91159 DIREC TIONS IN DE VELOPMENT Energy and Mining Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector Lessons from Two Decades of Experience Mohua Mukherjee Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector DIREC TIONS IN DE VELOPMENT Energy and Mining Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector Lessons from Two Decades of Experience Mohua Mukherjee © 2014 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000; Internet: www.worldbank.org Some rights reserved 1 2 3 4 17 16 15 14 This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. The findings, interpreta- tions, and conclusions expressed in this work do not necessarily reflect the views of The World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Nothing herein shall constitute or be considered to be a limitation upon or waiver of the privileges and immunities of The World Bank, all of which are specifically reserved. Rights and Permissions This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 IGO license (CC BY 3.0 IGO) http:// creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/igo. Under the Creative Commons Attribution license, you are free to copy, distribute, transmit, and adapt this work, including for commercial purposes, under the following conditions: Attribution—Please cite the work as follows: Mukherjee, Mohua. 2014. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector: Lessons from Two Decades of Experience. Directions in Development. Washington, DC: World Bank. doi:10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0. License: Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0 IGO. Translations—If you create a translation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the attribution: This translation was not created by The World Bank and should not be considered an official World Bank translation. The World Bank shall not be liable for any content or error in this translation. Third-party content—The World Bank does not necessarily own each component of the content contained within the work. The World Bank therefore does not warrant that the use of any third-party-owned individual component or part contained in the work will not infringe on the rights of those third ­ parties. The risk of claims resulting from such infringement rests solely with you. If you wish to re-use a component of the work, it is your responsibility to determine whether permission is needed ­ for that re-use and to obtain permission from the copyright owner. Examples of components can include, but are not limited to, tables, figures, or images. All queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to the Publishing and Knowledge Division, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2625; e-mail: pubrights@ worldbank.org. ISBN (paper): 978-1-4648-0339-0 ISBN (electronic): 978-1-4648-0340-6 DOI: 10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Cover photo: NOAA. This photograph is in the public domain and available for public use. Please credit NOAA. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication data has been requested. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Contents Foreword xi Acknowledgments xiii About the Author xv Abbreviations xvii Overview 1 Lessons Learned from Two Decades of Efforts to Attract Private Investment in the Power Sector 8 General Observations and a View Ahead 15 Notes 16 References 17 Chapter 1 Introduction to Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector 19 The Prereform Period: From Independence to 1991 19 Phase 1 (1991–95): The Opening of the Sector to Private Investment in Generation—Independent Power Producer Policy 21 Phase 2 (1996–2003): Restructuring of SEBs, Introduction of Sector Regulators, and Initial Attempts at Privatization in Orissa and Delhi 24 Phase 3 (2003–12): Enactment of the Electricity Act and Subsequent Policy Initiatives to Introduce Competition and Create a Market in Generation, Transmission, and Distribution 25 Phase 4: Investor Uncertainty at the Start of the 12th Five-Year Plan 28 Private Participation in Generation, Transmission, and Distribution 29 Notes 29 Reference 30 Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   v   vi Contents Chapter 2 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation 31 Key Messages 31 Importance of Power Generation 32 Placing the Indian Power Sector in an International Context 32 Growth of Private Sector Participation in Power Generation in India 33 Independent Power Projects Policy of the Early 1990s 35 Key Issues in Implementation of the IPP Policy 36 Intermediate Policy Initiatives for Private Sector Participation in Generation 37 Post–Electricity Act of 2003: Tariff-Based Competitive Bidding 38 Response of the Private Sector to Case 1 and Case 2 Procurement through Competitive Bidding 41 Comparison of Case 1 and Case 2 Bids with Noncompetitively Awarded (by Memorandum of Understanding) Projects 44 Prospects for Future Private Participation in Power Generation: What Is Holding Back Private Investors? 46 The Coal Crunch and Choices Facing Policy Makers 47 Logistical Difficulties with Physical Pooling of Imported and Domestic Coal 47 Notes 50 References 50 Chapter 3 Private Sector Participation in Transmission 51 Key Messages 51 Chronology of Private Sector Participation in Transmission 52 Legal Framework for Transmission Business 52 Private Participation Experiences 53 Current Models for Private Participation 55 Chapter 4 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 59 Key Messages 59 Distribution Performance and Chronology of Private Sector Participation in Distribution 60 Comparative Highlights of the Privatization Experience of Orissa and Delhi 64 DF Models 67 Review of Rural Franchisee Experiences 75 Review of Urban Franchisee Experiences 77 Lessons Learned for Improvement of the DF Approach: What Are the Key Variables That Must Be Properly Understood and Addressed in the Bid Process? 79 Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Contents vii Notes 94 References 94 Chapter 5 Private Sector Participation in the Indian Solar Energy Sector 97 Key Messages 97 Progress to Date 99 Potential Bottlenecks to Meeting Commissioning Schedule Deadlines 104 Note 105 References 106 Chapter 6 Financing of the Power Sector 107 Key Messages 107 Distribution Sector Losses and Their Effects 107 Macroeconomic Outlook 109 Central Government Approach 109 Recommended Holistic Approach 111 Reference 113 Chapter 7 Emerging Issues and Proposed Approaches for the Indian Power Sector 115 Emerging Issue: The Need for Better Partnership Mechanisms with the Private Sector 115 Final Thought 118 Note 118 Chapter 8 Update 119 Review of Progress on Selection of DFs 119 Issuance of SBDs for the Appointment of DFs 122 Finalization of Key Terms of the Public-Private Partnership Model for Distribution 123 Impending Segregation of Wheeling and Supply License(s) 124 Review of Progress on Generation PPP 125 Review of Progress on Transmission PPP 127 Notes 128 Reference 128 Appendix A Organization of the Power Sector in India 129 Appendix B Dabhol–Enron: The First Lesson Learned under the New Independent Power Producer Policy 131 Appendix C Summary Case Studies of Distribution Privatization 133 Highlights of the Orissa Reform Experience 133 Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 viii Contents Highlights of the Delhi Distribution Privatization Experience 134 Appendix D Post-2012 Generation and Uncertainties Related to Domestic and Imported Fuel Supply 137 Domestic Coal-Related Uncertainties 137 Imported Coal Uncertainties 139 Improvement in CERC Indexation 140 Note 141 Appendix E Emerging Challenges for Private Investment in Transmission 143 Issues and Challenges for Private Transmission Line Developers 143 Experience in Private Projects Being Implemented versus the Transmission Framework 143 The Way Forward 145 Appendix F Comparison of Privatization to the Distribution Franchisee Approach 147 Privatization versus Distribution Franchisee 147 Appendix G Recommendations for the Way Forward on Distribution Franchisee Selection 151 Appendix H Standardization of the Distribution Franchise Process 157 Post-award Contract Management 160 Note 160 Boxes 1.1 The Green Revolution: Genesis of Free Power to the Agricultural Sector 20 2.1 What If the Coal Availability Projections Are Too Optimistic and There Is Still a Coal Shortage in 2018? 48 4.1 Shunglu Committee versus B. K. Chaturvedi Report 74 H.1 Bhiwandi Distribution Franchisee: A Success Story 157 Figures O.1 Bank Exposure to Power Sector 5 O.2 Growth Rate of Bank Credit to Select Sectors 5 O.3 Summary of Electricity Value Chain under Pressure 14 2.1 Growth of Private Sector in Power Generation Segment 33 2.2 Evolution of Ownership of Power Generation Assets, 2007–12 34 Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Contents ix 2.3 Competitive Procurement 39 2.4 Case 1 Bids 45 2.5 Case 2 Bids 45 3.1 Models for Private Sector Participation in Transmission 52 3.2 Private Sector Participation in Transmission 54 4.1 Average Cost of Supply and Average Revenue Realization per Unit Sold 61 4.2 Outcomes of the Privatization Experience 64 4.3 The Roles and Responsibilities of the Franchisee and the Business Model 71 4.4 Franchisee Area Attractiveness Analysis 81 4.5 Tenure of DFs 82 5.1 Bundling of Power Scheme: An Innovative Mechanism to Reduce the Price Burden of Solar 100 6.1 Summary of Electricity Value Chain under Pressure 108 6.2 Exposure to Power Sector 109 6.3 Growth Rate of Bank Credit to Selected Sectors 110 7.1 Combining Distribution Franchisee Bid with Case 1 116 A.1 Institutional Structure of the Electric Power Infrastructure 130 A.2 Key Players in the Electric Power Infrastructure Sector 130 Tables O.1 Installed Capacity of Indian Power Generation Assets 3 O.2 Causes for Increasing Vulnerability of Corporate Entities 6 O.3 First Integrated Rating for State Power Distribution Utilities, March 2013 6 O.4 Allocations of State Capacity under the National Solar Mission 8 2.1 Installed Electricity Generation Capacity of the Most Populous Countries 33 2.2 Installed Capacity of Indian Power Generation Assets 34 2.3 Eight Most Promising Fast-Track Projects 36 2.4 Competitive Procurement Characteristics by Case 39 2.5 Possible Tariff Structures for Case 1 and Case 2 Projects 40 2.6 Summary of Case 1 Bids 41 2.7 Summary of Case 2 Bids, Other than UMPPs 42 2.8 Status of Identified UMPP Projects 43 3.1 Summary of Joint Ventures Entered Into by PGCIL 55 3.2 Projects Developed under the Joint Venture Route by Maharashtra State Transmission Company 55 3.3 Summary of Bid Process Outcomes for Interstate IPTC Projects 56 3.4 Comparison of MOP and PC Models 58 4.1 Outcomes and the Process Followed by Delhi and Orissa 66 4.2 Selected Provisions of the Electricity Act of 2003 68 Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 x Contents 4.3 Key Characteristics of the Different Rural Franchisee Models 69 4.4 Nature of Franchisees and Number of Franchisees Appointed and Villages Covered across 18 States as of March 31, 2012 76 4.5 DFs for Identified Circles or Areas 77 4.6 Summary of Targets of the Recent Bids 83 4.7 Incentive on the Collection of Arrears on Service Provided during the Prefranchise Period 85 4.8 Quality and Extent of Baseline Data 87 4.9 Experience Criteria Included in Past DF Bidding Documents 89 4.10 Summary of Parameters for Financial Qualification Criteria 90 4.11 Time Taken for Concluding the Bid Process 91 4.12 Key Reasons for Abandoned Bid Processes or Failure of Completed Bid Processes 92 5.1 National Solar Mission Targets, 2010–22 98 5.2 State Participation in Phase 1 Installations 100 5.3 Solar Project Land Development Options 104 6.1 Causes for Increasing Vulnerability of Corporate Entities 110 6.2 First Integrated Rating for State Power Distribution Utilities, March 2013 111 8.1 Bid Processes, Jharkhand and Bihar States, 2012–13 120 8.2 Elements Needing Improvement in Standard Bidding Documents 122 8.3 Key Features of the Recommended PPP Model 123 8.4 Interstate and Intrastate Transmission Projects Awarded through the Bidding Process, 2013 127 B.1 Dabhol Power Project: Timeline of Key Events 131 D.1 Selected Private Sector Generation Projects Facing Fuel-Related Issues 138 E.1 Risks for Private Transmission Line Developers 144 E.2 Evaluations and Recommended Approaches 145 F.1 Privatization versus Distribution Franchisee 148 G.1 Recommended Approaches on Distribution Franchisee Selection 151 BH.1.1 Bhiwandi Distribution Franchisee Parameters 158 Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Foreword The Indian experience of more than two decades of experimentation and adaptation in attracting private capital to invest in the power sector has much to offer the rest of the world, particularly countries that are still attempting to expand electricity coverage. The passage of the Electricity Act of 2003 represented a landmark for the Indian power sector, and implementation of the act over the past decade also has offered a rich set of lessons in the generation, transmission, and distribution sectors. Indian power sector authorities and policy makers appreciated early on that the response to a critical shortage of electricity and a supply–demand imbalance should not be limited to an increase in generation only. Accordingly, a steady focus has been centered on increasing the footprint and carrying capacity of the transmission grid, raising voltages, and connecting regional grids to allow power to flow from surplus to deficit regions. Interesting approaches have been tried in the distribution sector. To attract private sector management in that sector, authorities and policy makers have offered incentives to upgrade the distribution network and focus on customer service. An elaborate regulatory apparatus has been set up at the central and state government levels. Much has been achieved, and the Indian power sector can rightfully take its place among the bold reformers. Yet a large agenda remains, and a more rigorous focus on implementation will be required. Close coordination among various stakeholders and unrelenting attention to efficient execution through decentral- ized authority to make technical decisions, together with a robust emphasis on monitoring, evaluation, and transparent sharing of data and performance statis- tics, will help in achieving this objective. Electricity will remain a crucial underpinning to India’s growth aspirations, and once these are attained, the sector will need to function reliably and continu- ously to maintain the country’s economic prosperity. This agenda will therefore remain in the forefront for many decades to come. We trust that some of the early lessons of experience, which are captured in this book, will be helpful in moving the debate forward. Julia Bucknall Practice Manager Global Energy Practice World Bank Group Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   xi   Acknowledgments This book is a background study for the India Power Sector Review undertaken by the World Bank at the request of the government of India in 2012. The research and data in this book are mostly for the two decades ending in 2012. However, in view of the important developments in the Indian power sector that occurred in 2013, I have added at the end of the book a chapter that summarizes and updates some of the headline developments up to April 2014. The Indian Power Sector Review was led by Sheoli Pargal and Sudeshna Ghosh Banerjee. I am indebted to both of them for the valuable discussions, insights, and vigorous debates, all of which provided the necessary impetus to continue the task. The work was carried out under the overall supervision of Jyoti Shukla and Julia Bucknall, with further guidance from John Henry Stein and Subramaniam Vijay Iyer. Valuable comments were received from Ashish Khanna, Kavita Saraswat, Rohit Mittal, Kwawu Gaba, Chandrasekeren Subramaniam, Mani Khurana, Kristy Mayer, Varsha Marathe, Dhruba Purkayastha, Mark Moseley, Bernard Tenenbaum, and Ruchi Soni, all of whom are, or have been, close colleagues at the World Bank. I would like to thank Pankaj Gupta and Sameer ­ Shukla for their feedback and guidance on the need to sharpen messages. Onno Ruhl and Martin Rama provided vital encouragement, advice, and perspective at crucial stages of the writing process. I would also like to thank the Technical Advisory Panel of Experts convened to advise on the overall body of work—the Indian Power Sector Review. The members of the panel were Jyoti Arora, J. L. Bajaj, Shantanu Dixit, Rajat Misra, Sunil Mitra, M. Govinda Rao, and Anil Sardana. Their first-hand experience and insights on the role of the private sector over time have been invaluable in gain- ing perspectives on a multiplicity of issues. Sushanta Chatterjee of the Central Electricity Regulatory Commission provided important insights and understand- ing of transmission sector reforms. R. V. Shahi has been generous with his advice throughout the process. Much of the data collection and primary analysis were carried out in 2012 by Deloitte LLP, under the leadership of Shubhranshu Patnaik and Anujesh Dwivedi. I am grateful to them for affording many subsequent discussions and for deepening my understanding. I would also like to acknowledge many debates with and insights acquired from Anish De of AF-Mercados EMI, together with Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   xiii   xiv Acknowledgments his team, whose background work for the larger study particularly aided my understanding of challenges faced by the distribution sector. The solar section was largely informed by discussions and documents provided by Arunabha Ghosh from the Council on Energy, Environment and Water. Shaukat Javed deserves recognition for excellent administrative support. Bartley Higgins, Amrita Kundu, and Pranav Vaidya provided timely research assistance. Mary-Ann Moalli’s editorial assistance is highly appreciated. Many others have helped to shape the book, and their timely contributions are gratefully acknowledged, though it is not possible to do so by name. All remaining errors and inaccuracies are the sole responsibility of the author. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 About the Author Mohua Mukherjee is a Senior Energy Specialist in the World Bank’s Global Energy Practice, working on issues related to distribution utility reform, energy policy, and renewable energy. Most of her career has been at the World Bank, where she has been privileged to work on a variety of development projects in more than 30 countries. Those projects involve the water and sanitation sector, health and education sector, private sector development and microfinance, trade policy and export-led development, financial workouts for countries during the commercial banking crisis in Latin America, agribusiness in Africa, and, for the ­ rivate sector for past several years, the energy sector. She has also worked in the p five years as an investment banker in Nairobi, Kenya, where she headed the cor- porate finance unit at two international banks and led the introduction and rollout of financial products that were new to the East African market. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   xv   Abbreviations ACQ annual contracted quantity AECL Ahmedabad Electricity Company Ltd. APDRP Accelerated Power Development and Reforms Programme AT&C aggregate technical and commercial (loss) BOOM build-own-operate-manage BSEB Bihar State Electricity Board BSES Brihanmumbai State Electricity Supply Bt billion tons CAGR compound annual growth rate capex capital expenditure CCEA Cabinet Committee on Economic Affairs CEA Central Electricity Authority CERC Central Electricity Regulatory Commission CESC Calcutta Electric Supply Corporation CIL Coal India Ltd. COD commercial operation date CoS cost of supply CPSU central public sector undertaking CTU central transmission utility CZ Central Zone DBFOT design-build-finance-operate-transfer DF distribution franchisee DFA distribution franchisee agreement discom distribution company DT distribution transformer DVVNL Dakshinanchal Vidyut Vitran Nigam Ltd. EOI expression of interest EPC engineering, procurement, and construction EZ Eastern Zone Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   xvii   xviii Abbreviations FSA fuel supply agreement FY fiscal year GenCo generation company GTD generation, transmission, and distribution GW gigawatts H1 highest bidder HVPNL Haryana Vidyut Prasaran Nigam Ltd. IPP independent power producer IPTC independent power transmission company JUSCO Jamshedpur Utilities and Services Company JV joint venture KESCO Kanpur Electricity Supply Company Ltd. kV kilovolt kWh kilowatt-hour L lowest bidder LOI letter of intent MNRE Ministry of New and Renewable Energy MOP Ministry of Power MOU memorandum of understanding MSEB Maharashtra State Electricity Board MSEDCL Maharashtra State Electricity Distribution Company Ltd. Mt metric ton MU million units MW megawatt NPA nonperforming asset NPC Noida Power Company NSM National Solar Mission NTPC National Thermal Power Corporation NVVN NTPC Vidyut Vyaparan Nigam Ltd. O&M operation and maintenance OERC Orissa Electricity Regulatory Commission PC Planning Commission PFC Power Finance Corporation PGCIL PowerGrid Company of India Ltd. POC point of connection POWERGRID Power Grid Corporation of India Ltd. PPA power purchase agreement PPP public-private partnership PPPAC Public Private Partnership Approval Committee Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Abbreviations xix PSP private sector participation R-APDRP Restructured APDRP REC Rural Electrification Corporation Ltd./renewable energy certificate R-LNG regasified liquefied natural gas RFP request for proposal RFQ request for qualification RGGVY Rajiv Gandhi Grameen Vidyutikaran Yojana RPO renewable purchase obligation SBD standard bidding document SEB state electricity board SECL Surat Electricity Company Ltd. SERC state electricity regulatory commission SHR station heat rate SPPS single-point power supply SPV special purpose vehicle T&C technical and commercial TEC techno-economic clearance TPC Tata Power Company TransCo transmission company TSA transmission service agreement UMPP ultra mega power plant UPPCL Uttar Pradesh Power Corporation Ltd. VGF viability gap funding WBSEB West Bengal State Electricity Board WZ Western Zone Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Overview The 2005 National Electricity Policy of the government of India recognizes elec- tricity as one of the key drivers for rapid economic growth and poverty allevia- tion in the country. Its aim was to achieve the target of electricity for all and the per capita availability of power of 1,000 kilowatt-hours (kWh) by 2012. However, this target was not met for a variety of reasons. Numerous challenges need to be addressed before India can achieve the desired national policy objec- tives. One of the most important concerns is that despite the 20-year reform process and private sector participation, the rate of resource augmentation and growth in energy supply has been less than the rate of increase in demand. Therefore, India continues to face severe energy shortages. The average per capita consumption of electricity of 704 kWh in India is a fraction of the global average of 3,240 kWh. Irrespective of the expected growth in demand for electricity in the coming years, significant capacity additions need to be made merely to bridge the current demand-supply gap. The peak demand is expected to be 218,209 megawatts (MW) in fiscal year (FY) 2016/17, compared to 97,269 MW of demand in FY2005/06. The passage of the Electricity Act of 2003 was a signature achievement of the Indian power sector and demonstrated the intent to move away completely from the previous route of negotiated memoranda of understanding with investors to a market-driven situation. The latter would force potential investors to compete aggressively for generation (and later also transmission) contracts. The only two cases of distribution privatization (in the states of Orissa and Delhi) in India preceded the Electricity Act of 2003. The act provided for the appointment of any person (franchisee) to undertake distribution and supply on behalf of the licensee (state distribution utility) within the licensee’s area of supply. This approach would, it was hoped, confer the benefits of private ownership through a concession arrangement, but not transfer actual ownership, which was contro- versial and resisted by most state political authorities. The introduction of reforms and competition under the Electricity Act of 2003 produced a signifi- cant private sector response in generation, a limited but respectable response in Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   1   2 Overview transmission (because not many transmission lines were tendered in the first place), and a very limited response in distribution. Private participation in generation therefore offers about a decade of experi- ence before the Electricity Act of 2003 (1991–2002) and another decade since it was enacted (2003 to the present). A major criticism of the early independent power producer (IPP) policy (in the 1990s), and an illustration of how the risk was disproportionately borne by the public sector and consumers, was that few of the early IPPs were designed to meet peak demand even though that was the most pressing need at the time. Instead, contractual obligations of capacity charges and take-or-pay clauses forced the displacement of cheaper base-load power from state or central generation facilities in the early transactions. State electricity boards were relatively inexperienced because they had previously dealt with only public sector entities and thus were initially not adequately equipped to negotiate highly commercial contracts with private legal teams. After the enactment of the Electricity Act of 2003, the negotiated approach for generation investments, through memoranda of understanding entitling the investor to a guaranteed 16 percent rate of return, began to be phased out. The act required all procurement of generation capacity to be undertaken exclusively through the competitively determined tariff method starting in January 2010. Both private generation investors and central and state sector generation inves- tors had to go through competitive bidding to be awarded contracts after the January 2010 cutoff date. The generation segment of the power sector value chain has witnessed the maximum interest from private players, which are primarily Indian companies. A few multinational players such as China Light and Power (CLP) and AES are in the Indian market, but their generation capacity is limited. Since the Electricity Act of 2003 and subsequent clarification of the regulatory framework, borrowing has been relatively easy for private firms, and their interest in the power sector has grown. Not only did private companies in the power and infrastructure sec- tors participate, but also companies in other sectors (noninfrastructure, but cash rich) displayed great interest in competing for contracts in the generation busi- ness. The bulk of companies in the transmission and distribution segments, how- ever, are owned and operated by central and state government–owned entities, respectively. Table O.1 shows the evolution of private sector generation capacity in MW and in percentage terms from 2006 to 2012. The capacity installed and owned by the central sector remained relatively stable over the period, showing only a slight decline. The capacity installed and owned by the state sector declined more sharply, from 53 percent to 43 percent, while private sector capacity grew almost threefold in terms of MW and slightly more than doubled in terms of percent- ages. Note that table O.1 shows a final total installed capacity of 199,877 MW as of the end of FY2011/12, whereas the total installed capacity stands at 211,000 MW as of the end of March 2012. Despite the impressive addition of generation capacity during FY2006/07 through the present, the poor financial health of the power sector is most acutely Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Overview 3 Table O.1  Installed Capacity of Indian Power Generation Assets Megawatts Share (%) Total Total Central State Private installed Central State Private installed Fiscal year sector sector sector capacity sector sector sector capacity 2006/07 45,121 70,096 17,113 132,329 34 53 13 100 2007/08 48,361 74,689 20,011 143,061 34 52 14 100 2008/09 48,971 76,116 22,879 147,965 33 51 15 100 2009/10 50,993 79,392 29,014 159,398 32 50 18 100 2010/11 54,413 82,453 36,761 173,626 31 47 21 100 2011/12 59,683 85,919 54,276 199,627 30 43 27 100 Source: World Bank 2012. exposed in the distribution segment, where revenues enter the system at the customer interface. The revenues collected from customers should be adequate to cover all costs incurred along the value chain before final delivery to the end user, that is, the costs of bulk power purchase, transmission, distribution, and retailing (metering, billing, and collection). In practice, large amounts of power that have been purchased and paid for by the distribution company (discom) are stolen, and therefore revenues cannot be recovered for those units of power although costs have already been incurred. In addition, the power grid is in dis- repair as a result of years of neglected maintenance and causes a portion of the purchased power to be undeliverable to the customer because of technical losses arising from the poor physical condition of the network. Finally, a practice of providing free, unmetered power to agricultural users exsits in many states, although this amount of power consumption is unlikely to account for the major share of unaccounted-for power. The discom purchases the power and seeks to recover revenues from sales to its final customers. In some cases, the unit rate at which it bills its customers is lower than the unit rate at which it purchases power, particularly from private power suppliers. This disparity creates a built-in loss even if the discom could account for every unit. Furthermore, a large portion of the power is stolen or otherwise lost and can never be billed. This is the major reason that discoms are dependent on state subsidies to remain afloat and that despite large injections of subsidies, they are still sometimes unable to repay their commercial bank loans. Most states have not succeeded in enforcing strict mechanisms to reduce dis- tribution losses and curb theft of electricity. In addition, there is a pervasive lack of commercial culture or any sense of commercial pressure; no one is personally accountable for spiralling losses and poor operational efficiency in the bureau- cratic setup that defines the operating environment of the state-run power sector. Over one-third (35 percent) of the volume of power purchased by a distribution utility is typically lost and never billed to the final customer, or at least the utility can never account for such revenue. These losses are the aggregate technical and commercial (AT&C) losses, which in India are among the highest in the world. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 4 Overview Clearly the distribution segment is in the most urgent need of the commercial focus and management practices that come through private participation. Yet, possibly primarily related to political interference from the state level (that is, possible condoning of some of the rampant power theft by large industrial ­ customers who are well connected to state authorities), the distribution segment continues to remain in the stranglehold of state-owned utilities with compliant management that is not averse to obeying orders from politicians. Tepid attempts at introducing a commercial focus via limited private participation through fran- chising of electrically ring-fenced areas have yielded modest results, though they have made important differences in some urban areas where they have been successfully introduced. Nonetheless, franchising has not yet been attempted on a scale that can have a transformative effect. However, this book presents the lessons to be learned from the successes and failures of the handful of franchising attempts over the past few years, with a view to improving future success rates of such private involvement in distribution. Distribution segment finances have continued to worsen considerably to a level that has been characterized at times as “India’s subprime crisis.” Especially from 2008 to 2013, the problem has attained mammoth proportions with the annual financial gap now at US$20 billion before subsidies. Even after one con- siders subsidies paid out to utilities from the State Exchequer (often not paid on time), the deficits are US$7 billion annually, which means the financial deficits of the distribution segment before subsidies are equal to more than half the aggregated annual budgets of the states of Uttar Pradesh, Maharashtra, Rajasthan, Madhya Pradesh, and Bihar, five of India’s most populous states. The poor shape of finances has several adverse effects, resulting in poor quality of supply on the one hand and inadequate capacity utilization on the other hand in generating stations, because distribution companies lack the purchasing power to buy enough power from generating stations. This further affects sector finances and requires ever-increasing subsidies. The distribution segment’s losses threaten to derail the power sector and also jeopardize the health of the financial sector, given the high level of commercial bank exposure to power sector risk. The banking sector’s exposure to the power sector has continued to increase in absolute terms, and nonperforming assets (NPAs) increased nearly tenfold between September 2011 and September 2012, from Rs 12 billion to Rs 117 billion, as illustrated in figure O.1. The growing number of NPAs in the power sector has a number of implica- tions. Among other side effects, it is likely to have accounted for a decrease in commercial lending to the power sector and possibly a long-term reduction in the commercial lending appetite for power sector assets. Figure O.2 illustrates the decrease (see “Infrastructure” in figure O.2). The macroeconomic outlook beyond 2012 is challenging, and the private sec- tor will increasingly be competing with the government to access declining pub- lic savings. The Reserve Bank of India conducted a sample study of 12 corporate entities with high exposure to infrastructure, particularly power, and found (a) sharply increased ratios of debt to equity and debt to earnings before interest, Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Overview 5 Figure O.1  Bank Exposure to Power Sector Share of standard and impaired accounts (Rs billion) 676 422 117 12 September 2012 September 2011 3,886 3,945 Standard accounts NPA Standard restructured accounts Source: RBI 2012, 32. Note: NPA = nonperforming asset. Figure O.2  Growth Rate of Bank Credit to Select Sectors 50 40 30 Percent 20 10 0 Retail sector Real estate Priority Infrastructure Banking sector sector system March 2011 September 2011 March 2012 Source: RBI 2012, 32. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 6 Overview tax, depreciation, and amortization and (b) decreasing interest coverage. These findings point to increasing vulnerability of both the corporate entities and their lenders (table O.2). Over the past decade, the reaction of the central government to the financial crisis in the distribution segment has been rather muted, although at least two centrally funded no-strings-attached bailouts have been offered to state ­ utilities—in March 2001 and September 2012. Finally, as of March 2013, the Ministry of Power has undertaken leadership on this issue and has released a rat- ing of distribution utilities’ financial health to help lenders assess the risks of specific distribution utilities. Utilities have been rated on the basis of seven parameters including financial status and compliance with regulatory norms. The integrated ratings shown in table O.3 use an annualized basis and range from A+ to C (A+ is best, and C is the minimum). The total score is 100. The integrated grading scale of A+ to C is different from the existing, standard rating scale adopted by credit rating agencies (AAA to D), because the standard credit rating measures only the degree of safety for timely servicing of financial obligations based on probability of default. In contrast, the integrated grading exer- cise shown in table O.2 analyzes the operational and financial health of the dis- tribution entities on the basis of the rating framework approved by the Ministry of Power. Furthermore, the standard credit rating for distribution utilities entails comparison with nonspecific “other corporates,” whereas the Ministry of Power’s newly developed integrated rating exercise is based on a comparison of the entity with other distribution utilities only. Table O.2  Causes for Increasing Vulnerability of Corporate Entities Element in decline Element on the increase • Household savings • Inflation • Growth • Current account deficit • Rupee depreciation Table O.3  First Integrated Rating for State Power Distribution Utilities, March 2013 Number of Score distribution Grade utilities Grading definition Between 80 and 100 A+ 4 Very high operational and financial performance capability Between 65 and 80 A 2 High operational and financial performance capability Between 50 and 65 B+ 11 Moderate operational and financial performance capability Between 35 and 50 B 10 Below average operational and financial performance capability Between 20 and 35 C+ 8 Low operational and financial performance capability Between 0 and 20 C 4 Very low operational and financial performance capability Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Overview 7 Private investors in generation need to be concerned about the financial health of discoms, because discoms are their customers. The primary source of revenue for discoms to purchase power comes from their ability to efficiently collect revenue from delivery of power to end users. Revenue shortfalls are supple- mented by subsidies from state coffers, but this practice is unsustainable over the long term. Discoms must improve revenue collection practices by cracking down on theft and repairing obsolete networks or seek approval of the state regulator to charge end users a retail tariff that is closer to the cost at which they are pur- chasing power, or both. Despite all the caveats and concerns about discom finan- cial health, one must recognize that the 11th Five-Year Plan (2007–12) coincided with a period of buoyant economic growth in India, a stock market bubble, record tax collections, and high levels of government support to the power sector. In addition, the highest-ever rate of private participation in the power sector occurred, as well as the highest-ever achievement of total generation capacity addition over a five-year period (52,000 MW for the central and state govern- ment sectors and private sector combined). An analysis of private participation in the Indian power sector would not be complete without considering the National Solar Mission (NSM), and the remarkably high levels of private participation (including from international investors) attracted to central and state government efforts to increase solar generation capacity. The NSM, headed by the Ministry of New and Renewable ­ Energy, was launched in January 2010, when the Indian solar energy market had a capacity of only 17.8 MW. By March 2012, the cumulative capacity had grown to 506.9 MW. Of this capacity, 203.4 MW was commissioned under the NSM and other central government schemes. Another 303.5 MW was deployed under initiatives of various states. The targets are bold: the NSM seeks to install 20,000 MW of grid-connected solar power by 2022. Qualifying projects, sourced from private sector investors, are selected through a reverse auction procurement mechanism and are ostensibly technology neutral, employing either solar photo- voltaic or solar thermal technology. Eight states have participated in phase 1 installations (photovoltaic and solar thermal) of the NSM, with Rajasthan by far in the lead in terms of allocations (table O.4). However, Rajasthan’s state-level incentive program has been sus- pended because of worsening financial conditions of the state utilities and doubts about their ability to pay private developers. (The NSM offers the advantage of bundling the solar cost with the thermal power cost and making the blended price more affordable for utilities to purchase.) Making news headlines in late 2011, competitive bidding for the NSM’s sec- ond batch of projects in phase 1 drove prices for grid-connected solar energy as low as Rs 7.49 (US$0.15) per kWh, approaching grid-parity with fossil fuel– powered electricity. Phase 1 also attracted large conglomerates and new players into the solar market. During the mission’s first phase, more than 500 bidders competed for 63 projects allocated during two reverse auctions, driving prices to a record low. New solar energy investments in India increased to more than Rs 12,000 billion (US$2.5 billion) in 2011. This was in a general context of Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 8 Overview Table O.4  Allocations of State Capacity under the National Solar Mission Megawatts State Batch 1 (2010–11) Batch 2 (2011–12) Rajasthan PV: 100 PV: 295 ST: 400 Gujarat ST: 20 — Maharashtra PV: 5 PV: 25 Karnataka PV: 5 — Tamil Nadu PV: 5 PV: 10 Andhra Pradesh PV: 15 PV: 20 ST: 50 Orissa PV: 5 — Uttar Pradesh PV: 5 — Source: CEEW and NRDC 2012. Note: PV = photovoltaic; ST = solar thermal; — = not available. investments in the overall renewable energy markets in India reaching approxi- mately Rs 51,000 billion (US$10.3 billion) in that year, that is, solar projects accounted for about one-third of the overall investments. In conclusion, the road to full financial recovery of discoms and high perfor- mance of the power sector as a whole remains long. Much has been learned on the way, and many adjustments and modifications have been admirably made. New adjustments are needed to deal with the fossil fuel risks (coal and gas shortages) that have recently emerged and to make better use of private service delivery and new technologies to reduce losses in power distribution. The most important challenges—of providing governance and leadership and of reaching consensus that the power sector should not be treated as a source of political patronage— remain entirely homegrown. There is no imported expertise or technique or reform model that can expedite such political will. Once the political will is in place to fix the “leaking bucket,”1 in the memorable words of Shri Deepak Parekh, there will be no holding back the power sector. Enough capable and experienced private investors, capital, and expertise are poised to propel the sector forward into the 21st century and put wind in the sails of India’s overall economic growth. Lessons Learned from Two Decades of Efforts to Attract Private Investment in the Power Sector What Worked Well in the Indian Power Sector Experience with Private Participation? With respect to private participation in the power sector in India, the following worked well: • The reform process to attract private investors has been evolutionary and has involved “learning by doing” rather than importing any wholesale approach. Indian states and the central government have attempted to attract private participa- tion through a continuously evolving and action-learning process, starting with Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Overview 9 the IPP policy of the early 1990s, which sought to attract new generation investments. The incentives initially offered to potential investors were per- haps overly generous, but ultimately, few companies were able to take advan- tage of the incentives because of checks and balances contained in a massive bureaucracy. Investors were required to obtain approvals and clearances from numerous ministries that were not necessarily eager to extend special treat- ment to IPP investors. The unraveling of the Dabhol-Enron power project was a major learning experience for Maharashtra and the rest of the nation. IPPs with take-or-pay clauses would not be allowed to displace lower-cost base-load power procurement arrangements already in place with state and central gov- ernment generators. No sovereign counterguarantees would be offered again to fast-track projects. • Leadership on sector reforms and improvement of distribution performance has come from various initiatives by states governments (Delhi, Maharashtra, Orissa, and others) as well as the central government (Electricity Act of 2003). Orissa and Delhi privatization experiences are other clear examples of learning by doing and letting future actions be informed by lessons of experience. The Orissa privatization divested entire, large, mixed-load utilities (with external support and timetables to be followed), whereas the Delhi privatization divested parts of an urban utility over a relatively compact customer base into smaller geo- graphic territorial boundaries. The Delhi privatization was done without exter- nal support, in a manner that suited the authorities and allowed them to provide discreet transitional support to the winning bidders who had been selected on the basis of their commitment to acceptable loss reduction trajec- tories. The focus had shifted from simple divestiture of government ownership in Orissa to loss reduction in Delhi and from no transitional support in Orissa to an offer of front-loaded transitional support in Delhi that was designed to phase out as efficiency gains kicked in. These are concrete examples of lessons learned and applied. • Passage of the Electricity Act of 2003 was a signature achievement of the Indian power sector and demonstrated the intent to move away completely from the previ- ous route of negotiated memoranda of understanding with investors to a market- driven situation that forced potential investors to compete aggressively for generation (and later also transmission) contracts. On the basis of the provisions of the act, several policy initiatives were implemented by both central and state govern- ments. The National Electricity Policy, issued by the central government in February 2005, had among its objectives making power ­ available to all house- holds in a period of five years. It also provided guidelines for the commercial turnaround of utilities and protection of the consumer interest. The National Tariff Policy of January 2006 had the objective of ensuring financial viability of the power sector and attracting investments, as well as promoting transpar- ency, consistency, and predictability in regulatory approaches across jurisdic- tions. Other key initiatives at the central government level include the Rural Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 10 Overview Electrification Policy. The state electricity regulatory commissions have also issued their own policies and directives in compliance with the provisions of the Electricity Act of 2003 and other policy initiatives. • Private investment in generation under the market-driven competitive bidding ­ scenario did well in the 11th Five-Year Plan (2007–12), and the initial rounds of bidding coincided with a booming economy and a stock-market bubble in which private companies responded in large numbers. Therefore the competitive bid- ding rounds resulted in extremely low tariffs being quoted by the ­ private ­ sector and illustrated a very high value for money resulting from the competi- tive route as opposed to the negotiated route. (In some cases, companies bid too aggressively and are now locked into long-term power purchase agree- ments [PPAs] that they will be unable to execute owing to a spike in fuel costs, because their hedging arrangements have unraveled as a result of regulatory changes in Indonesia and Australia. This issue remains unresolved, but it raises doubts about whether some of the triumphs of the 11th Five-Year Plan’s best deals in terms of lowest bids for multiyear power purchases can in fact ever materialize fully over the 25-year life of the PPA.) Nevertheless, about 27 percent of installed capacity addition is now financed and owned by the private sector, according to competitively awarded contracts, and this is a ­ positive testament to the ability of the government to engender enough confi- dence in the private sector to invest in generation. • Competitive bidding for transmission projects is now the default mode for project execution at both the interstate and the intrastate level. Two models currently are being used to solicit private participation in transmission: the Ministry of Power model and the Planning Commission model. There are some similarities in the models. Under both models, the private investor arranges financial resources and undertakes construction, maintenance, and operation of the transmission line for an annual transmission charge paid by the beneficiary. This approach suggests that the private investor assumes all project-related risks. However, in terms of eligibility requirements (qualifications of bidders), there is a difference in the way both models treat interested private investors. Whereas the Ministry of Power model does not consider experience in trans- mission projects to be one of the requirements, the Planning Commission model provides a benefit to private investors who have previous experience specifically in transmission. Once construction is complete, both models also require the private investor to be responsible for the operation and mainte- nance of the project, though this function can be undertaken by the private investor or a third party hired by the project developer. The major difference is that the private sector retains ownership of the transmission line in the Ministry's model (build-own-operate-manage [BOOM]) whereas the asset is transferred back to the state in the Planning Commission model at the end of a pre-agreed period, such as 20 years (design-build-finance-operate-transfer [DBFOT]). Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Overview 11 • The Central Electricity Regulatory Commission (CERC) has shown leadership in modernizing the transmission sector’s operating environment. A major inter­ vention by CERC during the 11th Five-Year Plan, in pursuit of relieving con- gestion on the grid, included framing of regulations on point-of-connection transmission charges. This action sought to introduce a scientific approach to transmission tariff determination, based on distance, direction, and quantum of power flow and corrected the shortcomings of the earlier “postage stamp” methodology of allocation of transmission charges among different users. • Ultra mega power plants (UMPPs) introduced the relative allocation of tasks in the true spirit of a public-private partnership. UMPPs, or very large coal-fired power plants generating 4,000 MW or more and using advanced high-efficiency tech- nology, adopted a novel approach to the preconstruction tasks that recognized the relative comparative advantage of the public sector over the private sector in certain areas. The UMPP approach consists of forming a special purpose vehicle (SPV) company that has completed tasks requiring intragovernment coordination such as securing permits, clearances, licenses, and even large tracts of land. Shares in the SPV are then auctioned as part of the bid process, which also contains the levelized tariff as a bid variable. The winning bidder acquires the SPV and begins with a company that has already completed the time- consuming steps involved in up-front project preparation that can often take 18 months or more. In this manner, the private party is able to proceed imme- diately with activities that correspond to its core competence—design; con- struction; project management; commissioning; and operations, maintenance, and management. • The success of the Bhiwandi franchisee in both the steep loss reduction achieved by Torrent Power Ltd. and the improvement in quality and reliability of supply under the franchisee model has encouraged several utilities and states to undertake such initiatives in areas where the licensees have been struggling to improve efficiency levels. The distribution franchisee model has evolved since the Bhiwandi model was implemented with only the key terms of the distribution franchisee agree- ment on hand at the stage of bidding. The distribution franchisee agreement under the present model is more like a management and outsourcing contract because the ultimate responsibility for the area still remains with the licensee. Also, the competitive bidding process by the franchisee affects only the effi- ciency levels and recovery of the licensee, which continues to file its annual revenue requirement and tariff petition as usual for its overall license area, regardless of whether a distribution franchisee has been appointed. Thus, the distribution franchisee is virtually nonexistent for the regulator with respect to the routine business scenario. • The National Solar Mission has rapidly added on-grid solar capacity and has attracted very widespread private sector interest, with sharp drops in tariffs result- ing from highly competitive reverse auctions. For both batches of phase 1 of the Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 12 Overview NSM, the central government used the reverse auction as a price discovery mechanism. Reverse auctions have two main benefits. They allow government procurers to select projects based on lowest cost (thereby keeping the burden on fiscal resources and taxpayers low), and they ensure that a price-based selection process will be fair and transparent. Project developers bid on dis- counted tariffs set by the CERC. A 5-MW parcel-size requirement for batch 1 and a 20-MW maximum parcel-size requirement for batch 2 opened the mar- ket to allow a broad range of companies to enter the sector, as long as they met the criteria set out in the guidelines. In late 2011, competitive bidding for batch 2 projects of phase 1 of the NSM drove prices for grid-connected solar energy as low as Rs 7.49 (US$0.15) per kWh, which approached grid-parity with fossil fuel–powered electricity. Large con- glomerates and new players were attracted to the solar market in phase 1 also. In that phase, more than 500 bidders competed for 63 projects allocated during two investments reverse auctions, which drove prices to record lows. New solar energy ­ in India increased to more than Rs 12,000 billion (US$2.5 billion) in 2011. What Worked Less Well in the Indian Power Sector from 1992 through 2012? With respect to the power sector in India from 1992 through 2012, the following worked less well than anticipated: • Distribution losses have not been adequately addressed over time and are now harming the sector’s growth prospects, because other stakeholders’ risk perceptions about the ability of utilities to pay for power purchases are causing them to hold back. The critical importance of distribution reforms has become clear over time, because a utility’s revenues to pay for power purchases from private generators are collected through the distribution segment. When distribution utilities incur massive losses, and remain dependent on subsidies from the State Exchequer to pay private investors for power, a point comes when pri- vate investors and their commercial lenders reach their risk tolerance thresh- old and retreat to the sidelines. This response may be in progress at the moment; after the flurry of private investor response to tenders for power generation in the 11th Five-Year Plan, very few new transactions were recorded in 2012. (There are also other reasons for the current lack of private investment in generation, which are discussed further below.) ­ • Postponement of distribution reforms while losses have skyrocketed in almost all states has occurred because of the lack of commercial pressures in the state bureaucracy, of which the distribution utility is a part. Use of the distribution franchisee approach to address the ills of the distribution segment has been notably muted, and very few states that have tried have successfully awarded urban franchises for ring-fenced portions of their distribution networks. Most states have failed in enforcing strict mechanisms to reduce distribution Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Overview 13 losses and curb theft of electricity, and a commercial culture or any sense of commercial pressure is absent because there is no personal accountability for the increasing losses and poor operational efficiency in the bureaucratic framework in which the state power sector operates.2 More than 35 percent of the volume of power purchased by a distribution utility is frequently lost in some states, and never billed to the end user; for whatever reason, the util- ity cannot account for that lost revenue. These are the aggregate technical and commercial losses, of which India has some of the highest in the world. • Rural access is increasing but not through any large-scale investment efforts by the private sector. Private involvement in rural electrification has been confined mainly to revenue cycle management and use of private parties for out- sourced metering, billing, and collection. A few pilot business models for the private sector have been demonstrated to be commercially viable in the off- grid space, through innovative combinations of renewable energy technol- ogy and information technology applications to increase the span of control over multiple power generation sites and to manage demand through mobile phone communication with customers, smart payment systems, and other demand-responsive features. However, these business models, although very encouraging, are still in an early stage of development. • Load shedding in the face of both power shortages and customers who are willing to pay but cannot purchase the power from private suppliers is a clear warning sign that resources are not being allocated efficiently. The only channel in which buy- ers and sellers of power can meet is the inefficient state discom, because state regulators have not done their jobs in implementing open access that would allow private investors to bypass the discom and sell directly to large custom- ers. When the state discom has no money to buy available power, the power is simply shut off along feeder lines going to customer premises, and customers must deal with a blackout, or incur very high costs of generating captive power. So private generators exist, who would be able to sell power directly to large users through a bilateral contract under the open access arrangement, which is also allowed under the Electricity Act. This is not happening in practice, how- ever. Discoms are afraid to lose their large customers who cross-subsidize the residential customers. They impose financial penalties (known as the “cross- subsidy surcharge”) on industrial customers wishing to purchase power directly from private generators, in order to make it prohibitively expensive to leave the discom. Inefficiencies are compounded on all sides. • The lack of distribution segment reforms is the glaring gap in the value chain. Almost all attempts to attract private investment in generation have been made in the absence of distribution segment reforms, most likely because of the political sensitivities associated with such reforms. Sensitivities include, for example, measures for loss reduction, which in turn require the utility to disconnect practitioners of electricity theft (who may be politically powerful); the Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 14 Overview introduction of retail tariff increases before power supply improvement can be felt by long-suffering customers, which may lead to defeat of the incumbent political party if elections are looming; or the necessity of making metering investments in the network for which the utility does not have the funds. As noted several times above, the distribution segment is the power sector’s inter- face with the final customer. This is the last mile—entering customer premises and collecting customer revenues, which will be used toward covering all costs of power delivery incurred up to the point where power reaches the final user. It is also the segment where governance concerns are often legitimate. (For clarification, the rational decision making by utility heads that was referred to earlier is not a governance concern in that sense. Instead, the governance concern here is political patronage using electricity as the handout. Many state politi- cians use electricity for handouts and favoritism and issue instructions to the distribution utility to comply.) Political interference, high levels of losses and unaccounted-for power, and low levels of transparency about discom finances and subsidy allocations from state coffers persist. See figure O.3. Figure O.3  Summary of Electricity Value Chain under Pressure 2007–11 Weakest link – Discom • A period of high economic growth • Financial losses – US$16 billion • New IPPs aggressively bidding for market share • Annual public subsidies – US$7 billion • Some private transmission lines • Financial gap after subsidy – US$9 billion • T&C losses – ~35% 2012 to present • Slowing economic growth • Rising international fuel (coal) prices • Deteriorating credit worthiness Reform constrained by political deadlock and corruptions GenCo TransCo Discom Consumers PPI mixed result/failure PPI considered successful PPI partially successful Deteriorating credit worthiness • Facing rising fuel cost with • Some private transmission • High losses no ability to pass through lines closed • Low customer satisfaction • Rising OPEX Fuel crisis Credit crisis • High commercial and technical losses as well as low collection rates in combination with compromised political economy puts high pressure on DisCos. PPAs with IPP force dispatch of expensive plants, pressuring tari . Attempts to bring private expertise delivered mixed results. • The GenCos are facing financial pressure because of tight PPA tariffs and no pass through ability on rising fuel prices, while simultaneously facing reduced credit worthiness of DisCos. Note: Discom = distribution company; GenCo = generation company; IPP = independent power producer; OPEX = operating expenses; PPA = power purchase agreement; PPI = private participation initiative; T&C = technical and commercial; TransCo = transmission company. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Overview 15 General Observations and a View Ahead It is too early to comment on the ultimate success of the 11th Five-Year Plan rounds of competitively awarded power contracts, because most of the pri- vately owned power plants and transmission lines are still under construction. Only one UMPP has been commissioned, and it is experiencing some hiccups (Tata Mundra). Other plants are beset by uncertainties about their commercial viability, after changes in the world coal markets have altered the cost assump- tions built into very aggressively low-priced bids, as noted above. Creditworthiness of the distribution segment is not only a power sector issue. It imposes systemic risks to banking sector stability. Several large public sector banks are heavily exposed to discom assets, because they have issued more than 80 percent of discom debt. NPAs have risen from Rs 12 billion to Rs 117 billion between 2011 and 2012. There are now real possibilities of cross-default trig- gered by the potential failure of big public banks with heavy discom exposure, if discoms do not receive adequate subsidies in time and default on their loans to these banks. It is not yet clear whether the centrally funded bailout of September 2012 has been effective, apart from postponing the immediate threat of defaults, nor whether it will be the last bailout required. Without distribution segment reforms and a change of the underlying eco- nomics of the segment, the pattern of a central government–funded bailout for the power sector every decade looks set to continue. The first bailout (March 2001) was accompanied by unfulfilled promises from chief ministers to intro- duce metering, demand-side management measures, loss reduction investments, and increased basic rates for agricultural consumption—all in the form of a com- mon minimum action plan. The second bailout (September 2012) occurred in the face of a far greater exposure by private investors to power sector risk than did the previous bailout. This time commercial lenders and private equity investors were also involved, unlike in 2001 when no private parties had a financial stake. The 2012 bailout was quietly announced and implemented without any of the fanfare or public declarations and promises that occurred in 2001. Implementing regulations had not been fully worked out, and there may have been an element of panic that caused the announcement to be made prematurely (before knowing which states would participate), simply as a mechanism to address the risk perceptions of the commercial banks, which were starting to abandon the power sector. Yet the day of reckoning seems to have arrived, despite the announcement of the bailout to allow banks to address their exposure to the power sector. Now, without substan- tial introduction of reforms at the state level, particularly to improve governance of the distribution segment, the power sector likely will require a third bailout, probably much sooner than in another decade from now. The current state of the Indian power sector is an acknowledged constraint to the country’s growth aspirations. Power supply in India presents a chronic and acute problem that has refused to go away for the past several decades in spite of a range of policy actions. Going forward, adequate electricity supply will be Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 16 Overview crucial to India’s success in achieving its previously targeted annual gross domes- tic product growth of 8–9 percent. Prospects for private generation investment in the Indian power sector since 2013 have looked less promising than they did during the economic boom of the 11th Five-Year Plan. The pinch is coming from both the generation and dis- tribution segments; the transmission segment’s difficulties are less serious by comparison. Three large red flags loom over the power sector for private inves- tors at present, associated with the following: • Fuel risks loom, as well as uncertainties related to both domestic and imported coal, because more than two-thirds of the Indian power sector meets its base load needs through coal-fired generation. Prices have spiked since 2011, while private investors are committed to competitively awarded 25-year PPAs, which affects commercial viability of plants still under construction. Originally there was no provision for a pass-through of fuel price increases. These are now per- mitted, on a limited basis, but given the financial difficulties of distribution companies, it is not entirely clear how the increased payments for power will be made. • Liquidity risks and declining creditworthiness in the power sector exist because of poor distribution company finances, which affect all parties with exposure to distribution companies. How will distribution companies continue to be able to pay IPPs for power? • A system of sector governance and use of electricity for political patronage in the state distribution utilities has changed little in three decades. Notes At the time (September 2001), Shri Deepak Parekh was Chairman of the 1. Infrastructure Development Finance Corporation Ltd. 2. For example, utility managers have no personal accountability and no performance penalty for incurring operating losses, which are seen as the nationwide norm for the sector. They are employed at a utility for a limited rotation in their highly presti- gious civil service career. They are also typically professional administrators and managers rather than technical specialists in utility matters, so they do not necessar- ily feel technically competent to sign off on the introduction of major process changes, such as deciding to upgrade from one metering system to another and signing off on all the training that would be required to accompany such a change. They do not want to risk labor unrest at the utility during their tenure. It is also likely that they will not be around to claim credit for future improvements to the utility’s bottom line that may (or may not) result from any operational changes they may consider introducing during their tenure. The downside risk is high and imme- diate, in the sense of personal blame to be assumed if unrest, technology failure, or customer complaints arise from any changes introduced at someone’s personal ini- tiative. This is a brief conjecture on how the noncommercial culture at state utilities has resulted in total operating losses of US$20 billion, before adjustments for vari- ous transfers from state coffers. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Overview 17 References CEEW (Council on Energy, Environment, and Water) and NRDC (Natural Resources Defense Council). 2012. “Laying the Foundation for a Bright Future: Assessing Progress under Phase 1 of India’s National Solar Mission.” Interim report, CEEW, New Delhi, and NRDC, New York. RBI (Reserve Bank of India). 2012. Financial Stability Report, Issue No. 6. Mumbai, India: Reserve Bank of India. World Bank. 2012. “Analysis of Experience with Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector.” South Asia Regional Energy Studies Series. Prepared by Deloitte Touche Tohmatsu India Private Limited. World Bank, Washington, DC. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 CHAPTER 1 Introduction to Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector This book reviews the major developments in—and the lessons learned from— the 21-year (1991–2012) experience with private sector participation (PSP) in the power sector in India. It discusses the political economy context of the policy changes, looks at reform initiatives that were implemented for the genera- tion sector, describes transmission and distribution segments at different points in the evolution of the sector,1 and concludes with a summary of lessons learned and a suggested way forward. The evolution of private participation in the Indian power sector can be divided into different phases. Phase 1 was launched with the opening of the generation sector to private investment in 1991. Phase 2 soon followed—early experiments with state-level unbundling and other reform initiatives, including regulatory reform, culminating in divestiture and privatization in Orissa and Delhi respectively. Next came phase 3—the passage of the Electricity Act of 2003 by the central government, followed by a large increase in private entry into generation and forays into transmission and experiments with distribution fran- chise models in urban and rural areas during the 11th Five-Year Plan (2007–12) period. In phase 4, at the start of the 12th Five-Year Plan (2012–17), the sector is seeing a sharp reduction in “bid euphoria” and greater risk aversion on the part of bidders, who are concerned about access to basic inputs such as fuel and land. Before tracing the different phases of the reform process, we will begin with a brief assessment of the pre-reform period and consider the condition of the ­ sector prior to its 1991 opening to private entry. The Prereform Period: From Independence to 1991 At the time of India’s independence in 1947, private companies or local authori- ties accounted for more than four-fifths of the country’s total generation capacity of approximately 1,400 megawatts (MW). However, the Electricity Supply Act Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   19   20 Introduction to Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector of 1948 brought all new power generation, transmission, and distribution facili- ties under state purview.2 This law resulted in almost every state and territory creating its own vertically integrated entity or state electricity board (SEB). When they were first established, most SEBs operated as extensions of the states’ energy ministries. They were indebted in perpetuity to the government because they were financially structured entirely through state government loans.3 The 1948 act gave tariff-setting authority to the SEBs.4 The act antici- pated that the SEBs would function commercially and achieve a minimum 3 percent return on capital. Any operating losses incurred by the SEBs were to be covered through direct subsidies from the state exchequer; there was no pro- vision for SEBs to incur financial losses. The combination of structural inefficiencies introduced through political interference and forced subsidies required from SEBs without timely or adequate government compensation led to a situation in which most SEBs were often in serious financial trouble. The only way that many of them could meet their statu- tory requirement of 3 percent annual return on capital was through discretionary state government support. Because SEBs were already faced with serious cash flow problems, the governments often had no option other than to introduce cross-subsidies, such that industrial tariffs were high relative to the average or even marginal cost of supply to compensate for near-zero revenues from a grow- ing agricultural sector (see box 1.1). Yet political considerations did not allow any Box 1.1  The Green Revolution: Genesis of Free Power to the Agricultural Sector By the late 1960s, India had launched the Green Revolution in its agriculture sector, which involved the widespread use of high-yielding crop varieties, with significant increases in inputs of water and fertilizer in fields that had hitherto been almost solely dependent on rainfall. In states such as Tamil Nadu and Punjab, this initiative meant that two or three crops per year could be harvested, thereby significantly raising farm productivity and profits. Many early irri- gation projects were large and publicly funded, involving surface-water resources. However, groundwater pumping on individual farms using electrical or diesel pump sets became increasingly popular, especially in the 1980s. Irrigation of both forms was widely credited with significant increases in food production in the country. Irrigation had broad appeal because it seemed to be accomplishing two important political goals: achieving food security while increasing the profits of farmers, who could thereby be organized into large vote blocs. Politics were indeed quite crucial in determining events related to the power sector in this period, and subsequently they led to a type of institutional lock-in (free power to farmers) with profound effects on the sector.a a. Although the political claims for many agricultural power subsidies are typically made on behalf of poor farmers, several studies confirm that the constituencies at stake are the kulak, or landed classes, to whom the bulk of the subsidies are directed. The kulak are the classes most likely to invest in irrigation and either use the surplus water to grow high-value crops or sell it to other farmers (Sant and Dixit 1996). Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Introduction to Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector 21 significant withdrawal of subsidies for nonindustrial customer categories, for which political control over SEBs was essential. Cross-subsidies undoubtedly caused disaffection among industrial consumers who finally found it expedient to set up their own captive generation plants to supplement, if not replace, grid supply, which was also becoming increasingly unreliable. Thus, although industrial consumption had constituted nearly two- thirds of total SEB sales in 1960, by 1991 its share had dwindled to about 40 percent. This decline occurred not only because agriculture experienced rapid growth (its share jumped from about 10 percent to 25 percent), but also because many industrial consumers had cut back on their consumption from the grid and were now supplying themselves. The net result was that cross-subsidies from industrial consumers were not sufficient to compensate for a shortfall in reve- nues, and SEB financial health went into decline. Other operational problems appeared as high technical and commercial losses (the former arises from a poorly maintained network and the latter is a euphemism for theft). Also, because many connections that were subsidized were also left unmetered, a growing gray area of the sector was using power but not paying for it. It is important to clarify that most of the theft was occur- ring outside of the agricultural customer category (often by very large and well-connected industrial consumers), mostly with the connivance of SEB workers who, in turn, claimed that they were being pressured by high-level authorities of the states’ political machineries. Unaccounted-for power had risen to between one-third and one-half of the power entering the distribution network by the 1980s; this was power that had been purchased by the SEB from the generator but was lost before revenues could be collected for it from the end user. By 1991, SEBs controlled more than 70 percent of power generation and virtually all distribution. For some time, broad consensus had been emerging that the power sector was in dire straits and that major reforms were needed to change the way it functioned. There were peaking shortages in many parts of the country, severe financial burdens were being imposed on state governments because revenues did not match costs, and everyone was experiencing the same poor quality of supply from the public grid. This situation, then, was the prere- form scenario in the Indian power sector. Phase 1 (1991–95): The Opening of the Sector to Private Investment in Generation—Independent Power Producer Policy The macroeconomic crisis of 1991 precipitated remarkable external and internal pressure to deregulate, if not privatize, major segments of the economy that had been tightly controlled for nearly a half century under independent democratic governance following colonial rule. For the power sector, reform began in October 1991, when the Ministry of Power (MOP) of the government of India Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 22 Introduction to Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector began to publish a series of notifications seeking to encourage the entry of privately owned generating companies into the electricity sector. ­ It is important to note that the 1991 power sector reform sought only to add generation capacity and bring more power into the sector,5 despite the unsat- isfactory underlying performance of the sector as a whole. From the states’ viewpoint, the critical problem that needed to be addressed was the peak defi- cit that led to power shortages and rationing. These government orders at the start of the reform, some of which were later enacted in Parliament to become the Electricity Laws (Amendment) Act of 1991, radically revised prevailing legislation by permitting private entities to establish, operate, and maintain generating power plants of virtually any size and to enter into long-term power purchase agreements (PPAs) with SEBs who remained in charge of distributing power to end users. The initial government notification also provided generous incentives to these independent power producers (IPPs), the most noteworthy of which was a guar- anteed minimum 16 percent (repatriable) return on equity (in any currency) for plants that operated at their rated capacity for at least 6,000 hours in a year (of a total of 8,760 possible hours), with additional bonuses for improved capacity utilization. Other attractions for potential investors included a five-year tax holi- day, a two-part tariff (the first part covering fixed costs, including the assured return, and the second covering variable costs), equity requirements as low as 20 percent of project costs, and selective counter-guarantees from the central government to cover payment default by SEBs. The rules were clearly intended to attract foreign private capital into the sector, because they allowed for 100 percent foreign equity but insisted that Indian financial institutions provide no more than 60 percent of the total debt component of any given project. In a typical transaction in which equity would cover only 20 percent of project costs, and the remaining 80 percent would be financed through debt, Indian banks could meet at most 60 percent of the 80 percent debt requirement, and foreign lenders would have to cover the remaining 40 percent.6 The Indian project spon- sor would have to be strong enough to attract foreign commercial borrowing of 28 percent of project cost in this illustrative example. The rules did not allow Indian bankers to fund all of the debt in these early days of IPPs. The response to the incentives offered was overwhelming from both domestic and international investors. By mid-1995, there were about 189 offers to increase capacity by more than 75 gigawatts, involving a total investment of more than US$100 billion. Of these, 95 projects for a total installed capacity of 48,137 MW had reached the stage of memoranda of understanding (MOUs) or letters of intent (LOIs) with state governments. To help these projects reach financial clo- sure, the central government introduced another set of carrots by granting fast- track status to eight of the most promising projects and agreeing to offer them sovereign counter-guarantees. For all the excitement with which it was launched, the reform program turned out to be a dud overall: against a target of more than 40,000 MW in the 8th Five-Year Plan period (1992–97), fewer than 17,000 MW were added. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Introduction to Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector 23 In the course of trying to implement the 1991 IPP policy, the government lacked coordination between the MOP and other agencies. Investors frequently confronted what they considered to be the recalcitrance of other government departments, but this lack of coordination would be defended by officials as a well- established, if complex, network of rules relating to fuel security, import policy, environmental protection, and the like. There were also instances in which the legacy of older institutions hindered IPP development. For example, the IPPs found it complicated to secure contracts for Indian coal because the vertically integrated SEBs had traditionally defaulted on payments to public companies managing coal and railways. Neither the Ministry of Coal nor the Ministry of Railways was willing to change its procedures radically to accommodate IPPs, because the ministries continued to perceive payment risks. However, many IPPs preferred to seek imported fuel for their projects, in spite of import tariffs, because fuel costs were typically passed through to SEBs purchasing power from them. Without going into further detail, it is clear that IPP developers found themselves confronting an array of government agencies that were stakeholders, but were not themselves promoters of the IPP policy. This situation may account for the fact that such a small percentage of IPP investment targets was actually achieved in phase 1. Meanwhile, commercial lenders who had been cautious about the bankabil- ity of projects, but who were generally satisfied as long as sovereign counter- guarantees were offered, began to seek new ways to finance IPP projects when the central government announced that these guarantees would be limited to only the fast-track projects. Lenders clearly understood that the long-term viabil- ity of the new arrangements would depend on stable revenue streams from distribution. They began to seek mechanisms such as escrow accounts for prime ­ distribution areas, limited debt guarantees from multilateral donors, even pursu- ing (unsuccessfully) use of the Power Grid Corporation of India Ltd. as the prime purchaser to manage and consolidate creditworthiness concerns and, ultimately, started to advocate for the restructuring of SEBs. Escrow quickly began to be seen as the most attractive of these options, allowing lenders to ring-fence reve- nue streams of SEBs and place a first charge on cash flows that would repay the loans the lenders had extended to IPPs. Against the objections of several planners and bureaucrats who were concerned about the further burden on SEB credit- worthiness this would involve, several state governments that wished to sat- isfy requirements of commercial lenders began to set up escrow accounts for IPPs. However, that too reached its limit very quickly, when those governments realized that most SEB revenue streams were too thin to support escrow require- ments of all the IPP projects that were seeking to come on line. Despite the substantial policy changes and intent demonstrated by the central government, only three of the eight fast-track projects were ever commissioned.7 Among these three projects was the first phase of the gas (regasified liquefied natural gas [R-LNG]) Dabhol Power Project, which was planned despite the questionable economics of an R-LNG–based base load power plant in Maharashtra. By the mid-1990s, Enron’s Dabhol Power Project had run into several issues with the state government,8 with opposition parties in Maharashtra alleging Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 24 Introduction to Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector irregularities and high power tariffs being locked in immediately after the signing of the PPA with the SEB in 1993. After the ruling party was voted out of power in the state’s general elections in 1995, the terms of the PPA were renegotiated with Enron in a hostile environment of mutual suspicion. When phase I of the plant was commissioned and the plant started supplying power in 1999, the SEB and Dabhol traded charges over the exorbitant cost of power. Ultimately, the Maharashtra SEB (MSEB) stopped payments to Dabhol in 2001 and sought to cancel its PPA. The Dabhol Power Project marks a watershed in the sector reforms started in 1991. What were the main lessons of phase 1 of the Indian power sector reforms? The government announced very generous incentives to IPPs and received an enthusiastic response, but may not have initially realized the implications of some of the IPP clauses such as “take or pay.” This clause was the source of the problem with power procurement for base load. IPP power is much more expensive and therefore better suited to peaking power requirements, than other alternatives that were previously used for base-load (such as lower-cost state power generation plants or efficiently run large-scale National Thermal Power Corporation power, both of which are cheaper than privately generated power for SEBs). However, to guarantee the IPP investor all the generous financial returns that the IPP policy promised, SEBs would have to buy “all IPP power, all the time,” and stand down cheaper base-load plants in order to fulfil their finan- cial commitments. The Dabhol Power Project experience showed that if SEBs believed power costs were too high, a point would come when sanctity of con- tracts was no longer observed. This realization conveyed a chilling message to other IPP investors, present and future. A major criticism of the early IPP policy, and an illustration of how the risk was disproportionately borne by the public sector and consumers, lay in the fact that few of the IPPs were designed to meet peak demand even though that was the most pressing need of the time. In Maharashtra, the Enron-Dabhol project constituted surplus capacity in the state, and the dilemma for the SEB was how to sell the excess power it had been obliged to buy at very high rates to neighboring states in order to recover losses. SEBs did not have adequate legal and commercial support to enter into negotia- tions on internationally binding PPAs. Phase 2 (1996–2003): Restructuring of SEBs, Introduction of Sector Regulators, and Initial Attempts at Privatization in Orissa and Delhi9 The call for SEB reforms, though largely unheeded, did not fall on entirely deaf ears during the IPP policy phase. Yet power sector restructuring in India in the mid-1990s was a trip into uncharted waters; restructuring had never been done at the state level, and the central level may have been unprepared to deal effi- ciently with the complex questions for which it had responsibility. As such, although the basic ingredients of the restructuring model were fairly simple— horizontal and vertical restructuring, privatization, competition, and regulatory reform were well established by then as international best practice of the Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Introduction to Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector 25 time—the state and national contexts in which the reform would be imple- mented were complex, challenging, and capacity constrained. It was against this background that, in 1996, the Orissa state government initi- ated a comprehensive reform and restructuring of the power sector. At the time, the Orissa SEB was the worst-performing SEB of any major state. Blackouts and brownouts were common, and only about 20 percent of the households in the state were connected to the grid. The power sector was a major fiscal burden on the state, and inefficiency, losses, and corruption were endemic. Orissa became the first Indian state to embrace what was then a new and bold power sector restruc- turing model for India. There was high political commitment: the political leader- ship had repeatedly emphasized that privatization was inevitable; the only factor to determine was how the transition could be made smoothly. The World Bank supported the reform process through a US$350 million assistance package. With the establishment of the Orissa Electricity Regulatory Commission (OERC) in 1996, Orissa became the first state in the country to create an inde- pendent regulatory body in the electricity sector that was responsible for regulat- ing and determining tariffs for the sector. In many ways, the formation of successor entities to an unbundled, consolidated SEB through the issuance of statutory transfer schemes by the state government, together with the creation of OERC, were significant contributions to the sector in India. These steps would later be adopted as a tested basis for staff member transfers, formation of electric- ity regulatory commissions, and so forth, and were finally adopted as part of the Electricity Act of 2003. Following Orissa’s experience, many states adopted simi- lar reform approaches. Assam, Delhi, Gujarat, Haryana, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, Rajasthan, and Uttar Pradesh adopted state-level legislations to reform their power sectors, with Delhi going as far as privatizing distribution under a performance-linked, benefits-sharing model. What were the main lessons of phase 2 of the Indian power sector reforms? The privatization of utilities in Delhi rested in large measure on lessons learned from the Orissa experience: the most important design feature of Delhi’s approach was use of a realistic trajectory for the reduction of aggregate technical and commercial losses as the bid variable, rather than an emphasis on the out- right sale price as in the case of the Orissa divestiture. In addition, the govern- ment’s continued engagement in the Delhi case, through provision of transitional support over five years to the private owners, helped the process by overcoming the cash flow crunch of early years before network improvements and loss reduc- tion measures started yielding results. Phase 3 (2003–12): Enactment of the Electricity Act and Subsequent Policy Initiatives to Introduce Competition and Create a Market in Generation, Transmission, and Distribution In addition to the experience with divestiture in Orissa and privatization in Delhi, several states passed legislation to reform their power sectors in the wake of weak commercial and operational performance of their power utilities and the Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 26 Introduction to Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector fiscal burden imposed by their need for budget support. The Electricity Act of 2003, which followed, was the first comprehensive attempt to create an enabling environment for fundamental reforms in the sector. The Electricity Act of 2003 was a key milestone in the history of India’s power sector. The act addressed competition at various levels in a coordinated manner, thus providing the enabling framework to overcome barriers to private participa- tion. The act resulted in significant improvements in the risk perception of the sector and once again whetted the investment appetite of investors who had hitherto been deeply skeptical of the structure and operations of the Indian power sector. The greatest effect was felt in the generation sector. The following provisions of the legislation (and policies under it) represented the most substantial changes from the reform process as it was intended to function: • The act did away with the need for techno-economic clearances (TECs) by the central government for thermal power projects and retained this requirement only for hydro projects above a given threshold of investments. • The act provided for unbundling of the SEBs and for independence of the transmission function from all forms of trading. This independence created a new route for private capital to enter the power sector, that is, through invest- ment in privately owned transmission lines that could be tendered by states. • The act introduced open access at the transmission level from the first day and accorded choice of power suppliers to consumers above 1 MW, from no later than January 2009. Together with independence of transmission, the provisions for open access made a significant contribution to diminishing the purchasing power of erstwhile SEBs. Open access also created an alternative route to supply to third parties, including other state-owned utilities or third-party end consum- ers in case of default by a particular state-owned distribution utility under a PPA. • The act made a decisive move toward competition in procurement of power and transmission services (and contracting with generators and transmission companies) through the provisions of Section 63 of the act. Guidelines were framed by MOP under the act and were adopted by states to procure power through tariff-based competitive bidding. • In the critical distribution segment, the act provided a framework for the appointment of franchisees that is currently being pursued in a handful of states in both urban and rural areas. This, in many ways, provided a politically acceptable way forward on private participation in distribution, which had otherwise come to a standstill after the Delhi experience for lack of political willingness in other states. The above policy and legislative provisions contributed significantly to changing private sector appetite toward investing in the sector. A conscious, ­ Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Introduction to Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector 27 coordinated procurement of power on a very large scale, initiated by the central government, also allowed the industry to leapfrog to advanced technologies (for example, supercritical thermal generation technology for ultra mega power pro­ jects that were designed to supply 4,000 MW from a single plant) and offered much higher levels of efficiency and lower levels of emissions. Similar technologi- cal considerations are also integral now to interregional independent transmission projects, which include several 765-kilovolt-level projects on a regular basis. The 11th Five-Year Plan (2007–12) coincided with a period of buoyant eco- nomic growth in India, a stock market bubble, record tax collections, and high levels of government support to the power sector. The plan also witnessed the highest rate ever of private participation in the power sector, as well as the high- est achievement ever of total generation capacity addition (52,000 MW for the central sector, state sector, and private sector combined). Last but not least, the 11th Five-Year Plan also coincided with a rare global financial meltdown in late 2008, which sharply constrained (and still continues to constrain) investment in other parts of the world but seems to have had a less dampening effect on domestic private investment in the Indian power sector. What then, has been learned from phase 3 of the Indian power sector reforms? Promulgation of the Electricity Act of 2003 unquestionably brought a new para- digm into the development of the power sector. The act helped outline bold and radical changes in the sector and its structure with the mandatory unbundling of SEBs, thereby helping the sector move away from negotiated MOUs (with guar- anteed rates of return to the investor) for power procurement and introduce competition across the value chain, usher in open access in transmission and distribution, and take a differentiated approach to handling generation and sup- ply in rural areas in the country. The 11th Five-Year Plan showcased the best performance to date of PSP in the power sector. Today, it represents a unique window for the study of private sector involvement. It is the first time that the effect of the reforms ushered in under the Electricity Act of 2003—and primarily the effect of competition among private bidders—can be studied. Without ques- tion, achievement of generation investment targets was substantially higher than in previous five-year plans. Another lesson is that the only two cases of distribution privatization (Orissa and Delhi) in India preceded the Electricity Act of 2003. With the promulgation of the Electricity Act of 2003, the legitimacy of so-called distribution franchisees became well established, because the act provided for appointment of any person or entity to undertake distribution and supply on behalf of the distribution licensee within the licensee’s area of supply. The central government hoped that this approach would confer the benefits of private ownership through a conces- sion arrangement, but not transfer actual ownership, which was controversial and resisted by most state political authorities. However, as discussed in chapter 3, only a limited number of private sector distribution franchisees were established during the phase 3 reform period. To sum up the momentous events of phase 3 and the lessons learned, one must recall that the introduction of reforms and competition under the Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 28 Introduction to Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector Electricity Act of 2003 brought forth a huge response in generation, a limited but respectable response in transmission (because not that many transmission lines were tendered in the first place), and a very limited response in distribution. Yet the distribution sector appears to be in the most urgent need of commercial focus and management practices that come with private participation. Many of the financial woes and shortfalls in operational performance that continue to haunt the distribution sector can be traced to the pre-reform period. Despite all the reforms, the political economy context for power sector distribution at the state level has, in fact, remained surprisingly unchanged over three decades. Phase 4: Investor Uncertainty at the Start of the 12th Five-Year Plan Despite the initial success of tendering more than 50,000 MW of new generation projects under the processes established in 2005 pursuant to the Electricity Act of 2003, the period since 2012 has highlighted significant structural and policy issues that, if unaddressed, are likely to sharply reduce future PSP in power ­ generation. New capacity addition has already experienced a marked slowdown since 2011, with several aspects of the risk-sharing arrangements in the existing framework coming to the fore. The challenges ahead arise primarily from fuel risk (the spike in imported coal prices or the lack of supply for those generators who are relying on domestic coal) and liquidity risk (the negative net worth of the state utilities that are the primary customers for private generation investors). Governance concerns in the sector are an additional red flag. In September 2012, the central government bailed out the state distribution companies through rescheduling of commercial debt to lighten their liquidity crunch.10 However, the fundamental economics of the sector remain unchanged and do not inspire confidence among investors. Many utilities suffer from a shortage of cash flow and cannot buy power for customers, so the utilities pre- fer to use rolling blackouts and cut off power instead. A private investor in power generation capacity therefore faces the increasingly real prospect that it will be unable to sell its power despite an environment of acute power short- ages, because its primary customer, the distribution company, cannot afford to buy power. At the same time, third-party customers with a load of 1 MW or higher are entitled to buy directly from the generator through the open-access mechanism. However, there have been implementation delays on the part of state regulators in operationalizing this mechanism of the Electricity Act of 2003, and therefore the pool of customers for a private generation investor is still largely limited to the distribution companies. What then has been learned so far from phase 4, which started in mid 2012? At present, the private investor community in generation is gripped by uncer- tainty over how to deal with shortages of domestic coal and highly volatile imported coal prices. A number of private investors who bid aggressively for contracts in the 11th Five-Year Plan are now locked in to 25-year PPAs with a near-bankrupt power procurer (that is, the distribution company). A looming, unanswered question preoccupying both lenders and investors is related to Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Introduction to Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector 29 whether the private sector can recover its required rate of return from selling services to bankrupt state distribution companies. State distribution companies, regardless of what they are paying for power to the generation companies, have not been able to commensurately increase their tariffs to the end users (although some have sharply increased tariffs very recently after a long interval), and there is a growing gap between average cost of production and average revenue real- ized for every unit of power. More to the point is the persistent problem of inef- ficient performance (high levels of losses and unaccounted for power) in state distribution companies that are still under substantial political control by state authorities and, therefore, far from operating on commercial principles. Thus, a dilemma exists: how to create the political will needed to implement far-reaching distribution reforms that will force utilities to deal with their performance prob- lems; decrease technical losses to international standards (which are about one- sixth of present Indian averages); substantially reduce theft; collect all the revenues that the utilities are entitled to collect under the existing tariff regimes; and then (after demonstrating that in-house inefficiencies and distortions are being successfully addressed) make a case to the state regulator for any adjust- ments in tariff, if required. Until there is political will among state politicians, or until there is sustained public pressure to undertake drastic reform of the poorly performing distribution sector, the distribution situation is unlikely to change much. Private Participation in Generation, Transmission, and Distribution The following chapters examine the generation, transmission, and distribution segments of the power sector value chain in detail. Generation capacity is now procured and contracted by the state distribution utilities under the case 1 and case 2 methods, depending on whether the state distribution utility specifies the particular land and fuel to be used. For PSP in transmission, state transmission companies or the central power transmission company can use three modalities if they want to invite private investment: the MOP model, the Planning Commission model, and the joint venture route. For PSP in distribution, the option of outright privatization of utilities no longer appears to be on the table. Instead, a distribution franchise is the preferred approach to attracting private investment in a geographically ring-fenced part of a state utility’s distribution network. All of these modalities of private participation throughout the power sector value chain will be presented and analyzed through the respective chapters on generation, transmission, and distribution. ­ Notes 1. Appendix A contains a summary description of the sector’s institutional structure. 2. Legacy private distribution companies exist in Mumbai, Kolkata, Surat, and a few other cities. The companies were originally set up with private ownership at the turn of the 20th century and have remained privately managed ever since. They buy power Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 30 Introduction to Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector from state-owned generators, with few exceptions (for example, Tata in Mumbai is one of the private distribution companies and also has its own generation facility). Legacy private power companies are well managed but are few in number, and they predate the reforms that are discussed in this book by almost a century. 3. Under the Indian Constitution, electricity is a concurrent subject, meaning that both the central and state governments have jurisdiction over the sector. Administratively, therefore, central government organizations and the states have traditionally regu- lated different aspects of planning, sector policy, financing, and operations through a fairly noncontentious division of labor. Appendix A contains figure A.1, showing the institutional setup of the Indian power sector. 4. An exception occurred when central generators supplied electricity to one or more states, in which case the central government prescribed a tariff that was based on a negotiated power purchase agreement with the SEBs. 5. The reforms did not include any measures that would have diluted the state governments’ control over the politically powerful distribution sector, where ­ patronage coexisted with toleration of high levels of power theft, generous subsi- dies, and inefficient networks. 6. In such a case, therefore, foreign equity would fund 20 percent of project cost, foreign debt would cover 32 percent, and Indian debt would finance 48 percent of project costs. Foreign parties would have a total of 52 percent exposure against Indian lenders’ exposure of 48 percent. To take a different example, where the equity investor was Indian and mobilized, for example, 30 percent of the project cost as equity, the debt requirement would be 70 percent. The Indian banks could meet at most 60 percent of the 70 percent debt requirement, that is, 42 percent of the total project cost. In this case, Indian parties would have 30 percent equity and 42 percent debt exposure, and the remaining debt of 28 percent would still have to come from foreign parties. 7. The three fast-track projects commissioned were (a) phase 1 (740 MW) of the 2,184-MW combined cycle gas-based Dabhol Power Project in Maharashtra (phase 2 ­ was 90 percent complete when Enron exited India); (b) the 235-MW combined cycle gas-based Jegurupadu Power Project in Andhra Pradesh; and (c) the 250-MW Lignite- Based Power Project of ST-CMS in Tamil Nadu. 8. Appendix B contains the milestones and timeline of Dabhol project developments. 9. Appendix C contains a summary of the Orissa and Delhi privatization experiences. More detailed accounts of the Orissa and Delhi cases will be found in a forthcoming companion volume to this report that will contain case studies. 10. This was the second such taxpayer-funded central-sector rescue of the power sector in about a decade. The first bailout in March 2001 had been accompanied by unful- filled promises from chief ministers to introduce metering, demand-side management measures, loss reduction investments, and increased basic rates for agricultural ­ consumption in the form of a common minimum action plan. Reference Sant, G., and S. Dixit. 1996. “Agricultural Pumping Efficiency in India: The Role of Standards.” Energy for Sustainable Development 3 (1): 29–37. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 CHAPTER 2 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation Key Messages • Growth in India’s available power generation capacity has not kept pace with Indian demand. • India continues to face severe energy shortages that will constrain economic growth rates; power supply is unreliable for those with access to the grid, and universal access objectives are far from being met (over 300 million Indians had no access in 2012). • Various approaches to attract private investment in power generation have been tried since 1991; tariff-based competitive bidding introduced through the Electricity Act of 2003 has yielded the highest response and occurs through two approaches that contain different risk allocations to the private sector (cases 1 and 2). • Ultra mega power plants introduced the relative allocation of risk and respon- sibilities based on perceived comparative advantages of the public and private sectors. • Today, private sector investment in power generation accounts for about 27 percent of ­ overall power generation capacity in India. • Coal India Limited (a state-owned monopoly) has been unable to supply ade- quate coal for power generation since 2012, and this inability has dampened prospects for future private investment in thermal generation. • Substitution of domestic coal with higher-priced imported coal raises power generation costs that cannot be passed on to customers (power utilities) because of the latter’s weak financial situation and inability to charge higher retail tariffs to their customers who are the end users of electricity. Imported coal is also not always suitable to boilers and other power generation equip- ment that has been manufactured for use of domestic coal, which has ­ different calorific and ash content relative to imported coal. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   31   32 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation • Future allocation of limited low-cost domestic coal availability is a key short- to ­ medium-term policy choice: should it be allocated to new plants owned by private generation investors or to fully-depreciated government-owned plants? • Current projections indicate a drop in imported coal from fiscal year (FY) 2018 onward. If the projections turn out to be correct, then domestic coal non- availability may be an interim problem because coal production is supposed to increase with additional mines being ­ contracted out and three main railway trunk routes under construction. Interim policies are therefore more likely to be focused on managing the blending of imported coal with domestic coal in the interim under a price-pooling mechanism, until annual contracted quan- tity picks up gradually for the power plants. Importance of Power Generation The National Electricity Policy document of the government of India recognizes electricity as one of the key drivers for rapid economic growth and poverty alleviation and had aimed to achieve the target of electricity to all and per capita availability of power of 1,000 units (that is, kilowatt-hours [kWh]) by 2012. This target, however, has not been met. Several challenges need to be addressed before India can achieve this objective. One of the most important concerns is that despite the reform process and private sector participation, the rate of resource augmentation and growth in energy supply has been less than the rate of increasing demand; therefore, India continues to face severe energy shortages. The average per capita consumption of electricity of 704 kWh in India is a frac- tion of the global average of 3,240 kWh. Irrespective of the expected growth in demand for electricity in the coming years, significant capacity additions need to be made even to bridge the current demand-supply gap. The peak demand is expected to be 218,209 megawatts (MW) in 2016/17 compared to 97,269 MW in FY2005/06. Placing the Indian Power Sector in an International Context After the United States, China, Japan, and the Russian Federation, India has the fifth-largest installed electricity generation capacity in the world. However, per capita availability of power in India is a negligible fraction compared to all the countries listed in table 2.1. Power generation, which ensures supply of power and therefore validates other objectives such as energy access, is the first link in the value chain. For two decades, the government has been trying to attract a growing share of private capital for investment in power generation, in the hope of alleviating shortages. Continued robust economic growth in India will depend on, among other things, an adequate and reliable supply of electricity to the economy. The 12th Five-Year Plan (2012–17) envisages the addition of 100,000 MW of capacity by the private sector, which would represent a doubling of the capacity addition that was achieved in the 11th Five-Year Plan (2007–12). Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation 33 Growth of Private Sector Participation in Power Generation in India Figure 2.1 depicts the growth of private sector investment in power generation since 1991. Private sector installed capacity in 1992 was 2.85 gigawatts (GW) and grew to 46.11 GW in 2012, at a 15 percent compound annual growth rate (CAGR). The overall share of private installed generating capacity was only 4 percent during FY1991/92 and substantially increased to 25 percent in the span of Table 2.1  Installed Electricity Generation Capacity of the Most Populous Countries Installed power generation Country Population capacity (gigawatts) Primary fuel China 1,347,000,000 1,140 Coal India 1,241,000,000 212 Coal United States 312,000,000 1,190 Coal Brazil 197,000,000 115 Hydro Russian Federation 143,000,000 230 Gas Japan 128,000,000 245 Nuclear + hydro + coal Mexico 115,000,000 59 Gas, fuel oil, and diesel Turkey 74,000,000 55 Gas + hydro United Kingdom 62,700,000 94 Gas Source: Based on U.S. Energy Information Agency and International Energy Agency data. Figure 2.1  Growth of Private Sector in Power Generation Segment 50 80 70 40 60 50 30 Gigawatts Percent 40 20 30 20 10 10 0 0 Mar-92 Mar-97 Mar-02 Mar-07 Jan-12 Private sector installed Private share in capacity (GW) total capacity (%) Central share (%) State share (%) Source: World Bank 2012. Note: GW = gigawatts. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 34 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation 20 years. The major growth occurred in 1997–2002 and again in 2007–12, with almost 22 percent CAGR. Figure 2.1 also indicates how the state governments’ share in total generating capacity declined over the period, while the share of the private sector grew significantly and that of the central government increased only marginally. The generation segment of the power sector has attracted the most interest from private sector players, largely dominated by Indian companies. A few inter- national firms such as China Light and Power (CLP) and AES figure in the market, but their generation capacity in India is limited. Over the years, India has built a private developer base not only from companies in the power and infra- structure sectors, but also from companies in other sectors that have come for- ward to submit bids for investment in the power sector. Table 2.2 and figure 2.2 illustrate again the growth in private investment and shrinkage of state and central sector investment in the growing installed capacity of power generation ­ assets, specifically during the 11th Five-Year Plan (2007–12). Table 2.2  Installed Capacity of Indian Power Generation Assets Megawatts Share (%) Central State Private Total installed Central State Private Total installed Fiscal year sector sector sector capacity sector sector sector capacity 2006/07 45,121 70,096 17,113 132,329 34 53 13 100 2007/08 48,361 74,689 20,011 143,061 34 52 14 100 2008/09 48,971 76,116 22,879 147,965 33 51 15 100 2009/10 50,993 79,392 29,014 159,398 32 50 18 100 2010/11 54,413 82,453 36,761 173,626 31 47 21 100 2011/12 59,683 85,919 54,276 199,627 30 43 27 100 Source: World Bank 2012. Figure 2.2  Evolution of Ownership of Power Generation Assets, 2007–12 250,000 199,627 200,000 173,626 Installed capacity (MW) 159,398 147,965 143,061 150,000 100,000 50,000 0 2007–08 2008–09 2009–10 2010–11 2011–12 State government Private investors Central government Source: Central Electricity Authority. Note: MW = megawatt. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation 35 Independent Power Projects Policy of the Early 1990s Private participation in generation started with the Electricity Laws (Amendment) Act of 1991 amid a serious financial crisis at central and state levels, when public coffers had limited or no surplus to invest in power generation projects. The amendment allowed private parties (including foreign investors) to establish, operate, and maintain electricity generation plants as independent power producers (IPPs) with up to 100 percent ownership and to enter into long-term ­ power purchase agreements (PPAs) with state electricity boards (SEBs). The amendment was supported by the independent power projects policy ­ implemented in 1992 that established new financial arrangements for private producers. Key features of the policy were as follows: • Sale of power at a structured two-part tariff covering fixed costs and variable costs (capacity charge and energy charge). • Assured 16 percent return on equity in the currency of investment, at 68.5 ­percent plant-load factor for thermal power projects and 90 percent availability for hydropower plants. • Foreign currency risk allowed as a pass-through in tariffs, to be borne by the SEBs. • Incentive scheme based on capacity utilization of power plants. • Provision of counter-guarantee by the central government on a case-by-case basis to the private power companies, backing the payment obligations of SEBs upon specific request by the concerned state government. The above incentives were initially applauded by the private sector; by 1995, around 189 offers worth US$100 billion in investment and potential capacity addition of 75 GW had been put forward. However, only a handful of projects ultimately moved to a stage of financial closure. Many administrative hurdles emerged in gaining required clearances from states and the central government authorities—besides challenges in obtaining the Central Electricity Authority’s (CEA) techno-economic clearance (TEC) and negotiating the various project agreements such as the PPA, fuel supply agreement, and fuel transportation agreement—which quickly dampened the mood of several investors. For accelerated implementation, the government declared eight of the most promising projects to be fast-track projects with expedited statutory clearances and provided a four-tiered payment security against nonpayment of dues by SEBs, including letter of credit, escrow accounts, state government guarantees, and counter-guarantees by the central government (table 2.3). Despite the substantial policy changes and intent demonstrated by the central government, only three of the eight fast-track projects were commissioned.1 Among these three projects was the first phase of the Dabhol Power Project,2 which was planned despite the questionable economics of a liquefied natural gas–fired base-load power plant in Maharashtra. By the mid-1990s, Enron’s Dabhol Power Project had run into several issues with the state government, Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 36 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation Table 2.3  Eight Most Promising Fast-Track Projects Project Capacity (megawatts) State (developers) Dabhol Power Project (LNG) 2,184 Maharashtra (Enron, Bechtel, General Electric) (740 + 1,440) Jegurupadu (CCGT) 235 Andhra Pradesh (GVK Reddy) Neyveli Thermal Power Station 250 Tamil Nadu (ST-CMS Electric Company Private Ltd.) Bhadravati (coal) 1,072 Maharashtra (Central India Power Company Ltd. by Nippon Denro Ispat Ltd.) Godavari (CCGT) 208 Andhra Pradesh (Spectrum Power) Visakapatnam 1,040 Andhra Pradesh (Hinduja National Power) Mangalore Power Project 1,000 Karnataka (Cogentrix, China Light and Power) Ib Valley 420 Orissa (AES Transpower) Source: World Bank 2012. Note: CCGT = combined cycle gas turbine; LNG = liquefied natural gas. including high power tariffs being owed by the state immediately after the sign- ing of the PPA with the SEB in 1993 and opposition parties in Maharashtra alleging irregularities. After the ruling party was voted out of power in the state general elections in 1995, the terms of the PPA were renegotiated with Enron in an environment of mutual mistrust and recriminations. When phase 1 of the plant was commissioned and the plant started supplying power in 1999, the SEB and Dabhol traded several charges against each other over the exorbitant cost of power, and ultimately, the Maharashtra State Electricity Board stopped payments to Dabhol in 2001 and sought to cancel its PPA. The complete Dabhol case study is provided in a companion volume to this book (volume 2, Case Studies). Key Issues in Implementation of the IPP Policy The following were significant issues in the implementation of the IPP policy of the 1990s: • The SEBs were in poor financial health and were not perceived as reliable counterparts to IPP contracts, either by prospective developers or by their financiers. Guarantees by the state governments and counter-guarantees by the central government were available only to the fast-track projects and not com- monly to other projects. • The cost-plus negotiated method3 of project development, with tariffs deter- mined on the basis of capital costs, meant that private parties had no real incen- tives to be efficient. It was not surprising, therefore, that a majority of developers proposed investments that translated into tariffs well above the benchmarks existing in the public sector. Moreover, the pass-through in tariffs of foreign currency risks added to the risk perception on the part of state governments. • Except for the fast-track projects, obtaining statutory clearances on power projects was arduous and time consuming in the 1990s. Procedures for envi- ronmental clearances in particular have subsequently undergone a fair degree Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation 37 of standardization,4 and today they are reasonably time-bound for thermal projects in particular. All thermal projects in the 1990s also required a TEC, which was an added due diligence in the absence of competitive measures to determine capital costs or tariffs. The requirement of a TEC was abolished later upon enactment of the Electricity Act of 2003. • Delays in finalization of contracts (power purchase, fuel supply, fuel transpor- tation, and so forth) were routine. SEBs were left to negotiate contracts on their own with little or no prior knowledge of international contracts (for example, “take or pay” clauses) and their implications. Lack of standardization in approach meant that each project was treated differently, and it was not uncommon for fully negotiated contracts to be reopened after a change in management within the SEB or in political leadership in the state government. The lack of transparency in this approach also allowed for allegations of cor- ruption and malfeasance to be leveled more easily, making civil servants wary of finalizing contracts involving such large investments during their tenures. • The cost of power from private projects was much higher than that from p ­ ublic sector generation projects. Several factors led to a higher capital cost: (a) the absence of competition and therefore a lack of any real effort by the private sec- tor to optimize costs; (b) the use of imported equipment, resulting in increased foreign exchange exposure; and (c) the overall higher risk perception of such contributed signifi- projects, resulting in higher cost of capital. All these factors ­ cantly to making IPP power very expensive relative to what had prevailed before, when most power was purchased by SEBs from public ­ generation companies. Despite the initial euphoric interest among Indian and foreign investors, the actual implementation of projects (because of the factors outlined above) was dismal. It also became clear over time that SEBs, being weaker financially, had little bargaining power in the process. The procurement process was inefficient and costly because of a lack of competition and transparency. Intermediate Policy Initiatives for Private Sector Participation in Generation Following the initial experience of the private power policy of 1991, the central government made several additional isolated attempts to attract the private sector into generation projects. Some of the significant efforts were as follows: ­ • To meet the demand-supply gap faster, the government promoted liquid fuel– based generation (because of its relatively shorter gestation period) through the Liquid Fuel Policy (1995). This resulted in some existing gas-based power plants stepping up their plant utilization through the use of naphtha, but no new capacity was planned for liquid fuel, because of its high cost of generation (from high fuel charges). Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 38 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation • State governments were postponing critical renovation and modernization requirements. This, in turn, resulted in decreased efficiency in state-owned coal-fired generation plants in particular. The central government created pol- icy guidelines for private sector participation in renovation and m­ odernization of existing plants, but not a single project to date has ­ actually been imple- mented through private participation in renovation and modernization. • In 1998, the central government issued the Hydropower Development Policy, intended to exploit the huge hydroelectric potential in the northern and northeastern regions of India. A few medium-size and large hydro projects have been developed since then. • With the growth in generation, the central government also felt the require- ment for substantial additional investment in transmission lines. The Electricity Laws (Amendment) Act of 1998 was passed to recognize transmission as a distinct activity, thereby enabling private investment in the transmission sector through issuance of transmission licenses at interstate and intrastate levels. • The Ministry of Power issued a Mega Power Policy in 1995 to allow investors to benefit from economies of scale by setting up large-scale power projects directly at coal mines (pit-head) and supplying coal to load centers through appropriately planned, dedicated transmission infrastructure. The policy sought to award projects through competitive bidding, and the central agencies—­ namely, the CEA, National Thermal Power Corporation (NTPC), and Power Grid Corporation of India Ltd. (POWERGRID)—were to provide catalytic support through project identification, feasibility, and transmission access arrangements. The policy later factored in certain fiscal concessions to pass on the benefits of scale to consumers. The fiscal benefits were in the nature of waiver of customs duty and “deemed exports” benefits. Most of the above attempts met with limited success. The Electricity Act of 2003 replaced the legal framework for the sector that had hitherto been governed by the Indian Electricity Act of 1910, the Electric Supply Act of 1948, ­ and the Electricity Laws (Amendment) Act of 1998. Promotion of competition in the electricity industry in India has been one of the key objectives of the Electricity Act of 2003. Post–Electricity Act of 2003: Tariff-Based Competitive Bidding Three sections of the Electricity Act of 2003 provide for tariff regulation and determination across different segments of the industry. Sections 61 and 62 of the act provide for those aspects for generation, transmission, wheeling, and retail sale of electricity by the “Appropriate Commission.” Section 63 of the act states that “notwithstanding anything contained in Section 62, the Appropriate Commission shall adopt the tariff if such tariff has been determined through Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation 39 transparent process of bidding in accordance with the guidelines issued by the Central Government.” The central government issued tariff-based competitive bidding guidelines in 2005 for procurement of power by distribution licensees (state utilities, also referred to as distribution companies). This issuance was done under Section 63 of the act to create competition in generation and to reduce overall power procurement cost by distribution companies. Distribution companies had previ- ­ ously purchased power under contracts on a case-by-case basis with IPPs, assur- ing the IPPs of a 16 percent return on equity. Thereafter, the competitive bidding guidelines were applicable for long-term procurement (seven years and above) and medium-term procurement (one to seven years) of base-load, peak-load, and seasonal power requirements. Two routes are available for competitive procurement of power by distribu- tion licensees—case 1 and case 2. These routes are compared in table 2.4 and figure 2.3 (note that the procurer is the distribution company). Table 2.4  Competitive Procurement Characteristics by Case Case 1 Case 2 • Procurer is not to specify the location, • Procurer must specify the location, technology, and technology or fuel and is interested only in fuel and shall make the land available for project the power to be procured. development along with clearances and approvals. • Bidder takes on the responsibility for all • Procurer shall make the fuel available for the project clearances, approvals, and so forth. in all cases except for imported fuel situations. • Case is relevant for states with limited • Case is relevant for states that can identify feasible feasible sites for power generation projects. sites for power generation and provision. Note: Procurers may, subject to approval of the appropriate commission, use terms different from the competitive bidding guidelines; for example, for the Lakhisarai and Pirpainti thermal power projects in Bihar (case 2), the bidders were able to arrange for fuel for the entire term of the power purchase agreement, a deviation approved by the Bihar Electricity Regulatory Commission. Figure 2.3  Competitive Procurement Case 1 Case 2 Bidder to arrange Procurer to arrange • Land • Land • Domestic fuel Bidder to • Domestic fuel Linkage arrange Linkage Captive • Imported Captive • Technology fuel • Technology • Clearances and • Clearances and approvals approvals Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 40 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation Bid Process For long-term procurements under case 2, a two-stage bid process with a sepa- rate request for qualification (RFQ) and request for proposal (RFP) stage is to be adopted. The procurer (distribution company) may adopt a single-stage bid process for long-term or medium-term procurement under case 1, combining the RFP and RFQ processes. Tariff Structure The guidelines specify a two-part tariff structure comprising separate capacity and energy components. The energy charge and capacity charge can, in turn, be quoted on the basis of escalable and nonescalable components. Table 2.5 sum- marizes the possible tariff structures for case 1 and case 2 projects. Selection of bidders is on the basis of lowest levelized tariff. Nonescalable components are to be quoted year-on-year for each contract year from the com- mercial operation date, over the term of the PPA. Escalable components are to be quoted only for the first year and are then automatically escalated by using the relevant Central Electricity Regulatory Commission (CERC) index over the term of the PPA. The evaluated tariff for any contract year is then computed as the summation of all escalable and nonescalable components for the contract year. The quoted tariff stream over the term of the PPA is then levelized by using the CERC specified discount rate to arrive at the quoted levelized tariff for each bidder. Payment of the escalable components over the term of the PPA is based on payment indexes revised semiannually by CERC. Nonescalable components are paid as quoted for the contract year without any adjustments. Table 2.5  Possible Tariff Structures for Case 1 and Case 2 Projects Tariff Case 1 Case 2 Capacity • Bidder can quote escalable capacity • Bidder may quote firm capacity charge charges and nonescalable capacity charges for the PPA term with “Nil” charges. escalable quoted charges. Energy charge • Bidder can quote escalable energy charges • Bidder may quote firm quoted energy and nonescalable energy charges. The charges for the PPA term with “Nil” escalable or nonescalable components escalable quoted charges. may include the following elements, depending on the type of fuel: –– Inland transportation charge –– Overseas transportation charge –– Fuel handling charge Transmission • Applicable only when quoted tariffs must • Not applicable charges be adjusted for transmission charges and and losses losses to arrive at the cost of procurement at the state interface Note: PPA = power purchase agreement. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation 41 Response of the Private Sector to Case 1 and Case 2 Procurement through Competitive Bidding Since the introduction of tariff-based bidding guidelines, procurement of 19,527 MW of power has been concluded through the case 1 approach. Gujarat and Maharashtra are the leading states, having procured 5,810 MW and 5,154 MW of power, respectively, during 2007–10. The highest level of total case 1 procurement occurred in 2010, with 8,410 MW, followed by 7,613 MW of power procured through case 1 in 2007. Table 2.6 presents a summary of all case 1 bids, showing amounts and prices in Indian rupees per kilowatt-hour. As of 2012, there were seven state-level bids for procurement of power through the case 2 approach, aggregating to 10,440 MW of power procured. (This excludes the four ultra mega power plants [UMPPs] for which contracts have been awarded, totalling 15,880 MW; see following paragraph for more information on this program.) The major procuring states under case 2 are Uttar Pradesh (three projects totalling 4,500 MW) and Punjab (two projects total- ling 3,300 MW). Among all state-level case 2 bids, the lowest tariff recorded was Rs 0.81/kWh for the 1,320-MW Bhaiyathan Thermal Power Project in Chhattisgarh that was awarded to Indiabulls Power Limited. The maximum selected tariff was Rs 3.02/kWh for the 1,980-MW Phase 1 of the Prayagraj– Bara Thermal Power Project awarded to Jaiprakash Power Ventures Ltd. (JPVL) in Uttar Pradesh. Table 2.7 provides the summary of all the case 2 bids (note that apart from Jhajjar and Anpara C, none of the other projects have, as yet, been commissioned). Table 2.6  Summary of Case 1 Bids Winning bid prices Quantity of power (Rs/kilowatt-hour) Year Procurer (megawatts) Minimum Maximum 2007 Gujarat Urja Vikas Nigam Ltd. (GUVNL) 3,200 2.2498 2.8900 2007 Haryana Power Generation Corporation Ltd. 2,113 2.3600 2.9400 2007 Madhya Pradesh Power Trading Company 2,300 2.3400 2.9500 2008 Maharashtra State Electricity Distribution 2,304 2.6424 2.7286 Company Ltd. 2009 Rajasthan Rajya Vidyut Prasaran Nigam Ltd. 1,200 3.2483 3.2483 2010 Gujarat Urja Vikas Nigam Ltd. (GUVNL) 2,610 2.3450 2.8000 2010 Bihar State Electricity Board 450 2.6400 2.6400 2010 Power Company of Karnataka Ltd. 2,180 3.7570 3.8890 2010 Maharashtra State Electricity Distribution 2,850 2.8790 3.2800 Company Ltd. 2010 Reliance Infrastructure Limited 320 3.4210 3.4210 Source: World Bank 2012. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 42 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation Table 2.7  Summary of Case 2 Bids, Other than UMPPs Quantity of power Winning bid prices Project (megawatts) Developer (Rs/kilowatt-hour) Project status Bhaiyathan Thermal 1,320 Indiabulls Power 0.81 Forest clearance for captive coal Power Project Limited mine rejected by Forest Advisory Committee; project construction doubtful Anpara C Thermal 1,200 Lanco Kondapalli 1.56 Commissioned in November 2011 Power Project Power Ltd. Sangam–Karchana 1,320 Jaiprakash Power 2.97 Promoter reportedly expressed Thermal Power Ventures Ltd. unwillingness to construct this Project project Prayagraj–Bara Thermal 1,980 Jaiprakash Power 3.02 Expected COD by July 2014 Power Project Ventures Ltd. Jhajjar Power Station 1,320 China Light and 2.99 Commissioned in 2012 but ongoing Power India problems at plant with supply of Private Ltd. domestic coal Talwandi Sabo Thermal 1,980 Sterlite Energy Ltd. 2.86 Expected COD by January 2014 Power Project Rajpura Thermal Power 1,320 L&T Power 2.89 Expected COD by May 2014 Project Development Ltd. Source: World Bank 2012. Note: COD = commercial operation date; UMPP = ultra mega power plant. Ultra Mega Power Plant Projects UMPP projects have a capacity of about 4,000 MW each, use advanced high-efficiency technology, and aim to derive economies of scale in generation as ­ well as transmission of power. These projects are developed with supercritical technology to achieve high fuel efficiency, resulting in fuel savings and lower greenhouse gas emissions. The projects have been conceived either as pit-head projects (using dedicated captive coal blocks) or as coastal projects using imported coal to be arranged by the bidders themselves. UMPPs adopted a novel approach to the preconstruction tasks that recog- nized the relative comparative advantage of the public sector over the private sector in certain areas. The Power Finance Corporation (PFC) is the focal point (nodal agency) entrusted with the responsibility of coordinating and conducting the competitive bid process for selection of a developer for each project through tariff-based competitive bidding. PFC sets up a special purpose vehicle (SPV) as a 100 percent–owned subsidiary for each identified UMPP. It completes all the groundwork, including acquisition of land, acquisition of environmental clear- ance and water allocation, and allocation of the captive mine (in the case of a captive coal mine-based UMPP) in the name of the SPV, before bidding out the project. Once a successful bidder is identified, the bidder buys 100 percent equity in the SPV. The UMPP modality is designed to allocate responsibilities based on comparative advantage; that is, as a public sector nodal agency, PFC should be more easily and more efficiently able to undertake steps involving government clearances and interface, and this leaves the tasks of designing, Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation 43 financing, constructing, and operating the plant to the private sector. In this manner, the private party can proceed immediately with the activities that ­ correspond to its core competence and does not spend 18–24 months up front ­ trying to put in place the preconstruction arrangements. Response of the Private Sector Twelve proposed UMPPs have been identified, of which four have already been awarded to developers on the basis of the two-stage competitive bidding process (RFQ + RFP) outlined earlier. Table 2.8 provides the status of identified UMPP projects. Most of the awarded projects are still in the construction stage, and the first unit of Mundra UMPP has been commissioned recently. The private sector’s Table 2.8  Status of Identified UMPP Projects Selected bid Status of project Project Developer Fuel source (Rs per unit) commissioning (COD) Coastal Gujarat Power Limited, Mundra Tata Power Imported coal 2.26 First unit COD: UMPP, Gujarat (5 × 800 MW) (arranged by February 2012 developer) Project COD:- February 2013 Sasan Power Limited, Sasan UMPP, Reliance Allocated domestic 1.196 First unit COD: Madhya Pradesh (6 × 660 MW) Power coal mine March 2013 June 2014 Coastal Andhra Power Ltd., Reliance Imported coal 2.336 February 2015a under Krishnapatnam UMPP, Andhra Pradesh Power (arranged by the signed PPA (6 × 660 MW) developer) Jharkhand Integrated Power Ltd., Tilaiya Reliance Allocated domestic 1.77 June 2017 UMPP, Jharkhand (6 × 660 MW) Power coal mine Orissa Integrated Power Ltd., Orissa UMPP, Allocated domestic Bid process restarted in 2014 under Sundargarh District coal mine revised standard bidding documents Chhattisgarh Surguja Power Ltd., Allocated domestic Bid process restarted in 2014 under Chhattisgarh UMPP, coal mine revised standard bidding documents Surguja District in Chhattisgarh Coastal Tamil Nadu Power Ltd., Bidding yet to commence Cheyyur UMPP, Tamil Nadu Coastal Maharashtra Power Ltd., Bidding yet to commence Maharashtra UMPP Coastal Karnataka Power Ltd., Bidding yet to commence Karnataka UMPP Tatiya Andhra Mega Power Ltd., Bidding yet to commence Andhra Pradesh 2nd UMPP Sakhigopal Integrated Power Co. Ltd., Bidding yet to commence Orissa Additional UMPP 1 Ghogarpalli Integrated Power Co. Ltd., Bidding yet to commence Orissa Additional UMPP 2 Source: Power Finance Corporation. Note: COD = commercial operation date; MW = megawatt; PFC = Power Finance Corporation; RFQ = request for qualification; UMPP = ultra mega power plant. a. Since June 2011, the developer has halted construction work at the project site, citing new regulations by the government of Indonesia that imposed a tax on the sale of coal, based on a benchmark price, irrespective of actual sale value. The procurers have served a termination notice on the developer, and the matter is in court. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 44 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation response to UMPP projects was enthusiastic, in terms of both participation and overall reduction of tariffs. Reliance Power won three of the first four UMPP projects with Sasan UMPP, resulting in the lowest bid (Rs 1.196/kWh), whereas the highest bid is for the imported coal–fueled Mundra UMPP (Rs 2.260/kWh). Comparison of Case 1 and Case 2 Bids with Noncompetitively Awarded (by Memorandum of Understanding) Projects Under the National Tariff Policy of 2005, a five-year exemption was pro- vided for public sector projects to contract with distribution utilities without going through a competitively bid process pursuant to Section 63 of the Electricity Act of 2003. In effect, the tariff of public sector projects continued to be negotiated and determined by appropriate commissions under Section 62 of the act on a cost-plus basis. In September 2010, when this five-year exemption came up for review, the CERC issued statutory advice to the central government not to defer the deadline. In effect, this advice initiated a ­ transition of the public sector to also take part in competitive tariff-based ­ bidding beginning January 6, 2011. Before making its recommendation, the CERC carried out a detailed exercise5 of comparing tariffs realized on competitively bid projects, with an assumed construction of an equivalent plant contracted as a memorandum of understand- ing (MOU) plant (with tariffs determined through the negotiated route by the appropriate commission). The hypothetical MOU plant was assumed to be no more efficient than the most efficient NTPC plant, in effect yielding a public sector comparator for the project; that is, the CERC compared the bidding pattern for each project with an equivalent tariff, assuming that the plant was ­ built with the same degree of efficiency as an NTPC plant. The hypothetical comparator is referred to as the MOU route as opposed to the competitive bidding route. The CERC accepted 14 projects, which had recently participated in case 1 and case 2 tenders. Figure 2.4 shows that, in the majority of cases, the competi- tively bid case 1 tariff was substantially lower than the expected tariff that would have resulted from the MOU route. For case 2 bids, as shown in figure 2.5, all of the results are significantly lower than under the MOU route. On the basis of this comparison with public sector projects, which were still using the MOU route under their five-year exemptions, the CERC reiterated its advice to the central government to transition all public sector projects to a com- petitive basis of procurement under case 1 or case 2. This approach would effectively remove any regulatory determination of tariffs for projects for which ­ developers signed PPAs after January 5, 2011. In general, certain other factors can be concluded for case 1 and case 2 ­ projects as follows: • Comparable case 1 project quotes appear to be significantly more expensive than case 2 project quotes (Tiroda phases 1 and 2 are differently priced, for the very same project, under case 2 and case 1, respectively). This outcome is not Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation 45 Figure 2.4  Case 1 Bids Mahanadi (3 × 600 = 1,800 MW) Tiroda, Ph. 2 (2 × 660 = 1,320 MW) Nandgaonpeth (2 × 660 = 1,320 MW) Mahan (2 × 660 = 1,320 MW) Chitrangi, Ph. 1 (3 × 660 = 1,980 MW) Tiroda, Ph. 1 (2 × 660 = 1,320 MW) Mandva (2 × 660 = 1,320 MW) Babandh (4 × 660 = 2,640 MW) Kamalanga (3 × 350 = 1,050 MW) 2.000 2.200 2.400 2.600 2.800 3.000 3.200 3.400 Rs/kilowatt-hour Tariff MOU route Competitively bid tariff Source: Central Electricity Regulatory Commission. Note: MOU = memorandum of understanding; MW = megawatt. Figure 2.5  Case 2 Bids Sangam (2 × 660 = 1,320 MW) Prayagraj (3 × 660 = 1,980 MW) Jhajjar (2 × 660 = 1,320 MW) Rajpura (2 × 700 = 1,400 MW) Talwandi Sabo (3 × 660 = 1,980 MW) 2.000 2.200 2.400 2.600 2.800 3.000 3.200 3.400 3.500 Rs/kilowatt-hour Tariff MOU route Competitively bid tariff Source: Central Electricity Regulatory Commission. Note: MOU = memorandum of understanding; MW = megawatt. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 46 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation surprising, because case 1 projects leave all risks of obtaining consents and clearances, including exposure to fuel-related uncertainties, to the bidder. This higher risk is reflected in a higher price quoted by the bidders. • In most cases of coal-linked projects (that is, case 2 projects), when the pro- curer has the obligation to supply domestic coal, the linkage provided by Coal India Limited (CIL) or its subsidiaries is only for 70 percent of the requirements of the plant. It is assumed that the balance has been sourced by the developer through the CIL e-auction process6 or through imports. Shortfalls are therefore extremely costly, and they are being increasingly fac- tored into case 2 bids in a gradual manner (that is, case 2 prices are starting to rise). Even more disturbing are the instances in which CIL is failing to meet its commitment to supply the basic 70 percent of the fuel required by coal- linked case 2 projects, such as the recently commissioned 1,320-MW Jhajjar Power Station. Prospects for Future Private Participation in Power Generation: What Is Holding Back Private Investors? Although the initial private sector response to case 1 and case 2 projects was overwhelming, it has now dropped sharply on account of the uncertainties in the sector. Prospects for continued private sector investment in generation will depend largely on how and when the following three primary concerns of private generation investors are resolved: • Fuel Risks—Domestic and Imported Coal–Related Uncertainties for Private Power Developers.7 As explained above, in the case 1 power procurement model, the private developer is expected to arrange the fuel requirements for its project and assumes the entire risk on this account. Case 1 technical quali- fications require the bidder to have linkages (supply contracts) for the entire capacity for which it is bidding. However, CIL has resorted to providing coal linkages for substantially lower capacity utilizations for projects, even where it has signed on to firm fuel supply agreements. This is both a risk and a con- cern for developers, who are not sure of the amount of coal that would actu- ally be made available by CIL, even though they have uncovered commitments under the case 1 PPA to ensure plant-load factors and availability of the order of 80 percent. Bidders must then procure the shortfall of coal through e-­auction or blend with imported coal, but both may lead to substantially higher tariffs (over the life of the contract) after a PPA is entered into on the basis of a competitively bid tariff. Bidders who have chosen to rely on imported coal (to avoid interacting with CIL) are also facing massive difficulties. These difficulties are due to unexpected regulatory changes in Indonesia and Australia that have unravelled the bidders’ hedging strategies and sharply raised the cost of imported coal, while the bidders also remain locked into 25-year PPAs. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation 47 • Liquidity Crisis in the Sector: This topic will be analyzed in detail in chapter 4 on distribution sector issues. • Governance Issues: The power sector has transitioned from outright state ­ ownership of vertically integrated SEBs in the 1990s to a more unbundled scenario for generation, transmission, and distribution, with a state regulatory commission in attendance. However, realities at the project level (and political interference at the state level) have not changed significantly from the SEB days. Governance remains a challenge. There is often a sense of excessive camaraderie and common purpose among state politicians, state regulators, and the heads of the state distribution utilities. Use of electricity as a tool of political patronage (mentioned earlier) remains widespread. The Coal Crunch and Choices Facing Policy Makers India’s annual thermal coal demand is expected to climb to 730 million metric tons by 2017, compared to a demand of 650 million metric tons and production of about 440 million metric tons today. A study by Prayas Energy Group (2013) notes that 42 GW of planned capacity have been mothballed as of January 2012 because of coal supply bottlenecks and price curbs. Private investors had won rights to build plants by bidding prices at which they would sell electricity. Power companies that have put additional coal-fired capacity construction on hold had bid to sell electricity at an average of Rs 2.50 (US$0.05) per kilowatt-hour, while current fuel prices put the cost of producing power at about Rs 3.00 per kilowatt-hour, thereby slowing the growth of coal-fired plants. According to the New Coal Distribution Policy (amended July 26, 2013), all plants to be commissioned between January 4, 2009, and March 31, 2015, will have fuel supply agreements signed with annual contracted quantities of 65 percent, 65 percent, 67 percent, and 75 percent, respectively, over the remain- ing years of the 12th Five-Year Plan. The option of preference in coal distribution is thus addressed only through curtailing supply to these plants. Recent projec- tions indicate that production and transportation bottlenecks should ease beyond 2017 to result in a nominal reduction in coal imports (see box 2.1). Imported coal price is still about 25–35 percent higher than Indian domestic coal prices based on heat content. Thus, one could assume that a combined or pooled price would be higher than current domestic coal prices paid by thermal power plants. Logistical Difficulties with Physical Pooling of Imported and Domestic Coal In July 2012, CIL reported that it planned to import up to 30 million metric tons of coal in 2012 to meet rising domestic demand and mitigate power shortages. However, imports are only a first step. Coal imports and delivery of the imports to intended destinations require considerable logistical capability and planning. Coordinated transport arrangements at ports and railways, as well as suitable Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 48 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation Box 2.1  What If the Coal Availability Projections Are Too Optimistic and There Is Still a Coal Shortage in 2018? Fast forward to a scenario in 2018 where coal shortages persist. Who should receive the scarce domestic coal? The following is one scenario, of two radically different, alternative approaches that are presented for discussion purposes: • First priority could be given to the old vintage central sector and state sector power genera- tion plants that are fully depreciated (commissioned in 1993 and earlier). • Next priority could be given to newer central and state sector plants (commissioned from 1994 to 2004). • Next priority could be given to private sector plants that have sourced their equipment to be able to function on Indian coal only and would face hardship if they had to use other grades of coal, and thus they need access to Indian coal even if they cannot achieve 80 or 85 percent plant-load factor. In an alternative scenario, which may be focused on reviving waning private sector interest in generation investments and rescuing half-built private plants that risk becoming stranded because of the coal shortage, the following could be a likely way forward: • UMPPs may be first in line because they are highly visible and attract significant amounts of private sector capital per plant (about Rs 20,000 billion). Future UMPPs are expected to have a full pass-through of fuel price risk, but existing ones have asked for and received some relief (Tata Power as well as Sasan coal for Chitrangi by Reliance Power Ltd.). • Next in line would be large subcritical plants that were recently commissioned, particularly those linked to private transmission lines, so that two categories of private investors generation and transmission) would be placated with the coal allocation policy, and overall (­ investor confidence in the power sector would increase. • Central and state sector plants would come last in this scenario, which would be focused on wooing the private sector with the coal allocation policy. loading and unloading facilities, may not be in place, meaning that imported coal movements may be constrained by on-ground realities and limitations and that true pooling may not be physically possible. Domestic coal raises similar logistical challenges because of the uneven ­ geographical allocation of India’s coal resources: • Most of the reserves are found in the eastern region and are mostly vested with states such as Jharkhand, Orissa, and West Bengal. This region has 173.12 billion tons (Bt) (62.7 percent) of reserves in its inventory and has 293 mines owned by Eastern Coalfields Ltd., Bharat Coking Coal Ltd., Central Coalfields Ltd., Mahanadi Coalfields Ltd., and some private players. produced around 232.554 metric tons (Mt) of coal in FY2010/11. This region ­ • In the western region, coal reserves are found in Chhattisgarh, Madhya Pradesh, and Maharashtra. The region has 78.97 Bt (28.6 percent) of coal reserves with Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation 49 186 mines owned by Western Coalfields Ltd., South Eastern Coalfields Ltd., and others, and the region produced 223.631 Mt of coal in FY2010/11. • The southern region ranks third with 22.01 Bt (8 percent) of coal reserves found mainly in Andhra Pradesh. It has 67 mines owned by Singareni Collieries Company Ltd. and some others, and the region produced 51.333 Mt of coal in FY2010/11. Although pooling seems difficult in physical terms (because of logistical chal- lenges), pooling is much easier in pricing terms (for example, weighted average of import and domestic costs). However, the effects are likely to be highly unequal. Power generators—generally public sector generators—that currently have access to cheap domestic coal will suddenly face a hike in their input costs. And generators currently reliant on expensive, imported coal—generally private- sector generators—will benefit from a lower average price. Price pooling is a pure redistribution from the state sector (and eventually the consumer) in favor of the private sector power producer. One way of mitigating the across-the-board negative effect of pooling could be a requirement that power plants that actually received the physical supplies of blended imported and domestic coal (meaning that the plants did not suffer from logistics constraints) should pay the blended price. Other plants that were logistically unable to receive blended coal should not face the pooled price. Otherwise, as an extreme example, pit-head-based power plants that face no logistics costs and have no need for imported coal would be subsidizing plants that are entirely dependent on imported coal. Pit-based-plants would be forced to give up their cost advantage and pay a higher cost of fuel, so that the plants importing coal could pay a lower cost. Ninety percent of domestic coal supplies used in the power sector are ­ estimated to be consumed by plants that were commissioned before March 2009. Presumably these plants also supply the majority of electricity consumers, because only a handful of plants were commissioned in 2010 and 2011 (and almost none in 2012). Pooling would likely suggest fuel price rises (and tariff hikes) for the majority of power consumers. Some order of magnitude of the problem to be confronted is provided by the following statistics: • In August 2011, a study by Prayas Energy Group (2011) found approximately 590,000 MW of coal projects in the pipeline that had received or were expect- ing imminent environmental approval. However, since the release of the Prayas study, a major slowdown has occurred among planners of new coal capacity. • As of May 31, 2012, 41,650 MW of projects had been deferred (that is, progress was on hold), and an additional 22,420 MW of projects had been cancelled. The reasons for the slowdown were multiple: (a) dramatic rises in the cost of imported coal in 2012; (b) insufficiency in domestic coal output; (c) an Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 50 Private Sector Participation in Thermal Generation unfolding domestic crisis over the integrity of the coal allocation process, known as “Coalgate”; and (d) difficulties in obtaining financing. Nevertheless, 87,122 MW of projects were still under construction as of May 31, 2012, and an additional 68,200 MW of projects were in advanced development, having achieved most milestones (permits, water, land, coal, and financing). Allocation of the scarce low-cost domestic coal among multiple claimants is complicated. Avoiding difficult choices in doing so is impossible. Notes 2,184-MW 1. The three fast-track projects commissioned were phase 1 (740 MW) of the ­ combined cycle gas-based Dabhol Power Project in Maharashtra (phase 2 was 90 percent complete when Enron exited India); the 235-MW combined cycle gas- based Jegurupadu Power Project in Andhra Pradesh; and the 250-megawatt lignite- based Neyveli Thermal Power Station of ST-CMS Electric Company Private Ltd. in Tamil Nadu. 2. Appendix B contains a chronology of events in the Dabhol Power Project. 3. The cost-plus tariff is determined on the basis of total project capital cost and the norms specified in the terms and conditions of tariff. The tariff has two components: (a) annual fixed charges consisting of interest on loan, depreciation, operation and maintenance cost, return on equity, and interest on working capital; and (b) energy charges covering fuel cost based on plant-load factor norms. The anticipated lower tariffs as a result of efficient private generation actually were higher than for the ­ state-run plants because the costs were well above the benchmarks. 4. For example, procedures for ash utilization have undergone significant amendments over the years, with mandatory use of fly ash required in user industries within a given radius of power plants, permission for commercial sale of fly ash, and so forth. 5. The statutory advice is available at http://www.cercind.gov.in/2010/Advice_Gov​ timeframe_tariff_based_16-09-2010.pdf. For a detailed analysis, visit the CERC /­ ­website, http://www.cercind.gov.in/. 6. CIL introduced coal distribution through e-auction to provide access to coal for buyers who are unable to source coal through an available institutional mechanism ­ (Spot e-Auction) and for buyers who wish to have an assured supply over long periods (forward e-auction). For this purpose, 10 percent of the annual production of CIL is marked for e-auction. 7. Appendix D contains a detailed analysis of fuel risks. References Prayas Energy Group. 2011. “Thermal Power Plants on the Anvil: Implications and Need for Rationalisation.” Discussion Paper, Prayas Energy Group, Deccan Gymkhana, India. ———. 2013. “Black and Dirty: The Coal Challenge in India—Climate and Resources.” Prayas Energy Group, Pune, India, February. World Bank. 2012. “Analysis of Experience with Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector.” South Asia Regional Energy Studies Series. Prepared by Deloitte Touche Tohmatsu India Private Limited. World Bank, Washington, DC. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 CHAPTER 3 Private Sector Participation in Transmission Key Messages • The private sector has a limited presence in the Indian transmission sector, which is dominated by the national company PowerGrid Company of India Ltd. (PGCIL) for interstate lines, and by state-owned transmission companies for intrastate lines. • Apart from the joint venture (JV) approach, there are two optional modalities for a state seeking private investment in transmission on a competitive basis: the Ministry of Power (MOP) model and the Planning Commission (PC) model. • The MOP model is design-build-own-operate, and the line is owned by the private sector in perpetuity; the bid variable is the levelized tariff. Prior transmis- sion experience is not required. • The PC model is design-build-finance-operate-transfer (DBFOT) and includes a tariff that is specified by the state transmission utility, with a viability gap grant from the central government, which is the bidding variable (that is, reverse auction where the winner requires the least viability gap grant). Prior transmission experience is preferred. • For intrastate projects, a line built under the PC model has been commissioned in Haryana, whereas the line tendered out in Rajasthan under the MOP model has experienced delays on account of Rajasthan Electricity Regulatory Commission (RERC) setting aside the bid process initially, because it deemed that due process had not been followed under Section 63 of the Electricity Act of 2003. RERC revised its order in June 2012 and cleared the projects subse- quent to direction from the Appellate Tribunal for Electricity based on an appeal by the Bid Process Coordinator. • Some transmission investors’ projects are negatively affected by fuel shortages upstream at generation plants, which is causing uncertainties around the pos- sibility and timeframe for commissioning of such projects, thus threatening the feasibility of associated transmission evacuation projects. • Overall, it is too early to judge the experience of private sector investment in transmission, because most lines (other than JVs) have been operational for a short time or are not yet complete. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   51   52 Private Sector Participation in Transmission Chronology of Private Sector Participation in Transmission Given the scale of capacity additions planned in generation, particularly in the private sector, private participation in transmission is a logical corollary. With the success achieved in generation through ultra mega power plants (UMPPs), which were procured by using tariff-based competitive bidding, the central government envisaged attracting private investment for certain identified new transmission projects on a similar basis, in keeping with Section 63 of the Electricity Act of 2003. Guidelines were framed for interstate transmission projects, with the expectation that these could later be adopted by the state governments as well for their intrastate projects. Legal Framework for Transmission Business The Electricity Rules (Amendment) Act of 1998 for the first time authorized transmission to be a separate activity, making way for a transmission license, and brought in the legal framework enabling private sector participation (PSP). To pave the way for private sector investment, the central government issued ­ guidelines in January 2000 for two routes of PSP in transmission (figure 3.1): • Joint venture: The central transmission utility or the state transmission utility shall own a minimum of 26 percent of the equity in the JV, with the private participant holding the balance. • Independent power transmission company: Transmission projects are bid out under a competitive process with the private developer holding 100 percent of the equity in the project. Figure 3.1  Models for Private Sector Participation in Transmission • In collaboration with Joint CTU and STU venture route • CTU and STU to hold Models for PSP in minimun 26 percent transmission • 100 percent holding of IPTC private companies route • Bid out under a competitve framework Note: CTU = central transmission utility; IPTC = independent power transmission company; PSP = private sector participation; STU = state transmission utility. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Transmission 53 The Electricity Act of 2003 outlined provisions for a transmission license to be granted by the Central Electricity Regulatory Commission (CERC) for all interstate transmission projects and by the state electricity regulatory commis- sions for all intrastate transmission projects. Sections 61 and 62 of the Electricity Act of 2003 also provided that, where the tariff had been determined through a bidding process, the appropriate regulatory commission “shall adopt the tariff so determined.” The National Tariff Policy of 2006 refers to private investment in the trans- mission space through a competitive bidding process. To further the intent of the National Tariff Policy of 2006, the MOP, in exercise of its authority under Section 63 of the Electricity Act of 2003, issued guidelines for tariff-based com- petitive bidding in transmission, which included model bidding documents containing a model project agreement. The guidelines issued by MOP provide for ­ the appointment of a bid process coordinator by the central or state government to manage the bidding process. In October 2010, the PC, which had developed a series of model contracts for various public-private partnership (PPP) transac- tions, published its own model transmission agreement that was envisaged to be used for intrastate transmission projects. Both models (MOP and PC) have a similar scope, that is, attraction of private participation to transmission investment; however, the models vary in their approaches to achieving their objectives and in their perceptions of the transmis- sion sector. Whereas the MOP model considers private participation to be com- mercially viable, the PC model envisages the use of viability gap funding (VGF). The two models treat project ownership differently. The PC approach requires the title in the transmission assets to revert to the relevant utility at the end of the concession period. The MOP model does not provide any express provision for change in asset title beyond the concession period, that is, the ­ private investor continues to own the transmission assets in perpetuity. Besides the MOP and PC models, the JV route (which is a classic PPP arrange- ment) has also been explored. A few utilities have chosen the JV route with positive results. Figure 3.2 provides a summary of milestones for PPP in the ­ power transmission sector. Private Participation Experiences The first transmission line investment through private participation took place in 2006 as a JV between Tata Power and Power Grid Corporation of India Ltd. (POWERGRID) for implementing the Indo-Bhutan power transmission line (Powerlinks Transmission Limited). The project partner was chosen by the PGCIL, through an international competitive bidding route; although Powerlinks was very successful in meeting its objectives, PGCIL did not take up a second project under this mode. In yet another variation of the JV model, POWERGRID entered into several project-specific JVs with generation project developers for joint development of transmission evacuation projects associated with spe- cific generation projects. The latest development is in the form of tariff-based Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 54 Private Sector Participation in Transmission Figure 3.2  Private Sector Participation in Transmission 2010 Planning Commission issues model transmission agreement for intrastate transmission projects. 2005–06 2010 onward National Electricity Increase occurs in private Policy is issued, recognizing participation in transmission private participation in the 2006 projects (both intrastate and transmission space. Standard bidding documents are issued interstate). by the Ministry of Power. Frist transmission project under the joint venture route, “Powerlinks Transmission Ltd., ” starts commercial operation. 1998–2003 Electricity rules and the Electricity Act of 1998 recognize transmission as a distinct activity and paves way for private participation. competitive bidding for transmission projects, which has been made mandatory for interstate projects bid after January 5, 2011 and for intrastate projects after January 5, 2013. Projects Using the Joint Venture Approach A summary of the JVs entered into by PGCIL is outlined in table 3.1. The ownership stakes (percentage) outlined in table 3.1 are the ownership portion ­ controlled by PGCIL. In addition to the above six transmission projects under the JV route initiated by PGCIL for interstate transmission, state-level examples of JV partnerships between the public and private sectors also exist. Maharashtra State Transmission Company has developed two projects under the JV route, and its holdings in each of these are outlined in table 3.2. Projects Using the Independent Power Transmission Company Approach Pursuant to Section 5.1 of the National Tariff Policy, the IPTC route (that is, no public ownership and tariff-based competitive bidding) has also been tried in several interstate and intrastate transmission projects. Table 3.3 summarizes the outcomes of the bid process for interstate IPTC projects, showing the lowest levelized tariff quotes of the winning bidders. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Transmission 55 Table 3.1  Summary of Joint Ventures Entered Into by PGCIL Company Ownership as of March 31, 2011 (%) Powerlinks Transmission Ltd. 49.0 Torrent Power Grid Ltd. 26.0 Jaypee Powergrid Ltd. 26.0 Parbati Koldam Transmission Company Ltd. 26.0 Teestavalley Power Transmission Ltd. 26.0 North East Transmission Company Ltd. 24.9 Source: World Bank 2012. Note: PGCIL = PowerGrid Company of India Ltd. Table 3.2  Projects Developed under the Joint Venture Route by Maharashtra State Transmission Company Company Ownership (%) Jaigad Power TransCo Ltd. (with JSW Steel Ltd.) 26 Maharashtra Eastern Grid Power Transmission Company Ltd. 26 Source: World Bank 2012. Projects Using the Planning Commission Approach In 2010, the Haryana state utility company, Haryana Vidyut Prasaran Nigam Ltd. (HVPNL), used the PC’s model transmission agreement in the process of awarding an intrastate transmission project to Jhajjar KT Transco Private Ltd., an ­ India-based special purpose vehicle (SPV). The project involves approximately 100 kilometers of a 400-kilovolt (kV) direct-current transmission line, plus two 400 kV substations. Because the tariff levels were prescribed in the bidding documents, the main bidding parameter was the extent of VGF to be provided ­ to the SPV. At the end of the concession period, ownership of the transmission assets will revert to HVPNL. Current Models for Private Participation As indicated, two models exist for awarding projects to private sector partici- pants under a competitive bidding framework: • PC model (which has been used for the HVPNL intrastate project) • MOP model (all inter-state projects and two intra-state lines in Rajasthan) The PC has been responsible for furthering the concept of PPP infrastructure projects. In 2005, the Cabinet Committee on Economic Affairs (CCEA) issued detailed guidelines for the approval of PPP projects. The guidelines apply to all PPP projects in all sectors that are sponsored by the central government, central public sector undertakings (CPSUs), and statutory authorities or entities under their administrative control. This process requires projects to be approved by the Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 56 Private Sector Participation in Transmission Table 3.3  Summary of Bid Process Outcomes for Interstate IPTC Projects Levelized tariff Estimated project Project Award year Bidder (Rs, millions/year) cost (Rs, millions) East North Interconnection October 2006 Sterlite Technologies 1,188.00 8,000 Company Ltd. Lanco Deepak Consortium 1,676.90 Reliance Power Transmission Ltd. 2,400.00 Talcher II Transmission April 2010 Reliance Power Transmission Ltd. 1,440.00 14,000 Company L&T Transco Private Ltd. 2,094.00 Bidder (name unavailable) 2,510.00 Sterlite Technologies 2,279.90 North Karanpura May 2010 Reliance Power Transmission Ltd. 2,580.00 27,000 Transmission Company Lanco Deepak Consortium 3,831.00 L&T Transco Private Ltd. 4,432.00 Sterlite Technologies 5,376.00 Raichur Sholapur January 2011 Patel Engineering, Simplex 294.00 3,000 Transmission Company Infrastructure, and BS Ltd. Transcomm Lanco Infratech 315.90 Sterlite Transmission Projects Ltd. 367.20 Reliance Power Transmission Ltd. 479.90 Bhopal Dhule Transmission February 2011 Sterlite Transmission Projects 1,995.30 9,000 Company Ltd. Ashoka ICOMM Consortium 2,184.80 Lanco Infratech 2,448.90 Soma Enterprises 2,590.20 L&T Transco Private Ltd. 2,807.50 Nagapattinam Cuddalore March 2012 PGCIL 987.02 11,000 L2 1,529.44 L3 2,082.51 L4 2,085.92 L5 2,389.54 Source: World Bank 2012. Note: IPTC = independent power transmission company; L = lowest bidder; PGCIL = PowerGrid Company of India Ltd. Public Private Partnership Approval Committee (PPPAC), comprising secretaries of the Department of Economic Affairs (in the chair), PC, Department of Expenditure, and Department of Legal Affairs and the secretary of the depart- ment sponsoring the project. The MOP has maintained that projects under Section 63 of the Electricity Act of 2003 fall outside the requirements for being referred to the PPPAC. This posi- tion is based on two contentions. First, the MOP argues that the provisions under the Electricity Act of 2003 provide for specific guidelines to be issued by the central government for projects that are bid out under Section 63 of the Electricity Act of 2003 and that as long as projects are bid out in conformance with these guidelines, the projects need not follow the PPP guidelines outlined by the CCEA. Second, the MOP has also noted that the CCEA guidelines apply to projects sponsored by the central government, CPSUs, or statutory authorities Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Transmission 57 under the central government. In the case of projects bid out under Section 63, the concession agreements are signed with distribution utilities and these proj- ects are neither sponsored by the central government nor concessioned by any of the central government authorities or CPSUs. As such, the MOP has followed an approach independent of that specified by the CCEA as far as approval by the PPPAC is concerned. There are some similarities in the models. Under both models, the private investor arranges financial resources and undertakes construction, maintenance, and operation of the transmission line for an annual transmission charge paid by the beneficiary. This approach suggests that the private investor takes all project- related risks. However, in terms of eligibility requirements (qualifications of bidders), both models treat interested private investors differently. Whereas the ­ MOP model does not require experience in transmission projects, the PC model provides a benefit to private investors who have previous experience specifically in transmission. Once construction is complete, both models also require the private investor to be responsible for the operation and maintenance of the pro­ ject, though the private investor or a third party hired by the project developer can undertake this operation and maintenance. A comparison of the models is summarized in table 3.4. To date, attracting private investors for either model has not been difficult. The Rajasthan project used the MOP guidelines to award its IPTC transmission lines competitively, whereas the Haryana project used the PC approach. Although it is too early to tell whether there is any difference in performance or outcome based on the approach selected, significant procedural difficulties in the Rajasthan case have resulted in delays and unexpected costs for the developer. In contrast, the line constructed under the PC model has been successfully commis- sioned. However, two cases alone do not permit any conclusions to be drawn. The provision of central government VGF for projects adopting the PC model is an obvious attraction for state governments to opt for this route, because it results in a lower burden for the state government and the utilities. However, how long the central government VGF provision can continue is unclear, given that it is provided only for transmission projects, along the electricity value chain straddling generation to distribution. Transmission in general has traditionally been viewed as the least risky portion in the electricity value chain and has not struggled to recover its full costs from beneficiaries. The provision of VGF for transmission in isolation thus raises doubts on its continuity over a longer period, given in particular the demands for VGF from so many competing PPP projects across the country. At present, the primary drivers for private interest in bidding are affected by uncertainties in the generation sector; revenues for transmission become risky when the generation project, which will need the transmission line to evacuate power, itself faces delays or uncertainties. Also, only a limited number of projects are completed, and they have not been in operation sufficiently long for com- ment on their performance. Nevertheless, appendix E contains some lessons learned on some emerging issues for transmission investors. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 58 Private Sector Participation in Transmission Table 3.4  Comparison of MOP and PC Models Development model Parameter Planning commission Ministry of Power Regulatory approval Prior regulatory approval is required, because No prior approval is required if the MOP the model sets a prescribed tariff for the standard bidding documents have been transmission project. used. Viability gap funding The procuring utility provides support to VGF is not deemed necessary for the project. the construction and the operations and The MOP model requires all construction maintenance costs of the project through costs and the operation and maintenance viability gap funding (VGF). costs to be borne by the private developer. Asset ownership At the end of the concession period, the asset There is no provision for transfer of the asset. is transferred to the procuring utility. The The project company always owns the project is developed under the DBFOT asset. Project is developed under the BOOM (design-build-finance-operate-transfer) model. build-own-operate-manage). (­ Bidding criteria The bid parameter is the lowest financial grant Levelized annual transmission charges are (VGF) required by bidders to the project. quoted by the bidders to the project. This annual transmission charge is inclusive of project capital cost and the operation and maintenance cost for the project life. Bidders have the option of quoting the transmission charges on a split basis, reflecting variable and fixed costs. Eligibility A natural person, single entity, or group of A company or a consortium of companies can entities in consortium can bid for the project. bid for the project. Project cost The bid coordinator indicates estimated Project cost indication is not provided. project cost. Timeframe for 150 days 75 days completion of RFQ stage Number of bidders No more than six bidders are to be considered. There is no restriction on maximum number of bidders. Minimum number of bidders prescribed for ensuring competitiveness is two. Noncore revenue Revenue from real estate development or use Such provisions are not included. of transmission poles for advertisement is considered. Source: World Bank 2012. Note: MOP = Ministry of Power; PC = Planning Commission; RFQ = request for qualification. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 CHAPTER 4 Private Sector Participation in Distribution Key Messages • Financial weakness of the distribution segment has threatened private invest- ment in power in India along the entire value chain since the early 1990s, because distribution companies (discoms) have remained dependent on subsi- dies, which has, in turn, made generation investors nervous about discoms’ future ability to pay for power. • Poor operational efficiency, high levels of theft, and obsolete network equip- ment have led to average levels of aggregate technical and commercial (AT&C) losses of around 27 percent, among the highest in the world. This level means that nearly one-third of power purchased by the discom from the generation company is lost before revenues can be collected. • On average, an estimated one-third of customers do not pay (because of theft) and close to another one-third do not have to pay (because of free electricity provided to agriculture). Therefore, only an estimated one-third of customers are paying for the two-thirds of power that is supplied relative to what is pur- chased by the discom. • In this scenario, raising tariffs for full cost recovery from the few customers who are paying would be a politically sensitive and difficult approach. • Although a few discoms are performing well, the majority are in poor financial health; discoms in five states account for more than 60 percent of the total losses. Total financial losses by utilities are estimated at US$20 billion before subsidies; and after an allowance of US$7 billion in subsidies from state coffers, there is still a US$9 billion financial gap. • Commercial banks are already heavily exposed to the distribution sector; the Ministry of Power introduced a rating system for discoms in March 2013 to provide guidance to ­ commercial banks and to limit further exposure. • Distribution privatization occurred in Orissa and Delhi before passage of the Electricity Act of 2003. Subsequently, private involvement has been Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   59   60 Private Sector Participation in Distribution competitively invited through a distribution franchise arrangement instead of ­ outright privatization. • There has been rich experience with distribution franchising in urban and rural areas, and much has been learned despite a relatively limited number of attempts. Important lessons have been learned—particularly from failed urban distribution franchising efforts—and such lessons can be built into the future design of bids to attract private participation in distribution. • A further model, developed at the Planning Commission, is currently at the discussion stage. It would offer viability gap funding to a competitively selected concessionaire, with exclusive use of the distribution network for 25 years, appropriate incentives and penalties, and recognition of two categories of customers (open access and regulated). ­ Distribution Performance and Chronology of Private Sector Participation in Distribution Starting with the reforms in the 1990s, through to the latter half of the 11th Five- Year Plan (2007–12), the weak financial performance of the distribution segment in India has threatened repeatedly to derail private sector investments across the entire value chain. The distribution segment is the intake point for revenues from customers; it must be used to cover costs and provide a return on investment to all parties in the value chain. Discoms pay to purchase bulk power and then sell it to retail customers. If discoms are unable to cover their costs, they must be granted subsidies to cover the gaps, and this practice is perceived as unsustainable in the long term (and therefore risky) by private investors and their lenders. Probably largely because of political interference from the state level, the distribution segment continues to remain in the stranglehold of state-owned utilities. Tepid attempts at introducing private participation through franchising have yielded modest results across the board, though the attempts have made important differences in some urban areas where they have been successfully introduced, because of political will. In any case, franchising has not yet been attempted on a scale that can have transformative effect. Because the introduc- tion of franchising automatically excludes the continued use of electricity as a tool of political patronage within the franchise area, there is a strong connection between the political will to reform the sector and the introduction of a com- petitively awarded distribution franchise. The most acute problem facing the Indian power sector is the weakening finances of distribution utilities, particularly in the larger states,1 and the widen- ing gap between their average tariff to end users and their cost of supply. The key causes of this problem are as follows: • Nonapproval of expenses by state regulators because of shortfalls by utilities in achieving efficiency targets • Populist and politically influenced tariff determination (some states have gone without tariff revisions for years) Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 61 • An inability by utilities to collect the full amount of revenues that are owed to them, because of commercial inefficiencies (that is, even when the tariff is too low, utilities cannot manage to collect all revenues they are entitled to collect at that low tariff) • Inability of utilities to incur necessary capital investments for efficiency improvement and loss reduction as a result of poor financial health In combination, these factors have produced a vicious cycle of financial decline. With increasing costs of power and continued poor operational efficiencies, the accumulated financial losses of distribution utilities have been on the rise since fiscal year (FY) 2005/06 and had already reached Rs 928 billion (US$15 billion) by FY2011/12 (without considering subsidies). By FY2011/12, the accumulated losses had crossed more than Rs 1,000 billion (US$16 billion). Also, as can be seen in figure 4.1, the gap between the average cost of supply and Figure 4.1  Average Cost of Supply and Average Revenue Realization per Unit Sold a. Aggregate losses of utilities 0 –10 Rs 1,000 (billions) –20 –30 –40 –50 –60 –70 FY05 FY06 FY07 FY08 FY09 FY10 Loss (subsidy received basis) Loss (w/o subsidy) b. Cost of supply versus realization (paise/unit) 400 100 350 90 80 300 70 250 60 200 50 150 40 30 100 20 50 10 0 0 FY05 FY06 FY07 FY08 FY09 FY10 Fiscal year CoS Realization Gap Source: Power Finance Corporation Ltd. 2013. Note: CoS = cost of supply; FY = fiscal year. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 62 Private Sector Participation in Distribution the average revenue realization per unit sold at the national level had worsened to 107 paise (US$1.73 cents) per unit (from a low of 37 paise [US$0.60 cents] per unit over the corresponding period). Such an increase in the per-unit revenue realization gap for distribution utilities is mainly attributable to continued high technical and nontechnical (AT&C) losses, an increase in costs (especially power purchase costs), and noncommensurate adjustments in tariffs. The increase in costs was primarily led by the sharp increase in the price of fuel for generation toward the end of the previous decade. The Central Electricity Regulatory Commission has approved a substantial increase in wholesale tariffs for central generation plants for the period 2009–14. The second important rea- son for the sharp increase in costs is the revision of pay for all government (and government enterprise) employees, in accordance with the recommendations of the Sixth Pay Commission. Although passing on the increased costs for the generation and transmission utilities to the distribution utilities has been easier ­ because of the lower sensitivities involved (that is, all public agencies charging each other a higher price), the tariff for the distribution segment where all costs converge—and must be recovered from the end users—has not been revised ­ commensurately, mainly because of political pressures. This situation has led to exponential growth in losses for the distribution utility. There is a valid reason, other than political pressures, for distribution utilities to hesitate about approaching the regulator for permission to increase tariffs. One may well ask why the burden for high levels of inefficiency and losses should be borne by the end users. Conversely, if a utility acknowledges that it loses about one-third of the power purchased on the way to delivering it to the final customer, how can anyone be sure that a higher price paid by the c ­ ustomer would not lead to bigger governance problems—that is, to more of the customer’s money finding its way into the leak? Serious distribution reforms resulting in improved commer- cial and operational performance, and higher technical efficiency (loss reduction), should be implemented at once, rather than allowing distribution utilities to con- sume ever higher subsidies from state coffers to ­ balance their books. However, despite the worsening financial situation of the distribution utilities, distribution reforms have taken a back seat in several states. Most state governments are reluc- tant to permit tariff revisions and are also unable to enforce sustainable efficiency improvements under government ownership in situations where performance and remunerations have traditionally not been linked. The economic success of India and the associated buoyancy in the fiscal condi- tion of many of its states during the latter part of the 10th Five-Year Plan (2002–07) and the early part of the 11th Five-Year Plan (2007–12) made it pos- sible for state governments to sustain higher levels of financial (subsidy as well as equity) support to the utilities. This support, along with high levels of financial support under the Accelerated Power Development and Reforms Programme (APDRP) and Restructured APDRP (R-APDRP) from the central government, contributed to state governments and utilities postponing or backtracking on essential bold and radical reform measures. As a result, India is faced with a veri- table “lost decade” of distribution reforms during which inefficiencies have Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 63 become chronic and private participation in this segment has been overlooked in all but a few cases of distribution franchisees (DFs) over the past 10 years.2 The central government continued the APDRP program over the 11th Five- Year Plan period in the form of the R-APDRP initiative by making provisions for capital investment–led efficiency improvements in the power distribution segment with a total outlay of more than Rs 550 billion (US$8.88 billion). R-APDRP consists of two main parts. Part A focuses on the introduction of infor- mation technology initiatives and creation of reliable baseline data for measuring efficiency improvements. Part B focuses on actual network interventions to bring in the targeted efficiency improvements. R-APDRP projects undertaken by the various state utilities are mostly in the part A stage at present. The weak institu- tional endowment of distribution utilities in several states imposes constraints on the efficacy of the program. Private distribution utilities (such as North Delhi Power Ltd., Brihanmumbai State Electricity Supply (BSES) Rajdhani Power Ltd., BSES Yamuna Power Ltd., Calcutta Electric Supply Corporation, Tata Power Company Ltd., and Brihanmumbai State Electricity Supply, which have much better institutional capacity and incentives) in places such as Delhi, Kolkata, and Bhiwandi are not covered under the R-APDRP program. Additionally, the central government initiated an ambitious program for achieving 100 percent village electrification under the Rajiv Gandhi Grameen Vidyutikaran Yojana (RGGVY) scheme, launched in April 2005, with a revised total outlay of Rs 439.54 billion (US$7.1 billion) spread over the 10th and 11th Five-Year Plan periods. Under this program, 112,228 villages and 27,755,314 households have been electrified to date—the grid has reached the villages. The program requires that at least 10 percent of the households in a village have access to an electricity connection, but it does not specify how many hours a day power must be available. In fact, the central government considers that its respon- sibility is to extend the grid, while noting that the states’ responsibility is to supply power to that grid (but because of severe power shortages at the state level, those rural connections remain unenergized for large periods of time). Yet the sudden increase in access to electricity connections in the rural areas, owing to the large- scale electrification (capital expenditure) undertaken as a part of the RGGVY scheme, has led to rapid growth in the number of subsidized consumers in several states. This growth has added further to the immediate need for ­ revenue enhance- ment or subsidy support mechanisms for the state distribution companies. Private participation in distribution has long been considered one of the most effective solutions to resolving the efficiency issues in distribution. The private distribution utilities in Kolkata, Mumbai, Surat, and Ahmedabad, (which have been in private hands since before Indian independence and are hence referred to as the legacy private companies), with their exemplary performance in efficiency and customer service measures, have been recognized as obvious examples of private efficiencies in the Indian environment. In this context, despite immense opposition from employees and unions and certain sections of the political community, privatization of power distribution was taken forward first in Orissa ­ and then in Delhi.3 The outcomes of the privatization experience (as set out Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 64 Private Sector Participation in Distribution Figure 4.2  Outcomes of the Privatization Experience Prereform 1997 2002 2007 2009 2010–11 2011–12 Ujjain, Sagar, Gwalior in MP, CESC, AECL, Nagpur, Orissa Delhi Bhiwandi and Kanpur and Jamshedpu, SECL, BSES, Aurangabad, privatization privatization Nagpur DFs Agra DFs and NPC, TPC and Jalgaon DF Ranchi in Jharkhand Spanco Ltd., GTL Essel Infra Bhiwandi was Infrastructure Projects Ltd., Recently, UPPCL Orissa was the the first DF Ltd., and declared winner Private utilities awarded its first state to to be Crompton for 3 DF areas have been Delhi privatized Kanpur and privatize awarded in Greaves Ltd. in MP, Ranchi, existence even its distribution Agra circle to the distribution January 2007. awarded and before the utilities in 2002. TPC; TPC started utilities in Nagpur DF bid Nagpur, Jamshedpur reforms. operation postreform era. process was Aurangabad, awarded to in Agra. scraped. and CESC and Jalgaon. Tata Power. Note: AECL = Ahmedabad Electricity Company Ltd.; BSES = Brihanmumbai State Electricity Supply; CESC = Calcutta Electric Supply Corporation; DF = distribution franchisee; NPC = Noida Power Company; SECL = Surat Electricity Company Ltd.; TPC = Tata Power Company; UPPCL = Uttar Pradesh Power Corporation Ltd. in figure 4.2) have been mixed, and other state governments have lacked the political will to pursue an ownership transition from the public sector to the pri- vate sector systematically, despite the well-known problems of the status quo. In view of the reluctance of states to proceed with outright privatization, following the experiences of Orissa and Delhi, another approach was needed ­ to secure private involvement in distribution. With the promulgation of the Electricity Act of 2003, the legitimacy of the distribution franchisee (DF) con- cept became well established, because the act provided for appointment of any person to undertake distribution and supply on behalf of the licensee (that is, the state utility) within the licensee’s area of supply. Maharashtra, driven by the distribution losses being suffered in certain areas of the state, was the first to test the input-based franchisee approach in the Bhiwandi area. The success of this experience made Bhiwandi a good example for DFs. Unfortunately though, few distribution franchises have been pursued subsequently. Although Bhiwandi was a success, there were several failures too, highlighting the urgent need for a set of standardized approaches to franchisees based on the insights and lessons learned from these examples. Comparative Highlights of the Privatization Experience of Orissa and Delhi The Orissa and Delhi experiences of privatization for ailing discoms resulted in different outcomes and have been extensively cited as examples both for and against privatization in recent times (see appendix B for more information and volume 2 for a full case study of each). Unlike private participation in generation or transmission, which are typically greenfield ventures, private participation in Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 65 distribution involves taking over an existing system of networks, employees and customers (“brownfield”), and is therefore vastly more complex and sensitive. The expectations of existing customers must be managed, as well as those of existing workers in the utilities who perceive that they may be displaced by the new arrangements (and will therefore resist). The investors may require some initial hand-holding to prevent disruptions to either set of stakeholders that will create difficulties. Specifically, the Orissa privatization experience has been widely studied4 and compared and contrasted with Delhi’s experience. Some of the key lessons are as follows: • Private participation in an operating business, like distribution, requires all key public sector stakeholders to be aligned on the key expectations and risk- sharing arrangements with the private party. In Orissa, there was a wide disconnect between, on the one hand, the expectations of the regulator (the ­ Orissa Electricity Regulatory Commission) and, on the other hand, the priva- tized distribution utilities (and, presumably, the state government, which managed the privatization process). ­ • The crucial period in a private participation process is the first few years immediately following handover to the new owner. Recognizing the complex- ity of the distribution business, both the state government and the regulator need to demonstrate flexibility and should be ready to provide all possible support to the private party to bring about changes, which have not been pos- sible for years under public ownership or control. This point underscores the importance of transition period support, in the form of a safety net from the state government and the ability of the regulator to recognize realities on the ground and be flexible in adjusting the tariff regime. • The Orissa privatization experience also outlines the need to structure as many controllable parameters up front as part of the transaction and through a bid- ding process, rather than leaving that aspect to the discretion of the regulator or the state government. The Delhi privatization process incorporated this lesson. • Finally, for distribution, which is a public utility business, transaction frame- works need to provide for alternatives to replace an operator, in case the pri- vate operator should fail to discharge its duties or fail to meet the commitments integral to its bid. This was not present in the Orissa case, and the government had to take over operation of one of the discoms following privatization, upon the departure of the private operator. Orissa versus Delhi Privatization Experience The key benefit for the Delhi government when it undertook the electricity sec- tor reforms was the live example of Orissa, which showed clearly that mere transfer of ownership to a private party was no guarantee for efficiency improve- ments and improved customer service levels. Nevertheless, it is essential to Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 66 Private Sector Participation in Distribution Table 4.1  Outcomes and the Process Followed by Delhi and Orissa Parameters Delhi Orissa Targets Yearly loss reduction targets were provided. No targets were provided. Bid parameter Yearly AT&C loss reductions were for Highest bid was for 51 percent equity. five-year period. Financial Clean balance sheets were provided to Clean balance sheets were provided to restructuring new entities. new entities. Transition Government provided subsidy for power Government did not provide any support purchase for five years. subsidy post-privatization. Pre-privatization Government retained all pre-privatization Pre-restructuring liabilities were held liabilities liabilities. back in Gridco. Tariff Setting Government made the bid conditions The Orissa Electricity Regulatory binding on the regulator, the Delhi Commission set tariffs based on Electricity Regulatory Commission, which aggressive loss reduction targets. determined the tariff as per regulations. Return Regulated return of 16 percent return on Regulated return on equity is 16 percent equity was subject to achieving loss on all investment. Transition to reduction target. Transition to MYT multiyear tariff regime occurred began after the end of the five-year from 2004 onward. period. Outcome The loss level was reduced considerably, One investor in the four privatized with high consumer satisfaction. distribution companies abandoned it after two years. The loss level continues to be high, with low consumer satisfaction. Source: Deloitte research. Note: AT&C = aggregate technical and commercial; MYT = multiyear tariff. understand the difference in terms of the outcomes and the process followed in these two cases for any future initiatives (as outlined in table 4.1), because the outright privatization model has not been subsequently attempted in India. What Occurs Next on Distribution Reforms? There have been no privatizations since those in Orissa and Delhi, and there has been limited distribution reform overall since passage of the Electricity Act of 2003. Yet utility finances have continued to worsen considerably to a level that has been characterized at times as India’s sub-prime crisis. Especially in the past three to four years, the problem has attained mammoth proportions with the annual financial gap now at approximately US$16 billion prior to subsidies (Ghosh, Majumdar, and Kadam 2012). Even after one considers subsidies paid out to utilities from the state exchequer (most often not paid on time), the defi- cits are approximately US$7 billion per annum. For an overall perspective, the financial deficits of the sector before subsidies are equal to more than half the aggregated annual budgets of the states of Uttar Pradesh, Maharashtra, Rajasthan, Madhya Pradesh, and Bihar, five of India’s most populous states. The poor shape of distribution finances has several adverse effects. At the first level, it affects the utilities that are unable to pay for their costs and to make the investments that are required to serve customers. Utilities are also not able to pay Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 67 for power purchases even when electricity is available in the markets (preferring to resort to power cuts instead), resulting in poor quality of supply on the one hand and inadequate capacity utilization on the other in generating stations. This poor supply and utilization further affect sector finances. The distribution utility bailout of October 2012 (Financial Restructuring Scheme of State Distribution Companies) is unlikely to resolve the long-term fundamentals of the liquidity crisis in the power sector. Although the states of Tamil Nadu, Rajasthan, Haryana, Uttar Pradesh, Jharkhand, Bihar, and Andhra Pradesh are likely to benefit under the scheme, at best, the bailout will benefit private investors’ risk perceptions temporarily by reducing the debt loads of the utilities in the short term and improving cash flows. However, without funda- mental changes in how business is done, it is likely to be only a matter of time before another bailout is required. Distribution franchising seems to be the only innovation in distribution that seeks private sector involvement in an area that has substantially remained in the purview of state distribution utilities. However, the franchise approach has sig- nificant drawbacks, some of which are attributable to the fact that the franchisees are not license holders. Instead, the licenses remain with the state utility compa- nies, which grant the franchises on a competitive basis (just as the private genera- tors are competitively selected by the distribution utilities acting in their capacity as power procurers). This book has devoted the bulk of its analysis to DF models because distribu- tion is the cutting-edge segment of the power sector value chain for which the most work is still needed to improve overall performance. In view of the resis- tance by state authorities to wider adoption of outright privatization, it is impor- tant to ensure maximum value addition through the DF approach. There have been some successes and failures, all of which contain important lessons for suc- cessive rounds of bidding for franchisees. There are still far too few success stories of distribution franchising, and the author believes that the key to improving sector performance lies in creating more and better franchise agreements. The remainder of this chapter on distribution is, therefore, devoted to a detailed pre- sentation and analysis of DF models for rural and urban areas. DF Models Although the urban Bhiwandi transaction has become the byword for this model (see appendix H, box H.1), one must recall that the DF model found its genesis in India in the context of improving access to electricity for rural communities. Rural areas were the focal point for attracting private parties, because the utility had limited reach in this area. It was thus envisaged that local community orga- nizations (considered to fit the description of private parties) could take respon- sibility for small segments of the distribution system in rural or remote areas and carry out activities such as metering, billing, collection, and so forth. The distribu- tion licensee would remain the state distribution utility, and the franchisee would essentially serve as the subcontractor to the licensee. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 68 Private Sector Participation in Distribution Table 4.2  Selected Provisions of the Electricity Act of 2003 Provision Extract from Electricity Act of 2003 Section 14 (c) “Provided also that in a case where a distribution licensee proposes to undertake distribution of electricity for a specified area within his area of supply through another person, that person shall not be required to obtain any separate licensee from the concerned State Commission and such distribution licensee shall be responsible for distribution of electricity in his area of supply” Section 2 (27) “Franchisee means a [person] authorized by a distribution licensee to distribute electricity on its behalf in a particular area within his area of supply” Source: Ministry of Power, Government of India, New Delhi, http://www.cea.nic.in/reports/electricity_act2003.pdf. The relevant provisions of the Electricity Act of 2003 (table 4.2) set out the legal position of DFs. The definition of franchisee under the act provides a con- siderable amount of flexibility in the choice of the scope of the activities that may be undertaken by the franchisee. Therefore, the range of services that can be delegated by the licensee to the franchisee can vary from any single role (for example, collection) to the full range of distribution activities in any particular area. Notwithstanding the extent of delegation of scope to the franchisee, the distribution licensee remains completely responsible to the state regulatory com- mission in the exercise of its duties and obligations for its entire license area of supply. There is no discrimination between rural and urban franchisees with respect to the definition in the Electricity Act of 2003. However, different models are emerging, according to their suitability to a particular area (rural or urban) and also depending on the relative willingness of distribution utilities across the coun- try to engage with franchisees. The basic different types of models being deployed in rural and urban areas are elaborated here. Rural Distribution Franchisee Models A decisive push toward rural franchisees was achieved because of the precondi- tion in the RGGVY (centrally funded rural electrification) scheme that defines a franchisee as an entity empowered by the state either to develop or operate a generation and distribution system or to be ready to distribute electricity within an identified contiguous area for a prescribed duration and collect revenues directly from consumers. The basic objective of such franchisees is to ensure revenue sustainability and to help state utilities with the management of rural distribution networks that have significantly expanded under the RGGVY scheme (although most often there is insufficient power in the system to supply the networks that have been created in rural areas). The rural areas, with characteristics that differ from those of the urban areas (which have high consumer-load density), call for a differentiated franchisee model. The consumer mix in rural areas is generally dominated by low-income households with nominal amounts of power consumption (because of a lack of appliances that require electricity). The utility’s reach and physical presence in rural areas, especially in newly expanding networks, is limited, and billing and Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 69 collection are therefore often neglected. In many cases, state-owned utilities are content to recover only the government subsidy corresponding to their sale of electricity to subsidized consumers in rural areas, whereas the amount recover- able from consumers themselves is not acted upon because of high transaction costs. Therefore, the concept of franchisees is, in fact, welcomed by utilities in rural areas. The approach creates scope for the involvement of village- or town- level intermediaries as partners in metering, billing, and collection and also activi- ties related to operation and maintenance (O&M) in which the required numbers of skilled workers are available. In general, the lack of the requisite skill sets and financial capability at the rural or village level is a constraint that sharply limits the range of activities that can be outsourced by the state-owned utilities to rural franchisees. For example, it may not be possible for village- or panchayat-level personnel to undertake O&M and capital expenditure activities. However, those personnel can readily undertake revenue cycle management activities, such as new consumer registra- tion, meter reading, billing, collections, and disconnections and reconnections. Also, although some states have vibrant community-based structures such as panchayati raj (local self-government) and women’s self-help groups, other states are fairly weak in this regard, leading to variations in DFs across states. Under the types of rural franchisee models that are being deployed across states, the range of activities varies from revenue collection to entire revenue cycle management to revenue cycle management plus O&M activities. Table 4.3 provides a comparison of the key characteristics of the different rural franchisee models on key parameters. Table 4.3  Key Characteristics of the Different Rural Franchisee Models Model Responsibility Revenue or business model Remarks Pure collection • Revenue collections, • Margin or percentage on • Franchisee focuses franchisee and disconnections and collections on achievement of primarily on collection reconnections target efficiency. • Incentive or disincentive for over- or underachievement Revenue • Revenue cycle management: • Margin or percentage on • Franchisee is not a partner collection– billing, revenue collections, collections on achievement in T&D loss reduction. based and disconnections and of target • Franchisee focuses franchisee reconnections • Incentive or disincentive for primarily on collection • Handling of complaints over- or underachievement efficiency. • New connections and disconnections Input-based • Revenue cycle management: • Supplied input energy • Franchisee is a partner in franchisee billing, revenue collections, measured at 11-kilovolt feeder AT&C loss reduction. and disconnections and level or DT level reconnections • Franchisee payment of utility at • Handling of complaints a prefixed tariff on energy input • New connections and disconnections table continues next page Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 70 Private Sector Participation in Distribution Table 4.3  Key Characteristics of the Different Rural Franchisee Models (continued) Model Responsibility Revenue or business model Remarks O&M • Revenue cycle management: • Supplied input energy • Franchisee is a partner in franchisee billing, revenue collections, measured at 11-kilovolt feeder AT&C loss reduction. and disconnections and level or DT level • Franchisee also contributes reconnections • Franchisee payment of utility at to reliability of power • Handling of complaints. a prefixed tariff on energy input supply. • New connections and disconnections. • O&M of downstream network Rural electric • Society funding, ownership, and • Supplied input energy • State authorization is co-operative operation of distribution system measured at 11-kilovolt feeder usually needed. franchisee • All consumer-related activities level or DT level • Franchisee is responsible • Franchisee payment of utility at for all facets of distribution a prefixed tariff on energy input in the given area. Distributed • Franchisee funding, ownership, • Franchisee operation of • Model is mostly used in generation- and operation of generation and independent business model areas that are far from grids based distribution system in remote with no transaction taking and lack feasible or viable franchisee areas not connected by grid place with the incumbent options for connection. • All consumer-related activities distribution licensee Source: Deloitte research. Note: AT&C = aggregate technical and commercial; DT = distribution transformer; O&M = operation and maintenance; T&D = transmission and distribution. Urban Distribution Franchisee Models After the success of the Bhiwandi input-based urban DF model, several states have commenced adoption of similar models. Franchises in Agra and Kanpur in Uttar Pradesh and in Nagpur, Aurangabad, and Jalgaon in Maharashtra have already been awarded to successful bidders, although it is too early to comment on the effectiveness of any of these.5 Several other states are attempting to imple- ment similar DF models in identified areas or circles. The urban areas are distinguished from the rural ones by their significantly higher load and network density and the mix of high-consumption, high-tariff consumers. The urban areas are more likely to be financially viable and to attract highly capable private parties, and therefore structuring full-service franchisees in these urban areas becomes feasible. Bhiwandi in particular was characterized by a predominantly industrial load (power looms), representing a more commer- cially viable type of customer base than the typical urban mix of predominantly residential customers. This commercial and industrial load in Bhiwandi, repre- senting customers undertaking productive end-uses with the energy input, may be a partial explanation for the success of this initial urban franchisee experiment. An urban full-service franchisee takes over all responsibilities of the distribu- tion licensee in a given area and retains the revenue that it collects from the consumers in the area. The franchisee pays for the energy input into the area at a tariff that is normally determined through a competitive bidding process (the highest bidder for energy procured from the utility is selected as the franchisee). Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 71 Figure 4.3  The Roles and Responsibilities of the Franchisee and the Business Model Licensee revenues and benefits Licensee responsibilities • Revenue security at input rate • Guaranteed energy input to the determined through bidding franchisee area • AT&C loss reduction • Authorization to the franchisee to Distribution licensee perform its duties • Avoided O&M costs • Avoided capital expenditure • Pass through and consideration toward past assets Licensee revenues and benefits Licensee responsibilities • Revenue from sale of power at • Entire consumer-related activities: approved tariff metering, billing, collection, • Miscellaneous charges recovered complaint management from consumers Distribution franchisee • Reduction of AT&C losses; • Incentive on arrears collection • Capital expenditure • Residual value of assets added at • Network O&M activities the end of contract period • Compliance to standards of performance Note: AT&C = aggregate technical and commercial; O&M = operation and maintenance. The roles and responsibilities of the franchisee and the business model are shown in figure 4.3. In the typical input-based urban DF model, the franchisee takes over the defined area of supply (including assets and consumers) and pays for the energy input into the franchisee’s area (which is electrically ring-fenced) and performs the entire gamut of activities ordinarily undertaken by the distribution licensee. Normally, the responsibilities of the franchisee include the following: • The franchisee undertakes the capital investment necessary to maintain the quality and reliability of power and to meet the expected growth in demand in the franchisee area on a proactive basis. • The franchisee is responsible for meeting AT&C loss reduction targets; there could be incentives and penalties built into the distribution franchisee agree- ment (DFA) with respect to achievement of set target levels. The faster the loss reduction targets are met, the earlier the franchisee can capture the sur- plus of revenues collected over and above the fixed amount to be paid for the energy input. There is accordingly an incentive for the franchisee to expedite loss reduction investments and capture the maximum surplus revenues. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 72 Private Sector Participation in Distribution • The franchisee undertakes O&M of the assets being taken over, although these assets continue to be owned by the distribution licensee. • The franchisee undertakes all customer-related activities such as metering, bill- ing, collection, disconnections and reconnections, and complaint management. • The franchisee may arrange for procurement of additional power to supply the consumers in its area (over and above what it is receiving from the utility) and recover revenues for this through reliability charges to customers who require the extra power, in accordance with conditions in the DFA and after due approval from the appropriate regulatory commission. The franchisee is allowed to retain the entire revenue collected from consum- ers in its area, after it has paid the utility for the input energy at the competitively determined price. Such revenues for the franchisee may include the following: • Revenue includes amounts billed to consumers against sale of power (billed at the same regulator-approved tariff that would have applied to the licensee). • Miscellaneous charges include meter rent charges, connection and disconnec- tion charges, fuse-off charges, call attendance charges, and so on. • There could also be a pass-through of the government subsidy provided for retail tariffs, if applicable (for example, if the government provides subsidies to the utility for serving certain customer categories). However, this aspect has been treated differently in franchisee models across states. • Incentives on collection of arrears that are still pending from late payments incurred during the prefranchise period, when power was supplied by the licensee, are included. A part, or all, of the amount collected may be retained by the franchisee depending on the conditions of the DFA. • The franchisee is compensated for the residual or depreciated value of the assets it has financed, at the end of the franchisee period when such assets are transferred to the licensee. • Electricity duty collected by the franchisee is to be passed on to the licensee, which in turn passes this duty on to the government body entitled to it. This approach may vary from one state to another. The yearly tariffs for energy input prices quoted by the selected DF at the time of bidding are duly indexed for any future tariff change because of tariff approvals by the respective state electricity regulatory commission (SERC) or change in consumer mix to ensure that the effect of the change is appropriately shared between the licensee and the franchisee. The formula to calculate the indexed input rate for any particular month is arrived at by multiplying the quoted rate for the year by the actual average tariff for the month and dividing it by the opening or base average tariff. Such an average tariff is also often called the average billing rate, and the practice differs across states. The responsibilities of the licensee normally include making available the guaranteed quantum of power to the franchisee’s area and providing authoriza- tion or assistance (clearances and approvals from local agencies) to the franchisee Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 73 as necessary for undertaking the activities entrusted to it. Such responsibilities depend on the DFA conditions. The competitive bidding process—with the selection of the bidder who quotes the highest rate for energy input into the electrically ring-fenced area for every year of the contract period—ensures that only bidders with the most aggressive or sharpest loss reduction trajectories emerge as successful. This approach passes on a significant portion of the benefits that may be achieved to the distribution licensee. The key benefits that may be reaped by the distribution licensees through franchising out appropriate areas to highly motivated and qualified private ­ parties include the following: • The licensee receives assured revenues at the quoted input rate into the franchisee area for the entire period. ­ • There are efficiency improvement initiatives and assured reduction of AT&C losses in the franchisee area by the franchisee, who is highly incentivized to make up-front investments in loss reduction in order to maintain his profitability. • The utility avoids the cost of capital expenditure in the franchisee’s area that is undertaken by the franchisee for the period of the DFA. • The utility avoids O&M expenses in the franchisee’s area, and such resources can be deployed in other areas to achieve better efficiency levels. • The utility is able to recover the outstanding past arrears for its period of sup- ply by offering an incentive to the franchisee, or the utility may sell its claims outright to the franchisee at the time of handing over. Box 4.1 summarizes the views of two expert panels on the way forward with distribution franchising. Planning Commission member B. K. Chaturvedi headed a subgroup to proceed with the public-private partnership (PPP) model that would enable limited recourse financing by financial institutions and viability gap funding support from the union government to mobilize the requisite volumes of investment. The Shunglu Committee favored the distribution franchising (DF) approach where the private party tasked with lowering AT&C losses would be selected based on a competitive bid price for input energy to be purchased from the discom. The PPP model would provide the requisite flexibility to the conces- sionaire to procure bulk power from the market at competitive prices. The PPP in distribution subgroup has recommended a 25-year concession period (possibly extended by another 10 years), separate tariffs for regulated and open-access con- sumers, and a billing and payment mechanism, besides a predetermined system of incentives and penalties on the key performance indicators, to ensure quality and reliability of supply by the concessionaire. According to the subgroup, neither privatization (the Delhi model) nor the distribution franchisee model would deliver the desired outcome. Instead, a well-formulated PPP model could be the way forward. Moreover, the model would be consistent with the Electricity Act of 2003, which requires distribution to be a licensed business under the regulatory Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 74 Private Sector Participation in Distribution Box 4.1  Shunglu Committee versus B. K. Chaturvedi Report A task force was set up by the Planning Commission to examine and evolve the framework for the distribution franchisee (DF) and public-private partnership (PPP) models. The Chaturvedi panel favored the PPP model over the DF model or privatization model of Delhi for private participation in the power distribution sector (Planning Commission 2011, paras. 2.2 and 2.3). The Chaturvedi panel pointed out the following: • The DF model is incapable of bringing adequate capital investments. • The DF model would not ensure quality and quantity of supply, competition, and open access. • The DF model will not ensure financial stability of the sector. • The franchisee is not required to obtain a distribution license and is hence outside of the purview of a state electricity regulatory commission (SERC). • The DF model suffers from legal issues that restrict the purchase of power from the market. The Chaturvedi panel recommended a PPP model in the distribution of electricity as c ­ onsistent with the Electricity Act of 2003 and a way forward. The panel suggested that a con- cessionaire, selected through competitive bidding, would be responsible for maintenance, operation, and upgrading of the distribution network. The panel recommended enough flex- ibility to the concessionaire to procure bulk power from the market at competitive prices. The panel also observed that the PPP model would enable limited resource funding by financial institutions and viability gap funding support from the government. The Shunglu Committee, which came out with its report after the Chaturvedi report, contested the Chaturvedi claim and questioned the financial and administrative viability ­ of the PPP model (Shunglu Committee 2011, paras. 3.4.7 and 3.4.8). The Shunglu Committee supported the DF model. The committee found the following: • The success and the legality of the DF model are proved in Bhiwandi and the Bombay High Court order, respectively. • Franchisees are accountable to licensees who are, in turn, accountable to the SERCs. • Torrent Power has completed Rs 1 billion (US$16.13 million) of capital expenditure (capex) in Bhiwandi every year; hence, the DF is capable of completing capex. • The PPP model would cause tariff anomalies in the states and reduce the number of partici- pating companies, which would further hinder competitive bidding and necessitate capital support from the government. • The PPP model would complicate sharing of assets between the government and the ­ private player. Meanwhile, many states such as Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka, and Maharashtra have objected to the suggestions of the Chaturvedi panel, while citing successful implementation of the DF model in Bhiwandi. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 75 oversight of the SERC for ensuring consumer protection. The concessionaire would be given the exclusive use of the distribution assets, but the ownership of the assets would remain with the government. The nature and extent of the use of distribution assets would be regulated in accordance with the concession agree- ment and the applicable laws. Thus, the licensee would be responsible only for activities under its control: (a) transmission and distribution (T&D) losses and efficiency in carrying current from substation to consumer and (b) billing and collecting for the energy sold. According to the subgroup, the concession agree- ment will specify the existing power purchase agreements (PPAs) that will be transferred to the concessionaire for the supply of electricity to the regulated consumers. The concessionaire would also be free to procure additional power by entering into new PPAs or making other arrangements with the approval of the SERC with regard to supplies to the regulated consumers. Further, the tariff to be charged by a distribution licensee from all regulated consumers (including all consumers other than open-access consumers) would consist of the tariff for sup- ply of electricity and a fixed charge reflecting the wheeling or distribution charge. In the case of open-access consumers, the supply tariff would have to be deter- mined bilaterally between the suppliers and the consumers in accordance with Section 49 of the Electricity Act of 2003. However, the wheeling charge for open- access consumers would be at par with the wheeling or distribution charge pay- able by regulated consumers in accordance with the provisions of the concession agreement. The subgroup has submitted its report to the Planning Commission. The previous sections have elaborated on the definitions and modalities of DFs in rural and urban settings. What has been the actual experience on the ground? The following sections summarize the short experience so far. Review of Rural Franchisee Experiences Several states have implemented rural DFs in connection with RGGVY schemes. However, the extent of involvement of private players is very limited in such arrangements. In addition, most DFs involve routine outsourcing with only cer- tain activities or responsibilities transferred to the franchisee (usually no capital investment because of the weak financial standing of parties who come forward to participate in rural franchises). More than 37,000 rural franchisees are in operation, covering more than 216,000 villages across 18 states in the country. Information regarding the nature of franchisees and the number of franchisees appointed and the villages covered across states as of March 31, 2012, is summarized in table 4.4. The data show that most of the rural franchises are collection franchises in which the franchisee either takes a portion or percentage of the revenue collec- tions achieved or earns an incentive amounting to a predetermined collection efficiency target, depending on the contract. These collection franchisee con- tracts are usually annual contracts with flexibility to grant extensions. In addition to the collection franchises, there is also a group of input-based franchises in which the franchisee purchases the energy that is input into its area, Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 76 Private Sector Participation in Distribution Table 4.4  Nature of Franchisees and Number of Franchisees Appointed and Villages Covered across 18 States as of March 31, 2012 State Nature of contract Number of franchisees Number of villages covered Andhra Pradesh Revenue collection 3,647 7,442 Assam Input-based 978 3,914 Bihar Input-based 19 723 Chhattisgarh Revenue collection 40 6,743 Gujarat Revenue collection 16,658 17,985 Haryana Revenue collection 18 5,290 Himachal Pradesh Revenue collection 102 7,554 Karnataka Revenue collection 12,261 24,310 Madhya Pradesh Revenue collection 411 654 Maharashtra Revenue collection 1,346 40,292 Meghalaya Revenue collection 9 66 Nagaland Input-based 610 683 Orissa Revenue collection 48 17,165 Rajasthan Revenue collection 66 31,742 Tripura Revenue collection 69 787 Uttar Pradesh Revenue collection 665 27,388 Uttarakhand Revenue collection 22 10,514 West Bengal Revenue collection 645 12,803 Total 37,614 216,055 Source: Ministry of Power, Government of India. and then resells that energy to consumers (similar to the input-based model used for some urban distribution franchises). In total, 1,607 of the 37,614 rural fran- chises are input-based. The most notable and tested version for the rural input-based approach is the single-point power supply (SPPS) scheme that is referred to in the Rural Electrification Policy of 2005. The SPPS franchisees have traditionally been appointed on a first-come, first-served basis (rather than the competitively selected urban input-based franchisees who must bid for the price that will be paid to the utility for the power supplied). The rural SPPS franchisee sells power to consumers at tariffs approved by the regulator and pays a fixed fee to the distribution licensee. This fee is worked out by the licensee—10 percent of low- voltage line losses, a commission or profit of 15 percent for the franchisee, and a low-voltage line maintenance allowance of 2 percent. Additionally, the licensee offers the franchisee an incentive of 2 percent on timely payment of its bills and a cash incentive (Rs 100 [US$1.60]) per new connection issued through the franchisee. The difference in treatment for urban and rural franchisees is quite clearly based on the number of likely interested private parties in each case, and this number is, in turn, a function of how potentially lucrative the business pros- pects are in rural areas versus urban areas. Rural franchise models have been helpful to the distribution licensees in many states in substantially improving the revenue collections achieved from the rural Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 77 areas that were traditionally ignored by the licensees. Therefore, in view of the significant increase in rural electrification being achieved under the RGGVY projects across the country, it has become imperative for licensees to increase their revenue collection focus in rural areas. Although the input-based franchisee has definite advantages over the collec- tion franchisee, finding entities or agencies with the required skill sets has proved to be a challenge, even before the program has been undertaken on a large scale. Therefore, it is often beneficial for the licensees to initially start with revenue collection-based franchisees and then move on to upgrading these businesses into an input-based franchisee system within a predetermined time frame once the franchisee develops or acquires the requisite skill sets. Training programs intro- duced by the Rural Electrification Corporation through the Central Institute for Rural Electrification could be leveraged for achieving this at a faster pace. Review of Urban Franchisee Experiences Encouraged by the experience of Bhiwandi, a handful of attempts have been made to introduce DFs for identified circles or areas in the states of Bihar, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, and Uttar Pradesh. See table 4.5 for an expanded list. In addition to the successfully concluded initiatives, table 4.5 shows that there have also been several cases of failures in which the bidding process could not Table 4.5  DFs for Identified Circles or Areas Area Area profile Bidders Successful bidder Bhiwandi, • Tenure: 10 years Torrent Power Ltd., Crompton Torrent Power Ltd. Maharashtra • Input: 2,420 MU Greaves Ltd. (2 total) (operational since January 26, • Consumers:174,000 2007) • Revenue: Rs 3.5 billion Agra, Uttar Pradesh • Tenure: 20 years Torrent Power Ltd., Reliance Torrent Power Ltd. • Input: 1,799 MU Infrastructure Ltd., JUSCO (operational since 1 April 2010) • Consumers: 271,000 (3 total) • Revenue: Rs 3.47 billion Kanpur, Uttar • Tenure: 20 years Torrent Power Ltd., JUSCO (2 total) Torrent Power Ltd. Pradesh • Input: 2,664 MU (hand-over process under way) • Consumers: 489,000 • Revenue: Rs 6.45 billion Nagpur, • Tenure: 15 years Indu Project, GTL Ltd., Crompton Spanco Ltd. Maharashtra • Input: 1,090 MU Greaves Ltd., SMS Infrastructure (DFA executed between • Consumers: 347,000 Ltd., Reliance Infrastructure Ltd., MSEDCL and Spanco Ltd. • Revenue: Rs 3.37 billion CESC, Tata Power Company Ltd., on February 23 2011; Spanco Ltd., A2Z Private Ltd., Spanco Ltd. started Vijai Electricals Ltd., Indiabulls operation in May 2011) Financial Services (11 total) Aurangabad, • Tenure: 15 years Indu Project, GTL Ltd., A2Z Private GTL Ltd. Maharashtra • Input: 1,276 MU Ltd., Ashoka Buildcon Ltd., (LOI issued) • Consumers: 205,000 Spanco Ltd., Indiabulls Financial • Revenue: Rs 4.21 billion Services (6 total) table continues next page Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 78 Private Sector Participation in Distribution Table 4.5  DFs for Identified Circles or Areas (continued) Area Area profile Bidders Successful bidder Jalgaon, • Tenure: 10 years Lanco Infratech Ltd., A2Z Crompton Greaves Ltd. H1 (DFA Maharashtra • Input: 667 MU Private Ltd., Essar Power, SMS executed between MSEDCL • Consumers: 115,000 Infrastructure Ltd., Crompton and Crompton Greaves Ltd. • Revenue: Rs 2.03 billion Greaves Ltd., Konark Power, GMR on June 1, 2011) Group (7 total) Gwalior, CZ-Bhopal, • Tenure: 15 years Dainik Bhaskar Power, Montecarlo Smart Wireless (Essel Group) Madhya Pradesh • Input: 1,031 MU Construction Ltd., Spanco Ltd., emerged as H1 • Consumers: 184,000 A2Z Private Ltd., Essel Group, • Revenue: Rs 3.32 billion Torrent Power Ltd., DPSCL Ltd., CESC, PNC Infratech Ltd. (9 total) Ujjain, WZ-Indore, • Tenure: 15 years Dainik Bhaskar Power, Montecarlo Smart Wireless (Essel Group) Madhya Pradesh • Input: 389 MU Construction Ltd., Spanco Ltd., has emerged as H1. • Consumers: 95,000 A2Z Private Ltd., Essel Group, • Revenue: Rs 1.30 billion CESC, GTL Ltd., Shyam Industries Ltd., ACME Group, PNC Infratech Ltd. (10 total) Sagar, EZ-Jabalpur, • Tenure: 15 years Dainik Bhaskar Power, Montecarlo Smart Wireless (Essel Group) Madhya Pradesh • Input: 163 MU Construction Ltd., Spanco Ltd., emerged as H1 • Consumers: 55,000 A2Z Private Ltd., Essel Group, • Revenue: Rs 0.55 billion ACME Group (6 total) Bhilai Steel Plant • Tenure: 15 years Due 20 March 2012 Bid process aborted/n.a. Township, • Input: 206 MU Chhattisgarh • Consumers: 34,029 • Revenue: Rs 0.41 billion Bokaro Steel City • Tenure: 15 years Due March 20, 2012 Bid process aborted/n.a. Township, • Input: 257 MU Jharkhand • Consumers: 38,792 • Revenue: Rs 0.21 billion Rourkela Steel • Tenure: 15 years Due March 20, 2012 Bid process aborted/n.a. Plant Township, • Input: 173.32 MU Orissa • Consumers: 27,974 • Revenue: Rs 0.15 billion Durgapur & IISCO • Tenure: 15 years Due March 20, 2012 Bid process aborted/n.a. Steel Plant • Input: 33.7 MU Township, • Consumers: 19,097 West Bengal • Revenue: Rs 0.0355 billion Sheel-Mumbra- • Tenure: 10 years Process aborted n.a. Kalwa, • Input: 409 MU Maharashtra • Consumers: 145,000 • Revenue: Rs 1.11 billion Roorkee, • Tenure: 15 years Process aborted n.a. Uttarakhand • Input: 104 MU • Consumers: 27,989 • Revenue: Rs 0.19 billion Rudrapur, • Tenure: 15 years Process aborted n.a. Uttarakhand • Input: 66 MU • Consumers: 17,865 • Revenue: Rs 0.12 billion table continues next page Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 79 Table 4.5  DFs for Identified Circles or Areas (continued) Area Area profile Bidders Successful bidder Patna, Bihar • Tenure: 10 years • EOIs submitted by 14 bidders • Not available • Input: 2,082 MU • Only Essar Power submitted bid • In first round, consortium • Consumers: 374,000 issue with Glodyne • Revenue: Rs 4.86 billion Technoserve Ltd. led to • AT&C loss: 43.4% cancellation of process. • In second round, no LOI was placed because only one bid was submitted. Muzaffarpur, Bihar • Tenure: 10 years Process aborted twice n.a. • Input: 187  MU • Consumers: 59,000 • Revenue: Rs 0.35 billion • AT&C loss: 53.4% Gaya, Bihar • Tenure: 10 years Process aborted twice n.a. • Input: 129 MU • Consumers: 57,000 • Revenue: Rs 0.27 billion • AT&C loss: 43.4% Bhagalpur, Bihar • Tenure: 10 years Process aborted twice n.a. • Input: 176 MU • Consumers: 54,000 • Revenue: Rs 0.32 billion • AT&C Loss: 59.5% Janjgir-Champa, • Tenure: 15 years Process aborted twice n.a. Chhattisgarh • Input: 880 MU Urban area was twinned with • Consumers: 234,000 rural area that attracted • Revenue: Rs 0.85 billion few serious big players. In • AT&C Loss: 67.39% the initial bid, no firm could qualify technically.) Source: Deloitte research. Note: AT&C = aggregate technical and commercial; CESC = Calcutta Electric Supply Corporation; CZ = Central Zone; DFA = distribution franchisee agreement; EOI = expression of interest; EZ = Eastern Zone; H1 = highest bidder; JUSCO = Jamshedpur Utilities and Services Company; LOI = letter of intent; MSEDCL = Maharashtra State Electricity Distribution Company Ltd.; MU = million units (million kilowatt-hours); WZ = Western Zone; n.a. = not applicable. be completed. This included the two rounds of bidding originally held by Bihar State Electricity Board (BSEB) for Patna, Muzaffarpur, Gaya, and Bhagalpur Circles and by Maharashtra State Electricity Distribution Company Ltd. (MSEDCL) for Nagpur (first round in 2007) and Sheel-Mumbra-Kalwa, and so forth. Lessons Learned for Improvement of the DF Approach: What Are the Key Variables That Must Be Properly Understood and Addressed in the Bid Process? Important common factors that led to success or failure of the various initiatives for appointing DFs have been analyzed to identify lessons learned for future cases. They are discussed below. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 80 Private Sector Participation in Distribution Area Selection for Urban DFs The urban DF model is structured in such a manner that the successful bid should be the one that offers maximum efficiency improvement (whether it is loss reduction or cost optimization, and so forth). The model ensures, in effect, that the front-loaded capital expenditure required during the initial years (to improve efficiency levels and to improve on the reliability and quality of supply) is fully recovered from the incremental revenues generated by the DF. ­ These incremental revenues arise from the steep reduction of inefficiencies and improved collection performance. At the same time, none of this burden for increased up-front investments is passed on to the licensee. The franchisee’s business lives or dies by its ability to be efficient and thereby to recover from the ­ customer base what it has invested in upgrading the network to improve the service, reduce losses, and increase customer satisfaction. However, the franchisee is allowed to charge the customers only the published tariff rates that the cus- tomers were being charged previously by the state utility. Therefore, the franchi- see must focus on drastically reducing losses and improving collections to recover the input energy price as well as its capital investment in upgrading the network in its area. In view of the above, it is essential for the utility to carefully identify potential areas for implementing DF models. Lessons learned seem to point to the follow- ing characteristics that make a given area a viable and attractive proposition for the prospective bidders: • Size of the area in terms of energy input and network infrastructure • Good and independently viable customer mix in terms of high consumption– high tariff consumers and the growth potential of the area • Limited geographical spread so that the area is manageable • Substantial (very high) AT&C losses or inefficiencies that the licensee has not been able to improve in the past years, but with which the private party can do much better (high loss-making areas offer better opportunities [win-win] for both the licensee and the franchisee) As can be seen from the analysis in figure 4.4 on attractiveness of the franchi- see areas bid out so far by various state utilities, the most successful areas have been mainly the sizeable areas with an input of around 500 million units (MU, or million kilowatt hours) and above and with high loss levels. The areas with low energy input (falling toward the left-hand side of figure 4.4) have largely been seen as unattractive by prospective bidders, and the ­ process for most of such areas has been aborted by the respective distribution utilities. With the utilities developing strict qualification criteria for attracting credible private sector players as prospective franchisees, the utilities have often been unable to attract enough participants for such areas. In the case of the franchises offered by Madhya Pradesh utilities for Gwalior, Ujjain, and Sagar, the areas for all three circles included a mix of rural and urban Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 81 Figure 4.4  Franchisee Area Attractiveness Analysis 80 Bhagalpur Janjgir-Champa 70 Gaya 60 Roorkee Muza arpur AT&C losses (%) Bhiwandi Gwalior 50 Sheel-Mumbra-Kalwa Agra Kanpur Sagar Ranchi 40 Nagpur Ujjain Patna Rudrapur Jamshedpur 30 Jalgaon Aurangabad 20 0 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 2,500 3,000 Energy input (MU) Under process Failed Operational Source: Deloitte research. Note: AT&C = aggregate technical and commercial; MU = million units (million kilowatt-hours). Size of bubble indicates quantum of losses (MU). areas in the initial versions issued in April 2011. These areas were finally changed to only urban areas after receiving feedback from prospective bidders, during the prebid conferences, that they were not interested in also taking on rural areas. Patna is a unique case. Despite being one of the most attractive areas put on offer so far, Patna’s original franchise could not be awarded to any successful bid- der because of other technical reasons in the bidding process. In the first round of bids invited in 2009, Glodyne Technoserve Ltd. emerged as the successful bidder. However, as a result of issues arising in the consortium arrangement through which it had qualified, the process had to be called off. In the second round, the BSEB had set the reserve price for the bids at an extremely high level, making it a very high-risk proposition for most bidders. Ultimately, only a single bid was received, that from Essar Power. Because of the single bidder and, there- fore, the lack of competition, the process had to be aborted by BSEB. Key Terms of DFAs Although most utilities have by and large followed the Bhiwandi contractual model, certain variations in the approaches have been adopted for different areas by different utilities. These variations have been evaluated and analyzed with respect to their effect on the viability or efficacy of the DF model. Tenure or Length of the DFA The term of the contract becomes critical in view of the extent of the franchi- see’s responsibilities for making capital investments in the urban input-based Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 82 Private Sector Participation in Distribution franchisee model. A tenure of at least 15 years or longer is desirable for the ­following reasons: • Investments required in the T&D network in the franchisee area would yield results only several years after their commissioning; the franchisee must have enough time to recover the costs of the investment. • The quantum of capital investments usually is lop-sided during the first five years, because of the loss reduction and reliability improvement interventions necessary for achieving the targeted loss reduction and consumer service levels. Therefore, a longer-term DFA will ensure that a significant portion of the assets put in place by the DF is suitably depreciated by the end of the term. If not, the utility will be paying a high residual value to the franchisee at the end of the contract. • Several technical loss reduction initiatives such as underground cabling, gas- insulated switchgears, and high voltage distribution systems have longer pay- back periods. If the tenure of the DFA is too short, the franchisee will have no incentive to undertake such initiatives in the franchisee area. Maharashtra has adopted tenures of 10 years for Bhiwandi and Jalgaon and 15 years for Aurangabad and Nagpur. Uttar Pradesh has adopted a tenure of 20 years for the Agra and Kanpur DFs, and Madhya Pradesh has adopted a tenure of 15 years for the ongoing bids for Gwalior, Ujjain, and Sagar (figure 4.5). Performance Targets Set for DFs Although the competitive bidding mechanism for appointment of the DF ensures to a large extent that the intended efficiency benefits are achieved and Figure 4.5  Tenure of DFs 25 Uttar Pradesh 20 Maharashtra Madhya Pradesh 15 Years 10 5 0 i d ur r on ur n ra r d io ga i ba ja an Ag gp np ga al Sa Uj ga Gw w Na Ka l Ja i n Bh ra Au Source: Deloitte research. Note: DF = distribution franchisee. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 83 passed on to the licensee, the licensees have started to put additional clauses into the DFAs, giving specific targets to the DFs for the following parameters (this type of micro-management by the utility has also allegedly dampened the enthu- siasm of participants to later bidding rounds for DFs): • AT&C losses and collection efficiency targets, or both, for the franchise period (though some utilities have given targets in a flexible manner to be achieved over a period of time, others have specified annual loss reduction targets) • Minimum capital investment specified during the first few years or during the entire franchise period directives • Metering levels to be achieved, in view of any targets drawn from the ­ given to the distribution licensee by the respective regulatory commission • Creation of call centers and complaint management systems to monitor the compliance levels against standards of performance mandated by the respective regulatory commission and to improve the customer service levels in general The targets given in the DFAs in some of the recent bids are summarized in table 4.6. Table 4.6  Summary of Targets of the Recent Bids Distribution Capital Collection Customer franchisee Loss reduction expenditure Metering efficiency satisfaction Bhiwandi No target specified Not specified Not specified Not specified Not specified Agra 15 percent AT&C losses Capex target as per Not specified Not specified Not specified within five years infrastructure roll-out plan Nagpur Loss level of 10.02 percent at Capex target as per Not specified Achieve 99.50 Not specified end of 15 years infrastructure percent rollout plan collection efficiency every year Kanpur AT&C loss level of 20 percent Capex target as per Not specified Not specified Not specified within five years infrastructure rollout plan Aurangabad Loss level of 3.85 percent at Not specified Not specified Not specified Not specified end of 15 years Jalgaon Loss level of 15 percent Capex target as per Not specified Not specified Not specified within five years of infrastructure operations rollout plan Gwalior Loss level of 15 percent Mandatory capex 100 percent 100 percent Round-the-clock until December 2013, target metering operationalized maintained until within two call center December 2018; years within 30 days reduction of 1 percent before end of every year thereafter until transition period it reaches 10 percent table continues next page Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 84 Private Sector Participation in Distribution Table 4.6  Summary of Targets of the Recent Bids (continued) Distribution Capital Collection Customer franchisee Loss reduction expenditure Metering efficiency satisfaction Ujjain Loss level of 15 percent Mandatory capex 100 percent 100 percent Round-the-clock until December 2013 target metering operationalized and maintained until within two call center December 2018; years within 30 days reduction of 1 percent before end of every year thereafter until transition period it reaches 10 percent Sagar Loss level of 15 percent Mandatory capex 100 percent 100 percent Round-the-clock until December 2013 target metering operationalized and maintained until within two call center in December 2018; years 30 days before reduction of 1 percent end of transition every year thereafter until period it reaches 10 percent Source: Deloitte research. Note: AT&C = aggregate technical and commercial; capex = capital expenditure. As can be seen in table 4.6, the licensees have realized the potential benefits that can be achieved through the private sector interventions in the loss-making distribution areas. Therefore, they have been giving increasingly difficult targets to prospective franchisees in the recent bids. It is also standard practice to introduce regulatory approvals on the franchi- see’s proposed capital expenditure toward the end of the franchisee period. Such assets would be transferred to the licensee at depreciated values and could lead to a sharp tariff increase (based on a spike in the assets that form the rate base) at the end of the franchisee period. Most licensees have not included contractual clauses in the DFAs specifically dealing with collection efficiency because collection efficiency is considered to be implicit in the AT&C loss levels and it is in the financial interest of the DF itself to collect the entire amount billed. However, some utilities have mandated 100 percent collection efficiency during all years of the franchisee period, espe- cially in the case of the recent Madhya Pradesh DF bids. The DF bids in Madhya Pradesh are also unique in terms of their focus on establishing systems for measurement of compliance to the Standard of Performance Regulations implemented by the Madhya Pradesh Electricity Regulatory Commission. Also, the DFA mandates the DF to set up a round-the- clock call center within 30 days of taking over, for recording and monitoring of technical and commercial complaints received from consumers. Penalties are specified also in some of the DFAs for nonachievement of the set targets. In the cases of Agra and Kanpur DFAs, if the DF fails to meet the loss reduction targets, a penalty amounting to 10 percent of the revenue loss to the licensee is imposed on the DF (for each year of the contract). In the cases of Gwalior, Ujjain, and Sagar, there is a yearly penalty for any loss of revenue to the utilities, which varies from 1 percent to 5 percent from year to year. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 85 Treatment of Subsidy and Collection against Arrears The treatment of subsidies arising out of the sale of power by the DF to customer categories in which tariff subsidies are provided or approved by the state govern- ment, especially in the agricultural and the below-poverty-line customer catego- ries, has varied across states. It is important to note that the treatment of subsidies (that is, whether the subsidy is to be retained by the licensee or to be passed on the franchisee) may significantly affect the viability of the franchisee model, especially if the consumer mix is skewed toward the categories that attract subsidies. Another important parameter that may significantly affect the viability of the franchisee is the incentive that is allowed on the collection of arrears that are owed to the licensee from service provided during the prefranchise period. The details are provided in table 4.7. The DFAs for Bhiwandi, Nagpur, Aurangabad, and Jalgaon by the MSEDCL allowed for pass-through of subsidies to the DFs. However, bids invited by other states such as Uttar Pradesh and Madhya Pradesh have allowed for subsidies to be retained by the licensees. Different levels of incentives have been provided to the franchisees for arrears pertaining to connected and disconnected consumers. Although almost all utili- ties have allowed the DFs an incentive of 10 percent on connected consumers’ arrears, the incentive for collection of arrears pertaining to disconnected consum- ers has varied between 20 percent and 25 percent across different DF bids. The DF bids recently invited in the state of Madhya Pradesh for Gwalior, Ujjain, and Sagar are unique in the treatment of arrears, because the entire Table 4.7  Incentive on the Collection of Arrears on Service Provided during the Prefranchise Period DF bid Treatment of subsidy Treatment of collection against arrears Bhiwandi Claim against subsidy would be • 10 percent incentive on collection from connected consumers remitted to DF. • 20 percent incentive on collection from disconnected consumers Agra DVVNL would retain the subsidy. • 10 percent incentive on collection from connected consumers • 20 percent incentive on collection from disconnected consumers Nagpur Claim against subsidy would be • 10 percent incentive on collection from connected consumers remitted to DF. • 25 percent incentive on collection from disconnected consumers Kanpur KESCO would retain the subsidy. • 10 percent incentive on collection from connected consumers • 20 percent incentive on collection from disconnected consumers Aurangabad Claim against subsidy would be • 10 percent incentive on collection from connected consumers remitted to DF. • 25 percent incentive on collection from disconnected consumers Jalgaon Claim against subsidy would be • 10 percent incentive on collection from connected consumers remitted to DF. • 25 percent incentive on collection from disconnected consumers Gwalior Licensee would retain the • Franchisee could keep all arrears against connected and subsidy. disconnected consumers collected after effective date of operation. Ujjain Licensee would retain the • Franchisee could keep all arrears against connected and subsidy. disconnected consumers collected after effective date of operation. Sagar Licensee would retain the • Franchisee could keep all arrears against connected and subsidy. disconnected consumers collected after effective date of operation. Source: Deloitte research. Note: DF = distribution franchisee; DVVNL = Dakshinanchal Vidyut Vitran Nigam Ltd.; KESCO = Kanpur Electricity Supply Company Ltd. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 86 Private Sector Participation in Distribution outstanding arrears are considered sold to the DFs. It may also be noted that, in the absence of consistent and reliable data being made available to all prospective bidders to accompany arrears clauses, the bidding process becomes speculative and subjective (that is, the franchisees will acquire all past claims of the licensees, but this is not helpful unless the amount is also credibly specified). Treatment of Additional Power Purchase by DFs Although all DFAs have allowed for additional power purchases by DFs in the event of shortfall in the supply being made available by the licensee, subject to regulatory approvals, the mechanism for recovery of costs for these purchases from the ultimate consumers is not addressed. This omission leaves scope for regulatory uncertainty and assumptions by the bidder that may lead to future disputes. However, the recently invited DF bids in the state of Madhya Pradesh for Gwalior, Ujjain, and Sagar suggest that recovery of expenses may be sought on such additional power purchases. Recovery may come through reliability charges that may be approved by the Madhya Pradesh Electricity Regulatory Commission. Review of the Process for Appointment of DFs The process in which the appointment of urban DFs is conducted is critical to the utilities’ ability to build confidence among prospective investors or bidders. It also affects the ability of a utility to appoint a suitable partner, keeping in mind the long-term interests of all stakeholders including, most important, its consumers. As mentioned previously, the process of appointing a DF is much more critical than the standard generation and transmission bidding processes whereby bids are generally invited for new-build assets by prospective investors. In a DFA, existing customers of the licensee are handed over to the appointed DF. A single- stage process has been followed in the DF bids invited in the past, with a single request for proposal (RFP) stage similar to the bidding process being followed for case 1 bids in generation. Quality and Extent of Baseline Data Once a suitable area is identified, based on the potential benefits that may be achieved and the attractiveness of the area to potential bidders, the licensee needs to undertake preparation of the baseline data that will be made available to the potential bidders in the RFP or the data room, or both. The availability of credible baseline data on the parameters provided in table 4.8 is essential, as has been seen in past bids. The quality of baseline data is essential not only for the potential bidders, but also for the licensee in deciding on trajectories of key performance indicators (such as distribution losses, collection efficiency, and investment requirements) to set appropriate targets for the franchisee. Without reliable baseline data, the licensee will be unable to monitor progress by the franchisee. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 87 Table 4.8  Quality and Extent of Baseline Data Key aspects Specific data points Remarks and observations Billing and The following historical information is required for the To ensure availability of such information, the recovery- previous three- to five-year period: following shall be a prerequisite: related • Number of consumers and connected load, by • An IT-based billing system is implemented information customer category that contains complete repository of the • Units billed, by customer category billing history of consumers in the selected • Breakup of metered and un-metered sales for each area. category • Consumers for the proposed DF area are • Amount billed, by customer category, with a identifiable or marked in the billing system, breakdown into tariff components, subsidy, duties so that appropriate reports and data can and cess (tax), surcharges, and so forth be extracted and made available to the • Collection and recovery, by customer category prospective bidders. • Aging analysis of connected and disconnected arrears, by customer category • Status of consumer metering, by customer category, with details of the population with various types of meters, aging of meters, specifications of meters, number of working or faulty meters Energy input The following historical information is required for the To ensure availability of such information, the preceding three- to five-year period: following shall be a prerequisite: • Energy input at the 33-kV level • The proposed area must be demarcated in • The loading pattern, voltage characteristics, and so terms of its energy input points at the 33-kV forth level. • Preferably, feeder-level information (as done in • In case there are any crossovers at lower certain states) voltages, these may either be done away with or be appropriately metered and recorded. • Meter readings and other details must be recorded on a daily basis in either a manual logbook or software-based logs, so they can be verified by the prospective bidders. Network The following historical information is required for the If the licensee does not maintain appropriate infrastructure preceding three- to five-year period: records, it will need to undertake a information • Subtransmission lines in circuit kilometers at 33-kV field asset survey to provide the listed level and 11-kV level information to the prospective bidders • Low-voltage lines, in circuit kilometers, along with on the as-is network infrastructure in the number of poles and so forth proposed DF area. • Numbers and ratings of power transformers of 33- and 11-kV • Status of metering at 33- and 11-kV substation levels • Numbers and ratings of distribution transformers of 11 kV and 415 V • Status of metering at distribution transformer level • Power transformer failure rate • Distribution transformer failure rate Ongoing The licensee needs to make available information on A summary of such contracts or works may be Contracts or the following: provided in the RFP (for example, R-APDRP works • Ongoing or tied-up capital works being undertaken works that were mentioned in the recently by the licensee that may be commissioned or may invited Madhya Pradesh DF bids) and spill over to the franchisee period copies of the underlying contracts made • Various O&M contracts entered into by the licensee available to the prospective bidders on that may or may not be continued by the franchisee request. Source: Based on study. Note: DF = distribution franchisee; kV = kilovolt; O&M = operation and maintenance; RFP = request for proposal; R-APDRP = Restructured Accelerated Power Development and Reforms Programme; V = volt. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 88 Private Sector Participation in Distribution In addition to the above, the licensee also needs to assess the O&M costs and capital costs that are avoided through the appointment of a franchisee in the selected area. This assessment will allow the licensee to calculate potential ­ savings during the franchisee period. Qualification Criteria for Prospective Bidders Although direct experience on the part of the franchisee in undertaking power distribution with a comparable customer base would appear to be the most appropriate technical criterion for prequalifying prospective bidders, such a cri- terion would seriously limit competition. This is because private sector participa- tion in distribution has been available to only a few players in the legacy utilities in Ahmedabad, Kolkata, Mumbai, and Surat. Table 4.9 provides the various criteria included in past DF bidding documents. Licensees have attempted to widen the pool of potential bidders by including players who either have experience in undertaking civil works in the distribution business for existing licensees or have direct experience in handling large cus- tomer bases in other sectors such as telecoms and so forth. Opening up the pool of potential bidders, by prequalifying players with expe- rience of handling customer bases in other industries, has resulted in much more aggressive quotations relative to conventional private sector power distribution players who understand the pitfalls of the power distribution business. The DF procurement process has resulted in the emergence of Spanco Ltd. (for Nagpur), GTL Ltd. (for Aurangabad), and Smart Wireless (for Gwalior, Ujjain, and Sagar) as the winning bidders. However, the actual ability of such players to manage power distribution has yet to be demonstrated; Nagpur and Aurangabad have only recently been handed over and the handing-over process for Gwalior, Ujjain, and Sagar has yet to be completed. Once the actual operational results for Nagpur, Aurangabad, and other such cities are observed for a period of time, it will become clear whether implement- ing such broad-based qualification requirements to attract new investors has resulted in real benefits for the licensee. The bids invited in the state of Uttar Pradesh largely followed the qualification requirement used by the distribution licensee (MSEDCL) in the state of Maharashtra. However, the licensees in the state of Madhya Pradesh also included parties who were involved in other seg- ments of the power sector, such as generation; transmission; and engineering procurement and construction contracting. Although bidding through consortia has been allowed in most cases, this approach did not apply to bids for Bhiwandi and Aurangabad that were invited by the MSEDCL in Maharashtra. It may be noted that such consortia are critical only in cases where either the experience requirement is very unique or the size of required investments is very large, both of which are not true for most DF bids. Therefore, once the technical experience requirement has been broadened to include players with experience in any segment in the power sector (for example, generation and transmission as well as distribution) or with handling of custom- ers in other sectors (nonpower), or both, the need for consortium bidding Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 89 Table 4.9  Experience Criteria Included in Past DF Bidding Documents DF bid location Experience criteria Consideration for consortiums Bhiwandi • Experience of handling 200,000 consumers, or • 500 employees for two years and • At least five personnel with power sector experience of more than 10 years Agra • Two years experience in power sector in GTD, or • No more than three companies are • Experience of handling 200,000 consumers for two years, or allowed, lead partner must have • 500 employees for three years and 51 percent equity, and no member • At least five personnel with power sector experience of more may have less than 10 percent than 15 years equity. Nagpur • Experience of handling 200,000 consumers, or • No restriction • 500 employees for two years and • At least five personnel with power sector experience Kanpur • Two years experience in power sector in GTD, or • No more than three companies are • Experience of handling 200,000 consumers for two years, or allowed, lead partner must have • 500 employees for three years and 51 percent equity, and no member • At least five personnel with power sector experience of more may have less than 10 percent than 15 years equity. Aurangabad • Experience of handling 200,000 consumers, or • Not allowed • 500 employees for two years and • At least five personnel with power sector experience of more than 10 years Jalgaon • Experience of handling 200,000 consumers for two years, or • No restriction • 500 employees for two years and • At least five personnel with power sector experience Gwalior • Experience of owning a power generation project with • No more than three companies are capacity of 250 MW, holding a power distribution or allowed, lead partner must have transmission license, or constructing a generation or 51 percent equity, and no member transmission facility worth at least Rs 330 billion for a state or may have less than 10 percent central utility, or equity. • Experience of handling 200,000 consumers for two years and • 350 employees for two years Ujjain • Experience of owning a power generation project with • No more than three companies are capacity of 250 MW; holding a power distribution, allowed, lead partner must have transmission, or trading company; constructing a generation 51 percent equity, and no member or transmission facility worth at least Rs 100 billion for may have less than 10 percent a state or central utility; or manufacturing a generation, equity. transmission, or distribution equipment worth at least 100 billion, or • Experience of handling 334,000 consumers for two years and • 170 employees for two years Sagar • Experiencer of owning a power generation project with • No more than three companies are capacity of 250 MW, holding a power distribution or allowed, lead partner must have transmission license, or constructing a generation or 51 percent equity, and no member transmission facility worth at least Rs 100 billion for a state may have less than 10 percent orcentral utility, or equity. • Experience of handling 50,000 consumers for two years and • 100 employees for two years Source: Deloitte research. Note: GTD = generation, transmission, and distribution; MW = megawatt. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 90 Private Sector Participation in Distribution Table 4.10  Summary of Parameters for Financial Qualification Criteria Franchisee Financial criteria Maharashtra—Bhiwandi • Net worth for the past financial year • Annual turnover for the past two financial years • Cash flow from operations for the past two financial years • Listing on a recognized stock exchange Uttar Pradesh—Agra, • Net worth for the past financial year Kanpur • Annual turnover for the past three financial years • Cash flow from operations for the past three financial years • Listing on a recognized stock exchange Maharashtra—Nagpur, • Net worth for the past financial year Aurangabad • Annual turnover for the past two financial years • Cash flow from operations for the past two financial years • Listing on a recognized stock exchange Maharashtra—Jalgaon • Net worth for the past financial year • Annual turnover for the past three financial years • Cash flow from operations for the past three financial years • Listing on a recognized stock exchange Madhya Pradesh—Gwalior, • Net worth for the past financial year Ujjain, Sagar • Annual turnover for the past two financial years • Positive profit after tax for the past two financial years is diminished. The risk associated with consortium bidding is the potential for dilution of ownership, commitment, and responsibility as the number of parties ­ increases. There have also been significant variations in the financial qualification criteria set for prequalification in the various DF bids. In the transactions conducted to date, different criteria have been used, including net worth, turnover, cash flows, profit track records, and so forth, and various combinations thereof. The param- eters on which the financial qualification criteria were based in some recent bids are summarized in table 4.10. There were several modifications or changes made to the technical and finan- cial qualification criteria in certain bids in the past. The perception was that these were tailored to include certain players who were keen to undertake DF business in certain areas. Time Taken for Concluding the Bid Process A period of six to eight months, starting from the issue of the first set of RFP and DFA documents up to final handing over of the area to the appointed DF, would be a reasonable time frame for undertaking the various intermedi- ate activities involved. However, for the transactions conducted to date, there have been several procedural delays caused by resistance from employees and other stakeholders and by data-quality issues. These delays in the completion of the bidding process have occurred even in cases where the successful bidder had already been identified and the letter of intent (LOI) issued. Some ­ examples of the time taken for concluding the bid process are provided in table 4.11. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 91 Table 4.11  Time Taken for Concluding the Bid Process Date of issuance Franchisee of notice of intent Date of start of Utility area to tender Date of signing of agreement DF operation DVVNL, Uttar Agra February2009 Agreement executed April 2010 Pradesh on May 18, 2009, and supplementary agreement on March 17, 2010 KESCO, Uttar Kanpur February 2009 Agreement executed on Not yet started Pradesh May 18, 2009 MSEDCL, Nagpur January 2010 Agreement executed on May 2011 Maharashtra February 23, 2011 MSEDCL, Aurangabad January 2010 Agreement executed on May 2011 Maharashtra February 23, 2011 MSEDCL, Jalgaon November 2010 Agreement executed on November 2011 Maharashtra June 1, 2011 Source: Deloitte research. Note: DF = distribution franchisee; DVVNL = Dakshinanchal Vidyut Vitran Nigam Ltd.; KESCO = Kanpur Electricity Supply Company Ltd.; MSEDCL = Maharashtra State Electricity Distribution Company Ltd. Although all utilities have normally taken approximately a year and a half to complete the handling of the bid process, certain cases have been delayed much longer. Torrent Power Ltd., despite entering into the DFA for Kanpur in March 2009, had still been unable to take over the franchise, which was later aban- doned, primarily because of employee resistance, which had not been resolved by the licensee to date. The Kanpur story demonstrates that the characteristics of the area to be franchised can be as important to the success or failure as the characteristics of the franchisee (in this case, a very capable and experienced company with a demonstrated track record). Review of Successes and Failures From a review of past cases, one clearly sees more cases of failure than success in urban input-based distribution franchises. After the success of the Bhiwandi fran- chise undertaken by Torrent Power Ltd., the Maharashtra utility and utilities in a handful of other states started actively pursuing the idea of implementing the DF model in high loss-making urban areas where they had been unable to reduce losses and improve the quality of supply on their own. However, the process of appointing DFs has not been an easy experience for the distribution licensees, and several failures have occurred. Despite the fact that more than five years have passed since the demonstrated success of the Bhiwandi model, there are at present still only four operational DFs in the country: Agra, Aurangabad, Jalgaon, and Nagpur6 in addition to Bhiwandi. ­ The aborted or failed bid processes point to the underlying weaknesses, lack of transparency, unbalanced approach, and the unclear rationale of the processes undertaken. Some of the key reasons for abandoned bid processes or failure of completed bid processes are presented in table 4.12. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 92 Table 4.12  Key Reasons for Abandoned Bid Processes or Failure of Completed Bid Processes DF bid Reason Nagpur (round 1) by MSEDCL, after the success of Bhiwandi, initiated the bid process for appointing a franchisee for the city of Nagpur that had a full-fledged DFA (an MSEDCL improvement over Bhiwandi) and a minimum expected input rate trajectory worked out on the basis of AT&C loss reduction from 39 percent to 12 percent during the 15-year franchise period. The reasons that led to the failure of the bidding process include the following: • The input rate quoted by the winning bidder was unrealistic, because after a few years the rates were higher than the average revenue realization. This circumstance suggested that even without consideration of labor, financing charges, administrative expenses, and so forth, the revenue realized from the business would not sustain the quoted input rate to be paid to MSEDCL. The other bids were at least 25–30 percent lower than that of the successful bidder. • Unfortunately, there was no such methodology prescribed in the financial bid evaluation process to highlight and reject such bids; therefore, despite the issue being apparent, MSEDCL went ahead and accepted the bid. • There were also cases in the high court challenging MSEDCL’s decision to award franchises for parts of Nagpur city, and because the questions of loss reduction and benefits to MSEDCL were involved, the case was referred to the MERC by the High Court. • Thereafter, the successful bidder pulled back and did not execute the DFA with the MSEDCL. Patna, Muzaffarpur, Bihar franchisees, round 1, 2009: Gaya, and BSEB had invited bids for appointment of DFs for Patna, Gaya, Muzaffarpur, and Bhagalpur. One of the conditions was that the bidders for Patna would have Bhagalpur by to bid for at least one more DF area. Reliance Infrastructure Ltd. had bid for all four areas, CESC for Patna and Muzaffarpur, and Glodyne Technoserve Ltd. BSEB for Patna and Gaya. The following issues led to the abandoning of the bid process: • Glodyne Technoserve Ltd. had emerged as the highest bidder for Patna. However, because of certain issues identified in the consortium structure, a LOI was not issued by BSEB to Glodyne Technoserve Ltd.; BSEB challenged the admissibility of the Glodyne Technoserve Ltd. bid in the Patna High Court. • Thereafter, BSEB abandoned the bid process. Bihar franchisees, round 2, 2011: BSEB started a fresh bidding process for the appointment of DFs for Patna, Gaya, Muzaffarpur, and Bhagalpur in 2011. Again, one of the conditions was that the bidders for Patna would have to bid for at least one more DF area. The following issues again led to the cancellation or abandonment of the process by BSEBa: • BSEB had specified a very high reserve price for input rate. • Only Essar Power submitted its bid. • Essar Power emerged as the single bidder for the DF areas, and BSEB did not issue the LOI. • Essar went to court to get the LOI issued. table continues next page Table 4.12  Key Reasons for Abandoned Bid Processes or Failure of Completed Bid Processes (continued) DF bid Reason Rudrapur and The NITs for appointment of DFs for Rudrapur and Roorkee cities were issued by UPCL in October 2010. However, the process stalled because of the Roorkee by UPCL following issues: • A very high reserve price in the bid documents was noted by the potential bidders • Employee resistance occurred. Dewas and Ujjain by MPPKVV initiated the process for appointment of DFs for Dewas and Ujjain cities in fiscal year 2006/07. M/s Dainik Bhaskar had emerged as the preferred Madhya Pradesh bidder from the competitive bidding process. Despite the completion of the bidding process, the LOI was never placed on the successful bidder because discoms of the following inconsistencies identified in the DFA: • There was no clause for tariff indexation in the input rates quoted by the DF. • No efficiency improvement targets were specified for the interim years of the franchisee period against which the DF could be held liable. • Procedures for adjustment of spillover revenues during the initial transfer and the final transfer-back years were not specified in the DFA. • Clauses regarding discriminatory load shedding and the consequential effect on the DF’s revenues were missing in the DFA. • A mechanism for recovery of additional power purchases by DF from external sources was not specified in the DFA. Although the MPPKVV retained the rights to undertake capital works in the franchisee area at its sole discretion, the demarcation between the obligations of the licensee and the franchisee were not addressed in the DFA. Note: AT&C = aggregate technical and commercial; BSEB = Bihar State Electricity Board; CESC = Calcutta Electric Supply Corporation; DF = distribution franchisee; DFA = distribution franchisee agreement; discom = distribution company; LOI = letter of intent; MERC = Maharashtra Electricity Regulatory Commission; MPPKVV = Madhya Pradesh Paschim Kshetra Vidyut Vitaran Company Ltd.; MSEDCL = Maharashtra State Electricity Distribution Company Ltd.; NIT = notice of intent to tender; UPCL = Uttarakhand Power Corporation Ltd. a. Another round of a failed bid for Patna occurred in 2013. 93 94 Private Sector Participation in Distribution Distribution remains the critical weak link in the power sector reform process. There is limited appetite for outright privatization, and therefore, DFs are the most likely way forward. A number of lessons have emerged, as captured above, and these will be used to refine the process going forward. There is no alternative for the sector but to proceed with implementation of all possible instruments to improve efficiency and reduce losses and to improve customer satisfaction. Appendix G contains a summary of recommendations for the way forward on DF selection, based on lessons learned from successes and failures so far. Appendix H suggests a way for standardizing the approach to future distribution franchising, informed by lessons of successes and failures that have been observed in the past two years. Notes 1. Uttar Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Madhya Pradesh, Rajasthan, and Maharashtra together account for more than 60 percent of the total losses without subsidy and 40 percent of total sales of all distribution utilities in India for fiscal year 2009/10. 2. Delhi’s distribution companies were the last example of distribution privatization in India, completed in 2002. Since then, only a handful of DFs have been implemented, starting with Bhiwandi in 2007. Appendix F provides a detailed analysis of the priva- tization approach compared to the distribution franchising approach. 3. In addition to the private licensees mentioned, there are private licensees in the Greater Noida area (Noida Power Company Ltd.), Jamshedpur (Jamshedpur Utilities and Services Company and Tata Steel), and so forth, which are also performing at significantly high efficiency levels in comparison to the state government utilities in the respective states. 4. Three World Bank reports (2003a, 2003b, 2004) provide substantial insights on Orissa and Delhi privatization experiences. 5. Distribution franchisees in Gwalior, Ujjain, and Sagar in Madhya Pradesh; Muzaffarpur, Bhagalpur, and Gaya in Bihar; and Ranchi and Jamshedpur in Jharkhand have also been awarded to respective successful bidders during the past few years. 6. Bhagalpur, Gaya, Muzaffarpur, and Sagar have also been made operational during 2012–14. References Ghosh, A, S. Majumdar, and G. Kadam. 2012. “State-Owned Electricity Distribution Companies: Some Positives, though Several Concerns Remain.” ICRA Rating Feature March, ICRA Ltd., New Delhi. Planning Commission. 2011. “Report of the Sub-Group on Public Private Partnership in the Distribution of Electricity.” Secretariat for Infrastructure, New Delhi. Power Finance Corporation Ltd. 2013. “Report on the Performance of State Power Utilities for the Years 2009–10 to 2011–12.” Ministry of Power, New Delhi, India. Shunglu Committee. 2011. “Report of High-Level Panel on Financial Position of Distribution Utilities.” Planning Commission, New Delhi. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in Distribution 95 World Bank. 2003a. “The Delhi Electricity Discom Privatizations: Some Observations and Recommendations for Future Privatizations in India and Elsewhere.” Energy and Mining Sector Board Discussion Paper Series 8, World Bank, Washington, DC. ———. 2003b. “Regulation by Contract: A New Way to Privatize Electricity Distribution?” Energy and Mining Sector Board Discussion Paper 7, World Bank, Washington, DC. ———. 2004. “Implementation Completion Report on the Orissa Power Sector Restructuring Project.” Report 30269, World Bank, Washington, DC. ———. 2012. “Analysis of Experience with Private Sector Participation in the Indian Power Sector.” South Asia Regional Energy Studies Series. Prepared by Deloitte Touche Tohmatsu India Private Limited. World Bank, Washington, DC. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 CHAPTER 5 Private Sector Participation in the Indian Solar Energy Sector Key Messages • In 2009, the Indian Ministry of New and Renewable Energy (MNRE) announced the National Solar Mission (NSM), a plan to add 20,000 megawatts (MW) of new grid-connected solar generation capacity from the private sector. • The NSM, which is being implemented in three distinct phases up to 2022, has rapidly added on-grid solar capacity and has attracted widespread private sector interest, with sharp drops in tariffs resulting from reverse auctions. • The Indian Renewable Energy Development Agency, the financial arm of the MNRE, finances solar photovoltaic (PV) projects; commercial banks have largely stayed away. • State utilities are subject to renewable purchase obligations (RPOs) and can buy or sell renewable energy certificates (RECs); the RECs are the institu- tional underpinnings of the market for solar energy. • The feed-in tariff for grid-connected solar generation started at Rs 17.91/kilo- watt-hour (kWh) and has now fallen to Rs 7.49/kWh as a result of price dis- covery through reverse auctions. • There is an innovative partnership between the MNRE and the commercial arm of the ­largest central government–owned thermal power producer—NTPC (National Thermal Power Corporation) Vidyut Vyaparan Nigam Ltd. (NVVN). • To lower the cost of solar power for financially strapped utilities, NVVN arranges a blended price of thermal power and solar power to make the cost of solar power more affordable. • States also operate their own grid-connected solar programs, but they are unable to offer the blended thermal price to lower the cost of solar power for their distribution companies (discoms) because this price is available only for capacity procured under the NSM. This chapter was prepared in 2012 on the basis of discussions and consultations with the Council on Energy, Environment, and Water, with regard to the National Solar Mission. The author particularly wishes to thank Arunabha Ghosh, chief executive officer of the council, for discussions and sharing of back- ground documents. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   97   98 Private Sector Participation in the Indian Solar Energy Sector The NSM document, released by the MNRE in November 2009, sets out the mission’s varied targets and objectives and provides guidelines and policy tools to achieve these goals. The targets are bold: NSM seeks to install 20,000 MW of grid-connected solar power by 2022. Qualifying projects, sourced from private sector investors, are selected through a reverse auction procurement mechanism and are ostensibly technology-neutral, employing either solar PV or solar thermal technology. The mission was launched in January 2010, when the Indian solar energy market size was 17.8 MW. By March 2012, the cumulative capacity had grown to 506.9 MW. Of this capacity, 203.4 MW were commissioned under the NSM and other central government schemes. Another 303.5 MW were deployed under initiatives of various states. Table 5.1 provides NSM targets for 2010–22. The NSM objectives consist of both specific goals to be accomplished within the phased timeline and broader goals without a definite deadline. Phase 1 focuses on setting up an environment to enable solar technology penetration at centralized and decentralized levels. Phase 1’s guidelines explicitly aim to facili- tate quick implementation of the NSM, while ensuring serious participation by, and enhanced confidence in, the selected project developers. Promoting private sector manufacturing in India’s solar sector is another phase 1 goal. Phase 2 contemplates an aggressive capacity ramp-up to facilitate competitive solar energy penetration in India. The guidelines envision scaling up through enforcement of a mandatory RPO for utilities, backed by a preferential tariff. Phase 3, the final phase, aims to meet or exceed the end target of 20,000 MW of grid-connected solar power by 2022. Rapid scaling-up of installation during phase 3 is anticipated through the availability of international finance and tech- nology. The NSM seeks to achieve grid parity by 2022 and parity with coal-based thermal power by 2030. The success of the mission is contingent on coordination among existing and new institutions. The NSM is overseen by the MNRE. In a good example of public-private partnership, the NVVN enters into 25-year power purchase agreements (PPAs) to procure power from private sector project developers and supplies an allocated amount of MW capacity to the discoms or utilities. The MNRE and NVVN also manage a payment guarantee fund to insure NVVN against losses should the power remain unsold or the buyer default on payments. The Indian Renewable Energy Development Agency is a public Table 5.1  National Solar Mission Targets, 2010–22 Solar technology Phase 1 (2010–13) Phase 2 (2013–17) Phase 3 (2017–22) Grid-connected or rooftop (megawatts) 1,000–2,000 4,000–10,000 20,000 Off-grid solar applications (megawatts) 200 1,000 2,000 Solar hot water collectors (square meters) 7 million 15 million 20 million Rural solar lanterns or lighting (systems) n.a. n.a. 20 million Source: CEEW and NRDC 2012. Note: n.a. = not applicable. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in the Indian Solar Energy Sector 99 limited government company that operates as the MNRE’s financial arm and finances solar PV projects. Three sets of policies operate to create the strategic environment within which private developers are functioning: (a) the NSM as the backdrop; (b) state policies, which could either complement the mission or offer alternative policy designs from which private developers could choose; and (c) non-NSM national policies, particularly the RPOs and RECs.1 Three sets of private sector stakeholders are involved in ensuring the success of the NSM: • Project developers, who bid for projects and, if successful, are primarily respon- sible for commissioning projects on time to supply the committed amount of solar-generated electricity into the grid. • Engineering, procurement, and construction contractors, who implement projects for developers and have expertise in building projects and understanding ­ on-the-ground challenges that affect project completion. • Financiers, including Indian commercial banks, Indian nonbanking financial institutions, and international funding channels (including multilaterals, gov- ernment-channeled funds, and public-private funds), which complement a developer’s equity contribution by providing debt, loan guarantees, or risk insurance in order to commission the solar plant. Progress to Date India’s total solar power installation currently stands at 2,208 MW, of which 661 MW have been contributed from projects selected under the NSM. The bal- ance is from the state schemes for solar power development, with 70 percent coming solely from Gujarat. Madhya Pradesh is looking to add another 800 MW of solar power by June 2014. Phase 1 of the NSM aimed to ramp up grid-connected solar energy to 1,100 MW by 2013, with 500 MW of PV power, 500 MW of concentrated solar thermal power, and 100 MW of rooftop PV power. However, this did not materialize, and just 252.5 MW of new capacity was added under the NSM during 2010–13. The targets were initially perceived as too ambitious, because India had little solar PV and no solar thermal projects in 2010. However, the market has grown tremendously with an increased number of developers, lower prices, and interested financial institutions. As of March 26, 2012, there was a total of 506.9 MW of installed capacity. The central government con- ducted two batches of reverse auctions, offering feed-in tariffs and long-term PPAs to the selected least-cost developers. The feed-in tariffs to developers were complemented by support to power utilities (discoms) through the bun- dling of solar power with thermal power, reducing the average per unit cost of solar power (figure 5.1). Eight states have participated in phase 1 installations (PV and solar thermal). Rajasthan is in the lead by far (see table 5.2). Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 100 Private Sector Participation in the Indian Solar Energy Sector Figure 5.1  Bundling of Power Scheme: An Innovative Mechanism to Reduce the Price Burden of Solar Solar power developers NTPC unallocated power NVVN has been designated as the nodal agency by the Ministry of power to purchase PV: Rs 17.91 unit x kWh 4x kWh Rs 2.50/unit and sell power during phase 1 CSP: Rs 15.31/unit of the NSM. NVVN buys the solar power at a preferential tariff of Rs 15.39/kWh (US$0.30/kWh) from the solar PV power plant developers Cost of bundled power to NVVN through a power purchase NVVN PV: (17.91x + 10x)/5x = Rs 5.58/unit agreement (PPA). NVVN is CSP: (15.31x + 10x)/5x = Rs 5.06/unit authorized to bundle up to 1,000 MW of grid-connected solar power with conventional power. NVVN is allocated four times as much MW capacity from the cheaper unallocated quota of State Cost of power to state utilities for thermal power form NTPC coal utilities 50:50 ratio of PV and stations to bundle together with CSP = Rs 5.32/unit the more expensive solar power. This bundled power is provided to state utilities at rates determined by CERC. These state utilities can use the solar part of the bundled power to meet their RPOs. Source: Renewable Markets India 2011. Note: CERC = Central Electricity Regulatory Commission; CSP = concentrated solar power; kWh = kilowatt-hour; MW = megawatt; NTPC = National Thermal Power Corporation; NSM = National Solar Mission; NVVN = NTPC Vidyut Vyaparan Nigam Ltd.; PV = photovoltaic; RPO = renewable purchase obligation. Table 5.2  State Participation in Phase 1 Installations Megawatts State Batch 1 (2010–11) allocation Batch 2 (2011–12) Rajasthan PV: 100 PV: 295 ST: 400 Gujarat ST: 20 — Maharashtra PV: 5 PV: 25 Karnataka PV: 5 — Tamil Nadu PV: 5 PV: 10 Andhra Pradesh PV: 15 PV: 20 ST: 50 Orissa PV: 5 — Uttar Pradesh PV: 5 — Source: CEEW and NRDC 2012. Note: PV = photovoltaic; ST = solar thermal; — = not available. For both batches of phase 1, the central government used the reverse auction as a price discovery mechanism. Reverse auctions have two main benefits. They allow government procurers to select projects based on the lowest cost (thereby keeping the burden on fiscal resources and taxpayers low) and ensure that a price-based selection process will be fair and transparent. Project developers bid Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in the Indian Solar Energy Sector 101 on discounted tariffs set by the Central Electricity Regulatory Commission. A 5-MW parcel-size requirement for batch 1 and 20-MW maximum parcel-size requirement for batch 2 opened the market for a broad range of companies to enter the sector, as long as they met the criteria set out into the guidelines. Making headlines in late 2011, competitive bidding for NSM’s second batch of projects in phase 1 drove prices for grid-connected solar energy as low as Rs 7.49/kWh (US$0.15/kWh), approaching grid-parity with fossil-fuel-powered electricity. Phase 1 also attracted large conglomerates and new players into the solar market. During the mission’s first phase, more than 500 bidders competed for 63 projects allocated during two reverse auctions, driving prices to record lows. New solar energy investments in India increased to more than Rs 12,000 billion (US$2.5 billion) in 2011. This was in a general context of investments in the overall renewable energy markets in India reaching approximately Rs 51,000 billion (US$10.3 billion) in that year, that is, solar projects accounted for about one-third of the investments. Bid euphoria, however, is wearing off, and serious questions remain as to whether the mission’s phase 1 projects will meet commis- sioning deadlines. During batch 1’s reverse auction process, 36 projects were selected, with nearly 400 developers bidding in late 2010. A total of 140 MW was allocated to 28 PV projects and nearly 470 MW to seven solar thermal projects. The central government also migrated existing solar projects to count toward the National Solar Mission, at a premium tariff of Rs 17.91/kWh (US$0.45/kWh), providing an additional 84 MW of migrated capacity. The central government started the reverse auction at Rs 17.91/kWh (US$0.45/kWh). The lowest bid price was Rs 12/kWh (US$0.32/kWh). Because two PV projects failed to meet NVVN requirements, the projects were with- drawn from the process. Nineteen of the 36 batch 1 projects are located in Rajasthan. Major challenges and delays have affected the commissioning of batch 1 projects, which were all due for commissioning by January 2012. By early 2012, the central government had fined 14 PV project developers for failing to meet their commissioning deadlines and had warned another 14. By late March 2012, 100 MW of PV projects were considered commissioned, and the remainder were to be commissioned shortly, but some experienced further delays. As the mission moves forward, compliance with deadlines will be a main focus in order to maintain the credibility of the government’s policies and guide- lines, as well as its enforcement capabilities. India’s batch 2 reverse auction sent ripples through international solar markets. The lowest winning bid, by French company Solairedirect, was Rs 7.49/kWh (US$0.15/kWh) for a 5-MW plant. This price was impressively lower than mar- kets had predicted, suggesting that solar energy could attain grid parity with traditional energy sources sooner than initially anticipated. Current Indian grid-power prices in the top energy-consuming states range from approximately Rs 3.90/kWh (US$0.08/kWh) in Andhra Pradesh to Rs 5.90/kWh (US$0.12/kWh) in Rajasthan, with a nationwide average of Rs 4.70/kWh (US$0.09/kWh). Commercial and industrial power prices Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 102 Private Sector Participation in the Indian Solar Energy Sector are generally higher, making the lowest winning bid of Rs 7.490/kWh (US$0.135/kWh) very close to the higher-end grid power price—just Rs 1.60/kWh (US$0.03/kWh) short of grid parity and at parity with diesel. Batch 2’s progress toward grid parity was widely remarked on internationally. In Batch 2, 22 companies were awarded contracts, with a total of 27 winning bids. Welspun Energy Ltd., Azure Power, Mahindra Solar, Green Infra Ltd., and Jakson Power won multiple projects, with Welspun Energy Ltd. securing the maximum 50-MW allotment for a single company. Green Infra Ltd. and Mahindra Solar secured 40 MW and 30 MW, respectively. All but three of the winning batch 2I bids were for projects located in Rajasthan. The other three projects were in Andhra Pradesh, Maharashtra, and Tamil Nadu. Although larger companies such as Reliance Energy Ltd. did not participate as aggressively as expected during batch 2, some of these companies are under- taking big projects through state-level programs, such as the 40-MW Dhanu power project in Jaisalmer, Rajasthan, by Reliance Energy Ltd. The NSM has created momentum at both the central and state levels, as demonstrated by ­ falling prices at the state level, too. Although developers view state-level solar programs as more profitable than the national program (because of higher feed- in tariffs and other state-level incentives), they typically have more certainty of being paid through NVVN under the NSM. Although largely praised, the reverse auction has also been criticized. Some observers have raised concerns about the prices being driven so low that projects are financially unviable. The reverse auction process has also been criticized for not adequately vetting bidders, because the eligibility criteria simply required that bidders have a net worth of about Rs 150 million (about US$3 million). The resulting selection of some inexperienced, small developers quoting very aggres- sive prices has raised fears that many projects may not be commissioned. In addi- tion, inadequate vetting and monitoring have also led to accusations that some large companies have exploited guidelines and may corner a significant market share of NSM projects. In phase 1, engineering, procurement, and construction (EPC) contractors have also risen as a central force in the emerging solar energy market. Project developers with limited experience in the solar market have relied heavily on their EPC contractors to support their projects with potentially unsustainable bid prices. The role of an EPC contractor can cut both ways. On the one hand, EPC contractors have experience executing projects, and the more experience they gain, the further marginal costs of installing additional projects could be reduced. On the other hand, too much reliance on an EPC contractor can also blur the distinction between the project developer, who bears the ultimate responsibility for producing solar electricity, and the contractor. Projects should ultimately be selected after due diligence is performed on both developers and associated EPC contractors. Phase 1 is also a mechanism to test and evaluate the performance of project developers and to allow many domestic and foreign developers to enter the Indian solar market. One view holds that though the Indian solar energy market Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in the Indian Solar Energy Sector 103 has immense potential, it will ultimately consolidate to support only 8–10 primary developers. The significantly lower number of companies participating ­ in batch 2 bidding, as compared to batch 1, is an early sign of such consolidation. The experience of other solar markets, such as that in California in the United States, suggests that consolidation is a sign of a maturing industry. In India, com- panies such as Welspun Energy Ltd., Azure Power, Mahindra Solar, and Lanco Infratech Ltd. are starting to dominate the grid-connected solar market. Although the batch 2 50-MW limit per project developer remains a low limit for a growing market, consolidation of companies is likely to continue as the market matures. Clearly, state-level solar programs are having an effect as well, and NSM is not the only industry driver. As phase 1 bidding was underway, several states launched their own solar energy programs. For example, Welspun Energy Ltd. began new projects under Gujarat’s policy and also competed for Karnataka’s allotments. Similarly, Azure Power has a 2-MW solar power plant under ­ operation in Punjab and Maharashtra State Power Generation Company Ltd. (Mahagenco) is working to commission a 150-MW plant in Maharashtra. Valuable experience and scale from multiple projects are giving these bidders the confidence to bid low and yet be profitable. Both batches of phase 1 were con- sidered a success, but it is too early to tell yet whether individual selected proj- ects can claim success. The central government and states will need to increase their levels of coordination given the increased scale of phase 2 projects. The Indian banking sector has not been as enthusiastic toward lending to solar energy projects as it has been for thermal coal-based energy projects, because it perceives solar energy as an unproven technology. Lenders have also expressed concerns about the poor financial health of discoms as a big risk, even though this is a system-wide issue and not unique to the solar industry. Although innova- tive approaches such as bundling thermal power with solar power have reduced the cost burden on discoms for already-signed PPAs, uncertainty about the con- tinuity of such schemes creates additional concerns for stakeholders who are assessing repayment risks for the future. For phase 1, project developers were required to achieve financial closure within 180 days after signing a PPA with NVVN. Arranging financing for projects presented challenges, and goals were met in accessing domestic and overseas debt funds and using developers’ own company equity. While equity financing may have largely helped to meet the relatively small scale of investments needed in phase 1, it will not be able to support the higher targets for phase 2 where it is estimated that up to US$20 billion will be required to reach implementation targets. Phase 2 will therefore require an active government role to give financial players the confidence to invest in Indian solar projects. Concrete actions that can be taken to improve commercial banks’ perceptions and address their lack of information concerning the sector include the following: • Documentation of successful projects’ track records and whether performance claims can be achieved. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 104 Private Sector Participation in the Indian Solar Energy Sector • Documentation of technological effectiveness (unlike wind turbines, which are certified by an industry body, there is no equivalent certification of solar components). • Irradiance and insolation data about different parts of the country to underpin claims for site-specific generation estimates. • Focused channels for dissemination of solar project performance information to banks to increase the understanding of the solar industry among potential lenders (there are more than 170 banks and 80,000 bank branches in India). Potential Bottlenecks to Meeting Commissioning Schedule Deadlines Acquiring Land and Obtaining Requisite Clearances Land costs are usually only 5 percent of total project costs; however, local authori- ties are understandably slow to convert land-use designations from agricultural to nonagricultural. After an allocation under a lease or sale by a state government, reviewing of local claims on the land presents an additional hurdle. Locating proj- ects in areas of high solar irradiance, close to the power grid, and with adequate resources and infrastructure is also a challenge, especially given India’s limited geographic mapping and limited data on solar irradiance. The grid proximity and irradiance challenges are compounded by traditional difficulties faced by nearly all energy projects, such as poor grid infrastructure, transmission problems, and chronic power shortages. Land development options are shown in table 5.3. Table 5.3  Solar Project Land Development Options Land Disadvantages for ownership Key features Advantages for developers developers Developer SPV owns the land on its Full flexibility in choice of High up-front costs purchased balance sheet location Challenging process if and SPV Use of land as collateral land-use category must owned Option of sale or renewal be changed or if there are at end of project life multiple claims Lease by Government purchases or Lower up-front investment Less flexibility in choice government earmarks land for solar in land cost of location development Ability to spread costs over Limited opportunities to Lease periods typically project life and match lease government land match project life (for revenues with costs Increased government example, 30 years) Preapproved clearances interface and processes and permits Solar park Government or private Economies of scale in High reliance on developer acquires land procurement and government for correct Solar parks usually include permitting siting and assessment of incentives such as Faster and more reliable optimal solar resource permits for developers project execution Weaker negotiating and provide dedicated with fewer risks for position with respect to infrastructure to developers with well- government and solar evacuate power planned solar parks park developer Note: SPV = special purpose vehicle. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Private Sector Participation in the Indian Solar Energy Sector 105 Power Evacuation: Grid Connectivity and Proximity There is currently a mismatch between the speed at which solar power proj- ects can be set up and the time needed to provide the supporting infrastruc- ture. Grid connectivity for utility-scale solar projects depends on grid capacity, proximity, and availability. Many project developers have difficulties with siting projects in areas with sufficient grid capacity, resulting in increased costs and project commissioning delays. There have been questions on whether the government should invest in substations and transmission facili- ties before projects are set up. Yet, for current projects in Gujarat and Rajasthan, where the majority of solar PV power is being deployed, grid con- nectivity has not been a major issue because of the states’ approach to using solar parks. Decisions on siting the solar parks have been made on the basis of connectivity to the grid. As the market grows, however, and larger capaci- ties are commissioned (particularly in phase 2), planning for future grid upgrades must receive emphasis in advance so that the infrastructure is ­ available as projects are commissioned. There is also a need for greater clarity on who is responsible for the last-mile infrastructure, that is, how solar projects are physically connected to the grid and who bears the cost of making that connection: state utilities or project develop- ers. The answer to this question seems to vary according to state or central government policies. In some cases, developers who had not anticipated the last-mile construction cost have seen project costs exceed allocated budgets. The NSM specifies that state agencies and utilities are responsible for evacuating power from project sites to transmission lines. There is no additional national- level support for power evacuation. The cost for last-mile infrastructure can be 5–10 percent of total project costs, according to a 5-MW phase 1 developer in a statement to the media. Community Involvement and Habitat Protection With 5–10 acres required per MW, ground-mounted solar power is a land- intensive operation. The majority of phase 1 grid-connected solar projects are in remote locations where the primary contentious issues are conflicting land claims and land allocation for animal grazing. More social and ecological issues may surface as the NSM ramps up, and it is critical for the overall success of the mis- sion that government policies and developers minimize negative effects on the local communities and ecosystems. Note 1. Because renewable resource distribution is unequal across India, a system for trading RECs has been implemented to allow state discoms, which are the responsible enti- ties, to meet their RPOs. Strong enforcement of RPOs will be fundamental to the success of the REC market and will in turn lower the costs of implementing solar projects by ensuring markets for solar power. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 106 Private Sector Participation in the Indian Solar Energy Sector References CEEW (Council on Energy, Environment, and Water) and NRDC (Natural Resources Defense Council). 2012. “Laying the Foundation for a Bright Future: Assessing Progress under Phase 1 of India’s National Solar Mission.” Interim report, CEEW, New Delhi, and NRDC, New York. Renewable Markets India. 2011. “Jawaharlal Nehru National Solar Mission: Process, Opportunities, and Risk.” Mission document presented at Global Solar Investment Summit, Mumbai, India, April 15–16. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 CHAPTER 6 Financing of the Power Sector Key Messages • Given the high level of commercial bank exposure to power sector risk, the sector’s losses threaten to derail the power sector and potentially distribution ­ also the health of the financial sector. • The macroeconomic outlook is negative, and the private sector will increas- competing with the government for declining private savings. ingly be ­ • The Ministry of Power is introducing a ratings system for distribution compa- nies that ­analyzes their operational and financial performance and compares them to each other. • Commercial banks are cutting back their exposure to the power sector. Distribution Sector Losses and Their Effects With increasing losses, and inadequate subsidy support from the state govern- ments, most of the state distribution utilities have been forced to increase their level of borrowings, mostly bank borrowings, beyond their sustainable limits. In the past, banks have generally relied on government guarantees for taking loan exposures to the state power distribution utilities and have contin- ued to increase their lending exposure sizably. At present, bank borrowings (mostly short-term borrowings) fund a major portion of the losses of state distribution utilities. With signs of severe financial strain emerging in the dis- tribution sector in certain states, lending institutions, especially banks, have become cautious about new lending. As a result, the fund flow to the entire state power sector has been adversely affected. Although commercial banks have large exposure, two central government–owned lending agencies are the largest lenders. The central government established the Power Finance Corporation (PFC) in July 1986 to exclusively focus on financing and developing the country’s power sector. Today, PFC is the single-largest lender to the Indian power sector and ­supports about 23 percent of the country’s installed power generation capacity. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   107   108 Financing of the Power Sector Rural Electrification Corporation Limited (REC) is another leading public infrastructure finance company in India’s power sector. The company finances and promotes rural electrification projects across India and also provides loans to the central and state power sector utilities, state electricity boards, rural electric cooperatives, nongovernemtal organizations, and private power developers. The electricity value chain in India is summarized in figure 6.1, which also captures the source of financial pressure in the system. Given the high level of commercial bank exposure to power sector risk, the distribution sector’s losses threaten to derail the power sector and also the health of the financial sector. The banking sector’s exposure to the power sector continued to increase in absolute terms, and nonperforming assets (NPAs) increased nearly tenfold between September 2011 and September 2012, from Rs 12 billion to Rs 117 billion (US$218 million to about US$2 billion), as illustrated in figure 6.2. ­ Figure 6.1  Summary of Electricity Value Chain under Pressure 2007–11 Weakest link – Discom • A period of high economic growth • Financial losses – US$16 billion • New IPPs aggressively bidding for market share • Annual public subsidies – US$7 billion • Some private transmission lines • Financial gap after subsidy – US$9 billion • T&C losses – ~35% 2012 to present • Slowing economic growth • Rising international fuel (coal) prices • deteriorating credit worthiness Reform constrained by political deadlock and corruptions GenCo TransCo Discom Consumers PPI mixed result/failure PPI considered successful PPI partially successful Deteriorating credit worthiness • Facing rising fuel cost with • Some private transmission • High losses no ability to pass through lines closed • Low customer satisfaction • Rising OPEX Fuel crisis Credit crisis • High commercial and technical losses as well as low collection rates in combination with compromised political economy puts high pressure on DisCos. PPAs with IPP force dispatch of expensive plants, pressuring tari . Attempts to bring private expertise delivered mixed results. • The GenCos are facing financial pressure because of tight PPA tariffs and no pass through ability on rising fuel prices, while simultaneously facing reduced credit worthiness of DisCos. Note: Discom = distribution company; GenCo = generation company; IPP = independent power producer; OPEX = operating expenses; PPA = power purchase agreement; PPI = private participation in infrastructure; T&C = technical and commercial; TransCo = transmission company. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Financing of the Power Sector 109 Figure 6.2  Exposure to Power Sector Share of standard and impaired accounts (Rs billion) 676 422 117 12 September 2012 September 2011 3,886 3,945 Standard accounts NPA Standard restructured accounts Source: RBI 2012, 32. Note: NPA = nonperforming asset. The growing number of NPAs in the power sector likely accounts for the decrease in commercial lending to the power sector. Figure 6.3 shows the decrease (as shown in the infrastructure data in figure 6.3). Macroeconomic Outlook The macroeconomic outlook beyond 2012 is negative at present, and the pri- vate sector will increasingly be competing with the government to access declin- ing public savings. The Reserve Bank of India conducted a sample study of 12 corporations with high exposure to infrastructure, particularly power. The bank found (a) sharply increasing ratios of debt to equity and debt to earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization and (b) decreasing interest coverage. Those findings point to the increasing vulnerability of both the corpo- rations and their lenders (table 6.1). Central Government Approach Over the past decade, the reaction of the central government to the financial crisis in the distribution sector has been rather muted, although at least two centrally funded bailouts were offered to state utilities in March 2001 and Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 110 Financing of the Power Sector Figure 6.3  Growth Rate of Bank Credit to Selected Sectors 50 40 30 Percent 20 10 0 Retail sector Real estate Priority Infrastructure Banking sector sector system March 2011 September 2011 March 2012 Source: RBI 2012, 32. Table 6.1  Causes for Increasing Vulnerability of Corporate Entities Element in decline Element on the increase • Household savings • Inflation • Growth • Current account deficit • Rupee depreciation September 2012, respectively. However, the central government also approved a new financial restructuring plan for state distribution companies in September 2012 to accompany the latest bailout, which was not the case earlier, when no strings were attached. The September 2012 scheme offers central government support conditional on measures for both state distribution companies and state governments successfully achieving the financial turnaround of distribution ­ companies. The scheme proposes that (a) 50 percent of outstanding short-term liabilities would be converted into respective state government guaranteed bonds, and the remainder be rescheduled at favorable rates; (b) committees at state and central government levels would monitor progress of the turn-around measures; and (c) the central government would provide incentives through grants for accelerated aggregate technical and commercial loss reduction beyond the targeted levels under the central electricity reform scheme (Restructured Accelerated Power Development and Reforms Programme). In March 2013, the Ministry of Power (MOP) finally undertook leadership with respect to the financial crisis in the distribution sector and released a rat- ing of distribution utilities’ financial health to help lenders assess the risks of Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Financing of the Power Sector 111 specific distribution utilities. The utilities were rated on the basis of seven parameters, including financial status and compliance with regulatory norms. The integrated ratings shown in table 6.2 are determined on an annualized basis and range from A+ to C (A+ is the maximum, C is the minimum, and 100 is the total score). The proposed grading scale of A+ to C is different from the existing, stan- dard rating scale adopted by credit rating agencies (that is, AAA to D), because the standard credit rating measures only the degree of safety regarding timely servicing of financial obligations based on the probability of default. In contrast, the new grading exercise shown in table 6.2 analyzes the operational and finan- cial health of the distribution entities using the rating framework approved by the MOP. Furthermore, the standard credit rating for distribution utilities entails comparison with unspecified corporations, whereas the MOP’s newly developed integrated rating exercise compares the entity with other distribu- tion utilities only. Recommended Holistic Approach In general, bailouts create a moral hazard (that is, allow a return to business as usual) unless accompanied by strong monitoring measures. The key issues are ensuring the following: state utilities meet efficiency targets, regulators set ade- quate tariffs that are revised annually in line with existing legal requirements, financial institutions maintain hard budget constraints, and state governments pay subsidies as promised. A holistic approach would improve the investment climate for generation and commercially sound operation of distribution utilities, achieve a better balance between demand and supply, and prevent the system from again reverting to crisis. Aspects to be addressed for financial sustainability of the state power sector are discussed below. Table 6.2  First Integrated Rating for State Power Distribution Utilities, March 2013 Score distribution Grade Number of utilities Grading definition Between 80 and 100 A+ 4 Very high operational and financial performance capability Between 65 and 80 A 2 High operational and financial performance capability Between 50 and 65 B+ 11 Moderate operational and financial performance capability Between 35 and 50 B 10 Below average operational and financial performance capability Between 20 and 35 C+ 8 Low operational and financial performance capability Between 0 and 20 C 4 Very low operational and financial performance capability Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 112 Financing of the Power Sector Improvement of the Financial and Operational Performance of Distribution Utilities Initially, the focus should be on the six states that are responsible for 70 percent of the accumulated losses of the distribution sector. Action should be taken with regard to service delivery, tariffs, efficiency, and profitability: • Service delivery. The willingness of consumers to pay for power is intrinsi- cally tied to the quality and quantity of power received. Utilities can improve their credibility with consumers by improving customer service, providing relevant service information, and responding to complaints in a timely fashion. • Tariff revisions. Regular, transparent tariff revisions that respond to increases in costs and provide utilities with a reasonable return are critical to ensuring that utilities earn profits that can be reinvested into system upgrades and perfor- mance improvement measures. Reduction of cross-subsidies, as mandated by the National Tariff Policy, is another key action. • Efficiency. The reduction of distribution losses must be a priority. In addition, efforts need to be made to increase transparency, collect reliable energy data to guide management, use performance management systems to enhance accountability, and implement appropriate measures to give management and employees a stake in improving performance. • Profitability. Utilities need to earn a profit to be viable, to be able to invest, and to be able to upgrade their service to their consumers. Commercial Operation throughout the Value Chain The legislative framework for the power sector is robust. However, although unbundling and other reforms have been undertaken on paper, they have not always been implemented fully. The Electricity Act of 2003 and associated reforms aimed to disrupt the single-buyer model, create competition in distribu- tion and generation through open access and competitive bidding, ring-fence utilities from political interference, and create incentives for utilities to improve service and performance. Today, however, many state utilities continue to operate as de facto government agencies without functional independence. For a sound power sector, power utilities must operate on commercial principles. Subsidizing the provision of power to poorer consumers is not inconsistent with good sector performance, provided that such subsidies are transparent, targeted, and actually paid on time. West Bengal Power Sector Reforms West Bengal state has been a leader in implementation of reforms. Since the unbundling of the erstwhile West Bengal State Electricity Board (WBSEB) in 2007, all of the successor entities have been profitable each year, and only the distribution company received a small government subsidy in fiscal year (FY) 2010/11 targeted toward the poorest consumers. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Financing of the Power Sector 113 Before reforms, the WBSEB was inefficient, operated at a loss, and required budget support to sustain its operations. West Bengal’s approach to reform was gradual. Before unbundling the WBSEB, West Bengal reviewed the strengths and weaknesses of the existing framework, identified best practices from interna- tional and Indian experience, developed a financial and institutional restructuring plan built on credible data, and engaged in intensive stakeholder consultations throughout the process to ensure commitment to the reform agenda at all levels. The WBSEB adopted computerized billing, 100 percent feeder metering, strict monitoring and vigilance activities to prevent electricity theft, and near 100 percent metering of consumers. The state government also induced changes in top management by appointing seasoned bureaucrats with strong manage- ment and business acumen. In addition, West Bengal has been exceptional by consistently raising tariffs— each year from FY2008/09 through FY2011/12. However, the West Bengal ­ distribution utility received regulatory approval to raise tariffs only after three years of significant improvements in power supply and energy access, improved customer service (including universal metering and computerization of billing), ­ and negligible dependence on state subsidies. Improvement of Corporate Governance The autonomy and functioning of boards of directors of state power utilities can be improved as can the length of directors’ management tenures (managing directors of most state utilities have an average tenure of about one year). Timely audits of finances and information on energy flows are also necessary inputs to performance improvement. Reference RBI (Reserve Bank of India). 2012. Financial Stability Report, Issue No. 6. Mumbai, India: Reserve Bank of India. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 CHAPTER 7 Emerging Issues and Proposed Approaches for the Indian Power Sector Emerging Issue: The Need for Better Partnership Mechanisms with the Private Sector First Proposed Approach: A Combined Generation and Distribution Contract Loss reduction and efficiency improvement have been the main bidding variables to date in competitive selection of private partners for distribution. However, these factors need not remain the sole criteria for looking at private sector par- ticipation in the power distribution segment. There are now several private sec- tor players who have built up significant portfolios in power generation projects and who are keen to participate in the distribution business so that they can contribute to reducing their own risks in the generation segment. Combining the procurement of power (case 1 bid) with a distribution franchisee (DF) bid would create a win-win situation for the licensee (state utility) and the franchisee (case 1) generation bidder (figure 7.1). Private sector participants may be able to add significant value in terms of power procurement cost-related efficiencies, if the revenues from the sale of power from their own generating assets are financially secured through revenues expected to be sourced from distribution franchise areas that they also operate. The whole cost of intermediation through the state utility can be avoided, which can lead to lowered risk perceptions, thereby result- ing in lower power costs. Evidence already shows that the outcome of case 1 bids run by financially stressed licensees (utilities) have yielded higher tariffs in com- parison to the outcomes of projects run by more progressive and fiscally sound states such as Gujarat. In view of those results, and if one considers that several major private sec- tor power generation companies in the country also have expertise in the power distribution businesses, bundling a power procurement bid under a case 1 bidding route with a distribution franchise bidding process could be a win-win situation for licensees. This situation could work for an identified Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   115   116 Emerging Issues and Proposed Approaches for the Indian Power Sector Figure 7.1  Combining Distribution Franchisee Bid with Case 1 Sale of power to discom IPP Payment to IPP for power purchase Payment to discom for power input Utility account or DF escrow Credit or debit Discom matching monthly settlements Note: The dashed line is not an actual cash flow, but rather a monthly settlement. The bold line is delivery of power, and the notched lines are flow of money. DF = distribution franchisee; discom = distribution company; IPP = independent power producer. urban area with adequate revenue potential. For example, a special purpose escrow fund could be established to channel the payables from the DF for energy input received from the licensee (state utility) to the receivables of the generation business against sale of power to the licensee by the selected developer. In other words, the state utility remains involved, but the power seller knows that the revenues for the sale of power to the licensee from its generation business are not dependent on the parlous financial condition of the state utility. Instead, the revenues to pay for the power are emanating from the DF, which has direct access to customers. Furthermore, the DF would be controlled by the same entity that is supplying the power. The state utility (licensee) is effectively serving an intermediary function, and the ben- efits are flowing to the franchisee’s customers in the form of cheaper and more reliable power, and possibly also to the customers who are directly served by the state utility—that is, those outside the franchise area. The spe- cial purpose escrow fund guarantees that the funds from the DF are not comingled with the rest of the state utility’s revenues, but are ring-fenced for payment to the power generation company. To reiterate, the arrangement discussed would substantially eliminate the pay- ment security risk associated with the sale of power, as perceived by the selected developer, particularly because the size of the DF ring-fenced area may be pro- gressively increased in concentric circles on the basis of good performance and customer satisfaction with improved power supply quality. It may, therefore, hold immense potential for the licensee (state utility) to be able to access Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Emerging Issues and Proposed Approaches for the Indian Power Sector 117 competitive or lower-priced power to meet the state’s supply requirements at lower costs resulting from lower risk perceptions. Second Proposed Approach: Private Sector Engagement for Project Management Capacity, Information Technology Expertise, and New Technology for the Grid Another model could be one to promote new, specific, and capital-intensive technology interventions, such as advanced metering infrastructure and SmartGrid initiatives, under a franchisee-like private sector participation scheme in which the selected franchisee is required to undertake capital invest- ments related to specific items. The revenue model could be similar to that of the DF, wherein the franchisee retains revenues from sale of power to retail customers and quotes an input rate for power supply at a predetermined input point to be provided by the licensee. This arrangement is similar to the existing DF model, except it does not leave the network upgrading investment strategy to the discretion of the franchisee but, instead, specifies what technologies shall be used. These technologies will eventually revert to the public sector when the franchise agreement ends. Third Proposed Approach: Urban Franchisees Partner with Rural Franchisees, as a Condition of the Urban Franchise Agreement, to Build Capacity and Upgrade the Rural Franchisee’s Scope of Work Rural franchisees are essential and have been helpful for utilities in improving the potential revenue collections from remote rural areas, which licensees have traditionally ignored. Rural franchisees are becoming more important as more and more villages and consumers are getting electrified and connected to the grid, leading to sharp increases in the demand for, and potential sale of, energy in rural areas. There are more than 37,000 rural franchisees operating across 18 states, though at present almost all of them are collection franchisees with limited responsibilities. Revenue collection franchisees need to be gradually converted to distribution transformer or feeder input-based franchisees. This conversion will ensure that the franchisees can more meaningfully contribute to transmission and distribution loss reduction and network operation and maintenance, in addi- tion to fulfilling their present responsibility of revenue collections. Urban franchisees are unlikely to partner with rural franchisees voluntarily. However, one possibility would be to include a license condition that an urban franchisee partner with a rural franchisee of its own choosing (in their state or another) and invest in that rural franchisee’s training and capacity building in a way that can measurably improve the rural franchisee’s productivity and perfor- mance. If appropriate capacity-building measures are taken to impart the requisite skill sets to the rural franchisees, then revenue collection franchisees could gradually be converted to input-based franchisees within a predetermined time ­ frame. The training programs introduced by the Rural Electrification Corporation Ltd. through the Central Institute for Rural Electrification could also be leveraged. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 118 Emerging Issues and Proposed Approaches for the Indian Power Sector Most important, partnerships structured with winners of bids for urban franchises would be expected to introduce rural franchisees to a commercial culture, develop their skills, and expose them to technology. Final Thought The road to recovery and high performance remains a long one. Much has been learned on the way, and many adjustments and modifications have been admira- bly made. New adjustments are needed to deal with the fuel risks that have recently emerged and to make better use of private service delivery and new technologies to reduce losses in power distribution. The most important chal- lenges still remain: fostering governance and leadership and reaching a consensus that the power sector should not be treated as a source of political patronage. No imported expertise or technique can expedite the political will. Once the political will is in place to fix the “leaking bucket” (as described in the memorable words of Shri Deepak Parekh1), no one will be able to hold back the power sector. With enough capable and experienced private investors, capital and expertise are poised to propel the sector forward into the 21st century and put wind in the sails of India’s overall economic growth. Accountability and com- mercial focus will transform the sector. Note 1. “India’s power sector is a leaking bucket; the holes deliberately crafted and the leaks carefully collected as economic rents by various stakeholders that control the system. The logical thing to do would be to fix the bucket rather than to persistently empha- size shortages of power and forever make exaggerated estimates of future demands for power. Most initiatives in the power sector (IPPs [independent power producers] and mega power projects) are nothing but ways of pouring more water into the bucket so that the consistency and quantity of leaks are assured. … Every MW [megawatt] of power produced today produces losses. Roughly speaking about 60% of the power produced is billed and about 60% of that is collected. Can we honestly run a power system sustainably in this manner?” (Shri Deepak Parekh, former Chairman of Infrastructure Development Finance Corporation, September 2001). Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 CHAPTER 8 Update This book analyzes the Indian power sector for the period from 1991 to 2012. Since then, several new bid processes have been conducted, particularly in distri- bution. The Ministry of Power (MOP) has recently taken steps to standardize bidding documents for selection of distribution franchisees (DFs). In addition, standard bidding documents (SBDs) for the generation sector have been com- pletely overhauled, and changes are being considered in the transmission sector, but are not yet finalized. This chapter provides a brief update—up to April 2014—on the changes that have followed the period analyzed in this book. Review of Progress on Selection of DFs During the past two years, the states of Jharkhand and Bihar have run bid pro- cesses for appointment of a DF for a substantial portion of their supply area. A summary of those bid processes is provided in table 8.1. Some standardization was seen in the requests for proposal (RFPs) issued dur- ing the period as evidenced in the incorporation of lessons and improvements in the previous rounds of bids. The MOP issued SBDs for the appointment of input-based DF in June 2012. The bidding documents in the state of Bihar issued during the subsequent period largely followed the SBD. Although the number of participants or bidders in the recent bid processes has not greatly expanded, those processes have been far more successful in taking the method of appointing a DF to a logical conclusion. Of seven processes initi- ated since mid-2012, the distribution franchisee agreements (DFAs) have been signed for five DF areas, and the process for two areas has not yielded the desired results. Major observations from the bid processes held since mid-2012 are as follows: • Utilities are increasingly trying to lean toward established and experienced players for larger and more important DF areas. The Jharkhand utility for Jamshedpur and Ranchi and the Bihar utility for Patna DF area had set the eligibility condition in a manner that limited participation exclusively to the leading experienced private sector utilities such as Tata Power Company Ltd., Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   119   120 Update Table 8.1  Bid Processes, Jharkhand and Bihar States, 2012–13 Area Area profile Bidders Successful bidder Patna, Bihar • Tenure: 15 years No bidders • Not applicable (2013 bid • Input: 2,133 MU process) • Consumers: 352,521 • Revenue: Rs 7.49 billion • AT&C loss: 41% Muzaffarpur, Bihar • Tenure: 15 years GTL Ltd., Essel • Essel Group • Input: 339.53 MU Group • DFA signed • Consumers: 132,714 • Operational since • Revenue: Rs 1.11 billion November 2013 • AT&C loss: 56.23% Gaya, Bihar • Tenure: 15 years GTL Ltd., Essel • DPSC Ltd. • Input: 330.84 MU Group, DPSC Ltd. • DFA signed • Consumers: 99,613 • Handing over expected in • Revenue: Rs 0.66 billion May 2014 • AT&C loss: 68.25% Bhagalpur, Bihar • Tenure: 15 years GTL Ltd., Essel • Subhash Projects • Input: 314.52 MU Group, DPSC Ltd., • DFA signed • Consumers: 115,669 Subhash Projects • Operational since January • Revenue: Rs 0.71 billion 2014 • AT&C loss: 67.90% Ranchi, Jharkhand • Tenure: 15 years CESC, Tata Power • CESC • Input: 1,500 MU Company Ltd. • Handing over pending • Consumers: 256,868 • Independent audit delayed • Revenue: Rs 3.13 billion • AT&C loss: 41% Jamshedpur, • Tenure: 15 years Tata Power • Tata Power Company Ltd. Jharkhand • Input: 1,394 MU Company Ltd., • Handing over pending • Consumers: 247,939 CESC • Independent audit delayed • Revenue: Rs 3.5 billion • AT&C loss: 32.81% Dhanbad, • Tenure: 15 years Essel Group • Process aborted because of Jharkhand • Input: 959 MU single bidder • Consumers: 1.8 million • Revenue: Rs 2.13 billion • AT&C loss: 45% Source: Deloitte research. Note: AT&C = aggregate technical and commercial; CESC = Calcutta Electric Supply Corporation; DFA = distribution franchisee agreement; MU = million units. CESC, Torrent Power Ltd., and Reliance Power Ltd. By the time these bid processes were initiated, the difficulties that newcomers to the sectors were facing at the operating DFs in Nagpur, Aurangabad, and elsewhere were well known. Therefore, with regard to the large and important areas being offered to the private sector for DFs, the distribution utilities have apparently been seeking to minimize performance risk by setting the qualification require- ments to attract significantly experienced and established players only. Although the bid for Patna failed because of the unreasonable reserve price set by the Bihar State Electricity Board (BSEB), the Jharkhand State Electricity Board (JSEB) has been able to appoint CESC for Ranchi and Tata Power Company Ltd. for Jamshedpur as the respective DFs. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Update 121 For smaller areas, which are not as attractive for large players, the utilities have set relatively relaxed qualification criteria for ensuring adequate partici- pation and competition in the bids. Such areas include Muzaffarpur, Gaya, and Bhagalpur in Bihar and Dhanbad in Jharkhand. • Utilities lack adequate systems and processes to conduct bid processes based on reliable and auditable data. The process for a third-party independent audit for the baseline data for Ranchi and Jamshedpur in Jharkhand has still not been completed despite signing of the DFA in December 2012. The qual- ity of records maintained and systems and processes of the erstwhile JSEB pose substantial challenges for conducting a quality audit process. Therefore, despite the appointment of reputable auditors for undertaking the process over a year ago, the process has not been concluded so far. However, BSEB, which also maintains poor records and has weak systems and processes in place, has chosen to proceed with the audit of the baseline records before the RFP stage itself. In the case of BSEB, no provision exists for any joint audit with the successful DF bidder, or any review at a post-award stage. The approach adopted by BSEB would stand only if the quality of the audits, which are being done upstream, is sufficient and balanced toward the interest of all parties. If the baseline information is found to be erroneous at a later date, there could be serious financial consequences for the private devel- opers–DFs as well as BSEB. • Utilities continue to use their monopolistic strength to negotiate terms with private players. Recent developments indicate that the distribution utilities, which happen to be the concessioning authorities in the DF appointment pro- cess, have been able to negotiate certain terms with the selected bidders that are beyond those specified in the bid documents and DFAs. Some of these instances are as follows: –– In the case of Ranchi and Jamshedpur, wherein the independent auditors were expected to be appointed by the respective selected developers (with due approval from the JSEB), the JSEB has eventually made the selected developers agree to devolve the responsibility of appointing the auditor onto itself. –– The bid documents and the clarifications issued during the pre-bid process had maintained that the funding of the ongoing, prepared, and approved schemes under the Restructured Accelerated Power Development and Reforms Programme (R-APDRP)1 would be undertaken by the BSEB or the respective successor licensees, following the unbundling process. The DFs were told that they would be responsible for only the investments required over and above those in the R-APDRP list. However, the selected developers for Muzaffarpur, Gaya, and Bhagalpur have now been made to agree to take on the cost of the funding of the (R-APDRP) so-called “Part B investments,” through a back-to-back arrangement with the BSEB and ­successor licensees. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 122 Update Issuance of SBDs for the Appointment of DFs In June 2012, the MOP issued SBDs for appointment of input-based DFs. Given the nature and extent of inconsistencies that were prevalent in the previous rounds of bids, the issuance of recommended SBDs by the MOP has been seen as a major step toward standardizing the process for appointment of DFs. Unlike the model documents published earlier by the Central Electricity Authority and the Forum of Regulators, the SBD issued by the MOP has addressed several important issues and attempts to balance the interests of all stakeholders. The SBD has already been used as the base document for the bid processes conducted in the state of Bihar for Bhagalpur, Gaya, Muzaffarpur, and Patna with due approvals from the regulator for the changes and adaptations made therein. Several of the key elements of the SBDs identified and recommended from the review have been addressed in the SBD issued by the MOP. However, further scope potentially exists for improving the SBD with regard to a number of clauses that are still not addressed and are being treated on a case-by-case basis. These points are summarized in table 8.2. Table 8.2  Elements Needing Improvement in Standard Bidding Documents Clause or aspect Rationale for inclusion in an SBD Selection of urban Because of experiences of successful and failed DF attempts, empirical franchisee area calculation of the “minimum energy input for the proposed area” is essential for identification of suitable areas and needs to be recommended by the Ministry of Power, in either the covering note or the annex to the SBD. Prequalification criteria The SBD prequalification criteria are too stringent and need to be relaxed to attract greater participation by prospective bidders in future DF bids. However, at present the utilities may adopt such relaxed criteria on a case-by-case basis depending on the size, attractiveness, and critical nature of the individual area(s). Consortium Allowing creation of a consortium is in the interest of attracting new players who have the financial capability to invest in the power sector but do not have the technical experience in the sector. Allowing the formation of consortiums would allow such players to take on a partner who could supplement their financial strength with the requisite technical capabilities. Input rate and loss Providing a reasonable and achievable loss reduction trajectory will provide reduction trajectory guidance to the utilities in fixing the same and for calculating the reserve prices in the bid documents. In the past, utilities have provided unreasonable loss reduction targets and reserve prices, leading to failure of several bid processes. Commercial and Such systems should be included for better transparency and timely action management in case of contractual default by the appointed DF. information systems and compatibility of information technology systems Note: DF = distribution franchisee; SBD = standard bidding document. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Update 123 Finalization of Key Terms of the Public-Private Partnership Model for Distribution The final report of the Task Force on Private Participation in Power Distribution (headed by B. K. Chaturvedi) issued in July 2012 has recommended adoption of a proposed public-private partnership (PPP) model for prospective private sector participation in the power distribution sector. The recommended PPP model requires identification of prospective areas that could be ring-fenced and carved out for a separate license under a special purpose vehicle (SPV). The shares in the SPV would then be sold to a private developer to be appointed through a competitive bid process under a design-build-finance- operate-transfer model. The assets in such carved-out area would continue to remain under the ownership of the state government or the incumbent licensee and would be transferred back to it at the end of the concession period. Although the state government would not have any equity in the SPV, it would be pro- vided with an affirmative vote on certain issues of public policy through a golden share. The SPV would operate as a normal licensee under the purview of the concerned state electricity regulatory commission and therefore would have flex- ibility for conducting power purchases and undertaking all necessary investments essential for making a quality and reliable supply available to the consumers. Key features of the recommended PPP model are summarized in table 8.3. Table 8.3  Key Features of the Recommended PPP Model Criteria Feature Compliance with the The concessionaire would be required to procure a distribution license Electricity Act of 2003 under Section 14 of the act. Feasibility report The state government would need to engage an experienced and qualified firm as technical consultant to prepare the feasibility report, which would be provided to the bidders as part of the bidding documents. Selection criteria Selection criteria would be based on open, competitive bidding. All project parameters would be clearly stated upfront. The short-listed bidders would be required to submit their financial bids. The bidder who seeks the lowest grant or offers the highest premium would win the concession. Concession model A design-build-finance-operate-transfer model would be adopted. Inventory of assets Replacement or repairs of defective assets such as transformers, cables, and so on during the concession period would have to be carried out by the concessionaire, who may retain or dispose of the defective equipment that has been replaced. Use of assets The concessionaire would be given the exclusive use of the distribution assets, but the ownership of the assets would remain with the state government. Concession period The concession will be granted for a period of 25 years in accordance with the provisions of the Electricity Act of 2003. Equity structure The state government would not have any share in the concessionaire’s company. The government would be provided with an affirmative vote on certain issues of public policy through a golden share. table continues next page Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 124 Update Table 8.3  Key Features of the Recommended PPP Model (continued) Criteria Feature Tariff The tariff would be set in accordance with the provisions of section 45(3) (a) of the Electricity Act of 2003. Wheeling and distribution The wheeling and distribution charge would be predetermined on the charge basis of the projected investment, the likely costs of distribution, and the trajectory of transmission and distribution losses. Continuation of financial The state government would have to provide substantial subsidies to the support concessionaire to prevent a sharp rise in tariffs, especially during the initial years of the concession period. The document lists three elements of subsidy in the system that may need to continue during the initial phase: (a) direct tariff subsidy; (b) cross-subsidy; and (c) uncovered distribution losses. Capital investment Based on the feasibility report, the bid document shall specify the level of investment for an initial period, such as five years, to be made by the concessionaire for augmenting and upgrading the existing distribution system to specified standards. Performance standards Operation and maintenance of the distribution system are proposed to be governed by strict performance standards with a view to ensuring a high level of service to the users. Loss reduction In accordance with the concession agreement, aggregate technical and commercial loss reduction would be done yearly. Transfer of assets At the end of the concession period, the concessionaire would be required to transfer a fully functional distribution system to the state government. Source: Government of India 2012. The states of Jammu and Kashmir, Uttar Pradesh, and Assam are reportedly considering the award of identified areas to private developers under the PPP route. However, not much progress has happened to date. Uttar Pradesh Power Corporation Ltd. had initiated a process for appointment of consultants for project formulation and undertaking of various preparatory activities for the award of Ghaziabad, Kanpur, Meerut, and Varanasi to private developers. However, the process was called off because of stiff resistance from employee unions. Although the proposed model does not lead to any privatization of existing assets owned by the state government, it is still perceived as similar to full priva- tization. The efficacy and acceptability of the PPP model are yet to be estab- lished. The detailed transaction documents have not been prepared so far and could possibly be created together with a real transaction process. The next few years will be crucial for developing model cases under this route. Impending Segregation of Wheeling and Supply License(s) The MOP, by Notification No. 42/6/2011-R&R (Vol-III) dated October 17, 2013,2 issued the proposed amendments to the Electricity Act of 2003, which are expected to be put up for debate and approval of the Lok Sabha (Lower House of Parliament, known as House of the People) during the 2014–15 winter Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Update 125 session of the Parliament. The proposed amendments seek segregation of wheel- ing and supply of electricity into distinct licensed activities. The manner in which the DF contracts are devised, the same envisaged roles, and the revenue streams pertain to both wheeling as well as supply of electricity. With the proposed segregation of wheeling and supply licenses, it is important that creation of the reporting responsibility of the DFs and the mechanism for segregation of the revenues to be generated from the DFS between two licensees is achieved in a fair and balanced manner. It is recommended that the process for the same should be initiated at the earliest opportunity, championed by the MOP. Review of Progress on Generation PPP Following legal and regulatory changes in Indonesia with respect to the tax on the sale of coal at a benchmark price, several imported coal–based power gener- ating stations approached the Central Electricity Regulatory Authority (CERC) for revision in tariffs in their power purchase agreements (PPAs) on grounds ranging from a change in law to force majeure. Ultimately, CERC, having consid- ered these representations for Coastal Gujarat Power Ltd. (a subsidiary of Tata Power Company Ltd. that is operating the Mundra ultra mega power plant [UMPP] project), ruled in April 2013 that a package of compensatory tariff shall be determined by a committee and should be paid to the generating company over and above the tariffs in the PPA to restore viability to the projects. The com- mittee’s recommendation was considered by CERC, which then passed an order in February 2014 for implementation of revision in tariffs.3 Similar revisions were determined for the Adani Power Ltd. project that was supplying power under the Case 1 route to more than one state utility. As observed previously, Coal India Ltd. (CIL) has since 2011 revised the New Coal Distribution Policy to reflect the shortage in supply of domestic coal for the thermal power projects commissioned over the 12th Five-Year Plan (2012–17). CIL’s annual contracted quantities (ACQs) for fiscal year (FY) 2014 through FY2017 were thus set at 65 percent, 65 percent, 67 percent, and 75 percent, respectively, of the letter of assurance (LOA). This approach confers on success- ful bidders with domestic coal under Case 1 and Case 2 processes an uncovered obligation to supply power up to 85–90 percent availability without adequate coal linkage for the same. After consulting CERC, the MOP issued a clarification to CERC and state electricity regulatory commissions in July 2013 that the dif- ference between the ACQ and the quantity in the LOA shall be allowed to be imported by CIL or by the generating station and allowed as a pass-through in tariffs under the PPA. While these fuel-specific issues were being addressed, the MOP started delib- erations on a new set of SBDs for Case 1 and Case 2, which were structured primarily on payment of energy charges on a predetermined basis with competi- tion focused mostly on efficient construction and operation of the power plant. The new set of SBDs were notified on November 9, 2013, and were substantially Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 126 Update different from the earlier formulations, which had been in existence since 2007. Two UMPP projects—a captive mine–based power project in Sundargarh district of Odisha and an imported coal–based power project in Kanchipuram district of Tamil Nadu—are the first two projects being bid out under the new set of SBDs. The following are some of the features of the new SBDs, that have been high- lighted by prospective bidders, lenders, and utilities as being likely to pose chal- lenges in implementation: • Deviations from guidelines (including SBD) are permitted only with the per- mission of the central government (as opposed to the appropriate commission according to the earlier guidelines). • Because the same documents have been circulated for case 1 and case 2, a two- stage process is the default for case 1 too and many provisions (such as select- ing one successful bidder) shall need necessary modification to be used practically for case 1. • No more than seven bidders are to be prequalified at the request-for-­ qualification stage. This provision is waived for UMPPs only, in which case all qualified bidders are short listed for the bid stage. Although this approach is acceptable for a case 2 process, several case 1 bid processes have resulted in multiple successful bidders at various quoted tariffs. Running a process with only seven qualified bidders can thus severely limit competition in case 1 procurement. • Qualification criteria are not distinguished between case 1 and case 2 procurement processes. Elaborate technical qualification criteria are appli- ­ cable for case 1 bidders, even though their generation projects may already be operational. • A clause on change in law for imported projects now recognizes legal changes in the countries from which coal is imported. • The SBD requires a fuel supply agreement to be signed for 25 years in favor of the utility, which is a highly unrealistic proposition because the longest coal supply agreements in the current market are for five years. This clause is likely to create issues particularly for imported coal–based projects, for which much shorter coal supply agreements are the market norm. An exception would be equity coal, that is, a coal supply agreement that is linked to a mine owned partly or fully by the plant sponsor, such as Tata Mundra’s agreement with mining subsidiaries of Bumi Resources Tbk., of which Tata Power Company Ltd. has 30 percent ownership. • Point of delivery is to be specified by the utility, and all quotes are for the point of delivery after factoring in auxiliary consumption and transmission losses. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Update 127 • Incentives are allowed in the form of an increase in the fixed charge, if the actual station heat rate (SHR) outperforms the prespecified SHR in the RFP. So far, even for stations whose tariffs are determined by the regulator, SHR is a normative parameter for computation of energy charges and actual SHR is not measured or determined by a third party. The SBDs thus introduce a new obligation to determine SHR, which can lead to differences over the operating period of the PPA. • Further, SHR is specified to be measured at the point of delivery, which is accept- able for case 2 projects but introduces an uncontrollable element of transmission losses for case 1 projects, and thereby adds a risk factor for the developer. • For case 1 procurement, utilities have concluded that separate bid processes must be conducted for each type of fuel—domestic linkage coal, captive coal, imported coal, and so on. Review of Progress on Transmission PPP Since 2012, a few interstate projects and one intrastate transmission project have been awarded through the competitive bidding route. These are listed in table 8.4. States have showed a general inclination for the Planning Commission model, because they are able to apply for central government financial assis- tance through viability gap funding (VGF) to the extent of 20 percent of the project cost, thus reducing the financial burden on the state government and end users. However, this isolated provisioning of VGF for only one segment of Table 8.4  Interstate and Intrastate Transmission Projects Awarded through the Bidding Process, 2013 Project Successful bidder Status Interstate (MOP model—BOOM) Kudgi Transmission Ltd. L&T Infrastructure Development SPV transferred Projects Ltd. Vizag Transmission Ltd. Power Grid Corporation of SPV transferred India Ltd. Purulia and Kharagpur Transmission Sterlite Grid Ltd. SPV transferred Company Ltd. Patran Transmission Company Ltd. Techno Electric and Engineering SPV transferred Company Ltd. RAPP Transmission Company Ltd. Sterlite Grid Ltd. SPV transferred NRSS–XXXI (A) Transmission Ltd. Power Grid Corporation of LOI Issued India Ltd. Intrastate (PC model—DBFOT) Satpura-Ashta 400 kV transmission line Kalpataru Power Transmission Ltd. LOI issued in April 2013 Source: Deloitte research, http://www.deloitte.com/view/en_BG/bg/insights/deloitte-research. Note: BOOM = build-own-operate-manage; DBFOT = design-build-finance-operate-transfer; kV = kilovolt; LOI = letter of intent; MOP = Ministry of Power; PC = Planning Commission; SPV = special purpose vehicle. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 128 Update the power sector value chain is an incongruity that the central government may need to reassess, especially because competitive bidding is the mandatory route for construction of transmission projects under the National Tariff Policy. The estimated expenditure on transmission projects under the 12th Five-Year Plan is Rs 1,800 billion (~US$30 billion). If VGF is to be provided to all state-sector projects, the extent of central government assistance can be very high and needs to be carefully assessed. The use of VGF therefore raises doubts about the sus- tainability of supporting such large investments in a single power sector seg- ment, where recovery of full costs through user (transmission) charges has not generally been a problem and thus the feasibility of such projects has not been much in doubt. Since the framing of SBDs by both the MOP and the Planning Commission, a significant change in transmission charges and sharing methodology (point of con- nection [POC] charges) was implemented by the CERC for the interstate trans- mission system effective November 2011. The POC methodology determines transmission charges and losses based on connection nodes in the network and does not require the beneficiary to pay for individual elements or projects in the interconnected transmission system. This delinking of assets from beneficiaries requires a change in the counterparty to the transmission service agreement (TSA) entered into by the independent transmission service provider. The MOP has been working on revising its SBD to align itself with this changed regime, where the TSA will need to be entered into with Power Grid Corporation of India Ltd., which in turn will provide the service of collecting all POC charges and reimburs- ing private transmission developers for their share of transmission charges. Notes 1. The Ministry of Power launched the R-APDRP in July 2008. This program, with a focus on establishment of baseline data, fixation of accountability, reduction of aggre- gate technical and commercial losses up to 15 percent through strengthening and up-gradation of the subtransmission and distribution network, and adoption of infor- mation technology (IT), will result in recommendations that shall be taken up in two parts. Part A shall include the projects for establishment of baseline data and IT appli- cations for energy accounting and auditing and for IT-based consumer service centers. Part B shall include regular distribution-strengthening projects and will cover invest- ments in system improvement, strengthening and augmentation, and so on. 2. For further detail, see http://www.powermin.nic.in/acts_notification/electricity_act2003​ /­pdf/Draft_amendments_in_Electricity_Act_2003.pdf. 3. Procurer utilities have since filed appeals against this order with the Appellate Tribunal for Electricity. Rajasthan and Punjab filed by April 2014, and a few others were considering doing so shortly thereafter. Reference Government of India. 2012. Report of the Task Force on Private Participation in Power Distribution. Secretariat for Infrastructure, New Delhi. http://www.infrastructure.gov​ .in/pdf/Private_Participation_in_Power_%20Distribution.pdf. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 APPENDIX A Organization of the Power Sector in India Electricity is under the jurisdiction of both the central (federal) and state provincial) governments, that is, both governments have powers to legislate on (­ the subject. Figure A.1 depicts the institutional structure at the central and state levels. At the central level, the Ministry of Power is responsible for the policy- related aspects of the sector and overall sector planning is entrusted to the Central Electricity Authority (CEA). However, the role of the CEA has been diluted over the past few years to the point where it now focuses mainly on the national grid and reviews of large hydropower project applications. The Central Electricity Regulatory Commission addresses the regulatory aspects of the sector involving more than one state. State electricity regulatory commissions address regulatory issues at the state level. In line with the philosophy of a national grid, the National Load Dispatch Centre and the regional load dispatch centers are envisaged as system operators in the national and regional networks, with each state housing a state load dispatch center. Figure A.2 shows the main entities in the power sector. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   129   130 Organization of the Power Sector in India Figure A.1  Institutional Structure of the Electric Power Infrastructure At central level At state level Policy • Ministry of Power • State government • Central Electricity Authority Planning • State government (CEA) • Central Electricity Regulatory • State Electricity Regulations Commission Regulatory Commission • Central Advisory Council • State Advisory Council • National Load Dispatch Centre System (NLDC) • State Load Dispatch operations • Regional Load Dispatch Centre (SLDC) Centre (RLDC) Dispute • Appellate Tribunal resolution Source: CRIS analysis. Figure A.2  Key Players in the Electric Power Infrastructure Sector Generation Transmission Distribution • NTPC; NHPC • PGCIL Central sector • NPCIL • State • State • State generating transmission distribution companies utilities such as companies such as State sector such as GSEC GETCO and MSETCL MSEDCL, UGVCL, and Mahagenco and DHBVN • Integrated utilities, such as Kerala SEB and Bihar SEB, that are not yet unbundled under provisions of Electricity Act of 2003 • Large number of • Few JV companies: • Few players private generation Tala Transmission such Tata Power, companies such as Project, Torrent Power Ltd., Private sector Tata Power, Reliance JSW–Maharashtra JV and Reliance Power Ltd., • IPTC such as Reliance Power Ltd. and Adani Power Ltd. Power Transmission Company Traders: PTC India Ltd., Adani Power Ltd., JSW Steel Ltd., and Tata Power Trading Company Ltd. Note: DHBVN = Dakshin Haryana Bijli Vitran Nigam; GETCO = Gujarat Energy Transmission Corporation Limited; GSEC = Gujarat State Electricity Corporation Ltd.; IPTC = independent power transmission company; JV = joint venture; Mahagenco = Maharashtra State Power Generation Company Ltd.; MSEDCL = Maharashtra State Electricity Distribution Company Ltd.; MSETCL = Maharashtra State Electricity Transmission Company Ltd.; NHPC = National Hydroelectric Power Corporation; NPCIL = Nuclear Power Corporation of India Ltd.; NTPC = National Thermal Power Corporation; PGCIL = PowerGrid Company of India Ltd.; SEB = state electricity board; UGVCL = Uttar Gujarat Vij Company Ltd. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 APPENDIX B Dabhol–Enron: The First Lesson Learned under the New Independent Power Producer Policy Table B.1  Dabhol Power Project: Timeline of Key Events Timeline Dabhol power project—key eventsa 1991–92 India opens its power sector to private foreign investors. February 1992 Enron Corporation begins investigating opportunities in the Indian power sector. June 1992 Enron and General Electric (GE) sign a memorandum of understanding with the Maharashtra State Electricity Board (MSEB) to begin the Dabhol power project. The operating entity, Dabhol Power Company, forms as a joint venture with Enron (majority owner, 65 percent), MSEB (15 percent), GE (10 percent), and Bechtel Corporation (10 percent). A project capacity of 2,184 megawatts (MW) is envisaged in two phases of 740 MW and 1,444 MW, along with an integrated 5 million metric tonnes per annum liquefied natural gas (MMTPA LNG) terminal. December 1993 Dabhol Power Company and MSEB sign a power purchase agreement (PPA). 1994–95 Enron obtains US$635 million in financing, insurance, and loan guarantees from Bank of America, ABN AMRO Bank, a group of Indian banks, Export-Import Bank of the United States, and Overseas Private Investment Corporation (OPIC). 1995 A new government is voted to power in the state elections. Munde Committee is appointed to review the Dabhol power project. Maharashtra state government issues notice to end the project. Enron enters arbitration and seeks compensation. The state government files suit to void the agreement, alleging fraud and misrepresentation. February 1996 The state and Dabhol Power Company agree to and finalize a revised agreement. 1997 Enron obtains approval from the central government to expand the Dabhol LNG terminal to allow it to process 5 MMTPA. May 1999 Dabhol phase 1 (740 MW) begins generating power. January 2001 The state stops payment to Dabhol power project on its December 2000 bill and subsequently seeks to cancel the PPA. table continues next page Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   131   132 Dabhol–Enron: The First Lesson Learned under the New Independent Power Producer Policy Table B.1  Dabhol Power Project: Timeline of Key Events (continued) Timeline Dabhol power project—key eventsa April 2001 Enron begins arbitration proceedings. May 2001 MSEB rescinds the PPA. June 2001 Dabhol Power Company ceases operation of phase 1 and halts construction on phase 2 (1,444 MW), which is 90 percent complete. December 2001 Enron files for bankruptcy in the United States under allegations of large-scale corporate fraud and corruption. March 2002b Indian lenders move that the Bombay High Court appoint a court receiver. Punj Lloyd Ltd. is appointed as court receiver for undertaking the preservation of plant assets. November 2004 Union Cabinet of India constitutes an Empowered Group of Ministers. The central government plans to revive the project. Restructuring framework is approved, and stakeholder negotiations begin. July 2005 Settlements are reached between Indian and offshore stakeholders. Payments are made to foreign lenders, OPIC, GE, and Bechtel against release of all future claims. July 8, 2005 Ratnagiri Gas and Power Private Ltd. (RGPPL) is incorporated with an equity contribution from the National Thermal Power Corporation (NTPC); GAIL Ltd.; and a group of financial institutions, including ICICI Bank, IDBI Bank, the State Bank of India, Canara Bank, Industrial Finance Corporation of India Ltd., and Gujarat Industries Power Company Ltd., to take over the project and complete its revival. September 2005 RGPPL board approves an investment of Rs 10,303 billion for acquiring and reviving the assets of the former Dabhol power project. RGPPL and international finance institutions (IFIs) sign a common term loan agreement giving effect to a loan facility and to the equity contribution of promoters to acquire the assets of the project. Present Shareholding structure of RGPPL is as follows: NTPC (31.52 percent), GAIL (31.52 percent), IFIs (20.28 percent), and MSEB (16.68 percent). Dabhol power project’s power blocks are fully revived and operational as a result of gas links from the Krishna-Godavari Basin. LNG terminal is undergoing investments in backwater infrastructure for revival. Note: MSEB = Maharashtra State Electricity Board; MW = megawatt; NTPC = National Thermal Power Corporation; ​ PPA = power purchase agreement. a. Minority Staff Committee on Government Reform. 2002. “Fact Sheet: Background on Enron’s Dabhol Power Project.” U.S. House of Representatives, February 22, http://finance-mba.com/Dabhol_fact_sheet.pdf. b. Deloitte research. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 APPENDIX C Summary Case Studies of Distribution Privatization Highlights of the Orissa Reform Experience Following an unsuccessful attempt at private participation through the manage- ment contract route in the central zone distribution company, the government of Orissa established the privatization program and simultaneously divested 51 percent ownership in its four distribution utilities in 1999. Whereas manage- ment control of three distribution companies (discoms) was transferred to the highest bidder, the transfer of the fourth discom (Central Electricity Supply Company, CESCO) proved unsuccessful after two rounds of bidding. Therefore, management control of the fourth discom was transferred to an international investor, AES Ltd., on a negotiated route. The transfer of ownership in distribution and generation companies resulted in substantial monetary inflows for the government of Orissa. Because the state government concluded that the sector as a whole would improve under private ownership in distribution, the state stopped all forms of subsidy support to dis- tribution companies. But several unforeseen developments took place shortly after privatization in Orissa. In late 1999, a super cyclone (hurricane) caused substantial damage to the electrical network, especially in the CESCO areas. The state government maintained its position of not providing subsidy support to distribution compa- nies. AES quit CESCO in 2001, and the distribution undertakings were subse- quently transferred to the public sector again through the Central Electricity Supply Undertaking (CESU) in 2006. In 2004, the Orissa Electricity Regulatory Commission had instituted a mul- tiyear tariff regime, accepting actual starting loss levels in 2004 and setting more realistic targets of loss reduction over the first and second control periods. As a result, two of the discoms (Wesco and Nesco) are now close to break even with tariff increases also granted in 2011 and 2012. However, their efforts at reducing transmission and distribution losses, even after a decade and a half of private ownership, have been far below expectations. Rural electrification, which was Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   133   134 Summary Case Studies of Distribution Privatization an unfinished agenda item at the start of privatization, has been completely neglected; more than half of households in Orissa still lack access to electricity. CESU and Southco continue to be the most inefficient discoms, requiring sub- stantive focused efforts at improving efficiencies. After Orissa’s experience, many states adopted similar reform approaches at the end of the 1990s and early 2000s. Assam, Delhi, Gujarat, Haryana, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, Rajasthan, and Uttar Pradesh adopted state-level legislation to reform their power sectors. Delhi has succeeded in privatizing distribution under a performance-linked, benefit-sharing model. Highlights of the Delhi Distribution Privatization Experience To combat the worsening power situation it faced, the government of Delhi developed a Strategy Paper in 1999 that envisaged the following: (a) establishing a state-level regulatory commission, (b) unbundling the consolidated electricity company, Delhi Vidyut Board (DVB), (c) increasing disinvestment in the distri- bution segment, (d) implementing interim measures to improve the perfor- mance of the DVB, and (e) protecting staff members’ interests. The reform process continued with setting up and operationalizing the Delhi Electricity Regulatory Commission and appointing consultants to undertake the reforms process. A tripartite agreement was signed, ensuring no retrenchment of staff, no change in service conditions, continuity of service under DVB and the restructured entities, creation of a retirement benefits fund managed by a trust, continuation of welfare schemes, and an ad hoc pay increase of Rs 500 per month upon transfer to the new corporate entities. Thereafter, in 2000, the Delhi Assembly proposed the Delhi Electricity Reform Bill that was finally passed as the Delhi Electricity Reform Act in 2001 (after presidential assent). The act furthered reform initiatives in the state and eventually resulted in privatization of the distribution segment. Six prospective bidders were prequalified, of which five were Indian and one was international (AES Corporation). To take the process forward, six shell companies (a holding company, a generating company, a transmission company, and three distribution companies) were registered. Those companies would become the successor enti- ties upon operationalization of the transfer scheme. Thereafter, the government issued the transfer scheme rules leading to the opening balance sheets of the new entities and outlined the manner in which the assets and functions would be transferred to the new entities. Unlike in Orissa, where the state sought to sell its stakes to the highest bidder, the Delhi privatization process recognized that loss reduction was the top prior- ity and structured its bid variable accordingly. The Delhi bids, which were received on the basis of the aggregate technical and commercial loss reduction to be achieved postprivatization, were initially not acceptable to the Delhi govern- ment. Therefore, negotiations were held with the preferred bidders. In June 2002, the negotiations resulted in successful agreement on the loss reduction trajectory, execution of the shareholders’ agreement, and other issues. The successor entities Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Summary Case Studies of Distribution Privatization 135 finally became effective at midnight on June 30, 2002. The Brihanmumbai State Electricity Supply emerged as the preferred bidder for two discoms, and Tata Power for the third discom. The Delhi experience has been the only example of electricity distribution privatization in India’s postreform era. The stakeholders have benefited from the privatization exercise in the following manner: • The Delhi government benefits from a reduced burden on the exchequer, and efficiency levels have improved and are now among the best in the country. • Consumers receive a reliable and high-quality supply. There is significant ­ difference in the customer service orientation, relative to the DVB days. For example, the number of payment centers has increased from about 20 to more than 5,000. Reliability of supply has improved dramatically. More than 40 percent of the workforce is new (old and aging DVB employees were offered an attractive voluntary retirement scheme), and capital investments have been consistently maintained, leading to substantial system strengthening. • Barring a couple of years, the private utilities have not experienced losses and have been able to raise funds from the market to invest in the network and systems. The Delhi experience has been unique because of the Delhi government’s well-conceived plan that consisted of the following: • Fixing achievable loss reduction and other improvement targets during the initial years of the transition period kept the focus on efficiency improvement alive during the entire process. Efficiency improvement and reduction in losses were considered the most significant measures for reducing the cost of supply to authorized customers, thus helping avoid tariff increases. • The Delhi government’s transition support, amounting to Rs 34.5 billion during the first five years of the existence of the private utilities, helped the private utili- ties avoid the cash crunch they would have otherwise faced during the initial years when the efficiency levels were extremely poor, as was the case in Orissa. • Following an inclusive approach by bringing the regulator, government, and other key stakeholders together helped resolve issues that were likely to affect the success of the project during the transition period. Making the bid param- eters binding on the Delhi Electricity Regulatory Authority for the purpose of tariff determination was among the key measures for building and ensuring investor confidence in the privatization process. The key benefit for the Delhi government when it undertook electricity sector reforms was having the live example of Orissa, which demonstrated that the mere transfer of ownership to a private party was no guarantee for efficiency improvements and improved customer service levels. For success in any possible future distribution privatization initiatives with transfer of ownership that may ever be considered, one must understand the key differences between these two beacons in terms of the process followed and outcomes achieved. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 APPENDIX D Post-2012 Generation and Uncertainties Related to Domestic and Imported Fuel Supply Despite the initial success of tendering more than 50,000 megawatts (MW) of projects under either case 1 or case 2, developments from the start of the 12th Five-Year Plan in April 2012 have revealed significant structural and policy issues that need to be addressed for the sector to move to predominantly private- led capacity additions. Our concluding comments on generation are related to the most pressing issue of fuel supply, in terms of not only domestic coal and imported coal, but also the indexation used by the Central Electricity Regulatory Commission (CERC). Apart from fuel supply, the other two red-flag issues iden- tified (governance and liquidity risk) are also important, but we believe that fuel uncertainty is holding back private investment in the 12th Five-Year Plan (2012–17). Therefore, we focus on that issue. Domestic Coal-Related Uncertainties It has been proposed for consideration that the failure of Coal India Ltd. (CIL) to meet its fuel supply agreement (FSA) commitments could be solved by CIL purchasing coal for import and that the prices of such purchases should be eligible for pass-through in the FSAs as well as the associated power purchase ­ agreements (PPAs). This proposal appears to be a workable solution, but only if the quantities of shortfalls are minimal and only in the nature of interim deficits. Ultimately, projects that have been developed on the basis of domestic coal should obtain domestic coal, and separate projects should be planned on the basis of imported coal. Blending of coal, although feasible in theory, is not always technically feasible or economically the best choice, because it does not allow for efficiencies in procurement and use of imported coal. Depending on the physical condition and properties of the coal that is being blended, the combustion efficiency and carbon loss might be affected. In addition, the presence of trace ­ Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   137   138 Post-2012 Generation and Uncertainties Related to Domestic and Imported Fuel Supply elements (such as mercury) could increase ash deposition, thereby affecting corrosion and precipitator performance. ­ After CIL failed to meet the March 31, 2012, deadline for signing FSAs, as set out in the directive issued by the Prime Minister’s Office, the Ministry of Coal announced a presidential decree forcing CIL to guarantee long-term fuel supply, even if it has to import the coal. Accordingly, the CIL board approved the modi- fied FSA applicable to thermal power stations commissioned between April 1, 2009, and December 31, 2011, as recommended by the Central Electricity Authority and the Ministry of Power. The FSA to be signed, with some 48 companies for 18,522-MW capacity mandates, contains a commitment to supply ­ 80 percent of the coal requirement of each company. A token percentage of the basic value for the shortfall quantity has been specified, which would be effective three years after the date of signing the FSA. For a list of some projects facing fuel-related issues, see table D.1. Table D.1  Selected Private Sector Generation Projects Facing Fuel-Related Issues Status update/ Project Developer Fuel type COD Issues Mundra UMPP Tata Power Imported coal All five units The regulatory changes in the pricing of have been Indonesian coal makes the product commissioned market linked, which poses critical Krishnapatnam Reliance Power Imported coal Construction work challenges for imported fuel–based UMPP Ltd. stopped projects. Developers of projects that have already Mundra Phase 1 Adani Power Ltd. Imported coal 2009–10 been bid are seeking rate revisions to Mundra Phase 2 Adani Power Ltd. Imported coal 2010–11 ensure viability. CERC has granted rate Mundra Phase 3 Adani Power Ltd. Imported coal 2010–11 revisions to a few projects; this has been Ratnagiri JSW Steel Ltd. Imported coal 2010–11 challenged by procurers before the ATE. Mundra Phase 4 Adani Power Ltd. Blended coal 2012–13 Fuel security issues have arisen from both (domestic + domestic and imported fuel sources, imported) because the domestic coal link lacks sufficient quantity and Indonesian coal prices have increased. Mundra Phase 3 Adani Power Ltd. Domestic coal 2012–13 Even after signing the FSA with GMDC to supply 4 MTPA of coal from Morga II block, supply of the committed quantity could not be ensured because the MOEF refused to permit mining in the blocks falling under the “no-go” area. CLP Jhajjar CLP India Private Domestic coal 2012–13 This is a case 2 project, which has continued Ltd. to face coal supply shortages. Tiroda Phase 3 Adani Power Ltd. Domestic coal 2012–13 The MOEF withdrew terms of reference for mining in allocated Lohara block because of its proximity to a tiger reserve. AES AES Ltd. Domestic coal 2016–17 The MOEF declared the allocated Sayang Chhattisgarh coal block a no-go area. Mahan Essar Captive coal 2012–13 The MOEF declared Mahan coal block in Madhya Pradesh a no-go area. Note: ATE = Appellate Tribunal for Electricity; CERC = Central Electricity Regulatory Commission; COD = commercial operation date; FSA = fuel supply agreement; GMDC = Gujarat Mineral Development Corporation Ltd.; MMTPA = million metric tonnes per annum; MOEF = Ministry of Environment and Forests; UMPP = ultra mega power plant. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Post-2012 Generation and Uncertainties Related to Domestic and Imported Fuel Supply 139 Suggestions have been made that pending resolution of linkage and captive allocation issues, energy charges from case 1 projects should also be made a pass- through in tariffs. We believe that this suggestion is regressive and is an attempt to fix a default in commitment and performance by CIL through relaxations in the PPA—that is, an attempt to place the burden of CIL’s shortcoming on the power customer. The only lasting solution is for all parties in the power sector value chain to honor their contractual commitments. Therefore, it is imperative for CIL to be more transparent and sign binding FSAs with developers, and these FSAs should have predetermined, serious penalties for defaults. (At present, the penalty has been set at a nominal level, which is unlikely to have any meaningful financial effect). Imported Coal Uncertainties There are two fundamental issues that have been raised by stakeholders with regard to the bidding framework adopted for competitive bidding of imported coal–based projects: • Does the framework ensure that the least cost power is being procured at all times? • Does the framework adequately compensate bidders for regulatory changes in the country from which the coal is being imported? With regard to the first question, there have been concerns (voiced by p ­ rocurers and auditors) about the efficacy of the competitive bidding frame- work because of the outcomes of the Mundra ultra mega power plant (UMPP) bid process and the current tariffs that the project is incurring. Comparing the bids of Tata Power and Adani Power Ltd. in Mundra UMPP, many people have noted that Adani’s tariffs would have remained below Rs 3 per unit for long periods over the term of the PPA. In contrast, Tata Power’s tariffs1 have escalated significantly—45 percent of their energy charges are linked to international coal indexes, which have risen from around US$50/ton at the bidding stage to the current level of US$120/ton. Although there could be merits in improving the indexations developed by CERC for both evaluation and payment, one should not compare the payment streams of two bidders for a year and then draw conclusions about the efficacy of the competitive bidding system. Assumption of all coal-related price variation risks by the bidder is not an ideal scenario and is rather impractical. Therefore, although Adani’s bid (which assumed all coal-related price variation risks) would theoretically have yielded better results for the procurer at this point in time, one cannot determine how Adani could have made this project profitable with fixed coal-related compensation and in a scenario where substantial regulatory changes have raised the price of coal from Indonesia and Australia in particular. We already have the example of similar bidding practices in the Krishnapatnam UMPP, resulting in a project that is not proceeding. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 140 Post-2012 Generation and Uncertainties Related to Domestic and Imported Fuel Supply On the issue of compensation in tariffs for unanticipated and fundamental regulatory changes in the country from which coal is being imported (that is, Indonesia), the following aspects must be considered: • The effect of the regulatory changes is, undoubtedly, substantial, and the changes would have clearly been difficult for any bidder to anticipate. The most likely scenario is that none of the bidders factored these changes into their bids for the Mundra UMPP. Tata Power (the winning bidder) has argued that regulatory changes should be considered as a force majeure incident, given the bidders’ lack of control over such an eventuality and given those changes’ critical relevance to the project. This argument is made even though the PPA did not provide for any political force majeure for regulatory or policy changes outside India. Although the circumstances in which Tata Power finds itself are unfortunate, Tata Power may be able to successfully claim the regula- tory changes as a force majeure incident under the agreement. A preferable approach may be for the government of India/CERC to mediate and work with both Tata Power and the concerned distribution companies to reach a mutual agreement on revisions to the PPA. • Conceivably, the effect of these regulatory changes will be reflected in future contracts and should be factored into the benchmark price index for Indonesian coal. If bidders had a substantial part of their bid in the escalable component, with adequate incorporation of discounts to benchmark prices (because of a long-term contract with preferential sale prices), they would be hedged against such risks. • In revisions to the standard bidding documents, a fundamental change in law in countries from which coal is being imported should be allowed in the PPA. Improvement in CERC Indexation The escalation rates approved by the CERC for imported coal are determined today using API4 (price of South African coal) for short-term data series. Almost 60–70 percent of the fuel contracts are long-term contracts on which these esca- lation rates (based on short-term data) are applied. Major fuel imports in India are mostly from Indonesia, followed by Australia. The current indexation does not incorporate price fluctuations or indexes for import from these countries, and this would appear to be a major problem area. Given the large quantum of coal imports required for large-sized thermal power units planned under supercritical technology in India, it makes sense to provide tailor-made indexes for each country of import rather than arriving at a composite index. PPAs could then recognize the primary country of import and allow country-specific price indexation. This adjustment would closely reflect the underlying pricing structure in the long-term coal supply agreements and would remove any index-related uncovered risks for bidders. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Post-2012 Generation and Uncertainties Related to Domestic and Imported Fuel Supply 141 Note 1. According to the tariff-based competitive bidding guidelines, the bidders can quote separate escalable and nonescalable components of tariff (capacity charge and energy charge) as explained in chapter 2. Payment of the escalable components over the term of the PPA is based on payment indexes that CERC revises semiannually. Nonescalable components are paid as quoted for the contract year without any adjustments. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 APPENDIX E Emerging Challenges for Private Investment in Transmission Issues and Challenges for Private Transmission Line Developers Although private participation has been observed across all 15 projects that have been offered under competitive bidding, a few inherent challenges have now surfaced and have been acknowledged by all players in this segment (table E.1). Experience in Private Projects Being Implemented versus the Transmission Framework The biggest advantage that private players eventually bring is efficient project execution capabilities. However, the experience of private participation in the transmission space in India is too brief to conclude how successful the players have been in executing projects efficiently. The following observations can be made on inputs obtained from several developers that were contacted as part of this study. The initial optimism in private transmission that attracted a very broad base of players from divergent segments now appears to converge to a set of players who have requisite project management capabilities. This is reconfirmed from the recent bidding for the Nagapattinam–Cuddalore (450-kilometer, 765-kilovolt transmission lines) project for which 18 bidders showed initial interest but only five finally bid for the project. Private players are now realizing the virtues of undertaking detailed project cost estimation with a higher degree of prudence. For most of the projects bid out, there continues to be a very wide range in the bids submitted. This variation indicates a wide divergence in the risk percep- tion of developers and in their estimation of project costs. For example, in the recent Nagapattinam–Cuddalore project, the bid of PowerGrid Company of India Ltd. (PGCIL), which emerged as the winner, was just around 66 percent of the next bidder. This difference can be attributed to PGCIL’s eagerness to establish itself through competitive bid out projects, its experience in imple- menting transmission lines, and its ability to appreciate and handle project-related Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   143   144 Emerging Challenges for Private Investment in Transmission Table E.1  Risks for Private Transmission Line Developers Risk Particulars Financial closure With fuel issues affecting certain generation projects, transmission projects that are linked to evacuation of power from such generation projects are viewed as risky and have been affected. Payment default With the onset of the point-of-connection regime, a structural change has occurred in the modalities of transmission charges and routing to the transmission service provider. Point-of-connection regime provides for generation companies that have not identified their procurers to be beneficiaries under the transmission service agreement and take on obligations for payment of transmission charges. Although the PowerGrid Company of India Ltd. (PGCIL) obtains a deposit from all private generation players as part of the application process for connection to the interstate grid, this security is not available to transmission service providers. Private players bidding for transmission projects have asked for enhancement in the security obtained by PGCIL and for the ability to pass this on to the transmission service provider in case of defaults in timely execution of generation projects by the private developer. Approvals Private developers are responsible for obtaining all approvals and clearance related to the projects. Because transmission projects transverse long distances, each tower location could be considered as one specific project (specifically in the Indian context). Furthermore, forest clearances take long periods of time, and any delay in approval leads to cost escalation. Right of way Transmission lines themselves do not need any land acquisition. However, they require that a right of way be obtained for constructing and laying the towers. According to the Indian Telegraph Act of 1885, only crop compensation is to be paid to the farmers for a right of way and no additional payouts are envisaged. In practice though, obtaining a right of way involves not just crop compensation but also additional payments to the landowners to enlist their cooperation in ensuring that the towers are installed in time. For almost all developers, the cost attached to obtaining a right of way is impossible to estimate accurately and varies widely depending on the negotiations at the local level. Cost escalation Cost escalation is not a pass-through for private developers of transmission projects. This is always a concern because most projects could incur increased costs because of delays on account of lack of rights of way for laying the transmission towers. Transmission projects are structured under a competitive tariff-bidding route. Bidders are entitled to an agreed tariff over the period of the projects. At the time of bid submission, the bidders assume certain levels of capital expenditure. However, there are high probabilities of cost escalation owing to delays in multiple approvals related to the projects. In addition, volatilities in the cost of input materials cannot be predicted with precision. The bidder therefore must be prepared to bear escalation in the project cost. The bidding framework does not provide for any cost pass-through—in fact, the bidding framework does not require any disclosure of project cost assumed by the developer. risks confidently. PGCIL’s understanding of the transmission business is its defini- tive strength. For most of the regions where new extra-high voltage transmission lines are being proposed, PGCIL has existing operating lines. This provides PGCIL with an understanding of the topography and a better grasp of the imple- mentation challenges that are prevalent in the area. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Emerging Challenges for Private Investment in Transmission 145 The Way Forward Private participation in the transmission space will not stand on its own and must be viewed under the overall boundary of underlying generation projects to which it is proposed to be dedicated. In the Indian context, there are no concerns as such with regard to the public-private partnership framework under which trans- mission projects are envisaged. The concerns largely emanate from the perceived fate of the generation projects for the transmission projects that are proposed. For instance, the recent bidding for the Nagapattinam–Madhugiri interstate transmission lines had attracted many players when the bidding documents had been floated. However, at the time of bidding only a handful participated. Discussions with a few of the participants have indicated that most of them perceived risks concerning the commissioning of the underlying generation assets. Competitive bidding for transmission projects is now the default mode for project execution at both the interstate and intrastate levels. There are experi- ences in the course of implementing projects that are worth considering for undertaking improvements in the existing framework. These aspects are evalu- ated, and a way forward and a possible recommended approach around them are provided in table E.2. Table E.2  Evaluations and Recommended Approaches Area Approach Models Two models are currently considered for engaging private players in the transmission space. The MOP has created a set of standard bidding documents that are derived from tariff-based competitive bidding framework. The Planning Commission has also produced a framework that stems from a model built around bidding for grants based on pre-determined tariffs. The sector cannot afford to have dissimilar models of project development, particularly in transmission, which needs to move harmoniously toward a unified structure with universal application of the point-of-connection regime. The process outlined under the Planning Commission framework was not in conformity with Section 63 of the Electricity Act of 2003, which required guidelines to be issued by the central government, in this case the MOP. In 2012, the MOP clarified that the Planning Commission framework could be adopted for intrastate projects under the guidelines issued by the MOP. Elements of the Planning Commission model that are superior should be included in the standard bidding document issued by the MOP, and only one model should be available for implementation of tariff-based competitive bidding in the sector. Distributed Although PGCIL and the STU are currently responsible for the overall interstate and intrastate grids, ownership and a very dispersed ownership of elements of the grid will pose inevitable issues around interfacing implications on and communication, which are not insurmountable but would require strict standards and grid operations protocols under the Grid Code to be adhered to by all owners of transmission assets for an integrated operation of the grid. Grid codes are being progressively implemented by the SERCs. Section 86(1)(h) of the Electricity Act of 2003 provides that SERCs shall specify state grid codes that shall be consistent with the Grid Code formed by the CERC. For higher voltage levels, the SERCs mostly adopt the Grid Code promulgated by the CERC. We believe the STUs and CTU will have a larger role to play in ensuring that the capacity of private developers is built to adhere to grid-based protocols. table continues next page Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 146 Emerging Challenges for Private Investment in Transmission Table E.2  Evaluations and Recommended Approaches (continued) Area Approach State support Competitive guidelines consider project development–related risks to be best assumed by the agreement developer and are accordingly passed on to the successful bidder. This creates an obvious challenge for the project developer in terms of obtaining statutory approvals and clearances, and so on, which are widely dispersed and numerous for transmission projects. We observe that for most projects developed under the joint venture route with PGCIL, PGCIL that has been responsible for all clearances and approvals. As a public sector body, PGCIL is well positioned to handle such aspects that by nature do not come easily to private sector players. A mechanism for state support should be formulated with obligations by the state governments to support private players in obtaining all clearances and approvals so that the private players could continue to focus on more important aspects related to design, engineering, and execution. The continued role of the STUs and CTU in obtaining clearances and approvals is critical and should go beyond extending letters of support, as currently envisaged under the TSA. Generation Bidders are highly uncomfortable in accepting generation companies as signatories to a TSA and beneficiaries being responsible for payment of transmission charges. Adequate safeguards should be built into the TSA and the security collected by PGCIL from such generators enhanced to cover against risk of defaults in payment of transmission charges. However, there has been no instance of any commissioned transmission project under the IPTC route. Therefore, the possibility of any default on this account has not been observed under this structure. Parity among Private players consider PGCIL to have an advantage over them. This view is strengthened on bidders account of the following aspects: • PGCIL sits on the empowered committee that determines the projects to be bid out. Further, PGCIL is also a bidder for such projects. • PGCIL as a public sector undertaking has an edge when obtaining a right of way for transmission lines. Historically, for all lines owned by PGCIL, the onus for obtaining a right of way lies with PGCIL. • There is a likelihood that PGCIL may already be operating another line in the region where the new project being bid is considered for implementation. State support framework could be a way to create parity between the private players and PGCIL. Access to Many parties acknowledge that there is scope for improving the depth of information that is information provided to bidders. Information in general is considered wanting in the areas of topographical details, detailing of forest areas, existing natural hazards in the vicinity, and existing built structures in the vicinity. A standard template taking stock of the information that needs to be detailed while inviting bids for a project could be created. The survey report provided by the central bid process coordinators has been observed to be of poor quality and is rarely relied upon by serious bidders who must undertake their own surveys. Importantly, the survey reports should also elaborate on implementation risks emanating from the topography of the tentative route considered in the reports. Note: CERC = Central Electricity Regulatory Commission; CTU = central transmission utility; IPTC = independent power transmission company; MOP = Ministry of Power; PGCIL = PowerGrid Company of India Ltd.; SERC = state electricity regulatory commission; STU = state transmission utility; TSA = transmission service agreement. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 APPENDIX F Comparison of Privatization to the Distribution Franchisee Approach Privatization versus Distribution Franchisee Although the urban input-based distribution franchisee (DF) experience has clearly shown value in terms of acceptance by stakeholders and outcomes, con- cluding that it is better than complete privatization of distribution licensees would be premature. A comparison of the urban DF framework with complete privatization is shown in table F.1 to identify the key differences and similari- ties that could form the basis for improving either of the models in future transactions. An evaluation of the past cases of privatization and distribution franchising experiences reveals that the key reason for greater acceptance of the DF frame- work is its relative acceptance by the employees of the existing government- owned licensees compared with outright privatization. The privatization model offers several advantages over the DF model that may appear more important going forward. First, the private licensees operating under a perpetual license are in a much better position to introduce new and state-of-the-art technologies in the distribution and customer care infrastructure that may not appear appropri- ate to a DF because of the longer payback period for such investments. Several capital-intensive works could be beneficial from a customer service perspective, but may not have any tangible benefits for the franchisee, particularly closer to the end of the DF term. Second, with the primary responsibility for power pro- curement still resting with the licensee, the responsibility and the ability of the franchisee to make affordable and continuous power available to the ultimate consumers are limited to a substantial extent. Additionally, the urban DF framework appears to be tailored to suit high loss (aggregate technical and commercial loss), creating areas where the fran- chisee pays an input rate to the licensee for the amount of energy input into the area, thereby leaving enough margin for itself to incur capital expenses and operation and maintenance (O&M) expenses and earn a profit. The very essence of the franchisee model—the concept of funding the loss reduction Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   147   148 Comparison of Privatization to the Distribution Franchisee Approach Table F.1  Privatization versus Distribution Franchisee Parameters Privatization Distribution franchisee Term of agreement The term is perpetual. Fixed terms are typically for 10, 15, and 20 years. Choice of area If existing area of distribution company is not Configuring any potential area into a proposed preferred by bidders, substantial efforts area for franchisees is easy and flexible. must be made in getting a transfer scheme approved for reorganization into a separate distribution company with the preferred configuration. Ownership transfer Equity participation of 51 percent or more is No equity participation in licensee is needed. required. Responsibility All responsibilities are the same as those for a Power purchase (for additional procurement only) distribution licensee. Capital expenditure Operation and maintenance All revenue cycle activities Customer care Regulatory Private licensee is answerable to the regulator Franchisee is answerable only to the licensee recognition (SERC). Ability to No such provision has been seen in past cases. Licensee is free to terminate DF contract for DF terminate events of default. in events of default Binding efficiency Binding targets, as in the case of Delhi Licensee sets targets at the transaction stage. improvement privatization, may be agreed at the Licensee is isloated from the actual efficiency targets on transaction stage itself. levels once the input rate is determined private player through the competitive bidding process Employee care Existing employees are transferred to private Employees have the option to work for the licensee. Option for VRS may also be given. franchisee or to remain with the licensee. Note: DF = distribution franchisee; SERC = state electricity regulatory commission; VRS = voluntary retirement scheme. related capital expenditure through additional revenues generated by effective and rapid loss reduction initiatives—would no longer be valid if there were significant loss reductions to be achieved. Also, as has been seen in the case of rural areas where the retail tariffs are primarily cross-subsidized at the utility level, revenue recovery from the retail tariff for select or identified rural areas by the franchisee may not be sufficient for incurring capital and O&M expenses under the existing DF model, thus leaving such areas unattractive to prospec- tive bidders. Privatization of distribution business in select areas may hold the key to attracting private sector efficiencies in the distribution segment on a sustained and long-term basis and will need to be weighed against the franchisee mode. Clear insights from the Orissa and Delhi privatization experiences point toward the prerequisites and pitfalls in distribution privatizations in the country. Mere change in ownership is not a guarantee for efficiency improvements, and the privatization approach therefore needs to align the expectations of the state government, the regulatory commission, and the bidders. The Delhi model is clearly a step forward over the Orissa experience, but if privatization were to be Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Comparison of Privatization to the Distribution Franchisee Approach 149 considered by a state government, the following additional issues may need to be considered in future transactions: • Clear, long-term efficiency-level targets may be incorporated into the bidding process itself, which could be agreed upon or approved by the concerned regu- lator as part of the multiyear tariff regulations for the utility. • Desired outcomes in terms of customer service–related parameters, such as availability and reliability of supply, and so on, may be made mandatory on the licensee. The same requirements may be over and above the standards of ­ performance mandated by the concerned regulator. • Minimum capital expenditure for specified periods may be mandated as has been done in DF bids. • To keep a check on the retail tariffs, the government (bidding authority) may put specific limits or conditions on the controllable cost parameters. • The government (bidding authority) should have an option to terminate or cancel the appointment of the selected private player at any stage going for- ward in the event of clear default of conditions mandated at the bidding stage. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 APPENDIX G Recommendations for the Way Forward on Distribution Franchisee Selection Table G.1  Recommended Approaches on Distribution Franchisee Selection Clause or aspect Recommended approacha Selection for urban On the basis of a review of past experiences, the following desirable or mandatory attributes franchisee area may be considered for identifying or short-listing suitable areas for implementing the distribution franchisee (DF) framework: • The minimum size of the area, in terms of energy input, should be set to make the opportunity sizable and attractive for the desired set of potential investors. • An area with a high level of losses, a dense load base, and a subsidizing consumer base would make franchising an attractive proposition for the utility as well as the prospective bidders. Term of the agreement A longer time frame helps the franchisee undertake capital-intensive investments in the distribution system that may have longer payback periods but are in the interest of the reliability of the network and the quality of supply. Ideally, DFs should have a minimum term of 15 years. Prequalification criteria An important parameter that needs to be considered when fixing the prequalification criteria for appointment of DFs is found in the sixth proviso of Section 14 of the Electricity Act of 2003: the conditions for eligibility for grant of a distribution franchise should not normally be more onerous than the conditions for grant of a second distribution license, specifically in terms of capital adequacy, credit worthiness, and code of conduct. Although the prequalification criteria are standardized, they may still vary from case to case, which can be linked to the existing revenue size of the area or other parameters. In view of the limited number of players in power distribution and the successful precedence in the power generation, telecom, and banking and insurance sectors, any prospective bidder who meets the following criteria should be allowed to participate: • A company registered under the 1956 Companies Act • Experience in the power and allied sectors (the same may be defined appropriately) • Experience in handling labor (linked to size of the area in personnel and number of consumers) • Turnover equivalent to 75 percent of the gross annual revenue of the franchise area • Net worth of 25 percent of annual revenue of franchisee area • Positive Profit After Tax in any two of past three years of audited annual accounts table continues next page Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   151   152 Recommendations for the Way Forward on Distribution Franchisee Selection Table G.1  Recommended Approaches on Distribution Franchisee Selection (continued) Clause or aspect Recommended approacha Consortium Allowing a consortium is in the interest of attracting (and offering a route for entry to) new players who have the financial capability but do not have the technical experience in the power sector and therefore intend to acquire a partner who can complement the same. The following may be adopted in this context: • As a safeguard, the utility mandates incorporation of a special purpose vehicle (SPV) within a certain time frame (such as 45 days within issuance of letter of award). • The technically qualified partner should not have less than a 26 percent share in the SPV. • No more than three entities should be allowed to enter into a consortium. • There should be a lock-in period of at least five years in the proposed shareholding of the technically qualified partner in the SPV. Preparatory activity— To build investor confidence, reliable baseline data must be provided, such as the following: information • Provide five-year historical data on billing and recovery-related information, energy availability for input, network infrastructure, and so on and the details of the latest ongoing contracts or bidding works in the request for proposal (RFP) to be issued and the data room to be created for potential bidders. • A third-party audit of the commercial and technical data for the last or base year, including key items such as sales, revenue collections, and energy input, completed prior to issuance of the RFP may be recommended. Input rate and implied The competitive bidding process for a DF is designed for selecting the bidder who considers a loss reduction pass-through of the maximum possible efficiency improvements and loss reduction in the trajectory franchisee areas in the input rate to be quoted for the area. The following may be included in the guidelines or standard bidding document (SBD) in this context: • A reasonable and achievable aggregate technical and commercial (AT&C) loss reduction trajectory may be provided for in the RFP or distribution franchisee agreement (DFA). However, there is no separate need for any additional incentive or disincentive to be added for the achievement or non-achievement of the loss reduction because the franchisee shall be making the payments to the licensee as per the quoted rates and therefore the same is implicit. • To prevent front loading and to get a more even tariff structure, there can be a minimum mandatory ratio of 0.7 between the minimum tariff and the maximum tariff that the franchisee can quote for any particular year. This is in line with SBD in transmission and generation. • In terms of minimum benchmark rate, there could be a minimum expected rate to be quoted by the franchisee in any year. The same can be arrived at by evaluating the level of recoveries in the base year after duly adjusting for the potential savings in terms of the avoided costs after appointment of the franchisee. Specifying yearly benchmark rates or reserve prices limits the franchisees’ flexibility and enhances the risk perception of bidders. Input rate revision There could be a change in average tariff owing to a change in sales mix, consumption pattern, or any tariff revisions by the concerned state electricity regulatory commission (SERC). The input rate to be quoted by the franchisee for each year of the franchisee period may be adjusted on a monthly basis to ensure that risks and benefits are appropriately shared between the licensee and the franchisee: Indexed input rate for a month = (Quoted rate for the year) × (Average tariff for the month)/ Average tariff for the base year table continues next page Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Recommendations for the Way Forward on Distribution Franchisee Selection 153 Table G.1  Recommended Approaches on Distribution Franchisee Selection (continued) Clause or aspect Recommended approacha Availability of power Whereas most utilities commit to a minimum level of energy input for the entire period of the supply contract, no commitment is given on any future increase in availability. The franchisee and investors need to be assured that no discrimination will occur in making energy available for sale within the franchisee area going forward. The following may be included in the standard guidelines and SBD in this regard: • There should be no reduction in energy availability to the franchisee below the base level that can also be called the minimum committed level. • The licensee should make available increased energy input to the franchisee at least in the ratio of the increase in supply taking place for the licensee itself on a year-on-year basis. • The licensee should not discriminate in the supply of electricity between the franchisee area and other similar areas under its license area. • In the event that the licensee is unable to meet the entire demand of the franchisee, the franchisee shall be allowed to purchase power from external sources (under a tripartite arrangement with the licensee) and fully recover for it in the form of reliability charges or any other charge as may be approved by the respective SERC. Treatment of tax, duties, The following may be considered in the SBD with respect to duties, taxes, and levies: and levies • The input rate quoted by the franchisee should be exclusive of electricity duty; tax on sale of electricity; municipal taxes; and other taxes, duties, levies, and so on that may be levied by the state government from time to time. • The franchisee shall pass on the taxes, duties, and levies to the utility on a collected basis. • Any new ruling from the state or central government on taxation (other than corporate income tax) or introduction of new tax shall be borne by the utility. Treatment of subsidy The licensee receives a subsidy directly from the state government even for the power sold in the franchisee area. In areas where a bulk of the revenues comes in the form of government subsidies, the activities of the franchisees may not be a viable proposition in the absence of a pass-through of the subsidy being received from the state government. The following may be considered in the SBD in this context: • The input rate to be quoted by the franchisee should be exclusive of tariff subsidy. • A subsidy may be retained by the licensee in areas where such revenue forms less than 25 percent of the total revenues for the licensee in the base year. • A subsidy may be passed through to a franchisee in areas where such revenue forms more than 25 percent of the total revenues for the licensee in the base year. Capital investment Although it is essential that the franchisee have independence in undertaking capital investments in the franchisee area, the approach may be subject to the following: • First, a minimum capital expenditure (capex) may be specified during the initial years of the franchisee period to ensure that the investments are lop sided in the initial years. The same is essential in view of the intense loss reduction initiatives to be undertaken by the franchisee. Second, most of the investments made during the initial years would be largely depreciated by the end of the franchisee period, thus having minimal effect on the licensee when transferred at book value. • If the franchisee intends to undertake any underfunded works or subsidized government schemes, the utility shall help by acting as an intermediary and passing on all costs and benefits to the franchisees. The franchisee may be required to maintain a Bank Guarantee equivalent to the loan outstanding in the name of the licensee as security for undertaking such assistance. • There should be a provision for regulatory approval of the capex during the last five years of the franchisee period, excluding the capital investment requirements for adding any new consumer to the network or those that are necessary to maintain continuity of supply. table continues next page Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 154 Recommendations for the Way Forward on Distribution Franchisee Selection Table G.1  Recommended Approaches on Distribution Franchisee Selection (continued) Clause or aspect Recommended approacha Incentive of arrears Different utilities have followed varied approaches toward treatment of collections against arrears pertaining to the licensee period of supply by the franchisee. Selling out the entire value of the arrears upfront has occurred, as in the case of the recent bids in Madhya Pradesh, in the absence of detailed and reliable data. Where arrears baselines are reliable, a percentage of the arrears collected by the franchisee may be allowed to be retained by it as an incentive. The following incentive mechanism may be adopted in the SBD: Within 1st From 3rd year to two years from 5th year from After 5th year from effective date effective date effective date Connected consumer (%) 20 17 14 Disconnected consumer (%) 30 27 24 Relationship with The regulator needs to develop a mechanism for approval of reliability charges for recovery of regulator any additional or external power purchase that may be undertaken by the franchisee. Also, the regulator’s involvement in overseeing the process for appointment of entry into a franchising arrangement will need to be expanded as the utilities increasingly begin to appoint DFs. Treatment of employees Treatment of employees is among the most critical issues with regard to a DF to ensure smooth implementation of franchisee arrangements by utilities. The following may be adopted in the guidelines and SBD: • During the first three months from the effective date, the distribution licensee should provide diligent support to the franchisee for which the franchisee shall bear the cost of salary and allowances payable to the licensee’s employees involved therein. • Thereafter, the franchisee shall have an option to take the licensee’s employees on deputation. On the request of the franchisee, the licensee shall make available such number of its employees from the franchisee area who are willing to work with the franchisee, for such further period as considered appropriate, on a deemed deputation basis as per the terms and conditions of deputation applicable to the employees of the DF. • During the deputation period, the entire cost of employees shall be paid directly by the licensee to the licensee’s employees and the same shall be reimbursed by the franchisee on the last business day of every month. • Employees on deemed deputation with the franchisee should have an option to revert back to the licensee at any time on giving one month’s notice to the franchisee. In case the services of the licensee’s employees working with the franchisee are required by the licensee, it shall also have the right to recall those employees prior to the completion of the deputation period by serving one month’s notice to the franchisee. Treatment of existing The utility might have entered into various contracts for capital works in the franchised area, contracts which may be ongoing or awarded at the point of handover of the area to the franchisee. The following may be considered in the SBD and guidelines in this context: • With respect to ongoing or awarded capital works, the utility may continue with the project, complete it per schedule, and hand over such assets to the franchisee for routine operation and maintenance (O&M). In case the works proposed are critical to the success of the franchisee and the franchisee is not satisfied with the progress of the contractor appointed by the licensee, the franchisee may have the works cancelled by the licensee after due justification or explanation to the satisfaction of the licensee and may undertake such works itself at the budget or value approved by the licensee. In such cases, the franchisee shall bear the cancellation cost of such contracts, if any. • In the case of O&M contracts awarded by the licensee, the contracts shall be transferred to the franchisee. The franchisee shall be free to continue with or cancel such contracts at its will. The penalties or costs arising out of cancellation of such contracts should be borne by the licensee. • At the bid stage, the licensee should provide to the prospective bidders all details of capital works and O&M-related contracts entered into by it with various parties for the franchisee area. The contracts shall be made available to the franchisee in the data room. table continues next page Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Recommendations for the Way Forward on Distribution Franchisee Selection 155 Table G.1  Recommended Approaches on Distribution Franchisee Selection (continued) Clause or aspect Recommended approacha Audits and inspection Auditing of critical parameters important to the commercial interest of the licensee and the franchisee during the period of the contract is essential for maintaining transparency and avoiding any possibility of a potential conflict between the two parties. In this respect, a third-party audit of the following may be considered: • One-time audit at the commencement of franchisee operations: – Utility assets being handed over to the franchisee – Opening level of arrears – Inventory and spares being handed over to the franchisee – Energy input, sales, losses, and base year average billing rate • Routine or periodic audit during the franchisee period: – Average billing rate on an annual basis – Subsidy booked or claimed, as applicable on an annual basis – Audit of asset register through field verification and validations on an annual basis Commercial and Licensees should aim at developing comprehensive IT-based franchisee monitoring systems management that will interface with the franchisee’s systems and provide periodic and online reporting information systems access to the licensee. Such systems may generate performance reports, exceptions lists, and compatibility flagging of critical issues, and so on. of information The DFA may contain such clauses that would enable the licensee to interface with the technology (IT) franchisee’s systems. The DFA shall mandate that the IT systems and tools (especially systems those pertaining to consumer billing and complaint management) being developed by the franchisee are compatible with the IT systems of the licensee and could be interfaced as needed. Sharing of master data with respect to the revenue cycle should be made mandatory in the DFA and strictly enforced. Performance security For performance security, an unconditional, irrevocable, revolving letter of credit (LC) from a scheduled commercial bank (endorsed by Reserve Bank of India) for an amount equivalent to two months’ estimated revenue billed should be recommended for DFAs in place of conventional bank guarantees. The value of such LC may be revised on a yearly basis to adjust for any changes in the value of the two-month billing base. a. Subsequent to the study, the Ministry of Power issued standard bidding documents for appointment of distribution franchisees. A comparison of the recommendations provided in this section and the standard bidding document is provided in chapter 8. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 APPENDIX H Standardization of the Distribution Franchise Process The success of the Bhiwandi franchisee, in terms of both the steep loss reduc- tion achieved by Torrent Power Ltd. and the improvement in quality and reli- ability of supply under the franchisee model, has encouraged several utilities and states to undertake such initiatives in areas where the licensees have been struggling to improve efficiency levels (see box H.1). The distribution franchi- see (DF) model has evolved since the Bhiwandi model was implemented with only the key terms of the distribution franchisee agreement (DFA) on hand at the stage of bidding. In several cases, utilities across states have failed to appoint DFs for two primary reasons. The first and most important reason has been the inconsistency ­ in approach toward balancing stakeholder interests in the terms and conditions of the DFAs that are being tailor made by the states and state utilities on a case- by-case basis. The second reason is the lack of availability of quality baseline data and measurement systems for undertaking such transactions. The DF under the present model is more like a management and outsourcing contract. The ultimate responsibility for the area still remains with the licensee. Also, the competitive bidding process by the franchisee affects only the efficiency levels and recovery of the licensee, which continues to file its annual revenue Box H.1  Bhiwandi Distribution Franchisee: A Success Story • On January 26, 2012 Torrent Power Ltd.–run Bhiwandi distribution franchisee (DF) completed its five years of operations. • Bhiwandi DF, based on an input-based DF agreement with Maharashtra State Electricity Distribution Company Ltd. for a period of 10 years, is responsible for metering, billing, collection of revenues, and capital expenditure (capex). ­ box continues next page Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0   157   158 Standardization of the Distribution Franchise Process Box H.1  Bhiwandi Distribution Franchisee: A Success Story (continued) • Capital expenditure is subjected to regulatory approval and jointly verified by distribution company and franchisee. • Torrent Power Ltd. is able to aggressively reduce the gap between average tariff and ­ revenue realization. • Bhiwandi, a textile hub of the country, was reeling under a severe power shortage in 2006 with no investment in system improvements, inadequate metering, low collection, and high losses. • Because of inaccurate aggregate technical and commercial loss figures in 2006, the bid for DF couldn’t be based on loss reduction targets. • DF was not subjected to minimum capex investment commitment. • Torrent Power Ltd. built robust, safe, and reliable distribution network in these five years. • Technical losses were reduced through network strengthening, revamping of low-­ tension network, maintenance and addition of distribution transformers, and reactive power management. • Use of information technology applications like Supervisory Control and Data Acquisition (SCADA) and Automated Meter Reading (AMR) was introduced. • Unauthorized connections were regularized under Ujjal Bhiwandi Abhiyan, especially in  slum areas: 38,000 connections were regularized, and 17,000 new connections were provided. • Torrent Power Company replaced more than 80 percent of the old meters with electronics meters. • Two new customer service centers were opened. • A round-the-clock call center and a mobile van were introduced for quick resolution of complaints. See table BH.1.1. Table BH.1.1  Bhiwandi Distribution Franchisee Parameters Parameters 2006–07 2010–11 AT&C losses (%) 58 18.50 Number of transformers 2,254 2,611 DT failure rate (%) 42 3 Metering (%) 23 98 Collection efficiency (%) 58 99 Reactive compensation (MVAR) 0 160 Number of feeders 46 86 EHV capacity (MVA) 550 1,000 Number of customers 174,000 235,000 Use of IT — SCADA, AMR Source: Deloitte research. Note: AMR = Automated Meter Reading; AT&C = aggregate technical and commercial; DT = distribution transformer; EHV = extra high voltage; IT = information technology; MVA = million volt-amperes; SCADA = Supervisory Control and Data Acquisition; — = not available. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Standardization of the Distribution Franchise Process 159 requirement and tariff petition as usual for its overall license area, irrespective of whether a DF has been appointed or not. Thus, the DF is virtually nonexistent for the regulator with regard to the routine business scenario. The process for appointment of DFs does not fall under Section 63 of the Electricity Act of 2003 unlike the competitive bids held for procurement of power by distribution licensees or for development of requisite transmission lines, for which the Ministry of Power (MOP) has issued standard competitive bidding documents. Even the recommendation to privatize distribution networks of cities with a population of 10 million or more has been eliminated in the Mega Power Policy. At present, the central government has recommended the approach to mandatory franchising of rural areas only under the Rajiv Gandhi Grameen Vidyutikaran Yojana scheme. However, the MOP has not specified a policy direc- tive, common approach to DFs in the form of standard bidding documents (SBDs), model DFA, baseline data requirements, and so no. Although the Central Electricity Authority (July 2009) has issued a sample request for proposal for urban DF and the Forum of Regulators (September 2010) has issued a report on standardization of DFA, there are several differences between the two in certain key aspects such as area selection, bid parameters, minimum benchmark rate or reserve price, prequalification criteria, allowance of consortiums, quality of baseline parameters, loss reduction targets, and capital investments to be undertaken by the franchisee. Moreover, both of these docu- ments are only suggestive or advisory in nature and have not been adopted by the utilities and licensees in the same spirit as was done in the case of the SBDs issued by the MOP for case 1, case 2, and independent power transmission com- pany bids. A comparison of the two documents is provided in annex X to Volume 2, for reference. Based on the experience of the various state utilities to date, it is recom- mended that the MOP develop well-conceived recommended guidelines and SBDs for both rural and urban franchisees. This action will have a far-reaching effect on reducing difficulties with the bid processes being followed across states and will increase the confidence of participants and investors. However, unlike generation and transmission, there is no provision under the Electricity Act 2003 to create guidelines or SBDs for DFs. Nevertheless, the central government through its MOP may undertake the following options to resolve the issue at a policy level: • Amend the National Electricity Policy (NEP) to provide for the MOP to spec- ify the guidelines and SBDs for appointment of DFs, separately in rural and urban areas. The guidelines can empower the respective state electricity regu- latory commissions to permit any specific deviations from the guidelines and SBDs issued thereunder in keeping with the context of specific cases. • Issue a set of guidelines and SBDs as a recommended approach to DFs, separately for rural and urban areas, that would not be binding on the state ­ distribution licensees.1 Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 160 Standardization of the Distribution Franchise Process It should be noted that the guidelines and SBDs to be recommended by the MOP would need to distinguish between the routine activities of a distribution licensee, including outsourcing of certain functions such as billing, metering, and recovery, and those of a full-fledged, input-based DF for both rural and urban areas. Based on the review of the past bidding experiences of utilities for appointing DFs, annex 3 in volume 2 contains a summary of findings that could be used in formulating a standardized approach to DFs in India. Post-award Contract Management Utilities that have undertaken implementation of the input-based franchisee model have faced several issues arising out of the contractual framework such as verification of the average billing revenue in the case of Bhiwandi and establish- ment of the process for third-party audit, which were not envisaged at the ten- dering or bidding stage. There could be situations of commercial complexities that the utilities may not otherwise be able to resolve in a timely manner, thereby leading to disputes, defaults, and so on. It would be essential to train and deploy specialized personnel in a separate franchisee monitoring cell of the distribution utility, which could also act as the single point of contact for the franchisees, thus facilitating smooth implementa- tion and monitoring of the franchisees. Finalizing such team structure at an appropriate stage and clearly defining the roles and responsibilities would be critical to success. Personnel being deployed in such teams must be provided with intensive training on the provisions of the DFA and the modalities and implementation issues associated therewith. The DFA requires a specialized skill set and approach to monitor the performances of franchisees to ensure that the licensee’s interests are protected and the objectives of appointing the franchisee(s) are achieved. Such a team could also undertake appointment of third-party agencies for inde- pendent auditing of the average billing rate; the subsidy booked or claimed, as applicable; and the asset register through field verification or validations on an annual basis. Note 1. The Ministry of Power issued the standard bidding documents for appointment of input-based distribution franchisees in June, 2012. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 Environmental Benefits Statement The World Bank Group is committed to reducing its environmental footprint. In support of this commitment, the Publishing and Knowledge Division lever- ages electronic publishing options and print-on-demand technology, which is located in regional hubs worldwide. Together, these initiatives enable print runs to be lowered and shipping distances decreased, resulting in reduced paper consumption, chemical use, greenhouse gas emissions, and waste. ­ The Publishing and Knowledge Division follows the recommended standards for paper use set by the Green Press Initiative. Whenever possible, books are printed on 50 percent to 100 percent postconsumer recycled paper, and at least 50 percent of the fiber in our book paper is either unbleached or bleached using Totally Chlorine Free (TCF), Processed Chlorine Free (PCF), or Enhanced Elemental Chlorine Free (EECF) processes. More information about the Bank’s environmental philosophy can be found at http://crinfo.worldbank.org/wbcrinfo/node/4. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0339-0 The passage of India’s Electricity Act of 2003 was a signature achievement, moving the sector toward a market-driven approach that forced potential investors to compete aggressively for generation and transmission contracts. India’s 2005 National Electricity Policy recognized electricity as one of the key drivers ­ for rapid economic growth and poverty alleviation in the country. Yet the policy’s target—electricity for all and 1,000 kilowatt-hours (kWh) available per capita by 2012—was not met. Despite a 20-year reform process and private-sector participation, the rate of resource augmentation and growth in energy supply has been less than the rate of increase in demand. Numerous challenges need to be addressed before India can overcome severe energy shortages and achieve its desired national policy objectives. Private Participation in the Indian Power Sector: Lessons from Two Decades of Experience examines the home-grown Indian experience with private sector participation in power, identifies emerging risks, and ­ proposes specific actions for government consideration, so that the power sector may fulfill its important role in India’s growth story. Much has been achieved, and the Indian power sector can rightfully take its place among the bold reformers. Yet a large agenda remains, and a more rigorous focus on implementation, particularly on last-mile reforms in the distribution sector, will be required. Close coordination among various stakeholders and unrelenting attention to efficient execution through decentralized authority to make technical decisions, together with a robust emphasis on monitoring, evaluation, and transparent sharing of data and performance statistics, will help in achieving this objective. ISBN 978-1-4648-0339-0 SKU 210339