WPS8018 Policy Research Working Paper 8018 Ageing Poorly? Accounting for the decline in earnings inequality in Brazil, 1995–2012 Francisco H. G. Ferreira Sergio P. Firpo Julián Messina Development Research Group Poverty and Inequality Team March 2017 Policy Research Working Paper 8018 Abstract The Gini coefficient of labor earnings in Brazil fell by nearly wage disparities during the period. Substantial reductions a fifth between 1995 and 2012, from 0.50 to 0.41. The in the gender, race, informality and urban-rural wage gaps, decline in earnings inequality was even larger by other mea- conditional on human capital and institutional variables, sures, with the 90–10 percentile ratio falling by almost 40 also contributed to the decline. Although rising mini- percent. Although the conventional explanation of a falling mum wages were equalizing during 2003–2012, they education premium did play a role, an RIF regression-based had the opposite effects during 1995–2003, because of decomposition analysis suggests that the decline in returns declining compliance. Over the entire period, the direct to potential experience was the main factor behind lower effect of minimum wages on inequality was muted. This paper is a product of the Poverty and Inequality Team, Development Research Group. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted at fferreira@worldbank.org, firpo@insper.edu.br, and julianm@iadb.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team Ageing Poorly? Accounting for the decline in earnings inequality in Brazil, 1995-2012 Francisco H. G. Ferreira Sergio P. Firpo Julián Messina Keywords: Earnings inequality; Brazil; RIF Regressions JEL Codes: D31, J31  Ferreira (1818 H Street, N.W. Washington, D.C., 20433, USA, +1 (202) 473-4382, fferreira@worldbank.org) is at the World Bank and IZA. Firpo (Rua Quatá 300, São Paulo, SP, 04546-042, Brazil, +55 (11) 4504-2400, firpo@insper.edu.br) is at Insper Institute of Education and Research and IZA. Messina (1300 New York Ave, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20577, USA, +1 (202) 623-3272 julianm@iadb.org) is at Inter-American Development Bank and IZA. We are grateful to Camila Galindo, Nicolás Guida Johnson and, especially, to Juan Pablo Uribe for excellent research assistance. We are also grateful to Edmund Amann, Armando Barrientos, Nora Lustig, Ben Ross Schneider and seminar participants at MIT, DFID/University of Manchester and University of Cape Town workshops, as well as at the LAMES 2014, LACEA 2015, NIP 2015, and SOLE 2015 conferences for comments on earlier versions. All errors are our own. 1. Introduction Rising income inequality has recently attracted a great deal of attention in both academic and policy circles. Best-selling books by Piketty (2014) and Stiglitz (2012) have described pronounced increases in inequality in advanced economies, and discussed their myriad social costs. The sustained rise in wage and income inequality in the United States since 1980 has attracted particular attention, with a long and distinguished literature documenting it and debating the relative importance of various contributing factors. Changes in relative skill supplies have been central to the debate, as they can affect the structure of earnings directly through composition effects (Lemieux, 2006) or indirectly through changes in the schooling and experience premiums (Katz and Murphy, 1992; Card and Lemieux, 2001). Changes in technology, subsumed under the rubric of skill-biased technical change, have long been thought to affect the relative demand for skilled and unskilled labor, and hence their relative wages.1 Others have emphasized the role of changes in labor market institutions, such as the decline in unionization rates and in real minimum wages (e.g., DiNardo, Fortin and Lemieux, 1996). Changes in trading patterns and the effect of rising import competition on domestic wages have also gained prominence (Autor, Dorn and Hanson, 2013). As the vibrant debate on the causes of rising inequality in the United States continues, it seems increasingly unlikely that a single culprit will ultimately be identified. But inequality can fall, as well as rise. A recent World Bank study has found that income inequality fell (by more than one Gini point) in 39 of 91 countries for which data were available in the 1993-2008 period (World Bank, 2016). Most of these declines were found among emerging and developing countries: inequality fell in 10 African and 11 Latin American countries, for example. Of course, as the World Bank study acknowledges, in many developing countries there are serious concerns about data quality and comparability, which make reliable analysis difficult. Yet, this is not true in all cases and, in those countries where the data are reliable and where the inequality trends are markedly different from those in the United States and Western Europe, it would seem possible to learn much that is of general interest.2 It is therefore surprising that so little attention has been given in the mainstream                                                              1 See, for example, Bound and Johnson (1992), Katz and Autor (1999), Acemoglu (1998 and 2002), and Card and DiNardo (2002) among many others. More recently, changes in the distribution of occupations and, in particular, in the role that different tasks within occupations have on wage determination, have become central to the discussion of technical change (e.g. Autor, Levy and Murnane, 2003). 2 This argument is analogous to the suggestion by Hamermesh (2004) that much of general interest could be learned from studying the determinants of labor demand in developing countries: “It is true that in many cases the data on labor markets in developing countries are not as complete as in developed economies, but in some cases they are, and in those instances the availability of good data that cover periods of widespread policy 2    economics literature to the drivers of inequality dynamics in countries other than the United States, Britain, France and Germany. In particular, studying cases where inequality actually fell for a sustained period of time can presumably teach us something about the combination of economic environments and policies under which such a trend is possible—even if, as in the case of rising disparities in the United States, there turn out to be many factors at play. In this paper, we investigate the proximate determinants of a substantial decline in the inequality of labor incomes in Brazil—the largest economy in Latin America, and one of the 10 largest in the world—during the 1995-2012 period. Starting from very high levels, the Gini coefficient of the country’s distribution of household per capita income fell by 12 percent, from 0.59 in 1995 to 0.52 in 2012. A 7 basis points reduction in the Gini coefficient in 17 years is truly remarkable. For comparison, the Gini coefficient of household income inequality in the US increased by 8 basis points between 1967 and 2011, from 0.40 to 0.48 (Jacobson and Occhino, 2012). Most of the decline in inequality in Brazil can be attributed to changes in the distribution of labor earnings (Barros et al., 2010; Azevedo et al., 2013), and the Gini coefficient for that distribution fell by 18% in the same period, from 0.50 to 0.41. Economic studies of changes in inequality fall into two broad categories: the first uses exogenous sources of variation (instruments or experiments, say) to identify the effect of one or two factors on the overall distribution (e.g., Autor, Dorn and Hanson, 2013). The second group of studies decomposes the overall change in the distribution into its statistical components (e.g., DiNardo, Fortin and Lemieux, 1996; Juhn, Murphy and Pierce, 1993). There are, of course, advantages and disadvantages to both approaches. In the former, a successful identification strategy would render us confident of the causal impact of the particular factor under consideration (e.g., the effect of trade with China on wages in certain parts of the United States), but the remainder of the change—including any offsetting effects—remains unidentified. In the latter approach, one obtains an exact statistical decomposition of the overall change, but the assumptions required for treating that decomposition as causal identification are somewhat stronger (see Fortin, Lemieux and Firpo, 2011). We view these two approaches as complements, rather than substitutes. In this paper, we follow the second route and use recent decomposition methods based on re-centered influence function (RIF) regressions (Firpo, Fortin and Lemieux, 2009; and Fortin, Lemieux                                                              changes allows us to make inferences about labor demand that should be useful for students of labor market behavior generally” (Hamermesh, 2004: 554). 3    and Firpo, 2011) to estimate the quantitative impact of five groups of candidate explanatory factors on changes in the Brazilian earnings distribution. These factors are: i) human capital; ii) labor market institutions; iii) demographic characteristics of workers; iv) spatial segmentation; and v) sectoral distribution of the labor force. For each group of factors we separate out what can be attributed to changes in the distribution of observable workers’ characteristics, the composition or endowment effect, and what is due to changes in the premiums associated with those characteristics, the pay structure effect.3 By casting the net wide and avoiding preconceived ideas, we come to somewhat different conclusions from those of most of the earlier literature about the recent decline in Brazilian—and Latin American—inequality. During the study period, Brazil experienced a large increase in the supply of relatively skilled workers (with completed secondary schooling or higher), which led to a decline in the returns to education (or skill premiums). Most early papers on falling inequality in Brazil (and elsewhere in Latin America) tend to attribute most of the decline to this falling skill premium effect. 4 More recently, other authors have attributed much – even most – of the decline to the direct and indirect effects of a rising real minimum wage policy (Alvarez et al., 2016, and Engbom and Moser, 2016). To the best of our knowledge, ours is the first study to allow for possible contributions from all of these competing factors—as well as others—within a single empirical model. In so doing, we find that falling skill wage premiums did contribute to lower wage disparities, but that this effect was almost entirely offset by the inequality-increasing effect of higher endowments of education (which moved workers towards a steeper section of the convex earnings-schooling profile). 5 As a result, the overall effect of changes in education—taking both composition and structure effects into account—was economically insignificant. Similarly, rising minimum wages did contribute to falling wage inequality during 2003-2012 but were actually inequality-increasing in the earlier sub-period (1995-2003), when falling compliance with the policy led to higher wage gaps between workers who kept formal sector jobs and those who did not. We find that the bulk of the decline in wage inequality in Brazil over the 1995-2012 period can be accounted for by two other factors. The first is a marked reduction in returns to potential experience 6 —an effect consistent with the age-biased technical change                                                              3 This follows a long tradition that can be traced back to Oaxaca (1973) and Blinder (1973). 4 See, e.g., Ferreira, Leite and Litchfield (2008), Barros et al. (2010), Lustig, López-Calva, and Ortiz-Juárez (2013), and Gasparini et al. (2011). 5 This is the “paradox of progress” of Bourguignon, Ferreira and Lustig (2005), on which more below. 6 Our data, discussed below, does not permit us to observe actual experience for workers, so we rely on potential experience, defined as age minus years of schooling minus six. 4    hypothesis that has been put forward elsewhere in the literature. 7 Combining both composition and structure effects, experience accounts for 3.5 of the 9.0 Gini points decline in the full period. The second factor is a reduction in wage gaps associated with race, gender, location and formal work status, conditional on the observed human capital and labor market institutional variables. These gaps were closing in both of the sub-periods we study (1995- 2003 and 2003-2012), thus substantially reducing what one might call “horizontal wage inequalities”: between observationally equivalent men and women; blacks and whites; rural and urban areas; and formal and informal sector workers. We think of this effect as a move towards leveling the playing field in the Brazilian labor market. These two main findings are robust to widely different specification choices, including changes in the inequality indicator whose influence function is used as a dependent variable in the RIF regression. By reporting on a statistical decomposition of inequality dynamics, we hope that this paper contributes an important first step in the analysis of Brazil’s remarkable inequality dynamics during the late 1990s and until 2012, prior to the onset of its more recent economic crisis. But while it establishes the stylized facts that must be explained, it does not offer a causal analysis of why returns to experience and horizontal labor market inequalities fell. That task is left for future work. The paper is organized as follows. The next section briefly describes our data. Section 3 then reviews the evidence on falling inequality in Brazil, and describes the main trends in the key variables under study. Our empirical approach is described in Section 4, and Section 5 presents the results. Section 6 concludes.                                                              7 See, for example, Behaghel and Greenan (2010), Friedberg (2003) and De Koning and Gelderblom (2004). 5    2. Data The main data source for this study is the Pesquisa Nacional por Amostra de Domicílios (PNAD), and the period of analysis is 1995-2012. The PNAD is an annual, nationally representative household survey, covering both rural and urban areas.8 It is fielded by the Brazilian Census Bureau (Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística, IBGE) every year, except for census years. The descriptive analysis uses all available years in the period 1995-2012, but for the decompositions we use the PNAD datasets for six years: 1995, 1996, 2002, 2003, 2011 and 2012. The following filters were applied to the data to generate our working sample. Our sample includes all workers aged 18-65 who reported positive earnings during the survey’s reference week. Our measure of earnings is total monthly earnings from all jobs, and it is expressed in real values using the CPI deflator with base-year 2005. Monthly earnings are trimmed at the 1st and 99th percentiles. Sample sizes vary somewhat over time, but about 130,000 individuals per year are included on average. All variables used in the analysis are categorical, except for earnings, schooling and experience in the labor market. The last two are measured in years. Demographic worker characteristics include a gender dummy and a three-way categorical variable for race (white, black and other). The analysis also distinguishes between rural and urban workers. Rural and urban areas are classified in accordance with the Brazilian census definitions. Spatial measures also include dummies for the five main geographic regions of Brazil: North, Northeast, Center-West, Southeast and South. Finally, regarding sectoral distribution, workers are divided into 17 different sectors of economic activity (see Table 2 below). In terms of institutional factors, we distinguish three characteristics of the job. Workers are classified as formal employees if they have a job that is properly registered in their work-card or “carteira de trabalho,” which provides workers with various benefits including rights to pensions, unemployment insurance and severance payments. Those employees whose employers have not registered their job in the “carteira de trabalho” are considered informal employees, and we also include in the analysis own-account or self- employed workers (“conta própria”) as a separate category. Self-employment in developing countries is often considered as an indicator of informality, although it also encompasses workers engaged in liberal professions and some entrepreneurs with no employees of their                                                              8 Except for the rural areas of Acre, Amapá, Amazonas, Pará, Rondonia and Roraima states, which correspond to the Amazon rain forest. These areas, which according to census data account for 2.3 per cent of the Brazilian population, were excluded from the survey before 2003. To preserve sample comparability, we exclude these areas from our sample in all years. 6    own. We have also included in the analysis an indicator variable for workers below or at the national minimum wage in a given year. Minimum wage information is collected from the ILOSTAST Database. The description of trends in earnings and other variables in the next section is based on this dataset and variable definitions. 3. Falling Inequality in Brazil and Its Five Potential Drivers As noted earlier, Brazil has experienced a non-trivial reduction in income inequality since the macroeconomic stabilization of 1994-1995. This decline was particularly pronounced since 2003, a period during which average incomes also grew relatively rapidly (Figure 1, Panel A) and poverty fell sharply.9 Brazil was not alone: similar trajectories were observed in a number of other Latin American countries over the same period. A comprehensive discussion of the trends in Argentina, Brazil, Mexico and Peru can be found in López-Calva and Lustig (2010).10 Much of the popular discourse on falling inequality in Latin America has stressed the role of growing fiscal redistribution, through new social protection instruments such as conditional cash transfers (CCTs). Indeed, Brazil’s federal government launched a conditional cash transfer program named Bolsa Família in 2003, which has since reached over 50 million people, and become one of the world’s largest CCT programs. Although Bolsa Família and other fiscal redistribution programs did contribute to the reduction in household income inequality, the best available estimates put this contribution at between 30-40 percent of the overall decline (Barros et al., 2010; Azevedo et al. 2013). Another 10 percent or so has been attributed to demographic factors, chiefly the rapid decline in family sizes, which has been most pronounced among poorer households. The remaining 50-60 percent of the decline in inequality in household incomes has been attributed to changes in the distribution of labor earnings. It is these changes that are our subject here. Figure 1 provides a visual description of the basic income trends in Brazil over this period. Panel A depicts trends in levels, rather than in dispersion: real labor earnings and (per capita) household incomes behaved similarly in the 1995-2012 period, but their behavior differed markedly across two sub-periods. From 1995 to 2003, both earnings and household incomes were either stable or declining: median labor earnings and average household per capita incomes were roughly constant, while mean labor earnings fell by 18 percent. The                                                              9 This section draws in part on our earlier paper (Ferreira, Firpo and Messina, 2016). 10 In addition to these four in-depth case studies, this volume contains thematic chapters looking at the Tinbergen race between educational upgrading and technological change, the political economy of redistribution and trends in top incomes. 7    situation changed around 2002-03, when all three series began to trend sharply upwards. Average labor earnings, for example, increased by about 40 percent from 2003 to 2012. Median earnings and household incomes also grew rapidly in this second sub-period.11 [Insert Figure 1 around here] Panels B, C and D of Figure 1 present the trends in inequality. Panel B shows the point estimates and 95 percent confidence intervals for the Gini coefficients of total household income per capita and of labor earnings. During 1995-2003, the decline in income inequality is clearly less rapid than that in labor earnings, for which the Gini loses four points, but both fall throughout. The second sub-period sees a continuation in the decline in labor earnings inequality, and an acceleration in the decline for household incomes. Over the full seventeen years, income inequality falls by about 12 percent and earnings inequality by as much as 18 percent, when both are measured by the Gini coefficient. Furthermore, Panels C and D show that the decline in earnings inequality is robust to the choice of index: the reductions are actually proportionally larger when measured by the Theil index and by the 90-10 percentile ratio, at 34 percent and 37 percent, respectively. The recent literature on the decline of income inequality in Brazil, exemplified by Barros et al. (2010) and Ferreira, Leite and Litchfield et al. (2008), suggests two main (and clearly related) mechanisms that may account for this reduction in earnings inequality: i) rising levels of educational attainment in the labor force, particularly at the secondary level; and ii) a decline in the wage schooling premium. In other words, they suggest that the dominant explanation for falling wage inequality in Brazil lay firmly in the domain of human capital and, more specifically, that of education: as the supply of educated workers rose faster than the demand for them, the skill premium fell, leading to a more compressed wage distribution. But other factors besides rising levels of educational attainment and reductions in the school premium were also at play during these 17 years, including in the broad domain of human capital. For example, there was a sharp reduction in the experience or age premium, a phenomenon that may be related to the aging of the labor force (although those composition changes were small) or may indicate that technical change was most beneficial to young workers, who are more likely to be familiar with new technologies. There were also changes in the gender and racial composition of the labor force and in the corresponding                                                              11The causes of this inflection and of the boom decade of 2002-2013 go beyond the scope of this paper. 2002 was the year in which President Luis Inácio Lula da Silva took office. It is also now commonly viewed as the beginning of the commodity price super-cycle, which benefited all commodity exporting countries in Latin America, including Brazil. Messina and Silva (2017) discuss possible mechanisms through which the super-cycle may have affected the proximate drivers of earnings inequality. 8    wage premiums. Similarly, changes in Brazil’s labor market institutions, such as the level and coverage of minimum wages, and the degree of enforcement of formal employment contracts, may have played a role. Indeed, in a recent paper using administrative matched employer-employee data from Brazil’s formal sector (the RAIS dataset), Engbom and Moser (2016) claim that the rise in the real value of the minimum wage, including indirect spillover effects along the distribution, may account for as much as 70 percent of the reduction in the variance of log earnings in essentially the same period we study here (1996-2012). The commodity boom that benefited Brazil during the 2000s may have triggered sectoral reallocation of employment, with additional effects on skill premiums and inequality, to the extent that different sectors have different intensities of demand for skills. Finally, there were also changes in employment and wage gaps across spatial areas: both rural versus urban, and across the country’s five main geographical regions. We have therefore grouped the factors that may have affected earnings inequality in Brazil into five major categories: human capital, demographics, institutions, geography and sectoral distribution. Before describing our methodological approach in more detail in Section 4, and presenting results in Section 5, the remainder of this section looks descriptively at each of the five groups of candidate explanatory factors in turn. We first describe changes in the distribution of the relevant variables, and then report—again, descriptively – on changes in the partial correlation between labor earnings and each variable. 3.1 Changes in the Distribution of Candidate-Proximate Factors We begin with human capital. Figure 2 shows the cumulative distribution functions for years of schooling in the working age population (18-65), at three points in time: 1995, 2003 and 2012. These distribution functions illustrate an impressive expansion in the supply of years of schooling in the labor force. The proportion of the working age population with at least 10 years of schooling, for example, doubled from 25 percent to 50 percent between 1995 and 2012.12 [Insert Figure 2 around here] In the absence of information on actual experience per worker, we look at age and potential experience, defined as age minus years of schooling minus six, for each worker. As life expectancy increased over this period, the proportion of the working-age population aged                                                              12This increase in the supply of educated workers reflects educational policy changes dating back to the late 1980s, but also the subsequent decentralization of basic education funding from the state level to municipal level, as well as changes in the funding system with the creation of FUNDEB (Fundo Nacional para o Desenvolvimento da Educação Básica) to reallocate funding according to demand. See Cruz and Rocha (2016). 9    30 or over increased from 64 percent to 69 percent (an 8 percent increase over the period), and those aged 45 or over increased from 22 percent to 29 percent (a 32 percent increase). Yet, the increase in years of schooling documented in Figure 1 proved sufficient to offset the age effect on experience: as shown in Table 1, average potential experience in the labor force experienced a slight decline from 23.1 years in 1995 to 22.3 years in 2012. [Insert Table 1 around here] The second group of factors concerns changes in Brazil’s labor market institutions. Under this heading, we focus on two variables in particular: changes in the level and coverage of the national minimum wage; and changes in the extent of formal and informal employment, as well as self-employment. Panel A of Figure 3 plots the trajectory of minimum wages in the 1995-2012 period, alongside those of mean and median earnings. While real mean and median earnings increased by 14 percent and 43 percent, respectively, the real minimum wage increased by 103 percent over the full period. Interestingly, the bulk of that increase took place in the second sub-period: between 2003 and 2012, the real minimum wage index in Figure 3 (Panel A) rose from 1.26 to 2.03. [Insert Figure 3 around here] Panel B of Figure 3 plots the density functions for real earnings for the years 1995- 96, 2002-03 and 2011-12.13 Vertical lines indicate the values of the minimum wage in each year, and the corresponding spikes are clearly visible. One can also see how the earnings distribution shifted to the right and became more compressed over time. Nevertheless, although such a large increase in minimum wages is clearly associated with a move of density mass to the right, there is a non-negligible mass of workers that remains below the minimum wage threshold. Over the full period, the proportion of employed workers earning strictly less than the minimum wage actually increased by about four percentage points, from 12 to 16 percent. As documented in Table 1, this tendency was dominant in the first sub-period: Between 1995 and 2003 the share of workers below the minimum wage increased by 6 percentage points, and then declined during the 2003-2012 boom. This turns out to have important consequences for our results. The relative extents of formal and informal employment also changed during this period, with a marked increase in the proportion of employees with formal labor contracts (“carteira de trabalho assinada”). This trend may reflect two underlying forces. First, the economic boom of the 2000s, which reduced unemployment rates to record levels and thus                                                              13These pairs of surveys were pooled to increase precision in the non-parametric estimation of the kernel densities. 10    reduced job insecurity, may have increased the leverage of workers to demand that the labor contract be formalized. The second driver has to do with a more active role of two Brazilian institutions, the Brazilian Public Prosecutor’s Office, or PPO (Ministério Público), and the Ministry of Labor and Employment (MLE). Corseuil, Almeida and Carneiro (2012) present evidence of increased enforcement from these two institutions. They document a causal relationship between changes in the frequency and effectiveness of labor inspections and increases in formal employment from 1996 to 2006, using municipality-level data on labor inspection intensity and job flows. Whatever the exact causes for the increase in formalization, the fact is that the proportion of workers employed under formal contracts increased by almost a fifth, from 48 percent to 57 percent, over the complete period, as shown in Table 1. This came at the expense of both informal employees and self-employment. Interestingly, Table 1 also shows that the increase in the proportion of workers earning below the minimum wage during 1995- 2003 occurred despite this rising formalization: doubling the real level of the minimum wage proved to be too large an increase to sustain coverage, even as informality as a whole was in retreat. The third group of factors affecting earnings inequality is related to the demographic composition of the labor force. As shown in Table 1, there was a substantial increase in female labor force participation between 1995 and 2012, as a result of which the proportion of female workers increased by 10 percent, from 38 percent to 42 percent. This trend is associated with increases in women’s educational attainment levels but, more recently, there were also large increases in the provision of public childcare. From 1991 to 2007, the proportion of 0-6 year old children attending childcare increased from 27% to 44.5%, according to the IBGE.14 It is likely that such a large increase might also have had an enabling impact on female labor force participation. Table 1 also shows that the proportion of non- white workers (mostly Afro-Brazilians and people of mixed race) in the working-age population increased by 8 percentage points, to just over 51 percent of the total. The fourth set of candidate explanatory factors relates to the spatial distribution of the labor force. Table 1 points to the continued trend towards a more urban labor force, with the rural share of the working-age population decreasing by 38 percent, from 16 percent to 10 percent of the total. On the other hand, changes in the regional composition of the labor force were not particularly pronounced, as seen in the same table.                                                              14 See http://seriesestatisticas.ibge.gov.br/series.aspx?vcodigo=CAJ318. 11    Finally, changes in the sectoral structure of the workforce may have a bearing on changes in inequality, since sectoral labor demands differ in skill intensity. Despite the commodity boom, the period was still characterized by a reduction in the proportion of workers in agriculture. The expansion of the construction sector (which gained 2 percentage points) and construction-related services (2 percentage points in the real estate sector) were also noteworthy. Because both agriculture and construction are sectors intensive in unskilled labor, the impact of these sectoral changes on the relative demand for skills is a priori ambiguous. 3.2 Changes in Labor Market Premiums Having briefly described the main distributional and institutional changes that may have affected earnings inequality in the previous subsection, we now turn to the changes in the partial associations between these candidate explanatory variables and earnings. We use an extended Mincerian equation as a descriptive tool and will loosely refer to its coefficients as returns or “premiums” to various observed worker characteristics. Table 2 reports the coefficients of an OLS regression of log earnings on the characteristics listed in the previous subsection, by year. [Insert Table 2 around here] Once again we start by looking at the behavior of the human capital premiums. To simplify the exposition, we used the coefficients of our only two continuous regressors— years of schooling and years of potential experience, both of which are entered as quartic polynomials—to plot the predicted earnings-education and earnings-experience profiles. Both of these curves, shown in Figure 4, have changed dramatically over time. The convexity of the education premium and the concavity of the experience premium are preserved, but the average returns to both education and experience fell over the period. Other things equal, the wage gap between a highly-skilled worker—whether in terms of education or experience—and a low-skilled worker was considerably smaller in 2012 than in 1995. [Insert Figure 4 around here] Focusing on the evolution of the schooling premium, it is interesting to note differences across sub-periods. Between 1995 and 2003, returns to secondary education (complete or incomplete) and of incomplete tertiary fall, relative to no schooling. But the returns to completing tertiary education rise relative to secondary or incomplete tertiary. In other words, even as the earnings-education profile in Panel A of Figure 4 shifts downwards in this first sub-period, it also becomes more convex. In contrast, the 2003-2012 period is characterized by a reduction of all schooling premiums, as the log-earnings curve continues 12    to move downwards but also becomes less convex, a feature that is shared with other Latin American countries (Gasparini et al., 2011). Returns to potential experience also fall markedly, as shown in Panel B of Figure 4, and most of the observed decline takes place in the second sub-period. In terms of the marginal effects related to institutional factors, there were two important changes during this period, which may have contributed to some earnings compression. As shown in Table 2, the (conditional) gap between those above and below the minimum wage fell from 102 percent to 94 percent, and that between formal and informal sector employees (that is, excluding the self-employed) fell from 13 percent to 2 percent. The marginal effects of demographic characteristics also became smaller towards the end of the period. The gap between black and white workers, for example, fell from 13 percent to 8 percent,15 and that between men and women fell from 35 percent to 26 percent,16 a trend shared with other Latin American countries (Ñopo, 2012). This pattern is also a continuation of trends observed through the late 1980s and early 1990s (Ferreira, Leite and Litchfield, 2008). Disparities across the five main geographical regions of the country, conditional on other observables, were generally stable over the study period, but the gap between rural and urban workers narrowed by two percentage points. Finally, sectoral wage gaps also declined. Earnings in the agriculture, fishing and, in particular, mining sectors—all of which tend to pay relatively low wages, but which benefitted from the commodity boom of the 2000s— grew closer to those in other sectors. 4. Methodology As discussed in the previous section both the distribution of relevant worker characteristics and their partial correlations with earnings have changed over time, and these changes must have shaped the final earnings distribution. Indeed, we have already seen that both the mean and several inequality measures of the earnings distribution changed considerably over the                                                              15 The omitted group is the “indigenous and other” category that basically consists of Asian descendants, as the remaining indigenous population is very small in the Brazilian labor market, particularly since the rural areas of the Northern region are excluded from the sample. The negative coefficient on the white dummy comes from workers of Asian (mostly Japanese) descent, who have typically commanded a premium over observationally comparable white workers. 16 Until the early 1980s the existence of such wage gaps was generally interpreted as a measure of labor market discrimination. Although we are now more careful, because of various omitted variables that may well be correlated with race or gender (such as the probability of taking time off for child care, or the quality of education), it is of course still quite possible that some of these gaps do reflect active discrimination. 13    1995-2012 period. So, we now briefly discuss how to connect changes in covariates and premiums to changes in the earnings distribution. If one is interested in comparing average earnings between two time periods, say t = 1 and t = 2; then it is possible to apply the method proposed by Blinder (1973) and Oaxaca (1973). Following their seminal papers, one could postulate that earnings are linear and separable in observable and unobservable characteristics, for each time period t = 1 and t = 2: (1) ′ , 1, 2, where is a vector of length k and β is a parameter vector of same length, such that ′ is the inner product of these vectors. We also write a pooled model for earnings that combines both time periods: (1)’ . Let the variable be an indicator of being observed at time t = 2. If unobservable components are mean independent of observable ones (and normalized to have same mean) then the overall mean earnings gap can be written as (2) E | 1 E | 0 E | 1 ′ – E | 0 ′ E | 1 E | 0 ′ Replacing expected values with sample averages (denoted by variables with an upper bar) and parameters with estimated coefficients, one obtains an estimate of the overall mean earnings gap: (3) – – Δ Δ . The first term of the sum in equation (3) is the estimated pay structure effect, Δ – – , while the second term is the estimated composition effect, Δ . As their names and formulae indicate, Δ is an estimate of how changes in average earnings can be explained by changes in premiums, whereas Δ is an estimate of how changes in average earnings can be explained by changes in the distribution of covariates. Because of the additive linearity assumption, it is easy to compute the various elements of a detailed decomposition, in which each term corresponds to a single covariate or observable characteristic. The structure and composition effects can be written as sums over the explanatory variables, indexed by j, as follows: 14    (4) Δ ∑ , , – , – , (5) Δ ∑ , , where , , and , , – , – , are the respective contributions of the jth covariate to the composition and wage structure effects. One can allow for an intercept, which means that , =1 for t=1, 2. That means that the structure effect will have a component , – , that reflects changes in average returns to unobservables. This standard Oaxaca-Blinder framework has been a workhorse of labor economics for decomposing gaps in average earnings since the 1970s. Because we are ultimately interested in how covariates have impacted not only average earnings, but also other features of the distribution, we use a variant of this method based on re-centered influence function (RIF) regressions, which was introduced by Firpo, Fortin, and Lemieux (2009). Usage of RIF-regressions as a way to extend the method by Oaxaca and Blinder to functionals of the distribution, such as quantiles and inequality measures, has been extensively discussed in Fortin, Lemieux and Firpo (2011). In fact, RIF-regressions, when applied to the mean, yield exactly the same decomposition proposed by Blinder (1973) and Oaxaca (1973). RIF-regression methods provide a simple way of performing detailed decompositions for any statistic of the earnings distribution, as long as that statistic admits an influence function. The influence function can be understood as the leading part of a linearization procedure. Therefore, by using influence functions one can approximate non- linear functionals of the distribution, such as quantiles or specific inequality indices, by an expectation. The RIF-regressions are used in exactly the same way as standard regressions in Oaxaca-Blinder decompositions, except that the dependent variable, Y, is replaced by the (re-centered) influence function of the statistic of interest. Let be a functional of the earnings distribution. In this paper, our choices for are the mean , the Gini coefficient G and the τth percentile . Then the structure and composition effects for a functional can be written as sums over the explanatory variables: (6) Δ ∑ Δ , ∑ , , – , – , (7) Δ ∑ Δ , ∑ , , 15    where , and correspond respectively to the coefficients associated with covariate j in a regression of the re-centered influence function of on X for period t and for the pooling of the two periods. Interestingly, if , then RIF equals Y, so the standard OLS regression used in the traditional Oaxaca-Blinder method is a special case of the decomposition method using RIF. We then aggregate the contribution of each Δ , and Δ , into our five groups (human capital, institutional factors, demographics, geography and sectors), although we also further disaggregate human capital into education and experience, and institutional factors into minimum wage and formalization. A relevant detail for the implementation of our method is the fact, noted in Section 2, that many of our regressors are categorical variables. It is well-known in the literature on Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition methods that results are not invariant to the choice of the excluded category (Oaxaca and Ransom, 1999; Yun, 2005; Gardeazabal and Ugidos, 2004; and Fortin, Lemieux, and Firpo, 2011). Several attempts to solve the invariance problem have been proposed in the literature. In this paper we do not impose restrictions on the parameters beyond the usual practice of dropping one from each set of dummies and including the constant. We opted for choosing the best performers (i.e., the categories displaying the highest wages in the pooled sample) to be the omitted categories (white males, urban center-west, and being a formal employee). There is a practical rationale for this choice: 1995-2012 is a period of rapid inequality reduction in Brazil. Hence, the earnings of the most disadvantaged groups tended to grow faster than the earnings of the most advantaged. By selecting the most advantaged as our reference category we minimize the role of the unobserved component in the decomposition.17 5. Results We present our results in three parts. First, we briefly discuss the main features of the typical Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition for the mean, breaking the analysis down into the two sub- periods: 1995-2003 and 2003-2012. We then decompose the Gini coefficient in the same way. Finally, we consider individual percentiles and three specific percentile ratios (90/10, 90/50 and 50/10).                                                              17 As a robustness check, we tried all possible permutations of omitted categories. There are no important differences in the results, once the effects of the unobserved component are discounted. 16    5.1 Average Earnings Table 3 presents the results of the Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition of differences in average earnings over time, disentangling the composition and pay structure effects of each of the five groups of candidate explanatory factors listed in the Introduction, and described in Section 3. The first column presents results for the full period, 1995-2012, whereas the next two columns refer to the first (1995-2003) and second (2003-2012) sub-periods, respectively. To improve the accuracy of the estimates we have pooled two years of data on each end: 1995 refers to the pooling of 1995 and 1996, 2003 refers to the pooling of 2002 and 2003 and 2012 refers to the pooling of 2011 and 2012. The top panel gives log earnings in each relevant year, the difference between them, and the decomposition of this difference into the overall composition and structure effects. The second panel further decomposes endowment effects into those of individual (or groups of) variables, whereas the third panel does the same for structure effects. The bottom panel combines structure and composition effects for each individual or group of variables, and reports their total contribution. [Insert Table 3 around here] Average earnings increased 0.26 log points in the entire period, but decreased 0.12 in the first sub-period and increased by 0.38 in the second. For the full period, the composition and structure effects are roughly identical: 0.12 and 0.13, respectively. However, looking at each sub-period separately, we find that changes in premiums explain all of the change in 1995-2003, while structure effects explain about two thirds of the increase in average earnings in 2003-2012. For the full period, pure compositional changes associated with the increase in educational attainment had a large effect on the rise of labor income (0.18 log points), but they were counter-balanced by the decline in the education premium (the structure effect of -0.26 log points). Changes in sectoral premiums (mainly in the first sub-period) and in the returns of unobservable components that are captured by changes in the intercept (mainly in the second sub period) explain most of the increase in earnings for the entire period. The earnings losses during 1995-2003 are largely accounted for by unobserved structure effects, which may be attributable to macroeconomic factors that affect earnings in ways that are uncorrelated with specific individual characteristics. 18 Weak education and experience premiums also contributed significantly to the decline of income levels. The role of the unobserved factors is even more important during 2003-2012 (0.51 log points) but with the opposite sign, possibly reflecting economy-wide terms of trade gains associated with the commodity boom that are uncorrelated with the five forces discussed above. However,                                                              18 In particular, the 1999 currency crisis was associated with a large GDP decline. 17    there were also non-negligible effects of minimum wage increases, increasing formalization and the declines of the gender and ethnic wage gaps in overall earnings growth during this second sub-period. 5.2 Changes in the Gini Coefficient Let us now consider changes in inequality and, in particular, in the Gini coefficient, whose RIF-decompositions are described in Table 4 (for the full 1995-2012 period), Table 5 (for 1995-2003) and Table 6 (for 2003-2012). Each table has the same four-panel structure as Table 3. The six columns present different, incrementally richer, specifications. In column 1 we report decomposition results when only education and potential experience are included as regressors in the Gini RIF regression. Columns 2-6 add the remaining candidate explanatory factors outlined earlier, one at a time: minimum wage, formality status, race and gender, geographical factors and sector of economic activity.19 Overall, the Gini coefficient decreased by 9 percentage points, from 0.498 in 1995 to 0.408 in 2012. In 2003, it was 0.467, so most of the reduction occurred in the second sub- period. Structure effects explain all of the inequality reduction between 1995 and 2012, and were indeed partly offset by a positive composition effect. Had only changes in distributions (the “composition effect”) taken place during this period, inequality would have increased by four points (Table 4). The same pattern holds for both sub-periods, as changes in the distribution of observable characteristics of the workforce were inequality-enhancing between 1995 and 2003 (2.85 Gini points) and 2003 and 2012 (1.78 points). [Insert Tables 4 to 6 around here] To understand the inequality-increasing endowment effect, note that it is driven predominantly by the education component, both for the full period and in each sub-period. This is consistent with what is known as the “paradox of progress” (Bourguignon, Ferreira and Lustig, 2005): 20 increases in educational attainment—even when its dispersion declines—may be inequality-enhancing because of the marked convexity of the earnings- education profile. As the distribution of education shifts to the right, the density mass at the range of years of schooling with the steepest returns increases. That contributes to an increase in average earnings (as seen in Section 5.1), but also to rising earnings inequality.                                                              19 Although a number of insights can be gained by comparing results across columns, the discussion below focuses on the preferred specification in Column 6. Specific results refer to that specification, unless otherwise explicitly noted. 20 See also Knight and Sabot (1983) and Lam (1999). 18    The second element in importance for the endowment effect is the minimum wage, which has an interestingly differentiated effect across the two sub-periods. Overall, changes in the proportion of people earning less than the minimum wage were inequality-enhancing (by 1.13 Gini points) and that is driven basically by the first sub period, when it added 1.84 points to the Gini. During 2003-2012, in contrast, the minimum wage endowment effect was negative. This result should be seen in the light of the changes in the proportion of workers below the minimum wage (Table 1), and of the real minimum wage trends and associated density functions in Figure 3. The picture that arises suggests that increases in the real minimum wage reduce inequality only if labor markets can afford them. In the first sub- period there was a decrease of 13 log points on average earnings (Table 3, second column), which reflected the weak conditions of the labor market for that period. Despite the weak labor market, the real minimum wage increased by 26 percent, contributing to an increase in the proportion of workers below the minimum wage of 6 percentage points (Table 1). It was this increase in non-compliance with the minimum wage policy that contributed to increasing inequality. Aside from education and minimum wages, all of the remaining compositional changes contributed to reducing inequality. But their contributions were much smaller than those of education and minimum wages, in absolute terms. For example, in 1995-2003, the increase in the proportion of people earning less than the minimum wage contributed to an increase in inequality of 1.84 Gini points. The combined negative effects from changes in the distribution of potential experience, formality, race and gender, geographical and sectoral allocation was about one third that value. In the second sub-period, the “paradox of progress” effect was very substantial, with educational endowments contributing 3.1 Gini points towards higher inequality. Changes in the distribution of all other factors, including the proportion of workers below the minimum wage, contributed 1.32 Gini points to reducing inequality. If compositional changes were by and large inequality-enhancing, then the bulk of inequality reduction during 1995-2012 must be explained by changes in different premiums, or the structure effect. The main drivers of the negative (inequality-decreasing) structure effect were the declines in those earning gaps outlined above. In particular, potential experience, formal vs. informal, race, gender and location gaps declined, all contributing to reductions of inequality. The most important structure effect was the reduction in returns to experience. Its contribution to the reduction in inequality ranges from 4.9 Gini points (column 1 of Table 19    4) to 3.1 Gini points when all explanatory factors are included in the decomposition (column 6 of Table 4). But although it was the most important factor, the structure effect of potential experience did not act alone. Column 6 of Table 4 reports reductions in the wage penalty of informal workers (-1.14 Gini points), in the gender and racial wage gaps (-1.59) and in regional disparities in wages (-1.27). All of these are both statistically and economically significant. If we take these three factors together and add their impact through composition and structure effects their overall contribution to inequality reduction during 1995-2012 is 4.61 Gini points, or 51 percent of the observed inequality reduction during the period.21 Driven by a strong structure effect that was equalizing across these three dimensions, this “leveling the playing field” effect was stronger during the 1995-2003 period than during 2003-2012. The contribution of changes in the schooling and experience premium merits a separate discussion. For the 1995-2012 period as a whole, changes in the schooling premium had moderately negative (i.e., decreasing) effects on inequality, although they were not statistically significant in the full model (column 6 of Table 4). However, if we add the positive impact of compositional changes associated with increased schooling in the labor force, the total effect of education was strongly inequality-enhancing (by almost four Gini points; see bottom of Table 4). There were important differences across sub-periods: Between 1995 and 2003, the total contribution of education to inequality is strongly positive (3.8 Gini points according to the estimates in column 6 of Table 5). The positive effect of compositional changes is reinforced by a positive structure effect. As noted in Section 3, this is a period when the high school premium with respect to basic or no education is falling, but the premium of tertiary education with respect to high-school is rising. This second effect turns out to dominate, in terms of the Gini coefficient. The 2003-2012 interval, in contrast, is characterized by a reduction in all schooling premiums. The between-group differences across all schooling levels declined, as captured by a negative and significant structure effect (-2.9 in column 6 of Table 6). The total effect of education (combining composition and structure) is slightly positive but statistically insignificant (column 6 of Table 6), reflecting opposing forces of similar magnitudes. Potential experience turns out to be the main driving force behind Brazil’s inequality reduction in 1995-2012. Both the endowment and structure effects of potential experience                                                              21 This corresponds to the joint total effects of formality status (-1.46), race and gender (-1.86) and geography (-1.29), according to column 6 of Table 4 (bottom panel). 20    reported in Table 4 are negative, although the structure effect was much larger in absolute terms. This large inequality-reducing structure effect comes entirely from the second sub- period, 2003-2012, reflecting the reduction of the experience premium previously discussed. A diminished gap between older and younger cohorts has also been documented in other countries (Behaghel and Greenan, 2010), and been attributed to changes in technology that are biased towards younger workers. Given that the supply of potential experience was essentially unchanged over the period, one can be reasonably confident that the falling returns to experience in Brazil were driven by declining demand.22 Beyond that, the deeper causes of this decline lie beyond the scope of the present paper, and remain a question for future research into Brazil’s distributional dynamics. A number of plausible hypothesis suggests themselves. Age-biased technical change à la Behaghel and Greenan (2010) is one. Another is that sharp changes in terms of trade after 2003 altered the sectoral demand for labor in Brazil (Messina and Silva, 2017). Such a process generates employment and wage opportunities for those workers who are able to move from “losing” to “gaining” sectors. But worker mobility may be costlier for experienced workers, because older workers may face more difficulties to retrain, or a higher opportunity cost in general. The premiums associated with unobserved skills, captured in our framework by the constant term under the structure effect, also fell and contributed to reducing inequality. This is consistent with a single index model of residual inequality, where the price of unobserved skills falls if the premium on observable skills declines (Acemoglu, 2002). In Appendix Tables A1-A3 we report a number of robustness checks, both for the whole period, and for each sub-period separately. We show regressions without sampling weights, using only the male sample, using hourly earnings as the dependent variable and finally using hourly earnings for full-time workers only (those working more than 20 hours). Qualitatively, the main results are largely robust to these changes. 5.3 Percentiles and Percentile Ratios We have also performed the RIF regression decompositions for each percentile of the earnings distribution, that is letting , ∈ 0,1 . In practice, 99 percentiles were used, and point estimates are presented graphically in Figure 5.23 The curves plotting observed log                                                              22Table 1 shows average potential experience declining slightly from 23.07 years in 1995 to 22.32 years in 2012. 23To facilitate the exposition, we exclude from the decomposition the sector effects, which were never found to be significant in the Gini decompositions, and were not significant either for the percentiles in exercises available upon request. 21    earnings differences in Figure 5 are essentially earnings growth incidence curves (see Ravallion and Chen, 2003), and the curves denoting each of the specific endowment or structure effects are the corresponding counterfactual growth incidence curves (see Ferreira, 2012). The top panel of Figure 5 presents the overall decomposition of observed log income differences at each percentile into endowment and structure effects. These high-level results are very consistent with what we learned from the decomposition of the Gini. First, for the entire period, the structure and endowment components had partially mutually offsetting effects on earnings inequality: the structure effect is mostly downward-sloping (inequality- reducing) whereas the endowment effect is upward-sloping along the distribution. Thus, changes in the distribution of labor force characteristics were generally unequalizing, and the observed decline in earnings inequality (captured by the growth incidence curves) is driven by changes in the structure of pay. The only part where structure effects were un-equalizing was at the very bottom of the distribution, up to the 20th-25th percentile. This feature is only present in the first sub period, 1995-2003, and is consistent with a minimum wage spike that lifted earnings substantially around the minimum wage, but not by as much for those earning less than it. [Insert Figure 5 around here] Further decomposing the earnings changes at each percentile into detailed structure and endowment effects (middle panels in Figure 5), we see that the endowment effects associated with the minimum wage and with education are upward-sloping, and thus inequality-enhancing, in the first sub-period. 24 Moreover, the minimum wage effect fundamentally operates up to the 40th percentile, as its impact is less relevant for the top of the earnings distribution. The same is not true for composition effects associated with education, which are monotonically increasing after the 20th percentile. During the second sub-period only education contributes to the endowment effect in a way that increases inequality (the paradox of progress effect). By contrast, the minimum wage presents different endowment and structure effects. The endowment effect during 2003-2012 depresses inequality at the bottom half of the distribution. The structure effect instead shows a mild inequality enhancing effect up to the 20th percentile, but inequality reducing from the 20th to the 50th. During this period, the minimum wage rises from 50 percent of median labor earnings in 2003 to 65 percent in 2012. The decomposition suggests that the minimum wage pulled up the wages of workers in the centiles right below the                                                              24 This too is highly consistent with results from the decomposition of changes in the Gini coefficient. 22    minimum (wage employees whose employers are not complying with the law and low- earning self-employed), but not the wages of the first centiles of the distribution. The structure effect graphs in Figure 5 reveal some additional results. First, between 1995 and 2003, the education and experience structure effects are both U-shaped. Thus, the structure of pay components for education and experience were inequality-reducing for low- income workers, but inequality-enhancing for those higher up the distribution. In the case of education, this is consistent with our earlier observation that returns to completed high- school fell relative to no education, while the premium for a completed college education rose relative to high-school, between 1995 and 2003. For the second sub-period, the structure effects of education and experience were downward-sloping throughout, and thus unambiguously inequality-decreasing. The remaining factors played relatively minor roles, but the gaps associated with demographic, geographic and informality factors tended to be equalizing, which is in line with our previous finding for the Gini. It is only when all of these factors are combined that they gain more importance for the reduction of inequality during 1995-2003 than education itself. In fact, when we sum endowment and structure effects for each factor (bottom panel of Figure 5) we can see that education is the sole exception that was inequality-enhancing. All the other factors contributed to the reduction of inequality. Particularly important was potential experience, which was a crucial inequality reducer. These conclusions, based on visual inspection, are confirmed by a more formal analysis based on selected percentile ratios. In particular, we look at the log 90/10 percentile ratio, a measure of top-to-bottom gaps, and at the log 90/50 and log 50/10 ratios, which are informative of inequality developments at the top and bottom of the distribution, respectively. Results of the RIF decomposition applied to these three inequality measures are presented (as log differences) in Table 7. [Insert Table 7 around here] As in Table 3, the top panel of Table 7 shows the evolution of the three inequality measures in 1995-2012 and in the two sub-periods considered in the analysis, and shows how structure and endowment effects contributed to the observed patterns. For 1995-2012, the log difference of the 90/10 range declined by an impressive 0.45 log points, confirming the sharp inequality reduction in Brazil. This reduction was proportionally more marked at the bottom of the distribution. The 90/50 ratio decreased from 1.31 to 1.09, while the 50/10 ratio declined by 0.23 log points, from 0.94 to 0.71. Inequality declined during the two sub- periods and the reduction took place both at the top and at the bottom, but it was particularly 23    strong in the lower half of the distribution, and during 2003-2012. During this period the 90/10 ratio declined by -0.37 log points (of a total of -0.45), and about 76 percent of the inequality reduction (-0.28) was concentrated in the bottom half of the distribution. The top panel of Table 7 also confirms our finding from the Gini decomposition that the endowment effect was always inequality-increasing during the period. The decline of earnings inequality was driven by changes in the structure of pay. The decomposition of the detailed determinants of the evolution of the 90/10 percentile ratio, reported in the lower panels of Table 7, confirms some of the patterns discussed for the evolution of the Gini coefficient, but places even greater emphasis on the importance of the reduction in the experience premium. Reductions of the experience premium explain even more than the observed changes in p90-p10 inequality during 2003- 2012, and compensate for other factors that were inequality-augmenting. The reduction of the schooling premium has also a large equalizing role, but this equalizing force was mostly offset by the composition effect, which was strongly unequalizing, as seen earlier. Increases in the minimum wage played a smaller, but still significant role, explaining less than 10 percent of the total reduction of the 90/10 ratio. Some of the “leveling the playing field” effects also lose importance. Changes in formality status retain a small equalizing effect that is statistically significant, but geographic, race and gender factors become generally insignificant.25 As expected, the minimum wage has much stronger inequality effects at the bottom half of the distribution, but some impacts at the top half are observed, which is suggestive of spillover effects that can extend up to median earnings. 26 The contribution of the minimum wage for inequality reduction is particularly strong in 2003-2012. About 40% of the p50-p10 inequality reduction during this period is associated with minimum wage increases. 6. Conclusions After decades of rising or roughly stable income inequality, the period since macroeconomic stabilization in 1994 has seen a steady decline in income dispersion in Brazil. While increases in the volume and improvements in the targeting of social transfers have played a role in that decline, perhaps its most important driver has been a reduction in inequality in labor earnings:                                                              25 The latter is marginally significant but positive, hence unequalizing. 26 See Engbom and Moser (2016) for a discussion of possible mechanisms for these minimum wage spillovers, related to a dilution of firms’ monopsony power in a search-theoretic setting where matching occurs with friction. 24    between 1995 and 2012 the Gini coefficient for earnings fell by 18% and other measures, such as the Theil index and the p90-p10 ratio, by between 30% and 40%. The dominant narrative in the literature attributes this decline primarily to educational dynamics: a substantial increase in years of schooling for working-age adults has translated into a rising supply of skills, followed by a decline in the returns to those skills in the labor market (revealing, presumably, that demand for skills has failed to keep pace with supply). Our analysis draws on RIF regression-based decompositions to investigate the relative roles of a broader set of potential determinants including—beside human capital— changes in minimum wages and formal employment; in demographic characteristics of the labor force (chiefly race and gender); and in the sectoral and spatial distribution of employment. We find that the decline in earnings inequality between 1995 and 2012 was driven primarily by changes in the structure of remuneration in the Brazilian labor market, rather than directly by changes in the distribution of worker characteristics. The main exception to this was the inequality-augmenting effect of the increase in years of schooling across the population. This is the so-called “paradox of progress” effect, whereby a rightward movement in the distribution of years of schooling shifts population density to steeper segments of the earnings-education profile, leading to wider earnings gaps. Thus, contrary to the conventional view, the educational upgrade was roughly neutral for inequality dynamics. The reduction of the schooling premium was strong and did have important equalizing effects, particularly during 2003-2012, but it was largely offset by the inequality-augmenting compositional changes. The most important driver of the observed inequality dynamics was the reduction in the experience premium, in particular during 2003-2012. Almost two-thirds (63 percent) of the reduction in the Gini during this period can be attributed to reductions in the returns to potential experience. If one considers the p90-p10 earnings ratio instead, the reduction in the experience premium accounts for even more than the observed changes in inequality, and was partly offset by other, inequality-augmenting, factors. Since the supply of potential experience was largely unchanged over the period—because population ageing was offset by longer educational spells—one can be relatively confident that this large change in returns was driven by a decline in the demand for more experience workers. The deeper causes of this reduction in the demand for experience—which is consistent with evidence on “age- biased technical change” from elsewhere—are beyond the scope of this paper, but invite further research. 25    Other changes in pay structure that contributed to declining inequality can be understood straightforwardly as declines in various different conditional wage premiums: reductions in the gender wage gap (with women’s earnings rising faster than men’s), the racial wage gaps (with wages for people of color rising faster than for whites), and the urban-rural wage gap (with wages rising faster in rural areas). Each of these gaps was, of course, estimated conditionally on the full set of observable characteristics, including education and experience. Another gap whose narrowing contributed to the overall earnings equalization was that between formal (“com carteira”) and informal (“sem carteira”) employees. While these changes in the structure of the labor market are equilibrium phenomena, which may well reflect market forces such as an increase in the bargaining power of workers vis-à-vis their employers, we have argued that they also reflect changes in enforcement patterns by government institutions. The other key institutional variable we considered was the real minimum wage, which more than doubled over the period, generating a formidable spike in the density function of earnings by 2012. As suspected, this rise in the minimum wage contributed to falling inequality in the 2003-2012 sub-period. Its effects were particularly large for the bottom half of the distribution. Some 40 percent of the reduction of p50-p10 inequality was associated with increases in the minimum wage. However, minimum wage increases during 1995- 2003—a period characterized by a much softer labor market—triggered non-compliance with the law, and rising self-employment. During this period rises in the minimum wage were inequality-enhancing, which emphasize the importance of business cycle considerations for the effectiveness of minimum wage policy. 26    Figures and tables Figure 1: Household incomes and labor earnings in Brazil, 1995-2012. Panel A. Levels. Panel B. Inequality (Gini Index). 893.6 0.59 900 0.60 0.57 781.5 800 0.55 0.52 2005 Reals Gini Index 700 670.4 638.4 0.50 0.50 600 637.1 0.46 486.7 0.45 500 447.6 0.40 400 445.0 421.5 0.40 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 Year Year Average Labor Median Labor Average Household Household per Earnings Per Capita Income Labour Earnings 95% CI 95% CI Earnings Capita Income Panel C. Inequality (Theil Index & P90/P10 Ratio). Panel D. Inequality (P90/P50 & P50/P10 Ratios). 1.0 1.4 1.36 0.92 0.9 1.2 1.18 1.02 0.8 0.86 1.0 1995=1 Ratio 1.05 0.94 0.81 0.7 0.66 0.8 0.6 0.63 0.6 0.5 0.4 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 Year Year Theil Index (1995=0.45) P90/P10 (1995=10.00) log(p90/p50) log(p50/p10) Labor Earinings Labor Earinings Labor Earinings Labor Earinings Notes: All measures are calculated over the estimating sample (formal, informal and self-employed of ages 18-65). Negative incomes and the 99th and 1st percentiles of earnings are trimmed. Labor earnings refer to monthly earnings reported in the main occupation. The household per capita income includes all the incomes perceived by the household members. Source: Pesquisa Nacional por Amostra de Domicílios PNAD. 27    Figure 2: Schooling and age distributions by year. Panel A. Education. 1.00 Fraction in the population aged 18-65 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 0 5 10 15 20 Years of Education 1995 2003 2012 Note: The distributions of years of education are calculated for all the individuals over the estimating sample (formal, informal and self-employed of ages 18-65). The year 1995 includes 1995 and 1996 PNAD samples, the year 2003 includes 2002 and 2003 PNAD sample, and the year 2012 included 2011 and 2012 PNAD sample. Figure 3: Minimum Wage and the Distribution of Earnings Panel A. The evolution of real minimum Panel B. Earnings distributions and minimum wage and earnings: 1995-2012. wage spikes by year. 2.03 2.0 1.0 1.8 0.8 1.6 1.43 0.6 kdensity 1995=1 1.4 1.26 1.2 0.4 1.14 1.0 0.95 0.2 0.8 0.82 0.6 0.0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 4 5 6 7 8 Year log(Earnings).2005 Reals Average Earnings Median Earnings Minimum Wage 1995 2003 2012 Notes. Panel A: Median and average labor monthly earnings are calculated with the estimating sample (formal, informal and self-employed of ages 18-65). Negative earnings and the 99th and 1st percentiles of earnings distribution are trimmed. The minimum wage is the national monthly minimum wage. All series are deflated using 2005 Consumer Price Index (CPI) from the World Development Indicators. Panel B: Kernel density functions for all years use the same bandwidth, 0.7. Source: Pesquisa Nacional por Amostra de Domicílios PNAD. 28    Figure 4: Education and experience premium by year. Panel A. Education. Panel B. Potential Experience. 2.0 0.8 log(Earnings). 2005 Reals log(Earnings). 2005 Reals 1.5 0.6 1.0 0.4 0.5 0.2 0.0 0.0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 Years of Education Potential Experience 1995 2003 2012 1995 2003 2012 Note. Each line represents the predictions of a yearly regression that includes a quartic polynomial in education, a quartic polynomial in potential experience, a dummy variable for workers below the minimum wage, two dummies for formality status, two race dummies, a gender dummy, four region dummies and an indicator of work in rural areas (see Table 2). The year 1995 includes 1995 and 1996 PNAD samples, the year 2003 includes 2002 and 2003 PNAD sample, and the year 2012 included 2011 and 2012 PNAD sample. Source: Pesquisa Nacional por Amostra de Domicílios PNAD. 29    Figure 5: Decomposing Changes in Earnings by Percentile Overall 2003-1995 2012-2003 2012-1995 log difference 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 -0.20 -0.40 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 percentile Observed difference Endowments Structure Endowments 2003-1995 2012-2003 2012-1995 0.40 log difference 0.20 0.00 -0.20 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 percentile Structure 2003-1995 2012-2003 2012-1995 0.20 0.00 log difference -0.20 -0.40 -0.60 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 percentile Total 2003-1995 2012-2003 2012-1995 0.20 log difference 0.00 -0.20 -0.40 -0.60 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 percentile Education Potential Experience Demographics Geography Informality Minimum Wage Note: The graph shows the generalized kernel-weighted local polynomial Oaxaca decomposition for each centile of the earnings distribution. See notes in Table 3 for details on the individual effects included in each category. 30    Table 1: Summary Statistics Mean 1995 2003 2012 Years of Education 6.31 7.41 8.92 Potential Experience 23.07 22.51 22.32 Below Minimum Wage 0.12 0.18 0.16 Self-Employment 0.27 0.25 0.21 Informal 0.25 0.27 0.21 Formal 0.48 0.48 0.57 White 0.56 0.54 0.48 Black 0.43 0.45 0.51 Other 0.01 0.01 0.01 Female 0.38 0.40 0.42 Rural 0.16 0.12 0.10 Northeast 0.25 0.24 0.24 North 0.04 0.06 0.06 Southeast 0.47 0.46 0.46 South 0.16 0.16 0.16 Center-West 0.07 0.08 0.08 Agriculture, Fishing and Mining 0.15 0.12 0.09 Industry 0.15 0.16 0.14 Construction 0.07 0.08 0.09 Services 0.62 0.64 0.67 Earnings in 2005 Reals 780.12 655.01 870.97 log(Earnings). 2005 Reals 6.22 6.10 6.48 Note: All the statistics are calculated over the estimating sample (formal, informal and self-employed of ages 18-65). 31    Table 2: Labor Market Premiums. Marginal Effects (1) (2) (3) 1995 2003 2012 Coeff. Std. Error Coeff. Std. Error Coeff. Std. Error Years of Education 0.058** 0.003 0.073** 0.003 0.068** 0.003 Years of Education^2/100 -0.884 ** 0.098 -1.722 ** 0.079 -1.816 ** 0.077 Years of Education^3/1000 1.389** 0.098 2.002** 0.076 1.900** 0.071 Years of Education^4/10000 -0.412** 0.031 -0.531** 0.023 -0.475** 0.021 Potential Experience 0.073** 0.002 0.071** 0.001 0.048** 0.001 Potential Experience^2/100 -0.238** 0.014 -0.275** 0.01 -0.184** 0.009 Potential Experience^3/1000 0.037 ** 0.004 0.051 ** 0.003 0.036 ** 0.003 Potential Experience^4/10000 -0.002** 0.000 -0.004** 0.000 -0.003** 0.000 Below Minimum Wage -1.020** 0.004 -1.037 ** 0.003 -0.941 ** 0.003 Self-employment 0.078** 0.004 -0.011** 0.003 0.081** 0.003 Informal -0.133** 0.004 -0.100** 0.003 -0.023** 0.003 White -0.170 ** 0.025 -0.060 ** 0.017 -0.027 * 0.013 Black -0.296** 0.025 -0.156** 0.017 -0.105** 0.013 Female -0.351** 0.003 -0.297** 0.003 -0.259** 0.002 Northeast -0.211 ** 0.005 -0.217 ** 0.004 -0.224 ** 0.003 North -0.059** 0.006 -0.101** 0.004 -0.113** 0.004 Southeast 0.067 ** 0.004 0.023 ** 0.003 -0.019 ** 0.003 South -0.017** 0.005 -0.022** 0.004 -0.008* 0.004 Rural -0.104** 0.004 -0.054** 0.004 -0.084** 0.004 Agriculture -0.621 ** 0.013 -0.403 ** 0.012 -0.364 ** 0.011 Fishing -0.581** 0.02 -0.416** 0.02 -0.455** 0.019 Mining and Quarrying -0.344 ** 0.024 -0.183 ** 0.021 -0.002 0.019 Manufacturing Industries -0.341** 0.012 -0.304** 0.011 -0.260** 0.01 Electricity, Gas and Water -0.273** 0.019 -0.03 0.019 -0.081** 0.019 Construction -0.423 ** 0.013 -0.354 ** 0.012 -0.266** 0.011 Trade -0.424** 0.012 -0.329** 0.011 -0.308** 0.01 Hotels and Restaurants -0.447** 0.014 -0.367** 0.012 -0.325** 0.011 Transport and Storage -0.212 ** 0.013 -0.133 ** 0.012 -0.182** 0.011 Real Estate -0.385** 0.015 -0.304** 0.012 -0.270** 0.01 Public Administration -0.403 ** 0.013 -0.179 ** 0.012 -0.129 ** 0.011 Teaching -0.681** 0.013 -0.430** 0.011 -0.346** 0.011 Social and Health -0.443** 0.014 -0.297** 0.012 -0.258** 0.011 Community Services -0.550 ** 0.014 -0.353 ** 0.012 -0.288 ** 0.011 Domestic Service -0.558** 0.013 -0.388** 0.011 -0.370** 0.011 Extra-territorial Org. 0.158 0.161 0.238 * 0.121 0.315 ** 0.118 Constant 6.097** 0.03 5.915** 0.022 6.396** 0.018 Observations 214,001 263,774 270,053 R-squared 0.62 0.66 0.61 Note: Robust standard errors in brackets. **, * and + denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. The omitted categories are: above minimum wage, formal employees, center-west, other race, male, urban and financial services. 32    Table 3: Decomposition Results. Changes in Average Earnings. 2012-1995 2003-1995 2012-2003 Overall Post 6.48** 6.10** 6.48** [0.002] [0.002] [0.002] Pre 6.23** 6.23** 6.10** [0.002] [0.002] [0.002] Difference 0.26** -0.12** 0.38** [0.003] [0.003] [0.002] Endowments 0.12** 0 0.12** [0.002] [0.002] [0.002] Structure 0.13** -0.13** 0.26** [0.002] [0.002] [0.002] Endowments Education 0.18** 0.08** 0.10** [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] Potential Experience -0.02** -0.01** -0.00** [0.000] [0.001] [0.000] Minimum Wage -0.04** -0.06** 0.02** [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] Formality Status -0.00** -0.00** 0.00** [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] Race and Gender -0.02** -0.01** -0.01** [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] Region and Urban 0.01** 0.00** 0.00** [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] Economic Sector 0.01** 0.01** 0.01** [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] Structure Education -0.26** -0.11** -0.16** [0.006] [0.006] [0.006] Potential Experience -0.27** -0.07** -0.19** [0.010] [0.012] [0.008] Minimum Wage 0.01** -0.00* 0.02** [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] Formality Status 0.03** -0.01** 0.04** [0.002] [0.002] [0.002] Race and Gender 0.06** 0.04** 0.02** [0.003] [0.003] [0.003] Region and Urban -0.04** -0.02** -0.02** [0.005] [0.005] [0.004] Economic Sector 0.16** 0.13** 0.04* [0.015] [0.016] [0.014] Constant 0.44** -0.07** 0.51** [0.021] [0.022] [0.019] Total Education -0.08** -0.03** -0.06** [0.006] [0.006] [0.006] Potential Experience -0.28** -0.09** -0.20** [0.011] [0.012] [0.008] Minimum Wage -0.03** -0.06** 0.04** [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] Formality Status 0.02** -0.02** 0.04** [0.002] [0.002] [0.002] Race and Gender 0.04** 0.03** 0.01** [0.003] [0.003] [0.003] Region and Urban -0.03** -0.02** -0.02** [0.005] [0.005] [0.004] Economic Sector 0.18** 0.14** 0.04** [0.015] [0.016] [0.014] N 484,054 477,775 533,827 Note: Robust Standard Errors in Brackets. **, * and + denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. Standard errors are calculated using the delta method. Each category summarizes the contribution of the sum of individual effects. Education and experience refer to quartic polynomials in education and experience, respectively, in the underlying regressions. Minimum wage refers to a dummy variable that takes value one for individuals below minimum wage. Formality status summarizes the contribution of two dummies: informal employee and self-employed. Race and gender capture the interactions between a gender and race dummies (‘mestiço’ and Afro-Brazilian, white and others). Region and urban includes the interactions between an indicator variable of living in an urban area and region (northeast, north, southeast, south and center-west). Economic sector adds 17 dummies for economic sector. Omitted categories in the underlying regressions are: above minimum wage, formal employees, center-west, white, male, urban and financial services. 33    Table 4: Decomposition Results. Changes in Inequality. Gini. 2012-1995. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Overall Post 40.83** 40.83** 40.83** 40.83** 40.83** 40.82** [0.077] [0.075] [0.075] [0.075] [0.075] [0.075] Pre 49.79** 49.79** 49.79** 49.79** 49.79** 49.77** [0.071] [0.071] [0.071] [0.071] [0.071] [0.071] Difference -8.96** -8.96** -8.96** -8.96** -8.96** -8.95** [0.104] [0.104] [0.104] [0.103] [0.103] [0.103] Endowments 1.27** 4.46** 4.26** 4.21** 4.15** 4.01** [0.051] [0.058] [0.059] [0.060] [0.060] [0.066] Structure -10.23** -13.42** -13.23** -13.17** -13.10** -12.96** [0.109] [0.103] [0.103] [0.103] [0.103] [0.106] Endowments Education 1.61** 3.66** 3.81** 3.94** 3.98** 4.11** [0.053] [0.054] [0.055] [0.056] [0.056] [0.060] Potential Experience -0.34** -0.41** -0.40** -0.40** -0.40** -0.39** [0.012] [0.013] [0.013] [0.013] [0.013] [0.013] Minimum Wage 1.21** 1.15** 1.18** 1.15** 1.13** [0.031] [0.030] [0.031] [0.030] [0.029] Formality Status -0.29** -0.28** -0.26** -0.32** [0.011] [0.011] [0.011] [0.012] Race and Gender -0.24** -0.29** -0.27** [0.012] [0.012] [0.012] Region and Urban -0.04** -0.03** [0.008] [0.009] Economic Sector -0.22** [0.022] Structure Education 2.74** 1.62** 0.58* 0.90** 0.75** -0.16 [0.279] [0.235] [0.238] [0.248] [0.247] [0.258] Potential Experience -4.92** -2.91** -3.60** -3.18** -3.16** -3.12** [0.600] [0.566] [0.568] [0.565] [0.566] [0.577] Minimum Wage -0.16** -0.04+ 0.07** 0.09** 0.07** [0.018] [0.024] [0.025] [0.025] [0.026] Formality Status -1.38** -1.47** -1.43** -1.14** [0.104] [0.104] [0.105] [0.112] Race and Gender -1.60** -1.58** -1.59** [0.171] [0.173] [0.177] Region and Urban -1.59** -1.27** [0.289] [0.285] Economic Sector 2.16 [1.472] Constant -8.05** -11.97** -8.79** -7.89** -6.18** -7.91** [0.690] [0.641] [0.654] [0.652] [0.719] [1.646] Total Education 4.35** 5.28** 4.40** 4.84** 4.73** 3.95** [0.285] [0.239] [0.242] [0.252] [0.252] [0.263] Potential Experience -5.26** -3.32** -4.00** -3.58** -3.55** -3.52** [0.600] [0.567] [0.568] [0.565] [0.566] [0.577] Minimum Wage 1.05** 1.11** 1.25** 1.24** 1.20** [0.037] [0.039] [0.040] [0.040] [0.040] Formality Status -1.67** -1.74** -1.69** -1.46** [0.103] [0.102] [0.104] [0.111] Race and Gender -1.84** -1.88** -1.86** [0.173] [0.175] [0.180] Region and Urban -1.62** -1.29** [0.288] [0.285] Economic Sector 1.94 [1.472] N 485,442 485,442 485,442 485,407 485,407 484,054 Note: Robust Standard Errors in Brackets. **, * and + denote statistical significance at the 1% ,5% and 10% levels, respectively. The Gini coefficient is expressed in percentage points and goes from 0 (perfect equality) to 100 (perfect inequality). Standard errors are calculated with the delta method. See notes in table 3 for details on the individual effects included in each category. 34    Table 5: Decomposition Results. Changes in Inequality. Gini. 2003-1995. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Overall Post 46.77** 46.77** 46.77** 46.77** 46.77** 46.74** [0.073] [0.073] [0.073] [0.072] [0.072] [0.072] Pre 49.79** 49.79** 49.79** 49.79** 49.79** 49.77** [0.079] [0.078] [0.078] [0.078] [0.078] [0.078] Difference -3.01** -3.01** -3.01** -3.01** -3.01** -3.03** [0.108] [0.107] [0.106] [0.106] [0.106] [0.106] Endowments 0.02 2.98** 2.99** 2.99** 2.94** 2.85** [0.036] [0.048] [0.049] [0.049] [0.049] [0.053] Structure -3.04** -6.00** -6.00** -6.00** -5.95** -5.87** [0.105] [0.100] [0.099] [0.099] [0.099] [0.100] Endowments Education 0.29** 1.32** 1.42** 1.47** 1.49** 1.61** [0.037] [0.040] [0.041] [0.042] [0.041] [0.044] Potential -0.27** -0.33** -0.33** -0.32** -0.32** -0.32** Experience [0.010] [0.012] [0.012] [0.012] [0.012] [0.012] Minimum Wage 1.99** 1.89** 1.93** 1.89** 1.84** [0.034] [0.032] [0.033] [0.032] [0.032] Formality Status 0.01+ 0.02** 0.02** 0 [0.006] [0.006] [0.006] [0.006] Race and Gender -0.11** -0.12** -0.11** [0.008] [0.008] [0.008] Region and Urban -0.03** -0.03** [0.005] [0.006] Economic Sector -0.14** [0.018] Structure Education 0.98** 3.22** 2.43** 2.74** 2.46** 2.14** [0.256] [0.221] [0.225] [0.236] [0.235] [0.249] Potential -2.21** 0.45 0.03 0.47 0.46 0.69 Experience [0.675] [0.641] [0.642] [0.640] [0.642] [0.652] Minimum Wage 0.16** 0.22** 0.34** 0.40** 0.35** [0.017] [0.023] [0.024] [0.024] [0.024] Formality Status -0.93** -1.03** -0.96** -0.81** [0.114] [0.114] [0.116] [0.125] Race and Gender -1.45** -1.40** -1.42** [0.161] [0.163] [0.169] Region and Urban -0.84** -0.70* [0.292] [0.289] Economic Sector 0.27 [1.548] Constant -1.80* -9.82** -7.75** -7.07** -6.08** -6.40** [0.758] [0.715] [0.733] [0.722] [0.790] [1.749] Total Education 1.27** 4.54** 3.85** 4.21** 3.95** 3.76** [0.258] [0.223] [0.227] [0.239] [0.238] [0.252] Potential -2.48** 0.12 -0.3 0.14 0.14 0.37 Experience [0.676] [0.642] [0.643] [0.640] [0.642] [0.652] Minimum Wage 2.15** 2.11** 2.27** 2.30** 2.19** [0.038] [0.040] [0.041] [0.041] [0.040] Formality Status -0.92** -1.01** -0.94** -0.80** [0.114] [0.114] [0.116] [0.125] Race and Gender -1.55** -1.52** -1.53** [0.161] [0.164] [0.169] Region and Urban -0.87** -0.72* [0.292] [0.289] Economic Sector 0.12 [1.549] N 479,686 479,686 479,686 479,635 479,635 477,775 Note: Robust Standard Errors in Brackets. **, * and + denote statistical significance at the 1% ,5% and 10% levels, respectively. The Gini coefficient is expressed in percentage points and goes from 0 (perfect equality) to 100 (perfect inequality). Standard errors are calculated with the delta method. See notes in table 3 for details on the individual effects included in each category. 35    Table 6: Decomposition Results. Changes in Inequality. Gini. 2012-2003. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Overall Post 40.83** 40.83** 40.83** 40.83** 40.83** 40.82** [0.078] [0.077] [0.076] [0.076] [0.076] [0.076] Pre 46.77** 46.77** 46.77** 46.77** 46.77** 46.74** [0.067] [0.067] [0.067] [0.067] [0.067] [0.067] Difference -5.95** -5.95** -5.95** -5.95** -5.95** -5.92** [0.103] [0.102] [0.102] [0.102] [0.102] [0.102] Endowments 1.34** 2.00** 1.86** 1.80** 1.79** 1.78** [0.040] [0.050] [0.051] [0.051] [0.051] [0.054] Structure -7.29** -7.95** -7.81** -7.74** -7.74** -7.71** [0.100] [0.094] [0.094] [0.094] [0.094] [0.094] Endowments Education 1.46** 2.86** 2.91** 3.02** 3.02** 3.10** [0.040] [0.043] [0.044] [0.045] [0.045] [0.047] Potential Experience -0.11** -0.14** -0.13** -0.14** -0.13** -0.13** [0.009] [0.012] [0.011] [0.011] [0.012] [0.011] Minimum Wage -0.72** -0.70** -0.72** -0.71** -0.67** [0.033] [0.032] [0.033] [0.032] [0.032] Formality Status -0.21** -0.20** -0.19** -0.23** [0.010] [0.010] [0.010] [0.011] Race and Gender -0.17** -0.21** -0.19** [0.009] [0.010] [0.009] Region and Urban 0.01 0.01 [0.005] [0.005] Economic Sector -0.10** [0.014] Structure Education 1.62** -2.12** -2.37** -2.39** -2.25** -2.91** [0.293] [0.240] [0.241] [0.254] [0.253] [0.263] Potential Experience -2.67** -3.30** -3.57** -3.59** -3.56** -3.75** [0.515] [0.475] [0.478] [0.478] [0.479] [0.488] Minimum Wage -0.37** -0.31** -0.30** -0.35** -0.31** [0.023] [0.030] [0.031] [0.032] [0.032] Formality Status -0.53** -0.53** -0.57** -0.43** [0.102] [0.102] [0.103] [0.108] Race and Gender -0.11 -0.15 -0.14 [0.174] [0.176] [0.180] Region and Urban -0.76** -0.58* [0.280] [0.275] Economic Sector 1.92 [1.502] Constant -6.25** -2.15** -1.04+ -0.82 -0.11 -1.51 [0.621] [0.562] [0.573] [0.577] [0.644] [1.635] Total Education 3.08** 0.74** 0.54* 0.63* 0.77** 0.19 [0.296] [0.244] [0.246] [0.259] [0.257] [0.268] Potential Experience -2.78** -3.44** -3.70** -3.72** -3.70** -3.89** [0.515] [0.475] [0.478] [0.478] [0.479] [0.488] Minimum Wage -1.10** -1.00** -1.02** -1.06** -0.98** [0.040] [0.043] [0.045] [0.045] [0.044] Formality Status -0.75** -0.73** -0.75** -0.65** [0.101] [0.101] [0.102] [0.106] Race and Gender -0.28 -0.35* -0.33+ [0.176] [0.177] [0.182] Region and Urban -0.76** -0.57* [0.279] [0.275] Economic Sector 1.82 [1.502] N 535,040 535,040 535,040 535,024 535,024 533,827 Note: Robust Standard Errors in Brackets. **, * and + denote statistical significance at the 1% ,5% and 10% levels, respectively. The Gini coefficient is expressed in percentage points and goes from 0 (perfect equality) to 100 (perfect inequality). Standard errors are calculated with the delta method. See notes in table 3 for details on the individual effects included in each category. 36    Table 7: Decomposition Results. Changes in log (p90/p10), log(p90/p50), and log(p50/p10). 2003-1995 2012-2003 2012-1995 p90- p90- p50- p90- p90- p50- p90- p90- p50- p10 p50 p10 p10 p50 p10 p10 p50 p10 Overall Post 2.17** 1.18** 0.99** 1.80** 1.09** 0.71** 1.80** 1.09** 0.71** [0.007] [0.009] [0.009] [0.004] [0.019] [0.023] [0.004] [0.023] [0.023] Pre 2.25** 1.31** 0.94** 2.17** 1.18** 0.99** 2.25** 1.31** 0.94** [0.006] [0.006] [0.004] [0.005] [0.009] [0.008] [0.005] [0.003] [0.003] Difference -0.08** -0.14** 0.05** -0.37** -0.09** -0.28** -0.45** -0.23** -0.22** [0.008] [0.012] [0.010] [0.007] [0.023] [0.027] [0.006] [0.023] [0.024] Endowments 0.29** 0.09** 0.20** 0.12** 0.08** 0.04** 0.37** 0.14** 0.23** [0.005] [0.002] [0.003] [0.003] [0.003] [0.002] [0.003] [0.005] [0.003] Structure -0.37** -0.22** -0.15** -0.49** -0.17** -0.32** -0.82** -0.37** -0.45** [0.006] [0.012] [0.010] [0.006] [0.025] [0.028] [0.007] [0.028] [0.026] Endowments Education 0.16** 0.07** 0.09** 0.21** 0.12** 0.09** 0.35** 0.17** 0.19** [0.004] [0.002] [0.001] [0.003] [0.003] [0.002] [0.003] [0.004] [0.003] Potential -0.03** -0.01** -0.01** -0.01** -0.01** -0.01** -0.03** -0.02** -0.02** Experience [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] Minimum Wage 0.17** 0.04** 0.14** -0.06** -0.01** -0.04** 0.09** 0.02** 0.07** [0.003] [0.001] [0.003] [0.002] [0.001] [0.002] [0.003] [0.001] [0.002] Formality Status -0.00** 0.00** -0.01** -0.01** -0.01** 0.01** -0.01** -0.02** 0.01** [0.000] [0.001] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.001] [0.001] [0.000] Race and Gender -0.01** -0.00** -0.01** -0.02** -0.01** -0.01** -0.03** -0.01** -0.03** [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.000] [0.000] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] Region and Urban 0.00** -0.00** 0.00** -0.00 0.00** -0.00* 0.00** -0.00* 0.00** [0.000] [0.000] [0.001] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.001] [0.001] Structure Education -0.19** 0.08** -0.27** -0.31** -0.10** -0.20** -0.48** -0.00 -0.48** [0.016] [0.015] [0.013] [0.020] [0.018] [0.021] [0.014] [0.015] [0.019] Potential -0.14** -0.11** -0.03 -0.41** -0.26** -0.15** -0.56** -0.37** -0.18** Experience [0.037] [0.043] [0.025] [0.033] [0.027] [0.034] [0.038] [0.027] [0.029] Minimum Wage 0.01 0.01** -0.00 -0.11** -0.04** -0.08** -0.09** -0.02** -0.06** [0.004] [0.001] [0.004] [0.004] [0.006] [0.007] [0.003] [0.005] [0.006] Formality Status -0.04** -0.08** 0.04** 0.04** -0.02* 0.06** 0.00 -0.09** 0.09** [0.008] [0.006] [0.004] [0.005] [0.008] [0.004] [0.004] [0.007] [0.004] Race and Gender 0.08** -0.02* 0.10** 0.03** 0.01 0.02** 0.11** -0.02* 0.13** [0.007] [0.009] [0.005] [0.009] [0.008] [0.006] [0.008] [0.009] [0.005] Region and Urban 0.03* 0.03 0.01 -0.04** -0.03* -0.01 -0.01 -0.00 -0.00 [0.016] [0.018] [0.012] [0.016] [0.015] [0.009] [0.015] [0.019] [0.006] Constant -0.12** -0.13* 0.01 0.31** 0.26** 0.05 0.20** 0.14** 0.06 [0.043] [0.063] [0.036] [0.043] [0.058] [0.081] [0.046] [0.052] [0.059] Total Education -0.03* 0.15** -0.18** -0.09** 0.02 -0.11** -0.13** 0.16** -0.29** [0.013] [0.014] [0.014] [0.020] [0.019] [0.021] [0.015] [0.017] [0.021] Potential -0.17** -0.13** -0.05+ -0.42** -0.26** -0.15** -0.59** -0.39** -0.20** Experience [0.038] [0.043] [0.024] [0.033] [0.027] [0.034] [0.038] [0.027] [0.029] Minimum Wage 0.18** 0.04** 0.13** -0.17** -0.05** -0.12** 0.01* -0.00 0.01+ [0.003] [0.002] [0.004] [0.004] [0.006] [0.006] [0.004] [0.006] [0.007] Formality Status -0.04** -0.07** 0.03** 0.04** -0.03** 0.07** -0.01+ -0.10** 0.10** [0.008] [0.006] [0.004] [0.005] [0.008] [0.005] [0.004] [0.007] [0.004] Race and Gender 0.06** -0.03** 0.09** 0.01 -0.00 0.01+ 0.07** -0.03** 0.10** [0.007] [0.009] [0.006] [0.010] [0.009] [0.006] [0.008] [0.009] [0.005] Region and Urban 0.04* 0.02 0.01 -0.04** -0.03* -0.01 -0.00 -0.01 0.00 [0.016] [0.018] [0.012] [0.016] [0.015] [0.009] [0.015] [0.019] [0.006] Observations 479,635 479,635 479,635 535,024 535,024 535,024 485,407 485,407 485,407 Note: Standard Errors in Brackets. **, * and + denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. Standard errors are bootstrapped with 100 replications. The ratios are calculated as the log difference between the effect at the 90th percentile and the effect at the 10th percentile (50th and 10th, 90th and 50th, respectively). See notes in table 3 for details on the individual effects included in each category. 37    References Acemoglu, Daron (1998) “Why Do New Technologies Complement Skills? Directed Technological Change and Wage Inequality”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 1055-1089. Acemoglu, Daron (2002) “Technical change, Inequality and the Labour Market”, Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 7-72. Alvarez, Jorge, Felipe Benguria, Niklas Engbom and Christian Moser (2016): “Firms and the Decline of Earnings Inequality in Brazil”, Columbia Business School working paper. Autor, David, David Dorn and Gordon Hanson (2013): “The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States”, American Economic Review, 103 (6): 2121-2168. Autor, David, Frank Levy and Richard J. Murnane (2003) “The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118 (4): 1279-1334. Azevedo, João Pedro, María E. Dávalos, Carolina Diaz-Bonilla, Bernardo Atuesta and Raul A. Castañeda (2013) “Fifteen Years of Inequality in Latin America: How Have Labor Markets Helped?” Policy Research Working Paper 6384, World Bank. Barros Ricardo, Mirela Carvalho, Samuel Franco and Rosane Mendonça (2010) “Markets, the state and the dynamics of inequality in Brazil.” in: L.F. Lopez-Calva and N. Lustig (eds): Declining Inequality in Latin America: A decade of progress? Washington (DC): Brookings Institution and UNDP. Behaghel, Luc and Nathalie Greenan. (2010) “Training and Age-Biased Technical Change”, Annals of Economics and Statistics. pp. 317-342. Blinder, Alan S (1973) “Wage Discrimination: Reduced Form and Structural Estimates”, Journal of Human Resources, 8: 436-455. Bound, John and George E. Johnson (1992) “Changes in the Structure of Wages in the 1980s: An Evaluation of Alternative Explanations”, American Economic Review, 82 (3): 371-92. Bourguignon, François, Francisco Ferreira and Nora Lustig (2005): The microeconomics of income distribution dynamics in East Asia and Latin America. Washington, DC: Oxford University Press and World Bank Publications. Card, David and John E. DiNardo (2002) “Skill-Biased Technological Change and Rising Wage Inequality: Some Problems and Puzzles” Journal of Labor Economics, 20 (4): 733-783. Card, David and Thomas Lemieux (2001) “Can Falling Supply Explain the Rising Return to College for Younger Men? A Cohort-Based Analysis”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 2001; 116 (2): 705-746. Corseuil, Carlos. H, Rita Almeida and Pedro Carneiro (2012) “Inspeção do trabalho e evolução do emprego formal no Brasil”, Texto Para Discussão 1688, IPEA, Rio de Janeiro. Cruz, Gabriela F. da, and Rudi Rocha (2016) “Efeitos do FUNDEF/B sobre Frequência Escolar, Fluxo Escolar e Trabalho Infantil: Uma Análise com Base nos Censos de 2000 e 2010”, Texto para Discussão 029, Instituto de Economia, Universidade Federal do Rio de Janeiro, Rio de Janeiro. 38    DiNardo, John E., Nicole M. Fortin and Thomas Lemieux (1996) “Labor Market Institutions and the Distribution of Wages, 1973-1992: A Semiparametric Approach”, Econometrica. 64 (5): 1001-44. Engbom, Niklas and Christian Moser (2016): “Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil”, Columbia Business School working paper. Ferreira, Francisco H. G. (2012): “Distributions in Motion: Economic Growth, Inequality, and Poverty Dynamics”, Chapter 13 in P. Jefferson (ed.) Oxford Handbook of the Economics of Poverty. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Ferreira, Francisco, Sergio Firpo and Julian Messina (2016): “Understanding Recent Dynamics of Earnings Inequality in Brazil”, Chapter 8 in B.R. Schneider (ed.) New Order and Progress: Development and Democracy in Brazil. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Ferreira, Francisco, Phillippe G. Leite and Julie A. Litchfield (2008) “The rise and fall of Brazilian inequality: 1981–2004”, Macroeconomic Dynamics, 12 (S2): 199-230. Firpo, Sergio, Nicole M. Fortin and Thomas Lemieux (2009), “Unconditional Quantile Regressions”, Econometrica, 77 (3): 953-973. Fortin, Nicole M., Thomas Lemieux and Sergio Firpo (2011), “Decomposition methods in economics.” Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol 4, 1-10. (Amsterdam: Elsevier). Friedberg, Leora (2003) “The Impact of Technological Change on Older Workers: Evidence from Data on Computer Use”. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 56 (3): 511-529. Gardeazabal, Javier, and Arantza Ugidos (2004). “More on identification in detailed wage decompositions.” Review of Economics and Statistics 86 (4): 1034-1036. Gasparini, Leonardo, Sebastián Galiani, Guillermo Cruces and Pablo Acosta (2011), “Educational upgrading and returns to skills in Latin America: Evidence from a supply-demand framework, 1990-2010.” IZA Discussion Paper 6244 and Policy Research Working Paper WPS 5921, the World Bank. Hamermesh, Daniel (2004): “Labor Demand in Latin America and the Caribbean: What does it tell us?”, Chapter 11 in J. Heckman and C. Pagés (eds.): Law and Employment: Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean. Chicago: NBER and University of Chicago Press. Jacobson, Margaret and Filippo Occhino (2012). Labor’s Declining Share of Income and Rising Inequality, Economic Commentary number 13. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Juhn, Chinhui, Kevin Murphy and Brooks Pierce (1993): “Wage Inequality and the Rise in Returns to Skill”, Journal of Political Economy, 101: 410-442. Katz, Lawrence F. and David H. Autor (1999) “Changes in the wage structure and earnings inequality”, in: O.C. Ashenfelter and D. Card (eds), Handbook of Labor Economics Vol. 3A, 1463–555. (Amsterdam: Elsevier). Katz, Lawrence F. and Kevin M. Murphy (1992) “Changes in relative wages, 1963-1987: supply and demand factors”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107: 35-78. Knight, John B. and Richard H. Sabot (1983) “Educational Expansion and the Kuznets Effect”, American Economic Review, 73 (5):1132-1136. 39    Koning, Jaap de and Arie Gelderblom (2004) “ICT and Older Workers: No Unwrinkled Relationship”, International Journal of Manpower, 27 (5): 467-490. Lam, David (1999) “Generating Extreme Inequality: Schooling, Earnings, and Intergenerational Transmission of Human Capital in South Africa and Brazil”, Research Report 99-439. Population Studies Center, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Lemieux, Thomas (2006). “Increasing Residual Wage Inequality: Composition Effects, Noisy Data, or Rising Demand for Skill?,” American Economic Review, vol. 96(3), pages 461-498, June. López-Calva, Luis Felipe and Nora Lustig (2010) Declining Inequality in Latin America: A decade of progress? Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press. Lustig, Nora, Luis F. López-Calva, and Eduardo Ortiz-Juárez. (2013). “Declining Inequality in Latin America in the 2000s: The Cases of Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico.” World Development 44 (C): 129–41. Messina, Julian and Joana Silva (2017). Wage Inequality in Latin America. Understanding the Past to Prepare for the Future. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications. Ñopo, Hugo (2012) New century, old disparities: Gender and ethnic earnings gaps in Latin America and the Caribbean, Washington, DC: World Bank Publications. Oaxaca, Ronald (1973) “Male-Female Wage Differentials in Urban Labor Markets”, International Economic Review 14 (3): 693-709. Oaxaca, Ronald and Michael R. Ransom (1999) “Identification in Detailed Wage Decompositions”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 81 (1): 154-157. Piketty, Thomas (2014): Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press. Ravallion, Martin and Shaohua Chen (2003): “Measuring Pro-Poor Growth”, Economics Letters, 78: 93-99. Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2012): The Price of Inequality: How today’s Divided Society Endangers Our Future. New York, NY: W.W. Norton & Company. World Bank (2016): Taking on Inequality: Poverty and Shared Prosperity Report 2016. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications. Yun, Myeong-Su (2005) “A Simple Solution to the Identification Problem in Detailed Wage Decompositions”, Economic Inquiry, 43: 766–772. 40    APPENDIX Table A.1: Robustness Decomposition Results. Changes in Inequality. Gini. 2012-1995. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Monthly Earnings Monthly Hourly Earnings full Monthly Hourly Without Earnings time workers (20-80 Earnings Earnings Sampling Males hours) Weights Overall Post 40.83** 41.20** 39.99** 41.74** 40.79** [0.075] [0.065] [0.094] [0.075] [0.078] Pre 49.79** 49.87** 48.66** 50.12** 49.83** [0.071] [0.071] [0.086] [0.069] [0.072] Difference -8.96** -8.67** -8.67** -8.38** -9.04** [0.103] [0.096] [0.128] [0.102] [0.106] Endowments 4.15** 4.57** 3.60** 3.03** 3.57** [0.060] [0.059] [0.075] [0.057] [0.061] Structure -13.10** -13.23** -12.27** -11.41** -12.61** [0.103] [0.098] [0.126] [0.106] [0.107] Endowments Education 3.98** 4.03** 3.49** 3.25** 3.83** [0.056] [0.053] [0.069] [0.056] [0.060] Potential Experience -0.40** -0.37** -0.43** -0.36** -0.43** [0.013] [0.013] [0.017] [0.012] [0.014] Minimum Wage 1.15** 1.37** 1.04** 0.71** 0.71** [0.030] [0.029] [0.034] [0.019] [0.022] Formality Status -0.26** -0.20** -0.23** -0.20** -0.16** [0.011] [0.009] [0.013] [0.011] [0.011] Race and Gender -0.29** -0.27** -0.10** -0.25** -0.28** [0.012] [0.011] [0.011] [0.012] [0.012] Region and Urban -0.04** 0.01 -0.16** -0.12** -0.10** [0.008] [0.010] [0.012] [0.010] [0.009] Structure Education 0.75** 0.50* 1.32** 0.43 1.14** [0.247] [0.233] [0.277] [0.272] [0.262] Potential Experience -3.16** -3.28** -3.42** -4.00** -3.50** [0.566] [0.527] [0.819] [0.586] [0.585] Minimum Wage 0.09** 0.04 0.04 -0.29** -0.29** [0.025] [0.022] [0.025] [0.031] [0.025] Formality Status -1.43** -1.34** -1.18** -0.75** -1.06** [0.105] [0.094] [0.130] [0.107] [0.102] Race and Gender -1.58** -1.50** -0.76** -0.88** -1.09** [0.173] [0.165] [0.111] [0.168] [0.170] Region and Urban -1.59** -1.66** -1.81** -0.39 -0.61* [0.289] [0.299] [0.358] [0.288] [0.298] Constant -6.18** -5.99** -6.44** -5.53** -7.22** [0.719] [0.671] [0.986] [0.753] [0.748] Total Education 4.73** 4.53** 4.81** 3.68** 4.98** [0.252] [0.233] [0.284] [0.278] [0.268] Potential Experience -3.55** -3.65** -3.86** -4.35** -3.93** [0.566] [0.529] [0.820] [0.586] [0.585] Minimum Wage 1.24** 1.41** 1.08** 0.42** 0.42** [0.040] [0.038] [0.044] [0.037] [0.034] Formality Status -1.69** -1.53** -1.42** -0.95** -1.22** [0.104] [0.094] [0.129] [0.105] [0.100] Race and Gender -1.88** -1.77** -0.86** -1.13** -1.36** [0.175] [0.165] [0.114] [0.171] [0.173] Region and Urban -1.62** -1.66** -1.98** -0.51+ -0.71* [0.288] [0.299] [0.357] [0.287] [0.297] N 485,407 485,407 287,390 482,368 457,735 Note: Robust Standard Errors in Brackets. **, * and + denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. Standard errors are calculated with the delta method. The Gini coefficient is expressed in percentage points and goes from 0 (perfect equality) to 100 (perfect inequality). Part-time workers in column 5 are those working less than 20 hours in the reference week. See notes in table 3 for details on the individual effects included in each category. 41    Table A.2: Robustness Decomposition Results. Changes in Inequality. Gini. 2003-1995. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Hourly Monthly Earnings Monthly Monthly Hourly Earnings full Without Sampling Earnings Earnings Males Earnings time workers Weights (20-80 hours) Overall Post 46.77** 47.05** 45.96** 48.23** 47.74** [0.072] [0.068] [0.090] [0.075] [0.078] Pre 49.79** 49.87** 48.66** 50.12** 49.83** [0.078] [0.071] [0.094] [0.076] [0.079] Difference -3.01** -2.82** -2.69** -1.89** -2.09** [0.106] [0.098] [0.130] [0.107] [0.111] Endowments 2.94** 3.28** 2.65** 2.10** 2.35** [0.049] [0.049] [0.063] [0.047] [0.051] Structure -5.95** -6.10** -5.34** -3.99** -4.45** [0.099] [0.089] [0.120] [0.101] [0.103] Endowments Education 1.49** 1.41** 1.26** 1.30** 1.50** [0.041] [0.042] [0.053] [0.044] [0.048] Potential Experience -0.32** -0.31** -0.35** -0.30** -0.33** [0.012] [0.012] [0.015] [0.011] [0.013] Minimum Wage 1.89** 2.20** 1.80** 1.26** 1.33** [0.032] [0.032] [0.037] [0.022] [0.025] Formality Status 0.02** 0.05** 0.05** 0.05** 0.04** [0.006] [0.005] [0.007] [0.005] [0.005] Race and Gender -0.12** -0.12** -0.03** -0.12** -0.12** [0.008] [0.008] [0.005] [0.008] [0.008] Region and Urban -0.03** 0.05** -0.07** -0.09** -0.06** [0.005] [0.008] [0.008] [0.007] [0.006] Structure Education 2.46** 2.73** 3.05** 2.38** 2.71** [0.235] [0.217] [0.260] [0.253] [0.253] Potential Experience 0.46 1.09+ 1.65+ -0.36 -0.14 [0.642] [0.568] [0.921] [0.673] [0.673] Minimum Wage 0.40** 0.41** 0.30** 0.27** 0.26** [0.024] [0.022] [0.024] [0.030] [0.024] Formality Status -0.96** -0.90** -0.76** -0.40** -0.66** [0.116] [0.103] [0.143] [0.118] [0.114] Race and Gender -1.40** -1.64** -0.58** -1.17** -1.28** [0.163] [0.158] [0.102] [0.162] [0.163] Region and Urban -0.84** -1.55** -1.62** -0.75* -0.81** [0.292] [0.305] [0.358] [0.303] [0.310] Constant -6.08** -6.24** -7.38** -3.95** -4.53** [0.790] [0.704] [1.089] [0.834] [0.835] Total Education 3.95** 4.14** 4.31** 3.67** 4.21** [0.238] [0.221] [0.264] [0.257] [0.257] Potential Experience 0.14 0.79 1.29 -0.66 -0.47 [0.642] [0.568] [0.922] [0.673] [0.673] Minimum Wage 2.30** 2.60** 2.10** 1.53** 1.59** [0.041] [0.039] [0.044] [0.038] [0.035] Formality Status -0.94** -0.85** -0.71** -0.35** -0.61** [0.116] [0.103] [0.143] [0.118] [0.114] Race and Gender -1.52** -1.76** -0.61** -1.29** -1.40** [0.164] [0.159] [0.103] [0.163] [0.163] Region and Urban -0.87** -1.50** -1.69** -0.84** -0.87** [0.292] [0.305] [0.358] [0.303] [0.310] N 479,635 479,635 289,598 478,798 451,938 Note: Robust Standard Errors in Brackets. **, * and + denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. Standard errors are calculated with the delta method. The Gini coefficient is expressed in percentage points and goes from 0 (perfect equality) to 100 (perfect inequality). Part-time workers in column 5 are those working less than 20 hours in the reference week. See notes in table 3 for details on the individual effects included in each category. 42    Table A.3: Robustness Decomposition Results. Changes in Inequality. 2012-2003. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Monthly Earnings Monthly Hourly Earnings Monthly Hourly Without Sampling Earnings full time workers Earnings Earnings Weights Males (20-80 hours) Overall Post 40.83** 41.20** 39.99** 41.74** 40.79** [0.076] [0.065] [0.096] [0.076] [0.079] Pre 46.77** 47.05** 45.96** 48.23** 47.74** [0.067] [0.068] [0.084] [0.070] [0.073] Difference -5.95** -5.85** -5.97** -6.49** -6.95** [0.102] [0.094] [0.127] [0.103] [0.107] Endowments 1.79** 1.99** 1.57** 1.61** 1.94** [0.051] [0.051] [0.066] [0.047] [0.052] Structure -7.74** -7.83** -7.54** -8.11** -8.88** [0.094] [0.088] [0.116] [0.100] [0.101] Endowments Education 3.02** 3.25** 2.80** 2.55** 2.94** [0.045] [0.045] [0.057] [0.045] [0.050] Potential Experience -0.13** -0.13** -0.16** -0.12** -0.14** [0.012] [0.012] [0.014] [0.010] [0.012] Minimum Wage -0.71** -0.77** -0.73** -0.43** -0.51** [0.032] [0.032] [0.038] [0.020] [0.024] Formality Status -0.19** -0.14** -0.19** -0.18** -0.12** [0.010] [0.009] [0.013] [0.011] [0.010] Race and Gender -0.21** -0.19** -0.10** -0.18** -0.22** [0.010] [0.009] [0.008] [0.009] [0.010] Region and Urban 0.01 -0.02** -0.06** -0.03** -0.02** [0.005] [0.005] [0.008] [0.006] [0.006] Structure Education -2.25** -2.85** -2.30** -2.54** -2.17** [0.253] [0.234] [0.285] [0.287] [0.276] Potential Experience -3.56** -4.30** -4.99** -3.58** -3.31** [0.479] [0.441] [0.682] [0.522] [0.518] Minimum Wage -0.35** -0.43** -0.29** -0.68** -0.66** [0.032] [0.029] [0.032] [0.038] [0.031] Formality Status -0.57** -0.54** -0.52** -0.43** -0.49** [0.103] [0.093] [0.129] [0.109] [0.103] Race and Gender -0.15 0.19 -0.15 0.34+ 0.25 [0.176] [0.167] [0.114] [0.175] [0.177] Region and Urban -0.76** -0.14 -0.22 0.36 0.18 [0.280] [0.291] [0.351] [0.287] [0.296] Constant -0.11 0.24 0.94 -1.58* -2.69** [0.644] [0.591] [0.869] [0.706] [0.698] Total Education 0.77** 0.39+ 0.50+ 0.01 0.77** [0.257] [0.235] [0.291] [0.290] [0.280] Potential Experience -3.70** -4.44** -5.15** -3.69** -3.45** [0.479] [0.441] [0.683] [0.522] [0.518] Minimum Wage -1.06** -1.20** -1.02** -1.11** -1.17** [0.045] [0.043] [0.049] [0.042] [0.039] Formality Status -0.75** -0.68** -0.71** -0.60** -0.61** [0.102] [0.094] [0.127] [0.108] [0.102] Race and Gender -0.35* 0 -0.25* 0.16 0.04 [0.177] [0.167] [0.116] [0.177] [0.179] Region and Urban -0.76** -0.16 -0.28 0.33 0.16 [0.279] [0.291] [0.351] [0.286] [0.296] N 535,024 535,024 312,910 532,750 503,761 Note: Robust Standard Errors in Brackets. **, * and + denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. Standard errors are calculated with the delta method. The Gini coefficient is expressed in percentage points and goes from 0 (perfect equality) to 100 (perfect inequality). Part-time workers in column 5 are those working less than 20 hours in the reference week. See notes in table 3 for details on the individual effects included in each category. 43