LAIPSq1 POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 1972 W hy Privatize? Argentina's experience suggests that bank privatization may succeed The Case of Argentina's only when accompanied by a Public Provincial Banks sound, incentive-compatible system of prudential regulation. George R. G. Clarke Robert Cull The World Bank Development Research Group Regulation and Competition Policy and Finance H September 1998 |POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 1972 Summary findings Argentina has been a leader among developing countries supervision combined with privatization. The provincial in restructuring its banking sector. Clarke and Cull banks that remained in the public sector did not analyze the performance of those banks before and after demonstrate the same performance gains as privatized privatization and estimate fiscal savings associated with provincial banks. The decision to maintain a public privatizing Argentina's banks rather than keeping them provincial bank is a costly one. public and later recapitalizing them. Policymakers should expect privatization to pass The authors describe the process of privatization, through some or all of the following steps: including the creation of residual entities for the assets * With respect to preprivatization audits, expect losses and liabilities of public provincial banks that private hidden in these banks to be larger than those indicated in buyers found unattractive and the creation of a special prior audits. fund (the Fondo Fiduciario) to convert the short-term * If residual entities are created, expect them to hold a liabilities of the residual entities into longer-term large share of the assets and liabilities of the old public obligations. provincial bank, if the quality of its loan portfolio was They argue that the Fondo, created through low. cooperation between the Argentine federal government * Do not expect the price paid for the privatized and the World Bank, was key in making privatization of entity (the so-called good bank) to be great, at least the banks politically feasible. Argentina privatized compared with assets and liabilities in the residual entity. roughly half of its public provincial banks. * If the residual entity is large, the province will be The Argentine experience suggests that bank confronted with substantial short-term liabilities. But privatization may succeed only when accompanied by a with assistance and an aggressive asset recovery strategy, sound, incentive-compatible system of prudential governments should be able to navigate their way regulation. The regulatory environment affects a bank's through short-term difficulty. solvency. * The costs of privatization are less than the costs of Improved regulation and supervision alone does not future recapitalization, even if the near-term deliver the same benefits as improved regulation and management of the residual entity does not go well. This paper - a product of Regulation and Competition Policy, and Finance, Development Research Group - is part of a larger effort in the group to investigate the causes and consequences of bank privatization. Copies of the paper are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Please contact Paulina Sintim-Aboagye, room MC3 - 422, telephone 202-473-8526, fax 202-522-1155, Internet address psintimaboagye@worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted at gclarke@worldbank.org or rcull@worldbank.org. September 1998. (36 pages) The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work In progress to encourage the exchaiige of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordisgly. The Dindings, interpretations, and conclsions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the autbors. They do not necessarily represent the view of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. Produced by the Policy Research Dissemination Center WHY PRIVATIZE? THE CASE OF ARGENTINA'S PUBLIC PROVINCIAL BANKS by George R.G. Clarke and Robert Cull. Draft: Please do not quote without permission Keywords: Latin America, Argentina, Banking, Financial Policy, Privatization, Public Expenditures. JEL Classifications: E58, G21, G28. We thank Stefan Alber, Jerry Caprio, Luis Guasch, Paul Levy, Saul Lizando, Paul Meo and Mary Shirley for many helpful comments and suggestions. For providing data and many helpful discussions we are indebted to .lavier Bolzico, Andrew Powell, Gabriel Caracciolo, Maria Hernandez, Andrea Molinari, Laura D'Amato. luan Barale, Horacio Fernandez, and Jorge Lombardi of the Central Bank of Argentina; Rogelio Frigerio, Alejandro Caldarelli, and Enrique Scala of the Fondo Fiduciario; and Raul Benitez and David Rosenblatt of the World Bank. I INTRODUCTION B1ankers' incentives matter. Banks are key institutions for attracting savings, in the form of short-term deposits, and converting them into longer-term investments, in the form of loans. When private capital is genuinely at risk, bankers have strong incentives to gather information about the credit-worthiness of potential borrowers, which they can then use to determine how, and on what terms, credit is allocated. This ensures that investment is directed towards the most productive purposes and imposes a hard-budget constraint on firms. i However, when political pressure distorts bankers' incentives, credit may be directed without due regard to commercial lending criteria. These pressures are likely to be especially pronounced for state-owned banks. In theory, bank privatization might, therefore, have a large effect on financial sector performance and, in turn, on aggregate long-term growth. 2 However, in practice, bank privatization has not always been successful. For example, Chile privatized many public banks in the early 1970s as part of its privatization program. In 1982, the financial distress of the industrial conglomerates caused by high interest rates and currency devaluation meant that many firms were unable to service their loans.3 This forced the governmenit to rescue, and re-nationalize, many of the recently privatized banks. World Bank (1989) suggests that an inadequate regulatory framework "allowed [the privatized banks] to be World Bank (1995) found a strong link between performance of state-owned enterprises and hard budget constraints. That report also summarizes the literature on hard budget constraints. Egypt's problems with overdrafts and government assumption of the liabilities of state-owned enterprises are described in Sherif (1992) and Sherif and Soos (1993); Poland's efforts to harden budget constraints in Baer and Gray (1994); and China's tendency to allocate state-owned bank credit and direct governmental subsidies to enterprises with relatively low productivity in Hwa (1992). 2 Demirguc-Kunt and Levine (1994) show that a variety of indicators of financial development (including general measures of financial depth) are all closely aligned with income levels. Similarly, King and Levine (1993 a,b) and Levine and Zervos (1996) highlight the strong link between financial development and aggregate growth rates. Not only do King and Levine find a strong connection between real per capita growth rates and financial development, they also find a link between total productivity growth and finance -- which is, perhaps, a more direct indication that well-developed financial sectors allocate resources better than others. World Bank (1989, p. 123) notes that some estimates indicate that the non-performing assets of Chile's banks might have been as large as 79% of capital and reserves in 1982 and 150% in 1983. acquired by industrial groups, which used them to make excessive loans to group firms" (p. 127). In a cross-country analysis, Cull (1997) finds that financial depth did not increase in countries that received World Bank loans with conditionalities tied to bank privatization, relative to countries that received other types of World Bank financial sector loans.5 These results emphasize that bank privatization might only be successful when accompanied by improved regulation. Unlike some other countries that undertook substantial bank privatization, Argentina tried to improve banking sector regulation and supervision. In thle 1990s, Argentina gradually raised capital adequacy ratios, adopted stricter loan classification and provisioninlg standards, improved the certification procedure for bank auditors, imposed minimum diversification standards for bank loan portfolios including lending limits to a single affiliate, maintained high reserve requirements, and re-created and strengthened the Superintendency of Banking.6 At the same time, Argentina took strides to loosen foreign entry restrictions and to privatize state- 7 owned banks, especially those owned by the provinces and municipalities. Thle substantial number of bank privatizations and the improvements in thie regulatory framework combine to make Argentina a unique case study -- the benefits of privatization slhould be especially noticeable given the attention paid to regulation and supervision. The data tihat follow indicate that state-owned banks allocated credit poorly and tlhus lost capital at a far greater pace thani Stallings and Brock (1993, p. 105) notes that although rules were in place to prevent this. that wvhen the groups found wvays around them the government made no effort to prevent this from happening. * uI'rther, Cull (1997) finds that subsequent changes in financial depth Nvere actually smaller in those coulntries that attcmpted privatization without regulatory reform. However, he notes that it is difficult to dmi1w strong conclusions regarding this because privatization without regulitory reform was attciipted in only one case ( E'gypt). [:or further details see Ministry of Economics and Central Bank of the Republic of Arggentina. Ixpc'rice anud Lessons lroni Financial Market Instability: The Argentina Experience. ( 10 Working Party onl EIlCmerging Market Instability. December. 1996. 7 At the beginning of this decade. each Argentine province had at least onie governmcnt-owvned haink. Of'tthe nearly thirty public provincial banks, almost half had been privatized as of December. 1996. 2 privatized banks; that privatization will likely reduce the fiscai burden associated with re- capitalizing struggling state-owned banks; and that privatized banks have substantially improved their loan portfolio quality and operational efficiency. Although thie post-privatization period has not been long, many of the privatized banks appear to be functioning as well as tile largest private banks in Argentina, a number of which are foreign-owned. The paper begins by estimating the fiscal impact of privatizing Argentina's public provincial banks. In Section II, using the estimated loss rates, we calculate the future costs of re- capitalization. The results indicate that the present value of future re-capitalization far exceeds the costs associated with privatization, and is large compared to either provincial deficits or provincial expenditures.8 Section III describes how assets and liabilities were apportioned between the privatized provincial bank and a "residual" entity, and discusses the fiscal implications of this strategy. The privatized bank that was created contained performing assets from the old public provincial bank which were matched with a nearly equal amount of the old bank's (mostly private) liabilities.9 Non-performing assets, and the remaining liabilities, were retained as a "residual entity" by the province.10 In addition, most provinces agreed to jointly capitalize the privatized provincial bank with the winning bidder.11 The sum of these The fiscal benefits of privatization may even be slightly greater than those estimated here because we ignore any additional tax revenue that will be collected from the privatized provincial banks. 9 As a result, the sales prices of the privatized entities were quite small, especially in comparison with the size of the residual entity. '° Interestingly, Argentina's bank privatization procedures were quite different from those in Mexico. While it may be a bit misleading to compare the larger banks privatized by Mexico with the smaller provincial banks privatized in Argentina, it is interesting to note that (I) Mexico did not have to create residual entities, (2) Mexico relied on a more de-personalized (and complicated) auction procedure than did Argentina, and (3) the prices paid for the Mexican banks were much higher. Timing effects may explain some of these differences. Mexico's privatizations occurred prior to the Tequila Crisis; Argentina's occurred after. Still, the differences in the two cases are striking and worthy of further study. See Unal and Navarro (1995) for further description of the privatization procedures in Mexico. On the impact of the Tequila Crisis on the provinces' decisions to privatize their banks in Argentina, see Clarke and Cull (1 997a). Put another way, many provinces decided to maintain ownership of some fraction of the shares of the privatized entity. Because they could have presumably sold these shares and used the proceeds for other government projects, the retained shares should be thought of as a fiscal cost associated with privatization. 3 capitalization costs and the eventual losses associated with liquidating the residual entity will be the realized costs of privatization.12 Importantly, even if no residual entity assets are recovered, the re-capitalization simulations indicate that the typical province would generate large fiscal savings from privatizing its public provincial bank. Another important fiscal issue is the future solvency of the privatized provincial banks. If privatized provincial banks continue to operate as poorly as public provincial banks, they will go bankrupt. Although predicting the future solvency of any bank, public or private, is a speculative endeavor, the available post-privatization data strongly suggest that the privatized provincial banks operate quite differently from public provincial banks. In fact, data presented in Section IV on credit allocation by sector, operating income and costs, and portfolio quality indicate that, by 1996, privatized provincial banks operated similarly to the ten largest private banks in Argentina. A case can be made, therefore, that the solvency risks posed by privatized provincial banks are no worse than those posed by the typical private bank -- although it should be emphasized that the post-privatization experience has not been long, and future data are required before firmer conclusions can be drawn. Finally, in Section V, we conclude and draw lessons from Argentina's bank privatization experience to date. II THE COST OF NOT PRIVATIZING Between 1991 and 1996, the net worth of most public provincial banks fell, even in nominal terms (See Table II in Appendix II). The notable exception was Banco de La Provincia de Buenos Aires (hereafter Buenos Aires), whose net worth increased at a pace commensurate with many well-established private banks. Given its location and the resulting implications for 12 To some small extent, they were defrayed by the sales price of the privatized entity. 4 its business, Buenos Aires' situation appears to be distinct from those of other public provincial banks.13 Therefore, Buenos Aires is treated separately in much of the analysis. Using balance sheet data from between 1991 and 1996, Appendix 11 estimates the rate at which provincial, private, and privatized provincial banks' net worth declined relative to total liabilities (and assets). The data indicate that loss rates were, on average, much higher for public provincial banks than for privatized or private banks. Based upon this data, we derive counter- factual estimates of the cost of re-capitalizing typical public provincial banks under a variety of scenarios. In the simulations, the ratio of net worth to total liabilities (NW/TL) of the public provincial bank is assumed to fall at the average rate that NW/TL fell for public provincial banks (except Buenos Aires) between 1991 land 1996 (i.e. 9%). It is also assumed that the province re-capitalizes the simulated bank every three years so that its ratio of net worth to total assets is 11.5%, the level dictated by Argentine prudential regulations.14 Finally, it is assumed that nominal liabilities grow at a rate of 11% per year, the average rate for public provincial banks during the period. For a bank with 25,000,000 pesos in reported net worth, a level very close to the median for public provincial banks (except Buenos Aires) from 1994-96, the nominal re-capitalization payments would total over 205.5 billion pesos if it remained in public hands. 5 13 As the flagship of the public banking system, Buenos Aires may be treated somewhat ditferently by regulators than other public provincial banks. A full discussion of how, and why, Buenos. Aires can be publicly owned and yet apparently function more effectively than other state-owned banks is beyond the scope of this paper. 4 The qualitative results of the re-capitalization simulations presented here are not overly sensitive to the duration of the re-capitalization cycle. We get very similar results, for example, if we assume that the province re- capitalizes its bank every five years. Is In this section, we calculate re-capitalization payments over the next hundred years. For most of the discounting scenarios presented here, the present value of payments received after that year is quite close to zero. The discounted re-capitalization payments, therefore, should be seen as reasonable estimates of the full fiscal cost of refusing to privatize a public provincial bank. 5 Discounted re-payment flows using a 10% interest rate are shown in column 7 of Table .16 The 10% rate implies a discounted payment stream of 383 million pesos. Recall that the simulated bank's total assets were only 217 million pesos at the start of the period (column 3). To put that 383 million peso figure into better perspective, note that the average size of the residual entities created to date has been about 46% of the pre-privatization assets, 66% of liabilities (Table 2).17 If the simulated bank were typical of the privatized provincial banks created to date, we would expect a residual entity of 125.8 million pesos in liabilities and 100.2 mnillion in assets. In general, the costs associated with capitalizing the privatized entity and its sales price were quite small in comparison with the size of the residual entity (See Section IV for details). Ignoring those factors for the moment, if the province recovered none of the assets of the simulated residual entity, and paid off all its liabilities immediately, the costs would be less than one-third of the estimates of discounted re-capitalization costs. Even a province that An appropriate discount rate should account for the inflation-adjusted opportunity cost of capital. The question is whose opportunity cost should be used. An argument can be made that, because the government must divert resources from the private sector through taxes to pay for re-capitalizations, the appropriate discount is the private sector's opportunity cost of capital. Baumol (1968) states the case as follows: *'The appropriate rate of discount for public projects is one which measures correctly the social opportunity cost. The decision to devote resources to investment in a public project means, given the overall level of employment in the economy, that these resources will become unavailable for use by the private sector. And this transfer should be undertaken whenever a potential project available to the government offers social benefits greater than the loss sustained by removing these resources from the private sector." In practice, Quirk and Terasawa (1991) note that this comes down to using a weighted average of the consumer rate of interest and the pre-tax corporate rate of return as the government discount rate. Those authors object to that discount rate because '-the true opportunity cost of a government project is the value of the best available opportunity foregone because of the project, not simply the value of any available opportunity foregone." Determining the value of the best opportunity foregone by the government seems difficult to operationalize, however. While no single rate is, perhaps, an adequate composite of private rates, recent data indicate that the interest rate on peso loans is presently 10% (International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics (IFS). May, 1997). Another school of thought holds that, since the government often borrows to finance its deficit, the appropriate rate is the one at which it can borrow. In the U.S., a reasonable proxy is the Treasury Bill rate. For Argentina, money markets rates (which in the U.S. case are typically slightly higher than the 30-day T-Bill rate), are currently 6%, which might suggest a lower discount rate than 10%. In practice, however, the World Bank uses a 10% discount on many of its long-term projects in Argentina. Given the other rates, that one seems a reasonable estimate. 7 These figures exclude data from Santiago del Estero due to measurement problems. That privatization was finalized in September, 1996. The Fondo Fiduciario data for the residual entity are dated July 3 1, 1996. and should, therefore, be an accurate reflection of assets and liabilities at the close of the sale. The asset and liability figures from the Central Bank for 1995 for Santiago del Estero are much smaller than those in the residual entity. 6 discounted future pesos at a rate as high as 15% would save 6 million pesos if it recovered nothing from its residual entity. 8 From a fiscal perspective, the choice is clear, even when a province manages the residual entity as poorly as is possible. In practice, however, provinces may be able to recover a significant portion of the residual entities' assets, and may negotiate their way out of some liabilities. In those cases, the choice to privatize should be even clearer. Table 1: Estimates of the Costs of Re-Capitalizing a Typical Public Provincial Bank Ratio of Net Worth to Assets in Year 1: .115 (Arg. Requirement) Net Worth in Year 1: 25,000,000 Loss Rate in Ratio of Net Worth to Liabilities: .090 (Sample Mean, Prov)* Rate of Growth in Nominal Liabilities: .113 (Sample Mean, 1996)* Discount Rate is 10% for Present Value Calculations* Year Net Worth Total Total Implied Nominal PV Assets Liabilities Asset Re-Cap. Re-Cap. Growth Payment Payment During millions millions millions Cycle Inmillions millions (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) 1 25 217 192 .020 0 0 3 -11.9 226 238 .020 42.9 29.3 6 -14.8 280 295 .020 53.1 27.2 9 -18.3 347 366 .020 65.8 25.3 12 -22.6 430 453 .020 81.5 23.6 96 -9092.0 172747 181839 .020 32731.0 3.2 99 -11262.8 213994 225257 .020 35881.6 2.6 Total 205515 383 Simulated re-capitalization costs are large not only in comparison with the residual entity, but also with respect to other fiscal variables. In 1996, the average expenditures for the provinces that had privatized their banks was 720 million pesos; their average deficit was 21 million (Table 3). The 383 million pesos, therefore, represent over half of yearly government Inflation in 1995 was relatively low, so it seems implausible that nominal assets and liabilities could have increased so much as to permit a residual entity larger than the old public provincial bank. 8 Qualitatively similar results for simulations that assume ditferent scenarios for loss rates in net worth appear in Appendix 1. 7 expenditures. In every third year, re-capitalization payments of 20-30 million pesos would more than double the typical 1996 deficit. Even under the assumption that the province manages the residual entity as poorly as possible, the savings from privatization (257 million pesos) would amount to a third of yearly government expenditures and could fulalice 1996 deficits for over twelve years. 9 In short, the potential fiscal savings associated with privatization are large, eveni with counter-factual re-capitalization estimates designed to be conservative. Had we used a discount factor of 5%, for example, the discounted re-capitalization stream would hiave been 4.2 billion pesos -- six years of provincial expenditures, enough to finance the equivalent of a 20 million peso deficit (in 1996) for some two hundred years. One might argue that public provincial bank quality has improved, or that the remaining banks are of higher quality than those that have already privatized, and thus the 9% loss rate in NW/TL overstates future losses. If the remaining public provincial banks are better ones (and thius have lower loss rates), their quality should be reflected in a smaller residual entity.20 Their discounted re-capitalization payments may be smaller than for the early privatizers but, because these payments are offset by the liabilities of a much smaller residual entity, privatization wi ll also make sense for them -- unless, of course, these banks are of such high quality tilat thley experience no losses in the future. The data on net worth and NW/TL, and that presented in Section IV on operating income and costs, however, make that proposition especially dubious.21 19 The comparisons with 1996 deficits are for illustrative purposes only. Deficits were, however, relatively small in that year. The average 1995 deficit for privatizers was 140 million pesos; in 1994 it was 84 million. It is unclear to us whether the 1996 deficits or those from prior years are better estimates of future deficits. 20 See regression in Section IV on the relationship between public provincial bank portfolio quality and the size of the residual entity. 21 Leaving Buenos Aires aside, those public provincial banks that have not begun the privatization process did have slightly better pre-privatization performance than those that eventually privatized. However, the disparities are not particularly striking. Non-privatizers had an average nominal net worth of 66 million pesos, and experienced declines in nominal net worth of 853,000 pesos per year and in NW/TL of 8.2% per year. Their nominal assets grew at a rate of 31.8%. A quick comparison with the figures in Table 11 indicates that non-privatizers are much more similar to public provincial banks that eventually privatized than they are to the private banks. 8 22 Table 2: Residual Entities as a Percentage of Pre-Privatization Assets/Liabilities Residual entity Year Assets Assets as a % Liabilities Liab. as a % of Created of Assets in Liab. in Year Year Prior to Prior to Priv. millions Priv. millions (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Chaco 1995 245.3 54.0 233.1 56.8 Formosa 1995 135.7 36.7 244.9 83.4 Mendoza 1996 666.6 61.2 666.6 71.4 Misiones 1995 144.2 28.6 331.8 66.0 Prev. Social 1996 292.1 49.7 292.1 56.4 Rio Negro 1996 49.2 24.6 47.4 26.2 Salta 1996 91.6 73.3 73.4 74.2 San Juan 1996 78.6 34.2 175.3 66.9 San Luis 1996 29.7 31.6 81.8 90.1 Sant del Est 1996 199.6 *81.1 227.3 *84.4 Tucuman 1996 261.7 66.7 262.9 70.2 Average . 199.5 **46.1 239.7 **66.1 *The asset data for Santiago del Estero implied that their residual entity was 135% of pre-privatization assets, an obviously unrealistic estimate. The figures reported here for Santiago del Estero are, therefore, based on their reported assets in the year of their privatization (1996). See footnote 17 for further discussion of the Santiago del Estero data. **Calculation excludes Santiago del Estero. Table 3: Fiscal Situation of Provinces in 1996 Sample Avg. Expenditures Avg. Revenues Deficits (million of pesos) (millions of pesos) (millions of pesos) 1. All Provinces 2,195.2 2,263.3 68.1 2. Provinces Except 1,075.0 1,105.2 30.2 Buenos Aires 3. Provinces that have 698.8 719.9 21.2 Privatized Provincial Banks Source: Ministry of Economy (National Directorate for Fiscal Coordination with the Provinces) III THE PRIVATIZATION PROCESS AND ITS FISCAL IMPLICATIONS The quality of the bank's portfolio, in practice, determines the size of the residual entity. Although a poor portfolio largely reflects past performance and, therefore, has nothinig to do with the privatization process per se, opponents are likely to claim, at least in the court of public 22 Notes: Prev Social is the former Banco de Prevision Social de La Provincia de Mendoza; Sant del Est is the forner Banco de La Provincia de Santiago del Estero. Source: Fondo Fiduciario. Assets in the year prior to privatization (used to construct data in columns 4 and 6) come from B.C.R.A. balance sheet data. 9 opinion, that the realized losses are due to privatization. In all observed cases, the purchaser of the privatized entity did not assume ownership of all pre-privatization assets and liabilities. While this might seem strange from an economic perspective -- buyers could have simply paid negative prices (i.e. been paid by the province) -- political reality and the buyer's desire to "start afresh" dictated that a residual entity be created to ensure a positive price. Although the individual cases varied, the basic strategy was to shift attractive assets to the privatized entity and then match those assets with liabilities, while leaving the privatized entity with sufficient net worth. The key determinant of the size of the residual entity was, therefore, the quality of the public provincial bank's assets (See Table 4). Table 4: Size of Residual Entities Bank % of Pre-Priv. % of Pre-Priv. % non- % Normal Physical Assets Assets Liabil. performing Pre-Priv. as % of Pre- Pre-Priv. Priv. Assets (1994) (1994) Chaco 54.0 51.3 **32.6 **52.6 8.9 Formosa 36.7 66.2 4.0 79.4 2.5 Mendoza 61.2 61.2 20.2 49.5 0.3 Misiones 28.6 65.8 12.5 71.6 5.3 Prv Soc Men 49.7 49.7 34.2 43.4 1.0 Rio Negro 24.6 23.7 47.3 28.4 1.2 Salta 73.3 58.7 75.9 7.5 4.5 San Juan 34.2 76.4 23.1 68.8 1.5 San Luis 31.6 87.1 12.9 80.9 35.5 Sant del Est *81.1 *84.4 ***71.8 ***13.8 3.7 Tucuman 66.7 67.0 53.4 43.8 4.6 Sources: See Table 2 with regard to % of pre-privatization assets and liabilities in the residual entity. The % non- performing and the % normal loans data comes from B.C.R.A. balance sheets. Data on physical assets comes from Fondo Fiduciario balance sheets for residual entities at the time of privatization. * Calculations described in Table 2. ** 1993 data were used. By 1994, the effects of privatization were evident in Chaco's portfolio quality data. *** 1993 data were used. No data were available for 1994. A simple regression shows that the worse the public provincial bank's portfolio, the larger the residual entity.23 23 The observation for San Luis was dropped from the estimation because the physical assets reported in its residual entity balance sheet implied an implausibly high percentage of those assets in its portfolio (Table 4). Although not reported here, the qualitative result is similar when % normal loans replaces % non-performing in the regression -- a high percentage of normal loans implies a smaller residual entity. These results are for portfolio quality measured prior to privatization -- before the pre-privatization audit. Similar qualitative results obtain, however, when post-audit portfolio quality replaces the pre-audit measures in the regression. The only 10 % Assets = 27.8 + .548 (% non-performing) + .798 (% physical assets) (t-stat) (2.53) (2.49) (0.39) N=9, Adj. R-Squared .352.24 Results for physical assets are less compelling. Although the coefficient is positive, it is not statistically significant. Given so few observations, however, provincial policy makers should consider the possibility that physical assets might increase the size of their residual entity and might require a different liquidation strategy than financial assets. In some cases the public provincial bank had negative net worth when privatized (ensuring that residual liabilities will be larger than residual assets.). In these cases, no matter how successful the recovery of residual assets, the provinces will face net losses. In the two worst cases (Formosa and Misiones), residual liabilities exceed assets by 100-200 million pesos. Althiough these losses are substantial, as the simulation results indicate, from a fiscal perspective privatization is still the best choice. For Misiones and Formosa, banks whose assets were roughly twice the size of the simulated bank in Section II, the discounted re-capitalization stream would total well over 500 million pesos, substantially more than the 200-350 million pesos they face in residual liabilities. While residual asset recovery will, hopefully, proceed quickly, it will neither be quick enough, nor on such advantageous terms, to cover most residual liabilities -- even in those cases where assets exceed liabilities. As a result, provinces needed some way to meet a substantial difference is that the pre-audit coefficient is somewhat larger than the post-audit measure, indicating yet again that problems will likely be more severe than indicated prior to the pre-privatization audit. 24 "% non-performing" is the percentage of total loans in the worst two B.C.R.A. loan classifications The physical asset variable is the percentage of pre-privatization assets that ended up in residual entity balance sheets under the heading "bienes de uso." Many of the public provincial banks had an abundance of branches and buildings that purchasers might have preferred not to own (so they would not have to re-sell them later). The dependent variable is the percentage of pre-privatization assets shifted to the residual entity (see Table 2). B.C.R.A. changed its loan classification guidelines in 1994 so that the bottom three categories -- those with problems and deficient coverage, those with high risk of borrower insolvency and recovery difficulty, and those deemed unrecoverable -- are now considered non-performing ("bad credits"). The portfolio quality data used in the regressions discussed in this section are for loans classified under the old guidelines. II portion of their residual obligations immediately. In an effort to address this, the Argentinean Government and the World Bank developed the Fondo Fiduciario, a part of the federal government that extends loans to provinces that have privatized their provincial banks. The provinces used the loan proceeds to pay off obligations. In this way, some short-term obligations were converted to longer terms. From a political perspective, financilig obligations in this way was clever, as the yearly loan payments due to the Fondo are less eye-catching than the short- term obligation payments would have been.25 The Fondo Fiduciario's experience to date is summarized in Table 5. For the smaller residual entities (below 200 million pesos in liabilities), Fondo Fiduciario loans typically covered well over half of their liabilities. For medium-sized residual entities (200-300 million pesos), Fondo loans met roughly one-third of their obligations. For the two largest residual entities, these loans covered less than a quarter of total liabilities. Clearly, those provinces with the largest residual liabilities will have the most pressure to re-coup residual assets quickly, as they were able to re-finance a relatively small portion of their obligations throughi the Fondo. It is also interesting to note that, in each case, at least half of the loan proceeds went to retire obligations to two creditors -- B.C.R.A. and Banco de la Nacion.26 Although the data provided by Fondo Fiduciario does not indicate why or when these debts were incurred, both B.C.R.A. and Banco de la Nacion were important sources of liquidity for the public provincial banks, especially during the Tequila Crisis. In those cases where a relatively small share of liabilities were financed through the Fondo, the short-term fiscal implications of privatization will depend largely on the province's ability to negotiate its way out of liabilities and to recover provincial assets. There is little 25 Assuming the terms of the loans are reasonable, the re-financing should, of course, make little difference from an economic (i.e., present value) perspective. 26 In many cases, 80-90% of the proceeds went to those creditors. 12 available evidence on the provinces' experiences to date. The Fondo Fiduciario had balance sheets for only three residual entities both at their inception and at some point later (when asset recovery and liability retirement should have already begun). Unfortunately, the balance sheet data for these three cases do not give any indications as to the terms on which the assets were recovered or liabilities retired. Assets may have been recovered at a rate of pennies on the dollar, while liabilities may have been retired at face value. Table 5: Fondo Fiduciario Assistance Bank Residual Total Loan Undisbursed Debts Paid to Debts Paid to Liabilities from FF as of 2/4/97 B.C.R.A. Banco De La (millions) (millions)27 Nacion Chaco 233.1 78.0 0 78.0 0 Entre Rios N/A. 78.0 0 45.3 0 Formosa 244.9 80.0 0 32.2 37.7 Jujuy N/A. 50.0 33.3 16.6 0 Mendoza 666.6 160.0 0 89.7 70.3 Prv Soc Men 292.1 100.0 0 79.3 20.7 Misiones 331.8 78.0 0 20.2 47.6 Rio Negro 47.4 80.0 0 32.3 11.5 Salta 73.4 50.0 0 16.7 9.5 San Juan 175.3 78.0 0 43.7 34.3 San Luis 81.8 50.0 0 21.0 0 Santa Fe N/A. 160.0 160.0 N/A. N/A. Sant del Est 227.3 50.0 33.3 3.0 0.0 Tucuman 262.9 80.0 25.0 53.6 18.1 Source: Fondo Fiduciario In many cases the province contracted the owner of the privatized entity to collect residual assets. The private owners receive a higher percentage of face value for recovering lower quality assets (i.e., loans for which re-payment problems have been most chronic). To the extent that residual balance sheets reflect the face value of assets, such contracts make it impossible for the province to receive compensation for the full value of its residual assets. This is not, of course, to imply that these contracts are a bad deal for provinces -- indeed, it is likely that private entities with the appropriate incentives are best equipped to re- 27 Fondo Fiduciario loans data are reported in U.S. dollars. Residual liability data are reported in pesos. Since the exchange rate is pegged so that a peso is worth a dollar, this presents little problem. 13 coup assets. Rather, we merely point out that, in many cases, the upper bound on asset collection may be somewhat lower than what is reflected in residual balance sheets. Table 6: Total Fiscal Costs Associated With Privatization Under Various Residual Asset Recovery Scenarios Province Amount Value of Total Total Total Total Fiscal Total Fiscal Paid for Privat. Liabil. of Assets of Fiscal Costs of Costs of Privat. Shares Residual Residual Costs of Privati- Privati- Entity Retained Entity Entity Privati- zation: zation: by Prov. zation: 0% 20% Asset 50% Asset (millions (millions (millions (millions Asset Recovery Recovery pesos) pesos) 28 pesos) pesos) Recovery [3+2-1] (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Chaco 6.3 2.9 233.1 245.3 229.7 180.6 107.0 Ent Rios 15.1 N/A. N/A. N/A. N/A. N/A. Formosa 9.3 4.0 244.9 135.7 239.6 212.4 171.7 Mendoza 20.1 0.6 666.6 666.6 647.1 513.8 313.8 PS Mend 8.2 0.2 292.1 292.1 284.1 225.7 138.0 Misiones 9.1 0.0 331.8 144.2 322.7 293.9 250.6 R Negro 10.2 1.8 47.4 49.2 39.0 29.2 14.4 Salta 4.4 1.1 73.4 91.6 70.1 51.8 24.3 San Juan 11.3 3.8 175.3 78.6 167.8 152.1 128.5 San Luis 5.4 0.0 81.8 29.7 76.5 70.5 61.6 Sant Est 6.7 0.0 227.3 199.6 220.7 180.7 120.9 Tucuman 10.3 2.6 262.9 261.7 255.2 202.9 124.4 Source: Fondo Fiduciario. Notes: N/A.- not applicable. In the Entre Rios privatization, no residual entity was created. As computed here, the total cost estimates are not meaningful for that case. PS Mend is the former Prevision Social de Mendoza; R Negro is Rio Negro; and Sant Est is Santiago del Estero. The value of shares left in public hands is an indication of the capitalization costs borne by the province. Most of the amounts paid for privatized entities went back to the new private banks either in the form of capital integrated or as deposits made by the provincial government. These small amounts should not, therefore, be seen as necessarily having improved the fiscal situation of the provinces. Given so little data, analyzing the effect of the liquidation contracts on asset recovery is beyond the scope of this paper. In the future, however, such an analysis may be possible, although it would require very detailed data on the quality of the assets recovered, the terms of each liquidation contract, and the terms on which credits were re-paid. Table 6 summarizes the total fiscal costs associated with privatization for individual provinces under various asset 2S Because the province could presumably sell them, the eventual fiscal implications of any shares it holds in the privatized entity are likely to be negligible. However, there is an opportunity cost associated with not selling them that should probably be considered among the costs of privatization. 14 recovery scenarios. The total potential short-term costs associated with privatization are equal to the sum of any capitalization costs borne by the province and residual entity liabilities, minus the price paid for the privatized entity (column 5). Final privatization costs will depend on the extent to wlhich provinces recover residual assets. Column 6 lists total privatization costs assuming that 20% of residual assets are recovered; Column 7 assumes a 50% recovery rate. Clearly, total costs will be quite sensitive to the success of the recovery effort. The total cost estimates in Table 7 assume that the province pays off all of the residual liabilities. To the extent that they are able to negotiate their way out of some liabilities, the total cost figures in columns 5-7 should be reduced. The bulk of the short-term fiscal implications will, thierefore, derive from the terms on which the residual entity is liquidated. The Fondo Fiduciario loan data, moreover, should be some guide as to the post-privatization financing assistance that provinces might expect. IV PRIVATIZED PROVINCIAL BANKS: INDICATORS OF FUTURE SOLVENCY Owners of privatized provincial banks should face the same incentives as other private bankers in Argentina. To the extent that prudential regulations and bank supervision are adequate -- and all indications are that both have improved substantially in the 1990s -- neither privatized nor private banks should be so crisis-prone that they pose a substantial bail-out risk, especially when one considers that Argentina's present system of deposit insurance has a disciplining effect on member banks.29 In a country with a strong private deposit insurance 2') That system is partly privately managed and imposes high premia (.36-.72% of deposits, depending on the class of deposit) by international standards on member banks. In Denmark, another country with privately managed deposit insurance, premia payments are only .2% of deposits. In Colombia premia are .15% of deposits; in Mexico they are .3% -- and coverage per depositor is unlimited. Membership in Argentina's program, moreover, is compulsory. Details regarding deposit insurance programs are drawn from, Alexander Kyei, "Deposit Protection Arrangements: A Survey," IMF Working Paper No. WP/95/134, Monetary and Exchange Affairs Department, Dec., 1995, and Samuel Talley and Ignacio Mas, "Deposit Insurance in Developing Countries," World Bank Policy Research and External Affairs Working Paper No, 548, 1990. 15 program, provinces that privatized their banks should have little incentive to bail out troubled institutions.30 However, owners of privatized provincial banks are not in exactly the same situation as other private bankers -- most received a contract to continue providing banking services to the province as part of their sales agreement. As banker to the provincial government, privatized provincial banks maintain a privileged position within the banking industry whicil may distort incentives. In this section, we compare privatized provincial banks with well-established private ones to determine whether they operate similarly. Available post-privatization data strongly suggest that, despite their service contracts with the provinces, privatized provincial banks did change their operations substantially. Their similarities withi private banks are now far more pronounced than their similarities with the remaining public provincial banks. Importantly, although we cannot quantify the social welfare benefits, the data indicate that credit allocation is improving. While the focus of this paper is on the fiscal benefits to the provinces -- which appear to be quite substantial -- it is quite likely that the most important benefit of privatization is the economic growth that should follow from improved credit allocation. Indeed, these benefits could make it wise to privatize even if the fiscal calculus did not favor privatization. IV.1 Operating Income and Costs The pubic provincial banks' low ratio of operating income to administrative costs is one indicationi of their inefficiency. Between 1993 and 1996 the typical public provincial bank generated only .77 pesos in total income (net financial income and income from services) for every peso spent on administrative costs (Table 7). The typical private bank, in contrast, generated 1.44 pesos in income for every peso incurred in costs and the typical privatized 30 We recognize, however, that systemic bank crises do occur, and that governments often intervene to prevent financial system collapse. See Gerard Caprio, Jr. and Daniela Klingebiel, "Bank Insolvencies: Cross Country Experience," World Bank, April, 1996. However, it should also be noted that, in the event of systemic crisis, the bail-out responsibility likely devolves to the federal rather the provincial governments. 16 provincial bank generated 1.41 pesos in income per peso of cost. There was, however, a difference between privatized and private banks in the composition of income. About two-thirds of the income of private banks was financial income, while only a third was from services. In contrast, over half of the income of the privatized banks was generated through services, perhaps due to their unique relationship with the provincial governments. As described below, however, that relationship is far less pronounced in credit allocation decisions -- neither private nor privatized provincial banks lend much to the public sector. Other than this, Table 7 indicates that the privatized provincial banks generate income as efficiently as large private banks, and far more efficiently that the remaining public provincial banks. Table 7: Ratios of Income to Cost Financial Income from Total Income/Administrative Services/Administrative Income/Administrative Costs Costs Costs Mean Mean Mean Overall:X Private .915 .529 1.44 Provincial .375 .402 .778 Privatized .669 .736 1.41 1994: Private .764 .543 1 .307 Provincial .524 .386 .911 Privatized .413 .798 1.211 1995: Private .883 .494 1 .377 Provincial .245 .339 .584 Privatized .633 .751 1.385 1996: Private 1.088 .506 1 .595 Provincial -.026 .425 .399 Privatized .758 .742 1.501 Data Source: B.C.R.A. Notes: The privatized sample includes only those banks that had completed their privatization as of March, 1996. Only these cases provided at least six months of post-privatization data on income and costs. The cases include Chaco, Corrientes, Entre Rios, Formosa, La Rioja, Misiones, Rio Negro, and Salta. The private sample includes the ten largest private banks in Argentina as of 1996. All public provincial banks are included in the provincial sample, including pre-privatization observations for the eight banks in the privatized sample. In those years where data were available for only a sub-sample of months for a given bank, the data were annualized. For example. for Salta in 1996, costs and income data were totaled over the six months for which data were available, and then multiplied by two. 17 Although, the privatized bank data are from different years (1995-96) than the private bank data (1993-1996), this does not appear to be driving the results.3' Table 7, which shows income and cost data broken down by year, indicates that the privatized and private banks generated comparable levels of total income per peso of cost each year that data on privatized provincial banks are available (1994-1996). Privatized provincial banks did generate a higher share of income through services than private banks each year but, in terms of efficiency in generating total income, their performances were remarkably similar to their well-established private competitors, and markedly better than the remaining public provincial banks. Total income outpaced administrative costs by a wide margin for the typical privatized and private bank every year. This should inspire some confidence in the future solvency of these iistitutions. In contrast, the financial and service income of the public provincial banks failed to outpace administrative costs every year. The improved performance of the public provincial banks is not, moreover, the result of improved performance in only one or two banks. In every instance in which the ratio of total income to administrative costs was less than one prior to privatization, the post-privatization ratio was greater than one (Table 8). This increased efficiency has coincided with substantial portfolio growth. Assets and liabilities have typically more than doubled in the years since privatization. It does not appear that privatized banks were content merely to maintain the portfolios that they inherited. Growth in assets has been fueled by the privatized banks' ability to attract deposits, which have increased at about the same pace as overall liabilities. Substantial post-privatization improvement in the ratio of portfolio income to administrative costs suggests that new loans created from the increase in deposits have been profitable. Figures on branches and employment make it clear that the improved operating In particular, the "Tequila Crisis" which occurred late in 1994 is unlikely to be causing the results. 18 margins are not merely the result of cost cutting. Since privatization, the number of branches decreased only slightly, if.at all, for each bank.32 Although some labor shedding has occurred, in no case has the work force been reduced by more than 15%. In summary, the data indicate that remaining employees generate profit far more efficiently than before. This suggests that the banks' loan portfolios became far more commercially oriented after privatization. Credit allocation data presented in the next sub-section provides additional support for this hypothesis. Table 8: Ratios of Income to Costs Before and after Privatization Fin Serv Total Assets Liabil. Net Depo- Loans # # Date Inc/ Inc/ Inc/ Worth sits Bra Em- Costs Costs Costs . nch ploy. Mean Mean Mean Pesos Pesos Pesos Pesos Pesos 000s IOOOsS OOOs IOOOs I000s Chaco Before -.379 .173 -.206 42883 34483 8400 10950 140 28 615 11/94 After .683 .683 1.366 220335 207088 13247 130995 63012 28 547 10/96 EntreRios Before -.161 .461 .300 395548 384548 11000 211900 226121 55 1542 1/95 After .726 .521 1.247 667609 614133 53476 503221 372225 68 1340 11/96 Formosa Before -1.589 .270 -1.319 26569 11569 15000 11569 5489 10 230 12/95 After .318 .733 1.051 129578 113064 16514 97379 77946 10 221 11/96 Misiones Before -.530 .333 -.197 70498 61498 9000 48131 47325 30 433 2/96 After .475 .890 1.364 157543 142820 14723 105159 77999 29 422 11/96 Rio Negro Before .333 .472 .805 49162 47362 1800 42212 41767 21 425 3/96 After .610 .524 1.134 134984 122142 12842 87640 85988 29 416 11/96 Salta Before 3.090 .289 3.379 58941 52711 6230 40892 18000 16 260 3/96 After 2.381 .842 3.223 250860 240924 9936 201988 173074 15 301 11/96 Data Sources: B.C.R.A. and Fondo Fiduciario Notes: The data on income and costs cover only 1993-96. Since Corrientes privatized in 1992, no pre-privatization data was available. For La Rioja, which privatized in 1994, pre-privatization data were not available because the bank had suspended operations in 1993. This leaves only the six cases listed above. 32 In some instances, owners of privatized banks are required to maintain a certain number of branches under the terms of their purchase agreements. 19 IV.2 Credit Allocation Portfolio composition data for privatized, provincial, and private banks in June, 1996 are presented in Table 9. While time series data on portfolio composition would show the evolution of privatized provincial bank credit allocation over time, the snapshot presented here is also telling.33 In general, regardless of the industry, the percent of total credits rated good was highest among private banks. The better established privatized provincial banks (those that privatized prior to April, 1996) eclipsed the private banks on one measure -- the percentage of good credits to the government services sector (99.9 versus 99.6%). The earliest privatizers approached the private bank percentages on two other measures -- family loans (77.2 versus 84.9% good credits) and construction (83.3 versus 91.8%). It is important to note that the private bank sample contains only the ten largest in Argentina, presumably among the best banks in the country.34 The percentage of good credit in other sectors (primary production, manufacturing, utilities, trade, and other services) was somewhat lower for the early privatizers than for private banks as of 1996. In general early privatizers had higher good credit percentages than either public provincial banks, recent privatizers (since June, 1996), or those that had begun but not completed the privatization process ("beginners"). Public provincial banks had slightly higher good credit percentages than early privatizers in only two categories -- primary production and utilities. Further, there are two reasons why the good credit percentages for the public provincial banks are likely to be significantly overstated. First, several measures of performance (nominal assets, net worth, and NW/TL) of privatized banks appear to have declined quite remarkably during the We did also have credit allocation data for December, 1995. However, for the five categories of banks in Table 9 the qualitative differences between that data and the 1996 data were not great. As a result, we present only the 1996 data. 34 Of course, because all new loans are good loans, it will more telling to observe privatized provincial banks' portfolio quality in coming years. They do, however, appear to be starting on very solid footing. 20 last year of public management (see Table I I and Figure 4 throughi Figure 6 in Appendix 11). This apparent decline was probably due to rigorous pre-privatization audits whichi typically occurred at this time. This would also explain the extremely low percentages of good credits for recent and beginning privatizers in Table 9 -- those banks hiad undergone pre-privatization audits but had not benefited from the creation of a residual entity. Data for beginninig and recent privatizers are, therefore, probably more reflective of the actual situation of the remaining public provincial banks than the data on public banks in Table 9. Table 9: Credit Allocation by Industry, 1996 Bank Primary Manuf. Const. Utilities Trade Gov't Other Family Type Prod. Srvcs. Srvcs. Loans (%) (%) ) () ( ) ((%) (%) Prov. Avg shr 11.6 20.2 4.0 0.2 12.8 17.6 7.2 15.6 %Good 52.2 41.9 53.8 75.2 43.2 93.9 63.8 71.9 (n=8) EstPrv Avg shr 7.2 6.4 5.8 .06 15.4 11.8 6.2 11.8 %Good 45.7 63.2 83.3 69.4 57.1 99.9 66.3 77.2 (n=8) RecPrv Avg shr 15.6 11.4 11.6 .04 20.4 10.2 14.6 6.2 %Good 18.8 11.2 22.4 18.4 13.1 82.7 29.6 55.1 (n=6) !ntPrv Avg shr 11.8 12.6 5.6 .22 28.8 14.8 7.0 15.0 %Good 25.7 37.2 25.3 83.8 32.0 80.7 35.1 59.9 (n=5) Private Avg shr 6.8 23.0 4.4 3.2 10.4 4.4 10.8 25.2 %Good 90.3 90.1 91.8 99.4 83.1 99.6 91.2 84.9 (n = I0) __ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ Data Source: B.C.R.A. Notes: Prov covers those eight public provincial banks that have taken no steps toward privatization (Buenos Aires, Chubut, Cordoba, Social de Cordoba, La Pampa, Neuquen, Santafesino de Inversion, and Cofirene Banco de Inversion). EstPrv covers better established privatized provincial banks -- those that had completed privatization as of March, 1996 (Chaco, Corrientes, Entre Rios, Formosa, La Rioja, Misiones, Rio Negro, and Salta). RecPrv covers recently privatized provincial banks, those that completed their privatizations in the last half of 1996 (Mendoza, Prevision Social de Mendoza, San Juan, San Luis, Santiago del Estero, and Tucuman). BegPrv covers those banks that have begun but not completed the privatization process (Catamarca, Juiuy, Santa Cruz, Santa Fe, and Tierra del Fuego). Private includes the ten largest private banks in Argentina in 1996. The columns of each row do not sum to one because we have omitted a catch-all category called "other loans." 21 Second, the figures for public provincial banks include Buenos Aires, a case apart from the others. When Buenos Aires data are removed, the percentage of good credits in each category drops by about 5%. After removing Buenos Aires and correcting for potential overstatements, the percentages of good credits will almost certainly trail those for the earliest privatizers by an even greater amount. Therefore, it is fair to conclude that, as of 1 996, the earliest privatizers had much higher quality portfolios thani the remaining public provincial banks. Whether the privatized banks can maintain quality is another important question. Indications are, however, positive. Of the early privatizers, nearly half have been private for at least two years -- the averages in Table 9, therefore, reflect some ability to maintain the portfolio quality inherited after purging residual assets and liabilities. In addition, the operating income and cost data presented above is encouraging. At the very least, beginning and recent privatizers can take heart that, in the cases to date, the provinces have been able to create a privatized entity whose initial portfolio quality approaches that of the top private banks. It is more difficult to draw strong conclusions regarding portfolio composition. To some extent, the composition may depend upon the resource endowments of the province in which the bank resides. It is difficult, therefore, to argue that the industrial composition of the private bank portfolios is inherently superior to that of the other banks, and that we should expect privatized provincial. banks to create similar portfolios over time. We might, however, expect less credit to be allocated to the government once political incentives have been replaced by purely economic ones. The data indicate that the remaining public provincial banks have the highest share of their portfolios concentrated in government services (17.6%), followed by beginning privatizers (14.8%). Recent and early privatizers allocate a little more than 10% of their portfolios to government services, while private banks devote a little less than 5% of theirs 22 to the sector, It appears that credit to the public sector does decline in importance after privatization, and that this portfolio shift does coincide with improved portfolio quality. Individual bank data confirms this observation. Table 10 shows public sector credit data before and after privatization for the eight banks that privatized prior to April, 1996. With the exception of Entre Rios, the privatized banks have substantially lower nominal credits to the public sector. Interestingly, the banks that now have the higlhest shares of bad credits are those that had the highest shares of public credit prior to privatization -- the two worst performers, La Rioja and Corrientes, loaned over 90% of their pre-privatization credit to the public sector. It is possible that these banks lacked both experience lending to the private sector and an established private clientele. In summary, when the pre-privatization share of credit to the public sector was low, and where there was a substantial reduction in nominal public credit, portfolio quality (as measured by the share of bad credits) has improved substantially. In fact, the average share of bad credit for the five banks satisfying these criteria is a little over 5%, slightly lower than for the private bank sample from 1994-96.35 3S Admittedly, the low shares of bad credit for some banks in Table 10 may merely reflect that all bad credits passed to the residual entity. Their "steady-state" bad credit shares may turn out to be a bit higher. 23 Table 10: Credit to the Public Sector, Before and After Privatization Bank Credit to Public Credit to Public Credit to Public Credit to Public Bad Credits as Sector, Pre- Sector, Post- Sector, Pre- Sector, Post- a Percentage of Privatization Privatization Privatization Privatization Total (Millions of Pesos) (Millions of Pesos) (% of Total) (% of Total) 1996 Chaco 379,892 (1994) 223 (1996) 46.5 0.4 13.8 Corrientes 378,469 (1992) 1,458 (1996) 90.9 15.6 35.2 Entre Rios 115,389 (1994) 108,281 (1996) 17.0 23.8 21.7 Formosa 54,065 (1994) 0 (1996) 20.7 0.0 0.0 La Rioja 379,083 (1991) 0 (1996) 95.8 0.0 28.4 Misiones 164,681 (1994) 38,234 (1996) 33.6 58.6 5.0 Rio Negro 158,419 (1992) 7,555 (1996) 18.8 9.2 9.1 Salta 33,227 (1995) 15 (1996) 19.5 0.0 0.0 Source: B.C.R.A. To summarize, the available data indicate that privatized provincial banks are far more similar to Argentina's ten largest private banks than they are to public provincial banks. First, they appear to operate as profitably and efficiently as the private banks as indicated by their ratios of operating income to costs. In addition, their composition of operating income has shifted slightly towards net financial income as opposed to income from services. Although the private banks continue to generate a higher share of their income through financial income, the privatized provincial banks are gaining ground. The improved situation of the privatized provincial banks is also reflected in their portfolio quality. Their percentage of bad credits is lower than for public provincial banks. These improvements in portfolio quality, moreover, have coincided with a decreased emphasis on public credit. All of this augers well for the future solvency of these banks. More importantly, perhaps, the data suggest that credit allocation is improving as a result of privatization. Although the social welfare effects of improved credit allocation are difficult to quantify, these may be privatization's most important legacy. V CONCLUSIONS The evidence from Argentina strongly suggests that, from a fiscal perspective, the decision to maintain a public provincial bank is a costly one. Loss rates for public provincial banks in Argentina were much higher than for other banks, implying that the future fiscal costs 24 of maintaining the solvency and liquidity of these institutions are hiigh. Although privatization might appear unappealing to policy makers with short time horizons, the long-term fiscal gains demonstrate the importance of privatization. Courageous policy makers should root out the problems caused by public provincial banks that misallocate credit and are frequently in need of re-capitalization. Although the short time series makes it difficult to draw strong conclusions, the data currently available indicate that privatization enhances future solvency prospects. No doubt, the regulatory environment into which these banks were sold also affects their solvency. To the extent that sound, incentive compatible prudential regulations are in place at the time of privatization (and, in Argentina's case that appears to be true), the future performance of all banks is likely to be improved. The results, hiowever, suggest that improved regulation and supervision does not deliver the same benefits as improved regulation and supervision combined with privatization -- the provincial banks that remained in the public sector did not demonstrate the same performance gains as privatized provinicial banks. This paper also has some important findings of special interest to policymakers in Argentina, and in other,countries considering privatizing state-owned banks. Based on the Argentinean experience, policy makers should expect the privatization to pass through some, or all, of the following steps. First, with respect to pre-privatization audits, expect losses hidden in these banks to be larger than indicated in prior audits. Second, if residual entities are created, expect them to comprise a large share of the assets and liabilities of the old public provincial bank if the quality of its loan portfolio was low. Third, based on the experience to date, do not expect the price paid for the privatized entity (the so-called "good bank") to be large, at least in comparison with the assets and liabilities in the residual entity. Fourth, if the residual entity is large, the province will be confronted with substantial short-term liabilities. With assistance (e.g. from Fondo Fiduciario loans in Argentina) and an aggressive asset recovery strategy, 25 however, governments should be able to navigate their way through short-term difficulty. It will take a significant amount of time to tell whether residual entity liquidations are proceeding well and, therefore, further analysis in this area is warranted as data becomes available. Finally, policy makers that make (or have made) the tough decision to privatize should take heart that the data strongly indicate that the costs of privatization are smaller than the costs of future re- capitalization, even if the near-term management of the residual entity does not go well. 26 VI REFERENCES Baer, Herbert, and Gray, Cheryl. "Debt as a Control Device in Transitional Economies: Thle Experiences of Hungary and Poland," Presentation to a Joint Conference of the World Bank and the Central European University Privatization Project, Washington, DC, 1994. Baumol, William J. "On the Social Rate of Discount," American Economic Review, September 1968, 58, pp.788-802. Caprio Jr., Gerard; Atiyas, Izak; Hanson, James A. and Associates. Financial Reform: Theory and Practice. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1994. Caprio Jr., Gerard, and Klingebiel, Daniela. "Bank Insolvency: Bad Luck, Bad Policy, or Bad Banking?," World Bank mimeo, April, 1996. Central Bank of the Republic of Argentina, "Main Features of the Regulatory Framework of the Argentina Financial System," mimeo, September, 1996. Central Bank of the Republic of Argentina., Boletin Monetario and Financiero, December, 1996. Clarke, George and Cull, Robert. "The Political Economy of Privatization: An Empirical Analysis of Bank Privatization in Argentina." World Bank mimeo, 1997a. Clarke, George, and Cull, Robert. "Privatizing Argentina's Public Provincial Banks," in Argentina: The Fiscal Dimension of the Convertibility Plan, World Bank mimeo, August, 1997b. Cull, Robert. "Financial Sector adjustment Lending: A Mid-Course Analysis," World Bank mnimeo, July, 1997. Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, and Levine, Ross. "The Financial System and Public Enterprise Reform: Concepts and Cases," World Bank mimeo, 1994. Goldsmith, Raymond W. Financial Structure and Development. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1969. Hwa, Erh-Chang., "Enterprise Reform in China: A Background Note," Draft Paper, World Bank Mission, Beijing, China, 1992. King, Robert G., and Levine, Ross. "Financial Indicators and Growth in a Cross Section of Countries," World Bank mimeo, January, 1992. King, Robert G., and Levine, Ross. "Capital Fundamentalism, Economic Development, and Economic Growth," in Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 1994, 40, pp. 259-92. King, Robert G., and Levine, Ross. "Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right," Ouarterlv Journal of Economics, August 1993a, 108(3), pp. 717-38. 27 King, Robert G., and Levine, Ross. "Finance, Entrepreneurship, and Growth: Tlheory and Evidence," Journal of Monetary Economics, December 1 993b, 32(3), pp. 513-42. Kyei, Alexander. "Deposit Protection Arrangements: A Comparative Study," IMF Working Paper No. WP/95/134, December, 1995. Levine, Ross, and Renelt, David. "A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions," American Economic Review, September 1992, 82(4), pp. 942-63. Levine, Ross. "Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda," World Bank inimeo, October, 1996. Levine, Ross, and Zervos, Sara. "Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth," World Bank mimeo, December, 1996. Marglin, Stephien A. "The Social Rate of Discount and the Optimal Rate of Investment," Ouarterly Journal of Economics, February 1963, 77, pp. 95-1 12. McKinnon, Ronald I. Money and Capital in Economic Development, Washilgton, DC: Brookings Institution, 1973. Ministry of Economics and the Central Bank of the Republic of Argentina, "Experience and Lessons from Financial Market Instability: The Argentine Experience," Paper prepared for GI 0 Working Party on Emerging Market Instability, December, 1996. Pigou, Arthur C. The Economics of Welfare. 4th ed; Londoni: Macmillan, 1932. Quirk, James, and Terasawa, Katsuaki. "Choosing a Government Discount Rate: An Alternative Approach," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 1991, 20, pp. 16-28. Schumpeter, Joseph A. Theorie der Wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, Leipzig: Dunker & Humblot, 1912. [The Theory of Economic Development, 1912, translated by Redvers Opie. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1934.] Sherif, Khaled. "Egypt's Public Enterprise Experience," Published in Arabic. Cairo: Al- Ahram. 1992. Sherif, Khaled, and Soos, Regina. "Egypt's Liberalization Experience and Its Impact on State- Owned Enterprise Industrial Performance," in lliya Harik and Dennis Sullivan, eds., Privatization and Liberalization in the Middle East. Bloomington, Ind.: Indiana University Press, 1993. Shirley, Mary, and Nellis, John. Public Enterprise Reform. The Lessons of Experience. Washington, DC: Economic Development Institute of the World Bank. Stallings, Barbara, and Brock, Philip. "Economic Adjustment in Chile: 1973-90," in Robert Bates and Anne Kreuger, eds., Political and Economic Interactions in Economic Policy Reform. Evidencefrom Eight Countries. Oxford, UK: Basil Blackwell Limited, 1993. 28 Talley, Samuel H., and Mas, Ignacio. "Deposit Insurance in Developing Coulitries," World Bank Policy Research and External Affairs Working Paper WPS 548, November, 1 980. Unal, Haluk, and Navarro, Miguel. "The Technical Process of Bank Privatization in Mexico," mimeo, 1995. World Bank, World Development Report 1989, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1989. World Bank. Bureaucrats in Business: The Economics and Politics of Government Ownership, Policy Research Report, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995. 29 APPENDIX 1 Fiscal Costs of Re-Capitalization Under Various Scenarios Scenario 1: Ratio of Net Worth to Assets in Year 1: .115 (Arg. Requirement) Net Worth in Year 1: 25,000,000 Loss Rate in Ratio of Net Worth to Liabilities: .090 (Sample Mean, Prov) Rate of Growth in Nominal Liabilities: .1 13 (Sample Mean, 1996) Year Net Worth Total Total Implied Nominal PV PV Assets Liabil. Asset Re-Cap. Re-Cap. Re-Cap. Growth Payment Payment Payment During 10% disc 15% disc millions millions millions Cycle millions millions millions (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) 1 25 217 192 .020 0 0 0 3 -11.9 226 238 .020 42.9 29.3 24.5 6 -14.8 280 295 .020 53.1 27.2 20.0 9 - 18.3 347 366 .020 65.8 25.3 16.3 12 -22.6 430 453 .020 81.5 23.6 13.2 96 -9092.0 172747 181839 .020 32731.0 3.2 .04 99 -11262.8 213994 225257 .020 35881.6 2.6 .03 Total 205515 383 132 Scenario 2: Same as 1, except Loss Rate in Ratio of Net Worth to Total Liabilities is .08 (Sample Mean for Public provincial banks except Buenos Aires, excluding the years with the highest and the lowest loss rates) l 99 -6765.7 225257 218491 .031 31901.8 2.3 .03 Total 182721 340 117 Scenario3: Same as 1, except Loss Rate in Ratio of Net Worth to Total Liabilities is .0627 (Sample Mean for Public provincial banks except Buenos Aires, excluding year with highest average loss rates) 99 994.7 225257 226251 .049 25034.2 1.8 .021 Total l 143386 267 92 Scenario 4: Same as 1, except Loss Rate in Ratio of Net Worth to Total Liabilities is . 125 99 -27031 198226 225257 -.018 49835 3.6 .04 Total | l [ _ | 285438 531 183 30 APPENDIX II. THE LOSS OF NET WORTH AMONG PUBLIC PROVINCIAL BANKS. Between 1991 and 1996, the net worth of most public provincial banks declined in both nominal and real terms (See Table 1 1). These small nominal drops in net worth coincided with large declines in the ratio of net worth to total liabilities (NW/TL), due to large increases in the nominal value of liabilities. The average net worth of private banks, Buenos Aires, and those privatized provincial banks that had already gone through their pre-privatization audits grew in nominal terms (Table 11 and Figure 1). 36 Although this was a roughi period for al I banks -- private banks' average NW/TL fell by 3.7% -- the 9% average decline for public provincial banks was over twice as large (See Table 11 and Figure 3).37 Thle large drops in NW/TL were partly due to severe financial disintermediation (low liability levels) early in the period. In 1991, inflation was 172% and, as a result, the ratio of M2 to GDP dipped to 10.6%. The ratio of quasi-money (timie, savings, and foreign currency deposits) to GDP was only 4.2%, low even by developing country standards. As inflation subsided (24.6% in 1992 and 10.6% in 1993), financial depth recovered (quasi-money was 8.7% of GDP in 1992 and 11.7% in 1993) and NW/TL dropped as bank liabilities increased. However, even excluding the dramatic drop in 1991, the average annual loss in NW/TL was 6.3% for public provincial banks.38 "Private banks" refers to a sample of the ten largest private banks in Argentina as of 1996. It was thought that these ten would be among the best performing banks in Argentina, and thus would provide a difficult comparitor for the privatized bank sample. In this way, we biased our analysis against the conclusion that newly privatized banks were performing well solely because they had improved relative to public provincial banks. Encouragingly, in the comparisons that follow, the privatized provincial banks tend to perform nearly as well as these large private banks. As noted earlier, Buenos Aires appears very different from the other public provincial banks. Therefore, results excluding Buenos Aires are presented in addition to results including Buenos Aires. Comparisons between privatized and private banks in Table II may be misleading in that almost ali privatizations occurred late in the period. To the extent that banking conditions were more tfvorable in these years, privatized provincial banks' relatively impressive performance with respect to net worth and NW/TL may be illusory. Of course, the Tequila Crisis years occurred late in the period, which makes it unlikely that the privatized provincial banks' performance benefited from timing etfects. Clarke and Cull (1 997b) offers the same comparisons between banks as in Table I1, except that they are broken down by year for the period 1994-6, the prime privatization years. The qualitative results remain largely unchanged. 31 Table 11: Net Worth/Assets by Type of Bank (1991-96)39 Bank Type Mean Std. Dev. Max. Min. Observ. Net Worth Provincial 87,476.8 208,054.1 1,282,039 -32,307 135 Prov - BA 44,622.4 47,491.6 227,959 -32,307 129 Private 221,535.6 168,059.1 687,052 9,478 70 Privatized Prov Last Year Public -16,938.7 53,275.7 58,352 -133,079 13 1st Year Private 17,896.8 11,441.0 37,403 4,500 6 2nd Year Private 28,041.0 16,448.6 45,852 13,423 3 Change in Net Worth Provincial 2,959.7 37,037.0 194,707 -128,424 109 Prov - BA -1,890.6 25,824.9 65,012 -128,424 104 Private 36,854.4 47,189.8 232,437 -93,911 60 Privatized Prov Last Year Public -50,778.8 64,395.5 14,240 -186,965 13 1st Year Private 46,818.8 73,145.3 146,231 -34,214 6 2nd Year Private 6,027.3 4,611.0 8,923 710 3 Chng in NW/TL Provincial -0.086 0.217 0.170 -1.523 106 Prov - BA -0.090 0.222 0.170 -1.523 101 Private -0.037 0.066 0.138 -0.307 58 Privatized Prov Last Year Public -0.150 0.208 0.054 -0.665 13 Ist Year Private +0.210 0.265 0.584 -0.052 5 2nd Year Private +0.005 0.045 0.053 -0.035 3 % Clhg in Assets Provincial +26.7 39.1 215.5 -50.6 108 Prov - BA +27.6 39.8 215.5 -50.6 103 Private +43.9 36.1 174.3 -27.1 58 Privatized Prov Last Year Public -8.1 37.7 66.8 -76.8 13 I st Year Private -13.1 64.6 80.8 -69.2 5 2nd Year Private +68.6 75.8 156.1 23.4 3 The performance of privatized provincial banks with respect to net worth and NW/TL depended on how far the bank was along the privatization process. In the year prior to the actual " Notes: Provincial covers all public provincial banks, including those observations for privatized provincial banks prior to privatization. As noted below, qualitative results for provincial banks are quite similar if these pre- privatization observations are dropped. Prov - BA is Provincial except for observations for Buenos Aires. Private covers a sample often large private banks. For privatized provincial banks, the data are broken into three categories. The first is all observations from privatized banks when they were in their final year as a public bank (when more rigorous audits occurred). The second, "I st year private," contains observations for all privatized banks during their first full year of private operations. "2nd year private" contains observations from their second years of private operation. 32 sale (the last year of public management), when rigorous pre-privatization audits typically occurred, net worth plummeted, usually dipping well below zero. In the first fuill year of private nanagement, net worth recovered, normally becoming positive. On average, the gains in net worth, when coupled with the reduced liabilities of the privatized provincial bank, were more thaii sufficient to offset the decline in NW/TL during the last year of public operation. The improvements left the average privatized provincial bank with a marginally acceptable NW/TL ratio (9.8%) that was often sustained throughout the second year of private operation (See Figure 4 throughi Figure 6 for examples). Figure I Net Worth By Bank Type 4,000,000 - - ~3,500,000 S 2,500,000 .. F_rw-iv-a-te Banks 3 ,000,000 rvMnsBeo 2 ,500,0007 Yea 2 by000 yea coprsn ewe ulcadprivatizing prvncaabnsnrkdficl *~1000,000 du oa akofdt.Norlabecmprsn can Pro mnus buenore19:olsCrine a z 500,000 A 0 ~~Prov Buenos A. 1990 1992 1994 1996 Year Year by year comparisons between public and privatized provinicial baniks are difficult due to a lack of data. No reliable comparisons can be made before 1993: onily Corrientes hiad 40 been privatized, and it was still not far along the post-privatization path. Between 1994 and 1996 there were typically provinces in the first, second and third years of privatization. The number of observations in each group were, however, quite small (less than four). With few exceptions, banks in their first and second full years of private operation out-performed all other 40 It should also be noted that Corrientes eventually went back to public hands. At present, the province has begun searching for a new private owner. Clearly, the Corrientes experience should be seen as distinct from the others. 33 banks.41 Privatized banks in their first year of private operations typically experienced dramatic post-audit increases in both net worth and NW/TL which were, no doubt, largely due to the provinces' efforts to create salable banks from the post-audit ruins. The dramatic increases are not, therefore, an indication that old public provincial bank operations had necessarily improved, but rather that tihe difficulties resulting from years of sub-par operations had been swept into the residual entities. Figure 2 Net Worth By Bank Type 1,400,000 1,200,000 :- 1,000,000 Privatizing Banks t 800,000 0 600,000 4 600,000 - . -' \ Prov Mnus Buenos , 400,000 [ :i A. 200,000 K _. . ov8uenosA 1990 1992 1994 1996 - Year Notes: Figure 2 is a re-production of Figure 1, except that private banks are eliminated to foster better visual comparisons. Figure 3 Ratio of Net Worth to Total Liabilities 0.4 I -u Privatizing t 0.15 0.2 ! .: :Prov w/o BA 015i .. Prov BA ,D 0.05 :; . . , - - i | T Prov w ,o BA, COR i z 0.0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 Year Notes: Private includes the ten large banks in the private b-anking sampie. Privatizing includes those had privatized by 1996, and five banks who were in the early stages of privatization in 1996, but had not as yet sold their banks. Prov 41 See Clarke and Cull (1997b) for details. 34 BA is Buenos Aires. Prov w/o BA is for all public provincial banks except Buenos Aires. Prov w/o BA, COR is for all public provincial banks except Buenos Aires and the Banco de La Provincia de Cordoba. Figure 3 presents data for only 1992-96 to foster better visual comparisons. As noted in the text, 1991 was a year of severe financial disintermediation. The result was a very high ratio of net worth to liabilities, which declined dramatically in 1992 as disintermediation subsided. The 1993-96 data probably give the most accurate depiction of the steady-state situation. Figure 4 Entre Rios: Ratio of Net Worth to Liabilities 4 0.3 5 A 0.25 _ .!0210ie> _ 0.15 1 0 a 0-.1 t a~0 z - 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 Year I . ____ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ ___ _ ____ _ _ __ _ _ ___ _ _ _ ___ _ _ _ , Figure 4,Fgr n iue6so httepivtzto yl -daai elnsi Formosa: Ratio of Net Worth to Liabilities 0.3 .2 0.2 0.1 2o _j 0 . -0.2 -f - 0.3 ~ 0.4 Z -0.5 Year Figure 4, Figure 5 and Figure 6 show that the privatization cycle --dramatic declines in NW/TL in the last year of public operations, and a recovery in the first year of private operations that is maintained in the second year -- is evident regardless of banking conditions in a given year. Entre Rios, Formosa, and San Luis all experienced dramatic declines in NW/TL in their last years as public banks (respectively 1994, 1995, and 1996). Both Enitre Rios and Formosa 35 recovered to NW/TL levels just under .10 (in line with the Basle guidelines for capital adequacy). As noted, Entre Rios maintained these levels in its second full year of private operation. It remains to be seen whether Formosa will do the same in 1997, and whether San Luis will recover and then maintain in 1997 and 1998. Figure 6 San Luis: Ratio of Net Worth to Liabilities 0.32i i t--0.11 1- 1992 I3 1994 199 1 6 -0.2 Year In summary, a province contemplating privatization should expect a rigorous pre- privatization audit to greatly decrease the public provincial bank's apparent NW/TL. Potential privatizers should, however, be assured that in every case to date provinces have created a salable entity from the ashes of the public provincial bank. After privatization, moreover, these new banks appear to function on par with well-established private banks (at least with respect to NW/TL). As demonstrated in Section II, the decreased risk of government re-capitalization will more than compensate the province for the short-term fiscal pain caused by realizing existing losses. 36 Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS1952 Enterprise Isolation Programs in Simeon Djankov August 1998 R. Vo Transition Economies 33722 WPS1 953 Trade Policies and Incentives in Garry Pursell August 1998 L. Tabada Indian Agriculture: Methodology, 36896 Background Statistics and Protection, and Incentive Indicators, 1965-95- Background Paper 1, Sugar and Sugarcane WPS1 954 Politicians and Firms in Seven StiJn Claessens August 1998 R. Vo Central and Eastern European Simeon Djankov 33722 Countries WPS1955 Appraising Workfare Programs Martin Ravallion August 1998 P. Sader 33902 WPS1 956 Benefit Incidence and the Timing Peter Lanjouw August 1998 P. Sader of Program Capture Martin Ravallion 33902 WPS1957 Bidding for Concessions Michael Klein August 1998 J. Dytang 37161 WPS1958 Total Strangers or Soul Mates? J. Luis Guash August 1998 J. Troncoso Antidumping and Competition Sarath Rajapatirana 37826 Policies in Latin America and the Caribbean WPS1959 Is There a Credit Crunch in Wei Ding August 1998 F. Fernandes East Asia? llker Domag 80453 Giovanni Ferri WPS1960 Calm After the Storms: Income Francisco H. G. Ferreira August 1998 G. llogon Distribution in Chile, 1987-94 Julie A. Litchfield 33732 WPS1961 Protecting the Environment and the Gunnar S. Eskeland August 1998 C. Bernardo Poor: A Public Goods Framework Chingying Kong 31148 Applied to indonesia WPS1962 The Political Economy of George R. G. Clarke August 1998 P. Sintim-Aboagye Privatization: An Empirical Analysis Robert Cull 38526 of Bank Privatization in Argentina WPS1963 Commodity Risk Management and Donald F. Larson August 1998 P. Kokila Development Panos Varangis 33716 Nanae Yabuki WPS1964 Public Investment and Economic Ulrich Lachler August 1998 C. Lazcano Growth in Mexico David Alan Aschauer 37776 Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS1965 Manufacturing Firms in Developing James Tybout August 1998 L. Tabada Countries: How Well Do They Do, 36869 and Why WPS1966 Sulfur Dioxide Control by Electric Curtis Carlson August 1998 T. Tourougui Utilities: What Are the Gains from Dallas Burtraw 87431 Trade? Maureen Cropper Karen L. Palmer WPS1967 Agriculture and the Macroeconomy Maurice Schiff August 1998 A. Valdes Alberto Valdes 35491 WPS1968 The Economics and Law of Rent Kaushik Basu August 1998 M. Mason Control Patrick Emerson 30809 WPS1969 Protecting the Poor in Vietnam's Dominique van de Walle September 1998 C. Bernardo Emerging Market Economy 31148 WPS1970 Trade Liberalization and Endogenous Thomas F. Rutherford September 1998 L. Tabada Growth in a Small Open Economy: David G. Tarr 36896 A Quantitative Assessment WPS1971 Promoting Better Logging Practices Marco Boscolo September 1998 T. Tourougui in Tropical Forests Jeffrey R. Vincent 87431