical change that do not involve formally organized R&D at all. Innovation surveys from the EU and Central European economies show that the key source of important information for innovation comes from enterprises themselves or from partners in value chains (suppliers, buyers). Infrastructure institutions are actually marginal as a direct source of information for innovation. The importance of non- R&D technology development suggests that it is inappropriate to nar- row down innovation policy to just R&D policy and to bridging insti- tutions. In fact, infrastructure institutions are much more important as sources of knowledge and skills carried by people who move among universities, R&D institutes, and firms, or between firms. Information services, training, and standard services as well as problem solving and R&D in all forms of people-centered types of output are the key function of extramural technology institutes. One of the most impor- tant roles played by R&D in public technology institutes is to contrib- ute flows of people into the technological activities of industry. In Armenia, as in many Eastern European and CIS countries, there seems to be a dearth of measures that stimulate firms to undertake their own technology development. Policy is focused much more on meas- ures that support institutions in undertaking S&T activities on behalf of industrial firms. Within the innovation policy, there are no policy measures that support and facilitate actions by firms themselves. In a nutshell, Armenia should avoid an exclusive focus on support- ing technology institutions in a supply-driven approach, with support to extramural institutions rather than to firms. The balance should be corrected between a focus, on the one hand, on directly strengthening the technology development capabilities and activities of firms, and on the other hand, building and strengthening various kinds of tech- Knowledge and Innovation 139 nology development and transfer institutions. Currently, there is not a system that would support firms to advance from technology use and maintenance to technology development and creation. Mechanisms to support technology transfer institutions (such as S&T parks) are an important component of the policy system. However, a major emphasis in policy development should be on mechanisms that assist and empower firms to make their own investments into technology absorption and development. Within that firm-centered approach to policy, increasing emphasis has to be given to stimulating and facilitating various forms of collective activity involving groups of firms. These groups may be established industry associations, or less formally structured groups organized around value chains, or clusters of firms in related industries. Among instruments for financing innovation in Armenia, grant- based mechanisms are notably absent. These mechanisms commonly provide grants to firms which undertake particular kinds of techno- logical activity (such as R&D, design, technological or managerial training, engagement of consultants, employment of qualified scien- tists and engineers, and many others). In most cases, the grants cover a defined proportion of the costs of the specific activity. ICT INFRASTRUCTURE: ASSURING ENTRY OF NEW SERVICE PROVIDERS The beginning of this chapter documents a very low level of develop- ment for ICT infrastructure. Figure 6.1 shows that Armenia performs just below the average for economies of the FSU, which is hardly satisfactory given Armenia's peculiar geographical position and aspi- rations to develop a competitive ICT cluster.5 This is mainly attribut- able to one single problem: the ArmenTel monopoly, which has been addressed in earlier chapters. FORMATION OF HUMAN CAPITAL: ENHANCING EDUCATION­INDUSTRY LINKAGES Many problems in the education sector, especially in the school sys- tem, are well understood and are being addressed through existing and planned reforms. This section will focus in more detail on the education­industry linkages. Chronic underspending. Armenian public spending on education is 2.8 percent of GDP, well below the OECD average of 5 percent and the 140 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth rate in other transition economies. Private spending is also low (less than 0.5 percent) as is education as a proportion of public spending (11 percent). Inefficiency. A dramatic fall in the school-age population since inde- pendence, plus only modest reductions in staffing levels, has resulted in staffing ratios which are low in international terms and, more important, unsustainable in the Armenian context. For example, there are only about 11 pupils for every full-time equivalent teacher. The Medium-Term Expenditure Framework (MTEF) proposes increasing these overall ratios to one teacher for every 16 students. Lack of relevance. There has been little reform of the curriculum, the assessment methods, or the teacher training since independence. The main challenge is the transition from a teacher-centered to a stu- dent-centered learning approach. Reforms supported under the EQ&R project will be a major step toward meeting this challenge. Equity. Enrollment in basic education continues to fall, and is now below 85 percent. Low levels of public spending have resulted in increasing levels of informal payments in "free" basic education. In higher education, expansion has been mainly in private institutions and fee-paying places at public institutions. While this has increased access--though still for only 16 percent of the cohort--public spend- ing overwhelmingly favors the rich, since state scholarships are given mainly to those who score highest on the entrance examination. Governance and management. One of the biggest and most difficult challenges Armenia faces is to move away from the top-down system of management, in which the Ministry of Education passes directives that are then uniformly applied to all institutions and in which the flow of information is one way and is used to control rather than empower local actors. Tertiary education. A major stakeholder conference was held in November 2002, organized during the preparation of SAC V. The equity concerns have been mentioned above. The lack of quality assurance mechanisms (accreditation, inspec- tion, and so forth) means that students and other stakeholders cannot choose better institutions and courses, and good-quality private insti- tutions are undermined by a small number of fly-by-night operators. Investment is low or nonexistent, resulting in poor quality, outdated teaching environments, and an almost complete absence of interna- tional level research. Knowledge and Innovation 141 EDUCATION­INDUSTRY LINKAGES Historically, Armenia has had a highly educated population, and educational attainment figures have remained remarkably high since independence despite the low levels of spending. However, the skills and knowledge that individuals have acquired have become increas- ingly obsolete in the labor market. Much of the education would have been fact-based information learned by rote; and, even if the educa- tion were more relevant to the labor market, high levels of unem- ployment, underemployment, and informal employment would have eroded skills and knowledge. Older adults, though they are more likely to be employed, would also have worked for longer periods in state-owned, static industries. The story of a private company Lycos illustrates the main issues and options for enhancing education industry linkages. Lycos is a fully owned subsidiary of the German-based Lycos Europe. Lycos Armenia is integrated into Lycos Europe's network of competence centers in Gutersloh, Copenhagen, Hamburg, Munich, Paris, and Stockholm for the development of its core services: search, communications, commu- nities, and shopping. Lycos Armenia is in the software development business (Web posting, e-mail, chat room communities, e-commerce) and provides technical support to the Lycos Europe portal. Impor- tantly, the company works closely with two universities in Yerevan and provides grant funding of about US$500,000 for a two-year bach- elor's degree program in Internet computing designed primarily by Lycos staff. Sixty to 70 percent of the lectures are also given by Lycos staff. Throughout the program internships are also offered in the Lycos offices in Armenia and elsewhere in Europe. The top graduates of the program are usually hired by the company. The fact that a private company establishes its own training pro- grams and, more important, does this in collaboration with major Armenian universities, is promising. This indication of the effective demand of private sector and private sector initiative is a foundation on which a coherent private-sector-led system of lifelong learning can be built. The following options for expanding and accelerating the existing education-industry linkages could be considered: Distance learning as a pilot project (Box 6.2). The advantage of this potential distance learning project is that it would bring together the ICT and education dimensions. As Box 6.2 out- lines, the Armenian diaspora can become involved in a new and productive way. In addition, as worldwide experience of distance learning indicates, these projects are easily scaled up and expanded when successful. 142 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth Box 6.2 Distance Learning as a Potential Pilot Project to Enhance Education­Industry Linkages Distance learning could be a low-cost opportunity for Armenia to accel- erate the transfer of global knowledge and drastically upgrade the qual- ity of teaching in its universities. For a landlocked, remotely located country, the modern technology could provide the following group of primary benefits: Access to high-caliber professors and lecturers, who would initially demonstrate how the core modern curricula should be delivered to students and therefore would greatly contribute to the training and retraining of trainers (local professors). The availability of various professional talent in the diaspora and the existence of an established professional diaspora network would simplify the future mobilization of potential participants and could further reduce project costs (many diaspora members may be ready to supply such lecturing on a pro bono basis). Recent examples from Turkey and Thailand confirm the feasibility of such an approach. Online access to modern experimental facilities and academic libraries. Economies of scale, including low-cost dissemination/sharing of popular courses among various local universities and training centers. As with many other collective diaspora initiatives, the distance learn- ing project, especially in the area of engineering, is likely to lead rather quickly to the second generation of (indirect) benefits. As experience from other countries suggests, professionals participating in advanced educational projects abroad tend to be eager to launch new business ventures with their local partners and frequently with their former stu- dents. On the parallel track, collective efforts of diaspora activists in the area of university education has the potential to evolve gradually toward more business-oriented projects, undertaken basically by the same group of initial diaspora sponsors, such as those associated with university business incubators. Source: Elaboration by the author. Establishment of a Skills Development Fund to encourage enter- prise sector training, subject, of course, to a thorough cost-benefit and fiscal priority assessment. Knowledge and Innovation 143 SUMMARY AND KEY RECOMMENDATIONS Armenia enjoys various advantages that should lead to future growth that is based on innovation and the skilled use of knowledge-inten- sive assets: it has a core of well-educated and motivated labor, the incentive regime is in place, and there are international linkages. But local entrepreneurship has been weak, and ICT is handicapped by high telecommunications costs and low R&D spending. In addition to the reform in competition discussed earlier, the government could facilitate private sector-driven centers of excellence in innovation and enterprise upgrading. The government could also pursue reforms in education, infrastructure, telecommunications, and aviation to take explicit account of the need to support ICT and innovation. business advisory and support services--SME and micro- enterprise support agencies facilitation of access to finance (including micro-finance) management and skills development Internet-based information services support for technology adoption and adaptation projects cluster-based approaches to stimulating innovation support for participation in international R&D networks (for example, the EU 6th Framework Program) encouragement of participation of national innovation leaders in national advisory bodies, technology foresight, and cluster processes NOTES 1. In figures like the one presented in Figure 6.1 the reader should note the following points. On the horizontal axis the 1995 KEI scores are plotted. On the vertical axis the KEI scores for the most recent year are plotted. The more advanced KE performers plot in the northeast quadrant of the graph, while the weaker ones plot in the southwest quadrant of the graph. Both the position along the 45-degree line and whether a country plots above or below the line are significant. The countries or regions that are plotted below the line indicate a regression in their performance relative to where they were in 1995. The countries or regions that are marked above the line signify an improve- ment in their position in the latest period compared to their position in 1995. Those countries that are plotted on the line have maintained their relative position over the two periods. Each country's performance as depicted in the figure is relative to the performance of the total country sample included in the KAM (121 countries). 144 Part I: Policies to Sustain Economic Growth 2. This reflects 2003 data from the Heritage Foundation. Nevertheless, the Heritage Foundation states the following in 2004 Index of Economic Freedom: "In 2001, according to the World Bank, Armenia's weighted average tariff rate was 2.5 percent, up from the 1.9 percent reported in the 2003 Index of Economic Freedom by the Heritage Foundation." The U.S. State Department reports that most imports are free of prohibitions, quotas, or licensing, but businesses complain about "cumbersome procedures [and] bribes solicited by customs officials." Based on new evidence of customs corruption, Armenia's trade policy score is 1 point worse in this year (2004). 3. In this analysis 15 FSU countries are ranked by the following FDI driv- ing elements: liberalization and deregulation of business activities, stability and predictability of the legal environment, corporate and public governance, liberalization of foreign trade and international capital movements, financial sector development, corruption level, political risk, country promotion and image, and targeted investment initiatives. 4. Based on statistical information management and analysis (SIMA) data for the year 2000, Armenia is performing better in tertiary enrollment rates than Albania, Tajikistan, and Turkey. 5. This section relies on the Public-Private Infrastructure Advisory Facility (PPIAF) presentation, "Sector Overview and Review of International Experi- ence, Identification of Bottlenecks and Recommended Roadmap to Develop a Rural Telecommunications Strategy in Armenia" (PPIAF 2004). Part II: Detailed Analysis Chapter 7 Growth Analysis from the Perspective of Employment Generation and Poverty Reduction SUBSECTORAL GROWTH, INVESTMENTS, AND EXPORTS Sectoral Growth This chapter1 discusses the economic transformation that is associ- ated with job creation outside of subsistence agriculture and financial deepening--processes that took place in new EU member countries. The transformation has been slow in Armenia, but has started to pick up recently. Agriculture's contribution to GDP in Armenia continues to be high at 25­30 percent and its contribution to employment is more than 45 percent, well above the levels of 4.5 percent and 5 per- cent in new EU member states. Agriculture is concentrated in low value-added products (dairy, meats, and grains). The services sector, which is concentrated in public administration and trade, generates 35­37 percent of GDP in Armenia, compared to more than 60 percent in new EU member countries (Figure 7.1). Growth was led by construction and industry (including manufac- turing), mainly through power production, food processing, and bev- erages, and in part by services, through trade and catering (but with services growth being notably slower than in other fast-growing transi- tion economies) and mirrored export and investment performance. Sectoral contributions to GDP have changed dramatically over the past decade. The most striking feature has been the growth of the services sector and construction at the expense of industry (Table 7.1). Changes in relative prices had a dramatic impact on agriculture (that is, a decline in agriculture terms of trade since the 1998 Rus- sian crisis). Real agricultural prices have been declining until recently, while real prices in services (led by the utility price adjustment) and 147 148 Part II: Detailed Analysis Figure 7.1 Armenia and the Slovak Republic, Employment by Sectors, 1994­2004 100 80 60 cent per 40 20 0 1994 2003 1994 2003 Armenia Slovak Republic employment in agriculture employment in industry employment in services Source: WDI. Table 7.1 Sources of GDP Growth in Armenia, by Sector Contribution to GDP Sector Share in GDP (percent) US$ million Agriculture 24.8 531.3 Construction 13.9 298.6 Diamonds 1.9 40.7 Dwellings 3.2 68.2 Industry 7.0 151.1 Manufacturing 11.9 254.8 Services 37.3 800.8 Total 100.0 2,145.5 Source: SAM (Chapter 8 of this book). Growth Analysis 149 industrial prices have been increasing consistently. Agriculture, which grew at a slower pace than the rest of the economy during the 1990s, has absorbed a surplus of (unskilled) labor released in the process of economic transformation. The fastest growing sector in the econ- omy--construction--has made a significant contribution to job crea- tion: the share of the labor force employed in construction has risen from 4 to 9 percent over the past five years. Job creation in industry in recent years was mostly concentrated in new private enterprises. Out of 26,500 jobs created in industry during 1999­2003, 22,000 were established in newly created private enterprises. Investments The sectoral composition of investments shaped the sectoral growth pattern. Figure 7.2 presents the structure of investments by sectors with housing representing about 30 percent of total investments dur- ing 1999­2003. Infrastructure has also attracted a considerable share of Figure 7.2 Sectoral Shares in GDP and Investments (average) 35 30 25 20 cent per 15 10 5 0 industry agriculture transport trade housing other sector share in investments 1999­2003 share in GDP 1999­2004 Source: WDI. 150 Part II: Detailed Analysis investment. Several profitable and competitive traditional sectors have attracted private investment during the process of economic transfor- mation (for example, gem cutting, brandy making, electric motors, hotels, high-technology manufacturing, and software services). A significant source of investment financing has been foreign direct investment (FDI). The major portion of FDI, both in infrastructure (tel- ecommunications through the privatization of the national telecom- munications company, ArmenTel) and in industry (privatization of the gas distribution network), was the direct result of large-scale privati- zation. Two Russian companies, including Gasprom and the energy corporation Itera, and the Greek OTE, are among the main investors in the country. The third largest foreign investor is Canada, with about 11 percent of the total investment, followed by the United States with 10 percent of the total cumulative investment. France, Luxembourg, the United Kingdom, Cyprus, Italy, Belgium, and Switzerland are other large investors in the country. FDI in the agro-processing sector, especially in beverages, has in several cases stimulated technology transfer and changes in the pro- duction pattern. One of the largest privatization deals in this sector involved the sale of the Yerevan Brandy Factory (YBF). The privati- zation of YBF generated strong linkages between farmers and buyers of agricultural produce. But this example is one of very few and an indication of the barriers that deter stronger private investment, both domestic and foreign, to the sectors with high export and growth, high value-added activities, and therefore high profit potential. Exports Further analysis of the investment structure is limited by the lack of detailed and consistent data on a micro level. The analysis of export performance gives a good indication of the sectors that have managed to attract investments. Armenia's exports have experienced impressive growth since the mid-1990s. In real terms, exports have grown by 13 percent per year since 1995. The share of exports in GDP has steadily grown and in 2003 the share of exports in GDP was 32 percent. Since 1995, Armenia has experienced impressive growth in its volume of trade--a trend only temporarily dampened by the Russia crisis. Table 7.2 shows the sources and sectoral distribution of exports in Armenia as given in 2002. The composition of exports has registered some encouraging devel- opments, with exports diversifying toward high value-added man- ufacturing goods and services. However, exports still remain quite concentrated, with precious stones and metals accounting for more Growth Analysis 151 Table 7.2 Sources of Exports in Armenia, 2002, by Sector Share in total exports Contribution to exports Sector (percent) (US$ million) Diamonds 37.0 258.0 Other 31.2 217.6 Heavy metals & machinery 14.4 100.4 Manufacturing 13.9 97.1 Electricity supply and dist. 1.9 13.4 Agriculture 1.6 11.5 Total 100.0 698.0 Source: SAM, 2002 (Chapter 8 of this book). than 40 percent of total exports. Uncut gems are imported into the country, are cut and sometimes mounted as finished jewelry, and then re-exported to Europe or the United States. Other large exports are food products and machine products. Armenia also demonstrates a high share of services exports. However, a closer look at the composi- tion shows that service exports are sensitive to transportation costs. Armenia's exports tend to be concentrated in the sectors with low or no transport costs (cut diamonds, services, electricity). The analysis highlights the following features of Armenian trade: The integration of Armenia into world trade remains limited and has not seen major improvements outside of the diamond trade. Armenian exports have become increasingly concentrated, even compared to other countries with a large share of mineral exports, which makes the exports more volatile and vulnerable to changes in external conditions, such as input arrangements and prices. Over the past decade the number of goods in which Armenia has demonstrated a revealed comparative advantage (RCA) has not expanded significantly (Table 7.3). Armenia also demonstrates a high share of services exports. However, a closer look at the composition shows that service exports are sensitive to transportation costs. Armenia's exports tend to concentrate in sectors with low or no transport costs (cut diamonds, services, electricity). Trade in services may have increased substantially, but trade data will not capture this, owing to transfer pricing by firms and the general bias toward "goods" trade by statistics departments (Figure 7.3). 152 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 7.3 Armenia: Revealed Comparative Advantage, 2003 Revealed comparative advantage 2003 Diamonds, not industrial, not set 75.7 Beverages 16.1 Metalliferous ores and metal scrap 12.0 Electric energy 10.1 Nonferrous metals 6.6 Nonferrous metals 1.5 Fruits and vegetables 1.1 Iron and steel 1.0 Electrical machinery, apparatus 0.1 Source: World Integrated Trade Solution (WITS). http://wits.worldbank.org. Note: The index for country i good j is RCAij = (Xij /Xit)/(Xwj /Xwt)*100 where w = world and t = total for all goods. The RCA index compares the composition of exports of a country with the composition of total world exports. An RCA index higher than 1 indicates that a country has a strong RCA in the export of the product. An RCA index lower than 1 indicates that the country has a comparative disadvantage in that product. An RCA index equal to 1 indicates that the country has neither an advantage nor a disadvantage. LINKS BETWEEN GROWTH, EMPLOYMENT, AND POVERTY Impact of Growth on Poverty A strong and almost decade-long rise in national income and, to a lesser extent, a reduction in inequality have been the two factors that have contributed to poverty reduction in Armenia. Since 1994, Arme- nia has grown at a remarkable average annual rate of over 7 percent and by 2004 its real GDP reached the pre-transition level. In addi- tion to output growth, private foreign transfers--invested mostly in construction--and remittances have played a key role in raising the national income. Both sources of growth in aggregate demand have triggered a high induced household income multiplier2 and produced strong spillover effects that have benefited multiple households. The poorest population in Armenia saw the strongest increase in consumption. Estimates based on the Armenia Integrated Living Con- ditions Survey (ILCS) indicate that Armenia saw a considerable decline in extreme poverty during 1998­2004. About 17 percent of the population, or more than half a million people, have moved out of poverty in the past five years. About 9 percent of the population, or 0.23 million people, escaped the basic food deprivation. This evidence is consistent with the evolution of inequality for the period--the Gini coefficient Figure 7.3 Matrix: Classification of Armenian Exports by Composition and Destination, 2003 SICT 6672 68 11 28 67 89 35 72 05 Export Diamonds Nonferrous Beverages Metal ores Iron & Miscellaneous Electric Electrical Fruit & metals & scrap steel manufacturing energy machinery vegetables Israel Belgium Russian Federation Germany Netherlands UAE United States United Kingdom Switzerland Georgia Iran Ukraine Gr Greece owth China Turkmenistan Analysis Thailand Canada Belarus Source: WITS database. http://wits.worldbank.org. 153 Note: SICT: Standard International Trade Classification 154 Part II: Detailed Analysis decreased from a value of 0.299 in 1998­99 to a value of 0.259 in 2004--and indicates that the growth was accompanied by a compres- sion in the overall structure of consumption distribution. Growth has been channeled to the households through multiple sources that have increased both factor and nonfactor income. A strong growth in factor income from both labor and capital was accompa- nied by a stable growth in remittances and a consistent improvement in public transfer programs. In fact, household income from all main sources rose in real terms between 1998­99 and 2004. Factor income remained a dominant source of household income for all quintiles, followed by income from remittances and public transfers. Such a mul- tiplicity of income sources has benefited various types of households and resulted in a broad-based poverty reduction in Armenia. Growth in factor income mirrored growth in output3 and was based on large productivity gains that were due to structural changes and labor shedding in the process of labor rationalization, and to a lesser extent, to a rise in employment. Survey data point to a 17 percent unemployment rate, which is an estimated 35 percent reduction in the unemployment rate estimated in 1998­99, but it is still the high- est unemployment rate registered among the transition countries. In addition, much of the work force is to be found in low-paid subsist- ence agriculture, trade, the informal economy, and temporary employ- ment. While the demand for additional formal labor grew slowly, pro- ductivity gains secured stronger earnings for current workers with stable employment arrangements, with real wages seeing a 50 percent increase between 1998­99 and 2003. The investment contribution to growth was also considerable and the share of capital value added in Armenia's GDP has increased over time. Income from capital has been growing rapidly, benefiting those who owned and/or received the assets at the outset and/or are in the process of economic transfor- mation. Armenia's recent growth has also benefited from large foreign capital transfers invested mostly in the construction sector, which is characterized by a strong income multiplier effect on employment, and therefore on household incomes. In addition to factor income, both public and private transfers have played an important role in boosting household income in Armenia. The poor rely heavily on government transfers (such as pensions, social assistance, and other transfers), with this source representing about 20 percent of household income and the third largest source of income (after labor income and remittances) in the poorest quintiles. Social protection benefits have increased in the past five years in real per capita terms. Benefits have also improved in terms of targeting the poorest, with the family poverty benefit system becoming an effective mechanism for reaching the poor. Growth Analysis 155 Box 7.1 Reconciliation of National Accounts and the Household Survey Data The National Accounts succeed in understanding Armenia's underlying production technology, trade position, and final demand structure. How- ever, the use of a "representative" household agent for total demand makes it impossible to determine whether economic growth in Arme- nia is helping to alleviate poverty. In our study we have scaled total household incomes to meet total factor endowments and total (official) transfers from abroad, from the government, and from investment. For poor households, this leads to a significant divergence from reported income from the 2002 Household Survey. The most onerous problem when using household data is to rec- oncile household consumption against household income. Several of the poorer deciles in Armenia report far lower incomes than they report expenditures. Even when government and family transfers are included, expenditure for the poorest decile in Armenia is at least 10 times as large as income. Indeed, according to the Statistical Handbook based upon the 2002 Armenian Household Survey (Table 1, p. 51), 2002 total monthly per capita income was 12,776 drams. Of this, monetary income was 9,781 drams and nonmonetary (that is, own-produced value of consump- tion) monthly income was 2,995 drams. Annual monetary income, based on the survey, is then 117,372 drams per year (12 × 9,781), or US$204.83 per year, taken at market exchange rates. This implies that average income is US$0.56 per day. However, when using the National Accounts, we find that total value added (GDP at producer prices) is US$2.145 billion. Using 3.1 million as the national population, per capita income is US$1.90, more than three times as large as income from the Household Survey. During the reconciliation, some of the differences between rural and urban incomes can be attributed entirely to the investment account. Source: SAM (Chapter 8 of this book). Remittances and other private transfers by far exceed publicly pro- vided resources in Armenia.4 They accounted for more than 10 percent of GDP during this period and boosted consumption levels, includ- ing among the poor, thereby helping to reduce poverty. An increas- ingly large number of households receive remittances reaching 50 percent of the monetary income of recipient households. Remittances have a direct effect on the recipient households' well-being as well as strong secondary multiplier effects for those who do not receive 156 Part II: Detailed Analysis remittances directly. External remittances comprise a large share of overall monthly income for households that receive them, which sug- gests that remittances have significantly improved the well-being of the poorest households and have been critical for keeping these quin- tiles out of poverty. Impact of Growth on Employment Armenia's labor force comprises about 50 percent of the total pop- ulation, which is comparable with the situation in other European countries. The situation with employment, however, is much worse in Armenia than in comparator countries. In contrast to the strong growth performance in Armenia, the evolution of aggregate employ- ment during the 1990s was negative. The labor force remains poorly utilized; the labor participation rate is low and unemployment is ram- pant (over 19 percent). The formal employment level is low and the main source of employment growth until recently was through the expansion of self-employment and low value-added agriculture and trade. High emigration has been negatively affecting the domestic supply5 of young and skilled labor, combined with slow growth on the demand side especially with slow growth in skilled jobs. Data on wages by professions suggest that the strongest increase was recorded in skilled labor, but, as mentioned above, the number of skilled job positions created was limited. The upswing has been shared by a range of professions, including unskilled and semiskilled labor. An economy's long-term growth is driven by the evolution of its underlying supply factors of production and physical and human cap- ital, and by the development of total factor productivity. In Armenia, the positive output trend has not translated into employment growth, and formal employment is currently below that reported in the early 1990s (Figure 7.4). Total factor productivity growth seems to be cap- turing most of the growth pattern, reflecting efficiency gains stimu- lated by structural changes over the mid-1990s and early 2000s. As with other transition countries, the surge in unemployment in Armenia was anticipated given the massive economic and geographic reallocation of labor during the transformation. This phenomenon, called "jobless growth," is not specific to Armenia but is typical of most transition economies, where initial growth is mostly based on large productivity gains due to structural changes and labor shedding in the process of labor rationalization and more efficient utilization of labor resources, rather than through an increased use of the labor force. In the process of a country's search for new equilibrium, the destruction of unproductive jobs is accompanied by the creation of new and more productive jobs. However, job losses usually exceed job gains, leading to a net fall in employment. Growth Analysis 157 Figure 7.4 Real Growth and Factors of Production, 1997­2004 15 1,000 800 10 600 rate 5 million growth 400 US$ 0 200 -5 0 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 year employment growth rate (adjusted) (left-hand side) real GDP growth (left-hand side) capital investment (US$) (right-hand side) Source: Armenian Department of Statistics. According to the household surveys, which are based on self-report- ing, unemployment overall was 29 percent in 2002, down only 2 per- centage points from 2001, with most of the decline being in Yerevan, where unemployment fell by 7 percentage points between 2001 and 2002. The persistence of high unemployment and underemployment even after more than a decade of economic growth may reflect some underlying structural problems. The pace at which the Armenian economy will be moving toward its new equilibrium, and the pattern it will assume, will depend on a variety of factors. We focus our analysis on a few of these factors which are relevant to our analysis (for example, the issues related to the flexibility of labor markets are deliberately omitted as they are being examined in the paper on labor markets). Strong labor productivity growth and an increase in the unit labor cost of current workers have crowded out the short-term potential for new employment. In general, growth in labor productivity, if associ- ated with slower growth in real wages, reduces unit labor costs and 158 Part II: Detailed Analysis creates room for new employment. In Armenia, rapid growth in labor productivity was accompanied by an increase in hourly compensation above the productivity growth level. Armenia started from a low level of productivity but exhibited one of the fastest productivity growth rates among the comparator coun- tries. Labor productivity in Armenia grew continuously over the last decade, and this growth accelerated during the early 2000s (Figure 7.5). During this period Armenia realized much of the "catch up" potential which arose following the economic transformation. As a result of this rapid productivity growth, the productivity gap between Armenia and industrialized countries has narrowed; how- ever it remains substantial and accentuates the importance of sustain- ing recent growth rates. The high growth rate of labor productivity was mainly due to Armenia's comparative advantage of an educated and skilled workforce and the country's strong tradition of having highly skilled craftsmen. Figure 7.5 Real Wage Growth and Productivity Growth, Unit Labor Cost (US$), 1998­2004 25 0.5 20 0.4 15 0.3 rate US$ growth 10 0.2 5 0.1 0 0 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 year real wage growth (left-hand side) productivity growth (left-hand side) unit labor cost (right-hand side) Source: Armenian Department of Statistics. Growth Analysis 159 Labor productivity growth in Armenia was outperformed by the increase in labor compensation. The unit labor cost (ULC) (influenced by diverse factors such as hourly compensation, productivity, and the exchange rate) gradually increased to about 46 percent of the U.S. ULC level (about 44 percent of the euro-area level) from as low as less than 3 percent in the early 1990s, and secured solid earnings for current workers.6 However, the benefits of recent economic growth have not generated higher employment and the increase in the labor cost has partly contributed to jobless growth (Figure 7.6). Figure 7.6 illustrates the mismatch between the rapidly expand- ing sectors and labor productivity. The contrast between the rapidly growing sectors and formal employment indicates that the majority Figure 7.6 Labor Productivity by Sector 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 index 1.0 0.5 0.0 e services uction industry average agricultur economic constr manufacturing sector 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 index2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 & food products uction power stonesprocessing average mining banking quarrying economic constr mineralecious transportation communication pr & and sector Source: Armenian Department of Statistics. 160 Part II: Detailed Analysis of the labor force has benefited only modestly from rapid economic expansion. Growth in Armenia has been concentrated in non-tradables and few tradable sub-sectors. Contrary to the industrialization pattern of the East Asian Tigers (like the Republic of Korea and Taiwan, China) with highly diversified export structures, recent growth in Armenia has been characterized by a mix of export-orientation toward capital intensive goods (such as scrap metal), commodities with low trans- portation costs (such as diamonds), and exports with a high price/ volume ratio (such as brandy), accompanied by import substitution of more labor-intensive commodities (such as subsistence agriculture). The export bias toward capital-intensive goods is explained by the high costs of exporting goods (and services) from Armenia and there- fore the concentration of exports around services/commodities with a high ratio of price to volume. This particularly high cost structure is a combination of common "transition economy" factors and Armenia's specific factors: In Armenia, as in any other transition economy, new jobs cre- ated differ in their salient characteristics from old jobs that were destroyed, and employment growth relies on business start-ups. The number of new businesses and new jobs created is directly associated with the profit margins generated by the new firms, while the costs of the new firms are generally high owing to initial investment and working capital needs, marketing, skills mismatch, high risks, and uncertainties (see subsequent chap- ters for detailed analyses). At the same time, new firms are con- fronted by severe resource constraints. Savings are low, financial intermediation is expensive, stock markets are underdeveloped, and insurance services are virtually nonexistent. These high costs are inflated by additional charges related to corruption, which is also common in other transition economies but to varying degrees (other chapters in this report will try to benchmark Armenia relative to other transition economies). The high cost of doing business in Armenia and the high transaction costs push businesses into the informal economy, reduce invest- ment opportunities, and prevent Armenia's participation in the global division of labor based on production fragmentation and direct impact on the number of jobs created. In addition to the above, Armenia faces the challenge of a small domestic market and market isolation. This makes the coun- try dependent on exports and at the same time makes exports expensive because of high transportation costs. Growth Analysis 161 And finally, the high costs of backbone services (such as air fares and telecommunications), higher, in fact, than in the countries that do not face structural problems in market access, exacerbate the cost of doing business to levels not affordable for an average start-up with a modest profit margin. As a result, only exports that have very low transportation costs (such as diamonds and electricity exports to neighboring countries) or exports with a high price/volume ratio (such as brandy)--in other words, capital-intensive industries--have proved to be profitable in Armenia and have attracted investment. On the other hand, labor- intensive commodities such as light manufacturing, which requires bulk exports, have been developing much more slowly. In addition to the above, the sectors that had the opportunity to reduce costs by capitalizing on the existing export markets through a brand name (for example, brandy in Russia) or an established chain of production (such as precious stones refinement) have continued to follow the high cost of doing business. Another arrangement that allowed new businesses to operate was becoming informal and oper- ating underground. Growth Spillover Channels Armenia's growth has recently benefited from an increase in remittances and capital transfers, similar to the resource boom type of growth, where sources of growth rest on concentrated and volatile internal sources of demand financed from external transfers. Sources of growth rely heavily on both consumption driven by remittances and private transfers7 (dis- cussed earlier in the chapter), and on investment, mainly in construction, which relies heavily on foreign capital transfers. In general, the high share of value added in production leads to a greater contribution of that particular activity to GDP and growth. A strong reliance on intermediate inputs leads to low value added in production and is associated with low value added multipliers. Typically, sectors with high value added and intersectoral linkage multipliers would have a higher growth impact, but the gains from a large multiplier depend on the sector's size. Armenia's economy, especially its industrial sector's reliance on intermediate inputs, is quite high. Despite low savings rates and low effective taxes, which represent other leakages from output, the total value added as a share of total production is about 50 percent. The share of value added in industry is just 30 percent and the share of manufacturing only 16 percent; and the GDP multipliers of these sectors are lower than the 162 Part II: Detailed Analysis economy average (close to 1 as compared to about 1.4 on average in the economy). Machinery and jewelry cutting have the lowest share of value added in production, which implies that these industries are comprised mostly of intermediate inputs. In contrast, the share of value added is quite high in construction, agriculture (crops, vegeta- bles, and fruits), and services (utilities and banking), which implies large value-added multipliers (above 1.5) for these three sectors and the much stronger impact of these sectors on GDP growth than industry and manufacturing. Growth in these sectors is more likely to contribute to higher personal income for Armenians. Relatively, these sectors demonstrate high household multipliers. Over time, the share of capital value added in Armenia's GDP has increased, and although this has led to high overall incomes, it has had a relatively narrow impact on poverty reduction, as the earners of profits in a capital-biased, value-added economy depend on how these profits are distributed. Some industries, such as cellular telecom- munications, mining, or utilities may exhibit a high degree of value added in production, but since those industries are capital intensive, their contribution to personal income will depend on who collects the capital rents. For example, a foreign-owned mine may capture signifi- cant rents, but most of this income could be sent off-shore. Intersectoral linkage multipliers (Box 7.2) are highest in some serv- ices sectors, particularly in real estate, banking, and insurance. The intersectoral linkage multipliers are particularly low in some manufac- turing sectors, such as light manufacturing and machinery and equip- ment that rely on imported inputs (the share of imports in absorp- tion has recently increased to 45 percent). The mismatch between the level of GDP and intersectoral linkage multipliers and the share of the sector in value added indirectly point toward distortions in resource allocation, suggesting that there may be a disincentive for firms to invest in potentially highly profitable activities. While the largest intersectoral linkage multipliers in agriculture are in high value-added crops such as fruits and vegetables, the share of these sectors in Armenia's GDP is lower than the share of those with much lower multipliers. This suggests that some sectors with high growth potential have a much lower impact on growth than they potentially could have if they were to develop significantly in the future. Capital- izing on such high multiplier sectors would require finding ways of channeling investments into such sectors through a set of policy actions, including eliminating price distortions. To strengthen the backward and forward linkages from agriculture to agro-processing and manufactur- ing, the authorities should develop a strategy that enhances the efficient use of Armenia's agricultural base, including through improved access to markets and an increase in productivity. Growth Analysis 163 Box 7.2 Linkages in the Model Based on the Social Accounting Matrix The model based on the social accounting matrix (SAM) provides insights about the input and output relationships between goods and services markets, as well as the interlinkages between the demand for labor and capital in the process of production. This is made possible by analyzing a set of comparable direct and indirect intersectoral linkage multipliers in the context of the relative importance of each economic activity. Multipliers in the SAM-based model reflect how much a unit-increase in the demand and production of a commodity affects the demand for more commodities. The multiplier effect entails a higher demand for activities leading to higher wage incomes and profits (that is, higher household incomes), which create the demand for domestic or imported commodities. Direct multipliers: Value-added multipliers--show how much a unit-increase in the demand for a commodity directly affects the demand/ production of the same commodity. Intersectoral linkage multipliers--illustrate how much a unit- increase in the demand for a commodity increases the demand/ supply of commodities produced by other activities. Indirect multipliers: Induced household income multipliers--show how much a unit- increase in the demand for a commodity affects household income. Employment multipliers--show how many jobs are ultimately created directly or indirectly as a consequence of a unit-increase (1 million dram) in the demand for a commodity. The level of multipliers reflects the level of value added in produc- tion. Strong reliance on intermediate inputs leads to low value added (to labor and capital) and, hence, small multipliers. This could be the result of large leakages from an economy, due to a large proportion of imported inputs, taxes, and savings. Strong linkages entail direct and indirect spillovers of subsectoral growth on growth in other sectors, employment generation, and income distribution. Source: SAM (Chapter 8 of this book). 164 Part II: Detailed Analysis Remittances represent a considerable source of household income (US$207 million approximately)8 and are one of the main sources of foreign exchange for the country. An increasingly large number of households receive remittances in Armenia. Within these households, remittances tend to account for around 50 percent of their monetary income. The overwhelming part of remittances is spent on current consumption and only a small percentage is used for investment. Remittances have a direct effect on the recipient households' well- being as well as strong secondary multiplier effects. We have used the social accounting matrix to simulate the multiplier impact of remit- tances on the national economy. Impact on employment and household incomes by sector. Construction-- the fastest growing sector in Armenia--has had a strong impact on employment as well as on household incomes (see Table 7.4 for the employment and income multipliers as derived from an SAM con- structed for Armenia). Direct short-term spillover effects associated with the construction sector are strong, as is illustrated by large mul- tipliers and validated by the high share of the construction sector in the total economy's value-added and low-import content. The construction sector is strong in generating jobs, but the perma- nence of such jobs will depend on continued activity. The prospect of Millennium Challenge Account funding is, therefore, encouraging for employment. But, equally, a possible decline in construction would depress the direct demand for multiple economic activities. The spill- overs from these would be strong. The decline in incomes would result from a reduction in incomes generated in the construction sec- tor, as well as indirectly from other sectors. Suppressed household incomes would, in turn, depress the demand for commodities and services produced domestically. This would produce multiplier effects and exacerbate the effect of the original shock. There are a number of subsectors in agriculture, services, and manufacturing that are relatively stable and could potentially pro- duce stronger spillover effects and contribute significantly to growth, sustainable employment, and poverty reduction (the value-added share in production is high, and direct and indirect multipliers are quite significant). However, their ability to attract investments seems to be distorted. Their relatively low size and high export share in total production indicate that they may react strongly (may easily gener- ate double-digit growth and significant exports) when the constraints to growth are eased and/or incentives are provided. Capitalizing on such activities will be critical for increasing growth sustainability, diversifying the sources of exports, and creating better-paid jobs. Growth potential and the spillover effect of a number of activities that have not been growing rapidly are high in the sectors with the following characteristics: Growth Analysis 165 A high value-added share in production, particularly in some agriculture subsectors (above 60 percent) but also in services (banking and insurance and real estate). The share of value added is quite high in construction, agriculture (crops, vegetables, and fruits), and services (utilities and banking), which implies large value added multipliers (above 1.5) for these three sectors and a much stronger impact of these sectors on GDP growth than industry and manufacturing. Growth in these sectors is more likely to contribute to higher personal income for Armenians. Related to these characteristics, these sectors demonstrate high household multipliers. High intersectoral linkage multipliers such as banking and insur- ance and real estate. The large share of exports in total production for processing sec- tors and, at the same time, weak export performance of these activities indicate that: (i) the potential of these sectors is under- utilized and (ii) growth potential in these sectors can most likely be realized through export. The recent strong export expansion has had a limited impact on poverty reduction. Exports are concentrated in diamonds (37 percent of total exports, or US$ 258 million in 2002). The sector's contribution to the economy's value added is just 2 percent as the sector relies heavily on diamond imports (Table 7.5). This is an enclave activity with modest spillover effects for growth. In terms of employment, the sector does not create many jobs, but the jobs created are high-quality ones and are critical for the economy. In addition to diamond process- ing, export diversification in other semiskilled and skilled labor and higher value-added activities would generate stronger spillover effects and would translate into job creation and overall poverty reduction. The results of the simulations show that further diversification of the economy is critical for reducing the vulnerability of growth to external shocks and maintaining a reasonable growth momentum in the medium to long terms. As earlier sections of this chapter indi- cated, the economy has a small nondiamond production/export bas- ket. With the exception of a few traditional commodities and power, this basket does not reveal a comparative advantage in any particular commodity. However, it does suggest a natural comparative advan- tage through its linkages to the country's agricultural base and other economic resources as well as skilled human capital. The challenge for policy makers is to provide the general policy and institutional underpinnings for faster development of formal private sector activi- ties, which (i) tap into the higher-value elements of this basket that can create high-wage employment, and (ii) capitalize on the external demand by meeting the scale and quality requirements. 166 Table 7.4 Direct and Indirect Multipliers Linkage Induced Capital Part Share Own with other HH income Labor and land Sector in GDP VA/output multiplier sectors multipliers multiplier multiplier II: Detailed 1 grn: Wheat, potatoes, and legumes 4.6 63.5 1.1 4.9 1.6 0.8 0.8 2 vfr: Vegetables and fruits, including grapes and dried fruits 5.4 87.1 1.1 5.6 1.9 0.9 1.0 3 vol: Vegetable oils and fats 0.0 6.0 1.0 3.2 0.9 0.4 0.5 Analysis 4 ocr: Crops not elsewhere classified 3.8 78.7 1.1 5.5 1.8 0.8 1.0 5 mil: Dairy products, including eggs and milk 7.8 49.1 1.4 5.0 1.6 0.8 0.8 6 omt: Beef, pork, mutton, and poultry meat 3.1 42.0 1.1 5.1 1.6 0.8 0.8 7 enr: Energy--oil and natural gas 0.0 0.0 1.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 8 min: Mining and quarrying 1.8 59.8 1.2 5.4 1.7 0.7 1.0 9 fod: Food processing and beverages 7.4 36.7 1.4 4.6 1.5 0.8 0.7 10 tbc: Tobacco products 0.6 17.0 1.1 3.2 0.9 0.4 0.5 11 lmf: Light manufacturing and textiles 0.2 10.1 1.2 2.8 0.8 0.4 0.4 12 crp: Chemicals, rubbers, and plastics 0.5 19.6 1.1 3.5 1.0 0.5 0.5 13 mnm: Mineral products and precious stones 1.9 15.1 1.0 2.9 0.8 0.4 0.4 14 mtl: Metals and metal products 2.0 39.7 1.1 4.5 1.4 0.7 0.7 15 mch: Machinery equipment and motor vehicles and precision optical equipment 0.3 6.5 1.1 2.3 0.6 0.3 0.3 16 omf: Other manufacturing 0.8 29.3 1.1 3.5 1.0 0.5 0.6 17 utl: Electricity, gas, and water supply 5.2 73.5 1.3 5.4 1.8 0.7 1.1 18 ele: Electricity supply and distribution 4.8 62.6 1.2 4.5 1.5 0.7 0.8 19 con: Construction 13.9 57.6 1.1 4.7 1.5 0.7 0.9 20 trn: Transport and communications 7.1 58.9 1.2 5.0 1.6 0.8 0.8 Table 7.4 (continued) Linkage Induced Capital Share Own with other HH income Labor and land Sector in GDP VA/output multiplier sectors multipliers multiplier multiplier 21 trd: Retail and wholesale trade and public catering 13.5 64.5 1.3 5.0 1.7 0.7 1.0 22 bnk: Banking, lending, and insurance 1.7 69.1 1.1 5.6 1.8 1.0 0.8 23 gov: Governance, defense, and public procurements 9.2 54.5 1.2 5.2 1.7 1.0 0.7 24 osr: Other services not elsewhere classified 1.1 25.2 1.1 4.2 1.2 0.5 0.7 25 dwe: Housing and dwellings 3.2 73.6 1.1 5.9 1.9 0.5 1.4 Total 100.0 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. Total agriculture 24.8 58.4 1.1 4.9 1.6 0.7 0.8 Total manufacturing 11.9 29.0 1.1 3.5 1.0 0.5 0.5 Gr Total industry 8.9 15.9 1.1 3.4 1.1 0.5 0.6 owth Total construction 13.9 65.7 1.1 4.7 1.5 0.7 0.9 Total services 40.5 55.5 1.2 5.1 1.6 0.7 0.9 Analysis Total 100.0 49.5 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. Source: SAM, 2002 (Chapter 8 of this book). Note: Here, share of VA in output means that for every dram of production only x percent is value added. So, while production or output from an activity can be very large, the value added can be very small because of the high share of intermediate, especially imported, inputs. 167 168 Table 7.5 Armenian Economy, Sectoral Structure Depicted by SAM Part Share Share Share II: Sector in GDP VA/Output in exports in nondiamond exports Detailed grn: Wheat, potatoes, and legumes 4.6 63.5 0.0 0.1 vfr: Vegetables and fruits, including grapes and dried fruits 5.4 87.1 0.8 1.3 vol: Vegetable oils and fats 0.0 6.0 0.0 0.0 Analysis ocr: Crops not elsewhere classified 3.8 78.7 0.7 1.1 mil: Dairy products, including eggs and milk 7.8 49.1 0.1 0.1 omt: Beef, pork, mutton, and poultry meat 3.1 42.0 0.0 0.0 enr: Energy--oil and natural gas 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 min: Mining and quarrying 1.8 59.8 5.5 8.8 fod: Food processing and beverages 7.4 36.7 7.3 11.6 tbc: Tobacco products 0.6 17.0 0.5 0.8 lmf: Light manufacturing and textiles 0.2 10.1 4.2 6.6 crp: Chemicals, rubbers, and plastics 0.5 19.6 1.2 1.9 mnm: Mineral products and precious stones 1.9 15.1 37.0 mtl: Metals and metal products 2.0 39.7 6.4 10.1 mch: Machinery equipment and motor vehicles and precision optical equipment 0.3 6.5 8.0 12.7 omf: Other manufacturing 0.8 29.3 0.7 1.1 utl: Electricity, gas, and water supply 5.2 73.5 0.0 0.0 ele: Electricity supply and distribution 4.8 62.6 1.9 3.0 Table 7.5 (continued) Share Share Share Sector in GDP VA/Output in exports in nondiamond exports con: Construction 13.9 57.6 0.9 1.4 trn: Transport and communications 7.1 58.9 12.6 19.9 trd: Retail and wholesale trade and public catering 13.5 64.5 0.0 0.0 bnk: Banking, lending, and insurance 1.7 69.1 1.0 1.5 gov: Governance, defense, and public procurements 9.2 54.5 1.1 1.7 osr: Other services not elsewhere classified 1.1 25.2 10.1 16.1 dwe: Housing and dwellings 3.2 73.6 0.0 0.0 Total 100.0 n..a. 100.0 63.0 Total agriculture 24.8 58.4 1.6 2.6 Total manufacturing 11.9 29.0 28.3 44.9 Total industry 8.9 15.9 42.5 8.8 Gr Total construction 13.9 65.7 0.9 1.4 owth Total services 40.5 55.5 26.7 42.3 Total 100.0 49.5 100.0 100.0 Analysis Source: SAM (Chapter 8 of this book). Note: Here, share of VA in output means that for every 1 dram of production only x percent is value added. So while production or output from an activity can be very large, the value added can be very small because of the high share of intermediate, especially imported, inputs. 169 170 Part II: Detailed Analysis The impact of growth on formal job creation was limited, as the sec- tors that have experienced strong growth in Armenia have not been labor-intensive (Table 7.6). On the contrary, agriculture, which has been growing more slowly than the rest of the economy, has absorbed surplus labor released in the process of economic transformation. The government--the most labor-intensive activity in Armenia--has been negatively affected by fiscal adjustment. Other labor-intensive sectors (such as banking and light manufacturing) have been growing slowly. The main reason for the unfavorable progress in the light manufac- turing sector is related to high transportation costs, such as aviation. The construction sector, which has been a leading growth sector, has provided quite a few employment opportunities. However, the sus- tainability of these jobs depends on the sustainability of the source of its financing, which is volatile. Diamond cutting, which is a sector with good jobs, is capital-intensive but the contribution of labor value added in the sector is not. The effective reallocation of jobs released as a result of the termination of large construction projects depends on the ability of the economy to provide alternative opportunities outside of the construction sector in case of demand contraction. The causes of the centering of growth on sectors that are not labor-intensive are explored in Chapter 11 of this book. The mismatch between rapidly expanding sectors and labor productivity. The contrast between the rapidly growing sectors and formal employ- ment indicates that the majority of the labor force has benefited only modestly from rapid economic expansion. Armenia has shown some signs of export diversification, but a number of sectors with high growth potential remain idle. The mis- match between the level of GDP and intersectoral linkage multipliers and the share of the sector in value added indirectly point toward the distortions in resource allocation, suggesting that there may be a disin- Table 7.6 Sources of Employment in Armenia: Distribution by Sector, 2002 Share in total employment Contribution to employment Activity (percent) US$ thousands Agriculture 49.5 548 Construction 4.8 53 Industry 1.6 18 Diamonds 1.4 15 Manufacturing 10.6 117 Services 32.1 355 Total 100.0 1,106 Source: SAM, 2002 (Chapter 8 of this book). Growth Analysis 171 centive for the firms to invest in potentially highly profitable activities. Earlier sections have noted that despite the apparent diversification of the nongold export basket, very few--mostly primary--exports reveal a comparative advantage and even fewer export items show signs of emerging competitiveness in regional markets (the dairy indus- try and heavy manufacturing are two examples). The present export basket, however, reflects strong backward linkages to the country's natural resource endowments and agricultural base and other eco- nomic resources, as well as skilled human capital. As reflected in the presence of supply chains in several sectors, there are also clear for- ward linkages, especially with respect to agro-processing and light manufacturing, although these linkages are weak, particularly toward the upper end of the supply chain. A diversified export basket that takes advantage of the presence of these supply chains will not only facilitate the production and export of raw materials from agriculture and industry, but will also facilitate higher value-added processed and manufactured products from the same supply chains (such as canned vegetables and fruit juices). High value-added agricultural products. The trade data analysis sug- gests that crops such as vegetables and fruits, which presently have a relatively high share of GDP but a miniscule share of nondiamond exports, have significant growth potential--evident from their high value-added shares in total production (over 80 percent)--and export potential. The existing forward linkages of these commodities to agro- processing suggest that if their supply is sufficiently expanded, they can generate even higher value in the form of processed food. To strengthen the backward and forward linkages from agriculture to agro-processing and manufacturing, the authorities should develop a strategy that enhances the efficient use of Armenia's agricultural base, including through improved access to markets. Manufacturing (particularly textiles, chemical production, machinery and equipment, and motor vehicle production) can aid export diversification. The large share of exports in total production in the processing sectors, together with the observed weak export performance of these activi- ties, indicate that (i) the potential of these sectors is underutilized, and (ii) growth potential in these sectors can most likely be realized through export. High transportation costs and domestic barriers to the development of the higher end of these supply chains are the main obstacles to the expansion of these subsectors (for more details, see Part II, Chapters 9­11). Their relatively low size and high export share in total production indicate that they may react strongly (eas- ily generating double digit growth and significant exports) when the constraints to growth (such as policy-induced high business trans- actions costs or aviation and telecommunications costs) are eased. Capitalizing on such activities will be critical for increasing growth 172 Part II: Detailed Analysis sustainability, diversifying sources of exports, and creating better paid jobs. The main distortion for a stronger interest in high value-added activities with large export potential is transportation costs. Armenia has experienced a sharp drop in its trade transported by air in recent years, despite its landlocked nature and its subjection to a blockade by Turkey and Azerbaijan. The cost of air cargo in Armenia is much higher than that in other landlocked countries such as Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, or Mongolia, or the semi-landlocked Turkmenistan. Such high costs have caused a relative shift toward road transport (despite poor infrastructure) and even railways. Liberalizing air trans- port by expanding the participation of several carriers could greatly enhance export competitiveness in Armenia. Finally, a number of subsectors in services such as banking and insurance, ITC, and tourism present cases where the potential has not been fully exploited. In addition, these sectors demonstrate high intersectoral linkage multipliers, which suggests that these sectors potentially produce stronger spillover effects and contribute more to growth, sustainable employment, and poverty reduction (the value- added share in production is high and direct and indirect multipli- ers are quite significant). However, their ability to attract investments seems to be distorted. A key barrier, especially for the services sec- tor, is the lack of competition and the high prices of telecommunica- tions. The telecommunications infrastructure in Armenia is currently one of the least developed in the CIS, despite being one of the first in the CIS to privatize. The 15-year monopoly granted to the single private investor since the privatization of ArmenTel in 1997 to the Greek operator OTE, coupled with the government's ineffective regu- lation of the operator, has led to severe underinvestments and has stifled growth even in mobile phones, where the penetration ratio in Armenia is one-tenth that of its neighbors. The extremely high cost and poor quality of telecommunication services has handicapped the country in production and exports. ANALYZING EXTERNAL SHOCKS AND SOURCES OF VULNERABILITY IN ARMENIA: SAM-BASED SIMULATIONS OF ALTERNATIVE SCENARIOS Assumptions and Scenarios As discussed in the previous sections, Armenia has demonstrated a strong growth performance in the last several years. The generation of baseline growth does not seem to be a constraint for Armenia. The challenges that Armenia faces seem to be (i) how to ensure growth Growth Analysis 173 sustainability, and (ii) how to enhance a growth pattern that secures job creation and rising household incomes. Based on these considerations and taking into account the previous analysis of the growth pattern, we have decided to focus our simula- tions on the following issues: Construction is the leading, yet unstable, growth sector that strongly relies on a highly volatile source of financing--capital transfers. Direct short-term spillover effects associated with the construction sector (illustrated by large multipliers and validated by the high share of the construction sector in the total econo- my's value added) are strong. The sector may not be generating long-term sustainable employment, nor may it be a future source of growth, but the first-round effects on growth and employment seem to be large. A negative shock in the sector could therefore trigger a decline in growth, a reduction in employment, and an increase in poverty. The sector is not a viable source of growth unless accompanied by growth in export-oriented, high value- added activities that generate future sources of income through a demand for skilled jobs. An economy cannot grow by sim- ply continuing to build houses and infrastructure financed by uncertain external flows, unless it ensures that the demand for the new houses and infrastructure is strong and the returns on investment are generated. Exports are quite volatile, with diamonds representing the most important source of revenue from exports (37 percent of total exports, or US$258 million in 2002). Diamonds are susceptible to price fluctuations as well as conditions in inputs markets and are therefore vulnerable to external shocks; the sector's share in GDP, however, is only 2 percent. Although the sector is also an important source of foreign exchange, it is an enclave activity with modest spillover effects for growth in terms of employ- ment. The sector does not create many jobs and the jobs created are highly skilled. In this regard, export diversification toward high value-added activities should be pursued to reduce export concentration and export reliance on this highly volatile source of foreign exchange and to safeguard the economy from the negative impact of external shocks. As was mentioned above, remittances are an important source of household incomes (about US$207 million). Remittances are, however, an unreliable source of income, and are perhaps unproductive if they are channeled toward consumption alone, as may be occurring in Armenia. While this is an unsustain- able source of growth, as it is consumption-based and does not 174 Part II: Detailed Analysis generate long-lasting income and jobs, its first-round effects are large. Therefore, the negative shock associated with the reduc- tion of remittances may have a devastating effect on the econ- omy and on household incomes. There is a need to build an incentive mechanism to channel a portion of these remittances into savings that can be invested in sectors with future growth potential. Simulation Results The results of the simulations of a negative shock on cut-diamond production are provided below. We have assumed a 50 percent decline in diamond exports (that is, about US$135 million). The effects of this export decline on growth, employment, and poverty are relatively moderate due to the enclave character of the diamond activity (the sector's contribution to GDP is about 2 percent) and its strong reli- ance on unprocessed diamond imports. The diamond sector's link- ages with the rest of the economy are not as strong as they would appear, judged by the large share of diamonds in exports. The effect of a comparable shock on construction would be much stronger, as the sector has large multipliers and a relatively low import share. The impact is also stronger on employment. This has an important implication for growth impetus in Armenia, which currently relies strongly on construction. This is a sector fueled by investments--the most volatile component of the aggregate demand. In 2004, as a result of the termination of the Lyndsey project, with the associated US$100 million in injections into the economy, the construction contribution to GDP declined substantially and many people employed in the sector were laid off. A decline in construction would depress the direct demand for multiple economic activities, with strong spillovers to the rest of the economy. There would be a decline in incomes resulting from lowered income in the construction sector as well as, indirectly, in other sectors. Suppressed household incomes would, in turn, lower the demand for commodities and serv- ices produced domestically and, through multiplier effects, would exacerbate the effect of the original shock. The third simulation was conducted to see the effect of a com- parable shock to remittances. The associated negative effect on GDP was stronger than in the diamond export shock case but weaker than in the construction case owing to smaller value added multipliers. However, this shock had the strongest impact on household incomes (­11 percent). Based on our analysis, we would argue that construction is a good but volatile source of growth and, in order to cushion the economy against its sudden decline, the economic development policy should Growth Analysis 175 enhance more stable sources of growth and employment in the ser- vices and manufacturing sectors. The manufacturing sector has lower multiplier effects in the short run but provides sustainable employ- ment with a strong potential for future income generation. We have simulated a case when the sectors with high export poten- tial are given incentives, or when certain barriers to trade are elimi- nated (for example, transportation costs are reduced). The results of the simulations show that this scenario has a strong positive effect on growth, household incomes, and job creation.9 This positive effect on employment is even stronger when we take into consideration that jobs that are created are sustainable and well paid (Table 7.7). Future Growth Prospects and Desirable Growth Patterns with Stronger Spillover Effects The intersectoral linkages and transmission mechanism, which in recent years enabled strong economic growth to penetrate down to households through higher incomes, are likely to prevail in the medium term. Stronger growth in export-oriented sectors, driven by a shift toward higher value­added production, would clearly bring higher overall GDP growth in the medium term. Such a shift would also be instrumental in preparing the economy to face the difficult challenge of maintaining modest growth rates should any of the shocks described above materialize. For purely illustrative purposes we have also demonstrated the result of a 10 percent shock to agriculture output through higher pro- ductivity. However, higher productivity may be commensurate with lower prices, especially if the agricultural goods cannot be exported. In September 2004, there was a good melon crop and all of the farm- ers had excess melons. As there is only so much demand for melons on the domestic market, many of the melons were left to rot, since no one would buy them, even at near-zero prices. Unfortunately, water- melons are low-value per pound, so the melon growers are not able to sell them internationally. This underscores the importance of linkages of agriculture to agro-processing, which may boost productivity and create additional demand. Model Simulations: Sustainable Growth and Job Creation, Using Export Diversification The results of the simulations show that further diversification of the Armenian economy is critical to reduce growth vulnerability to external shocks and maintain a reasonable growth momentum in the medium to long terms. As earlier sections of this chapter have indicated, the Armenian economy presently has a relatively small 176 Part II: Table 7.7 Tables Generated Using the 2002 SAM-based Model for Armenia Detailed Effect on labor Effect on jobs income, US$ & numbers & percent change percent change Analysis Effect on GDP, Effect on household income, Shock US$ & percent change Skilled Unskilled Skilled Unskilled US$ & percent change I. Negative shocks Diamonds (­50% = US $135 m) ­109.5 ­8.6 ­44.8 ­5,500 ­52,700 ­109.5 (­5.1%) (­3.7%) (­5.5%) (­3.8%) (­5.5%) (­4.4%) Construction (­30% = US$135 m) ­204 ­13 ­76 ­8,300 ­89,500 ­204 (­9.5%) (­5.7%) (­9.3%) (­5.8%) (­9.3%) (­8.3%) Remittances (­5.5% = US$135 m) ­139.2 ­10.1 ­64.1 ­6,400 ­63,600 ­275 (­6.5%) (­4.4%) (­6.6%) (­4.4%) (­6.6%) (­11.1%) Source: SAM (Chapter 8 of this book). m = million. Growth Analysis 177 nondiamond production/export basket. With the exception of a few traditional commodities and power, this basket does not reveal a com- parative advantage in any particular commodity. However, it does suggest a natural comparative advantage through its linkages to the country's agricultural base and other economic resources as well as skilled human capital. CONCLUSIONS The single most important factor explaining the recent poverty decline in Armenia was high growth combined with declining inequality. The principal sources of growth, household income, and foreign exchange in Armenia (that is, construction, remittances, and con- centrated exports), are quite concentrated, although there are clearly some elements of economic and export diversification. Trade and export-oriented growth beyond diamond processing should become a leading strategy of the development model pursued by the gov- ernment. While domestic savings need to continue to grow, FDI as well as portfolio investment as opposed to private transfers should become more important drivers of economic growth. More generally, the country should open up to benefits from intensified international flows of information and technology (Box 7.2) and the promotion of concepts of good governance and business management. In this con- text, efforts to develop a policy framework for shared growth beyond the construction sector, which is a major beneficiary of current invest- ment inflows, needs immediate attention. Armenia's manufacturing and services sectors should also benefit more from investments and the associated intensified international flows of information and tech- nology. Some generic recommendations are A discussion of the future agenda is contained in other sections of the documents. 178 Table 7.8 Simulation Assuming Export Diversification Part Effect on II: Effect on labor Effect on jobs household Detailed income, US$ & numbers & income, Magnitude of shock Effect on percent change percent change US$ & effected through GDP, US$ & percent Analysis policy reforms percent change Skilled Unskilled Skilled Unskilled change Total shock to economy based on the US$135 m 158.4 12.5 63.0 7,800 74,100 158.4 strategy of export diversification (7.4%) (5.5%) (7.7%) (5.4%) (7.7%) (6.4%) Vegetables and fruits, including grapes and dried fruits (9% = US$2.8 m) Crops not elsewhere classified (10% = US$2.5 m) Food processing and beverages (13% = US$2.5 m) Light manufacturing and textiles (50% = US$27 m) Metals and metal products (26% = US$22 m) Machinery equipment, motor vehicles, and precision optical equipment (34% = US$28 m) Banking, lending, and insurance (12% = US$3 m) Other services not elsewhere classified (41% = US$35 m) Source: SAM (Chapter 8 of this book). m = million. Table 7.9 An Alternate Approach That Does Not Rely on Export Growth A 10 percent positive shock in agriculture versus a 10 percent positive shock in manufacturing and industry (excluding minerals and mining) Effect on Effect on labor Effect on jobs, household income, US$ & numbers & income, Effect on percent change percent change US$ & Inward-looking policies that promote all nonmineral GDP, US$ & percent sectors equally percent change Skilled Unskilled Skilled Unskilled change Agriculture 151.3 7.2 65.2 4.6 76.6 151.3 (10% = US$91 m) (7.1%) (3.2%) (7.9%) (3.2%) (8.0%) (6.1%) Manufacturing & industry 359.9 38.6 135.8 24.5 159.7 359.9 Gr (10% = US$241 m) (16.8%) (16.9%) (16.6%) (16.9%) (16.6%) (14.6%) owth Source: SAM (Chapter 8 of this book). Analysis m = million. 179 180 Part II: Detailed Analysis Box 7.3 Information and Communications Technology Sector The ITC industry could play a leading role in Armenia's economic development. It is a versatile technology and there are no areas of prod- ucts or services where ITC cannot be applied and benefits obtained. ITC also has multiplier effects on other economic activities. Given the regional constraints to the country's trade, the significance of ITC development, especially e-commerce applications, cannot be overem- phasized. Armenia's ITC industry development program is based on its comparatively large supply of qualified ITC professionals, the relatively short durations of ITC projects, relatively low capital requirements, low wage rates, and benefits in terms of high value-added products. In the former Soviet Union, Armenia was one of the main scientific centers of the country, with special focus on the ITC industry. There were about 40 R&D companies active in the field, the biggest of which, Yerevan R&D Institute of Mathematical Machines, had about 10,000 employees and was producing both hardware (mainframes, computers mostly for Soviet military industry needs) and the corresponding software (operat- ing systems, applications). Despite the country's economic and physical hardships experienced since its independence in 1991, the ITC industry has survived and has even developed. Since 1997, the ITC industry has been advancing at an accelerated pace in all three of its subsec- tors: (i) hardware; (ii) software; and (iii) media for collection, storage, processing, transmission, and presentation of information. More than 200 companies, including about 20 American and European companies, are currently operating in the ITC sector in Armenia employing local specialists. Because job opportunities are limited, a large number of program- mers are unemployed or work as computer maintenance specialists or operators, rather than for software firms. However, software develop- ment has become so popular in Armenia that many mathematicians and physicists are changing their specialties to become software pro- fessionals. Armenia has approximately 6,000­7,000 specialists in the field, with 300 graduating every year from the Engineering University and the State University's applied mathematics faculty. The biggest software company in Armenia is HPL Armenia, a subsidiary of Silicon Valley­based HPL Inc., which employs about 150 programmers. Soft- ware exports alone amounted to an estimated US$20 million in 2000. In support of ITC development, the government declared the ITC industry as one of the priorities for Armenia's economic development by a decree adopted in December 2000. The concept of ITC industry development was endorsed by the government in April 2001, while the sector devel- opment program is currently under preparation. Source: "National Human Development Report, Armenia," UNDP, 2001. Growth Analysis 181 NOTES 1. Prepared by Ekaterine Vashakmadze, Economist, World Bank. 2. This multiplier reflects how much a unit increase in the demand for a commodity affects household income. 3. It is difficult to accurately assess the distribution of factor income among wage income, mixed income, and income from capital, as the Armenian statis- tical data on wages include only the official wage bill, which clearly underes- timates the real level of the wage bill. (See also the discussion in Box 7.1.) 4. There have been two large waves of Armenian emigration: at the begin- ning of the twentieth century and after the collapse of the Soviet Union. This reflects the present structure of the Armenian diaspora, which comprises the two types of internationally recognized migrants. The first type is recent emi- grants who are relatively young, have immediate families in Armenia, and support their families' incomes from abroad. This source of funds mostly finances consumption and is relatively stable at least over the future 20 to 30 years; from the pure accounting point of view this source is reflected as net transfers and net income from abroad. The second type of emigrant is the earlier emigrants, people whose families left about 100 years ago, and who are investing money in their country of origin if they see investment opportunities there. 5. It is estimated that at least some 20,000 people leave the country every year, mostly for economic reasons. 6. The higher the value added by labor is, the greater is the remuneration to labor and the stronger the poverty impact of an activity, if its share in all activities is large. At the same time, sectors with high employment multipli- ers have the potential to absorb a lot of employment, but the earnings from those jobs depend on the quality of jobs in the sector. The growth pattern is decisive in creating higher-wage jobs versus expanding the number of low- paid jobs. In general, low value-added agricultural activities and trade create the greatest amount of employment if one counts only the number of jobs generated per 1 million drams. However, there is a trade-off between the number of jobs and the quality of new jobs created. In contrast, the financial sector generates fewer jobs per million drams, but the quality of these jobs is superior and therefore provides sustainable sources of income and long-term security, moving more people out of poverty versus temporary employment and a reduction in transient poverty. That said, the creation of quality jobs may be constrained by the supply of skilled labor. 7. Remittances from the Armenian diaspora are a very important source of financing, signaling strong investment interest and business opportunities abroad and pointing to the potential for exploiting these opportunities back home. This source should be counted as a tremendous asset in terms of inte- gration into global markets. This source of funds primarily finances invest- ment, reacts to the macro environment and investment climate, and may be 182 Part II: Detailed Analysis highly volatile; from an accounting point of view, these are capital inflows which are debt-creating or returns-creating. 8. Unofficial remittances may be two to three times larger than official estimates. 9. The effect of the shocks on household income and GDP is identical in absolute value. Annex 7.1. Disaggregated Effect of Shocks on GDP (by sector), Armenia SAM Table 7A.1.1 Effect of a (­50%) Shock on Diamonds Base Impact Change Share in GDP (%) GDP on GDP in GDP (US$ million) (US$ million) (%) Old shares New shares Total agriculture 531.3 ­24.7 ­4.7 24.8 24.9 Total manufacturing 254.8 ­12.0 ­4.7 11.9 11.9 Total industry 191.8 ­27.7 ­14.5 8.9 8.1 Total construction 298.6 ­3.2 ­1.1 13.9 14.5 Total services 869.0 ­41.9 ­4.8 40.5 40.6 Total 2145.5 ­109.5 ­5.1 100.0 100.0 Source: Armenia SAM. Table 7A.1.2 Effect of a (­30%) Shock on Construction Base Impact Change Share in GDP (%) GDP on GDP in GDP (US$ million) (US$ million) (%) Old shares New shares Total agriculture 531.3 ­40.6 ­7.6 24.8 25.3 Total manufacturing 254.8 ­16.9 ­6.6 11.9 12.3 Total industry 191.8 ­9.8 ­5.1 8.9 9.4 Total construction 298.6 ­87.8 ­29.4 13.9 10.9 Total services 869.0 ­49.0 ­5.6 40.5 42.2 Total 2,145.5 ­204.1 ­9.5 100.0 100.0 Source: Armenia SAM. 183 184 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 7A.1.3 Effect of a (­5.5%) Shock on Remittances Base Impact Change Share in GDP (%) GDP on GDP in GDP (US$ million) (US$ million) (%) Old shares New shares Total agriculture 531.3 ­51.5 ­9.7 24.8 23.9 Total manufacturing 254.8 ­18.6 ­7.3 11.9 11.8 Total industry 191.8 ­11.6 ­6.1 8.9 9.0 Total construction 298.6 ­2.3 ­0.8 13.9 14.8 Total services 869.0 ­55.1 ­6.3 40.5 40.6 Total 2,145.5 ­139.2 ­6.5 100.0 100.0 Source: Armenia SAM. EXPORT DIVERSIFICATION INTO MANUFACTURING AND HIGH-VALUE NONTRADABLES Table 7A.1.4 Effect of a (+US$135 million) Combined Shock Based on Relative Export Shares Base Impact Change Share in GDP (%) GDP on GDP in GDP (US$ million) (US$ million) (%) Old shares New shares Total agriculture 531.3 47.0 8.8 24.8 25.1 Total manufacturing 254.8 38.7 15.2 11.9 12.7 Total industry 191.8 10.6 5.5 8.9 8.8 Total construction 298.6 4.3 1.4 13.9 13.1 Total services 869.0 57.8 6.7 40.5 40.2 Total 2,145.5 158.4 7.4 100.0 100.0 Source: Armenia SAM. AGRICULTURE VERSUS MANUFACTURING AND INDUSTRY, EXCEPT MINERALS AND MINING Table 7A.1.5 Effect of a (+10% = US$91 million) Positive Shock in Agriculture Base Impact Change Share in GDP (%) GDP on GDP in GDP (US$ million) (US$ million) (%) Old shares New shares Total agriculture 531.3 95.6 18.0 24.8 27.3 Total manufacturing 254.8 12.0 4.7 11.9 11.6 Total industry 191.8 7.3 3.8 8.9 8.7 Total construction 298.6 2.1 0.7 13.9 13.1 Total services 869.0 34.4 4.0 40.5 39.3 Total 2,145.5 151.3 7.1 100.0 100.0 Source: Armenia SAM. Growth Analysis 185 Table 7A.1.6 Effect of a (+10% = US$241 million) Positive Shock in Manufacturing and Industry, except Minerals and Mining Base Impact Change Share in GDP (%) GDP on GDP in GDP (US$ million) (US$ million) (%) Old shares New shares Total agriculture 531.3 85.6 16.1 24.8 24.6 Total manufacturing 254.8 58.1 22.8 11.9 12.5 Total industry 191.8 31.4 16.4 8.9 8.9 Total construction 298.6 5.6 1.9 13.9 12.1 Total services 869.0 179.2 20.6 40.5 41.8 Total 2,145.5 359.9 16.8 100.0 100.0 Source: Armenia SAM. Annex 7.2 Methodology Used in the Paper T his paper depicts the Armenian subsectoral economic structure by analyzing a newly constructed 2002 Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) (see Light, Vashakmadze, and Khachatrian 2005). The results of this paper are derived from simulations based on a multiplier analysis of the SAM. The objective of our analysis was threefold: (i) to examine the vulnerabilities of the present growth pattern; (ii) to understand the channels through which growth penetrates to the labor market through employment creation and household incomes; (iii) to identify possible constraints to higher and more shared growth, which will generate sustainable jobs and lead to more effective poverty reduction. While approaching this task we have asked ourselves the follow- ing questions: (i) What are the sources of Armenia's current growth? What are their implications for jobs and household incomes? What does the structure of the Armenian economy imply in terms of sub- sector growth; (ii) How sustainable are these sources and what are the implied vulnerabilities of the current growth pattern? (iii) Are the sectors that have managed to attract investment indeed the ones with high future growth potential? (iv) What is the effect of growth on future productive assets: is the current growth pattern creating productive assets or mainly consuming foreign inflows with a lesser impact on future sustainable growth? Answering these questions will help us to understand what is needed to achieve a sustainable and balanced growth with strong spillover effects, especially on employ- ment generation and the well being of low-income households. We have applied a step-by-step approach that includes the following: 186 Growth Analysis 187 We have conducted an economic analysis that depicts a disag- gregated picture of the Armenian economy by constructing and analyzing different information sources, including the SAM, and by revealing the interrelationships between sectors as they grow. We have conducted a multiplier analysis that considers the eco- nomic impact of growth across different sectors and analyzes the linkages between growth, employment, and poverty. Based on preliminary findings, we have formed certain hypoth- eses that we have tested through a set of simulations. For this study we have developed and applied an SAM-based sup- ply-side model. The model is practical but has certain limitations; it assumes fixed prices, which is plausible in the short term for a country with highly unutilized capacity, like Armenia. The 25 sector SAM for Armenia (Light and Rutherford 2004) provides a good initial base for such an analysis. The model has been elaborated by incorporating the information on households, employment, and current account bal- ance. The 2002 SAM for Armenia is the first attempt to systematically combine data from disparate Armenian agencies in order to create a balanced, representative framework for economic analysis. It is also the first time that the Armenian survey of household consumption has been integrated together with the Armenian National Accounts. By providing a bridge between these two fundamental data sources, the SAM provides a basis for the comparison of data sources and a sound methodology for checking the consistency of the national and household accounts. Annex 7.3 Summary Notes on Labor Statistics in Armenia SOURCES OF DATA There are several NSS publications on labor statistics in Armenia: 1. Monthly reports of "Socio-Economic Situation in Armenia" are the main sources of the current situation on labor statistics, and sections of "Labor Market Indicators" generally comprise monthly data and monthly accumulative data on the following: nominal wages and salaries per worker number of economically active population by sectors number of employed persons unemployment rate 2. Data from monthly publications are used by NSS to prepare the annual Statistical Yearbook of Armenia. The yearbook is the main source of finalized and summarized labor statistics in Armenia. The sections on "Employment" and "Living Standards of Population and Social Sphere" contain the following average annual data: labor resources number of economically active population by sectors number of economically nonactive population number of employed persons number of unemployed persons registered unemployment rate unemployment benefits and average monthly data on the same nominal wages and salaries per worker 188 Growth Analysis 189 The data published in the Statistical Yearbook of Armenia are final and have priority in case of differences compared with the data on the "Socio-Economic Situation in Armenia." 3. However, the results of 2001 Census of Armenia (Armenia 2003c) may be considered a more comprehensive and detailed statisti- cal source for labor statistics in Armenia, though the census was undertaken only for a certain period of time. Along with some other valuable statistical data, the 2001 census results contain the following more useful information on "Economically Active De Jure Population" by the following categories: rural and urban occupation and employment status sex and age educational attainment type of economic activity All the indicators since 2002 represented in the section on "Employment" in the Statistical Yearbook of Armenia (excluding the officially registered unemployed) were based on data recal- culated by the results of the 2001 census. 4. Other labor surveys conducted by NSS are useful. The "Labor Force Sample Survey in the Urban Settlements in Armenia" (August­September 2001) was aimed at deriving statistical infor- mation on issues concerning sex and age, specialty composition, employment structure of the economically active population of the urban settlements in Armenia, factors influencing the latter, unem- ployment, underemployment, and the labor market in general. In this analytical publication outputs of the survey were summarized and general conclusions were drawn. Meanwhile, to have a com- plete picture, the derived indicators were compared with the offi- cial macroeconomic indicators on employment for Armenia. CONCLUSION The officially registered unemployment rates are calculated according to the Armenian law "About Employment." According to this law, the unemployed are considered persons 16 years and older who meet these conditions: do not have work have applied to the Employment State Service of Armenia to receive work and have at least one year's work experience/practice 190 Part II: Detailed Analysis Except for the officially registered unemployment rate, the labor force survey and the census are allowing the real unemployment level to be estimated. As a basis for the labor force survey and census, the International Labor Organization (ILO) recommendations on the defi- nition of unemployment were taken. According to this definition, during the reference period the unem- ployed are considered to be all persons who satisfy all three of the following criteria: do not have work or a profitable job are actively seeking work at the Employment State Service (as well as independently) are ready to start working immediately Table 7A.3.1 Selected Labor Indicator Definitions Source of definition Total labor force Employment Unemployment Statistical Economically active population Number of persons employed Officially registered unemployed are Yearbook includes all employed and includes those persons who able-bodied citizens of working age 2004 unemployed population who work at institutions and all who are resident in the territory of the develop labor markets (related organizations of all types, Republic and who in the period under to labor force demand for including those employed at review do not have work (profitable production of commodities and small organizations, public activity), seek a job with the aid services). organizations, peasant farms, of employment territorial centers, and also those engaged in and who are ready to begin work entrepreneurial activity, and self- immediately or during the period employed persons. defined by legislation. Labor Economically active population Persons were employed, did Persons were unemployed, did not Gr Force is the sum of employed and some paid work, or had some have a job during the observation owth Survey unemployed persons who form profitable employment during the week, looked for a job, and were the labor force demand in the observation week, even if it lasted ready immediately to take up work. Analysis labor market. for an hour. (continued on next page) 191 Table 7A.3.1 (continued) 192 Source of definition Total labor force Employment Unemployment Part 2001 The economically active The employed population must The unemployed comprise all those Census population (labor force) comprises satisfy one of the following two persons 15 years or older who during II: those individuals 15 years or categories: the reference period satisfy all three of Detailed older who are either employed the following criteria: 1. Paid employment or unemployed (according to a. Those who performed work a. Without work; in other words, the ILO definition) during the for wage or salary, in cash not in paid or self-employment as reference period. Analysis or kind defined in the employed population b. Those that have a job but b. Currently available for work; in were temporarily not at other words, available for paid work during the reference or self-employment, during the period, but had a formal nearest two-week period attachment to their job c. Seeking work; in other words, took specific steps in a recent period to 2. Self-employment find paid or self-employment a. Those who performed work for profit or family gain, in Also considered unemployed are those cash or kind individuals who stated they that were b. Those that have their not looking for a job due to one of the own enterprise but were following reasons: not working during the a. Have applied for a job and will be reference period for some starting it in near future specific reason b. Have applied for a job and are According to current ILO waiting for the answer recommendations, work means at least one hour of work performed during the reference period. Chapter 8 A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia INTRODUCTION This chapter1 provides documentation related to the 2002 Armenian SAM. Development of this SAM is necessary to identify the potential linkages between economic growth and poverty alleviation and for basic economic analysis of Armenian tax and trade policies. The credibility of these studies depends upon an accurate and complete depiction of Armenia's economy. The 2002 SAM for Armenia is the first attempt to systematically combine data from disparate Armenian agencies in order to create a balanced, representative framework for economic analysis. It is also the first time the Armenian survey of household consumption has been integrated with the Armenian National Accounts. By provid- ing a bridge between these two fundamental data sources, the SAM provides a basis for comparison of data sources and a sound methodol- ogy to check the consistency of the national and household accounts. The development phase was influenced by the particular uses for the SAM. Some of these uses are itemized here: Economic analysis. A disaggregated picture of the economy is made possible by combining the national data with industry- level data. This disaggregation reveals the interrelationships among sectors as they grow. Economic growth and the incidence of poverty. By connecting poor and rich households to different factors of production, dif- ferent consumption bundles, and different transfer patterns, the household SAM provides the basis to determine what linkages exist between Armenian economic growth, employment, and the alleviation of poverty. 193 194 Part II: Detailed Analysis Multiplier analysis. The inclusion of an input-output (IO) matrix into the social accounts means that we can invert this matrix and generate economic output "multipliers." This is often a straight- forward way to consider the economic impact of growth across different sectors.2 Policy and impact analysis. This SAM provides the basis for a standardized computable general equilibrium (CGE) model of the Armenian economy. CGE models are the most common tool for tax and trade policy analysis. The underlying data describe the industries and individuals that pay taxes in Armenia and also describe who is consuming imports and who is producing exports. Data improvement. A well-documented "benchmark" dataset can be used as a starting point for further data development. We hope this SAM will be used as a benchmark to measure the quality of new data sources. Data integration. The official data produced by various Arme- nian ministries and departments, such as the NSS, Ministry of Finance, customs authorities, and the tax authorities, should be "consistency checked" with other divisions' output. Although perfect coordination is not possible, we hope this SAM will permit each organization to compare their own data with the outputs that would be applied by combining data from other sources. With these needs in mind, we developed three SAMs to represent Armenia's economy; each one reveals a different level of detail. The macro SAM represents the most aggregated national accounts. The cells from this matrix replicate the basic national accounting identities, such as GDP, national income, and the current/capital accounts. The micro SAM disaggregates total national production into 25 separate industries. Each industry has a distinct production tech- nology that includes intermediate inputs from other industries and uses different combinations of production factors. This matrix decom- poses aggregate value added into four distinct factors: skilled labor, unskilled labor, capital rents, and land rents. Total direct and indi- rect taxes are distinguished using the major Armenian tax streams: value-added taxes, income taxes, profits taxes, excise taxes, import tariffs, and payroll (social security) taxes. The international accounts are decomposed by sector, so that imports, exports, domestic supply, and total aggregate supply are known for each of the 25 industries. The micro SAM combines all of these components into a single, bal- anced matrix. A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 195 Finally, the household (HH) SAM projects income and expenditure profiles from a single representative agent onto 20 income deciles. Ten rural and 10 urban households are categorized by income; then each household's factor income, expenditure patterns, and transfers are mapped onto the 25 industries and four factor types. Although we believe these social accounts represent the best avail- able data for Armenia at this point, there is room for improvement. Closer collaboration with the NSS could yield a more accurate depic- tion of total sectoral output. By the same measure, closer collaboration with the NSS household survey division might yield more accurate factor incomes for each income decile. Accurate factor share informa- tion is critical in order to identify the effect of industrial growth upon wages and capital rents. Finally, an Armenian-based IO table would be an improvement because it would dispel suspicions that the core nature of Armenian production is not correctly captured. We hope the current dataset will lower the cost of further data development and lead to a universally accepted set of national accounts for the country. This documentation should facilitate further improvements, especially because a detailed description of the build- ing process has been included in the Annex. The remainder of this documentation is arranged as follows. Sec- tion 2 presents three depictions of the Armenian social accounts. Section 3 briefly describes past and future applications of the Arme- nian accounts for economic analysis. Section 4 concludes and offers potential avenues for further improvements. A lengthy and detailed Annex documents the SAM building process; Annex subsections "Matrix Balancing" and "The Build Distribution" detail the algebraic mechanics and files needed to build the SAM from scratch. THREE SOCIAL ACCOUNTS MATRICES In this section we present the Armenian accounts using three separate matrices, each with an increasing level of detail. The macro SAM con- tains only aggregate national accounts values; the micro SAM adds sectoral detail by disaggregating production, consumption, and trade to 25 goods and industries. Finally, the household SAM adds fur- ther detail by disaggregating the single consumer into 20 separate households using data from the 2002 Armenian Household Survey of income and consumption. All of the social accounts are based upon a set of input tables. These input tables are based upon published government statistics, analytical reports, and judgments from local experts and staff. 196 Part II: Detailed Analysis The Aggregate macro SAM We have chosen a specific split of accounts to reveal sufficient detail for calculating the output both from expenditure and the revenue side for constructing the macro SAM. Furthermore, we have made an effort to preserve the mandatory data entries fully comparable with the System of National Accounts. We have included the follow- ing major accounts in the macro SAM: productive sector, commodity markets, factors of production, two institutions (governance and the rest of the economy), the savings/investment account, and the "rest of the world" account. By using the column totals provided in two of the input tables, Annex Tables 8A.1.2 and 8A.1.3, we can produce most of an aggregate SAM. Several national indicator statistics from the NSS can be found in the macro SAM below. For example, GDP at producers' prices is equal to total value added, or US$2,145.5 million. The macro SAM is reproduced here as Table 8.1. Table 8.1 Aggregate Social Accounts for Armenia, 2002 (US$ millions) A B C D E F G H ACT COM VA RA GOV ROW I/S Total 1 ACT -- 4,337.6 -- -- -- -- -- 4,337.6 2 COM 1,962.1 -- -- 2,033 237 698 514.8 5,444.9 3 VA 2,145.5 -- -- -- -- -- -- 2,145.5 4 RA -- -- 2,145.5 -- 117.7 206.7 -- 2,469.9 5 GOV 230 -- -- 72 -- 54.7 -- 356.7 6 ROW -- 1,107.3 -- -- -- -- -- 1,107.3 7 I/S -- -- -- 364.9 2.0 148 -- 514.9 8 Total 4,337.6 5,444.9 2,145.5 2,469.9 356.7 1,107.4 514.8 -- Key: ACT Activities account, total production COM Commodities account, aggregate demand, and supply of goods VA Value-added account RA Representative-agent account GOV Government account ROW Foreign account. I/S Investment and savings account Source: Authors' calculations. Note: -- = not available. A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 197 These figures should be easy to recognize. Reading by ROW/COL- UMN, we see that total value-added (RA/VA) equals US$2,145 mil- lion. This figure is identical to the column sum for VA0 from Annex Table 8A.1.2. Total imports, found in the ROW/COM cell, are also equal to the column total under M0, US$1,107. At some point, how- ever, adjustments were impossible to avoid. For example total inter- mediate demand, ID0, is slightly larger in the macro SAM than it is in input Annex Table 8A.1.2, (US$1,962 versus US$1,924). Other cells can be checked in a similar way. Table 8.2 compares the macro SAM from Table 8.1 to officially published statistics from the NSS. There is a clear linkage between the macro SAM and the Armenian System of National Accounts. The macro SAM cells are presented in column three of Table 8.2, and the corresponding National Accounts spreadsheet cell is presented in col- umn four. Table 8.2 Replication of Selected National Accounts Measures by the Macro SAM Value SNA Account (US$ millions) Macro SAM spreadsheet cell GDP (producer prices) 2,146 A3 SNA (An7) Net indirect taxes 230 A5 SNA (An4) GDP at (market prices) 2,376 A3+A5 SNA (An3) Total absorption 2,786 D2+E2+G2 SNA (An28) GNP 2,464 A3+A5+F4+118.7 SNA (An60) GNI (disposable) 2,638 A3+A5+F4-F5 SNA (An61) GDS 105 A8-A2-D2-E2 SNA (An50) GNS 367 D7+E7 SNA (An53) GDI 515 G2 SNA (An36) Direct taxes 73 D5 GFS (AN11) Total net current transfer 173 F5+118.7 SNA (An49) Imports of goods and services 1,107 B6 SNA (An26) Exports of goods and services 698 F1 SNA (An25) Current account balance 148 F7 BOP (AN36) Source: Authors' calculations. Note: The macro SAM cell coordinates are used to calculate each macroeconomic statistic. These values can be compared with the corresponding National Accounts spreadsheet cells. SNA: System of National Accounts. 198 Part II: Detailed Analysis The micro SAM Construction of a complete SAM is done by disaggregating each cell contained in the aggregate (macro) SAM. Using more detailed tables for industrial supply (for example, see Table 8A.1.2), we can produce disaggregated statistics for production, industrial demand, value- added, final demand, and trade. The dimensions of the micro SAM for Armenia are listed in Table 8.3. The following paragraphs describe how the micro SAM accounts are organized. Activities/Commodities. We used official NSS statistics to compute participation for major sectors, but some sectors that were provided needed further disaggregation from outside data sources. For exam- ple, the NSS official statistics use "industry" to describe all manufac- turing sectors. We used output shares taken from an IMF Country Report for Armenia to further disaggregate this super-sector into six subsectors. Given total output for each sector, we then use a surrogate IO table as a starting point to describe each industry's production technology. For most sectors, we assert that the production technology is similar, agricultural industries are typically labor-intensive in low-income coun- tries, and manufacturing industries are typically capital-intensive.3 Some sectors are clearly unique to Armenia and required manual adjustment. For example, Armenia's "cut jewelry" sector accounts for one-third of total imports and exports. This sector uses only one inter- Table 8.3 Structure of the Disaggregated (micro) SAM for Armenia, 2002 Number Name of account of accounts Description Activities/commodities 25 Industries are described in Table 8.4 Factors of production 4 Skilled labor, unskilled labor, capital, and land Tax streams 6 VAT, excise, labor tax, profits tax, payroll tax, and import tariffs Government 1 Central government Households 1 One single, representative agent Trading partners 1 ROW trading partner Margins n.a. Trade and distribution (TRD) margins, collected as a production activity and used as an intermediate input Savings-investment 3 Private, government, and foreign Source: Authors' calculations. A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 199 mediate input, uncut gems. The remainder of the value accrues to labor and capital, so the IO matrix was corrected to reflect Armenia's special circumstances in the jewelry industry. In other cases, aggregate intermediate demand was larger than total supply. Adjustments to the IO matrix were required in these cases as well. A full description of the SAM-balancing process is included in the Annex. Tax Streams. Upon request, the Armenian Ministry of Finance has supplied figures for tax collections across tributary streams for each of the 25 commodities. Each of the six taxes is presented individually in the SAM, but where they appear in the matrix depends on whether they are classified as direct or indirect taxes. Total tax collections in our treatment are about 20 percent smaller than total government revenues for 2002. Collections are smaller in this dataset because we chose to omit some of the revenues from special taxes, fees, and other miscellaneous incomes that are not consistent year to year. Government. All government activity, local and national, is pre- sented using a single government agent, and a single government production technology. Government income comes mostly from tax collections and from transfers. Revenues are spent primarily to pur- chase the "government good," which is produced using intermedi- ate materials, labor, capital, and land. The government also transfers funds to households and contributes to savings. Households. The micro SAM includes a single representative agent (RA). The RA earns income by selling production factors, and the RA consumes goods as final demand. Total factor earnings by the RA in this matrix sums to US$2,145 million, which equals gross domestic product, taken at producer prices. Other income comes from govern- ment transfers and remittances from abroad, which are placed in the ROW account. Sector Descriptions. Table 8.4 presents 25 industrial sectors with labels and descriptions. These sectors reflect our best notion of Armenia's stra- tegic and important industries. While some of the sectors in the social accounting matrix have been disaggregated from the Armenian national statistics, others are a combination of less-important sectors that were included on separate lines in the NSS accounts. Table 8.4 presents a detailed description of each sector, and a mapping between the NSS out- put statistics and the sectors in Table 8.4 can be found in the Annex. Armenia 2002: A Snapshot The micro SAM depicts the Armenian economy at a fairly disaggre- gated level and helps us to understand the implications of its present structure in terms of subsectoral growth. Table 8.5 displays Arme- nia's production and trade statistics for 2002. The largest single out- put sectors were construction, trade, and processed foods. Other large 200 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 8.4 Detailed Sector Descriptions for Each Industry in the 2002 Armenian micro SAM Symbol Description GRN Grains, potatoes, and legumes. Taken from the 2002 agriculture dataset (available in the Armenia SAM distribution). This sector combines wheat, potatoes, and leguminous plants. VFR Vegetables and fruits, including grapes. Includes vegetables, dried fruit (without grapes) and the grapes account. VOL Vegetable oils. Directly from 2002 agriculture accounts. OCR Other crops. Crops that are not classified elsewhere in the social accounts. MIL Milk and milk products. Dairy products including raw or processed milk, eggs, and related products OMT Other meats. Includes the beef, pork, mutton, goat, and poultry categories from the 2002 agriculture dataset. ENR Energy. Oil and natural gas. This sector is not produced in Armenia--it is a pure import. MIN Mining and quarrying. This sector comes from two sources. The first source is the National Accounts (Macro Data.xls) sector "Geology." The second portion comes from the IMF Statistical Annex, page 7, Table 4: Structure of Industrial Production (1996­2001). The portion for "Mining and Quarrying" is taken from the "industry" sector of the National Accounts. FOD Processed food and beverages. Includes all processed foods, alcoholic, and nonalcoholic beverages. This is one of the largest consumption sectors in Armenia. TBC Tobacco and tobacco products. CRP Chemicals, rubber, and plastic. This sector was apportioned from the industry macro-sector in the 2002 NSS official output statistics. Oil and natural gas refining or processing is included in this sector. OMF Other manufacturing. Manufacturing industries not elsewhere classified. LMF Light manufacturing and textiles. Includes textiles, dressing, and dying of fur. MNM Minerals and precious stones. This sector mainly captures the jewelry-cutting business in Armenia. The single largest import and export good in Armenia is jewels. Uncut jewels enter the country and finished jewelry is exported. Shares are taken from Table 4 of the IMF Statistical Annex. This datasheet is available as part of the Armenia SAM distribution (see Annex for details). MTL Metals and metal products. Basic metals and fabricated metals, taken directly from the IMF Statistical Annex. Represents 8 percent of industrial output. (continued) A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 201 Table 8.4 (continued) Symbol Description MCH Machinery and equipment. Combines machinery, equipment, and motor vehicles with optical, medical, and other precision devices, IMF Statistical Annex, Table 4. Combined share is 3.8 Percent. UTL Gas, water, and trash utilities. This sector appears twice: once in the industrial section from the IMF Statistical Annex, then again as a separate account in the official NSS accounts. We combine these two accounts for the total. The totals are the "utility sector" from the macro report and "electricity, gas, and water" from the IMF Statistical Annex, Table 4. ELE Electricity production and distribution. Captures nuclear electricity production and the distribution of power across the Armenian electricity grid. CON Construction. Taken directly from the official NSS National Accounts. TRN Transportation and communications. Includes public transportation activity, postal communication, and fixed-line and wireless telecommunications. TRD Trade and distribution activities. Wholesale and retail trade plus commerce combines two macro lines: Retail trade and catering plus general commerce. BNK Banking and finance. Combines two lines from the 2002 National Accounts: insurance and lending. GOV Government, defense, and public procurement. This represents government activities within the economy. Taken from the macro data spreadsheet, and also compared with general statistics regarding the government sector. This sector also includes "social spending," including four lines from the national accounts: health & sport, education, culture, and science. DWE Dwellings and housing. One line from the national accounts: housing. activities include the public sector (GOV), cut gems, transportation services, and electricity output. Food is probably more important to the Armenian economy than it appears in this table. If we combined the four largest food industries (processed foods (FOD), dairy (MIL), meats (OMT) and grains (GRN)), then consumable food would be the largest single industry in Armenia. Total combined output for these four industries accounts for 25.1 percent of total production. Table 8.5 also displays exports (X0), imports (M0), and total domes- tic supply (A0) for each sector. Import and export volume is domi- nated by a single sector: uncut and cut gems (MNM). This sector alone 202 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 8.5 Armenian Production Statistics by Sector, 2002 (US$ million) Sector Y0 Y0(%) D0 X0 M0 A0 Construction 518.3 11.9 512.1 6.2 2.9 515.0 Retail & wholesale trade & catering 447.2 10.3 447.2 0.0 0.0 447.2 Food processing & beverages 430.7 9.9 379.6 51.1 46.7 426.3 Governance, defense, & public spending 362.5 8.4 354.8 7.7 7.8 362.6 Dairy products, eggs, & milk 342.6 7.9 342.1 0.5 6.8 348.9 Mineral products & precious stones 269.3 6.2 11.3 258.0 206.3 217.5 Transport & communication 259.9 6.0 172.2 87.7 24.0 196.2 Electricity supply & distribution 163.2 3.8 149.8 13.4 5.6 155.5 Beef, pork, mutton, & poultry meat 159.0 3.7 158.9 0.1 23.1 182.0 Wheat, potatoes, & legumes 155.5 3.6 155.2 0.3 50.7 206.0 Electricity, gas, & water supply 152.0 3.5 152.0 0.0 0.0 152.0 Vegetables, grapes, dried fruits 132.5 3.1 126.9 5.6 24.0 150.9 Metals & metal products 109.9 2.5 65.3 44.7 55.3 120.6 Crops not elsewhere classified 103.1 2.4 98.1 5.0 19.9 118.0 Services not elsewhere classified 93.7 2.2 23.1 70.6 60.5 83.6 Housing & dwellings 92.6 2.1 92.6 0.0 0.0 92.6 Machinery, vehicles, precision equipment 88.7 2.0 33.0 55.7 186.4 219.5 Tobacco products 80.9 1.9 77.3 3.6 30.0 107.3 Energy (oil & natural gas) 75.7 1.7 75.7 0.0 156.5 232.2 Mining & quarrying 65.9 1.5 27.2 38.7 1.1 28.4 Other manufacturing 61.2 1.4 56.1 5.0 52.1 108.3 Chemicals, rubbers, & plastics 53.0 1.2 44.7 8.3 81.7 126.4 Light manufacturing & textiles 52.6 1.2 23.5 29.1 40.1 63.7 Banking lending & insurance 51.6 1.2 44.9 6.7 11.3 56.2 Vegetable oils & fats 15.8 0.4 15.8 0.0 14.3 30.1 Source: Authors' calculations and NSS statistics. Key: Y0: Aggregate production value Y0 (%): Production share of total output D0: Supply to domestic market X0: Supply to export markets M0: Import value (cif) A0: Armington supply (D0 + M0) represents about one-quarter of the total trade volume for Armenia. Uncut gems are imported into the country, they are then cut and sometimes mounted as finished jewelry, then re-exported to Europe or the United States. Transportation, services, and machine products are the other large exports for Armenia. A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 203 Table 8.6 Value Added in Production for Armenia, 2002 (US$ million) Sector VA0 VA0(%) VA/Y L/VA K/VA Construction 298.6 13.9 57.6 40.7 59.3 Retail & wholesale trade & catering 288.6 13.5 64.5 30.2 69.8 Governance, defense, & public spending 197.7 9.2 54.5 86.1 13.9 Dairy products, eggs, & milk 168.2 7.8 49.1 55.4 44.6 Food processing & beverages 158.1 7.4 36.7 64.0 36.0 Transport & communications 153.1 7.1 58.9 57.0 43.0 Vegetables, grapes, dried fruits 115.4 5.4 87.1 48.7 51.3 Electricity, gas, & water supply 111.6 5.2 73.5 29.3 70.7 Electricity supply & distribution 102.1 4.8 62.6 48.7 51.3 Wheat, potatoes, & legumes 98.7 4.6 63.5 51.0 49.0 Crops not elsewhere classified 81.1 3.8 78.7 42.5 57.5 Housing & dwellings 68.2 3.2 73.6 0.0 100.0 Beef, pork, mutton, & poultry meat 66.9 3.1 42.0 53.0 47.0 Metals & metal products 43.6 2.0 39.7 67.9 32.1 Mineral products & precious stones 40.7 1.9 15.1 60.3 39.7 Mining & quarrying 39.4 1.8 59.8 38.6 61.4 Banking lending & insurance 35.7 1.7 69.1 68.0 32.0 Services not elsewhere classified 23.6 1.1 25.2 28.3 71.7 Other manufacturing 17.9 0.8 29.3 40.4 59.6 Tobacco products 13.7 0.6 17.0 50.4 49.6 Chemicals, rubbers, & plastics 10.4 0.5 19.6 52.2 47.8 Machinery, vehicles, precision equipment 5.8 0.3 6.5 56.8 43.2 Light manufacturing & textiles 5.3 0.2 10.1 66.2 33.8 Vegetable oils & fats 1.0 0.0 6.0 71.2 28.8 TOTAL 2145.5 100.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Source: Authors' calculations and NSS statistics. Key: VA0: Total value added (US$ million) VA0 (%): Value added as a share of total VA0 VA/Y: Value added share of total output L/VA: Labor share of value added K/VA: Capital share of value added If we reorganize these statistics according to value added, a different story emerges. Table 8.6 contains a breakdown of factors and value added in production for each sector. The government is the most labor-intensive activity in Armenia, where labor represents 86.1 percent of total value added. Other labor- intensive industries are banking (BNK), light manufacturing (LMF), and jewelry cutting (MNM). Column three (VA/Y), displays the inten- sity of value added in production. Machinery, tobacco, and jewelry 204 Part II: Detailed Analysis cutting have the lowest share of value added in production, which implies that those industries are comprised mostly of intermediate inputs. Crops, vegetables and fruits, banking, and utilities have a rela- tively higher share of value added in the production process--growth in these sectors is more likely to contribute to higher personal income for Armenians. Some industries, such as cellular telecommunications, mining, or utilities may exhibit a high degree of value added in pro- duction (VA/Y may be large), but since these industries are capital- intensive, their contribution to personal income will depend upon who collects the capital rents. For example, a foreign-owned mine may capture significant rents, but most of this income could be for- warded offshore. Taxes Like all former CIS countries, Armenia is faced with challenges related to tax collection and public finance. Despite relatively high statutory tax rates, tax evasion and multilevel corruption are significant impedi- ments to collection. The result is a relatively weak public tax system. Table 8.7 presents Armenia's major tax streams and breaks down tax collections by sector. Value-added taxes contribute most to the public coffers: about US$158 million was collected from the VAT in 2002. The statutory VAT rate is 20 percent, and more than one-half of these revenues are collected at the Armenian border. Excise taxes on motor fuel, tobacco, and beverages collected US$56 million in 2002, labor and social secu- rity taxes accounted for approximately US$50 million, the profits tax (denoted here by TK) contributed US$22.8 million, and import tariffs amounted to approximately US$15.2 million. These main tax streams represented US$302 million in 2002.4 According to the 2004 Aide- Mémoir on Armenia, we know that 2002 tax revenues were closer to US$385 million. The collections here represent only the major tax streams, excluding several fees and additional royalties collected by the central and local governments. Consumption Household demand, government demand, and intermediate demand can help to identify how price changes, such as inflation, can have an impact on households or producers. Table 8.8 displays the total com- modity supply for Armenia (A0 = D0 + M0) and each component of demand for these goods. A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 205 Table 8.7 Tax Payments by Sector in Armenia, 2002 (US$ million) Tax instruments Sector Total REVS % VAT TM TL TXS TK Energy (oil & natural gas) 75.0 24.8 49.3 0.0 0.0 25.7 0.0 Food processing & beverages 32.9 10.9 16.1 2.7 3.7 9.1 1.2 Tobacco products 30.5 10.1 5.8 1.4 0.4 22.0 0.9 Machinery, vehicles, precision equipment 18.8 6.2 14.9 3.2 0.4 0.0 0.3 Other manufacturing 17.3 5.7 11.7 0.8 2.9 0.0 1.8 Retail & wholesale trade & catering 14.9 4.9 7.4 0.0 6.2 0.0 1.3 Governance, defense, & public spending 13.7 4.5 0.0 0.0 13.7 0.0 0.0 Electricity gas & water supply 12.8 4.2 4.2 0.0 2.5 0.0 6.2 Transport & communications 11.4 3.8 3.7 0.0 5.0 0.0 2.8 Chemicals, rubbers, & plastics 11.1 3.7 10.0 0.5 0.4 0.0 0.3 Wheat, potatoes, & legumes 8.7 2.9 8.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Beef, pork, mutton, & poultry meat 7.6 2.5 3.9 1.8 0.4 0.0 1.6 Construction 7.5 2.5 2.1 0.0 3.3 0.0 2.1 Light manufacturing & textiles 6.4 2.1 4.3 1.3 0.4 0.0 0.4 Mineral products & precious stones 5.9 2.0 3.9 1.1 0.4 0.0 0.5 Vegetable oils & fats 5.1 1.7 3.5 1.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 Mining & quarrying 5.0 1.7 2.2 0.0 0.4 0.0 2.4 Housing & dwellings 5.0 1.6 0.0 0.0 4.6 0.0 0.4 Metals & metal products 4.6 1.5 3.2 0.0 1.2 0.0 0.1 Banking, lending, & insurance 3.9 1.3 0.0 0.0 3.3 0.0 0.5 Crops not elsewhere classified 2.4 0.8 1.9 0.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 Diary products, eggs, & milk 2.2 0.7 1.3 0.3 0.4 0.0 0.1 TOTAL 302.8 100.0 157.9 15.2 50.0 56.8 22.8 Source: Authors' calculations and Ministry of Finance statistics. Key: REVS: Total tax revenues for sector %: Share of aggregate tax revenues VAT: Value-added tax revenues--all sources TM: Import tariffs TL: Labor taxes TXS: Excise taxes TK: Profits taxes 206 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 8.8 Total Commodity Supply and Component Demand by Consumer, 2002 (US$ million) Demand Sector Supply A0 C0 C0(%) G0 ID0 I0 Food processing & beverages 426.4 275.0 13.5 0.0 151.4 0.0 Dairy products, eggs, & milk 349.0 231.3 11.4 0.0 117.7 0.0 Retail & wholesale trade & catering 377.3 226.4 11.1 0.0 150.9 0.0 Energy (oil & natural gas) 232.3 131.3 6.5 0.0 101.0 0.0 Vegetables, grapes, dried fruits 150.8 109.8 5.4 0.0 41.0 0.0 Beef, pork, mutton, & poultry meat 182.1 103.3 5.1 0.0 78.8 0.0 Tobacco products 107.4 102.7 5.0 0.0 4.8 0.0 Electricity, gas, & water supply 152.0 97.5 4.8 0.0 54.5 0.0 Construction 631.6 83.9 4.1 0.0 136.3 411.4 Transport & communication 196.2 79.2 3.9 0.8 116.2 0.0 Wheat, potatoes, & legumes 205.5 75.9 3.7 0.0 129.6 0.0 Governance, defense, & public spending 316.6 73.1 3.6 230.1 13.4 0.0 Mineral products & precious stones 217.7 68.0 3.3 0.0 149.6 0.0 Electricity supply & distribution 155.4 63.0 3.1 0.0 92.5 0.0 Housing & dwellings 92.6 48.2 2.4 0.0 44.4 0.0 Banking, lending, & insurance 56.3 39.0 1.9 0.0 17.2 0.0 Other manufacturing 108.2 38.5 1.9 0.0 63.7 6.0 Crops not elsewhere classified 118.0 38.1 1.9 0.0 79.9 0.0 Machinery, vehicles, precision equipment 218.7 37.5 1.8 0.0 97.9 83.3 Light manufacturing & textiles 63.7 29.2 1.4 0.0 34.5 0.0 Metals & metal products 120.6 26.5 1.3 0.0 86.7 7.4 Chemicals, rubbers, & plastics 126.5 23.9 1.2 3.2 99.4 0.0 Vegetable oils & fats 30.1 17.9 0.9 0.0 12.2 0.0 Mining & quarrying 28.3 8.8 0.4 0.0 19.6 0.0 Services not elsewhere classified 83.5 4.9 0.2 3.0 68.9 6.8 TOTAL 4,747 2,033 100 237 0 515 Source: Authors' calculations and NSS statistics. Key: A0: Armington aggregate supply (D0 + M0) C0: Final demand by households C0(%): Budget share of household consumption by sector. G0: Government demand for commodities ID0: Intermediate-inputs (firm) demand I0: Investment demand A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 207 Table 8.8 is ranked according to final demand (C0). We see that processed foods, dairy products, trade margins, and fossil fuels are the largest components in final demand by households. Beyond these staples, the second-tier demand commodities are vegetables, meats, tobacco products, and basic utilities. The Household SAM The national accounts go far to explain Armenia's underlying produc- tion technology, trade position, and final demand structure. However, the use of a "representative" household agent for total demand makes it impossible to determine whether economic growth in Armenia helps to alleviate poverty. To determine the distribution of income and expenditure as the economy grows, we further disaggregate the SAM to distinguish household types. In the HH SAM, we disaggregate a single house- hold agent into 20 individual households, each distinguished by income (by deciles) and location (rural or urban). This sort of disag- gregation is made possible by using data from the annual "Survey of Living Conditions"--a survey of incomes and expenditures compiled by the NSS. Figure 8.1 shows how total sectoral expenditures are disaggregated into household-level expenditures by good. Total final demand is bro- ken down into rural and urban household spending, but the total demand still equals aggregate final demand. To do this, the 25 × 1 vector of expenditure shares, shown in the top panel of Figure 8.1, is expanded into a 25 × 20 matrix of expenditure shares by commodity and household. Likewise, aggregate value added is allocated to each household according to income decile and location. This 4 × 1 vector is disag- gregated into a 4 × 20 matrix of factor allocations. The column sums equal each household's total factor endowments and each row total equals national factor supply. The combination of row and column totals equals total value added, or GDP at producer prices. We see that this figure equals US$2,145, which is identical to value added in the macro SAM discussed early in this chapter, as well as the factor incomes from the above section on the micro SAM. The disaggregation does not come without difficulty. The most onerous problem when using household data is to reconcile house- hold consumption against household income. Several of the poorer deciles in Armenia report far lower income than they report expen- ditures. Even when government and family transfers are included, expenditure for the poorest decile in Armenia is at least 10 times 208 Part II: Detailed Analysis Figure 8.1 Expansion from a Single RA to Multiple Households expenditure shares: RA to 20 households (25×1 to 25×20) RA U1 U2 . . . R1 R10 GRN 75.9 GRN CUgrn grn grn 1 . . . . . . CR 1 CR 10 VFR 109.8 VFR . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ... ... ... . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . DWE 48.2 DWE CUdwe dwe dwe 1 . . . . . . CR 1 CR 10 income shares: RA to 20 households (7×1 to 7×20) RA U1 U2 . . . R1 R10 LAB 817.9 LAB 2.8 8.5 . . . . . . 110.8 SKL 228.7 SKL 0.1 1.1 . . . . . . 27.8 . . . ... ... . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . GOV 117.7 GOV 5.5 5.9 . . . . . . 3.7 Source: Author. Note: Each household has a unique expenditure and income pattern, as depicted here. as large as income. As Deaton (2003) notes, this difference can be attributed to several factors. Because aggregate household income and spending must also be coordinated within the national accounts, we chose to use income shares and expenditure shares to distinguish households, then scale household totals to meet expenditures from the Living Standards Survey, and also meet aggregate final demand and factor endowments from the SAM. Table 8.9 displays income sources for each household, and Table 8.10 displays 2002 expenditures for each household. Figures from the "Total" row of Table 8.9 should be familiar by now, as they are identical to total factor incomes from the micro SAM. Total household incomes were scaled to meet total factor endowments and total (official) transfers from abroad, from the government, and invest- ment. For poor households, this leads to a significant divergence from reported income from the 2002 Household Survey. Deaton (2003) notes that this is not an anomoly only in Armenia; on page 8 he states: Income measured in the survey is on average larger than con- sumption measured in the surveys, but is in most cases less than national accounts consumption, and much less than GDP. Survey income is less than 60 percent of GDP on average." A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 209 Indeed, according to the Statistical Handbook (Armenia 2003b) based upon the 2002 Armenian Household Survey (Table 1, p. 51), 2002 total monthly per capita income was 12,776 drams. Of this, monetary income was 9,781 drams and nonmonetary (that is, own-produced value of consumption) monthly income was 2,995 drams. Annual monetary income, based upon the survey, is then (12 × 9,781)--117,372 drams per year, or US$204.83 per year, taken at market exchange rates. This implies that average income is US$0.56 per day. However, when Table 8.9 Household Income by Factor, 2002 (US$ million) Deciles SKL LAB CAP LND GOV ROW INV TOTAL Y/K $/DAY Rural households R1 0.0 2.5 5.1 0.6 6.0 0.0 0.0 14.2 91.3 0.3 R2 0.8 8.2 14.6 2.1 5.1 0.1 0.0 30.8 198.6 0.5 R3 2.0 12.8 21.8 3.4 5.7 0.1 0.0 45.7 294.8 0.8 R4 4.4 21.4 23.6 3.4 6.5 0.4 7.6 67.2 433.8 1.2 R5 8.4 31.3 25.4 3.7 5.6 0.9 9.6 85.0 548.5 1.5 R6 9.7 44.7 28.5 4.3 6.2 0.9 12.0 106.3 686.0 1.9 R7 12.0 52.7 39.2 6.0 4.3 2.7 14.9 131.9 850.9 2.3 R8 14.9 65.3 51.3 7.8 4.4 5.8 19.0 168.5 1087.3 3.0 R9 17.8 78.7 76.8 11.2 4.5 18.3 26.4 233.6 1507.3 4.1 R10 27.8 110.8 205.6 30.7 3.7 62.5 56.1 497.3 3208.5 8.8 Urban households U1 0.0 2.8 4.9 0.9 5.5 0.0 0.0 14.2 91.3 0.3 U2 1.1 8.5 12.3 2.9 5.9 0.1 0.0 30.8 198.6 0.5 U3 2.8 13.2 18.1 4.5 7.0 0.1 0.0 45.7 294.8 0.8 U4 5.8 19.7 21.1 4.7 7.9 0.5 11.4 71.0 458.2 1.3 U5 10.4 27.2 24.0 5.1 7.3 1.4 14.4 89.8 579.5 1.6 U6 12.3 38.0 28.6 5.9 8.1 1.4 18.0 112.3 724.7 2.0 U7 15.4 45.2 38.3 8.3 6.0 3.9 22.3 139.3 898.9 2.5 U8 19.1 56.0 49.3 10.7 6.1 8.2 28.5 178.1 1148.7 3.1 U9 23.0 69.3 69.9 15.2 6.4 23.5 39.6 246.8 1592.4 4.4 U10 41.1 109.6 167.8 41.2 5.5 76.0 84.2 525.4 3389.6 9.3 TOTAL 228.7 817.9 926.2 172.7 117.7 206.7 364.1 2834.0 Source: Authors' calculations, based upon Social Snapshot report by NSS (Armenia 2003b). Key: Figures are in millions of U.S. dollars, unless noted. R1 ... R10: Rural deciles U1 ... U10: Urban deciles SKL Skilled labor LAB Unskilled labor CAP Capital rents LND Land rents GOV Government transfers ROW Foreign remittances INV Savings demand Y/K Per-capita income $/DAY Per-capita income per day 210 Table 8.10 Final Demand Disaggregated by Household Type and Commodit, 2002 (US$ million) TOTAL R1 R2 R3 R4 R5 R6 R7 R8 R9 R10 U1 U2 U3 U4 U5 U6 U7 U8 U9 U10 Part TRD Retail & wholesale II: trade & catering 311.4 1.9 4.7 7.0 8.2 9.3 13.2 15.2 18.4 25.6 58.4 1.7 3.8 4.0 7.8 9.1 7.9 14.0 18.6 21.9 60.5 Detailed FOD Food processing & beverages 274.9 2.2 6.1 7.9 9.3 11.1 11.6 18.1 16.4 25.3 55.6 1.1 3.2 3.5 6.5 7.0 6.7 10.5 14.5 16.1 42.1 MIL Dairy products, eggs, & milk 231.2 1.0 2.7 4.8 7.2 8.5 9.6 15.7 12.9 21.3 38.7 1.0 2.7 3.0 5.4 6.8 6.3 10.0 13.3 18.1 42.4 Analysis ENR Energy (oil & natural gas) 131.3 0.6 1.8 1.9 2.3 3.2 5.1 4.4 6.0 11.1 26.8 0.7 1.7 2.3 3.3 4.7 4.0 5.9 7.3 10.7 27.6 VFR Vegetables, grapes, dried fruits 109.8 0.5 1.4 1.9 2.5 2.7 5.8 4.4 4.4 7.0 24.4 0.5 1.5 1.8 3.2 3.8 3.4 4.9 6.9 10.4 18.5 OMT Beef, pork, mutton, & poultry meat 103.2 0.5 1.2 1.9 2.5 2.2 3.9 4.1 5.7 7.8 16.1 0.6 1.3 1.8 2.4 3.3 3.3 5.1 7.1 9.6 22.6 TBC Tobacco products 102.6 0.6 1.5 1.7 2.4 2.7 4.8 4.5 5.3 8.3 16.8 0.6 1.4 1.8 2.4 3.3 3.4 5.6 5.9 9.6 20.0 UTL Electricity, gas, & water supply 97.5 0.6 1.5 2.2 2.6 3.0 4.1 4.8 6.2 8.2 17.3 0.6 1.3 1.8 2.4 2.9 3.1 4.4 5.8 6.8 17.9 TRN Transport & communications 79.1 0.3 1.2 1.2 1.7 2.1 2.6 2.2 2.3 6.9 15.8 0.5 0.8 1.3 2.7 2.3 2.3 3.8 4.9 7.9 16.3 GRN Wheat, potatoes, & legumes 75.9 0.5 1.4 2.1 2.3 3.1 3.8 3.4 3.7 8.1 14.1 0.4 1.2 1.5 2.1 2.5 2.5 3.8 4.5 5.2 9.9 GOV Governance, defense, & public spending 73.1 1.5 1.1 1.6 1.4 1.8 0.0 3.1 5.1 7.7 22.0 0.7 0.6 2.1 0.0 0.0 1.1 5.1 3.4 14.8 0.0 MNM Mineral products & precious stones 68.0 1.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 4.3 0.0 0.0 8.7 6.7 0.0 3.3 4.8 13.5 0.0 1.3 16.2 0.9 0.0 0.0 6.9 ELE Electricity supply & distribution 62.9 0.4 1.0 1.4 1.7 2.0 2.7 3.1 4.1 5.3 11.1 0.4 0.9 1.2 1.6 1.9 2.1 2.8 3.8 4.4 11.4 Table 8.10 (continued) TOTAL R1 R2 R3 R4 R5 R6 R7 R8 R9 R10 U1 U2 U3 U4 U5 U6 U7 U8 U9 U10 DWE Housing & dwellings 0.3 0.7 1.1 1.3 1.5 2.0 2.4 3.1 4.1 8.4 0.3 0.7 0.9 1.2 1.4 1.6 2.2 2.9 3.3 -- 8.7 BNK Banking, lending, & insurance 38.9 0.3 0.6 0.9 1.0 1.2 1.7 1.9 2.5 3.3 6.8 0.3 0.5 0.8 1.0 1.2 1.3 1.7 2.3 2.7 7.0 OMF Other manufacturing 38.5 0.2 0.5 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.3 1.8 2.6 3.7 8.6 0.2 0.5 0.6 0.9 0.9 1.1 1.9 1.7 3.0 6.6 OCR Crops not A elsewhere classified 38.1 0.1 0.1 0.6 0.8 0.9 0.2 2.9 0.7 0.0 6.5 0.3 0.6 0.7 0.8 1.4 2.1 2.3 1.9 5.4 9.8 Social MCH Machinery, vehicles, precision equipment 37.4 0.2 0.1 3.0 0.1 0.1 3.3 0.4 11.7 2.0 1.4 0.1 0.6 0.1 0.2 0.4 0.6 2.2 6.7 0.7 3.7 Accounting LMF Light manufacturing & textiles 29.2 0.1 0.4 0.5 0.8 0.6 1.1 1.1 1.7 2.8 6.4 0.2 0.5 0.5 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.3 1.6 1.7 5.6 MTL Metals & metal products 26.5 0.1 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.9 1.1 1.6 3.1 6.4 0.1 0.4 0.6 0.4 0.5 0.8 0.8 1.5 2.5 3.6 Matrix CRP Chemicals, rubbers, & plastics 23.9 0.3 1.0 1.1 0.0 0.3 0.0 1.6 0.3 3.8 4.8 0.2 0.5 0.3 0.6 2.2 1.3 0.6 0.0 5.0 0.0 VOL Vegetable oils & for fats 17.9 0.1 0.4 0.4 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.6 1.0 1.8 4.2 0.1 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.6 0.8 0.8 1.0 2.1 Armenia MIN Mining & quarrying 8.7 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.4 1.0 0.7 0.5 2.7 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.2 0.3 0.5 0.8 OSR Services not elsewhere classified 4.8 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.2 0.3 0.3 1.4 TOTAL 2,033.0 13.9 30.0 44.5 50.3 63.3 79.0 98.1 125.4 174.4 373.5 13.9 30.0 44.5 46.5 58.6 73.2 90.8 116.1 161.5 345.4 21 Source: Authors' calculations based upon Social Snapshot (Armenia 2003b) and other NSS publications. 1 Note: -- = not available. 212 Part II: Detailed Analysis using the National Accounts, we find that total value added (GDP at producer prices) is US$2.145 billion. Using 3.1 million as the national population, per capita income is US$1.90, more than three times as large as income from the Household Survey. As an initial pass, we used rural/urban shares that are approxi- mately equal. Some of the differences between rural and urban incomes can be attributed entirely to the investment account. The 2002 Household Survey includes an indicator for both rural and urban set- tlements. A straightforward improvement to this household dataset would be to replicate the urban-rural income and expenditure pat- terns more accurately. Table 8.10 presents household consumption patterns for each commodity. The household expenditure survey uses a "diary" for households to fill out, which contains a detailed list of food goods for purchase. For durable goods and nonrecurring expenses, a basic questionnaire is provided. We used a mapping procedure to connect each of the goods in the survey with the commodities in our SAM. Correctly classifying the survey goods was difficult, but a more prob- lematic issue arose when some types of goods were not covered in the survey. SAM-BASED APPLICATIONS Several studies are now possible using the multiple-household SAM. The most important research goal of this task is to identify where link- ages exist between economic growth, employment, and poverty. The next three subsections present a brief outline for future SAM-based applications. Economic Growth and Poverty Alleviation The important advantage of a SAM-based model is that it provides useful insights into the interrelationships that exist between goods and services markets, as well as the interlinkages between the demand for labor and capital in the process of production. Using the household SAM, which reflects how much a unit-increase in the demand and production of a commodity affects the demand for inputs, we can detect the vulnerabilities in the present economic growth pattern and estimate what the input requirements are to achieve sustainable and balanced growth. A detailed analysis will be presented in the separate paper on SAM-based applications. We can also calculate the economic growth patterns that affect mostly the consumption in the lowest-income deciles. As an example, consider benchmark consumption for the rural decile number four A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 213 (R4). Decile four is the group that is most likely to make the transi- tion away from poverty because they currently stand at or near the poverty line. Average per capita income for this decile is slightly less than US$1 per day, at US$340.70 per year. As we can see in Table 8.11 almost 60 percent of all expenditures are allocated to processed foods, dairy, meats, vegetables, and utilities. This includes 16.3 percent of expenditures which represent the retail markups paid as part of retail consumption (TRD). We can now com- pare household expenditure for R4 against the World Bank's poverty line for Armenia. For 2002, the overall poverty line, in value terms, was 12,261 drams per month, and the food-value poverty line was 7,516 drams.5 When translated to dollar values at market exchange rates, we get US$258 per year for overall poverty or US$159 per year for food-value poverty. If we add the top four food categories in con- sumption (FOD, MIL, OMT, and VFR), average annual purchases of these goods equals US$154, just US$4 less than the poverty line (see Figure 8.2). A straightforward strategy is to target policies that are most effec- tive for the lowest income deciles. These policies must either raise income or lower the real cost of consumption. For example, if the Table 8.11 Consumption and Income for Rural Household Decile No. 4 Sector R4(%) R4($) Family(4) R4(%) R4($) Family(4) FOD 18.5 60.1 240.6 SKL 8.2 28.1 112.4 TRD 16.3 52.8 211.1 LAB 40.6 138.2 552.8 MIL 14.3 46.3 185.4 CAP 44.7 152.2 608.9 UTL 5.1 16.6 66.2 LND 6.5 22.2 88.9 OMT 4.9 15.9 63.7 VFR 4.9 15.9 63.7 TBC 4.7 15.4 61.6 ENR 4.6 14.8 59.3 GRN 4.5 14.7 58.7 TRN 3.4 11.0 44.0 ELE 3.3 10.7 42.8 OTHERS 15.4 50.0 199.9 TOTAL 100 324.2 1,297 TOTAL 100 340.7 1,363 Source: Authors' calculations. Key: R4(%): Share of consumption or income as a percentage of total. R4($): Annual dollar value of income or consumption in per capita terms. Family(4): Annual dollar value of income or consumption for a family with four members. 214 Part II: Detailed Analysis Figure 8.2 Impact of Increased Wages or Lower Food Prices on Poverty for Rural Decile No. 4 10% wage increase labor 10% up income poverty line $159 $154 average food spending RD 4 $/year 77.5 155,000 poverty reduction 10% price cut income poverty line $159 $/year $153 new poverty line 155,000 77.5 poverty reduction Source: Authors' calculations. A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 215 return to unskilled labor (LAB) increased by 10 percent, then the aver- age individual in R4 would earn an additional US$13.82, and the aver- age household would earn an additional US$55.28. Holding all other prices constant, and assuming preferences are homothetic, the average per capita food bill would rise by US$5.91 (about 45 percent of the total increase in wages). Of the approximately 155,000 households in R4, this wage increase would pull 5,000 to 10,000 Armenian residents out of poverty. We get a similar result when the price of FOD is reduced by 10 per- cent. Given R4's baseline spending of US$60.1 on FOD, the reduction, other things being equal, is equal to US$6.01 of additional income. In both cases, the average change in income is about US$6.00 per year. All else being equal, we know that households will be better off in the first scenario, when income rises. The wage increase acts as a pure income effect, whereas the food price cut involves both an income effect and a substitution effect. Although the household can reallocate the savings under the price-cut scenario, the welfare gain is smaller because consumers will be faced with a different bundle of prices. Using this simple methodology, it would be possible to compute the feasible set of income and price changes, for all sectors and factors, which would achieve a given level of poverty reduction. This sort of analysis is not possible without a fully balanced, multiple-household SAM. Distribution of Tax Incidence Using the Armenian SAM, we can now evaluate the relative burden of taxation across household types. We can also consider how best to use Armenia's taxation and transfers system to alleviate poverty. The government collects taxes and spends the funds on public projects and on transfers to poor segments of the population. The net impact of tax reform upon households depends upon the following factors: production cost effects for firms, and the resulting impact upon employment and wages for key industries income and expenditure patterns of each household group transfer payments, as government revenues rise or fall These distributive impacts can now be determined using a CGE model. The model determines factor prices and commodity prices after a discrete shift in taxation. The resulting household income and consumption profiles can be determined as part of this equilibrium. This approach is often useful, because it captures all of the effects at the same time. For example, a government policy to increase transfers 216 Part II: Detailed Analysis to the poor may be ill advised if the additional funds are generated through a new tax on food items. The net effect may be increased transfers, but also higher food bills. The distortionary effect of new taxes then adds to the welfare burden, for all residents. Trade Liberalization and Poverty A third application of the Armenian SAM is to consider the effect of further trade liberalization in Armenia, and international trade's potential role for poverty reduction. Even though Armenia currently supports an open trade regime, where statutory tariff rates are 10 percent for most goods, the country remains highly isolated. This isolation comes from a closed border with two neighboring countries: Turkey and Azerbaijan. As the government considers the benefits and costs of a potentially open border with Tur- key, our dataset will be helpful in quantifying the net price effects for many staple goods, as well as the corresponding impact upon wages and employment for some of the more important production sectors. CONCLUSION AND DIRECTIONS FOR FUTURE IMPROVEMENT Our goal is to raise the level of policy debate in Armenia by providing a consistent, well-documented dataset that describes key production industries, household groups, international accounts, tax, and spend- ing streams. We understand that this dataset is preliminary, but we believe that policy decisions are better informed by a roughly param- eterized model, based upon the Armenian SAM, than upon the uncali- brated logic of economic theory. The dataset presents three views of the economy. The first is a top- level overview, which we call the macro SAM because it can be used to derive most of Armenia's macroeconomic indicators. The second is a mid-level view called micro SAM, which will serve as the workhorse dataset for most analysis projects. This dataset describes the interrela- tions among industries, the government, domestic households, and foreigners. Finally, we have developed a household SAM that can be used to identify the distributive effects of public policy. In many cases, a multiple-household model can be overly cumbersome for analysis, especially for tasks with a short timeframe. But there is no substi- tute for a multiple-household model to consider how government and nongovernmental policies are likely to affect the poor. In fact, for detailed poverty analysis, a much higher degree of granularity in the household accounts would be needed. We hope that future users A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 217 of this dataset endeavor to increase the consistency of the Household Survey data, and improve the corresponding household accounts in the Armenian SAM. We leave the reader with a short list of near-term data improvements. These improvements were chosen both because they will potentially improve the data quality for this SAM, and because they are relatively easy to carry out. Data Improvement We expect this document to be used for policy or academic pur- poses, so we invite the reader to use the Armenian SAM and to make improvements. Naturally, these improvements will only become ben- eficial if the reader intends to share and document any changes made to the dataset. Some near-term potential for data improvements are itemized below. Sectoral detail. This dataset distinguishes 25 production and con- sumption sectors. Our choice of industries had to be made at an early date, and it therefore missed some potentially important industries, either from a supply or a demand viewpoint. A useful and relatively painless improvement is to reorganize the sectoral aggregation in order to focus upon the most important sectors for a particular study. For example, if the SAM is used for a trade-policy study, identify the key import and export industries. Or, if the study is directed at poverty analysis, expand upon those goods most important for the lower-income deciles, which are mainly food, housing, and utilities. Multiple trading partners. We do not distinguish regional trad- ing partners. The single existing partner (ROW) could be disag- gregated into five or six distinctive trading regions. Household income and spending patterns. Additional analysis of household spending and income patterns will greatly improve the HH component of the Armenian SAM, without requiring any readjustment of other SAM submatrices. In the Annex we have included our mapping between goods in the Household Sur- vey and the sectors defined in the SAM. A more careful remap- ping of these goods could help create a closer fit and a clear count of Armenia's poor population. A separate improvement is to account for Armenia's very rich population. We believe that this tiny segment of the population (perhaps 1 percent), could account for more than 20 percent of the country's spending and more than 50 percent of the country's income. Without an assess- ment of this population segment, we will always find a yawning gap between household income and GDP. 218 Part II: Detailed Analysis Production statistics. Although output for some sectors is care- fully measured (electricity production is an example), other sectors report output that clearly conflicts with other national accounts, such as imports and exports. Additional clarification of what the NSS reports, and whether pertinent information is missing, would help to identify those industries that are truly important to Armenia's economic growth. Annex 8.1 Social Accounts Construction--A Manual T his Annex contains a detailed description of the SAM develop- ment process. The process begins with construction of several input data tables of industrial production, consumption, trade, and taxation. These input tables are combined and compared against some standard accounting identities. Where large discrepancies arise, basic judgment is combined with matrix-balancing techniques to impose a balanced set of accounts that resembles Armenia's economy. The resulting industrial data are then merged with data from the House- hold Survey into a single, balanced SAM for industries as well as households. First we discuss some challenges we encountered; then we elaborate on the actual process of building the SAM in subsequent sections of the Annex. SAM BALANCING AND MISSING DATA Development of a balanced SAM typically requires adjustments that reconcile disparities within existing data, but Armenia is the first case where at least one part is wholly missing. To complete the social accounts, we used a surrogate input-output (IO) table from another country (Poland). Of course, the new IO table did not fit perfectly with aggregate output values for Armenia. We found, however, that the production technology for most sectors is similar across develop- ing countries. A few sectors, such as jewel cutting for Armenia, are unique and require special consideration. When balancing a SAM, we attempt to utilize as much information as possible and adjust the data by weighting credible and accurate sources most heavily. Data elements that are less credible are adjusted more intensively than 219 220 Part II: Detailed Analysis others. Two techniques for SAM-balancing seem to be popular: RAS and maximum entropy (ME).6 We believe that the choice of balancing minimand (such as ME or least squares) is not as important as the choice of which data elements are being adjusted and why. Our experience has been that the study results are more sensitive to the policy variables, rather than IO coefficients. For example, results from a tax policy study are more biased by errors in the tax rate than by an equal percentage error in the IO coefficients. Therefore, when we balanced the 2002 Armenian SAM, the tax rates were held fixed, while the IO coefficients and other data were adjusted according to traditional Bayesian priors. A Structured Build Approach In the process of developing the 2002 Armenian social accounts, we tried to design a "structured build process" for developing countries where some data are missing. We hope that the process developed here can be refined and applied to new countries rapidly and cost- effectively. The approach requires access to the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) database,7 competence with the General Algebraic Modeling System (GAMS) programming system,8 and with Microsoft Excel. The process does not eliminate the need for local and international exper- tise and judgment, but it can help to speed up the difficult task of SAM deployment. The approach first requires basic data collection from the host country, to be presented as a set of input tables. These tables are then combined, and if necessary, augmented with surro- gate data to generate the SAM for the target economy. This process is described in detail earlier in this chapter. DATA COMPILATION Only a limited number of data tables are required to generate SAMs. We now present these input tables and describe how they are com- bined and adjusted as the dataset is built. We emphasize that these input tables should be straightforward to construct by local experts, and that they are probably best left to these experts because they require an intimate understanding of the local economy and local accounting practices. Data acquisition and organization can be the most time-intensive portion of the process. In the Armenian case, it took several months to construct the input tables, and only a few weeks to combine the tables into a consistent SAM. A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 221 INPUT DATA The required input data are listed below. The data were collected, reviewed several times, and then placed into Excel (XLS) worksheets. We present an enumerated list of the required inputs: 1. Sectoral output (Y0), value-added (VA0), and intermediate demand (ID0). This is basic data that should be supplied by the country for each sector or commodity in the SAM. This input table was provided as a spreadsheet. It has been replicated here as Table 8A.1.2. 2. Sectoral imports (M0) and exports (X0). International trade sta- tistics are almost always available at the highest level of dissa- gregation, and the trade data will usually need to be aggregated to match the sectoral structure in the SAM. Aggregating trade values is simple, but aggregating the corresponding tariff rates is more difficult. For this SAM, we used a trade-weighted average of import tariffs. The tariff was weighted by the relative share of each sub-sector during the aggregation. Bach and Martin (2001) show that the trade-weighted average tariffs will under-estimate the true tariff-equivalent in a CGE model. They do not, how- ever, develop a useful alternative measure for the applied CGE modeler. Thus, the trade values are included together with other sectoral data into Input Table #1. The tariff values are included separately, in Table 8A.1.3. 3. Collected taxes. Collections, by sector of each type of tax in the economy. At a minimum, this would include import duties, labor taxes, payroll taxes, value-added taxes, and excise taxes. Vari- ous intermediate taxes, production levies, and corporate taxes may be available. Most importantly, these taxes should be sup- plied by sector as well as tax stream. This is also provided in spreadsheet format, but has been included in this report as Table 8A.1.3. 4. Intermediate input coefficients. Armenia does not have an IO table, so the IO coefficients were constructed using representa- tive values taken from the GTAP database. Poland was used for the surrogate data. Despite the Armenian conventional wisdom, we have found in a previous study that tax-policy results are not highly sensitive to IO coefficients, and that another (similar) country's production technology could be used. 5. Value-added shares. Like the IO coefficients, these values were only partially available for Armenia. We utilized local data where possible, then filled in the gaps using the GTAP database. 222 Part II: Detailed Analysis 6. Consumption shares. Government expenditures are almost always available, but they are listed by functionary stream, not by production sector. Investment demand by firms, households, and the government also lacked specific sectoral detail. House- hold demand can be computed as the residual demand after government, investment, and exports, but it is useful to consider final demand shares from different economies as a comparison. 7. Macroeconomic and financial totals. Net public and private investment, borrowing, net trade positions, international remit- tances, and other financial transactions are not crucial when con- structing a CGE model, but accountants and politicians tend to focus upon these figures. Therefore, it is best to include them in the aggregate SAM for completeness. In our case, the financial transactions and institutional transfers are found in the Macro SAM presented as Table 8.1. This Annex includes five input tables for the SAM, plus two addi- tional tables required to construct the multiple-household SAM. Input tables #1 to #4 are presented in this section of the Annex. Input Table #5, the macro SAM, is listed at the beginning of the report, as Input Table 8.1. Input tables #6 and #7 are also printed in the main body of the chapter. They are Tables 8.9 and 8.10, respectively. These tables are also included in the distribution archive as Excel spreadsheets. The data-flow process is depicted using a flow chart in Figure 8A.1. This chart shows how each of the data tables is used to generate either the micro or HH SAM. ECONOMIC VARIABLES AND THEIR CONSTRUCTION Since the SAM will be used as the basis for economic research, we may as well begin considering the data using economic terminology. Identifying these data in economic terms will help to streamline the data-automation process later. During the build process, these variables are assigned to each account in the input data, then combined to build the SAM. The construction process in which these variables are used is described next. ACCOUNTING IDENTITIES In order for the overall SAM to be balanced, we must impose a basic set of accounting identities. These identities must hold across all of the input tables before construction of the SAM. It is the responsibil- ity of the local expert to ensure that the input tables conform to the accounting identities presented in this section. A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 223 Table 8A.1.1 Input Tables Required for the Structured Approach to SAM Development Table Description Table #1 Sectoral production and trade values for Armenia (Table 2A.1.2) Table #2 Collected taxes by sector and tax stream (Table 2A.1.3) Table #3 Surrogate IO table for Armenia (Poland) (Table 2A.1.4) Table #4 Sectoral value-added and consumption shares (Table 2A.1.5) Table #5 Aggregate social accounts for Armenia (Table 2.1) Additional household tables Table #6 Expenditures for each household and each commodity (Table 8.10) Table #7 Incomes for each household, by factor and transfer type (Table 8.9) Figure 8A.1 Simplified Structure of SAM Development Process Macro-SAM Output Taxes IO Table recalib.gms sam.gms Micro-SAM HH-CONS HH-expend ReadHH.gms HHsam.gms HH-SAM Source: Author. Note: Three social accounting matrices are generated in this process: macro-SAM, micro-SAM, and HH-SAM. The input data enters at one of two points in the process, either before or after the micro-SAM is built. Four main GAMS (.gms) programs are used to combine the data in each table and accommodate the various discrepancies between each data source. 224 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 8A.1.2 Input Table #1: Sectoral Production and Trade Values for Armenia, 2002 (US$ million) Sector Y0 VA0 ID0 M0 X0 D0 GRN 156 103 53 51 0 156 VFR 144 126 18 24 6 138 VOL 1 1 1 18 0 1 OCR 102 84 18 20 5 97 MIL 346 168 178 7 1 346 OMT 155 67 88 23 0 155 MIN 58 39 19 1 42 16 ENR 0 0 0 165 0 0 FOD 406 158 248 47 51 355 TBC 48 14 34 30 4 44 LMF 42 5 37 42 30 13 MNM 268 41 228 214 259 9 CRP 35 10 25 85 8 27 MTL 104 43 61 56 45 59 MCH 64 6 58 164 56 7 OMF 42 18 25 49 5 37 ELE 170 108 62 6 13 157 UTL 146 109 37 0 0 146 CON 516 298 218 3 6 510 TRN 247 144 103 24 82 165 TRD 432 266 166 0 0 432 DWE 91 66 25 0 0 91 BNK 49 36 13 11 7 42 OSR 85 24 61 61 71 14 GOV 362 211 150 8 8 354 TOTAL 4,070 2,145 1,924 1,107 699 3,371 Source: Author's calculations based upon NSS statistics. Y0: Total production for Armenian sectors VA0: Total value-added in production by sector ID0: Total intermediate demand by sector M0: CIF import value by sector X0: FOB export value by sector D0: Armenian production that is sold to the domestic market: by definition, D0 = Y0 ­ X0 Descriptions for each sector listed in this table can be found in Table 8.4. A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 225 Table 8A.1.3 Input Table #2: 2002 Collected Taxes by Sector and Tax Stream VAT collections (US$ million) Other tax collections (US$ million) Sector VATP VATS VATM VATD TXS TM TL TK TSS ENR 0 0 22.11 31.75 28.07 0 0 0 0 81.9 OMF 6.84 0 2.11 3.86 0 0.88 1.23 2.46 2.67 17.4 FOD 0 0 8.42 9.12 1 2.98 1.58 1.58 3.44 33.7 TBC 3.33 0 2.81 0.18 24.04 1.58 0.18 1.23 0.38 33.3 MCH 0 0 14.74 1.58 0 3.51 0.18 0.35 0.38 20.4 TRD 3.33 2.81 0 1.93 0 0 2.63 1.75 5.73 12.5 CRP 0 0 9.30 1.58 0 0.53 0.18 0.35 0.38 11.9 TRN 1.58 0.53 0 1.93 0 0 2.11 3.68 4.59 9.8 GRN 0 0 9.47 0 0 0 0 0 0 9.5 OMT 0 0 4.21 0 0 1.93 0.18 2.11 0.38 8.4 UTL 0.70 0 0 3.86 0 1.05 8.25 0 2.29 13.9 LMF 0 0 3.86 0.88 0 1.40 0.18 0.53 0.38 6.8 CON 0 0 0 2.28 0 0 1.40 2.81 3.06 6.5 MNM 0 0 2.81 1.40 0 1.23 0.18 0.70 0.38 6.3 MIN 0 0 0.18 2.28 0 0 0.18 3.16 0.38 5.8 GOV 0 0 0 0 0 0 5.79 0 12.61 5.8 VOL 0 0 3.86 0 0 1.75 0 0 0 5.6 MTL 0 0 1.58 1.93 0 0 0.53 0.18 1.15 4.2 OCR 0 0 2.11 0 0 0.53 0 0 0 2.6 DWE 0 0 0 0 0 0 1.93 0.53 4.20 2.5 MIL 0 0 1.40 0 0 0.35 0.18 0.18 0.38 2.1 BNK 0 0 0 0 0 0 1.40 0.70 3.06 2.1 VFR 0 0 1.05 0 0 0.35 0 0 0 1.4 SOC 0 0.53 0 0 0 0 0.88 0 1.91 1.4 TOTAL 16 4 90 65 62 17 22 31 48 353.6 Source: Authors' calculations based upon Ministry of Finance statistics. Definitions: Presumptive (VATP): VAT revenues collected via the presumptive tax legislation Simplified (VATS): VAT revenues collected via the simplified tax legislation Customs (VATM): VAT revenues collected at the Armenian border by customs authorities Domestic (VATD): VAT revenues collected via the traditional VAT system Tariffs (TM): Tariff revenues collected at the Armenian border Income (TL): Income tax revenues from individuals filing and from paycheck withholdings Profits (TK): Corporate profits tax revenues Payroll (TSS): Social security and other earmarked taxes applied to labor income Table 8A.1.4 Input Table #3: Production Technology Structure for Armenia (%) 226 Sector OCR OMT VOL MIL CRP ELE OMF TRD DWE GRN VFR ENR MIN FOD TBC LMF MNM MTL MCH UTL CON TRN BNK GOV OSR OCR 30.4 19.8 2.9 17.6 0.1 -- 7.2 0.7 -- 0.9 3.2 -- -- 8.9 14.9 0.4 -- 0.1 0.0 -- 0.0 -- -- 0.3 0.0 Part OMT 6.1 1.8 18.5 2.0 -- -- -- 0.7 -- 10.5 3.3 -- 0.3 19.7 0.7 0.0 -- -- -- -- -- -- -- 0.4 -- VOL -- 7.0 50.0 4.4 0.1 -- -- 0.4 -- -- 0.4 -- -- 2.5 0.6 0.0 -- -- -- -- -- -- -- 0.2 0.0 II: MIL 3.0 7.7 0.6 29.4 0.1 -- -- 2.7 -- 5.7 1.6 -- -- 0.3 0.3 0.1 -- -- 0.0 -- -- -- -- 3.4 0.2 Detailed CRP 6.0 4.6 7.4 8.0 45.6 0.6 6.8 8.1 -- 27.5 13.3 9.6 1.5 4.3 3.5 12.4 14.6 9.8 9.8 1.5 6.5 5.2 0.5 4.5 3.5 ELE 1.3 2.2 0.8 2.1 4.6 37.1 2.5 0.9 -- 2.5 3.3 -- 10.8 1.0 0.7 1.8 5.9 6.9 1.4 5.7 0.3 0.9 1.5 -- 5.4 OMF 14.1 1.6 2.4 4.7 6.9 2.4 41.0 6.2 -- 8.3 23.0 4.4 1.6 2.9 5.6 1.9 5.4 4.9 1.6 0.9 6.0 7.2 6.4 4.7 8.0 TRD 4.6 2.4 1.2 2.3 4.0 1.1 3.0 29.1 -- 4.2 5.3 5.8 2.0 2.0 2.7 2.0 4.4 2.1 5.5 2.4 7.3 13.3 24.3 16.7 10.4 Analysis DWE -- -- -- -- -- -- -- 0.0 -- -- -- -- -- -- -- -- -- -- -- -- 0.0 0.0 -- 0.0 0.0 GRN 0.0 29.8 0.1 6.1 -- -- -- 0.7 -- 15.5 0.0 -- -- 6.3 8.0 0.0 -- -- -- -- -- -- -- 0.5 -- VFR -- 0.1 0.5 0.2 0.1 -- -- 2.2 -- -- 7.7 -- -- 7.4 0.8 0.0 -- -- -- -- -- -- -- 0.9 -- ENR 2.0 0.2 -- 0.0 3.6 51.7 18.1 -- -- -- 9.8 -- 1.6 0.4 0.3 0.5 6.5 3.2 0.2 15.0 0.2 -- -- 0.4 0.7 MIN 0.4 -- 0.3 0.1 0.5 -- 0.1 0.1 -- 0.6 1.5 1.1 68.3 0.0 -- 0.1 2.2 15.0 0.0 -- 1.3 0.1 -- 0.3 0.6 FOD 0.6 12.0 5.6 5.0 0.4 -- 0.1 7.1 -- -- -- -- -- 34.4 23.6 1.5 -- -- -- -- -- 0.1 0.3 3.5 0.7 TBC 0.1 -- 0.3 0.1 0.1 -- -- 0.8 -- -- -- -- -- 0.3 20.0 -- -- -- -- -- -- 0.1 0.4 0.4 0.7 LMF 1.4 0.6 0.3 1.9 4.6 -- 3.3 4.2 -- 0.1 2.3 3.1 -- 0.5 1.6 64.5 2.4 0.5 0.9 0.1 1.0 1.4 0.1 4.9 1.4 MNM 3.8 0.2 0.0 0.4 1.0 -- 1.0 0.9 -- 1.2 3.4 1.1 0.8 0.5 1.9 0.4 26.0 2.4 0.8 1.0 20.0 0.6 0.1 1.3 3.5 MTL 6.5 1.1 0.3 2.2 1.8 0.2 4.0 5.9 -- 1.2 4.3 15.7 1.2 0.5 1.1 0.5 6.2 40.3 16.8 6.3 11.8 2.0 -- 1.0 2.0 MCH 9.4 3.4 5.0 4.9 2.1 2.3 2.4 7.1 -- 10.2 2.8 34.5 4.2 2.0 2.2 1.7 8.1 5.8 53.2 2.0 10.5 18.2 2.4 6.5 6.9 UTL 0.3 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.2 -- 0.2 1.5 0.4 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 57.1 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.7 1.1 CON 1.3 0.8 0.1 0.7 2.6 0.9 ­0.5 1.5 100 2.4 1.0 7.3 0.7 0.3 0.6 0.4 1.7 1.2 0.7 2.8 21.6 1.7 -- 20.2 5.4 TRN 4.8 1.7 1.3 2.4 5.8 1.7 4.3 8.6 -- 3.1 4.0 4.8 5.6 2.8 2.7 2.2 8.1 2.9 2.7 1.7 5.2 38.7 11.0 8.1 6.1 BNK 0.8 0.4 0.8 1.3 1.1 0.4 1.9 1.2 -- 1.0 1.4 -- 0.2 1.2 2.9 3.5 2.4 1.2 1.6 0.4 0.6 1.1 34.5 1.8 0.6 GOV 0.4 0.6 -- 0.7 0.7 0.1 0.2 1.1 -- 0.2 0.7 1.3 -- 0.2 0.4 0.5 0.3 0.1 0.4 1.0 0.3 0.6 3.4 6.7 1.3 OSR 2.7 1.7 1.4 3.1 13.7 1.5 3.4 9.5 -- 4.6 6.2 10.9 1.1 1.6 4.7 5.4 5.8 3.5 3.9 2.1 7.2 8.7 14.8 12.7 41.5 TOTAL 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 Source: Authors' calculations based upon GTAP dataset. Note: This table displays the production technology for a surrogate country (Poland) that constitutes the starting point for Armenia's assumed production technology. The final IO shares differ substantially for some sectors (such as the cut-jewels sector) based upon local knowledge. Other changes are required in order to satisfy the basic accounting identities listed below. -- Not available. A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 227 Table 8A.1.5 Input Table #4: Value Added and Consumption Shares (%) Sector LAB SKL CAP LND Total C G I Total OCR 43.2 1.5 28.1 27.1 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 OMT 52.3 0.7 11.9 35.1 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 VOL 61.6 10.4 19.4 8.6 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 MIL 52.8 2.6 21.3 23.3 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 CRP 41.3 10.6 48.1 0.0 100 80.9 19.1 0.0 100 ELE 32.4 13.6 54.0 0.0 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 OMF 34.8 5.2 60.0 0.0 100 82.5 0.0 17.5 100 TRD 20.8 3.4 75.8 0.0 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 DWE 0.0 0.0 100 0.0 100 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 CGD 0.0 0.0 100 0.0 100 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 GRN 52.2 0.8 12.0 35.0 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 VFR 52.2 0.8 12.0 35.0 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 ENR 51.3 3.7 4.4 40.6 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 MIN 33.6 4.9 47.9 13.5 100 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 FOD 54.0 9.9 35.1 1.0 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 TBC 44.0 6.4 49.6 0.0 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 LMF 57.8 8.4 33.8 0.0 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 MNM 52.0 8.3 39.7 0.0 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 MTL 58.4 9.5 32.1 0.0 100 28.8 0.0 71.2 100 MCH 45.0 11.9 43.2 0.0 100 31.8 0.0 68.2 100 UTL 21.3 8.7 70.0 0.0 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 CON 35.4 5.5 59.2 0.0 100 14.5 0.0 85.5 100 TRN 44.4 9.9 45.7 0.0 100 98.3 1.7 0.0 100 BNK 36.1 32.0 32.0 0.0 100 100 0.0 0.0 100 GOV 33.6 53.4 13.0 0.0 100 15.8 84.2 0.0 100 OSR 15.0 13.3 71.7 0.0 100 73.8 11.5 14.7 100 Source: Authors' calculations from NSS and GTAP database. Notes: LAB: Unskilled labor SKL: Skilled labor CAP: Capital LND: Land rents C: Final demand by households G: Government demand I: Investment demand 228 Part Table 8A.1.6 Symbol Table II: Symbol Description File location Detailed Yi Total output supply. Source: NSS National Accounts, subtables from the IMF Statistical Annex Armenia.xls (2002), and the Agriculture subtable. Xi, Mi Imports and exports of goods and services. Provided for 2002 by the customs authorities and Armenia.xls Analysis the NSS. Each traded good was mapped onto the model sectors. Di Domestic supply. This is an imputed parameter that depends upon the values for Yi and Xi. n.a. Ai Armington aggregate supply. Ai represents the total supply for a good in Armenia. It is a n.a. computed parameter, which combines Di and Mi, net of import and value-added levies applied at the border and domestically. Although this value is not incorporated directly into the SAM, it is a common input for CGE models. IDji Intermediate demand. Aggregate values for intermediate demand are provided in the National Armenia.xls; Accounts data. But individual input coefficients are taken from a surrogate IO table. This IO GTAP database table is reproduced for the reader in Table 2A.4. Li, Ki Labor and capital demand for production in sector i. Total value added is provided in the Armenia.xls; National Accounts, but the share of labor, capital, land, and indirect taxes is not provided by GTAP database the NSS. These values are based upon the surrogate IO tables from the GTAP database. The capital intensity can be an important determinant of labor/capital returns and should be reviewed more carefully by experts in Armenia. Table 8A.1.6 (continued) Symbol Description File location fi Factor endowments. Factor endowments for labor, capital, and land are computed from total n.a. demand by firms and government. Total sales of labor and capital are then allocated to households based upon the 2002 household consumption and income survey. A data discrepancy exists between official wage statistics and the official value added statistics. Although total value added is reported to be more than US$2,100 million, officially reported wages are only (approximately) US$600 million, A which implies that labor's share in value added is less than 30 percent of total value added. The Social typical labor share in value added is closer to 70 percent. Gi Government demand for good i. These values are based upon the GTAP surrogate dataset, GTAP database Accounting but can be reconciled also by reports by the Armenian Ministry of Finance. INVi Investment demand for good i. Taken from the surrogate dataset from GTAP. World Bank LDB; Armenia.xls FDi Final demand for good i. Computed as a residual based upon total supply and total demand. World Bank LDB; Matrix Total final demand should be compared with the surrogate data, as well as with Armenian Armenia.xls household surveys. This task is forthcoming in a future study. ti Direct and indirect taxes. Tax rates are computed as the ratio of collections to tax base. For example, Armenia.xls for applied import tariffs for good i equal duties for good i, divided by imports for good i: ti M = TM0i Armenia . M0i Note: Each symbol is listed together with a brief description and file location. n.a. Not applicable. 229 230 Part II: Detailed Analysis The accounting behind any SAM reflects the basic economics of pro- ducer competition, market equilibrium, and resource exhaustion. For pro- ducers, the output (sales) value must be at least as large as the combined input cost; and when the sales value exceeds input costs, this excess is often attributed to undocumented or unreported costs, such as the return to capital or depreciation. The supply of goods must be sufficient to sat- isfy total demand. Total supply for a commodity is reported as the col- umn total, and demand for a commodity is reported in the correspond- ing row total. A difference in these totals indicates a market imbalance. Finally, households in the economy earn money either by selling factors or through government and foreign transfers. The government collects revenue by levying taxes. Each agent's income must be sufficient to cover the purchases for that year. If there is an imbalance, this value is attrib- uted to either savings or borrowing. In all three situations, the data are considered to have been the result of optimizing economic agents. These basic conditions are understood more clearly if we present a handful of accounting identities related to individual SAM accounts. First, we take the set I to represent individual production sectors in the model and the corresponding output commodity.9 For example, I is the set {GRN, MIN, FOD, etc...}. We define the following conditions for producer profits and market equilibrium:10 The total sales value must equal the total cost of production: Yi = IDji + Li + Ki + Ti (8A.1.1) j Total output or sales for good i (Yi), at producer prices, must be large enough to cover the cost of production. This includes the purchase of intermediate inputs (IDji), value added (Li, Ki), and taxes (Ti). Total supply must equal demand for all commodity markets: Yi + Mi IDij + Gi + FDi + INVi + Xi (8A.1.2) j where total supply in this framework equals total output (Yi) plus imports (Mi) and demand comprise intermediate demand by firms (IDij), government demand (Gi), final consumer demand (FDi), invest- ment demand (INVi), and demand by the rest of the world (Xi). The same condition holds for factor markets. Supply of labor and capital must be sufficient to satisfy producer demand: Lh Di L (8A.1.3) h i Kh Di K (8A.1.4) h i where Lh is each household (h)'s endowment (or supply) of labor, and Kh is each household's capital endowment, and Di is the demand for L labor by sector i. So, total factor supply equals factor demand. A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 231 DATA MAPPING An inevitable, and unenviable, task is to map various sector types between each other. A mapping that aggregates many sectors onto a single sector is fairly easy. Values are added together and relabeled. A mapping that disaggregates a single sector into many smaller sectors is much more difficult. Additional information must be uncovered from a separate source in order to generate a useful disaggregation. This disaggregation problem was encountered with the Armenia data when mapping the industry megasector into several smaller indus- trial units. We used output shares within production to identify each subsector's production, but the relative share of intermediate inputs, labor inputs, and capital inputs were not available, so each subsec- tor uses an equivalent split between intermediate inputs and value added. Of course, we know these are different. The sector mappings between the NSS National Accounts, GTAP, and the 2002 Armenian Household Survey are described in this section. Soviet Accounts to National Accounts As of 2004, the NSS has been preparing to develop a system of national accounts based on the United Nations' International Stand- ard Industrial Classification (ISIC). Unfortunately, the 2002 statistics still rely upon the old Soviet-style system of accounts. In the old-style accounts, industry is listed as a single activity, which comprises one- third of total GDP. At the same time, small and meaningless sectors are included, like geology, which represents less than 1 percent of GDP, and has no clear corresponding economic sector. Table 8A.1.8 presents a mapping that we chose between the NSS GDP accounts and the sectors which are believed to be representative of Armenia's economy. Where possible, the percentage breakdown is shown next to the sector abbreviation. We aggregate and disaggre- gate the data in both directions. Industrial activity is disaggregated into several smaller activities, while health, education, and science are combined into a single sector, GOV. This mapping is available elec- tronically as part of the Armenian SAM distribution. The spreadsheet is named mapping.xls. GTAP Database to Armenian Industries In order to use the GTAP surrogate IO data together with the Armenian NSS data and outside data, we are required to map GTAP codes onto each 2002 Armenian SAM sector. Table 8A.1.7 presents this mapping. The left-hand column contains the three-letter Armenian code, the center 232 Part II: Detailed Analysis column is the GTAP Version 5 code, and the right-hand column is a short description of the GTAP sector being aggregated. The interested reader can further identify GTAP's sectoral classification, and a mapping between GTAP and the ISIC (International Standard Industrial Classifi- cation) accounts, on the GTAP Web site (http://www.gtap.org/). Table 8A.1.7 Mapping GTAP V5 Sectors onto 2002 Armenian SAM Sectors Armenian SAM GTAP GTAP description GRN PDR Paddy rice WHT Wheat GRO Cereal grains nec VFR V_F Vegetables, fruit, nuts VOL OSD Oil seeds VOL Vegetable oils and fats OCR CB Sugar cane, sugar beet PFB Plant-based fibers OCR Crops nec FRS Forestry SGR Sugar OMT CTL Bo horses OAP Animal products nec MIL RMK Raw milk MIL Dairy products FOD FSH Fishing CMT Bo meat products OMT Meat products PCR Processed rice OFD Food products nec TBC B_T Beverages and tobacco products ENR COL Coal OIL Oil GAS Gas MIN OMN Minerals nec LMF WOL Wool, silk-worm cocoons TEX Textiles WAP Wearing apparel LEA Leather products OMF LUM Wood products PPP Paper products, publishing P_C Petroleum, coal products OMF Manufactures nec CRP CRP Chemical, rubber, plastic products MNM NMM Mineral products nec MTL I_S Ferrous metals NFM Metals nec FMP Metal products A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 233 Table 8A.1.7 (continued) Armenian SAM GTAP GTAP description MCH MVH Motor vehicles and parts OTN Transport equipment nec ELE Electronic equipment OME Machinery and equipment nec ELE ELY Electricity UTL GDT Gas manufacture, distribution WTR Water CON CNS Construction TRD TRD Trade TRN OTP Transport nec WTP Water transport ATP Air transport CMN Communications BNK OFI Financial services nec ISR Insurance OSR OBS Business services nec ROS Recreational and other services GOV OSG Public administration, defense, education, health DWE DWE Ownership of dwellings Source: Armenia SAM. SURVEY CONSUMPTION CATEGORIES TO NATIONAL ACCOUNTS INDUSTRIES AND FACTORS Similar to the industrial and income classifications, we mapped house- hold consumption categories from the 2002 Armenian Household Sur- vey onto the 2002 Armenian SAM sectors. There are 480 consumption categories distinguished in the Household Survey--most of the food items. Table 8A.1.9 presents an excerpt of this mapping. MATRIX BALANCING In order to finish with a balanced set of national accounts, several balancing routines were applied to the data at various points in the construction process. This subsection describes where the balancing was applied and why. Manual Approach Our first approach is to review the input data and consider why cer- tain accounts do not balance. As we review each account discrepancy, 234 Part II: Detailed Analysis we often find that the largest imbalances are caused by errors in data translation or errors in data mapping. When the data are translated properly, or are mapped more tightly to the true meaning of the eco- nomic activity, many of the larger errors do not require mechanical adjustments. This has been the case for some accounts in Armenia. For example, this country has traditionally been a major center for cut diamonds. Uncut and cut gems are the single largest import and export items for Armenia. Two issues arose while generating the national accounts for precious gems. First, the national accounts were inconsistent. Total exports were US$259 million, and imports were US$214 million; but the NSS also reported that domestic production was only US$9 mil- lion, when the accounting identity implies that it is at least US$45 mil- lion. The second issue comes from the surrogate IO table. The precious stones sector is aggregated together with other mining and minerals in the GTAP database, which is the source of the IO table. Thus, the production shares for this sector did not reflect the fact that in Arme- nia more than 90 percent of intermediate demand is own-use (uncut gems). The IO table was manually adjusted to reflect expert opinion related to the jewelry industry there. Other accounts were adjusted using the least-squares methodology. The main point of this exposition is to demonstrate that "SAM balancing" cannot be a completely automatic process. As described in Round (2003, p. 174), . . . Data reconciliation methods were not as arbitrary as it might at first seem. There were essentially three steps involved in the judgement approach. First, the initial data were set alongside each other in the accounting framework to take initial stock of the problem. Secondly, a qualitative judgement was taken on the relative reliability of the alternative estimates, relying on expert local advice. Thirdly, after choosing the most reliable estimates, further scaling and adjustments were made manually to achieve consistency The same three steps are taken here, except that the third step can now be achieved using a computer. Mechanical Approach After some work using the manual approach, the remaining loose ends (and there are plenty) are balanced using a least-squares approach. Most of the new imbalances arise as we disaggregate intermediate demand (ID0ij), final demand (C0j), government demand (g0j), and A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 235 factor incomes (VA0Fj). After disaggregation from the macro SAM, we face the problem that some (if not all) of the basic accounting identi- ties above no longer hold, as they did for the aggregate SAM. In the least-squares approach, ID0ij, C0j, and D0j are adjusted in order to satisfy the producer competition (zero profits) and market equilibrium (supply-demand) equations. Later in the build process, we enforce the income-expenditure identities for each household decile. We describe the first problem, balancing supply and demand, first. The market-balance problem is defined in the recalibration routine as follows: min i 0 1 2 0 1 0 (8A.1.5) , j(IDi, j- IDi, j)2 + i Di - Di ( ) + i Ci - Ci ( ) 2 10 such that Mi + Di = j IDi 0 (8A.1.6) , j+ Ci + Gi + Ii 0 0 Di + Xi = j IDj 0 ,i + l L0l ,i + k Kk,i + ti 0 0 This minimization problem chooses values for ID, D, and C with zero-profit and market-balance conditions as constraints. We have applied different weights to each choice variable. The choice of weights in the objective function is somewhat arbitrary. In this prob- lem, consumption and domestic supply are weighted less heavily, so that changes in these values do not penalize the objective function as much as changes to ID. In sam.gms, another least-squares rebalancing problem is solved. Instead of squaring the absolute difference between input variables, in sam.gms we chose to square the percentage difference between input variables. For example, government consumption is adjusted accord- ing to this penalty function: Gi - 1 Gi 2 (8A.1.7) 0 i The SAM-balancing problem in sam.gms includes all of the social accounts, including taxes, international trade and savings, and gov- ernment collections and expenditures. Remaining imbalances in any account are corrected here. Finally, the household income and expenditures are fit to macro data, also by using a mechanical balancing approach. In the GAMS program file, readhh.gms, we separately fit income to aggregate factor income and transfers, and we fit expenditures to total net-domestic supply. In each case, we adjust the percentage difference between the final variables and the target values.11 236 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 8A.1.8 Mapping of Armenian Output Statistics to SAM Sectors Total production (Y0) Armenian sector (million dram) SAM sectors (%) Industry 611,879 FOD (35.7) TBC (3.1) CRP (2.3) MNM (9.2) MCH (1.2) OMF (1.3) MIN (9.8) UTL (24.4) Agriculture 522,634 GRN (18.7) VFR (23) VOL (0.2) OCR (15.4) MIL (30.6) OMT (12.2) Forestry 942 OCR (100) Construction 297,088 CON (100) Transport & communication 142,670 TRN (100) Retail trade & catering 233,889 TRD (100) Public procurements 8,576 GOV (100) Spare parts 1,526 TRD (100) Information & tech. srvcs 1,288 OSR (100) Real estate transactions 4,914 OSR (100) General commerce 5,295 TRD (100) Geology 417 MIN (100) Other branches 3,300 OSR (100) Housing 52,471 DWE (100) Utility sector 84,605 UTL ELE Health, sport 68,277 GOV (100) Education 52,541 GOV (100) Culture 9,630 OSR (100) Science 6,988 GOV (100) Lending 26,748 BNK (100) Insurance 1,485 BNK (100) Governance and defense 71,791 GOV (100) NGOs 10,645 GOV (100) Financial intermediaries 0.0 (Not Included) Source: Armenia SAM. Note: This mapping is available as an Excel spreadsheet, included as part of the distribution archive: mapping.xls. Industrial shares were apportioned based on IMF statistics. A full listing of the IMF industrial shares is available in the program distribution: Armenia SAM. Agriculture shares were apportioned according to the Armenian national accounts, provided by the NSS, and relisted in the SAM distribution file as: Armenia agriculture 2002.xls. A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 237 Table 8A.1.9 Mapping GTAP V5 Sectors onto 2002 Armenian SAM Sectors (continued) SAM code Survey code Survey description MIL 10408 Cheese of cow milk (chanack, lory, other) MIL 10409 Homemade cheese, cow milk MIL 10410 Gruyere and Dutch cheeses MIL 10411 Cream cheese MIL 10412 Ice cream MIL 10499 Other milk products MIL 10501 Eggs MIL 10502 Dry eggs MIL 10601 Butter MIL 10602 Melted butter MIL 10603 Margarine VOL 10604 Sunflower oil VOL 10605 Olive oil VOL 10606 Other vegetable oils VOL 10699 All sorts of oil and animal fat VFR 10701 Apples . . . CRP 20502 Laundry detergent CRP 20503 Laundry whitening CRP 20504 Other laundry goods CRP 20599 Other cleaning materials OMF 20601 Linoleum OMF 20602 Pile OMF 20603 Wallpaper OMF 20605 Basin OMF 20606 Toilet CON 20607 Cement OMF 20609 Oil-based paint Source: Armenian Living Standards Measurement Survey (LSMS). THE BUILD DISTRIBUTION The main text describes the SAM development process, but the actual program files used to generate the dataset can appear completely differ- ent. This section of the Annex steps the reader through the program files and describes how they are combined to build a complete SAM. The SAM is based solely upon the input data files provided by the local experts. There are places in the process, however, that require manual adjustment techniques. These manual adjustments are difficult to avoid, and they are different for each country. For this reason, it is unlikely that readers will be able simply to drop in new input files and 238 Part II: Detailed Analysis mappings for their own country and expect a reasonable, balanced SAM to materialize. This distribution offers a structured approach to the thought process while constructing the SAM, but it is not a sub- stitute for careful consideration of a given country's economy. First we list the contents of the distribution file: Armenia SAM. zip:12 | run.bat | +---build | | aggr.gms | | Armenia.xls | | buildsam.gms | | extract.zip | | recalib.gms | | setup.bat | | shares.gms | | soedata.gms | | tables.gms | | | \---data | arm25.map | gtap001.set | POL.GDX | +---sam | Armenia_hh_2002.xls | hhsam.gms | printxls.gms | readhh.gms | sam.gms | \---SourceData 2002_GDP_NSS.xls Armenia_agriculture_2002.xls Export Import data in 2002 Revised.xls IMF-Statistical-Annex(Industry Shares).pdf There are three directories: build, sam, and sourceData. Most of the data management is handled in the build directory, where setup.bat directs the aggregation, mapping, and combination of each of the four input tables. The data is recalibrated using recalib.gms, the main pro- gram in the build directory. Most of the remaining GAMS programs A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 239 are optional; they produce descriptive tables based upon the pre- and post-calibrated data. A subdirectory, data, contains the IO table for Poland and the mapping between GTAP and our 25-sector SAM. Finally, extract.zip contains the necessary files to extract an IO table from the GTAP database. The extraction process requires the entire GTAP database, a 3MB file (gtap001.zip). The programs in the SAM directory write out the micro-SAM and then generate the household SAM. sam.gms is handed data from the build process, re-checks the calibration, then writes the micro-SAM to a comma-delimited file. Then the household dataset, Armenia hh 2002.xls, is read by readhh.gms and combined with the national accounts by hhsam.gms. printxls.gms is the program that "flat- tens" the social accounts into a single, two-dimensional matrix. Finally, a minimal SourceData directory is included. This directory contains spreadsheets that were used to build Input Tables #1 and #2, output, value added, trade, and taxation, for each sector. The most important file is run.bat, the command file. If everything is correctly in place, this file builds and writes the entire social account- ing matrix from scratch. The contents of this file are shown here: cd build call setup pol cd ..\sam call gams sam call gams printxls --dataset=ekasam call gams readhh call gams hhsam rem workbook: : call e:\gams211\xlwrite msam.csv sam.csv hhsam.csv Armenia_2002_SAM.xls if `%1'=='cleanup' goto cleanup cd .. goto end :cleanup del *.lst del *.gdx del msam.txt del *.csv cd .. goto end :end 240 Part II: Detailed Analysis First, we enter the build directory and call the setup.bat subcom- mand file, indicating that we wish to use POL for the surrogate IO table. This extracts Poland's production structure from the GTAP database13 and computes intermediate demand shares, value-added shares, and final consumption shares. The program recalib.gms com- bines the source output and tax data together with the surrogate data to generate most of the micro social accounts. These data are returned in a GAMS data container labeled sam2002.gdx. NOTES 1. This chapter was prepared by Miles K. Light, University of Colorado, and by Ekaterine Vashakmadze and Artsvi Khatchatryan, both at the World Bank. 2. While the model has limitations in many aspects, its simplicity offers certain advantages: (i) its underlying assumptions of fixed prices and fixed technology in an economy with ample underutilized capacity like Armenia are reasonable at present; (ii) the model can be applied for understanding the nature of the backward and forward linkages in the economy; (iii) the simplicity of the model permits both easy tracking of information gaps and easy transfer to the relevant counterparts for technical capacity building. At the same time, at this stage in the data development process, we advise cau- tious use of input-output analysis, since the IO table we currently use is an adjusted surrogate table. 3. Interestingly, the labor/capital intensity is reversed for high-income countries. In the United States, for example, agriculture is a capital-intensive industry and chemical manufacturing is labor-intensive, due to high R&D costs. 4. Note that US$302 million equals the ROW-SUM along the GOV accounts in the macro SAM, minus the transfers from ROW. 5. Figures are taken from Armenia (2003c), p. 116, Table 4. 6. See, for example, Robinson et al. (2001). 7. http://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/. 8. http://www.gams.com/. 9. In this treatment, each producing sector provides only one output good. 10. Table 8A.1.6 contains descriptions for each symbol. 11. The target values are the original household income and expenditure figures based upon the 2002 Armenian Household Survey. 12. This archive is freely available to interested readers. It can be downloaded from the Armenia Project Web site, located here: http://www.mileslight.com/ armenia/. A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia 241 13. This distribution does not include the full GTAP dataset. Instead, we have extracted these data and placed them into the GAMS data container, pol25.gdx. Chapter 9 Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia INTRODUCTION While Armenian economic growth has been robust for the past few years, tax revenue collections have fallen short of expectations.1 Tax revenue as a fraction of GDP has fallen steadily, particularly through reductions in the collection of direct taxes. In total, tax revenues have fallen by more than 2.5 percent of GDP, with 1 percent due to reduc- tions in personal income tax collections and 1.25 percent due to reduc- tions in receipts from the profits tax. While early stages in transition and development may be led by the private sector, sustained development and reductions in poverty require public sector resources. Health, education, and public infra- structure are all essential for sustainable development, and the provi- sion of these goods and services demands an efficient and reliable tax system. There are several recent studies of the Armenian tax system that have evaluated the prospects for tax reform from legal and structural viewpoints.2 The present paper reports results from a CGE model that has been formulated to explore, from a quantitative perspective, the economic consequences of different types of tax reforms in Armenia. We use the model to consider the marginal cost of funds from direct and indirect tax instruments, and we also present a set of scenarios for increasing tax revenue by between 0.5 and 2 percent of GDP. Data discrepancies and omissions make Armenian tax policy analy- sis difficult. Presently, there does not exist a "post-Soviet" IO table or any comprehensive source of economic data for Armenia. In the absence of a consistent set of national economic statistics, our model is based on information from a variety of sources. Sectoral value added, aggregate output shares, trade statistics, and components of final 243 244 Part II: Detailed Analysis demand are based on data from the NSS. Input-output coefficients in our model are based on recent IO tables from 1997 for Hungary and Poland. We use two alternative sources of these coefficients in order to evaluate the robustness of our result. Our findings indicate that the results are not overly sensitive to the choice of production technology. The results are much more sensitive to benchmark tax rates and the elasticities of substitution that characterize trade-offs between formal and informal goods and services. Despite the data limitations inherent in this study, we still believe that policy decisions can be better informed by a roughly parameter- ized model than by the uncalibrated logic of economic theory. For example, the model can be used to assess how collections in tax rev- enue from one tax instrument are affected by changes in other tax rates. These types of assessments are particularly important in view of the high and growing level of informal activity. With some effort on the part of statistical authorities, the input data for our model can be substantially improved; thus we regard the present set of results as preliminary. The general lessons the model is now providing are, however, highly informative. The standard "first- best" rules for taxation (low rates, broad base), which apply in many competitive economies, may be inappropriate in a second-best setting. Armenia clearly represents a second-best economic environment, as is evidenced by the low collection rates of its principal taxes. Revenues from income and profits taxes are reduced by underreporting of both labor and capital income.3 VAT revenues appear to have a somewhat higher rate of compliance, but as of 2002 the relative efficiency of VAT collections is about half that of developed countries. The NSS includes an estimate of informal economic activity as part of the officially tabulated GDP. According to this estimate, one-third of the US$2.9 billion Armenian GDP is produced within the informal sector. Labor and capital income from this sector are omitted from the tax base, and tax collections based on payments within the informal sector are low. Additionally, factor earnings from informal firms can more easily evade VAT and profits taxes, or a portion of them. Several international teams, including the IMF, United States Agency for International Development (USAID), and the World Bank, have assessed the Armenian tax system and made recommendations for tax reform. Although the foci of these analyses all differ, there are some common themes that arise in these studies: The tax revenues in Armenia are low relative to developed coun- tries, and they are low even compared to most CIS countries. The IMF Fiscal Affairs Department reported 2004 tax income to be Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 245 17.7 percent of GDP (IMF 2004). Most alarming is the precipitous fall in tax collections between 1999 and 2003, during which time revenues fell from 20 percent to 17.2 percent of GDP. Most of this decline resulted from the fall in rates of collection for income and profits taxes. Official tax policy in Armenia has conformed to IMF recommen- dations. The VAT has only two rates (20 percent and 0 percent), personal income taxes have only three rates (0 percent, 10 per- cent, and 20 percent), and, where import tariffs exist, the rate is a uniform 10 percent. Tax collection and administration are reported to be weakly enforced. Despite a clear and simple tax code, collections are low. This could imply either weak administration or some forms of corruption, or both. The tax system is perceived to be unfair. Residents in Yerevan do not believe that tax revenues are used for public goods and services. Small taxpayers believe that the rich individuals do not pay their share, while wealthy taxpayers complain that tax audi- tors are unpredictable and punitive.4 As is apparent from a cursory study, the issues that surround tax policy in Armenia are wide ranging. Our analysis of these issues, however, focuses solely on economic welfare and the aggregate burden of tax collection. We implement a CGE model with which to assess the factors that determine how tax revenues respond to changes in tax rates.5 The study is macroeconomic in nature and does not consider individual firms, organizations, or any legal inter- pretation of the tax code. Our model is based on a dual economy in which there coexist formal and informal firms and markets. Firms operating in both the formal and informal sectors are assumed to maximize profits. Prices of goods and factors adjust so that supply equals demand in all markets. Informal activity in our model is calibrated to information regard- ing the level of informality in different sectors. In our central cases we adjust sectoral shares of informal activity to target the NSS estimate that 30 percent of the aggregate Armenian economy is represented by informal activities. Informal production in the model is able to evade taxes for profits wages, and value added. Our analysis demonstrates that rising levels of evasion produce a corresponding increase in the marginal cost of public funds. This implies that the cost-benefit test for publicly funded health, education, and infrastructure investments becomes increasingly more stringent as informality increases. In the present economy, an additional dol- lar of public expenditure costs between US$1.30 and US$1.60. When 246 Part II: Detailed Analysis we account for the long-run response of investment and capital stock to the perverse incentives introduced by the informal sector and the tax system, the marginal cost of funds might easily introduce a 100 percent premium on public expenditure. In view of the crucial role in economic development played by public expenditures and invest- ments, there are potential dire consequences for the long-term health of the Armenian economy if the trend toward increasing levels of informal activity cannot be reversed. Faced with the high efficiency costs of raising revenue, there are limited possibilities for raising significant revenue from any of the tax bases. In the short term, efficiency costs are smaller because capital is fixed and unable to escape, yet raising tax revenue remains costly due to the ability of firms and consumers to substitute untaxed, informal products for formal goods that are subject to tax. In the long-term model, we find that tax policy has costly impacts on capital accumulation and economic growth. The existing profits, income, and value-added taxes all tend to discriminate against investment in formal sectors, and the long-run perspective underscores the need for avoiding further discouragement of investment in these areas. We find that the long-run efficiency cost of taxes on agricultural products is low because existing profits and income taxes tend to discriminate against formal activities in manufacturing and industry. These taxes lead to underinvestment in industry, an effect that is par- tially offset by a tax on agricultural income. As has been pointed out elsewhere, taxes on agricultural activity face administrative difficul- ties because most farmers are small-holders. These farmers would be exempt from income and profits taxes in any case, if revenues and income are low. The marginal cost of public funds from any of the direct and indi- rect tax instruments are increased when a substantial fraction of the tax base is able to avoid payments, or when individuals are more willing to substitute informal goods and services for formal goods and services. These results provide strong support for tax policies that underscore the need to reduce tax evasion and informal activities organized primarily as a means of evading tax payments. The remainder of this chapter is organized as follows. The next section presents the model formulation. The third section presents some stylized facts regarding the economic structure of Armenia as represented in our dataset. The fourth section compares the relative efficiency among each tax stream and goes on to consider some tax proposals presented by the IMF in 2004. A detailed review of how the results are affected by the use of surrogate data sources for pro- duction technology is discussed in the fifth section. The last section provides conclusions. Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 247 A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL FOR ARMENIA Our model represents Armenia as a small open economy with two types of economic activity: formal activities, which are subject to tax, and informal activities, which are untaxed. The model portrays an Arrow-Debreu economy with constant returns-to-scale and perfect competition across all modes of production. As a small, open economy, Armenia faces fixed relative prices for imports and exports. Produc- ers maximize profits taking prices as given, and consumers maximize utility subject to a budget constraint that depends upon the value of their endowments, transfers from the government, and remittances from abroad. These assumptions imply that no producer earns above- normal profits and that consumers cannot increase consumption of all goods simultaneously. These are the basic economic concepts of economic scarcity and competition. Following Mathiesen (1985), we formulate and solve the model as a complementarity problem with three types of equilibrium conditions: market clearance, zero profit, and income balance. Production tech- nology and consumer preferences are characterized using the nested, constant-elasticity of substitution (CES) functional form. The model accommodates analysis of both the static and steady-state welfare effects through alternative representations of the capital stock. The numerical equations are based on data derived from the 2002 Armenian National Accounts together with reports provided by the IMF, USAID, GTAP, and the World Bank. The present version of the model distinguishes 25 industries, the government, and a single, rep- resentative consumer. In each industry, in the reference equilibrium a given share of production is produced informally.6 Economic Flows The relationship between different sectors and consumers in the model is shown in Figure 9.1. Various aspects of the economy are depicted here, with the exception of taxes subsequently. Production in sector i (Yi) combines four primary factors: capital (K), skilled labor (LS), unskilled labor (LU), and land (N). Intermediate inputs are added to produce outputs for the domestic (Di) and export (Ei) markets. An "Armington composite good" (A) is a combination of domestic goods (D) and imports (M). Armington aggregate goods are the basic consumption commodity. They are consumed by industry as an intermediate input and they are also goods for final consumption (C), government consumption (G), and or investment (I). Consumers are endowed with factors of production (LS, LU, K, N), which are sold to industry (Y). They are also the final consumers, who use income 248 Part II: Detailed Analysis from factor sales to purchase Armington goods (C via A), to invest (I), or to create government services (G). For sectors, Yi, appearing in Figure 9.1 there are two associated activities: formal production (Yi ) and informal production (Yi ). The F I formal sector is subject to various taxes (VAT, profits, payroll, and income taxes), whereas the informal sector pays only those taxes col- lected at the border (import tariffs). These activities produce goods that are consumed in final and intermediate demand. A schematic for the formal/informal consumption activity is presented in Figure 9.2. Algebraic Formulation Our model is based on CES functions. CES functions are widely applied because they are globally regular and can be defined by their zeroth, first, and second order properties. This means that the loca- tion (price and quantity), slope (marginal rate of substitution), and curvature (or convexity) completely characterize a CES production or consumption function. This permits a simplified representation of production technology and consumer preferences. Using this general approach, the supply side of the Armenian model is as shown in Figure 9.1. We use to denote the elasticity of substitution for production inputs and to denote the elasticity of transformation for outputs.7 In the model, any choice for elasticities in each sector can be applied in order to reflect local expertise related to particular sectors. Production Functions Production Inputs Goods are produced according to a nested Leontief-Cobb Douglas technology. Intermediate inputs and aggregate value added enter at the top level: Y , vbi Yi = min min xji i j aji , mM . i (9.1) ai In this expression, xji represents intermediate inputs of good j from the domestic market and represents specialized imports for re-export in sector i.8 Value added represents a Cobb-Douglas aggregation of unskilled labor (LU), skilled labor (LS), capital (K), and land (N):9 vi = LUiLSiKi Ni , u s (9.2) in which constant returns to scale imply that F + I + + = 1. Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 249 Figure 9.1 Armenian Production Structure for Formal and Informal Activities C,G,I Ai = 4 Ei Di Mi = 4 Yi = 0 RA = 1 = 0 N K L A1 . . . Aj Source: Authors. Symbol Description: Y Goods production D Production sent to the domestic market A Armington aggregate good--this activity combines domestic production with imports to produce an Armington aggregate good for intermediate use or final demand. E Production which is exported M Imports L Labor inputs--labor is either skilled or unskilled K Capital input N Land inputs I Fixed investment demand. Combines goods from A to produce an investment good. G Government demand. Tax revenues purchase goods from A to produce the government good. C Final consumption demand. Final demand by households. Households sell labor and capital endowments to pay for final consumption. Elasticity of substitution for inputs. Elasticity of transformation for outputs. RA Representative agent. Note: Imports for re-export in the mineral products and precious stones sector have been omitted from this diagram. Production Outputs Each production sector Y produces two types of commodities: domes- tic goods Di and goods for export Ei. These goods are assumed to be imperfect substitutes, and they have a constant elasticity of transfor- mation. An algebraic formulation of this transformation function is written Yi = g(DiEi = i Di ) D 1+1/ 1/(1+1/) , (9.3) 250 Part II: Detailed Analysis where i D is the benchmark value share of domestic sales in total output for sector i, and corresponds to the model input etrndx. Imports The model adopts an Armington representation of the import demand. Armington goods, Ai, are produced by combining domestic goods with imports from the same sector. These goods are treated as imper- fect substitutes (for example, autos from Russia versus autos from Japan), with an Armington elasticity, DM, describing the degree to which these substitute in intermediate and final demand: Ai = i Mi ( M 1-1/DM + 1 - i ( M )D 1-1/DM i )1/(1-1/DM ) . (9.4) Some confusion can arise trying to distinguish between produc- tion, Yi, output (Di, Ei) and the consumption good (Ai). The Arming- ton aggregate good, Ai, combines domestic output, Di, with imports, Mi. Ai is the good used as an intermediate input and also for final demand. Trade Balance The shadow value of foreign exchange, , adjusts to clear the market for foreign exchange, a good which is "produced" with exports and consumed by imports: pi EEi + B = pi (Mi + ai M MYi) . (9.5) i i Holding all else equal, rising import demand will increase , which reflects increased demand for external currency. The exogenous param- eter B denotes a current account balance. Because this is a small, open economy, import and export prices (p¯i , p¯i ) are fixed exogenously. E M Consumption, Investment, and Government Final Consumption A single representative agent (RA) is endowed with primary factors of production: capital, labor, and resources. The RA demands final goods for consumption. Investment and government output also demand final goods, but the level is exogenously specified, while private demand is endogenously determined by utility maximizing behavior. The RA utility function is Cobb-Douglass as shown below: U (Ai = ) Ai i,i = 1 . (9.6) i i Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 251 The RA maximizes utility subject to a budget constraint: maxU (Ai ) Ai s.t. . (9.7) i piAi pK K + pLL + pN N + trn - I + B In this problem, the RA maximizes the utility function subject to a budget constraint. The Armenian budget constraint is equal to the total value of factor endowments (K, L, N), plus any transfers from the government, minus the cost of investment, plus the net current account balance. The current account balance for Armenia reflects substantial cash remittances from abroad, amounting to US$175 million, a substan- tial sum in comparison with US$683 in goods and services exports. Investment In the static formulation, investment demand is held constant at base- year levels. Investments are aggregated into a single, national invest- ment pool, then distributed among production and government sec- tors according to base-year accounts. Investment funds come from households and government. The level of investment can be altered in the steady-state formulation, as is discussed in the next section, "Armenia's Economic Structure." Government Government purchases of goods and services are supported with tax revenue, capital earnings, and net foreign exchange transfers. The model tax system and total tax revenues are described in the next section, "Armenia's Economic Structure." Steady-State Capital A major drawback of tax policy analysis in a static model is that the capital stock is fixed and unresponsive to tax-induced changes in the net rate of return. Logically, the level of investment depends upon depreciation, interest rates, and the rate of return to capital stock. Static CGE models fail to address the changes to investment and capital stock associated with changes in the tax code. We address these issues by including a steady-state model formulation. The steady-state model allows capital and investment to change in response to tax policy in a way that is consistent with a long-run analysis. The long-run equilib- rium condition links the cost of capital with the return to capital: pinv = rK (9.8) 252 Part II: Detailed Analysis This equilibrium condition in the steady-state model is associated with an equilibrating variable, , which represents the level of the capital stock. When the return to capital rises relative to the price of investment, increases to scale up investment and reflect this arbi- trage condition. Thus, in the steady-state equilibrium, adjusts invest- ment so that the cost of capital is consistent with the return to capital. This condition is equivalent to assuming "Tobin's q" is calibrated to unity in the reference equilibrium and returns to that value in the long run. Informal Market Activities We treat informal products as close but imperfect substitutes for formal goods. Consumers and firms thus distinguish between formal and informal products, and choose between these goods on the basis of relative prices. Figure 9.2 shows how formally and informally pro- duced goods are combined to produce a good "X" that is consumed across all types of demand: final demand by consumers, investment, the government, and intermediate demand by firms. x denotes the elasticity of substitution between each good type. In an economy where underground goods or services are qualitatively similar to for- mal products, or where informal activities are commonplace, there would be a high value of x. As will be shown below, as the value of x increases, so too does the cost of public funds. Figure 9.2 Demand for Formal and Informal Goods C,G,I Y X = 4 YF YI TL, TK, VAT, TM, TXS TM Source: Author. Note: Formally produced goods are subject to all official taxes, while informally produced goods prices incorporate only import tariffs. Goods from each type of production are imperfect substitutes in final and intermediate demand. Final demand and intermediate demand within each sector has a different share of informally produced goods. Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 253 Tax Structure Production inputs are subject to five major types of taxes. Final con- sumption is taxed at rate vati. Labor income in the formal economy is taxed at rate tF, and social security taxes are also imposed as a tax on labor income in the formal economy, applied at rate tpyrl. The total tax rate on labor in the formal sector is then tL = tF +tpyrl. Capital earnings in the formal economy are taxed at rate tK, imports pay tariffs at rate tm, and land rents are taxed like capital returns, where a national rate for profits taxes is applied. Differences in VAT, import, or formal/informal tax rates across sectors lead to efficiency costs that are captured in the model. An important segment of the tributary system is the invoice- rebate feature available for the VAT. Under this system, value-added taxes paid for intermediate inputs can be reclaimed by the firm. In theory, the rebate eliminates the tax distortion between intermediate inputs. This distinction is less clear in practice, because the paperwork required for collection is complicated and repayments are unpredict- able. According to a 2004 survey of Armenian companies, both of these difficulties exist. The tax-inclusive cost of production for formally-produced goods is then Ci = pjxji + pL (1 + tL L + (1 + tK ) )(rkKi + riNi ) +pi ai . M m (9.9) j Tax-inclusive revenue value for Y is denoted as Ri: Ri = pi Di + pi X . D X (9.10) In equilibrium, the tax-inclusive cost of production equals output value across all sectors (Ri = Ci), and this represents the zero-profit equilibrium condition. Import tariffs and value added taxes are included in the Armington commodity's unit cost function for formally produced goods: 1/(1-) pi = (1+ vati M )i pi (1 1- + tiM D - M pi 1 . (9.11) M D pi ) + pi The benchmark tax rate applied on formal labor inputs (tL) is based on direct tax payment by households in the SAM and gross payments to formal labor. The benchmark tax rate applied to private capital (tK) is based on the direct tax payments by private firms and the gross payments to capital in all nongovernment sectors. 254 Part II: Detailed Analysis There is perfect arbitrage in factor markets, so there is a wedge between the marginal product of labor, capital, and land in the formal and informal economies. One important aspect of the efficiency cost of taxation therefore corresponds to this difference in productivity. Any policy that leads to an increase in informal activity therefore exacer- bates this inefficiency. ARMENIA'S ECONOMIC STRUCTURE Our base-year statistics come from a variety of sources. We target the model to match official figures provided by the NSS. Although our figures do not match NSS figures to the exact dram or dollar, our benchmark represents a more consistent accounting framework than is provided by the NSS. By combining information from disparate (official) sources, and by adjusting the data to match up with the equilibrium conditions, we have been able to uncover several incon- sistencies in the Armenian national accounts. The Armenian GDP in 2002 was 1.36 trillion Armenian drams. This is equal to US$2.3 billion at a market exchange rate of 573 drams per dollar. According to the CIA's World Factbook for 2003,10 Arme- nia's GDP was US$12.13 billion in 2002, on a purchasing power parity basis. The official population, according to a 2001 Armenian census, is 3.0 million, so that annual GDP per capita in 2002 was US$766 at market exchange rates. Our model represents the economy through 25 sectors of produc- tion, trade, and consumption. The sectoral aggregation was tailored to highlight the most important industries and goods in the coun- try (subject to the availability of data). IO coefficients for the model are drawn from the 1997 IO table for Hungary, which is part of the GTAP5.4 database (Hertel 1997).11 Table 9.1 describes the sectors that are in our model, and Table 9.2 ranks these sectors by output.12 Since 1997, Armenia has enjoyed strong economic growth: over the period 2000­03, the economy grew at an annual rate of 12 percent, and inflation has remained low. Most SMEs are privatized, and the antiquated energy system inherited from the Soviet era has been mod- ernized. The country's nuclear power station, Metsamor, produces sufficient electricity, so that Armenia is now a net electricity exporter. Armenia still depends upon imported oil and natural gas, all of which comes from Iran as a result of the conflict with the energy-rich neigh- boring state of Azerbaijan. Armenia maintains a large trade deficit which has been offset by remittances, international aid, and FDI. Eco- nomic ties with Russia remain close, especially in the energy sector. Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 255 Table 9.1 Economic Sectors in the Armenian Model Code Description Y0 (US$ million) Agriculture GRN Wheat, potatoes, legumes 170.7 VFR Vegetables, fruits, grapes 209.3 VOL Vegetable oils and fats 1.4 MIL Dairy products 279.2 OMT Beef, pork, poultry 110.9 OCR Other crops 140.1 Industry ENR Energy: oil and natural gas 0 MIN Mining and quarrying 95.0 FOD Food processing & beverages 381.0 TBC Tobacco products 33.1 LMF Light manufacturing and textiles 65.7 MTL Metals and metal products 121.2 CRP Chemicals, rubbers, and plastics 105.2 MNM Mineral products and precious stones 311.7 MCH Equipment, motor vehicles, and optical 119.9 OMF Other manufacturing 77.6 UTL Electricity, gas, and water supply 146.5 Services and other CON Construction 519.8 TRD Retail & wholesale trade, catering 434.8 GOV Governance, defense, and public expenditures 364.8 TRN Transport and communications 248.9 OSR Other services 221.2 DWE Housing and dwellings 91.6 BNK Banking, lending, and insurance 87.0 Source: Totals from NSS. Individual sectors: authors' calculations. See Annex for data details. Y0 Base-year (2001) sectoral output (US$ million) In 2002, the single largest industry was construction. Growth in this sector was driven mostly by charitable donations from the Ameri- can-Armenian diaspora, such as the Lyndsey foundation. Food and agriculture represent almost 45 percent of the country's output. The remaining industry reflects the country's legacy from the Soviet era where metal-cutting machine tools, forging machines, electric motors, instruments, tires, chemicals, gem cutting, and brandy-making were the major tradable goods and services. Most heavy industries have 256 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 9.2 Base-Year Production and Trade Statistics by Sector for Armenia, 2002 (US$ million) Code Description Y0 VA D0 E0 M0 CON Construction 519.8 297.4 513.6 6.2 2.9 TRD Retail & wholesale trade, catering 434.8 264.8 434.8 0.0 0.0 FOD Food processing & beverages 381.0 156.9 329.8 51.2 44.0 GOV Governance, defense, and public expenditures 364.8 208.8 285.8 79.0 68.5 MNM Mineral products and precious stones 311.7 40.4 52.5 259.2 212.3 MIL Dairy products 279.2 169.9 278.7 0.5 6.6 TRN Transport and communications 248.9 140.3 166.9 82.0 141.1 OSR Other services 221.2 213.6 211.3 9.9 0.8 VFR Vegetables, fruits, grapes 209.3 127.6 203.7 5.6 24.0 GRN Wheat, potatoes, legumes 170.7 104.1 170.4 0.3 50.8 UTL Electricity, gas, and water supply 146.5 101.1 140.8 5.7 13.4 OCR Other crops 140.1 85.4 135.1 5.0 19.5 MTL Metals and metal products 121.2 59.8 76.4 44.8 55.7 MCH Equipment, motor vehicles, and optical 119.9 46.3 63.6 56.3 160.3 OMT Beef, pork, poultry 110.9 65.5 110.8 0.1 21.4 CRP Chemicals, rubbers, and plastics 105.3 90.5 96.9 8.4 84.6 MIN Mining and quarrying 95.0 37.4 52.9 42.1 22.9 DWE Housing and dwellings 91.6 0.0 91.6 0.0 0.0 BNK Banking, lending, and insurance 87.0 71.8 80.3 6.7 11.3 OMF Other manufacturing 77.6 49.4 72.5 5.1 47.8 LMF Light manufacturing and textiles 65.7 22.6 36.1 29.6 40.7 TBC Tobacco products 33.1 12.7 29.5 3.6 28.6 VOL Vegetable oils and fats 1.4 0.9 1.4 0.0 16.8 ENR Oil & natural gas 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 151.4 Total 4,336.6 2,367.0 3,635.3 701.3 1,225.4 Source: Authors' calculations based upon total supply provided by the NSS (2002). Key: Y0 Base-year output VA Base-year value added D0 Base-year supply to domestic market E0 Base-year exports (FOB) M0 Base-year imports (CIF, net tariff) Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 257 declined precipitously since 1990. Some of these activities have been replaced by high-technology manufacturing and software services. These sectors are still small, however, and they must compete in a global market for business and ITC services. International trade statistics are presented in Tables 9.3 and 9.4. Armenia's open trade policy has been hampered by the closure of its borders with Turkey and Azerbaijan. All trade is shipped from the north through Georgia or from the south via Iran. Personal imports of goods make up an unknown but potentially significant portion of total imports. In value terms, the largest import and export is jewelry, gems, and cut stones (model sector MNM). The gem-cutting industry adds value and reexports the gems at a higher price. The key import sectors for final consumption are oil and gasoline, food and food products, and manufactures such as automobiles, machinery, and computers. Armenian exports are limited to processed gems and jewelry, preci- sion instruments, tourism and related transportation, and some gold, precious stones, and minerals.13 Sectoral value added, ranked accord- ing to labor intensity, is shown in Table 9.5. The Informal Economy A portion of the officially reported economic statistics in Armenia comes from a survey of the informal economy. This portion of eco- nomic activity is not reported to the government, but represents a cer- tain amount of economic production and consumption. Traditionally, informal economic activity is small-plot farming and marketing. Other examples are certain domestic services and street markets. The NSS estimates that in 1999 the informal economy represented 26 percent of total economic activity. The estimate for 2002 is said to have risen to 30 percent, but the official statistics are not yet available. In order to identify the nature and size of these activities, the NSS conducts a survey of 9,000 individuals. The questions they ask, or how they tabulate the value of output based upon the survey was not pro- vided. Table 9.6 shows the share of informal activity and employment as estimated by the NSS for 1999. We use these data to calibrate levels of informal activity at the sectoral level, contingent on the assumed informal share of aggregate GDP. We include the estimates from Table 9.6 in our model to identify the portion of production in each sector that escapes taxation. This portion of the economy is legally obligated to pay taxes, but does not. Presumptive and simplified taxes have been introduced in part to capture economic activity from the informal market, but the col- lections from these tax instruments are low and we have therefore omitted these taxes from the database and model. 258 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 9.3 Benchmark Import Statistics for Armenia, 2002 Code Description M0 (US$ million) M0 (%) % M % VA MNM Mineral products and precious stones 212.3 17.3 79.8 13.0 MCH Equipment, motor vehicles, and optical 160.3 13.1 70.5 38.6 ENR Oil & natural gas 151.4 12.4 100.0 0.0 TRN Transport and communications 141.1 11.5 45.8 56.4 CRP Chemicals, rubbers, and plastics 84.6 6.9 46.5 86.0 GOV Governance, defense, and public expenditures 68.5 5.6 19.3 57.2 MTL Metals and metal products 55.7 4.5 42.2 49.4 GRN Wheat, potatoes, legumes 50.8 4.1 23.0 61.0 OMF Other manufacturing 47.8 3.9 39.5 63.7 FOD Food processing & beverages 44.0 3.6 11.7 41.2 LMF Light manufacturing and textiles 40.7 3.3 52.1 34.4 TBC Tobacco products 28.6 2.3 48.0 38.3 VFR Vegetables, fruits, grapes 24.0 2.0 10.6 61.0 MIN Mining and quarrying 22.9 1.9 30.2 39.3 OMT Beef, pork, poultry 21.4 1.7 16.0 59.1 OCR Other crops 19.5 1.6 12.6 61.0 VOL Vegetable oils and fats 16.8 1.4 84.8 61.0 UTL Electricity, gas, and water supply 13.4 1.1 8.7 69.0 BNK Banking, lending, and insurance 11.3 0.9 12.4 82.5 MIL Dairy products 6.6 0.5 2.3 60.9 CON Construction 2.9 0.2 0.6 57.2 OSR Other services 0.8 0.1 0.4 96.6 TRD Retail & wholesale trade, catering 0.0 0.0 0.0 60.9 TOTAL 1,225.4 100.0 0.0 0.0 Source: Aggregate values supplied by Armenian customs. Sectoral disaggregations are authors' calculations based upon shares from the NSS. Key: M0 Base-year imports (US$ million) M0 (%) Base-year imports as % of total imports % M Base-year imports as % of domestic sales % VA Base-year imports as a percent of sectoral value added Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 259 Table 9.4 Export Statistics for Armenia, 2002 Code Description X0 (US$ million) X0 (%) % X % VA MNM Mineral products and precious stones 259.2 37.0 83.2 13.0 TRN Transport and communications 82.0 11.7 32.9 56.4 GOV Governance, defense, and public expenditures 79.0 11.3 21.7 57.2 MCH Equipment, motor vehicles, and optical 56.3 8.0 47.0 38.6 FOD Food processing & beverages 51.2 7.3 13.4 41.2 MTL Metals and metal products 44.8 6.4 37.0 49.4 MIN Mining and quarrying 42.1 6.0 44.3 39.3 LMF Light manufacturing and textiles 29.6 4.2 45.1 34.4 OSR Other services 9.9 1.4 4.5 96.6 CRP Chemicals, rubbers, and plastics 8.4 1.2 7.9 86.0 BNK Banking, lending, and insurance 6.7 1.0 7.7 82.5 CON Construction 6.2 0.9 1.2 57.2 UTL Electricity, gas, and water supply 5.7 0.8 3.9 69.0 VFR Vegetables, fruits, grapes 5.6 0.8 2.7 61.0 OMF Other manufacturing 5.1 0.7 6.6 63.7 OCR Other crops 5.0 0.7 3.6 61.0 TBC Tobacco products 3.6 0.5 10.9 38.3 MIL Dairy products 0.5 0.1 0.2 60.9 GRN Wheat, potatoes, legumes 0.3 0.0 0.2 61.0 OMT Beef, pork, poultry 0.1 0.0 0.1 59.1 VOL Vegetable oils and fats 0.0 0.0 0.0 61.0 TRD Retail & wholesale trade, catering 0.0 0.0 0.0 60.9 TOTAL 701.3 1.0 0.0 0.0 Source: NSS (2001) (reconciled by authors). Key: X0 Base-year exports (US$ million) X0 (%) Base-year exports as % of total exports % X Base-year exports as % of domestic production % VA Base-year exports (FOB) as percentage of sectoral value added 260 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 9.5 Sectoral Value Added, Ranked by Labor Intensity VA LAB LND SKL CAP Code Description (US$ million) (%) (%) (%) (%) MIN Mining and quarrying 37.4 72.2 0.0 9.4 18.4 LMF Light manufacturing and textiles 22.6 60.1 0.0 8.7 31.2 OMT Beef, pork, poultry 65.5 53.7 33.9 0.7 11.6 OCR Other crops 85.4 52.7 23.4 1.8 22.1 MTL Metals and metal products 59.8 52.6 0.0 8.6 38.8 GRN Wheat, potatoes, legumes 104.1 52.3 35.0 0.7 12.0 VFR Vegetables, fruits, grapes 127.6 52.2 35.0 0.8 11.9 FOD Food processing & beverages 156.9 51.2 0.0 9.4 39.4 MIL Dairy products 169.9 48.0 13.4 3.3 35.3 OMF Other manufacturing 49.4 46.0 0.0 6.9 47.0 MNM Mineral products and precious stones 40.4 42.8 0.0 6.7 50.4 TRD Retail & wholesale trade, catering 264.8 42.5 0.0 7.0 50.5 VOL Vegetable oils and fats 0.9 40.6 18.3 2.8 38.3 TBC Tobacco products 12.7 40.0 0.0 5.6 54.4 CON Construction 297.4 37.0 0.0 5.7 57.3 UTL Electricity, gas, and water supply 101.1 34.4 0.0 14.3 51.3 MCH Equipment, motor vehicles, and optical 46.3 32.6 0.0 8.6 58.8 CRP Chemicals, rubbers, and plastics 90.5 32.1 0.0 8.2 59.6 TRN Transport and communications 140.3 30.2 0.0 9.6 60.2 GOV Governance, defense, and public expenditures 208.8 25.0 0.0 39.8 35.1 BNK Banking, lending, and insurance 71.8 22.0 0.0 19.5 58.5 OSR Other services 213.6 12.4 0.0 11.0 76.6 TOTAL 2,367.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Source: Base shares from GTAP database. Some sectors were adjusted to reflect Armenia country-office staff calculations. Key: VA Sectoral value added at factor cost (US$ million) LAB Unskilled labor share of sectoral value added (%) LND Land share of sectoral value added (%) SKL Skilled labor share of sectoral value added (%) CAP Capital share of sectoral value added (%) Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 261 Table 9.6 Estimated Level of Underground and Informal Activity Percentage Corresponding sectors in model Industry 28.7 MIN,FOD,TBC,LMF, CRP, MNM,MTL,MCH,OMF Construction 46.1 CON Transport and communications 21.1 TRN Trade 75.5 TRD Agriculture 21.0 GRN,V F,VOL,OCR,MIL,OMT Other branches 27.1 ENR,UTL,BNK,GOV,OSR,DWE GDP at market prices 28.9 Source: NSS (1999). Tax Revenue Table 9.7 shows that total government collections in 2002 were 242.3 billion drams (US$422.8 million). Value-added taxes were the larg- est revenue source, contributing 39.2 percent of total tax revenues (US$165.8 million). Excise taxes were 14.6 percent of total taxes, and payroll contributions to social security totaled 15.7 percent of revenue. These tax bases are followed distantly by enterprise taxes, income taxes, and other taxes. Table 9.7 shows tax collections for the major levies in Armenia during 2002, and Table 9.8 further disaggregates these collections by production sector. Armenia's statutory tax code is straightforward. There exists a sin- gle VAT rate of 20 percent, a single tariff rate of 10 percent, and a sin- gle low-profit tax (20 percent). Income taxes are 10 percent for 80,000 drams per month (US$139), or 20 percent if income is above 80,000 drams. Excise rates are higher, but they are only applied to tobacco products, alcoholic beverages, and petroleum. Tax collections are more complicated, but we can review the trend in collections briefly. Profits tax collections have declined precipitously since 1999, as have income tax collections. Collections from profits taxes fell by 50 percent between 1999 and 2003, from 2.2 percent of GDP to 1.1 percent. Similarly, personal income taxes fell from 1.9 per- cent to 1.0 percent over the same period. The combined loss is 2.0 percent of GDP (US$58 million if considered in 2002). The trend is strange in light of the very strong economic growth over the same period, during which time GDP increased by approximately 30 per- cent. No other tax streams have risen to compensate for this loss, and total government revenues have declined as a proportion of GDP. 262 Part II: Background Papers Table 9.7 Armenian Tax Collections, 2002 (by source) Tax stream Billion drams US$ million Percent Value-added tax 95.0 165.8 39.2 Excise tax 35.3 62.6 14.6 Profits tax 17.4 30.3 7.2 Personal income tax 12.5 21.8 5.2 Payroll taxes 37.9 66.1 15.7 Import duties 9.8 17.1 4.0 Main streams: 207.9 363.3 85.9 Other taxes (omitted from the model) Stamp taxes 14.3 24.9 5.8 Environment and property 5.4 9.4 3.7 Presumptive tax 6.4 11.2 2.6 Simplified tax 3.7 6.5 1.5 Other streams 29.8 52.0 13.6 Total 237.7 415.7 99.5 Source: Table II.1, IMF Aide-Mémoire (2004). ILLUSTRATIVE SIMULATIONS Table 9.9 presents welfare-cost estimates of raising funds from four major revenue streams. The experiments on which these calculations are based consider inframarginal changes in rates; hence we label these estimates the "Average Cost of Funds" (ACF). The ACF meas- ures the efficiency cost of raising an additional US$20 million from each of the primary tax streams. The ACF values provide a very useful input to the public policy debate, specifically related to the cost-benefit calculus of public expen- ditures. When the ACF equals 1.4, this means that US$1 of public funds costs the representative consumer US$1.4. As the ACF increases, the requisite benefit through which a public project can be justified increases, and one would expect that as the ACF exceeds 1.5, fewer public expenditures are justifiable than is the case when the ACF equals 1.2. Another consideration is the shadow economy and its role in tax revenue leakage. For some of the major taxes, it is reported that non- compliance is as high as 50 percent. The tax leakage in the shadow economy is parameterized by both the benchmark share (, shown in Table 9.10) and , the elasticity of substitution between legal goods and black-market (informal) goods of the same variety. is the econ- omy-wide share of production occurring underground. Our default assumptions are = 30 percent and = 4. The average tax leakage, and the consequent average cost of funds, rises as each parameter Table 9.8 Benchmark Tax Collections, 2002 by Production Sector (US$ millions, 2001) Description Y0 VAT TK TSS TXS TL TM Total Oil & natural gas 0 53.9 0.0 0.0 28.1 0.0 0.0 81.9 Food processing & beverages 381 17.5 1.6 3 10.0 1.6 3.0 37.1 Tobacco products 33 6.3 1.2 0 24.0 0.2 1.6 33.7 Equipment, motor vehicles, and optical 120 16.3 0.4 0 0.0 0.2 3.5 20.7 Other manufacturing 78 12.8 2.5 3 0.0 1.2 0.9 20.0 Governance, defense, and public expenditures 365 0.0 0.0 13 0.0 5.8 0.0 18.4 Retail & wholesale trade, catering 435 8.1 1.8 6 0.0 2.6 0.0 18.2 Electricity, gas, and water supply 147 4.6 8.2 2 0.0 1.1 0.0 16.2 Transport and communications 249 4.0 3.7 5 0.0 2.1 0.0 14.4 Chemicals, rubbers, and plastics 105 10.9 0.4 0 0.0 0.2 0.5 12.3 Construction 520 2.3 2.8 3 0.0 1.4 0.0 9.5 Wheat, potatoes, legumes 171 9.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 9.5 Beef, pork, poultry 111 4.2 2.1 0 0.0 0.2 1.9 8.8 Light manufacturing and textiles 66 4.7 0.5 0 0.0 0.2 1.4 7.2 Mineral products and precious stones 312 4.2 0.7 0 0.0 0.2 1.2 6.7 Housing and dwellings 92 0.0 0.5 4 0.0 1.9 0.0 6.7 Mining and quarrying 95 2.5 3.2 0 0.0 0.2 0.0 6.2 Vegetable oils and fats 1 3.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.8 5.6 Metals and metal products 121 3.5 0.2 1 0.0 0.5 0.0 5.4 Banking lending and insurance 87 0.0 0.7 3 0.0 1.4 0.0 5.2 Other crops 140 2.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.5 2.6 Diary products 279 1.4 0.2 0 0.0 0.2 0.4 2.5 Vegetables, fruits, grapes 209 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Other services 221 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 TOTAL 172.6 30.5 46 62.1 21.1 16.7 348.8 Source: Official statistics from the Ministry of Finance, provided at the authors' request. Note: Excise taxes (TXS) have been changed. Collections reported in this table (Table 9.8) were taken from Table II.1, IMF Aide-Memoire (2004). Key: Y0: Sectoral output VAT: Value-added tax revenue TK: Profits tax revenue TSS: Payroll tax (social security) revenue TXS: Excise tax revenue TL: Wage (income) tax revenue TM: Tariff revenue TOTAL: Total tax revenues of the indicated sector 264 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 9.9 Cost of Raising 0.5% GDP (US$15 million) in Tax Revenues: A Comparison of Tax Bases Short-run R R% t% ACF-SR ACF-LR WAGE 19.1 78 118 1.3 1.6 0 PAYROLL 41.7 36 54 1.3 1.6 0 PROFITS 27.9 54 71 1.3 5.2 ­4 TARIFF 16.7 90 129 1.4 2.5 ­1 EXCISE 62.1 24 29 1.2 1.2 0 VAT 172.6 9 11 1.2 1.8 ­1 Source: Authors' calculations. Key: R 2002 base revenue (US$ million) R Revenue required as percentage of the original tax base t Required percentage increase in tax rate ACF-SR Average cost of funds in the short run (=­EV /G) ACF-LR Average cost of funds after allowing sufficient time for capital stocks () to adjust Percentage change in Armenia's aggregate capital stock as a result of additional taxes rises. The marginal cost of funds increases more rapidly than the aver- age and is most sensitive to . Table 9.9 shows some of the "central" tax estimates by tax stream. The tax stream called WAGE denotes taxes upon labor income, typi- cally deducted from worker paychecks on a monthly basis. The PAY- ROLL tax stream represents additional payments for social security and pensions. The PROFITS tax is collections for firm profits, modeled as a tax on the return to capital. In all of the scenarios, the ACF is compared to raise an additional half percent of GDP, equal to US$15 million. In the short run, when capital and investment are fixed, labor and payroll taxes have the highest cost of funds, especially for high or . Armenia has seen increase for these two tributary systems over the past four years. Personal income taxes declined by 45 percent between 1999 and 2003, from 1.9 percent of GDP to 1.0 percent. A similar (less dramatic) trend can be seen for payroll collections (3.2 percent to 2.8 percent), and profits taxes (2.2 percent to 1.1 percent). This trend can be interpreted as a broad increase of and/or . The ACF when is high (40 percent of the economy) is 1.53 and 1.42 for labor-based taxes. Capital-based taxes have a lower ACF of 1.24. Conversely, consumption-based taxes such as the VAT and excise taxes have a much lower ACF when is large. ACF estimates in the last column of Table 9.10 for TARIFF, EXCISE, and VAT are 1.19, 1.14, and 1.30, respectively. Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 265 Table 9.10 Indices of Informality and the Average Cost of Funds = 4 = 0.3 = 8 Timeframe = 0.2 = 0.3 = 0.4 = 2 = 4 = 8 = 0.4 Short run Income tax 1.24 1.29 1.36 1.24 1.29 1.40 1.58 Payroll tax 1.24 1.29 1.36 1.24 1.29 1.40 1.58 Profits tax 1.26 1.29 1.35 1.24 1.29 1.42 1.58 Import tariff 1.35 1.38 1.42 1.34 1.38 1.47 1.57 Excise tax 1.14 1.16 1.18 1.13 1.16 1.25 1.30 Value added tax 1.15 1.17 1.21 1.15 1.17 1.22 1.28 Long run (steady state) Income tax 1.53 1.59 1.70 1.55 1.59 1.69 1.91 Payroll tax 1.53 1.59 1.70 1.55 1.59 1.69 1.91 Profits tax 5.03 5.17 5.44 4.89 5.17 5.87 6.83 Import tariff 2.41 2.46 2.54 2.38 2.46 2.66 2.88 Excise tax 1.15 1.18 1.20 1.15 1.18 1.25 1.31 Value added tax 1.76 1.80 1.87 1.77 1.80 1.87 1.99 Source: Armenian general equilibrium model calculations. Key: : A measure of the acceptance of acceptance of informal goods in place of formal goods. This elasticity reflects willingness of consumer and producers to substitute formal and informal goods and services. : Base year economy-wide share of informal activity, a measure of the extent of informality within the economy. When the shadow economy () is small, capital (profits) taxes repre- sent an attractive revenue source, with a low ACF. This all changes in the long run. In the steady-state equilibrium we calibrate the model to an assumed equalization of the cost of capital and the rate of return. To the extent that increases in taxes directly or indirectly depress the rate of return to capital or increase the cost of capital replacement, the long-run impact of tax increases will be to reduce the level of the capital stock. This neoclassical growth mechanism can substantially increase the average cost of funds, as indicated by comparing the short- and long-run results in Table 9.10. IMF Tax Reform Packages A tax reform typically involves the combined adjustment of a number of tax rates and several tax bases. Indeed, a crucial role that can be played by a general equilibrium model is to evaluate the combined 266 Part II: Detailed Analysis effect of the simultaneous adjustment of several tax instruments. This more complex approach to tax reform is required when political fea- sibility becomes an important component in tax policy. We have constructed model-based representations of several pos- sible reform packages as is indicated in Table 9.11. These scenarios are (loosely) based upon the recommendations made in the 2004 Aide- Mémoire, as prepared by the IMF Fiscal Affairs Department. Including the agriculture sector in the tax base is considered in AGR5 and AGR. TM5 and UNIF5 present two tariff reforms. UNIF5 removes within- sector exemptions, setting the tariff rate to 5 percent for all sectors in which tariffs are currently applied while retaining trade preferences with other CIS countries. TM5 is a more profound reform that applies Table 9.11 Revenue and Welfare Impacts of Selected Tax Reforms Total revenue Change in revenue % EV Timeframe Benchmark Scenario Direct Indirect NET GDP (US$) ACF Short run AGR5 172.6 178.9 6.27 ­0.05 6.22 0.2 ­6.4 1.03 AGR 219.7 236.1 16.39 0.25 16.64 0.6 ­17.1 1.03 UNIF5 16.7 24.2 7.57 ­0.22 7.35 0.3 ­7.0 0.95 TM5 16.7 49.0 32.30 ­0.32 31.98 1.2 ­29.8 0.93 TXS10 62.1 67.9 5.76 ­0.37 5.39 0.2 ­6.1 1.13 TXS 62.1 75.8 13.73 ­0.39 13.33 0.5 ­13.7 1.03 Long run (steady state) AGR5 172.6 178.9 6.27 ­0.05 6.22 0.2 ­6.7 1.07 AGR 219.7 238.4 18.77 1.48 20.25 0.7 ­15.2 0.75 UNIF5 16.7 24.2 7.58 ­0.26 7.33 0.3 ­15.1 2.07 TM5 16.7 49.2 32.50 0.59 33.10 1.2 ­46.7 1.41 TXS10 62.1 68.5 6.39 2.21 8.60 0.3 ­6.2 0.72 TXS 62.1 76.5 14.43 2.19 16.62 0.6 ­14.1 0.85 Source: Armenian CGE model calculations. Key: AGR5 Apply a 5% value-added tax on all agricultural sectors AGR Apply a 5% tax on value added, profits, and wages in the formal agricultural sector UNIF5 Move to a uniform tariff of 5%, retaining exemptions for imports from free- trade partners TM5 Apply a uniform 5% tariff on all imports TXS10 Increase excise tax rates by 10% from current levels TXS Increase excise taxes by 10% on the current base and tax domestic tobacco Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 267 a uniform levy equal to 5 percent on imports from all trading part- ners. A target value of 5 percent was used for the ad valorem rate because about 50 percent of Armenian imports come from free trade partners such as Russia. Five percent represents half of the standard 10 percent rate. As discussed, capital- and tariff-based taxes are most efficient in short time frames, but in the long run, high tariffs are detrimental to eco- nomic growth and they encourage smuggling and higher underground activity--and the ACF for import tariffs consequently increases. Among the tax policy reforms presented here, we conclude that there are several directions in which the tax system might be improved. The elimination of preferences for agriculture in the tax system strengthens revenues over the long term and does not dis- courage economic growth. As indicated in Table 9.11, revenues raised through tariffs are efficient in the short run, with ACF values of: 0.95 (UNIF5) and 0.93 (TM5). The ACF for moving to a uniform tariff is less than 1 because the tariff-reform package increases efficiency as well as revenues. Import tariffs are less attractive in the long run, where the ACF is 2.07 and 1.42, respectively. Conversely, the AGR scenario, where agricultural activity is included into all streams of the tax system (VAT, profits, and income), has a relatively low short-run ACF of 1.03, and a long-run ACF of 0.75. The long-run efficiency cost of taxes on agricultural products is low because of existing profits and income taxes, which tend to discrimi- nate against formal activities in manufacturing and industry. These taxes lead to underinvestment in industry, an effect that is partially offset by a tax on agricultural income. In the long run, by including agriculture in the tax stream like other sectors, we collect revenues, but also increase the overall efficiency of the tax system. It is pointed out in the IMF Aide-Mémoire that taxes on agricultural activity are difficult to administer, since most farmers are smallholders. These farmers would be exempt from income and profits taxes in any case, if revenues and income are low. Large agricultural firms, however, currently enjoy preferential treatment as a side effect of well-intentioned tax breaks for small farmers. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS In a typical CGE sensitivity analysis, results are compared across a range of elasticity values. In the present application, however, the level of uncertainty is heightened by the construction of the base- year IO table. In order to develop a better understanding of the degree of uncertainty introduced through the data construction, we have 268 Part II: Detailed Analysis repeated the calculations reported above using source data from the Hungarian IO coefficients in place of the Polish coefficients. We find that our model results are remarkably robust in this dimension. The structure of the IO matrix turns out to be a third-order determinant of model results, as can be seen in the ACF-SR and ACF-LR columns in Table 9.12. Least-squares methods are used to construct the benchmark data- base for the model. When IO coefficients are drawn from different sources, this leads to slight differences in the benchmark value shares, as suggested by comparing the R and t columns in Table 9.12. Our calibration procedure holds tax revenue and sector GDP more or less consistent, but it returns somewhat different benchmark tax rates. The new benchmark tax rates remain very close to the originals, produc- ing a negligible change to the short-run and long-run cost of funds estimates. Table 9.12 Sensitivity Analysis for the Cost of Raising 0.5% of GDP R R t ACF-SR ACF-LR Hungarian IO coefficients WAGE 19.1 78 118 1.3 1.6 0 PAYROLL 41.7 36 54 1.3 1.6 0 PROFITS 27.9 54 71 1.3 5.2 ­4 TARIFF 16.7 90 129 1.4 2.5 ­1 EXCISE 62.1 24 29 1.2 1.2 0 VAT 172.6 9 11 1.2 1.8 ­1 Polish IO coefficients WAGE 19.1 78 131 1.3 1.6 0 PAYROLL 41.7 36 60 1.3 1.6 0 PROFITS 28.1 53 77 1.3 5.5 ­5 TARIFF 16.7 90 150 1.5 2.8 ­2 EXCISE 62.1 24 31 1.2 1.5 0 VAT 172.6 9 11 1.2 2.1 ­1 Source: Authors' calculations. Key: R 2002 base revenue (US$ million) R Revenue required as percentage of the original tax base t Required percentage increase in tax rate ACF-SR Average cost of funds in the short run (= ­EV /G) ACF-LR Average cost of funds after allowing sufficient time for capital stocks () to adjust. Percentage change in Armenia's aggregate capital stock as a result of additional taxes Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 269 CONCLUSIONS This paper has demonstrated the feasibility of a quantitative analysis of tax policy issues in Armenia, despite the unavailability of current IO statistics. In the presence of missing IO statistics, policy decisions are still better informed by a roughly parameterized model than by the uncalibrated logic of economic theory. The cost of public funds in Armenia, measured as the ratio of lost consumption per additional dollar of public revenue, ranges from 1.3 to over 5, depending on the tax base and the model horizon. In the short run, the cost of public funds lies between 1.3 and 2 US$ per additional dollar of funding. Our analysis highlights the efficiency cost of informal activity. The marginal costs of public funds from any of the direct and indirect tax instruments are increased when a substantial fraction of the tax base is able to avoid payments, or when individuals are more willing to substitute informal goods and services for formal goods and services. These results provide strong support for tax policies that underscore the need to reduce tax evasion and informal activities organized pri- marily as a means of evading tax payments. Our model-based analysis emphasizes the important impact of tax policy on capital accumulation and economic growth. The exist- ing profits, income, and value-added taxes all tend to discriminate against investment in formal sectors, and the long-run perspective underscores the need for avoiding further discouragement of invest- ment in these areas. We have shown that certain "first-best" rules for taxation (low rates, broad base), which apply in many competitive economies, may be misleading in Armenia's second-best environment. ANNEX 9.1 SECTORAL CLASSIFICATIONS T he Armenian CGE model has 25 sectors. This aggregation has been chosen because it offers a reasonable characterization of the Armenian economy given data available from the Armenian Ministry of Finance and NSS, along with an ad hoc set of reports provided by various international organizations. Some aspects of the current national accounts are notable. The first is that 10 years after separating from the Soviet Union and undertak- ing market reforms, the NSS remains loyal to the original socialist accounting system. In this system, several superfluous accounts that comprise less than 0.5 percent of GDP are distinguished, whereas several more impor- tant categories of economic activity such as manufacturing and food processing are ignored. These shortcomings are rectified to a certain extent by leveraging evidence from IMF country reports, auxiliary data, and outside accounts, such as the GTAP database. This annex is designed to be comprehensive so that the inter- ested reader can recreate, append, or improve our Armenian dataset, although the NSS intends to switch accounting methods to the Inter- national Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC). SECTORAL MAPPING Some of the sectors in our accounts have been disaggregated from the Armenian national statistics. Other sectors reflect aggregations of inconsequential sectors from the accounts. A detailed description of each sector is included here. The tables used to compute total output for these sectors are provided at the end of this annex. 270 Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 271 grn Grains and legumes. This sector comes from the NSS agri- culture accounts dataset for 2002 (see Figure 9A.1.1), combining wheat, potatoes, and leguminous plants. vfr Vegetables and fruits, including grapes. This sector includes vegetables, fruit, and grapes. vol Vegetable oils. This sector is taken directly from 2002 agricul- ture accounts. sgr Sugar. This sector is taken directly from 2002 agriculture accounts. mil Milk and milk products. This sector comprises eggs and milk (without butter). omt Other meats. This sector includes the beef, pork, mutton, goat, and poultry categories from the 2002 agriculture dataset. min Mining and quarrying. This sector comes from the national accounts' (Macro Data.xls) "Geology" sector. It is also based on the IMF Statistical Annex (IMF 2002), page 7, Table 4: Structure of Industrial Production (1996­2001). The portion for "Mining and Quarrying" is taken from the "industry" sector of the national accounts. fod, tbc, crp, omf Each of these sectors is disaggregated directly from the industry macro-sector via Table 4 from the IMF Statistical Annex (IMF 2002). The shares listed for year 2001 are used. lmf Light manufacturing and textiles. This sector includes textiles, dressing, and dying of fur. mnm Minerals and mining goods. This sector mainly represents the gem-cutting business in Armenia. The single largest import and export good in Armenia is gems. Uncut gems enter the country and finished jewelry is exported. Shares are taken from Table 4 of the statistical annex. See Figure 9A.1.2 in this annex. mtl Basic metals and fabricated metals. This sector is taken directly from the IMF Statistical Annex (IMF 2002). It represents 8 percent of industrial output. mch Manufacturing. This sector combines machinery, equipment, and motor vehicles with optical, medical, and other precision devices. The combined share is of these activities in GDP is 3.8 percent. trd Wholesale and retail trade and commerce. This sector com- bines macro lines for retail trade and catering with general commerce. bnk Banking and insurance. This combines two lines from the 2002 national accounts. enr Energy This sector accounts for natural gas and oil. Energy imports are used to calculate total domestic supply. 272 Part II: Detailed Analysis utl Gas, water, and electricity. This sector appears twice; first in the industrial section of the IMF report, then again as a sepa- rate account in the official NSS accounts. We combine these two accounts for the total. The totals are the "utility sector" from the macro report and "electricity, gas, and water" from IMF (2002), Table 4. gov Government, defense, and public procurement. This sector rep- resents government activities within the economy. It is based on the macro data spreadsheet and also is compared with gen- eral statistics regarding the government sector. This sector also includes "social spending," including four lines from the national accounts: health and sport, education, culture, and science. dwe Dwellings and housing. This sector is based on the housing entry in the national accounts. con Construction. This sector is taken directly from the official NSS National Accounts (see Figure 9A.1.3 in this annex). osr Other services. This sector captures the sectors real estate, culture, and information technology. cgd Savings good. This good represents net savings and capital investment for the country. The sector consumes mostly durable goods and construction. ACCOUNTING IDENTITIES The economic model for Armenia represents an Arrow-Debreu equi- librium. This means that firms are assumed to maximize profits and face competition, households maximize utility, and markets for goods are balanced (supply equals demand). These basic conditions require a handful of accounting identities to hold. These identities are discussed in this section. First, we take the set I to represent sectors in the model {grn, min, fod, etc. . .}. Then we have the following conditions: The total sales value must equal the total cost of production: Yi =IDji + Li + Ki +Ti = Ci. (9A.1.1) j Total output or sales for good i (Yi), at producer prices, must be large enough to cover the cost of production (Ci). This includes the purchase of intermediate inputs (IDji), value added (Li, Ki), and taxes (Ti). Supply must equal demand for all markets: Ai IDij +Gi + FDi + INV , (9A.1.2) j Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 273 where Ai = Di + Mi . (9A.1.3) Total supply is represented by the "Armington Composite Good" (Ai), which combines domestic production (Di) with imported goods (Mi). Domestic endowments of value added (fi) can also be included in this condition, where fi represents the aggregated endowments of labor (Li) and capital (Ki). Domestic supply is either consumed or exported: Yi = Di + Xi . (9A.1.4) Total production for a given good (Yi) is either sold to the domestic market, or it is exported. The export share represents the value of exports divided by total output xi/yi. These basic conditions are sufficient to identify or compute most of the national accounts for Armenia. The origin of each variable appearing in the equilibrium bench- mark identities is listed in Table 9A.1.1. INPUT-OUTPUT DATA When the total production, value added, and intermediate demand values are calculated from the national accounts data, we then decom- pose the intermediate demand structure using our surrogate IO table. We follow a similar procedure to compute the capital/labor shares in value added. The current implementation distinguishes four factors: skilled labor, unskilled labor, capital, and land. Each factor's share in pro- duction is presented in the main text of this chapter. We include the dollar payments to those factors below, in the IO table. We also include payments made by producers to various tax authorities. Although the employer does not distinguish tax payments from labor costs (they are still factor payments), we know that the labor costs will change when tax rates are altered, so they are distinguished here. External Data Sources In this section, we include tables from the data sources mentioned above. Each table represents an Excel (XLS) worksheet. These data are available upon request, but they are also printed in this section for convenience. Different accounts data are stored as a set of spreadsheets and archived on the Armenia project Web site. These files have been posted to http://mileslight.com/armenia/. A password may be nec- essary to access this site. Please contact the authors if necessary. 274 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 9A.1.1 Origin of Each Variable Yi Total supply. This parameter is given by the NSS National Accounts data, the subtables from the IMF Statistical Annex (2002), and the Agriculture subtable. Xi, Mi Imports and exports of goods and services. Provided for 2002 by the customs authorities and the NSS. Each traded good was mapped onto the model sectors. Di Domestic supply. Computed parameter based on the values for Yi and Xi. Ai Armington aggregate supply. Ai represents the total supply for a good in Armenia. It is a computed parameter, which combines Di and Mi, net of import, and value-added levies applied at the border and domestically. IDji Intermediate demand. Aggregate values for intermediate demand are provided in the national accounts data (Figure 9.5). But individual input coefficients are taken from a surrogate IO table for Hungary. This IO table is reproduced for the reader in Tables 9.1 and 9.2. Li, Ki Labor and capital demand for production in sector i. Total value added is provided in the national accounts, but the share of labor, capital, land, and indirect taxes is not provided by the NSS. These values are based upon the surrogate IO tables from the GTAP database. The capital intensity can be an important determinant of labor/capital returns, and should be reviewed more carefully by experts in Armenia. fi Factor endowments. Factor endowments for labor, capital, and land are computed from total demand by firms and government. Total sales of labor and capital are allocated to households. A data discrepancy exists between the official wage statistics, provided by the NSS, and the official value- added statistics. Although total value added is reported to be more than US$2,100 million, officially reported wages are only (approximately) US$600 million, which implies that labor's share in value added is less than 30 percent of total value added. Gi Government demand for good i. These values are based upon the GTAP surrogate dataset, but can also be reconciled by reports by the Armenian Ministry of Finance. INVi Investment demand for good i. Taken from the surrogate dataset from GTAP. FDi Final demand for good i. Computed as a residual based upon total supply and total demand. Total final demand should be compared with the surrogate data, as well as with Armenian household surveys. This task is forthcoming in a future study. Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 275 Table 9A.1.2 External Data Sources File Description armdata.xls Macroeconomic production statistics for import into GAMS. This spreadsheet was taken from Macro Data.xls. The spreadsheet reports value added only, not the total production value. Nevertheless, the shares from this sheet for year 2002 are used to calculate the share of total production in Armenia. arm ag 2002.xls Contains major agricultural sectors, including production, imports, exports, and final demand. This is a very useful spreadsheet. The agricultural information from this sheet is used in the model. Stat. Annex 2001 IMF macroeconomic statistics for Armenia for 2001 (IMF 2002). Several tables are used from this report, including industrial production (p. 7) and the statutory tax code (pp. 52­57). 276 Part Table 9A.1.3 Production Technology Structure for Armenia (US$ million) II: Sector GRN VFR VOL OCR MIL OMT MIN FOD TBC LMF CRP MNM MTL MCH OMF UTL CON TRN TRD BNK GOV OSR DWE Detailed GRN 24.35 0.01 0.00 0.16 5.50 6.93 0.00 11.82 1.21 0.03 0.01 0.56 0.02 0.01 0.02 0.00 0.43 0.03 1.02 0.00 0.39 0.01 0.00 VFR 0.00 23.61 0.00 0.10 3.98 1.53 0.20 15.94 0.88 0.06 0.06 1.07 0.13 0.05 0.15 0.00 0.91 0.13 2.89 0.05 0.75 0.05 0.00 VOL 0.60 1.04 0.31 0.49 1.48 1.75 0.00 8.82 0.03 0.10 0.01 0.09 0.01 0.00 0.03 0.00 0.05 0.00 0.27 0.00 0.16 0.00 0.00 Analysis OCR 0.30 0.89 0.01 25.35 3.49 2.20 0.34 6.78 2.66 1.73 0.03 0.41 0.05 0.04 0.28 0.01 1.18 0.15 0.94 0.00 0.25 0.01 0.00 MIL 0.48 0.42 0.00 0.30 43.59 1.05 0.31 0.56 0.24 0.08 0.03 1.18 0.12 0.04 0.04 0.02 1.16 0.13 2.91 0.05 2.74 0.05 0.00 OMT 0.19 0.00 0.11 0.18 9.14 8.85 0.00 65.46 0.12 0.07 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.41 0.00 0.84 0.00 0.34 0.01 0.00 ENR 0.02 0.27 0.00 0.05 0.42 0.05 1.03 0.94 0.15 0.06 0.52 16.58 1.32 0.01 7.87 7.95 0.17 0.03 0.00 0.00 1.77 0.06 0.00 MIN 0.00 0.06 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.78 0.05 0.01 0.02 0.39 5.43 0.45 0.01 0.03 0.44 0.84 0.08 0.03 0.00 0.19 0.01 0.00 FOD 2.57 7.44 0.02 2.71 11.00 10.64 0.31 36.34 1.37 0.45 0.08 0.71 0.21 0.07 0.14 0.01 0.45 0.21 3.03 0.00 5.35 0.06 0.00 TBC 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.13 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.29 1.90 0.01 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.07 0.26 0.00 0.59 0.07 0.00 LMF 0.53 0.82 0.00 0.73 0.79 0.08 0.59 6.33 0.62 11.96 0.45 9.22 0.40 1.07 4.17 0.07 4.68 1.30 3.57 0.33 6.37 0.22 0.00 CRP 11.03 13.04 0.02 5.23 6.37 2.30 5.12 12.07 1.46 3.57 5.96 34.55 5.50 3.62 1.63 3.99 10.05 8.92 4.29 0.11 13.17 0.23 0.00 MNM 0.85 0.99 0.00 0.50 0.53 0.24 0.83 0.91 0.58 0.24 0.18 27.77 1.67 1.00 0.12 0.13 39.45 0.39 0.97 0.01 1.19 0.25 0.00 MTL 2.29 2.55 0.00 1.28 1.63 0.63 5.69 4.05 0.72 0.67 0.50 24.64 30.04 9.30 0.46 0.48 24.33 2.04 2.99 0.20 2.21 0.24 0.00 MCH 4.30 3.90 0.01 2.53 3.36 1.21 9.25 5.99 0.82 1.24 0.65 16.83 3.71 43.61 0.51 1.73 16.59 9.78 7.19 2.04 11.59 0.35 0.00 OMF 2.49 3.52 0.01 1.50 2.27 0.50 1.69 6.08 1.36 12.10 1.63 19.89 0.69 1.64 5.16 5.01 7.15 7.03 9.31 0.54 12.76 0.43 0.00 UTL 1.29 2.24 0.00 1.63 2.20 0.70 12.36 4.79 0.45 0.99 0.83 22.66 3.44 0.64 0.36 13.07 1.27 2.83 1.74 0.25 8.11 0.33 0.00 CON 0.00 0.17 0.00 0.06 0.16 0.00 0.38 0.27 0.07 0.00 0.05 1.10 0.16 0.13 0.01 0.23 3.03 3.09 2.05 0.44 0.58 0.33 0.00 TRN 2.25 3.00 0.01 2.41 1.83 0.57 3.75 6.51 0.78 2.28 0.67 18.31 3.55 2.23 0.86 1.34 38.42 16.97 40.88 2.08 15.09 0.68 0.00 TRD 8.71 12.51 0.02 5.85 6.96 3.11 3.84 13.20 1.16 2.90 0.71 19.34 4.88 3.48 1.29 0.46 27.25 14.94 18.60 1.74 18.20 0.91 0.00 BNK 1.75 2.10 0.00 0.96 1.09 0.31 1.28 2.61 0.55 0.51 0.30 4.98 0.71 0.72 0.22 0.61 5.10 3.50 8.48 0.90 2.53 0.15 24.70 Table 9A.1.3 (continued) Sector GRN VFR VOL OCR MIL OMT MIN FOD TBC LMF CRP MNM MTL MCH OMF UTL CON TRN TRD BNK GOV OSR DWE GOV 1.11 1.30 0.00 0.91 1.33 0.45 2.73 2.32 0.34 0.66 0.25 13.34 1.22 1.02 0.32 0.29 8.59 3.95 10.03 1.06 12.26 0.58 0.00 Taxation OSR 1.49 1.75 0.00 1.57 1.78 0.19 4.62 8.90 1.72 2.69 0.91 31.80 2.38 4.36 1.08 1.36 26.64 27.42 43.39 3.42 33.79 2.55 0.00 DWE 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.03 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.00 Skilled and labor 0.76 1.01 0.02 1.51 5.69 0.46 2.95 14.20 0.71 1.96 7.46 2.72 5.16 3.99 3.44 14.42 16.96 13.45 18.59 14.00 83.20 23.48 0.00 Unskilled Economic labor 54.45 66.65 0.35 43.67 81.54 35.21 22.52 77.65 5.06 13.58 29.05 17.30 31.44 15.11 22.77 34.78 110.19 42.34 112.46 15.80 52.30 26.48 0.00 Land 36.45 44.73 0.16 21.93 22.76 22.22 5.31 5.14 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Capital 12.49 15.24 0.33 18.33 59.55 7.17 5.60 56.50 6.42 6.68 53.59 19.96 22.07 26.84 20.64 49.01 167.26 80.07 128.05 38.90 60.50 163.60 66.90 Capital tax 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.17 2.05 2.94 1.47 1.14 0.50 0.35 0.69 0.17 0.35 2.13 7.79 2.73 3.34 1.65 0.65 0.00 0.00 0.00 VAT rebate ­3.03 0.00 ­0.07 ­1.03 ­0.81 ­1.63 ­6.96 ­25.49 ­2.84 ­5.68 ­0.83 0.00 ­2.92 ­7.43 ­2.95 ­1.45 ­1.65 ­1.57 ­7.43 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Effi Labor tax 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.18 0.18 0.18 1.58 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.53 0.18 1.23 1.05 1.40 2.11 2.63 1.40 5.79 0.00 0.00 Payroll tax 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.38 0.38 0.38 3.44 0.38 0.38 0.38 0.38 1.15 0.38 2.67 2.29 3.06 4.59 5.73 3.06 12.61 0.00 0.00 ciency Output 167.7 209.3 1.3 139.0 278.4 109.3 88.0 355.5 30.2 60.0 104.4 311.7 118.3 112.5 74.7 145.1 518.2 247.3 427.4 87.0 364.8 221.2 91.6 Source: Authors' calculations based on Armenia SAM. in Note: This table displays the zero profit accounting for each production sector. The table includes intermediate inputs, factor inputs, and tax Armenia payments by producers. 277 Figure 9A.1.1 Armenian Agricultural Accounts for 2002 278 min. U.S. $ Average Consumption per capita retail Stocks Food Stocks kg/ gram/ kilo- Part prices beginning Gross consump- Animal Other end of Satisfaction year day calorie/ AMD/kg of year Production Import supply tion feed Losses Seed Export use year Use rate % day II: Wheat 95.4 9.0 47.4 57.9 114.2 75.5 13.4 1.7 6.0 0.3 0.0 17.3 114.2 45.2 151.2 414.2 1325.6 Detailed Potato 154.3 20.5 100.7 0.5 121.7 32.5 19.2 7.3 32.8 0.0 0.0 29.9 121.7 99.5 40.2 110.1 82.5 Vegetables 80.0 3.1 77.5 1.0 81.6 66.2 1.6 3.5 0.4 3.1 0.0 6.7 81.6 102.8 158.1 433.2 130.0 Analysis Fruit (without grapes) 250.0 2.6 36.0 4.1 42.7 34.8 0.0 3.4 0.0 2.0 0.0 2.4 42.7 94.6 26.6 72.9 109.4 Leguminous plants 475.0 0.7 2.9 3.3 6.9 5.7 0.0 0.3 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.7 6.9 46.7 2.3 6.3 18.2 Vegetable oil 574.0 1.1 1.2 12.4 14.7 13.4 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.1 14.7 8.8 4.5 12.2 80.7 Sugar 257.9 1.4 0.0 30.8 32.2 30.4 0.0 0.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.3 32.2 0.0 22.5 61.6 237.8 Eggs 718.5 0.4 33.0 0.1 33.5 29.2 0.0 1.8 1.1 1.0 0.0 0.4 33.5 102.7 7.8 21.3 11.3 Milk (without butter) 250.1 20.0 213.5 4.6 238.2 189.5 21.4 9.5 0.0 0.3 0.0 17.4 238.2 98.0 144.7 396.4 158.5 Beef 1111.7 1.6 57.4 17.1 76.0 73.3 0.0 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.0 1.6 76.0 77.3 12.6 34.5 62.1 Pork 1197.1 0.4 21.5 7.9 29.9 28.8 0.0 0.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.6 29.9 73.1 4.6 12.6 26.4 Mutton & goat 999.5 0.2 10.3 0.0 10.5 10.1 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 10.5 100.0 1.9 5.3 8.5 Poultry meat 1146.7 0.8 8.8 25.6 35.2 34.2 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.8 35.2 25.6 5.7 15.6 16.7 Grape 387.0 1.5 70.2 2.4 74.1 68.5 0.0 3.4 0.0 0.4 0.0 1.8 74.1 97.2 33.8 92.6 4.2 Total 63.1 680.4 167.7 911.3 692.2 55.6 33.3 40.5 7.5 0.0 82.2 911.3 2272.0 average ex. rate 1 US$ = 573.35 AMD Note: These accounts were used to compute production values for agricultural sectors in the current Armenia dataset. Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 279 Figure 9A.1.2 Industrial Production Shares According to the National Statistical Service Total industry 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Mining and quarrying 3.6 3.5 3.9 3.9 5.3 6.6 Manufacturing 74.4 69.6 62.6 64.1 64.5 64.8 Food processing and beverages 44.1 45.6 40.7 39.1 36.6 35.6 Tobacco products 0.1 0.9 2.2 3.9 3.8 2.8 Textiles, dressing, and dyeing of fur 1.7 1.5 1.7 1.3 1.3 1.4 Chemical, chem. products, rubber, plastics 4.2 3.3 2.8 2.9 3.4 3.0 Other nonmetallic mineral products 3.1 3.9 3.8 3.3 2.4 2.7 Basic metals and fabricated metal 2.3 1.5 2.6 3.6 6.6 8.0 Machinery, equipment, and motor vehicles 8.0 4.7 3.1 1.9 2.5 3.1 Medical, precision, optical instruments 1.0 1.1 0.8 0.3 0.4 0.7 Jewelry and related articles 9.3 6.0 4.0 6.3 5.7 5.4 Other 0.6 1.3 0.9 1.4 1.8 2.1 Electricity, gas, and water supply 21.9 26.9 33.5 32.0 30.2 28.6 Source: Armenian authorities, National Statistical Service. Note: Taken from IMF (2002). 280 Part II: Detailed Analysis Figure 9A.1.3 Official Armenian National Production Statistics for 2002 2002 Current prices VA IDO YD millions of drams Industry 256,925 354,955 611,879 Agriculture 318,773 203,861 522,634 Forestry 713 229 942 Construction 172,238 124,850 297,088 Transport and communication 83,640 59,031 142,670 Retail trade and public catering 144,051 89,838 233,889 Public procurements 5,703 2,873 8,576 Sear-parts 1,016 510 1,526 Information-technological provision 959 330 1,288 Real estate transactions 3,987 927 4,914 General commerce 3,538 1,758 5,295 Geology 279 137 417 Other branches 2,200 1,099 3,300 Housing 38,331 14,140 52,471 Utility sector 63,270 21,334 84,605 Health, sport 32,418 35,860 68,277 Education 43,296 9,245 52,541 Culture 6,532 3,098 9,630 Science 4,856 2,132 6,988 Lending 19,470 7,278 26,748 Insurance 1,223 261 1,485 Governance and defense 35,833 35,958 71,791 NGOs 6,283 4,362 10,645 Financial intermediaries -14,937 14,937 0 Total by branches, in main prices 1,230,597 989,003 2,219,600 Net taxes on production and import minus subsidies 131,875 Taxes 140,145 Subsidies 8,271 Gross domestic product at market price 1,362,472 Source: NSS. Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia 281 NOTES 1. This paper was prepared by Miles K. Light, University of Colorado, and Thomas F. Rutherford, Ann Arbor, MI. 2. These studies include the "Tax White Paper," a survey on business opin- ions produced by the Armenian Chamber of Commerce, 2004, Chamber of Commerce and the IMF Aide-Mémoire (2004). 3. Four of the largest firms in the country reported losses for two straight years, despite GDP growth of 15 percent. 4. See the "Tax White Paper," a survey on business opinions produced by the Armenian Chamber of Commerce in 2004. 5. We do not deal with the distributional consequences of tax reform in the present analysis, although the extension of the present analysis to account for the impact of taxes on poverty would be quite interesting and surely important. 6. Our definition of the "informal market" in this analysis includes those economic activities that do not pay taxes. Part of this group is small farmers and businesses that do not have the capacity to calculate and pay their taxes; another part is those individuals or corporate entities who are explicitly evad- ing government taxes by not reporting their activities. The latter represents illegal economic activities that do not generate taxable transactions. 7. The values for and in the central scenarios are shown in Figure 3.1 8. The greatest sectoral imports in the base-year data are for sector MNM (mineral products and precious stones), in which total imports equal US$230 million. The MNM sector also generates the largest level of exports, equal to US$269 million. We characterize imports in this sector as specialized interme- diate inputs to the production sector through technology parameter ai M rather than as part of final demand. For all other sectors aiM = 0. 9. The numerical model permits the more general CES functional form for value-added based on model input esubkl. When this input is unity, value- added aggregates are Cobb-Douglas as shown here. 10. https://www.cia.gov/cia/publications/factbook/index.html. 11. The Global Trade and Analysis Project (GTAP) develops a consist- ent and balanced trade database that includes 57 production sectors and 55 regions. For more information about the GTAP database, see http://www. gtap.org. 12. A more detailed description of the sectoral classification is included in the first section of Annex 9.1. 13. While there exists a perception among Armenians that software is a major export industry, this claim is not supported by data from the NSS. The NSS reports that computer-related services account for less than 1 percent of GDP. The statistic is believed to be low because most multinational cor- porations that purchase IT services in Armenia account for the business as 282 Part II: Detailed Analysis a cost center for the corporation. Lycos is one example. The company hired 60 programmers in 2004 at an average monthly salary of US$600. According to informal sources, computer and information service exports were US$9.9 million in 2002. We have not yet been able to introduce this sector in our database and model for lack of official statistics. Chapter 10 Strengthening Competition INTRODUCTION The Armenian economy has registered sustained, rapid growth over the past decade, especially in the last few years.1 In 2003, GDP increased by 14 percent in real terms after having increased by 12.9 percent in 2002. Economic growth continued at 10.1 percent in 2004, with agriculture, construction, and services leading the growth; and at 13 percent per annum in 2005 and 2006. This growth performance is one of best in the world. The government has committed itself to eco- nomic reform and the economy is gradually being transformed. It has made private sector development the main pillar of its growth strat- egy and has been working to improve the business environment by reducing regulations, improving the bankruptcy law, improving cus- toms administration, strengthening the banking system, and reducing the capacity of officials to hamper businesses. In this process, the gov- ernment has received substantial support from donors. Nevertheless, per capita GDP remains low. Although extreme poverty and poverty have fallen strongly over recent years, there are still large numbers of poor in Armenia, especially in the rural areas and urban centers out- side the capital, Yerevan. Unemployment statistics still show a large number of unemployed, although the informal sector, which currently is about half as large as official GDP, probably has absorbed a substan- tial number of those who are recorded as being out of work. Although the growth performance of the economy has been strong, the government is anxious to ensure that it is sustainable. In this regard there is concern that the lack of competition within Armenia could threaten the long-term sustainability of growth and that it has been a contributing factor to the apparent failure of the recent eco- nomic expansion to benefit more of the population. The aim of this chapter is to arrive at a preliminary judgment on the importance of competition for the development of the Armenian 283 284 Part II: Detailed Analysis economy. The chapter examines the scope of anticompetitive behav- ior, the sectors that are the most affected, the relevant work that has been undertaken regarding these issues, the policy options that are available to deal with the problems, and the additional work that is needed. The discussion touches on the political economy issues related to areas of the economy in which competition is lacking and suggests policy options for the government. The chapter is organized as follows. We look at three main areas in which competition issues are important in Armenia. In the first section, we discuss briefly those sectors that are traditionally regu- lated and where there are natural monopolies or where competition is inherently limited, such as utilities, telecommunications, and trans- portation. In the second section we look at sectors of the economy that in Armenia are generally viewed as being controlled by a small number of incumbents who either singly or in cartels dominate the distribution of particular products. These include gasoline, wheat, cut flowers, and sugar. We also discuss some of the methods that appear to be used to maintain market dominance and make suggestions for dealing with this situation. In the third section, we look at barriers to entry into economic activities more generally. The higher the entry barriers, the less likely growth will trickle down to the population and the greater the long-run constraint on growth. The final section of the paper provides some conclusions and policy implications. ARMENIAN BUSINESS COMPETITIVENESS INDICATORS Competitiveness indicators aim to distinguish the strengths and weak- nesses of the economy and thereby identify actions to improve com- petition. The most notable institutions that produce international com- petitiveness rankings are the World Bank, the World Economic Forum (WEF), and the International Institute for Management Development. Although these research organizations include a significant number of countries in their competitiveness assessments, currently none offers a sector-specific country analysis2 that would be useful for this study. For Armenia, we used the following indicators to assess the com- petitive environment (see Tables 10.1­10.4):3 Business formation Entry-exit turnover Gross value added (GVA)4 Employment Average earnings Table 10.1 Business Formation Indicators, 2001­04 Number of registrations as a proportion of the total Number of Number of number of registrations registered entities deregistered entities at the start of the year Sector 2001 2002 2003 2004 2001 2002 2003 2004 2001 2002 2003 2004 Agriculture, forestry, and fishery 121 119 97 61 38 31 33 51 4.9 4.7 3.7 2.3 Industry (including mining) 632 443 371 252 139 141 146 203 7.7 5.1 4.1 2.7 Electricity, gas, and water supply 15 18 21 23 3 11 1 13 6.2 7.5 8.5 8.6 Str Construction 178 147 162 144 14 28 51 105 7.6 5.9 6.2 5.3 engthening Wholesale and retail trade 915 742 621 432 333 351 362 541 4.1 3.2 2.7 1.8 Transportation and communications 189 180 124 96 31 18 31 52 13.8 11.8 7.3 5.4 Financial services 23 13 15 17 4 4 1 6 13.4 6.8 7.5 7.9 Real estate, renting, and commercial activity 256 214 152 118 55 42 51 76 10.6 8.2 5.5 4.1 Education 58 35 33 28 16 6 20 17 11.4 6.4 5.7 4.7 Competition Health 62 89 53 37 70 56 24 132 7.1 10.3 5.9 4.0 Social and other services 325 204 147 113 41 49 49 97 10.5 6.0 4.2 3.1 Source: NSS. 285 286 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 10.2 Employment Indicators, 2001­04 (%) Sector 2001 2002 2003 2004 Agriculture, forestry, and fishery 18.7 22.3 24.7 28.9 Industry (including mining) 12.3 9.7 11.1 10.3 Electricity, gas, and water supply 5.1 3.5 3.2 3.8 Construction 3.9 5.3 6.2 8.9 Wholesale and retail trade 12.5 14.1 17.4 12.6 Transportation and communications 5.1 5.5 5 4.7 Financial services 0.7 0.7 0.4 0.4 Real estate, renting, and commercial activity 1.4 0.4 1 2 Education 16.4 15.5 13.6 10.4 Health 6.8 6.5 4.2 5.5 Social and other services 5.2 5.5 5.1 5.3 Source: NSS. Table 10.3 Average Earnings Indicators, 2001­04 2001 2002 2003 2004 Agriculture, forestry, and fishery 3.0 3.1 4.1 5.6 Industry (including mining) 7.1 7.1 10.5 11.7 Electricity, gas, and water supply 11.2 11.4 12.5 14.7 Construction 8.1 7.8 9.7 11.8 Wholesale and retail trade 2.1 3.7 3.2 3.9 Transportation and communications 8.4 8.7 10.5 11.0 Financial services 15.0 18.9 24.9 29.0 Real estate, renting, and commercial activity 5.5 6.5 8.0 9.5 Education 2.6 2.6 3.5 4.6 Health 2.6 2.3 2.7 3.9 Social and other services 4.9 4.6 5.8 6.6 Source: NSS. For 2001, we used the above indicators to compare selected sectors and develop Figure 10.1. Another important element to consider in assessing competitive- ness is the exchange rate in comparison with Armenia's major trading partners (Table 10.5). Tables 10.1­10.5 illustrate the following:5 The number of new businesses registered per year declined between 2001 and 2004 in virtually all sectors (Table 10.1). At first glance this seems surprising, as the economy has been grow- ing rapidly and reform has been proceeding. However, further consideration reveals that it is plausible that business formation Strengthening Competition 287 Table 10.4 Gross Value Added Indicators, 2000­01 (% of the total value added) 2000 2001 Agriculture, forestry, and fishery 16.56 17.93 Industry (including mining) 32.67 31.50 Electricity, gas, and water supply 6.81 6.33 Construction 13.85 12.43 Wholesale and retail trade 13.00 14.71 Transportation and communications 9.45 9.39 Financial services 2.87 3.04 Real estate, renting, and commercial activity 0.40 0.45 Education 2.28 2.44 Health 0.43 0.38 Social and other services 1.68 1.39 Source: NSS. Figure 10.1 Business Competitiveness Indicators for Selected Sectors trade as % of GDP (75.00) 16.0 14.0 12.0 10.0 8.0 6.0 X X 4.0 2.0 0.0 average earnings employment electricity, gas, and water supply wholesale and retail trade transportation and communication financial services Source: World Bank Doing Business Indicators (http://www.doingbusiness.org). 288 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 10.5 Foreign Exchange Rate Comparisons, 2001­04 (index) 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 REER 108.7 105.5 96.2 86.8 90.8 REER-Russia 168.9 159.7 152.2 147.5 144 REER-United States 92.3 91.1 90.6 90.2 90 REER-Euro Area 116.2 117.1 118.6 118.8 117.6 REER-Iran 61.5 59.6 58.2 56.8 55.1 Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics (http://ifs.apdi.net/imf/). is slowing down. First, Armenia is emerging from many years during which the economy was centrally directed. There must be limited capacity among potential entrepreneurs to estimate realistic opportunities and to determine whether a market is satu- rated, what opportunities exist, and the extent of the competition. As experience is acquired, judgment will improve. Second, later sections of this chapter point out that the benefits of formality, in the sense of access to the financial system or accessibility of the legal system to contract and resolve disputes, is still very limited. Until reform improves these incentives, many entrepreneurs will prefer to operate informally. Entry into the wholesale and retail trade sector faces various constraints.6 High levels of employment but low average earn- ings characterize this sector. These features, coupled with high levels of GVA, indicate that the sector's anticompetitive practices are harmful to total welfare. Although high entry levels characterize the financial services sector--the entry-exit turnover and business formation indica- tors are high--its GVA figures illustrate that general activity is suppressed and the sector remains underdeveloped in terms of participating in the development of the Armenian economy. The high entry levels in the transportation and communications sector are explained by the large number of retail service pro- viders in the telecommunications sector and the recent increase in the number of lines in public transportation. Importantly, the procedure for granting ownership rights for specific lines remains anticompetitive. The increased number of different sector-specific services provided in the country also explains the high entry fig- ures (for example, freight). The electricity, gas, and water supply sector has moderate entry, GVA, and employment levels. Although there are issues still to be resolved, the sector's restructuring practice is one of the suc- cess stories in Armenia. Strengthening Competition 289 COMPETITION POLICY IN ARMENIA This section looks briefly at some of the issues related to sectors that are traditionally regulated in most economies, including telecommuni- cations, power, water, natural gas, transport, and airports. In Armenia, telecommunications regulation was brought under the jurisdiction of the Public Service Regulatory Commission (PSRC) in 2006 by legisla- tive change. The PSRC also regulates power, water, and natural gas. Other sectors are regulated differently. The General Department of Civil Aviation regulates air traffic. Yerevan Airport is operated under a concessional agreement by a foreign company. A concessional agree- ment was an important step in creating favorable initial conditions for successful air transportation regulation. The Ministry of Transport reg- ulates transportation. The railway company is still state owned, and unfavorable practices have been reported in this sector (see below). In addition, the Commission for the Protection of Economic Competition (CPEC) has authority regarding actions by companies in these sectors that are deemed harmful to the consumer. This authority has not yet been exercised, although the CPEC is adamant that it could exercise this authority in the future. The PSRC has been the recipient of substantial support from donors, both to provide technical assistance to upgrade skills and to improve its operating infrastructure. As a result, the capacity of the PSRC to regulate the industries under its jurisdiction has improved. Competition Law in Armenia A full analysis of the Competition Law is beyond the scope of this chapter. Furthermore, there are many aspects of competition in Arme- nia that, although relevant, are outside the ambit of the law. Nev- ertheless, some observations on certain features of the law and its application in Armenia are pertinent. Competition law is a relatively recent innovation in Armenia. The law establishing the State CPEC was passed in 2000 and the CPEC itself began prosecuting cases in 2001. Some key aspects of the law include the following: The law prohibits collusion among enterprises, although it fails to distinguish between vertical and horizontal collusion. Gener- ally, economists view horizontal collusion as potentially much more damaging to consumers. Vertical agreements can also present problems, but the circumstances under which this occurs need investigation and analysis. Potential problems could arise in Armenia because the CPEC's technical capacity for this analy- sis is limited. 290 Part II: Detailed Analysis Article 4 of the law prohibits anticompetitive practices between loosely connected groups, although the criteria for determining such behavior are loosely set out and would require intensive investigation, involving several different levels of complexity. Article 6 of the law indicates that a firm may be considered to have a dominant position in the market if it is not exposed to substantial competition, or if it commands a market share of more than one-third of total sales. The law forbids the abuse of dominant market power. In Arme- nia, the CPEC maintains a list of firms with such power and supposedly tracks them to ensure that their behavior does not involve abuse. Most of the cases brought by the CPEC have involved firms that are in this list. Cases have been prosecuted under Article 7 of the law, which applies to the abuse of a domi- nant market position. The Foreign Investment Advisory Service (FIAS) has criticized this approach on the grounds that the CPEC appears to consider that any firm in the list is automatically sus- pect--which essentially means any large company. Once a firm is on the list of dominant firms, scrutiny intensifies and transac- tions costs for the firm rise sharply. The CPEC has brought a number of cases of "unjustified pric- ing" based on a methodology involving comparisons between the selling prices of the company and general price indices. Such action makes little analytical sense, in that there is no allowance for shifts in relative prices, and it implicitly assumes that profits should not differ among products, companies, and sectors. Article 8 of the law defines market concentration and control through mergers and acquisitions and revolves around a market share of 35 percent or more. Combined with Article 10 of the law, which prohibits concentration unless it fosters competition, Article 8 is used to justify action against such companies. Article 9 requires that firms with substantial market power must be registered as being dominant. Implementation of the law presents a number of problems. The weak institutional framework in Armenia appears to result in some cases (especially in the areas outlined in later sections of this discussion) not being prosecuted, whereas other cases appear to show an excessive tar- geting of some firms. As in many other areas of private sector issues in Armenia, the law itself is not the primary problem. The existing leg- islation, while inadequate in some areas, could be used to prosecute uncompetitive behavior. Rather, problems lie in the application of the law, the protection that some groups appear to have, and the generally weak private sector business environment that limits opportunities for new entrants. These issues are explored at greater length below. Strengthening Competition 291 Telecommunications After independence, Armenia inherited a relatively extensive but low- quality telecommunications network. The design of the network was not commercially driven, which led to misallocated lines and low call volumes. These elements, combined with politically driven low local tariffs and in spite of high international call rates, resulted in low rev- enues per line. The outcome was outdated equipment, poor network quality, and a slow digitalization rate due to chronic underinvestment in the sector. During the early stages of restructuring, the government added substantially to the problems of the telecommunications sector by awarding a long-term monopoly (granted until 2013) to ArmenTel, the local telecommunications company, owned by the Hellenic Telecom- munications Organization (OTE), a Greek company. The process of privatization was poorly handled, was not transparent, and occurred without an adequate regulatory framework. In November 2004, the government issued a new license to Armen- Tel (after a longstanding dispute and renegotiations)7, signed a new Settlement Agreement with OTE/ArmenTel, and issued a second Glo- bal System for Mobile Communications (GSM) license with immediate effect, thereby partially liberalizing the market. The settlement agree- ment provides for a third GSM license to be issued on January 1, 2009. In addition, ArmenTel was deprived of its monopoly over Internet use in Armenia. At the same time, the government granted the company a monopoly for telephony based on the Voice over Internet Protocol (VoIP). The award of the second telecommunications license was not con- sistent with international good practice, given that only one candidate, K-Telecom (the operator in Karabakh using GSM technologies that is associated with Karabakh Telecom) was considered. The government perceived the issuance of this license as a "case of exceptional impor- tance" for Armenia's national security and provided Karabakh with international access to all telecommunications services. It is socially desirable to have an entrant in a competitive market for the following reasons: Entrants often offer a differentiated service not offered by incumbents. Entrants often provide existing services at a lower cost. Entrants often force the incumbent to produce services more efficiently. It is generally agreed (see Laffont and Tirole 2000) that an intelli- gent interconnection policy is the key to the harmonious development 292 Part II: Detailed Analysis of competition in the telecommunications industry. The offering of mobile services by ArmenTel and K-Telecom will give rise to two-way termination access charges. The government should therefore imple- ment interconnection charges and policies to facilitate competition, induce efficient network use, and encourage investment along with cost minimization. To ensure this end, the PSRC needs continued donor assistance to enhance its regulatory capabilities in the telecom- munications sector. Regulatory Challenge On the basis of the terms and conditions of both parties' licenses and the 2004 ArmenTel Settlement Agreement, it is unlikely that the cur- rent market configuration will change significantly and allow new entrants, at least not until 2009.8 In the early stages of partial market liberalization, however, embryonic competition if left to itself gen- erally favors the incumbent. Clearly, in the Armenian telecommuni- cations sector, competition is asymmetric: ArmenTel and K-Telecom compete for subscribers, but the former already has 205,000 mobile phone subscribers. Unfortunately, there have been few contributions (even theoretical) to the study of asymmetric competition, mainly owing to the compli- cations that arise by assuming that access charges should not be set reciprocally (see Cave, Majumar, and Vogelsgang 2002). The policy implications of the findings vary with the assumed underlying eco- nomic environment. Demand-Side Asymmetry and Nonreciprocal Termination Charges Demand-side asymmetry and nonreciprocal termination charges closely resemble Armenia's current situation in the telecommunica- tions sector. With the new law and its expectations regarding the regu- lation of the retail level, the implications may need to be modified; however, they are case sensitive and will require additional research. These implications include the following: Large differences in access charges (where the well-established firm is paid the higher access charge) act to reduce competition for subscribers. Two existing firms may differ over the setting of termination charges, and regulation is generally needed to resolve disputes. Generally, sector profits will increase with the increased difference in termination charges, but the gains to firms from this increase Strengthening Competition 293 change depending on the firm. This situation can lead to collusion between firms, with side payments from one firm to another. The market share of the networks affects total welfare. The mag- nitude of the effect depends on demand elasticity. In contrast to service providers, the increased access charges lower consumer welfare, which necessitates balanced access pricing policy in Armenia's telecommunications sector. The high cost of telecommunications in Armenia is particularly severe given that the country is isolated from Europe and the United States: there is an acute need for low communications costs in small, remote economies. It is critical, therefore, that the government and the PSRC deal with this situation appropriately and proactively. Utilities The electricity sector has been substantially restructured over the past few years. First of all, the distribution system has been privatized--an effort that appears to have been very successful. Whereas prior to privatization, inefficiencies, and large arrears strained the system to the breaking point, arrears have now been eliminated, electricity bills are collected on time, and the system is functioning reliably. This is one of the success stories of Armenian privatization. The power generation sector consists of five large generators, one of which is nuclear, two of which are thermal, and two of which are hydroelectric. One of the hydro generators and one of the thermal generators are run by Russia, which acquired the generators from the Armenian government in a debt-for-equity swap. Russians also run the nuclear station under a management contract. In addition to the large generators, there are a substantial number of small private hydro producers who supply the grid, which is compelled to purchase any power that they produce. The PSRC also regulates the natural gas distribution sector. Many of the same issues appear to apply to this sector and there is no indication that it was being run ineffectively. The Russian-Armenian joint-stock company "ArmRusGasProd" has invested intensively in developing a gas distribution network in the country. The CPEC regulates the producers9 on a rate-of-return basis. Although it is possible to quibble over the efficiency of rate-of-return regulation, a brief review has indicated that it appears to be carried out competently, although a more in-depth study would be needed to confirm this. The challenge will be to move economic regulation gen- erally onto more efficient, credible, multiyear, price-cap regulation. 294 Part II: Detailed Analysis Railways More than a decade of economic transition in Armenia is a lively illus- tration of forgone development opportunities owing to the transpor- tation blockade. Transportation is essential to promote sustained eco- nomic growth and prosperity, given companies' need to obtain inputs for production and deliver goods to the market. Armenia has suffered severely in this regard, not only because of the blockade by Turkey and Azerbaijan but also because productivity in the transport sector, particularly in railways, has been low. The evidence suggests that the operation of Armenia's state-owned railway is politically motivated at the expense of operational efficiency and social welfare. There have been reports of nontransparent and opportunistic price setting by the Armenian railway company. For example, during rate negotiations that the Ministry of Transportation and Communication was undertaking with the Gold Mining Company, the state-owned railway company attempted to extract very high profits through its dominant position in the sector by proposing high rates for transport- ing ore. The Gold Mining Company needed to connect its mining facilities (situated in the northeastern part of the country) with its melting facilities (located in the southwestern part of the country), and other means of transportation were economically inefficient. The min- ing company was in a weak position that the railway company was exploiting. Hence, the railway industry and the state-owned railway company in particular need to be restructured so as to contribute to sustained economic growth. The government of Armenia has decided to concession the railway and has selected the vertically integrated concession option. It will undertake the concession through a trans- parent and competitive international tender. A government decree dated September 16, 2006, appointed an Intersectorial Commission to present specific recommendations on implementation of the conces- sioning. A number of important issues related to the railway law, the concession design, and the oversight regime must be resolved to suc- cessfully concession the railway. The next section provides concepts to guide the process and ensure restructuring and regulation efficiency. Restructuring When considering rail transportation restructuring, Armenia needs to analyze the industry more generally within the context of its techno- logical and organizational features as well as evaluating the recent performance in detail. Five generic options for the vertical restruc- turing of railway are considered in the literature (see Kessides and Willig 1995). The competitive access option presented below has the Strengthening Competition 295 potential to bring more competition, market-based decision making, and innovation into the railway industry.10 Competitive access is char- acterized by the existence of an integrated operator11 required to make rail facilities, such as tracks and stations, available to other operators on a fair and equal basis through the trading of, for example, circula- tion rights. The potential for the implementation of the competitive access option in Armenia is favorable for a number of reasons. Active Intermodal Competition The passenger transportation data provided in Table 10.6 illustrate the small share of the railway sec- tor, which is mainly due to the enormous growth of motorization, to Armenia's landlocked geographic location coupled with its bad rela- tions with neighboring countries, and to the poor condition of the existing railway facilities (such as stations and passenger wagons). In freight, the expanding competitive trucking sector has gained the largest percentage of the transportation market. The figures on inter- nal freight volumes (see Table 10.7) illustrate the existing competitive pressures on the rail sector. This phenomenon is explained in terms of the following: Geographic size and road conditions inside the country. Virtually all of the destination points along the internal haul are connected by roads in good condition, which enables trucks to transport loads effectively and without delays. Industry dependence. Ore constitutes about 50 percent of deliv- ered (internal and imported) freight. Construction materials, both mineral and nonmineral (such as stones and cement), constitute Table 10.6 Percentage Share, by Weight, of Different Modes of Transportation, 1999­2003 Mode 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Passenger transportation Railway 1 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.6 Vehicle 73.2 75.7 80.3 82.7 85.5 Air transportation 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 Other (underground, trams) 25.4 23 18.4 16 13.4 Freight Railway 29.2 31.8 28 26.8 30.1 Vehicle 52.4 46.3 52.1 63.1 57.9 Air transportation 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.1 Pipeline 18.1 21.6 19.7 10 11.9 Source: NSS. 296 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 10.7 Internal Freight in Volumes and Percentage Shares, 1999­2003 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Railroad Internal (thousands tons) 407.1 333.6 355.3 854.1 891.4 Internal (%) 0.29 0.23 0.25 0.42 0.42 Vehicle Internal (thousands tons) 2,157.6 1,776.0 2,203.1 4,323.4 3,548.4 Internal (%) 0.87 0.86 0.84 0.91 0.87 Source: NSS. another 15 percent. Therefore, an integrated operator would be unable to exercise its power on captive shippers (like the Gold Mining Company) if the competitive access restructuring is cou- pled with efficient regulation. In other words, Armenia's railway sector is far more contestable12 due to the strong competitive pressure from other modes of trans- portation. Economies of Scope, Coordinated Planning, and Reduced Transaction Costs It is often noted that the relationship among the supplied serv- ices, the rolling stock used, and the quality, quantity, and technical characteristics of the infrastructure is so close that these aspects need to be planned together. Thus, assigning different services to several operators may decrease the utilization of the sector's staff and physi- cal assets. This argument is especially relevant for the Armenia rail network, which is far from extensive. Increased Investment Incentives In a vertically separated structure, an infrastructure owner considering an investment in a facility with only one potential operator will anticipate bargaining away some of the benefit from the new service once it comes on line. The other problem that may arise with a vertically separated structure is the difficulty of the coordination of the operator with the infrastructure owner on investment decisions. A competitive access structure (with an integrated operator) is not dependent on such coordination, which reduces incentive problems. However, there is a possible shortcoming associated with the implementation of a competitive access option that needs to be considered: an integrated operator may have strong incentives to keep possible entrants out. Strengthening Competition 297 The solution to this problem is usually addressed by involving private management through concession contract arrangements and through regulatory policy (the latter being the subject of the next sub- section.) A private concession contract has the potential to stimulate the efficient development of the Armenian railway sector if the gov- ernment implements a competitive access restructuring. (Concessions are a broader form of lease in which the contractor agrees to make cer- tain fixed investments and maintains the use of the assets for a longer period.) A greater risk of closure of certain services, or of larger insta- bility, is obviously a potential issue with a private company. Again, concession systems reduce the risks inherent in the involvement of private enterprise. The design of a concession contract is a complex undertaking that should take into account, among other things, the type of contract (for example, horizontal versus vertical, passenger versus freight), award and duration (for example, type of auction, selection), content (for example, obligation, rights, asset ownership), price control, quality regulation, and so forth. It requires additional in- depth analysis of the sector, which is beyond the scope of the current report. But the quality of the concession contract will determine the design of regulatory policy and is therefore critical to the process. Efficient Regulation Although it is difficult to predict every situation that could undermine competition within the "competitive access/concession restructuring" option, Armenia should avoid two arrangements that affect incentives and deter efficient entry when designing its regulatory policy: Regulation should not constrain what an integrated operator can earn through cooperating with another entity. If earnings are constrained, the operator has a strong incentive to enlarge the portion of services it provides by hindering entry. Regulation should not permit firms to charge higher prices to shippers the more of their business they have, as this would also provide incentives for the firm to exclude other participants. These two situations suggest that Armenia should adopt pricing principles (widely discussed in the literature on regulation economics) that are efficient under the competitive access option. These pricing principles include the following: Ramsey pricing. This pricing scheme is appropriate with multi- service operation segments with actual or potential competitive pressure. The Ramsey approach apportions all unattributable fixed 298 Part II: Detailed Analysis and common costs of the railway among its services on the basis of their demand characteristics. The challenge for the regulatory body in implementing this policy is the complex task of estimating demand for the services provided by the integrated operator. Stand-alone costs. Where there is market dominance, Armenia should implement economically rational ceilings on rates, which can be obtained from the stand-alone costs. Stand-alone costs are the costs of serving any captive shipper if the shipper is isolated from the railway's other customers. The benefit of this pricing principle is that it overcomes the problem of entry deterrence possible under a competitive access restructuring option.13 Armenia should establish regulatory standards based on the principle that the integrated carrier that possesses a bottleneck should not refuse an agreement that provides full compensa- tion of all its costs, including opportunity costs. The standards should be implemented once disputes about predation through competitive access arise. Given that with railways there is a one-way access bottleneck, access fees should be priced using the principle of efficient com- ponent pricing. Pricing should be based on the idea that an inte- grated carrier should offer the services of its bottleneck at a price that yields it the same return as if it had performed the end user's services itself. Civil Aviation Issues relating to air traffic also provide grounds for concern. The national flag carrier, the state-owned Armenian Airlines, went bank- rupt and was liquidated in 2003. A local company, Armavia, bought the liquidated Armenian Airlines and acquired Armenian route rights for flights to and from Armenia via an agreement with the govern- ment. There have been reports that whenever foreign airlines operat- ing in Armenia have wanted to increase the number of their flights and have applied for permission to Civil Aviation, Civil Aviation has in turn sought the views of Armavia, which must be given greater weight by the Armavia agreement. This clearly substantially puts Armenia at a disadvantage. A small, remote economy that implements policies that drive up the price of communications (whether they are telecommunications policies or transportation policies) is effectively exacerbating the costs of its small size and remoteness. The Armenian national interest requires that the government take as bold a policy towards air transport as it appears to be taking with the telecommunication monopoly. An Open Skies policy should be implemented without delay, provided an arrange- ment can be made with Armavia.14 Strengthening Competition 299 LACK OF COMPETITION IN DISTRIBUTION Many private sector participants in Armenia operate in ways that would be unusual in the industrial countries. As is common in many countries with weak institutions, facilitation payments are frequently used as a means of ensuring that dealings with the public sector pro- ceed without undue delay. However, unlike other countries, in Arme- nia the system has to date not degenerated into one where massive corruption is pervasive, although undoubtedly there is corruption that extends to the highest levels. Rather, facilitation payments have evolved into a system in which interlocking obligations arising from favors and interventions govern much of the interaction among the business community as well as that between businesses and the legal system. A person who acts to intercede on behalf of another becomes a roof and the benefactor incurs an obligation to return the favor in one form or another at some point in the future. In Armenia, there appear to be few rules which cannot be modified or adjusted through the intervention of a roof, even within the judicial system. In sec- tors where a powerful roof exists, the incumbents appear to have the power to make life extremely difficult for new entrants. It is also noteworthy that foreign investors often do not have the network which provides them with a roof, and thus they frequently have more difficulty in navigating their way through the various bureaucracies and the judiciary. This reality has been reflected in all of the foreign investment surveys done on Armenia. In addition, companies that are only exporters claim that they are singled out for unfavorable treatment, especially with respect to VAT refunds. This phenomenon can act as a substantial barrier to entry in the economy, on the part of foreign investors as well as for new local businesses that attempt to compete with well-established companies and individuals operating in the Armenian economy. Although there have been improvements recently, subtle methods are used to impose severe operating constraints on new competition, ranging from prob- lems in clearing goods through customs, to inspections of various types by government officials, to outright sabotage of operations. Fur- thermore, such behavior is difficult to identify clearly because it is protected by all the members of a particular roof. There are numerous and widespread anecdotes to the effect that the economy is dominated by a few powerful groups that maintain a tight control on certain activities, particularly imports of petroleum, sugar, flowers, and wheat. It is, however, difficult to obtain hard evidence on the allegations, and the deeper the investigation is, the greater the contradictions are. There do appear to be roofs operating in these sectors but, on the face of it, there is some competition. On the other hand, there are also widespread allegations that companies in this 300 Part II: Detailed Analysis area are anonymously owned by interlocking share holdings, so that effectively the sectors are controlled by a small number of people who are making large profits and who engage in extremely conspicuous consumption. Petroleum Products Having no oil or natural gas resources, Armenia is totally dependent upon imports. Imports of fuel products constitute about 20 percent of total imports. This import group includes two major components in terms of volumes: petroleum products (including gasoline and diesel) and natural gas imports. Statistics on petroleum product imports appear to have been underreported. First, all of the data largely exclude imports by the Defense Ministry, Internal Affairs, and the nuclear power station, so it is not possible to determine the total imports of these prod- ucts. Furthermore, in spite of very rapid growth, statistics on gaso- line and diesel imports into Armenia show that in 2000 there was a sharp drop in import volumes and only a very modest growth afterwards. This occurred despite a very sharp increase in auto- mobile imports, which rough statistics indicate exceed 14,000 vehi- cles per year compared with 1,200 per year in 1999. Although oil prices rose in 2000, and demand may have been depressed by the fuel efficiency of recently imported automobiles and conversion of some motor vehicles from gasoline to natural gas, it does not seem likely that in the face of such rapid growth fuel consumption could go down. One explanation for the flat fuel imports is that there is smuggling of petroleum. The structure of market concentration underwent changes during 1999­2000. In 1999 there was only one gasoline importer in Armenia, so that market power was located inside the borders of the country. In 2000 and 2001 the number of importers into the country increased; looking only at the number of operators within Armenia, the mar- ket could not be defined as uncompetitive. However, analyzing the import chain reveals that one supplier provides the bulk (88 percent) of imported gasoline to importers. While the concentration of direct importers has declined, the virtually single sourcing of supply for gasoline importers means that the supply chain remains highly con- centrated. Even though it has been reported that one more company started to supply importers with gasoline in 2002, the share of the incumbent supplier firm remained dominant. It constituted about 70 percent of total supply to importers. (Noncompetitive behavior and its impact on the gasoline market and relationships to welfare losses are discussed in Box 10.1 and also shown in Table 10.8.) Strengthening Competition 301 Box 10.1 Noncompetitive Behavior in the Gasoline Market To stress the negative impact of noncompetitive behavior in the gaso- line market we made a very simple calculation of welfare losses (see text Table 10.8). (For the explanation of the terms used in the analysis below, see Tirole 1988.) We assumed a linear market-specific demand curve and estimated its slope and intercept considering price-increase versus demand-decrease scenarios during 1999­2000. Such a decrease in demand is mainly explained by increases in international oil prices in contrast to the observed nonprice impact (such as increased imports of cars after 2000) on demand during later years. It turns out that welfare loss, as a result of noncompetitive behavior in the gasoline market alone, was averaged at 1.3 percent of GDP. This loss figure can be even higher if we consider that there is a double marginalization (we have not included in the calculations the dead- weight loss, which can occur as a result of the monopoly power of one supplier of importers) and that the same situation dominates in many other similar markets (such as the diesel market). Moreover, the importance of liberalizing the petroleum oils market is accentuated by the fact that concentrated, rather high gasoline market profits (about 3.7 percent of GDP) have not contributed to reducing the unequal distribution of income in the country. Source: Authors' calculations. More interestingly, even though the large number of retail compa- nies operating in Armenia, ensures retail competition, the retail mark- up price was substantially higher than the imported (wholesale) price (which we took to be customs clearing price). The gross profit mark- up, most of which probably occurs at the wholesale level, constituted more than half of the retail price in 2001 (Figure 10.2). Since competi- tion at the retail level is strong, it is most unlikely that excess prof- its are being earned by retailers: most of the profits probably accrue to the wholesalers. These very rough calculations indicate that there appear to be large welfare losses arising from the concentration of the petroleum market, which could amount to the equivalent of over 1 percent of GDP. This loss figure would be even higher if we take into consideration the further profit margin earned by the single-source monopoly supplier of imports. Moreover, similar welfare losses can be expected to be experienced in other fuels, such as diesel. This is not included in the calculations of the deadweight loss, which can occur as a result of the monopoly power of the one supplier of imports. 302 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 10.8 Welfare Calculations in the Petroleum Market, 1999­2001 1999 2000 2001 Retail price (drams per ton) 265,133.7 370,307.4 362,576.0 Customs clearing price (drams per ton) 118,300.0 145,100.0 159,200.0 Quantities consumed (tons) 258,100.0 181,400.0 187,500.0 Total profit (drams) 37,897,777,970.0 40,852,622,360.0 38,133,000,000.0 Estimated slope of the demand curve ­1.4 ­1.4 ­1.4 Estimated intercept of the demand curve 626,473.7 626,473.7 626,473.7 Quantities under customs clearing price 362,981.2 343,838.4 333,766.9 Deadweight loss (drams) 7,700,048,377.0 18,291,160,036.2 14,873,591,432.6 Deadweight loss (US$) 14,528,393.2 33,256,654.6 26,094,020.1 GDP (US$ million) 1,845.5 1,911.5 2,118.4 Deadweight loss as a percentage of GDP 0.8 1.8 1.3 Source: Author's calculations. Sugar The vast majority of sugar imports are brought into Armenia by a sin- gle importer. The sugar importing company was investigated by the CPEC, but before a judgment could be reached, the importing com- pany was dissolved and a new one was opened, but with the same shareholders. As a result, the original case did not proceed. Trade data indicate that 70 per cent of the imported sugar comes from the United Kingdom. Monopoly power in the sugar market is reflected in the price and markup data. Figure 10.3 shows that the difference between the cus- toms clearing price and the retail price of sugar is substantial--the retail margin is 47 percent, very high by any standards. As with petro- leum, there is substantial competition at the retail level so excess prof- its are unlikely to be earned at this stage. Table 10.9 reveals the patterns of the markup. Sugar has a very low demand price elasticity, which allows a high-profit-seeking importer with dominant power to hinder potential entrants. The sugar mar- ket profit was estimated to average around US$14 million during 1999­2002. Strengthening Competition 303 Figure 10.2 Gasoline Price Structure, 1999­2001 (drams per ton) 100 146,833 225,207 203,376 90 80 70 60 50 percent 40 118,300 159,200 145,100 30 20 10 0 1999 2000 2001 year margin over wholesale price customs clearing price Source: NSS. Figure 10.3 Sugar Price Decomposition (US$ per kilo) 100 0.21 0.22 0.18 0.18 90 80 70 60 0.25 0.26 50 0.24 0.25 percent 40 30 20 10 0 2002 2001 2000 1999 year markup customs clearing Source: Author's calculations. 304 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 10.9 Sugar Market Data, 1999­2002 1999 2000 2001 2002 Markup (US$/kilogram) 0.185 0.176 0.222 0.205 Percentage annual change of markup -- ­4.650 25.933 ­7.349 Import of sugar (metric tons) 69,836 69,422 73,485 68,400 Percentage annual change in volumes of imported sugar -- ­0.592 5.853 ­6.921 Source: NSS. -- Not available. Some in Armenia argue that there are no large welfare issues aris- ing from the importation of sugar. They point out that the market is small and the main supplier can use its dominant position to purchase large quantities of sugar at a low price. Therefore, even if there are some monopoly rents being extracted, the welfare losses are offset by lower wholesale prices than would exist if there were several import- ers buying at higher prices in the exporting countries. The flaw in this argument is that if the current importer had concerns about new entrants, it would not exploit market dominance to the same degree and would extract lower rents. In addition, the large number of busi- nesses opening in areas where there is no restriction on competition illustrates the potential dynamism of the economy. Companies in the areas of ITC, restaurants, retail outlets, and building are being created in large numbers. Clearly, there is an entrepreneurial and dynamic element in the Armenian economy. Restricting competition harms this element as well as consumers. Wheat and Cut Flowers Gathering data in other markets proved more difficult, and it was not possible to undertake an analysis as detailed as that for petro- leum and sugar. Approximately 50 percent of Armenia's wheat is imported, as is the majority of cut flowers. There are widespread reports of the concentration of distribution in both of these prod- ucts. Potential competitors are being harassed at the borders by customs, which has employed many nontariff restrictions (such as health standards, quality standards, and valuation prices) in order to delay imports to the point where costs arising from dealing with the delay erode any potential profit. These issues are discussed at greater length in the next section. Strengthening Competition 305 HOW MONOPOLIES ARE MAINTAINED Corruption and rent sharing with state officials are a pervasive reality of doing business in Armenia. These practices affect the competitive environment in many ways. Market incumbents make illicit payments to or enter into collusion with governmental officials, agreeing to share rents, which are generated as a result of collusion. There are reports of state officials being given shares in the incumbent companies, which distorts the incentives associated with increasing public welfare through greater competition. The incentive for officials who are also shareholders in the incumbent companies is to maintain the status quo. As a result, the abuse of the state power is used as a tool for maintain- ing monopolies in the market. Although illicit and sometimes violent "private methods" have been used to maintain a dominant position in one specific market, the abuse of state power remains the most effec- tive and widespread method of maintaining monopoly power. The Customs Office Armenia has made great strides in attaining compliance associated with WTO access. This has not prevented the Customs Office from remaining one of the predominant instruments for hampering or elim- inating potential competitors, particularly in the distribution sector. Customs clearance and valuation procedures are far from being trans- parent and standardized (see Box 10.2), with substantial discretion being applied in the licensing of brokers, storage, freight transporters, and the operation of the free trade zone. In addition, the continued widespread use of reference pricing in contravention of WTO commitments is another method of delay- ing imports. Since customs also has some responsibility for enforc- ing product standards (for example, on health and safety grounds), the number of potential administrative barriers is legion, particularly since some of these standards are also under the jurisdiction of the Ministry of Health. There are therefore numerous opportunities for delaying imports for a number of reasons. Some of these issues are discussed in greater detail in the following sections. Limiting the Number of Customs Brokers and Associated Activities The Customs Office controls "unwanted" private enrollment in cus- toms operation through the widely reported unfair and discretionary licensing of customs brokers.15 The Customs Office appears to strictly limit the number of brokers through customs examinations. Each year 306 Part II: Detailed Analysis Box 10.2 Anti-Competitive Practices of the Customs Office Royal Armenian JV LTD imports 8,000­9,000 tons of green coffee annu- ally, processes it, and exports 70 percent of the processed product (mostly to Europe). The company was founded in 1998, and 96 percent of its capital belongs to a private person, a citizen of the Republic of Cuba. On July 2004 the chairman of the company publicly accused the State Customs Committee Deputy Chairman and other senior officials of personally soliciting a bribe last year in return for undervaluing the price of imported coffee beans, thereby reducing the import tax the company would be required to pay. After the company refused the offer, customs retaliated by overstating the value of the coffee imported at US$1.8 per kilogram; the actual cost was US$1.2, and the estimated cost for other importers was calculated to be less than US$1 per kilogram. Royal Armenia won a legal action against the Customs Committee for discrimination, but the ruling that the increased tariff on their imports should be reduced has not been enforced. The chairman of the com- pany was later reported as having retracted his accusation regarding the customs authorities. Source: Based on interviews and newspaper reports. there are examinations for customs brokers: even incumbents must take annual exams.16 A reliable source reported to the mission that in 2003 apparently 30 out of 36 applicants passed the examination but after internal review the Customs Committee declared that there were only 5 successful applicants. One of the unsuccessful applicants (an operating broker) was apparently able to get another minister to call the chairman of the Customs Committee on his behalf, so that finally there were 6 successful applicants. On the face of it, the procedure is entirely valid--a written examination subject to scrutiny and appeal. In practice, however, the results of the examination are subject to internal review and adjustment at the whim of the Customs Committee. This "informal review" procedure is not written down anywhere. Since there is such wide discretion, however, the Customs Committee can strictly con- trol the number of brokers and can ensure that they are compliant through the annual examination. Clearing Procedures Customs have introduced electronic clearing procedures to expedite the clearance of goods. Customs brokers, however, do not have access Strengthening Competition 307 to the computer system and therefore have to deal with paper doc- umentation that nullifies many of the advantages of computerized clearance and that also keeps the brokers in the dark with respect to the status of the goods that they are attempting to clear. The result is that there are uncertainties in the process and delays that can cost importers substantial amounts, especially since they are charged for the storage of the goods that are held up. In late 2005 the customs authorities began piloting a direct trader input system and reforms towards automation in clearances in goods covering about 5 percent of imports. They undertook to extend the pilot to about 70 percent of imports by April 2006. If they are implemented successfully and in line with international good practice, these steps would constitute a major reform in customs administration and significantly benefit the forces of competition. Another issue frequently cited by importers is the continued use of reference pricing by customs unless extensive documentation accom- panies shipments.17 If any of the documents are missing, then customs applies reference prices to the shipment, a practice that is not consist- ent with WTO rules. In other countries goods can be cleared with partial documentation under surety bonds that provide a guarantee in the event that the declaration was incorrect. However, the lack of financial system development in Armenia implies that surety bonds are difficult to obtain and that even when they are obtained, the cost is high. The problem of reference prices is further compounded by the relatively high VAT rate (20 percent) and the historic difficulty in obtaining drawbacks of VAT payments upon the export of any goods that use imports as inputs. However, a significant improvement has taken place in the practice of refunding VAT dues to exporters, in the course of 2005, both as to amounts and as to timeliness; this trend should continue. The Role of the CPEC Should the CPEC be one of the pillars of the policy of promoting com- petition in Armenia? There are understandable concerns that it could become yet another layer of bureaucracy that leads to "inspections" and interference in the ability of businesses to function, which in turn could be used to harass entrepreneurs and to protect incumbency. Arguments in favor of the strengthening of the CPEC are based on the recognition that it could be one of the ways in which the restrictions on competition that abound in several sectors of the economy could be resisted. The view of this chapter is that, in its present form, the CPEC is not a significant bulwark against anticompetitive behavior. It has neither the necessary skills, nor the staff, nor the facilities to operate effectively. Although it has been successful in a limited number of cases,18 it is not 308 Part II: Detailed Analysis a force in areas where competition is obviously restricted. Its report on the petroleum market is deficient in depth as well as analysis.19 This does not mean that attempts to assist the CPEC therefore should be abandoned, since over the longer term the commission could be one of the instruments for promoting competition in Armenia. Modest technical assistance is warranted and perhaps some help with improv- ing its ITC resources. It is unrealistic, however, to perceive the CPEC as useful in the shorter term. It needs several years to evolve into an instrument against restrictions on competition. Nevertheless, its con- tinued existence is assured, and the interests of the private sector lie in its improving its technical competence. BARRIERS TO ENTRY Formal barriers to entry have been reduced. For example, the cost of registering a business is now much reduced and occurs with few delays. The Armenian authorities are determined to eliminate delays altogether. However, reducing the costs of formalization does not address the many issues related to the benefits of being formal. As the next sections will point out, public goods related to the business sector are still inadequate. To enhance competition, the authorities are focusing on access to finance and access to the system of for- mal contracting. In Armenia, financial markets function poorly and the system of contracting and dispute resolution is haphazard at best and under normal circumstances is not effective. It does not provide Armenian businesses with incentives to formalize, particularly since it also allows petty officialdom to target formal businesses with inspec- tions that have payoffs as their aim. There has been some progress in reducing these inspections. For example, tax officials can only conduct one audit per year. However, they are still allowed to undertake "fact finding," which is not clas- sified as an audit. Nevertheless, businesses report that information obtained during fact finding, which can occur as often as requested, is used in annual audits. The protection of the restriction on auditing is therefore no more than limited. Financial Markets The relationship between financial market development and pov- erty alleviation is well established (see, for example, Holden and Prokopenko 2001). Financial markets play a key role in intermediat- ing between savers and investors. In addition, the financing of new projects enhances openness and competition by ensuring that prof- Strengthening Competition 309 itable investment opportunities do not go untapped. Although it is currently difficult to measure the overall severity of anticompetitive practices owing to inefficient financial markets, two practices do put pressure on Armenia's competitive environment. First, in product markets where a firm (usually with power or con- nections) has propitious access to or controls over financial instruments, the incentive is created to use them to affect the product market and thus hinder possible entrants. Second, there is indirect or financially driven deterrence. Because of the vulnerability of the financial sector Armenia's lending institutions are constrained by two lending options: either to be particularly cautious in entering into financial contracts with an incumbent firm or to restrict lending to other business entities in the same or a closely related product market as their returns become more or less sensitive to the effect of product market competition.20 In both cases there is excessive pressure on product market competition. Financially driven entry deterrence is most important when financial market competition is limited. This situation establishes an important policy implication: it is difficult to promote product market competi- tion if financial markets are concentrated? This in turn suggests the need for more antitrust coordination among the regulators of financial and product markets than is currently the norm in Armenia. Financial Underdevelopment Financial markets in Armenia are bank dominated, underdeveloped, and effectively finance neither local production nor foreign trade. Figures 10.4 and 10.5 show the level of financial market devel- opment in Armenia compared to that in other countries at various stages of development.21 Even by the standards of low-income coun- tries (those with per capita incomes of less than US$1,000) the ratio of credit to the private sector is very low--only one-fourth that of the average credit-to-GDP ratio in other low-income countries. The lack of finance for business acts as a severe barrier to entry. Potential competitors cannot obtain finance for their businesses, either in the form of working capital or to finance foreign trade. The result is that incumbents' market dominance is rarely threatened by new entrants and that wealth remains concentrated among those with resources. In spite of the low amount of credit to the private sector, there does not appear to be an excess demand for loans. On the contrary, at cur- rent rates of interest there is an excess supply of loanable funds. For example, the largest bank in Armenia, Hong Kong and Shanghai Bank- ing Corporation (HSBC), lends a much smaller proportion of its liabili- ties (10 percent) to private business than it does in other countries in which it operates, where it lends 60 to 70 percent of liabilities. 310 Part II: Detailed Analysis Figure 10.4 Interest Rate Spreads (lending rate minus deposit rate) 60 Armenia 50 low income lower middle income upper middle income 40 high income countries cent 30 per 20 10 0 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 year Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics. http://ifs.apdi.net/imf/. Although interest rate spreads between borrowing and lending rates have fallen, they remain higher than in other low-income countries. Financial activity in the foreign trade sector is limited. Some import- ers do use letters of credit in the banking system, but the practice is not widespread. There is little export financing. The practice of using irrevocable letters of credit as a basis for providing funds to fulfill export orders appears to be nonexistent. As a result, the financial sys- tem cannot be said to support the growth of trade, which in turn is the key to promoting more competition in Armenia. The essential skills in raising letters of credit are confined to a small number of banks. Before exporting under letters of credit can occur, training in the minutiae of the procedures will be required for most banks in Armenia. Financial sector development is constrained by weaknesses in financial infrastructure, such as creditor rights, credit information, and corporate governance. Weak Creditor Rights Weak creditor rights raise losses in the event of default, contributing to wider lending margins and reducing the availability of credit. This Strengthening Competition 311 Figure 10.5 Domestic Credit to the Private Sector (percent of GDP) 160 140 120 100 80 percent 60 40 20 0 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 year Armenia high income upper middle income lower middle income lower income Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics. http://ifs.apdi.net/imf/. weakness arises from deficiencies in the law and practices govern- ing collateral. To enhance creditor rights, the authorities will need to address the following issues. Secured Transactions Framework. In Armenia, movable property cannot be used effectively as collateral to secure loans.22 There are numerous problems with the secured transactions framework. Float- ing pledges are not allowed and there are no registries that allow pledges to be perfected. Repossession is time-consuming and costly. A particular problem with financing exports is that there is no provi- sion that allows the use of future production as collateral and thus financing against export orders is not feasible. A similar problem arises with imports because there is no provision for pledging goods that are not in the possession of the borrower: goods that are being imported, even though they have been paid for by letter of credit, 312 Part II: Detailed Analysis cannot be seized in the event of default. The effect of the inadequacies of the collateral framework extends throughout the economy, with the result that banks correctly perceive lending as extremely risky.23 To understand the necessary conditions for establishing a framework for secured transactions, it is essential to understand the four economi- cally important stages of any system, which use the following: 1. Creation. The process by which the creditor establishes a security interest in a specific property (the collateral) 2. Priority. The process by which the lender establishes the priority of the security interest 3. Publicity. The process that makes public the priority of the secu- rity interest 4. Enforcement. The process by which, upon the debtor's default, the creditor will seize and sell the collateral to satisfy its claim Each of these stages must function effectively for collateral-based lending to occur. The authorities are aware that currently none of these stages work well in Armenia and that they will need to ensure that reform supported by the World Bank as part of the PSRC, USAID, and other international financial institutions on collateral framework is implemented effectively. The government has adopted a plan to strengthen creditor rights, improve the civil procedures for debt recov- ery, and simplify the procedures for the certification for property sales and the registration of secured credit. The government has established a working group to review six draft laws in this connection which would establish the required legal environment for strengthening creditor rights. Commercial Law and Contracting The law governing commercial transactions is inadequate, with the result that contracts tend to be informal and to take place between people who know each other well. The effect is a barrier to entry-- arm's length contracting is a requirement of a well-functioning eco- nomic system. It also has the effect of increasing incentives for infor- mal behavior, which is widely observed in Armenia. Problems include the following: Decisions on issues related to commercial transactions are based on an agglomeration of civil code laws, which makes the appli- cability of contract provisions uncertain. Contractual agreements are based on "unless otherwise governed by law" rather than on "unless otherwise stated in the contract" Strengthening Competition 313 provisions. Since many commercial transactions are subject to a wide range of laws rather than a more unified commercial code, this provision requires full knowledge of all the laws and imple- menting regulations that may apply to an agreement, which com- pounds the problem of the unavailability of translations. Not only does precedent not play a role in court decisions, but there is no record of cases being kept, although this is partly being addressed by a World Bank legal reform project. On top of the uncertainty arising from the commercial code, judges are widely viewed as incompetent and corrupt. As a result, businesses have little recourse if they are the victims of anticompetitive behavior. Notaries and Formal Contracts The role of the notaries adds to the barriers to entry and the incentives for informal behavior. Notaries (appointed by the Minister of Justice) provide public services and are required to validate most contractual documents. Procedures are antiquated and slow. Notaries also act as judges and determine the validity of documents (and in many cases insist on preparing the documents). Notary fees and stamp fees are high and are based on the value of the transactions covered by the con- tract being notarized. The result is that many contracts remain infor- mal because of the high cost of notarization. This situation also favors incumbents who have experience with working with one another. Credit Information The credit registry, which was introduced by the Central Bank in January 2003, aims to reduce credit risk by the crea- tion of an information system on the creditworthiness of customers of banks and credit organizations operating in Armenia. However, while the credit registry has been beneficial to banks' supervisors, this information is limited to debtors of banks only. A private Credit Bureau began operations in early 2004 and has focused in its first year on obtaining information on debtors from the banks, from other finan- cial institutions, from utility companies, and from government offices. This information should improve the ability of creditors to evaluate prospective borrowers' creditworthiness. However, the Credit Bureau has faced difficulties, because most banks are reluctant to provide information for free and to then have to pay for services. Furthermore, based on tradition and culture, Armenian borrowers are reluctant to share their information with others, and ensuring privacy protection substantially constrains the effectiveness of the Credit Bureau. It is currently revisiting its operating model and expanding ownership to include banks, with a view to remedying these obstacles. 314 Part II: Detailed Analysis In countries where credit bureaus have been established success- fully, the central bank plays an important role in creating incentive mechanisms for commercial banks to share information on their cus- tomers. The analysis suggests several situations in which Armenia's Central Bank could play an active role in facilitating private credit bureau development: Credit bureau reports should be made a requirement for lending coupled with mechanisms to ensure efficient entry and exit by bureaus to avoid abuse of their exclusive rights. A borrower's explicit consent should be required prior to any- one's gaining access to their file, to ensure better privacy protec- tion. Other actions that may prevent privacy violations include restrictions on banks for gathering certain kinds of information, the customer's right to access account information, validation of one's own files, and elimination of individual files after a certain period. Access to information by borrowers and credit institutions should be granted on the basis of membership. In other words, the prin- ciple of reciprocity should guide credit bureaus and should be stated in the contractual agreement between the bureau and credit institutions. Membership should not be based on fees in any form. However, credit bureau activity should be profit-ori- ented. In cases where a member provides inaccurate information or fails to provide data, sanctions (ranging from fines to loss of membership and hence denial to the bureau's files) should be imposed. Credit bureaus are exposed to potential conflicts of interest, especially if they are owned by a group of lenders (each lender wants to exploit the information provided by other lenders with- out disclosing his/her own). Therefore, Armenia should adopt a balanced-ownership policy. For example, credit bureaus could be incorporated as private companies and owned by a consor- tium of lenders to create the incentive for information exchange. Alternatively, independent ownership, coupled with a proper membership policy, could serve as an incentive to lenders to exchange information. Apart from the efficiency debate and the coexistence of different institutional arrangements, there is concern regarding the opti- mal amount of information sharing and its content. In contrast to relying on the general statement that information dissemi- nation reduces adverse selection problems (due to bad risks in the population of credit seekers) and makes the information on which banks base their lending decision homogenous, the policy Strengthening Competition 315 for the development of an efficient credit-information sharing system should be focused on the regulation of the quality of the disclosed information. Furthermore, the authorities should work to enhance corporate governance, which is weak. While company law is sound, imple- mentation is weak. Many corporations and some banks are not listed, and they may have relatively few owners who do not see the benefits of adopting the governance structures covered by the law (that is, open and closed joint-stock companies) that are intended to ensure good corporate governance. There is a need to broaden the coverage and enhance the enforcement of company law to strengthen disclosure, accounting, and oversight by corporate boards of directors. Corporate Governance Corporate governance in Armenia is weak owing in large part to the lack of transparency of ownership and con- trol in the banking and corporate sectors. The Detailed Assessment of Compliance with the OECD Principles of Corporate Governance indi- cated that while company law governing open and closed joint-stock companies is sound, implementation is weak. Only a limited number of corporations and banks choose to operate under this law, which is covered under securities legislation and enforced by exchanges and securities commissions. Many entities are closely held, are not pub- licly traded, and may have few owners who do not see the benefits of adopting a more formal governance structure. Hence, the enforcement of sound corporate governance practices through securities legislation and securities regulators is weak. There may be a need for a fundamen- tal reform to enhance the coverage and enforcement of company law if corporate governance, disclosure, and accounting are to improve. The opaque ownership structure of the corporate sector makes it more difficult for the banking sector to assess the risks on corporate sector exposures. Official disclosures of direct and indirect owner- ship are substantially weaker than in other transition economies. No disclosure of beneficial owners is required under Armenian law. This limits the ability of banks to ensure compliance with prudent limits on loan portfolio concentrations and related party transac- tions. Although legislation requires all companies to prepare their financial accounts in line with the Accounting Standards of the Republic of Armenia, in practice these standards are not observed or implemented, partly because of lack of training. Steps should be taken to improve accounting and auditing practices and finan- cial reporting requirements and to strengthen public information, including information regarding beneficial owners of banks and publicly traded companies. Furthermore, the supervising boards of 316 Part II: Detailed Analysis Armenian companies are not sufficiently effective or accountable. The company law should establish the separation of company own- ers from company managers and should strengthen and clarify the fiduciary duties and accountability of boards of directors. These shortcomings in corporate governance can be addressed through legal, institutional, and supervisory reforms. Given the weak implementation of company law, the Central Bank has developed a proposal to accelerate improvements in corporate governance in the banking sector through legislative and supervisory means and by introducing upward-consolidated supervision to address exposures to beneficial owners. There are a number of specific reforms applying to the corporate sector that should be implemented to address the shortcomings in corporate governance. They include improvements in accounting and auditing practices; financial reporting requirements; enhanced disclosure of the shareholders of corporations; improved access to information by the public, in particular by making the com- pany registry publicly available; and strengthening the role of boards of directors. Bureaucracy A further problem for businesses in Armenia is the failure of the gov- ernment to issue VAT refunds to those companies that are primarily or solely engaged in exporting. For example, a company that exports smelted copper is owed large refund amounts that stretch over more than 12 months. While this is not an issue that can be said to impinge directly on competition in Armenia, it is another illustration of the failure of the state to protect property rights and the rights of busi- nesses, and it is a further example of the limited benefits of being formal. Similar problems are reported by one of the major hotels in Yerevan, which is having difficulty getting VAT refunds on the cost of building. A recent FIAS Report (World Bank 2004b) highlights the role of the tax authorities in raising transactions costs. Over 80 percent of respondents indicated dissatisfaction with their dealings on tax issues. Within the tax system and tax administration the most problematic issues are the "extra-legal requirement for advance payment of taxes," the "frequency of changes in rules and rates," and the "availability of information regarding the laws and regulations." While these data must be interpreted cautiously (Armenian businesses are not known for their compliance with the tax codes), the widespread dissatisfac- tion with the lack of transparency of the process is indicative of the extent to which taxation can be used as an instrument for harassing entrants into areas that are dominated by incumbents. Strengthening Competition 317 CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS There is little doubt that there is a serious lack of competition in some sectors of the Armenian economy. The preceding analysis indicates that in several sectors, particularly those related to imports and dis- tribution, monopoly profits are being earned by a small group that is profiting greatly and imposing welfare losses. This chapter concludes that the concerns regarding lack of competition are warranted. It iden- tifies three separate areas of the economy where competition, or the lack of it, is an issue. These areas are the following: the traditional sectors that are regulated--utilities and natural monopolies areas in which competition is widely perceived to be restricted, especially petroleum, sugar, wheat, and flowers barriers to entry that maintain the position of market incum- bents Nevertheless, it is important to recall that Armenia has been among the fastest-growing economies in the world for several years. This rapid growth is all the more noteworthy because it has taken place against a backdrop of closed borders. Lack of competition, however, carries long-run efficiency implica- tions as well as the danger that the apparent concentration of wealth could reduce political support for reform and limit the benefits of rapid growth. There is ample evidence of poverty in Armenia, even in Yerevan, and outside of the capital it is far worse. Poverty reduc- tion requires that the benefits of growth are realized by the mass of the people. The more that competition is restricted and activities are reserved for incumbents, the less likely it is that the benefits of growth will be widespread. There are additional unfortunate consequences of the dominance of the oligarchs in some sectors. The concentration of wealth pro- vides substantial ability to grant "favors" to officialdom to subtly (and sometimes not so subtly) hinder competitors entering the market. The phenomenon of roofs, discussed in the section on business practices, is one manifestation of the way in which incumbents maintain their market power. In other cases, it appears that there are direct attempts to prevent competition. Widespread subversion of the "rules of the game" by the rich and powerful sends strong messages to those who are on the outside. It contributes to a general attitude that taxes should not be paid, officials should be bribed, and goods should be smug- gled. This does nothing to develop the foundation for a modern com- petitive economy. 318 Part II: Detailed Analysis Geography and Competition Policy The Armenian economy is small and remote. One of the aims of policy should therefore be to ensure that nothing exacerbates these geographic facts of life. In particular, policy should ensure that com- munications and transport are as low cost as possible. In the past, this principle has not been adhered to and almost appears to have been designed to intensify the disadvantages of Armenia's geographic limi- tations. The ill-conceived awarding of the telecommunication monop- oly to ArmenTel has substantially raised the cost of communications. The policy regarding regulating flights into and out of Yerevan raises the cost of traveling to and from the country. There is no valid eco- nomic reason for these restrictions. The government has started to take action regarding the telecommunications issues. It should take similar measures with regard to air transport and should declare an Open Skies policy, allowing any airline that wishes to fly to Armenia to land at Yerevan. Regulated Sectors In the sectors that are traditionally the object of regulation, progress is being made. Actions are being taken to deal with the ArmenTel monopoly, and telecommunications regulation will come under the jurisdiction of the PSRC once pending legislation is passed by Par- liament. Regulation of power generation and distribution, as well as natural gas, has advanced. Both of these industries are also regu- lated by the PSRC. The functioning of the PSRC appears to have improved--for example, they have reversed price increases in the energy sector. Although it is possible to quibble about the methods used as well as some of the details of regulation, there is no doubt that in this area significant progress has been made. There are concerns regarding regulation in sectors that are still state-dominated, especially the railways, which are a vitally impor- tant industry given Armenia's transport problems. Currently, railways are both administered and regulated by the Ministry of Transport and Communications. Transport-intensive industries such as mining complain that attempts are being made to raise tariffs without any apparent justification. No options should be dismissed without con- sideration, including privatization of the railways and bringing regu- lation under the purview of the PSRC. Regulatory capabilities are scarce in Armenia, and consolidation under one body, which could then be the recipient of intensive technical assistance, could be the best policy option. Strengthening Competition 319 Areas Where Competition Is Restricted This chapter examines sectors of the economy that are widely regarded as suffering from lack of competition through monopoly and the restriction of competition in the distribution chain. It concludes that there is evidence that prices are higher than they would be if there were more competition, and that welfare losses are significant. Most of the sectors discussed are involved with the distribution of imported products. In one sense, the problem would disappear immediately if there were the ability to import freely. However, the chapter points out that customs has become an instrument for maintaining the monop- oly position of incumbents. There are several things that can be done about this situation. The first is to increase the transparency of the process. When light falls upon irregular practices, they tend to decline. Two steps are pos- sible in the short run. First, make the computerized customs data- base available to brokers, including the clearance of all goods, so that restrictions on shipments must be explained. Second, make the cus- toms examinations more transparent by following the letter of the law in this regard. All examination papers and the marking of the papers should be available for inspection. Whether this is feasible from a political economy perspective is another matter. Recommendations for the reform of customs have been made by donors almost from the time of the country's independ- ence. Some progress has been made, particularly with respect to the procedures related to Armenia's WTO accession. Nevertheless, there is still a long way to go in this regard and the process is clearly the main way in which monopoly positions are maintained. Since the number of access points to Armenia is limited as a result of closed borders with Azerbaijan and Turkey, the effectiveness of restricting certain imports is enhanced. In addition, the use of reference pricing is still widespread, in contravention of WTO undertakings. Although cus- toms and revenue officials claim that it is necessary to check invoices in order to ensure that there is no cheating on VAT payments, there are alternative procedures that allow goods to be cleared pending a check on prices that are used successfully in other countries. There is no reason why these methods could not be adopted in Armenia. Another avenue is open to the authorities to improve competition in the petroleum market. They could require that a high proportion (perhaps 50 percent) of the petroleum imported into Armenia must come from one of the large Western petroleum companies and that the invoices supplied with the shipment are made available for public inspection. Such a step would introduce contestability into the market and would improve transparency. 320 Part II: Detailed Analysis The CPEC In its present form, the CPEC's ability to ensure competitive markets in Armenia is limited. It lacks the resources and the skills to be effec- tive, and it has no power to enforce its own judgments except through the court system, which itself is arbitrary and open to outside influ- ences. The policy question is therefore whether devoting resources to strengthening the CPEC is warranted. Such assistance would take the form of upgrading the CPEC's resources, particularly in the ITC area, upgrading the skills of the CPEC, and perhaps giving it the power to enforce its judgments. Concerns regarding strengthening the CPEC rest on the under- standable desire to avoid yet another layer of bureaucracy that could be used as an instrument to harass business. However, the CPEC is not going to disappear; its existence is enshrined in law and it appears to have powers that so far have been untested. Upgrading its skills is necessary to prevent it from turning into the very institution that some fear it could become. The more professional the CPEC is, the less likely it will turn into an instrument for restricting rather than promoting competition. The Long-Term Promotion of Competition and Development In the long run, promoting competition in Armenia is inseparable from promoting private sector development in the country. The ability to restrict competition frequently arises because the institutions that underlie private sector activity are underdeveloped, providing strong incentives for informal behavior. In Armenia, the public goods that provide the foundation for private sector development are weak. The court system does not function effectively, and arm's length contract- ing is risky, so that transactions tend to take place among those who know and trust each other. This gives powerful advantages to incum- bents. Similarly, the financial system remains underdeveloped even by the standards of low-income countries. Hence, those who have substantial financial resources are in an especially strong position to maintain and strengthen their market dominance. The development of institutions supporting the private sector is the only long-run solu- tion to promoting a competitive market environment. Legal reform, the strengthening of property rights, and corporate governance are some of the measures that will greatly enhance private sector activity. In addition, the institutions of government must be upgraded. They need to be of positive assistance to the private sector, rather than being the instruments for maintaining anticompetitive behavior that they are now. In particular, the reform of the customs service is the key to promoting competition. Strengthening Competition 321 Shorter-Term Measures Several of the suggestions in the preceding sections could be imple- mented with little delay. The announcement of an Open Skies policy would signal the government's commitment to establishing a more competitive business environment. An immediate change in the exam- inations for customs brokers would signal a commitment to transpar- ency in customs procedures, as would giving brokers access to the computerized clearing system. Another measure that would promote competition would be to insist that a certain percentage of imports of petroleum be purchased from one of the large international petroleum companies and that the documentation be made publicly available. Suggestions for Further Work There are a number of areas in which further work is needed in order to suggest more detailed reforms. The most important of these are the following: A thorough review of the commercial code is required in order to identify areas that are inimical to modern commercial prac- tice and to suggest reforms. This review should be undertaken not only by lawyers but also by a team consisting of a lawyer and an economist in order to ensure that the incentives inherent in the code are identified from an economic as well as a legal perspective. A similar review of the consumer protection law is warranted in order to take stock of the system for consumer protection that underlies the role of the CPEC. Such a review would ensure that the CPEC does not become an instrument for the harassment of businesses and that the incentives in the law make sense from an economic perspective. This review could also look into the feasibility and desirability of establishing a small claims court where consumers and producers who have been harmed by anti- competitive behavior could sue the perpetrators. At this point, a stocktaking and review of the regulatory frame- work is also warranted, to determine how well it is now func- tioning, where further strengthening is needed, and how the PSRC can be further supported in its work. A thorough review is needed of the issues related to secured trans- actions reform, from an economic as well as a legal perspective. This should include the feasibility of using a similar approach to that taken in Romania (see Annex 10.1 to this chapter). ANNEX 10.1 An Example of Successful Secured Transactions Reform in Romania R ecent reform of the secured transactions framework in Romania has transformed the lending environment by facilitating the use of collateral as security for lending, not only by the banking system but also by equipment suppliers, wholesalers, and agricultural sup- pliers. There were many similarities between the Romanian financial sector before this reform and that in Armenia: severe financial under- development, the inability of a large sector of the economy to access credit, and a distrust of banks. Therefore, use of this model could have significant potential for the development of the Armenian financial system in a way that could substantially reduce barriers to entry. The essential elements of a well-functioning system of collateral provide for the creation and registration of collateral as security for a loan and its rapid repossession in the event of default. The Roma- nian reform involved first changing the law and legal institutions and second establishing a privately run registry where security interests regarding the pledging of property as collateral for loans could be recorded. This was done within the context of the civil code system that exists in Romania, which has further lessons for Armenia. The main features of the reform included the implementation by the government (with the support of the World Bank) of a Law of Secured Transactions that permitted movable property, both tangi- ble and intangible, to serve as collateral for a loan. The second step involved setting up the filing archive to permit the law to operate by recording pledges of property and establishing priority regarding which creditors have the first rights to repossess and sell the collateral in the event of default. 322 Strengthening Competition 323 There are a number of innovative features of the secured transac- tions reform: The law abrogated all existing legislation affecting debt, so that there was no danger of ambiguity regarding the validity of the pledges. The filing archive in which pledges are recorded is run by an association of lenders, so that the public sector is not involved. The archive is electronic and priority is determined electronically at the time when pledges are recorded. No documents are necessary to file a security interest. This allows Internet-based filing, currently the only filing archive in the world to have this feature. The effect is to broaden coverage, particularly in the rural areas, as well as to reduce costs. No notaries are involved in the process. Repossession takes place outside the court system. If repossession is not disputed, the creditor can simply collect the pledged prop- erty. Lenders confirmed that repossession was not a problem. In the event of dispute, upon evidence of the validity of the debt, which does not require proof beyond the entry in the filing archive, an officer of the court can seize the pledged property without the necessity of a court hearing. Very harsh penalties for wrongful repossession discourage credi- tors from abusing the system. The new law and filing archive are among the most modern in the world, even among the developed countries. Prior to the new law, credit in Romania was scarce and expen- sive. The Romanian financial sector was underdeveloped even by the standards of many transition economies and ranked near the bottom of Central and Eastern European economies in terms of financing pri- vate sector activities: in 2000, credit from deposit-taking banks to the private sector was equivalent to about 9 percent of GDP. Furthermore, this figure is an overestimate of the true provision of credit because some of it reflects loans from the state banks to bankrupt former state- owned enterprises (SOEs). In 1999, Romanian banks' nonperforming loans amounted to over one-third of total loans. Average real lending rates were high, but effectively there was very little arm's length lend- ing. Financial markets were distorted by subsidized credit that pro- vided opportunities for arbitrage across different loan instruments. Following the introduction of the secured transactions reform in 2001, the impact on lending in Romania has been dramatic. In the first 18 months after the reform was implemented, there were over 324 Part II: Detailed Analysis 400,000 loans against which security interests were registered. Over 100 banks registered security interests in the filing archive. Since there are 38 licensed banks in Romania, the implication is that scores of non-Romanian banks were lending in the country against collateral and registering their security interests. Of the security interests that were registered and current in Septem- ber 2003, nearly 20 percent represented nonbank secured loans. This is especially beneficial in rural areas that do not have bank offices. In addition, the geographic coverage has been extensive. As of 2003, there were filings of security interests in 42 of Romania's 43 counties. The ratio of domestic currency lending to the private sector to GDP rose by 86 percent in the period from 2000 to September 2003, and long-term lending denominated in lei rose sharply from less than 20 percent of total credit to nearly 40 percent. The business community supports the reform enthusiastically. Many of those interviewed spoke positively of the new framework. Bankers and members of the busi- ness community were equally enthusiastic. Credit is granted not only to companies in urban areas but also in rural regions where such diverse assets as cows and tractors are taken as collateral. Given the uniqueness of the secured transactions reform, this report recommends that there be an in-depth analysis of its impact. It is important to note, however, that that the secured transactions reforms are difficult and require a great deal of attention to detail. Many attempts at secured transactions reforms in developing countries have not been successful and some are already being redone: the secured transactions reform in Ukraine initiated by the World Bank is an effort to redo the unsuc- cessful USAID reform of a few years ago. NOTES 1. This chapter was prepared by Paul Holden, Enterprise Research Insti- tute, Washington, DC. 2. Moreover, the latter two organizations do not provide a competitiveness ranking for Armenia. This is due to the lack of relevant data and survey stud- ies. A recent initiative will provide the WEF with the necessary information to include Armenia in their "Global Competitiveness Indicators" report. 3. For definitions please refer to the "Business Competitiveness Indica- tors" published semiannually by the Department of Trade and Industry in the United Kingdom (http://217.154.27.195/sd/bci/index.htm). We have not constructed business survival rates, claimant counts, or income deprivation, owing to the lack of data. 4. Business formation, employment, and average earnings figures are for 2001­04; gross value added figures are for 2000 and 2001. Strengthening Competition 325 5. The conclusions in the bulleted points that follow are a preliminary assessment; a deeper analysis based on the kind of data not yet available is required to draw firm conclusions. 6. These findings are based on evidence provided by the sample survey conducted by the NSS in 2002. 7. The dispute arose from existing inefficiencies. The mobile phone cards issued by ArmenTel were sold at a high premium on a secondary market. ArmenTel issued insufficient quantities of calling cards to meet the demand and the price was bid up to 3 or 4 times the face value of the cards. In addi- tion, ISPs (Internet service providers) were required to go through ArmenTel to connect to the Internet, which resulted in unreliable connections and restricted their ability to compete on price. Service was also limited to modem connec- tions only. ArmenTel maintained a monopoly on high-speed connections and charged prices that are 20 to 30 times more than countries with competition in the telecommunications sector. 8. ArmenTel was granted exclusive rights to a wide range of services under the 2004 license. However, Article 4.D states that under some condi- tions (which collectively may be called cases of inactiveness of the licensee in providing services), the regulator may allow another person to provide these services. It is difficult to imagine a situation where ArmenTel does not pro- vide, among other things, fixed-line, international call, and mobile services. 9. Except for small producers, which can sell at a predetermined price until 2007. 10. Another possible form of restructuring is complete vertical separation. Under this arrangement the management (and, possibly, the ownership) of facilities is fully separated from other rail functions. The main advantage of this vertical unbundling is that rail transport is placed in a similar situation as road transport, especially regarding infrastructure planning. However, this form of restructuring is currently unacceptable to the Armenian railway sector given the reasons outlined in the chapter. 11. Integrated means that the operator controls not only the infrastructure but also other railroad services. 12. The theory of contestable markets (Baumol, Panzar, and Willig 1982) helped clarify the proper definition of the natural monopoly concept. It is true that duplicating the network infrastructure in the railway industry is generally inefficient due to fixed costs that, in addition, are largely sunk. Hence, the physical network is characterized by natural monopoly and there are significant entry barriers. However, the approach may be modulated if we consider a situation in which the main activities are subject to effective competitive pressure. 13. As an example, consider the case of the Gold Mining Company. With the competitive access option implemented, if ceiling prices were set using stand-alone cost practices, the integrated carrier would have ordinary business incentives to find and cooperate with efficient participants in its businesses 326 Part II: Detailed Analysis (say, finding a new company that is cost-efficient in loading and unloading freight), as the result of this cooperation would reduce the overall cost of serving a particular shipper and leave them with extra profit to share. 14. A comprehensive analysis is contained in Chapter 13 of this book. The study includes detailed recommendations and suggestions for the liberaliza- tion of the aviation sector and its effective regulation. 15. Customs brokers were legalized only three years ago. 16. Licensing fees are US$500 per year, very high in a country where civil servants' salaries rarely exceed US$100 per month. 17. Importers are required to present original documents, including the invoice, the contract covering the import, the certificate of origin, and an export declaration from the country of origin. 18. The CPEC has investigated a number of recent cases, among which was the successful elimination of a monopoly granted by the airport operator to a taxicab company. There have also been several hearings concerning the abuse of monopoly power by ArmenTel. The company had cut off the telephone lines of some Internet service providers (ISPs) without prior notification, sus- pecting them of providing VoIP service in Armenia. In almost all cases the CPEC made decisions in favor of the ISPs and fined ArmenTel to cover the losses incurred by ISPs. 19. A four-page analysis concluded that there is competition in the distribu- tion of petroleum because of the fact that there are several wholesalers/importers within Armenia. The paper does point out that there is only one supplier/seller to the wholesalers but appeared not to view this as a problem. 20. Which attitude is the most relevant in practice is largely an empirical question. Overall insights demonstrate that difficulty in obtaining funding, rather than fear of aggressive behavior by an incumbent, is the factor which prevents firms in Armenia from entering the market. 21. The data for Armenia appear as percentages superimposed on the fig- ures. For the countries in the sample, the figure is based on the ratio of credit to the private sector from deposit money banks and other financial institu- tions. For Armenia it is the ratio of credit to the nongovernment sector (sam- ple of 47 countries). High-income countries are defined as countries where GDP per capita in 1999 was higher than US$10,000. 22. For a more comprehensive review of collateral issues, see Holden (1997). Upper-middle-income countries are defined as countries where GDP per capita in 1999 was between US$3,000 and US$10,000. Lower-middle-income countries are defined as countries where GDP per capita in 1999 was between US$1,000 and US$3,000. Low-income countries are defined as countries where GDP per capita in 1999 was lower than US$1,000 (Source: International Financial Sta- tistics Database [http://ifs.apdi.net/imf/] and the World Bank's WDI Data- base [http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/DATASTATISTICS/ 0,,contentMDK:20899413~menuPK:232599~pagePK:64133150~piPK: 64133175~theSitePK:239419,00.html]. Strengthening Competition 327 23. Some advocate "relationship lending" in terms of which banks make loans on the basis of the analysis of business plans and the borrower's his- tory as an entrepreneur. This is unlikely to happen. First, most lending to businesses in the United States is secured by collateral. Second, the skills available for drawing up business plans are scarce. Third, those who have run businesses successfully are often the entrenched interests in Armenia, so that loans go to those who have tight control of the business sector. Chapter 11 Real and Formal Ease of Doing Business in Armenia in Comparative Perspective: Implications for Regulatory Reforms "Those who wish to offer their countries the chance to become a mod- ern society must direct their efforts not only toward eliminating cer- tain conditions--the barriers of access to formal activity, the costs of remaining legal, the discrimination in capital markets, the state corpora- tions--but also toward creating the basic institutions on which efficiency, social peace, and spontaneous cooperation are based in more advanced nations." (De Soto 1999, p. 259) INTRODUCTION Well-developed, market-supporting institutions, the contestability of domestic markets, the capacity of a government to enforce the rule of law, and macro-stability are all crucial to establishing an environment friendly to conducting business operations.1 But so are regulations and other conditions influencing the transaction costs of business opera- tions. Regulations, while important, do not have to be unnecessarily burdensome or costly, thereby deterring the entry of new businesses or undermining the competitiveness of existing ones. The high "hassle" cost of conducting business provides a strong disincentive to establishing new firms and encourages existing firms to slip into the informal economy. In a similar way, burdensome customs procedures, the low efficiency of ports, high transportation costs due to regulatory arrangements, and high costs of other services raise transaction costs and undermine the competitiveness of domestic producers in international markets. To successfully take advantage of growth and employment opportunities in domestic dimensions, the hassle cost of conducting business has to be reduced in both domestic 329 330 Part II: Detailed Analysis and foreign dimensions. Better facilitation measures for foreign trade will be of little relevance if the domestic environment discourages the entry of new businesses and encourages the exit of firms either per- manently or to the informal economy. Similarly, the limited capacity of firms to recover payments due from other firms discourages increased ties and limits the intensity of business activity, with negative conse- quences for domestic production and exports. This analysis focuses on the domestic dimension of conducting business using the results of the World Bank's Doing Business sur- vey (http://www.doingbusiness.org). In contrast to various other assessments of the quality of governance,2 the Doing Business sur- vey captures the tangible legal components of the investment climate together with their cost-burden and time-burden imposed on busi- nesses across 145 countries (Djankov et al. 2000). The World Bank's Cost of Doing Business comparative survey (World Bank 2005) pro- vides a useful diagnostic tool for conducting an initial assessment of the quality of the business environment in Armenia. It provides data on the tangible components shaping the cost of conducting busi- ness in Armenia and allows casting them in a comparative perspec- tive. The survey covers the following seven areas: starting business, labor market flexibility, registering property, contract enforcement, bankruptcy, protection of investors, and getting credit. Each area has several different indicators ranging from 1 (protection of investors) to 5 (getting credit and labor market flexibility). These are not firms but local professionals dealing with issues related to each of these areas that have been surveyed in respective countries in both large cities and rural areas. The Cost of Doing Business's advantage over surveying firms is obvious. Professionals deal with respective issues on a day-to-day basis, whereas firms confront the issues only to the extent that the issues directly affect them. The former have an overall view, whereas the latter do not. The procedure used to assess the ease of doing business in Armenia consists of two stages. First, we identify Armenia's relative position among transition economies in terms of an overall, formal ease of doing business. We identify best-practice indicators for each "doing business" area--not worldwide but among transition countries. Indi- cators for countries are expressed in terms of percent of the best prac- tice set at 100. These are demanding benchmarks, as two transition countries--Lithuania and the Slovak Republic--are among the top 20 economies in the world on ease of doing business. We average the benchmarks for each of the seven areas covered in the Doing Business survey to obtain an overall assessment of the ease of doing business for each country. Second, in order to capture the full extent to which the business environment is friendly or unfriendly, we bring to the fore the size Real and Formal Ease of Doing Business in Armenia 331 of the informal economy. The rationale is straightforward. The use of Cost of Doing Business indicators allows assessing the extent to which a country deviates from the best practice on each indicator within each area in terms of business laws and regulations. It does not address the quality of the state administration. Neither does it assess hassles associated with tax policies, tax and customs administration, frequency of inspections, cost of licenses, and so forth. While there are many explanations why businesses decide not to go formal, three reasons stand out: low chances of getting credit, fear of predatory administration and discreetly applied taxes, and lack of trust in the state's capacity to enforce contracts. While the survey captures both getting credit and contract enforcement, it does not capture informal administrative interventions. Moreover, the overall ranking procedure assigns the same weight to all areas of doing business, and within each area the procedure assumes that each indicator implies similar levels of ease or hassle. Regulations may be very liberal on all indica- tors within an area except one: as a result, a country may have a very high overall score in an area, while in reality one barrier makes other friendly regulations completely irrelevant. The size of the informal sector provides indirect information on the weight of formal barriers as well as on variables not covered by the Doing Business survey. We assume that the sector provides infor- mation equal in terms of weight to the overall formal ease of doing business. Therefore, we take the average of performance in terms of the informal economy and ease of doing business as an indicator of the quality of the business environment. This index is referred to as the "revealed" or real ease of doing business. Detailed analyses of Armenia's performance on each indicator in each area follow the logic presented above, but with a twist. First, strengths and weaknesses for each area are identified and assessed in the context of other transition countries. Second, since there appears to be a gap between Armenia's relatively good performance in the formal ease of doing business and the large size of the informal sector, the analysis proceeds to identify factors that discourage firms to go formal. OVERALL EASE OF DOING BUSINESS IN ARMENIA AND OTHER TRANSITION COUNTRIES Table 11.1 presents the ranking of CIS and CEEC-10 economies in terms of the ease of doing business.3 For each area, the values of indi- cators were normalized in terms of best practice in CIS and CEEC-10 economies. For instance, two areas of flexibility of employment are taken into account: (i) the Rigidity of Employment Index, which is an average of three indices (hiring, hours, and firing); and (ii) firing 332 Part II: Detailed Analysis costs, expressed in the number of weeks that an employer has to pay wages. Every indicator for each country is expressed in values ranging between 100 (best practice among CIS and CEEC-10 economies) and a lower value that is larger than zero. However, the value of the indi- cator is set at zero--representing the worst possible practice--when what might be said to be the law of jungle prevails, for example, in the absence of any laws or regulations directed at protecting the interests of domestic or foreign investors. The aggregate index of the ease of doing business in the post-communist world is the average of average values for each area. In terms of the overall formal ease of doing business, Armenia ranks sixth among 20 transition economies. Doing business across all areas is on average easier than in three new EU member states (Hun- gary, Poland, and Slovenia) and easier than in all other CIS countries as well as in Bulgaria and Romania, the newest members of the EU. Only three Baltic states (Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania), the Czech Republic, and the Slovak Republic--all of them with strong reform credentials--score higher than Armenia. Within areas, Romania ranks highest in starting a business, the Slovak Republic in flexibility of the labor market, Lithuania in registering property and enforcing con- tracts, Latvia in closing a business, the Slovak Republic together with the Czech Republic and Lithuania in protecting investors, and the Czech Republic in access to credit (the high scores are marked in italics in Table 11.1). Armenia owes its elevated ranking to the greater flexibility of its labor markets as compared to those in other transition economies; but broader comparisons suggest that labor markets are fairly rigid, par- ticularly taking account of the size of compulsory severance payments. It owes its ranking also to simplicity and effectiveness in enforcing contracts and effective procedures in closing a business. Armenia's weakest areas are registering property and access to credit. Overall, however, even in the most streamlined and reformed areas, the level is well below the best practices in transition economies. Armenia's scores do not set it apart from countries ranked higher in ease of doing business, as even countries with the best indicators for any given area have a long way to go to catch up with the best practice. As can be seen from the last line of Table 11.1, the distance is particularly large for labor market flexibility and registering prop- erty. While the comparison involves "ideal types," (that is, nonexistent economies with the best set of indicators either region-wide or world- wide), it nonetheless demonstrates that even the best practice in the region is far away from the best practice in the world. The obtained ranking in terms of overall ease of doing business is surprising in two respects. First, considering the pressure of accession to the EU and the achieved degree of harmonization with the acquis Table 11.1 Ranking of CIS and CEEC-10 Economies by Ease of Doing Business in 2005 Starting Flexibility of Registering Enforcing Closing Protecting Getting Ease of doing Country business employment property contracts business investors credit business Real Armenia 47 64 38 65 68 50 37 53 Azerbaijan 44 33 29 56 43 33 24 38 and Belarus 18 50 48 54 44 17 44 39 Bulgaria 35 46 19 48 41 33 69 42 Formal Czech Republic 33 56 28 72 18 100 89 57 Estonia 40 37 40 83 45 67 63 53 Georgia 39 51 18 54 53 83 56 50 Ease Hungary 34 38 27 76 36 83 40 48 Kazakhstan 41 69 18 60 24 83 23 45 of Kyrgyz Republic 70 54 22 28 53 50 31 44 Doing Latvia 48 30 15 77 100 83 70 61 Lithuania 58 37 74 86 68 100 40 66 Business Moldova 33 50 26 51 41 50 36 41 Poland 32 49 19 51 60 67 57 48 Romania 79 17 17 51 27 33 53 39 Russian Federation 43 69 21 62 77 50 13 48 in Slovak Republic 39 100 27 49 31 100 54 57 Armenia Slovenia 28 28 20 45 27 67 48 38 Ukraine 27 17 14 65 32 50 28 33 Uzbekistan 33 39 10 45 47 67 39 40 Source: Own calculations based on data in WB 2005. 333 334 Part II: Detailed Analysis communautaire, that is, the body of laws governing relations within the European Union communities, one would expect the CEEC-10, in particular the 8 new EU member states, to dominate the top 10 countries in terms of the formal ease of doing business. To a large extent this is the case, as 5 new members top the list. But two CIS members--Armenia and Georgia--outperformed Poland. Further- more, another CIS country, Russia, also appears to have a friendlier regulatory framework for conducting business than two other new EU members, Hungary and Slovenia. The latter appears to have the most burdensome regulatory regime next to Ukraine, which is at the bottom of the list (Table 11.1). Bulgaria and Romania are relatively low in ranking in the formal ease of doing business, although they have already signed a protocol accession to the EU indicating the European Commission's seal of approval of their institutional and policy readi- ness to meet the requirements of membership scheduled for 2007. In addition to the countries mentioned above, Bulgaria ranks thirteenth, below Kazakhstan and the Kyrgyz Republic, while Romania ranks sixteenth, below Uzbekistan and Moldova. In contrast to most CIS economies, all CEEC-10 economies appear to score high on indicators describing the quality of the legal infra- structure of financial markets, in particular the bankruptcy laws and collateral as well as market information on the quality of borrowers. They compare favorably with international standards. But some of them, most notably Slovenia, clearly fail on other counts. Second, the relatively high position of Uzbekistan, a country that has made little progress in establishing market-supporting institutions, comes as another surprise. Its high position is due to the laws protect- ing investors and the ease of closing a business. These two areas alone are unlikely to encourage business start-ups and new investments in the presence of other impediments. Both surprises stem in large part from the fact that the Doing Busi- ness survey takes into account selected formal ingredients of the busi- ness climate. Furthermore, the procedure that we use to rank econo- mies in terms of the overall formal ease of doing business assigns equal weight to areas and indicators within areas. For instance, a low number of procedures would put a country higher up, which might not be offset sufficiently by a lengthy period needed to complete a procedure.4 As a result, the ranking may be higher than the actual ease of completing a required procedure. "REVEALED" EASE OF DOING BUSINESS The ease of doing business indicators for CIS/CEEC countries can- not capture each important ingredient determining the quality of the Real and Formal Ease of Doing Business in Armenia 335 business environment, simply because they are not designed to do so. Two examples illustrate what is left out.5 First, one of the "real world" tests of the quality of the regulatory regime is the size of the informal sector. Weak enforcement of property rights and difficulties in access to bank credits, combined with a capri- cious, corrupt, and predatory administration, keep businesses in the shadow economy. This implies that in countries with a higher value of the aggregate indicator for ease of doing business, the informal economy should be smaller, and vice versa. For instance, international evidence suggests that labor market rigidity is closely associated with the size of the informal economy (that is, the less flexible labor arrange- ments are the more frequent is exit to the informal sector). Yet the value of the correlation coefficient between values of the overall ease of doing business indicators and the size of the infor- mal economy in terms of gross national income (GNI) is, as expected, negative, but still low at 38 percent. Upon closer examination, this finding should not come as a surprise. Consider for instance a simple, relatively business friendly regulatory regime deficient in one dimension, namely, very difficult access to credit. This alone might discourage an entrepreneur from registering a small firm: while there is no reward in establishing credit, there is a penalty in terms of formal payments. Considerations of tax evasion and avoiding other possible nuisances from the state administration may prevail over going legal. This seems to be the case with many CIS countries, especially Russia and Armenia, both of which score high in other areas of doing business but rank relatively low in the area of getting credit. In both countries financial markets function poorly, nullifying one of the main reasons for going formal. Poor mar- ket functioning does not provide Armenian businesses with incentives to formalize, particularly since this situation also allows petty official- dom to target formal businesses with inspections that have payoffs as their aim. On the other hand, easy access to credit provides an incentive to move to or stay in the formal sector. For an entrepreneur seeking access to financing as well as to the system of formal contracting and legal protection in business transactions, credit alone may override concerns about other formal hassles associated with doing business. Access to credit probably explains the relatively low size of the infor- mal economy in Poland or Slovenia, despite significant barriers to doing business. Second, one would also expect the ease of doing business to be positively correlated with the falling incidence of corruption. But again this is not the case, at least when using the values of the Cor- ruption Perception Index (CPI), annually estimated by Transparency International surveys, as a measure of the incidence of corruption in a 336 Part II: Detailed Analysis country. The correlation with ease of doing business values is positive but low at 33 percent. Since corruption is highly correlated with the size of the informal economy, the use of the latter takes care of issues that are left out in the overall ease of doing business indicator. The ranking in terms of the values of CPI, averaged over 2000­04, does not widely diverge from that generated by the size of the informal economy. Countries perceived as having a lower incidence of corruption (that is, a higher value of CPI) tend also to have a smaller informal sector in terms of GDP. The correlation between corruption and the informal sector is 67 percent. Excluding the biggest spoiler, Belarus, the correlation goes up to 79 percent.6 Thus, a comprehensive assessment of the quality of the business climate should take into account both the formal ease of doing busi- ness and the size of the informal sector. Since the size of the informal sector is a less subjective measure than a CPI and both are strongly correlated, it is sufficient to incorporate information about the infor- mal economy into the composite index of ease of doing business. The proposed measure, which is thereafter referred to as the "revealed" overall ease of doing business,7 assigns equal weight to formal ease and the size of the of informal economy. The size is expressed in terms of GNI and is normalized along similar lines as indicators of ease of doing business (Table 11.2). The values of the informal sector size are expressed on a scale from 1­100, with 100 assigned to the lowest value of the informal sector in CIS/CEEC coun- tries. The Slovak Republic has the lowest size and therefore the value taken into account in calculating the "revealed ease" is 0.5 of 100. The lowest normalized level of this indicator is 28 for Georgia, with the highest informal economy of 67.3 percent in 2003. Except for Uzbekistan's high position, where the relatively low size of the informal economy may be due to strong state controls, the rela- tive rankings reflect countries' progress in building an institutional environment supporting private business activity. New EU members occupy the top 8 spots, with Slovenia moving up 11 spots compared to the overall ease of doing business indicator. On the other hand, several countries have dropped in overall ranking, with Georgia going down 10 spots, followed by Russia and Armenia. Thus, incorporating the size of the informal sector would appear to provide a better indication of the business-friendly conditions of the existing regulatory arrangements than an indicator of an overall ease of doing business. As demonstrated above, the informal sector and unfriendly business regulation usually go together, with some excep- tions. For reasons discussed earlier, the regulatory regime in Slovenia, despite the apparently heavy burden it imposes on businesses, does not encourage entrepreneurs to go underground. However, appar- Table 11.2 Size of the Informal Economy and "Revealed" Ease of Doing Business "Revealed" ease Overall ease Difference between Informal economy of doing of doing revealed and Memorandum: Country percent of 2003 GNI business indicator business indicator overall indicator CPI, 2000­04 Real Armenia 46.3 46.8 6 5 3.0 Azerbaijan 60.1 34.5 18 2 1.9 and Belarus 48.1 39.2 17 1 4.1 Bulgaria 36.9 46.4 13 ­1 4.0 Formal Czech Rep. 19.1 77.8 4 ­2 3.9 Estonia n/a 74.0 5 ­2 5.7 Georgia 67.3 39.3 7 10 2.1 Ease Hungary 25.1 61.5 10 ­5 4.9 Kazakhstan 43.2 44.6 11 3 2.3 of Kyrgyz Rep. 39.8 45.8 12 1 2.2 Doing Latvia 39.9 53.9 2 5 3.8 Lithuania 30.3 64.2 1 3 4.7 Business Moldova 45.1 41.4 14 2 2.3 Poland 27.6 58.2 8 ­2 3.8 Romania 34.4 47.2 16 ­6 2.7 Russian Federation 46.1 44.4 9 6 2.7 in Slovak Rep. 18.9 78.5 3 ­2 3.8 Armenia Slovenia 27.1 53.7 19 ­11 6.0 Ukraine 52.2 34.6 20 ­1 2.3 Uzbekistan 34.1 47.7 15 ­6 2.5 Source: Authors' calculations based on data in WB 2005 and Web site of Transparency International (http://www.transparency.org/). 337 Note: CPI is the average for 2000­04. 1 = maximum incidence of corruption; 100 = minimum incidence of corruption. 338 Part II: Detailed Analysis ently friendlier regimes in Armenia, Georgia, and Russia are not suf- ficient to retain businesses in the formal sector, to the detriment of economic growth and productivity. International experience suggests that productivity levels are two to four times lower in the informal sector than in the formal economy. When the size of the informal economy does not move in tandem with the difficulty of doing business, it suggests that other ingredients of the business climate that are not captured by the Doing Business survey effectively discourage potential entrepreneurs from enter- ing the formal economy. These other "negative" factors are strongly present in Armenia, Georgia, and Russia. Negative factors usually stem from capricious and predatory administrations whose interventions effectively weaken the poten- tially positive impact of regulatory reforms. They include excessive costs of transparency, burdensome tax regulations, and high, unstable tax rates. These factors may raise the hassle cost of doing business to levels not tolerated by most businesses. However, these explanations, together with the incidence of corruption, are generic answers, and more detailed analysis is needed in the particular country context. WEAKNESSES AND STRENGTHS OF THE REGULATORY REGIME How does Armenia score in various areas of doing business? We bench- mark the values of the respective indicators for Armenia against those for CEEC-8 countries,8 CIS economies, Russia, New Zealand, and best practice across the globe. The rationale behind the choice of CEEC-8, CIS economies, and Russia as comparators is straightforward. Except for Slovenia, they all share the legacy of central planning or, more precisely, of the overregulation and micromanagement of the economy by the administration. Therefore they provide a meaningful frame of reference for assessing the progress in establishing a business-friendly environment. Furthermore, Armenia potentially competes with them for foreign investments while it does not benefit from the advantage of its geographical location close to the core of the global economy. Russia has the least onerous regulatory environment among CIS econ- omies across all dimensions of doing business, whereas New Zealand scores highest in the world in terms of ease of doing business. Table 11.3 also contains information about the best values worldwide for each indicator. Reviewing the data in Table 11.3 leads to the following general observation: the regulatory burden of conducting business in Armenia is relatively low, especially when benchmarked against CIS and CEEC-8 economies. Real and Formal Ease of Doing Business in Armenia 339 On a positive note, Armenia fares quite well in several areas of doing business. Entry is easy. So is exit as well as transferring property rights. It is easy to start a business in Armenia. It costs only US$64 in administrative fees, requires a minimum capital of US$44 that the entrepreneur has to deposit before registration kicks in, and takes 25 days. Contrast these entry conditions with US$116, US$819, and 32 days in a median CIS economy or US$142, US$3,199, and 46 days in a median CEEC-8 economy. Although the difference in favor of Armenia is smaller as far as costs are concerned, when expressed in relation to GDP per capita it remains considerable. Armenia does not make it difficult--relative to CIS and CEEC-8 comparators--for investors to register property (that is, to transfer the property title from a seller to a buyer). It is a relatively simple operation involving four procedures and costing less than 1 percent of the value of the property. It takes less time (18 days) than in compara- tor countries, excluding the world's least repressive countries toward businesses. Neither do Armenian regulations create barriers for businesses that go bankrupt and are forced to exit. Claimants recover 39.6 percent of the amount they are owed. This is less than in Russia but almost the same as in a median CEEC-8 country and considerably more than in median CIS. It also takes less time to resolve foreclosure or bank- ruptcy and the cost of closing a business is a smaller percentage of the value of a troubled business. The cost (4 percent) is the same as in Russia but the time (1.9 years) is longer. Since the worst indicator does the most to discourage business activ- ity under most circumstances, the following question is pertinent to an overall assessment of the regulatory and policy hassle felt by busi- nesses: which aspects of Armenia's regulatory environment are the most burdensome for private firms? While overall in each area Arme- nia scores high compared to its peers from CIS and CEEC-8 countries, within some areas the indicators point to weaknesses. These areas are labor markets (firing and hiring), access to credit, and contract enforcement. As for contract enforcement, it takes more money (18 percent of the debt as compared with 14 percent), but other indicators favor Armenia. In a very important dimension of labor markets, Armenia's busi- ness environment has significant weaknesses even when benchmarked against only other CIS countries. The high value of the "difficulty to fire index," combined with an obligation to pay the wages of a fired worker over a period of 30 weeks, significantly reduces the flexibility of Armenia's labor market. More favorable values for the remaining two indicators do little to lessen constraints on hiring and firing in response to business conditions. 340 Table 11.3 Doing Business in Armenia and Selected Comparators, 2004 Part Best practice CIS-10 CEEC-8 in CEEC New Best II: Area Indicator Armenia median Russia median and CIS Zealand practice Detailed Starting a Number of procedures 10 10 9 9 5 2 2 business Time (days) 25 32 36 46 18 12 2 Analysis Cost (% of income per capita) 7.0 14.2 6.7 12.0 3.7 0.2 0.0 Minimum capital (% of income per capita) 4.5 23.3 5.6 47.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 Hiring and Difficulty of hiring index firing workers (0­100) 33 33 0 33 0 11 0 Rigidity of hours index (0­100) 40 60 60 60 20 0 0 Difficulty of firing index (0­100) 10 60 20 60 10 10 0 Rigidity of employment index (0­100) 28 44 27 44 10 7 0 Firing costs (severance payments in weeks of wages) 30 21 17 21 17 0 0 Registering Number of procedures 4 7 5 5 3 2 1 property Time (days) 18 71 354 72 3 2 1 Cost (% of property value) 0.9 2.2 9.5 2.1 0.5 0.2 0.0 Table 11.3 (continued) Best practice CIS-10 CEEC-8 in CEEC New Best Area Indicator Armenia median Russia median and CIS Zealand practice Real Enforcing Number of procedures 24 29 29 24 17 19 11 contracts Time (days) 195 324 395 333 150 50 27 and Cost (% of debt) 17.8 18.0 9.5 10.8 8.1 4.8 4.2 Formal Closing a Time of insolvency (years) 1.9 3.8 1.5 2.5 1.1 2.0 0.41 business Cost (% of estate) 4.0 7.4 4.0 18 4.0 4.0 1.0 Recovery rate (cents on Ease the US$) 39.6 5.3 48.4 39.8 85.0 71.4 92.0 of Protecting Investors disclosure Doing investors index (0­7) 3 3 3 5 6 5 7 Getting credit Cost to create collateral Business (% income per capita) 0.9 3.6 11.6 3.7 0.6 0.0 0.0 Legal rights index (0­10) 4 5.0 3 6 9 9 10 Credit information index (0­6) .. 0.0 0 4 5 5 6 in Public registry coverage Armenia (per 1,000 adults) .. 0.0 0 6 44 0 637 Private bureau coverage (per 1,000 adults) 0 0.0 0 17 380 978 1,000 Source: Data from World Bank (2005). 341 .. Negligible. 342 Part II: Detailed Analysis Research shows the crucial importance of labor market flexibility for both reducing unemployment and boosting investment. While the relationship between low unemployment rates and high flexibility is empirically firmly established, the impact of labor market flexibility on FDI appears to be significant as well. A recent study (Javorcik and Spatareanu 2004) using the labor market indicators from the Doing Business database for 2002 shows that, all else being equal, flexibility in labor markets has a significant impact on FDI flows. For instance, if the flexibility of the host country labor market increases from the level of the Slovak Republic (inflexible prior to reforms in 2003) to the level of Hungary (flexible), the volume of FDI goes up by between 14 and 18 percent. Moreover, in line with intuition, FDI in service sectors appears to be more sensitive to labor regulations than investment into manufacturing. Armenia also has a relatively low score in terms of investors' pro- tection, with the disclosure index of 3 putting it on a par with Russia. The absence of regulations compelling disclosure has several negative consequences: investment is lower as potential investors fear expro- priation, the stock market is undercapitalized, economic growth is lower than under full disclosure, and returns from investment are lower (World Bank 2005, pp. 56­57). But more powerful financial constraints to doing business relate to other legal underpinnings of financial markets in Armenia. Although the cost of creating collateral is very low by both regional and interna- tional standards and the legal rights index is within a median range, this should not necessarily imply easy conditions for getting credit. The contrary is the case, as the difficulties faced by firms in obtain- ing credit in Armenia clearly demonstrate. The absence of the insti- tutionalized information on borrowers that should be available to the banking sector curtails lending and also offsets the potentially positive impact of the relatively low costs of creating collateral and the decent standards of protection of creditor rights in bankruptcy. The lack of market information on the quality of borrowers, com- bined with the absence of a secured transactions framework, is a bind- ing constraint on lending. Furthermore, movable property cannot be used effectively as collateral to secure loans in Armenia, as repos- session is time consuming and costly. Neither can collateral-based lending function effectively, as Armenia does not have an effective framework for creating and enforcing claims--that is, a framework for secured transactions is not yet in place (Holden and Sahakyan 2004). The effects of the inadequacies of the collateral framework extend throughout the economy, with the result that banks correctly perceive lending as extremely risky. Real and Formal Ease of Doing Business in Armenia 343 The gap between Armenia and the median of comparators is lower in registering property: the number of procedures is only slightly higher (4 versus 3) but it takes significantly more time to complete the process (18 days versus 3 days). This is also the case in closing a business. The time of insolvency is longer (1.9 years versus 1.2 years), although it is lower than in New Zealand (2 years), with the best international practice at 0.41 years. The recovery rate of 39.6 cents on the U.S. dollar (that is, the percent of what creditors collect on their debt) is below Lithuania's level, but similar to the CEEC-8 median of 39.8. An indicator on starting a business is lagging behind comparator values; the indicator is higher than in Lithuania but lower than the median value for the CEEC-8. Although Armenia appears to be a top performer among CIS coun- tries, this is not sufficient. An important consideration is that Armenia has to neutralize the negative effects of its remoteness to the centers of gravity of global markets and of its being landlocked. The frame of reference for Armenia's regulatory reforms should be at least the best practice in the CIS/CEEC-10 region, if not the best international practice. Here, on both counts, the differences are huge, even though Armenia fares quite well overall in relation to other former centrally planned economies. THE COEXISTENCE OF FORMAL EASE OF DOING BUSINESS AND THE INFORMAL ECONOMY Why does such a large informal economy coexist with relatively high formal ease of doing business? The answer may be found in identify- ing the specific factors that raise the cost of doing business above the "formal" levels, namely those factors identified in the Doing Business survey. In other words, what are the main ingredients contributing to the fact that the actual costs exceed the formal costs of compliance? Interviews and surveys covering various areas of the business envi- ronment paint a picture of general dissatisfaction on the part of busi- nesses with the quality of the regulations, administrative requirements, and bureaucratic behavior of state agencies, despite some improve- ments over the last three years. The reasons for this assessment are manifold. First, difficulties encountered in interaction with tax adminis- tration, compounded by unstable and frequently changed rules and tax rates, are cited as a major barrier to conducting business in Armenia. This is perceived as a bigger problem than corruption by both local- and foreign-owned firms, albeit for local firms corruption continues to be regarded as a significant barrier.9 Administrative Regulatory Cost 344 Part II: Detailed Analysis Surveys (RCSs), which have been conducted in Armenia on an annual basis since 2000, persistently identify tax administration as the greatest obstacle to conducting business. For instance, in both 2003 and 2004 more than 80 percent of respondents identified tax administration as the largest obstacle. The view appears to be shared by foreign-owned firms to the tune of 90 percent of all respondents (FIAS 2003). Further- more, foreign-owned businesses complained that the tax burden in 2003 considerably increased compared to 1999. Uncertainty associated with frequent changes in policy was flagged by around three-fourths of RCS respondents. The second barrier relates to the costs that businesses have to incur in order to meet the requirements of administrative regulations. According to the RCS, the costs remain huge and there has been no major improvement over the past several years. Most costs are not related to formal and informal payments but to the imposed burden of time and resources that firms must allocate to assure regulatory compliance. The third barrier is the "irregular" payments extracted by customs and the time consuming procedures. Customs clearance procedures are applied with equal zeal not only to imports but also to exports. The time needed to complete customs clearance as well as the amount of effort undertaken by a firm to deal with customs are shocking, especially for exports. Furthermore, traders are charged by customs for the storage of the held goods. Such conditions add to the overall high cost of conducting foreign trade transactions in Armenia and corroborate businesses' complaints about nontransparent procedures and nontariff trade barriers. In consequence, it appears that the most obvious benefits of the computerization of customs services (that is, reducing the release time of consignments and slashing the documentation or bureaucratic bur- den put on a trader or customs broker) have so far failed to material- ize. Neither traders nor customs brokers have access to the system. The old practices of bureaucratic delays fueling corruption combined with lack of capacity in customs administration continue. Finally, although Armenia is no exception to the generally poor record of most transition countries in establishing the rule of law and strengthening the courts, the situation has improved on several impor- tant counts.10 Armenia has made large strides in judicial reforms and is "the only country where significantly more respondents viewed the courts as fairer in 2002 than in 1999" (Anderson, Bernstein, and Gray 2005). Considering, however, that in 2000 only 2 percent of firms sur- veyed viewed judges as honest (CES 2000), the improvement should be measured from the low starting point. Fairness, however, does not exhaust all of the dimensions related to efficiently functioning courts. Real and Formal Ease of Doing Business in Armenia 345 Other important dimensions from the point of view of conduct- ing business include the perceived honesty or dishonesty of judges, the capacity to implement enacted commercial laws, and the ability to adjudicate disputes in an efficient and timely manner. It appears that firms regard Armenia's courts as relatively honest. In response to a question about the frequency of unofficial payments when deal- ing with the courts, firms surveyed under Business Environment and Enterprise Performance Surveys (BEEPS) identified the courts as not extracting bribes on a significant scale. The percent of firms nega- tively assessing courts on this dimension was among the lowest in the region and on a par with Slovenia, Estonia, and Lithuania. Moreover, Armenia, together with Lithuania, recorded the largest improvement among 26 transition economies between 1999 and 2002. Although most respondents perceive the courts in transition countries as nei- ther honest nor fair, the percent of those who do not share this view is comparatively high at 30 percent, putting Armenia in the same group as Croatia and Latvia. Like most other transition economies, Armenia has experienced the growing gap between the enacted legislation that has laid the ground for a market economy and the capacity of courts to implement new commercial laws. This gap between the extent of commercial legis- lation existing in 1999 (the so-called "legal extensiveness") and the degree to which it was being implemented at that time (that is, the "legal effectiveness") was particularly high for Armenia. It was well above the level in other transition countries (EBRD 1999). Although this "implementation gap" persisted in 2002, it fell drastically, reach- ing the level registered in the Czech Republic. A very important dimension from the perspective of firms is the ability of courts to adjudicate disputes in an efficient and timely man- ner, as this reduces uncertainty in actual or potential business deals. The BEEPS surveys asked respondents about the fairness, honesty, affordability, ability to enforce decisions, and speed of the courts. Armenian courts had improved dramatically in terms of speed. In fact, Armenia, together with Hungary, Macedonia, Latvia, Lithuania, and the Czech Republic, showed the largest improvement in the per- ceived speediness of courts between 1999 and 2002. While in 1999 only 10 percent of firms viewed courts as quick, in Armenia this propor- tion rose to 25 percent of respondents, comparable to Hungary. This should rise further once the case management and court administra- tion systems currently being developed are put in place to help fill the statistical and knowledge gap that has been reducing the effectiveness of the courts in Armenia. According to firms participating in the BEEPS, Armenian courts are not only quick but also affordable by CEEC/CIS standards. 346 Part II: Detailed Analysis To sum up, the reasons for the large size of the informal sector in Armenia stem mostly from the high regulatory compliance costs that are due to official and unofficial payments, the instabilities in the state policies toward the business sector, and predatory tax and customs administrations, but not from weaknesses in the judicial system. While efforts designed to reform the judiciary should continue, improving tax and customs administration together with injecting stability into business regulations and policies stand out as major "other" ingredi- ents that account for the gap between the formal and the revealed real ease of doing business in Armenia. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS What does this imply for Armenian reforms? First of all, these "other ingredients" that allow the state administration (for example, tax, cus- toms, and sanitary administrations as well as building inspections) to harass businesses need to be dealt with. Beyond the reform of tax and customs administration and the continuing work on simplifying the state­business interface, other immediate measures might be imple- mented. These would include fixing tax rates for a specified period of time in a manner assuring the credibility of the government's com- mitment; limiting the number of inspections, audits, and fact-finding visits allowed over a specified period of time;11 and reviewing and simplifying customs clearance procedures. Although "other ingredients" should be at the top of the reform agenda, this should not imply a lack of urgency in bringing the dis- cussed areas of doing business in line with best practice. Armenia has to neutralize the negative effects of its remoteness to the centers of gravity of global markets and of being landlocked. While the authorities should aspire to move toward the best prac- tice in each area and in each indicator, some weaknesses could be overcome by instituting "quick fixes." Such fixes assume that political opposition to the loss of rents usually associated with opaque regula- tions could be overcome. The fixes might include the following meas- ures in the areas listed below: Getting credit. Establish market information on the quality of borrowers and undertake other measures that facilitate access to financing. This would involve, in particular, establishing a framework for secured transactions to ensure conditions for col- lateral-based borrowing.12 Reforming the labor market. Review and change labor regula- tions with the goal of removing those that do not allow for flex- ible and open (in terms of tasks performed) term contracts; those Real and Formal Ease of Doing Business in Armenia 347 that limit the number of work hours or the number of shifts; and those that compel an entrepreneur to pay a severance package currently comprising the equivalent of 30 weeks' wages. In par- ticular, the last should be drastically reduced, if not zeroed, as is the case in New Zealand. Starting a business. Streamline the number of procedures to two, remove the capital requirement, and lower fees and other admin- istrative charges. Although these significant capital requirements are often justified as protection against damage from failing busi- nesses, countries with the friendliest conditions for business startups impose very small costs, if any. The reasoning behind simplicity and low administrative costs is simple: to encourage new business activity and ensure that it takes place within the realms of the formal economy. Registering property. Reduce the time needed to register prop- erty. Ease of registering property is a necessary condition, albeit not sufficient, to bring assets into the formal sector, which, in turn, allows using the assets to obtain financing. Protecting investors. Introduce laws covering the remaining areas of disclosure of financial information and ownership that will protect investors and shareholders against fraud. Armenia has three out of seven relevant regulations. However, their posi- tive impact hinges critically on improvements in assuring the legal protection of investors. Enforcing contracts. Improving contract enforcement is a long- term project involving the review of judicial procedures and the organization of courts. Given its importance, which is growing with economic development, it should be a constant fixture on the government's reform agenda. Although the hassle cost of doing business has been significantly reduced, the challenge ahead is to bring regulations in line with the best international practice. Because of its remote location from major world markets, Armenia needs to remove all administrative barriers that unnecessarily raise transaction costs including the costs of entry and exit as well as the costs of conducting business operations. NOTES 1. This chapter was prepared by Bartek Kaminski, University of Maryland, College Park, and the World Bank. 2. Transparency International CPI scores, EBRD scores of the progress in transition, and the World Bank governance indicators capture either the per- ception of investors (transparency) of the extent of graft in the country or the 348 Part II: Detailed Analysis relative performance of a country in terms of implemented reforms (EBRD Transition Reports) or an overall assessment of a country's capacity to govern (Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi 2003). 3. The CEEC-10 includes eight new EU members (the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, the Slovak Republic, and Slov- enia) and two prospective 2007 members, Bulgaria and Romania. The CIS includes Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Georgia, Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, Moldova, the Russian Federation, Ukraine, and Uzbekistan. The Doing Business survey does not cover two remaining CIS members, Tajikistan and Turkmenistan. 4. This should not suggest that streamlining procedures is an exercise in futility. As long as it is accompanied by fewer documents and permissions, it may ultimately help reduce time spent on procedures and will certainly curtail the potential for extracting bribes. 5. For a more detailed discussion, see Kaminski (2005). 6. Countries that "spoil" to the largest extent an otherwise almost perfect picture are Belarus, Slovenia, and the Slovak Republic. The first two have large informal economies and a low perception of corruption, whereas the Slo- vak Republic has higher corruption in relation to its small informal sector. 7. It is "revealed" because it takes into account the extent to which busi- nesses express a preference to opt out from the official economy or to stay in it. 8. The CEEC-8 countries are the Czech Republic, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Hungary, Poland, Slovenia, and the Slovak Republic. 9. According to the 2004 RCS, 71 percent of respondents identified cor- ruption as a persistent problem, up from 66 percent over the previous year. Interestingly, corruption appears to be much less of a problem for foreign- owned firms than for domestic companies (FIAS 2003). 10. According to the World Bank study reviewing progress in judicial reform in transition economies, progress has been much weaker in all tran- sition countries than in other areas of institutional reform since 1990. Fur- thermore, firms' perceptions of the legal and judicial systems in transition countries are worse than comparable perceptions in most other regions of the world, according to a recent world-wide survey of business executives (Anderson, Bernstein, and Gray 2005). 11. Although tax officials can conduct only one audit per year, they are allowed to undertake as many "fact-finding" visits, not classified as an audit, as they wish. Furthermore, information obtained during such "fact finding" visits is used in annual audits. The protection of the restriction on auditing is therefore limited. 12. For practical recommendations concerning the design of a legal frame- work for secured transactions, see Holden and Sahakyan (2004). Chapter 12 Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies INTRODUCTION Armenia's macroeconomic growth performance has been impressive over the last half decade.1 So has its foreign trade performance, with exports having emerged recently as the major driver of GDP growth. Yet unemployment continues to stay at double-digit levels and the brain drain has not been reversed, which points to limited employ- ment opportunities across a wide range of skills in Armenia. A World Bank study (2002a) argued that to date Armenia's output growth had not been accompanied by employment generation and poverty reduc- tion, primarily because the business environment was not supportive of enterprise restructuring and new entry for most of the period. From the perspective of 2005, nothing points to any change in this respect. It appears that exports have also had a limited contribution to employ- ment growth. What can be done to increase growth rates beyond the levels already achieved and, simultaneously, reduce unemployment and poverty? Missed opportunities in the export of goods may be linked to four major barriers that prevent Armenia from fully reaping the benefits offered by globalization and that may jeopardize its impressive export growth performance: stalled structural reforms, transport, network- based information technology, and the customs/VAT rebate regime. Weaknesses in these areas have been responsible for some atypical features of Armenia's export performance, namely, the underrepresen- tation of unskilled labor-intensive products in its export basket due in large part to the limited participation in the clothing global value chains and the virtual absence of Armenian firms in a new division of labor spurred by production fragmentation. Network trade has been the most rapidly growing component of world trade over the last two 349 350 Part II: Detailed Analysis decades. Except for diamonds and software, Armenia appears to have missed this opportunity. Armenia's two export success stories--diamonds and software-- corroborate, with an ironic twist, the above assessment. While the two are different, drawing policy conclusions from their success stories would make it possible to circumvent the weaknesses of Armenia's regime in shaping external interaction as well as to soften the external adversities that are due to the country's geography. More important, these stories demonstrate that benefits from reforms that addressed the above weaknesses might be quick to come because they would tap into two great assets--the high quality of human capital and the Armenian diaspora. Several observations emerge from this discussion: Armenia has largely completed the process of implementing first-generation reforms. Prices are not only stable but are also almost fully shaped by market forces. Armenia's exchange and foreign trade regimes are liberal and do not obstruct trade and financial flows. Progress in the implementation of structural reforms has been uneven. For the last three years reforms appear to have stalled. Consequently, there has been no perceptible change in FDI inflows, although they remain some of the highest among CIS economies. While structural reforms take time, some measures that would improve Armenia's attractiveness can be implemented with the stroke of a pen. These include establishing a "white list" of com- panies to receive "flowing treatment" by customs, and a quick VAT rebate scheme. Other recommended measures--better regulatory oversight of telecommunications and unilateral open sky liberalization--may take time to implement, but they should be addressed urgently. Liberalization of trade in services may improve the quality and availability of services through competition, economies of scale, and, last but not least, incentives to policy makers to improve the regulatory environment. The benefits of services liberalization are not limited to the services sectors themselves: they affect all other economic activi- ties. In view of the fact that services contribute on average around 10­20 percent to the production cost of a product and account for all trading costs (transport, trade finance, insurance, communications, and distribution services), the savings from stronger competition from foreign providers can indeed be substantial, as can gains in competi- tiveness in the international markets of both services and goods. Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 351 FOREIGN TRADE AND UNTAPPED OPPORTUNITIES: PERFORMANCE, SPILLOVERS, AND FACTOR ENDOWMENTS Considering the adverse geopolitical conditions peculiar to Armenia and the country's lackluster trade performance through most of the 1990s, the very strong export growth performance after the contraction preceding the Russian financial crisis in August 1998 comes as sur- prise. Contrary to various assessments following the economic stagna- tion in 1998­99 the Armenian economy has displayed surprising vital- ity, driven mainly by its impressive export growth performance. This vitality indicates an important turnaround in Armenia's post-central planning economic performance in three important dimensions. First, the turnaround is based on restructured industrial capaci- ties. The inherited industrial capacities that were incompatible with market disciplines appear to have been mostly dismantled; the emerg- ing industrial structure meets the demanding requirements of inter- national markets, as witnessed by the export growth performance. No other CIS economy recorded such strong growth in 1999­2003. Armenian firms have also outperformed other non-oil CIS competi- tors in both the CIS (Russian) and the EU markets, with their shares in the respective markets increasing significantly in the 1999­2003 period. Their share in total EU imports doubled in 2003 alone. Against the background of falling Russian imports from most CIS countries, the Armenian performance appears particularly impressive, with the value of exports of goods more than doubling between 1999 and 2003. Trade with the CIS appears to be driven no longer by the post-Soviet hysteria in trade patterns, with the emerging trade reflecting a com- parative advantage in these now increasingly competitive markets as these countries make progress in structural reforms. Second, the readjustment in the geographical pattern of trade reflecting the economic weight of regional markets appears to be com- plete. While in 1995 Russia, together with other CIS countries, took 56 percent of Armenia's exports and supplied 49 percent of Arme- nia's imports of goods, these shares fell to 25 percent and 27 percent, respectively, in 1999, and 19 percent and 23 percent, respectively, in 2003. The shift has been largely toward the EU-15,2 whose share in Armenian exports rose from 26 percent in 1995 to 48 percent in 2003 and in imports from 15 percent to 32 percent over the same period. Last but not least, the expansion in exports has not been confined to goods but has also included services, especially if the estimate putting exports of ITC services at around US$100 million rather than US$11 million reported in the balance-of-payments category of "com- puter and information services" is roughly correct. With or without a revised figure for these services, revenues from services increased 352 Part II: Detailed Analysis more than expenditures. With a revised figure, the balance of trade in services swung to a surplus in 2003, and the overall deficit in trade in goods and services was significantly lower. Export Performance in a CIS Perspective Armenia's exports of goods and services--even excluding the estimate of unreported exports of ICT services--in terms of value recorded had the largest growth among the CIS peers in 1999­2003, well above the next best performer, Turkmenistan. Although it might be argued that the growth occurred against a very low base, the fall in trade over the 1990s was not a distinctive feature of Armenia's performance. All CIS countries experienced a huge slump in trade before and immediately after the collapse of the FSU, estimated at around 80 percent between 1990 and 1993 (Michalopoulos and Tarr 1994, p. 5). Although the 1998 financial crisis in Russia punctured the export recovery then under way in all CIS countries (World Bank 2004), exports had contracted earlier in terms of value. In order to account for the differences in the "initial base," as a baseline, Table 12.1 tabulates the index for 2003 using the peak value of exports in a year preceding the contraction (for the respective years, see note (1) to Table 12.1). Except for Azerbai- jan, exports of other CIS countries increased less than in Armenia. Sales to customers in Armenia's two most important markets--the EU and Russia--have driven export growth. These two markets jointly took 60 percent of its total exports in 2003. Armenia was the only country in the CIS that succeeded in readjusting its export offer to the dramatically expanding and shifting Russian import demand toward more sophisticated, higher-quality goods. While suppliers from highly developed countries outperformed Armenian exporters in Russian markets, these were not firms from other CIS countries. Armenia was the only CIS economy whose share in Russia's total imports increased over 1999­2003. Armenia's performance in EU markets has also been superior over the entire 1998­2003 period, except for the contraction in 2001. While, all other CIS non-oil exporters have increased their pres- ence in EU markets relative to other suppliers, except for the Kyrgyz Republic and Uzbekistan, Armenia's gains in import shares were the largest in the 1999­2003 period. Although Armenia's exports as share of GDP also recorded the strongest performance among the CIS economies, its share of exports in GDP was one of the lowest in the CIS. Despite a much larger popu- lation, Ukraine, with a GDP per capita that is only 7 percent larger than that of Armenia, has exports per capita that are 60 percent higher. Only in Georgia, the Russian Federation, and Uzbekistan was this share lower. However, except for Georgia, with a population 57 percent larger (albeit with a GDP only 20 percent higher), both Russia and Uzbekistan Table 12.1 CIS: Total Exports, Export Growth, and Share of Exports in GDP, 1999­2003 Armenia's Index, Total exports Index, Exports as Index, GDP per capita 2003 per capita 2003 percent of GDP 2003 Country 1999 2003 1999=100 1999 2003 1999=100(1) 1999 2003 Note (1)=100 External Armenia 601 916 152 125 338 271 21 37 267 Azerbaijan 550 838 152 154 351 228 28 42 311 Belarus 1,235 1,224 99 653 929 142 53 76 116 Performance Georgia 561 700 125 148 212 144 26 30 106 Kazakhstan 1,141 1,966 172 468 927 198 41 47 172 Kyrgyz Rep. 245 341 139 103 133 129 42 39 88 Moldova 278 443 159 146 236 162 53 53 85 Russian Federation 1,372 3,018 220 593 966 163 43 32 137 and Tajikistan 167 190 114 107 128 119 64 67 103 Ukraine 658 976 148 353 547 155 54 56 137 Policy Uzbekistan 333 378 113 119 137 115 36 36 83 Source: Derived from the World Bank Sima database (http://sima/datasite/sima-web/default.htm). Remedies Note: (1) Data are from 1995 for Tajikistan; 1996 for Armenia, Russia, and Ukraine; and 1997 for the remaining eight CIS countries. These are the years when the value of exports of goods peaked before it subsequently fell in 1997 and 1998. (2) Net exporters of oil and gas are marked in bold. No data were available for Turkmenistan. 353 354 Part II: Detailed Analysis have a much larger domestic economy. Furthermore, exports of goods and services as a percent of Armenia's GDP were also significantly lower than in Moldova (53 percent in 2003), with a smaller GDP per capita, and more developed in Lithuania (56 percent in 2003). Hence, the level of openness of the Armenian economy remains low and its prosperity critically depends on an acceleration in trade growth performance. Without strong export growth well above GDP growth, Armenia will not catch up with more developed economies. Commercial Services and Nondiamond Exports Since 1999 exports have been growing faster than GDP on an annual basis, with the differential sharply increasing in 2002­03 (Figure 12.1). The share of exports of goods and services in GDP rose from 19 percent in 1998 to 37 percent in 2003, while the share of imports fell from 53 percent to 49 percent. Consequently, the import cover- age by exports of goods and services has improved: exports in terms of imports increased from 42 percent in 1999 to 63 percent in 2002 and 64 percent in 2003. Moreover, a strong GDP growth performance considerably lessened an overall potentially negative macroeconomic impact of trade imbalances. In terms of GDP, the trade deficit has been falling rather rapidly, from 38 percent in 1997 to 27 percent in 2000 and 12 percent in 2003. While the annual growth rates of exports of services, as captured in balance of payments statistics, lagged behind the growth of GDP in 2001­03, exports of goods were the driving force behind Arme- nia's GDP growth performance. But international statistics may fail to account for exports of services. In fact, it appears that exports of services were an important factor behind Armenia's impressive exter- nal performance. Trade in Services Growth in Armenia's trade in services is well below the growth of trade in goods. The share of commercial services (excluding govern- ment transactions) in Armenia's total exports of goods and services peaked in 1998 at 34 percent and fell to 25 percent in 2002 and 19 percent in 2003. But the "contraction" or "stagnation" in exports of services is rela- tive and does not suggest that the services sector is not on a sound footing. The relative decline has occurred against a blockbuster per- formance of trade in goods and the rapid growth of the GDP. The value of exports of services increased 53 percent between 1999 and 2003. This would have been an impressive performance had there been a weaker performance in the trade in goods. But over the 1999­ Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 355 Figure 12.1 Dynamics of Exports of Goods and Services and GDP and Change in Exports and Imports as Percent of GDP, 1998­2003 60 60 50 50 40 percent 40 in percent 30 in rate 30 20 GDP in growth 20 10 share annual 0 10 -10 0 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 year imports as percent of GDP annual rate of GDP growth exports as percent of GDP annual rate of export growth Source: IMF Balance of Payments statistics and World Bank Sima database. 2003 period exports of goods more than tripled. Therefore, the matter deserves a closer examination. Trade in services is defined in GATS (the General Agreement on Trade in Services) as the supply of a service through any of four "modes of supply." Mode 1 is services supplied from one country to another (for example, international telephone calls), officially known as "cross-border supply." Mode 2 consists of consumers from one country making use of a service in another country (for example, tourism), officially known as "consumption abroad." Mode 3 involves a company from one country setting up subsidiaries or branches to provide services in another country (for example, a bank from one country setting up operations in another country), officially known as "commercial presence." Mode 4 involves individuals traveling from their own country to supply services in another country (for example, an actor or a construction worker), officially known as "movement of natural persons." 356 Part II: Detailed Analysis Although specific commitments under GATS are defined in terms of the four standard modes of supply, the trade statistics for the avail- able services are not reported according to a mode of supply and do not allow taking a full account of trade in services. International transactions as defined in the national accounts and balance of pay- ments statistics diverge from the GATS definition of services. Even if some transactions can be captured in balance of payments statistics, the latter suffer from three major deficiencies: they do not distinguish between modes of supply; the definition of a resident and a non- resident differs from the GATS; and the breakdown of services differs from the GATS. The factors of production staying longer than a year in a country are treated as having acquired the status of resident. Fur- thermore, local sales of foreign entities are no longer treated as trans- actions between residents and nonresidents, and as such captured by balance of payments statistics. Transactions falling into such modes of supply as commercial presence and movement of natural persons are not reported in these statistics. Balance of payments statistics do not distinguish between modes of supply (that is, cross-border sup- ply, consumption abroad, commercial presence, or presence of natural persons for less than a year). Furthermore, within WTO definitions, all services except transport and travel are identified as "other commer- cial services" and services exercised by governments are excluded. Hence, as long as a new reference framework for measuring trade in services according to GATS is not in place, proxies derived from the balance of payments statistics and information from other sources are the only way to estimate services trade. The current practice is to use balance of payments statistics categories other than travel and construction as a proxy for cross-border supply (mode 1); "travel" as an indicator of consumption abroad of a service (mode 2); and "com- pensation of employees" together with labor-related statistics from the balance of payments as a proxy for the presence of natural persons (mode 4). The balance of payments statistics do not allow the capture of activities falling under a commercial presence, with the exception of construction services (mode 3). Some estimates of mode 3 can be derived from FAT (foreign affiliate transfers) statistics, if available, or data on FDI stocks together with production statistics such as value added (share of foreign firms in a market) or turnover of foreign firms with their share in respective markets for services. Proxies are what they are--only surrogates for the absence of sta- tistical concepts and methodologies that would allow gauging trade in line with the GATS classification. The major problems stem from the two following weaknesses of balance of payments statistics from the point of view of the task at hand. First, the balance of payments category "travel" tends to overestimate trade in mode 1, as it includes Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 357 consumption of goods. The statistics do not provide information that allows for distinguishing what tourists and business travelers spend on hotels, transportation, services in restaurants, and foods and other goods. Second, some balance of payments components may fall into more than one mode of delivery; that is, it is impossible to assess how a service has been provided. For instance, the transaction between a resident and a nonresident of a country concerning the provision of a computer-related service may take place over the Internet (cross-border, mode 1) or on the site of a resident firm by an expert dispatched by a foreign firm (commercial presence, mode 4). Taking all these factors into consideration, the data presented in Table 12.2, limited to the balance of payments and FDI statistics, seek to capture trade in services according to the mode of supply. Not sur- prisingly, transborder trade in services (mode 1), comprising all bal- ance of payments categories except travel and construction, accounts for the largest share. Construction activities and information on FDI in services are used to assess the scope of trade under mode 3. No data have been available to assess the services trade related to the presence of natural persons (mode 4). Commercial presence (mode 3--that is, the supply of services by foreign-owned firms) is of particular interest, as it potentially has a positive impact on the business climate, provided that a competitive environment is in place. While we do not have data on the foreign firms' share of the total value of services provided by various sectors, the total stock of FDI in services appears to be quite large. On average, FDI inflows in services amounted to 3 percent of GDP over 1998­2003. Their impact on employment might have been considerably higher than the FDI figures alone might imply. For instance, provision of software services--a trademark of Armenia's rapidly developing spe- cialization--is a knowledge-intensive rather than capital-intensive activity, and such low-capital activities have been rapidly expanding in Armenia. Lycos Armenia, a subsidiary of a large multinational soft- ware corporation, is an interesting example (Box 12.1). However, some of these inflows have failed to generate high-qual- ity and low-price services. The primary example is the telecommuni- cations services. This sector accounted for 43 percent of total FDI flows to services over 1998­2003, but the restriction of competition in this sector (as discussed in chapter 10 of this book) has meant expensive and poor quality services. The existence of competitive markets for services combined with the commercial presence of foreign-owned firms is crucial to trade in both goods and services. FDI amounting to US$25 million invested in hotels and restaurants has probably contributed to exports in mode 2--that is, to tourism. FDI peaked over 1998­2000, whereas 358 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 12.2 Trade in Services by Mode of Supply, 1999­2003 (US$ million) Exports (revenues) Imports (expenditures) Mode of supply 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Mode 1: Transborder supply 93.6 91.7 112.2 104.6 115.9 142.9 136.5 146.5 155.2 170.1 Mode 2: Consumption abroad 31.0 37.8 64.9 63.3 71.3 36.7 39.7 39.7 53.9 68.5 Mode 3: Commercial presence Source: Own calculations based on Armenian official Balance of Payments statistics. Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 359 Box 12.1 Lycos Armenia on the Move Lycos Armenia provides four insights into the development of ICT serv- ices in Armenia. First, it shows the ability of Armenians to build upon human skills developed before independence. Lycos Europe (originally founded in May 1997 as a joint venture between Lycos Inc., USA, and Bertelsmann AG, Germany)a, a leading European Internet firm running one of the most popular Internet portals, moved to Armenia in August 2002 with the purchase of the local branch of Brience Inc., a mobile software solution provider company based in San Francisco. Brience Inc. did not establish the company in Armenia but acquired in 2000 a local Armenian company, started in 1986, that was one of first users worldwide of Java technology. Second, the case of Lycos Armenia illustrates strong growth potential and Armenia's strong comparative advantage in ICT-related activities. Lycos Armenia has become the largest developer of software within the Lycos Europe network. The staff of Lycos Armenia grew from 55 to 170 in early 2005, with plans to further increase to 220 employees over 2005. The French media reported that the company intends to lay off 75 employees in its Paris division and has offered 34 of them employment in its expanding subsidiary in Armenia. Third, these are highly paid jobs. According to ICT sources, an expe- rienced software expert makes around US$ 1,000 a month. Last but not least, Lycos Armenia cooperates mainly with other firms of the Lycos network. The commercial presence is designed not to serve local markets but to develop "programmed" products for sale in world markets. Sources: See Lycos' Web site (http://www.lycos-europe.am/pages/history.htm). a. Lycos Europe has branches in all major European capitals, and its total workforce is estimated at 900. The company's single largest shareholder is the U.S. group Terra Lycos, which created one of the world's first Internet search engines in the mid-1990s. the value of exports under mode 2 (mostly tourism) more than dou- bled over 1999­2001. Since exports continued to rise in 2003 despite falling inflows, clearly viable infrastructure for future business and individual travel has been established. The congruence in the time profiles of FDI inflows and exports under mode 2 does not seem to be accidental. Furthermore, investments of US$3.7 million in 2003 in air transportation services or, more precisely, in the modernization of Yerevan Airport (leased to a foreign contractor) have provided an incentive to returning tourists and business persons. The airport also has facilities to handle air cargo efficiently, with a potentially positive impact on trade in goods. 360 Part II: Detailed Analysis The link between commercial presence and trade in goods is both direct and indirect. The direct link is that without logistics-related and other commercial services, no trade on a significant scale can take place. Foreign providers may contribute to services' availability and low prices. The indirect link is the contribution of commercial pres- ence to an improved business climate and an increase in the country's attractiveness to FDI. For instance, the presence of internationally rec- ognized banks and freight integrators may tip the balance in favor of a decision to invest. Their presence has probably contributed to the expansion in exports of ITC services, as it established a safe venue for payments for services. Similarly, the foreign presence exceeding US$10 million over 2001­03 in such areas as R&D and education is likely to have valuable spillover effects that will enhance the competitiveness of knowledge-intensive sectors of the economy. Although Armenia's trade in services does not appear to be strong in contrast to trade in goods, the alleged contraction or stagnation in exports of services is relative and does not suggest that the services sector is not on a sound footing. In fact, it appears that trade in services has been grossly underesti- mated, as statistics fail to capture the lion's share of exports of services provided, for instance, over the Internet. The balance of payments statistics estimate the value of exports of computer and information services (falling in mode 11 of the transborder supply) at US$11 mil- lion in 2003, up from US$1 million in 2002. Other widely quoted esti- mates of ITC exports in Armenia put their value (almost exclusively encompassing Internet solutions, embedded system designs, and tel- ecommunication systems software architectures) at around US$100 million.3 If this is indeed the case, then Armenia has been a huge net exporter of services. Services as a share of total exports were 28 percent rather than the reported 19 percent. In brief, the inclusion of this estimate of ITC exports of services significantly changes the overall picture of Armenia's interaction with the global economy. It suggests a much higher level of openness of the Armenian economy. More important, it also suggests that external interaction has a crucial role in driving Armenia's GDP growth and reducing unemployment. Exports of Goods While diamonds have been major contributors to Armenia's expan- sion of exports of goods, they have not been the only levers of growth. First, an increase in the share of diamonds in total exports until 2003, which grew at an average least-square rate of 44 percent, reflected the impressive growth of all exports, not the result of the stagnat- Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 361 ing exports of nondiamond products. With an annual growth rate of 33 percent over 1999­2003, nondiamond exports also experienced impressive growth. As a result, they caught up with diamond exports in terms of value in 2003, with their share in total exports of almost 50 percent. But in 2004 nondiamond exports continued their impressive growth, while diamond exports contracted (Figure 12.2). Second, the increase in concentration was not merely the result of the growth in diamond exports but also of the deepening export specialization and less marginal presence in world markets. There has been little change in the largest export sectors, as the correlation between the shares of exports of 25 four-digit SITC product groups in 1999 and 2003 is very high at 98 percent. However, the top nine SITC Rev 2 four-digit sectors (excluding diamonds) in exports in 2003 expe- rienced stronger growth than diamonds. Their average annual growth rate was 39 percent in 1999­2003, and the share of diamonds in the top ten sectors fell from 63 percent in 1999 to 60 percent in 2003. What are the nondiamond products that Armenia exports? By far the single most important group is spirits and liqueurs (SITC 1124), whose Figure 12.2 Exports of Diamonds and Other Products, 1997­2004 600 exports of other goods 500 exports of diamonds 400 million 300 US$ 200 100 0 1997 1999 2000 2002 2003 2004 year Source: Derived from data reported by Armenia to the UN COMTRADE database. 362 Part II: Detailed Analysis foreign sales quadrupled between 1999 and 2003 and whose share in total exports of goods rose from 5 percent to 13 percent over this period. Other products include nonferrous base metals (SITC 28882), jewelry (8973), ores and concentrates of nonferrous metals (2879), ferro-alloys (6716), metal-cutting machine tools (7361), aluminum alloys (6842), copper alloys (6821), and copper ores (2871). Taken together, these products contributed 30 percent to total exports in 2003. Armenia appears also to have been regaining a competitive advan- tage in other products in which it used to specialize when it was part of the former Soviet Union. These products include ores and concen- trates of nonferrous metals, liqueurs, tungsten, molybdenum, tanta- lum, magnum, copper, and ferro-alloys. However, except for liqueurs and ores and concentrates of nonferrous metals, the EU has replaced the former Soviet republics as the major export market. In 2003 it took 100 percent of all exports of tungsten, molybdenum, tantalum, and magnum (SITC 6891), 100 percent of exports of ferro-alloys, and 95 percent of exports of copper alloys. Nevertheless, a bad sign is that manufactures other than diamonds were conspicuously absent in Armenia's exports. Although the share of manufactures excluding chemicals increased in Armenia's total exports from 39 percent in 2000 to 60 percent in 2003, this was mainly due to the increase in exports of diamonds. Other manufactured exports fell in terms of value from US$59 million in 2000 to US$44 million in 2002 and increased to US$54 million in 2003. Their share in total exports fell from 29 percent in 2000 to 11 percent in 2002 and 10 percent in 2003. While the sluggish growth of manufactured exports other than dia- monds in the presence of Armenia's potential comparative advantage should raise policy concerns, there is nothing inherently wrong with a large concentration of exports. High concentration is the result of the small size of the national economy and its narrow industrial base. There is one important stipulation, however. If the bulk of export reve- nues comes from a commodity subject to weather conditions and high volatility in international markets, then a national economy may be vulnerable to external shocks. But this is not the case with diamonds and Armenia. Diamonds seem to be less vulnerable than other "sin- gle crops," including textiles and clothing, to international supply or demand volatility for two reasons. First, Armenian firms are firmly entrenched in a global diamond value chain through international investors, albeit not completely invul- nerable. Armenian diamond-polishing factories are parts of both the Antwerp-centered link and the Israeli-based Lev Leviev Group. There is an important caveat, however: some activities depend on supplies from Russia. A contraction of almost 75 percent in the Russian supply of Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 363 raw diamonds in 2004 has affected Armenia's diamond export perform- ance. Thus in 2004, the value of Armenia's diamond exports contracted 33 percent. Both total and EU-destined exports, however, increased in terms of value, but exports to Israel, one of the major recipients of dia- monds cut in Armenia, significantly contracted (Table 12.3). Second, the diamond market remains fairly controlled, with prices displaying remarkable stability. Although previous performance is not necessarily an indication of future performance, a sudden fall in prices and demand is rather unlikely. As The Economist (2004) notes, "the cartel isn't forever." However, it adds that no major player would seek to bring the prices down. Yet spillovers from diamond production appear to be relatively lim- ited, as value added locally is limited to employing the local labor force and using energy and other services. There are no other inputs into diamond production, which is mainly a gem-cutting operation. Thus, the high value of diamond exports, accounting for half of total exports, overstates their overall impact on economic welfare. On the other hand, one may argue that reliance of exports on just one sector of the economy does not set Armenia aside from many other transition economies. For instance, the share of the 10 best- performing sectors in total exports exceeded two-thirds in 2003 in at least five transition economies--Albania, Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, and Moldova. A single sector was responsible for around half (or more) of the total exports of Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, and the Kyrgyz Republic (Table 12.4). There were different sectors involved--gold mining in the Kyrgyz Republic, oil in Azerbaijan and Kazakhstan, and textiles and clothing in Albania, Bulgaria, Macedo- nia and Moldova, albeit the concentration of exports in the last was significantly lower. Both oil and clothing, however, have different characteristics from diamonds, as they usually involve higher value left in a country (oil), higher value added in a country, or are produced locally. The cloth- ing sector is more labor intensive than diamond cutting and has the potential to generate spillover effects provided the economic regime is friendly toward private business activity. Revenues from oil, if not mismanaged by central authorities, can contribute to the development of a country's infrastructure, thereby facilitating trade. These observations should not diminish Armenia's success in find- ing an attractive niche in global markets. But they add urgency to adopting measures that would expand Armenia's export offer. Other exports are already emerging, indicating the growing specialization and falling marginalization of Armenian suppliers in international markets. It is hoped that diamonds will continue to shine, providing employment and reducing poverty. 364 Part II: Detailed Table 12.3 Recipients of Armenia's Exports, 2000­04 (US$ million) Analysis Index, 2004 Share of exports 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2000 = 100 European Union 247 196 245 351 401 162 Israel 2 20 80 123 100 5,005 Total 300 342 347 566 591 465 Total annual change n.a. 14% 2% 63% 4% 197 Memorandum share in world exports 0.005% 0.006% 0.005% 0.008% 0.007% 138 EU-15 imports (including intra-EU trade) 0.005% 0.004% 0.005% 0.008% 0.006% 139 Source: Own calculations based on data from the IMF Direction of Trade database (http://www.imf.org/external/data.htm#data). n.a. not applicable Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 365 Table 12.4 Sector Concentration of Exports in Selected Transition Economies, 2003 (percent) Share of Share of the largest Share of top ten item in a oil and SITC Rev 2 SITC Rev 2 Share of oil-related Country 4-digit sectors 4-digit sector clothing products Albania 69 26 34 n.a. Armenia 83 50 n.a. n.a. Azerbaijan 91 70 n.a. 85 Bulgaria 29 6 20 n.a. Kazakhstan 78 45 n.a. 58 Kyrgyz Republic 74 45 n.a. n.a. Macedonia 45 7 30 n.a. Moldova 53 28 15 n.a. Source: Own calculations based on the UN COMTRADE database (http://unstats.un.org/unsd/comtrade/default.aspx). Note: n.a. stands for not applicable; that is, the share in total exports is below 5 percent. Low Participation of Unskilled Labor in Exports Armenia's factor endowments suggest specialization in natural resources and labor-intensive products. Armenia has significant deposits of copper and zinc and traditionally has been a producer of industrial minerals. It is amply endowed in clay, construction stones, and semiprecious gems, with small amounts of mined gold as well. Armenia also has climate conditions that favor agriculture and is noted for the quality of its fruits and grapes. Last but not least, it has a large pool of a relatively low-cost labor, both highly skilled and unskilled. Hence, products that are intensive in the use of unskilled labor and in the use of natural resources should dominate its export basket. On the import side, Armenia should be a large importer of capital and skilled labor-intensive products together with fuels. The factor intensities of Armenia's exports of goods, however, do not fully corroborate these expectations. Armenia is a net exporter of skilled labor-intensive products and a net importer of all other products, including unskilled labor-intensive and natural resource- intensive products (Table 12.5). But in line with its endowments, natural resource-intensive products accounted in 2003 for more than half of Armenia's total exports. The evolution and the current factor content of Armenia's exports point to two conflicting developments: the emergence of market disci- pline and the persistence of domestic barriers to the efficient allocation 366 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 12.5 Factor Intensities of Armenian Trade in 1997, 2000, and 2003 Export value Export share (in US$ million) (in percent) Factor intensity 1997 2000 2003 1997 2000 2003 Natural resources 98 34 284 45.8 17.4 52.6 Unskilled labor 12 6 5 5.7 3.3 0.9 Capital 35 34 17 16.3 17.4 3.1 Skilled labor 63 111 214 29.3 57.1 39.7 Total 213 195 540 100 100 100 Exports in percent Import share of imports (in percent) Factor intensity 1997 2000 2003 1997 2000 2003 Natural resources 24.2 7.8 39.2 53.6 52.3 62.3 Unskilled labor 34.0 13.9 6.3 4.7 5.5 6.5 Capital 25.1 18.9 8.3 18.4 21.8 17.4 Skilled labor 94.1 120.6 133.4 8.8 11.1 13.8 Total 28.3 23.5 46.3 100.0 100.0 100.0 Source: Own calculations based on Armenia's national data as reported to the UN COMTRADE database (http://unstats.un.org/unsd/comtrade/default.aspx). Note: Factors are taken from SITC-4 Rev. 1. of resources in the national economy. The marginalization of exports of capital-intensive products points to an ongoing industrial restruc- turing in line with Armenia's endowments, illustrated by the disap- pearance of industrial capacities, inherited from Soviet-style industri- alization, that were noncompetitive without government subsidies. This readjustment occurred in 2000­03, with the share of capital-inten- sive products falling from 17 percent to 3 percent (Table 12.5). Their exports in terms of value fell 50 percent between 2000 and 2003. While the fall in capital-intensive exports provides evidence of the implementation of market-oriented reform measures, a very low share of unskilled labor-intensive products in Armenia's exports points to unfinished reforms. While among the CEEC-10 and SEE-5 economies the lowest share of unskilled labor-intensive products was 10 percent (Hungary), in 2003 this share in Armenia's exports--as well as in the exports of four other CIS economies (Azerbaijan, Georgia, Russia, and Kazakhstan)--was a mere 1 percent. The contraction in the share of unskilled labor-intensive products was not the result of faster growth of other exports, as the value of exports of unskilled labor-intensive products was lower in 2003 than in 2000. Similarly and more gener- Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 367 ally, stagnation in the exports of manufactures other than diamonds in 2000­03 points to the inability of tapping Armenia's major asset--the availability of a cheap and disciplined labor force. Hence, although open economies based on competitive markets have a unique trade pattern reflecting their endowment, this is yet to become the case with Armenia. The discord between Armenia's exports and its endowments in production factors points to either a deficiency in the mechanisms allocating capital and labor in the economy or to adverse external factors beyond government control. The former has to do with the low quality of the business environment, whereas the latter may include protectionist conditions in market access or high transportation costs. Access to most markets, excluding Azerbaijan and Turkey, is not a barrier, as it is either preferential (as with the CIS, EU-25 and other highly developed OECD economies) or based on Armenia's most favored nation status. But transportation is clearly a barrier in most land-locked countries. High transportation costs favor exports of those products with high value relative to weight and dis- courage sales of the bulky low-cost products of light industry, which usually involve unskilled labor-intensive activities. Whatever the explanation, the low share of unskilled labor-intensive products in Armenia's exports while unemployment remains at double- digit levels points to Armenia's inability to tap the opportunities offered by global markets. Furthermore, even a quick examination of Armenia's exports sug- gests that to date they have contributed little to reducing unemploy- ment and poverty. Unemployment has been locked for more than a decade at high double-digit levels (around 30 percent), two-thirds of the formally employed continue to be in the low value-added sectors of the economy (agriculture and trade), and one-third of Armenians were below the poverty line in 2003. In 2003, McKinsey warned that the Armenian GDP growth pat- tern, relying on a narrow base and generating limited employment effects, would encounter difficulties by 2005­06 (McKinsey & Com- pany 2003). Exports can help to reverse the current growth pattern provided that reform measures remove barriers to business activity. Once the barriers are removed, investors would take advantage of Armenia's assets--an educated labor force, the low labor cost, and the presence of the diaspora--and would turn the potential comparative advantage into a revealed one. Untapped Opportunities in Global Markets The idiosyncrasy of Armenia's export basket in terms of factor inten- sities stems, on the one hand, from its ability to tap the benefits of becoming part of a global value chain for diamonds and, on the other 368 Part II: Detailed Analysis hand, from its inability to take advantage of opportunities created by the emerging forms of the global division of labor. The outsourcing of services and production activities has been the driving force of world trade. Thanks to technological progress and the information revolution, it has become possible to divide the industry's value chain, including services, into smaller functions that can be contracted out to independent suppliers. This fragmentation of production has offered unique opportunities for producers in small countries to move from servicing their limited local markets to supplying large multinational firms and, indirectly, their customers throughout the world. The major sectors in which this process has been taking place are textiles and clothing, footwear, furniture, automobiles, computers, semiconduc- tors, and heavy machinery. Automobiles and ICT represent the most dynamic networks. The sequence observed in successful European transition economies was the movement from textiles and clothing, footwear, and furniture to automobiles, heavy machinery, and ICT. Armenia has successfully entered the diamond global value chain but has yet to participate in other value chains and networks, including first-stage simple networks. Textiles and clothing have almost disappeared in Armenian exports, as the value of their exports fell from US$13 million in 1999 to US$1.7 million in 2003. As for another easily accessible network, Armenia has never been an exporter of furniture and its parts. The situation has not changed, as Armenian firms have not plugged into the global supply chains of multinational retailers of furniture. Exports of furniture and its parts have been practically nonexistent: their value was well below US$100,000 in 2003. Nor have Armenian firms become part of the second- stage, more sophisticated, networks of production and distribution. Given the country's location and lack of tradition, it is not surpris- ing that no Armenian firm has become a supplier to major producers of automobiles. However, Armenia's absence from the global supply chains of ICT firms comes as a surprise. Despite outstanding success in the development of the ICT sector, nothing indicates the participation of Armenian firms in e-networks (such as electronics, including office equipment and telecommunications). ICT firms have not been able to take full advantage of huge opportunities for outsourcing created by recent changes in the ICT sector worldwide. With the disappearance of the global "one-stop-shop" industry structures in the early 1990s,4 opportunities have emerged for new entrants. Armenian firms have successfully entered the software and imaging technology niches. But they have failed to enter other stages of the production and delivery processes--in particular, as providers of front-end customer contact/ support services or suppliers of components (for example, metal, plas- tics, and electronic components).5 Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 369 In all, the manufacturing sector remains underrepresented in Arme- nia's export offer. It has clearly underperformed both domestically and internationally, as construction and other services have driven GDP growth and diamonds have driven export growth. This repre- sents an important missed opportunity. Owing to its ample endow- ment in skilled labor, Armenia's strongest comparative advantage lies in the manufacturing sector. FDI: Missed Opportunities and Factor Intensities of Armenian Exports The discord in Armenia's exports in terms of factor intensities reminds one of similar discords revealed in the exports of many economies dur- ing the initial stages of the transition from central planning.6 Former Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland experienced this in the early 1990s. FDI inflows have subsequently been responsible for closing the gap between the endowments and the factor content of exports. Trade in network products in particular has led to the increase in shares of skilled labor- and capital-intensive products in their exports. FDI has yet to accomplish the same task in Armenia for two reasons. First, FDI inflows have been relatively low. Armenia has performed very well in terms of attracting FDI by CIS standards, excluding oil- rich countries (Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, and Russia).7 But these have not been very demanding benchmarks. It should be borne in mind that its FDI inflows per capita were significantly lower than the simple average of FDI per capita in the CEEC-8 (Table 12.6). Second, although FDI as a percent of Armenia's GDP was quite significant (only 0.3 percentage points below the simple average for CEEC-8 economies), this would not change the picture significantly in terms of its impact on trade in part for at least three reasons. First, FDI inflows into Armenia are of relatively recent vintage. Until the sale of 90 percent of ArmenTel to OTE of Greece for US$142.5 million in late 1997,8 the total FDI inflows into Armenia in 1990­97 were less than US$50 million.9 Second, almost one-fifth of the total FDI inflows over 1995­2003 went into telecommunications with rather disappointing results, as current penetration rates for fixed and mobile services in Armenia remain significantly below the regional benchmarks, result- ing in a rather marginal improvement in the quality of these services. Third, other infrastructure-related sectors (such as water, electricity, and aviation have accounted for a sizable share of total FDI inflows (Table 12.6). While these inflows, as well as investment in hotels, restaurants, and so forth, are important for creating an environment enabling business activity, it usually takes time before they have a positive impact on such activities. 370 Part II: Detailed Table 12.6 FDI Inflows Compared, 1995­2003 Average Countries 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2000­03 Analysis FDI per capita Armenia 2 5 5 58 42 39 24 47 49 74 40 CIS-11 (simple average) 7 16 23 36 28 22 30 38 57 36 CIS-8 (excluding oil-rich) 5 7 14 24 16 15 15 20 22 18 CEEC-8 (simple average) 123 100 102 123 100 102 171 220 239 183 FDI as percent of GDP Armenia 0.5 1.1 1.1 12.3 7.0 6.3 3.6 6.0 5.5 5.5 5.3 CIS-11 (simple average) 1.1 3.0 3.7 5.7 4.1 3.3 3.6 4.5 6.8 6.8 4.5 CIS-8 (excluding oil-rich) 1.1 1.4 2.4 3.5 2.6 3.0 3.0 2.8 3.2 3.2 3.0 CEEC-8 (simple average) 3.7 3.1 3.2 5.5 4.8 5.8 5.6 7.4 5.0 5.0 5.8 Source: NSS and EBRD Annual Transition Reports (various issues) for other countries. Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 371 Indeed, there are reasons to believe that their impact on both exports and patterns of growth will be felt soon. It should be considered, first, that foreign inflows into Armenia have not consisted merely of FDI. In fact, Armenia has been the largest recipient of foreign aid per capita among CIS countries and, in addition, foreign remittances have amounted to around one-fifth of GDP on average for the last six years. Kuznetsov and Sabel (2004) rightly observe that remittances, private transfers from diaspora Armenians, and FDI inflows should provide a springboard for business development and entrepreneur- ship, provided that the institutional environment becomes more busi- ness friendly. Second, the high-quality FDI inflows--that is, those attracted by prospects of returns not based on special rents negotiated with the government (as was the case with the privatization of telecommunica- tions)--account for the growing share of FDI inward stock in Arme- nia. Total FDI in 2002­04 accounted for almost half (49 percent) of the total FDI inflows to Armenia since independence. This coincides with significant progress being made in implementing structural reforms, which usually augurs well for attracting high quality investors. So does the fact that 53 percent of total FDI over 2002­04 was not related to large-scale privatization (Figure 12.3). The composition of FDI inflows suggests that efficiency gains may be accruing in certain sectors to the benefit of potential exports. First, while the proportion of cumulative FDI inflows over 1995­2003 going to the industrial sector (56 percent) is in line with similar shares in the CEEC-8 economies, most of these investments have been concen- trated in two industries--electricity and beverage production. These two industries took almost two-thirds of cumulative inflows going to industries. Mining absorbed another 15 percent of cumulative FDI flows to the industrial sector. Exports of beverages (brandy) soared, confirming the positive impact of FDI on exports. Their value more than doubled in 2000 alone, with their share in total exports rising from 5 percent in 1999 to 8 percent in 2000 and 13 percent in 2003. Similarly, one suspects that the revival of exports of ores was linked to FDI. These exports collapsed in 1999 and reached the 1997 level only in 2002. Ores and other mining were among the largest recipients of FDI in 1998­99, taking US$50 million, or 27 percent, of all industrial FDI at that time. In addition, the successful privatization of the Zange- zur copper-molybdenum plant in Kajaran to Germany's Chronimet will dramatically increase the degree of processing embodied in the exports of molybdenum (Grigorian 2005). Second, there were also some investments in the manufacturing sector that may increase export potential. For instance, the medical, optical and measurement equipment area and the communications 372 Part II: Detailed Analysis Figure 12.3 Privatization and FDI Inflows, 1998­2004 200 100 80 150 percent in 60 millions 100 FDI 40 US$ total in 50 20 share 0 0 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 year other 46% 48% 66% 64% 64% 57% 69% privatization 54% 53% 34% 36% 36% 43% 31% other 107 64 83 49 95 90 163 privatization 125 71 42 27 54 67 72 Source: Derived from NSS official data as reported in Grigorian (2005). equipment area, both regarded as knowledge-intensive sectors, have attracted significant FDI inflows. In 2003, US$57 million worth of FDI went to medical, optical and measurement equipment, which received US$9 million in 2002­03 (Table 12.7). Furthermore, the almost US$6 million in FDI that went to the furniture sector over 2001­02 may be a harbinger of participation in global furniture networks. But this remains to be seen. In all, although there appears to be a strong correspondence between sectors that received significant inflows of FDI and their export per- formance, the problem remains that FDI inflows did not rush to the labor-intensive manufacturing sectors. By the same token, Armenia has not become part of the sophisticated global production and dis- tribution networks. More significantly, except for diamonds, Armenia did not become part of value chains such as clothing and furniture, where outsourcing does not necessarily require significant inflows of FDI and know-how. Table 12.7 Receipt of FDI Inflows by Sector, 1998­2003 Armenia's US$ million Sector 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Total FDI 2003 Share in % Agriculture 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 3.4 0.0 3.6 0.4 External Industry 98.9 94.7 56.5 35.3 86.0 102.2 473.6 55.5 Electricity, gas, hot water, and steam production and distribution 43.3 42.0 42.0 24.9 42.4 3.8 198.3 41.9 Performance Food and beverage production 13.2 37.7 7.8 3.9 13.6 12.9 89.0 18.8 Medical, optical, and measurement equipment and watch production 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.9 0.5 57.0 58.5 12.4 Ore (metal-bearing) mining and other subsectors of mining 29.0 10.5 3.4 0.7 3.3 12.2 59.2 12.5 and Chemical industry 2.6 0.2 0.2 0.7 10.8 0.3 14.8 3.1 Policy Metallurgy 0.6 0.5 0.4 2.2 3.0 6.4 13.0 2.7 Radio, broadcasting, and communications equipment production 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.6 6.0 8.5 1.8 Remedies Services 133.5 35.6 63.5 40.4 51.5 51.3 375.8 44.1 Source: NSS. 373 374 Part II: Detailed Analysis Conclusion: The Cost of Missed Opportunities The cost of missed opportunities seems to be significant. First, where textiles and clothing are concerned, the activity is highly labor-inten- sive, creating employment opportunities for a low-skilled and cheap, usually female, labor force. The welfare cost of the collapse of these exports is very significant. Second, the incorporation of local producers into other produc- tion and marketing networks as well as the supply of ICT consumer services could extend significant benefits to Armenia. This arrange- ment usually brings new technologies and managerial know-how as well as direct access to larger markets and thus brings in the benefits of economies of scale. Networks boost exports without making local firms incur marketing expenses and provide for greater stability in earnings, thanks to the global reach of a "parent" company. The frag- mentation of production eliminates the need to gain competency in all stages and aspects of production and allows a small country to focus on a subset of activities. At the same time, production sharing can broaden the range of final products whose components are produced in the small country and thus protect the country from a demand shock to a particular good. Third, with a stronger export performance, the growth of the Armenian economy could have been potentially higher and more employment-oriented. While exports have recorded a healthy growth since 1999, export growth continues to be concentrated mainly in sec- tors with limited employment opportunities. The expansion of manu- factured exports, especially those associated with global value chains and production and distribution networks, would go a long way toward addressing the challenge of stronger export performance. BUSINESS ENVIRONMENT AND POLICIES OBSTRUCTING EXTERNAL BUSINESS INTERACTION The discord between Armenia's exports and its endowments in pro- duction factors points to either a deficiency in the mechanisms of allo- cation, which discourages domestic and foreign investment, or adverse external factors beyond government control. Governments have lit- tle control over geography, although they can do a lot to lighten the negative impact of remote locations from major world markets. As a beginning, they may address weaknesses in the business environment, improve the contestability of domestic markets, and introduce meas- ures to bring down the cost of entry, exit, and conduct of business activity in both internal and external dimensions. In fact, the experi- Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 375 ence of successful transition economies suggests that two elements have to be in place: the successful implementation of first-generation reforms (such as liberalization of prices, foreign trade, and exchange regimes), and a consistent movement toward a rule-based institutional regime with the capacity of enforcement. The former is relatively easy to implement, in the absence of political opposition, whereas the latter requires the state's advanced institutional capacity. The reasons for Armenia's failure to tap opportunities have nothing to do with first-generation reforms, as Armenia completed the first- generation reform project almost a decade ago. By 1995, prices for most if not all tradables were fully liberalized, small-scale privatiza- tion was completed, the domestic currency had become convertible, and foreign trade and exchange rate regimes were fully liberalized. Inflation, after a period of hyperinflation following the dissolution of the former Soviet Union, appears to be firmly under control. As a result of a tight monetary policy and the appreciation of the national currency, inflation was at 2 percent in 2004. According to international assessments, Armenia has caught up with highly developed econo- mies in first-generation policy areas. However, the benefits of first-generation reforms cannot be fully taken advantage of unless they are accompanied by steady progress in implementing institutional, second-generation reforms. Instead, the unfinished agenda of much more demanding and complex structural reforms together with trade facilitation measures appears to be a bar- rier to a more extensive involvement of Armenian firms in the finer global division of labor based on in-time production, inventory man- agement, and complex Web-based communication links. The question to which we shall now turn is about the progress achieved in struc- tural reforms and their impact on FDI inflows. Unfinished Agenda of Second-Generation Reforms While progress in first-generation reforms is relatively straightfor- ward to assess (for example, by inflation, or convertibility of domestic currency for current account transactions), this is not the case with second-generation reforms that cover, as a rule, activities and policy areas in which progress can be gauged only indirectly. Moreover, these reforms usually tend to be highly intertwined. Progress in one area can be "neutered" by the lack of progress in another. For instance, large-scale privatization may be completed. Yet its benefits may not materialize if privatized companies are subsidized by state-owned banks, as was the case in the Czech Republic in the mid-1990s, or the competition policy is unable to contain the banks' abuse of a domi- nant position. The same applies to various indicators that measure the 376 Part II: Detailed Analysis quality of the business climate. Huge minimum capital requirements or instabilities in tax policies, for example, may offset the simplicity of procedures for business entry. How does Armenia compare with other transition economies in terms of progress achieved in economic reforms? Since Armenia's performance has been superior to that of other CIS economies, we use two other, more demanding, comparators: new Central Euro- pean EU members (CEEC-8), and Lithuania (like Armenia, a former Soviet republic). In order to answer this question, we construct an index of progress in second-generation reforms. The index is derived from EBRD transition indicators of policies that achieved progress in different areas directly related to restructuring. These areas include government and enterprise restructuring, large-scale privatization, banking reform and interest rate liberalization, security markets and nonbank financial institutions, and competition policy. The average of scores in each of these areas--normalized for a minimum score of 1 to equal zero and a maximum score of 4.5 to equal 100--is the indicator of progress in structural reforms. For countries that achieved institutional maturity in terms of establishing institutions supporting competitive markets, the indicator is equal to 100, whereas for those that have not started the process, it equals zero. The indicator of progress in structural reforms also appears to pro- vide a good measure of the quality of governance and the incidence of corruption. The value of the correlation coefficient for the structural progress indicator for 27 transition economies of Europe and Central Asia and corruption perception indices compiled by Transparency International was 73 percent in 2004. The positive correlation is higher for governance indicators (including average of political stability, gov- ernment effectiveness, and regulatory quality),10 as compiled by the World Bank. For the 1998­2002 averages, its value was 93 percent. In other words, countries with higher values of the structural progress indicator are better governed and are less corrupt. The results presented in Figure 12.4 clearly show that moving to the institutional environment of highly developed countries takes time. The median value of a structural aggregate reform index for new EU CEEC-8 member states stood in 2004 at 66 percent of the level of mature market economies. While it is almost two-thirds percent above the level of institutional maturity achieved by Armenia (40 percent), CEEC-8 countries have a long way to go to catch up with highly developed countries. Armenia also has long way to go. The greatest "distance" separat- ing it from institutions in highly developed countries is in competi- tion and security markets and nonbank financial institutions--both at 29 percent of the "normal market-economy" level (Table 12.8). Other Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 377 Figure 12.4 Progress in Structural Reforms: Values of SRI, 1994­2004 (in percent) 70 60 50 40 percent 30 20 10 0 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 year Lithuania CEEC-8 median Armenia SEE-4 Note: The aggregate is the average of scores ranging between 1 (no liberalization) and 4.5 (liberalization at the levels of highly developed market economies) for government and enterprise restructuring, competition policy, banking reform and interest rate liberalization, security markets and nonbank financial institutions, and large-scale privatization. It has been normalized with 1=0 and 4.5=100. SEE- 4 includes Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Macedonia, and Serbia and Montenegro. Source: Own calculations based on data from EBRD Annual Transition Reports. institutional areas where the value of the index is below its average for second-generation reforms are government and enterprise restructur- ing (38 percent) and banking reform and interest rate liberalization (38 percent). The most advanced area of structural reforms is large-scale privatization (67 percent). Another interesting observation that can be derived from data in Figure 12.4 and Table 12.8 is that EBRD's scores move in leaps and bounds. They appear to catch not incremental changes but rather step- wise changes. It is as though various reform measures have to reach momentum pushing them to a higher level of institutional maturity, although reversals are possible. Large-scale privatization was locked 378 Part Table 12.8 Progress of Structural Reform in Armenia and Lithuania, 1994­2004 II: Area of reform 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Detailed Large-scale privatization Armenia 0 29 57 57 57 57 57 57 67 67 67 Lithuania 57 57 57 57 57 57 57 67 76 76 76 Analysis Government and enterprise restructuring Armenia 0 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 38 38 38 Lithuania 29 29 57 48 48 48 48 48 57 57 57 Banking reform and interest rate liberalization Armenia 0 29 29 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 38 Lithuania 29 57 57 57 57 57 57 57 57 57 57 Security markets and nonbank financial institutions Armenia 0 0 0 0 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 Lithuania 29 29 29 38 38 48 57 57 57 57 57 Competition policy Armenia 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 29 29 29 29 Lithuania 29 29 29 38 38 38 48 57 57 57 57 Source: Own calculations based on data from EBRD Annual Transition Reports. Note: For an explanation, see notes to Figure 6.4. Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 379 at the same level for seven years in Lithuania and six years in Arme- nia before moving to a higher level in 2001 and 2002, respectively. However, while Lithuania progressed subsequently, Armenia remains at the level of the Lithuanian privatization program in 2001. How do the two countries compare in other areas? First, let us note that Armenia's progress in areas other than large-scale privatiza- tion has been less than Lithuania's. Second, Lithuania is ahead on all structural counts, but the gap is the largest in competition policy and security markets, with Armenia at Lithuania's level in 1994­96 in both areas. In banking reform and interest rate liberalization, Lithuania's experience illustrates how much can be achieved within one year. While in 1995 Armenia lagged one year compared with Lithuania, the latter jumped to a higher plateau of 57 percent in 1996; a level that Armenia has yet to achieve. A similar gap in government and enterprise restructuring again illustrates that a faster pace of structural reforms is possible provided the government is credibly committed to these reforms. Hence, although the indicators suggest that Armenia is lagging behind Lithuania, the gaps can be closed relatively swiftly, as the experience of structural reforms in Lithuania clearly shows. The chal- lenge is to accelerate the implementation of often painful measures. Their implementation is critical, as is argued throughout this study, in order to shift Armenia's export patterns to those that would generate larger gains in employment and would take advantage of Armenia's unique assets. Second-Generation Reforms and FDI The absence of rapid progress in structural reforms has a nega- tive impact on FDI, as empirical research has amply demonstrated. Garibaldi et al. (2002) have shown that the quality of institutions explains the variation in FDI flows to transition economies. In a simi- lar vein, Broadman et al. (2004, p. 20), plotting the data on FDI per capita and EBRD's governance and enterprise restructuring indices for all Balkan countries, also find a strong positive association between these two variables. There is evidence that institutional quality tow- ers over other determinants of FDI location. For instance, Campos and Kinoshita (2003) examined three groups of determinants: The first group comprised the cost of labor, the size of the domestic market, the skills of labor, the quality of infrastructure, and proximity to EU mar- kets. The second group included institutions, macroeconomic policy, and other policies that facilitate the conduct of business. The third group was related to agglomeration economies (that is, new inves- tors following decisions made by earlier investors to take advantage 380 Part II: Detailed Analysis of positive spillovers related to knowledge spillovers, and the avail- ability of specialized labor and intermediate inputs). Their main find- ing was that institutions and agglomeration economies explain the directions of FDI flows to transition economies; taken together they outweigh other determinants related to labor costs, proximity to EU markets, and size of the domestic market. Although the conclusion about the primacy of institutions appears to contradict other findings on the determinants of FDI inflows, the contradiction is more apparent than real for three reasons. First, most empirical studies identify unit labor cost, openness to trade, the size of the host economy, and the proximity to the EU as major factors explaining the differences in FDI inflows. But countries bordering the EU-15 (except those bordering Greece) have also moved rapidly in transition to competitive markets. Consequently, proximity has also somehow influenced the pace of transition, although the presence of potential foreign investors has also probably had an influence on reforms. Second, richer countries are, to paraphrase Fisher, Sahay and Vegh (1998), closer to Brussels. Richer countries have also better insti- tutions and are thus more attractive to FDI. Last but not least, open- ness to trade influences the extent to which domestic markets are competitive. The contestability of domestic markets, in turn, reduces the extent to which distortions might affect the developments in unit labor costs. The structural reform indicator indirectly captures the contestability of domestic markets and thereby the developments in unit labor costs. The variation in progress in structural reforms and the quality of governance correspond fairly closely to the variation in cumulative FDI net inflows per capita over 1990­2003. The coefficient of correla- tion for the CEEC-10, CIS-12, and SEE-4 countries between the val- ues of the Structural Reform Index (SRI)11 averaged over 1999­2003 and cumulative FDI per capita over 1990­2003 was 79 percent. The value of the correlation coefficient increases to 83 percent when oil- rich economies are excluded. The rationale is straightforward: the oil sector operates according to different rules from those for the rest of the economy, and oil rather than governance is a magnet for FDI. As can be seen from Figure 12.5 and Table 12.9, countries whose institutions were below 40 percent of the level in industrialized mar- ket economies failed to exceed US$500 worth of cumulative net FDI inflows per capita. The only exception was oil-rich Kazakhstan. Kaza- khstan, however, had the highest value of SRI (41.9) among CIS econo- mies in 2003, followed by the Kyrgyz Republic (40.0) and Armenia (39.9). Geography--probably combined with the size of the domestic economy and good external contacts--does count. Its impact is par- Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 381 Figure 12.5 Total FDI Inflows per Capita and SRI, 1999­2003 80 03)- 1999 (average 40 Index Reform Structural 0 0 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 2,500 3,000 3,500 4,000 cumulative FDI per capita in 1992-03 (in US$) Source: NSS and EBRD Transition Reports (various issues) for other countries. ticularly visible in the case of the CIS economies as compared with the SEE economies and in the variation of FDI inflows. Macedonia, with a similar value of SRI as Armenia, obtained 61 percent more in cumulative FDI inflows per capita. Less advanced Albania obtained 12 percent more. But this may also work the other way around--better- located Moldova has attracted less FDI than Armenia, despite similar progress in reforms. The explanation lies in the political instability in Moldova. An additional factor that may explain the variation is the choice of method of large-scale privatization and, therefore, the ability to attract strategic investors from abroad. The fact that variation of FDI flows to non-oil CIS economies can- not be directly linked to differences in progress in structural reforms paradoxically may point to the reforms' importance. The coefficient of correlation between FDI flows to non-oil CIS economies and an SRI of a mere 20 percent suggests that a certain threshold in struc- tural reforms has to be achieved in order to attract FDI inflows equal roughly to a value of SRI of 50. Geography, the size of the domestic market, and preferential access to Russian markets may explain the FDI stock per capita of Belarus (now bordering the expanded EU), 382 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 12.9 Correlation of FDI (1990­2003) and SRI (1999­2003) FDI FDI Country SRI (US$) Country SRI (US$) Albania 27.4 351 Latvia 52.9 1,461 Armenia 35.4 313 Lithuania 56.4 1,184 Azerbaijan 27.1 934 Macedonia 36.6 505 Belarus 13.0 222 Moldova 35.8 227 Bosnia & Herzegovina 20.2 258 Poland 65.5 1,166 Bulgaria 48.4 676 Romania 40.8 455 Croatia 51.0 1,712 Russian Federation 37.7 67 Czech Republic 67.4 3,939 Serbia and Montenegro 9.9 260 Estonia 66.7 2,027 Slovak Republic 60.2 2,161 Georgia 35.4 222 Slovenia 53.7 1,875 Hungary 73.9 2,335 Tajikistan 17.5 32 Kazakhstan 39.2 1,078 Ukraine 35.8 115 Kyrgyz Republic 36.2 84 Uzbekistan 28.6 42 Source: Own calculations based on data derived from EBRD Transition Reports and IMF balance of payments statistics. Note: Table shows the correlation of FDI cumulative inflows per capita over 1990­ 2003 in U.S. dollars and values of the SRI averaged over 1999­2003. despite a disastrous record of structural reforms--roughly the same as the much more institutionally advanced Georgia or Moldova. Similarly, Armenia, with relatively easy access to seaports in Georgia, attracted 3.7 times more FDI on a per capita basis than the Kyrgyz Republic, despite a similar record of structural reforms. While geography may be part of the explanation, the bottom line is that in both countries the rules for FDI entry are crafted outside of the rules that apply to domestic businesses. Furthermore, privatization decisions, especially in telecommunications, distort the overall picture for countries that have attracted relatively low FDI inflows. Had a similar diagram been produced for Central European transition economies in 1996, the val- ues of FDI stock per capita and the progress in structural reform indi- ces would be similarly dispersed, with Hungary as an outlier.12 While academics often ponder whether FDI determines the quality of the business climate or vice versa, the bottom line is that politi- cians cannot coerce foreign investors into investing in a country; but they can create an environment that attracts investments, domestic and foreign alike. The challenge facing the government is to revive the implementation of structural reforms. Being at the top among the CIS economies in transitioning to competitive markets is not sufficient Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 383 for competing successfully for foreign investment. It should be noted that former "CMEA13 comrades" from Central Europe not only have a much better location but also belong to the pan-European economic architecture underlying the largest free trade area for industrial prod- ucts in the world. Armenia cannot compete on this count. On top of this, these economies are much more advanced in terms of institu- tional structures that support markets. This is the only area where Armenia could compete. Armenia's position at the halfway point of the most advanced of these economies will not do. The negative impact of geography may be partly offset by the establishment of a business environment that is friendly to foreign and domestic inves- tors. Given its location, Armenia is potentially attractive not only for firms operating out of the EU but also for firms willing to expand their presence in the Middle East. "Doing Business" Environment: Small Firms and the Diaspora Armenia's huge asset is its highly entrepreneurial and very success- ful diaspora, spread mostly throughout the Middle East, the United States, Russia, and Western Europe. It is not only successful but also large, amounting to about 4.7 to 5.3 million people compared to the country's population of around 3.8 million. It has already contrib- uted enormously to the country's well-being through lobbying in its respective countries for foreign aid, promoting foreign investment in Armenia from firms in its countries of residence, supplying humani- tarian assistance, building transport infrastructure, transferring know- how, and providing valuable commercial contacts. Grigorian (2005) provides many illustrations of the Armenian diaspora having been the drivers of numerous important business projects in Armenia includ- ing the entry of the HSBC Bank, now the largest bank in Armenia, the management of the Yerevan Airport, and the development of the ICT sector. Nevertheless, there is a widespread sense that this potential has not been fully tapped. The perception is justified by the gap between the diaspora's developmental assistance, private transfers, and remit- tances, on the one hand, and the diaspora's FDI in Armenia on the other hand. The latter has been huge, whereas the former has been rather limited. Thus, the policy challenge is not only to attract the diaspora's direct investments but also to encourage the recipients of remittances to use them in establishing new small businesses. This can be accomplished only through improving the business climate. Complaints by large foreign firms operating in Armenia about the business environment are fewer and less intense than those voiced 384 Part II: Detailed Analysis by smaller firms. Large foreign firms do not complain about corrup- tion, and their assessment of interaction with state administration is also less critical (Grigorian 2005, Kaminski 2005b). This comes as no surprise; with easy access to the authorities, large firms are less likely to fall prey to various government agencies. While these comments should not be read as painting a rosy picture of the regulatory regime for large firms, the crux of the matter is that small firms have a much tougher life and that formal arrangements constrain them to a greater degree. However, size should not be the reason for discrimination. Small firms, especially foreign-owned small firms, can be beautiful. They often have a much larger impact on the domestic economy than their size might indicate. The experience of many countries shows that foreign-owned firms do not have to be large in order to have a posi- tive impact on economic growth and employment and to boost for- eign trade performance. For instance, the drivers of Romania's recent impressive export expansion have been small, foreign-owned (mainly Italian and German) firms (Kaminski and Ng 2004). Their presence entails significant benefits to a country going well beyond their small size. The Romanian experience indicates that a very large number of relatively small foreign firms can generate significant knowledge spillovers to domestic firms. An econometric study of the CEEC-8 (excluding Latvia and Lithuania but including Bulgaria and Roma- nia) has found the existence of these spillovers only in Romania and not in other studied transition economies (Damijan et al. 2003). In a similar vein, Javorcik and Spatareanu (2004a) have also found positive horizontal spillovers in Romania. Many different components, including public safety, the quality of the environment, and so forth, determine whether a country's business environment is friendly or unfriendly toward small businesses. The World Bank's Doing Business survey offers the possibility of identify- ing the formal barriers and also compares the changes between 2003 (the date of the first survey) and 2005. In addition, it provides infor- mation on formal arrangements existing in other countries. The 2005 survey differs from the 2003 survey, as its scope has been significantly extended. Two new areas--registering property and protecting inves- tors--were added to the previously covered areas of starting a busi- ness, labor market flexibility, contract enforcement, and bankruptcy. In addition, there were changes in indicators within areas. Indicators describing "labor market flexibility" have been expanded to include a very important variable--the cost of firing in terms of weeks of severance payments. Also, the indicators describing "closing a busi- ness" have new variables--the cost of recovery and the cost of closure. Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 385 Similarly, a new indicator--the cost of creating collateral--has been added to the "getting credit" area of doing business. Armenia has one of the friendliest (if not the friendliest) formal regimes for doing business among the CIS countries. Its formal regu- latory arrangements also compare favorably with those of new EU member states, although when other factors not covered by the Doing Business survey are taken into account, Armenia's ranking drops.14 The 2003­05 period witnessed improvements in many areas deter- mining the formal cost of doing business (Table 12.10). First, it has become easier to start a business. The cost of registration fell 18 per- cent and the minimum capital requirement was lowered almost 60 percent. Second, labor regulations now allow for greater flexibility, with the index of rigidity of employment falling 50 percent. Last, but not least, the formal legal protection of creditors has improved. What are the major formal barriers as seen from the point of view of a potential small investor from abroad or a local resident contem- plating starting a business thanks to remittances from abroad? We assume that getting credit is somehow much less relevant. Two con- cerns would top the list: labor flexibility and contract enforcement. First, the firing cost of 30 weeks of wages constitutes a huge barrier to increasing employment and, therefore, to starting a business. Second, there appears to be some deterioration in the conditions relevant to enforcing contracts. The cost of debt collection has increased. So has the number of days needed to enforce a contract, although this may be the result of too optimistic an assessment for 2003. But formal regulations do not tell the whole story. Barriers stem not only from regulations but also from the administrative environment. Various surveys indicate that, despite significant progress achieved over the last couple of years, significant barriers still remain. Among the areas not covered by the Doing Business surveys are the tax and customs administrations, policy-induced uncertainties, corruption, limited access to financing, and weak infrastructure.15 Policy-induced uncertainties combined with the tax administration appear to stand out as the major factor constraining entry to business and preventing firms from exiting the informal sector. Hence, in order to have the diaspora play a larger role in business development, the following areas have to be addressed: severance costs; contract enforcement; stability of economic policies; and reform of the tax and customs administrations. The empirical evidence from countries that have succeeded in attracting investment from their emigrants indicates a strong and direct relationship between the business climate and the number of firms established with foreign participation. Table 12.10 Formal Barriers to Doing Business in Armenia, 2003 and 2005 386 In percent Best of Best Part Change Practice CIS/CEEC Area Indicator 2003 2005 (%) in CEEC/CIS Practice II: Starting a business Number of procedures 10 10 0 5 50 Detailed Time (days) 25 25 0 18 72 Cost (% of income per capita) 8.5 7 18 3.7 53 Minimum capital (% of income per capita) 11 4.5 59 0.0 0 Analysis Hiring and firing Difficulty of hiring index (0­100) 51 33 35 0 0 workers Rigidity of hours index (0­100) 84 40 52 20 50 Difficulty of firing index (0­100) 37 10 73 10 100 Rigidity of employment index (0­100) 57 28 51 10 36 Firing costs: severance payments in weeks of wages) -- 30 -- 17 57 Registering property Number of procedures -- 4 -- 3 75 Time (days) -- 18 -- 3 17 Cost (% of property value) -- 0.9 -- 0.5 56 Enforcing contracts Number of procedures 22 24 ­9 17 71 Time (days) 65 195 ­200 150 77 Cost (% of debt) 15.3 17.8 ­16 8.1 46 Closing a business Time of insolvency (years) 1.9 1.9 0 1.1 58 Cost (% of estate) -- 4.0 -- 4.0 100 Recovery rate (cents on the US$) -- 39.6 -- 85.0 47 Protecting investors Investors disclosure index (0­7) -- 3 -- 6 50 Getting credit Cost to create collateral (% income per capita) -- 0.9 -- 0.6 67 Legal rights index 0­10 2 4 100 9 44 Source: Data from World Bank (2005a). -- = not available Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 387 Unfriendly Environment for Attracting Outsourcing A host of factors determines whether a country can successfully enter new forms of global division of labor based on outsourcing. Armenia passes the global test on several of them but fails on many others, thereby eroding the benefits from good policies. These factors include the contestability of domestic markets (that is, the extent to which imports and foreign investors may challenge their domestic equiva- lents) and the quality of services linking domestic production facilities with external outlets. The provision of services, including customs, in a timely and smooth fashion at low cost is critical to a country's becoming part of the global supply chains now mostly based on the in-time management of production and inventories. Liberal Foreign Trade and Investment Regimes Are Not Enough Armenia's foreign trade regime is liberal and stable, thanks to WTO commitments. First, access to Armenian markets of goods is very lib- eral in terms of official border and behind-the-border arrangements. Tariffs are low, not only by CIS standards but by international stand- ards as well. Although Armenia's weighted and unweighted average MFN tariff rates are twice as high as in the EU, they are still well below 5 percent (Table 12.11). Second, commitments made upon accession to the WTO have infused a considerable degree of stability and predictability into Armenia's foreign trade policy. This has also reduced, though not completely eliminated, the potential for the capture of foreign trade decisions by narrow interest groups by providing a government with tools to tame the rent-seekers. Armenia's two-band tariff regime, with applied MFN tariff rates at 0 or 10 percent ad valorem, has been locked at low levels, thanks to accession to the WTO. Armenia's schedule of MFN "bound" tariff rates has seven ad valorem rates--0, 4, 5, 6.5, 8, 10, and 15 percent.16 But, as a condition of accession, Armenia has been required to bind tariffs across all Harmonized System items. In addition, Armenia has committed itself, as a result of direct pressure from members of its WTO working party, to review periodically the specific tariff rates to assure that these do not exceed their equivalents of ad valorem bound tariff rates.17 Third, the legal arrangements concerning entry to the services sec- tors are very liberal and are locked in by Armenia's commitments made as a condition for accession to the WTO in 2003. With the nota- ble exception of telecommunications services, which are temporarily exempt from MFN, other sectors have been open to most modes of supply, with the usual caveat concerning restrictions on the employ- ment of foreigners.18 388 Part II: Table 12.11 Average Applied and Bound MFN Tariff Rates in Selected Countries (percent) Detailed Armenia Kyrgyz Republic Lithuania European Union (15) Good Tariff 2001 2002 2003 2002 Analysis Total goods Simple average (%) 3.3 4.5 1.3 1.5 Weighted average (%) 2.2 3.2 0.6 1.4 Agricultural goods Simple average (%) 8.3 7.1 4.7 3.2 Weighted average (%) 6.6 6.6 4.3 2.9 Industrial goods Simple average (%) 2.9 4.3 1.0 1.3 Weighted average (%) 1.1 2.7 0.3 1.3 Bound rate of all goods Simple average (%) 8.5 7.4 9.2 3.9 Weighted average (%) 9.6 6.4 9.4 3.0 Binding Coverage (%) 100.0 99.9 100.0 100.0 Memorandum: Simple average tariff rate in 2004 3.0 5.2 1.5 1.5 Sources: UNCTAD Trade Analysis and Information System (TRAINS) (http://www.unctad.org/trains); WTO IDB database (http://wits.worldbank.org/witsweb/); and IMF Trade Policy Information database (http://www.imf.org/external/data.htm#data) for 2004. Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 389 Fourth, no legal restrictions are in place on foreign capital inflows. The foreign investment regime, governed by the 1994 Law on Foreign Investment, provides for national treatment, MFN treatment, and full repatriation of capital and earnings. The law banning foreigners from owning land (they can only lease it) is not restrictive, as companies registered by foreigners in Armenia as Armenian business entities have this right. However, Armenia's capacity to generate a stronger export perform- ance thanks to entering outsourcing operations ultimately depends on the strength of those areas in which it does pass the global test of becoming an attractive location for business operations. Despite lib- eral arrangements underlying both foreign trade and foreign invest- ment regimes, these areas are not fully business friendly. Consider the following: WTO rules on trade in goods tend to be loosely imple- mented, which raises export and import transaction costs significantly. In contravention of the WTO rules, the Armenian customs uses refer- ence prices for a number of imported goods. The GATT Agreement on Customs Valuation requires customs inspectors to rely on the transac- tion value--the price paid or payable in the market--when calculating ad valorem duties instead of using reference or minimum prices that are set artificially by the government.19 Although Armenia has made significant strides in dismantling the Soviet-era GOST mandatory standards and establishing a modern, market-based standards regime, imports still face both technical and sanitary and phytosanitary bar- riers. The latter are not only complex but are arbitrarily implemented (see Holden and Sahakyan 2004, p. 13). The barriers, in the opinion of international businesses, relate to the inconsistent application of tax, customs (especially valuation), and regulatory rules, especially in the area of trade. While these may not be prohibitive for large firms with easy access to high levels of state administration, they create a perception of unfair competition and add uncertainty for medium-size businesses and other market entrants. Furthermore, neither commitments under the WTO agreements nor legal provisions protecting private property rights and enforcing contracts are sufficient when the capacity of the courts remains lim- ited. The courts operate slowly in the enforcement of contracts and in mediating commercial disputes and firms do not trust the ability of the courts to act independently and enforce decisions. Neither do they trust the impartiality of the state administration, regarded by businesses as corrupt. To make things worse, there are weaknesses in the tax administration, the capacity of the CPEC to enforce competi- tion laws is weak, and the capacity of the judicial system to enforce contracts and protect private property is weak. In all, Armenia's relatively liberal foreign trade and foreign invest- ment regimes will fail to bring benefits in the absence of transparency, 390 Part II: Detailed Analysis consistency, fairness, and effectiveness in the implementation of regu- lations and laws. This absence has been responsible for the relatively low FDI inflows despite an apparent lack of formal barriers. Barriers to Just-In-Time Operation and Global Networking Never- theless, Armenia's success in entering the diamond global value chain shows that even within the constraints related to weaknesses in the business, institutional, and policy environments, economic policy "quick-fixes" are available. In order to attract outsourcing activities, several conditions have to be met. They all boil down to time and transaction costs. Since interaction among the production blocs of bor- der-spanning production networks is based on just-in-time production and inventory management, such interaction is particularly vulnera- ble to delays and disruptions in individual stages of the supply chain. The weakest link in the service chain in a country may tip the balance against including a firm in the global supply chain. A service chain includes backbone services (for example, telecommunications, trans- port, financial services such as banking and insurance, and securities trading), distribution and business services (such as legal, accounting, and consulting services), as well as customs procedures. Hence, the quality of service links that would ensure their smooth operation is critical in the location decisions of multinational corpora- tions. Services linking production operations include procedures for the simplification and harmonization of international trade, the state of the infrastructure and its management, together with the provision of such backbone services as telecommunications, banking, insurance, transportation, business services, and so forth. Together with customs, related border clearance regulatory procedures, technical standards regulations, and port efficiency, backbone services shape the ease and speed with which goods and services move across national borders, and therefore they are crucial to trade in goods. Poor-quality back- bone services and trade facilitation deter foreign firms from incor- porating domestic firms into their supply chains. They also act as a barrier to other types of trade. Consequently, improvements in the domestic business climate may produce limited beneficial economic effects if they are not accompanied by similar improvements in trade facilitation. In short, weakness in any of these services may take a country off the radar screen of firms searching to locate outsourcing activities abroad. Which of these services that facilitate the maintenance of smoothly operating links among production operations in various countries are the most restraining in Armenia? As can be seen from data based on EBRD's assessment of the quality of infrastructure in terms of offered services (EBRD, various years), Armenia has a long way to go to achieve the levels found in highly developed economies, not to men- Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 391 tion the CEEC-8. Across all categories, Armenia's level is below 40 percent of the levels in highly developed economies (Figure 12.6). The difference is largest for rail transport, still managed by a highly inef- ficient, state-owned railway company (Holden and Sahakayan 2004). But there are two important caveats. First, although roads are a better alternative for shipments than rail transport, ultimately the quality of roads and port management in Georgia will determine the final cost of transportation for many goods shipped through Georgia's seaports. Second, the EBRD's assessment of the telecommunications infrastruc- ture, which puts it on a par with Georgia, appears to be based solely on the change of ownership from state to private. The indicator was raised to 38 percent in 1997 following the privatization of ArmenTel and subsequently stayed at this level. A positive development that can be inferred from Armenia's bal- ance of payments statistics related to services is that transport appears to have become much less of a barrier than in the past. The combina- tion of Armenia's landlocked situation and problems in transport cor- ridors, exacerbated by geopolitics, has always contributed to very high Figure 12.6 Quality of Infrastructure in Armenia against Georgia, the CEEC-8, and Highly Developed Countries 80 average CEEC-8 70 Armenia Georgia 60 50 40 percent 30 20 10 0 telecommunications rail roads infrastructure sector Source: Calculated from data in the EBRD infrastructure database. Note: The scores ranging between 1 (worst case) and 4.5 (level of highly developed market economies) have been normalized with 1=0 and 4.5=100. 392 Part II: Detailed Analysis transportation costs. Competition in logistics-related sectors combined with the improvement in the security situation in Georgia appears to have resulted in falling transport costs of trade. This is not to suggest that transportation has ceased to be a bar- rier. The ratio of transportation to the value of exports, a measure used by Faye et al. (2004) to compare transportation barriers faced by landlocked countries, remains high, although it has declined con- siderably. The Faye et al. (2003) study put the Armenian value of this ratio at 0.35 in 2001, well ahead of other landlocked countries such as Kazakhstan (0.04), Azerbaijan (0.07), Moldova (0.10), Georgia (0.08), the Kyrgyz Republic (0.13), Mongolia (0.16), and Turkmenistan (0.15). Although the value of this ratio for 2003 (0.22) still places Armenia at the top of this particular sample of landlocked countries, this is 40 percent below the level in 2001. The consensus emerging from interviews and various studies of the Armenian economy including the EBRD report (EBRD various years) on infrastructure in transition economies, seems to point to barriers in network-based ITC infrastructure, customs and other nontariff trade barriers, and transportation. Considering the significant externalities associated with the telecommunications infrastructure, this sector is clearly close to, if not at the top of, the list of major impediments. A high level of telecommunications infrastructure is not only rele- vant for global supply chains but also has a huge potentially positive impact on education, health services, government services including customs, and so forth. The Telecommunications Infrastructure as a Barrier Rapid techno- logical development in the electronics, computer, and telecommuni- cations industries has eroded the inherent natural monopoly charac- teristics of telecommunications. By the same token, it has weakened the negative impacts of the government's decision to grant a legal near monopoly (until 2013) to ArmenTel, the local telecommunications company owned by OTE. The weakening is not significant, however, because until the end of 2004 the monopoly also encompassed cellu- lar and "last mile" Internet services (that is, it covered technological changes that open competition to other providers).20 As a result, the only area that has escaped the monopoly's reach, albeit not completely, is VoIP via satellite. This might have contributed to a lower volume of officially captured international calls. But satellite communication is not a full substitute for access through lines, and these are monopo- lized. While modern technologies offer some ways of circumventing the monopoly reach of ArmenTel, the bottom line is that it controls the decisive "last mile" and cable access. How has ArmenTel's monopoly affected the development of tel- ecommunications in Armenia? One way of addressing this question Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 393 is to compare the cost and the use of telecommunications services in Armenia with other CIS countries. This may not be a very demand- ing benchmark, as many other CIS countries have had equally poorly handled privatizations and some still maintain a state monopoly. But even against these not very demanding comparators, the general con- clusion one may draw from the data tabulated in Table 12.12 is that, overall, Armenia's telecommunications services compared to other CIS countries contracted over 1998­2002. This movement down has varied depending on the indicator. Armenia, the Kyrgyz Republic, and Turkmenistan are the only CIS countries in which the number of telephone main lines per 1,000 peo- ple declined between 1998 and 2002. Despite an increase in 2002 over 2001, the international outgoing traffic from Armenia declined signifi- cantly more, on average, than that from other CIS countries. Last but not least, the negative impact of the monopoly exercised by ArmenTel on the development of the Internet has also been signifi- cant, albeit probably lower than in other areas discussed. The cost of using the Internet in Armenia was 41 percent higher than the average for the CIS. Users in Azerbaijan and Tajikistan were charged more. The price in terms of gross national income was lower than the aver- age but only because Tajikistan's charges raised the average. Again, users in Armenia paid more than users in other CIS countries, except for Azerbaijan and Tajikistan. The high cost of access, combined with the lack of telephone serv- ices in many rural areas, has resulted in a surprisingly low number of Internet users. As can be seen from data in Table 12.12, Armenia was well below the CIS average and, except for the Kyrgyz Republic, had the lowest increase in 2002 over 2001. This does not augur well for the continuing development of the ICT sectors in Armenia. These indicators do not capture the quality of telephone services nor the cost and availability of mobile phones. Both are reportedly low and are not available in many rural areas. In 2002 the average number of mobile phones per 1,000 people in the EU-8 was, on average, 32 times higher, in the SEE-4 it was 12 times higher, in the CIS, 3 times higher, and in neighboring Georgia, more than 5 times higher. While in 2003 the number of mobile phones increased more in Armenia (to 38.1 per 1,000 people) than in Georgia (111.3 per 1,000), the density is still almost three times lower. The number of cellular phones per 1,000 people is significantly lower than in neighboring Georgia. Unreliable connections, limited to modem connections, result in a low quality of Internet services. Moreover, ArmenTel's monopoly hinders the ability of Internet service providers to compete in price (Holden and Sahakyan 2004). The prices for high-speed connections charged by ArmenTel are around 30 times those in countries where telecommunications services are not monopolized. Table 12.12 Indicators of Telecommunications Penetration in Armenia and Other CIS Countries, 394 1998­2003 Internet total Part monthly price II: International (US$ (% of Detailed Telephone Mobile telecom, per monthly mainlines phones outgoing traffic 20 GNI (per 1,000 (per 1,000 (minutes per hours per Analysis people) people) subscriber) of use) capita) Internet users Country 1998 2002 2001 2002 1998 2002 2003 2003 1998 2002 Armenia 147 143 6.7 18.9 102 67 45 68 1.1 15.8 Azerbaijan 89 113 91.4 106.9 58 35 108 183 0.4 36.9 Belarus 248 299 13.9 46.7 71 81 13 11 0.7 81.6 Georgia 122 131 60.6 102.1 73 -- 26 48 1 14.9 Kazakhstan 109 130 36.2 64.3 67 63 34 27 1.2 15.7 Kyrgyz Republic 78 77 5.4 10.4 81 46 15 62 0.7 29.8 Moldova 150 161 51.3 76.9 81 75 19 50 2.5 34.1 Russian Federation 199 242 52.8 120.1 36 34 10 6 8.1 40.9 Tajikistan 37 37 0.3 2.1 45 42 54 362 -- 0.5 Turkmenistan 82 77 -- -- 43 64 20 20 -- -- Ukraine 191 216 44.2 83.8 48 36 17 26 2.9 18 Uzbekistan 64 66 5.1 7.4 47 36 20 54 0.2 10.9 Average CIS 126 141 33.4 58.1 63 53 32 76 2.7 44.4 Armenia in % CIS 116 101 20.1 32.6 163 126 141 89 39 36 Source: WDI. -- not available Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 395 How can the poor state of telecommunications services be recon- ciled with the very impressive development of the export-oriented ICT sector, which sets Armenia apart from other countries in the region? The answer is relatively straightforward: ICT firms in Armenia spe- cialize in software development, whose final product is amenable to cross-border supply. Software can be sent over the Internet. While the quality of connections may create problems, these problems can be overcome--for example, through the use of satellite connections. These possibilities notwithstanding, telecommunications services are a barrier to the development of the ICT sector. Satellites may allow the transmission of data and operations on line for ICT firms, but they fail when it comes to the high-quality transmission of voice. Provid- ers of front-end customer contact/support services cannot perform many functions through satellites. The problem is that the only other available mode, a high-speed landline connection, is too expensive (as mentioned above, 30 times more than under competitive conditions) to perform these services from Armenia. Consequently, despite the availability in Armenia of cheap, highly skilled labor, other countries take advantage of the outsourcing of these services, which has been dramatically growing in recent years. Another area in which the availability of new information and communications technologies is increasingly popular is just-in-time production/inventory management. Without these technologies, it is impossible to track the movement of products among various produc- tion operations and their inventories. The ability to introduce sophisti- cated information links is the key to success, not only in sophisticated production processes, but also, increasingly, for garment manufactur- ers (Abernathy et al. 1999; Evans and Harrigan 2003). The broader point is that high-quality telecommunications infra- structures and services are crucial to the development of a contempo- rary economy and the shift toward higher knowledge-intensity activ- ity. The absence of high-quality services and their high costs affect all sectors of the economy, often amounting to the equivalent of a prohibitive tax. It is impossible to estimate how many transactions have not taken place because of this situation. Neither is it possible to say how many industrial operations would have been transferred to Armenia had there been more efficient telecommunications services. It is, however, indisputable that very high telecommunications costs have severely exacerbated the disadvantages associated with Arme- nia's geographical location. Customs: An Impediment to Network Trade The major problems with customs stem from the lack of the harmonization of customs practices in Armenia and Georgia, nontransparency in clearance regu- lations and procedures accompanied by corruption, and the limited 396 Part II: Detailed Analysis application of ITC in border clearance systems. Corruption and the imposition of unofficial fees at the border are widespread and dramat- ically raise the transaction costs. According to one estimate, unofficial fees accounted for around 6­13 percent of the total cost of transport on the railway from Armenia to Georgia (Molnar and Ojala 2003). The WTO accession process and the computerization of customs have so far fallen well short of improving the quality of customs services. In defiance of the WTO rules, reference prices arbitrarily set by the government are used, and customs procedures have yet to achieve the WTO standards of transparency. Finally, there is a built- in asymmetry in the customs/traders relationship, hugely favoring the latter and offering little resort to WTO-determined rules for the settlement of disputes in cases such as differences in the valuation of a consignment. The time needed to complete customs clearance, as well as the amount of effort undertaken by a firm to deal with customs, are con- siderable, especially for exports. Furthermore, traders are charged by customs for storage of the held goods. This further adds to the overall high cost of conducting foreign trade transactions in Armenia. Thus, it appears that the most obvious benefits of the computeriza- tion of customs services (that is, reducing the release time of consign- ments and slashing the documentation or bureaucratic burden put on a trader or customs broker) have so far failed to materialize. Neither traders nor customs brokers have access to the system. The old prac- tice of bureaucratic delays fueling corruption, combined with lack of capacity in customs administration, continues. VAT Rebate Mechanism: An Impediment to Network Trade While many different factors unnecessarily raise the transaction costs of foreign trade activities, discouraging the entry of new firms and expansion, one stands out in particular--the VAT rebate mechanism. Following the practice of most countries using VAT, Armenia levies VAT on imports to be reimbursed on imported inputs used to make exported products. The complaint of Armenian businesses is that VAT reimbursements do not occur quickly enough and are underpaid by the government. A recent survey notes that only 44 percent of sur- veyed firms entitled to the refund have claimed it. The reason is not difficult to understand. Consider that for the remaining 56 percent of companies, it took, on average, 145 days to receive their VAT refund. Moreover, on average, they received 15 percent less than the amount to which they were entitled by the law. Delays in VAT reimbursements amount to firms being compelled to provide interest-free loans to the government and to expend their limited managerial and administrative resources on interacting with Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 397 the state administration. Under any circumstances, this practice raises the cost to businesses. In Armenia, limited liquidity owing to high interest rates and difficulties in access to financing further raise this cost, turning it into a significant barrier to trade. In all, VAT refund procedures are a huge barrier to the integration of Armenian businesses into global markets and to FDI inflows. The extra costs of transaction undercut the competitiveness of Armenian firms and discourage potential investors, such as large multinationals, to move parts of their global production to Armenia to take advantage of the available skills and cheap labor. Air Transport: An Untapped Opportunity to Reduce Distance One of the most surprising developments in Armenia's foreign trade has been the shift from air transport to land transport as a major mode of transporting goods in and out of Armenia. This is rather unexpected, considering that Armenia is landlocked and the problems in transport corridors are exacerbated by geopolitics. It also defies the international trend of air service outputs growing approximately twice as fast as GDP (Gillen, Morrison, and Stewart 2003). It seems that the falling cost of road and sea transport compared to the cost of air transport has triggered the change. Consider the follow- ing. First, there has been a very considerable fall in the transportation costs of exports and imports of goods. The ratio of total freight and insurance to total trade in goods fell from 0.12 in 2000 to 0.08 in 2003, driven almost exclusively by the falling cost of shipping exports. The ratio to exports fell from 0.41 to 0.22 (Table 12.13).21 Second, the improvement in transportation costs has been accom- panied by falling shipments of goods by air. Freight shipped by air measured in terms of weight stood in 2003 at 64 percent of its 2000 level and 57 percent of this level in terms of million tons per kilometer (Andrew 2005). Table 12.13 Ratio of Transportation Costs to Trade, 1998­2003 Ratio 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Ratio of total freight and insurance to exports of goods 0.45 0.44 0.41 0.37 0.26 0.22 Ratio of total freight and insurance to imports of goods 0.08 0.10 0.10 0.10 0.10 0.09 Ratio of total freight and insurance to total trade in goods 0.10 0.11 0.12 0.12 0.09 0.08 Source: Own calculations based on Armenian official balance of payments statistics. 398 Part II: Detailed Analysis Third, the cost of airfreight has risen, as expenditures and reve- nues from airfreight services--as reported in Armenia's balance of payments statistics--fell only slightly from US$2.2 million in 2000 to US$2.1 million in 2003. Thus, one may conclude that while the cost of transportation by land and sea was falling, that by air has been increasing. Providers of air cargo services have proved to be unable to retain their clients or to lure new ones with more attractive prices. On the contrary, the cost appears to have been going up. Had more aircraft belly space been available thanks to the increase in the number of passenger flights, lower air cargo rates would have attracted a much larger portion of shipments than has been the case. This clearly has not happened, as there was no significant increase in the frequency of flights. Furthermore, the fall in the share of the most dynamic worldwide mode of transport, air transport, in Armenia's exports and imports cannot be attributed to the fall in the competitiveness of air transport services owing to poor infrastructure. It is the result of the govern- ment's restrictive aviation policy. The poor infrastructure component has been largely addressed thanks to the government's decision, in line with the current best international practice, to sign a 30-year concession agreement with Argentina-based Corporación America for the management of the Yerevan Zvartnost International Airport in 2003. Already, perceptible improvements in airport infrastructure and management, combined with the airport's modern container handling facility built with financing from the EBRD, has considerably eased the infrastructure barrier. However, a well managed airport is yet to be matched by a govern- ment policy that removes regulatory obstacles to an increase in supply of aviation services and a drop in their costs. CONCLUSION Armenia misses several ingredients that are needed if it is to become attractive to foreign investments and international outsourcing, includ- ing participation in a new form of the division of labor driven by the globalization of production. First, the quality of the business environ- ment as measured by the SRI is below 50 percent of the institutional maturity of highly developed market economies. As the experience of transition economies amply demonstrates, no significant inflows of high-quality FDI take place unless the value exceeds 50 percent. Structural reforms appear to have failed to produce competitive mar- kets, despite progress achieved in the formal regulatory arrangements that shape the hassle cost of doing business. But some unreformed Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 399 major policy areas (such as inflexible employment, nonstable tax poli- cies, and burdensome and predatory tax administration) continue to discourage the establishment of new businesses, including those of potential Armenian expatriates. Second, there are three major barriers that prevent Armenia from fully reaping the benefits offered by globalization and from sustain- ing its impressive export growth performance. These barriers relate to transport, telecommunications, and the efficiency of the customs/ VAT rebate regime. While the outsourcing of just-in-time production and supply-chain management has been altering the competitive landscape of many countries by relocating business activities and providing new sources of entry into international markets, weak- nesses in these areas have been responsible for Armenia's missed opportunities in tapping new markets and sources of growth. More precisely, weaknesses in these areas account for some atypical features of the Armenian export performance (that is, the under- representation of unskilled labor-intensive products in its export basket due in large part to the country's limited participation in clothing global value chains and the virtual absence of network trade). The low quality of telecommunications services in Armenia makes it virtually impossible, or extremely costly, to implement the just-in-time production/inventory management under which many international networks of production and distribution operate. The impact of high transportation costs is similar. In short, the three major barriers inhibit participation in the division of labor based on production fragmentation. POLICY REMEDIES Armenia's limited presence in the global garments value chain and network trade, and the almost complete absence of Armenian provid- ers of some ICT customer support services, have not been the result of adverse external conditions. On the contrary, the adversities have been home made and as such can be addressed by a change in gov- ernment policies. While the constraints imposed by geography or the requirements of "high politics" are difficult to overcome, contemporary technology, combined with the right mix of policies, may considerably ease their negative impact. The country will not become part of network trade as long as weaknesses in the service chain produce delays and disrup- tions that raise transaction costs. The weakest link in the service chain in a country may tip the balance against the inclusion and establish- ment of firms that will participate in the global supply chain. 400 Part II: Detailed Analysis Why Diamonds and Software--and Nothing Else? Neither the potential constraints of geography or politics on out- sourcing has affected Armenia's strong and expanding presence in the diamond value chain and the export of software. This raises the question of whether the experience from these two success stories is transferable to other areas of outsourcing. While the two are different, they share three characteristics in common: they demonstrate a high quality of human capital, they have the ability to tap external contacts helped by the Armenian diaspora, and they have characteristics that allow them to circumvent the vagaries of Armenia's economic regime and the adversities due to geography. On these counts, Armenia's success in software supply chains is much less sensitive to the quality of the business environment and geographical distance. Exporters do not have to deal with customs controls and the state authorities cannot monitor their external sales. Moreover, distance is not a barrier as long as there is access to the Internet. In contrast, government policies weigh more heavily on the dia- mond chain. There are four factors that set diamonds apart. First, the cost of transporting them is inherently low, albeit not as low as for software exports. Diamonds entering or leaving Armenia do not face a transportation barrier. Since they are light and high value-added items, they can be cheaply transported by air and airfreight rates have little impact on the overall cost. Second, the government has provided a relatively friendly customs services regime for diamonds that has not been extended across all sectors of the economy. Unlike firms in other sectors, diamond firms are subject to a simplified customs clearing regime, which compels customs to have gems cleared within a day, accept the invoice value, and conduct in-house clearance, if needed.22 Third, delayed VAT rebates are much less of a problem than for other exporters, as less capital is tied up. The MFN applied tariff rate on raw diamonds is zero, and an importer does not have to pay VAT on imported inputs but only on local ones. Since the operation mainly involves the use of local labor, these expenditures are very low. Last but not least, just-in-time production and supply-chain man- agement are of lesser importance in the diamond business. So is the intensity of communications links. Although diamonds are unique, their success provides an indica- tion of what needs to be done in terms of policies to increase the probability of the emergence of other supply chains in Armenia. First, while not much can be done to reduce land transport costs (except for better management of railways), liberalization of the aviation policy Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 401 is clearly within the purview of the government. Although there are no guarantees that liberalization would immediately cut airfreight costs, international experience suggests that it usually does. Second, the friendliness of the customs and VAT rebate mechanism is trans- ferable, although the latter needs closer redesigning. Third, the issue of telecommunications and network-based information technology is critical to participation in the networks of production and distribu- tion, but not in all networks. Participation in the clothing value chain appears to be less dependent on the quality of information services. The lesson from both diamonds and software is straightforward: the removal of the administrative barriers that raise the cost of inter- national transactions, combined with measures to "reduce distance" from major markets and to address the telecommunications infrastruc- ture, is the best way to tap Armenia's most important asset--its high- quality human capital. Customs and VAT: "White List" and Other Remedies Ideally, the government should extend the same customs rules that it applies to diamond-cutting activity to other sectors of the economy, albeit with some extras. This would entail reducing the time for cus- toms clearance to a day, accepting the invoice value, and conducting in-house clearance, if needed. While these steps would be a dramatic improvement over the current practice, other elements that raise transaction costs would also have to be addressed. The existing VAT refund system clearly tops the list. As mentioned earlier, even firms in the diamond-cutting business complain about it, although they do not pay VAT on diamonds brought for cutting. However, extending a "diamond-like" regime with an improved VAT refund mechanism to all sectors of the economy may be difficult for the following reason. Diamond operations are under the customs regime of inward processing, but with a twist. Whereas inputs cross- ing customs borders are usually subject to tariff rates and indirect taxes if sold domestically, the tariff rate on diamonds is zero and no taxes are levied. By the same token, a domestic firm has no incen- tive to sell the imported input, which circumvents customs domesti- cally and deprives the budget of customs and other tax revenue. In short, there is no need for duty drawback, temporary admissions, or bonded warehouse schemes, which require a considerable capacity on the part of the customs administration to be really effective. Compu- terization, if accompanied by administrative reforms and changes in customs procedures commensurate with the newly acquired techno- logical capacities, may significantly improve this capacity. However, improvement may take some time. 402 Part II: Detailed Analysis Therefore, the alternative would be to move gradually and establish a dia- mond-like regime in terms of administrative efficiency for a selected group of firms on a "white list." Firms on the white list would be subject to special treatment by the customs and VAT administrations. Customs would be obliged to complete customs clearance within a day; they would have to observe the provisions of the WTO Agreement on Customs Valuation instead of using reference prices; and they would be obliged to run an effective scheme that provides duty waivers and exemptions from other restrictions on imported inputs for established exporters that import inputs, whether for domestic production or export, or both.23 VAT administration would be obliged to rebate VAT to a firm on the same day that exports are cleared by customs. For any delays, a firm would be entitled to a refund plus interest. Which firms, in addition to diamond-cutting firms, should be put on a white list? While the criteria may be subject to further discussion, the general guidelines are easily discernible. The process and criteria should be transparent and open to pub- lic scrutiny by the mass media and by nongovernmental organi- zations, such as business associations. Foreign-owned firms publicly traded on the U.S. and EU stock exchanges should be automatically included. Their operations are subject to the highest standards of international scrutiny-- they can ill-afford to enter into shady business operations. This would take care of participation in the global networks of pro- duction and distribution, simply because their major movers are publicly traded large multinational corporations. Firms operating in the ICT sector should also be included in the white list. The reasons are straightforward. Their use of imported inputs is limited and the value added created locally is huge. Their exports are not subject to customs clearing pro- cedures. In fact, they are virtually impossible to monitor. But in order to claim duty and VAT rebates, they would have to dis- close some transactions to the financial authorities. The overall direct benefits to ICT firms of being included in the white list are lower than for exporters of manufactures, although firms in this sector are as vociferous in their criticism of the VAT rebate scheme as diamond-cutting firms. Furthermore, this would be a significant step in improving the business climate for one of the most important sectors of the Armenian economy: ICT is critical to Armenia's move to a knowledge-intensive economy. For the remaining firms, one would have to identify one or two criteria related to a record of past dealings with the tax admin- istration. One criterion might involve the number of years in Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 403 existence; another might take into account the past record of dealing with tax and customs administration. Both would have to be very clearly defined. The general idea would be to reward law-abiding firms. Firms that do meet the criterion of length of existence but are involved in inward processing, such as gar- ments and footwear, might be exempted. Representatives from government and other relevant business administrations would annually or semiannually update the white list. A mechanism should be designed and implemented to address the grievances of those that have not been included. However, if the criteria are precisely defined and transparently implemented, the number of cases handled under this mechanism would be limited. A white list alone would not be sufficient. There are other areas which might be fixed relatively quickly. These "quick fixes" would include the following: Establish an Independent Professional Association of Customs Brokers. The association would be empowered to license and scrutinize its members. In order to assure integrity and respon- sibility, it would operate according to a transparent Code of Con- duct that would be obligatory for all its members, and it would have an institutional voice in the government bodies responsible for overseeing customs administration. Open the customs computer system to customs brokers. Bring customs-related documents in line with what is really required under a computerized system of the Automated System for Customs Data (ASYCUDA) type. Simplify the customs clearance procedures for exports. Under normal circumstances, the customs clearance of exports serves one major purpose: to make sure that the shipment does not contain products banned for exports. Once an exporter produces a certificate of origin issued by the Chamber of Commerce, the shipment should be cleared immediately. Hence, one should introduce a strict time limit on releasing a shipment; if it is exceeded, a shipment should be released immediately. Sign the WTO Information Technology Agreement (ITA).24 This would place zero MFN applied tariff rates on most ITC-related products. The above measures are relatively easy to implement. While they require the close attention of policy makers, they consume administra- tive resources in a very moderate way. Over the longer haul, they will actually reduce the administrative burden. 404 Part II: Detailed Analysis Air Transport: Liberalization For a small landlocked economy the best aviation policy is that of unilateral liberalization (that is, opening access to the country to any carrier meeting financial and safety requirements from any country). This should be the option that Armenia should adopt as quickly as possible. However, given the government's transfer of route rights as part of the privatization deal with Armavia in 2001, there may be poten- tial problems with the implementation of the unilateral liberalization option. While these commitments require detailed examination, the combination of unilateral and bilateral Open Skies agreements might be the best option to pursue. The former would simply involve Arme- nia's unilateral commitment to open its air space and airports to car- riers (subject to their meeting safety requirements) from a selected country or a regional grouping. The bilateral arrangement, which would have to be negotiated bilaterally, would open the country's market (airspace together with landing rights) to any provider from either country and provides the fifth freedom of the air.25 Armenia should be able to strike Open Skies agreements with the United States, United Arab Emirates, and Bahrain. Since all three are important markets and the latter two offer outlets to other connec- tions, these agreements would be of significant economic importance to Armenia. The reason that United Arab Emirates and Bahrain might be interested in Open Skies agreements is that both have carriers with well-connected hubs offering a Yerevan passenger extensive connec- tions throughout the Middle East and Asia. In addition to the Middle East and Asia, this would also offer an extra air cargo link to European markets.26 Unilateral liberalization is probably the only option available to Armenia in its dealings with the EU. The EU has to date displayed little interest in signing Open Skies agreements with small countries and appears to be interested in pursuing a different approach to liberalization from that used by the United States. The EU has been extending European Civil Aviation Area types of arrangements to other countries. Within the parameters of this approach, the CIS might be a potential partner but not Armenia alone. Under these circumstances, the Open Skies agreement is an unlikely option, and Armenia should remove restric- tions on carriers and inbound flights. A preferred option would be to announce full unilateral opening with the stroke of a pen. However, depending on the assessment of arrangements with Armavia, and in order to soften the negative impact of increased competition and lower fares on Armavia, the Armenian government could declare a sequence of steps over time toward full unilateral Open Skies for EU carriers. Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 405 What approach should be taken toward the aviation arrangements with Russia? An unequivocal answer to this question would require a detailed examination of the current bilateral agreement as well as the CIS framework. Theoretically, Armenia can gain a lot from Open Skies arrangements among CIS countries fashioned after the EU European Civil Aviation Area model. But this would take time, as Armenia would have to sell the idea to other CIS members. In the meantime, the change in the status quo would lose its urgency once the recommended mix of Open Skies bilateral agree- ments and unilateral liberalization with the EU was implemented. A likely increase in the number of flights connecting Yerevan with the Middle East, United States, and the EU would exert competitive pres- sures on airlines servicing routes to Moscow and other destinations in Russia. Without a detailed econometric exercise it would be impossible to provide a quantitative estimate of the static and dynamic costs imposed on the national economy by the current aviation policy; how- ever, these costs are significant. But some insights as to the impact of the restrictive aviation policy on airfares can be derived from the experience of bilateral Open Skies agreements27 in countries that have deregulated the domestic aviation sector, as well as a look at airfares on routes similar to those to Yerevan. The U.S. Department of Trans- portation (DOT) compared average passenger airfares over 1996­99 in transatlantic markets in non-Open Skies and Open Skies traffic: the latter fell 20.1 percent and the former 10.3 percent (U.S. DOT 2000). Passengers traveling on Open Skies arrangements have thus gained an additional 12 percent. The consulting firm Brattle Group attributed the fall of between 18 percent and 28 percent in airfares to transatlan- tic alliances made possible by EU-U.S. Open Skies agreements (Brattle Group 2004). Econometric studies have sought to estimate the impact of inter- national liberalization on airfares. Doove et al. (2001) report on the OECD study to model the influence of various provisions of bilateral aviation agreements on air transport. Designation requirements (limits on the number of airlines allowed to provide services), restrictions on airlines' capacity and market share, and restrictions on charter services collectively raise international airfares by between 3 and 22 percent. Doove et al. (2001) warn, however, that given the limited coverage of the restrictions on international aviation, the OECD study seriously underestimates the cost of restrictive arrangements. Their own study covering routes among 35 countries finds a very high cost of bilateral restrictions. The transportation costs increase with the restrictiveness of a bilateral regime--the more restrictive the regime is, the higher are the airfares. For instance, business airfares on routes to and from Mexico (high restrictions) are 227 percent higher than under a liberal 406 Part II: Detailed Analysis benchmark regime, whereas in Ireland (low restrictions) they are 32 percent higher (Doove et al. 2001, p. 39). Other evidence suggesting that airline liberalization has been a con- tributing factor to economic development comes from Ireland, often described as a Celtic Tiger because of its spectacular economic growth performance over the last decade or so. It is often overlooked that among the measures that created a "virtuous circle" leading to the Irish economic boom were not only public expenditure cutbacks that allowed for tax reductions but also airline deregulation. The latter "facilitated a more than doubling of tourist numbers over the follow- ing decade" and contributed significantly to FDI inflows (Barry 2003, p. 909). Indeed, the historical evidence from countries that have deregu- lated the domestic aviation sector (such as the United States and the EU) is indisputable. Passengers and shipping companies in both the EU and the United States have experienced a dramatic decline in air- fares. Thanks to the opening of the sector to new entrants, the exist- ing carriers have been exposed to strong competitive pressures. These pressures in turn have reduced profits and costs through gains in pro- ductivity. The entry of the so-called low-cost carriers (LCC) has halved airfares and stimulated volume by at least 70 percent in both the EU and the United States. Competition has also been responsible for a more rapid adaptation and diffusion of new technologies. The com- bination of liberalization and technological progress has been behind a 3.5 percent average annual decline in real yield over 1991­2001. It should be understood, however, that the costs of bilateral avia- tion agreements are not only higher prices of air transport due to the absence of competition or to limited competition. In fact, they also involve the much more important, and more difficult to estimate, costs of forgone opportunities. These costs are potentially huge, as lower airfares boost tourism and create new opportunities for firms to market their products. Tourists, in turn, increase the demand for a variety of services and goods. Examples abound. Not solely oil but mainly the unilateral liberalization of aviation policy has contributed to Dubai's impressive economic development, driven largely by tour- ism and services. The result of a formal, unilateral, open-access policy pursued by the UAE since the 1980s is that Dubai is now served by around 100 airlines to 145 destinations and its local carrier has become a formidable world-class competitor. More important, it has become a tourist and business center in the Middle East. Last but not least, one suspects that the probability for a firm to become incorporated in the global production and distribution networks increasingly on the basis of just-in-time production is low in the absence of reliable low-cost air transport services. Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 407 Network-based ITC: Importance of a Good Regulatory Structure and Government Policies The issue of telecommunications should be part of a broader strategy designed to support the development of network-based ITC that draws on Armenia's revealed multiple strengths in this area. The existence of externalities justifies the government's support. These externalities include a positive impact on education, government services, health services, and labor productivity in other sectors of the economy, as well as the prospects of participation in global supply chains. Tel- ecommunications is part of a broader ITC infrastructure. The government faces the difficult task of reducing the negative impact of some of the most damaging monopoly provisions of its con- tract with ArmenTel without endangering the credibility of Armenia's commitment to the rule of law. It has already made significant strides in improving the contestability of the telecommunications markets by (i) revoking some provisions through negotiations, and (ii) enhancing the capacity of the regulatory structure. Despite the progress made, both tasks are far from being complete. As mentioned earlier, the new Settlement Agreement between the government and ArmenTel/OTE has provided for the immediate partial liberalization of the market and further liberalization in 2009. The government issued a second GSM license to K-Telecom. Although K-Telecom did not face com- petitive tenders, the license is more demanding in terms of required investments than that of ArmenTel's GSM branch. Competition in the mobile sector between ArmenTel and K-Telecom is already positively affecting sector development. There is the continuing challenge of creating a highly transparent regulatory structure to oversee the ArmenTel and subsequently doing what regulators should do--liberalizing markets in order to facilitate competition. Leaving aside the legal issues involved, the negative impacts of the monopoly might have been significantly eased had the government earlier established a body to oversee the implementation of the privatization agreement. The existing structure empowering the CPEC to intervene in telecommunications is not yet regarded as fully satisfactory.28 Thus, as long as a monopoly is in place, the best remedy to limit its costs would be to establish a board overseeing the implementation of the privatization agreement and the practices of ArmenTel. The inde- pendent board should have all of the institutional features that would enable it to function effectively once telecommunications is demonopo- lized. The government might consider adopting the provisions on regu- latory principles contained in the WTO Telecommunications Reference Paper that WTO member countries should follow. The reference paper 408 Part II: Detailed Analysis has been used effectively by WTO members not only as a guideline but also as a credibility-enhancing mechanism (Mattoo 2000). SUMMARY OF POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS Recommendations on how to deal with the three major barriers of transportation, telecommunications, and customs and the VAT regime can be summarized as follows: Transport. The focus should be on aviation policy. The recom- mendations are as follows: --Conclude Open Skies agreements with the United States, Bah- rain, and Dubai. --Undertake unilateral liberalization with the EU--that is, give EU-based carriers unlimited access to Armenian air space and airports. Telecommunications. Independently of efforts to legally revoke monopoly provisions of the agreement, the government should take the following actions: --Set a highly transparent regulatory structure initially overseeing the provision of telecommunications services by ArmenTel. --Sign the WTO Information Technology Agreement. Customs and VAT Regime. The recommendations can be sum- marized as follows: --Create a "white list" of firms with VAT and customs preferen- tial treatment (similar to the one currently afforded to diamond firms). Preferential treatment means the following: Complete customs clearance within a day. Terminate the practice of reference prices. Establish an effective scheme that provides duty waivers and exemptions from other restrictions on imported inputs for established exporters. Rebate VAT to firms on the same day that exports are cleared by customs. For any delays, a firm would be entitled to a refund plus interest. Establish an Independent Professional Association of Cus- toms Brokers. Open the customs computer system to customs brokers. Bring customs-related documents in line with what is really required under a computerized system of the ASYCUDA type. Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 409 Simplify customs clearance procedures for exports with a strict time limit on releasing a shipment; if it is exceeded, a shipment should be immediately released. NOTES 1. This chapter was prepared by Bartek Kaminski, University of Maryland, College Park, and the World Bank. 2. The EU-15 countries are Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. 3. This estimate may be closer to the mark than that in the balance of payments statistics. The ICT sector, employing about 0.5 percent of the total workforce, generates almost 5 percent of Armenia's GDP (Adonian, Chala- byan, and Gurdjian 2004). Therefore, the value added of this sector would be around US$140 million in 2003. With the ICT sector output almost exclusively designated for sales mainly in the United States, Russia, the Netherlands, Germany, Georgia, and France (ADA 2003, p. 14), a conservative estimate that 25 percent of the sector's valued added is sold domestically would yield around US$100 million in exports. 4. A large number of firms connected through complex and borderless sup- ply chains made up of high-volume multicustomer and multinational special- ists at each level have replaced the vertically integrated firms still dominant in the 1980s and early 1990s. 5. The front-end, customer centric, portion of the supply chain includes service providers such as contact centers, order processing, and technical sup- port. At the same level is the order fulfillment hub, which is a combination of a logistics center with order picking and configuration capabilities. 6. There is a caveat. While skilled labor-intensive products were under- represented in their export baskets and unskilled labor-intensive exports grew fastest, Armenia "suffers" from the "excessive presence" of the former and underrepresentation of the latter. 7. In terms of the average FDI in terms of GDP in 1998­2003, Armenia ranked second among non-oil CIS countries after Moldova--the average was 8.5 percent for Moldova and 5.3 percent for Armenia. 8. ArmenTel was established in 1994 as a joint venture between the Min- istry of Communications (51 percent) and Trans World Telecom (49 percent); the venture was formed to upgrade the network and introduce mobile serv- ices. Trans World Telecom received US$55 million, or 39 percent, of the total amount of the sale to OTE. 9. In 1998, privatization proceeds amounted to US$125.1 million, of which US$118.3 million came the from privatization of two enterprises in the tel- ecommunications and energy sectors (Grigorian 2005). 410 Part II: Detailed Analysis 10. There are two arguments for focusing solely on these indicators. First, these indicators are critical dimensions of the business climate. Political sta- bility affects investment decisions and in extreme situations its absence may disrupt economic activities. The quality of regulation is of little relevance unless supported by the government's capacity to enforce regulations. Second, three other indicators pertinent to such dimensions of governance as the rule of law, control of corruption, and voice and accountability are not taken into account, as they do not yield extra information. For all transition economies, they are strongly correlated with the selected three indicators, with the values of correlation coefficients equal to or above 0.9. For the explanation and data, see http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/gov_data.htm. 11. The SRI is derived from EBRD transition indicators for competition policy, government and enterprise restructuring, large-scale privatization, banking reform and interest rate liberalization, and policy and regulations for security markets and nonbank financial institutions. 12. This was clearly the case with Hungary in 1995, when the govern- ment opened so-called strategic sectors to foreign investors, producing a huge increase in FDI inflows. In this year alone the stock of FDI increased 67 per- cent, and the annual inflow was not matched in 1996­2004. 13. Council for Mutual Economic Assistance. 14. For an in-depth analysis, see Kaminski (2005). 15. For an extensive analysis based on firms' surveys, see "Administrative Barriers Update: Fourth Annual Regulatory and Administrative Costs Survey: Armenia," by Development Network NGO for FIAS (March 2004). 16. The simple average bound tariff rate for all products is 8.6 percent, with the average rate of 14.9 percent for agricultural products and 7.7 percent for industrial products (own calculations based on Armenia's "Bound" Sched- ule). Both averages put Armenia in the middle of transition economies. For agricultural products, Albania, the Slovak Republic, and the Czech Republic (prior to EU accession) have lower rates of 9.4 percent and 10 percent. Esto- nia's and Latvia's rates are higher--17.5 and 34.6 percent, correspondingly. For industrial products, Albania, the Czech Republic together with the Slovak Republic, Hungary, and Estonia have lower average rates of 6.6, 4.2, 6.9, and 7.3 percent, respectively. 17. This is an extra Armenia-specific commitment coming on top of all other commitments to observe the provisions of the WTO Agreement. 18. Armenia, however, has made a precommitment to "provide unlimited market access for all basic and value added telecommunications services to the sub-sector initially covered by the monopoly immediately upon suspen- sion or termination of monopoly rights in that sub-sector on or at anytime prior to the end of the monopoly" (WTO 2002). 19. The agreement spells out procedures to follow when customs inspec- tors suspect that traders are misreporting. 20. On November 25, 2004, the government signed a new Settlement Agreement that ended the arbitration and litigation process and terminated Armenia's External Performance and Policy Remedies 411 ArmenTel's exclusive rights by the issuance of a second mobile license, and provided for the possibility of a third GSM license in 2009. 21. In spite of an 85 percent increase in the value of total trade turnover in goods between 1999 and 2003, expenditures and receipts from cargo services--taxing both exports and imports--increased over this period by only 36 percent. Since there has been no major change in the composition of trade over 1999­2003, one can argue that the fall in logistics-related costs has made possible a larger increase in trade in goods than in expenditures on freight and insurance. 22. The standard procedure is as follows. Upon the arrival of a shipment at the airport or cargo terminal, it is transported in a sealed case to a factory by the special security service unit escorted by customs officers. Once it is safely delivered, a customs officer opens the sealed case and proceeds with customs clearance. The same steps in reverse order are followed when diamonds are ready for export. 23. The design and implementation of waivers and exemptions would require the attention of policy makers. The possible mechanisms are a rebate scheme on account, a deferred drawback, or a temporary admissions mecha- nism. 24. The ITA is a tariff-cutting mechanism that emerged from the Singa- pore WTO Ministerial in 1996. The Agreement zeroes out tariff rates on all IT products--components as well as final products. Most of these products have a high R&D component, but not all of them. For instance, articles as ordinary as cash registers and water pressure gauges are also considered "information technology." For details, see http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/inftec_e/ inftec_e.htm. As of July 2004, there are 63 participants, including the remaining CIS WTO members (that is, Georgia, the Kyrgyz Republic, and Moldova). 25. The "fifth freedom of the air" offers the right of an airline from one economy to carry traffic between two other economies provided the flight originates or terminates in its own economy. 26. The reasons the United States is likely to accept the offer are twofold: one is related to the Armenian diaspora and commercial relations in the United States, and another is related to its international aviation policy. The pressure from the diaspora would be seconded by pressure from U.S. carriers interested in further expansion of flights to Armenia. As for the U.S. aviation policy aspect, signing an agreement would be only natural, as the United States has a proven record of willingness to negotiate and sign these agreements. At present, it has Open Skies deals with 63 countries including Uzbekistan. The U.S. type of Open Skies agreement typically includes the fifth freedom code- share rights for U.S. carriers extended beyond hubs outside the United States. This would allow a U.S. carrier to add its code to any strategic partner airline, for example, a EU carrier flight into Yerevan. 27. These agreements vary in their provisions, but one component is con- stant: any carrier from either country can operate any service from its home country to any destination in the other country. 412 Part II: Detailed Analysis 28. A blatant example of the absence of any meaningful oversight is the case of mobile phone cards. The scheme, reminiscent of the rationing of short- ages under central planning, consists in setting the official price well below the market clearing level and selling some portion of them with a huge pre- mium (3­4 times above the nominal price) on the black market. The scheme is a rip-off not only for consumers but also for the owners of ArmenTel. No sensible regulator would have tolerated it under any circumstances. Chapter 13 Civil Aviation Policy SUMMARY Armenia has fairly poor international civil aviation connectivities.1 There are five flights a day to Moscow, an average of five to European hubs, and infrequent connections to Middle East and Asian hubs. Lim- ited capacity translates through to relatively higher prices. While it is likely that Armenian air markets will grow, probably faster than the economy grows, the level of value added by aviation to the economy and job creation will be less than it could be. Current government policy contributes to the suboptimal growth: both regulatory and commercial arrangements are restrictive. The benefits from the low- cost carrier (LCC) innovation are unlikely to be realized. International experience shows the competition and economic development benefits from removal of such restrictions. Armenia should seek to eliminate these government-imposed economic entry barriers, subject to Arme- nian airlines having the opportunity to compete, as soon as possible. The government's agreement regarding Armavia would need to be reevaluated as part of a reform process. Well-managed Armenian airlines should be viable in less restric- tive, more competitive markets, although this cannot be guaranteed, as it cannot be in any market. Even were Armenia to move to a non- restrictive policy immediately, restrictions on certain key routes would continue to remain as a result of policies followed by other countries. There is a need to ensure that competition law is operating effectively. The remaining restrictive airline ownership and control requirements internationally are a problem that requires a multilateral solution. In a more liberal environment, the government's focus in the future should be on ensuring safety, and security, addressing any adverse environmental impacts, and ensuring an effective and efficient infra- structure. 413 414 Part II: Detailed Analysis INTRODUCTION Civil aviation has been recognized increasingly as being an important component of a successful strategy for economic development and poverty alleviation. The advantages that aviation offers in terms of saving time and "reducing" distance play a major role in creating opportunities, growing markets, strengthening international linkages, and reducing barriers. This is particularly important and valuable for countries with limited or no land linkages. Landlocked countries tend to have lower per capita incomes than other countries (Gallup and Sachs 1998). A study on the effects of higher transport costs (land and sea) faced by landlocked countries suggests that a 10 percent reduction in these costs will boost trade by 20 percent (Limao and Venables 2001). The evidence suggests that air cargo allows distant countries actually to have a comparative advan- tage in high value-added products for high-income markets (see, for example, the use by Chinese firms of air freight in supplying the U.S. market, suggesting that China has developed a surprising degree of comparative advantage in high value-added products). These studies suggest a strong imperative to undertake all possible policies to offset the fundamental disadvantage: international civil aviation policy is an obvious instrument. An appropriate government policy, effectively implemented, is important in maximizing the potential of aviation. In addition to the government's core responsibility of ensuring national security, the gov- ernment has placed a priority on high rates of sustainable economic growth to lift living standards and alleviate poverty. Where restrictive agreements exist in aviation, local airlines usually argue that there is the necessity of continuing the restrictions to protect or assist them for a variety of reasons. As with any protection or industry assistance, there are costs to the consumers, the businesses, and the economy along with the loss of critical competitive pressures on airlines. The government has to evaluate these economy-wide costs of the benefits obtained from the protection against its overall objectives. In addition, if these benefits are important, the government would want to consider whether there are lower-cost ways of delivering these benefits, for example, as explicit subsidies to any airline willing to provide the desired additional service rather than continuing with the government-imposed entry barriers. The international evidence in aviation and Armenia's own expe- rience with liberalization and competition in other markets suggest that the government's policy towards aviation should emphasize the objective of totally eliminating the historic and comprehensive gov- ernment-imposed economic entry barriers to Armenia's aviation mar- kets (see Box 13.1). Civil Aviation Policy 415 Box 13.1 Armenian Aviation Market Entry Restrictions These restrictions include the following: government limits on the number of airlines government limits on the frequencies, schedules, capacities, and services offered by airlines strict limits on networks (the so-called fifth freedom)* requirements or permissions for airlines to "coordinate" activities pricing restrictions ownership and control requirements Source: Staff analysis. * The "right" of an airline to carry traffic between two other countries if the flight originates or terminates in its home country. A number of countries have made substantial progress towards the full elimination of such restrictions in international air markets. Full liberalization has not been fully achieved anywhere internation- ally in civil aviation, but the EU single air market perhaps offers the best example implemented to date. For example, subject to satisfy- ing safety and security requirements, Czech-owned airlines (but not U.S. or Armenian) can now fly between London and Dublin offering any range of services they wish, subject only to safety, security, and general competition law. The Czechs now have an LCC, Smartwings, operating in EU markets and started operations in markets outside of the EU in 2005 (further details can be found in Attachment 6). Latvia's airBaltic,2 which has LCC characteristics, has grown rapidly and now operates out of both Riga and Lithuania's Vilnius (further details can be found in Attachment 5). Governments can and will continue to place a high priority on safe and secure air services, in line with international treaty obligations. This should be the focus of government policy and administration along with ensuring that general laws, including competition law, work well and the key infrastructure services operate efficiently and effectively. These are major challenges in their own right and will need ongoing government attention. This chapter has the following structure: the approach followed in the preparation of this chapter the current international situation the key facts 416 Part II: Detailed Analysis existing government policy Armenian airlines and the agreement with Armavia international experience with aviation liberalization policy options for the government concerns with liberalization aviation infrastructure government decision-making processes conclusions APPROACH OF THIS CHAPTER Following the agreement between the government and the World Bank that the issue of the regulation of Armenian international air services would be studied further, meetings were held with a range of govern- ment and private sector officials in Yerevan. This allowed the key areas of concern to be better defined and a work program identified. Information and data have been provided by the General Director of Civil Aviation (GDCA). We are grateful for this cooperation and assistance. A survey of departing passengers at Yerevan International Airport was undertaken in early November 2004 to ascertain origin and departure information. International studies on the experiences of other countries with avia- tion liberalization were examined and are summarized in this report. With the cooperation of the authorities in the respective countries, the Bank also prepared short case studies on the experience of some Eastern European countries with international aviation policy. These are sum- marized below and the case studies are attached. Reform options were examined from the perspective of their applicability to the Armenian circumstances. A draft of the report was submitted to the government in March 2005. This report reflects comments received to date. THE CURRENT INTERNATIONAL SITUATION As a result of the 1944 Chicago Convention, the operations of interna- tional civil air services are mainly regulated by air service agreements (ASAs) established on a bilateral basis. Since World War II, air markets have been highly regulated by governments for economic rather than safety reasons.3 Box 13.1 lists the range of restrictions involved in this approach. The current intergovernmental bilateral nature of air service regulation means that achieving a fully (economically) unrestricted air service market in line with other liberalized markets requires the agreement of each partner country as an initial step. Such agreements can be regarded as "liberal" or nonrestrictive, as with the U.S. Open Skies agreement model, or they might be restrictive, as with the cur- Civil Aviation Policy 417 rent U.S.­U.K. air service agreement--the so-called Bermuda II Agree- ment. For example, under the latter only two U.S. carriers can serve Heathrow­U.S. markets. It would be possible for Armenia to "offer" to, say, Austria that Armenia desires to modify the existing air service agreement so that any EU airline4 could fly between Austria and Armenia offering as many services as it wishes regardless of whether Austria was will- ing to agree to the same arrangements for Armenian carriers. Logi- cally, Austria should accept this offer but Austria's agreement to the new arrangements is still likely to be necessary. Open Skies policies involve two countries agreeing to the elimination of all of the restric- tions listed in Box 13.1 for carriers meeting the ownership and control requirements. This means that neither country's airlines could effec- tively monopolize the market as another carrier from either country could enter the market, although not necessarily a carrier owned by nationals of third countries. Ownership Restrictions Will Remain a Problem Thus, even the most unrestrictive bilateral agreements still impose requirements that airlines operating under these agreements must be substantially owned and effectively controlled by nationals of one of the partner states.5 This restriction is particularly important for coun- tries with small capital markets, but even for bigger countries it is an increasing problem and constraint. Some countries are more willing than others to interpret the rules flexibly. There are examples where, often for very sensible reasons, substantial ownership and effective control is held by non-nationals (for example, Air Pacific, in theory a Fijian airline under Fijian ASAs, is generally regarded as being con- trolled by Australian-owned Qantas). Increasingly, the rules are being circumvented in arrangements such as the Air Pacific model. These technically nonconforming arrange- ments are always at risk of challenge by any bilateral partner country with landing rights potentially being withdrawn. Thus, the particular ownership and financing arrangements for an airline must meet the requirements of the most "demanding" partner country: ownership and control arrangements are unique and ubiquitous for each airline. Quid pro quos are often involved to achieve this. THE KEY FACTS In spite of a fast-growing economy, Armenian aviation outputs have been dropping for cargo, but rising recently for passengers, albeit from a low base (see Table 13.1 and Figure 13.1). Recovery from the Russian 418 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 13.1 Zvartnots' Airport Freight Volumes, 1997­2004 Freight 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Freight shipped 26.5 18.9 13.5 13.8 11.5 8.4 8.8 9.2 by air transport (thousand metric ton) Freight turnover 21.2 15.2 12.7 9.6 9.1 5.8 5.5 9.9 in air transportation (million tonne-km) Source: GDCA. economic crisis is cited as the explanation for the situation and improved land links is the explanation for Russia's economic recovery. Armenian and foreign airlines report increasing traffic currently. Given the coun- try's high economic growth rate, this is the normal expectation. Figure 13.1 gives a longer view in respect of passenger numbers and distance traveled. Armenia has adequate aviation infrastructure, including an EBRD- funded cargo facility, although the terminal at Yerevan's Zvartnots International Airport (the country's main airport) is not designed to handle the number of passengers carried by modern aircraft, given the security requirements and passenger expectations. The airport6 has embarked on a terminal expansion program. When completed this will allow the airport to handle 4 million passengers annually. Generally, air service outputs grow approximately 50 percent faster than the economy (Gillen, Morrison, and Stewart 2003). Given Arme- nia's starting position of low incomes, an underdeveloped air mar- ket, and strong economic prospects, this outperformance should be regarded as minimal. On the other hand, a restrictive international air service regime and the ensuing higher costs and prices would reduce output and probably growth. The flights offered to and from Arme- nia appear relatively limited compared with other countries with a similar population. A printout of a typical day's Departure Board at Zvartnots International Airport is contained in Attachment 1. It shows that there are approximately five flights a day on average to Western hubs, five flights per day to Moscow, and limited connections to the east and south. Countries with more liberal ASA policies often have higher inter- national air connectivities. For example, Latvia currently has a popu- lation of 2 million, although with a higher per capita income than Armenia. Riga Airport's timetable currently shows 28 daily flights to hub airports (the weekly timetable is given in Attachment 2). New Civil Aviation Policy 419 Figure 13.1 Zvartnots Airport Passenger Volumes, 1990­2005 2.0 6,000 1.8 passengers) 5,000 1.6 (million 1.4 4,000 traffic 1.2 passenger-kilometers) 1.0 3,000 (million passengers 0.8 2,000 0.6 turnover outgoing 0.4 and 1,000 0.2 passengers incoming 0 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 year volume of passengers annually arriving and departing (left-hand side) passenger-kilometers traveled in millions, annually (right-hand side) Source: GDCA, Armenia. Zealand (an isolated country with a slightly larger population than Armenia's but with higher incomes) has approximately 50 flights on a typical day to a recognized hub airport such as Sydney. Many of these flights are by high-capacity, wide-body aircraft. The Czech air- line (CSA) has a current winter schedule offering approximately 35 daily connections to hubs. It has not been possible to obtain good data on actual air fares and cargo rates in Armenia. Craig Jenks (see Annex 13.1) has used infor- mation on actual passenger yields from Computer Reservation Service 420 Part II: Detailed Analysis (CRS) databases to produce some data on the Armenian air services markets. The study drew on data from travel on the Yerevan to EU markets, as well as the Riga (RIX), Tallin (TLL), and Larnaca (LCA) to EU markets over the same time periods. The data exclude Internet and direct bookings with carriers. The comparators were chosen as being distant from the main EU markets (although not as distant as Arme- nia) but, more important, as markets being subject to EU liberalization effects. This is not a rigorous study of the effects of liberalization but it is illustrative and is suggestive of lines for further research. Jenks's report can be found in Annex 13.1. Table 13.2 summarizes the results. The consultant concludes that the data show that Yerevan­EU yields (the average actual air fares on a per passenger-kilometer basis), when adjusted for differences in distance, are higher than the comparators, with the partial exception of Tallin. The consultant highlights the impact of the entry of an LCC, Ryanair, on the Heathrow­Riga yields when the airline entered the market but serving it from Stansted, U.K. Connectivities The relatively low level of connectivity except for Moscow must mean that travelers face either the need to transit via Moscow or an intermit- tent schedule, by international standards, with costs in terms of time and reduced options. Two or three flights a day on a particular route to a recognized hub would be more consistent with modern busi- ness and tourism requirements. For example, Austrian Airlines now operates three flights a day between Sofia and Vienna.7 This is not to suggest that the Armenian market is currently large enough for such frequencies and volumes in the short term but is just to indicate that it will be potentially costly if government regulation precludes such development. The Latvian experience discussed later in the chapter is instructive. Results of the Airport Survey A survey using the U.K. Civil Aviation Administration (CAA) airport survey methodology was prepared and undertaken by a local consult- ant under the supervision of the General Civil Aviation Department and the World Bank. The airport survey was undertaken over a one- week period in early November 2004. Armenian residents made up just over half of the sample. The analysis suggests that the average return ticket price was US$350. This is high in relation to the incomes of even Armenian business travelers. Of this group, 60 percent had incomes below US$6,000 per year. Almost 90 percent of nonbusiness travelers had incomes below US$6,000 per year. Civil Aviation Policy 421 Table 13.2 Comparative Yerevan­EU Air Fares Fare in What fare Fare in last Compared to February­ Compared to "should be" 12 months "should be" April 2005 "should be" EU (US$) (US$) (%) (US$) (%) EVN 333 355 6.6 over 377 13.2 over TLL 225 209 7.1 under 287 27.5 over RIX 200 178 11 under 171 14.5 under LCA 312 202 35.2 under 197 36.8 under Source: See Annex 13.1. Passengers traveling for the stated purpose of business made up 30 percent of the sample (51 percent of travelers destined for Europe had business as their prime purpose for traveling). However, the propor- tion of those traveling on business class tickets was around 6 percent: most of them were flying on economy-class tickets. Consistent with the observation from airline schedules, the initial destination of 77 percent of travelers was Russia, 4 percent were going to other CIS countries, and 15 percent were flying directly to European airports, leaving only a small percentage of travelers flying to the Middle East, Turkey, and Iran. However, in terms of final destinations, 57 percent were terminating their flights in Europe or the Americas. This may be indicative of the current restrictive regime forcing people to hub through Moscow rather than using more desirable direct connections if available and cost-effective. Cargo The other benefit of modern passenger aircraft is its incidental cargo capacity. As cargo and mail services are offered almost as a side ben- efit of passenger services, pricing can be much more flexible than that required by dedicated cargo aircraft. Wide-body aircraft offer par- ticular benefits to the cargo market. The evidence suggests that the available cargo space is generally in high demand for time-sensitive valuable cargos. CURRENT ARMENIAN INTERNATIONAL AVIATION POLICY Armenia has a current statement of aviation policy and strategy. The government also has some 43 bilateral air service agreements, with some negotiated but still to be signed. The key features in the 422 Part II: Detailed Analysis air service agreements with Armenia's main potential air markets are outlined in the table in Attachment 4. This table, reflecting the elements in Box 13.1, specifies whether the current agreements, as implemented by subsequent intergovernmental agreements, allow or require the following: the designation of only one or of multiple airlines by Armenia limitations on the number of seats offered or the size of the plane operated limitations on frequencies offered fifth freedom rights coordination between airlines on services and prices government intervention on air fares national ownership and control of airlines From an economic perspective, all of the current agreements can be regarded as being restrictive, some potentially important ones highly so. For example, we understand that the Armenia-Russia bilateral agreement limited the airlines of each country to providing no more than 135,000 seats in 2004. We also understand that this was fully used and that the limit for 2005 has been agreed at 161,000 seats in each direction, together with an option for additional flights at peak periods. Austrian Airlines' usual policy is to provide daily flights as a mini- mum. Austrian operates a year-round service, reducing aircraft size if necessary during the low season. Austrian cited its Vienna­Sofia service to illustrate its strategy. During the pre-reform 1980s the airline provided three to five services per week owing to a restrictive Aus- trian-Bulgarian ASA. Now, with a more liberalized policy environ- ment, Austrian is operating three daily services (see Attachment 7). The air service agreement with United Kingdom permits a desig- nated airline from each nation to provide a daily service on Armenia- United Kingdom routes with narrow body aircraft. This includes the option of access to the well connected Heathrow airport, airport slots permitting. A British Airways affiliate, BMed, provides less than weekly services currently, operated in connection with their service flying onto Bishkek. Armenia does not permit BMed to provide serv- ices between Yerevan and Bishkek (or Tashkent, which was served on the same basis previously); that is allow fifth freedom rights. It is obvious that BMed would have space available on these type of routes as passengers would leave and join the service in Yerevan from/to London. While GDCA informed us that nonscheduled charter flights and dedicated cargo flights are unconstrained by either regulation or Civil Aviation Policy 423 policy, we understand that there have been some difficulties in get- ting approval for particular services. In addition, as charter airlines are increasingly offering schedules of flight-only services in response to the competition of LCCs such as Ryanair and Internet bookings, these otherwise charter services will be constrained by the relevant air service agreement restrictions on scheduled services. Overall, the current policy is likely to have the effect of preventing services that otherwise would be offered. ARMENIAN AIRLINES AND THE AGREEMENT WITH ARMAVIA Two carriers were designated by the Armenian government in respect of its air service agreements: Armenian International Airlines (AIA) Armavia Integral to the establishment and operation of these airlines was the transfer of what were regarded as valuable route rights to each of the airlines. These rights are only valuable if they are restrictive. Capacity is less than would be provided in the absence of these restrictions, prices are higher, higher profits are earned, and national output is lower. AIA AIA had one aircraft that operated routes to Beirut, Paris, Athens, and Dubai with low frequencies up until the end of 2004. According to the privately owned AIA, it was operating a higher-frequency service than the now-defunct state-owned Armenian Airlines had operated to both Paris and Dubai. However, the rights transferred to AIA expired on December 31, 2004. At that point the rights were transferred to Armavia under the government's agreement with Armavia. AIA has ceased operations, leasing out the aircraft. If AIA had retained the rights the airline management said that it would have considered expanding its fleet. Armavia At the time of its establishment, Armavia was substantially owned and effectively controlled by the Russian airline, Siberian Airlines. The bulk of the Armenian route rights are held by Armavia under a 424 Part II: Detailed Analysis ten-year agreement with the government and Siberian Airlines titled, "Investment Agreement Relating to the Provision of Finance to Arma- via," signed on March 14, 2003 (the "Agreement"). This Agreement requires that Siberian Airlines shall own no less than 67 percent of Armavia (Clause 4.2). Siberian's interest has now been sold to Arme- nian interests. The route schedule for winter 2004­05 for Armavia is in Attach- ment 3. There is an obvious focus on Russian routes in the schedule with less emphasis on Western and southern linkages (for example, the schedule shows only a handful of flights per week into Euro- pean hubs). From Armenia's perspective there would seem to be two concerns, given the importance of the Armenia-Russia air market for Armenian economic development: The restrictive nature of the Armenian-Russian ASA. The restrictive nature of Russian ASAs generally, limiting con- necting opportunities for Armenia­Moscow market customers, offering as it does the most frequent connection opportunity. For example, Aeroflot has only one, or possibly two, daily flights to Los Angeles and two flights a week to the key Chicago hub. The cost and the loss of opportunities resulting from this focus could be a double "tax" on the Armenian economy. The Agreement gives Armavia Armenian route rights on a "long- term exclusive basis" (Schedule 2 2.1[a]). Clause 2(1)(f) of Schedule 2 of the Agreement suggests that Armavia can initiate and finance any Armenian government attempts to improve existing ASAs or enter into new ASAs. The former is to be from Armavia's perspective alone, whereas new ASAs are from Armavia's and Armenia's perspective jointly. Armavia has the right of "first refusal" for any new rights received by Armenia under air service agreements. Thus, there are significant limitations on available route rights being given to any potential Armenian competitors to Armavia. In addition, the govern- ment would be required to indemnify the airline for any damages caused by government actions that modify or hinder the perform- ance of the Agreement (Section 5[2]). This would seem to cover the government's agreeing to allow more foreign airline capacity and to allow the entry of new Armenian airlines into Armenian international air markets without Armavia's agreement. Unlike many countries, Armenia does not now have a state-owned airline; however, the implicit policy via the Agreement with Siberia and Armavia reflects a desire to have some Armenian airline capacity. The Agreement requires that Armavia should operate modern Boeing and/or Airbus equipment at least on Western routes. Civil Aviation Policy 425 INTERNATIONAL EXPERIENCE WITH AVIATION LIBERALIZATION The removal of government-imposed economic entry barriers to avia- tion has been associated with the rapid growth of these markets in many countries. The removal of these economic restrictions occurred first in the United States in the late 1970s, and subsequently in Chile, the EU, and the Antipodes. A more recent example is some degree of deregulation of domestic aviation and liberalization of international air services in India (Financial Times 2005). The outcome of liberaliza- tion has been dramatic: indeed, the development of LCCs such as Southwest Airlines in the United States and Ryanair in the EU is often regarded as the most visible example of the benefits of the removal of government-imposed economic entry barriers in any market. Safety standards have been maintained. New services, more serv- ices, and lower airfares (including by the so-called legacy or incum- bent carriers) are widespread results of deregulation. Airlines are able and willing to serve markets where it is profitable to do so. The airline industry has become much more efficient. As in any market, some air- lines have financial problems, and some disappear into bankruptcy. In spite of that, and indeed, because of that, the services have continued to be provided and markets have continued to grow. The contribu- tion to the economy is higher. In India, reform has resulted in greatly improved services to customers and the increased competition has forced the incumbent airlines, the state-owned Air India and Indian Airlines, to improve their performance. Empirical Evidence The United States Moving beyond the anecdotal examples, there is considerable empiri- cal evidence of the benefits of comprehensive reform. For example, air fares in the United States are estimated to be 24 percent lower than they would have been if the regulated market had continued (Winston and Morrison 2003). Lower average air fares have resulted in substan- tial market expansion and an increased range of services. The LCC innovation is unlikely to have occurred in regulated markets. Perhaps just as important, the research suggests that the threat of competition, rather than the actual competition, that arises from reform also results in benefits to consumers. That is, the evidence is that the opportunity for a competing airline to enter a service puts pressure on incumbent airlines to improve their services and lower prices, thereby benefiting customers. This is important for smaller markets such as Armenia. 426 Part II: Detailed Analysis This evidence might be criticized as being domestic in nature and ignoring the complications imposed by the international bilateral system. A U.S. Department of Transportation study on the effects of U.S. Open Skies agreements compared to traditional ASAs suggests that the liberalization due to Open Skies agreements has resulted in increased services and lower fares.10 A comprehensive study of the effects on U.S. international air cargo markets of Open Skies agreements suggests a reduction in prices (Micco and Serebrisky 2004): this is in a situation in which U.S. bilateral agree- ments usually did not constrain dedicated cargo airliners in any case. The EU A recent study commissioned by the European Commission investi- gated the benefits to be gained by removing the remaining govern- ment-imposed economic restrictions in the overall U.S.-EU interna- tional aviation market. Even though some key U.S.-European bilateral agreements are of the Open Skies type,11 (for example, the U.S. agree- ments with the Netherlands, France, and Germany), the removal of the remaining restrictions is estimated to generate a further increase of approximately 10 percent in aviation outputs along with substantial cost savings (The Brattle Group 2002a). The Netherlands It might be argued that these are major markets and similar results may not be found for smaller markets. A study for the Dutch government (The Brattle Group 2002b) estimated that the Dutch Open Skies agree- ments boosted outputs on the Netherlands­U.S. routes by 51 percent and on the Netherlands­Kenya routes by 157 percent. There was a sig- nificant positive effect on aviation employment in the Netherlands as a result. The study also indicated that the Netherlands received a strate- gic benefit by being the first among its European neighbors to reform. Australia The Australian Productivity Commission's investigation of the effects of the removal of government-imposed restrictions on Australian international aviation produced estimates of significant overall gains to the economy (Productivity Commission 1999). Chile The Chilean government considers that the Chilean Open Skies policy contributed to the rapid 10 percent per year growth in passengers over Civil Aviation Policy 427 the 1989­2002 period (with 9 percent per year for cargo). The number of services offered in the Chilean international air services market increased from 104 to 329 over the same period. Chilean carriers provided 47 of these services in 1989, rising to 148 over the period. A short paper by the Chilean government on this issue, provided to the International Civil Aviation Organization (ICAO), is provided in Attachment 8. Lebanon A recent European Commission (EC) paper on the EU's international aviation strategy (EC 2004) cites Lebanon's own Open Skies policy as delivering a dynamic air market as the local tourism markets grow rapidly. The local airline, MEA, appears to have coped and responded to the challenge successfully. The European Commission's estimate is calculated by fully offset- ting the much larger gains to existing passengers from these lower prices by the reduced benefits to the airlines.12 The estimate is purely indicative and is likely to be the upper bound for the likely gains from price changes resulting from liberalization. In particular, the available liberalization options for the government, even when fully implemented, may still not make the Armenian market attractive to LCC operations. Moreover, even if Armenia were to fully liberalize immediately, these gains would not occur straight away. As is noted above, the agreement of the bilateral partner country is needed to implement full liberalization. Even with this agreement, airlines need to decide on increasing schedules and undertaking the necessary market devel- opment activities. The European experience shows that LCCs do not enter markets immediately and that LCCs are only starting to enter markets regulated by ASAs. Further examples of the experiences with liberalization are given in Box 13.2. Effects of Liberalization in Armenia Airline yields have indeed been falling in real terms for some time. With full competition, prices will come closer to best practice least- cost over time, as is the trend in the United States, the EU, and other liberalized markets with the removal of government-imposed regula- tory barriers, the full entry of LCCs, and the efficient utilization of new technologies. This estimate of the effects of liberalization does not allow for the gains in quality that come from greater competition. With competi- tion, airlines will have a stronger incentive to target service quality more closely to consumer preferences and willingness to pay. This would boost economic welfare further (see also Box 13.3). 428 Part II: Detailed Analysis Box 13.2 Case Studies: Additional Liberalization Experiences In response to suggestions from some interested parties in Armenia we also examined the experiences of some smaller countries (Latvia, the Czech Republic, and Bulgaria) that had engaged in liberalization in cooperation with the respective authorities. Latvia Latvia and the Czech Republic liberalized ahead of EU accession, for different reasons. Latvia saw the importance of air links, was unwilling and unable to cover the losses incurred by the incumbent airline (an Aeroflot legacy operation), and decided to allow market solutions to the provision of air services while focusing scarce government resources on aviation infrastructure. There has been a dramatic opening of the Latvian-European air markets over the last 10 years. Air travel vol- umes initially reduced dramatically as subsidies on the old internal USSR routes disappeared. Following a period of much lower activity, rapid growth in the air markets occurred with EU accession and the reorientation of airBaltic toward an LCC model to meet the LCC chal- lenge that came with the EU-required liberalization (see Attachment 5 for more details). The Czech Republic In the early 1990s, the Czech government saw the potential in their tourism market as being best addressed by unrestricted international markets. The incumbent carrier (CSA) was not able to refute these argu- ments. Growth has been extremely rapid and the incumbent carrier has adjusted to meet the increasingly competitive threats. Other Czech carri- ers have entered the market (see Attachment 6 for further details). Bulgaria While still operating fully within the bilateral Austrian-Bulgarian ASA framework, Bulgaria has liberalized to ensure that air services are pro- vided, given that the incumbent state carrier was performing poorly. The level of connectivity is high as a result of increased services by nonBulgarian airlines. No LCCs have yet attempted to enter these mar- kets. This reflects the earlier observation that LCCs function best in deregulated markets and their operation seems inconsistent with the inherent rigidities of the regulation and associated compliance under bilateral ASAs. (Fuller details are given in Attachment 7.) Source: Staff analysis. Civil Aviation Policy 429 Box 13.3 Economic Benefits of Liberalization: An Illustrative Calculation The available Armenian data do not permit a comprehensive assessment of the likely effects of the removal of the existing economic restrictions. A possible way of thinking about the effects of liberalizing Armenia's aviation market would be to consider the results from the U.S. domes- tic liberalization, the best documented and analyzed case, as being the benchmark for the long-term effects of full liberalization. As is noted in the text, the movement away from the highly regulated U.S. domestic market in the 1970s resulted in a drop in prices of 24 percent. This drop factors in the effect of the entry of LCCs such as Southwest Airlines, which were able to expand nationwide with liberalization. A recent surveya suggests price elasticities as being in the range of 1 (that is, demand grows by 10 percent in response to a price reduction of 10 percent). Thus the 24 percent price reduction estimated would result in outputs being 24 percent higher, all other things being equal. With Armenian passenger volumes being in excess of 1 million in 2004 (Table 13.1), a 24 percent increase in volumes would translate into approximately another 250,000 passengers through the airport in a year. The airport survey indicates average single price of US$184 and a return ticket price of US$436. Assuming a single ticket price of US$200, this suggests a net economic welfare gain of over US$6 million per year to Armenia from better pricing alone. Source: Staff analysis. a. Gillen, Morrison, and Stewart (2003). This survey shows short-haul business travelers to be less responsive to price changes whereas leisure travelers are much more responsive. All of the business-class travelers to and from Armenia probably fall into the former category. While the airport survey shows that some 30 percent of travelers could be regarded as being business travelers, most were traveling on cheaper economy tickets. Overall an elasticity of 1 is probably reasonable. ICAO in its publication Economic Contribution of Civil Aviation (2000) estimates a threefold multiplier between aviation outputs and wider economic impacts: that is, US$100 of aviation outputs generate US$325 of additional outputs in the wider economy. The employment multi- plier is higher, according to the same publication. Policy Options for the Government The foregoing suggests that there are gains available to the govern- ment from instituting a comprehensive liberalization policy for civil aviation. The government would wish to convince itself and other interested parties that benefits from liberalization policy would likely 430 Part II: Detailed Analysis exceed any costs in comparison with the next best policy option and that any policy and implementation risks could be managed. The main policy options that would represent a movement from the status quo include the following: unilateral liberalization adoption of the EU single air market principles adoption of an Open Skies policy for international air services phased liberalization The Status Quo The status quo, the continuation of the current policy, would not mean that the government would not change bilateral agreements and their implementation at all. In fact, it would probably mean that the government would respond to proposals from Armavia or from partner governments (usually on behalf of their airlines) to under- take negotiations that would result in the creation of additional traffic "rights." Even monopolies respond to changes in demand and costs. For example, constraining airline schedules to allow 100 percent load- factor aircraft operation is not a profitable commercial strategy, even for monopolists: operating schedules that result in lower load factors are more profitable. The increases in capacity offered by incumbent airlines and the entry of Lufthansa can be seen in this context. Airline behavior is a factor in the restrictiveness of the current pol- icy. Traditional bilateral air service agreements tend to create duopo- lies: namely, two airlines, one from each country. The degree of "coop- eration" between them depends on a range of factors including the attitude of both governments and whether competition law is applied and is effective.13 Highly "cooperative" duopolies behave as monopo- lies, constraining the capacity to raise prices to the profit-maximizing level. Depending on these factors, either one or both of the airlines will approach the government(s) when it seems profitable to expand capacity. These expansions will be less than what would prevail in a competitive market, but they will occur. Air services would increase with a growing market, but opportunities would be forgone and costs would be higher than they need to be. The need for government agree- ment, negotiations, permits, and so forth obviously raises the costs of making proposals for new capacity. The government's agreement with Armavia will result in a more restrictive approach to capacity additions than would prevail if the government were able to consider or initiate proposals for additional services without such an agreement. The length of the agreement and the exclusivity given to Armavia, along with the indemnifications Civil Aviation Policy 431 given under the agreement, mean that the government is effectively committed to a restrictive approach until March 2013. The govern- ment's approach to the obligations regarding a minimum of network operations, and the sanctions available for breaches, may have some offsetting influence on an otherwise restrictive approach. Never- theless, the existence of the agreement, with its clear and exclusive allocation of existing route rights, including those reallocated from AIA, suggests that the government's international aviation policy will be strongly influenced by Armavia's commercial interests while the agreement is in place. Unilateral Liberalization The general view is that the policy that contributes most to a country's economic output and income is the earliest possible removal of trade restrictions such as import quotas and tariffs, regardless of other coun- tries' actions. Political economy considerations have caused countries to liberalize more slowly and often on bilateral and multilateral bases. Because of the bilateral nature of aviation, unilateral liberalization, while removing barriers, carries with it the risk that the other coun- tries may allow their airlines to monopolize the bilateral markets. This would place the country that is liberalizing at a disadvantage unless the other country is credibly committed to liberalization. For this reason the unilateral liberalization of aviation regardless of the policy of other countries may not be the best policy for a reforming country. Liberalizing within an intergovernmental framework is likely to be less risky even if it is slower. Because of the network nature of efficient airline operations and the benefits of air markets being open to the more efficient airlines, a multilateral approach is the most desir- able one, although it is more difficult to achieve. The EU probably offers the best model. Adoption of the EU Single Air Market Principles The adoption of the EU single air market principles would remove all government-imposed economic entry barriers (as would Open Skies) but would, in principle, also provide greater flexibility in terms of ownership and control requirements. Any airline owned and control- led by nationals of a signatory country would be free to serve any route to and from Armenia. The notions of route rights and freedoms would disappear. The only regulatory approvals would be for safety, generally handled through the issuance and monitoring of an Air Operator's Certificate, along with associated permits, licenses, and so forth for airlines and staff registered in Armenia. No further permits 432 Part II: Detailed Analysis or licenses relating to economic regulation would be necessary. In such a liberalized policy environment an airline's assessment as to whether to provide a service would be based on the potential passenger and cargo markets both ways, as well as the fares and charges versus the costs of providing the services. If a service on the route is expected to be profitable, then the service is likely to be provided (and to continue to be provided); if it is not profitable, service would be suspended. The EC's statement on its aviation policy towards its neighbors (mentioned earlier in this section) suggests that the EC is unlikely to offer entry to its single air market to countries such as Armenia in the near future: its priorities are elsewhere (such as the United States and the Asia-Pacific region, where bilateral Open Skies and multilateral arrangements are in place). If such an equivalent arrangement could be negotiated with a regional or CIS grouping (as African countries have done, although with little evident effectiveness to date, with the Yamoussoukro Declaration concerning a single African air market), this would offer intrinsic benefits and would also increase the pros- pect of such an arrangement "joining" the EU single air market, pro- vided it is compatible with EU principles. Adoption of an Open Skies Policy for International Air Services An Open Skies policy would involve the government's stating that its aim, with the coming into force of new agreements, would be the removal of the following restrictions, provided Armenian airlines have reciprocal opportunities to compete: government limits on the number of airlines government limits on frequencies, schedules, capacities, and services offered by airlines requirements for airlines to "coordinate" activities pricing restrictions Competition between the airlines of the two countries would be regulated only by competition law in addition to normal safety and security laws. As a result, competition law would normally mean that interairline agreements in these markets would generally only be per- mitted if there were demonstrated net benefits to consumers. Chile pioneered this policy approach in 1979 (Attachment 8). The United States initiated its Open Skies model in the 1980s. Open Skies would be implemented by bilateral negotiations with partners. To communicate its policy stance, Armenia could consider joining the APEC-related Multilateral Agreement on the Liberalization of International Air Transportation.14 This agreement makes clear that Civil Aviation Policy 433 the restrictions listed above no longer apply. Airlines from signatory nations can act without any economic regulatory restraint in the air markets in these nations. Any nation that is a signatory to core inter- national treaties on aviation security can join the agreement. The key elements are outlined in Attachment 9. Bilateral negotiations to achieve full liberalization may be rapid: the bilateral partner agrees with the policy and a new ASA is agreed upon, literally by the exchange of faxes, e-mails, or diplomatic notes/ letters. Negotiations may also be slow: the partner only wishes for gradual implementation. In the latter case the government will need to decide on its tactics of balancing the long-term policy objective ver- sus protecting its interests in the short term (for example, by avoiding foreign foreclosure of the relevant Armenian air market). Staged or phased implementation is often the outcome of such balancing. Phased Liberalization There is obviously a wide range of possibilities although it is desirable that the long-term objective of the liberalization is clear. In addition to the inherent phasing that would probably occur in full liberaliza- tion because of the bilateral nature of the current arrangements, the government could communicate to bilateral partners that it would be willing, on a reciprocal basis, to immediately ease airline designation requirements and capacity and frequency restrictions. The multilateral Pacific Islands Air Service Agreement provides one approach. Three phases are included with the liberalization according to this agreement: Phase 1: When the Agreement comes into effect, signatory nations allow airlines of the signatory nations to have unrestricted access on routes between these nations; frequency, capacity, and pricing limits are removed. Phase 2: Six months after Phase 1, the Agreement becomes an Internal Single Aviation Market (ISAM), in which airlines can also exercise fifth freedom rights that allow signatory airlines to operate networks between signatory states. Ownership and control rules would be relaxed. Phase 3: Two years after Phase 1, the ISAM becomes a Full Single Aviation Market and Australia and New Zealand would become eligible to join. One practical policy for the government would be for it to state that each airline operating on each current air route could operate as many 434 Part II: Detailed Analysis frequencies as could be, or are, operated on the Yerevan-Moscow route (for example, three per day) without further capacity restrictions, pro- vided the aircraft is type-approved by the JAA/EASA15 or the equiva- lent. This could be coupled with the government endorsing a multi- airline policy on each ASA together with declaring a willingness to unilaterally grant fifth freedom rights. A more modest reduction in restrictions would be to offer each existing bilateral partner a daily frequency for each airline with no other capacity limitations, with immediate effect. This would allow CSA and Lufthansa, for example, to increase their services if it was commercially viable. It would also allow airlines to operate higher- capacity, wide-body aircraft during the peak season if the airline con- sidered that the demand warranted this. As with Lebanon, fifth freedom rights could be liberalized imme- diately, unilaterally. For example, Armenia could permit U.K. airlines to provide services on the Yerevan­Tashkent and Tbilisi­Yerevan mar- ket. The services would be provided only if the option was commer- cially viable and the agreement of the other country was forthcoming. The argument for this arrangement is that there would be benefits to Armenia in terms of increased services. The cost would be reduced bargaining power (for example, the cost of obtaining the right from the United Kingdom for Armavia to fly London­Los Angeles). We assess these costs as being small. First, the probability of receiving such rights is low outside of broader liberalization packages; second, the value to Armenia (and Armavia) is very low, because the addi- tional costs to Armavia of flying beyond London would be high com- pared with its competitors, and the effects on the Armenian economy from additional competition on the transatlantic market would be near zero. Effects of the Government-Armavia Agreement on Reform Options As discussed above, this agreement gives Armavia exclusive rights for a period of 10 years from March 2003 to operate the existing Armenian air rights, with the London, Vienna, and Brussels air routes being the noted exceptions. There is explicit provision for indemnities from the government for any actions that adversely affect the airline. The gov- ernment would need to be clear about any constraints this agreement would impose on the usual government freedom of action to remove regulatory impediments. These issues would require careful legal analysis, and any subse- quent policy decision should be constrained by the overarching policy aim of ensuring respect for property rights, including those given via contracts. Civil Aviation Policy 435 PROBLEMS WITH LIBERALIZATION The main arguments and concerns that are raised when liberaliza- tion is proposed for international aviation are the following: the risk of the loss of services to and from Armenia the related concern that Armenian-based carriers will be uncom- petitive the concern that opportunities for Yerevan hub development may be forgone These are related questions. In a liberalized market there is obvi- ously no guarantee that any airline will survive even as more services are provided in a growing market. Even in highly regulated markets commercial success is not guaranteed. As with any market, the greater percentage of new firms will either fail or remain small. Few will suc- ceed and grow substantially. As competition is introduced through reductions in government-imposed entry restrictions, incumbent air- lines may have to adjust by lowering costs, including employment costs. The overwhelming evidence is that the outcome of this process is better for customers and the economy than the outcome of highly regulated markets or markets dominated by state or private enterprises that are protected or inefficient. Employment in the aggregate is higher, even if the employment costs of the previously protected airlines come under pressure. With airlines, the risk of "nonentry" is not a major issue in a liberalized environment: AIA has shown that commercial airline operators are quick to exploit profitable opportunities. The bilateral approach also gives some advantages to incumbent airlines at their "home" airport (such as location of crews). These advantages may partially offset the higher costs at the partner airport and in the partner's airspace (a concern raised by Armavia in respect of Russia). The rules under the Chicago Convention that established the ICAO oblige member states to operate their air traffic services on a purely cost-recovery basis. In addition, countries are under obliga- tion not to discriminate between home and foreign carriers. Even so, the rules allow considerable flexibility in terms of cost allocation and charging structure. Maintaining restrictive ASAs is a costly mecha- nism for addressing this problem. Without regulatory impediments and with an "investment-condu- cive" business climate, entry to the airline business does not appear to be a problem. Airlines exist to serve commercially viable markets, and with liberalization markets are larger than they otherwise would be. Recent experience suggests that there are few, if any, economies of scale in airlines--certainly, fewer than was considered the case. Sunk 436 Part II: Detailed Analysis costs are low. Point-to-point services are competing very successfully with network carriers in the United States, Europe, and developing countries such as India. They are generally gaining market share at the expense of the legacy carriers. It is not clear whether the network carriers using hub airports will ultimately out-perform point-to-point carriers or vice versa. Only the latter have been consistently profitable in recent years, but they are now coming under pressure from new entrants. The LCCs have costs advantages, including higher aircraft utilization and higher employment productivity. The network carri- ers offer higher frequencies but require transfers, which often entail longer journey times for customers. There seems little reason why a well-managed, customer-focused, cost-effective Armenian airline would not be viable in a liberalized environment. The example of airBaltic is illustrative, as is AIA. We reiterate the point that such carriers would receive some protection (although a declining amount) as liberalization is implemented and other airlines respond to new opportunities (possibly including other Armenian carriers). There would a basic and growing point-to-point business. Well-run Armenian airlines would probably have a medium- term labor cost advantage but a fuel cost disadvantage. There is and will be considerable excess infrastructure capacity, although the air- lines and the CPEC are concerned about airport charges (this is dis- cussed further below). The ownership and control restrictions are a problem for countries with smaller capital markets and must disad- vantage airlines domiciled in these markets. However, the experience of AIA (and, indeed, Armavia) suggests that the problem is not insur- mountable. Beyond the assistance given by the home base and the assistance from the inevitable gradual withdrawal of regulatory protection, it is important, in terms of ultimately developing a liberalized air services market, that no further government assistance (whether fiscal, owner- ship, or regulatory) is given to local airlines. International experience has shown that such assistance or protection, no matter how well intentioned, usually results in management's losing focus on custom- ers, markets, and competitors, and concentrating instead on ensuring continued government assistance. The withdrawal of protection or assistance is often difficult to achieve so that the costs to the economy continue longer than expected. Protected firms rarely prosper on a self-sustaining basis. Transit Traffic Depending on the quality and pricing of the airlines and the infra- structure compared to that of other locations (such as Vienna, Cairo, Istanbul, or Dubai), transit traffic may or may not develop. The mar- Civil Aviation Policy 437 ket for transit traffic is inherently competitive compared to point-to- point markets. Success depends on an effective combination of airline and infrastructure services as well as a sound location. Successful air- lines generally determine whether an airport becomes a hub rather than vice versa: Vienna/Frankfurt and Brussels/Zurich are contrast- ing examples. In the latter cases considerable investment in the infra- structure has delivered a lower than expected payoff because of weak- nesses in the airlines compared to their competitors. The Role of Competition Law Incumbent airlines often argue that they will be at risk for increased predation in a liberalized environment. International experience sug- gests that the increase in competition resulting from liberalization has required competition authorities to respond appropriately but few real problems have arisen, despite many concerns about predation (such as pricing being below an airline's [avoidable] costs in order to reduce competition). It is generally recognized that predation is more of concern with state-owned commercial entities, including airlines. Although issues of jurisdiction have to be addressed, given the inher- ent international status of aviation, agreements between the competi- tion authorities in the countries at either end of a particular market are generally adequate to address this problem. We understand that the Armenian competition law offers the usual protection in the form of a prohibition against the abuse of a dominant market position to distort competition. The competition authorities con- sider that there may be a jurisdictional problem in the law in terms of the Armenian international aviation markets. Jurisdiction could be reviewed if there is indeed a problem, although the authorities have advised that there is also a CIS agreement covering anticompetitive behavior that they can utilize. We acknowledge that the risk of predatory behavior is higher with state-controlled airlines such as Aeroflot; there- fore, ensuring that the law is robust is desirable. There are also suitable bilateral arrangements for addressing any jurisdictional concerns. Safety Safety regulators may be faced with a greater number of airlines entering (and exiting) the air markets. Issues concerning the fund- ing of the regulators together with their efficiency and effectiveness are likely to arise. Generally, airlines are willing to pay cost-related charges for cost-effective regulatory services. It would be desirable if government budgetary and civil service rules recognized this fact and allowed a well-performing, transparent, and accountable safety regulator a greater degree of autonomy in regard to the remuneration 438 Part II: Detailed Analysis of key technical staff and overall budgets. Contracting out may be a viable least-cost option for ensuring that specialized regulatory skills are available. One aspect of accountability is a requirement for the safety regulator to consult with airlines concerning its business plan- ning, resourcing, rule making, and general enforcement policies. ARMENIAN AVIATION INFRASTRUCTURE Infrastructure costs (airports and air traffic control [ATC]) can make up 10 percent or more of an airline's costs. Ensuring an effective home base assists a locally domiciled airline. Alternatively, if the "home" airport delivers poor value for money, a home base makes it more difficult for local carriers to survive and prosper. Local carriers can be advantaged or disadvantaged by local infrastructure performance, as it often uses more of those services than the foreign carriers do. The local airlines usually face higher unit costs at foreign airports than the foreign airlines face at their home airports (for example, because relatively low usage of those airports would not usually qualify for volume discounts, and the use of an airline's ground handling serv- ices is uneconomic). The Zvartnots Airport concession places limits on real core aero- nautical charges (landing, parking, passenger, and so forth) but these charges can be adjusted to allow the airport to earn a 20 percent internal rate of return (post tax) on the funds invested in the airport over the life16 of the concession.17 The airport manager is required to modernize the airport and is implementing an investment program that will significantly increase capacity and service quality over the next three years. The funds invested in the airport will rise by some US$35 million from this first tranche of investment. The concession agreement will thus allow the company to seek to increase charges to earn the allowed return on the enlarged investment. The incentives for the airport manager will be to set airport charges that will maximize profits, given the expected demand, subject to the 20 percent cap on rate of return. The airport passenger charge (of US$11 currently)18 would generate the bulk of the airport's revenue, but other areas are likely to be subject to new or increased charges. The recent debate over the increase in the kerosene charge by the air- port as the monopoly supplier (under the concession) is an example. If the 20 percent allowed rate of return is above the airport's cost of capital then the airport will have an incentive to increase the funds invested up to the point at which further allowed charge increases would no longer be profitable.19 The concession provides for the air- port's investment plan to be specified in a master plan for the airport. This plan needs government approval. The government, then, is in the Civil Aviation Policy 439 usual position of an economic regulator of having to take a position on the value of a proposed airport investment that will avoid the pos- sible overinvestment risks posed by the allowed rate of return. This assessment is difficult in the absence of the full output-related pricing of airport services. The government would have to use public sector cost-benefit analysis as a core assessment tool to inform its reaction to the airport's proposals. The airport passenger charge, given the additional government departure levy of approximately US$28 per passenger and other charges to airlines, may raise questions about whether attempting to pass on all costs to airline customers would be a commercially viable strategy in the short term. That is, the restriction on pricing from the concession may not be binding in the near term. The expected traffic volumes are the critical uncertainty and volumes will be affected by both the total cost of using the airport and the restrictiveness of the civil aviation reg- ulatory regime. It is noteworthy that the Latvian government recently abolished its approximately US$15 per passenger departure charge at Riga airport in an attempt to boost the Latvian air market.20 Managing the Zvartnots concession will be a challenge for the government. It is desirable that the Concession Agreement and com- petition law operate in a consistent manner to ensure the following conditions: All parties (airport and airlines in particular) are clear as to their rights and obligations in terms of airport infrastructure services and charges thereon. Commercial arrangements between the infrastructure service providers and customers are encouraged to the extent possi- ble and that the master plan for the development of the airport services arises out of this process rather than vice versa. This would allow a better sharing of risk and would improve incen- tives for the best possible business decisions, thereby increasing the chances that airport investments are customer driven. There is a clear government policy on airport pricing under, and consistent with, the concession, developed after consulta- tion with the airport and customers. Among other things, this policy could cover how the government will assess revisions to the master plan, its expectations as to the airport's consultations with airlines and other interested parties, the way in which the government will approach the issue of demand projections, the relevant cost and revenue basis, and the expectations as to the frequency of price adjustments. The last issue bears on whether the government would wish to have the concession operate more as a price cap with its stronger incentive properties rather than purely on a rate-of-return basis. 440 Part II: Detailed Analysis The concession agreement also gives Yerevan Airport exclusive rights on Armenian non-CIS air links. This is an undesirable restraint on trade. Interairport competition has been shown to deliver benefits to airlines, to customers, and to the economy. However, as it is a term in the concession, the agreement of the airport manager would have to be obtained to change this restraint. GOVERNMENT DECISION-MAKING PROCESSES Sound and transparent government decision-making processes for future Armenian civil aviation policy should lead to better policy formulation and implementation. The first step would seem to be the development of a government policy on international civil avia- tion. This is now under way. Such a policy should be consistent with the government's overall development strategy. To ensure the own- ership of such a policy by interested parties to the extent possible, this policy should be developed openly, both within and outside of government. Government departments with interests in economic development, international linkages, and tourism should also be involved, along with consultation with such key parties as airlines and the airport, to ensure an economy-wide perspective. The Czech Republic case study (see Attachment 6) highlights the fact that government economic agencies played an important part in developing and implementing Czech international aviation policy. Once the policy is finalized, following the consideration of and responses to the consultation, the most appropriate agency needs to be tasked with implementing the policy and to be held accountable accord- ingly. As the issues involved in implementing the policy will often require government input, it would be desirable to have the ongoing involvement of these other agencies in advising the government. We understand that a commission chaired by the GDCA already exists to address some aviation issues. This commission's mandate could be extended to cover international civil aviation policy. The commission could be tasked with developing a strategy for implementing the gov- ernment's policy and reporting the progress of the implementation. CONCLUSIONS International aviation policy is a strategic issue for the government. The evidence suggests that landlocked countries have lower per capita incomes. It also suggests that air transport can give isolated countries Civil Aviation Policy 441 a comparative advantage in high value goods compared to countries closer to major markets. The evidence also indicates that current policies result in relatively expensive air services. It is unlikely that LCCs would be attracted to serving the Armenian market. These facts emphasize the importance of making sure that government policies do not impede growth of Armenia's international commercial air links. Armenia has relatively poor connectivities and capacities for inter- national aviation. While the outlook is toward growth as the demand grows, the performance could be better. The current government pol- icy, both regulatory and commercial, contributes to poor performance. The benefits to be gained from liberalization appear significant. The costs of liberalizing, apart from problems with the agreement with Armavia, would be low. Unilateral liberalization has risks and the EU single air market model may be difficult to implement. A policy approach along the lines of an Open Skies liberalization offers the highest return to Armenia. With the government's priority of sustained high rates of economic growth, the analysis and evidence suggest that the government should adopt the objective of eliminating government-imposed economic entry bar- riers to Armenia's air markets as soon as possible, provided Armenian airlines have reciprocal opportunities to compete. The development of a strategy to renegotiate the agreement with Armavia to ensure that the desired civil aviation policy can be imple- mented may need to be part of the initial work program for aviation policy. It is likely that, even if the government adopts full liberaliza- tion on a reciprocal basis as its policy, the practicality of implementa- tion will give significant protection to Armavia over the medium term. In addition, given the small size of the markets and the size of the aircraft operated, the addition of capacity, even when permitted, will be incremental, albeit important. There is no guarantee that services will be provided in a liberalized environment: rather, services will depend on the underlying commer- cial viability and on customer demand. Generally, however, outputs are higher in liberalized situations than in highly regulated alterna- tives. Compared to the liberalization of other markets, the inherently gradual approach to liberalization in international aviation will enable the government to better monitor developments. The Dutch case study cited earlier suggests that there are advan- tages to being the "first mover" in liberalization. This may be impor- tant in the region. The EU expansion and the spread of Open Skies agreements (like that between India and the United States) signal increasingly competitive air services markets internationally. It is important that airlines are exposed to competitive pressures as early as possible so that they can take advantage of the opportunities 442 Part II: Detailed Analysis resulting from liberalization, rather than needing protection from it, in view of the much higher costs to the economy of protection. Well-managed incumbent airlines will clearly recognize both the opportunities and threat arising from liberalization and will change their organizations so as to take advantage of the opportunities and, importantly, to manage the increased risks. Zvartnots Est./ Scheduled Actual Est./ Actual Sample WINTER 2005 aircraft Sched. check-in Check-in Actual aircraft Flight No Destination Code Airline type time start end Desk time type Remark D9 664 ROSTOV ROV AEROFLOT-DON, JSC TU-154 30, 11:45 30, 08:44 30, 11:31 02, 11:45 DELAYED U8 516 MOSCOW DME ARMAVIA AIRCOMPANY LTD A-320 30, 18:05 30, 15:05 23 31, 20:00 BOARDING U8 510 MOSCOW DME ARMAVIA AIRCOMPANY LTD A-320 31, 09:45 31, 06:45 31, 19:59 31, 20:15 DELAYED International A U8 991 NOVOSIBIRSK OVB ARMAVIA AIRCOMPANY LTD A-320 31, 11:35 CANCELED Departure CPN 7917 TEHRAN THR CASPIAN AIRLINES TU-154 31, 13:00 31, 10:04 31, 13:18 03, 13:00 DELAYED ttachment MI 6338 MIN.VODY MRV KAVMINVODYAVIA SAC TU-134 31, 15:00 CANCELED SU 194 MOSCOW SVO AEROFLOT-RUSSIAN AIRLINES OJSC TU-154 31, 16:15 31, 13:14 31, 15:48 31, 17:10 TU-154M S7 906 MOSCOW DME SIBERIAN AIRLINES, OJSC TU-154 31, 16:55 31, 14:03 31, 16:43 31, 20:00 BOARDING 9D 324 KAZAN > KZN PERM AIRLINES FSUE TU-134 31, 18:00 31, 15:05 31, 17:35 31, 22:00 DELAYED 9D 324 > PERM PEE PERM AIRLINES FSUE TU-134 31, 18:00 31, 15:05 31, 17:35 31, 22:00 DELAYED 1 Civil Board U8 516 MOSCOW DME ARMAVIA AIRCOMPANY LTD A-320 31, 18:05 31, 15:05 12,22 31, 20:15 DELAYED Airport, U8 5011 ISTANBUL IST ARMAVIA AIRCOMPANY LTD A-320 01, 00:30 31, 21:30 3,4 ON TIME Aviation U8 5011* ISTANBUL IST FLY AIR A-320 01, 00:30 31, 21:30 5,6 ON TIME U8 825 ODESSA ODS ARMAVIA AIRCOMPANY LTD A-320 01, 00:35 31, 21:35 17,18,19 ON TIME U8 347 ALEPPO ALP ARMAVIA AIRCOMPANY LTD A-320 01, 02:30 31, 23:30 10,11,12 ON TIME Policy SU 192 MOSCOW SVO AEROFLOT-RUSSIAN AIRLINES OJSC TU-154 01, 04:55 01, 01:55 17,18,19 ON TIME 443 Riga 444 International Part Riga to Amsterdam DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT II: Detailed 1234567 07:10 08:30 KL1320 F70 Amsterdam Airport Schiphol 1-3-5-7 07:20 08:40 BT611 735 Amsterdam Airport Schiphol 1234567 13:50 15:10 KL1324 F70 Amsterdam Airport Schiphol January Analysis Riga to Berlin A DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT Airport ttachment 1234567 10:05 10:50 EZY4596 319 Berlin--Schönefeld Airport -----6- 13:10 14:00 BT211 AR7 Berlin--Tegel Airport 2005 12345-7 18:05 18:55 BT211 735 Berlin--Tegel Airport Riga to Brussels Departure 2 DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 12345-7 07:30 09:15 BT601 AR7 Brussels International Airport Company Riga to Cologne DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 12345-7 07:00 08:15 BT227 735 Cologne/Bonn Airport Board, Note: Under "Days" number 1 refers to Monday, 7 to Sunday. Riga to Copenhagen DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 1234567 07:00 07:30 BT131 735 Copenhagen--Kastrup International Airport 1234567 13:20 13:50 BT135 735 Copenhagen--Kastrup International Airport 1234567 18:10 18:40 BT139 735 Copenhagen--Kastrup International Airport Riga to Dublin DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT -2-4-6- 22:55 00:10 BT661 735 Dublin Airport Riga toFrankfurt DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 1234567 13:40 15:10 LH3247 AR8 Frankfurt Airport Civil 1234567 22:10 22:30 FR4373 738 Frankfurt-Hahn Airport Riga to Geneva Aviation DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT -----6- 06:25 08:15 BT641 735 to 26.03 Geneva International Airport Policy Riga to Hamburg DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT -----6- 11:05 11:55 BT251 735 Hamburg Airport 445 12345-7 13:30 14:10 BT251 735 Hamburg Airport Note: Under "Days" number 1 refers to Monday, 7 to Sunday. 446 Riga to Helsinki DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT Part 12345-- 07:30 08:40 BT301 F50 Helsinki--Vantaa Airport 12345-7 11:20 12:35 AY3124 AT7 Helsinki--Vantaa Airport II: -----6- 12:10 13:25 AY124 AT7 Helsinki--Vantaa Airport Detailed 1234567 13:50 15:00 AY3128 AT7 Helsinki--Vantaa Airport 12345-- 17:45 18:55 AY3126 AT7 Helsinki--Vantaa Airport Analysis 12345-7 18:05 19:15 BT305 F50 Helsinki--Vantaa Airport Riga to Kiev DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 12-45-7 13:30 15:15 BT402 AR7 Kiev--Boryspil State International Airport Riga to London DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 1-3-567 09:10 10:10 BA881 320 London--Heathrow Airport ---4--- 10:45 11:45 BA881 320 London--Heathrow Airport 1234567 16:05 17:05 BT651 735 London--Heathrow Airport 1234567 22:50 23:25 FR2643 738 London--Stansted Airport Riga to Manchester DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 1-3-5-- 13:00 13:55 BT671 735 Manchester Airport Note: Under "Days" number 1 refers to Monday, 7 to Sunday. Riga to Milan DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT -2-4-67 13:00 14:55 BT701 735 Milan--Malpensa Airport Riga to Minsk DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 1-3-5-7 13:20 14:35 BT412 F50 Minsk National Airport Riga to Moscow DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 1--4-6- 07:00 09:50 SU184 TU5 Moscow--Sheremetyevo Airport 12-45-7 11:00 13:40 BT502 735 Moscow--Sheremetyevo Airport Riga to Munich DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT Civil 1234567 16:30 17:50 LH3248 CR7 Munich International Airport Riga to New York Aviation DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT ---4--7 12:40 15:30 HY101 763 New York--John F Kennedy I. A. Policy Riga to Oslo DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 12345-7 20:00 20:35 BT151 735/AR7 Oslo Airport 447 Note: Under "Days" number 1 refers to Monday, 7 to Sunday. 448 Riga to Prague DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT Part 1234-67 07:00 08:00 OK883 735 Prague--Ruzyne Airport 12345-7 15:15 16:10 OK881 735 Prague--Ruzyne Airport II: Riga to St. Petersburg Detailed DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 1-3-5-7 20:00 20:35 BT443 F50 Pulkovo International Airport Analysis Riga to Stockholm DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 1234567 07:40 07:50 BT101 735 Stockholm--Arlanda Airport -----6- 16:10 16:15 BT109 AR7 Stockholm--Arlanda Airport 1234567 17:20 17:35 FR1963 738 from Stockholm--Skavsta Airport 21.02 12345-7 18:15 18:20 BT109 AR7 Stockholm--Arlanda Airport Riga to Stutgart DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 1-3-5-7 17:35 19:05 BT295 AR7 Stuttgart Airport Riga to Tallinn DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 12345-- 07:45 08:40 BT311 F50 Tallinn Airport 12345-- 19:40 20:35 BT315 F50 Tallinn Airport Note: Under "Days" number 1 refers to Monday, 7 to Sunday. Riga to Tampere DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 1234567 19:40 20:50 FR2734 738 Tampere--Pirkkala Airport Riga to Tashkent DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 1---5-- 11:15 19:05 HY102 763 Tashkent--Yuzhny Airport Riga to Vienna DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 1-3-567 07:30 08:35 BT231 AR7 Vienna International Airport 1234567 15:00 15:50 OS694 CR1 Vienna International Airport Riga to Vilnius Civil DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 12345-- 08:30 09:25 BT341 F50 Vilnius International Airport Aviation 12345-- 17:00 17:55 BT343 F50 Vilnius International Airport Riga to Warsaw Policy DAYS DEPARTURE ARRIVAL FLIGHT NR AIRCRAFT NOTE AIRPORT 1234567 14:35 14:55 LO784 ER4/E70 Warsaw--Frederic Chopin Airport Note: Under "Days" number 1 refers to Monday, 7 to Sunday. 449 450 Part II: Detailed Analysis Attachment 3 Part 1: Armavia Route Schedule (Winter 2004­05) Region Destinations Weekly Frequency Middle East and Gulf Aleppo 1 Europe Amsterdam 1 Russian Federation Anapa 2 Asia Ashkhabad 1 Europe Athens 1 Middle East and Gulf Beirut 1 Middle East and Gulf Dubai 2 Russian Federation Yekaterinburg 1 Ukraine Kiev 1 Russian Federation Krasnodar 3 Russian Federation Min-Vodi 3 Russian Federation Moscow (Dom) 20 Russian Federation Nizhniy Novgorod 1 Russian Federation Novossibirsk 4 Ukraine Odessa 1 Europe Paris 2 Russian Federation Rostov 2 Russian Federation Saint Petersburg 1 Russian Federation Samara 1 Russian Federation Min-Vodi 3 Russian Federation Moscow (Dom) 20 Russian Federation Nizhniy Novgorod 1 Russian Federation Novossibirsk 4 Ukraine Odessa 1 Europe Paris 2 Russian Federation Rostov 2 Russian Federation Saint Petersburg 1 Russian Federation Samara 1 Ukraine Simferopol 1 Russian Federation Sochi 4 Europe Istanbul 2 Russian Federation Stavropol 2 Asia Tashkent 1 Middle East and Gulf Tehran 2 Russian Federation Volgograd 1 26 routes 62 Civil Aviation Policy 451 Part 2: Armavia Route Schedule versus Its Obligations in the Investment Agreement Guaranteed network of routes Region Destination Frequency Number of routes Frequency Asia Ashkhabad 1 No requirement Asia Tashkent 1 TOTAL 2 Europe Amsterdam 1 Western and Eastern Europe Europe Athens 1 Europe Paris 2 Europe Istanbul 2 TOTAL 4 6 4 10 Middle East and Gulf Aleppo 1 Middle East and Gulf Middle East and Gulf Beirut 1 Middle East and Gulf Dubai 2 Middle East and Gulf Tehran 2 TOTAL 4 6 3 6 Russian Federation Anapa 2 Russia Russian Federation Yekaterinburg 1 Russian Federation Krasnodar 3 Russian Federation Min-Vodi 3 Russian Federation Moscow (Dom) 20 Russian Federation Nizhniy Novgorod 1 Russian Federation Novosibirsk 4 Russian Federation Rostov 2 Russian Federation Saint Petersburg 1 Russian Federation Samara 1 Russian Federation Sochi 4 Russian Federation Stavropol 2 Russian Federation Volgograd 1 TOTAL 13 45 10 25 Ukraine Kiev 1 Ukraine Ukraine Odessa 1 Ukraine Simferopol 1 TOTAL 3 3 2 5 Comment: This data suggests noncompliance for Europe and Ukraine in terms of the Investment Agreement. 452 Part Key II: Air Detailed Features Coordination between Government Multiple or single Limitations on the Limitations of airlines on services and intervention No. Country Date of signature airline designation number of seats offered frequencies offered prices on air fares Service Analysis 1 Austria February 2002 Single. n.a. 7 flights per week. The designated Double A airlines shall agree approval between themselves regime. on the tariffs to be of ttachment charged in respect of Agreements the agreed services. Main 2 Belgium June 2001 Multiple: each n.a. 1 weekly is allowed. Tariff shall be Double contracting party has established by each approval the right to designate of the designated regime. 4 Armenia one or more airlines airlines, if possible (Art. 3, Clause 1). after consultation between those airlines (Art. 13, Clause 1). Coordination between Government Multiple or single Limitations on the Limitations of airlines on services and intervention No. Country Date of signature airline designation number of seats offered frequencies offered prices on air fares 3 Czech Multiple, in Yes. If a designated Four flights per Neither regulator Double Republic principle. At the airline of one week. A third flight will require their approval same time, unless country wishes may be introduced designated airlines to regime. explicitly agreed to change type at any time. Czechs consult other airlines otherwise between of aircraft to one plan to do so in before filing tariffs the regulators, there with higher seating spring (end of off- for approval, nor shall be no more capacity, it shall season). will they prevent than one designated request permission such consultation airline from each from the regulator (Art. 13, Clause 4). country for each of other country Designated airlines individual route (Art. 14, Clause 4). of one country shall (Article 3, Clause 1). Narrow-body aircraft take into account only approved at the interests of Civil this stage. other country's airline so as not to affect unduly the Aviation services that the latter provide on the whole or part of the Policy same routes (Art. 14, Clause 2) 453 454 Part II: Detailed Coordination between Government Multiple or single Limitations on the Limitations of airlines on services and intervention No. Country Date of signature airline designation number of seats offered frequencies offered prices on air fares Analysis 4 Germany May 1998 Multiple (Art. 3, To ensure fair and In the initial phase n.a. Double Clause 1a). equal treatment the frequencies approval of any designated are limited to two regime. airline, the frequency, weekly services the type of aircraft (Route Schedule, to be used with Clause VI). regard to capacity, as well as flight schedules shall be subject to approval by respective aeronautical authorities (Art. 8, Clause 4). Coordination between Government Multiple or single Limitations on the Limitations of airlines on services and intervention No. Country Date of signature airline designation number of seats offered frequencies offered prices on air fares 5 Greece December 1994 Single (Art. 3, Clause The capacity to be Current agreement The designated Double 1). provided (including is for two flights per airlines shall agree approval frequency of services week. between themselves regime. and the type of on the tariffs to be aircraft to be used charged in respect of by the designated the agreed services airlines of the (Art. 12, Clause 2b). contracting parties on the agreed services) shall be agreed upon by the aeronautical authorities upon Civil recommendation made by airlines. The airlines shall make such Aviation recommendation after due consultations Policy between themselves (Art. 11, Clause 5). 455 456 Part Coordination between Government II: Multiple or single Limitations on the Limitations of airlines on services and intervention Detailed No. Country Date of signature airline designation number of seats offered frequencies offered prices on air fares 6 Iran January 2001 Multiple (Art. 3, The capacity to be 3 weekly flights are The designated Double Clause 1). provided (including allowed. airlines shall agree approval Analysis frequency of services between themselves regime. and the type of on the tariffs in aircraft to be used respect of the agreed by the designated services (Art. 10, airlines of the Clause 2b). contracting parties on the agreed services) shall be agreed upon by the aeronautical authorities upon suggestion made by airlines. The airlines shall make such suggestion after due consultations between themselves (Art. 8, Clause 5). Coordination between Government Multiple or single Limitations on the Limitations of airlines on services and intervention No. Country Date of signature airline designation number of seats offered frequencies offered prices on air fares 7 Kazakhstan September 1999 Multiple. Respective The designated Double aeronautical airlines shall agree approval authorities regulate between themselves regime. the capacity and on the tariffs to be frequency of flights charged (Art. 11, (Art. 6, Clause 3). Clause 2). 8 Lebanon September 1998 Multiple. The capacity 1 weekly flight. The capacity to be Double provided by provided shall be approval designated airline of agreed between regime. one party together the airlines and with the capacity approved by provided by the the aeronautical Civil designated airline authorities (Art. 5, of the other party Clause 5). shall be maintained Aviation The tariffs shall, if in reasonable possible, be agreed relationship. upon between the designated airlines Policy (Art. 8, Clause 2). 457 458 Coordination between Government Multiple or single Limitations on the Limitations of airlines on services and intervention Part No. Country Date of signature airline designation number of seats offered frequencies offered prices on air fares II: 9 Netherlands November 1999 Single. The airline 2 weekly flights. The tariffs shall be Double designated by one agreed between approval Detailed party shall notify designated airlines regime. the aeronautical (Art. 6, Clause 2). authorities about the frequency, Analysis type of aircraft, configuration, and number of seats (Art. 9, Clause 1). 10 Russia October 1993 Multiple; Russia has The airline The tariffs shall, if Double designated Aeroflot designated by one possible, be agreed approval and Siberia. party shall notify upon between the regime. the aeronautical designated airlines. authorities about (Art. 13, Clause the frequency, 2). If not agreed, type of aircraft, each airline would configuration, and determine tariffs number of seats (Art. in its own way 14, Clause 1). but no and upon its sole approval or veto in discretion. The ASA. The 2004 seat clause above calls limit was 135,000. for cooperation and coordination only in cases when it is possible. Coordination between Government Multiple or single Limitations on the Limitations of airlines on services and intervention No. Country Date of signature airline designation number of seats offered frequencies offered prices on air fares 11 Syrian Arab December 2001 Single. The capacity to The designated The tariffs shall, Double Republic be provided at airline of one party if possible, be approval the outset shall be shall provide to established by regime. agreed between the aeronautical mutual agreement both contracting authorities of by the designated parties before the the other party airlines of both agreed services are information parties (Art. 14, inaugurated (Art. 3, regarding the Clause 2). Clause 4). nature of services, timetables, and types of aircraft, including capacity (Art. 14, Clause 5). 1 weekly flight is allowed. Civil 12 Turkmenistan August 1993 Multiple (Art. 3, The capacities of The designated The tariffs shall, if Double Clause 1). each of the parties airline of one party possible, be agreed approval should be equal, shall provide to upon between the regime. Aviation unless otherwise the aeronautical designated airlines agreed to by authorities of (Art. 6, Clause 2). the aeronautical the other party authorities (Art. 14, information Policy Clause 4). regarding the nature of services, timetables, and types of aircraft, including capacity (Art. 15). 459 460 Part Coordination between Government II: Multiple or single Limitations on the Limitations of airlines on services and intervention No. Country Date of signature airline designation number of seats offered frequencies offered prices on air fares Detailed 13 Ukraine June 1995 Multiple (Art. 3, Capacities are The tariffs, if Double Clause 1). defined by mutual possible, shall approval agreement between be agreed upon regime. Analysis the contracting between the parties (Art. 11, designated airlines Clause 4). (Art. 12, Clause 2). 14 United February 1994 Multiple (Article 4, Armenian approval Up to seven services The designated Double Kingdom Clause 1). is needed on per week; three are airline of one approval and Northern specific aircraft to operated. country shall take regime. Ireland be operated, but into account the in theory any U.K. interests of the airline could seek designated airlines of to operate any size the other country so aircraft they wish. as not to affect unduly the services that the latter provide on whole or part of the same routes. Note: The fifth freedom rights are not granted or stipulated in any of the ASAs. In all ASAs there is an ownership and control requirement; that is, the regulator shall have the right to withhold authorization if the ownership and control requirement is not satisfied. Civil Aviation Policy 461 Attachment 5 Case Study: Latvian Civil Aviation Policy* L atvia has a population of 2 million. With the breakup of the Soviet Union, Latvia, like Armenia and other FSU states, had an inte- grated service that comprised the airline, the airport, and air traffic control (ATC). Riga Airport was handling around 2 million passengers a year at that time. The air markets were entirely within the USSR, all operated by Aeroflot. The high volumes of air travel resulted from the extraordinary low air fares charged by Aeroflot (11 rubles, US$6, for a Moscow-Riga round trip). Air fares were below economic costs. The assets of all aspects of the aviation services were run down and service quality was low. REBUILDING INFRASTRUCTURE AS THE INITIAL PRIORITY The Latvian government was heavily constrained in terms of financial resources. In a period of rapid change and adjustment, the govern- ment's initial priority was to restore the aviation infrastructure, which included allowing and requiring the Latvian state airline, operating Aeroflot legacy equipment initially, to pay its own way. Relatively high charges were introduced at Riga Airport: US$15 per departing passenger, similar to the charge at the much more expensive Stock- holm Airport. The airport and ATC were set up separately as joint stock state-owned enterprises (SOEs). Formally, the shares are held by the Minister of Transport on behalf of the government. Today, separate units in the Ministry of Transport advise the Minister on ownership versus regulatory/policy issues. The aviation infrastructure has developed considerably and is up to EU standards. There is ample capacity for the foreseeable future. Cost competitiveness has become a concern. As a consequence, the departure charge was abolished on November 1, 2004. In addition, the airport introduced volume discounts for airlines. These discounts are published and can amount to 80 percent for the largest volume operators--currently, airBaltic and Ryanair. *This case study describes conditions and policies as of 2004. 462 Part II: Detailed Analysis LATVIAN AIRLINES Air Baltic, the state airline, went bankrupt in 1995. The company was resurrected as airBaltic, majority owned by the government but with a "strategic" partner, SAS, with 47 percent of the shares. Initially air- Baltic operated as a small feeder service into SAS hubs using only six aircraft. Over the last few years it has transformed itself into a larger operator in the style of the U.K.-based easyJet company and has been focusing on an LCC model with both Riga and Vilnius as bases. However, airBaltic only acquired the LCC "workhorse" Boeing 737s in significant numbers in 2004. AirBaltic has operated at a profit from since 2001­02 and reported a LVL 1.1 million profit on sales of LVL 33.5 million and assets of LVL 15.8 million in fiscal 2003.21 With regard to the long-term ownership of airBaltic, it seems that the government would like to divest its shareholding. It is also understood that SAS would like to increase its holding. However, the government and airBaltic are concerned with the ownership and control requirements in Latvian non-EU ASAs: Russia is the obvious example. Although it is accepted that many countries are now treating these requirements in a flexible manner, Latvia is concerned that such "good will" is required on a continuing basis and may have a "price." To avoid this, Latvia would have to ensure that "ownership and control" would remain in Latvian hands if the government shares were privatized. This might be both costly and restrictive in the small Latvian capital market. AirBaltic considers that its costs are now below those of easyJet but still above Ryanair. This is partly a scale factor, but Ryanair, in their view, has the advantage of better prices for infrastructure serv- ices (that is, Ryanair holds auctions among airports for new services and often achieves net payments for new services). AirBaltic has a small labor-cost advantage for nonpilot staff, reflecting lower Latvian labor costs. AirBaltic does not have the aircraft utilization that Ryanair has, partly because of its different aircraft mix and partly because it flies into hubs such as Heathrow and Copenhagen where rotations are inevitably lower. Although airBaltic does not believe that there are offsetting margins from passengers from services to such airports, presumably they would not operate such services if this were not the case. Overall, however, airBaltic, with very little regulatory protection, has cost fundamentals that are close to best practice. GOVERNMENT INTERNATIONAL AVIATION POLICY (IAP) The emphasis on developing infrastructure, with the consequential effects on the cost base (mainly fixed and sunk), has led the govern- ment to have a bias towards measures that would stimulate the growth Civil Aviation Policy 463 in traffic to boost the revenue of the infrastructure services. Thus, the government has attempted to negotiate liberal rather than restrictive air service agreements. Operating within its Law on Aviation, Latvia, for example, accepted a liberal agreement with the United Kingdom in 1992. This agreement permitted multiple designations of airlines by each country, unlimited frequency/capacity, and a requirement for the double disapproval by governments of air fares (a more liberal arrangement, given that it would be difficult to get two governments to agree to disapprove an airline proposal). Fifth freedom rights were given to both parties. Latvian airlines first developed the London mar- ket with services to Gatwick Airport. Although these services eventu- ally ceased, British Airways entered the market with daily services to the better-connected Heathrow Airport where the slot values are very high.22 AirBaltic now also offers daily services to Heathrow. The bilateral agreements with the Scandinavian countries were more restrictive, reflecting the countries' focus on SAS and their objec- tive of developing Stockholm and Copenhagen as hub airports. Thus, in contrast to the U.K. ASA, only single designation of an airline was allowed by either party. In addition, only one city (that is, airport) was allowed to be served. No fifth freedom rights were included. Impor- tantly, however, airline cooperation was discouraged in the ASAs. The ASA with Germany was one of the first negotiated. Essentially because of German requirements, it was much more restrictive. While it allowed for two airlines on each side, it did so only because the Ger- man government needed to accommodate a Hamburg-based airline. Otherwise, it was a single designation agreement specifying a maxi- mum of 8 weekly frequencies to one point in Germany. A renegotia- tion in 1996 reduced the restrictions slightly, increasing the frequency limit to 14 as demand increased, adding more city points that could be served (Berlin, for example), and adding fifth freedom rights. The Austrian ASA was more restrictive again, and the Latvian government could not get a French agreement to open negotiations. These agreements and those with other EU members have been overtaken by Latvia's accession to the EU, with the consequential adoption of essentially Open Skies policies along with the more liberal EU-wide ownership and control requirements.23 Once Latvia was to join the EU, it was obvious that LCCs would be both a threat to and an opportunity for Latvian economic development. Market stimula- tion from more services and lower prices was clearly seen to benefit the Latvian economy, particularly the developing tourism market. Incumbent airlines such as airBaltic would have greater exposure to competition, and home-base cost disadvantages would become a major issue. On the other hand, Latvia still does not have an ASA with Russia. An initial ASA has been negotiated but never formally signed. The 464 Part II: Detailed Analysis initialed agreement is very restrictive. It inherently requires air serv- ices to be agreed between airlines and then by the respective govern- ments. This allows and encourages the air market to be controlled by a monopoly, albeit with two airline parties and subsequent government endorsement. (It is worth noting in passing that competition law in Latvia does not cover international aviation markets.) The outcome is restrictive: seven frequencies a week to Moscow by airBaltic and Aeroflot (the latter operates only four frequencies, currently). Recently the airlines agreed to a daily frequency to Saint Petersburg. In contrast, Latvia's agreements with Ukraine and Belarus are simi- lar to the U.K. ASA described above. A factor in these countries has been the weakness of their respective airlines. This is also the position with Bulgaria, but not with Romania, where attempts continue to be made by the government to strengthen the incumbent state airline by retaining regulatory restrictions in the market. Cargo is unrestricted, as are charters. Cargo is generally handled entirely by belly-hold capacity in the passenger aircraft. OUTCOMES Outputs measured in terms of aircraft movements and passengers have grown steadily since the mid-1990s (see Table 13.3 below). Growth in recent years has accelerated dramatically with airBaltic alone report- ing a 75 percent increase in passengers carried in the first nine months of 2004, compared to the same period in 2003. Airfares in the competi- tive markets have dropped significantly. It is not clear how sustainable the increased supply is. Load factors are barely 50 percent on aver- age. There may be supply adjustments by the less competitive airlines unless demand continues to grow rapidly. Current volumes, however, are still below the (abnormal) levels experienced in the years immediately prior to the collapse of the USSR. Thus the last 15 years have seen a dramatic and ongoing reo- rientation of the Latvian air markets toward the less regulated and more commercial markets with Europe. Deregulation has allowed the commercial development of the market, particularly delivery of the benefits from the LCC innovation. Well-managed Latvian carriers sug- gest that local airlines can survive and develop in such environments. Air links with the economically important but regulatory constrained Russia remain poor and massively underdeveloped. Civil Aviation Policy 465 Table 13.3 Passenger Throughput, Riga Airport, 1990­2005 Year Numbers (thousands) 1990 2,200 1991 1,828 1992 341 1993 310 1994 392 1995 491 1996 497 1997 531 1998 555 1999 562 2000 574 2001 623 2002 633 2003 712 2004* 1,000 2005* 1,500 * Indicates estimate and forecast, respectively. Source: Latvian Civil Aviation Policy 466 Part II: Detailed Analysis Attachment 6 Case Study: Czech Experience with Aviation Liberalization THE SITUATION Since the Czech Republic's accession to the EU, the government has had a fully liberal international aviation policy (IAP) with respect to EU markets. However, the Czech government had been liberalizing international air services since the collapse of the Soviet Union and the ending of the communist regime in the Republic. For example, the Czech Republic signed one of the first Open Skies agreements with the United States in 1996. It has effective Open Skies agreements with Lebanon, the United Arab Emirates, and Jordan. It has managed to achieve the introduction of "multi-designation" clauses in many bilateral ASAs so that each country can nominate as many airlines as it wishes to operate services in that bilateral market. For example, this was achieved with France in 1990 and the United Kingdom in 1998. It also aims to remove any restrictions on routes, frequency, and capacity. The Czech Republic also seeks the ability to grant the fifth freedom rights allowed for in ASAs. For example, the Czech ASAs with the United Arab Emirates and Sri Lanka allow Czech airlines to carry Dubai-Colombo passengers. The Czechs also seek to have what is usually regarded as a relatively liberal price-setting regime, namely, "double disapproval"24 of air fares, rather than the more restrictive "double approval" regime where each fare change must be approved by both government parties to the ASA. In spite of this the Czech Republic has a number of restrictive bilateral ASAs--for example, with Russia, Ukraine, Turkey, Romania, and Arme- nia. This illustrates the point that in international aviation, liberalization requires bilateral agreement. The Czech Republic-Russia bilateral ASA limits the number of airlines (one from each country--CSA [Czech Air- lines] and Aeroflot currently). It further limits the markets that can be served (only four cities in Russia) and the capacity that can be offered. Capacity is currently limited to 14 frequencies per week for CSA and 7 for Aeroflot in the Prague-Moscow air market, with substantial code- sharing by Aeroflot using CSA aircraft. The two airlines are required to come to a commercial agreement in respect of services actually offered, given those permitted by the then-current ASA. This reinforces the Civil Aviation Policy 467 already strong incentive to the two airlines to act as a monopoly and to restrict capacity below the level that would otherwise be offered by the two, generating higher prices and profits as a result. (Public policy and law in virtually all other markets outlaws such monopolization and price fixing for that reason.) Such requirements for commercial coopera- tion have been quite common in ASAs internationally, with the excep- tion of those involving the United States, where antitrust law had early application to international aviation. Even without such requirements, the incentives for collusion are high where ASAs are restrictive and if international air service markets are excluded from competition law, or if such law is ineffective. THE MARKETS The Czech Republic's international air markets in aggregate have grown rapidly since 1994.25 Outputs measured in terms of passengers and passenger-kilometers (p-km) have almost tripled since then and are expected to have done so by the end of 2004. Cargo has grown less rapidly, reflecting the Russian economic crisis in the late 1990s and the improved competitiveness of land transport in the period leading up to, and after, EU accession. Outputs at Prague Airport have been growing by 35 percent per year in recent years. And the airport has developed a significant transfer passenger business: over 10 percent of passengers are now in transit. As a comparison, 34 percent of travelers through London's Heathrow airport are in transit. The presence in the Czech Republic markets of LCCs, including the Czech Republic-domi- ciled Smartwings, along with EastJet, is solid and visible evidence of liberalization and the benefits to customers, Czechs, and visitors. The key data are summarized in Table 13.4. Table 13.4 Czech Airline Data, 1999­2003 Czech airlines only 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Passenger 1,622 1,805 1,916 2,104 2,328 2,850 3,450 3,894 4,243 4,531 (thousands) Passenger/km 2,581 3,029 3,148 3,502 3,671 4,335 5,855 6,383 6,882 7,081 (millions) Cargo 26 33 26 27 56 30 38 29 32 41 (million tons/km) All passengers 2,818 3,278 3,919 4,508 4,716 4,945 5,696 6,241 6,431 7,737 (thousands) 468 Part II: Detailed Analysis CZECH AIRLINES Czech Airlines (CSA) has coped with the introduction of competition. It is a very different airline from the one operating in the late 1980s. It now has modern equipment and operates to best practice standards. CSA is effectively a state-owned airline, substantially owned by gov- ernment banks and investment funds. It operates broadly on a break- even basis with a small profit in 2003. In spite of significantly increased competition, it is maintaining market share on routes containing tradi- tionally strong competitors. An examination of CSA's 2004­05 winter schedule shows an extensive network including approximately 35 daily connections to hub airports, with linkages to Paris's Charles-de-Gaulle Airport being particularly important. This reflects CSA's membership in the Delta-Air France Sky Team alliance. Travel Service is a privately owned charter airline. With the Czech Republic joining the European Civil Aviation Area, and in anticipation of EU accession, the Travel Service established Smartwings as an LCC. POLICY The Czech Republic does not have a formal policy statement of its approach to international aviation policy. Authorities pointed out that in the immediate period after the end of World War II, Czechoslovakia operated what could be regarded as a nonrestrictive policy by inter- national standards. Under the communist governments a more tradi- tional restrictive policy was followed. With the collapse of the Soviet Union, the Czech Republic moved rapidly toward a less restrictive approach. This reflected the liberalizing tendencies of the new govern- ment in the Czech Republic and a desire to open up rapidly to the West by building maximum international linkages. There was an awareness of the significant tourism potential of the Czech Republic. Governments saw that this could be best achieved by a less restrictive IAP, and CSA was unable to defend a completely restrictive policy. It must be noted that CSA does obtain some assistance via higher prices from being the main beneficiary of the restrictive ASAs that have been in place and are likely to be in place for some time to come (for exam- ple, the Russian ASA). POLICYMAKING PROCESS In developing negotiating positions for the Czech Republic, the authorities are strongly guided by the requests of Czech airlines, pre- dominantly CSA to date. In respect of developing or expanding new Civil Aviation Policy 469 markets the airlines are expected to approach the other government to obtain the necessary approvals. The Czech government would expect to be approached only after negotiations had been undertaken to the furthest extent by the airlines. Prior to seeking talks with the bilateral partner country, a proposed negotiating strategy would be developed by the Ministry of Transport and circulated to interested ministries for their views. These ministries usually comprise Foreign Affairs, Finance, Industry, Regional Development (with a particular interest in tourism), and the Civil Aviation Authority. A governmental nego- tiating position emerges from these consultations and discussions. With substantial progress in liberalization, the Civil Aviation Author- ity's focus in regard to IAP has increasingly been on safety and security issues. This is in line with developments in other developed countries. Understandably, much of the effort is now undertaken in EU forums. The Czech Republic is heavily involved in the ICAO process and EURO- CONTROL26 and, in line with international best practice, implements ICAO rules and recommendations regarding safety and security. INFRASTRUCTURE Czech aviation infrastructure in the form of airports and air traffic control is not regarded as an impediment to the development of avia- tion in a liberalized market. The international airports are SOEs with a high degree of autonomy devolved to the boards of the enterprises. They are developing in line with the expected demand and are man- aging to keep their charges well below the European average while improving service quality. CONCLUSION The Czech Republic has for several reasons moved from a restrictive to a relatively open IAP since the late 1980s. There remain several important restrictive ASAs to the east and southeast of the Repub- lic. The air services markets, where restrictions have been lifted or removed, have grown relatively fast with considerable benefits to consumers and the Czech economy. The Czech air service providers have expanded but, as in any competitive market, ongoing pressure will be placed on them by other EU-domiciled airlines that may be able to offer services more cost-effectively or to offer service combina- tions with better value for money. But there is little doubt given this experience that the desired services will be provided as the market changes and grows. Costs will continue to evolve toward least-cost levels with the impetus being driven by LCCs. 470 Part II: Detailed Analysis Attachment 7 Case Study: Bulgarian International Aviation Policy BULGARIA'S APPROACH TO INTERNATIONAL AIR SERVICES NEGOTIATIONS OVER THE LAST DECADE AND HOW BILATERAL AIR SERVICES AGREEMENTS HAVE CHANGED Over the last 10 years bilateral ASAs have not changed substantially. They are still based on the Chicago Convention principles. Since 1990 a multiple designation clause has been used instead of single designation. Multiple designations mean that each of the contracting parties may designate one or more carriers to operate scheduled air services on the routes specified in the ASA. Single designation means only one carrier. To date, none of Bulgaria's bilateral contracting parties has designated a LCC to operate scheduled air services to Bulgaria and vice versa. In the view of the Bulgarian authorities, the LCC's philosophy and mar- keting behavior is oriented toward the kinds of services that counter- balance scheduled operation's traditions and practices. The agreements between Bulgaria and the following countries have a multiple designa- tion clause: Azerbaijan, Armenia, Bahrain, Belarus, Georgia, Iran, Ire- land, Kazakhstan, Korea, Latvia, Macedonia, Maldives, Moldova, Rus- sia, the Slovak Republic, Uzbekistan, Ukraine, South Africa, Croatia, Algeria, the United Kingdom, Ghana, Ethiopia, Zambia, Zimbabwe, Cuba, Lebanon, Luxembourg, Nigeria, Singapore, Syria, Sudan, Tanza- nia, Tunisia, Turkey, Finland, France, Austria, Greece, Albania, Serbia and Montenegro, and the United Arab Emirates. Since 1997, some new clauses have been included in ASAs such as security clauses and code-sharing clauses. A few agreements contain a provision for fifth freedom traffic rights, but on a strict reciprocal basis. The ASA with Austria contains such a clause. Other fifth free- dom provisions have been agreed through memorandums of under- standing (MoUs) or exchange of letters (for example, with Iran, the United Arab Emirates, the Maldives, Macedonia, and Albania). This traffic right is basically granted on a portion of a route and requires the explicit consent of a third country involved. For instance, a Bulgarian carrier that operates Sofia-Skopje on third- and fourth-freedom traffic rights wishes to extend the service to Tirana and to take passengers from Skopje to Tirana and vice versa. That could only happen when Civil Aviation Policy 471 both Macedonian and Albanian authorities grant such a right. In this case Albania is a third country with respect to the bilateral agree- ment between Bulgaria and Macedonia. In the view of the Bulgarian authorities, the fifth freedom right is usually granted on a case-by- case basis, has operational character, and involves market and politi- cal considerations. This is why it is obtained by virtue of confidential MoUs or letters rather than by bilateral agreements. It helps carriers to optimize aircraft capacity, to increase load factors, and to advertise and sell two or more portions of a service as a through service (that is, seamless service). Intergovernmental negotiations on airline capacity and frequency still ensure allocations on the basis of fair and equal opportunities for designated carriers of both sides, as well as on the basis of market demand (that is, designated carriers are required to prove the "public need of air transportation"). The partner governments usually agree on the maximum number of weekly frequencies irrespective of the size of aircraft or seats available. However, over the last three or four years, and especially after Bal- kan Airlines ceased operations, the main Western European carriers increased their capacity and frequencies to and from Bulgaria (see Table 13.5). This was affected mainly through MoUs signed between aviation authorities. Thus, despite equal opportunities, the real capacity offered by those carriers exceeds that of their Bulgarian competitors. Those are the maximum rights granted and used, irrespective of the size of aircraft or seats available. That is, airlines have scheduled services to the maximum that the bilateral agreements permitted. Alternatively, Bulgaria and its main air market partners negotiated for what the airlines wanted to fly. LH and AUA were granted the right to increase their services because none of the Bulgarian carriers oper- ated to Germany and Austria in 2001 and because the traffic demand Table 13.5 Weekly Frequencies of Air Services Offered Carrier 1994­95 2001­02 2002­03 2004­05 Alitalia 3 11 10 11 British Airways 4 7 7 7 Lufthansa (LH) 4 21 21 21 Austrian Airlines (AUA) 3 18 21 21 Air France 4 7 7 7 CSA 3 6 9 11 Malev 3 7 9 9 Olympic 3 6 7 9 LOT (Polish company) 1 7 7 7 472 Part II: Detailed Analysis on these destinations had always been very high. In addition, their fares, reflecting their level of service, are also high; therefore, in prin- ciple whoever enters the respective market at a later stage (using the Bulgarian rights) and offers cheaper services should be successful in terms of load factor, profit, etc. This was the case on the Sofia­Vienna route when Bulgaria Air and Viaggio entered the market, and it was the reason why AUA's share fell in 2003 despite AUA's much greater frequencies than those of their Bulgarian competitors. The above serv- ices contain no fifth freedom traffic right--they are third and fourth freedoms. According to the Bank Settlement Plan, data for market shares in terms of revenue, passenger traffic, and tickets sold are as follows (Table 13.6): Table 13.6 Market Shares Carrier June 2001 (Percent) 2003 (Percent) Austrian Airlines 16 9.82 Lufthansa 16 16.25 Air France 13 n.a CSA 11.9 10.66 Alitalia 9.8 n.a Malev 9.3 n.a Bulgaria Air 0 16.86 The Bulgarian CAA and the Ministry of Transport and Communi- cations have elaborated a strategy for the development of air trans- port in Bulgaria. It is available on the CAA Web site or through the Transport Policy Directorate at the Ministry. The CAA does not have an English translation. ASAs do not deal with charter or cargo services. In respect of an air fare approval mechanism, this is typically "dou- ble-approval"--that is, both governments need to approve a new air- fare before it can be offered. Only the ASA with Bosnia and Herze- govina contains a "double-disapproval" clause. Bulgaria Air is a 100 percent state-owned company. It will be pri- vatized soon. It is not an LCC but is a traditional scheduled operator. Other main airlines are as follows: Scheduled: Hemus Air and Viaggio Charter: Bulgarian Air Charter, Air Via, and Balkan Holidays Air Mainly cargo: Air Sofia and Vega Airlines Civil Aviation Policy 473 With regard to ownership and control provisions, this matter is regulated by bilateral agreements. After accession to the EU, Bulgarian airlines will be regulated by the European Community Law (commu- nity carriers will be majority owned and effectively controlled by EU nationals). Any Bulgarian carrier that wishes to operate scheduled services should comply with the requirement of majority ownership and control contained in bilateral ASAs (up to EU accession). For char- ter or cargo operations, there is no such requirement. The process of EU accession preparations started in 1998­99 with the harmonization of primary and secondary legislation. In 2003 Bul- garia finalized technical negotiations with the European Community on Chapter 9, which was provisionally closed. Until accession, Bul- garia will continue adopting new European Community air transport acquis, the JAA requirements, and the EASA regulations. 474 Part II: Detailed Analysis Attachment 8 The Policy of Open Skies in Chile BACKGROUND At the end of the 1970s, Chile started to make profound changes to its economic structure, promoting a social market economy system based on private ownership of the means of production, private initiative, and social harmony, as elements necessary for the economic develop- ment of the country. In this context, Executive Order 2.564 was issued in 1979, confirming the so-called Open Skies policy in our country. This policy is based on the following fundamental principles: Free entry into markets The power to grant commercial air permits was repealed, since it was considered that these are granted directly by the act that allows both Chilean and foreign airlines to operate freely in the country, provided that they comply with insurance requirements and technical/operational safety requirements. As an exception, the Junta de Aeronáutica Civil de Chile (JAC) may restrict foreign airlines in the following cases: i) if their country of origin applies restrictions to Chilean airlines (bilateral reciprocity) ii) if the foreign airline operates on a route which is restricted by another country for Chilean airlines and it is considered that such restrictions are significantly affecting Chilean airlines (optional power and at the judgment of the authority). Freedom of prices Airlines are permitted to freely establish tariffs. They only have to register them with the JAC. The authority does not have power to set and object to prices. As an exception, the JAC can set tariffs if the authority of the other country does not accept the freedom of tariffs; this situation has never occurred in practice. Within Chile, there is a totally open system in operation. When all the tariffs were set by the authority, lower tariffs were not achieved and competition was avoided. The tariff levels were proposed by the airlines and were gen- erally accepted by the authority, since it did not have access to the actual cost basis of the airlines. Civil Aviation Policy 475 Minimum intervention by the authority This is reflected in the following: i) The markets are competitive, with the advantages of quality and prices that this implies. ii) Air transport services were moved totally to the private sector; iii) The authority was debureaucratized when irrelevant procedures and controls were removed. It was thus possible for airlines to quickly modify their operations whenever they needed to and only the technical implications were checked. LIBERALIZATION OF THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK The harmony between Article 1, paragraph 1, of Executive Order 2.564 and Articles 4, 5, and 10 of the same Executive Order ensures adherence to the principle of free entry into the market. Chilean and foreign airlines will be able to establish domestic, international, scheduled, or nonscheduled passenger or cargo air transport services, as well as specialized aerial work services, without limitations with respect to aircraft, title held on it, capacity offered, places of operation, frequency of services, itineraries, and tariffs, and without the need for further approval by the commercial air authority other than insurance requirements and the technical/operational safety requirements. Furthermore, freedom of tariffs is one of the basic assumptions of the social market economy, and it is thus being applied in air trans- port. Executive Order 2.564 repealed the powers of the JAC to set tariffs and these were left to be set freely by each airline. At first, tariffs rose, but then they were quickly stabilized with competition until they stayed at normal levels. Nevertheless, Article 2, paragraph 4, of Executive Order 2.564 establishes that in cases where the JAC has not set tariffs, the airlines will have to register with that authority the tariffs that they will apply. The purpose is to give transparency to the market by keeping a public record of tariffs. Finally, minimum intervention by the authority is reflected by the fact that Executive Order 2.564 did not grant the JAC extensive powers to intervene in markets, except on an ad hoc and specific basis--that is, to check insurance and to negotiate reciprocity. If the international air traffic rights are restricted by another country and if there is more than one Chilean airline interested in exercising the same rights, Executive Order 2.564 establishes that there should be a call for tenders for these rights on the basis only of money tenders, without any other consideration by the JAC. The objective is to avoid subjective evaluations in assigning routes. 476 Part II: Detailed Analysis EFFECTS AND EVOLUTION In order to see what the effects have been of the Open Skies policy applied by Chile, it is useful to differentiate what has occurred domes- tically from what has occurred internationally. Domestic Domestically, the policy of absolute freedom to enter into markets and set prices has been maintained. This has made it possible to expand domestic traffic from 800,000 passengers in 1989 to 2,900,000 passen- gers in 2002--an increase of 255 percent and with an annual average growth rate of 11 percent. Air cargo increased by 225 percent in the same period, with an annual average growth rate of 10 percent. The number of services departing from Santiago increased from 100 per week in 1989 to around 364 per week at the end of the last century. This means that it more than tripled in this period. International Internationally, in all bilateral negotiations, the Chilean aviation authority offers and promotes extensive and unrestricted openness, which is not always shared by other countries. Since 1989, the gov- ernment has been intensifying efforts to obtain greater openness with other countries, in order to create greater opportunities for Chilean airlines through negotiations between aviation authorities, on the basis of economic complementation agreements signed by Chile. This has helped to increase Chile's international traffic from 957,000 passengers in 1989 to 3,066,000 in 2002--a 221 percent increase with an annual average growth rate of 10 percent. International air cargo measured in tonnes has increased in the same period by 207 per- cent, with an annual average growth rate of 9 percent. The number of international services increased from 104 in 1989 to 329 in 2000. This means that supply tripled. In spite of the strong competition that has existed between Chilean and foreign airlines on Chile's international routes, Chilean airlines increased their international passenger traffic; participation, also measured in terms of passengers, increased too. Furthermore, there are presently 15 foreign airlines with 134 services per week competing in Chile's market. Chilean airlines presently have 148 international services per week, in comparison with the 47 that they had in 1989. International cargo traffic (tonnes) of Chilean airlines increased by 162 percent, with an annual growth rate of 8 percent. Civil Aviation Policy 477 Attachment 9 Multilateral Agreement on the Liberalization of International Air Transportation* W ith the purpose of promoting Open Skies air services arrange- ments, the Multilateral Agreement on the Liberalization of Inter- national Air Transportation was negotiated on October 31­November 2, 2000, at Kona, Hawaii, and signed in Washington, DC on May 1, 2001, by Brunei Darussalam, Chile, New Zealand, Singapore, and the United States. The Agreement entered into force on December 21, 2001. A Protocol to the Agreement was also negotiated and was signed in Washington, DC, on May 1, 2001, by Brunei Darussalam, New Zea- land, and Singapore. The Protocol provides for parties to exchange seventh freedom passenger and sabotage rights. The Protocol entered into force on December 21, 2001. The key features of the Multilateral Agreement are as follows: an open route schedule open traffic rights including seventh freedom cargo services open capacity airline investment provisions that focus on effective control and principal place of business, but protect against flag of conven- ience carriers multiple airline designation third-country code-sharing a minimal tariff filing regime The Agreement is open to accession by any state that is party to the following aviation security conventions: the Convention on Offences and Certain other Acts Committed on Board Aircraft, done at Tokyo on Sep- tember 14, 1963; the Convention for the Suppression of Unlawful Seizure of Aircraft, done at The Hague on December 16, 1970; the Convention for the Suppression of Unlawful Acts against the Safety of Civil Aviation, *This attachment is copied from the Web site for the Multilateral Agreement on the Liberalization of International Air Transportation: www.maliat.govt.nz. 478 Part II: Detailed Analysis done at Montreal on September 23, 1971; and the Protocol for the Sup- pression of Unlawful Acts of Violence at Airports Serving International Civil Aviation, done at Montreal on February 24, 1988. The Web site for the Multilateral Agreement is also used to give notice of the following: For the Agreement: accessions to the Agreement designation of airlines any exercise of the right to withhold, revoke, suspend, limit, or impose conditions on the operating authorization of an airline nonapplication of the Agreement as between any parties amendments to the Agreement withdrawals from the Agreement For the Protocol: expressions of consent to be bound by the Protocol reservations with respect to the grant of sabotage rights nonapplication of the Protocol as between parties amendments to the Protocol withdrawals from the Protocol The New Zealand Government is the depositary state for the Agree- ment and Protocol. Annex 13.1 Yerevan, Riga, Tallinn, and Larnaca Airlines--CRS MIDT Yield Analysis CONTEXT The Armenian government has a restrictive bilateral access policy for aviation. Latvia and Estonia started to liberalize a few years ago and have been totally open for intra-EU flights since EU accession on May 1, 2005. Cyprus has been largely open for many years due to a focus on tourism industry needs. The objective of this study, as per the agreed Terms of Reference, is to compare yield data (average fare divided by distance) for key EU markets to/from these four countries. Acquisition of CRS Data CRS MIDT passenger bookings data has been acquired and analyzed for the following selected markets: 13 mainly EU markets to/from YEREVAN, ARMENIA (EVN) 11 mainly EU markets to/from TALLINN, ESTONIA (TLL) 11 mainly EU markets to/from RIGA, LATVIA (RIX) 13 mainly EU markets to/from LARNACA, CYPRUS (LCA) The markets were selected according to these criteria: The largest EU markets by nonstop capacity were all included. Airports with no nonstop capacity to EVN and other airports are included if they are high in the normal "pecking order" of EU 479 480 Part II: Detailed Analysis airports and likely to have significant 1-stop flows, despite the absence of nonstops (for example EVN­BRU). Most of the markets selected are above 1,400 kilometers in order to reduce the yield-distorting impact of shorter distances (but this impact will still need to be addressed). For London traffic, Heathrow (LHR) was selected.* EVN­Moscow data was also acquired due to importance of this market. A pair of key non-EU markets, Dubai and New York (JFK), was acquired for EVN, RIX, TLL, and LCA. Each airport pair comprises the following data: Trip Origin and Destination Airports Annual passenger bookings Premium Booking (first) Class 2 Booking (business) Class 3 Booking (full economy) Class 4 Booking (discount economy) Average fare Premium Booking (first) Class 2 Booking (business) Class 3 Booking (full economy) Class 4 Booking (discount economy) Total passenger bookings Industry average total fare per airport pair Yield per revenue passenger kilometer Data for two time periods were bought: The most recent time period is May 1, 2004­April 30, 2005. A previous time period was bought for comparative purposes: May 2002­April 2003. CRS MIDT data: comprises traffic bookings acquired from a computerized reser- vations system (CRS) is adjusted for all CRS bookings (under an agreement between all CRS providers) *Key nonstops from London to EVN, RIX, and LCA have in recent years all served LHR. But TLL has been served from Gatwick (LGW): our data do not capture that flow. Since Estonia and Latvia joined the EU, low-cost service not booked via CRS has been added from Luton (LTN) and Stansted (STN). Our data show the impact of this on yields at LHR. Civil Aviation Policy 481 is adjusted for no-shows (bookings that do not result in travel) is largely not adjusted for non-CRS bookings by Internet or direct purchase from a carrier excludes all taxes from the fare computation What is the reliability of CRS MIDT data? The answer varies by market. For the data acquired here, we estimate: Yield data is fairly reliable. Volume data is not reliable, as non-CRS bookings are common in our target markets. --There are extensive bookings via pre-CRS methods like visiting an airline office. --There are extensive bookings via post-CRS methods such as carrier Internet sites. The volume data in several EVN markets is clearly understated. However, the yield data corresponds to all other available informa- tion about EVN markets (including known BA or other pricing) and is fully credible. Box 13A.1.1 Sequence of Data in Excel File Raw data EVN, RIX, TLL,LCA raw data for two selected 1-year periods Target data As above, organized by market by month Target summary Annual summaries Cluster summary Summaries per 3-month period for EVN, RIX, TLL, and LCA: · to/from eight key EU airports: LHR, CDG, AMS, BRU, FRA, DUS, VIE, and FCO · to/from LHR only Fare chart Fare vs. distance for sample of 2,000 marketsa Yield chart As above, by yield a. It should be pointed out that the sample of 2,000 markets or the fare versus distance analysis does not include domestic U.S. or intra-Western Europe data, where the full impact of low-cost carriers has been most felt and fares are much lower. The fare versus distance chart should be seen in relation to a recent U.S. DOT report, which showed that the average fare for a 1,600 kilometer (1,000 mile) trip has dropped 20 percent in the past 5 years and is now US$118, well below the fare for that distance in our chart. 482 Part II: Detailed Analysis In the attached Excel file, the data is arranged in the following sequence of sheets, progressing from raw data to user-friendly format- ting of the material: The reason for the last two charts is to facilitate average fare and yield comparisons on a distance-adjusted basis: EVN markets generally feature greater distances than the RIX, TLL, and LCA markets (even after our attempt to select longer- haul markets from the non-EVN points). It is therefore vital to adjust for the distance differential, by fac- toring in by how much yields per kilometer should be lower as distance increases. RESULTS What does the MIDT data show? The key tables to focus on are the Cluster Summary. They allow yield analysis comparison along these dimensions: differences between EVN, RIX, TLL, and LCA over time by 3-month period over time for May 2002­April 2003 versus May 2004­April 2005 for just LHR, or LHR/CDG/AMS/BRU/FRA/DUS/VIE/FCO combined. The Fare and Yield Charts (at end of the Excel file) should be con- sulted simultaneously with the analysis of the Cluster Summary. The reason is that average yield must be looked at only in relation to dis- tance, due to the very substantial efficiency gains in operating cost per kilometer as an aircraft travels a progressively greater distance. The Cluster Summary invites close perusal and analysis. The data show that: EVN yields have been largely higher than for the other three markets LHR­RIX and ­TLL have had some LCC-induced yield declines since EU accession LCA yields have been consistently lower throughout the periods analyzed. Here are some of the key findings, factoring in the distance adjust- ment, for LHR only: Civil Aviation Policy 483 Table 13A.1.1 Key Findings, LHR Only What fare "should be" Fare in last Compared to Fare in Compared to (US$ as 12 months "should be" Feb.­April "should be" LHR only per chart) (US$) (%) 2005 (US$) (%) EVN 350 388 11 over 323 7.7 under TLL 233 197 15.5 under 206 11.5 under RIX 225 163 27.5 under 78 65 under LCA 333 201 39.6 under 197 40.8 under Here are comparable findings, factoring in distance adjustment, for the eight key EU cities: Table 13A.1.2 Key Findings, Eight EU Cities What fare "should be" Fare in last Compared to Fare in Compared to (US$ as 12 months "should be" Feb.­April "should be" EU cities per chart) (US$) (%) 2005 (US$) (%) EVN 333 355 6.6 over 377 13.2 over TLL 225 209 7.1 under 287 27.5 over RIX 200 178 11 under 171 14.5 under LCA 312 202 35.2 under 197 36.8 under EVN fares have been generally: over the "should be" level higher in relation to the "should be" level than the three other airports There is just one exception to each of these generalizations: In the February­April 2005 quarter, EVN-LHR fares dropped below the "should be" level. However, they did so by much less than the LHR fares to the other three points. In the February­April 2005 quarter, TLL to/from eight cities fares soared and so were further above the "should be" level than EVN. What were some of the trends over time? 484 Part II: Detailed Analysis Box 13A.1.2 Impact of Ryanair on the Market Ryanair entered the London­Riga route (RIX­STN) on November 1, 2004, six months after the accession of Latvia to the EU. Ryanair passengers book mainly on the Internet and so are not shown in our MIDT data. However, a good estimate of Ryanair volumes and yields on RIX­STN can be obtained from how it operates elsewhere. The capacity offered by Ryanair is a daily flight with a 189-seat Boeing 737- 800. The system load factor of Ryanair in 2004 was 83 percent (slightly higher at 84 percent in May 2005). Applying the 83 percent load factor, Ryanair's annual passenger volume on RIX­STN would be 114,515 per year. It is unlikely to be much different from this number. Ryanair's average yield has been running at about 4 U.S. cents per kilometer. Applying this 4 cents per kilometer to the STN­RIX 1,659 kilometer distance, Ryanair will charge an average of about US$66 per one-way fare (probably less, as the distance is above Ryanair's aver- age and so yield per kilometer is likely to be lower). This compares with a US$55 average fare network-wide fare on Ryanair. US$55 is also (coincidentally) the fare to which the LHR­RIX fare had dropped for network carrier traffic in the MIDT data, in the last month of our sample (April 2005). In general, the markets surveyed showed yield increases from the first to the second one-year period. EVN yields rose by somewhat less but not enough to significantly change its high-yield status in the group. One noteworthy change is the substantial drop in RIX­LHR yield in the last surveyed quarter. This is the direct result of Ryanair entering the Stansted­Riga market late last year. This report addresses yields much more than volume, due to inabil- ity to get at volumes reliably. It is nevertheless of interest to estimate the impact of Ryanair on the market (Box 13A.1.2). Riga yields have in effect embarked on a path towards Larnaca yields. In the near future, further LCC incursions into both TLL and RIX from not only London but also other western European cities are likely to further depress yield and stimulate traffic. In discussion with the government of Armenia, the points to high- light could pivot around the observation of EVN yield versus the other three markets in the last quarter surveyed: The numerical values of EVN versus TLL and RIX yields per RPK are apparently quite similar. But this is hugely misleading. EVN is at about double the distance, so yield per distance should be much lower. In effect, passengers to/from EVN are paying a very large penalty for the distance that they should not have to pay. Civil Aviation Policy 485 Figure 13A.1.1 Average Fare 1,200 series 1 log (series 1) 1,000 800 600 US$ 400 200 0 0 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 2,500 3,000 3,500 4,000 4,500 5,000 kilometers Figure 13A.1.2 Yield by Distance 0.50 yield 0.45 log (yield) 0.40 0.35 kilometer) 0.30 per 0.25 cents 0.20 (U.S. 0.15 0.10 yield 0.05 0.00 0 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 2,500 3,000 3,500 4,000 4,500 5,000 distance (kilometers) 486 Part II: Detailed Analysis LCA yields are clearly much lower. One might expect this result in a tourism market with large volumes. Again this would be very misleading. Cyprus is a large tourism market because of a concerted, multipronged hotel, infrastructure, and airline indus- try effort over many decades. It is not just a question of beaches, as that does not explain why tourists flock to Prague, Singapore, or many other places. Armenia has strong tourist (and other price-sensitive) potential that will very likely not be realized if the pace of liberalization and level of air fares is consistently more aggressive in other countries. The findings of this report are consistent with other evidence on the impact of airline industry liberalization and deregulation. NOTES 1. This chapter was prepared by Douglas Andrew, World Bank. 2. With 47 percent of the shares owned by Scandinavian Airline Systems (SAS). 3. It is generally considered that the United Kingdom's concern about the competitiveness of U.S. airlines with U.K. airlines immediately after the end of World War II resulted in these protective arrangements which have endured up to the present. The concerns of the immediate postwar period can be regarded as a variant of the usual "infant industry" argument for protection. Sixty years later many airlines, benefiting from the remaining restrictions, still use elements of these arguments to resist liberalization and competition. 4. Austria as a member of the EU would only be able to agree to a change that covers all EU carriers. 5. As is noted above, the EU is requiring member countries to change this provision in ASAs to cover any airline owned and controlled by an EU member. 6. American International Airports. 7. See Attachment 7 for details. 8. However, any Armenian airline would have to obtain slots at Heathrow. Qantas was reported recently as buying two pairs of slots (landing and take- offs) for US$36 million (Gatwick or Stansted Airports would be alternative, much cheaper airports). In spite of this, airBaltic does operate into Heathrow using, it is understood, slots provided by SAS. See Attachment 5. 9. We understand that there have even been examples of travelers flying from Armenia to London and then to Tashkent via Yerevan and returning the same way. 10. The list of the 59 countries with which the United States has Open Skies agreements can be found at www.dot.gov/aviation. Uzbekistan and Civil Aviation Policy 487 the United Arab Emirates have such agreements, for example. India and the United States have recently agreed on an Open Skies agreement. South Africa and the United States are in talks on such an agreement. 11. That is, there are none of the restrictions mentioned in Box 13.1, but there are the usual ownership and control restrictions. 12. Noting that the airlines are all actually foreign owned, it could be argued that the actual gross economic welfare gain to Armenia is the total of US$6 million plus the savings to existing passengers, a further US$50 million (approximately US$50 per ticket multiplied by 1 million passengers). 13. Collusion to fix prices directly or indirectly is usually per se illegal under competition law. 14. MALIAT, www.maliat.govt.nz. The United States, Singapore, Chile, and New Zealand are the main current signatories. 15. Joint Aviation Authorities, European Aviation Safety Agency. 16. Thirty years, but the term can be adjusted as another mechanism for allowing the airport to earn its return. 17. We understand that the concessionaire also has taken over the respon- sibility for servicing the debts associated with the EBRD loan that was used to finance the airport cargo facility. 18. There is a separate government charge on departing passengers of approximately US$20. 19. In regulatory economics this is called the "Averch-Johnson" effect after the two American economists who identified the effect as a consequence of rate-of-return regulation of U.S. utilities. See, for example, Spulber (1989), p. 287. 20. See Attachment 5. The United Arab Emirates recently imposed a depar- ture charge of Dh 30 (US$4) per passenger. 21. www.airbaltic.com. AirBaltic leases most of its aircraft. 22. QANTAS recently won an auction to buy 4 slot pairs at Heathrow for US$36 million. 23. EU replaces national ownership and control. 24. This means that both governments that are party to a particular ASA would have to disagree with an air fare for it to be blocked. Even this require- ment has costs, given the desirability of no restrictions beyond competition law once government economic entry barriers are removed. 25. The Czech authorities informed us that there are data problems prior to 1994. For example, the Slovak Republic and the Czech Republic were formed as separate countries in 1993. 26. http://www.eurocontrol.int/corporate/public/subsite_homepage/ index.html. Chapter 14 Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness SUMMARY Why Knowledge? Armenia's Growth Paradox (Section 1) Knowledge has always been an essential element for progress in economies and societies.1 In today's global economy, knowledge has become an even more decisive factor in competitiveness, growth, and wealth. What could be called a "knowledge revolution" has been trig- gered by the conjunction of several global trends that have created new opportunities for access and use of knowledge and information. What could and should a landlocked, low-income country with an educated population do to exploit new opportunities associated with the knowledge revolution? Armenia stands out from other FSU countries (and some would say, from the rest of the world) by a peculiar blend of the follow- ing five features that are of particular relevance to knowledge-based competitiveness:2 A significant annual inflow into the labor force of motivated people who value knowledge and higher education. Armenia's private higher education (although of a predictably low quality) is one of the most vibrant sectors of the economy. A large stock of highly educated population yet with largely obsolete specialized skills. In the former USSR, Armenia spe- cialized in R&D, and, all the tribulations of the past 12 years notwithstanding, Armenia still boasts a critical mass of human capital that sustains a culture that values knowledge. However, this stock has been eroded recently owing to emigration, a low level of public spending on education, and delayed reforms in university education. 489 490 Part II: Detailed Analysis A large and entrepreneurial diaspora that is as generous in phil- anthropic contributions to Armenia as (with few exceptions) it is reticent in business initiatives. Weak local entrepreneurship. Although there are some first movers (for example, in the software and jewelry sectors), they are nowhere close to the critical mass. Clusters and value chains are not developing. There are of course the usual reasons of a weak investment climate and geographical isolation, but these do not appear to be the main problem. Armenian entrepreneurs and policy makers alike do not appreciate (and hence do not seek to improve) the value of intangibles (brand names, busi- ness reputation, marketing and managerial skills, networks, and so forth). This is where a large stock of educated engineers and scientists, with their attendant focus on assets one can touch, turns to a disadvantage. Fragmentation of the policy debate. Traditions of collective actions and public-private partnership are also weak. The main objective of this study is to suggest how Armenia's three main advantages--the demand for knowledge among young people, the stock of existing domestic human capital, and the diaspora net- works--can trigger a quick expansion in skill-intensive and export- driven entrepreneurship. The strong growth Armenia boasts now is a unique window of opportunity to generate self-reinforcing dynamics: that is, virtuous circles of interaction of the flow and the stock of human capital and the diaspora. The issue is not so much new investments in physical assets (which still dominate the agenda of the government, the international financial organizations, and the diaspora) but the mobili- zation and recombination of the existing human capital, triggered by an initially modest investment in intangibles such as mechanisms of knowledge and skill transfer from the diaspora to Armenia. Hence, the major value of the study is not necessarily its specific policy recom- mendations but that it provides (i) a different perspective on familiar problems, (ii) an invitation for policy makers to change the mindset, and (iii) the identification of pilot knowledge-intensive initiatives. Armenia faces a "study overhang": donors finance far too many studies in comparison with innovative practical initiatives. The fol- lowing three components of the potential value added of the study are deemed most important: "Credible provocateur." This conveys a sense of urgency for a new policy agenda so that, given the global challenges the country faces, the agenda (at least in some areas, such as life-long learn- ing) cannot deal in the business as usual mode. Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 491 Lessons from the relevant best practices. These lessons give the gist of how others accomplished the transition to a knowledge-based economy and competitiveness. There was particular interest in the lessons from Ireland, Greece, and Israel. Policy recommendations: more on the "how" than the "what." The study intends to emphasize the importance of pilot projects as an instrument for building public trust and broadening opportuni- ties for investment and knowledge transfer. After a severe recession in the early 1990s, the Armenian economy demonstrated a strong economic recovery. Yet the sustainability and quality of Armenia's economic recovery remains a concern. The issue is: What will be the source of further growth in the medium and long terms? The factor advantages that Armenia possesses are an educated labor force, low labor costs, and the presence of a diaspora. To take advantage of these factors, Armenia needs to embark on a transition to a knowledge economy. The term "knowledge economy" (KE) has been coined to reflect the increased importance of knowledge as a critical factor for economic performance. A knowledge-based economy is one in which organi- zations and people acquire, create, disseminate, and use knowledge more effectively for greater economic and social development. Such an economy requires the following: an economic and institutional regime that provides incentives for the efficient creation, dissemination, and use of existing knowledge an educated and skilled population that can create and use knowledge a system of research centers, universities, think tanks, consult- ants, firms, and other organizations that can tap into the grow- ing stock of global knowledge and assimilate and adapt it to local needs a dynamic information infrastructure that can facilitate the effective communication, dissemination, and processing of information The first section of the report sets the stage for the report's recom- mendations by providing a detailed benchmarking of Armenia's posi- tion in the global KE. It describes Armenia's growth paradox: there is a high potential of knowledge utilization that shows tantalizing prom- ise (for instance, in the nascent software cluster and certain enterprises of heavy industry) yet remains largely untapped. 492 Part II: Detailed Analysis Which Way Forward? Toward a National Agenda of Knowledge-Based Competitiveness (Section 2) To move forward, Armenia needs to implement major reforms in inno- vation, education, and ICT systems. The reform agenda is as challeng- ing as the institutional impediments to reforms. A pragmatic agenda to get around the many institutional rigidities that Armenia faces is to create both a bottom-up and a top-down momentum for change by fos- tering stakeholder awareness. This should help achieve a consensus on dealing with some of the key obstacles at the national level (to enhance demand for an institutional change) and moving ahead with concrete, manageable, bottom-up approaches that can serve as demonstration projects for the larger agenda (to ensure success breeds success). Armenia has already made some advances in that direction. Draw- ing on a diversity of best practices, we suggest that Armenia construct and implement a strategy to move toward knowledge-based competi- tiveness in three stages: Immediate agenda. Embark on massive awareness-building and initiation of pilot projects and initiatives to demonstrate the potential of knowledge-based competitiveness. Medium-term agenda (2005­08). Create a springboard for major reforms by assuring that the following happen: --make major improvements in the investment climate --strengthen stakeholders for reforms --proceed with a private sector-led shared vision process (Armenia 2025). Long-term agenda (2008 onward). Undertake major reforms that will transform and create world-class innovation, education sys- tems, and an ICT infrastructure. Table 14.1 outlines the medium-term agenda (establishing a spring- board for a KE) and longer-term agenda (major reforms and creating a world-class KE infrastructure). In retrospect, we view the last decade (from 1995 to 2003) as a phase of "building foundations." Armenia's accession to the WTO in 2003 was an important event signaling that Armenia had assured macroeconomic and socioeconomic stability and created the basic institutional foundations for a market economy. We argue that the time has come for a new stage of policy: the creation of a critical mass of stakeholders for reforms. That, in turn, would imply a two-pronged strategy: Top-down approach: Dramatically reduce the administrative barriers to growth and dramatically improve the investment climate. Table 14.1 Sequencing of the Armenia KE Policy Agenda Stages of economic Thrust of Examples of reform and growth Major constraints Drivers of growth government policy policy initiatives Benchmarks Building Sustainability of Remittances and Assuring macro and Infrastructure Signaling event: accession to foundations macroeconomic other transfers social stability projects WTO (2003) 1995­2003 stability and from abroad Some initiatives to Creation of Other indicators: investment market reforms Infrastructure and improve innovation business council share in GDP, private investment services climate in GDP (reasonably high) Moving Level of knowledge-based exports (very low) Business share in innovation toward (practically nil) Establishing Dearth of role Increasing share Assuring a critical Competitive Signaling events: a springboard models and of merchandise mass of stakeholders grant schemes to Knowledge-Based A multinational establishes for KE, 2005­8 stakeholders for exports; growing for reforms through a enhance business knowledge-intensive operations reforms (self-made role of services two pronged strategy: innovation in Armenia start-up and spin- Top-down: dramatic Creation of off entrepreneurs) Elimination of ArmenTel reduction of innovation monopoly administrative barriers council to growth Some skilled emigrants come Competitiveness back and become successful Bottom-up: facilitation entrepreneurs of private sector-driven "centers of excellence" Rising share of business R&D and merchandise exports Major reforms: Human capital Skill-intensive Major overhaul Wide-scale Significant return migration of creating world-class constraint: exports of education, ICT introduction of highly skilled. KE infrastructure, inadequate stock infrastructure, and income-contingent Robust internal Robust knowledge-intensive 2008­15 and flow of innovation systems scheme to finance demand clusters are established 493 technical skills private higher education Inadequate ICT infrastructure Source: Elaboration by the author. 494 Part II: Detailed Analysis Bottom-up approach: Facilitate private sector-driven "centers of excellence" in innovation, enterprise upgrading, education, and ICT. This policy stage should be characterized by more strategic and proactive government policies to improve innovation, the education systems, and the ICT infrastructure. By a proactive approach we do not mean a "picking winners" sectoral industrial policy. Rather, the focus should be on functional interventions that are open to all eligi- ble stakeholders and that would accelerate the existing policy trends rather than creating from scratch. Examples of policy initiatives in this vein include competitive grant schemes to enhance business innovation (more on this appears below) and the establishment of an innovation council to assure linkages among higher education, R&D organizations, and the enterprise sec- tor. Benchmarks and signaling events of the completion of this stage of reform could be as diverse as the following: A brand name multinational establishes knowledge-intensive operations in Armenia. The ArmenTel monopoly is eliminated. Some skilled emigrants come back to Armenia and become suc- cessful entrepreneurs. There is a rising share of business R&D in the overall R&D budget and of merchandise exports in overall exports. The achievement of these benchmarks will signal the formation of a critical mass of stakeholders for reform, which would allow Arme- nia to engage in major (and quite painful) reforms in innovation, the enterprise upgrading system, and the ICT infrastructure. We will not discuss in detail the long-run agenda for change. The discussion that follows focuses on the "what" and "how" of the medium-term agenda (establishing a springboard for the KE). The report shows that from the perspective of the KE, two major immediate constraints are (i) an extremely weak and fragmented innovation system characterized by the isolation of productive sec- tor, universities, and research institutes; and (ii) the low quality and high prices of ITC infrastructure. From a longer-term perspective, human capital (particularly technical and managerial skills) is a major constraint. Table 14.2 summarizes these critical constraints from the perspective of the KE and a relevant medium-term policy agenda to alleviate these constraints. Table 14.2 Specific Policy Initiatives as Entry Points to Address Systemic Constraints Relevant best practices System Main objectives Specific initiatives (discussed in Section 3) Moving Innovation system Enhance linkages between Competitive grant scheme to U.K. Teaching Company Scheme. productive sector, universities, promote business R&D and and science organizations. training. toward Seed support to venture capital fund. Knowledge-Based Education system Reform curriculum of basic, Technology/design facility on Competence center models secondary, and higher the basis of major university. (in design stage in Estonia). education. Distant education project collaboration with diaspora. Establish National Innovation Council to bring together Competitiveness education, R&D organizations, and industry. ICT infrastructure Improve quality of ICT Institutional strengthening of Liberalization policies in ICT services and reduce its costs. public utility regulator. infrastructure in some central European countries. Source: Author's own elaboration. 495 496 Part II: Detailed Analysis How to Implement the Strategy? From Vision to Action (Section 3) Implementation capabilities are a critical issue not only in Armenia but in many semi-industrialized economies. This is due to the simulta- neous weakness of both government and market institutions. Pragma- tism--adopting and adapting what works even though it may result in idiosyncratic institutions--is a main thrust of our recommenda- tions. Given that most knowledge-based activities are concentrated in the capital city of Yerevan, Armenia is tantamount to a city state. It can become a laboratory for pragmatic institutions to enhance the transformation of knowledge to wealth. Some pilot solutions can be adopted and adapted, starting with Armenia's two nascent clusters: the jewelry and diamond cluster and the software cluster. The third section of this report analyzes the reasons for the dis- appointing performance of the existing initiatives (including those financed by the World Bank), such as the Enterprise Incubator Foun- dation (EIF) and the Armenia Development Agency (ADA). We sug- gest that implementation problems could be fixed by strengthening or replacing the management of these organizations and significantly increasing the presence of the business sector and the diaspora in their governing bodies. Improvements in the performance of ADA/EIF could then be used as a trigger for donor support for future enterprise and innovation support initiatives. Such initiatives could include the following: Create a private-public National Innovation Council to bring together education, R&D organizations, and industry. Realign and strengthen the incentive structure to attract FDI. Implement a series of pilot initiatives to raise the demand for business R&D and enhance education-industry linkages. For example, introduce a competitive grants scheme for business R&D; introduce a system of support for productivity improve- ment, implement a distance education pilot; reform and expand the system of quality support to firms; and improve the system of technology transfer by a "teaching company" scheme. Improve growth statistics to permit better measurement of the development of the KE. The meaningful participation of Armenia's highly successful business and R&D diaspora will be vital for the success of these initiatives and for Armenia's transformation to a knowledge-based economy in gen- eral. However, the way in which the diaspora engages in the Armenian economy has to change very dramatically. Rather than being merely a Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 497 source of donations, it needs to become a bridge to FDI (foreign direct investment) and other technical and managerial knowledge (as in India), and eventually a source of FDI (as in China). Clues on how the diaspora can contribute in a more substantive manner are already emerging, albeit slowly. The diaspora played a key role in articulating the Armenia 2020 vision (McKinsey and Company 2003), although again the govern- ment showed insufficient commitment in this initiative. To change the current situation, (that is, to make the diaspora a source of expertise and FDI rather than a source of philanthropy and poverty relief), we propose the following: Go after "low-hanging fruit": design and implement relatively low- cost private sector projects in higher education, innovation, and ICT. A distance education pilot is one example of such projects. Once these pilot projects demonstrate signs of success, scale them into specific organizations. This would require more substantial com- mitments from successful and influential businessmen of Arme- nian origin. Higher education is particularly ripe with these opportunities. Organize a top-level leadership conference to start transforming diaspora interest so that it becomes involved in specific investment projects in Armenia. Once pilot projects start to show results, we propose to organize a high-level leadership conference in California. The objective of assembling a group of "overachievers" of Arme- nian origin to attend the leadership conference would be to translate general benevolence into productive action. It is a complex and subtle process, and the essential element is that this group must believe that they are not being hit upon for money. Instead, they are usually asked to participate in the vision-building exercise--the design of a new direction for the country or an important part of it. In the course of discussing the existing problem and its possible solutions, the group comes to a shared understanding of real development priorities and becomes personally committed to the implementation of the recom- mendations that were set up with their direct participation. It is natu- ral that having become a part of the "design team" they would sup- port the agreed recommendations with their resources and influence. Such a participatory process also helps to convince major donors to refrain from pushing their individual vanity projects. The new role of the Armenian diaspora will bring not only critical managerial and technical expertise. It will be a litmus test of how well Armenia is progressing toward knowledge-based competitiveness. By this benchmark, Armenia's progress is very disappointing, as diaspora involvement is overwhelmingly philanthropic in nature. 498 Part II: Detailed Analysis Issues for Future Analysis Many issues in this report were merely outlined here and deserve future analysis. For the second section of this report (the way forward), two issues deserve detailed empirical analysis: From the labor market perspective, the nature of the demand for new and different skills and knowledge needs to be better under- stood. It is likely that demand from enterprises is low, since most are in sectors with low productivity and are focused on local markets. High unemployment and major industry restructuring have meant low incentives for investments in new skills and knowledge. Another issue that needs to be better understood is where workers might get their skills and knowledge upgraded, whether through public or private providers, and what incen- tives or disincentives exist for individuals and enterprises to use these providers. A skills survey (in collaboration with the Arme- nia education team) will need to be undertaken to this end. From the enterprise sector perspective, there is a need for a survey of sources and forms of innovation in firms. Such a survey (with a fairly standardized methodology) was undertaken in most tran- sition economies but not in Armenia. This survey would shed some light on how to accelerate the emerging pockets of excel- lence and vitality in the Armenian economy. For the third section of this report (the "how to" of recommenda- tions), a survey of the business diaspora and of emerging new means of diaspora involvement would be helpful. For example, a discussion of the results of such a survey in Argentina proved critical in changing the attitude of the government toward the country's business environ- ment and the R&D diaspora. WHY KNOWLEDGE? ARMENIA'S GROWTH PARADOX This section sets the stage by establishing the case for a knowledge- based economy in Armenia. The subsection immediately below deals with the vulnerability of the current sources of growth. The next sub- section outlines stylized scenarios of a model in the light of experi- enced comparator countries including Croatia, Latvia, Chile, Singa- pore, and Israel. The following two subsections introduce the notion of a KE and benchmarks of Armenia's performance. The concluding subsection returns to the scenario analysis for Armenia and introduces Armenia's growth paradox. Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 499 Peculiar Structure of Growth After a severe recession in the early 1990s, the Armenian economy demonstrated a strong economic recovery. Yet the sustainability and quality of Armenia's economic growth, particularly of the quality of jobs it generates, remains a concern. Growth has been concentrated mainly in sectors with limited employment opportunities. Recovery in agriculture and energy and expansion in the construction and service sectors were the main factors contributing to growth. In contrast, the manufacturing sector underperformed, although, owing to its skilled labor endowment, Armenia's strongest comparative advantage lies in this sector. As highlighted in the country study (2002a), Armenia's output growth to date has been accompanied by insufficient employ- ment generation and poverty reduction, primarily because the busi- ness environment has not been supportive of enterprise restructuring and new entry for most of the period. In early 2001, the government made essential adjustments to its eco- nomic strategy. It has shifted the focus of reform efforts to improving the business environment, developing consultative mechanisms with the private sector, and building capacity for export and investment promotion. The government's effort in these areas has been broadly successful as reflected in the major outcomes of the ongoing reform programs. Recent enterprise surveys also show increased private sec- tor satisfaction with the government's economic policy. The strong economic growth of 2001­02 was for the first time driven by a high rate of export expansion. Manufacturing exports grew by more than 50 percent in two years, with a positive impact on employment and household incomes. However, as can be seen from Tables 14.3 and 14.4, the sectoral decomposition of GDP and export growth suggests that skill-intensive and knowledge-intensive sectors continue to underperform. The pri- mary sources of economic growth in Armenia relate to such sectors as jewelry and diamond cutting, food processing, textiles, construction (to a large extent driven by donor funding of major investment projects in public infrastructure), and low-end services. However, the domestic demand for qualified labor remains depressed.3 The situation in the machinery sector remains mostly stagnant. The significant increase in the volume of exports and the overall acceleration in GDP annual growth over the past four to five years (3.3 percent in 1999 and 12.9 percent in 2002) has not had a substan- tial impact on employment, which, at 1.28 million population in early 2003 (having stagnated over the past four years) was still about 10 percent lower than in 1997 (Economist 2003). According to official esti- mates, total registered unemployment in 2002 was around 9.5 percent, 500 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 14.3 Gross Domestic Product by Sector, 1998­2003 (US$ million) Growth between 1998 and Sector 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2003 (%) Agriculture and forestry 30.8 27.0 23.2 25.0 23.1 21.5 ­43 Construction 8.0 8.3 10.3 10.7 13.9 15.8 49 Industry 19.9 21.2 21.9 20.2 20.5 21.5 7 Services 31.8 34.9 35.5 34.4 32.0 30.8 ­3 Trade & catering 8.7 9.0 9.4 9.8 10.0 10.4 16 Transport & communications 6.9 7.6 7.2 7.5 7.2 6.3 ­10 Source: Armenian Ministry of Trade and Economic Development. Table 14.4 Sector Contributions to Export Growth, 2000­02 (percent) Sector Growth contribution Total export growth 100.0 Total of five leading sectors (below) 96.6 Diamonds and jewelry 57.8 Prepared food products 14.1 Machinery, equipment, and mechanisms 9.4 Instruments and apparatus 8.9 Textile articles 6.4 Source: Author's own elaboration. but the inclusion of nonregistered unemployment could raise the rate to over 30 percent. High-tech exports, as a percentage of manufactured exports, are minimal (1.7 percent in 2002 and 4 percent in 2000); the average for the lower-middle-income group is several times higher. Manufacturing exports as a percentage of total exports are not particularly low4 but they are concentrated in natural-resource-based products and tradi- tional industries, such as precious stones, metals, foodstuffs, base met- als, mineral products, textiles, and machinery. Overall, total revenue from exports of goods and services has been on an upward trend, ris- ing by 50 percent between the years 2001and 2002 and accounting for 30 percent of GDP in 2002, the highest share since 1994. Growth has been driven mainly by the processing of diamonds and stones whose exports accounted for more than 50 percent of total export revenue Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 501 in 2002, up from 35 percent in 2001. Exports of prepared foodstuffs, Armenia's second largest export commodity, posted their third suc- cessive year of growth in 2002, indicating strong competencies in the domestic food-processing industry. FDI has not remained at consistent levels throughout the past years. FDI was close to 5 percent of GDP in 2002 and lower than in the period 1998­2000. It is also interesting to note that in the CIS group Armenia has the highest inflows of foreign assistance per head (Economist 2003) and that foreign remittances have accounted for 20 percent of GDP on average for the last five years. This extra volume of inflows, in conjunction with the volume of FDI, should provide a good base for business development and entrepreneurship in the country. Nevertheless, according to a very recent survey there are signifi- cant constraints on business development and operation in Armenia (FIAS 2004). The companies surveyed indicated, in the order evalu- ated, that taxes and tax administration/regulation, policy instability, infrastructure, financing, and corruption are the top five constraints affecting the operations and growth of private Armenian businesses. The same survey indicates that there is some improvement in the busi- ness start-up process in Armenia with the simplification of company registration and some reduction in registration costs (from US$88 in 2002 down to US$75 in 2003). Overall, however, the total cost of start- ing a business and conducting some key activities (that is, equipment and product certification) has increased since 1999. In 2002 the aver- age cost to Armenian companies incurred for registration and organ- izing some operations was equivalent to around US$5,200, while in 1999 it was around US$3,970. The higher costs for registration and operation occurred in the manufacturing sector and in larger com- panies. However, small companies pay substantially higher costs for import/export operations. Furthermore, the survey strongly indicates that there has been a substantial worsening of the situation related to business operations, mainly due to taxation and tax administration, customs regulations, and inspections. McKinsey and Company (2003) estimate that this growth pattern will encounter difficulties by 2005­06. The issue is what the sources of further growth will be in the medium and long terms. The factor advantages that Armenia possesses are an educated labor force, low labor cost, and the presence of the diaspora. However, these are not drivers of growth per se. It is difficult to generalize about drivers of growth across different countries. Growth is always an idiosyncratic process that is driven by a variety of very specific and complementary factors that jointly generate a virtuous circle of growth. Nevertheless, initial spurs of a growth such as Armenia's could be initiated through coordinated policy actions to remove key constraints. The gap between 502 Part II: Detailed Analysis the potential for growth and the very low current income levels is of such magnitude that coordinated policy actions, that would remove a variety of sectoral obstacles, would produce a marginal long-term spur in growth. This would be a sound basis for building sustainable long-term growth anchored in knowledge-based activities. Toward Growth Scenarios for Armenia To derive policy lessons, throughout this report we compare Armenia with two types of countries: "role models" and what we call "realistic comparators." Role models are small, open economies such as Israel, Ireland, Chile, and Slovenia that have managed to thrive in innova- tion and knowledge-intensive industries and to develop competitive clusters. Armenia is also compared with economies such as Russia, Latvia, Croatia, and Costa Rica. Russia is a large economy with sig- nificant trade and political affiliations with Armenia. Latvia, Croatia, and Costa Rica have good foundations and have made substantial progress but have also encountered significant difficulties. Tables 14.5 and 14.6 summarize the main features of Armenia's growth versus selected role models and other comparators. To analyze the growth factors in more detail, we now turn to define the main generic factors of growth: knowledge and the capability to transform it into wealth. Knowledge Economy and Knowledge Revolution Knowledge has always been a critical factor in economic develop- ment. In today's global economy, knowledge has become an even more important factor for competitiveness, growth, and increased welfare. We are in the midst of what could be called a "knowledge revolu- tion," triggered by rapid scientific and technological progress in many fields such as biotechnology and ITC and by increased speed in the dissemination and application of knowledge. Reduced transportation and communications costs and the fact that knowledge seeks larger markets for its application are all features of increased globalization and competition. The result of this very dynamic process is a constant state of restructuring, at global, country, sector, and firm levels. While this raises tremendous possibilities for improvement, it also carries risks that countries or firms and organizations will fall behind. The term "knowledge economy" has been coined to reflect this increased importance of knowledge as a critical factor for economic performance (see Box 14.1 for some of the key trends in the KE). Table 14.5 Countries That Have Successfully Aligned Key Drivers of Growth and Developed Innovation Clusters Drivers Ireland Israel Armenia Moving Leverage country advantages. English speaking talent pool close High-quality talent, partly High-quality talent, particularly in to EU market. immigrants. engineering and mathematics. Strong assistance by diaspora Highly successful and toward but which inhibits regional entrepreneurial diaspora. integration. Attract "brand name" FDI. Dell Microsoft Should be a priority. Knowledge-Based Crucially important as trigger for future growth. Focus on highly specific market Off-shore business processes. Defense industry. ITC cluster. niches. Security software. Diamonds and jewelry. Future possibilities: Competitiveness -- fine chemicals -- precision machine building. Provide government support. Irish Development Agency. Developed support to firms' Strengthen enterprise incubator growth. and ADA. Fiscal incentives. Create high-level innovation council. Source: Adapted from McKinsey and Company (2003). 503 504 Table 14.6 Countries with Obstacles to Aligning Key Drivers of Growth Part Driver Croatia Russia Latvia Costa Rica Leverage A close proximity to EU Educated labor (particularly engineering A close proximity Substantial progress in II: country market has not yet been and R&D talent) has not been leveraged. to developed EU transforming two main assets-- Detailed advantages. leveraged with specific markets and skilled nature and educated labor force-- Natural resources are not transformed country advantages. labor force has not into sustained advantages. into high value-added clusters as in yet been converted Finland, Norway, or Chile. Costa Rica as a widely recognized into an asset. Analysis tourism brand and Intel semiconductor plant as a flagship of manufacturing industry. Attract High unit-labor costs Failure to attract brand-name FDI, yet Limited FDI in Intel investment has not been "brand have attracted only local there are important exceptions both on manufacturing sector. followed by wave of other name" FDI. market­seeking FDI high-end (R&D and design--Boeing) Mainly market- investors. (banks, telecoms). and low end (oil and gas). seeking FDI. Focus on Country competitive With the exception of the advantages General awareness High-brand and nature tourism highly advantages have not yet inherited from the Soviet era (arms that knowledge-based has been successful as a niche. specific been differentiated. exports to Asia high-performers, capital activities are far Other knowledge-based services market goods for atomic power stations), ahead has not been have not. niches. country competitive advantages have matched by specific not been differentiated. actions. Provide Government has not Many programs and declarations. No Tax support to Tax support to certain government yet taken seriously coherent vision of Russia as knowledge- high-tech activities manufacturing activities; variety support. knowledge-based economy based economy and monitorable including software. of SME programs. agenda. program of concerted action. Source: Adapted from McKinsey and Company (2003). Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 505 Box 14.1 The Growing Importance of Knowledge: Global Trends The OECD uses the term "knowledge economy" to draw attention to the importance of knowledge in all economic activities. The defini- tion has been evolving from focusing just on manufacturing industries that make intensive use of technology to including services that are also heavily knowledge based. The KE now accounts, on average, for roughly half of nongovernment economic activity in the OECD. More investment and trade in intangibles Investment in intangibles has been skyrocketing. In OECD countries, public investment in intangibles (such as education, R&D, and software) has now reached almost the same level as that for machinery and equip- ment--8.6 percent of GDP compared to 9.0 percent. This estimate almost certainly understates the level of investment in "intangibles," since it does not include private investment in education, public and private investment in skills training, or investment in design, marketing, adver- tising, brand development, engineering, publishing, and the arts. More importance for education and training In OECD countries the proportion of adults with at least a secondary education has risen from 44 percent to 72 percent; and tertiary educa- tion has doubled, from 22 percent to 44 percent over the last generation. According to UNESCO the number of students enrolled in postsecond- ary institutions worldwide increased from 28 million in 1970 to 88 mil- lion in 1997. But the gap between developing countries and developed countries widened from 21 million to 45 million, even though the popu- lation of developing countries is larger and growing faster. Developed countries have also been up-skilling labor through extensive continuing education both in universities and in firms. Developing countries lag in this respect as their educational attainments are low, and the workforce needs retraining to be competitive in a new economy. More foreign investment Foreign investment, one of the key agents of globalization, is moved mainly by the desire to exploit knowledge assets on a global scale-- assets that include technology, management, access to markets, and access to such special resources as finance, labor, and natural resources. FDI inflows increased 15 times between 1982 and 1999. And FDI's share in world gross fixed capital formation increased from 2.6 percent to 14.3 percent. More R&D Of global R&D, 88 percent is undertaken by high-income countries, with 31 percent of global R&D centered in one single country: the United States. Multinational companies, now carrying out R&D in countries 506 Part II: Detailed Analysis other than their home countries, are establishing more strategic alli- ances--even mergers and acquisitions--to collaborate on technology and acquire technological assets. Also on the rise is the number of international collaborations in patenting and technical publications. In the OECD, the share of foreign co-inventors rose from 5 percent in the mid-1980s to 9 percent eight years later. And the share of scientific pub- lications with foreign co-authors more than doubled for many OECD countries, to an average of 26 percent for 1995­97. Source: Knowledge for Development (K4D) Program. http://www.worldbank .org/wbi/knowledgefordevelopment. A knowledge-based economy is one where organizations and people acquire, create, disseminate, and use knowledge more effectively for greater economic and social development. This requires the following: an economic and institutional regime that provides incentives for the efficient creation, dissemination, and use of existing knowledge an educated and skilled population that can create and use knowledge a system of research centers, universities, think tanks, consult- ants, firms, and other organizations that can tap into the grow- ing stock of global knowledge, and assimilate and adapt it to local needs a dynamic information infrastructure that can facilitate the effective communication, dissemination, and processing of information Underpinning the above is the need to coordinate actions across these four pillars, because there are strong interdependencies among them. A New Economic Incentive and Institutional Regime Taking advantage of the potential offered by the knowledge revolu- tion requires a flexible society and economy, able to cope with the need for constant change. This, in turn, requires: (i) effective economic incentive regimes and institutions to facilitate the redeployment of resources from less efficient to more efficient uses; (ii) conditions con- ducive to entrepreneurship, risk-taking, and the expansion of small enterprises; (iii) sufficiently flexible labor markets to facilitate the redeployment of labor, appropriate social safety nets to facilitate the relocation and retraining of people for new jobs, and assistance to Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 507 those adversely affected by restructuring; and (iv) legal governance systems to cope with the many demands emanating from such restruc- turing and redeployment. Skilled and Creative Human Resources for the KE Education is the basis for creating, acquiring, adapting, disseminat- ing, and using knowledge. Basic education increases peoples' capacity to learn and to use information, as does technical secondary educa- tion. Higher education in engineering and scientific areas is needed to monitor technological trends, assess what is relevant for the firm or the economy, and use new technologies. The production of new knowledge and its adaptation to a particular economic setting is gen- erally associated with higher-level teaching and research. Creating a culture of continuous learning and openness to new ideas is critical for a knowledge-based economy. An Effective Innovation System An innovation system consists of the network of institutions, rules, and procedures that affect how a country acquires, creates, dissemi- nates, and uses knowledge. Some of the key organizations for the cre- ation of knowledge include universities, public and private research centers, and policy think tanks, as well as firms, nongovernmental organizations, and the government. Some of the key institutions for the dissemination of knowledge include agricultural and industrial extension services, engineering consulting firms, and economic and management consulting firms. What is important is how effective they are in creating, adapting, and disseminating knowledge to the firms, government, and other organizations or people who put it to use. Therefore, networking and interaction among the different organiza- tions, firms, and individuals is essential. A Dynamic Information Infrastructure The rapid advances in ICT are dramatically affecting economic and social activities, as well as the acquisition, creation, dissemination, and use of knowledge. As knowledge becomes more important for competitiveness, the effective use of ICT reduces transaction costs, time and space barriers, and allows the mass production of custom- ized goods and services, substituting for limited factors of produc- tion. ICT has now become a pervasive and essential infrastructure for the knowledge-based economy. To support Internet-based economic activities, countries need to ensure the competitive pricing of Internet services and provide an appropriate legal infrastructure to deal with 508 Part II: Detailed Analysis online transactions. It is also essential to assess the knowledge and skills required to design, implement, and use the new ICT. Armenia and the KE: Benchmarking the Country's Position The Knowledge for Development program (K4D) of the World Bank Institute (WBI)5 has developed a knowledge benchmarking methodol- ogy built on an interactive Web-based tool--the Knowledge Assess- ment Methodology (KAM).6 The KAM includes a wide range of quantitative and qualitative variables that help to benchmark how an economy compares with neighbors, competitors, or countries it wishes to emulate on the four pillars of the KE (see Box 14.2). The KAM helps to identify the problems and opportunities that a country faces in making the transition to the KE, and where it may need to focus policy attention or future investments.7 The KAM assesses a country's or region's knowledge readiness in relative terms, meaning relative to the available country sample (currently 121 countries). The figures in this subsection illustrate a preliminary picture of Armenia's knowledge readiness from the mid-1990s to the early years of this decade. Figure 14.1 demonstrates the relative performance of countries and regions in the Knowledge Economy Index (KEI), a composite index that measures the preparedness of the country for a knowledge-based development framework. The KEI is calculated by computing the average of the performance scores of a country or region in all four pillars of the KE (see Box 14.2). Box 14.2 The Four Pillars of the KE The following variables are chosen as proxies for each of the four pil- lars of the KE: Economic and institutional regime: tariff and nontariff barriers, regulatory quality, and rule of law Education and human resources: adult literacy rate (percent age 15 and above), secondary enrollment, and tertiary enrollment Innovation system: researchers in R&D, patent applications granted by the USTPO, and scientific and technical journal articles (weighted by per million population) Information infrastructure: telephones per 1,000 people, computers per 1,000 people, and Internet users per 10,000 people Source: K4D. Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 509 Figure 14.1 Armenia and the World: KEI 10 Canada Finland 9 Germany G-7 LEVEL Western Europe United Ireland States 8 G7 Australia Latvia Poland Japan Developed 7 Europe & Central Asia Chile Israel Oceania Mexico East Asia Korea, Rep. of recent) 6 ENTRY LEVEL Brazil Russian Federation Jordan Costa Rica 5 Middle East & North Africa Argentina (most Tunisia South Africa 4 COPING China Turkey ECONOMIES World index 3 Latin America Kenya Indonesia Ghana India 2 LAGGARDS Africa South Asia 1 Pakistan Nigeria 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 index (1995) Source: KAM 2005 (www.wordlbank.org/kam). Overall, during the last five to seven years Armenia improved, rather marginally, its performance in the KEI. In the knowledge map (Figure 14.1), as defined by countries' performance in the index, Armenia stands within the medium performers group, yet noticeably below the average of the ECA region. Armenia falls further behind OECD and EU members, and the performance gap between Arme- nia and its selected comparators is significant.8 In particular, Armenia trails Israel and Ireland alarmingly. These elements should signal the sense of urgency for Armenia, which despite its well-documented, large potential and impressive economic growth trends does not seem to be maximizing the benefits from its competencies. Armenia is also falling behind other former socialist economies which have managed to compete more successfully in a fast-changing, knowledge-based environment. Following the KAM methodology, the figures below divide the world's knowledge performance into four broad classes: Very low endowments--laggards. Relatively low endowments--coping economies. "Accession club"--entry-level to KE--a class that is character- istic of upper middle-income economies starting to compete in 510 Part II: Detailed Analysis knowledge and innovation, not low labor costs alone. These are more advanced ECA and Asian countries. G-7 levels of knowledge endowments. While the criteria distinguishing one class from another are neces- sarily arbitrary, the messages for Armenia are quite clear: On the overall KE score, Armenia is among the coping econo- mies: it is within the same league as Russia, Ukraine, and Costa Rica and within the healthy distance from both laggards and entry-level economies. Yet Armenia's performance across the four KE pillars (economic incentive regime, education, innovation, and ICTs) is unusually unbalanced. On economic and institutional regime Armenia per- forms very well, on a par with recent EU entrants. In contrast, the ICT pillar is shockingly underdeveloped. Not only is Armenia squarely among laggards (the worst category, occupied by Sub- Saharan Africa, Albania, and the Central Asian republics of the FSU), but its relative position actually has worsened significantly since 1995. This is all the more worrisome given its geographical isolation. Because of its landlocked status and unfriendly neigh- bors it should have at least ranked in the accession club on ICT. On education, Armenia still performs reasonably although lag- ging behind many Eastern European economies. However, the relatively good human capital is a heritage of Soviet times that has not translated into adequate innovation performance. The innovation pillar remains weak. Using the KAM, it is also possible to isolate Armenia and its com- parators and illustrate their relative performance in the four pillars that comprise the KEI.9 In Figure 14.2, the two bars per country repre- sent the aggregate KEI score for that country for the most recent year (upper bar) and for 1995 (lower bar), split into the four KE pillars. Each shaded band represents the contribution of a particular pillar to a country's overall knowledge readiness. An examination of performance in the four KE pillars (economic incentive regime, education, innovation, and ICT) that define the aggregate KEI (Figure 14.3) indicates that Armenia performs poorly in the ICT pillar, an area in which it lost significant ground relative to the world. In absolute terms, Armenia did improve its ICT indi- cators (explicitly shown in Figure 14.4), but the world on average (defined by the 121 countries in the KAM sample) made a significantly larger improvement. Armenia's strongest pillar is its economic incen- tive regime (EIR), which was the weakest in the mid-1990s, an area in which the country demonstrated significant improvement and has Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 511 Figure 14.2 Armenia and Comparators: Disaggregated Performance in the KE Ireland 1995 Slovenia 1995 Israel 1995 Latvia 1995 Chile country 1995 Russia 1995 Costa Rica 1995 Armenia 1995 0.0 2.0 4.0 6.0 8.0 10.0 index economic incentive regime education innovation information infrastructure Source: KAM 2005 (www.wordlbank.org/kam). Figure 14.3 Armenia: Performance in the Four KE Pillars (most recent and 1995) normalization group: all economic incentive regime 10 5 information 0 innovation infrastructure most recent 1995 education Source: KAM 2005 (www.wordlbank.org/kam). 512 Part II: Detailed Analysis remained particularly competitive in the ECA region. In the educa- tion pillar, a traditionally strong area for the country, Armenia lost some ground, while in the innovation pillar the country regressed even more. In Figure 14.4 we illustrate how Armenia performed throughout in each of the 12 variables that describe the four KE pillars, and therefore the aggregate KEI, plus 2 performance variables (GDP growth and Human Development Index--HDI). In the EIR pillar, the country demonstrated the largest improvement in the ECA region, currently performing well above the regional aver- age, behind Latvia and Hungary (Figure 14.5). Armenia significantly improved its terms of trade by reducing tariff and nontariff barriers10 and also managed to significantly improve (relative to the world) its regulatory quality indicators by implementing policies friendly to markets and business. Rule of law indicators did not improve sig- nificantly and they are below the regional average levels, but still the country showed more improvement than the average of the KAM country sample; therefore it demonstrates improvement relative to the world. Armenia lags behind all of its selected comparators in this pil- lar with the exception of Russia, which is moving particularly slowly toward a modernized institutional phase. Figure 14.6 shows several additional KAM indicators that describe performance in the EIR pillar. The scorecard indicates that Armenia is characterized by low levels of gross domestic investment, the lowest among its comparators. On average for the years 1995­2002, Armenia Figure 14.4 Armenia KE Index Variables, Basic Scorecard (1995 and most recent) GDP growth (%) Internet users per 10,000 people 10 Human Development Index computers per 1,000 people tariff & nontariff barriers 5 telephones per 1,000 people regulatory quality 0 tertiary enrollment rule of law secondary enrollment researchers in R&D/million adult literacy rate (% age 15 scientific & technical journal & above) patent articles/mil. pop. applications most recent granted by the USPTO/mil. pop. 1995 Source: KAM 2005 (www.wordlbank.org/kam). Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 513 Figure 14.5 Economic Incentive Regime: Armenia and the World 10 Australia Finland 9 Canada Developed G-7 LEVEL Western Europe 8 Oceania Chile Germany G7 7 Latvia Ireland Europe & Central Asia Japan Israel Middle East & Central Asia Poland Mexico United recent) 6 ENTRY LEVEL Costa Rica States Rep. of Korea Armenia World 5 South Africa Turkey (most Ghana East Asia 4 Russian Federation Tunisia Jordan Brazil index 3 COPING China India Latin America ECONOMIES Indonesia 2 Africa South Asia Argentina Kenya 1 Nigeria Pakistan LAGGARDS 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 index (1995) Source: KAM 2005 (www.wordlbank.org/kam). spent around 19 percent of GDP on domestic investments--the lowest share with Costa Rica--while the closest, Russia, spent 20 percent, and Latvia and Slovenia topped the list with 25 percent. Armenia on average for the same time period (1995­2002) spent significantly less on domestic investments (see Table 14A.3.1 in Annex 14.3) than was spent, on average, by the groups in the low and low and middle income countries. Armenia is an open economy with total trade representing cur- rently 75 percent of GDP, which is still below the average for the ECA region. Armenia's exports of goods and services as a share of GDP--a solid indication of international competitiveness--is sig- nificantly lower than all comparator countries (Table 14.7) and the same income group average. In Armenia in 2002, despite the fact that exports of goods and services had increased significantly since 1995 and accounted for almost 30 percent of GDP, imports accounted for 47 percent of GDP, causing Armenia to carry over a significant trade deficit, much larger than any of its comparator countries. In the governance and institutional quality variables presented in Table 14A.3.3 in Annex 14.3, Armenia performs significantly worse (with the exception of Russia in rule of law, and Israel in voice and 514 Part II: Detailed Analysis Figure 14.6 Armenia's Scorecard in the EIR (most recent) Armenia (most recent) gross capital formation (18.80) 10 domestic credit to private general government sector (% of GDP) (6.00) 5 budget balance as % of GDP (-2.50) 0 interest rate spread trade as % of (lending rate minus GDP (76.76) deposit rate) (14.00) exports of goods and tariff & nontariff services as barriers (8.00) % of GDP (36.10) Source: KAM 2005 (www.wordlbank.org/kam). Note: Data for gross capital formation shown in the figure above is the average for the period. accountability indicators) than all other comparators and the average of the region. In particular, despite a national campaign against cor- ruption, the high incidence of corruption continues to affect business and the attraction of foreign investment. The Heritage Foundation (2004) states in its analysis that "bribery is widespread and is the most common form of corruption, especially in the areas of government procurement, all types of transfers and approvals, and such business- related services as company registration, licensing, and land or space allocation." The Bleyzer Foundation,11 in a benchmarking analysis of 15 FSU countries on FDI driving conditions, ranks Armenia thirteenth in the corruption level index, while in the overall composite index Armenia is ranked sixth, behind Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Kaza- khstan, and Russia. Furthermore, the shadow economy in Armenia, which equals 45 percent of GDP, is significantly larger than that in some of its compara- tor economies and the average of the region (Table 14.8). This reveals the poor institutional capacity and high incidence of corruption in Armenia, combined with the increasing tax burden and social security payments. The size of the shadow economy in Armenia is a prohibitive factor for fiscal revenue generation which could create a vicious cycle with tax base erosion, resulting in higher taxes, the worsening of fiscal Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 515 Table 14.7 Exports of Goods and Services, 1995­2002 (percent of GDP) Trade account Avg. 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 1995­2002 Armenia 23.9 23.2 20.3 19 20.8 23.4 25.5 29.6 ­30 Israel 30.6 29.8 30.7 31.7 36.2 40.4 35.5 37.2 ­9 Slovenia 55.2 55.8 57.4 56.6 52.5 56.5 57.9 57.9 ­2 Russian Federation 29.3 26.1 24.7 31.2 43.2 44.1 36.3 34.7 10 Ireland 76.4 77.5 79.7 86.1 88 98 98.2 -- 13 Chile 30.5 28.7 28.1 26.7 26.9 29.8 34.7 35.9 0 Costa Rica 37.6 39.3 40.7 47.4 51.6 48.5 41.6 42.4 ­2 Latvia 47.3 51.3 51.1 51.3 43.9 45.6 44.4 45.5 ­9 Low income 19.9 19.6 20.5 26 22.4 26.6 26 25 ­1 Low & middle income 23.7 23.3 24 25.3 26.7 29.7 29.2 30.6 1 Middle income 24.4 24 24.7 25.2 27.5 30.3 29.8 31.7 1 Source: SIMA, World Bank (http://sima/datasite/sima-web/default.htm). Table 14.8 The Size of the Shadow Economy (as percent of GDP) Country 1990­1993 2000­01 Armenia 40.1 45.3 Estonia 34.3 39.1 Ireland 15.4* 15.7** Russian Federation 27.8 45.1 Slovenia 22.9 26.7 Average Central & Eastern Europe 23.4 29.2 Average FSU 32.9 44.8 Average of 21 OECD countries 15.7* 16.7** Source: Schneider (2002). *1994­95; ** 2001­02. constraints (Economist 2003) and ambiguous effects on private sector development and the quality of products and services. Unless urgent and radical reforms transform the effectiveness of the governance and institutional capacity of the country, Armenia will face competitiveness challenges that will be hard to meet. In education, a pillar in which Armenia has a strong tradition, the country has lost some ground relative to the world, and remains weak 516 Part II: Detailed Analysis Figure 14.7 Education: Armenia and the World 10 Finland Australia Developed Oceania 9 G-7 LEVEL Ireland G7 Canada Russian Federation Poland United 8 Latvia States Argentina Germany 7 ENTRY LEVEL World Japan East Asia Armenia Western Europe Jordan Korea, Rep. of Israel recent) 6 Brazil Chile Europe & Central Asia 5 Latin America COPING Costa Rica Turkey (most South Africa ECONOMIES Tunisia 4 Mexico China Middle East & North Africa Indonesia index 3 LAGGARDS India Kenya 2 Ghana South Asia Pakistan Nigeria 1 Africa 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 index (1995) Source: KAM 2005 (www.wordlbank.org/kam). relative to the regional ECA average (Figure 14.7). With adult literacy rates lower than the vast majority of other countries of the region,12 enrollments in secondary education fell significantly and remain well below the (ECA) regional average. On the other hand, enrollments in tertiary education improved significantly but still remain at very low levels by regional standards.13 The vast majority of ECA economies, and all selected comparators (with the exception of Costa Rica), out- perform Armenia in the KAM variables used to define aggregate per- formance in the education pillar (see Table 14A.3.5 in Annex 14.3). In Figure 14.8 we isolate Armenia and present the available set of variables that are used in the KAM to define performance in the educa- tion pillar. It is striking to realize, relative to the large availability and potential of educated human capital in the country, how little Armenia spends on education--less than 3 percent of GDP (2000 data). The sig- nificant gap in education spending between the ECA regional average (4.6 percent of GDP) and Armenia is particularly alarming. Based on the KAM variables that define the innovation pillar, which in the mid-1990s was the strongest pillar of the country, Armenia has lost significant ground relative to the world, and its performance cur- rently falls below the ECA regional average (Figure 14.9). Considering Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 517 Figure 14.8 Armenia's Scorecard on Education (most recent) adult literacy rate (% age 15 and above) (99.40) 10 5 public spending on secondary education as % enrollment (86.54) 0 of GDP (3.20) life expectancy tertiary at birth, years (74.80) enrollment (25.84) Source: KAM 2005 (www.wordlbank.org/kam). Figure 14.9 Innovation: Armenia and the World 10 Finland United States 9 G-7 LEVEL Germany Western Europe Israel Japan Korea, Rep. of G7 Canada 8 Australia Ireland Developed 7 ENTRY LEVEL Russian Oceania Europe & Central Asia Argentina Federation Jordan Latvia Chile recent) 6 East Asia Poland Brazil Armenia 5 COPING Turkey South Africa Kenya China Costa Rica (most ECONOMIES World 4 Mexico India Tunisia Middle East & North Africa index 3 LAGGARDS Latin America Indonesia South Asia 2 Nigeria Ghana Pakistan Africa 1 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 index (1995) Source: KAM 2005 (www.wordlbank.org/kam). 518 Part II: Detailed Analysis Figure 14.10 Armenia's Scorecard on Innovation (most recent) gross foreign direct investment as % of GDP (3.70) high-tech exports as % of science & engineering enrollment ratio manufactured exports (2.00) 10 (% of tertiary level students) (29.00) patent applications granted researchers in R&D (4,971.00) by the USPTO/mil. pop. (0.65) 5 patent applications granted researchers in R&D/ by the USPTO (2.00) 0 million (1,603.55) scientific and technical total expenditure for R&D journal articles/mil. pop. (37.36) as % of GDP (0.20) scientific & technical journal articles manufacturing & trade as % (142.00) of GDP (36.77) cost to enforce a contract cost to register a business (% of GNI per capita) (15.30) (% of GNI per capita) (8.70) Source: KAM 2005 (www.wordlbank.org/kam). the large diaspora, it is evident that Armenia has lost a significant part of its stock of researchers ("brain drain"), while the amount of scientific and technical publications has been falling throughout the years. Patent activity is minimal and has remained fairly stagnant throughout the years. Armenia, even though close behind Costa Rica and Chile, lags behind all selected comparators. In Figure 14.10, basic KAM indicators using the most recent avail- able data are presented that describe the performance of Armenia in the innovation pillar. One of the weakest indicators for Armenia is spending on R&D (0.2 percent of GDP), when the average for the lower middle income group is close to 0.9 percent (see Table 14.9). Looking into the financing situation in Armenia, we see that lend- ing rates remain high even in comparison with other transition econo- mies, preventing the banking system from fulfilling its financial inter- mediation capacity (Economist 2003). Between 1998 and February 2003 the annual refinancing rate fell from 39 percent to 10 percent, while the average lending rate fell from 48.5 percent to almost 21 percent. Evidence from the banking sector suggests that one of the reasons that lending rates remain high is the poor quality of financial management between banks and enterprises. A further reason is the underdevel- oped and corrupt judiciary, which keeps business risk high. Weighted average deposit rates fell from 25 percent in 1998 to 9.6 percent in 2002. The interest rate spread in Armenia, as shown in Table 14.10, is currently significantly higher than that in all its comparators. In the information communication technology (ICT) pillar, in the variables that describe the availability and penetration ratios of these Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 519 Table 14.9 Key Innovation Indicators, 1997­2004 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Research and development expenditure (% of GDP) Armenia 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.3 .. .. Slovenia 1.4 1.5 1.4 1.4 1.6 1.5 1.5 1.6 Russian Federation 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.2 1.2 1.3 1.2 Israel 3.1 3.3 3.8 4.7 5.0 5.0 4.7 4.5 Ireland 1.3 1.3 1.2 1.1 1.1 1.1 1.2 1.2 Chile 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.7 0.6 .. Manufactures exports (% of merchandise exports) Armenia 54.5 .. 62.6 61.1 .. 60.7 67.2 62.1 Slovenia 89.3 89.9 90.2 89.7 89.6 90.1 90.0 90.2 Russian Federation 23.2 28.7 24.7 22.1 21.6 20.3 21.1 20.9 Israel 92.1 92.4 93.2 94.1 94.5 92.9 92.5 94.4 Ireland 80.8 83.6 85.1 86.3 87.7 88.0 86.0 85.7 Chile 15.6 17.3 16.8 16.2 18.0 17.0 16.4 13.4 High-technology exports (% of manufactured exports) Armenia 5.4 .. 2.1 2.2 .. 1.6 1.3 1.1 Slovenia 4.1 4.3 3.9 4.7 5.1 5.2 6.3 5.5 Russian Federation 9.0 11.8 14.9 13.5 14.3 13.3 18.9 9.1 Israel 18.3 19.6 19.1 25.1 24.5 19.7 18.1 18.8 Ireland 46.2 44.1 46.7 47.5 47.3 40.6 34.5 33.8 Chile 3.3 3.7 3.2 3.4 3.2 3.8 3.4 4.8 Middle income 14.8 16.4 18.8 19.4 18.5 18.6 20.2 19.6 Lower middle income 15.1 16.6 18.3 19.3 18.8 19.3 21.9 23.0 Foreign direct investment, net inflows (% of GDP) Armenia 3.2 11.7 6.6 5.4 3.3 4.7 4.3 6.1 Slovenia 1.7 1.0 0.5 0.7 2.5 7.3 1.2 2.5 Russian Federation 1.2 1.0 1.7 1.0 0.9 1.0 1.8 2.1 Israel 1.6 1.7 3.0 4.4 3.2 1.7 3.5 1.4 Ireland 3.4 12.7 19.2 26.9 9.3 24.5 14.7 6.1 Chile 6.4 5.8 12.0 6.4 6.1 3.8 6.0 8.0 Middle income 3.1 3.3 3.7 3.1 3.1 2.7 2.4 2.7 Lower middle income 3.1 3.7 3.5 3.0 3.0 2.9 2.7 2.6 Source: SIMA, World Bank. 520 Part II: Detailed Analysis Table 14.10 Interest Rate Spread, 1996­2002: Armenia and Comparators 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Armenia 34.17 28.15 23.55 11.5 13.49 11.79 11.54 Estonia 8.82 5.57 6.99 6.9 3.67 3.75 3.96 Slovenia 7.51 6.84 5.55 5.14 5.72 5.24 4.93 Russian Federation 91.76 15.27 24.74 26.03 17.92 13.06 10.75 Israel 6.2 5.64 5.19 5.02 4.24 3.86 3.86 Chile 3.89 3.65 5.25 4.06 5.64 5.7 3.96 Ireland 5.56 6.11 5.79 3.24 4.67 4.74 3.73 Source: SIMA, World Bank. Figure 14.11 ICT: Armenia and the World 10 Australia United States Germany 9 G-7 LEVEL Korea, Rep. of G7 Ireland Finland 8 Israel Latvia Poland Canada Chile Japan 7 ENTRY LEVELEurope Developed & Central Asia Brazil Western Europe Oceania East Asia Costa Rica recent) 6 World Argentina Middle East & North America South Africa 5 China Jordan Russian Federation (most COPING Tunisia Turkey 4 ECONOMIES Mexico Latin America index 3 LAGGARDS Armenia Indonesia Kenya Africa 2 India Nigeria 1 Ghana Pakistan South Asia 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 index (1995) Source: KAM 2005 (www.wordlbank.org/kam). technologies, Armenia scores dramatically below the world and the ECA regional average, indicating the country's weakness in keeping up with regional and global technology penetration and usage trends (see Figure 14.11). ICT is the country's weakest pillar. In absolute terms, however, some improvement in Internet usage and computer penetration ratios was achieved, but the volume of those improve- ments was much less significant than those occurring globally. In Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 521 Figure 14.12 Armenia's Scorecard on ICT Variables (most recent) telephones per 1,000 people (178.10) international telecommunications, 10 main telephone lines per 1,000 cost of call (5.81) (148.00) 5 Internet users per 10,000 people mobile phone per 1,000 (394.72) (30.10) 0 internet hosts per 10,000 computers per 1,000 people (5.47) (15.80) daily newspapers per 1,000 (5.00) TV sets per 1,000 (229.00) radios per 1,000 (264.00) Source: KAM 2005 (www.wordlbank.org/kam). Armenia the current levels of Internet users per 10,000 people and computers available per 1,000 people are among the lowest in the region and globally. The availability of telephones and mobile phones per 1,000 people is also very limited, an additional element that indi- cates the profound weaknesses and state of emergency in the telecom- munications infrastructure of the country. The gap in performance between Armenia and its selected comparators is tremendous and is apparently widening. Figure 14.12 shows Armenia's performance relative to the world in ICT variables. Armenia's Growth Paradox Armenia's growth paradox is a high potential of knowledge utiliza- tion that shows tantalizing promise (for example, in software and cer- tain enterprises of heavy industry) but remains largely untapped. Box 14.3 gives the gist of how the growth paradox is seen at the micro level. It is manifested also as a shortage of skilled labor coexisting with major difficulties employing the highly skilled people returning, for example, from the United States. On a macro level, the growth paradox is led by a performance of total factor productivity (TFP). TFP is a proxy for the national capabil- ity to adopt, adapt, and create knowledge--a residual in the produc- tion function that cannot be explained by factor inputs.14 To illustrate formally Armenia's growth paradox, we produce projections for real GDP per capita for Armenia for the years 2003 to 2020 using different assumptions for the growth rate of TFP. 522 Part II: Detailed Analysis Figure 14.13 Armenia: Real GDP per Capita: Alternative Projections, 2003­20 7,000 actual projection 1: growth 6,000 (actual average 1993-2002) projection 2: 2% TFP growth 5,000 projection 3: 3% TFP growth projection 4: 4.81% TFP growth 4,000 (actual average 2000-02) thousands 3,000 US$ 2,000 1,000 0 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 year Source: Calculated by Derek Chen (WBIKD). TFP = total factor productivity. With reference to Figure 14.13, Projection 1 plots the path Armenia's real GDP per capita would take if the TFP growth rate were to take its 1993­2002 average value (that is, 0.66 percent per year). Projection 2 plots the path Armenia's real GDP per capita would take if the TFP growth rate were to take 2 percent per year (which was characteristic for such countries as Korea). Projection 3 plots the path Armenia's real GDP per capita would take if the TFP growth rate were to take 3 percent per year (Finland and Ireland). Lastly, Projection 4 plots the path that Armenia's real GDP per capita would take if the TFP growth rate were to take 4.81 percent per year, which is the actual value of the 2000­02 average for Armenia.15 The last projection, based on Armenia's TFP performance in 2000­02, is exceptionally good but it is clear that such high TFP rates are clearly not sustainable; yet, it is an indication of Armenia's potential. The growth projection based on the 1993­2002 TFP performance is more realistic but it promises a lackluster performance of slow growth. The big question is whether, over the next 10­15 years, Armenia would be able to catch up with role model countries and "realistic comparators" Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 523 Box 14.3 Armenia's Growth Paradox, Illustrated by Private Companies MSHAK Mshak is an Armenian company specializing in the modernization and retrofit of industrial equipment with computer controllers. It has a unique market for equipment automation projects that require the design and implementation of automation pilots, particularly for the machine tool manufacturers of the CIS region. The company was estab- lished in 1990 by highly skilled engineers with long-term experience in the design and production of control systems in the Ministry of Avia- tion Industry of the FSU. Fourteen specialists of Mshak engaged in the design of CNC (computer numerical control) systems. From 1994 Mshak started an exploration of the export markets. To demonstrate the advan- tages of its CNC systems, Mshak focused on the provision of complex engineering solutions to customers. This enabled the company to gain brand recognition and a good image in the CIS, Middle East (Iran), and Western markets. Today, Mshak, with its staff of 140 people, of which 90 are design engineers, is listed among the top five suppliers of complex management and engineering management systems for the Russian market. Mshak also offers state-of-the-art design and testing of industrial software as well as integrating unique machine and production-line automation solutions for international clients requiring specialized design and man- ufacturing of key high-precision components. The international clients of Mshak include companies such as National Semiconductor, Delta Tau Data Systems, and others. Only a few companies in the region are ready to provide solutions based on the advantages of state-of-the-art techno- logical improvements. Mshak is one of those companies. Nowadays, in close partnership with the Russian Staknoimport company, Mshak per- forms advanced research and implementation of new technologies, and has established a Processing Technologies Development Center. This is a facility focused not only on extensively promoting Mshak's production in Russia, but it also acts as a platform for the development of competi- tive technologies to be implemented in CIS and other foreign markets. The company is a "first mover" that demonstrates Armenia's promise as a knowledge-based economy. Yet the firm remains relatively small and far below the potential of engineering and design talent of Armenia. It illustrates Armenia's growth paradox on a micro level. NAIRIT Armenia's giant chemical factory, Nairit, is an example of large com- pany restructuring. The company's ownership has changed several times during recent years. 524 Part II: Detailed Analysis In Soviet times it had a monopoly and was the only factory in the Soviet Union making these products. It is still one of only five factories around the world producing synthetic rubber and exports in more than 20 countries. As a result of the most recent ownership "battle," all com- pany shares were acquired by a new and little-known Russian owner, in a sale welcomed by both government and company employees. The latest takeover of Nairit--one of Armenia's prime assets--follows the acrimonious departure last year of Ransat, the British-based company that tried to turn the factory around but ended up quarreling with the Armenian government after a row over responsibility for the factory's energy debts. A provisional deal was made with the help of the Arme- nian Development Agency and exercised by Armenia's Central Bank, which was in de facto control of the company, to sell Nairit to the Vol- gaburmash company, based in the Russian city of Samara. The new owner believes that Nairit is now undergoing a revival. According to the new management, about US$3.5 million had already been invested in the factory over the past 10 months and Nairit has recently crossed the profit threshold. The company started operating at full capacity, and obviously there are no more problems with production and sales. Almost 2,000 workers were receiving their wages regularly. Moreover, the company management was able to clear salary arrears of about US$350,000. The company now has a strong foundation, built on secure property rights and an educated labor force. But it has yet to show how these foundations can be transformed into sustained export- led growth. The same challenge applies to Armenia as a whole. Source: World Bank staff. and demonstrate 2­3 percent of TFP growth that countries as diverse as Korea, Ireland, and Finland show is feasible. One can see a threefold difference in per capita income by 2020 between the inertial scenario and the high potential scenario. Knowledge, quite literally, makes a dif- ference between poverty and wealth. Annex 14.1 provides more details on the theoretical framework for these growth projections. WHICH WAY FORWARD? TOWARD A NATIONAL AGENDA OF KNOWLEDGE-BASED COMPETITIVENESS This section discusses the actions required for Armenia's transition to a knowledge-based economy. The subsection immediately below introduces an overall strategy and discusses how this strategy can be Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 525 sequenced. The remaining sections identify key constraints--the fun- damental weaknesses of innovation, ICT, and education systems--and discusses how to alleviate them. Overall Strategy and its Sequencing To move forward, Armenia needs to implement major reforms. The reform agenda is as challenging as the institutional impediments to reforms. A pragmatic agenda for change often implies focusing on bottom-up entry points (immediate policy agenda), then scaling them up to assure coordination and concerted action (medium-term policy agenda), and then moving to major reforms (long-term policy agenda). The art and craft of policy making is about sequencing various hori- zons of the policy agenda in a virtuous circle of growth and reforms. Finland, Ireland, and Korea are the best-known, best-practice exem- plars of concerted action; they are countries that have engineered successful transitions to knowledge-based economies. In all these cases, national economic crises compelled diverse actors to define and implement a new agenda through explicit or implicit national agreements on goals and mechanisms to move forward. The crises also prompted policy makers and private sector leaders to lengthen the time horizon of the policies adopted. Thus, Nokia--Finland's first mover toward an innovation-based economy--dramatically increased R&D investments. Finland responded by increasing public R&D and transforming the innovation system to fit business needs. Members of parliament took courses and went on study tours demonstrating the need for the new agenda. National public innovation organizations played a crucial role, by transforming technology into businesses and assuring a critical mass of demonstration cases. Ireland also exemplifies a successful combination of top-down and bottom-up policies. It invested in education and R&D infrastructure in the 1980s, followed by drastic policy changes beginning in 1987. To complement its top-down policies, Ireland instituted pragmatic bottom- up programs, including regional partnerships to mitigate high unem- ployment and a program to expand national supplier linkages from FDI. Korea's powerful and shared national vision--and impetus which led to a private sector champion--was followed by effective govern- ment coordination (see Box 14.4). Three lessons are relevant for Armenia. First, simple institutional recipes do not exist for concerted action. Armenia will need to devise its own recipe for a KE. Given its great regional diversity, Armenia's regional and state-level policy initiatives would be a key entry point for a knowledge-based economy. Armenia has already advanced somewhat in that direction. 526 Part II: Detailed Analysis Box 14.4 Korea's Transition to a KE: Bottom-up Initiative Leads to Government Action In 1998, Korea officially launched a national strategy to move to a knowl- edge-based economy in the wake of a financial crisis. The initial impe- tus came from the private sector--the Maeil Business Newspaper--which concluded in 1996, even before the crisis, that there was an urgent need for a more coherent vision of the future of the Korean economy. This newspaper launched the "Vision Korea Project" as a national campaign in February 1997, and developed the first Vision Korea Report. Eventually, the government--the Ministry of Finance and Econ- omy--became the main champion of the KE policy agenda. The Korean Development Institute was a so-called system integrator and coordi- nated the work of a dozen think tanks. A joint World Bank and OECD report provided a framework, outlining concrete steps for reforms in the various policy domains. Progress was monitored closely. This was a crucial step in identi- fying and addressing any inertia or resistance, as, for example, with education. Korea's knowledge strategy of April 2000 evolved into a three-year action plan for five main areas: information infrastructure, human resources, knowledge-based industry, science and technology, and elimination of the digital divide. To implement the action plan, Korea established five working groups involving 19 ministries and 17 research institutes, with the Ministry of Finance and Economy coor- dinating the implementation. Every quarter, each ministry submits a self-monitoring report to the Ministry of Finance and Economy, which puts out an integrated report detailing progress. The midterm results and adjustments to the plan are sent to the executive director of the National Economic Advisory Council, which reports on the progress of the implementation and gives an appraisal of the three-year action plan to its advisory members. Source: Author's own elaboration. Second, the experiences of Korea and Finland teach us that even when major crises call for urgent economic transitions, countries must "prepare the bases." This essential preparatory stage is seen in the initial Vision Korea Report (see Box 14.4). It is seen in Finland's major effort to facilitate and accelerate business R&D. Third, although major reform efforts from the top are vital, they may not provide the all-important impetus for transformation. Con- certed effort must evolve. Bottom-up experiments in Armenia, some of which are already under way, must mature. These transitional stages then proceed to concerted efforts (the Korean knowledge strategy is Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 527 one example). Drawing on a diversity of best practices, we suggest that Armenia constructs and implements a strategy to move toward knowledge-based competitiveness in three stages: Immediate agenda: Begin massive awareness-building and initi- ate pilot/demonstration projects. Medium-term agenda (2005­08): Create a springboard for major reforms by assuring major improvements in the investment cli- mate, strengthening stakeholders for reforms, and proceeding with a private sector-led shared vision process. Long-term agenda (2008 onwards): Enact major reforms that would transform and create world-class innovation, education systems, and ICT infrastructure (see Table 14.11). Table 14.11 outlines a medium-term agenda (establishing a spring- board for KE) and a long-term agenda (major reforms, including creat- ing world-class KE infrastructure). We view the years from 1995 to 2003 as a stage of building foundations. Armenia's accession to the WTO in 2003 was an important event signaling that Armenia had a certain mac- roeconomic and socioeconomic stability and had created the basic insti- tutional foundations for a market economy. We argue that the time has come for a new stage of policy: assuring a critical mass of stakeholders for reforms. That, in turn, would imply a two-pronged strategy: Top-down approach: Dramatically reduce the administrative barriers to growth and improve in the investment climate. Bottom-up approach: Facilitate private sector-driven centers of excellence in innovation, enterprise upgrading, education, and ICT. To summarize, the sequencing of the transition to a knowledge- based economy in Armenia can be conceptualized as focusing on bot- tom-up entry points (the immediate policy agenda), then scaling them up to ensure coordination and concerted action (the medium-term pol- icy agenda), and then moving to major reforms (the long-term policy agenda). The art of policy making is about sequencing the various horizons of a policy agenda in a virtuous circle of growth and reforms. A pragmatic agenda for circumventing the institutional rigidities that Armenia faces would be to (i) create momentum for change by foster- ing stakeholder awareness, in order to (ii) gain consensus on tackling some of the key obstacles at the national level (to enhance the demand for an institutional change), and then to (iii) move ahead with concrete, manageable, bottom-up approaches that can serve as demonstration projects to move the larger agenda (Figure 14.14). Table 14.11 Sequencing of the Armenia KE Policy Agenda Stages of economic reform Drivers Thrust of Examples of 528 and growth Major constraints of growth government policy policy initiatives Benchmarks Building Sustainability of Remittances and Assuring macro and Infrastructure projects Signaling event: foundations macroeconomic stability other transfers social stability Accession to WTO (2003) Part Creation of business 1995­2003 and market reforms from abroad Some initiatives to council Other indicators: II: Infrastructure and improve innovation Investment share in GDP, Detailed services climate private investment in GDP (reasonably high) Level of knowledge-based Analysis exports (very low) Business share in innovation (practically nil) Establishing a Dearth of role models Increasing share Assuring a critical mass Competitive grant Signaling events: springboard for and stakeholders for of merchandise of stakeholders for schemes to enhance A multinational establishes KE, 2005­8 reforms (self-made exports; growing reforms through a two business innovation knowledge-intensive start-up and spin-off role of services pronged strategy: operations in Armenia Creation of innovation entrepreneurs) Top-down: dramatic council Elimination of ArmenTel reduction of monopoly administrative barriers Some skilled emigrants come to growth back and become successful Bottom-up: facilitation entrepreneurs of private sector-driven Rising share of business R&D "centers of excellence" and merchandise exports Major reforms: Human capital Skill-intensive Major overhaul Wide-scale introduction Significant return migration of creating world- constraint: inadequate exports of education, ICT of income-contingent highly skilled class KE stock and flow of Robust internal infrastructure, and scheme to finance Robust knowledge-intensive infrastructure, technical skills demand innovation systems private higher education clusters are established 2008­15 Inadequate ICT infrastructure Source: Elaboration by the author. Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 529 Figure 14.14 Virtuous Circle of Growth and Reforms from top to bottom Intermediate agenda Medium-term agenda Longer-term agenda demonstration projects critical mass structural reform sense of urgency of changes bottom up momentum Source: World Bank staff. Medium-Term Agenda: Alleviation of Critical Constraints The arguments about the sequencing of reforms discussed in the pre- vious section have been confirmed by experienced policy observers. For example, Dani Rodrik (2004) argues that the key to growth is not getting all or most institutions right at once, but rather overcoming the chief bottleneck to raising growth by, say, 2 percentage points a year, and using the proceeds of this improvement to overcome the next bot- tleneck--and so on. There is a kind of "bootstrapping reform" strategy that provides useful insight into the "how to" of reforms. As is evident from the analysis in Section 1, two major immediate constraints from the perspective of knowledge-based competitiveness are the following: An extremely weak and fragmented innovation system: lack of linkages between the productive sector, universities, and research institutes. The low quality and high prices of ITC infrastructure. From a longer-term perspective, human capital (particularly techni- cal and managerial skills) is a major constraint. Table 14.12 summarizes critical constraints from the perspective of the KE and the relevant medium-term policy agenda (to be discussed below) to alleviate constraints. 530 Table 14.12 Specific Policy Initiatives as Entry Points to Address Systemic Constraints Part Relevant best practices II: System Main objectives Specific initiatives (discussed in Section 3) Detailed Innovation system Enhance linkages between Competitive grant scheme to U.K. Teaching Company Scheme. productive sector, universities, promote business R&D and and science organizations. training. Analysis Seed support to venture capital fund. Education system Reform curriculum of basic, Technology/design facility on Competence center models secondary, and higher the basis of major university. (in design stage in Estonia). education. Distant education project collaboration with diaspora. Establish National Innovation Council to bring together education, R&D organizations, and industry. ICT infrastructure Improve quality of ICT Institutional strengthening of Liberalization policies in ICT services and reduce its costs. public utility regulator. infrastructure in some central European countries. Source: Author's own elaboration. Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 531 Innovation System: Making Innovation Relevant for Business An innovation system consists of a network of organizations, rules, and procedures that affect how a country acquires, creates, disseminates, and uses knowledge. Key organizations for the creation of knowledge include universities, public and private research centers, and policy think tanks. Private firms are at the center of the innovation system. If the private sector has little demand for knowledge, the innova- tion system cannot be effective. Effective R&D-industry linkages are vital to transform knowledge into wealth. Therefore, networking and interactions among the different organizations, firms, and individu- als are critically important. The intensity of these networks, as well as the incentives for acquiring, creating, and sharing knowledge, are influenced by the economic incentive regime in general. The innovation system framework, as it has been applied to a vari- ety of studies of OECD countries, relies excessively on innovation in the sense of the development of radical or incrementally new knowl- edge. Traditional measurements for an innovation system include indicators of expenditure on R&D, activity in high-technology sec- tors (biotechnology, ICT), patenting activity (number, intensity), and researchers per 10,000 population. These indicators proxy the ability to generate new knowledge. However, they are not particularly help- ful in understanding how a traditional, low-tech manufacturing firm can learn to upgrade its capabilities to compete in a more knowledge- based economy. Rather, these indicators are very often just the tip of the iceberg (see Figure 14.15), which conceals a layer of firms, mostly SMEs, for which the major issue is the acquisition of basic skills in marketing, design, engineering, and other operational areas rather than technology upgrading and R&D. Because of this, the traditional innovation system approach might be applicable to a very limited subset of the economy, such as firms in export-oriented sectors. It might also be useful for setting long-term goals and objectives in terms of creating the elements missing in the traditional approach. Table 14.13 flags a range of policy interventions, which should be considered as a menu of options, not all of them immediately relevant for Armenia. Armenian policy has a narrow view of technological development which is equated with R&D. The underlying model of technology development describes firms only as the demand side, relative to the supply side that is provided in R&D institutes and universities. The policy considers that the key to reducing the technology gap is not in the technology activities of enterprises themselves but through the expansion of intermediary institutions like technology centers and S&T parks. The problem of technology development is reduced to the issue of the commercialization of R&D results. 532 Part II: Detailed Analysis Figure 14.15 The Pyramid of the Learning Capabilities of Firms Research and technology development: advanced firms Very rarely present, mostly large firms R&D Design and engineering: technologically competent firms technology Capabilities rarely present in SMEs upgrading reverse engineering Technician and craft skills and capabilities: minimal technology firms In SMEs, strong skills sometimes present, technology acquisition though key skills often absent or weak assimilation Basic operating skills and capabilities: survival-oriented enterprises technology use In SMEs, often weak, with and operation limited and irregular upgrading Source: Adapted from Intarakumnerd et al (2002). Treating industry as purely demand side is quite misleading, because industrial firms not only generate the demand for industrial technology but they account for a very large part of the supply side as well. In fact, the generating capabilities of most technologies are located in industry (that is, in firms themselves), not in extramural organizations, whether S&T parks or R&D institutes. Business enter- prises fund between 50 and 60 percent of the GERD in North America, the EU, and the Nordic countries and they perform between 60 and 70 percent of GERD. Thus, the issue for Armenia is how to increase R&D in the business sector, not outside of it. In addition, using only R&D can be misleading, as a large contribution to technology development is made by types of technical change that do not involve formally organized R&D at all. Innovation surveys from EU and Central European economies show that the key source of important information for innovation comes from enterprises themselves or from partners in value chains (such as suppliers and buyers). Infrastructure institutions are actually marginal Table 14.13 Matching Policies to Capabilities: A Range of Instruments to Support Innovation Type of enterprise Policy objectives Instruments and interventions Survival-oriented To build basic competitive · business advisory and support services--SME and micro-enterprise support agencies enterprises capabilities by fostering · facilitation of access to finance (including micro-finance) awareness of scope and benefits · management and skills development of innovation Minimum To foster competitiveness by · support for business development, diversifying customer base Moving technology firms introducing basic innovation · product diversification and quality improvement skills and encouraging adoption · management and skills development and application of new ideas · Internet-based information services toward · technology awareness and marketing · support for technology adoption and adaptation projects · cluster-based approaches to stimulating innovation Knowledge-Based Technologically To support market development · business development, exports market support competent and entry into global value · Internet-based information services enterprises chains by fostering strategic · technology transfer support alliances and certain in-house · incubators and technology parks innovation capabilities · linkages with academic researchers · laboratory services and metrology services · consultancy and technical assistance support, such as on commercialization, Competitiveness intellectual property rights, licensing, patenting · supplier development and linkage promotion programs Advanced To facilitate moving up global · support for participation in international R&D networks (such as the EU 6th enterprises value chains by upgrading in- Framework Program) house innovation capabilities and · technology and other innovation-based spin-offs strategic alliances · university-industry collaboration · support for commercialization Diffuse experience of innovation · development of vibrant venture capital industry leaders as role models for the 533 · encourage participation of national innovation leaders in national advisory bodies, rest of the economy technology foresight, and cluster processes Source: Elaboration by the author. 534 Part II: Detailed Analysis as a direct source of information for innovation. The importance of non-R&D technology development suggests that it is inappropriate to narrow down innovation policy to R&D policy and to bridging insti- tutions alone. In fact, infrastructure institutions are much more impor- tant as sources of knowledge and skills carried by people who move between universities, R&D institutes, and firms. Information services, training and standard services, as well as problem solving and R&D, are all forms of people-centric types of outputs and are the key func- tion of extramural technology institutes. One of the most important roles played by R&D in public technology institutes is to contribute the flow of people into the technological activities of industry. In Armenia, as in many Eastern European and CIS countries, there seems to be a dearth of measures that seek to stimulate firms to undertake their own technology development. Policy is much more focused on measures that support institutions in undertaking S&T activities on behalf of industrial firms. Within the innovation policy, there are no policy measures that support and facilitate actions by firms themselves. In a nutshell, Armenia should avoid an exclusive focus on support- ing technology institutions in a supply-driven approach, with support to extramural institutions rather than to firms. The balance between those aspects concerned directly with strengthening the technology development capabilities and activities of firms, and those concerned with building and strengthening various kinds of technology develop- ment and transfer institutions, should be corrected. Currently, there is no system that would support firms to move upwards in technological activities, from technology use and maintenance to technology devel- opment and creation. Mechanisms to support technology transfer institutions (S&T parks) are an important component of the policy system. However, a major emphasis in policy development should be on mechanisms that assist and empower firms to make their own investments in technology absorption and development. Within that firm-centered approach to policy, increasing emphasis has to be given to stimulating and facili- tating various forms of collective activity involving groups of firms. These groups may be established industry associations or less for- mally structured groups organized around value chains or clusters of firms in related industries. Among the instruments of innovation policy in Armenia, grant- based mechanisms are notably absent. These mechanisms commonly provide grants to firms that undertake particular kinds of technologi- cal activity (for example, R&D, design, technological or managerial training, engagement of consultants, employment of qualified scien- tists and engineers, and many others). In most cases the grants cover a defined proportion of the costs of the specific activity. Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 535 ICT Infrastructure: Assuring the Entry of New Service Providers Section 1 documents a very low level of development for ICT infra- structure. Figure 14.16 shows that Armenia performs just below the average for the economies of the former USSR, which is hardly satis- factory given Armenia's peculiar geographical position and its aspira- tions to develop a competitive ICT cluster.16 This is mainly attribut- able to one single problem: the ArmenTel monopoly. As this issue is discussed extensively in an earlier chapter, here it is simply noted that Figure 14.16 Comparative Performance of Armenia's ICT Infrastructure 3,500 Ukraine 3,000 Latvia 2,500 (US$/yr) 2,000 capita 1,500 Turkmenistan per Kazakhstan 1,000 Uzbekistan Georgia Belarus Tajikistan GDP 500 Ukraine Armenia Kyrgyz Rep.Azerbaijan 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 Fixed teledensity (lines per 100 inhabitants) 3,500 Ukraine 3,000 Latvia 2,500 (US$/yr) 2,000 capita 1,500 Uzbekistan Turkmenistan per Kazakhstan 1,000 Belarus Georgia GDP 500 Ukraine Tajikistan Armenia Kyrgyz Rep. Azerbaijan 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 Total teledensity (lines per 100 inhabitants) Source: Author's own elaboration. 536 Part II: Detailed Analysis a full liberalization of the market and the institution of an appropriate regulatory framework are essential if the economy is to benefit from the low costs produced through genuine competition. Formation of Human Capital: Enhancing Education-Industry Linkages Many problems of the education sector, especially in the school sys- tem, are well-understood and are being addressed through existing and planned reforms (many under various World Bank operations). In this section we will focus in more detail on the education-industry linkages. Major Issues Covered by the Current Dialogue with the Government Chronic underspending. Armenian public spending on education is 2.8 percent of GDP, well below the OECD average of 5 percent and the rate in other transition economies. Private spending is also low (less than 0.5 percent), as is education as a proportion of public spending (11 percent). Inefficiency. A dramatic fall in the school-age population since inde- pendence, together with only modest reductions in staffing levels, has resulted in staffing ratios that are low in international terms and, more important, unsustainable in the Armenian context. For example, there are only about 11 pupils for every full-time equivalent teacher. The Multi-Task Expenditure Framework proposes increasing these overall ratios to 1 teacher for every 16 students. This major rationalization is being supported by the Structural Adjustment Credit (SAC) V and the Education Quality and Relevance (EQ&R) project. Lack of relevance. There has been little reform of the curriculum, the assessment methods, or teacher training since independence. The main challenge is the transition from a teacher-centered to a student- centered learning approach. Reforms supported under the EQ&R project will be a major step toward meeting this challenge. Equity. Enrollment in basic education continues to fall, and is now below 85 percent. The low levels of public spending have resulted in increasing levels of informal payments in "free" basic education. In higher education, expansion has been mainly in private institutions and fee-paying places at public institutions. While this has increased access--though still for only 16 percent of the cohort--public spend- ing overwhelmingly favors the rich, since state scholarships are given mainly to those who score highest on the entrance examination. Governance and management. One of the biggest, and most difficult, challenges Armenia faces is to move away from the top-down system Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 537 of management, in which the Ministry of Education passes directives that are then uniformly applied to all institutions, and in which the flow of information is one way and is used to control rather than empower local actors. Tertiary education. A major stakeholder conference was held in November 2002, organized during the preparation of SAC V. The equity concerns have been mentioned. The lack of quality assurance mechanisms (such as accreditation and inspection) means that students and other stakeholders cannot choose better institutions and courses, and good-quality private insti- tutions are undermined by a small number of fly-by-night operators. Investment is low or nonexistent, resulting in poor quality, an out- dated teaching environment, and an almost complete absence of inter- national-level research. Education-Industry Linkages Historically, Armenia has had a highly educated population, and educational attainment figures have remained remarkably high since independence despite the low levels of spending. However, the skills and knowledge that individuals have acquired have become increas- ingly obsolete in the labor market. Much of the education would have been fact-based information learned through rote; and, even if the education were more relevant to the labor market, high levels of unemployed, underemployment, and informal employment would have eroded skills and knowledge. Older adults, though they are more likely to be employed, would also have worked for longer periods in state-owned, static industries. The story of a private company, Lycos, illustrates the main issues and options to enhance education-industry linkages. Lycos is a fully owned subsidiary of the German-based Lycos Europe. Lycos Armenia is integrated into Lycos Europe's network of competence centers in Gutersloh, Copenhagen, Hamburg, Munich, Paris, and Stockholm for the development of its core services: search, communication, commu- nities, and shopping. Lycos Armenia is in the software development business (Web posting, e-mail, chat room communities, e-commerce) and provides technical support to the Lycos Europe portal. Impor- tantly, the company works closely with two universities in Yerevan and provides grant funding of about US$500,000 for a two-year bach- elor's program on Internet computing designed primarily by Lycos staff. Sixty to 70 percent of the lectures is also given by Lycos staff. Throughout the program internships are also offered in the Lycos offices in Armenia and elsewhere in Europe. The top graduates of the program are usually hired by the company. 538 Part II: Detailed Analysis The fact that a private company establishes its own training pro- grams, and, more important, does this in collaboration with major Armenian universities is promising. This indication of the effective demand of private sector and private sector initiative is a foundation on which a coherent private-sector-led system of lifelong learning can be built. The following options for expanding and accelerating the existing education-industry linkages could be considered: Distance learning as a pilot project (Box 14.5). The advantage of this potential distance learning project is that it would bring together ICT and education dimensions. As Box 14.5 outlines, the Armenian diaspora can become involved in a new and productive way. In addition, as world-wide experience of dis- tance learning indicates, these projects are easily scaled up and expanded when successful. Establishment of a Skills Development Fund to encourage enter- prise sector training (Box 14.6). Creation of a National Innovation Council to bring together three major stakeholders: the productive sector, university and other educational organizations, and R&D organizations. Such an inno- vation council consisting of 13­19 influential members represent- ing the three major stakeholders would take major decisions on innovation, enterprise upgrading, and education-industry link- ages. Companies such as Lycos, representing national best prac- tice, would become members of the Council and would have a platform to share and scale up their initiatives. HOW TO IMPLEMENT THE STRATEGY? FROM VISION TO ACTION This section focuses on the implementation of policies and projects outlined in the previous section. Implementation capabilities are a critical constraint not only in Armenia but in many semi-industrialized economies. This is due to the simultaneous weakness of both govern- ment and market institutions. Given this weakness, many projects and initiatives that worked well in a well-developed institutional environment show only mediocre results. This section discusses the kinds of incentives, governance, and management that will, given Armenia's difficult institutional environment, best implement the policies and projects of the KE. The section is structured as follows. The subsection immediately below introduces a key notion of prag- matic policies and institutions. The next two sections consider factors in the success of policies and programs and relevant lessons for Armenia. The section that follows considers new mechanisms to Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 539 Box 14.5 Distance Learning as a Potential Pilot Project to Enhance Education-Industry Linkages Distance learning could be a low-cost opportunity for Armenia to accel- erate the transfer of global knowledge and drastically upgrade the qual- ity of teaching in its universities. For a landlocked, remotely located country, modern technology could provide the following group of pri- mary benefits: Access to high caliber professors and lecturers, who would initially demonstrate how the core modern curricula should be delivered to students and therefore greatly contribute to the training and retraining of the trainers (local professors). The availability of various professional talents in the diaspora and the existence of an established professional diaspora network would simplify the future mobilization of potential participants and could further reduce project costs (many diaspora members may be ready to provide such lecturing on a pro bono basis). Recent examples from Turkey and Thailand confirm the feasibility of such an approach. Online access to modern experimental facilities and academic libraries. Economies of scale, including low-cost dissemination/sharing of popular courses among various local universities and training centers. As with many other collective diaspora initiatives, the distance learn- ing project, especially in the area of engineering, is likely to lead rather quickly to the second generation of (indirect) benefits. As experience from other countries suggests, professionals participating in advanced educational projects abroad tend to be eager to launch new business ventures with their local partners and frequently with their former stu- dents. On the parallel track, the collective efforts of diaspora activists in the area of university education has a potential to evolve gradually toward more business-oriented projects, undertaken basically by the same group of initial diaspora sponsors (for example, those associated with university business incubators). Source: Author's own elaboration. make the Armenian diaspora an entry point of Armenia's transition to knowledge-based competitiveness. The concluding section outlines specific proposals to enhance the innovation and enterprise upgrad- ing system in Armenia. Box 14.6 Toward a National System of Support for Continuous Vocational Training The innovation policy should offset as far as possible the "market failures" facing firms' investments in skills and technological capabili- ties. Building a knowledge-based economy requires that much greater national effort should be given to investments in the skills of the work- ing-age population. Steps should be taken to move forward as fast as possible with defining and implementing the details of a broad and comprehensive training support system within the framework of a Skill Development Fund. More specifically, the government could introduce a levy-grant system by which firms contribute a levy to a central fund from which they can secure a grant to reimburse costs incurred in under- taking training. The levy thus operates as a disincentive; if the firm does not invest in training it will not reimburse these costs. The levy rate should be defined as a proportion of the wage bill that can be set at x percent (2 percent, for example) on average. It can vary across the size of firms, with large firms paying more than small. Reimbursement of funds should be administered by the Skill Development Fund. Firms below a certain size should be exempt. For example, the mandatory training requirements should be specified only for firms with more than 100 employees. Firms below 100 employees would be excluded from this system owing to high administrative costs and the large number of low-value contributions from those firms. Reimburse- ment available to a firm could be capped at the level of its contribu- tion to the Skill Development Fund. Alternatively, firms that contribute disproportionately to the system could be allowed to secure reimburse- ment above the level of the levies that they have paid. Providers of training should come from a wide range of sources. These could include local training organizations and institutions, in-house train- ing, and specialized instruction by overseas providers, including suppliers and parent companies. Eligible forms of training should be specialized and should be for higher-level skills. In addition, groups of firms should collaborate in engaging training providers to run specific training pro- grams for them on a joint basis. This should help to match training provi- sion more closely to firms' needs while reducing costs per trainee. Routine training should not be 100 percent eligible for reimbursement, while high reimbursement should be allowed for training that develops high-level skills. For instance, reimbursable training would promote core skills for operating and using industrial technologies, intermediate-level technicians, engineering and managerial capabilities, and high-level R&D and management skills. Training that will not be reimbursed, such as basic operating skills and general management skills, should also be specified. Eligible firms should be entitled to vouchers to cover the proportion of the costs of training provided by supplier organizations. Where firms by explicit design and agreement could operate as training suppliers for any industry, its suppliers or its customers should be entitled to higher levels of grant payment. Source: Author's own elaboration. 540 Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 541 Pragmatism: Adopting and Adapting What Works Following the 1997 World Development Report (World Bank 1997), we adopt a two-pronged strategy to address the weakness of the imple- mentation capabilities: In the short run, match institutional design to the existing capa- bilities. In the long run, invigorate the institutional capabilities. Pragmatism--adopting and adapting what works, even though it may result in idiosyncratic institutions--is a hallmark of the proposed strategy. For instance, there have been several attempts to commercial- ize the intellectual property and human capital of hard sciences. The International Finance Corporation (IFC) has considered a venture cap- ital fund to be funded, at least partially, with diaspora contributions. It was generally viewed that the project was restricted to deal flow.17 But the problem of insufficient deal flow and lack of private financing for business innovation is a chicken-and-egg situation, which can be resolved by focusing simultaneously on investing in the project pipe- line and funding the resulting projects. Organizations that perform all of these functions are quite idiosyncratic in the sense that they are innovation systems under one roof. Yet they work. Box 14.7 discusses one such organization--Fundación Chile--and the relevance of the Fundación Chile model for Armenia. Box 14.7 The Fundación Chile Model and Its Relevance for Armenia One of the most successful attempts in the Latin American region was to establish national "antennae" for new technologies via Fundación Chile. The Fundación originally was a joint effort between the Chilean govern- ment and the U.S. firm ITT, but now largely autonomous. Fundación Chile uses four main techniques in its technology transfer and dissemi- nation work: (i) it captures and disseminates technologies to multiple users though seminars, specialized magazines, and project assistance; (ii) it develops, adapts, and sells technologies to clients in the produc- tive and public sectors, both in the country and abroad; (iii) it fosters institutional innovations and incorporates new transfer mechanisms; and (iv) it creates innovative enterprises, almost always in association with companies or individuals. The creation of demonstration companies by Fundación Chile has undergone successes and failures, but overall has proved effective as a 542 Part II: Detailed Analysis method for disseminating new technologies. The companies are trans- ferred to the private sector once the technologies have been proven in practice and their economic profitability has been established. One of the most successful cases, which exhibits many elements of the success- ful development of a knowledge cluster, is that of the salmon industry, which in a period of 10 years grew to become a dynamic export sector. By 2004, Fundación Chile had launched 61 such ventures, three-quarters of which have been sold to private investors. The six leading companies have generated more revenues than the total cost of the Fundación dur- ing its existence. The systemic technology focus of Fundación Chile includes biotech- nology, management, environment, financial engineering, and informa- tion. Recent focus areas include forestry genetics and DNA vaccines for aquaculture. Fundación Chile has also developed the identification of missing links for developing clusters with comparative advantage into a business practice. The clusters include the agribusiness, marine, tourism (agro/eco), forestry, and wood processing sectors. Fundación Chile is a powerful private organization that performs all the functions of the project cycle, from the identification of market niches to the creation of firms to take advantage of opportunities. It is an innovation system, as it should be, all under one roof. One can think of a possible Foundation Armenia focused on the transformation of Armenia's considerable human capital prowess into innovation projects valued at a marketplace as a reinvention of Fundación Chile in the Armenian context. Below we outline certain key features of Fundación Chile's success, and the availability of these features in Armenia. Factors of Success of the Fundación Chile Model Relevance for Armenia 1. An entrepreneurial, highly 1. Professional management is paid, and highly professional critical. Given the shortage of management team (which top-notch managerial teams, takes years to establish). this would be a challenge, but 2. Arm's length relationship a challenge that can be met. with the government; 2. Such independence could operates as a business, not as be a litmus test for diaspora a public sector organization. leaders that could leverage 3. Private shareholders that diaspora investments into the do not expect an immediate Foundation's endowments. return and tolerate risks 3. Risk tolerance and long-term (businessmen oligarchs with goals could be a litmus test a strategic agenda). for the new generation of private-sector champions. Source: World Bank staff. Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 543 Given that most knowledge-based activities are concentrated in the capital city of Yerevan, Armenia is tantamount to a city-state. It can become a laboratory for pragmatic institutions to enhance the trans- formation of knowledge to wealth. For that to happen, policy makers would need to focus on two issues: First mover problem: building credibility by focusing on a few entry points such as relatively low-cost pilot initiatives. Change begins with first movers; that is, firms and other organizations that cap- ture new opportunities first. In general, they are exceptions. The issue is how to move from exceptions to the mainstream. Collective action problem: achieving critical mass by building constitu- encies for reform and change. Modern management concepts such as clusters and value chains shed light on how to use collective action to build constituencies and work for change. Many pilot solutions can be adopted starting from Armenia's two nascent clusters: the jewelry and diamond cluster and the software cluster (see Box 14.8 on the notion of clusters and value chains). Box 14.8 Clusters and Value Chains Two analytical constructs drawn from management science have proved useful: clusters and supply chains (also known as value-added chains). The two concepts share the view that economic activity is not coordi- nated solely by means of signals generated by an impersonal market- place, but that such activity also involves direct coordination through face-to-face communication. Clusters are groups of firms, research centers, and universities that cooperate in a specific area of business in order to achieve economies of scale and scope. Innovation clusters are formed to conduct knowledge- intensive activities. A value-added chain is one of vertical linkages. It describes the full range of activities required to bring a product or service from conception and design, through the different phases of production (involving a combination of physical transformation and the input of various producer services), marketing, and delivery to final consumers. A value-added chain is usually defined for particular products (such as automobiles, electronics, garments, or pharmaceuticals), but it typically crosses different industries; and each stage of production is much more closely linked with the upstream and downstream industries in the chain rather than with other producers in the same industry. Source: Author's own elaboration. 544 Part II: Detailed Analysis The jewelry and diamond sector could be a much more significant driver of growth than it has been so far. The double-digit growth potential of this sector is still faced with several major external, inter- nal, and industry-specific obstacles. Low domestic purchasing power depresses the demand for jewelry, which makes Armenian producers excessively dependent on export. Low costs of labor do not stimulate producers to enhance productivity and diversify, and they face tough competition in downstream jewelry. The lack of a collective brand is compounded by a lack of direct access to consumers and an outdated product mix. The removal of major constraints to productivity growth in this sector would increase its output from the current US$45 million to US$150 million in 2010 (McKinsey and Company 2003). A full liberalization of the jewelry-trading regime, which would include the replacement of customs duties by retail sales taxes and negotiation of favorable access to consuming countries, would give a much-needed boost to the sector. Access to consumer markets abroad would be greatly facilitated if the industry could attract one or two global gem certification agencies and international banks and ensure a long-term diamond supply agreement with Russia. The removal of con- straints could then be followed by investments in education and infra- structure, which should ensure the sustainability of industry upgrading and that could be generated through the first--liberalization--step. A design center for the jewelry and diamond cluster could be a pilot ini- tiative to move the cluster up the value chain. It is important, however, that such a design center is a private-public initiative, with some invest- ments made by sector associations and/or by leading companies rather than by the public sector alone. A nascent software cluster is already in the limelight and looks promising. It demonstrates double-digit rates of export growth in spite of the recent ITC slowdown in the United States. Outsourcing from the business diaspora, mainly from California, is a main factor in the cluster's dynamism. Companies such as Virage Logic and oth- ers were first movers and role models. Importantly, joint programs between universities and companies, such as programs established by Lycos, indicate that these companies understand the importance of and promote concerted action. The recently established Enterprise Incubator Foundation is slowly starting to play the role of a catalyst for concerted action by clusters' companies. Building on these positive trends, the main challenge is the deepening of the current outsourcing model from the outsourcing of relatively simple operations to the out- sourcing of knowledge processes (such as corporate R&D and other knowledge-intensive operations). All companies in the sector need to strengthen their marketing and managerial capabilities, which are currently quite weak. These challenges were articulated in a number Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 545 of studies such as the McKinsey Armenia 2020 study (McKinsey and Company 2003). The challenge now is effective implementation. The discussion that follows focuses on the factors in the success of innovation and enterprise upgrading programs and discusses some recent interventions. Factors in the Success of Policies and Programs World experience shows that to be effective in promoting knowledge- based linkages and networks, interventions need to be customer- oriented, collective, and cumulative (Triple-C approach): Customer-oriented efforts must be driven by the needs and demands of the customer. This forces firms to face up to underly- ing problems of competitiveness. The most successful interven- tions are those that help firms to learn about their customers and then introduce the changes and innovations needed for them to meet market demands. Collective refers to outside assistance that is directed at groups of enterprises rather than at individual firms. This means working with business associations, producer groups, and other indus- try alliances. Where these do not exist, support can be linked to the formation of such groups. Collective assistance has two advantages: it is more cost-effective than assisting enterprises individually, and it helps to develop constructive relationships among firms, which can improve their efficiency and increase the potential for learning from each other. Cumulative means that one-off improvements are not enough; if firms are to remain competitive, they need to be able to change and develop in response to new market conditions and new opportunities. The objective should be to help generate this capacity within groups of firms, so that, in the longer term, pub- lic support is no longer needed. Other factors in the success and acceleration of linkages and enter- prise upgrading include the following: Development of a standard set of metrics to measure the perform- ance of programs. Performance orientation. The successful programs are loaded and driven by incentives and induce self-selection among firms, help- ing those that help themselves, illustrating how they can and should help themselves, and suggesting exit to those that are not capable, because of internal or external factors, of improving themselves. 546 Part II: Detailed Analysis Critical importance of entrepreneurial management. Successful organ- izations supporting technology and SMEs are often initiated by social entrepreneurs--individuals with unusual problem-solving and management skills and the motivation for enterprise adjust- ment. The success of a support agency is predicated on such an entrepreneurial manager at the top of the organization. Suc- cessful organizations tend to evolve from the reliance on a key top individual to a robust organization with efficient corporate governance. Cost recovery. A successful support organization should aim for eventual full cost recovery. Extensive use of follow-up techniques (benchmarking). Successful programs help, through benchmarking indicators, to diagnose where firms are, what they need to do to improve, and what the alternatives are for those unlikely to survive. Leveraging their effectiveness with the use of ICT. Develop Internet portals and Internet immersion institutes, improve access to the Internet, provide access to ICT instruments, train firms accord- ingly, and inform them about the benefits. A number of these initiatives should be developed at the state level and coordinated at the federal level. Participation of clients in the design of the programs. Clients not only need to pay for the services of the support organization; they also need to participate in the design and evaluation of pro- grams. To ensure that they do, SME programs should never be run by governments (whether federal or subnational) but rather by an autonomous private management contractor working in cooperation with the government but independently of it. Gradualism and assistance linked to performance. Successful pro- grams link assistance with performance as firms improve them- selves. For SMEs, in particular, a touch of realism in assisting SMEs to identify their possibilities and potential is essential, as is assistance with exit for firms that are not viable. Building on Lessons from Enterprise Development and Investment Promotion Programs The best-practice principles outlined above were the guiding principles for the design of the Enterprise Incubator Foundation (EIF) to support the nascent ITC cluster and the Armenia Development Agency (ADA) to market Armenia as a prime location for FDI. Yet the outcomes to date have not fulfilled stakeholders' expectations, including Arme- nian stakeholders, the international business community, and the gov- ernment. Both initiatives were financed by the World Bank through learning and innovation loans (LILs). The problems of the ADA and Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 547 EIF are characteristic of other enterprise and investment promotion programs and organizations. This is why it is paramount to learn their implementation lessons before proceeding to a new program or project. Three factors appear important in explaining this somewhat disappointing performance. 1. Difficulties in matching local talent with global expertise to form a stellar managerial team. Given the daunting challenges of carrying out the job, these organizations must have exceptional manage- rial teams with outstanding technical capabilities. The relevant expertise, however does not exist in-house almost by definition. It would have been advisable to hire management through inter- national recruitment (targeting particularly the diaspora) with a mandate that the expatriate manager would nourish a local managerial team. Of the two projects, ADA is performing better, not only because it is a smaller project but because it is more con- servative in its objectives. ADA has an Irish manager (number two in the organization), and through various grant schemes ADA has managed to gain regular access to international con- sultants, some from the diaspora. 2. Government rent-seeking and insufficient strategic commitment from the government. The government should have maintained stra- tegic commitments to the projects by critically reviewing per- formance and resorting to personnel and other organizational challenges if necessary. In contrast, even simple measures such as endowing EIF with adequate real estate in an attractive loca- tion turned out to be a major problem. Although there is insuf- ficient strategic commitment, the government desires to control the day-to-day management of the organizations. High salaries sometime raise stakes in rent-seeking rather than leading to the selection of the best and brightest. 3. Slow learning curve. Given the organizational challenges, the learning curve is inevitably slow and more so in Armenia's dif- ficult institutional environment. Given the slow learning curve, one should have encouraged low expectations from stakehold- ers and the organizations should have been focused on "low- hanging fruits"--really simple projects with visible and tangible results. To the extent that EIF follows this strategy of focusing on tangible entry points (in organizing technical and managerial training, for instance), it could gradually build its credibility in the eyes of its private sector clients and other stakeholders. In general, external funding should be used to support programs, not new organizations. Rodrik (2004) gives a very persuasive explana- tion of why international organizations should only exceptionally aim 548 Part II: Detailed Analysis to support the building of new organizations. He argues that there are no noncontext-specific ways of achieving desirable institutional outcomes (that is, institutional outcomes are always context specific). This means that any transfer of ready organizational models from elsewhere will be faced with the problem that there is no unique map- ping of functions that organizations should undertake for their own forms (that is, effective institutional outcomes do not map into unique institutional designs). From this it follows that institutional forms will always be different from their designed institutional functions. This hints at serious problems with the transfer of organizational models, which would require not only transfers of organizational functions and organizational forms but also should ensure their matching. However, this strategy would face the constraints of context specificity, which will always block one-to-one mapping of forms and functions. Instead, we suggest that external assistance be based on funding a variety of programs that should be undertaken by existing organiza- tions. If organizations are to be created then they should be created based on programs (functions) rather than on forms. In fact, forms of programs implementers should be secondary as long as they enable the effective implementation of programs. For example, the establishment of a Skills Development Fund should be secondary to its key function, which is the funding of vocational training programs (see below). Another example is the establishment of technoparks where form has been given preference over functions. The example of French tech- nopoles shows how the reality may be very far from the model. The S&T parks in the United Kingdom, attached to universities, represent a huge variety of local situations. Analysis of the Taiwanese Hsinchu Park shows how the model can develop as an outcome of a variety of very specific conditions. The lesson learned from these cases is that the form has been given preference over function. This explains why in the real world it is difficult to distinguish any clear national model, as all parks differ with respect to the functions they fulfill. In this respect, opting for just one organizational form seems to us to be futile. We would suggest that priority be given to the support of the functions of technoparks, rather than the organizational form of the technopark. Supporting technology transfer and the emergence of new-technol- ogy-based businesses via the formation of new organizations such as technology business incubators (technoparks) is quite risky. Unlike funding projects for existing organizations, building new organiza- tions is a demanding task, fraught with difficulties. New organiza- tions are heavily reliant on entrepreneurs, and on the acceptance of organizations on which they depend. Managers of technoparks have to combine a range of personal traits, and their success is dependent on a variety of external factors outside their control. Very often, the Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 549 bulk of the money going into technoparks is invested in buildings, while other tasks--such as generating synergies among parks, bring- ing in innovative projects, and developing incubation services--are relegated to secondary status or not supported at all. The whole proc- ess takes several years, and the failure rate is very high. The key point is to distinguish between support for technopark/ business incubator activities (such as cooperation with R&D and higher education institutions, active management of technology trans- fer, and support for technology-intensive activities) and support for technoparks as organizations. Instead of being focused on technoparks as organizations, the government should focus its support, first, on innovation projects, second, on the people who will be involved in the management of innovation projects, and, third, on supporting techn- oparks as organizations. The ranking of support functions would be as follows: activities (innovation projects) people (training for technology transfer) organizations (technoparks and enterprise incubators) What we often find is that the reality is exactly the opposite: the primary focus is on organizations, with the focus on activities being relegated to the background. The policy lesson is that the focus should be on supporting functions (that is, linkages and technology-based activities) rather than only on organizational forms (technoparks, incubators, etc.), as very often these forms are empty shells where close proximity gives the illusion of technological synergies, while in reality not much happens. The Diaspora Role It is evident from the previous discussion that stakeholders in Arme- nia (and in developing economies in general) must have the capac- ity to acquire new knowledge if they are to compete in the world economy.18 Learning, in turn, supposes, and contributes to, the abil- ity to search out and recombine usefully scattered information about production methods, markets, and resources. And because develop- ment depends on learning and learning on searching, development almost invariably depends on linking the domestic economy to the larger, foreign world--for even the strongest economies quickly redis- cover (if they ever forget) that they cannot generate world-class ideas in isolation. Historically, contact with the outside world was often established through skilled immigrants and the ethnic communities they founded in the host country: think of the contribution of the 550 Part II: Detailed Analysis Huguenots in France; the Jews in Monterrey, Mexico; the Chinese in the Philippines, Indonesia, or Malaysia; or the Indians in East Africa, then Great Britain. During much of the twentieth century, multina- tional firms have facilitated knowledge transfers by establishing facili- ties--usually for the manufacture or assembly of mature products--in developing countries, often with the assistance of local elites. Viewed in this long, historical perspective, network diasporas are but the lat- est bridge institutions connecting the developing economy insiders, with their risk-mitigating knowledge and connections, to the outsiders in command of technical know-how and investment capital. At least for the developing economies the attraction of diaspora networks as compared to immigrant communities and multinational firms is that diaspora networks help depoliticize relations between the domestic and foreign actors from whom they learn. Thus they can transform a volatile, often irrational struggle for power into a mutu- ally beneficial economic exchange. That learning is often connected to ugly frictions is a commonplace: Economically powerful ethnic minori- ties are traditionally suspected of having greater loyalty to their own community than to the host country and therefore of being tempted to exploit the latter to the profit of the former. Powerfully autono- mous, and often footloose, multinational firms are easily seen as the agents, even the masters, of economic imperialism more than partners in development. The actors in diaspora networks, in contrast, are native sons and daughters. Even if they are personally wealthy, or connected to wealthy families or important multinationals, they seldom command anything like the resources attributed to economically potent minorities (whose riches, though real enough, are often magnified by envy) or to the world's largest companies. They are therefore, in prospect at least, a connection to the indispensable world of foreign knowledge, but a connection that can be domesticated and then used to discipline the behavior of ethnic communities and multinationals. That the members of network diasporas are likely to be suspected in their host countries of putting personal gain or ethnic ties above managerial professional- ism makes them (from the point of view of the sending country) more pliant, and more willing to cooperate on a truly equal footing. Diaspora networks seem to form spontaneously as the result of the shortcomings as well as the successes of the mesh of individual and national strate- gies for economic advancement; this spontaneity only completes the picture of the diaspora network as the solution to a crucial problem of coordinated learning too long fraught with political passions. The diasporas of India and China have demonstrated that expatri- ates can play a very productive role in development. Armenia, how- ever, presents quite a different case. The Armenian diaspora is mas- sive: more than 1 million Armenians live in the United States, and at Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 551 least another million in Europe, the Middle East, and Latin America. This diaspora is famously successful both economically and profes- sionally; and it is also well organized politically and socially. Another 1.5 million Russian Armenians, traditionally quite influential in the Kremlin, could be counted on as well. Finally, the territorial conflict in Karabakh has mobilized Armenians worldwide, greatly strengthened ethnic identity, and advanced national consolidation. While Armenia has also had serious economic disadvantages--its landlocked location, the impact of the 1988 earthquake, and loss of markets in the Soviet Union--on balance the country has great potential for development. "Despite their outspoken support for investments, the Armenian government has been mostly interested in receiving humanitarian aid and long-term unrestricted loans--sources of funding they can con- trol much more easily than direct investments" (Bremmer 2001). The hostility of insiders has thwarted many of the diaspora's attempts to invest. And compounding the problem, major diaspora organizations have never systematically tried to protect their members from the elite's abuse. Rather, the diaspora tends to limit its public criticism out of concern for the government's reputation. Nor has it attempted to evaluate rigorously the results of the massive assistance it has pro- vided in the last decade. For this diaspora, as for others in similar situ- ations, the act of giving seems more important than the actual effect. The diaspora did not use this reliance to secure a more active role in Armenia's development process. Quite the opposite is the case: the diaspora gave unconditional financial and political support to a regime that has actually been blocking the diaspora's attempts to expand pro- ductive investments. At best, the diaspora's support relieves pressure on the government and therefore undermines the demand for further reforms, especially for improvements in the business environment. This situation is starting to change, albeit quite slowly. The diaspora played a key role in articulating the Armenia 2020 vision (summarized in McKinsey and Company 2003), although again the government did not participate fully in this initiative. To make a diaspora a source of expertise and FDI, we propose proceeding in the following manner: Go after "low-hanging fruit": design and implement relatively low-cost private sector projects in higher education, innovation, and ICT. The distance education pilot is one example of such a project (see Box 14.5). Once these pilot projects demonstrate signs of success, scale them into specific organizations. This would require more substantial commitments from successful and influential businessmen of Armenian origin. Higher education is particularly ripe with these opportunities (see Box 14.9 on relevant best practices from a neighbor country). 552 Part II: Detailed Analysis Box 14.9 Private Universities in Turkey and the Turkish Diaspora of the Highly Skilled Turkey's private universities, all of which were established as nonprofit foundations, are a major strength of the country's innovation system. The first such university was established 20 years ago in Ankara, and nonprofit universities now account for 23 of Turkey's 76 universities. The following are two examples of these innovative undertakings: Bilgi. Established by a young entrepreneur and graduate of Cam- bridge University in England, Bilgi is situated in the poor Kustepe and Dolaptere districts of Istanbul. It supports some 6,000 students, one-third of whom receive tuition scholarships of US$6,000 per year. Bilgi focuses on the social sciences and business management. It has developed ties with the London School of Economics and notably has instituted a series of innovative programs, including an e-MBA (mas- ter's degree in business administration via the Internet); media, ITC law, and design and business courses; and a night program in computer learning for local people. Koc. Created by an industrialist in 1993 and funded by the Koc Foundation, which also supports primary and secondary schools, Koc comprises three colleges for science and the arts, business, and engi- neering. The main university campus is in Sariyer, 30 kilometers north of Istanbul at the meeting of the Black Sea and the Bosphorus. Fac- ulty members are graduates mainly of U.S. and European schools and include many returning Turkish scientists. The university has 12,000 students, one-third of whom are granted tuition scholarships valued at US$11,500 per year. The engineering college has won contracts with Nokia and Mitsubishi, among others. Turkey has a diverse diaspora of many educated professionals that became particularly populous after World War II. As these two exam- ples demonstrate, diaspora members take initiatives to improve higher education at home--either by founding and financing private centers of excellence in higher education or by returning to work at these private centers of excellence. Source: Author's own elaboration. Organize a top-level leadership conference to start transforming diaspora interest to become involved in specific investment projects in Armenia. Once pilot projects start to show results, we propose to organize a high-level leadership conference in California. This should follow a so-called alumni model (see Box 14.10) with a proven track record of results. Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 553 Box 14.10 Toward a New Type of Diaspora Involvement in Armenia's Economy: Lessons of the University Alumni Model One sector of modern society that has been spectacularly successful in cultivating its "diaspora" and mobilizing their skills and resources for accelerating its own development is the university sector. The pri- vate university sector in the United States, and particularly among elite universities, has perfected the craft of nurturing its dispersed alumni. A successful alumni program in such universities can return in philan- thropic contributions to the university 12 times its expenditure every year. The alumni model has considerable relevance for developing countries and the organizations that support them. The first important element is that while all alumni are asked for support, the actual support is highly concentrated. It is not unusual for 1 percent of the alumni base (often with 100,000 or more members) to provide 90 percent of contributed resources. The universities are very skilled at identifying this leadership group of alumni and maintaining contacts with them through individually crafted programs. Universities are very careful, but still efficient, in selecting and culti- vating the small number of alumni who form a group of financial and intellectual leaders for the entire alumni community and who can be critically important for the success of alumni mobilization. Universities bring these people together physically as a defined leadership group to build an exclusive community of over-achievers and the most valu- able supporters. All of its members must have similar accomplishments and prestige in their own eyes and in that of the larger alumni com- munity, which would make them proud of being affiliated with the group. Intensive personal interaction between the group members leads to major synergies: through group discussions, the members tend to acquire a better understanding of their universities' actual needs, which helps them to produce better development proposals and ultimately makes them more generous in their financial support. Internal competi- tion within the group often generates a tendency toward an increase in the average size of individual contributions. Formation of the leadership group according to these principles is a difficulty for many diaspora communities. The alumni model sug- gests that, first, the government in home countries should be proac- tive in building a more strategically oriented and more exclusive (than most current expatriate associations) diaspora leadership group. Sec- ond, some solution must be found to exclude the traditional type of diaspora leaders, without entirely discouraging them, from the lead- ership meetings. This was a critical element in the formation of the 554 Part II: Detailed Analysis very successful Indus Entrepreneurs (TIE) organization. Their strictly observed rule was that charter members had to bring status to the group rather than obtain it there. The alumni model, with its simple but strict requirements, provides a highly efficient way to tap into an enormously valuable development resource. Source: Richard Devane, personal communication, May 2003 (business consultant). The objective of assembling a group of "over-achievers" of Armenian origin is to translate general benevolence into productive action. The alumni model suggests that it is a complex and subtle process, and the essential element is that this group must believe that they are not being hit upon for money. Instead, they are usually asked to participate in the vision-building exercise--the design of a new direction for the coun- try or an important part of it. In the course of discussing the existing problem and its possible solutions they come to share an understanding of real development priorities and personally commit themselves to implementing the recommendations that were set up with their direct participation. It is natural that once they are part of the "design team" they support the agreed recommendations with their resources and influence. Such a participatory process also helps to convince major donors to refrain from pushing their individual vanity projects. The alumni model--engaging influential diaspora members--has already demonstrated its potential for Armenia. For example, the report on Vision Armenia 2020 was undertaken by McKinsey and Com- pany (2003) "for free," just because influential Armenians in the top management of McKinsey decided it was important to do so. The price tag for such a report could have been about US$2­3 million. Building on these important starters, one should proceed to more diverse and business-oriented commitments from the Armenian diaspora. Proposals of Specific Projects and Policy Initiatives Equipped with some understanding of how to build successful organ- izations and programs, we outline below specific proposals for Arme- nia. Whenever possible, we outline a relevant SWOT (strength, weak- ness, opportunities, threat) matrix for proposed initiatives. Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 555 Redesign an Incentive Structure to Attract FDI Whether countries should rely on tax and other special incentives to attract FDI remains a controversial issue. The fact is that most devel- oped countries rely on them very heavily, while in Armenia these incentives are mostly lacking (see Table 14.14). We would recommend considering some special incentives to attract FDI as a transitional measure. As already noted, the arrival of a brand-name FDI would boost the country's reputation and put it on the map of other strategic investors. To trigger such a virtuous circle of "success breeds success," some special incentives might be very helpful. Needless to say, any special incentives should go hand-in-hand with aggressive improve- ment in the investment climate and would make no sense whatsoever without such improvement. Improve Growth Statistics to Better Measure Developments of the KE At the moment, the state statistics are not well equipped to meas- ure KE aggregates such as output in the ITC sector, value added in knowledge-intensive industries, export of these industries, business investment in R&D, and so forth. Reform and Expand the System of Quality Support to Firms Armenia ranks very poorly in terms of quality certification. The ISO database shows that Armenia had only 23 ISO9000 certificates regis- tered in the period 1997­2001. This suggests that Armenian companies have not yet fully mastered production capability (that is, the capa- bility to operate at the best practice level with the given technology). This is one of the key preconditions for expanding exports. The aim of SWOT of Proposed Initiative Focus on one key area for There would be no substantial increased competitiveness in weaknesses if the system is export based on "vouchers," which simplify administering Potential for Armenia to Possibility that poor substantially increase its export implementation leads to small number of applicants Criteria for assessment: Percentage of enterprises that have registered ISO certificates at ISO. 556 Part II: Detailed Analysis this program should be to radically increase the number of Armenian firms that are internationally certified. The program should be heav- ily advertised and supported by "free phone" lines and implemented through the regional offices of the Chamber of Commerce. Its reorgan- ization should be based on world experiences of best practice and it should involve firms in all sectors. A small feasibility study should be commissioned to design a country-wide quality support program. Introduce a System of Support to Productivity Enhancement Activities "20 Keys" The competitiveness of the Armenian economy depends crucially on the ability of its firms to increase productivity through quality, effi- ciency, and new processes and products. This requires the introduc- tion of innovative behavior in companies and among employees. The Practical Program of Revolution in Factories and Other Organizations (PPORF), also known as the 20 Keys, is the program that helps organi- zations to increase productivity. The Slovenian Ministry of Economy has been implementing this program since 1999. The idea is for Arme- nia to develop a similar program and use these experiences in its design and implementation. The aim of the program is to encourage the introduction of perma- nent improvements in strategy and to maintain competitive advantages in companies (for example, by introduction of permanent improve- ments by 20 Keys methodology and introduction of international qual- ity standards). Initially, a project would require the systematic training of consultants to use approaches and tools--the training of groups of at least 10 consultants for knowledge transfer into companies. The trained group would ensure further development after the project ends. Funding would be given for introducing productivity-enhancing systems into companies. Up to 50 interested companies would join the project and would receive cofinancing of consulting and train- ing for a two-year period, after which the companies will be able to sustain quality themselves. The methodology and the license to use it should be spread to other companies that are not direct beneficiaries of the program. Target groups are large companies interested in the implementation of 20 Keys. The measure should be implemented in cooperation with an international consultancy company. The government budget should cofinance the following activities (for no more than two years): consulting and mentoring with systems introduction of up to 50 percent of costs training of managers and internal coworkers at home and abroad of up to 75 percent of costs Table 14.14 FDI Incentives in Armenia versus Comparator Countries Type of investment incentive Latvia Turkey Poland Hungary Czech Rep. Slovenia Slovak Rep. Croatia Armenia Tax allowances Moving Corporate tax allowance for 10 or 5 years X X X X X X Tax allowance on the interest of the loan for investors including SMEs X X toward Corporate tax allowance or reduced rate for locating in priority region or in an enterprise zone X X X X X X X Corporate tax allowance for investing in selected technology- Knowledge-Based based activities (R&D, technopark, and so forth) X X R&D-related tax allowance (R&D costs are deductible from the tax base) X Other exemptions Exemption from customs duties and fund levies (for FDI from the list of machinery and equipment) X X VAT deferral for imported and locally purchased Competitiveness machinery and equipment for FDI (based on list of machinery and equipment) X X Exemption from certain taxes, duties, and fees for exporters X X Losses of FDI may be carried forward for 5 years X X Reduction of taxable base by x% for investments X Accelerated depreciation of tangibles and intangibles (5% for premises; 50% for computers) X X 557 Table 14.14 (continued) 558 Type of investment incentive Latvia Turkey Poland Hungary Czech Rep. Slovenia Slovak Rep. Croatia Armenia Subsidies: explicit Part The nonrepayable state grants as % of total investment costs X Job creation grants (x amount per employee or % of costs) X X X X II: Retraining grants (x % of training costs per employee) X X X Detailed Investment subsidies (grants) covering up to x% of investment outlays, often in selected industries/regions X X X Tax allowances Analysis Investment subsidy for technology centers (innovation centers closely related to manufacturing) X Grants for infrastructure development related to FDI to municipalities X Investment credits from the Investment Incentives Fund for selected types of investments like R&D, technoparks, and so forth X Subsidies: implicit Purchase of real estate from government estate at reduced prices X Total number 10 7 6 5 5 5 5 1 1 Source: National Investment Promotion Agency Note: Table does not state threshold levels or requirements for individual incentives. Conclusions based on the table: 1. There are big differences across countries in the number of investment incentives. 2. Number of investment incentives is not positively related to relative size of FDI (for example, Hungary vs. Turkey). 3. All countries offer tax allowances and other exemptions but not all countries offer subsidies. 4. Central European economies that have attracted large FDI offer large number of subsidies. 5. Armenia ranks at the low end in terms of investment incentives. Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 559 SWOT Directly focused on improving Restricted to small number of productivity in large enterprises firms; administratively and organizationally demanding Opportunity to significantly Danger that demonstration change attitude of large effect may be less than expected and medium firms toward productivity Criteria for assessment: Percentage of productivity increases in enter- prise participants + number of enterprises that are implementing the 20 Keys system. introducing information systems to support systems and moni- tor results of up to 50 percent of costs obtaining a license to use methodology of up to 50 percent of costs. Introduce a System of Grants for Technological Activities by Enterprises A study should be undertaken to examine how to implement a simple and flexible grant-based mechanism to stimulate firms to undertake technology development activities involving forms of design and engineering work that would not meet the eligibility conditions for the R&D.19 This scheme should encourage firms to deepen their technology development activities. It would be available to individual firms for a limited period of time or for a limited number of projects. Thereafter, firms would be expected to "graduate" to meet the eligibil- ity conditions required by R&D funding. In parallel with this, a flexible grant-based mechanism could be established in order to assist firms to invest in training and related capability-building activities concerned with strengthening their human resources for design, engineering, and R&D. The funding could be given for design/engineering projects with high levels of training/learning content. The study would consider ways of assist- ing investment in such activities by both individual firms and groups of enterprises with common interests. This study may explore whether the grant mechanism should be general or specific. If specific, grants could be given for particular types of technology, or particular types of firms, or cooperation among firms, or cooperation with universities, or the adoption of technology, or particular types of training. However, given the absence of such 560 Part II: Detailed Analysis SWOT Direct focus on technological Success is highly dependent and innovation activity of on quality of administration of enterprises program Opportunity to stimulate A possible misuse of funds for enterprises on systematic nontechnological activities of technological improvement so enterprises that they become R&D active in medium term Criteria for assessment: Number of enterprises as users of program in relation to the respective group of enterprises + productivity and technological improvement indicators. a mechanism, priority should be given to a scheme which is nondis- criminatory in these respects. Consideration should be given to possible misuse of funds and ways to reduce such occurrences by contracting services to indepen- dent organizations. Improve the System of Technology Transfer Support by Creating a Teaching Company Scheme of Support People are the key to technology transfer and partnership between the universities/R&D institutes and business. To strengthen the competitive- ness and wealth creation of Armenia by stimulating innovation in indus- try, we propose the introduction of a Teaching Company Scheme (TCS). This scheme is a program of subsidized employment for graduates who work on R&D projects in economy. Its design should be based on the successful British TCS. Its key objective is not employment per se but technology transfer and the building of a country's technology base. The TCS should be applicable to PhD students and MA students and should enable them to work in companies on challenging projects central to the developmental needs of participating companies. Projects on which students should work do not have to be R&D projects but could be any technology development project for which an interest in cooperating has been expressed by an R&D institute/university. The categories of knowledge transfer that can be covered under a TCS cover a wide range of skills, from conventional technology transfer to design, process enhancement, quality issues, and management or mar- keting skills. The main criteria for a project to be considered are that Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 561 the proposed knowledge transfer will enable the partner company to make a strategic advance. The objectives of the TCS are the following: to facilitate the transfer of technology and the spread of technical and management skills and encourage industrial investment in training, research, and development to provide industry-based training, supervised jointly by per- sonnel in the science, engineering, and technology base and in business, for high-caliber graduates intending to pursue a career in industry to enhance the levels of research and training in the science, engineering, and technology base that is relevant to business by stimulating collaborative research and development projects and forging lasting partnerships between the science, engineering, and technology base and business The TCS can help R&D institutes and universities to: extend their services to business customers enhance their levels of industrially relevant research develop their own staff A government grant, plus the contribution from the partner com- pany, should fully cover an R&D institute/university's costs of par- ticipating in a TCS program. Through a TCS, the research staff in an institute or a university can: assist strategic change in businesses by the commercialization of their research results stimulate innovation supervise and act as mentors for postgraduates working on com- pany-based projects enhance their own skills and knowledge enhance the industrial relevance of their research A project is agreed between an institute/university and a company. The agreed project could be for any length of time between one and three years, with the overall aim of helping the company make a change in an area that it has identified as high priority. Businesses of all sizes in most industries and commercial sectors can take part. Limitations on the types of projects and the sectors that can be supported will be specified in the TCS program. 562 Part II: Detailed Analysis SWOT This program would alleviate There are no significant the problem of junior R&D weaknesses as it is demand specialists and would establish driven real links between enterprises and research organizations Opportunity of high rate of Possible weak interest of R&D return of funds as PhDs would organizations work on issues that solve problems of enterprises Criteria for assessment: Number of enterprises beneficiaries, percent of junior R&D specialists that have secured employment in industry, and value of joint projects after program ends. Annex 14.1 Theoretical Framework for Growth Projections T o calculate total factor productivity, we consider a neoclassical aggregate production function that accounts for the quality of labor. For simplicity, we assume a human-capital augmented version of the Cobb-Douglas production function along with perfect competi- tion and constant returns to scale: Y = AK(HL)1 ­ (14A.1.1) where Y is the level of aggregate output K is the level of the capital stock H is the level of the human capital stock L is the size of the labor force A is total factor productivity is the share of capital in national income. Taking logs and time derivatives and rearranging leads to the esti- mate of growth rate of total factor productivity with human-capital augmentation: A^ = Y^ ­ K^ ­ (1 ­ )(H^ + L^) (14A.1.2) where X^ represents the growth rate of variable X. Following Woessmann (2000), we specify human capital stock to have the Mincer specification with the simplest form being H = ers (14A.1.3) 563 564 Part II: Detailed Analysis where r is the market returns to education s is the average years of schooling. DATA SOURCES Real GDP (in constant 1995 U.S. dollars and labor force figures were taken from the World Development Indicators 2003. The capital stock was constructed using gross capital formation (in constant 1995 U.S. dollars) obtained from the World Development Indicators 2003. The perpetual inventory method was used with an assumed depreciation rate of 5 percent. To calculate the initial value of the capital stock, we used the average growth rate of gross capital formation for the first five years and applied the formula for the sum of an infinite geometric progressive series. Estimates for the returns to education for Ireland, Korea, and Mexico were taken from Bils and Klenow (2000). In the case of Finland, there are no available data on the returns to education. As such, we used as a proxy the average of 17 high-income countries for which there were available data provided in Psacharopoulos (1994). As for the average years of schooling, we used the simple average of the estimates obtained from Barro and Lee (2001) and Cohen and Soto (2001). It should be noted that given that data for the average years of schooling were available only on a decade basis, we used interpolation by growth rates to obtain annual estimates of the average years of schooling in order to construct the human capital stock on an annual basis. The estimates for the labor shares in national income for Korea and Finland were taken from Gollin (2001), while those for Ireland and Mexico were taken from Bernanke and Gürkaynak (2001).20 RESULTS The table below presents the results of the TFP decomposition. Our annual growth rates of TFP were averaged to produce decade averages.21 Table 14A.1.1 Annual Growth Rates of Total Factor Productivity (in percent) Years Ireland Finland Korea, Rep of Mexico 1961­1970 n.a. 2.8691 0.5301 0.2922 1971­1980 2.8346 1.3350 ­0.1400 0.4048 1981­1990 2.2632 0.9824 2.8704 ­2.5922 1991­2000 4.2404 1.5278 1.8207 ­0.1286 n.a. Not available Annex 14.2 Knowledge Assessment Methodology (KAM) T he WBI's program on Knowledge for Development (K4D) uses an interactive Web-based tool (http://www.worldbank.org/kam). This tool is the knowledge assessment methodology, which consists of a set of 76 structural and qualitative variables that benchmark how an economy compares with its neighbors, competitors, or the countries it wishes to emulate. This simple benchmarking tool is a first step in helping to identify the problems and opportunities that a particular country faces in the four pillars of the KE (see below) and where it may need to focus policy attention or future investments. The com- parison for the 76 variables is undertaken for a group of 121 countries that includes almost all of the OECD economies (except Luxembourg) and about 90 developing countries. The set of 76 variables serves as proxies for the following four pil- lars that are critical to the development of a KE: an economic and institutional regime that provides incentives for the efficient use of existing and new knowledge and the flourishing of entrepreneurship an educated and skilled population that can create, share, and use knowledge well a dynamic information infrastructure that can facilitate the effec- tive communication, dissemination, and processing of informa- tion an efficient innovation system of firms, research centers, univer- sities, consultants, and other organizations that can tap into the growing stock of global knowledge, assimilate and adapt it to local needs, and create new technology 565 566 Part II: Detailed Analysis Included in the KAM also are several variables that track the overall performance of the economy. These variables help to illustrate how well an economy is actually using knowledge for its overall economic and social development. BASIC SCORECARD As working with a large set of 76 variables can be unwieldy, a sim- plified "basic scorecard" consisting of 12 variables that are based on the four pillars of the KE, plus two relating to performance, has been developed. In essence, this scorecard attempts to capture a country's preparedness for the knowledge-based economy. This scorecard can be captured for two points in time: for 1995 (or closest available) and for the most recent available year. The indicators used in the basic scorecard are as follows: i. Performance Indicators Two variables are used to illustrate the overall performance of a coun- try: annual GDP growth and the human development index (HDI). Annual GDP growth is a good indicator of a country's overall economic devel- opment. The HDI is a composite measure of three components: lon- gevity (measured by life expectancy), knowledge (adult literacy rate and mean years of schooling), and standard of living (real GDP per capita in purchasing power parity). The HDI provides information on the human development aspect of economic growth. ii. Economic Incentive and Institutional Regime Three variables are used as proxies for this pillar. The first, tariff and nontariff barriers from the Heritage Foundation (http://www.heritage .org/research/features/index/), provides a measure of the degree of competition and is a composite of the rating on the average tariff rate, nontariff barriers, and corruption in the Customs Service. The other two variables have been chosen from WBI's Governance Dataset (http:// www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/wp-governance.html). Regula- tory quality measures the incidence of market-unfriendly policies such as price controls or inadequate bank supervision, as well as perceptions of the burdens imposed by excessive regulation in areas such as for- eign trade and business development. Rule of law measures the extent to which agents have confidence in and abide by the rules of society. These include perceptions of the incidence of both violent and nonvio- lent crime, the effectiveness and predictability of the judiciary, and the enforceability of contracts. Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 567 iii. Education and Human Resources Three variables are used for this pillar: the adult literacy rate (percentage of population aged 15 and above) gives a very broad stock measure of the educated population, while secondary and tertiary enrollment rates provide a flow rate. The adult literacy rate refers to the percentage of people aged 15 and above who can, with understanding, read and write a short, simple statement on their everyday life. The gross enrollment ratio is the ratio of total enrollment, regardless of age, to the population of the age group that officially corresponds to the level of education indicated. Secondary education completes the provision of basic education that began at the primary level, and aims at laying the foundations for lifelong learning and human development by offering more subject- oriented or skill-oriented instruction using more specialized teachers. Tertiary education, whether or not to an advanced research qualifica- tion, normally requires, as a minimum condition of admission, the successful completion of education at the secondary level. iv. Innovation System Three variables have been chosen to represent this pillar. As an input into the innovation system, we use researchers in R&D per million popu- lation. For output, we have patent applications granted by the USPTO per million population, and scientific and technical journal articles per million population. Patents granted by the USPTO include utility patents and other types of U.S. documents, such as design patents, plant patents, re-issues, defensive publications, and statutory inventions and regis- trations. The origin of the patent is determined by the residence of the first-named inventor. Scientific and technical journal articles refer to the number of scientific and engineering articles published in the follow- ing fields: physics, biology, chemistry, mathematics, clinical medicine, biomedical research, engineering and technology, and earth and space sciences. v. Information Infrastructure Three variables are used for this plank of the knowledge-based econ- omy. Telephones per 1,000 population is the sum of telephone mainlines and mobile phones and provides a better indicator of connectivity than either in isolation. Computers per 1,000 population refers to the number of self-contained computers designed to be used by a sin- gle individual and is an indicator of personal computer penetration and the use of relatively new technology for information processing. 568 Part II: Detailed Analysis Internet users per 10,000 population refers to the number of computers with active Internet Protocol (IP) addresses connected to the Internet and is used as an indication of how well a population has advanced to the level of adapting and using advanced communication channels to serve its priorities. Note: While there may be more robust data describing a coun- try's preparedness for a knowledge-based economy, the 14 variables selected and described above are generally available for a larger time series and remain regularly updated for the vast majority of the coun- tries that are assessed by the KAM. KNOWLEDGE ECONOMY INDEX (KEI) AND KNOWLEDGE INDEX (KI) The basic scorecard is used to derive the KEI as well as the KI. The KEI is calculated based on the average of the performance scores of a country or region in all four pillars related to the KE (economic incen- tive regime, education, innovation, and ICT). The KI is the simple average of the performance of a country or region in three KE pillars (education, innovation, and ICT). The aggregate score for each pillar is derived based on the calculation of the average normalized scores of the three variables that describe a pillar. For both the KEI and the KI, the data are shown for two points in time: 1995 and most recent. ANNEX 14.3 KAM Data Used for Assessing Knowledge Preparedness-- Armenia and Selected Comparators Table 14A.3.1 Gross Capital Formation, 1995­2002 (percent of GDP) Average 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 1995­2002 Armenia 18 20 19 19 18 19 20 21 19 Israel 26 26 24 23 23 21 20 18 23 Slovenia 23 23 24 26 28 27 24 23 25 Russian Federation 25 24 22 15 15 19 22 21 20 Ireland 18 20 22 24 24 25 24 n.a. 22 Chile 26 27 27 27 21 22 21 23 24 Costa Rica 18 16 18 21 17 17 20 22 19 Latvia 17 19 23 28 27 27 29 27 25 Low income 25 23 23 20 19 20 20 20 21 Low & middle income 26 25 25 23 22 23 23 23 24 Middle income 26 26 25 24 23 24 24 23 24 Source: SIMA, World Bank. n.a. Not applicable. 569 570 Part Table 14A.3.2 Performance--Economic Regime Variables II: Average Composite Unemployment Gross Capital General Gov't Detailed GDP annual GDP per Human ICRG Risk rate Formation as budget Trade Tariff & (current GDP growth capita 2002 Development Rating % of total % of GDP balance as as % nontariff US$ bn) 1998­2002 (Current Index Dec. labor force (Average) % of GDP of GDP barriers Analysis 2002* (%) $ PPP) 2001 2002 1995­2002 1991­2001 2002 2002 2003** Armenia 2.4 7.80 2,957 0.73 60.30 9.60 18.80 ­3.00 75.00 10.00 Latvia 8.4 5.70 8,965 0.81 76.50 13.80 24.70 ­1.70 99.60 8.00 Russia 346.5 3.80 7,926 0.78 70.00 10.23 24.20 1.70 53.90 4.00 Slovenia 22 3.90 17,748 0.88 80.30 7.20 22.80 ­2.60 120.54 4.00 Israel 103.7 1.80 20,055 0.91 65.30 8.30 23.20 ­4.00 83.12 8.00 Ireland 121.4 8.10 32,960 0.93 88.80 7.40 19.70 ­0.30 175.90 8.00 Chile 64.2 2.40 9,561 0.83 76.80 7.80 24.40 ­0.70 67.30 8.00 Costa Rica 16.8 4.50 8,470 0.83 73.50 5.80 18.50 ­5.40 86.42 8.00 Europe and Central Asia 46.06 4.08 7,143 0.78 70.81 9.41 22.93 ­3.20 101.00 5.64 *This variable is not included in the KAM dataset. It is included in the table above for the purposes of this report only, so as the reader can comprehend better the size and dynamics of the economy when compared to other nations. In addition, the particularly small GDP volume of America needs to be taken into consideration when translating variables calculated as share of GDP. **Variable adjusted for 0­10 normalization scale. Source: http://www.worldbank.org/kam. Moving Table 14A.3.3 Governance Variables Regulatory Government Voice and Political Control of Press Quality Rule of Law Effectiveness Accountability Stability Corruption Freedom toward 2002 2002 2002 2002 2002 2002 2003 Armenia 0.13 ­0.44 ­0.42 ­0.42 ­0.53 ­0.72 65.00 Knowledge-Based Latvia 0.86 0.46 0.67 0.91 0.82 0.09 18.00 Russia ­0.30 ­0.78 ­0.40 ­0.52 ­0.40 ­0.90 66.00 Slovenia 0.81 1.09 0.82 1.10 1.21 0.89 19.00 Israel 1.03 0.97 1.02 0.61 ­1.35 1.08 27.00 Ireland 1.64 1.72 1.62 1.40 1.31 1.67 16.00 Chile 1.50 1.30 1.19 1.12 1.04 1.55 22.00 Costa Rica 0.74 0.67 0.37 1.16 1.00 0.88 14.00 Competitiveness Europe and Central Asia 0.03 ­0.20 ­0.16 0.01 0.10 ­0.34 46.77 Source: http://www.worldbank.org/kam. 571 572 Part Table 14A.3.4 Innovation Systems Variables II: Science & Detailed engineering enrollment Scientific Patent High- ratio Scientific and Patent applications Technology 1981­1991 Total Manuf. and technical applications granted exports Analysis (% of Researchers expenditure Trade technical journal granted by the as % of FDI as tertiary Researchers in for R&D as as % journal articles/ by the USPTO manufactured % of GDP level in R&D/ % of GNP of GDP articles mil. pop. USPTO 2001/ exports 1990­2000 students) R&D millions 2000 2001 1999 1999 2001 mil pop. 2001 Armenia 3.10 29.00 4,501 1,604 0.18 30.68 142 31.36 1 0.32 4.00 Latvia 5.40 23.00 2,626 1,094 0.40 49.81 153 64.02 1 0.42 3.00 Russia 1.50 50.00 505,118 3,493 1.00 18.22 15,654 106.99 239 1.65 8.00 Slovenia 1.10 26.00 4,458 2,248 1.48 85.51 599 301.69 21 10.55 5.00 Israel 2.60 49.00 9,161 1,519 3.62 54.58 5,025 823.10 1,031 162.11 25.00 Ireland 11.80 31.00 8,211 2,191 1.21 110.34 1,231 329.69 166 43.23 48.00 Chile 1.20 42.00 6,441 419 0.56 23.10 819 58.53 15 0.91 1.00 Costa Rica 3.10 20.00 1,866 533 0.20 53.15 69 18.50 12 3.10 36.00 Europe and Central Asia 3.42 31.33 41,600 1,535 0.61 58.99 1,549 81.21 21 1.32 6.56 Source: http://www.worldbank.org/kam. Table 14A.3.5 Education Variables Moving Adult literacy Primary pupil- Life expectancy Public spending rate (% age 15 Secondary Tertiary teacher ratio, at birth, on education and above) Enrollment Enrollment pupils per teacher, years, as % of GDP, toward 2001 (2002 ILO) 2000 2000 2000 2002 2000 Armenia 98.50 73.28 20.18 18.80 74.80 2.90 Knowledge-Based Latvia 99.80 90.89 63.11 15.00 70.40 5.90 Russia 99.60 83.33 64.09 17.30 65.80 4.40 Slovenia 99.60 92.19 60.55 14.10 75.90 n.a. Israel 96.20 93.25 52.67 12.20 78.70 7.30 Ireland 100.00 109.08 47.53 20.30 76.90 4.40 Chile 95.90 75.45 37.52 25.20 75.90 4.20 Costa Rica 95.70 60.19 16.04 24.90 77.60 4.40 Competitiveness Europe and Central Asia 97.52 86.44 38.96 18.18 70.32 4.59 Source: http://www.worldbank.org/kam. n.a. Not applicable. 573 574 Part Table 14A.3.6 ICT Variables II: Telephones Detailed per 1,000 Main people telephone Mobile Daily Internet Internet 2002 lines phones Computers TV sets Radios newspapers hosts users Analysis (telephone per per per per per per per per mainlines 1,000 1,000 1,000 1,000 1,000 1,000 10,000 10,000 + mobile people, people, people, people, people, people, people, people, phones) 2002 2002 2002 2001 2001 2000 2002 2002 Armenia 152 140 12 9 230 225 5 8 184 Latvia 695 301 394 172 840 700 135 152 1,331 Russia 363 242 121 89 538 418 105 28 409 Slovenia 1,242 407 835 301 367 405 169 179 4,008 Israel 1,422 467 955 246 335 526 290 221 3,014 Ireland 1,240 485 755 391 399 695 150 347 2,709 Chile 659 230 428 119 286 759 98 80 2,014 Costa Rica 378 251 128 170 231 816 91 21 934 Europe and Central Asia 504 227 277 87 389 525 120 85 928 Source: http://www.worldbank.org/kam. Annex 14.4 KE Basic Scorecards: Armenia and Selected Comparators Figure 14A.4.1 Armenia and ECA average annual GDP growth (%) Internet users per 10,000 10 Human Development Index computers per 1,000 tariff & nontariff barriers 5 telephones per 1,000 regulatory quality (mainlines & mobiles) 0 tertiary enrollment rule of law secondary enrollment researchers in R&D/mil. pop. adult literacy rate (% age 15 scientific & technical journal & above) patent articles/mil. pop. applications Armenia granted by the USPTO/mil. pop. Europe & Central Asia Figure 14A.4.2 Armenia and Latvia average annual GDP growth (%) Internet users per 10,000 10 Human Development Index computers per 1,000 tariff & nontariff barriers 5 telephones per 1,000 regulatory quality (mainlines & mobiles) 0 tertiary enrollment rule of law secondary enrollment researchers in R&D/mil. pop. adult literacy rate (% age 15 scientific & technical journal & above) patent articles/mil. pop. applications Armenia granted by the USPTO/mil. pop. Latvia 575 576 Part II: Detailed Analysis Figure 14A.4.3 Armenia and Slovenia average annual GDP growth (%) Internet users per 10,000 10 Human Development Index computers per 1,000 tariff & nontariff barriers 5 telephones per 1,000 regulatory quality (mainlines & mobiles) 0 tertiary enrollment rule of law secondary enrollment researchers in R&D/mil. pop. adult literacy rate (% age 15 scientific & technical journal & above) patent articles/mil. pop. applications Armenia granted by the USPTO/mil. pop. Slovenia Figure 14A.4.4 Armenia and Russia average annual GDP growth (%) Internet users per 10,000 10 Human Development Index computers per 1,000 tariff & nontariff barriers 5 telephones per 1,000 regulatory quality (mainlines & mobiles) 0 tertiary enrollment rule of law secondary enrollment researchers in R&D/mil. pop. adult literacy rate (% age 15 scientific & technical journal & above) patent articles/mil. pop. applications Armenia granted by the USPTO/mil. pop. Russia Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 577 Figure 14A.4.5 Armenia and Israel average annual GDP growth (%) Internet users per 10,000 10 Human Development Index computers per 1,000 tariff & nontariff barriers 5 telephones per 1,000 regulatory quality (mainlines & mobiles) 0 tertiary enrollment rule of law secondary enrollment researchers in R&D/mil. pop. adult literacy rate (% age 15 scientific & technical journal & above) patent articles/mil. pop. applications Armenia granted by the USPTO/mil. pop. Israel Figure 14A.4.6 Armenia and Chile average annual GDP growth (%) Internet users per 10,000 10 Human Development Index computers per 1,000 tariff & nontariff barriers 5 telephones per 1,000 regulatory quality (mainlines & mobiles) 0 tertiary enrollment rule of law secondary enrollment researchers in R&D/mil. pop. adult literacy rate (% age 15 scientific & technical journal & above) patent articles/mil. pop. applications Armenia granted by the USPTO/mil. pop. Chile 578 Part II: Detailed Analysis Figure 14A.4.7 Armenia and Costa Rica average annual GDP growth (%) Internet users per 10,000 10 Human Development Index computers per 1,000 tariff & nontariff barriers 5 telephones per 1,000 regulatory quality (mainlines & mobiles) 0 tertiary enrollment rule of law secondary enrollment researchers in R&D/mil. pop. adult literacy rate (% age 15 scientific & technical journal & above) patent articles/mil. pop. applications Armenia granted by the USPTO/mil. pop. Costa Rica Figure 14A.4.8 Armenia and Ireland average annual GDP growth (%) Internet users per 10,000 10 Human Development Index computers per 1,000 tariff & nontariff barriers 5 telephones per 1,000 regulatory quality (mainlines & mobiles) 0 tertiary enrollment rule of law secondary enrollment researchers in R&D/mil. pop. adult literacy rate (% age 15 scientific & technical journal & above) patent articles/mil. pop. applications Armenia granted by the USPTO/mil. pop. Ireland Moving toward Knowledge-Based Competitiveness 579 NOTES 1. This chapter was prepared by Yevgeny Kuznetsov (World Bank) with support from Aimilios Chatzinikolaou (World Bank), who wrote a signifi- cant part of Section 1, Slavo Radosevic (University of London), who made substantial inputs to Sections 2 and 3, and Lev Freinkman (who provided many inputs and much guidance in the preparation of the report). Derek Chen (WBIKD) developed growth projections of the report. Faythe Calandra provided administrative assistance. 2. There are other factors as well, such as a long record of macroeconomic stability and high rates of growth. 3. There are signs, however, that traditional sectors have gradually expanded their demand for high-skill labor. For instance, jewelry firms show more interest in getting higher-quality designers, software engineers, and so forth, as well as in upgrading their management capabilities. 4. These indicators need to be used with caution when analyzing the poten- tial of Armenian exporters. Official export data overestimate the actual volume of value added created by Armenian exporters, since a relatively large portion of total export sales does not represent value added by local exporters. 5. http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/knowledgefordevelopment 6. The KAM (http://www.worldbank.org/kam) includes 76 quantitative and qualitative variables that help to benchmark a country's position on the key elements of the four pillars of the KE framework. The methodology con- sists of ranking 121 countries and 9 country groupings with respect to each of these variables and giving a score of 10 for the highest values and 0 for the lowest. 7. For more information, see Annex 14.1 and visit http://www.worldbank. org/kam. 8. In figures such as Figure 14.1 the reader should note the following. On the horizontal axis the 1995 KEI scores are plotted. On the vertical axis the KEI scores for the most recent year are plotted. The more advanced KE perform- ers plot in the northeast quadrant of the graph, while the weaker ones plot in the southwest quadrant of the graph. Both the position along the 45-degree line and whether a country plots above or below the line are significant. The countries or regions that are plotted below the line indicate a regression in their performance relative to where they were in 1995. The countries or regions that are marked above the line signify an improvement in their position in the lat- est period compared to their position in 1995. Those countries that are plotted on the line have maintained their relative position over the two periods. Each country's performance as depicted in the figure is relative to the performance of the total country sample included in the KAM (121 countries). 9. Each country's performance as shown in the figure is relative to the performance of the total of 121 countries included in the KAM. 580 Part II: Detailed Analysis 10. This reflects 2003 data from the Heritage Foundation. Nevertheless, the Heritage Foundation states the following in 2004 Index of Economic Freedom: "In 2001, according to the World Bank, Armenia's weighted average tariff rate was 2.5 percent, up from the 1.9 percent reported in the 2003 Index of Economic Freedom by the Heritage Foundation." The U.S. State Department reports that most imports are free of prohibitions, quotas, or licensing, but businesses complain about "cumbersome procedures [and] bribes solicited by customs officials." 11. Bleyzer (2002). In this analysis 15 FSU countries are ranked on the following FDI driving elements: liberalization and deregulation of business activities, stability and predictability of legal environment, corporate and pub- lic governance, liberalization of foreign trade and international capital move- ments, financial sector development, corruption level, political risk, country promotion and image, and targeted investment initiatives. 12. Based on statistical information management and analysis (SIMA) data for the year 2001, the only other countries in the KAM-defined ECA region that demonstrate lower adult literacy rates are Albania, Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, Romania, Turkey, and Uzbekistan. http://sima/datasite/sima-web/ default.htm. 13. Based on SIMA data for year 2000, Armenia is performing better in tertiary enrollment rates than Albania, Tajikistan, and Turkey. 14. Since this is a very imperfect proxy, Figure 14.13 is merely illustrative and serves to outline the qualitative scenarios of Armenia's development. 15. It should be noted that for all four projections, capital and labor were assumed to grow at their 2000­02 average growth rates for Armenia, which are 11.31 percent and 0.75 percent respectively. 16. This section relies on the Public-Private Infrastructure Advisory Facility (PPIAF) presentation "Sector Overview and Review of International Experi- ence, Identification of Bottlenecks and Recommended Roadmap to Develop a Rural Telecommunications Strategy in Armenia" (April 2004). 17. While deal flow was not spectacular it was adequate to start the opera- tions of the fund. Yet the diaspora did not give any money to cofinance the project, mostly for political reasons, thus closing any avenues to invest in future deal flow. 18. This section is based on Kuznetsov and Sabel (2004) and Freinkman (2001). 19. The WTO Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures defines maximum proportions for nonactionable, though specific, subsidies in the case of industrial research (75 percent) and precompetitive development activities (50 percent). 20. The estimates for labor shares for Ireland, Korea, Finland, and Mex- ico were 0.750, 0.796, 0.680, and 0.59, respectively. The capital shares were obtained by taking 1 and subtracting the respective labor shares. 21. Note that for Ireland, gross capital formation data were not available prior to 1971. As such, the average annual growth rate of TFP for the period 1971 to 1980 for Ireland in the above table is in fact the average for 1972­1980. References Abernathy, F.H., J.T. Dunlop, J.H. Hammond, and D. Weil. 1999. A Stitch in Time. Lean Retailing and the Transformation of Manufacturing--Lessons from the Apparel and Textile Industries. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. Adonian, Andre, Avetzik Chalabyan, and Pierre Gurdjian. 2004. "Armenia's Software Advantage." The McKinsey Quarterly 1: 12­14. Aghion, Philippe, and Peter Howitt. 1998. Endogenous Growth Theory. Cam- bridge, MA: The MIT Press. Aidt, Toke S. 2003. "Economic Analysis of Corruption: A Survey." The Eco- nomic Journal 113 (November). Alam, Asad, M. Murthi, R. Yemtsov, E. Murrugarra, N. Dudwick, E. Hamilton, and E. Tiongson. 2005. Growth, Poverty, and Inequality: Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union. ECAPOV2. Washington, DC: The World Bank American and European Union Chambers of Commerce in Armenia. 2003. Reform of the Armenian Tax System: The Foreign Investors' Perspective. A joint white paper. Yerevan, Armenia. August. Anderson, James H., David S. Bernstein, and Cheryl W. Gray. 2005. Judicial Systems in Transition Economies: Assessing the Past, Looking to the Future. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Andrew, Doug. 2005. "Armenia: Civil Aviation Policy." Unpublished report. World Bank, Washington, DC. (Chapter 13 of this book). Armenia, National Statistical Service (NSS). 2003a. 2002 National Accounts. Various spreadsheets included as figures in Annex. Yerevan, Armenia: NSS. ------. 2003b. Statistical Handbook. Income, Expenditures and Food Consumption in Armenia, 1999, 2001, and 2002. Yerevan, Armenia: NSS. _____ 2003c. The Results of 2001 Census in the Republic of Armenia. Yerevan, Armenia: NSS. 581 582 References ------. 2003d. "Value Terms of the Poverty Line and the Food Line According to the Results of Household Surveys." In Social Snapshot and Poverty in the Republic of Armenia. Yerevan, Armenia: NSS. ------. Various years. Social Snapshot and Poverty in the Republic of Armenia. Statistical analytical report. Yerevan, Armenia: NSS. Bach, Christian F., and Will Martin. 2001. "Would the Right Tariff Aggrega- tor for Policy Analysis Please Stand Up?" Journal of Policy Modeling 23 (6): 621­35. Barro, Robert J., and Jong-Wha Lee. 2001. "International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates and Implications." Oxford Economic Papers 3:541­563. Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 1995. Economic Growth. Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill. ------. 2003. Economic Growth (Second Edition). Boston, MA: The MIT Press. Barry, Frank. 2003. "Economic Integration and Convergence Processes in the EU Cohesion Countries." Journal of Common Market Studies 41(5):897­921. Baumol, William, John Panzar, and Robert Willig. 1982. Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.. BearingPoint and USAID. Armenia Tax, Fiscal, and Customs reform project. 2002. Review of Tax Policy and Tax Legislation in the Republic of Armenia. December. Bernanke, Ben S., and Refet S. Gürkaynak. 2001. "Is Growth Exogenous? Tak- ing Mankiw, Romer and Weil Seriously." National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper 8365. NBER, Washington, DC. July. Bils, Mark, and Peter J. Klenow. 2000. "Does Schooling Cause Growth?" Amer- ican Economic Review 90(5):1160­1183. Bleyzer, Sigma. 2002. The Bleyzer Initiative: Completing the Economic Tran- sition in FSU Countries. With the Bleyzer Foundation. Kiev, Ukraine and Houston, TX: Bleyzer Foundation. Brattle Group. 2002a."The Economic Impact of an EU-U.S. Open Aviation Area." Report prepared for the European Commission by James D. Reitzes, Dorothy Robyn, Boaz Moselle, and John Horn. The Brattle Group, London and Washington, DC. December. http://www.brattle.com. ------. 2002b. The Effectiveness of Dutch Air Transport Policy." Report pre- pared for the Netherlands Directorate General of Civil Aviation by James D. Reitzes, Adam C. Schumacher, and John Horn. The Brattle Group, Lon- don and Washington, DC. December. http://www.brattle.com. Brattle Group. 2004. Armenian Government Civil Aviation Policy. Airline Air- craft Project, Consulting and Advisory Services. Unpublished report. Cam- bridge, MA: Brattle Group. Brenmer, Ian. 2001. "The Political Economy of Banal Authoritarism. The Case of Armenia." Consultant's Report. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Broadman, Harry, Jim Anderson, Stijn Claessens, Randi Ryterman, Stefka Sla- vova, Maria Vaglasindi, and Galina Vincelette. 2004. Institutional Reform References 583 for Investment and Growth in South Eastern Europe. Washington DC: World Bank. Business Environment and Enterprise Performance Survey (BEEPS). 2005. The World Bank and the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development. Available at: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTECAREGTOPANT- COR/Resources/BAAGREV20060208Armenia.pdf Campos, Nauro F., and Yuko Kinoshita. 2003. "Why Does FDI Go Where It Goes? New Evidence from the Transition Economies." Working Paper WP/03/228. International Monetary Fund (IMF), Washington DC. Novem- ber. Center of Ethno-sociological Studies (CES). 2000. "Social Awareness of the Judicial Reforms--Survey Analysis." Yerevan, Armenia. Cohen, Daniel, and Marcelo Soto. 2001. "Growth and Human Capital: Good Data, Good Results." Technical Paper No. 179, OECD Development Centre. Paris: OECD. September. Crafts, N.F.R., and G. Toniolo. 1996. Economic Growth in Europe Since 1945. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Damijan, Joze P., Mark Knell, Boris Majcen, and Matija Rojec. 2003. "The Role of FDI, R&D Accumulation and Trade in Transferring Technology to Transition Economies: Evidence from Firm Panel Data for Eight Transition Economies." Economic Systems 27: 189­204. Datt, G., and M. Ravallion. 1992. "Growth and Redistribution Components of Changes in Poverty: A Decomposition with Application to Brazil and India." Journal of Development Economics 38:275­295. Deaton, Angus S. 2003. "Measuring Poverty in a Growing World (or Meas- uring Growth in a Poor World)." National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper No. W9822. NBER, Washington, DC. July. http:// ssrn.com/abstract=421783 De Soto, Hernando. 1999. The Other Path. The Invisible Revolution in the Third World. New York: Harper & Row Publishers. Dixit, Avinash. 2005. "Evaluating Recipes for Development Success." Paper presented at World Bank DEC Lectures, April 5. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Djankov, S., C. McLiesh, and A. Shliefer 2005. "Private Credit in 129 Countries." NBER Working Paper No. 11078. (January). Washington, DC: NBER. Djankov, S., R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes, and A. Shleifer. 2000. "The Regu- lation of Entry." NBER Working Paper 7892. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. September. (See also the 2002 update published on the World Bank Doing Business Website (http://www.doingbusiness .org/). Doove, Samantha, Owen Gabbitas, Duc Nguyen-Hong, and Joe Owen. 2001. "Price Effects of Regulation: Telecommunications, Air Passenger Transport and Electricity Supply." Productivity Commission Staff Research Paper. AusInfo, Canberra. October. 584 References Easterly, William. 2001. The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists' Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Economist. 2003. Armenia Country Profile 2003. Economist Intelligence Unit. ------. 2004. "The cartel isn't forever." Special report. July 17. European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). Various years. Annual Transition Reports. London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development. ------. 1999. Legal Indicators Survey 1999. London: European Bank for Recon- struction and Development. European Commission (EC). 2004. "A Community Aviation Policy towards its Neighbors." Communication from the Commission. COM(2004) 74 final. EC, Brussels. February 9. Evans, C.L., and J. Harrigan. 2003. "Distance, Time and Specialization." Work- ing Paper 9729. National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cam- bridge, MA. May. Faye, Michael, J. McArthur, Jeffrey Sachs, and Timothy Snow. 2004. "The Challenges Facing Landlocked Developing Countries." Journal of Human Development 5 (1): 31­68. Fink, Carsten, Aaditya Mattoo, and Randeep Rathindran. 2002. "An Assess- ment of Telecommunications Reform in Developing Countries." World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2909. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Fisher, Stanley, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos A. Vegh. 1998. "How far is East- ern Europe from Brussels?" IMF Working Paper WP/98/53. International Monetary Fund (IMF), Washington DC. Foreign Investment Advisory Service (FIAS). Various years. Administrative Regulatory Cost Surveys (RCSs). Washington, DC: FIAS. ------. 2003. Armenia. Removing Administrative Barriers to Investment. World Bank and International Finance Corporation, Washington, DC. ------. 2004. "Administrative Barriers Update--Fourth Annual Regulatory and Administrative Costs Survey: Armenia." By Development Network NGO for FIAS (March). Update to FIAS, 2003, Armenia. Removing Administrative Barriers to Investment. World Bank and International Finance Corporation, Washington, DC. Freinkman, Lev. 2001. "The Role of Diasporas in Transition Economies: Les- sons from Armenia." Policy Research Working Paper 2909. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Gallup, J. L., and J.D. Sachs. 1998. "Geography and Economic Growth." In Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics, B. Pleskovic and J.E. Stiglitz, eds. Washington, DC: World Bank. Garibaldi, Pietro, Nada Mora, Ratna Sahay and Jeromin Zettelmeyer. 2002. "What Moves Capital to Transition Economies?" IMF Working Paper WP/02/64. IMF, Washington DC. George, Donald A.R., Les Oxley, and Kenneth I. Carlaw (eds.). 2004. Surveys in Economic Growth: Theory and Empirics. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing. References 585 Gillen, David W., William G. Morrison, and Christopher Stewart. 2003. "Air Travel Demand Elasticities: Concepts, Issues and Measurement." Final report. Canadian Department of Finance. http://www.fin.gc.ca. Golan, A., G.G. Judge, and D. Miller. 1996. Maximum Entropy Econometrics: Robust Estimation with Limited Data. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Gollin, Douglas. 2001. "Getting Income Shares Right." Working Paper, Depart- ment of Economics. Williams College, Williamstown, MA. January. Grigorian, Karen. 2005. "The Role of Exports and FDI in Promoting Competi- tion and Advancing Economic Growth in Armenia." Unpublished manu- script. World Bank, Washington DC. Grossman, G.M., and E. Helpman. 1991. Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Gylfason, Thorvaldur. 1999. Principles of Economic Growth. Oxford University Press. Hausmann, Ricardo, L Pritchett, and D. Rodrick. 2005. "Growth Accelera- tions." Journal of Economic Growth 10(4):303­329. Hausmann, Ricardo, D. Rodrick, and A. Valesco. 2005 "Growth Diagnostics." Unpublished manuscript. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University. Heritage Foundation. 2004. 2004 Index of Economic Freedom. Available at: http://www.heritage.org. Hertel, T.W., ed. 1997. Global Trade Analysis: Modeling and Applications. Cam- bridge, MA: Cambridge University Press. Hodge, James. 2002. "Liberalization of Trade in Services in Developing Coun- tries." In B. Hoekman, A. Mattoo, and P. English (eds.). Development, Trade, and the WTO: A Handbook. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Holden, Paul. 1997. "Collateral without Consequence: Some Causes and Effects of Financial Underdevelopment in Latin America." The Financier 4 (1 & 2): 12­21. Holden, Paul, and Vahe Sahakyan. 2004. "Issues Related to Promoting a Competitive Business Environment in Armenia." Unpublished manuscript. Washington DC: The Enterprise Research Institute. Holden, Paul, and Vassili Prokopenko. 2001. "The Financial Sector and Pov- erty Reduction in Developing and Transition Economies: Issues and Policy Implications." IMF Working Paper 01/160. International Monetary Fund (IMF), Washington, DC. International Civil Aviation Organization (ICAO). 2000. Economic Contribution of Civil Aviation. Montreal, Quebec: ICAO. International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2004. "Aide-Mémoire of the Tax Policy Mission." Unpublished. IMF, Washington, DC. April 22. ------. 2002. Statistical Annex for the Republic of Armenia. IMF country report #02/225. IMF, Washington, DC. October. Intarakumnerd, P., P. Chairatana, et al. 2002. "National Innovation System in Less Successful Developing Countries: The Case of Thailand." Research Policy 31(8­9):1445­1457. 586 References Javorcik, Beata Smarzynska, and Mariana Spatareanu. 2004a. "Disentangling FDI Spillover Effects: What Do Firm Perceptions Tell Us?" In The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment on Development: New Measures, New Outcomes, New Policy Approaches, ed. M. Blomstrom, E. Graham, and T. Moran. Washing- ton, DC: Institute for International Economics. ------. 2004b. "Is Flexibility More Attractive? The Impact of Labor Market Regulations on Foreign Direct Investment." Unpublished manuscript (Jan- uary). Washington, DC: The World Bank. Jones, Charles I. 1997. An Introduction to Economic Growth. New York: Norton. Kaminski, Bartlomiej. 2005a. "Ranking Transition Countries in Terms of Real Ease of Doing Business." Unpublished manuscript. Washington, DC: World Bank. Kaminski, Bartlomiej. 2005b. "Real and Formal Ease of Doing Business in Armenia in Comparative Perspective: Implications for Regulatory Reforms." Background paper for Armenia's 2005 Country Economic Memorandum. World Bank, Washington, DC. May. Kaminski, Bartlomiej, and Francis Ng. 2004. "Romania's Integration into Euro- pean Markets: Implications for Sustainability of Current Export Boom." Policy Research Working Paper #3451. World Bank, Washington, DC. November. Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi. 2003. "Governance Matters III: Governance Indicators for 1996­2002." Research Department Working Paper. Washington, DC: The World Bank. ------. 2005. "Governance Matters IV: Governance Indicators for 1996­2004." Research Department Working Paper. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Kuznetsov, Y., and C. Sabel. 2004. "Work Globally, Develop Locally: Diaspora Networks as Springboards of Development." Unpublished paper. World Bank, Washington, DC. Kessides, Ioannis, and Robert Willig. 1995. "Restructuring Regulation of Rail Industry for the Public Interest." Policy Research Working Paper #1506. World Bank, Washington, DC. Klundert, Theo van de. 2001. Growth Theory in Historical Perspective: Selected Essays of Theo van de Klundert. Edited by Sjak Smulders. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. Kuddo, Arvo, et al. 2006. "Armenia: Labor Market Dynamics." Unpublished manuscript. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Kuznetsov, Yevgeny. 2004. Armenia: Moving Towards Knowledge-Based Competi- tiveness. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Kuznetsov, Y., and C. Sabel. 2004. "Work Globally, Develop Locally: Diaspora Networks as Springboards of Development." Unpublished manuscript. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Laffont, Jean-Jacques, and Jean Tirole. 2000. Competition in Telecommunications. Boston, MA: MIT Press. Limao, N., and A.J. Venables. 2001. "Infrastructure, Geographical Disad- vantage, Transport Costs and Trade." World Bank Economic Review 15 (3): 451­479. References 587 Light, M.K., and T.F. Rutherford. 2004. "Taxation and Economic Efficiency in Armenia." Technical Report. World Bank, Washington DC. October. Light, Miles, Ekaterine Vashakmadze, and Artsvi Khachatrian. 2005. "A Social Accounting Matrix for Armenia." Washington, DC.World Bank. Loukoianova, Elena, and Anna Unigovskaia 2004. "Analysis of Recent Growth in Low-Income CIS Countries." IMF Working Paper. Washington, DC: IMF. Lucas, Robert E. Jr. 2002. Lectures on Economic Growth. Cambridge and London: Harvard University Press. Mathiesen, Lars. 1985. "Computation of Economic Equilibria by a Sequence of Linear Complimentarity Problems." Mathematical Programming Study 23: 144­62. Mattoo, Aaditya. 2000. "Shaping Future GATS Rules for Trade in Services." Paper presented at an NBER Conference on Trade in Service, Seoul. June. NBER. McCombie, John, and Tony Thirlwall. 1994. Economic Growth and the Balance of Payments Constraint. London: Macmillan. McKinsey and Company. 2003. Armenia 2020: Key Levers of Productivity Improve- ment and Software and IT Services Potential. Final Report. Princeton Univer- sity. McKinsey and Company. Micco, A., and T. Serebrisky. 2004. "Infrastructure, Competition Regime and Air Transport Costs." Policy Research Working Paper #3355. World Bank, Washington, DC. Michalopoulos, C. and D. Tarr. 1994. "Summary and Overview of Develop- ment Since Independence." In C. Michalopoulos and D. Tarr, eds., Trade in the New Independent States. Washington, DC: World Bank/UNDP. Miller, Marc, Peter Wehrheim, and Peter Wobst. 2003. "A 2001 Social Account- ing Matrix for the Kyrgyz Republic." Technical background report. World Bank, Washington, DC. April. Mitra, Pradeep, and Nicholas Stern. 2003. "Tax Systems in Transition." Policy Research Working Paper 2947. World Bank, Washington, DC. January. Molnar, Eva, and Lauri Ojala. 2003. "Transportation and Trade Facilitation Issues in the CIS-7, Kazakhstan and Turkmenistan." Paper presented at the Lucerne Conference of the CIS-7 Initiative, Lucerne Switzerland. January. Productivity Commission. 1999 "International Air Services." Melbourne, Aus- tralia. http://www.pc.gov.au. Psacharopoulos, George. 1994. "Returns to Investment in Education: A Global Update." World Development 22(9):1325­1343. Public-Private Infrastructure Advisory (PPIAF). 2004. "Sector Overview and Review of International Experience, Identification of Bottlenecks and Rec- ommended Roadmap to Develop a Rural Telecommunications Strategy in Armenia." Presentation, unpublished. PPIAF, Washington, DC. Roberts, B.W., and K. Banaian. 2004. "Remittances in Armenia: Size, Impacts, and Measures to Enhance Their Contribution to Development." Special report commissioned by USAID Armenia Country Office (Contract No. #PCE-I-820-98-00012-0). USAID, Washington, DC. 588 References Robinson, S., A. Catteneo, and M. El-Said. 1998. "Estimating a Social Account- ing Matrix Using Cross Entropy Methods," International Food Policy Research Institute Discussion Paper No. 33, Washington, D.C. Robinson S., A. Cattaneo, and M. El-Said. 2001. "Updating and Estimating a Social Accounting Matrix Using Cross Entropy Methods." Economic Systems Research 13(1). Rodrik, Dani. 2004. "Getting Institutions Right." Unpublished manuscript. Harvard University. ------. 2004. "Rethinking Economic Growth in Developing Countries." The Luca d'Agliano Lecture for 2004 (Turin, October). Washington, DC: The World Bank. Rodrik, Dani (ed.) 2003. In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Romer, D. 1996. Advanced Macroeconomics. Chapters 1­3. Boston, MA: McGraw- Hill, Ros, Jaime. 2000. Development Theory and the Economics of Growth. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Round, J. 2003. "Constructing SAMs for Development Policy Analysis: Les- sons Learned and Challenges Ahead." Economic Systems Research 15(2): 161­184. Sadoulet, E., and A. De Janvry. 1995. Quantitative Development Policy Analysis. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Schneider, F. 2002. "The Size and Development of the Shadow Economies of 22 Transition and 21 OECD Countries." Discussion Paper No. 514 (June). University of Linz (Austria) and Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) (Bonn, Germany). Scott, M. Fg. 1989. A New View of Economic Growth. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Solow, Robert M. 2000. Growth Theory: An Exposition. 2nd edition. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Spulber, Daniel F. 1989. Regulation and Markets. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Stepanyan, Vahram 2003. "Reforming Tax Systems: Experience of the Bal- tics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union." IMF Working paper #WP/03/173. IMF, Washington, DC. September. Contact: vstepanyan Tirole, Jean. 1988. The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Tunyan, B. 2005. "The Shadow Part of the Armenian Economy." Unpublished manuscript. Washington, DC: The World Bank. United Kingdom, Department of Trade and Industry. Various years. "Business Competitiveness Indicators." http://217.154.27.195/sd/bci/index.htm. United Nations Development Program (UNDP). 2001. "National Human Development Report, Armenia." Washington, DC: UNDP. United States Agency for International Development (USAID). 2004. Arme- nia Competitiveness Assessment. Nathan Associates, JE Austin Associates. Arlington, VA. References 589 United States Department of Transportation (DOT). 2000. Transatlantic Deregula- tion. The Alliance Network Effect. Second Report, International Aviation Depart- ment, U.S. DOT, Washington, D.C. http://ostpxweb.dot.gov/aviation/. Weil, David N. 2004. Economic Growth. Boston: Pearson, Addison-Wesley. Wilson, John S., Catherine Mann, and Tsunehiro Otsuki. 2004. "Assessing the Potential Benefit of Trade Facilitation: A Global Perspective." Working Paper 3224. Washington DC: The World Bank. Winston, Cliff, and Steve Morrison. 2003. "The Remaining Role for Govern- ment Policy in the Deregulated Airline Industry." Brookings Institution, Washington, DC. World Bank. 1997. World Development Report. Oxford University Press. ------. 2002a. Armenia. Growth Challenges and Government Policies. World Bank Country Study. Washington, DC: World Bank. ------. 2004. "Regulatory and Administrative Costs Survey." FIAS Report. World Bank, Washington, DC. ------. 2005a. Doing Business in 2005: Removing Obstacles to Growth. Washing- ton, DC: The World Bank and Oxford University Press. ------. 2005b. From Disintegration to Integration: Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union in International Trade. Washington, DC: World Bank. ------. 2005c. Financial Sector Assessment Program Update, IMF and World Bank, unpublished. ------. 2006. Social Snapshot and Poverty in Armenia (National Statistics Institute of Armenia and World Bank). World Trade Organization (WTO). 2002. Report of the Working Party on the Accession of the Republic of Armenia, Part 2--Schedule of Specific Commitments in Services. List of Article II MFN Exemptions. WT/ACC/ ARM/23/ Add.2. December 6, 2002. Geneva. Index Note: f, t, and n indicate figures, tables, aid, monitoring results of, 551 and notes, respectively. Aide-Mémoire, 2004, 266, 267 Air Baltic, 462 air cargo, 109, 421 20 Keys, 556 Air France, 471t, 472t Air India, 425 air markets, 467, 479­482 A Air Pacific, 417 access charges, telecommunications, 292 air service agreements (ASAs), accountability, by country, 571t 416­417, 467 accounting and auditing, 81, 88­89, 315 duopolies, 430 accounting identities, 222, 230, 272­273 features of, 421­422, 452a­460a ACF. See average cost of funds Latvia, 462, 463 active intermodal competition, 295 air transport, 172, 289, 295t, 298 ADA. See Armenian Development Agency competition and LCCs, 406 administrative burden, reducing, 403 connectivity, 413, 418, 420 administrative efficiency, customs, 99, 100 costs, 397­398 administrative environment, barriers to declining, 109, 110 entry, 385 economies of scale, 435­436 administrative surveys, 60­61 liberalization (See aviation adult literacy, 125f, 516, 567, 573t, 580n liberalization) Aeroflot, 424, 466 passengers, 419f, 420­421, 429b Agreement on Subsidies and policy recommendations, 408 Countervailing Measures, 580n restrictions, 318 agricultural accounts, 278t traffic, 436­437 agriculture, 26, 148f, 149f air transportation services, investments employment, 164, 170, 170t in, 359 export share, 151t, 168t­169t airBaltic, 415, 436, 462, 463, 464, 486n FDI inflows, 373t airfares, 405, 420, 421f, 485f growth of, 147, 149 comparison data, 483t indicators, 285t­287t airline costs, 439 labor productivity, 30f, 159f airline viability in liberalized multipliers, 162, 166t­167t environment, 436 prices, 27, 27f airport charges, 438, 439 products, 171, 246 airport survey, 420 shock simulation, 175, 179t, 183t­185t Albania, 115n, 381, 410n 591 592 Index algebraic formulation, 248 international experiences, 425, 428b Alitalia, 471t, 472t multilateral agreement, 477­478 anti-competitive behavior, 63, 71, 290, policy options, 429­434 306b, 307­308 aviation market entry restrictions, 415b APEC-related Multilateral Agreement on aviation outputs, 417­418, 464, 467 Liberalization of International Air aviation policy, 110, 398, 400­401, 421­423, Transportation, 432­433 430­431, 440. See also aviation arm's length contracting, 65, 312­313 liberalization Armavia, 110, 298, 404, 422 Bulgaria, 470­473 agreement with Armenian Airlines, competition law, 437 423­424 contributing to poor performance, 441 agreement with government, 430­431, Czech Republic, 468 434, 441 developing infrastructure, 462­463 Open Skies, 113 economic development, 413­414 route schedule, 450a, 451a fifth freedom rights, 434 Armenia, 117­118, 489­490 freight volume, xxviii­xxix geographic limitations, 5, 160, 216, 318 monopolies, 467 MFN tariff rates, 388t Open Skies, 112 total exports, growth, and GDP, 353t ownership and control, 417, 462 Armenian Airlines, 298, 423­424 recommendations, 408 Armenian Development Agency (ADA), stopping government assistance, 436 496, 546­547 aviation safety, 477­478 Armenian International Airlines, 110 aviation study, fare and yield comparison, ArmenTel, 103­104, 107, 291, 410n, xxviii 479­484, 486 cutting off service, 73n Azerbaijan, 104t, 105t, 337t, 392, 394t impact on telecommunications, 392­393 exports, growth, and GDP, 353t minimizing negative impacts of, 108, financial indicators, 76t 407­408 mobile phone cards, 325n B monopoly abuse, 326n sale of, 369 backbone services, 101, 161, 387 Settlement Agreement, 292, 411n Bahrain, 112, 404 Armington goods, 247, 273 balance of payment statistics, 356, 357, ArmRusGasProd, 293 391­392 Arrow-Debreu economy, 247 bank concentration indicator, 77t Arrow-Debreu equilibrium, 272 bank costs, 78 audits, 308, 315, 348n bank failures, 75 Australia, 426 bank ownership and control, xxv­xxvi Austria, 452a, 463 bank reform, 43t Austrian Airlines, 420, 422, 471t, 472t Bank Settlement Plan, 472 Automated System for Customs Data bank supervision and regulation, 80b (ASYCUDA), 101 banking sector, 30f, 77, 159f. See also average cost of funds (ACF), 262, 264, backbone services 265t, 267 law, 82­83 Averch-Johnson effect, 487n reform, 35, 378t aviation agreements, 110, 405. See also risk assessment, 81, 315 bilateral agreements; Open Skies banking transactions, 78 aviation liberalization, 111, 400­401, 404, barriers to doing business, 60­61, 96, 308, 406, 441, xxix 309, 367, 374­375 arguments against, 435­438 formal, 386t Chile, 474­476 new businesses, 299 Czech Republic, 466­469 barriers to entry, 326n, 329, 344, xxiii effects, 427, 429, 429b air markets, 441 Index 593 aviation, 415b determining quality, 54­55 commercial law inadequacies, 312­313 firm dissatisfaction, 60, 343­344 formal contracts, 313­316 improvements, xxiii formalization, 331 quality, 398­399 barriers to globalization benefits, 349 weaknesses, 57 barriers to outsourcing, 102 Business Environment and Enterprise barriers to small business, 385 Performance Surveys (BEEPS), 345 barriers to telecommunications, 108 business formation indicators, 285t BEEPS. See Business Environment and business, linkages and upgrading, 545­546 Enterprise Performance Surveys businesses, 286, 288, 316, 389, 390 Belarus, 337t, 348n, 353t, 394t, 464 closing, 59t, 60 Belgium, 452a by country, 333t benchmarking, 508­510, 528t, 565­566 country comparison, 341t Bermuda II Agreement, 417 formal barriers, 386t best practice, 58t­59t, 545­546 innovation systems, 531­532 indicators, 330, 331­332 registering, 308 beverages, 153t, 166t, 361­362, 371 starting up, 58t, 59, 339 bilateral aviation agreements, 110, 111, 405, 430, 470. See also air service C agreements liberalization, 433­434, 466 capital inflows, foreign, 95­96 Bilgi, 552b capital market reform, 80b binding constraints, 40, 41­42 capital multipliers, 166t Bleyzer Foundation, 123, 514 capital-based taxes, 264 border closure, 5, 216 cargo, 109, 172, 421, 464 border fees, unofficial, 96, 98, 396 cellular phones, 104, 107 borrowers, 57­58, 314 Census 2001, 189, 192t brain drain, 126, 518 centers of excellence in innovation, 494 brandy, 371 Central and East European Countries Brattle Group, 405 (CEEC), 49, 49f, 50f, 343, 348n, 370t bribery, 123, 514 CPI, 51, 51t bridge institutions, 550 ease of doing business, 53t, 58t­59t, 334, Brience Inc., 359b 340t­341t British Airways, 422, 463, 471t ranking, 331­332, 333t broad money, 75 informal sector, 336 budget balance, percent of GDP, 123f infrastructure assessment, 391 Bulgaria, 334, 337t, 471t, 472t spillovers, 384 ASA with Latvia, 464 structural reform progress, 377f aviation policy, 428b, 470­473 unskilled labor­intensive products, 366 Bulgaria Air, 472, 472t Central Bank of Armenia, 19, 86, 91, 314 bureaucracy, 316 corporate governance, 81­82, 316, xxvi business climate, 52, 61, 66, 72n, 101, 336 Ransat, 524b and FDI, 382 supervision, 35, 82­83 discouraging activity, 56­57 CGE. See computable general equilibrium ease of doing business, 338 Chicago Convention, 416, 435, 470 indicators, 46n, 410n Chile, 519t, 520t regulatory burden, 55­56 KE performance, 511f, 577f business competitiveness indicators, 287f Open Skies, 112, 426­427, 474­476 business development constraints, 501 Chronimet, 371 business environment, 65, 67, 329, 330, CIS. See Commonwealth of Independent 383­385. See also barriers to doing States business civil aviation, 113t, 298 barrier policies, 374­375 clothing chain. See garment industry 594 Index clothing exports, 363, 368 competition technologies, development Cluster Summary, 482 of, 523b clusters, 543b, 544 competitive access option, 325n­326n collateral, 311, 312, 322, 323­324 competitive markets, 291, 357 enforcement, 83 competitiveness indicators, 284 framework, 342, xxvi computable general equilibrium (CGE) reform, 84 model, 194, 267, 274t­275t collective action, 543 benchmark tax rates, 268 collusion, 63, 289 distribution of taxation burden, 215­216 commercial code, 321 economic, 247­248 commercial law, 62, 312­316, 345 structure, 254­255, 260­261 commercial presence, 355, 356, 357, 360 informal vs. formal product demand, commercial services, 354 252, 252f commercial transactions, 65 sector output, 255, 255t Commission for the Protection of sectoral mapping, 270­272 Economic Competition (CPEC), tax reforms, 243, 245 63, 71, 289, 320, 407 tax structure, 253­254 cases, 326n Computer Reservation Service (CRS), role, 307­308 419­420, 479­482 utilities, 293 computers, 128f, 574t commodity supply and demand, 206t concerted action, 525, 544 Commonwealth of Independent States concerted efforts, 129, 526­527 (CIS), 49, 49f, 50f, 336, 351 concessions, 110, 297, 439­440 ease of doing business, 53t, 58t­59t, 334, constant-elasticity of substitution (CES) 340t­341t functions, 247, 248 ranking, 331­332, 333t construction sector, 148f, 159f, 164, 254­255 exports, growth, and GDP share, 353t employment, 170, 170t FDI, 370t, 381 indicators, 285t­287t mobile phone use, 393 labor productivity, 30f telecommunications penetration, 394t multipliers, 166t­167t communications costs, xxviii prices, 27f communications sector, 30f, 159f, 166t, 373t SAM, 176t indicators, 285t­287t share in exports, 168t­169t company law, 82, 315 shock simulation, 172, 174, 183t­185t comparators, 502 consumer demand for formal and competition, 307­308, 320, 321, 425 informal goods, 252, 252f air transport, 406 consumer preferences, CGE model, 247 aviation regulation, 432 consumer protection, 289, 321 business indicators, 287t consumption, 161, 204, 207, 212, 247, fair, 50, 66 250­251, 355 lack of, 70, 317, 319 and growth, 22­24 impact on growth, 283 by poor, 21, 152, 154, xxii lack of restrictions, 304 growth, 22f, 23f, 24 operating constraints, 299 patterns, 210t­211t, 212 petroleum, 68, 73n, 301 rural households, 213t policy, 41­42, 43t, 318, 378t SAM data, 215, 227t reforms and interventions, xxxt contestable markets, 95, 97­98, 325n, 387, quality impacts, 427 xxix, xxvii railways, 295 contract enforcement, 57, 58t, 347, 386t competition law, 63, 289­290, 413 country comparison, 341t aviation, 437 contracting, 312­313 implementation and enforcement, conventions on aviation security, 477 64­65 Corporación America, 398 weaknesses and strengths, xxiv­xxv corporate governance, 78, 315, xxv, xxvi Index 595 reform, 80b, 316 irregular payments, 344 transparency and control of banks, policy recommendations, 408­409 79, 81 reform, 100, 307, 319, 346 weaknesses, 81­82 white list, 114, 402­403 corruption, 50­51, 61, 123, 335­336, 514 Cyprus, 486 costs of, 160 Czech Airlines (CSA), 419, 434, 468, CPI and EBRD scores, 347n­348n 471t, 472t customs, 396 Russian ASA, 466 measuring, 376 Czech Republic, 337t, 410n, 467, 557t­558t RCS 2004, 348n airline data, 467t unofficial fees, 98 ASA with Armenia, 453a corruption control, by country, 571t aviation liberalization, 428b Corruption Perception Index (CPI), 45, aviation policy, 466, 468­469 335­336, 347n financial indicators, 76t by country, 337t tariff rates, 115n values, 51, 51t cost of doing business, 72n D Cost of Doing Business Survey, 330, 331 cost of public funds, 269 data, 220, 221­222, 235 Costa Rica, 504t, 511f, 519t, 578f data improvement, 194, 217­218 courts, 62, 313, 344 data mapping, 231­232, 234 capacity of, 97­98, 389, xxvii data source, 243­244, 273 CPEC. See Commission for the Protection data symbols, 228t of Economic Competition deal flow, 580n credit, 85, 313, 323­324 debt, 17, 17t, 18f, 19 growth rate, 76t management, 33, 45n to the private sector, 311f debt recovery, 339 credit access, 59t, 335, 342, 346 debt-sustainability analysis (DSA), 16­17 formal barriers, 386t Dell, 503t credit availability, 333t, 341t Delta Tau Data Systems, 523b credit bureaus, 85­86, 313­314 demand for commodities, 206t, 207 development of, xxvi demand for formal and informal goods, informational reciprocity, 87 252, 252f creditor rights, 83, 85, 310­311, xxvi demonstration companies, 541b­542b creditworthiness, xxvi deposits, rate of growth, 77 Croatia, 504t, 557t­558t deregulation of aviation, 111 cross-border supply, 355 development assistance, 4f CRS. See Computer Reservation Service development, promotion of, 320 CSA. See Czech Airlines diamond market, 102, 148f, 153t, 165, 363. currency appreciation, 19 See also jewelry customer contact and support supply customs policies, 400 chains, 409n employment, 170, 170t customer contact services, 395 export share, 151t, 360­361 customs brokers, 100, 305­306, 326n, 403 SAM, 176t customs examinations, 319 shocks, 173, 174, 362 customs office, 103, 305, 411n, xxvii simulation, 183t anti-competitive practices, 306b tariff rate, 99 barrier to network trade, 395­396 diamond-polishing factories, 362 barriers to new business, 389 diaspora, 141, 142b, 181n, 383 clearing procedures, 61, 101, business development, 385 306­307, 396 distance learning project, 539b computerization of, 98 entrepreneurial, 490, xxix, xxxii diamond policy, 400 innovation role, 496­497, 538, 549­552, equal treatment, 99, 401­402 554 596 Index diaspora, (continued) scorecard, 514f remittances, 371 variables, 566 transition to KE, 539 Economic Contribution of Civil Aviation, 429 Turkish, 552b economic development, 180b, 414 university alumni model, 553b economic flows, 247­248 diesel, 67. See also petroleum economic growth, 283, 501­502, xxxt direct trader input system, 307 informal activity, 246 disaggregation, 207, 231 link with poverty alleviation, 193 discrimination, small firms, 384 SAM applications, 212­213, 215 dispute resolution, 62­63, 323 sustaining, 491, 499 disputes, 345 Economic Incentive Regime, 122­123, distance learning, 141, 142b, 538, 539b 122f, 123f distribution networks, 94­95 economic model, 194 diversification, 4­5, 165, 170­171, 175, 177 economic performance, 3, 6, 13f, 351, 570t shock simulation, 178t economic perspectives, 216­217 Doing Business Survey, 52, 54, 72n, economic reform, stages of, 528t 330, 384 economic regulation, 293 domestic investment, 123 economic sectors and output, 255t domestic market, 36b­37b economic snapshot, 199, 201­204 contestability, 95, 97­98, 387, xxix, xxvii economic strategy, 499 dominant market power, 64, 299, 317 economic structure, CGE model, 254 abuse, 290 economic variables, SAM, 222 donor support, attracting, 496 Economically Active De Jure double disapproval and double approval, Population, 189 466, 472 economies of scale, aviation, 435­436 DSA. See debt-sustainability analysis economy, 168t, 354 Dubai, UAE, 111, 404, 406 EDC. See Electricity Distribution duopolies, 430 Company education, 20, 135t, 141, 489, 507 by country, 125f E enrollment, 536­537 e-network, 94 indicators, 285t­287t ease of doing business, 52, 58t­59t, KE pillar performance, 510 331­332, 334, xxv. See also revealed policy initiatives, 495t, 530t ease of doing business public spending, 126, 139­140, 516, by country, 333t, 337t 536, 573t coexistence with informal economy, rising student populations, 505b 343­346 tertiary, 140, 144n comparisons, 340t­341t Education and Human Resources pillar, constraints, 342 120, 124, 508b, 515­516, 516f, 565 indicators, 54 scorecard, 517f selected countries, 53t variables, 567 EastJet, 467 Education Quality and Relevance (EQ&R) easyJet, 462 project, 536 EBRD. See European Bank for education-industry linkages, 139­140, 141, Reconstruction and Development 142b, 539b EC. See European Commission human capital formation, 536 ECA. See Europe and Central Asia EIF. See Enterprise Incubator Foundation economic analysis, 193 EIR. See Economic and Institutional Economic and Institutional Regime (EIR) Regime pillar, 120, 121­122, 508b, 513, 565 Electricity Distribution Company country comparison, 513f (EDC), 34 performance, 510, 512 electricity sector, 151t, 153t, 254, 288, 293 Index 597 FDI inflows, 371, 373t exemptions, 557t­558t indicators, 285t­287t expenditure distribution, SAM data, multipliers, 166t 207, 208t emigration, 156, 181 expenditures, household composition, 213 Emirates airline, 111 expenditures, public, 20 employment, 25, 26f, 30, 499­500, xxiv. export diversification, 170­171, 178t, 184t See also unemployment export markets, 362, 364t Armenia and the Slovak Republic, by export performance, 349, 352, 354 sectors, 148f export statistics, by sector, 258t ECA countries, 5f exports, 94f, 260, 360, 363, 409n, xxvi flexibility, by country, 333t and GDP, 352, 355f growth, 27­28, 31, 156, 160 and revenues, 500­501 ICT, 180b by category and destination, 153t impact by sector, 164 by country, 515t indicators, 191t­192t, 286t by sector, 36b­37b, 201­202, 202t multipliers, 163 capital-intensive, 160, 366 new, 29, 157­158 composition, 13, 93, 150­151 sources, 170t by sector, 151t statistics, 188 diamonds and nondiamond, 361f energy multipliers, 166t expansion, 165, 351, 490 Energy Regulatory Commission (ERC), 34 factor intensities, 366t enterprise development, 546­549 growth, 150, 499, 500t Enterprise Incubator Foundation (EIF), high cost of, 160­161 496, 544, 546­547 high-technology, 572t enterprises, 43t, 533t, 545­546 innovation indicators, 519t entrepreneurship, 118, 490, 546, xxix, xxxii nondiamond, 354, 361­362 EQ&R. See Education Quality and sector concentration by country, 365t Relevance project sectoral structure, 168t Estonia, 115n, 337t, 410n, 520t services, 12, 358t financial indicators, 76t software, 281n­282n informal economy, 124t unskilled labor, 365­367 EU-15 countries, 409n VAT rebates, 98 Europe and Central Asia (ECA), 5f, 575f external debt, 17, 17t, 18f European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD), 38f, F 347n, 376 infrastructure assessment, 390­391, 392 facilitation payments, 299 European Civil Aviation Area, 112, 113 factor income, 154, 181n, 208 European Commission (EC), 427, 432 factor intensities, 365, 366t, 369, 371­372 European Union (EU), 51t, 352, 362, factor markets, 254 364t, 393 factor productivity, 6, 156, xxix ASAs, 486n factors of production, 157f, 356 aviation liberalization, 426, 431­432 Fare & Yield Charts, 482 aviation market, 415 farmers, tax exemptions, 246 Bulgarian accession, 473 FAT. See foreign affiliate transfer fare comparison data, 483t FDI. See foreign direct investment LCCs, 111 FIAS. See Foreign Investment Advisory Open Skies, 112, 113, 404 Service proximity and transition pace, 380 fifth freedom rights, 115n, 411n, 434, 470 tariff rates, 96t, 388t final demand, 207, 210t­211t, 252, 252f Exchange of Letters, 470­471 financial access, 76, 308 exchange rate, 11, 19 financial indicators, 76t excise taxes, 261, 264, 265t financial institutions, nonbank, 43t 598 Index financial market reform, 80b foreign investment law, 389 financial markets, 308­312, xxxit foreign savings, 13­14 financial services sector, 285t­287t, 288 foreign trade policy, 96­97, 387, 389 financial system, 75­76, 79, 90 foreign trade, costs, 396 development, 70­71 foreign transfers, 152 underdevelopment, 309­310 foreign-owned firms, 357, 383­384, financing, 40, 518 402­403 Finland, 129, 525 formal economic activities, 249f firing employees, 385 formal financial sector, 335 firing, country comparison, 340t formalization of businesses, 331 firms, 136f, 532f, 555­556 freight, 295, 295t, 296t foreign-owned, 357 volume, 418t, xxviii innovation, 137t, 531­532, 534 fruit, 153t, 171 new, 160 Fundación Chile, 541b­542b technology development, 534, 559­560 furniture exports, lack of, 368 white list guidelines, 402­403 first mover, 441, 543 G first-generation reforms, 375, xxii fiscal deficit, 19­20 GAMS. See General Algebraic flights, 413, 418, 420 Modeling System floating pledges, 83, 311, xxvi garment industry, 94, 95, 374, 395 flowers, 304 gas distribution sector, 293 food, 36bn gas indicators, 285t­287t food prices, impact of lowering, 214f, 215 gas sector, 288, 303f. See also petroleum food processing, 30f, 159f, 166t gasoline imports, 67 food-value poverty, 213 gasoline market, 69b, 301b foreign affiliate transfer (FAT) gasoline price structure, 68f, 303f statistics, 356 gems. See precious stones foreign aid, 4, 6, 371 General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade foreign capital inflows, 95­96, 389 (GATT) Agreement on Customs foreign direct investment (FDI), 57, 177, Valuation, 389 342, 359, 371, 501 General Agreement on Trade in Services and SRI, 381f, 382t (GATS), 97, 355­356, xxvii attracting, 497, 555 General Algebraic Modeling System driving elements, 580n (GAMS), 220 incentive comparison by country, general expenditures on research and 557t­558t development (GERD), 138 inflows, 372, 380, 410n geographic limitations, 5, 160, 318, and exports, 369 343, 346 and privatization, 372f geography and FDI flows, 380­381 by CIS and CEEC, 370t Georgia, 336, 337t, 352, 392 by sector, 373t ease of doing business, 334 innovation indicators by country, 519t financial indicators, 76t investment financing, 15­16, 150 infrastructure assessment, 391, 391f location determinants, 379­380 phone access, 105t, 393 missed opportunities, 369, 371­372 telecommunications sector, 104t, 394t rules of entry, 382 total exports, growth, and GDP, 353t statistics, 357 Germany, 454a, 463 foreign exchange rate comparisons, 288t global integration, xxxt foreign exchange sources, 164 global markets, opportunities, 367­369 foreign investment, 123, 505b global networking, barriers to, 390­392 Foreign Investment Advisory Service Global System for Mobile (FIAS), 64, 290 Communications (GSM), 291 Index 599 Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP), impact on job creation, 170 220, 231­232, 281n jobless, 25 mapping to SAM sectors, 232t­233t, 237t performance, 31, 45 globalization barriers, 349, 399 rates, 40 Gold Mining Company, 294, 325n­326n reform sequence effects, 529 governance, 71, 72n, 140 spillover effects, 164­165 corporate, 65­66 sustaining, 38, 39f, 186 indicators, 46n, 48t growth incidence curves, 21, 22f, 23f quality, 45, 49, 49f, 50, 376, 513­514 growth paradox, 491, 499, 521­522, FDI inflows, 380 523b­524b, 524 measuring, 47 GSM. See Global System for Mobile variables, 123, 571t Communications government, 48t, 50f, 251, 571t GTAP. See Global Trade Analysis Project aviation policy, 434, 440, 441 education issues, 536 H hostile to diaspora investment, 551 pension liabilities, 17 harassment of businesses, 346 restructuring, 43t, 378t hassle cost of doing business, 54, 56­57, SAM data, 198 71, 98, 329­330, 347 grant funds, absorption of, 20 HDI. See human development index grant-based mechanisms for technology health equipment, FDI inflows, 372, 373t development, 534, 559­560 health sector, indicators, 285t­287t grants, innovation financing, 139 Hellenic Telecommunications Greece, 455a Organization (OTE), 103, 291, gross capital formation, 123f, 569t, 570t 369, 392 gross domestic investment, 512­513 Heritage Foundation, 144n, 514, 580n gross domestic product (GDP), 26, high-skilled labor, demand, 579n 254, 352 hiring and firing workers, 58t, 386t and FDI, 369, 410n hiring, country comparison, 340t by sector, 500t Hong Kong and Shanghai Banking cost of raising, 264t, 268t Corporation (HSBC), 76, 309 exports and services as a percentage household consumption patterns, of, 355f 210t­211t, 212 growth, 8f, 148f, 354 household consumption survey, 187 by country, 570t household income, 154, 176, 179t, 208, index of and growth rate, 7f 209t, 217 per capita projections, 521­522, 522f household multipliers, 162, 163b sectoral shares, 16f, 149f Household Survey 2002, 195, 208, 209, 212 shock effects and SAM, 183­185 household survey data, 155b gross national and domestic savings, households, SAM data, 198 14, 15f housing, 148f, 149, 149f growth, 3, 6, 14, 133, 147, 148f, 529f, 555, finance, 80b, 90­91 xxiii. See also economic growth HPL Armenia, 180b and factors of production, 157f Hsinchu Park, 548 and poverty, 24t human capital, 117­118, 489, 507, xxix capital-intensive exports, 160 capability-building, 559 challenges to, 172­174 enhancing education-industry consumption, 21­24 linkages, 536­538 diagnostics, 39 recombination of, 490 drivers, 156, 503t, 504t, 528t, 544 human development index (HDI), exports, 11, 12 566, 570t factors, 161 Hungary, 115n, 244, 334, 337t framework for, 177 FDI, 410n, 557t­558t 600 Index I informal economy, 31, 52, 63, 71, 124, 260­261, 262, 265, 335, 514­515, IAP. See international aviation policy xxiv, xxv ICAO. See International Civil Aviation by country, 124t, 337t Organization by sector, 260t ICRG risk rating, 570t causes, 54 ICT. See information, communications, coexistence with formal, 343­346 and technology corruption, 336 IFC. See International Finance ease of doing business, 338 Corporation formal financial sector, 76 IFRP. See Integrated Financial indicators, 56­57 Rehabilitation Plan revealed ease of doing business, 56t ILCS. See Integrated Living Conditions size, 331, 346, 515t Survey unemployment, 283 IMF. See International Monetary Fund informal market, 281n implementation capabilities, 496, 538, 541 informal products, 252 implementation gap, 62, 345 informality indices and ACF, 265t import statistics, by sector, 257t information and communications imports, 250, 260, xxvi technology (ITC), 351­352, by sector, 36b­37b, 201­202, 202t 360, 407 factor intensity, 366t Information Infrastructure pillar, 508b, petroleum products, 67 510, 565, 567­568 services, by mode of supply, 358t Information Technology Agreement (ITA), sugar, 302, 303t, 304, 304t 97, 403, 411n income, 154, 155b, 213t information, communications, and income distribution, 207, 208t technology (ICT), 97, 180b, income multipliers, 166t 359b, xxix income per capita, 5f, 209, 212 barriers to development, 395 income taxes, 261, 264 by country, 127f income-expenditure gap, 207­208 infrastructure, 103, 134, 135t, 507­508, incumbent dominance, 70 535­536, xxviii Index of Economic Freedom, 144n, 580n lack of development, 139 Indian Airlines, 425 performance, 535f Indus Entrepreneurs (TIE) policy initiatives, 495t, 530t organization, 554b poor quality, 104, 105 industrial capacity, 11, 351 lack of new firms, 94­95 industrial production, 279t value added, 409n industrial restructuring, 366 variables, 128f, 574t industries, list of, 199, 200t­201t scorecard, 521 industry sector, 148f, 149f, 532 white list, 100, 402­403 education linkages, 139­140, 141, 142b, Information, Communications, and 536­538, 539b Technology (ICT) pillar, 510, 520f employment, 170t Information, Communications, and FDI inflows, 373t Technology (ICT) pillar, 120, indicators, 285t­287t 126­127, 518, 520­521 labor productivity, 30f, 159f infrastructure, 369, xxviii. See also multipliers, 166t­167t information, communications, prices, 27f and technology share in exports, 168t­169t aviation, 418, 461, 469 shock simulation, 179t, 183t­185t costs of, 438­440 inequality, poverty effects, 24 investment, 109, 149­150 inflation, 204 informal activity, 244, 245, 246, 249f, 269 Index 601 quality, 390­391, 391f, 392 International Civil Aviation Organization infrastructure institutions, 534 (ICAO), 429 innovation, 138, 496, 532, 533t, 534, international competitiveness, 513 549, xxxit International Finance Corporation by country, 126f (IFC), 541 diaspora participation, 549­552, 554 International Monetary Fund (IMF), 198, grant-based financing mechanisms, 139 265­267 indicators, 519t International Standard Industrial instruments and interventions, 137t Classification (ISIC), 231 pilot projects, 551 international transactions, 356 policy, 534, 540b Internet, 128f, 394t, 507, 574t R&D collaboration, 505b­506b benchmarks by country, 107t innovation clusters, 503t services, 392 innovation council, creation of, 494, 538 usage, 104, 127, 291, 393, 520 Innovation pillar, 120, 126, 508b, 516, intersectoral linkages, 166t, 172, 175 518, 565 interventions, 350, xxxt­xxxit country comparison, 517f inventory management, 395, 399 scorecard, 518f investment, 15, 19, 20, 95, 109, 123, 251 variables, 567 and savings balance, 14f innovation systems, 134, 135t, 136, 507, by sectors, 16f 532, 541, xxxii financing, 150, xxiv framework, 531 foreign savings reliance, 13­14 policy initiatives, 495t, 530t in intangibles, 505b technology transfer, 541b­542b incentives, 557t­558t variables, 572t manufacturing sector, 371­372 input data, 221­222 promotion programs, 546­549 input tables for SAM development, R&D, 129 223t­227t sectoral, 149­150, 149f input-output (IO) matrix, 194, 219 tax impacts, 269 input-output analysis, 240n investment climate, 330 input-output data, 273 investor protection, 57, 59t, 342, 347 inputs, 248 by country, 333t institutional environment, 41, 376 country comparison, 341t institutional maturity, 398 formal barriers, 386t institutional obstacles, 133 investors, foreign, 66 institutional quality, 123, 379­380, 513­514 inward processing, 401 institutions, bridge, 550 IO. See input-output insurance sector, 80b, 88­89. See also Iran, 456a backbone services Ireland, 129, 503t, 520t, 525 Integrated Financial Rehabilitation Plan airline liberalization, 111, 406 (IFRP), 34 informal economy, 124t Integrated Living Conditions Survey innovation indicators, 519t (ILCS), 152 KE performance, 511f, 578f integration, 93, xxxit, xxxt irregular payments, 61, 344 interest rate liberalization, 43t, 378t ISAM. See Internal Single Aviation Market interest rate spread, 77­78, 78t, 310, 310f ISO 9000 certificates, 555 country comparison, 520t Israel, 364t, 503t, 511f, 519t, 520t, 577f intermediation, 42, 75, 79, xxvi ITA. See Information Technology Internal Single Aviation Market Agreement (ISAM), 433 ITC. See information and communications international aviation policy (IAP), 462, technology 466, 469 ITT, 541b 602 Index J Knowledge for Development (K4D), 565 Knowledge Index (KI), 568 Jenks, Craig, 419­420 knowledge performance, 509­510 jewelry cutting, 162 knowledge preparedness, assessment jewelry-trading regime, liberalization data, 569­574 of, 544 knowledge revolution, 489, 506­507 job creation, 27, 147, 149 knowledge transfer, 142b, 550 growth impacts, 170 knowledge, efficient use of, 117 quality, 181n knowledge, obsolescence of, 537 raising rate, 29 knowledge-based competition, 129­130, jobless growth, 25, 156 132, 492 jobs, 176t, 180b constraints, 134, 529, 530t nonagricultural, 28f knowledge-based economy, 506 shock simulation, 178t, 179t transition to, 128­129, 130b, 132 judges, 65, 313, 345 knowledge-based linkages, 545 judicial capacity, 83 Koc Foundation, 552b judicial reform, 62, 73n, 344, 348n Korea, 130b, 525 Junta de Aeronáutica Civil de Chile Korean Development Institute, 526b (JAC), 474 Kyrgyz Republic, 76t, 334, 337t, 392, 394t just-in-time production, 102, 395, 399 tariff rates, 96t, 388t barriers to, 390­392 total exports, growth, and GDP, 353t K L K-Telecom, 291, 292, 407 labor, 11, 26, 93, 117, 181n K4D. See Knowledge for Development division, 102 Kazakhstan, 334, 337t, 353t, 392, 394t, 457a SAM, 176t KEI. See Knowledge Economy Index shock simulation, 178t, 179t KI. See Knowledge Index surplus, 170 knowledge, 134, 543, 549, xxxii unskilled, 28, 149 generation of, 531, xxix vs. capital intensity, 240n importance of, 505b labor indicator definitions, 191t­192t Knowledge Assessment Methodology labor intensity, sectoral value added, 259t (KAM), 122, 143n, 508, labor market, 29, 332, 497, xxiv 565­568, 579n flexibility, 57, 339, 342 assessment data, 569­574 hiring and firing, 340t country comparison of KE pillars, reforms, 346­347 510, 512 rigidity, 335 knowledge economy (KE), 502, 506, 507 labor multiplier, 166t benchmarking, 508­510, 579n labor productivity, 29, 157­159, 158f constraints to, 494 by sector, 29, 30f, 159f implementation capabilities, 496 expansion mismatch, 170 measuring, 555 labor statistics, 188 pillars, 120, 121f, 508b, 565 labor surveys, 189, 191t country comparison, 511f land multipliers, 166t performance, 510, 512 landlocked, 216, 343, 346 policy agenda, 131t, 493t, 528t Larnaca Airport, 420, 479­482 scorecard comparison by country, Latvia, 337t, 410n, 418, 439, 461 575­578 ASAs, 463­464 transition to, 491, 525, 527 aviation liberalization, 428b Knowledge Economy Index (KEI), 118­ FDI incentives, 557t­558t 119, 121, 143n, 508, 509, 509f, 568 indicators, 76t, 519t by country, 119f KE performance, 511f, 575f scorecard, 121f, 512, 512f Index 603 obstacles to growth drivers, 504t employment, 170t passenger throughput, 465t export diversification, 171 tariff rates, 115n export share, 151t, 168t­169t Latvian Airlines, 462 exports by country, 519t Law on Banks and Banking, 82­83 investments, 371­372 LCCs. See low-cost carriers labor productivity, 30f, 159f learning and innovation loans (LILs), 546 shock simulation, 179t, 183t­185t learning capabilities of firms, 136f mapping GTAP to SAM sectors, 237t Lebanon, 427, 434, 457a mapping output statistics, 236t legal effectiveness and extensiveness, marginal cost of funds, 245, 246, 264, 269 62, 345 market access, 115n lending, 76, 84, 309, 323­324 market concentration, 64, 290 constraints to, 60, 342, xxvi petroleum, 67­68, 301 creditor rights, 83, 85 market domination, 299 rates, 518 market information on borrowers, 57­58 secured transaction framework, 322 market integration, xxxt letters of credit, 77, 310 market power, 70 Lev Leviev Group, 362 marketing networks, 374 levy-grant system, 540b matrix balancing, 233­235 liberalization, 44b, 350, 377fn, 544. See also Medium-Term Expenditure Framework aviation liberalization (MTEF), 140 life expectancy, 125f, 573t Memorandums of Understanding LILs. See learning and innovation loans (MoUs), 470­471 liquidity management, 80b, 88 metallurgy, 373t Lithuania, 51t, 60, 337t, 343, 354 metals, 150­151, 151t, 153t, 166t governance quality, 49f Metsamor, 254 government effectiveness, 50f MFN. See most-favored nation reforms, 43t, 377f, 378t, 379 Microsoft, 503t tariff rates, 96t, 388t Millennium Challenge Account (MCA), Living Standards Survey, 208 20, 164 loans, demand for, 309 Millennium Challenge Corporation, xxiv location decisions, 42­43, 390 mineral products, 281n London Heathrow (LHR) Airport, 483t mining sector, 30f, 159f, 166t, 371, 373t London School of Economics, 552b missed opportunities, 349, 374 LOT, 471t aviation, 406, xxix low-cost carriers (LCCs), 111, 406, 415, FDI, 369, 391­372 420, 425, 436, 470 mobile phone cards, 325n, 412n Czech Republic, 467, 468 mobile phones, 128, 128f, 393, 394t Lufthansa, 430, 434, 471t, 472t penetration, 574t Lycos, 103, 141, 282n mobility, labor force, 29 education-industry linkages, 537­538 model, CGE, 194, 247­248 Lycos Armenia, 357, 359b distribution of taxation burden, 215­216 Lyndsey foundation, 255t tax reforms, 243, 245 Lyndsey project, 174 modes of supply, 355, 356, 357, 358t Moldova, 334, 337t, 381, 392, 394t exports as percent of GDP, 354 M financial indicators, 76t Macedonia, 381 total exports, growth, and GDP, 353t machinery, 162 molybdenum, 371 Malev, 471t, 472t monetary policy, 87­88 manufacturing sector, 148f, 153t, 166t­ Mongolia, 392 167t, 175, 369 monitoring of aid results, 551 monopolies, 305, 325n, 467 604 Index monopoly impacts, minimizing, 407 U.S. Department of Transportation mortgage lending, 91 study, 426 most-favored nation (MFN) status, 95 United States, 411n­412n most-favored nation (MFN) tariff rates, by ore, 371 country, 388t Organisation for Economic Co-operation MoUs. See Memorandums of and Development (OECD), 79, Understanding 81, 505b movable property, 322, 342, xxvi organizations, opposition to creating, movement of natural persons, 355, 356 547­548 Mshak, 523b OTE. See Hellenic Telecommunications MTEF. See Medium-Term Expenditure Organization Framework output, 25, 36b­37b, 249­250 Multilateral Agreement on the by sector, 255, 255t Liberalization of International Air Latvia, 464 Transportation, 477 shock recovery, xxii multiple designation clause, 470 statistics mapping, 236t multipliers, 162, 163b, 165, 166t, 172 outsourcing, 368, 372, 400 analysis, 194 attracting, 42­43, 387, 398­399 barriers to, 102, 390­392 ownership restrictions for airlines, 417 N ownership structure, 81 Nairit, 523b National Accounts, 155b, 187, 197t, 231 P National Bureau for Economic Research (NBER) study, 85­86 Pacific Islands Air Service Agreement, 433 National Semiconductor, 523b passenger surveys, 416, 420 National Statistical Service (NSS), 195, passenger transportation, 295t 197, 198, 231, 254 patents, 572t informal economy, 260­261 payments, irregular, 61 software export data, 281n­282n payroll contributions, 261 natural gas. See petroleum pension liabilities, 17 Netherlands, 426, 458a pension reform, 80b, 89­90 network trade and customs, 395­397 performance orientation, 545 networks, 94­95, 134, 550 petroleum market, 69b, 302t New Zealand, 60, 343, 418­419 competition, 73n, 319 ease of doing business, 58t­59t, petroleum products, 67, 300­301 340t­341t pipeline transport, 295t regulatory comparison, 338 pledges, 83, 311, 323, xxvi newspapers, 128f, 574t Poland, 244, 334, 337t Nokia, 129, 525 FDI incentives, 557t­558t nonbank financial institutions, 378t financial indicators, 76t Northern Ireland, 460a policy, 118, 194, 243. See also aviation notaries, 313 liberalization; aviation policy competition, 318 innovation, 135t, 137t O KE transition, 131t, 528t oil exports, characteristics, 363 addressing constraints, 495t Olympic, 471t matching to capabilities, 533t Open Skies, 113, 298, 404­405, 416­417 recommendations, 399, 408­409, adoption of, 432­433 xxxt­xxxit Chile, 112 short-term, 346, 350, 403 Czech Republic, 466 political stability, 48t, 72n, 571t promoting internationally, 477­478 poor people and consumption, 21, spread of, 441­442 152, xxii Index 605 port efficiency, 103 production technology, CGE model, 247 poverty analysis, 216­217 productivity enhancement activities, poverty indicators, 21t, 23­24 556, 559 poverty line, 3 productivity gains, 10, 11, 154, xxiii poverty reduction, 70, 152, 177, 212, 317 productivity gap, 6 consumption effects, 24 productivity, various countries, 9f distribution of taxation, 215­216 products, unskilled labor­intensive, driven by consumption growth, xxii 366, 367 export expansion impact, 165 profits tax, 261, 264, 265, 265t impacts of wage increase and food property registration, 58t, 60, 339, 340t price decline, 214f protection of rights of businesses, 316 link to economic growth, 193 protection rackets, 70 targeting, 213, 214 Protocol for the Suppression of Unlawful poverty, food-value, 213 Acts of Violence at Airports Serving poverty, growth impact, 24t International Civil Aviation, 4 power sector, 30f, 159f, 293 public expenditures, quality of, 20 Practical Program of Revolution in public goods and reliable tax system, 243 Factories and Other Organizations Public Services Regulatory Commission (PPORF), 556 (PSRC), 108, 318 Prague Airport, 467 precious stones, 150­151, 202, 281n Q press freedom, by country, 571t price changes, 204 Qantas, 417, 486n, 487n price shifts, agriculture, 27 quality certification, 555 prices, by sector, 27f pricing principles, 297­298 R pricing, customs, 307, 389, 396 pricing, unjustified, 64 R&D. See research & development private sector, 311f, 339, xxxii R&D Institute of Mathematical development, 70, 165, 320 Machines, 180b private transfers, 155 radios, 128f, 373t, 574t privatization, 43t, 150, 372f, 410n rail sector, 294­298, 295t, 391 land, 33­34 infrastructure, 391f reform progress, 378t regulation, 318 Zangezur, 371 restructuring, 325n processing sectors, 165, 171 Ramsey pricing, 297­298 production, 117, 248 Ransat, 524b value added, 161, 165 rate-of-return regulation, 293 by sector, 203­204, 203t RCA. See revealed comparative advantage production and trade values by sector, RCS. See Regulatory Cost Survey 224t real effective exchange rate (REER), 8f production blocs, 101 real estate, business formation indicators, production fragmentation, 368, 374, xxviii 285t­287t production functions, 248­250 real wage growth, 158f production networks, 94­95, 101, 374 recovery rate, 60 production shares according to NSS, 279t reference pricing, 307, 389, 396 production statistics, 36b­37b, 199, 201, reform, 81, 133f, 321, 529f, xxiii­xxiv, 280t xxxt­xxxit CGE model by sector, 256t civil aviation, 113t data improvement, 218 collateral-based lending, 84 production structure for formal and corporate governance, 316 informal activities, 249f customs, 100, 307, 319, 346 production technology structure, 226t, education, 140 276t­277t financial and capital markets, 80b 606 Index reform, (continued) research & development (R&D), 138, first-generation, 35, 38f, 375, xxii 532, 572t housing finance, 91 collaboration, 505b­506b judicial, 62, 73n, 344, 348n industry linkages, xxxii KE transition, 525 innovation systems, 531 knowledge-based competitiveness, investment, 129 129­130, 132 spending, 126, 518 labor market, 346­347 by country, 519t market-oriented, 33­34 transition to KE, 525 pension, 89­90 technology transfer, 560­561 progress index, 376 researchers in R&D, 572t regulatory, 338 reserve requirement increase, 88 second-generation, 42, 43t, 45, revealed comparative advantage (RCA), 375, xxiii 151, 152t, 152tn secured transactions, 312, 322­324 revealed ease of doing business, 54, 55, sequencing, 529 73n, 334­336, 338, 348n structural (See structural reform) by country, 337t tax system, 243, 265­267, 346 informal economy, 56t recommendations, 244­245 Riga Airport, 418, 439, 444a­449a, 461 transition to KE, 491 market fare and yield data, 479­482 registering a business, 308 passenger throughput, 465t registering property, 339, 343, 347, 386t roads, 295, 391f by country, 333t role models, 502 country comparison, 340t Romania, 334, 337t, 384, 464 regulation, 318, 344 secured transactions, 84­85, 322­324 air transport, 289, 416­417 roofs, 66, 70, 299 railways, 297­298 rule of law, 62, 122, 512, 566, 571t utilities, 293 Russia, 6, 45n, 337t, 352, 394t, 520t regulatory burden of business, 55­56 Armenia's exports, 11­12 regulatory compliance costs, 63 ASAs, 405, 422, 424, 458a, 463­464, Regulatory Cost Survey (RCS), 60­61, 73n, 466­467 343­344, 348n ease of doing business, 58t­59t, 334, regulatory environment, 103 336, 340t­341t regulatory framework, 34, 321 financial indicators, 76t regulatory quality, 48t, 50, 50f, 335 informal economy, 124t by country, 571t innovation indicators, 519t firm dissatisfaction, 343 KE performance, 511f, 576f indicator, 566 obstacles to growth, 504t regulatory regime, 338, 339 regulatory comparison, 338 reinsurance, 89 total exports, growth, and GDP, 353t relationship lending, 92n, 327n Russian markets, FDI stock per capita, remittances, 75, 152, 155­156, 181n­182n, 381­382 371, 501 Ryanair, 111, 420, 425, 462 growth, 154 impact on market, 484, 484b household income, 164 SAM, 176t S shocks, 173­174, 184t starting new businesses, 383 SAC. See Structural Adjustment Credit remoteness, 216, 343, 346 safety, 415, 425, 431, 437­438 rent seeking, 51 aviation, 477­478 reporting requirements, 81 SAM. See social accounting matrix repossession, 323 satellite communication, 103, 392 Index 607 savings, 14, 14f, 15f innovation indicators, 519t Scandinavian Airlines Systems (SAS), 462 KE performance, 511f, 576f science & technology (S&T) parks, 548 small businesses, barriers to entry, 385 scientific journal articles, 572t small- and medium-size enterprises second-generation reforms, 375, 376, (SMEs), 532f 379­383, xxiii Smartwings, 415, 467, 468 secondary education variable, 567 social accounting matrix (SAM), 163b, secondary enrollment, 573t 168t, 176t, 186­187, 216­217 sector descriptions, 270­272 accounting identities, 222, 230 sector export growth, 500t applications of, 212­213, 215­216 sectoral and consumer relationship, 247 balancing, 219, 234, 235 sectoral classification, GTAP, 231­232 build distribution, 237­240 sectoral earnings indicators, 286t deployment, 220 sectoral expenditures, 207, 208t development, 193, 194, 219, 222f, 223t sectoral structure, 168t household (HH), 195, 207­209, 212, 216 sectors and output, 255t input tables, 223t­227t secured transactions, 84, 311­312, 321, xxvi limitations, 240n security markets, 43t, 378t macro, 194, 195, 196­197, 197t, 207, sensitivity analysis, 267­268, 268t 216, 235 service chain, 44­45, 102, 390 mapping output statistics, 236t service links, 42­43 micro, 194, 195, 198­199, 198t, 207, services sector, 5, 95, 147, 148f, 172, 387 208, 216 by mode of supply, 358t symbols, 228t­229t customer contact, 395 social accounts, 195, 196t, 220 economic performance, 354­360 social protection, 22­23, 154 employment, 170t social security, 261 expansion, 351­352 social services, indicators, 285t­287t exports, 12, 151, 168t­169t software cluster, 544 FDI inflows, 373t software development, 180b, 359b, 395 integration, 93 software exports, 281n­282n labor productivity, 30f, 159f software supply chains, 400 liberalization, 44b, 350 Southeastern Europe (SEE), 51t, 366, multipliers, 167t 377f, 393 prices, 27f Southwest Airlines, 111, 425 shock simulation, 183t­185t Soviet accounts, 231 shadow economy. See informal economy spillovers, 39f, 161­162, 164­165, 186­187 shocks, 175, 178t, 179t, 183t­185t, 362 SRI. See structural reform index Siberian Airlines, 110, 423­424 stakeholders, 492, 494, 527 simulations, 178t, 262, 264­265 Staknoimport, 523b Singapore Ministerial Conference, 97 stand-alone costs, 298 skill development fund, creation of, 540b starting up a business, 286, 288, 304, skilled labor­intensive products, 409n 339, 347 Skills Development Fund, 142 by country, 333t skills mismatch, 28 comparators, 58t, 59 skills, obsolescence of, 537 costs, 501 Slovak Republic, 115n, 336, 337t, country comparison, 340t 348n, 410n formal barriers, 386t employment by sectors, 148f Statistical Handbook, 209 FDI incentives, 557t­558t Statistical Yearbook 2004, 191t Slovenia, 334, 336, 337t, 348n, 520t Statistical Yearbook of Armenia, 188­189 FDI incentives, 557t­558t steady-state capital, 251­252 informal economy, 124t Structural Adjustment Credit (SAC), 536 608 Index structural reform, 31, 398­399 tax administration, 60­61, 204, 343­344, country comparison, 40, 41f 348n. See also value added tax FDI inflows, 380 firm dissatisfaction with, 316 implementation of, 350 reform, 346 progress, 377, 377f, 378t tax allowances, country comparison, indicators, 376 557t­558t lack of, 379 tax audits, 308 structural reform index (SRI), 40, 41f, 42, tax burden by household types, 215­216 45, 410n tax code, 261 FDI, 381f, 382t tax evasion, 245­246, 261 structured build approach, 220, 223t tax payments by sector, 205t student-teacher ratio, 125f tax policy, 20, 251­252, 269 study overhang, 490­491 IMF recommendations, 245 subsidies, 557t­558t, 580n impacts on economic growth, 246 sugar, 302, 303t, 304, 304t tax rates, 3n, 268 supply chains, 44­45, 114n, 409n, 543b tax reform, 244, 265­267, 266t global, 368 tax revenue, 199, 262, 264t software, 400 collections, 243, 245, 261 supply modes, 355, 356, 357, 358t by sector, 263t supply side of economy, CGE model, 248 by type, 262t supply-chain management, 102, 399 tax structure, CGE model, 253­254 surety bonds, 307 Tax White Paper, 281n surveys taxes, 225t, 261. See also value added tax 2002 Household Survey, 195 agricultural products, 246 air transport passenger information, 416 capital-based, 264 airport, 420­421 excise, income, and payroll, 264, 265t business climate, 61 profits, 261, 264, 265, 265t Cost of Doing Business, 330, 331 teacher-pupil ratio, 573t Doing Business Survey, 72n, 330, 384 Teaching Company Scheme (TCS), 560­561 household consumption, 187 technology, 136f, xxxit Household Survey, 2002, 208, 209, 212 development, 138­139, 531, 559­560 ILCS, 152 technology gap, 136, 138 innovation in the enterprise sector, 498 technology transfer, 534, 541b, 548, 560­561 labor, 189, 191t technoparks, 548 Living Standards Survey, 208 Telecommunications Act, 407 RCS, 60­61, 73n, 343­344 telecommunications sector, 103, 104t, Survey of Living Conditions, 207 128, 401, 407. See also ArmenTel; Syrian Arab Republic, 459a backbone services barriers, 392­393, 394, 395 competition, 291­293 T FDI, 369 Tajikistan, 353t, 394t high cost of, 106, 293 Tallinn Airport, 420, 479­482 infrastructure, 106t, 172, 391f, 395, 521 tariffs, 96, 123f, 411n, 570t low quality of, 399 and non-tariff barriers' variables, 566 market access, 115n, 411n Chile, 474­475 new legislation, 114 economic growth impacts, 267 penetration indicators, 394t rates, 96t, 144n policy recommendations, 408 average applied and bound MFN PRSC, 108 by, 388t regulation, 318 bound, 115n, 410n services, 357 WTO accession, 387 termination charges, 292 Index 609 telephones, 105t, 127­128, 128f costs, 5, 109, 161, 367, 396, xxvii penetration, 393, 394t, 574t air, 397­398, 397t television, 128f, 574t impact of bilateral agreements, terms of trade, 512 405­406 Terra Lycos, 359b indicators, 285t­287t tertiary education, 140, 144n, 537, 567 share of different modes, 295t enrollment, 573t, 580n transportation and communications textile exports, lack of, 368 sector, 288 textiles, 374 transportation data, rail, 295 TIE. See Indus Entrepreneurs transportation sector, labor Organization productivity, 30f tobacco, 166t Travel Service, 468 total factor productivity (TFP), 521, tributary system, 253 563, 564t Triple-C approach, 545 trade, 101, 151, 216, 352, xxxt trucking sector, 295 air transport, 172 Turkey, 552b, 557t­558t and GDP, 123f, 149f, 513, 570t Turkmenistan, 392, 394t, 459a barriers, 61, 96, 395­396 costs, 102­103 U development, 177 estimating, 356, 357 U.S. Department of Transportation, 405, 426 facilitation, 103, 390 Ukraine, 76t, 337t, 353t, 394t factor intensities, 366t ASAs, 460a, 464 imbalances, 354 GDP per capita, 352 indicators, 285t­287t unemployment, 3, 25, 26f, 157, 189­190, intangibles, 505b 499­500, xxii link to commercial presence, 360 export effects, 367 policy, 97, xxvii informal sector, 283 services, 354­360, 358t rates, 31, 32n, 154 statistics, 36b­37b, 199, 201, 356 by country, 570t CGE model, by sector, 256t unit costs, banking, 78 international, 260 Unit Labor Cost (ULC), 10, 157, 158f, 159 transportation, 109 index, 10f VAT rebates, 396­397 United Arab Emirates (UAE), 111, 112 white list guidelines, 402­403 United Kingdom, 422, 460a, 463, 486n whole sale and retail, 288 United States, 111, 240n with CIS countries, 11, 351 aviation liberalization, 425­426 trade balance, 8f, 250 Open Skies, 112, 411n­412n trade turnover value, 411n universities, distance learning effects, 142b training, levy-grant system, 540b university alumni model for diaspora Trans World Telecom, 410n engagement, 553b, 554 transaction costs, 160, 296, 316, 344 university education activism, 539b transactions, 65, 356 unskilled labor, 149, 365­367, 409n transition economies, 365t, 380 utilities, 34, 293 transition economy factors, 160 Uzbekistan, 334, 336, 337t, 353t, 394t transition from Soviet era, xxii transition progress scores, 347n­348n V transition to market conditions, 11 transparency, 98, 315, 319, xxv value added, 36b­37b, 181n, 227t, 287 transport, 149f, 159f, 166t, 390. See also by labor intensity, 259t backbone services in production by sector, 203­204, 203t barriers, country comparison, 392 multipliers, 163b blockade, 294 production, 161 610 Index value chains, 101, 349, 368, 543b welfare losses, 68, 69b, 301, 301b, 304 value-added tax (VAT), 204, 261, 264, 265t welfare-cost estimates, 262 administration, 99 wheat, 304 policy recommendations, 408, 409 white list, 99, 100, 114, 350 rate, 307 guidelines, 402­403 rebates, 98, 114, 253, 316, 350, 396­397, World Bank, 52, 54, 284, 416 402, xxvii World Economic Forum (WEF), 284 diamonds, 400 World Trade Organization (WTO), 97, 403, revenues, 244 492, 580n vegetables, 153t, 171 accession commitments, 130­131, 387, vehicle transport, 295t, 296t 389, 411n, 492, 527, xxvii vertical linkages, 543b standards not achieved, 396 vertical mobility, labor force, 29 Viaggio, 472 Y Virage Logic, 544 Vision Armenia 2020, 554 Yamoussoukro Declaration, 432 Vision Korea Project, 526b Yerevan Brandy Factory (YBF), 150 vocational training, 540b Yerevan­Zvartnots International Airport, Voice over Internet Protocol (VoIP), 359, 398, 443a 291, 392 air freight, 418t, xxviii­xxix Volgaburmash, 524b concession agreement, 110, 439­440 growth incidence curves, 22f infrastructure costs, 438 W market fare and yield data, 479­482 wages, impact of increase, 214f, 215 passenger volumes, 419f water sector, 34, 288, 373t supply indicators, 285t­287t Z wealth concentration, 70, 317 welfare impacts of tax reforms, 266t Zangezur, 371 E C O - A U D I T Environmental Benefits Statement The World Bank is committed to preserving Saved: endangered forests and natural resources. · 16 trees The Office of the Publisher has chosen to print The Caucasian Tiger on recycled paper · 11 million BTUs of total with 30 percent postconsumer fiber in accor- energy dance with the recommended standards for · 1,368 pounds of net paper usage set by the Green Press Initiative, greenhouse gases a nonprofit program supporting publishers · 5,677 gallons of waste water in using fiber that is not sourced from en- dangered forests. For more information, visit · 729 pounds of solid waste www.greenpressinitiative.org. HE CAUCASIAN TIGER EXPLAINS THE FACTORS UNDERLYING Armenia's stellar economic growth record, which has led to the country's emergence as a pre-eminent reformer among the former Soviet republics, and provides advice on policies that will entrench growth over the next decade. e book is based on work carried out by the World Bank's economic team charged with providing analysis and policy advice to the Armenian government in the years 2005 ­ 06. Dur- ing this period, Armenia had established a solid decade-long record of sustained economic growth amid conditions of economic stability, low inflation, and modest fiscal deficits and external debt. Poverty rates also began to fall sharply. For an economy that had endured a collapse of economic output and hyperinflation in the immediate post-Soviet pe- riod, these were signal achievements. e Caucasian Tiger describes how Armenia created an environment of macroeconomic stability and pursued reforms aimed at establishing a market economy that was integrated with the rest of the world. But the central focus of the book is the reform agenda of the future. e con- tinuation of high rates of productivity gains requires Armenia to deepen reforms directed at sharpening the competitive framework of the econ- omy, achieving closer integration with international trade and capital markets, building financial markets, and creating the conditions for the absorption of knowledge that leads to higher technological sophistica- tion. us, this book is intended not only as a case study of success in post-Soviet economic transition, but also as a candid piece of policy advice for the future. As such, it will be of particular interest to readers working in the areas of economic policy and reforms,the economics and politics of transition to market economies, poverty reduction, competi- tion and corporate governance, banking and trade policies, and stimu- lating innovation within a knowledge-based economy. ISBN 0-8213-6811-7