78679 DIREC TIONS IN DE VELOPMENT Infrastructure Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean on the Role of the Private Sector, Regulation, and Governance in the Power, Water, and Telecommunication Sectors Luis A. Andrés, Jordan Schwartz, and J. Luis Guasch Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance Direc tions in De velopment Infrastructure Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean on the Role of the Private Sector, Regulation, and Governance in the Power, Water, and Telecommunication Sectors Luis A. Andrés Jordan Schwartz J. Luis Guasch © 2013 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000; Internet: www.worldbank.org Some rights reserved 1 2 3 4 16 15 14 13 This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. Note that The World Bank does not necessarily own each component of the content included in the work. The World Bank therefore does not warrant that the use of the content contained in the work will not infringe on the rights of third parties. The risk of claims resulting from such infringement rests solely with you. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this work do not necessarily reflect the views of The World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Nothing herein shall constitute or be considered to be a limitation upon or waiver of the privileges and immunities of The World Bank, all of which are specifically reserved. Rights and Permissions This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 Unported license (CC BY 3.0) http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0. Under the Creative Commons Attribution license, you are free to copy, distribute, transmit, and adapt this work, including for commercial purposes, under the following conditions: Attribution—Please cite the work as follows: Andrés, Luis A., Jordan Schwartz, and J. Luis Guasch. 2012. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance: Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean on the Role of the Private Sector, Regulation, and Governance in the Power, Water, and Telecommunication Sectors. Washington, DC: World Bank. doi:10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5. License: Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0 Translations—If you create a translation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the attribution: This translation was not created by The World Bank and should not be considered an official World Bank translation. The World Bank shall not be liable for any content or error in this translation. All queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to the Office of the Publisher, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2625; e-mail: pubrights@worldbank.org. ISBN (paper): 978-0-8213-9660-5 ISBN (electronic): 978-0-8213-9700-8 DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Cover drawing: Emily Cash Wilmoth; Cover design: Naylor Design Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Andrés, Luis Alberto. Uncovering the drivers of utility performance : lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean on the role of the private sector, regulation, and governance in the power, water, and telecommunication sectors. / Luis A. Andrés, Jordan Schwartz, J. Luis Guasch.     p. cm.   Includes bibliographical references. ISBN 978-0-8213-9660-5 — ISBN 978-0-8213-9700-8   1. Public utilities—Latin America. 2. Public utilities—Government policy—Latin America. 3. Privatization—Latin America. 4. Infrastructure (Economics)—Latin America. 5. Public utilities—Caribbean Area. 6. Public utilities—Government policy—Caribbean Area. 7. Privatization—Caribbean Area. 8. Infrastructure (Economics)—Caribbean Area. I. Schwartz, Jordan. II. Guasch, J. Luis. III. Title.   HD2768.L294A53 2013  363.6098—dc23 2012030889 Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Contents Acknowledgments xi About the Authors xiii Abbreviations xv Overview 1 Message 1: Even in regions such as LAC, where reform has led to sector performance improvements in electricity distribution, water and sanitation, and fixed telecommunications, there is still much room for improvement 3 Message 2: Both the government (as regulator and service provider) and the private sector (as service provider) can play active roles in improving sector performance 4 Message 3: Improving sector performance requires a holistic approach that is tailored to specific circumstances 6 Moving Forward 7 Notes 8 References 8 Chapter 1 Introduction 9 Analytical Framework and Scope 12 Notes 14 References 14 Chapter 2 Benchmarking Utility Performance 17 Why Benchmark Infrastructure Sectors? 17 Do Utilities with Private Sector Participation Outperform Public Utilities? 26 Conclusions 27 Notes 29 References 29 Chapter 3 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 31 Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   v   vi Contents Impact of Private Sector Participation on Electricity Distribution 33 Impact of Private Sector Participation on Water and Sewerage 42 Impact of Private Sector Participation on Fixed-Line Telecommunications 53 Impact of Contract Design 63 Conclusions 65 Notes 66 References 68 Chapter 4 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance 71 Benchmarking 72 Factors Accounting for Differences in Governance 80 Regulatory Governance and Sector Performance 86 Principal Components of the Governance of Regulatory Agencies 88 Conclusions 89 Notes 90 References 91 Chapter 5 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 93 Methodology and Framework of Analysis 95 Results of Corporate Governance Benchmarking 96 Corporate Governance and Performance 108 Conclusion 110 Notes 112 References 113 Chapter 6 Other Determinants of Sector Performance 115 Corruption 115 Cost Recovery 116 Role of Civil Society 116 Contract Arrangements 117 Private Sector Participation and Renegotiation 117 Private Sector Participation and Reputation 118 Economies of Scope, Scale, and Density 118 Competition in the Telecommunication Sector 119 Conclusion 119 Notes 120 References 120 Chapter 7 Conclusions 123 Note 129 Appendix A Empirical Approach 131 References 132 Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Contents vii Appendix B Data Sets 133 Performance Indicators Data Set 133 LAC Electricity Distribution Benchmarking Database 135 LAC Water and Sanitation Benchmarking Database 138 ITU World Telecommunication/ICT Indicators Database 141 Contract and Regulatory Characteristics Data Set 142 Regulatory Governance 143 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 144 Notes 145 References 145 Appendix C Benchmarking Analysis 147 Electricity Distribution 147 Water and Sanitation Sector 156 Telecommunications Sector 166 Public versus Private Benchmarking Assessment 172 Appendix D Detailed Results of the Empirical Analysis 183 Reference 212 Appendix E Dimensions of Regulatory Governance 213 Appendix F Regulatory Governance and Performance 227 Appendix G Corporate Governance and Performance 233 Box 4.1 Multiagency Regulatory Schemes 77 Figures 1.1 Analytical Framework for Analyzing Sector Performance 12 1.2 Internal, Sectoral, and External Conditions Affecting Utility Performance 13 3.1 Energy Distribution before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 36 3.2 Electricity Coverage before and after Private Sector Participation 37 3.3 Employment in the Electricity Distribution Sector before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 37 3.4 Labor Productivity in Electricity Distribution before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 38 3.5 Distributional Losses in the Electricity Sector before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 40 3.6 Quality of Electricity Distribution before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 41 3.7 Indicators of Water and Sewerage Output and Coverage before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 44 3.8 Water Distribution before and after Private Sector Participation 47 Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 viii Contents 3.9 Employment and Labor Productivity in the Water Distribution Sector before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 48 3.10 Average Price of Water and Sewerage before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 49 3.11 Losses in Water Distribution before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 51 3.12 Service Continuity and Quality of Water before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 52 3.13 Number of Fixed-Line Connections and Average Minutes Consumed before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 54 3.14 Coverage of Fixed-Line Telecommunications before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 55 3.15 Coverage Levels of Fixed-Line Telecommunications before and after Private Sector Participation 56 3.16 Number of Employees in the Fixed-Line Telecommunication Sector before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 57 3.17 Labor Productivity in Fixed-Line Telecommunications before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 58 3.18 Price of a Fixed-Line Telecommunications Service before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 60 3.19 Quality of Fixed-Line Communications before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 62 4.1 Framework for Assessing Governance of Independent Regulatory Agencies 74 4.2 Aggregated Index of Regulatory Governance 76 4.3 Indicators of Regulatory Governance in Electricity Distribution 78 4.4 Indicators of Regulatory Governance in Water Distribution 81 5.1 Framework for Assessing Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 96 5.2 Aggregate Index of Corporate Governance in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 98 5.3 Index of Legal Soundness in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 99 5.4 Index of Board Competitiveness in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 101 5.5 Index of Chief Executive Officer Competitiveness in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 102 5.6 Index of Professional Management in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 103 5.7 Index of Transparency and Disclosure in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 106 5.8 Performance Orientation Index in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 107 C.1 Regional Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Output, Coverage, and Labor Productivity 147 Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Contents ix C.2 Regional Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Distributional Losses and Quality of the Service 149 C.3 Regional Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Tariffs and Expenses 150 C.4 Utility Level Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Coverage, Output, and Labor Productivity 151 C.5 Utility Level Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Distributional Losses and Quality of the Service 153 C.6 Utility Level Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Tariffs and Expenses 154 C.7 Regional Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Coverage, Output, and Labor Productivity 156 C.8 Regional Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Efficiency, Labor Productivity, and Quality of the Service 158 C.9 Regional Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Tariffs and Expenses 159 C.10 Utility Level Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Coverage and Output 160 C.11 Utility Level Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Labor Productivity, Efficiency, and Quality of the Service 162 C.12 Utility Level Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Tariffs and Expenses 164 C.13 Fixed Telecommunications Sector 166 C.14 Public versus Private Benchmarking Assessment 172 C.15 Top Ten and Bottom Ten Percent Performers 179 E.1 Electricity Regulatory Agencies 213 E.2 Water Regulatory Agencies 220 Tables 2.1 Variable Definitions, by Sector 19 3.1 Effects of Private Participation in Electricity Distribution, Water Distribution, and Fixed-Line Telecommunications in Latin America and the Caribbean 34 3.2 Base Case for Regulatory and Contract Variables 64 5.1 Analytical Framework for Assessing Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 97 B.1 Electricity Coverage and Data Coverage (Base Year = 2005) 136 B.2 LAC Electricity Distribution Benchmarking Database—Summary Statistics 137 B.3 Water Coverage and Data Coverage (Base Year = 2004) 139 B.4 LAC Water and Sanitation Benchmarking Database—Summary Statistics 141 B.5 ITU Database—Summary Statistics (for LAC) 142 B.6 Contract and Regulatory Variables 143 D.1 Means and Medians Analysis in Levels—Electricity Distribution 184 Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 x Contents D.2 Means and Medians Analysis in Growth—Electricity Distribution 187 D.3 Econometric Analysis—Electricity Distribution 190 D.4 Means and Medians Analysis in Levels—Fixed Telecommunications 191 D.5 Means and Medians Analysis in Growth—Fixed Telecommunications 195 D.6 Econometric Analysis—Fixed Telecommunications 199 D.7 Econometric Analysis—Fixed Telecommunications, Liberalization 200 D.8 Econometric Analysis—Fixed Telecommunications, Mobile Competition 202 D.9 Econometric Analysis—Fixed Telecommunications, Instrumental Variables 204 D.10 Means and Medians Analysis in Levels—Water and Sewerage 205 D.11 Means and Medians Analysis in Growth—Water and Sewerage 208 D.12 Econometric Analysis—Water Distribution and Sewerage 211 F.1 Regulatory Governance and Performance—Existence of Regulatory Agency 228 F.2 Regulatory Governance and Performance—Existence of Regulatory Agency with Interactions 229 F.3 Regulatory Governance and Performance—Duration of the Regulatory Agency 230 F.4 Regulatory Governance and Performance—Regulatory Governance Index 231 F.5 Regulatory Governance and Performance—Principal Component Analysis 232 G.1 Correlation between Corporate Governance Indexes and Performance—Water and Electricity Distribution Sectors (in Levels) 233 G.2 Correlation between Corporate Governance Indexes and Performance—Water and Electricity Distribution Sectors (in Growth Rates) 233 G.3 Correlation between Corporate Governance Indexes and Performance—Electricity Distribution Sector (in Levels) 234 G.4 Correlation between Corporate Governance Indexes and Performance—Electricity Distribution Sector (in Growth Rates) 234 G.5 Correlation between Corporate Governance Indexes and Performance—Water Sector (in Levels) 235 G.6 Correlation between Corporate Governance Indexes and Performance—Water Sector (in Growth Rates) 236 G.7 Principal Component Analysis—Eigenvalues of Factors 237 G.8 Principal Component Analysis—Factor Loadings of Indexes after Varimax Rotation 237 Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Acknowledgments Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance: Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean on the Role of the Private Sector, Regulation, and Governance in the Power, Water, and Telecommunication Sectors is the product of a team effort by the Economics Unit of the Sustainable Development Department in the Latin America and the Caribbean Region of the World Bank, co-led by Luis A. Andrés, Jordan Schwartz, and J. Luis Guasch. The team gratefully acknowledges the sup- port of Diana Cubas, Barbara Cunha, Jose Guillermo Diaz, Georgeta Dragoiu, Raquel Fernandez, Julio Gonzalez, Alejandro Guerrero, and Maria Claudia Pachon. They also thank Sebastian Lopez Azumendi, who coauthored the back- ground papers to chapters 4 and 5. The team received valuable feedback through a rich consultation and peer review process. It received ongoing support and technical inputs from the regional chief economist, Augusto de la Torre, and his team, including Tito Cordella, Pablo Fajnzylber, and William Maloney. The team also gratefully acknowledges early inputs from the Sustainable Development Department team of Latin America and the Caribbean (LCSSD), which contributed ideas and sug- gestions at several meetings and workshops, through comments on earlier ver- sions of the chapters, and at a seminar on the main findings and messages of the report. The team appreciated early inputs from Daniel Benitez, Philippe Benoit, Susan Bogach, Juan Miguel Cayo, Makhtar Diop, Joshua Gallo, Manuel Mariño, Martin Rossi, Tomas Serebrisky, Tova Solo, Maria Angelica Sotomayor, and Carlos Velez. Insightful and constructive comments were also received from peer reviewers, Marianne Fay, Antonio Estache, Maximo Torero, and Maria Vagliasindi. For their generous financial support, the team is grateful to the Latin America and the Caribbean Chief Economist Office for the overall preparation of this report, to the Energy Sector Management Assistance Program (ESMAP) for funding the collection of the performance data in the electricity distribution ­ sector, to the Public-Private Infrastructure Advisory Facility (PPIAF) for its support of the background material for chapter 3, and to the U.K. Department ­ for International Development (DFID) for its support of the background material on corporate governance of state-owned enterprises. ­ Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   xi   About the Authors Luis A. Andrés is Lead Economist in the Sustainable Development Department for the South Asia Region of the World Bank. His work involves both analytical and advisory services and economic inputs, with a focus on infrastructure (mainly in the water and energy sectors), impact evaluations, private sector participation, regulation, and empirical microeconomics. Before joining the World Bank, he was the Chief of Staff for the Secretary of Fiscal and Social Equity and held other top positions in the Chief of the Cabinet of Ministries and the Ministry of Economy for the Government of Argentina. He holds a Ph.D. in Economics from the University of Chicago and has authored more than 30 publications on develop- ment policy issues. Jordan Schwartz is the World Bank’s Manager for Infrastructure Policy. He has worked in the field of infrastructure and economic development for over 20 years, focusing on investment design and strategies, PPPs, logistics, regulation, and regional integration. At the World Bank, Jordan has led analytical work and operations covering every sector of infrastructure. Before joining the World Bank in 1998, Jordan worked in management consulting, first in Booz Allen Hamilton’s Transport Strategy Consulting Group, and later, as the Senior Manager for Utility and Infrastructure Consulting at Deloitte Emerging Markets. J. Luis Guasch is the former Senior Regional Advisor in the Latin America and Caribbean Region in the World Bank, responsible for regulation, competitiveness, infrastructure and public-private partnerships (PPPs), innovation and technology issues, and investment climate. He was the Head of the World Bank Global Expert Team on PPP. He has also been a Professor of Economics at the University of California, San Diego, since 1980. He has assisted and advised governments in more than 50 countries on a variety of issues, among them competitiveness and infrastructure and PPPs. He holds a Ph.D. in Economics from Stanford University and an Industrial Engineering degree from the Polytechnic University of Barcelona. He has written extensively in leading economic and finance journals, and has written several books. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   xiii   Abbreviations GDP gross domestic product GWh gigawatt hours IRA independent regulatory agency IRGI Infrastructure Regulatory Governance Index ITU International Telecommunication Union kWh kilowatt hours LAC Latin America and the Caribbean Region MDG Millennium Development Goals MWh megawatt hours OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development PCA principal component approach PPP Public-Private Partnership SOE state-owned enterprise Twh terawatt hours UNICEF United Nations Children’s Fund WHO World Health Organization All dollar amounts are U.S. dollars unless otherwise indicated. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   xv   Overview For the past three decades, infrastructure economics has been preoccupied with answering the question “How?” When it appeared as if public ownership of utilities was the sole cause of massive utility debt and poor service throughout ­ the developing world, economists were rolled out to figure out how to privatize state-owned enterprises (SOEs). When the capture of utility operators became a concern, the question evolved into “How should public services be regulated?” And when, in recent years, the public’s patience with private operators began to wear thin, the questions became “How do we rebalance risks? How do we best design public-private partnerships (PPPs)? How do we take account of the rise in populism, the volatility in financial markets, and the flight of capital to safety?” The primary purpose of this study is to step back from the question of “how” and to answer the underlying question of “why.” Why do some utilities perform well and others perform poorly? This book provides insight into infrastructure sector performance by focusing on the links between key indicators for private and public utilities and changes in ownership, regulatory agency governance, and corporate governance, among other dimensions. By linking inputs and outputs over a 15-year period of reform, the analysis uncovers key determinants that have affected sector performance in infrastructure sectors in the region. The book explains why the effects of such variables result in significant changes in the performance of infrastructure service provision. Lack of adequate infrastructure is hampering the region’s ability to grow, compete, and reduce poverty (Fay and Morrison 2006). This book proposes a framework of analysis that addresses key elements in the design of mechanisms that can reduce the region’s infrastructure gap. The book focuses on the distribution segment of three types of basic infrastructure services: electricity, water and sanitation, and fixed telecommu- ­ nications. It uses original data on the performance of utility companies, includ- ing data on private providers and survey data from regulatory agencies and SOEs throughout the region.1 The databases are rich not only in the number Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   1   2 Overview and types of utilities surveyed but also in the diversity and ­ comprehensiveness of the indicators collected (for electricity and water alone, more than 20 indi- cators for each sector were collected). The analysis shows how performance ­ indicators—on output, coverage, labor productivity, inputs, operating perfor- mance, service quality, and prices—have shaped the three sectors over the past decade. Until now, data constraints have forced researchers to use small samples of companies, small samples of countries, and limited indicators. By collecting infor- mation from more than 250 electricity distribution companies and more than 1,700 water and sanitation companies, this study analyzes sector performance more comprehensively. It focuses on the relationship between s ­ector perfor- mance and ownership structure, regulatory agencies, and corporate governance. It tackles sensitive relationships and issues—such as the role of the private ­ sector—without the bias of case studies or the margins of error of partial datasets. It also provides enough observations to consider the effects of related elements, such as contract design and market structure. The methodology identifies the determinants of sector performance. It facili- tates the analysis of trends over time as well as a comparison of features common to all three sectors. This book does not describe all possible factors and conditions that may affect performance. It does not, for example, focus on the external environment or analyze factors that cannot be standardized. It does do the following: • analyzes sector performance against a broad set of indicators that describe the current situation as well its evolution over the past 15 years developed • proposes an analytical framework for issues that have not been well ­ in the literature on infrastructure economics, such as regulatory governance and corporate governance for SOEs • benchmarks the institutional designs of regulatory agencies in the water and electricity sectors • analyzes the relationship between sector performance and regulation, private sector participation, and corporate governance. The book’s main messages can be summarized as follows: 1. Even in regions such as Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC), where reform has led to sector performance improvements in electricity d ­ istribution, water and sanitation, and fixed telecommunications, there is still much room for improvement. 2. Both the government (as regulator and service provider) and the private ­ sector (as service provider) can play active roles in enhancing sector perfor- mance. The analysis reveals three important corollaries to this finding: • When carefully designed and implemented, private sector participation in service provision has a positive effect on sector performance. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Overview 3 • When independent regulatory agencies (IRAs) are transparent, account- able, and free of political interference, they contribute positively to sector performance. • A strong accountability mechanism that prevents discriminatory manage- ment is fundamental for improving SOE performance. 3. One size does not fit all. Improving performance requires a comprehensive approach that integrates a variety of mechanisms to address different aspects of sector performance. Message 1: Even in regions such as LAC, where reform has led to sector performance improvements in electricity distribution, water and sanitation, and fixed telecommunications, there is still much room for improvement Between 1990 and 2005, the LAC region witnessed significant improvements in coverage, service quality, and labor productivity in all three sectors. Coverage ­ increased to 95 percent for electricity distribution, 97 percent for the water utili- ties within the sample,2 and 62 percent for fixed telecommunications. For house- holds with access to these services, regional coverage reached about 92 percent in electricity, 80 percent in water, and 62 percent in fixed telecommunications. A similar pattern of improvement is evident for labor productivity. For electricity distribution, labor productivity doubled between 1995 and 2006. ­ For water, labor productivity almost doubled, rising from 252 to 425 connections per employee. In the telecommunications sector, labor productivity increased by a factor of seven between 1995 and 2007. Quality of service also improved. For electricity distribution, the frequency of interruptions fell 42 percent and the duration of interruptions fell 40 percent. The water sector experienced an 8 percent increase in the continuity of service during this period. The telecommunications sector saw a gradual but significant increase in the percentage of digital main lines and the number of telephone faults cleared by the next working day. The share of main lines that are digital increased from 63 percent in 1995 to 100 percent in 2007. The number of tele- phone faults per 100 main fixed lines a year dropped from 23 in 1995 to 8 by the end of 2007. Such improvements in quality have been accompanied by a reduction in the waiting list for main fixed lines, which averaged zero by 2007. The region hosts a wide range of strong and weak performers. In water and sanitation, the top 10 percent of utilities average 100 percent water and sanita- tion coverage. In contrast, the bottom 10 percent of water utilities average 66 ­percent coverage, and the worst sewerage utilities average just 15 percent coverage. In electricity distribution, utilities in the top 10 percentile were 10 times more productive than and sold 6 times as much energy (per ­ connection) as utilities in the bottom 10 percent in 2005. On average, private utilities outperform public utilities—although there are good public and private utilities and underperforming private and public utilities. For several indicators, the top 10 percent of public utilities performed better than Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 4 Overview the average private utilities; for other indicators, the bottom 10 percent of private utilities performed worse than the average public utility. The benchmarking exercise and data allow utilities to target improvements toward areas in which they lag most. Even top performers can improve their performance by analyzing selected indicators. LAC is performing well relative to other developing regions. In 2007, the weighted average for phone penetration (mobile and fixed-line telephone sub- scribers) was 85 percent in LAC, 71 percent for the world as a whole, 64 percent for middle-income countries, and 67 percent in East Asia and Pacific (authors’ calculations using data from the International Telecommunication Union dataset). In 2004, household water coverage was 80 percent in LAC, 70 percent ­ in East Asia and Pacific, 54 percent for the world as a whole, 26 percent in Africa, and 20 percent in South Asia (authors’ calculations using data from JMP). These achievements notwithstanding, millions of people in LAC still lack access to basic services. Although electricity coverage increased from 85 in 1996 to 95 percent in 2005 in the sample studied, many people, almost all of them poor and in rural areas, still lack electricity.3 Twenty-nine million households do not have a water connection. These figures indicate the importance of expanding electrification and water and sanitation services in rural areas in LAC, which lag urban areas. Differences in the performance of utilities raise a number of questions about its determinants. Has private sector participation in service provision changed the dynamics of the sector? Does the type of regulation—and in particular the way it is governed—affect utility performance? Do corporate governance frameworks that provide SOEs and private providers with similar incentives improve perfor- mance? Previous research yields few answers to these important questions. The analysis presented in this book shows that differences in ownership, regulatory governance, and corporate governance of SOEs explain some of the dispersion in utilities’ performance. Message 2: Both the government (as regulator and service provider) and the private sector (as service provider) can play active roles in improving sector performance • When carefully designed and implemented, private sector participation in service provision improves sector performance. This book presents a comprehensive and systemic assessment of the impact of private sector participation in LAC. It considers what happened before, during, and after the change in ownership in the electricity, water and sanitation, and telecommunications sectors because often the most dramatic effects of private sector participation are found in the transition period, when the enterprise is overhauled as part of the transaction process. Private sector participation has had a significantly positive effect on labor productivity, efficiency, and the quality of the service. In telecommunications, it Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Overview 5 has also increased output and coverage. After controlling for firm-specific time trends, there do not appear to be significant impacts on output and coverage. Although the picture is highly variable across sectors, prices tended to increase slightly. For electricity, labor productivity in private utilities is twice that of pub- lic utilities. Distribution losses declined 12 ­ percent in private utilities over the period studied, while public utilities saw their performance deteriorate by 5 ­percent. Annual service interruptions fell from 24 to 12 compared for private utilities and from 24 to 19 for public utilities. The average duration of outages also fell by more at private utilities. Examination of private sector participation contracts and process variables reveals how various design variables affect performance. Depending on a country’s priorities, certain contract characteristics may be more important than ­ others. One element of a contract, for example, could positively affect one variable while having a negative or insignificant impact on another. ­ • When independent regulatory agencies (IRAs) are transparent, accountable, and free of political interference, they contribute positively to sector performance. The existence of a regulatory agency has significant impact on sector perfor- mance, raising labor productivity, residential tariffs, and the cost-recovery ratio and reducing operational expenses and distribution losses. Different elements of the regulatory governance design affect performance indicators differently. Changes to the formal component or regulatory governance increase labor frequency of interruptions, and raise residential ­ productivity, reduce the ­ tariffs. Increases in formal autonomy and flexibility with respect to tariff setting are associated with higher labor productivity and shorter service interruptions. IRAs that promote transparency, ­ autonomy, independence, and accountability thus improve sector performance. • A strong accountability mechanism that prevents discriminatory management is fundamental for improving the performance of SOEs. Corporate governance arrangements in SOEs in water and electricity vary widely. Private enterprises tend to adopt standard corporate strategies. Standards at SOEs depend on countries’ institutional systems and the characteristics of the service. Performance at SOEs is directly and indirectly related to overall gover- nance within the country or province. A best practice corporate governance design for SOEs with a corporatized framework includes an independent performance-driven board of directors, a professional staff, transparency and clear disclosure policies, and a clear mechanism for evaluating performance. A corporate structure that prevents ­ political intervention, rewards performance, and is subject to public scrutiny serves as a benchmark for design comparison. State enterprises face conflicting goals that affect the establishment of a business strategy. Several departments usually compete to have their agenda ­ Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 6 Overview ­rioritized, often at the expense of service. Interference in the companies’ p business is often done informally, making it difficult for management to ­ ­ identify ways to improve efficiency. Because government subsidies can replace low revenues, efforts to increase efficiency are often muted. Poor ­ ­ accountability systems (at the regulatory or management levels) prevent development of an ­ ownership structure that triggers efficient behavior by senior management. In utilities with high levels of corruption and inefficiency, accountability systems should be created that prevent discretional management (from both ­ ­management and political authorities) and create incentives for good ­performance. Regulation and performance-based management can be considered complementary ways of achieving these goals. A system of checks and balances, ­ such as parliamentary oversight and state auditing, should be built into the ­governance design. Good corporate governance is associated with high levels of performance. Performance orientation and professional management seem to be the most important contributors to performance, although all of the factors cited above are associated with some performance indicators. Message 3: Improving sector performance requires a holistic approach that is tailored to specific circumstances The analysis in this book is based on a number of key dimensions; however, there are certainly other elements that can influence and explain sector per- formance. While the purpose of this book is to focus on particular utility level variables as determinants of sector performance, the book briefly sum- marizes a number of additional factors and the interaction of some of these factors, as they may impact sector performance. Researchers have modeled and empirically tested the influence of such issues as corruption, market structure, economies of scope and density, renegotiation, and ­ reputation. Other factors—such as subsidy mechanisms, lack of cost recovery, the politi- cal economy of ­ different sectors, and social accountability—also affect sector performance. Although these issues are widely discussed, few ­ econometric studies have been conducted; most analyses rely on comprehensive analytical case studies. By proposing a new framework of analysis and building a comprehensive data set, this book builds a foundation for innovative research that can explain links and variables for which theoretical models and case-based evidence but little empirical analysis exists. By identifying differences in performance among utilities, decision makers and utility managers can find ways to improve service ­ provision. The heterogeneity across utilities warrants a holistic approach to solving shortcomings in performance. Improving sector performance demands that key ­ determinants—such as ownership structure, regulatory governance and corpo- rate governance—be addressed strategically, not in isolation. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Overview 7 Moving Forward Improving sector performance goes beyond conducting a comprehensive assess- ment of a key determinant and proposing specific designs; it entails an approach that integrates policies that address a wide range of issues, some of which are discussed in detail in this book. The region can afford universal coverage of water, sanitation, and electricity if appropriate technologies and standards are used. Scarce resources imply that investments need to focus on bottlenecks in existing systems rather than overall expansion (Fay and Morrison 2006). Understanding differences in service providers and the environments in which they operate can help policy makers design comprehensive solutions to complex problems in infrastructure service provision. Policy makers considering sector reforms should first prioritize their perfor- mance objectives, in order to determine which solutions seem most appropriate. For instance, if a utility prioritizes quality and efficiency over retention of employees, private sector participation is likely to be an attractive option. If reducing distributional losses by an SOE is a key objective, governance changes in favor of corporate performance-oriented rules could be considered. The results presented in this book highlight pitfalls in sector reform programs. Poor design and faulty implementation explain many of the shortcomings of reform. Identifying the potential for problems in advance can help policy makers design countermeasures. This book can help policy makers make informed decisions and craft well-designed change strategies for achieving technical and ­ political objectives. Policy makers need to heed lessons from the past. Concession laws and con- tracts should focus on securing long-term sector efficiency, assigning and mitigating risk, and discouraging opportunistic bidding and renegotiation. They ­ should be embedded in regulations that foster transparency and predictability, support incentives for efficient behavior, impede opportunistic renegotiation, and force contract compliance; address social concerns and focus on poverty; and promote accountability. Governments remain at the heart of infrastructure service delivery; even in the presence of private sector participation, public involvement is necessary. SOEs that have a corporate governance structure that reduces political interfer- ence, rewards performance, and opens decisions to public scrutiny perform better than SOEs whose structure allows politics to influence decision making. Governments need to regulate infrastructure provision, contribute a substantial share of the investment, leverage their resources to attract complementary financing, set distributional objectives, and ensure that resources and policies increase access for the poor. To make reforms sustainable, policy makers need to address not only the ­ technical and financial aspects but also the social aspects most responsible for backlash. To do so, they need to support people in need who are adversely ­ affected by reform (through lay-offs and higher tariffs) and improve communica- tion. It is essential to publicize initiatives, promote program improvements, Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 8 Overview explain the (unsustainable) impact of maintaining the status quo, and make the case for cost-benefit tradeoffs represented by reforms. The communication ­ strategy must not only justify programs but also periodically inform on progress, changes, or problems. Reforms must not only be successful, their success must be communicated, in order to safeguard against corruption and build and maintain popular support. Notes 1. The exceptions are the databases for telecommunications and contract design (Guasch 2004). 2. The database includes 59 percent of the water connections in LAC. 3. These regional estimates correspond to the weighted average across the 250 utilities in the sample, which represent 89 percent of the total number of electricity connections. References Fay, M., and M. Morrison. 2006. Infrastructure in Latin America and the Caribbean: Recent Developments and Key Challenges. Washington, DC: World Bank. Guasch, J. L. 2004. Granting and Renegotiating Infrastructure Concessions. Doing it Right. Washington, DC: World Bank. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Chapter 1 Introduction This book conducts a micro-level analysis of various determinants of ­infrastructure sector performance that affect development. Analyzing infrastructure sector performance is about measuring, understanding, and improving conditions at the micro level in order to understand how utilities, and regulatory agents, contribute to the broader development agenda. Ultimately, sector performance is about the delivery of efficient, affordable, and sustainable infrastructure services. By correlating inputs and outcomes over the past 15 years, this book aims to ­ understand the various determinants of sector performance in infrastructure sectors in Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC). It is about understanding ­ how, and to what extent, several potential factors (including private sector participation, ­ ­ regulation, corporate governance) have resulted in significant changes in the performance of infrastructure services. A large body of empirical literature shows that infrastructure development promotes economic growth and poverty reduction. By facilitating access to basic services for the poor, infrastructure fosters development along all levels of the results chain. Different players are involved at each level of sector performance: consumers, communities, service providers, regulators, investors, governments, and nongovernmental organizations. A holistic understanding of infrastructure sector performance creates and strengthens a positive dynamic among key stakeholders. During the 1990s, most LAC countries implemented substantial reforms in the infrastructure sector to increase private sector participation and economic regulation and, when possible, promote competition as the main instruments for improving the quality, accessibility, and efficiency of services. Although some reforms successfully achieved these objectives, overall the reforms encountered difficulties, and most countries in the region now face new challenges. By the late 1990s and early 2000s, the region faced a series of financial and economic crises, corporate scandals, and market failures, within LAC and around the world. These challenges led to a significant decline in the rate of private investment, an increase in political opposition, and some dissatisfaction with privatization and liberalization policies. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   9   10 Introduction LAC’s infrastructure history, including the sectors in which LAC has ­ erformed relatively well, leaves no room for complacency: 112 million people p in the region lack access to household water connections, and 47 million have no access to electricity (World Bank 2010). Although time trends point to improved coverage and performance in LAC, they also shed light on the gap in i ­ nfrastructure services for many people. LAC increased coverage of piped potable water in premises from 73 percent of the population in 1990 to 86 percent in 2010 (WHO–UNICEF 2008). However, there are significant differences across ­ countries. Similarly, although electricity coverage in the region as a whole increased from 82 percent in 1990 to 92 percent by 2007, many households, most of them rural, have been left behind. An integral component of the findings presented in this book is the data collected for each chapter. The conclusions of the research are based entirely on these data. The wealth of information produced also lends itself to further analysis. The data are available upon request ­ for repurposing, allowing readers to pose ad hoc queries and regression analyses. The benchmarking efforts provide a regional and utility-level frame of reference for strong and weak sector performance in LAC. Understanding the various interventions and conditions that explain sector performance is indispensable to reducing the region’s infrastructure gap. To do so, the analysis draws on six sources of data (all except the ITU/ICT database are World Bank databases): • The LAC Electricity Distribution Database contains detailed annual informa- tion on 250 public and private utilities in 26 countries that cover 89 percent of the connections in the region.1 It contains data on more than 20 variables, on output, input, operating performance, quality and customer s ­ ervices, and prices. Data as early as 1990 are available, but the focus is 1995–2005. • The LAC Water and Sanitation Database contains detailed annual ­information on more than 1,700 public and private utilities in 16 countries that cover 59 percent of the water connections in the region.2 Like the Electricity Distribution Database, it contains data on more than 20 ­variables, on output, input, operating performance, quality and customer services, and prices. Data as early as 1990 are available, but the focus is 1995–2008. • The ITU World Telecommunication/ICT Indicators Database contains annual time series for 1975–2007 for about 100 telecommunication statistics, covering telephone network size and dimension, mobile services, quality of service, traffic, staff, tariffs, revenue, and investment.3 • The Comprehensive Database on Impact of Private Sector Participation in LAC covers what happened before, during, and after private sector ­ participation in three sectors—electricity distribution, water and sewerage, and ­telecommunications—by focusing on a range of performance variables (Andrés and others 2008). Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Introduction 11 • Additional data explore the governance of independent regulatory agencies (IRAs) in the water and electricity distribution sectors of LAC and the link between the governance of IRAs and the performance of both sectors (Andrés and others 2007). • Data on corporate governance of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) were collected through surveys sent to utilities in the region in the electricity ­ distribution and water sectors. These data cover 45 SOEs, including both ­ public companies with full state ownership and companies in which the state ­ category) owns at least 51 percent of all shares (only a few utilities fell into this ­ (Andrés, Guasch, and Azumendi 2011). This book focuses on the distribution segment of three basic infrastructure services: electricity, water and sanitation, and fixed telecommunications. Some of the features are s ­ imilar across sectors, allowing lessons to be drawn through comparison. 4 This books aims to answer four main sets of questions: • What are the main performance trends in the region, and how heterogeneous are they? • How does the performance of state-owned and private utilities differ? What correlations can be made between performance and regulation and between ­ performance and specific characteristics of market reforms (such as the introduction of wholesale markets and third-party access)? What impact did ­ private sector participation have on performance? Does regulatory quality ­ matter? Does competition (when possible) matter? What can be done to increase the efficiency of SOEs? What are the conditions for success? Are firms recovering costs? • How does the institutional design of regulatory agencies affect sector performance? To what extent does regulatory quality matter? Does regulation have any effect on sector performance? Is the independent regulatory agency model still valid for the region? Are there better alternatives? Who are the leaders in the region? Are procedures aimed at improving the governance of regulatory agencies being implemented? • What management mechanisms create incentives for improved performance? What have boards and managers of the most competitive and efficient u ­ tilities done to improve their governance? What have the governments that own utilities done? Why have they focused on corporate governance? What are the main legal difficulties and other obstacles they face in this work? How important is it to enjoy a good reputation and solid social support in carrying out governance reforms? Under what circumstances does social support make reform easier? How does operating in regions facing challenging social problems affect the chances of introducing reforms? What are the main ­ lessons so far? Are there any differences across sectors? ­ Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 12 Introduction Analytical Framework and Scope This book begins by describing the main elements that characterize sector performance, defined as the delivery of reliable, affordable service that complies ­ with certain quality standards. (Although any number of variables can be used to define performance, the set of indicators analyzed provides an overall assessment of the utilities; a different selection of indicators would not significantly change the key messages of this analysis.) It also analyzes some intermediate outcomes. For instance, distributional losses and labor productivity, as a proxy of efficiency, may be highly correlated with the quality of the service provided. Figure 1.1 depicts the framework of this analysis. Access to reliable infrastructure in the region as a whole improved signifi- cantly since the 1990s. However, the results are far from homogeneous at the utility level. This book aims to understand the drivers of these differences. It analyzes the effects of changes in policies on changes in performance. It focuses on the relationship between sector performance and the following determinants: private sector participation, regulatory agencies, and corporate governance. It also examines related aspects, such as contract design, market structure, and, for tele- communications, market competition. This book argues that these determinants significantly changed the landscape of the sectors studied. Other elements that are not examined may also affect sector performance (figure 1.2 depicts some of them). Even when exploring the specified determinants of sector performance, the book does not describe all pos- sible links or spheres of influence between each variable and sector performance. Figure 1.2 displays different environments of impact. This book first explains the dynamics of utility performance and the interac- tions between key internal variables and utility performance in each sector. Although it may refer to the components and impact of the external ­environment, Figure 1.1  Analytical Framework for Analyzing Sector Performance governance Regulatory e pr ne nc ter w na Co en p (w ise d en te-o ver mp os h sta go s eti sibl of rate tio e) n o rp Co Sector Other (macroeconomic Private sector performance environment, participation initial conditions) Quality and reliability of service Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Introduction 13 Figure 1.2 Internal, Sectoral, and External Conditions Affecting Utility Performance Macroec NT onomy N ME IRO Geo ENV gra RN AL phy EXTE SECTORAL Ot UTILITY tion he ENVIRONMENT ENVIRONMENT r is orrup su • Regulation • Ownership es c • Contracts’ design • Corporate Grand • Market structure governance • Other • Other it does not explain these elements, as they relate to sector performance. The impact of factors such as sovereign risk ratings, corruption, or consumer propen- sity to pay bills is external to sector and utility control and thus external to this analysis. The main objective of this analysis is to provide a factual ­ description of changes and policies that can be empirically tested and analyzed ­ “internally” by people with decision-making authority over sector policy, ­ regulation, governance, and investment. This book does the following: • depicts sector performance with a broad set of indicators that describe the current situation as well its evolution over the past 15 years • provides analytical frameworks for themes less developed in the broader ­ literature on utilities, such as regulatory governance and corporate governance for SOEs • benchmarks the institutional designs of regulatory agencies in the LAC region for the water and electricity distribution sectors • analyzes the relationship between sector performance and regulation, private sector participation, and corporate governance. The book is organized as follows. Chapter 2 outlines changes in the electricity distribution, water and sanitation, and fixed telecommunications sectors in the LAC region over the past 15 years. These changes are captured through bench- marking assessments based on the results of performance indicators such as output, coverage, labor productivity, inputs, operating performance, service quality, and prices. This chapter tells multiple stories of the substantial improve- ­ ment in these sectors and fills in knowledge gaps by benchmarking utility ­ performance at the regional, country, and utility levels. Chapter 3 synthesizes the impact private sector participation has had on electricity distribution, water and sewerage, and fixed-line telecommunications. ­ Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 14 Introduction In an attempt to understand the true impacts and determinants of private sector participation, it examines what happened before, during, and after private sector participation in LAC in these sectors by focusing on a range of performance variables. It then examines scenarios with and without private sector participa- tion. This chapter also identifies whether private sector participation characteris- tics such as the sale method (for example, auction); investor nationality; and award criterion affect performance. Chapter 4 explores the institutional design of regulatory agencies and the link between regulatory governance and sector performance. The first part of the chapter evaluates and benchmarks the governance of regulatory agencies in the electricity sector. It draws heavily on an index of regulatory governance that ranks all agencies in LAC. The index is an aggregate of four key governance characteristics: autonomy, transparency, accountability, and regulatory tools, ­ including not only formal aspects of regulation but also indicators related to actual implementation. The second part of the chapter builds on the benchmark- ing analysis. It examines whether there is a correlation between regulatory gov- ernance and sector performance. Chapter 5 assesses the governance of SOEs in infrastructure, based on survey results from 45 SOEs in the water and electricity distribution sector of LAC. It proposes an analytical framework for analyzing corporate governance of these utilities and benchmarks their institutional internal design. The chapter also evaluates the contribution of these dimensions to sector performance. Chapters 6 examines other potential determinants for sector performance, including corruption, cost recovery, contract arrangements, and competition. Chapter 7 summarizes the book’s main results and describes the array of possi- bilities for moving forward. Notes These data are publicly available. The complete database can be accessed at 1. http://info.worldbank.org/etools/lacelectricity/home.htm. 2. This database will be publicly available shortly. These data are publicly available. The complete database can be accessed at 3. http://www.itu.int/ITU-D/ict/publications/world/world.html. 4. Good data exist on the electricity distribution and telecommunications sectors. Better data are needed on water in order to compare this sector with the other two. References Andrés, L., J.L. Guasch, and S.L. Azumendi. 2011. “Governance in State-Owned Enterprises Revisited: The Cases of Water and Electricity in Latin America and the Caribbean.” Policy Research Working Paper, World Bank, Washington, DC. Andrés, L., J.L. Guasch, M. Diop, and S.L. Azumendi. 2007. “Assessing the Governance of Electricity Regulatory Agencies in the Latin American and the Caribbean Region: Benchmarking Analysis.” Policy Research Working Paper 4380, World Bank, Washington, DC. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Introduction 15 Andrés, L., J.L. Guasch, T. Haven, and V. Foster. 2008. The Impact of Private Sector Participation in Infrastructure: Lights, Shadows, and the Road Ahead. Washington, DC: World Bank. WHO (World Health Organization)–UNICEF (United Nations Children’s Fund). 2008. Joint Monitoring Programme (JMP) for Water Supply and Sanitation Database. http://www.wssinfo.org/data-estimates/table/. World Bank. 2010. “Understanding Sector Performance: The Case of Utilities in Latin America and the Caribbean.” Regional study under the Chief Economist Office for the LAC region. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Chapter 2 Benchmarking Utility Performance This chapter outlines the changes that have occurred in the electricity distribution, water and sanitation, and fixed telecommunications sectors during ­ the main period of utility reform (1995 to 2006) in Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC). The first part analyzes changes that have shaped the perfor- mance of these sectors. This analysis is derived from previous benchmarking ini- tiatives for the electricity distribution sector (Andrés, Diop, and Guasch 2008) as well as databases for the water sector (World Bank 2012) and the telecommuni- cations sector (ITU 2009). The chapter documents these changes and accounts for current performance of the sectors at the regional and utility levels. The findings were captured through benchmarking assessments based on the following performance indicators: output, coverage, labor productivity, inputs, operating performance, service quality, and prices. Considering the changes that have shaped the sectors during the past decade, such benchmarking efforts pro- vide a regional and utility-level frame of reference for strong and weak sector performance in LAC. There is a sharp divide between rural and urban coverage within countries. For water, electricity, roads, and telecommunications, coverage rates in rural areas tend to be much lower than average. Although more than 90 percent of the urban population of most countries in the region has access to safe water, rural access in Brazil (58 percent) and Chile (59 percent) is lower than in several much poorer African countries, such as Burundi (78 percent) and Zimbabwe (74 percent) (Fay and Morrison 2006). Given that poverty rates are usually much higher in the countryside, lower rural access rates explain much, though by no means all, of the great disparity in coverage between rich and poor in the region. Although this chapter does not make a distinction between urban and rural electricity and water and sanitation, it acknowledges rural-urban differences and intends to provoke further work in order to bridge this gap. Why Benchmark Infrastructure Sectors? Benchmarking is a means of providing countries and utilities with a point of refer- ence regarding their performance. Electricity lights homes and powers industries, Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   17   18 Benchmarking Utility Performance but in many developing countries, service quality remains unreliable—even for people who can afford to pay high prices. Expanding service to people in the region who live without basic infrastructure and improving the quality and reli- ability of service delivery are urgent socioeconomic priorities. The lack of good infrastructure services also costs businesses dearly. Against this backdrop, the benchmarking initiatives outlined in this chapter provide regional and utility-level direction and a framework for identifying where LAC utilities stand in relation to others, detecting their strengths and weaknesses, and setting goals for improvement. A number of empirical studies have used benchmarking methods within the electricity supply industry. These studies have traditionally focused on generation or vertically integrated utilities. Perhaps because of regulators’ demand, interest in benchmarking the natural monopoly segments (transmission and distribution) has recently increased. Surveys of the benchmarking literature (Jamasb and others 2005) conclude that because of problems of data standardization and cur- ­ rency conversion, international benchmarking has not been widely used. When international efficiency comparisons have been used, they have traditionally focused on developed countries. This chapter describes sectoral performance at the regional and utility levels. It does not assume an analytical or explanatory role. The intent is to contribute to a more consistent benchmarking analysis in the distribution segments and serve as a pathbreaker for other regional benchmarking initiatives. The benchmarking exercise covers the following databases (see appendix C for details): • The LAC Electricity Distribution Database contains detailed annual informa- tion on 250 public and private utilities in 26 countries that cover 89 percent of the connections in the region.1 It contains data on more than 20 variables, on output, input, operating performance, quality and customer ­ services, and prices. Data as early as 1990 are available, but the focus is 1995–2005. • The LAC Water and Sanitation Database contains detailed annual informa- tion on more than 1,700 public and private utilities in 16 countries that cover 59 percent of the water connections in the region.2 Like the Electricity Distribution Database, it contains data on more than 20 variables, on output, input, operating performance, quality and customer services, and prices. Data as early as 1990 are available, but the focus is 1995–2006. • The ITU World Telecommunication/ICT Indicators Database contains annual time series for 1975–2007 for about 100 telecommunication statistics, covering telephone network size and dimension, mobile services, quality of ­ service, traffic, staff, tariffs, revenue, and investment.3 Table 2.1 defines the variables used in the analysis. The following sections describe the benchmarking analyses for the three sectors evaluated. For simplicity, we present in this chapter the summary of the ­ results. The results for each of the indicators can be found in appendix C. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Utility Performance 19 Table 2.1 Variable Definitions, by Sector Variable Electricity distribution Water distribution Fixed telecommunications Output • Total number of subscribers • Total number of water subscribers • Total number of active and residential subscribers, as and residential water subscribers connections, as of December of each year • Total number of residential of December of each • Total energy sold annually (MWh) water subscribers and residential year • Energy sold per sewerage subscribers • Total number of local connection (MWh) • Total water production per year minutes annually (millions of cubic meters) • Total minutes per active • Total water sold per year (millions connection of cubic meters) Labor • Number of employees • Number of employees • Number of employees Labor • Number of subscribers per • Number of water connections per • Number of active productivity employee employee connections per • Total energy sold annually per • Water sold per employee employee employee • Local minutes per employee Efficiency • Energy lost in distribution • Percentage of total water • Percentage of (because of technical losses and produced that was not charged to incomplete calls illegal connections) the consumers Quality • Average duration of interruptions • Average number of hours with • Percentage of per consumer (hours/year) water service per day incomplete calls (faults) • Average frequency • Percentage of samples that • Percentage of digital of interruptions per consumer passed a potability test connections in the (number/year) network Coverage • Number of residential subscribers • Number of residential water • Number of active per 100 households subscribers per 100 households connections per • Number of residential sewerage 100 inhabitants subscribers per 100 households Prices • Average tariff (including fixed • Average price per cubic meter • Average cost for a three- and variable costs) for 1 MWh for of supplied water (dollars) minute, nonpeak local residential service in December • Average price per cubic meter call (dollars) of each year (dollars) of collected waste (dollars) • Average monthly cost • Average tariff (including fixed for residential service and variable costs) for 1 MWh for (dollars) industrial service in December of each year (dollars) Expenses • Annual operational expenses per • Annual operational expenses per connection (dollars) water connection (dollars) • Annual operational expenses per • Annual operational expenses per MWh sold (dollars) cubic meter sold (dollars) Electricity Distribution4 Since the late 1980s, a wave of reform has transformed the institutional frame- work, organization, and operational environment of infrastructure sectors, ­ particularly the electricity sectors, in most developed and developing countries. Although the structure of the power sectors and the approaches to reform vary across countries, all reforms seek to improve the efficiency of the sector as well as to increase coverage and improve the quality of service. Separation of roles, unbundling, competition, and private participation were used as key instruments to improve efficiency, the government’s fiscal position, and access to electricity Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 20 Benchmarking Utility Performance service for the poor. In many countries in the region, the combination of private participation, competition, and better regulation was effective in improving productive efficiency and quality of service. ­ The last decade has witnessed significant progress in the power sector of LAC. Although there are differences across countries, overall supply increased substan- tially and with it access to electricity. In terms of coverage, the best ­ electricity distribution performer in LAC is Uruguay, with 97 percent coverage, followed by Costa Rica, Brazil, Argentina, Chile, and Mexico, all of which have more than 95 percent coverage. Equally important is the improvement in c ­overage, as reflected in the growth rate of Peru, Paraguay, Honduras, and El Salvador, all of which increased coverage by an average of 20 percentage points between 1995 and 2005. Electricity distribution is at the forefront of infrastructure improvement in percentage LAC. By 2005, 95 percent of the region’s residents had electricity, a 10 ­ point increase over 1995.5 Between 1995 and 2005, most countries in the region made considerable progress in expanding access to electricity and improving the quality of their service. Private sector participation in electricity connections increased from 11 percent in 1995 to 60 percent 2005, and labor productivity doubled. Over the same period, the frequency of interruptions decreased 42 ­ percent, and the duration of the interruptions per connection per year declined 40 percent. Meanwhile, operational expenditures increased by 41–44 percent between 1995 and 2005 and tariffs rose 70 percent for residential users and 91 percent for industrial users. There were no significant changes in distributional losses. Although electricity coverage in LAC increased from 85 percent in 1995 to 95 percent in 2005, the rural poor were not the main beneficiaries. In many countries, industrial consumers and high-income residential consumers were the main beneficiaries of competition and the rebalancing of tariffs, which reduced substantial cross-subsidies of the prereform period (World Bank 2007). However, it is also true that private sector participation and cost-covering tariffs ensured the financial feasibility of efficient electricity providers, which were able to expand access and improve the quality of service to a large number of consumers in urban and p ­ eri-urban areas, including poor people. Regional Benchmarking Assessment Increased electricity coverage reflects high demand for access to the network by a growing number of residential, nonresidential, and rural users. As demand for electricity increased, so did private participation in electricity distribution throughout the region. Private participation grew substantially between 1990 and 2005, especially between 1995 and 1998. In 1990, there was little significant participation of the private sector in electricity distribution; by 1995, the private sector accounted for 11.1 percent of electricity connections in the region. By 2005, private utilities were providing 60 percent of electrical connections. Between 1995 and 2005, $102.6 billion was invested in 384 private electricity projects in the region. With important exceptions—most notably Mexico—most Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Utility Performance 21 LAC countries introduced private participation in electricity distribution as part of broader reforms attempting to establish a more competitive market structure. Private participation remained stagnant between 1995 and 2005, with low levels of investments. It is worth considering this phenomenon when analyzing the regional performance of electricity distribution in the following sections. Many people in LAC remain without electricity, almost all of them poor and in rural areas.6 Large increases in electricity coverage in Argentina, for example, are related to the normalization of illegal connections in urban slums rather than the expansion of electricity service to rural areas. Private investors have been effective in connecting consumers in urban and rural areas near the power grid, but they are reluctant to extend access to rural areas, where electricity service is not financially viable. In Bolivia and Nicaragua, both of which privatized distribu- tion, only 30 percent of the rural population has access to electricity. Further increases in coverage in rural areas usually require substantial investment subsi- dies and strong government support. The government of Chile, a leader in reform and privatization, provided investment subsidies of about $1,500 per household to increase electricity coverage in rural areas from 62 percent in 1995 to 92 ­percent in 2005. Energy sold per connection per year exhibits an increasing trend until 2000 followed by a sudden drop in sales, which continued to decrease until the end of 2005. Between 1995 and 2005, the average energy sold per connection was 5.5 MWh. Although the number of connections rose 45 percent between 1995 and 2005, the total amount of energy sold per connection declined. The fluctuat- ing values of the energy sold per connection may reflect the increase in residen- tial and industrial tariffs and the associated decrease in demand as well as the expansion of service into less wealthy peri-urban communities.7 Regional distribution losses experienced sporadic increases and decreases throughout the 10-year period. The lowest distributional loss was observed in 2001, with a 0.9 percentage point decrease from a 14.5 percent distributional loss in 1995. Between 2001 and 2005, distributional losses rose 1 percentage point, reaching 14.7 percent in 2005. The quality of electricity distribution improved between 1995 and 2005. The frequency of interruptions decreased by almost half, with a 42.4 percent drop in the frequency of the interruptions and a 40.2 percent decrease in the duration of the interruptions per connection per year. The number of interruptions per con- nection declined steadily over this period, falling from 20.5 times in 1995 to 11.8 times in 2005, a reduction of 5.4 percent a year or 42.4 percent in 10 years. A second indicator used to measure quality of service is the average number of hours the customer did not have service. This figure fell 40 percent between 1995 and 2005. Brazil and Paraguay were the main contributors to the increase in service disruptions in 1996; the hurricanes that affected the quality of service in Mexico explain the peak in 2002. These two indicators capture two root causes of interruptions: the reduction in the number of outages per connection shows managerial improvement; the duration of the interruption serves as a proxy for natural events or disasters that affect service. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 22 Benchmarking Utility Performance The decrease in the number of employees between 1995 and 2005 is inversely related to the rise in private participation. Between 1995 and 2000, when private sector participation reached its peak, the number of employees declined 23.2 ­ percent. No significant changes in the regional level of the labor force occurred between 2000 and 2005, consistent with decreased private participa- tion levels. Among the measures used for estimating labor productivity is the number of residential connections per employee. This value doubled between 1995 and 2005, rising from 384 residential connections in 1995 to 701 in 2005. Growth in population (about 1.1 percent a year) accounts for about one-fifth of that gain in labor productivity. A second factor is the substantial increase in electricity coverage. A third factor is the reduction in the labor force in the sector. Energy sold per employee—another measure of labor productivity—increased gradually from 2.2 TWh sold per employee in 1995 to 4.1 TWh in 2005, an increase of 85.1 percent. Average end-user tariffs for electricity supplied to residential connections increased, except in 1999, when tariffs fell 12 percent, mainly because of the crisis in Brazil. By the end of 2005, the average residential tariff was $104 per MWh, a 70 percent increase over the 1995 average residential tariff of $61 per MWh. Following the same pattern, the average industrial tariff increased 91 ­percent, rising from $44 in 1995 to $84 in 2005. Industrial tariffs rose steadily over this period, except in 1997–99, when there was a slight decrease in prices.8 The financial analysis does not consider reductions in state transfers to the power sector, which may have accompanied private participation. With respect to input indicators, the region witnessed fluctuating values of operational expenditures, with more prominent changes toward the end of the decade. Operational expenditures per connection increased 40.8 percent between 1995 and 2005. Despite irregular activity over this period, with unex- pected changes in expenditures between 2000 and 2003, the regional average was $128, with an average annual increase of 3.5 percent. The results for total expenditures per connection express the overall direction of operational and capital expenditures for LAC in the past decade. Total expenditures (defined as total operation and capital expenditures) exhibit a steady increase, except for declines between 1998 and 1999 and between 2001 and 2003. By the end of 2005, total expenditures reached $174 per connection, up from $99 in 1995. The results for operational expenditures per MWh energy sold show a similar tendency. Operational expenditures per unit of energy sold rose 44 percent, an annual growth rate of 3.7 percent, from a regional average of $26.60 per connec- tion in 1995 to $33 per connection by 2005. Utility-Level Benchmarking Assessment Three main features characterize electricity distribution performance in LAC: • significant differences in performance across utilities • improvement by underperforming utilities Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Utility Performance 23 • significant deterioration in distribution performance by some utilities, as reflected by indicators such as average tariffs and distributional losses. In order to assess the performance of electricity distributors at the utility level, the authors ranked the 250 utilities studied, placing them in three categories: the top 10 percent, the middle 80 percent, and the bottom 10 percent of distribution performance. Utilities in the top group have 100 percent electrification, an aver- age of 897 residential connections (6,402 MWh of energy sold) per employee, 6.5 percent distributional losses, and residential prices in the range of $591 per MWh consumed. Between 1995 and 2005, utilities not in the top 10 percent of performers doubled their electricity coverage and labor productivity, reduced the fre- quency of interruptions per connection by 73 percent and the duration of interruptions by 56 percent, and decreased total expenditures per connection ­ by 26 percent. Significant progress was made by the majority of the utilities in all categories throughout the past decade. But major differences are evident across utilities. In 2005, for example, utilities in the top 10 percent were 10 times more productive and sold 6 times the energy (per connection) of utilities in the bottom 10 ­ percent. Utilities in the top decile had one fifth the distributional losses of utilities in the bottom 10 percent. Coverage by utilities in the bottom 10 percent increased from 40 percent in 1995 to 61 percent in 2005—an increase of more than 50 percent. Similar improvements were observed in the frequency and duration of interruptions. Weak performers also improved their labor productivity, which tripled between 1995 and 2005. Some utilities experienced significant deterioration in performance, with both tariffs and distributional losses increasing. For the middle 80 percent, the average residential tariff increased 256 percent, from $44.40 in 1995 to $114.40 in 2005. In contrast, the top 10 percent increased their residential tariffs 37 percent, from $127 per MWh sold in 1995 to $174 in 2005. With respect to distributional losses, whereas the middle 80 percent did not exhibit a significant change during the decade, the bottom 10 percent showed a 27 percent increase in ­ distribution losses. Summary During the study period, the top decile of utilities in LAC achieved universal coverage, the middle 80 percent increased coverage by almost 15 percent, and the bottom 10 percent increased coverage by 26 percent. Although there are some variations within and among countries, in general, several companies in Brazil display the best performance in terms of labor pro- ductivity, distributional losses, operational expenditures, and coverage. Costa Rica benchmarks good performance in coverage, operational expenditures, and tariffs. Several utilities in Chile produced leaders for indicators measuring labor produc- tivity and technical efficiency. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 24 Benchmarking Utility Performance Water and Sanitation Of the 220 million people living in poverty in LAC, 112 million people lack access to a water connection. These figures attest to the challenge the region faces in meeting the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) in a sustainable way. It also underscores the need for timely and efficient interventions in the sector. Detailed information was collected on 16 countries and 1,700 water and sani- tation utilities in the region (see appendix B for details). An analytical framework was designed to produce a comprehensive description of the sector as well as a mechanism for ranking countries and utilities. The data collected for this bench- marking project are representative of 59 percent of the water and sanitation connections in the region from 1995 to 2006. Regional Benchmarking Assessment The main finding of this chapter is one of overall improvement across the region between 1995 and 2006. Significant achievements include the following: • a 4 percent increase in water coverage, which reached 97 percent within the coverage area of the utilities in the database9 • an almost doubling of labor productivity, from 252 connections per employee to 425 • slight increases in the average tariffs for both water and sanitation (27 percent for water and 35 percent for sewerage) • an 8 percent increase in the continuity of service. Water and sanitation coverage for the utilities benchmarked increased from 93 percent to 97 percent between 1999 and 2006. However, this coverage level represents about half of the households in the utilities’ area. This 4 percentage point improvement is consistent with the overall improvement in coverage for all the water and sanitation operators in the region, which reached 81 percent in 2006. Sewerage coverage rose 12 percentage points, from 72 percent in 1999 to 84 percent in 2006.10 Utility-Level Benchmarking Assessment Water and sanitation utilities were ranked based on their coverage, labor produc- tivity, output, input, operating performance, service quality, and prices and divided into three groups: the top 10 percent, the middle 80 percent, and the bottom 10 percent. (For certain indicators, such as operation and capital expen- ditures, ranking in the top or bottom 10 percent is not necessarily a benchmark of good performance.) Substantive differences are evident between the top and bottom performers. The top 10 percent of utilities have 100 percent water and sanitation coverage, an average of 581 cubic meters of water sold per connection a year, an average of 541 residential connections per employee, 15 percent losses in nonrevenue water, water residential prices of about $0.11 per cubic meters of water, and residential sewerage prices averaging $0.07 per cubic meter. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Utility Performance 25 In contrast, the bottom 10 percent average 66 percent water coverage and 15 percent sewerage coverage. Between 2000 and 2006, the top 10 performers maintained an average of 100 percent coverage in water and sanitation. Whereas the middle 80 percent of performers improved coverage slightly, the bottom 10 percent of water and sanitation utilities increased coverage 23 percent. This study assesses the efficiency of the water and sanitation sector based on the following indicators: labor productivity, nonrevenue water, collection ratio, and water connections that are micrometered. Significant heterogeneity is evident across utilities. ­ Compared with utilities in the lowest performance decile, utilities in the top decile are five times more productive, incur one-quarter of the nonrevenue water losses, collect 50 percent more revenue per total water billed, and have five times more micrometered households. In 2006, the best performers provided 24 hours of water service a day—about 1.5 hours more than the middle 80 ­percent. The bottom 10 percent of performers averaged just eight hours a day during 1997–2006. Progress in the water and sanitation sector has been made—including by weak performers—but there is still much room for improvement. Challenges include high nonrevenue water levels, low collection ratios (averaging 50 percent for the sample as a whole), and insufficient tariffs. Fixed Telecommunications During the 1980s and the 1990s, the state owned the fixed telecommunications company, which operated as monopolies. After Chile privatized its telecommu- nications companies in the 1980s, most countries in the region followed suit. The new owners generally had to comply with requirements such as network expan- sion and quality standards. In exchange, they were granted a monopoly period, after which new firms could enter the market. In most countries, liberalization of the long-distance market took place within a few years after privatization (Andrés, Diop, and Guasch 2008). Hence, it is possible that the perceived impacts of privatization were actually caused by liberalization. Although the indicators used refer to local telephone service, lib- ­ eralization of the long-distance market could be an indicator that liberalization of the local market was to come. By 2005, private companies operated almost 85 percent of the fixed lines in LAC. Only Colombia, Costa Rica, Paraguay, and Uruguay still had state-owned main telecommunication operators. By 2007, LAC had invested an average of $12 billion in telecommunication services—a 40 percentage point increase over the $8 billion invested in 1995. Of the $12 billion invested in 2007, $2.3 billion was allocated to fixed telephone services. By 2007, the share of households with a fixed telephone line reached 62 percent, up from 31 percent in 1995. Because mobile and fixed-line telephones are substitutes, penetration rates should consider both technologies. The total number of subscribers per 100 inhabitants for both fixed and mobile increased from 10 in 1995 to 83 in 2007. For fixed lines, the number of subscribers per 100 inhabitants doubled, rising Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 26 Benchmarking Utility Performance from 10 to 20. The number of mobile line subscribers per 100 inhabitants surged, rising from 0.7 in 1995 to 64 in 2007—a 90-fold increase in 12 years. By 2007, the region served 464 million (fixed and mobile line) telephone subscribers, 9.2 times the number in 1995. The number of main fixed lines in operation (73 percent of which were residential) increased 150 percent. The number of residential main lines increased steadily between 1995 and 2006. Perhaps because of increasing reliance on mobile services, it fell 2 percentage points between 2006 and 2007. Labor productivity, measured as the number of fixed and mobile connections per employee, increased by a factor of more than 11 between 2006 and 2007. Throughout the study period, service quality gradually improved. The num- ber of telephone faults per 100 main fixed lines a year dropped from 23 in 1995 to 8 by the end of 2007. Such quality improvements were accompanied by a reduction in the waiting list for main fixed lines, which by 2007 averaged zero. Do Utilities with Private Sector Participation Outperform Public Utilities? The data allow for various desegregations, including by country, size, ownership, and structure. The data are publicly available and allow users to identify and produce their own benchmarking exercises. All figures for this exercise are avail- able in appendix D. One of the scenarios selected compares public utilities with utilities that include private sector participation. The following results are based on averages across utilities in the electricity distribution benchmarking database. The utilities are divided into three categories: utilities that were public throughout 1995– 2005, utilities that privatized before 1995 and remained private through 2005, and utilities that privatized after 1995 and remained private through 2005. The initial conditions in 1995 as well as the overall trend between 1995 and 2005 were considered. As in the previous sections, the results are shown for the top 10 percent of performers, the middle 80 percent, and the bottom 10 percent. The findings reveal considerable improvement in the performance of the electricity distribution sector. The main differences in performance between the ­ two types of utilities have to do with labor productivity, distribution losses, the quality of service, and tariffs. Other indicators, such as coverage and operation expenditures, are similar in utilities with and without private participation. On average, utilities with private participation performed better than public utilities, with clear improvements after the change in ownership. • In 1995, the number of connections per employee was only 10.7 percent higher at utilities that subsequently privatized than at utilities that would remain public. However, by 2005, utilities that had privatized had tripled their productivity, whereas productivity at public utilities had only doubled. • In 1995, utilities that would remain public had distributional losses of 17.9 percent, where utilities that subsequently had private sector Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Utility Performance 27 participation had losses of 15.3 percent. By 2005, the privatized utilities had reduced distribution losses by 12.6 percent, whereas losses at public utilities had increased 4.9 percent. • In 1995, utilities that would remain public experienced an average fre- quency of 22 interruptions per connection, 5 interruptions fewer than utili- ties that subsequently had private sector participation. By 2005, public utilities had reduced the average frequency of interruptions to 18, whereas utilities that had private sector participation had cut their average frequency of interruptions to 13. In 1995, the difference in the duration of service interruptions was one hour. By 2005, the duration had risen 48.8 percent at public utilities and fallen 28.2 percent at utilities that had private sector participation. There are good public and private utilities and underperforming private and public utilities. For several indicators, the top 10 percent of public utilities per- formed better than the average private utilities. In other cases, the bottom 10 percent of private utilities performed worse than the average public utilities. Distribution losses in particular run counter to the overall trend of greater improvement by privatized utilities. Public utilities in the bottom 10 percent have fewer distribution losses than the average private utilities. Utilities that had private sector participation in the top decile have greater distribution losses than the average public utilities. Conclusions This chapter analyzes sector performance based on information on more than 250 public and private electricity distribution companies, more than 1,700 water and sanitation companies, and more than 40 telecommunications companies in 32 countries. The database is rich not only in the number and types of utilities surveyed but also in the diversity and representativeness of the collected indica- tors. As a result, the conclusions are diverse and conditioned by the unique char- acteristics of each sector and service provider. A Leap Forward in Sector Performance Sector performance for electricity distribution, water and sanitation, and fixed telecommunications improved significantly in LAC. Between 1990 and 2005, the region witnessed significant improvements, especially in coverage, service quality, and labor productivity in all three sectors. Coverage in the sample increased to 95 percent for electricity distribution, 97 percent for water utilities, and 62 percent for fixed telecommunications. A similar pattern of improvement is evident for labor productivity. For elec- tricity distribution, labor productivity doubled between 1995 and 2005; for water, it almost doubled (the number of connections per employee rose from 252 in 1995 to 425 in 2006). The telecommunications sector experienced a seven-fold increase between 1995 and 2007. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 28 Benchmarking Utility Performance The quality of service also improved. For electricity distribution, the fre- quency of interruptions fell 42 percent, and the duration of interruptions fell 40 percent. The water sector experienced an 8 percent increase in the continuity of service. In fixed telecommunications, gradual but significant increases occurred in the number of digital main lines and the share of telephone faults cleared by the following working day. For example, the share of digital main lines increased from 63 percent in 1995 to 100 percent in 2007. The number of telephone faults per 100 main fixed lines a year declined from 23 in 1995 to 8 in 2007. Such improvements in quality were accompanied by reductions in the waiting list for main fixed lines, which by 2007 averaged zero. Wide Differences between the Strongest and the Weakest Performers The region is home to a wide range of strong and weak performers. In water and sanitation, the top 10 percent of performers averaged 100 percent water and sanitation coverage. In contrast, the bottom 10 percent averaged 66 percent cov- erage, and the bottom 10 percent of sewerage utilities averaged just 15 percent coverage. Electricity distribution utilities in the top 10 percent were 10 times more productive in 2005 and sold 6 times more energy per connection than utili- ties in the bottom 10 percent. On average, private utilities outperformed public utilities—but there are good public and private utilities and underperforming private and public utilities. Remaining Challenges Although sector performance has improved, the region still faces challenges, particularly in expanding services in rural areas, minimizing distributional losses, and increasing cost-recovery levels. Despite the fact that electricity coverage in LAC increased to 95 percent in 2005, millions of people, almost all poor and in rural areas, remain without electricity. In the same vein, 29 million households, mostly in rural areas, do not have a water connection. These figures underscore the need to expand electrification and water and sanitation services in rural areas. Regional distribution losses display no apparent trend but rather sporadic increases and decreases. For electricity, the lowest distributional loss was observed in 2001, when losses fell to 13.7 percent, down 9 percentage points from 1995; average losses rose to 14.7 percent in 2005. Nonrevenue water increased slightly between 1995 and 2005, from 38 to 39 percent; it remains an obstacle for the region’s water utilities. Lack of cost recovery continues to hamper many utilities in LAC. As outlined in chapter 1, improving cost recovery requires an integrated approach involving tariff adjustments, the control of both operational and capital expenditures, and reliable transfers from government when capital expenditures are viewed as a public good, as may be the case with the expansion of sewerage networks or even rural electrification. The approach will depend on the specific conditions and environment of each sector and utility provider. Although the findings reported here provide only a glimpse of the three sectors, they yield insights about the region’s strengths and weaknesses. One of ­ Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Utility Performance 29 the goals of this work was to motivate research that builds on this knowledge and examines specific case studies. Notes 1. These data are publicly available. The complete database can be accessed at http:// info.worldbank.org/etools/lacelectricity/home.htm. 2. This database will be publicly available shortly. 3. These data are publicly available. The complete database can be accessed at http:// www.itu.int/ITU-D/ict/publications/world/world.html. The water database is avail- able at www.lacbenchmarkingutilities.org. 4. All the numbers in this section are from Andrés and Dragoiu (2008). 5. These coverage figures correspond to the weighted average of the 250 utilities in the LAC benchmarking database. Regional electricity coverage is estimated to have been 92 percent in 2007. 6. These regional estimates correspond to the weighted average across the 250 utilities in the sample, which represents 90 percent of the total number of electricity connections. 7. This reduction in energy sold per connection could also be related to the increase in residential access to poor families, which brings down the average intensity of electric- ity usage. 8. Tariffs in absolute terms are not an efficiency measure of utilities per se, as retail tariffs are related to generation costs. Ideally, one would need to measure the tariff gap or the value added of distribution (VAD) to isolate the cost for the distribution segment from the rest of the value chain. Data on costs are extremely difficult to collect. The authors attempted to collect these data. However, availability of operational expense indicators is uneven at best. These figures correspond to the coverage area for the concessionaires. Some 9. 146 ­million LAC residents lack adequate access to water supply; this measure is equivalent to access to potable water in 2004 (WHO–UNICEF 2008). The main dif- ference between these estimates and the estimated by the World Health Organization and UNICEF is that the lack of service estimate is calculated using census and house- hold surveys and thus includes the rural population and the population in areas not covered by the concessionaires in the sample used here. The changes in coverage presented here are based on data on 1,700 water and sanitation utilities, which cover half of the water connections in LAC. Extrapolating these figures to the connections not covered by the sample could be inappropriate, because the utilities not included in the sample may have lower coverage. 10. The percentage point increase in coverage may also depend on other factors, such as demographics. Although this chapter considers possible determinants for such observed changes, explaining the possible link between the results and determinants is beyond its scope. References Andrés, L., M. Diop, and J. L. Guasch. 2008. “Achievements and Challenges of Private Participation in Infrastructure in Latin America: Evaluation and Future Prospects.” In Euromoney Infrastructure Financing, edited by. H. Davis, 182–201. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 30 Benchmarking Utility Performance Andrés, L., and G. Dragoiu. 2008. Benchmarking Electricity Distribution Report 1995–2005. World Bank, Washington, DC. Fay, M., and M. Morrison. 2006. Infrastructure in Latin America and the Caribbean: Recent Developments and Key Challenges. Washington, DC: World Bank. ITU (International Telecommunication Union). 2009. World Telecommunication/ICT Indicators Database. Geneva. Jamasb, T., R. Mota, D. Newbery, and M. Pollitt. 2005. “Electricity Sector Reform in Developing Countries: A Survey of Empirical Evidence on Determinants and Performance.” Policy Research Working Paper 3549, World Bank, Washington, DC. WHO (World Health Organization)–UNICEF (United Nations Children Fund). 2008. Joint Monitoring Programme (JMP) for Water Supply and Sanitation. http:// www.wssinfo.org/. World Bank. 2007. LCR Energy Strategy. Washington, DC. ———. 2012 Water and Sewerage Utilities: A Benchmarking Analysis for Latin America and the Caribbean. LCSSD Economics Team, Washington, DC. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Chapter 3 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities Massive private investment in infrastructure flowed into Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC) beginning in the 1990s. This chapter focuses on the role private players played in shaping the region’s electricity distribution, water and ­ sewerage, and fixed-line telecommunications sectors.1 The introduction of private participation in infrastructure was an attempt to compensate for the shortcomings of state-operated utilities and to improve the coverage and quality of infrastructure.2 Between 1995 and 1998, private participation in LAC rose from roughly $17 billion to a peak of more than ­ $70 billion, before dropping back to $20 billion in 2002 (World Bank 2007). Until the 1980s, infrastructure services throughout the world were operated and financed exclusively by public entities. Ownership began to change in the 1990s, as a growing number of countries turned to a new approach. The ­ private sector participation phenomenon was based on the coincidence of two distinct but complementary trends. On the one hand, governments began to see the private sector as an attractive and manageable solution to the problems posed by infrastructure services. On the other hand, the private sector began to see the ­ commercial attraction of investing in emerging economies. ­ As a result, private capital flows to infrastructure projects in developing ­ countries grew sixfold during the mid-1990s (although they declined sharply thereafter). From a baseline of $20 billion in the mid-1990s, global investments ­ swelled to a peak of $131 billion in 1997. The increase was driven primarily by the rapid adoption of the new model in Latin America and East Asia. The countries of Eastern Europe and Central Asia were also partly responsible for the ­ increase, as the transition economies launched massive privatization programs. From 1997 until recently, private capital flows were in marked decline. Triggered by the financial crises—and resulting currency devaluations—in East Asia and Latin America, the decline coincided with various corporate crises. Some of the major telecommunications companies that invested in emerging Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   31   32 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities economies saw their average share prices fall 90 percent, and the shares of global energy firms fell as much as 70 percent. Private investment fell from $71 billion in 1998 to $16 billion in 2003, and the average contract attracted only two bidders (Fay and Morrison 2006). Rebuilding public and business confidence ­ in private-public partnerships in LAC will not be easy. Private participation has improved utility performance in the region, as chapter 2 shows. However, since the beginning of this decade, it has become ­ a topic of contention among LAC governments, and the region’s ability to attract investors has diminished. In November 2000, 36 percent of Argentines believed that infrastructure services should come back under government control; five years later, 78 percent supported government control (El Cronista, April 18, 2005). The change in Argentina reflects a general trend in Latin America.3 Public resistance has become a major constraint on private participation in infrastructure in some countries, both politically and o ­ ­ perationally. The average number of ­ bidders for power distribution privatizations in the region fell from more than four in 1998 to less than two in 2000 and 2001 (Harris 2003). There is a remarkable contrast between generally positive evaluations of private sector participation and the extreme public disaffection with it. ­ Martimort and Straub (2005) conclude that either important failures have gone unreported (although clearly not unnoticed by the people who suffered) or there has been a major problem with perceptions (and therefore a massive communi- cation ­failure). Although estimates of impact on service coverage, quality, and redistribution are generally positive, it is possible that some negative aspects were underreported. The quality of service may have deteriorated or failed to improve as much as expected; the redistributional impact of price increases may not have been sufficiently mitigated by subsidies; and the effect on jobs in infrastruc- ture was negative, although sector employment rebounded somewhat in the medium term (Fay and Morrison 2006). Perceptions may be the main driver for this disaffection. Negative public perception of private sector participation may actually reflect the downturn in ­ the economic cycle (Boix 2005), perceptions may have suffered from a gap between actual and expected performance, and the perceived transparency of the private sector participation ­process is likely to have been crucial in shaping public perceptions (Fay and Morrison 2006). Perhaps the gravest misconception during the peak of private participation in infrastructure was that governments could now pass on responsibility for infrastructure financing and management to the private sector. Although private ­ participation held promises of a new flow of finance and technological ­ innovations, it was not intended to substitute or play the role of the public sector but rather to complement it. As Fay and Morrison (2006) emphasize, ­ governments remain at the heart of infrastructure service delivery. They should continue to regulate and oversee infrastructure provision and pay for a large share of investments. The challenge currently facing the region is the low level of public and p ­ rivate investment in infrastructure. Low levels of investment are a concern because of the widely documented link between infrastructure and growth, productivity, Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 33 and poverty reduction (see Briceño-Garmendia, Estache, and Shafik 2004; Calderón and Servén 2004; Fay and Morrison 2006). Public investment in infra- structure in LAC dropped from 3 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) in 1980 to less than 1 percent in 2001 (De Ferranti and others 2004. By 2009, it reached 3–4 percent of GDP, including the stimulus packages launched in response to the financial crisis (Schwartz, Andrés, and Dragoiu 2009). In order to revive both public and private investment in the region, it is important to under- stand their distinct yet complementary roles and the true impacts and determi- nants of private sector participation in LAC. If governments and private actors are to increase infrastructure investments in feasible ways, it is critical that they learn from experiences, in order to make better investment and m ­ aintenance choices. This chapter contributes to this aim by presenting a comprehensive and systemic analysis of the impact of private sector participation in LAC. It looks at ­ what happened before, during, and after private sector participation in three ­ sectors (electricity distribution, water and sewerage, and telecommunications) by focusing on a range of performance variables. It is necessary to look at all three periods because the most dramatic effects of private sector participation are often found in the transition period, when the enterprise is overhauled as part of the transaction process. These changes constitute a one-time adjustment, however, and present a pace of improvement that is not necessarily sustained in the long run. The chapter focuses on changes and rates of changes in the three ­ periods rather than on absolute numbers, because in many cases, the performance vari- ables exhibit natural changes over time (with or without private sector participation). The analysis controls for such naturally occurring rates of changes. ­ The changes associated with private sector participation had a significant effect on labor productivity, efficiency, and quality (for fixed-line telecommuni- cations, they also had significant effects on output and coverage) (table 3.1). Prices tended to increase somewhat following the change in ownership, although the picture varies across sectors. Moreover, care should be exercised in interpreting changes in prices, because prices were highly ­ ­ distorted—most did not represent cost recovery—before private sector participation began. There do not appear to have been significant impacts on output or coverage The differences between publicly and privately operated distribution utilities showed up primarily with regard to labor productivity, distribution losses, quality of service, and tariffs. Other indicators, such as coverage and operational expen- ditures, were not significantly different in the two groups.4 The analysis in this chapter addresses the determinants of performance. Impact of Private Sector Participation on Electricity Distribution The poor performance of the public model of electricity distribution in the 1990s beckoned for reform in the sector. Reform introduced market principles, in an attempt to improve the quality, reliability, and efficiency of electricity ser- vices; strengthen the government’s fiscal position; and increase affordable access to energy services for the poor. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 34 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities Table 3.1 Effects of Private Participation in Electricity Distribution, Water Distribution, and Fixed-Line Telecommunications in Latin America and the Caribbean Electricity distribution Fixed-line telecommunications Water distribution Transition Posttransition Transition Posttransition Transition Posttransition Number of subscribersa Outputa Number of employees Labor productivitya Decline in distributional losses Quality Coveragea Average prices ? ? Monthly residential charges Price for a residential installation Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: Up and down arrows indicate that a positive or negative change occurred in addition to the natural change that would have been expected in the absence of private sector participation. An equal sign indicates that the trend observed during the previous period was sustained. A question mark indicates that insufficient observations were available to reach a conclusion. The size of the arrow represents the magnitude of the change. a. Net of firm-specific time trend. Market-oriented reform promoted the separation of policymaking, regulation, and service provision, limiting the role of the state to policymaking and regula- tion and relying on the private sector as the main investor and provider of electricity service. Wherever possible, reform also introduced competition and ­ economic regulation of natural monopolies to improve economic efficiency. This market model was supposed to improve the government’s fiscal position and ensure the financial sustainability of the sector by promoting the participation of private investors and the establishment of competitive prices for generation and cost-covering tariffs for transmission and distribution. It was considered socially and politically acceptable because it would improve access to energy services by the poor, based on a scheme of efficient subsidies. This section draws on the work of Andrés, Foster, and Guasch (2006), who built an original data set based on information from 116 electricity distribution companies in the region before and after their private sector participation. Their study used two complementary methodologies—a means and medians analysis and an econometric analysis—to examine the effects of changes in ownership. This section synthesizes their results, summarizing the effects on output and Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 35 coverage, employment and labor productivity, prices, distributional losses, and service ­quality during three periods: before the private sector participation (pre- transition), the three-year transition period, and after the private sector participa- tion (posttransition).5 Doing so reveals both the short- and longer-term effects. The change in ownership did not change the growth trend for number of connections, energy sold, or coverage. Employment fell during both periods, ­ primarily during the transition. Labor productivity accelerated during the ­ transition, followed by a deceleration during the posttransition period. ­ Distributional losses and quality improved during both periods. Average prices in real local currency increased somewhat over both periods (results for dollar price changes were smaller given Brazil’s currency devaluation in 1999). Output and Coverage The number of connections, quantity of energy sold each year, and coverage levels increased across all three periods—pretransition, transition, and ­ posttransition—but the effects were driven by secular trends. The annual changes in energy sold declined slightly after the private sector participation. Two measures were used to estimate output: the volume of energy sold each year (in MWhs) and the total number of connections at the end of each year. The amount of energy sold increased in all three periods (figure 3.1).6 According to the econometric analysis, the average amount of energy sold increased 22.3 ­percent during the transition; the average amount sold after the transition was 18.4 percent higher than transition levels.7 These output indicators exhibit a natural rate of growth that must be controlled for to isolate the impacts of private sector participation. The econo- ­ metric results show that there was a slight increase in the growth trend during the transition. After the transition (during the period after private sector partici- pation), however, the growth trend in the volume of energy sold slowed slightly.8 The number of connections increased significantly during all three periods.9 According to the econometric analysis, the average level of connection numbers was 16.2 percent higher during the transition than before the transition. The aver- age level after the transition was 19.2 percent higher than during the transition (see appendix table D.3). These increases were statistically significant by both the means and median analysis (see appendix table D.1) and the econometric analysis (see appendix table D.3). Examination of figure 3.1, however, shows that the increases largely followed a trend. The cross-country differences in the e ­ volution of connection numbers could potentially be explained by differences in initial coverage conditions or differences in contract and regulator characteristics. Increases in coverage occurred during all three periods: the average increase during the transition was 5.4 percent, and the average increase after that (with respect to transition levels) was 8 percent. Like the output increases, the coverage increases were statistically significant. However, after controlling for time trends and growth patterns, the impact of private sector participation becomes ­ ifficult to discern (figure 3.2). Brazil overtook Argentina to have negligible or d the highest coverage level—more than 95 percent—during the posttransition Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 36 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities Figure 3.1 Energy Distribution before, during, and after Private Sector Participation a. Volume of energy sold 160 140 Average MWhs 120 100 80 60 −5 0 5 Time b. Average number of connections 160 140 Number of connections 120 100 80 60 −5 0 5 Time Peru Colombia All Bolivia Chile Panama Brazil El Salvador Argentina Nicaragua Guatemala Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. period. Guatemala experienced the largest jump between the before and after transition periods. Employment and Labor Productivity Employment levels dropped substantially during the transition, not controlling for time trends. They also fell after the transition, but to a lesser extent. Most state-owned enterprises (SOEs) had excess personnel. Hence, as expected, significant reductions in the number of employees were observed across the three ­ Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 37 Figure 3.2 Electricity Coverage before and after Private Sector Participation 100 80 Percent of households with coverage 60 40 20 0 a ua a a ala a r ru il do in am bi ivi az Pe g em nt om l lva ra Br Bo n ge Pa ca at l Sa Co Ar Ni Gu El Before private sector participation After private sector participation Source: Andrés and others 2008. Figure 3.3 Employment in the Electricity Distribution Sector before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 250 Average number of employees 200 150 100 50 −5 0 5 Time Colombia All El Salvador Peru Brazil Bolivia Argentina Panama Chile Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. periods (figure 3.3).10 In some cases, the government reduced the number of employees before the change in ownership in order to increase the value of the firms (Chong and López-de-Silanes 2003). The analysis conducted here finds that labor force reductions during the transition were substantially larger than those after. The econometric analysis finds a 26.4 percent drop in the number of employees ­ during the transition; after the transition, there was an additional drop percent.11 Employment levels dropped substantially during the transition; of 17.6 ­ Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 38 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities they also fell after the transition, but to a lesser extent. Appendix table D.3 shows the changes in employment levels found by the econometric analysis. Increases in output and reductions in the number of employees increased labor productivity during both the transition and posttransition periods ­ (figure 3.4). Although the greatest gains came during the transition period, both the number of connections per employee and the quantity of energy sold per employee showed significant improvements during the transition and posttransition periods relative to the previous period.12 According to the econo- ­ metric analysis, ­connections per employee were 55.6 percent higher ­ during the transition and another 44.5 percent higher after the transition. Equivalent num- bers for energy sold per employee are 60.6 percent and 41.3 percent. Figure 3.4 Labor Productivity in Electricity Distribution before, during, and after Private Sector Participation a. Connections per employee 300 Connections per employee 250 200 150 100 50 −5 0 5 Time b. Electricity sales per employee 300 MWhs of electricity distributed 250 per employee 200 150 100 50 −5 0 5 Time Chile Bolivia Argentina Brazil Colombia Panama El Salvador All Peru Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 39 As was the case for the output and labor indicators, controlling for trends dramatically reduces the private sector participation impacts. With the effect of time trends removed, the number of connections per employee increased 5 per- cent and energy per employee increased 9 percent during the transition. Levels after the transition decreased slightly with respect to transition levels (−3.6 per- cent for connections per employee and −7.7 percent for energy per employee). The econometric growth rate analysis produced similar results: the average annual growth rate for both connections per employee and energy per employee increased during the transition and decreased after the transition. Connections per employee and energy sold per employee showed large gains during both the transition and posttransition periods. A temporary growth accel- eration occurred during the transition, followed by a deceleration after the transition. Prices Average prices in real local currency increased somewhat during the transition and posttransition periods. After excluding Brazil (which devalued its currency in 1999), dollar prices increased slightly. Tariffs in real local currency showed a clearly increasing trend, but prices in dollars decreased. The econometric analysis showed statistically significant increases in real local currency prices of 11.1 ­percent during the transition and 7.4 percent after the transition. In dollars, there was no significant change during the transition period and a −2.8 percent drop during the posttransition period. A plausible explanation for these trends is the 1999 currency devaluation in Brazil. To test this explanation, the analysis was repeated with Brazil excluded from the sample. With Brazil excluded, both series show increasing prices, but at a much lower rate. As a result of the smaller sample size and relatively small price changes, no significant differences were found between consecutive periods in the means and medians analysis. The same analysis found small but significant price increases in both local currency and dollars when comparing the pretransi- tion and posttransition periods. Distributional Losses Distributional losses under public ownership varied, increasing in some coun- tries and decreasing in others before private sector participation (figure 3.5). After the transition, almost all countries reduced their average distributional losses. The reason for the temporary increase in losses in some countries part way through the p ­ osttransition period is unclear. The transition period saw an average drop in distributional losses of 3.1 ­percent, according to the econometric analysis. In contrast, distributional losses plunged 13.2 percent during the posttransition period. The means and medians analysis tells a slightly different story. The mean for the transition period was 11.5 percent lower than the mean during the pretransi- tion period; the mean during the posttransition period was about 10 percent lower than during the transition period. Changes in the median are more similar Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 40 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities Figure 3.5  Distributional Losses in the Electricity Sector before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 120 Distributional losses (MWhs) 100 80 60 40 −5 0 5 Time El Salvador Chile Peru All Guatemala Colombia Nicaragua Argentina Bolivia Panama Brazil Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. to the econometric analysis. The median distributional loss was 6 percent lower during the transition period and 11 percent lower during the posttransition period with respect to the previous period (see appendix table D.1). (In this case, it makes more sense to analyze changes in loss levels rather than trends, because a natural trend is not expected.) The mixed results are likely the result of a conflation of technical and com- mercial distributional losses. To curb technical losses, new investments and upgrades are required that take time to implement. Hence, technical losses would be expected to occur following the transition period. In contrast, com- mercial losses can often be reduced quickly, by shutting off the connections of nonpaying customers. Declines in distributional losses during the transition period could be attributed to commercial losses. Quality of Service The quality of electricity distribution is measured by the frequency and duration of service interruptions per consumer. In general, these measures were defined at the time of reform, along with the creation of regulatory agencies, making it difficult to build long time series. ­ The good data that exist from the pretransition period indicate that both the average duration of interruptions and the average frequency of interruptions per consumer fell during both the transition and posttransition periods. Combining these two indicators yields an overall quality measure that shows improvement in both periods. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 41 Only Argentina and Brazil had information for the years before the transition. Argentina stands out as having been particularly successful in reducing the average duration and frequency of interruptions per consumer, in both ­ ­ relative and absolute terms (figure 3.6). In countries where quantitative quality data before ­private sector participation are not available, strong anecdotal evidence suggests that quality was poor. Both methodologies found improvements in average frequency and dura- tion of interruptions. According to the econometric analysis, the duration of interruptions fell 13.4 percent during the transition and an additional 29.1 ­percent after the transition. The frequency of interruptions fell 10.1 ­percent during the ­transition and an additional 26.5 percent after it.13 The means and medians analysis found similar quality improvements, although the frequency of interruptions results was not statistically significant for the posttransition period.14 Figure 3.6  Quality of Electricity Distribution before, during, and after Private Sector Participation a. Duration of interruptions per connection 200 Average duration of interruption per consumer (minutes) 150 100 50 0 −5 0 5 Time b. Frequency of interruptions per connection 250 Average frequency of interruptions per consumer (minutes) 200 150 100 50 −5 0 5 Time Argentina Bolivia Peru Brazil All Note: The average line for all countries appears erratic because of the relative scarcity of data. t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 42 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities Both the average duration of interruptions per consumer and the average ­requency of interruptions per consumer fell during both the transition and f ­ posttransition periods. Combining these two indicators yields an overall quality measure that shows improvement in both periods. ­ Summary The change in ownership did not change the growth trend for number of connections, energy sold, or coverage.15 Employment fell during both periods, ­ but primarily during the transition. Growth in labor productivity accelerated during the transition, followed by a deceleration during the posttransition period. Distributional losses and quality improved during both periods. Average prices in real local currency increased somewhat over both periods, although results for dollar price changes were less robust given Brazil’s currency ­ devaluation in 1999. Impact of Private Sector Participation on Water and Sewerage Growing dissatisfaction with the performance of national water monopolies, combined with political pressure for devolution across all areas of govern- ment, created the conditions for a move toward decentralized control of water infrastructure in the 1980s and 1990s. In general, water sector reforms comprised three components: decentralization, regulation, and private sector participation. Chile was the first country to modernize its water sector, passing new legisla- tion as early as 1988. By 1991, both Argentina and Mexico were beginning to conduct a series of experiments with private sector participation. In a second wave, Peru, Colombia, and Bolivia enacted ambitious legislation in the mid- 1990s. During the second half of the decade, reform began to take root in Brazil and Central America. By the end of the 1990s, few countries had not com- pleted reforms, had major reforms in process, or were actively considering reforms. As part of the reform process, many countries created national regulatory agencies for water, similar to the Water Services Regulation Authority (Ofwat) model developed in the United Kingdom. The responsibilities of these agencies typically included determination of tariffs, approval of investment plans, ­ oversight of quality of service, and protection of consumers. In some cases (for example, Peru), the agencies did not have final authority to determine tariffs. In the larger federal countries (Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico), regulatory func- tions were often organized at the state or provincial level. The regulatory agen- cies were seen as a precursor to private participation in the sector, although the ultimate scope of private participation was modest relative to initial expectations. Historically, the water and sewerage sectors have not been well analyzed in Latin America. In contrast to electricity distribution and telecommunications, firms tend to be based at the local or regional government level, making the private participation process slower and more fragmented. Despite the slow Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 43 ­ rocess, at least 11 percent of the water used by households in the region is p supplied by private firms Andrés and others (2007). ­ For the analysis in this section, data were collected for 49 firms that under- went a change in ownership in the previous 15 years. Two complementary methodologies were used to learn about the effects of changes in ownership: ­ a means and medians analysis and an econometric analysis. Output and coverage measures improved, but only consistent with the trend. The number of employees dropped substantially during the last years under public management, significantly increasing labor productivity, especially during the transition period. Labor productivity rates accelerated during the transition but decelerated in the posttransition period. Efficiency—measured by distribu- tional losses—improved, mainly after the transition. Prices for both water and sewerage rose, although the increases for sewerage were generally not robust because of the small sample size. Two measures were used to measure quality: the continuity of the water service and the number of water samples that passed a potability test. Both measures improved in both periods, but potability improvements occurred mainly during the transition. Output and Coverage The number of water and sewerage connections increased during the transition and posttransition periods, but these improvements were consistent with existing trends. Similar results were found for both water and sewerage coverage. Water production increased somewhat in both periods, but after controlling for trends, a slight deceleration occurred in the posttransition period. Two variables were used to measure output: the number of residential con- nections (for both water and sewerage) and the amount of water produced (in cubic meters) each year. The number of connections for both water and sewerage increased substantially during both the transition and posttransition periods ­(figure 3.7, panels a and b); the econometric analysis found increases of 15–20 percent for each period (see appendix D). The means and medians analysis found similar results. ­ A closer look at the results, however, shows that the increases can be accounted for by the existence of a trend. After controlling for firm-specific time trends, the econometric analysis found no significant changes in the number of water or sewerage connections. The econometric analysis found no significant changes in growth rates during the transition; after the transition, the average annual growth rate fell 1 percent for both water and sewerage.16 The second output indicator is the number of cubic meters of water produced a year (see figure 3.7, panel e). The econometric analysis found that ­ water ­ production increased 4.1 percent during the transition period and an additional 1.5 percent after the transition. However, taking trends into account—by controlling for firm-specific time trends or looking at changes in growth rates—erases those gains. In fact, the econometric analysis found no significant change in water production during the transition and a small drop after the transition.17 As shown later, a possible explanation for this Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 44 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities Figure 3.7 Indicators of Water and Sewerage Output and Coverage before, during, and after Private Sector Participation a. Average number of water connections Number of water connections 140 120 100 80 60 -5 0 5 Time b. Average number of sewerage connections 200 Number of sewerage 150 connections 100 50 −5 0 5 Time figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 45 Figure 3.7  Indicators of Water and Sewerage Output and Coverage before, during, and after Private Sector Participation (continued) 130 c. Average water coverage Water coverage (cubic meters) 120 110 100 90 80 −5 0 5 Time d. Average sewerage coverage 120 110 Sewerage coverage (cubic meters) 100 90 80 70 –5 0 5 Time figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 46 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities Figure 3.7  Indicators of Water and Sewerage Output and Coverage before, during, and after Private Sector Participation (continued) e. Average water production 160 140 Water production (cubic meters) 120 100 80 –5 0 5 Time Argentina Trinidad Chile Brazil All Mexico Colombia Bolivia Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. ­eceleration is the improvement in efficiency caused by the reduction in d ­distributional losses. Coverage in both water (figure 3.8) and sewerage improved during the transi- tion and posttransition periods. According to the econometric analysis, these improvements were statistically significant and ranged from 2.5 to 6.7 percent. The means and medians analysis found increases of 6.9–11.1 percent. These improvements were apparently driven by trends, however, and would have occurred even in the absence of private sector participation. After controlling for firm-specific time trends, the econometric analysis found no ­ significant changes. Growth rates showed no significant changes during the ­ transition period, com- bined with a small drop in the average annual growth rate of 0.4 percentage points for water and 0.8 percentage points for sewerage after the transition. Not surprisingly, these results are quantitatively similar to the results found for the number of connections. Water coverage levels are relatively high in most countries—more than 90 ­percent. Mexico stands out as an exception, with less than 80 percent coverage. For sewerage, actual coverage levels are lower—closer to 60 percent for ­ some ­ countries. Chile is an outlier, with close to 100 percent sewerage coverage. Employment and Labor Productivity The number of employees declined during the transition and posttransition periods, not accounting for time trends. Both types of analyses found significant ­ drops in employment during both periods, although the decline during Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 47 Figure 3.8  Water Distribution before and after Private Sector Participation 100 Percent of households 80 with coverage 60 40 20 0 Argentina Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico Before private sector participation After private sector participation Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: The y-axis is the number of connections per 100 inhabitants. the transition seems to have been greater (figure 3.9, panel a). The means and medians analysis found a 26.3 percent drop during the transition and an 11.7 percent drop after the transition. The econometric analysis found a 16.5 percent drop during the transition and a 17.6 percent drop after the transition.18 Given that most SOEs had excess personnel, the declines during the transition period should not be surprising. Many governments opted to trim the labor force before the ownership change, in an attempt to increase the value of the firm. Argentina had by far the most employees; it also experienced the largest absolute reduction in employee numbers. Labor productivity—measured by the number of water connections per employee—increased greatly during both the transition and posttransition p ­ eriods (figure 3.9, panel b). The econometric analysis found that water connections per employee increased 30.7 percent during the transition and another 42.5 ­ percent after the transition. The means and medians analysis found similar increases. Controlling for trends tells a somewhat different story. According to the econometric analysis, the average annual growth rate of connections per employee increased 4.7 percentage points during the transition. This increase was followed by a drop of 3.7 percentage points after the transition. There was thus a temporary acceleration in labor productivity growth (largely because of employment changes) during the transition before the annual growth rate returned to roughly 1 percentage point above the pretransition level. The means and medians analysis identified similar changes: an 11.6 percentage point increase during the transition followed by a 9.6 percentage point decrease after the ­transition. There was no statistically significant difference between the pre- transition and posttransition growth rates in the means and medians analysis. Prices Water prices in dollars showed little change during the transition period (because of Brazil’s devaluation) and rose after the transition. Water prices in real local Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 48 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities Figure 3.9 Employment and Labor Productivity in the Water Distribution Sector before, during, and after Private Sector Participation a. Number of employees 140 Number of employees 120 100 80 60 –5 0 5 Time b. Connections for drinkable water per employee 250 Connections for drinkable water 200 per employee 150 100 50 –5 0 5 Time Bolivia Brazil All Colombia Argentina Trinidad Mexico Chile Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. currency increased fairly substantially in both the transition and posttransition periods. Because of the small sample size, not much can be said about sewerage prices; however, a significant price increase in real local currency occurred during the posttransition period. Water prices increased before and after transition in both dollars and real local currency (figure 3.10). Brazil’s currency devaluation in 1999 accounted for the main difference between the two types of currencies. As a result of the devaluation, Brazil’s water prices fell in dollars and mainly rose in real local Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 49 currency. Given that the Brazil devaluation skewed the results for dollar prices so that they appeared artificially low, it is preferable to look at changes in real local currency. According to the econometric analysis, water prices in dollars did not change significantly during the transition but increased 10.2 percent after the transition. In contrast, water prices showed statistically significant increases in real local cur- rency of 15.7 percent during the transition and 23.7 percent after the transition. In the means and medians analysis, there were no significant changes between adjacent periods in dollars, but there was a statistically significant increase between the pretransition and posttransition periods. In real local currency, the Figure 3.10  Average Price of Water and Sewerage before, during, and after Private Sector Participation a. Average price of water in dollars 200 Dollars per cubic meter 150 100 50 −5 0 5 Time b. Average price of water in local currency 160 Local currency per cubic meter 140 120 100 80 60 −5 0 5 Time figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 50 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities Figure 3.10  Average Price of Water and Sewerage before, during, and after Private Sector Participation (continued) c. Average price of sewerage in dollars 300 250 Dollars per cubic meter 200 150 100 50 −5 0 5 Time d. Average price of sewerage in local currency 200 Local currency per cubic meter 150 100 50 −5 0 5 Time Brazil All Chile Colombia Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. means and medians analysis found significant price increases in each period. When Brazil was excluded from the sample, the means and medians analysis found statistically significant increases of 32.6 percent during the transition and 16.9 percent after the transition. Sewerage prices seem to have behaved in a similar fashion as water prices (see figure 3.10, panels c and d). Because of the small number of observations, ­ however, the only statistically significant change was the 24.9 percent increase in real local currency prices after the transition period in the econometric analysis. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 51 Distributional Losses Distributional losses fell substantially during both the transition and posttransition periods (figure 3.11). Indeed, the econometric analysis found a 3.8 percent drop in the percentage of water lost during the transition period followed by a 14.4 per- cent drop during the posttransition period. The means and medians analysis found results of a slightly larger magnitude (an 8.1 percent decline in the transition period followed by an 18.3 percent decrease in the posttransition period). Trends are not controlled for, because a natural trend is not expected and figure 3.11 does not signal a trend in the period before private sector participation. Quality of Service Improvements in service continuity appear to have occurred during both the transition and posttransition periods; no improvements occurred during the pre- transition period (figure 3.12). The means and medians analysis found that average continuity improved 27.8 percent during the transition and 14.8 percent ­ after the transition Presumably because of the relatively small sample size, the econometric analysis found a statistically significant improvement (of 7.7 ­percent) only in the posttransition period. Although the number of observations was small, it seems evident that water potability improved (see figure 3.12, panel b). Most of the changes occurred during the transition: according to the econometric analysis, potability improved ­ 6.1 percent during the transition and 1.2 percent in the posttransition period. Given that potability numbers were already close to 100 percent for many coun- tries (with the exception of Colombia), it is not surprising that improvements in the posttransition period were modest. Figure 3.11 Losses in Water Distribution before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 120 Percent of water lost in distribution 110 100 90 80 70 −5 0 5 Time Brazil All Argentina Chile Colombia Mexico Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 52 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities Figure 3.12 Service Continuity and Quality of Water before, during, and after Private Sector Participation a. Hours of water service per day 140 Hours of water service per day 120 100 80 60 −5 0 5 Time b. Percent of water that passes potability test 120 Percent of water that passes 100 potability test 80 60 40 −5 0 5 Time Bolivia Brazil Trinidad Chile Argentina All Colombia Mexico Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. Summary Output and coverage of water and sewerage improved following the change in ownership, but the improvements were consistent with the existing trend. The number of employees dropped substantially during the last years of public man- agement. These changes significantly increased labor productivity, especially dur- ing the transition period. However, labor productivity rates accelerated during the transition and decelerated in the posttransition period. Efficiency—measured Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 53 by distributional losses—improved mainly after the transition. Prices for both water and sewerage rose, although the increases for sewerage were generally not robust because of the small sample size. Two measures were used for quality: the continuity of water service and the number of water samples that passed a pota- bility test. Both measures improved in both periods, but potability improvements occurred mainly during the transition. Impact of Private Sector Participation on Fixed-Line Telecommunications During the 1980s and the 1990s, the state owned fixed-line telecommunications companies, which operated as monopolies in national markets. After Chile’s experience in the 1980s, most countries in the region privatized their telecom companies (Andrés and others 2008). The new owners generally had to comply with requirements such as network expansion and quality standards. In exchange, they were granted a monopoly period, after which new firms could enter the market. In most countries, liberalization of the long-distance market took place within a few years after privatization. It may therefore be that the impacts attrib- uted to private sector participation were actually caused by liberalization. This section analyzes a data set constructed by the International Telecommunication Union (ITU) (2008) that covers 16 fixed-line telecommuni- cation companies that were privatized.19 Two complementary methodologies were used to examine the effects of changes in ownership: a means and medians analy- sis and an econometric analysis. The period under analysis is separated into three parts: the period before private sector participation (pretransition), a three-year transition period, and the period after private sector participation (posttransition). Output Two variables are used to measure output: the number of connections and the number of local minutes consumed each year. Number of connections. The number of connections increased during all three periods for almost all countries (figure 3.13). Both the means and medians analy- sis and the econometric analysis confirmed that there were statistically ­significant increases in the number of connections between the pretransition, ­ transition, and posttransition periods (see appendix tables D.4 and D.6). The econometric analy- sis found a 29 percent increase in the number of connections during the transition period and an additional 64 percent increase during the posttransition period. Figure 3.13 indicates that growth in the number of connections accelerated, possibly temporarily, in the first few years of private ownership. The means and medians analysis found that average annual growth in the number of connections increased 6.9 percent in the pretransition period, 12.7 percent during the transi- tion period, and 7.2 percent in the posttransition period. The econometric analy- sis found that the average annual growth rate increased 2.7 percentage points during the transition; there was no statistically significant change from that level after the transition.20 After controlling for trends, it seems that an increase Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 54 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities Figure 3.13 Number of Fixed-Line Connections and Average Minutes Consumed before, during, and after Private Sector Participation a. Number of xed-line connections 300 Number of connections 250 200 150 100 50 −5 0 5 Time b. Average minutes consumed 200 150 Minutes 100 50 0 −5 0 5 Time Guyana Jamaica Trinidad Mexico Brazil Argentina Bolivia All Chile Guatemala Venezuela, RB Peru Panama Nicaragua El Salvador Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. occurred during the transition but that growth rates returned to normal levels after the transition. One possible explanation for the surge in the number of connections during and shortly after the transition is that newly privatized companies took action to meet pent-up demand. According to the ITU, waiting lists for connections in the year before the reform numbered 780,000 in Argentina (26 percent of connec- tions in operation), 308,247 in Peru (46 percent of connections in operation), and 175,000 in El Salvador (54 percent of connections in operation). Another contrib- uting factor was the spread of mobile telecommunications, especially during the second half of the 1990s, which likely reduced the demand for new fixed connections. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 55 In principle, private ownership in fixed-line telecommunications could shift pri- orities away from network expansion, because shareholders are likely to be reluctant to expand the network unless doing so is profitable or required by the contract (Ros 1999). In practice, private sector participation led to network expansion. Number of minutes. The second output indicator is the number of minutes consumed a year. Except in Argentina, this indicator generally increased, with growth particularly strong after the transition (figure 3.13). These results are not surprising given the greater number of connections discussed above. The means and medians and econometric analyses generally confirm what can be seen in figure 3.13, although the results are not always robust because of the relatively small number of observations. The econometric analysis found statistically significant increases of 8.2 percent in the transition period and 37.6 percent ­ during the posttransition period.21 ­ When time trends are taken into account in the econometric analysis, there was no significant change during the transition period, whereas the posttransition period showed an increase of 14.2 percent over transition levels. In contrast, the regressions found statistically significant increases in growth rates of 6.9 ­percentage points during the transition period and 5.3 percentage points during the post- transition period. Hence, the preponderance of evidence suggests that the ­ number of minutes of fixed-line telecom services increased in both the transition and posttransition periods after controlling for the trend. Coverage Consistent with the output measures, coverage (or teledensity, defined as the number of connections per 100 inhabitants) increased substantially during the periods under study (figure 3.14). The econometric analysis found an Figure 3.14 Coverage of Fixed-Line Telecommunications before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 250 Percent of households 200 with coverage 150 100 50 −5 0 5 Time Guyana Bolivia Jamaica Trinidad Mexico Argentina Chile Panama Nicaragua El Salvador Venezuela, RB Peru All Brazil Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 56 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities increase of 18.3 percent during the transition period and an additional increase percent during the posttransition period. The means and medians analysis of 52.3 ­ also found substantial statistically significant increases. The econometric analysis found that the annual growth rate increased 3.7 percentage points during the transition period and registered no additional changes after the transition. The means and medians analysis found that the average annual growth rate increased 6.1 percentage points during the transition ­ period and fell 5.9 percentage points (relative to transition rates) during the ­posttransition period.22 Figure 3.15 compares coverage levels across countries. Although considerable heterogeneity exists, most countries had coverage levels of 10–20 connections per 100 inhabitants. The number of connections increased during both periods, but after control- ling for trends, only the transition period showed abnormally high growth rates. After controlling for trends, the number of minutes increased in both periods, whereas increases in coverage occurred mainly in the transition period. Labor and Labor Productivity The number of employees declined during the transition and posttransition periods, not accounting for time trends. The average number of employees in ­ fixed-line telecommunications companies had been declining steadily since before the transition period. This average decline masks considerable differ- ences across firms and countries, however (figure 3.16). The econometric ­ analysis found that employment declined 9.2 percent during the transition period and another 23.2 percent after the transition period.23 A natural trend employment is not expected, but employment growth rates became increas- in ­ ingly negative during the transition and posttransition periods. The econometric Figure 3.15 Coverage Levels of Fixed-Line Telecommunications before and after Private Sector Participation 25 Percent of households 20 with coverage 15 10 5 0 RB a Gu la ca o ia ca a a na Sa le ru at r ad il tin Gu ado gu m ic a liv az i ai Pe Ch ya em ex a, Ve nid na n ra m Bo Br el lv ge M Pa Ja zu i Tr Ar Ni ne El Before private sector participation After private sector participation Source: Andrés and others 2008. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 57 Figure 3.16 Number of Employees in the Fixed-Line Telecommunication Sector before, during, and after Private Sector Participation 150 Number of employees 100 50 –5 0 5 Time Peru Brazil Venezuela, RB Trinidad Jamaica El Salvador Bolivia Panama Chile Argentina Guyana All Mexico analysis found that during the transition, the annual growth rate of employment was 4.1 ­ percentage points lower than during the previous period; annual growth fell an additional 2.6 percentage points after the transition. One reason for the decline in employment during the transition period is that governments decided to trim the labor force before the ownership change, with the intention of increasing the value of the firm and bringing ­ employment to a more sustainable level. Investors proved indifferent to these policies, and in the end the value of the firm remained at the same level or even declined when the government applied layoff programs in advance. One explanation is selection issues, which provide incentives for good employees to leave and bad employees to remain with the company (Chong and L ­ ópez-de-Silanes 2003). Two indicators were used to measure labor productivity: connections per employee and minutes per employee. As a consequence of the increase in the output measures and the general negative trend in the number of employees, labor productivity improved substantially, especially after the transition ­ (figure 3.17). Almost all countries in the data set at least doubled labor produc- tivity within five years of reform. The single exception was Panama, which already had relatively high teledensity (at the time of the reform, Panama’s teledensity was 13 percent; teledensity was 3 percent in Nicaragua, 4 percent in ­ Guatemala, and 6 percent in El Salvador).24 According to the econometric analysis, the number of connections per employee increased 35.1 percent during the transition (compared with the pre- transition period) and a whopping 106.9 percent after the transition. The results of the means and medians analysis were even more impressive: the increase dur- ing the transition was 65.6 percent, and the increase after the t ­ransition was 117.9 percent (see appendix table D.4). All changes were statistically significant. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 58 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities Figure 3.17 Labor Productivity in Fixed-Line Telecommunications before, during, and after Private Sector Participation a. Connections per employee 600 Connections per employee 400 200 0 –5 0 5 Time b. Call minutes per employee 400 Call minutes per employee 300 200 100 0 -5 0 5 Time Guyana Argentina Chile Panama Brazil Jamaica Trinidad Bolivia Peru Mexico Venezuela, RB All El Salvador Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. Fewer data were available for minutes per employee, but the econometric percent analysis still found impressive statistically significant improvements: 32.0 ­ during the transition and an additional 92.9 percent after the transition. The means and medians analysis found even larger increases: 43.2 percent during the transition and 117.2 percent after the transition. Controlling for trends dramatically reduces the impact of private sector partici- pation on labor productivity (see appendix D). It is appropriate to look at the changes in trends given the underlying indicators: in the previous sections, it was argued that the output indicators follow natural trends, but the number of employees does not. One way to examine trend changes is through growth rates. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 59 In this case, the annual number of connections per employee rose by 7 percentage points during the transition period and 3.3 percentage points after the transition. Minutes per employee increased 8.5 percentage points during the transition period and registered no additional statistically significant changes during the posttransition period. Actual (not normalized) labor productivity measures show large variance across countries. Brazil is by far the most productive country, with more than 1,000 connections per employee during the posttransition period. The next- closest country, Bolivia, had less than half that number. The number of minutes per employee in Brazil vastly exceeds that of other countries. Prices Three measures of fixed-line telecommunications prices were analyzed, in both dollars and real local currency: the average price of a three-minute local call, the average monthly charge for residential service, and the average charge for install- ing a residential line. The average price of a three-minute local call mainly increased during public ownership. One exception was Chile, which experienced a steep decline in prices leading up to the ownership change. On average, how- ever, prices increased during the first part of the transition, reaching a high point during the last year of public ownership. Prices then began to fall, but not as rapidly as the increases of previous years (figure 3.18). Trends in U.S. dollars and real local currency followed roughly similar patterns, although the 1999 ­ devaluation in Brazil introduced some variation. The econometric analysis found that average prices in both dollars and real local currency for a three-minute call increased roughly 45 percent. There were no significant changes during the posttransition period. The means and medians analysis did not find any statistically significant changes during either period. Monthly charges for residential service increased significantly during and after the transition, in both dollars and real local currency. The changes were largest during the transition: prices rose 75.9 percent in dollars and 62.6 ­ percent in real local currency. After the transition, both dollar and real local currency prices were roughly 22 percent higher than transition levels. The means and medians analysis also increased significantly (see appendix table D.4). Judging from figure 3.18 and the econometric trend analysis, it appears that residential monthly charges experienced an abnormal increase during the transition before returning to a slower rate of growth similar to the pretransition period. The analysis of average installation charges for a residential line produced somewhat mixed results, although the preponderance of evidence suggests that prices declined during the transition and posttransition periods. Panels e and f of figure 3.18 show a big drop in installation charges during the transi- tion and more modest declines after that. The means and medians analysis found a large statistically significant drop during the transition period; the drop during the posttransition period was not significant. The econometric analysis found the reverse: the drop during the transition was not significant, whereas the drop during the posttransition period was significant and roughly Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 60 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities Figure 3.18 Price of a Fixed-Line Telecommunications Service before, during, and after Private Sector Participation a. Price of three-minute call (dollars) 400 Price of three-minute call (dollars) 300 200 100 0 –5 0 5 Time b. Price of three-minute call (real local currency) 250 Price of three-minute call 200 (real local currency) 150 100 50 0 –5 0 5 Time c. Monthly charge for residential service (dollars) 1,000 Monthly charge for residential 800 service (dollars) 600 400 200 0 –5 0 5 Time figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 61 Figure 3.18 Price of a Fixed-Line Telecommunications Service before, during, and after Private Sector Participation (continued) d. Monthly charge for residential service (real local currency) 1,000 Monthly charge for residential service (real local currency) 800 600 400 200 0 –5 0 5 Time e. Price to install residential line (dollars) 600 Price to install residential line (dollars) 400 200 0 –5 0 5 Time f. Price to install residential line (real local currency) 1,000 Price to install residential line 800 (real local currency) 600 400 200 0 –5 0 5 Time Chile Mexico Brazil Argentina El Salvador Peru Venezuela, RB Trinidad Nicaragua All Guyana Panama Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 62 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 25 percent in both dollars and real local currency. There were no significant changes in the growth rate. Service Quality The percentage of incomplete calls was chosen as the most feasible measure of efficiency. Although considerable heterogeneity exists across countries, the aver- age percentage of incomplete calls declined (figure 3.19) Despite a relatively small number of observations, the econometric analysis confirmed that there was a statistically significant drop of 29.7 percent in the posttransition period. Neither the econometric results from the transition period nor the results of the means and medians analysis were statistically significant. Figure 3.19  Quality of Fixed-Line Communications before, during, and after Private Sector Participation a. Percent of incomplete calls 120 Percent of incomplete calls 100 80 60 40 20 –5 0 5 Time b. Quality of call index 300 250 Quality of call index 200 150 100 50 –5 0 5 Time Argentina Brazil Chile All Venezuela, RB Mexico Note: t = 0 is the base year, the last year in which the utility was publicly owned for at least six months. The y-axis is normalized at 100 when t = 0. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 63 The network digitization percentage was selected as a proxy for quality in fixed-line telecommunications. Network digitization increased during the transi- tion and posttransition periods, with the largest increase coming during the tran- sition, not controlling for time trends. The econometric analysis found increases of 36.3 percent during the transition and 58.1 percent after the transition. Similarly, the means and medians analysis found increases of 75.4 percent in the transition and 69.5 percent during the posttransition period. A natural trend is not assumed, but it is still interesting to control for trends and examine growth rate changes. The econometric analysis found that after controlling for firm-specific time trends, there was a statistically significant increase of 4.9 percent during the transition period; there was no significant change after the transition. The econometric growth analysis found a 5.6 ­percentage point decline in the average annual growth rate after the ­ transition but no significant change during the transition. A quality index was created that combines the percentage of completed calls and the share of the network that was digitized. This index steadily increased across all periods. Quality levels after the transition were generally comparable across countries (see figure 3.19). Network digitization increased during both periods, with the largest increase coming during the transition. Summary The change in ownership in the fixed-line telecommunication sector gener- ally increased output and coverage, even after controlling for firm-specific time trends in the sector. Employment fell and labor productivity increased during the transition and posttransition periods; efficiency (the percentage of incomplete calls) improved during the posttransition period. Prices showed mixed results: the price of a local call increased during the transition, residential monthly charges increased in both periods, and installation charges decreased in both periods. Quality—as measured by network digitization—improved. Impact of Contract Design This section deepens the analysis by introducing a number of private sector participation contract and process variables. The variables come from a World Bank data set of nearly 1,000 infrastructure transactions in LAC between 1989 and 2002 (see appendix B). This data set was merged with the data sets containing performance information on utilities in order to identify whether ­ private sector participation characteristics such as the sale method, investor nationality, and award criteria affect the performance variables discussed in previous sections. The main aim of this section is not to advocate a certain type of contract design but to emphasize that private sector participation is not simply a yes-no decision. Indeed, different contract design variables can have different effects on each performance outcome. The results in this section show that, depending on Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 64 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities the priorities of a country, some contract characteristics may be more important than others. There are many reasons to suspect that characteristics of the private sector participation process and regulatory environment would affect firm perfor- mance during and after the transition to private ownership. Large unexplained differences in ­performance across firms were found. For instance, large declines in employment occurred during both the transition and posttransition periods in electricity distribution sector. However, some firms experienced much larger the ­ declines than others. These large performance differences suggest that ­differences in private sector participation procedures or the regulatory environment may have played a significant role. The three sectors were pooled to maximize the amount of variation in the data set.25 (For more details on the data and methodology, see appendix A.26) Results from two time periods are analyzed: changes between the period before the transition to private ownership and the transition period and changes between the transition and posttransition periods. Overall changes are not reported. Rather, the changes shown are relative to the base case for each variable (table 3.2). For instance, when it is reported that the number of connections per 100 households increased from 5.8 to 6.8 when an auction process was used, this change is relative to cases in which auctions were not used—“no auction” being the base case. The effect of contract characteristics can be summarized as follows: • Sale method. Auctions were associated with lower sector employment and higher quality, by fairly large amounts. They were associated with price increases during the transition and price decreases after the transition, as well as reductions in distributional losses after the transition. • Investor nationality. The presence of only foreign investors was associated with a decline in output during both periods, lower coverage during the transition, lower sector employment during the transition, and lower distributional losses after the transition. Average dollar prices seem to have increased during both periods, and prices in real local currency first decreased then increased. When both foreign and local investors were involved, employment fell during both periods, distributional losses fell after the transition, prices in dollars first fell then rose, and quality improved. Table 3.2  Base Case for Regulatory and Contract Variables Category Variable Base case Sale method Auction No auction Investor nationality Foreign only; foreign and local Local only Award criteria Highest price; best investment plan Other criteria Tariff regulation Rate of return; price cap Other regulation Source: Andrés and others 2008. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 65 • Award criteria. When concessions were awarded according to the best invest- ment plan, employment fell substantially during both periods, prices in ­ dollars rose after the transition, and prices in real local currency fell during the transi- tion. When concessions were awarded based on the highest price, the number of connections fell slightly during the transition, coverage first fell slightly then increased, the number of employees fell substantially, and prices in real local currency fell moderately during both periods. • Tariff regulation. Price-cap tariff regulation was associated with slight increases in output and quality and slight declines in sector employment and labor productivity all during the transition. Distributional losses increased after the transition, and prices in real local currency increased during both periods. Rate of return regulation was associated with a moderate increase in the number of connections and a slight increase in coverage during the transition, as well as lower sector employment during both periods. Distributional losses fell after the transition, and prices in dollars first increased then decreased. Three messages emerge from this analysis: • Contract characteristics matter: the way private sector participation pro- cessses are undertaken can create significant performance differences. • Each contract characteristic affects each performance variable differently. A certain contract characteristic could have a positive influence on one per- formance variable and a negative or insignificant impact on another. • Some contract variables have greater impacts than others. Conclusions Private sector participation in LAC was associated with significant improvements in sector performance, including consistent improvements in efficiency and ­ quality and reductions in the workforce. There do not appear to have been significant impacts on output and coverage. Prices tended to increase somewhat, ­ although the picture is highly variable across sectors. The differences between publicly and privately operated distribution utilities showed up primarily with regard to labor productivity, distribution losses, quality of service, and tariffs. Other indicators, such as coverage and operational expendi- tures, were similar in public and private utilities. Although private sector partici- pation had positive effects, the bottom decile of performers in the public utility group underperformed the average private utility, and the bottom decile of per- formers in the private utility group underperformed the average public utility. Both groups of utilities had similar starting values for labor productivity and distribution losses. Following the change in ownership, the performance of the privatized group improved substantially. Labor productivity ended up being twice as high in private utilities. In the case of distribution losses, private utilities Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 66 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities improved their performance 12 percent whereas public utilities saw their perfor- mance deteriorate 5 percent. With regard to continuity of service, both groups started at about 24 interruptions a year. Private utilities reduced this number to about 12, whereas public utilities reduced it to about 19. Similarly, public utili- ties saw the average duration of their outages increase almost 50 percent, com- pared with a reduction of almost 30 percent at private utilities, from similar starting values. The results of private sector participation depend on the way the reform is designed. Key dimensions include sale method, award criteria, nationality of the firm, and details of the subsequent regulatory framework, including the degree of autonomy of any regulatory body and the principles used to set tariffs. Each of these aspects can significantly affect the incentives faced by the private party and, hence, the enterprise behavior reviewed above. Notes 1. This chapter draws heavily on Andrés and others (2008). 2. The four main types of private participation in infrastructure are management and lease contracts, concessions, greenfield projects, and divestitures. In this chapter, the terms private participation in infrastructure and privatization are used interchangeably to cover all four types. 3. An exception is Panama, where only about 40 percent of the population expressed discontent with private sector participation in 1998 (Andrés and others 2007). 4. As shown in the chapter 2, there is significant variation in performance within both groups. The top 10 percent of performers in the public utility group outperformed the average private utility, and the average private utility outperformed the bottom 10 percent of the private utility group. ­ oncession— 5. The transition period is defined as starting two years before the award of the c an approximation of when the reform was announced—and ending one year after the award. The pretransition period or the period before private sector participation refers to the three years before the transition period. The posttransition period or the period after private sector participation refers to the four years after the transition. 6. These increases were statistically significant by both the means and median analysis (appendix table D.1) and the econometric analysis (appendix table D.3). 7. In the rest of the chapter, “average” for a given variable refers to the simple average within the country. 8. Several reasons may account for this decline, as discussed later in this chapter. First, the average consumption per household may have declined, because of the increase in prices. Second, the composition of the average household may have changed. Among households that were not connected after a concession was awarded, most were prob- ably low-income families, with below-average energy consumption. Third, distributional technical and commercial losses may have fallen, reducing the volume of energy sold. 9. These increases were statistically significant in both the means and median analysis (appendix table D.1) and the econometric analysis (appendix table D.3). 10. Statistically significant drops were found by both the means and median analysis (appendix tables D.1 and D.2) and the econometric analysis (appendix table D.3). Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 67 11. The means and medians analysis found similar results: the mean number of employees during the transition was 38 percent lower than before the transition, and the mean number of employees after the transition was 14 percent lower than during the transition (see appendix table D.1). ­ 12. The increases were found to be statistically significant by both the means and median analysis (appendix tables D.1 and D.2) and the econometric analysis (appendix table D.3). 13. All of these declines in interruptions were statistically significant. 14. The means and medians analysis found a 23 percent drop in the duration of interrup- tions between the pretransition and transition periods and a 25 percent drop between the transition and posttransition periods. Both of these declines were statistically significant. The frequency of interruptions fell 26 percent between the pretransition ­ and posttransition periods; no statistically significant change occurred between the transition and posttransition periods (see appendix table D.1). 15. The results for the output, coverage, and labor productivity indicators are reported after controlling for time trends. A natural increase is expected for each of these ­ variables, regardless of whether ownership is public or private. 16. When actual (as opposed to normalized) water connection numbers are considered, Argentina and Chile have the largest water distribution companies. For sewerage, Argentina, Chile, and Colombia have companies of roughly the same size. In contrast, the electricity, water and sewerage companies in Brazil and Mexico fall at the small end of the spectrum (Andrés and others 2008). 17. The only significant result of the means and medians analysis was a drop of roughly 3 percent in the mean amount of water produced between the transition and post- transition periods. 18. Although a natural trend in employment is not expected, the numbers after control- ling for trends are reported in appendix C. 19. As of 2009, only six countries remained with public telecommunications companies: Colombia, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Honduras, Paraguay, and Uruguay. For a description of the data set, see appendix B. 20. Results from the econometric analysis that controls for firm-specific time trends tell a somewhat different story. The number of connections fell 4.9 percent during the transition, then increased 12.0 percent after the transition (with respect to transition levels). This model specification is less useful in this case, however, given the fluctuat- ing nature of the underlying data. 21. The means and medians analysis did not find a statistically significant difference between the pretransition and transition periods. Based on two observations, the analysis found that the average number of minutes was 40 percent higher during the posttransition period than during the transition period (see appendix table D.4). 22. The econometric analysis that controlled for firm-specific time trends found that coverage fell 6.3 percent during the transition and then increased 9.5 percent during the posttransition period. This model specification may be less applicable, however, given the shape of the underlying data (that is, the time trend analysis becomes less accurate when there is more than one shift in the presumed trend). 23. The means and medians analysis found that employment fell 14.5 percent during the transition and 18.2 percent more after the transition. All of these changes were statis- tically significant. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 68 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 24. Panama actually had more connections in 1998 than in 2003. In 1998, 419,000 subscribers had fixed connections; at the end of 2003, only 380,000 had fixed con- ­ nections. Not surprisingly, mobile telecommunications proliferated during this time. In fact, the number of mobile subscribers surpassed the number of fixed-line subscribers, jumping from 49,000 in 1998 to 834,000 in 2003 (ITU 2004). ­ 25. The models were run for each sector separately (these tables are available upon request); results were qualitatively similar to the results presented here (see Andrés and others 2008 for details). 26. The econometric analysis included several regression specifications using different combinations of independent variables (that is, for each performance variable, the impact of each contract variable was tested while controlling for different combina- tions of other contract variables). Controlling for other contract variables addresses collinearity issues, but it tends to reduce the number of statistically significant results. Multiple regression specifications can also produce a range of results. For this reason, the following sections mention either a range of impacts or mixed results. Andrés and others (2008) report the minimum and maximum percentage changes in each perfor- mance variable disaggregated by the contract variables. References Andrés, L., V. Foster, and J. L. Guasch. 2006. “The Impact of Privatization on the Performance of the Infrastructure Sector: The Case of Electricity Distribution in Latin American Countries.” Policy Research Working Paper 3936, World Bank, Washington, DC. Andrés, L., J. L. Guasch, M. Diop, and S. L. Azumendi. 2007. “Assessing the Governance of Electricity Regulatory Agencies in the Latin American and the Caribbean Region: A Benchmarking Analysis.” Policy Research Working Paper 4380, World Bank, Washington, DC. Andrés, L., J. L. Guasch, V. Foster, and T. Haven. 2008. The Impact of Private Sector Participation in Infrastructure: Lights, Shadows, and the Road Ahead. Washington, DC: World Bank. Boix, C. 2005. “Privatization and Public Discontent in Latin America.” Background paper commissioned for Marianne Fay and Mary Morrison, 2007, Infrastructure in Latin America and the Caribbean: Recent Developments and Key Challenges. Directions in Development. Washington, DC: World Bank. Briceño-Garmendia, C., A. Estache, and N. Shafik. 2004. “Infrastructure Services in Developing Countries: Access, Quality, Costs and Policy Reform.” Policy Research Working Paper 3468, World Bank, Washington, DC. Calderón, C., and L. Servén. 2004. “The Effects of Infrastructure Development on Growth and Income Distribution.” Policy Research Working Paper 3400, World Bank, Washington, DC. Chong, A., and F. López-de-Silanes. 2003. “The Truth about Privatization in Latin America.” Latin American Research Network, Research Network Working Paper R-486, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, DC. De Ferranti, D., G. E. Perry, F. H. G. Ferreira, and M. Walton. 2004. Inequality in Latin America: Breaking with History? Washington, DC: World Bank. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Understanding the Impact of Private Sector Participation on the Performance of Utilities 69 Fay, M., and M. Morrison. 2006. Infrastructure in Latin America and the Caribbean: Recent Developments and Key Challenges. Washington, DC: World Bank. Harris, C. 2003. “Private Participation in Infrastructure in Developing Countries: Trends, Impacts and Policy Lessons.” Working Paper 5, World Bank, Washington, DC. ITU (International Telecommunications Union). 2008. “World Telecommunication/ICT Indicators Database.” CD-Rom, 12th edition. Geneva: ITU. ______. 2009. “World Telecommunication/ICT Indicators Database.” Geneva. Martimort, D., and S. Straub. 2005. “The Political Economy of Private Participation, Social Discontent and Regulatory Governance.” Background paper commissioned for Marianne Fay and Mary Morrison, 2007, Infrastructure in Latin America and the Caribbean: Recent Developments and Key Challenges. Directions in Development. Washington, DC: World Bank. Ros, A. 1999. “Does Ownership or Competition Matter? The Effects of Telecommunications Reform on the Network Expansion and Efficiency.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 15 (1): 65–92. Schwartz, J., L. Andrés, and G. Dragoiu. 2009. “Crisis in Latin America: Infrastructure Investment, Employment and the Expectations of Stimulus,” Journal of Infrastructure Development 1(2) (December): 111–31. World Bank. 2007. Private Participation in Infrastructure Projects: PPP Database. Washington, DC. http://ppi.worldbank.org/. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Chapter 4 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance This chapter explores the governance of independent regulatory agencies (IRAs) in the water and electricity distribution sectors and the link between governance of IRAs and the performance of both sectors. The first part of the the ­ chapter analyzes the institutional design of regulatory agencies. It compares the different governance modes of IRAs based on various measures of autonomy, transparency, accountability, and tools. Measures of agencies’ governance are the result of both formal and informal practices of IRAs. The second part of the chapter describes the methodology and presents the results on the ­correlation between institutional design and sector performance. The analysis first focuses on the institutional design of IRAs. It attempts to determine the inputs or characteristics that contribute to greater autonomy and accountability. The presence of these features does not, of course, guarantee that either autonomy or accountability improves. The second phase of this work involves the application of techniques used in qualitative comparative politics to address issues of causality, sequencing, and complex interaction effects that better explain IRAs in policy making. The approach is used to capture aspects of the governance of IRAs that can be assessed against sector performance. Most of the literature on the governance of IRAs in Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC) has been conducted with the goal of comparing countries in the region in terms of formal attributes of IRAs. Analysis of causality is at best limited. IRAs are more widespread in LAC than in other developing regions (Sosay and Zenginobuz 2005). Created within the context of wide private sector participation ­programs, they were the chosen institutional arrangement to insulate decision making in various economic sectors, such as infrastructure, from political ­ intervention (Thatcher 2007). After the unbundling of the electricity industry, regulatory agencies were assigned the task of enforcing concession contracts and protecting consumers. Between 1993 (when Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   71   72 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance Argentina established the National Electricity Regulatory Agency) and 2001 (when Barbados ­ established the Fair Trading Commission), 70 percent of the countries in the region established separate entities regulating electricity mar- kets, with different degrees of i ­ndependence (Andrés and others 2007). There is a growing consensus that institutions matter for growth and development (Aron 2000; Rodrick 2004). This chapter emphasizes the positive ­ independent externalities associated with the presence and good governance of an ­ regulatory agency. Benchmarking Benchmarking Regulatory Institutional Design Studies of regulatory agencies in the infrastructure sector have considered the U.S. model of independent commissions as their benchmark of comparison and analysis. An institutional design model that emphasizes agencies that make decisions independently of the executive branch, are subject to the accountability ­ of the parliament, and have budgeting autonomy has emerged as the paradigm of an infrastructure regulator. The literature has dealt with the design of regulatory agencies in two ways: by focusing only on independence and by considering accountability and trans- parency as well. The first attempts to evaluate infrastructure regulatory agencies assessed the independence of central banks (Stern and Cubbin 2005; Oliveira and others 2005). For this reason, the original emphasis was on ­ agencies’ inde- pendence; less attention was paid to other aspects, such as accountability and transparency. The evolution of the subject and the initial stages of agencies’ functioning changed the original approach and introduced more comprehensive strategies to assessment. A different approach (OECD 1999) involves the consideration of mechanisms to achieve high-quality regulation, such as cost-benefit analysis of regulations and administrative simplification. Stern and Holder (1999) develop a framework for assessing the governance of economic regulators in several sectors in six developing Asian economies. Gilardi (2002) develops an independence index covering regulators from five sectors in seven European countries. He also proposes three ways of evaluating ­ independent regulators. Johannsen (2003) measures the formal independence of energy ­regulators in eight European countries. Gutiérrez (2003) develops a regulatory framework to assess the evolution of regulatory governance in the telecommunications sector between 1980 and 2001 in 25 LAC countries. They attempt to measure informal regulation. Three comprehensive approaches to assessing the governance of regulatory agencies have been developed by Brown and others (2006), Correa and others (2006), and Andrés and others (2007). Correa and others provide a detailed analysis of Brazilian regulatory agencies. Brown and others develop a framework to assess the effectiveness of a regula- tory system. Andrés and others develop a framework for LAC that is discussed more in detail in this chapter. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance 73 This chapter defines regulatory governance as the institutional design and structure of the agency that allows it to carry out its functions as an independent regulator. Based on selected literature on the subject, the chapter defines and assesses regulatory agencies’ governance according to four main characteristics: autonomy from political authorities and autonomy of their management and regulatory competencies; transparency before institutional and noninstitutional stakeholders; accountability to the three branches of government (executive, legislative, and judiciary); and tools and capacities for the conduct of the ­regulatory policy and the improvement of its institutional development. The governance of IRAs is measured by a main aggregated index and other indexes covering different aspects of governance.1 Indexes were built with data from a survey completed by 19 countries of the electricity distribution and water and sanitation sectors.2 Responses from the survey covered 43 electricity and 28 water regulatory agencies, which cover more than 90 percent of consumers in the region. All LAC countries except Chile and Colombia have introduced regulatory agencies in which the agency has both regulatory and oversight ­ responsibilities, with different degrees of independence from the government.3 Regulatory agencies are viewed here as both public bodies that are part of the public administration (and as such in charge of the delivery of public services) and instruments with which to implement regulatory policies. The analysis therefore draws on both the literature on infrastructure agencies’ designs and ­ notions and tools of public sector governance applied to decentralized structures of government. Figure 4.1 presents the framework used to assess the governance of IRAs. Only an institutional perspective of accountability, as defined by the relation- ships of the agency with the executive, legislative, and judiciary branches of government, is considered. Autonomy is divided into political, managerial, and regulatory autonomy; transparency is divided into social and institutional transparency; and tools are divided into regulatory and institutional tools. Variables for agencies’ governance reflect not only formal aspects (proce- dures and tools established in the agency’s statute or laws) but also the practices that derive from their implementation (informal regulation). Indicators for the informal elements of autonomy, accountability, and transparency represent the operationalization of some aspects of these variables. The variable “tools” is excluded from this analysis, because the mere existence of these instruments implies their implementation. The first variable of agencies’ regulatory governance is autonomy, defined as the procedures, mechanisms, and instruments aimed at guaranteeing the independence of the agency from political authorities (political autonomy), the ­ autonomous management of its resources (managerial autonomy), and the ­regulation of the sector (regulatory autonomy). Political autonomy repre- sents the level of independence of the agency from government authorities. It is measured by indicators that reflect the autonomy of the agency’s decision making. Managerial autonomy involves the freedom of the agency to determine ­ the administration of its resources. It is measured by indicators that reflect Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 74 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance Figure 4.1  Framework for Assessing Governance of Independent Regulatory Agencies Autonomy: Transparency: Political Social regulatory institutional managerial Formal/informal Formal/informal aspects of regulation aspects of regulation Selected variables and dimensions of electricity agencies, governance No distinction between Formal/informal formal and informal aspects aspects of regulation of regulation is made Accountability Tools: (No distinction between Regulatory formal and informal aspects institutional of regulation is made) Source: Andrés and others 2007. the powers of the agency to determine its organizational structure and the use of its budget. Regulatory autonomy is defined by the extension of the agency’s regulatory powers in the electricity sector. It is represented by indicators that capture agencies’ responsibilities in electricity regulation. The second aspect of an agency’s governance is accountability, defined as the procedures, mechanisms, and instruments aimed at guaranteeing an adequate level of control of the agency’s budget and performance by political authorities (the parliament). The accountability of the agency before the parliament is ­ prioritized for two reasons. First, the institutional design model adopted is that of a U.S. independent commission, where agencies are subject to congressional oversight. Second, the history of political interference of LAC line ministries in utilities underscores the importance of including other political stakeholders, such as the parliament, in the regulatory process. An institutional perspective of accountability is considered only as defined by the relationships of the agency with the three branches of government (executive, legislative, and judiciary); the variable is further disaggregated. The third variable is transparency, defined as the procedures, mechanisms, and instruments aimed at guaranteeing the disclosure and publication of relevant regulatory and institutional information, the participation of stakeholders in the agency’s regulatory decisions and decision making, and the application of rules aimed at governing the integrity and behavior of agency officials. Two dimensions Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance 75 of transparency are examined: social transparency and institutional transparency. Social transparency is composed of indicators related to the involvement of noninstitutional actors in the agency’s policy making, including their access to ­ the agency’s information. Institutional transparency is composed of indicators related to the transparent management of the agency that are not directly linked to stakeholder involvement. It includes issues such as the publication of the agency’s annual report, the use of norms of ethics, and the existence of public examinations for hiring employees. The fourth variable is tools, defined as the instruments and mechanisms that contribute to the strengthening of different aspects of an agency’s ­ functioning and the quality of its regulations. This variable includes not only regulatory tools (for example, mechanisms for tariff revision, regulatory accountability, and instruments for monitoring technical standards) but also instruments aimed at improving the institutional quality of the agency (for example, audits of agencies’ accounts, electronic files for consumer ­ complaints, performance-based payments for employees, and regulatory quality standards). This is the only variable whose analysis does not consider ­ its formal and informal aspects; the mere existence of agencies’ tools implies their implementation. Benchmarking Governance at the Regional Level LAC presents a wide spectrum of institutional design in its regulatory agencies. A regional analysis of regulatory governance indicates the prevalence of autonomy over the other variables, with tools as the index’s component with the ­ lowest score. Most independent regulators in the electricity sector have a board of directors appointed by the president with the authorization of the parliament, a separate status from the line ministry, and separate budgeting (although there are different levels of autonomy in the management of funds). The lowest levels of autonomy can be found in agencies in charge of both regulation and sector planning, where the government, through the line minister and other ministers, is part of the agency’s decision-making process. The top ranking of the autonomy variable and the lower scores given to transparency and institutional and regulatory tools might be explained by the lack of progress in improving the institutional quality of the agencies (­represented in the Infrastructure Regulatory Governance Index [IRGI] by several components of the transparency and tools variables). With some exceptions, the process that started with the creation of regulatory agencies has not been expanded or improved. For instance, few agencies publicize their job openings or have developed public examinations for hiring employees. On the tools side, few agencies use regulatory quality standards (such as cost- benefit analysis to assess the impact of regulations) or performance-based payment of employees. Figure 4.2 presents the distribution of the aggregated index for each sector. Agencies in the electricity sector show better performance than agencies in the water sector, not only in the general indexes but also in specific measures. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 76 Tr Tr in in id id ad Index (0–1) ad Index (0–1) an an d d 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 T 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 To Co oba ba lo go T 1 go m – b R Br ia– IC T Pe az CR Br ru il– A 1 az – A Br il– SU GR az AG N il A Bo Br ENE SS liv Br az R ia az il– SA i A El P e Co B l–A RC Source: World Bank 2008 and World Bank 2009. st ra GE E Sa ru lv a R zi RS Gu do a ica l–A A at r Br –ER GER em a Ar ala Ba zil– SAP ge rb AR S nt Br ado SA Ba ina az s L r il– –F b a A T Do m Br DA C Co dos Ho B azi SA in l ica om n Figure 4.2  Aggregated Index of Regulatory Governance nd raz l–A ur il– TR Re bia as AM pu Pa –E A ra RS E Ni bli gu AP ca c a S ra b. Water sector Br y–E Co gua a. Electricity sector az R T2 st i S aR Pa l–A SA n GE N Ur ica Br ama RG ug az – S ua il A M y Ar Bra –AR SEP ex ge zi SA ic l– Ja o A ntin AG M m Ar rge a– ES ai ge nt ER C Pa ca nt ina SA na in –E C m Ar a ge Bra –EN RAS a nt zi RE Ar ina l–A SS T2 ge – R Ec nt ERS SA ua in P E Ho do a– yO ER C nd r SA ur CT as Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance 77 Box 4.1 Multiagency Regulatory Schemes Agencies included in the index are agencies that exhibit a design similar to that of a formal inde- pendent regulator. Although several agencies embody the institutional patterns of a f ­ ormal IRA, the region’s most salient characteristic is a board composed of independent m ­ embers. Members appointed to the board should not be government ministers, state ­ secretaries, or other officials whose autonomy could be compromised by holding a policy-­ formulation position. Chile’s National Energy Commission (NEC) does not follow these criteria. Its board is ­composed of the ministers of mining, finance, defense, and planning and the secretary general of the presidency. This circumstance makes Chile a stand-alone case incomparable to the other IRAs. Moreover, tariffs in Chile are not determined by the NEC but by the minister of finance, the only authority that approves electricity tariffs in the country. Regulatory competencies in Chile are complemented by the Superintendencia de Electricidad y Combustibles, which is responsible for the enforcement of regulations as well as quality and technical standards. Colombia and the Dominican Republic have similar institutional designs. These cases were nevertheless included in the analysis, for several reasons. The board of Colombia’s National Energy and Gas Regulatory Commission includes five independent experts, who balance the influence of public sector officials, such as the ministers of mining and energy, finance, and the national director for planning. Moreover, the country’s score is the result of the combination of the complementary roles of the Regulatory Commission (in charge of the main economic regulation responsibilities) and the Superintendencia de Servicios Publicos Domiciliarios (responsible for enforcing standards and regulations). In the Dominican Republic, only the Superintendencia de Electricidad was included, because it is the only electricity regulator with policy-formulation responsibility. Benchmarking Governance at the Agency Level Agencies were grouped into three tiers based on their performance on several indicators (figure 4.3). Tier 1 encompasses agencies that have conditions ­ conducive to developing good regulatory governance. The responses of agencies in this tier are similar to the highest value for each survey question. Tier 2 encom- passes agencies that meet only the minimum conditions considered necessary to implement the independent regulator model. Agencies in this tier have fewer responsibilities than agencies in Tier 1 and lower levels of autonomy from the line minister. They also have fewer sophisticated mechanisms for publishing their decisions and policies. Tier 3 includes agencies that do not meet the ­ minimum conditions to implement the benchmark model of regulatory governance. Consistent with the regional analysis, autonomy is the variable with the highest score for Tier 2 and Tier 3 countries. Bolivia’s Superintendencia de ­ Electricidad,4 Nicaragua’s Comisión Nacional de Energía, and the Dominican Republic’s Superintendencia de Electricidad have the highest scores. The variable with the third-highest score is accountability. Trinidad and Tobago’s Regulated Industries Commission has the highest score. The main difference between the best and worst performers in accountability is greater Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 78 Tr in id Index (0–1) ad Index (0–1) 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 an d 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Do Bo To ba m l in Nica ivia go ica r n agu Gu Re at T1 pu a em bl al ic a Pe Br ru az Bo il B Ar raz Ba livia ge il rb El nti El ad Sa na Sa os lv Do lv ad m a Tr or in Co dor ica om l in id Co n ad s T1 Re bia an ta R pu d i bl To ca ic ba Pe Ba go r rb M u ad e Pa os Ni xic ca o n r Gu am a. Autonomy Co agu at a st a em b. Accountability a Ur ala Ar Ric ug ge a u nt Ja ay in m a ai Ur T M ca Figure 4.3 Indicators of Regulatory Governance in Electricity Distribution ex ug 2 Ho ic u nd o Ec ay u ua d Ec ras ua Ja or m do Ho ica r nd a Co T u lo 2 Pa ras m na bi m a a figure continues next page Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Index (0–1) Tr in Gu id ad Index (0–1) 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 at an em d 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 al To a b Br ag Ar az o ge il El nt Source: World Bank 2008. Sa T1 in a lv ad Pe or Ja ru m Pe r ai M u ca Tr ex in Co ico id T1 lo ad Bo m bi an d liv a To ia Bo ba liv go ia Ur Do Br ug m C a Co uay in ost zil ica a lo n R Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance El mb Re ica Sa ia pu lv a Ba blic Ni do rb ca r ra a Ar dos Co gua ge d. Tools/capacity st nt i c. Transparency aR Ba ica Ur na rb ug Do ad u m os Ja ay ni P a m ca na Ni aica n m ca Re a r pu Gu agu Figure 4.3 Indicators of Regulatory Governance in Electricity Distribution (continued) bl at a ic em al a Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Ec T2 ua do T Ho Pa 2 nd r na ur m as Ec a M ua ex Ho dor ico nd ur as 79 80 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance obligations to the executive by weak performers. Countries at the top of the aggregated measure of regulatory governance, except Bolivia and Peru, have a more balanced distribution of obligations between the executive and the ­ parliament and are not fully accountable to the executive. In contrast, countries at the bottom of this distribution are heavily dependent on the executive, to which they are, in most cases, fully accountable. The variable with the third-highest score is transparency. Trinidad and Tobago’s Regulated Industries Commission has the highest score; Honduras’ Comisión Nacional de Energía has the lowest score. Differences in scores between best and worst performers are narrower than for other measures (an exception is Ecuador among the worst performers). Both best and worst performers have collective decision-making structures, mechanisms to allow par- ticipation of stakeholders in rule-making processes, and adequate mechanisms to report their activities to the required institutions and to publish their annual reports. The only area in which the poorly performing countries have lower scores is public consultations. The variable with the lowest score is tools. This variable captures not only tools related to the application of the agencies’ regulatory policies such as ­benchmarking or the methodology for tariff revision but also instruments aimed at improving institutional and managerial quality (for example, the publication of the agency’s annual report or the use of performance-based payments). Guatemala’s Comisión Nacional de Energía Eléctrica has the highest ranking. Honduras’ Comisión Nacional de Energía and Mexico’s Comisión Nacional Reguladora de Energía have the lowest scores for this variable. The main factors that explain the differ- ences between best and worst performers in terms of the tools variable are the use of benchmarking, the extent and number of regulatory instruments, the publica- utilization of tion of the agency’s annual report, the registration of users’ claims, the ­ regulatory quality standards, and the existence of a structure of posts and salaries. Differences between IRAs in water and electricity are wider in informal transparency, formal accountability, tools, regulatory autonomy, social transpar- ­ ency, regulatory tools, and institutional tools. Although it might be expected to have higher scores in most of the indicators in the electricity sector than in the water sector, it could also be expected to have better results in the water sector in aspects where the sector is considered to be stronger, such as social public involvement in rule making. In fact, the measure of social transparency shows one of the largest differences, with average scores in countries above Tier 1 higher in the electricity than in the water sector. Similar results are seen in informal transparency (figure 4.4). Factors Accounting for Differences in Governance This section disaggregates the variables. Autonomy is broken down into political, managerial, and regulatory autonomy; transparency into social and institutional transparency; and tools into regulatory and institutional tools. Accountability considers only an institutional perspective regarding Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Tr in id Br ad az Index (0–1) an Tr il– d Index (0–1) in B B 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 To id ra ra ADA ba ad zil zi S g a –A l–A A 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Co Bra o–R Co nd T GE GE lo zil IC st ob NE R m –A a R a RS Br bi G ica go A az a– R –E –RI il– CR A A RS C AP Ba GE T Br S rb NE 1 a Br ad R Pe zil– T az o SA ru AR 1 il– s– F Br –SU SA a L Br AG TC E Br zil– NA Br azil RS az A SS az –A A il– E G Co il– G B st ra AR ER Br AGE SC a R zi SA a R ica l–A L Br zil– SA –E RC B Pa ar il– C az AR RS E ra ba AM E AP gu do A B S ay s– E Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance P Pa e az T r Ho Pan –ER FTC ra ru– il– 2 n a S gu S AT Ar du ma SAN ay UN R ge ras –A nt –E SE Br –ER ASS in RS P a S a A Br zil– SA Ar Bra –EN PS a. Autonomy az A N ge zil– RE Br il–A MA nt A SS az D E in RS P a– AM b. Accountability Ho an il–A ASA E Figure 4.4 Indicators of Regulatory Governance in Water Distribution nd am RS B Co ra RS ur a– AM lo zil AC a A m –A Br s–E SE bi G a R P a R Ar Bra zil– SAP Br Bra –CR ge zil AG S az zi A il– l–A Ar n –A ES g AG TR en Ar tina GE C R ER t Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 A ge –E G in GS a– E Ar rge ntin RSA S ge nt a– CT Ar B T2 RS P nt ina ER ge raz in – A nt il– yO C a– ER S Ar ina AR Ar B ER SA ge –E SA ge raz SP C nt RS E nt il– yO in AC in AR C a– T a– S ER EN AE AS RE SS figure continues next page 81 82 Br az Index (0–1) Pe Index (0–1) ru– Co il–A Tr 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 lo GE in SU Ho m R id NA bi GS ad Co SS nd a– an lom Br ra u C d bi T az s– RA To a– 1 il– E T ba C AG RS 1 g R Source: World Bank 2009. A Br o– A a Tr Br EN PS z Br il– RIC in P az ER az A il– GR id B eru il–A SA ad r –S R B A an azil UN CE Co Br ra RC d –A A st azi zil– E a R l– A A To G SS i A TR Co rge ba ERS Br ca– DAS st nt go– A az ER A a in R Ri a– IC il S ca E Br –AG APS –E RA az E il R Br RS S Br –AR SA az AP Br il– S B r Ho az zil SAL a a A nd il– –AG Br zil– GR ur AG E Ba azil AG as ER R rb –A ER Br Br –ER GS ad M az az SA o A il– il– P Br s– E S Br az FT Ba AGE AM a il C rb NE AE Br zil– –AT ad R az AG R os SA c. Transparency Ar –F d. Tools/capacity Br il–A ESC ge TC a R nt Ar Pa zil– SAM P Pa an na T2 i ge na AR ra am –E nt ma SA in – L Ar gua a– RAS Br a–E ASE ge y– AS az N P nt ER EP il– RE i S Pa Figure 4.4 Indicators of Regulatory Governance in Water Distribution (continued) AD SS Br na– SA ra az ER N g AS Ar ua ge y– A Ar Br il–A SA ge az RS C nt ER T2 nt il– AM Ar i n S i A ge Br a–E SAN Ar B na– GE nt azi RS ge ra EN SC Ar ina l–A AC Ar ntin zil– RES ge –E R ge a AR S nt RS SA nt –ER SA in P E in S E a– yO a– Py ER C ER O SA SA C CT CT Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance 83 relationships between the agency and the other branches of government; the ­ no further division is made of its indicators. Political Autonomy Political autonomy measures the independence of the agency’s decision ­ making from the authorities in charge of policy formulation (namely, the line minister). It includes the mechanism for selecting agencies’ directors, the renewability of directors’ mandates, the number of directors who have not completed their terms, the reasons why directors leave their positions, the interference of the minister in the agency’s decisions, and the composition of the agency’s budget. The number of countries with Tier 3 agencies is larger for this variable than for any other (see appendix E). Only Brazil is in Tier 1. Tier 3 countries represent a wide variety of agencies. The scores of best performers are significantly differ- ent from countries at the bottom of that index. Regulatory agencies in Brazil, the Dominican Republic, and Bolivia have a separate status from the line ministry, separate roles for the agency and government authorities, and a budget ­ composed exclusively of a regulation tax charged to electricity distribution com- panies. Directors leave mostly because of retirement, voluntary leave, or the completion of their appointments; the line minister has a low level of influence over the agency’s affairs, according to sources at the agency. In contrast, agencies at the bottom of this ranking have no autonomy from the line minister. The sector ministry is part of the agencies and chairs their boards; their budgets are composed exclusively of government funds, without any type of income from companies (regulation tax). Managerial Autonomy Managerial autonomy involves the freedom of the agency to determine the use of its budget and the organization of its resources. It includes aspects such as the ability of the agency to determine its organizational structure, the freedom to make its own decisions on personnel, the autonomy to determine its own expenses, and the type of legal regime that applies to its employees (private law, civil service law, or both). It also includes other aspects related to tools that contribute to improving its management, such as the existence of its own ­ structure of posts and salaries and performance-based payment of employees. ­ Argentina, Barbados, Brazil, Guatemala, Jamaica, Peru, and Trinidad and Tobago have desirable conditions to manage their resources. Agencies in these countries have adequate mechanisms and procedures to guarantee an autono- mous administration of the agency by its authorities. In contrast, agencies in Colombia and Honduras have less managerial freedom to determine their organizational structure or the use of their resources. Results in this section are not an indication of the effectiveness of the agency’s management but of powers aimed at allowing the agency an autonomous administration. Countries at the top of the distribution have full powers in all the aspects mentioned in the first paragraph of this section. Brazil is among the leading countries in managerial autonomy. ­ Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 84 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance Regulatory Autonomy Regulatory autonomy includes characteristics such as responsibility for regulation of the sector (the agency, parliament, the executive, or some combi- ­ nation of the three); the type of powers (consultative, oversight, pricing, and rule making); responsibilities regarding particular issues (tariffs, service quality, consumer complaints, companies’ investment plans, wholesale market, anti- competitive behavior, technical standards); and powers to enforce its decisions. Most countries in the region are in Tier 1; only four are in Tier 3. Countries with desirable conditions in regulatory autonomy have full responsibilities for tariffs, service quality, standards, and investments, as well as the power to imple- ment sanctions and regulations. In contrast, countries that do not meet the minimum requirements in terms of the extension of their regulatory prerogatives ­ have little responsibility for specific regulatory issues and no power to enforce regulations. The changes experienced by regulatory agencies in political versus regulatory autonomy explain the importance of linking political independence to the expansion of agencies’ regulatory powers. An agency can have the highest level of independence from political authorities but no relevant power in the regulation of the sector, making independence an abstract characteristic of the ­ agency’s functioning with no real impact on regulation. The same conclusion was observed in an assessment of European electricity regulators, which found that even if regulatory agencies shared the same regulatory objectives, there were significant variations in the means the regulators had to pursue those objectives (Johannsen 2003). Social Transparency The social aspects of transparency are related to the involvement of stakeholders in the agency’s decision-making and rule-making processes and their access to the agency’s information. Social transparency includes the participation of ­ stakeholders in the agency’s rule-making process, the publication by the agency of its decisions, the organization by the agency of public consultations, the existence of advisory committees in the agency’s structure, the existence of a ­ website, and the registration of users’ claims. Agencies’ positions in social trans- parency are presented in appendix E. This standard of governance is headed by Trinidad and Tobago, followed by Colombia, the Dominican Republic, Peru, El Salvador, and Bolivia. Differences between countries at the top and bottom of social transparency center on three main aspects. The first aspect is the participation of the stake- holders in the agency’s rule-making process. Although public consultations or public hearings are aimed at allowing the involvement of stakeholders in the agency’s main ­ decisions, the rule-making process is the mechanism through which regulatees are invited to contribute their opinions in the elaboration of the agency’s ­ regulations. In contrast to countries at the top, countries at bottom of the distribution either lack provisions to involve stakeholders the ­ Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance 85 in the rule-making process or have provisions but fail to involve stakeholders in that process. The second aspect is the existence of advisory committees integrated by ­ different stakeholders in the structures of best performing agencies. These committees are supposed to play an important role in the agency’s decision making by representing and promoting different interest groups (mainly consumers). The third aspect is the registration of users’ claims. Best-performing agencies register consumer claims through both paper-based and electronic mechanisms, allowing faster resolution of the cases and easier access to files by regulatees (both at the agency and through the website). Institutional Transparency Institutional transparency is composed of indicators related to the transparent management of the agency that are not directly linked to involvement of stake- holders. It includes aspects such as the nature of the agency’s decision making (collective or individual), the existence of quarantine rules for directors, the agency’s reporting instruments (annual report and public hearing before parlia- ment), the publication of the agency’s institutional strategy and annual report, the publication of the agency’s audit accounts and job openings, the existence of norms of ethics, the record of the board’s meetings, and the use of public examinations to hire employees. Several factors place agencies at the top of the index. The first factor is related to the existence of collective decision making by a board of directors. As opposed to a single decision-making structure, a board composed of directors with varied technical backgrounds allows for more comprehensive ­ and diverse debates on regulatory issues than a decision made by a single policy maker. The second factor is related to the publication of information such as job vacancies, an annual report, an institutional strategy, and audited accounts. The third factor is a record of the board’s meetings and the existence of quarantine rules for directors who leave the agency. ­ Agencies with good institutional transparency tend to possess characteristics related to administrative modernization. For instance, publication of the ­ organization’s institutional strategy, annual report, and job vacancies are indica- tors of agencies concerned not only with sector-based policies related to trans- parency (such as the conducting of public hearings) but also with mechanisms and procedures aimed at making them more effective as administrative bodies. Accountability Accountability was not disaggregated. Its indicators represent different institu- tional elements (for example, reporting obligations to the executive and the parliament and the ability to appeal its decisions before the executive and the judiciary) of the agency’s relationships with the executive, the legislative, and the judiciary. Hence, the institutional aspect of agencies’ accountability design is considered. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 86 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance Regulatory Tools More than three-quarters of the regulatory agencies in the region (78 percent) use benchmarking, mainly to determine tariffs; a smaller percentage of coun- tries have the full complement of tools listed in the survey. Many countries are in Tier 1, reflecting the importance LAC agencies give to the development of ­ several tools to implement their regulatory decisions. Brazil, El Salvador, Guatemala, and Peru lead the countries in Tier 1. Leading countries in this dimension make use not only of benchmarking but also of tools to conduct regulatory policies, such as a database for regulatory accountability, a method- ology for tariff revision, a ­methodology for annual tariff readjustment, instru- ments for monitoring quality and technical standards, a methodology for monitoring technical standards, a methodology for defining interconnection tariffs, and five-year revisions of these tools. Most countries in the region have developed specific ­ ­ onsumers’ rights. legislation to regulate c Institutional Tools The region shows better performance in regulatory than in institutional tools. There are large disparities between countries at the top and the bottom of this measure. Top performers use certain regulatory quality standards tools (­cost-benefit analysis, regulatory impact analysis, and administrative simplification) as well as performance-based payment of their employees; ­ ­ publish both annual reports and institutional strategies; and, with the exception of Peru, have a structure in place for posts and salaries. In contrast, weak performers lack ­ ­ regulatory quality standards, do not offer incentives to their employees, and have not developed institutional strategies. In addition, the reg- consumer complaints is facilitated through paper-based mechanisms istration of ­ rather than electronically. Regulatory Governance and Sector Performance This section combines the data on infrastructure agencies’ governance with data collected at the company level to assess the impact of regulatory agencies on utility performance. This work fills a gap in the literature on the subject, as ­ previous attempts to interrelate agency governance and utility performance focused on a limited number of factors, narrowing the scope and explanatory potential of the research.5 The analysis assesses the relationship between two strands of literature. The first is related to the impact of private sector participation on sector performance. The second is related to measuring the governance of regulatory agencies. Little is known about the relationship between the two. A few papers focus on the relationship between regulatory characteristics and performance. Sirtaine and others (2004) create a regulatory quality index based on three key aspects of regulatory quality: legal solidity, financial strength, and decision-making autonomy. Despite their small sample sizes, three of the four models show that the regulatory quality variables are Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance 87 statistically significant and explain 20–25 percent of the internal rate of return of private investment in infrastructure projects in LAC. Estache and Rossi (2008) explore the causal relation between the establishment of a regu- latory agency and the performance of the electricity distribution sector. They analyze a unique dataset comprising firm-level information on a representa- tive sample of 220 electric utilities from 51 developing countries and transi- tion economies between 1985 and 2005. Their results indicate that regulatory agencies are associated with more efficient firms and higher consumer welfare. The analysis presented here is based on unique databases (for descriptions, see appendix B). It merges the performance data described in chapter 2 with the regulatory governance analyzed in this chapter. Every country except Colombia was matched with its own regulatory agency (Colombia was assigned only one score, because it has two different agencies with regulatory functions). The following sections describe the results with different specifications.6 Existence of a Regulatory Agency A dummy was defined with a value equal to one starting in the year when the regulatory agency was established.7 Two specifications were run. The first ran the ownership dummies and the dummy for the existence of a regulatory agency (see appendix table F.1). These specifications allowed for the identification of the impact of ownership after controlling for the existence of a regulatory agency and the effect of the existence of regulation when controlling for ownership. The second set of specifications interacted the ownership dummies with the dummy for existence, allowing complementarities between the two phenomena to be identified (see appendix table F.2). Most of the results presented in chapter 3 hold when controlling for the existence of a regulatory agency. However, their magnitude is slightly reduced. For instance, the effect on labor productivity is reduced by one fourth. Similar to quality of service, the result during the transition becomes nonsignificant. In contrast, the results for the posttransition period on the impact of the change in ownership remain significant, with a 10 percent reduction in the electricity distribution sector and a 17 percent reduction in the water sector with respect to the results that did not control for the exis- tence of an agency. With respect to the existence of a regulatory agency, controlling for the change in ownership revealed the significant positive impact of most indicators. For instance, the presence of a regulatory agency is associated with increases in labor productivity of 19.4 percent in electricity distribution and 18.2 percent in water distribution. Similarly, utilities reported 18.9 percent less average duration and 17.3 percent less frequency of interruptions. With respect to ­ operational expenditures, utilities regulated by an agency had 27.4–32.1 ­ percent lower expenditures. Residential tariffs were 13.5 percent higher given the presence of a regulatory agency, industrial tariffs were 4.6 percent lower, and ­ recovery ratio was 13.3 percent higher. the cost ­ Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 88 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance Experience of the Regulatory Agency Experience was defined as the years since the establishment of the regulatory agency. As expected, these results are correlated with the results on the exis- tence of a regulatory agency. These estimations also support the hypothesis of gradual improvement of utilities’ performance given the presence of a ­ regulatory agency. Most of the results on the change in ownership hold when controlling for the experience of the regulatory agency, but the magnitude of the effect declines. For instance, after controlling for the change in ownership, labor productivity rose 1.4 percentage points with respect to the parameters obtained when the model does not control for experience. Distributional losses fell 1.8 percentage points a year according to the same comparison. Together these quality indicators resulted in annual improvement of 9.0 percentage points. Operational expendi- tures 1.6–5.5 percentage points a year. Residential tariffs improved 2.6 percentage points a year, and industrial tariffs fell 1.3 percentage points. Consequently, the cost recovery ratio improved significantly. Aggregated Measure of Regulatory Governance The models include various measures of regulatory governance developed in the previous sections. The IRGI is based on seven indicators: formal/informal auton- omy indexes, formal/informal transparency indexes, formal/informal account- ability indexes, and the tool index. The IRGI ranges between 0 and 1, with an average value of 0.483 and a standard deviation of 0.343. The purpose of these models is to test not only the existence of regulatory agencies but also their ­ governance. The mere existence of a regulatory agency has a significant impact on performance. This section tests whether there are additional effects of good regulatory governance.8 Most of the results on changes in ownership from chapter 3 hold when controlling for the regulatory governance of a regulatory agency, although there ­ is some reduction in the magnitude of their effect when the IRGI is added to the model. A one standard deviation increase in the IRGI is associated with an 8.7–9.1 percent increase in labor productivity and a 7.5–8.2 ­ ­ percent reduction in the duration and frequency of interruptions. Operational ­ expenditures fell more than 10 percent, and residential tariffs increased 5.7 ­ percent. Consequently, there was an improvement in the cost recovery ratio. Principal Components of the Governance of Regulatory Agencies Principal component analysis was used to break down the IRGI into its components, thus minimizing the loss of information associated with possible ­ correlation of some of the seven indicators.9 Principal component analysis may be helpful when there are multiple variables and a relatively small number of observations. An additional advantage of principal component analysis is that once patterns in the data are identified, the number of dimensions can be reduced without much loss of information.10 Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance 89 The results are presented by examining the impact on performance of an increase of one standard deviation for each factor.11 Factor 1 reflects informal governance aspects in a regulatory agency, which are correlated with informal autonomy, informal transparency, informal accountability, and tools and capaci- ties. Factor 2 reflects formal aspects of regulatory governance, which are highly correlated with formal transparency and formal accountability. Factor 3 reflects formal aspects of autonomy and the formal power of the agency to determine the tariff structure and level, which is highly correlated with the tariff regulatory and formal autonomy indexes. Most of the coefficients for the three principal components are significant and had the expected signs. However, each component had a distinct effect on each of the performance indicators. For instance, a one standard deviation change in the formal component had a large effect on improving labor productivity (15.9 percent) and reducing the frequency of interruptions ­ (13.8 ­percent) and residential tariffs (19.0 percent). A one standard deviation improvement in formal autonomy and the characteristics of the agency in terms of setting tariffs was associated with higher labor productivity (11.4 ­ percent) and a reduction in the average duration of interruptions (17.2 ­ percent). It was also associated with a 42.8–49.3 percent reduction in operation expenditure, with consequent improvements in the cost recovery ratio. Factor 1 had less influence than the other two factors: only 3 of 11 coefficients were significant. ­ Conclusions Regulatory agencies in LAC were created to isolate regulatory decisions from political intervention, a feature reflected in their governance design. About 75 percent of the agencies in the region have final decision responsibilities in determining the structure and levels of tariffs. The region has encountered difficulties in implementing safeguards to guarantee the autonomous management of agencies, however. The largest number of weak performers (agencies in Tier 3) was found for informal aspects of agencies’ governance and political autonomy. Informal aspects of agencies’ governance account for 14 percent of the variance in governance variables; they reflect informal autonomy, transparency, accountability, and tools. Almost 40 percent of agencies do not meet minimum governance conditions. Among these agencies, almost 70 percent do not meet the minimum governance requirements to guarantee the insulation of the agency ­ from political influence. Many agencies fall into Tier 3 on informal account- ability, which assesses the degree of an agency’s accountability to the executive. Regulatory agencies in the region do not perform well on institutional non- regulatory, mechanisms aimed at improving transparency and overall institu- tional quality. For the most part, governance does not reflect the use of regulatory quality standards, such as administrative simplification, or cost-benefit analysis in Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 90 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance the assessment of regulations. Moreover, 30 percent of agencies do not publish their job vacancies, and almost half do not use public examinations to hire employees. Regulatory governance matters for sector performance. The existence of a regulatory agency matters, the experience of the regulatory agency matters, and the governance of the agency matters. Significant improvement in utility ­ ­ performance occurs as a result of a regulatory agency, even in the case of SOEs. Notes 1. The measurement of agencies’ governance is not an indicator of the effectiveness of the use of their regulatory instruments (such as the methodology to calculate tariff readjustment) or the quality of stakeholders’ involvement in public consultations. It aims to capture the institutional conditions necessary to achieve good regulation regardless of their scope and impact on the sector’s performance (Correa and others 2006). 2. The countries are Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, the Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Jamaica, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Trinidad and Tobago, and Uruguay. 3. Chile and Colombia split regulatory responsibilities in two agencies, one in charge of the main regulatory functions (the National Energy Commission) and one in charge of enforcement of the regulatory framework, particularly in terms of the imposition of sanctions and the observance of service quality standards (Superintendencia). In 2009, the government of Evo Morales announced the elimination of 4. Superintendencias as sector regulator in Bolivia and the creation of Autoridades de Fiscalizacion y Control Social. Article 138 of supreme decree 29894, published February 7, 2009, stated that with the exception of the hydrocarbons regulator, all regulators that formed part of the sector regulatory system or the renewable natural resources regulatory system would disappear within 60 days from the date of the decree’s publication and their functions taken over by the corresponding ministries or a new regulatory authority. Their levels of autonomy as IRAs were reduced as the law made them directly accountable to the line minister. 5. Previous research on governance has focused on the existence of an agency, a legal framework, or particular aspects of its governance (mainly autonomy), emphasizing formal attributes. In terms of performance, only electricity generation per capita was used as an indicator related to governance (Stern and Cubbin 2005). Estache and Rossi (2008) study the relationship between the establishment of an agency and the efficiency of the utilities as well as the welfare of consumers. 6. All specifications were run using a semilogarithmic functional form of these models for each of the indicators. First, a dummy for the existence of a regulatory agency as well as its interactions with the ownership dummies was added. Next, the square of experience of the regulatory agency was included. Following this, the Infrastructure Regulatory Governance Index (IRGI) to the specifications was added as well as its interactions with ownership. Finally, the regulatory index was decomposed through a principal component approach, and three principal components were introduced in the models. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance 91 7. There are some differences between the year the agency was created (in general by law) and the year it was established. The governance data report both dates. The regressions used the year the agency was established; similar results were obtained using the year the agency was created. 8. This section reports the results of an increase of one standard deviation in governance. The data are cross-sectional. Hence, the underlying assumption is that once the agency was created, it followed a similar institutional design. Its governance is therefore assumed to be constant. 9. Principal component analysis develops a composite index by defining a real-valued function over the relevant variables objectively. When different characteristics of a set of events are observed, the characteristic with greater variation explains a larger proportion of the variation in the dependent variable than the variable displaying less variation. Therefore, the issue is one of finding weights to assign to each of the concerned variables, determined by the principle that the objective is to maximize variation in the linear composite of these variables. This approach allows patterns in data to be identified, and it allows the data to be presented in a way that highlights similarities and differences. 10. See Andrés and others (2008) for details on factor scores and their eigenvalues. 11. The standard deviations for the three principal components were 1.51, 1.41, and 1.28. References Andrés, L., J. L. Guasch, and S. L. Azumendi. 2008. “Regulatory Governance and Sector Performance in Electricity Distribution in Latin America.” In Regulation, De-Regulation, and Re-Regulation: Institutional Perspectives, edited by M. Ghertman and C. Menard. London: Edward Elgar. Andrés, L., J. L. Guasch, M. Diop, and S. L. Azumendi. 2007. “Assessing the Governance of Electricity Regulatory Agencies in the Latin American and the Caribbean Region: A Benchmarking Analysis.” Policy Research Working Paper 4380, World Bank, Washington, DC. Aron, J. 2000. “Growth and Institutions: A Review of the Evidence.” World Bank Research Observer 15 (1): 99–135. Brown, A. C., J. Stern, B. Tenenbaum, and D. Gencer. 2006. Handbook for Evaluating Infrastructure Regulatory Systems. Washington, DC: World Bank. Correa, P., C. Pereira, B. Mueller, and M. Melo. 2006. Regulatory Governance in Infrastructure Industries: Assessment and Measurement of Brazilian Regulators. Washington, DC: World Bank, Public-Private Infrastructure Advisory Facility. Estache, A., and M. A. Rossi. 2008. “Regulatory Agencies: Impact on Firm Performance and Social Welfare.” Policy Research Working Paper 4509, World Bank, Washington, DC. Gilardi, F. 2002. “Policy Credibility and Delegation to Independent Regulatory Agencies: A Comparative Empirical Analysis.” Journal of European Public Policy 9 (6): 873–93. Gutiérrez, L. H. 2003. “The Effect of Endogenous Regulation on Telecommunications Expansion and Efficiency in Latin America.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 23 (3): 257–86. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 92 Regulatory Institutional Design and Sector Performance Johannsen, K. S. 2003. Regulatory Independence in Theory and Practice: A Survey of Independent Energy Regulators in Eight European Countries. Energy Research Programme and the Danish Research Training Council, Copenhagen. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 1999. OECD Guiding Principles for Regulatory Quality and Performance. Paris: OECD. Oliveira, G., E. Machado, L. Novaes, L. Martins, G. Ferreira, and C. Beatriz. 2005. Aspects of the Independence of Regulatory Agencies and Competition Advocacy. Getulio Vargas Foundation, Rio de Janeiro. Rodrick, D. 2004. “Getting Institutions Right.” CESifo DICE Report: A Journal for International Comparisons 2: 10–15. Sirtaine, S., M. E. Pinglo, J. L. Guasch, and V. Foster. 2004. “How Profitable Are Infrastructure Concessions in Latin America? Empirical Evidence and Regulatory Implications.” Trends and Policy Options 2, World Bank, Latin America and Caribbean Region, Finance, Private Sector and Infrastructure Department, Washington, DC. http://rru.worldbank.org/documents/other/topic60_­ latinamerica.pdf. Sosay, G., and U. Zenginobuz. 2005. “Independent Regulatory Agencies in Emerging Economies.” Munich Personal RePEc Archive, Paper 380. Stern, J., and J. Cubbin. 2005. “Regulatory Effectiveness: The Impact of Regulation and Regulatory Governance Arrangements on Electricity Industry Outcomes.” Policy Research Working Paper 3536, World Bank, Washington, DC. Stern, J., and S. Holder. 1999. “Regulatory Governance: Criteria for Assessing the Performance of Regulatory Systems: An Application to Infrastructure in Developing Countries of Asia.” Utilities Policy 8: 33–50. Thatcher, M. 2007. “Regulatory Agencies, the State and Markets: A Franco-British Comparison.” Working Paper RSCAS 2007/17, European Union University. World Bank. 2008. LAC Electricity Regulatory Governance Database. Washington, DC. ———. 2009. LAC Water Regulatory Governance Database. Washington, DC. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Chapter 5 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises Governments and international donors no longer adopt a “one model fits all” approach to address the management framework of state-owned enterprises (SOEs). They recognize that public enterprises face different problems from private operators, related to deficiencies in service provision and financial short- comings unique to the environment in which they operate. Addressing issues such as performance-based management, the role of incentives, the professional- ization of senior management, and policies regarding transparency of utilities’ information systems requires a pragmatic, case-specific approach to reform. As a result of work by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) on corporate governance and concepts and tools of the New Public Management theories, policy makers now view SOEs as corporations driven by incentives that reward efficiency and transparency. The notion of cor- porate governance as applied to public enterprises tries to reflect as closely as possible the incentives that private enterprises face. In the case of SOEs, corporate governance refers to the organization of decision making in a public corporation. The OECD’s Guidelines of Corporate Governance in SOEs (OECD 2005) emphasize the importance of a legal framework that clearly establishes the separate roles of the state as owner, regulator, and policy formulator. ­ The ­institutional setting for SOEs should ensure a level playing field with respect to private enterprises in order to avoid distortions and inefficiency. The OECD Guidelines also stress the importance of an explicit legal mandate that regulates the provision of public service obligations, the sources of funding, and the scope of governance. They recommend the development of an ownership policy that defines the overall objectives of state ownership and the state’s role in the ­ corporate governance of SOEs and explains how the state will implement its ownership policy. It also recommends clear and equitable rules for all ­shareholders, particularly small investors. It emphasizes the need for a board of directors composed of officials with good qualifications, reasonable levels of autonomy, ­ and effective mechanisms of accountability. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   93   94 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises Two main approaches can be observed in the literature on corporate gover- nance of SOEs. The first approach emphasizes improved corporate governance of SOEs as a prerequisite to private sector participation. This approach assumes that the resemblance to a private enterprise with higher levels of autonomy in the management of funds that is subject to corporate law and eventually listed in the stock markets aligns internal incentives. Consequently, this approach improves performance, clearing the way to private sector participation. Critics of this view emphasize the approach’s focus on one of the several ways of organiz- ing state corporations. The second approach adopts a more comprehensive, less dogmatic view of the governance of SOEs. It considers improvement in the governance of SOEs as an end in itself rather than merely a strategy for eventual private sector participa- tion. It presents SOEs with various strategies for improving performance, includ- ing but not l­imited to private sector participation. According to Whincop (2005), government corporations SOEs face three main problems. The first is related to the alignment of the interests of the government corporations’ managers with those of its ultimate owners, the ­ ­ citizens (the agency costs of management). The constituency to which a ­ government corporation is ultimately accountable—the people—stands in a dual relation to the government corporation. On the one hand, the people are the government corporations’ residual claimants, as shareholders in a business corporation. On the other hand, they are frequently the principal recipients of the goods and services the government corporation provides. This dual relation between the government corporation and the public makes it difficult to concretize the mean- ing of acting in the best interests of the public. The second problem is associated with the alignment of the interests of the body wielding delegated governance power over managers with the interests of its ultimate owners (the agency costs of governance). Questions arise regarding the extent to which the people wielding this power are inclined to use it for political advantage. The third ­ ­ problem is the reduction of social costs associated with anticompetitive behavior by the government corporation. Whincop explores how the governance of government corporations can be evaluated in terms of three objectives—management costs, anticompeti- tive behavior costs, and costs of governance—which he evaluates from a “­constituency” perspective. He examines the major players whose interests may be affected by the governance of the government corporation and their relation to the ultimate principal, the public at large. Principal players are managers, empowered political agents, and active stakeholders, including customers and employees. Vagliasindi (2008, 2009) develops a detailed review of the substantial body of research on theoretical models of board effectiveness and ownerships structures. The literature (which is on the private sector) stresses the importance of ­independent directors. In the case of SOEs, even more than in private enter- prises, the appointment of directors with technical expertise and a reasonable level of independence acquires central relevance. Vagliasindi also emphasizes Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 95 the importance of external governance (by, for example, the government agency in charge of ownership decisions) and regulation. Schwartz (2006) examines the organizational model in state water utilities. He applies the two main organizational approaches—the bureaucratic model and the New Public Management model—to public water utilities in Mexico. He defines the bureaucratic model as one based on the preeminence of the law and rules, composed of civil servants with stability and civil service careers in public admin- istration, and organized around the principles of hierarchy and levels. The New Public Management framework proposes higher levels of decentralization of and autonomy for government entities; the use of performance-based instruments, such as performance-based payments; and accountability focused on results. Schwartz challenges conventional wisdom about the effectiveness of New Public Management, finding that well-performing public utilities tend to display stronger adherence to the Weberian ideal type than poorly functioning public service pro- viders. He concludes that the two strategies are better viewed as complementary than opposing, as both focus on reducing patronage and depoliticizing the man- agement of the utility (bureaucratic model) and emphasize the levels of service that must be delivered by the utility (New Public Management model). Both approaches lack empirical evidence about the impact of governance on performance. For instance, no assessment has been conducted of the c ­ ontributions of corporatization to access to finance or productivity or the role of shares in not-for-profit enterprises. There is, however, some evidence on performance ­ contracts, presented below. Methodology and Framework of Analysis This chapter focuses on the governance of SOEs in the water and electricity distribution sectors of Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC). As in the previous chapter, the focus is on governance design rather than effectiveness. ­ Figure 5.1 summarizes the framework of analysis. The data collected reflect the corporate arrangements that shape 45 state-run companies in the region, including both public companies with full state ownership and companies in which the state owns at least 51 percent of total ­ shares (only a few utilities are in this category). Governance of SOEs is measured through six indexes. The Corporate Governance Index, the main index, is an aggregate index based on the other five indexes (legal soundness, board competi- tiveness, professional management, performance orientation, and transparency and disclosure) plus a binary measure based on the listing of the company on the stock exchange. The data were collected through a survey implemented in 110 utilities in the electricity and water sectors. The benchmark used was a corporatized public enterprise for which access to finance and auditing requirements were similar to private enterprises. The benchmark was adjusted to allow sector specificities, such as the mechanisms for appointing the board of directors, economic regulation, and performance-based orientation. ­ Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 96 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises Figure 5.1  Framework for Assessing Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 7. Financial management 1. Ownership 2. Legal/ 6. Labor institutional Corporate governance framework of a SOE 3. Performance 5. Board orientation 4. Transparency/ disclosure Source: Andrés, Guasch, and Lopez Azumendi 2011. Also included in the study were the selection, appointment, salary, and edu- cational levels of staff. Previous approaches emphasized only the role of the board and its relationship with shareholders. For SOEs providing infrastructure services, the role of the staff is a vital aspect of good management. Most utilities are not profit oriented and do not focus on revenues as a measure of good performance. A good bureaucracy may also limit political intervention. An index ­ that reflects the professionalism of the staff (as measured by educational levels, hiring criteria, and rewards) may therefore provide a good proxy for the perfor- mance of the enterprise. Table 5.1 describes the components of this framework of analysis. As in chapter 4, three tiers were created. Tier 1 encompasses enterprises that have “desirable” conditions for developing good corporate governance. Utilities’ responses in this tier are close to the highest value for each of the questions. Their corporate governance design meets high standards. Tier 2 encompasses SOEs that meet only the minimum conditions considered necessary to implement a corporate governance program. Utilities in Tier 2 have weaker institutional design and less sophisticated mechanisms than utilities in Tier 1. Tier 3 includes utilities that do not meet the minimum conditions to implement the benchmark model of corporate governance. Results of Corporate Governance Benchmarking This section presents the results on the aggregated index and each of the indi- vidual indexes. The scores for each enterprise are aggregated to the country level. Although this approach simplifies the presentation, it conceals significant Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 97 Table 5.1  Analytical Framework for Assessing Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises Board/chief Ownership/legal executive officer Management/ Performance framework (CEO) staff Transparency disclosure orientation Components Ownership Appointments Educational Website’s contents, Assessment of structure, process levels, training, participation of civil performance of tax regime, (authority, criteria society in decision-making, company and its corporatization, criteria); origin for hiring, annual performance decision-making regulatory and background mechanism report, auditing of authorities, bodies and of directors; for rewarding company’s accounting, criteria, tools and functions, deliberative employees, financial disclosure mechanisms, restructuring, or executive salary levels standards, involvement evaluation procurement, roles; salary of consumers and civil authorities, public listing levels; scope of society representatives in and systems responsibilities; company’s decision making, for rewarding assessment of criteria for appointing senior employees performance management, criteria and mechanisms for hiring employees Benchmark Focus on company Emphasis on board Benchmark is Emphasis on decision-making Model of a state- that has of directors and company process in which civil society owned enterprise corporate CEO appointed that hires its has a say in the company’s with a focus on structure, is based on employees decisions (accountability performance-based subject to meritocratic through effect) and there is a strong management. the same criteria, with external focus on the publication Benchmark conditions as reasonable competition, of institutional and compensates lack of the private level of rewards performance information. incentives provided sector, and has independence, employees’ Involvement of private by the profitability the possibility and whose performance, auditors and the publication of a private of accessing performance and has salary of financial information company with a private and is assessed levels close to through best international framework in which public financing regularly private sector practices is prioritized. the performance of levels Importance also given public companies is to ways company hires properly assessed. employees (open process). Source: Andrés, Guasch, and Lopez Azumendi 2011. heterogeneity in the governance structures of utilities within a country (Brazil and Colombia, for example, are home to both best-performing and ­worst-performing utilities). Aggregate Index of Corporate Governance The aggregated measure of corporate governance ranks companies in the region based on account information from all five components of the frame- work: legal soundness, board competitiveness, professional management, performance-orientation, and transparency and disclosure (figure 5.2). The ­ results reveal that Colombia, Peru, and Brazil, have the best-performing SOEs in the region. None of them is above Tier 2, however. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 98 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises Figure 5.2  Aggregate Index of Corporate Governance in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 1.0 0.8 0.6 Index (0–1) 0.4 0.2 0 r T1 ca a ic ru il T2 y a ia ica ico go ay do az ua bi in bl liv Pe ai gu ba aR ex nt m ua Br pu ug m Bo ra lo ge To M st Ec Ja Re Ur Pa Co Co Ar d n an ica ad in id m in Do Source: World Bank 2009. Tr Component 1: Ownership and Legal Framework A legal framework in which companies are corporatized and subject to similar standards as private companies was prioritized in the assessment of governance (figure 5.3). Priority was also given to companies whose policies are established and monitored by a specialized government agency. The index gives higher scores to companies regulated by independent commissions or agencies and subject to the same tax obligations as private enterprises. Companies that are publicly listed also receive higher scores, because companies subject to the standards of the stock commission are assumed to have better corporate governance. Corporatization. The majority of the companies in the sample have been cor- poratized. The most common modality is to subject SOEs to the same legal framework as a limited liability enterprise (sometimes known as sociedades ­anónimas or capital variable companies in LAC). SABESP (Brazil) is the only company in the sample that is publicly listed, and, hence, subject to more quality controls by authorities and investors. Corporatized enterprises are subject to corporate law. Their institutional design is closer to a private company than a unincorporated enterprise. About 70 percent of SOEs can declare bankruptcy in case of insolvency, have a board of directors, and have a shares structure of ownership. Only 35 percent of SOEs require the pursuit of profits. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 99 Figure 5.3 Index of Legal Soundness in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 1.0 0.8 0.6 Index (0–1) 0.4 0.2 0 r ic ca ru a a il ay ia ica go ico y T1 T2 do az ua in bi bl liv Pe ai gu ba aR ex nt m Br ua pu ug m Bo ra lo ge To M st Ec Ja Re Ur Pa Co Co Ar d n an ica ad in id m in Do Tr Source: World Bank 2009. The landscape of companies with shares is diverse. Companies like Aguas de Rio Negro S.A. (Argentina) have not issued shares, even though the company is organized as a private enterprise. Other companies have distributed dividends but at very low levels. In Peru, shares have been used to reimburse users for the money spent on extending the network. Some companies that have not issued shares have earned significant profits. Empresas Publicas de Medellin, for example, transferred about $200,000 to the municipality of Medellin, the com- ­ pany’s shareholder. Ownership structure. Almost half of the sample of SOEs has some private sector participation, but in most cases the percentages are very small (­ ­ exceptions are SABESP, with 49.7 percent private ownership, and Aguas de Saltillo, with 49.0 percent private ownership). Some alternative mechanisms for private sector participation include share ownership by employees, trade associations, ­ citizens, and users, although they usually account for no more than 10 percent of shares. In Agua y Saneamiento Argentinos S.A., for example, employees ­ represented by the unions are the largest private shareholders. The National Association of Coffee Producers of Colombia owns shares in the Centrales Eléctricas Norte de Santander S.A. E.S.P., and the Association of Manufacturers of Pichincha (Cámara de Industriales de Pichincha) owns shares in Eléctrica de Quito S.A. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 100 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises Role of authorities. Ownership rights are usually exercised by the sector or line minister. In some cases, ministers of finance and auditing bodies also possess ownership rights. Where SOEs are subsidiaries of larger state enterprises, owner- ship rights are exercised by a holding company. Only 23 percent of the utilities sampled have an agency specifically in charge of policies.1 The rest have a wide range of policy formulation authorities. The sector ministry or some ministerial agency constitutes the most frequent policy formulation authority. Regulatory role. Economic regulation—particularly the relationship between tariffs and the quality standards of service provision—is a critical aspect of the sustainable management of SOEs. Only a very specific division of roles between the state as policy formulator, provider, and regulator can provide a framework for enforcing economic sustainability and quality of service. In the survey, 72 ­percent of respondents claimed that the regulator has final decision power in the sector in specific aspects such as tariffs, quality standards, and service expansion. The survey results suggest that the involvement of the government is ­ heavier when it comes to critical issues such as tariff levels and expansion of service and lighter when it is related to more technical, less controversial, aspects of service, such as technical standards and service quality. The distribution of competencies between regulatory agencies and the line ministry shows that the line ministry makes the critical decisions. Tax regime. Ideally, SOEs should be subject to the same tax obligations as private enterprises. More than half of the SOEs in the sample receive tax exemptions or discounts; only 43 percent reported receiving no fiscal privileges. ­ Exemptions and discounts usually come from differential treatment of income and value added taxes. In practice, SOEs that are not exempt from income tax do not pay income taxes, because they generate no revenues or capitalize ­ revenues as reserves. The legal soundness index benchmarks SOEs based on their legal framework. Priority was given to a legal structure that levels the playing field ­ for SOEs and private enterprises. The results were surprising, as companies well known for good performance, such as Agua y Drenaje de Monterrey, rank low on this index, and companies known for operational gaps rank high. Overall, companies with a limited liability framework and subject to similar rules as private enterprises score high, and companies with the legal typology of government departments or private enterprise but subject to public rules score low. The majority of SOEs in LAC have been corporatized and adopted the legal typology of a private enterprise. Several are integrated by shares and have varying degrees of private sector participation. SABESP and Aguas de Saltillo are the companies with the highest levels of private sector participation that have imple- mented a share structure that provides benefits to shareholders. Various commissions and agencies regulate SOEs in LAC. Their influence seems to be greater on issues such as quality standards. Line ministries seem to be the most influential actors in regulation. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 101 Component 2: Board and Chief Executive Officer This section focuses on the composition, qualifications, and performance of the board of directors and chief executive officers (CEOs) of SOEs (figures 5.4 and 5.5). It prioritizes a board in which political discretion is low, members are selected based on predefined criteria (particularly related to merit), and perfor- mance is assessed based on different governance arrangements. The greater the emphasis on transparency and accountability of the decision-making authorities of an SOE, the greater the possibilities of improving performance. The weak results indicate the prevalence of political authorities in the appointment of boards of directors, the low percentage of directors who come from within the SOE or from the ranks of private independent experts, and the lack of board selection criteria. At only 36 percent of utilities does the law establish the need to select directors based on certain criteria. Among utilities that have an established procedure, sector experience and a university degree seem to be the most common requirements. In only 2 percent of cases is political independence a precondition for board eligibility. The appointment of directors constitutes an interesting example of the ­ differences between SOEs and private enterprises. In for-profit private enter- prises, shareholders are interested in appointing a CEO and executive directors with the skills to improve financial performance. Hence, the selection process, whether conducted through the human resources department or based on Figure 5.4 Index of Board Competitiveness in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 1.0 0.8 0.6 Index (0–1) 0.4 0.2 0 r T1 ica ru T2 Ec ic ge il a Ur ia Co uay ad Jam a To a go Pa ico ay do z in bi c bl liv Pe a ai gu ba aR ex nt m ua Br pu ug Bo ra lo M st Re Co Ar d n an ica in id m in Do Tr Source: World Bank 2009. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 102 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises Figure 5.5 Index of Chief Executive Officer Competitiveness in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 1.0 0.8 0.6 Index (0–1) 0.4 0.2 0 ico ru ca ay r ica T2 a ic T1 y il a ia do in go ua az bi Pe bl ai gu liv ex aR nt ua m pu Br m ug ba Bo ra M ge lo st Ja Ec Re Ur To Pa Co Co Ar n d ica an in ad m id Do in Tr Source: World Bank 2009. the sole decision of shareholders, emphasizes the candidates’ ability to increase the company’s revenue. For SOEs, the selection criteria should focus on reducing political discretion in the appointment of decision-making authorities and creat- ing the incentives for good performance. Very few companies have developed specific criteria, beyond legal requirements, to select independent, qualified directors to the board.2 Of critical importance for SOE management is performance evaluation. Although responsibility for the achievement can adopt different criteria, the board of directors and CEO are ultimately responsible for the conduct of business. Private companies and SOEs measure performance differently. Profit ­ maximization is the main criterion for rewarding or dismissing directors of ­ private enterprises. All the company’s policies are aligned around this objective; its organizational structure and strategies also reflect this orientation. In contrast, at some state enterprises, the dispersion and conflicting interests of stakeholders prevent the formulation of consistent strategies and policies. As a result, assess- ment of the performance of the companies’ authorities is more challenging. The survey attempted to capture the way directors are evaluated. A significant number of SOEs indicated that their directors were evaluated. Answers to the rest of the survey questions remain unclear. When asked about the methodology/ criteria used for assessing directors, only 17 percent of SOEs identified specific criteria. Most indicated that although directors are assessed, there are no specific Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 103 criteria, confirming the existence of ad hoc mechanisms of evaluation. Very few SOEs identified a particular mechanism against which performance is evaluated. As in private enterprises, directors are assessed at the end of the fiscal year. In some cases, after approval of the accounting and financing reports, the president of the country approves the performance of directors by decree. Strikingly, com- panies that declared having specific criteria to set objectives responded that they do not have a particular mechanism (especially written) to evaluate directors. Component 3: Management/Staff The management/staff index measures the composition and characteristics of the enterprise’s staff by education, type of training, legal status, salary and benefit levels, hiring, and incentives (figure 5.6). Employees are a central part of SOEs in the infrastructure sector. They can buffer an SOE from political interference, as a professional and well-organized bureaucracy can oppose measures that hinder their career prospects. ­ Staff education levels. Most SOE employees work in operations.3 Thirty-seven percent of all workers are skilled workers, and 31 percent are unskilled workers. Twenty-four percent are nonoperational (administrative) workers. About 15 ­percent of employees in SOEs have university degrees. The average age in the sample is 44. Figure 5.6 Index of Professional Management in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 1.0 0.8 0.6 Index (0–1) 0.4 0.2 0 or T1 Ja 2 Ec a ic Co zil Ar bia a y go ico Co ivia ica Pa ru ay an gua c in T bl ica uad Pe a ai gu ba aR ex nt m Br l pu m Bo u ra lo ge To M st Re Ur d n ad in id m in Do Tr Source: World Bank 2009. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 104 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises The sample shows diverse educational backgrounds among both board mem- bers and staff. At 70 percent of utilities, all board directors have a university degree; at 30 percent, some directors have a university degree. Fifteen percent of companies indicated that all board members had graduate degrees, 55 percent indicated that some board members have a graduate degree, and 30 percent indicated that no members of the board had graduate degrees. Educational levels are higher among CEOs and managers. At 56 percent of utilities, the CEO has a graduate degree or some graduate education, at 38 ­percent the CEO has only an undergraduate degree, and at 6 percent the CEO does not have a degree. At 78 percent of utilities all managers have a university degree; at 22 percent some managers have a university degree. With respect to graduate studies, 12 percent of the companies said that all their managers have a gradu- ate degree, and 58 percent reported that some managers did so. At 30 percent of SOEs, none of the managers of the companies had pursued graduate studies. A common assumption regarding the management of SOEs is that rigid labor schemes prevent the restructuring of the labor force. In the sample, two-thirds of the utilities hired employees under the same laws governing private companies; the remaining utilities did so under civil service rules. The majority of the labor force is hired on a permanent basis; 84 percent of employees were hired under a regime that provides some degree of stability or a special regime, such as a labor agreement or convenio colectivo de trabajo. Managers and employees receive train- ing; training of members of the board of directors is rare. Managers benefit most from capacity building. A crucial aspect related to the proficiency of the human resources of state companies is the mechanism for selecting employees. Political discretion and the influence of trade unions were frequently cited in the past as drivers of overstaff- ing and low capacity. But the majority of survey respondents identified external competition as the primary way of selecting personnel, particularly for higher-level positions up to the managerial level. A third of unskilled workers are ­ selected through a noncompetitive process. Others mechanisms for hiring staff include internal competition and combinations of internal competition with external selection. A similar situation can be seen in the case of nonoperational workers, 25 ­percent of whom are selected based on discretion and 25 percent of whom are selected by unions. Half of the SOEs surveyed indicated that they selected their managers based on discretion rather than competition. These figures are not necessarily an indication of political intervention or undue influence of other stakeholders. They may reflect the need for professionals that the CEO, the board, or both trust. Performance evaluation. In addition to open and merit-based selection pro- cesses, staff of SOEs would benefit from a system of incentives that rewards good performance. The survey asked about the criteria for rewarding performance and the ways in which performance is rewarded. Criteria include years in the c­ompany, performance, and the discretional determination of rewards for employees. Rewards include promotion, salary increases, and bonuses. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 105 The majority of SOEs reward their staff based on years in the company and performance. A significant number of companies use only discretion or a combi- nation of discretion and performance/years in the company to reward their employees. Very few companies, including EPM in Colombia and Aguas de Saltillo in Mexico, pay bonuses for achieving certain revenue targets. Incentive payments in the public sector have been used to motivate civil servants and to increase efficiency and effectiveness. There is no empirical ­ evidence on the consequences of this type of reform. The anecdotal evidence on ­ its use in SOEs is mixed. In the sample, only 20 percent of companies have some type of performance-based payments. On average, employees earn more than board members. Remuneration of board members is similar to the private sector (and higher than in the public administration) at 30 percent of SOEs surveyed and similar to the public sector at 34 percent of SOEs. Among employees, 84 percent perceive that their sala- ries are similar to private sector levels or at least higher than public sector levels; 16 percent believe that their salaries are equivalent to public sector salaries. Salary benefits follow the same trend: 90 percent of SOEs pay their ­ employees benefits that are similar to or higher than the private sector or between private and public sector levels. Component 4: Transparency and Disclosure The transparency index measures the existence of mechanisms that allow transparent disclosure of the company’s financial and nonfinancial information, the involvement of civil society in decision making, and the independent auditing of accounts (figure 5.7). The tier analysis indicates that the majority ­ of SOEs meet only the minimum conditions for achieving the open disclosure of their performance and accounts. No SOE in the sample met the desirable criteria. Quality of companies’ websites. All but one company has a website. Websites include the annual report, financial accounts, corporate structure (chart), and mechanisms to receive consumers’ claims and suggestions. Issues such as perfor- mance statistics (coverage, quality of service, costs, and so forth); job openings; the names and backgrounds of directors; procurement processes (stages, prices, and so forth); or information for consumers or students were rarely included on the websites.4 Involvement of consumers and society in formulation of company policies. Civil society participation can be an important factor in reducing political discretion in the management of the company. Although inclusion of civil society members on the board is an important way of achieving transparency, the focus here is on mechanisms through which some decisions are subject to the scrutiny of society. Among companies that involve civil society, 90 percent do so on a voluntary basis (that is, the company is not obliged to request the views of users or other stake- holders on various aspects of service delivery). Both mandatory and nonmanda- tory mechanisms include consultations on issues such as tariff increases and infrastructure works for contracts over a specific threshold. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 106 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises Figure 5.7 Index of Transparency and Disclosure in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 1.0 0.8 0.6 Index (0–1) 0.4 0.2 0 r y ru Bo l Co via Ja ca M a Ar uay go T1 Co aica Pa ico Ec a ad Rep 2 To ic i do az ua bi in T l Pe an ub i ba aR i ex nt m ua Br l ug g m ra lo ge st Ur d an Tr nic i id m in Source: World Bank 2009. Do Publication of annual reports. Annual reports serve as accountability ­mechanisms, because companies must describe their achievements. The majority of SOEs surveyed publish annual reports of their performance. These reports range from the simple enumeration of works developed during the fiscal year to complete, detailed reports. Auditing of financial accounts. Although traditionally subject to public sector scrutiny, a significant number of SOEs are also audited by private auditors. The majority of enterprises sampled are audited by both government audit agencies and private auditors: only 5 percent of SOEs are audited exclusively by the gov- ernment, and 30 percent are audited only by private auditors. Forty percent use international accounting standards to report financial information. The majority of SOEs also publish their audited accounts. Eighty percent of companies that do so use their website and other means, such as newspapers and printed publications. Only 22 percent of companies in the sample do not publish their ­ audited accounts. consumers Integration of the board. Just 7 percent of boards of directors include ­ or members of civil society. At 23 percent of utilities, board members are appointed with the intervention of the parliament or the private sector. Component 5: Performance Orientation Performance-oriented management facilitates the identification of objectives and, consequently, increases efficiency, particularly for SOEs, where incentives for performance are difficult to create because of the lack of private investors. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 107 Three dimensions of the performance orientation of SOEs are examined: the process of setting objectives, the instruments used to set objectives and its enforcement, and the authority that conducts these assessments (figure 5.8). Objective setting. Answers from SOEs were not sufficiently clear about the ways performance objectives are established. The majority of responses focused on the instruments through which the evaluation takes place. A few were explicit about targets and the process of identification and establishment.5 Instruments. The strategic plan or business plan seems to be the most common mechanism used by SOEs to set objectives; the annual report is the way ­ companies inform stakeholders about the fulfillment of these achievements. Some companies also use public hearings as a way for board members to explain the results of the enterprise. It is not clear from the responses what constitutes a performance agreement and what constitutes a business strategy. Three compa- nies specifically recognize the use of a performance contract to guide the strate- gic direction of the enterprise. Other mechanisms that complement business plans are the balance scorecard and evaluation systems linked to national or local development strategies. Evaluation authorities. The line ministry, the regulator, and auditing agencies seem to be the principal centers of accountability for state enterprises. In some Figure 5.8 Performance Orientation Index in Selected Countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 1.0 0.8 0.6 Index (0–1) 0.4 0.2 0 Co dor T1 Ja y ca T2 a ico y Re zil ic ru Ec o Ar ica a ia a ua bi in g bl liv an Pe a ai gu ba aR ex nt m ua Br pu ug m Bo ra lo ge To M st Ur Pa Co d n ica ad in id m in Do Tr Source: World Bank 2009. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 108 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises cases, the company is self-assessed by its board of directors. Some companies are subject to the control of a specific agency, such as the Solidarity Fund of Ecuador or the SOE Oversight Council of Paraguay. The parliament has little say in the accountability of SOEs. Greater involvement of the parliament in the discussion of management issues related to SOE performance could serve as a counter- weight to the political discretion of the executive. Assessment of board of members and staff. SOEs have weak mechanisms for evaluating the performance of board members. Not surprisingly, executive directors—who are responsible for managing the enterprise—seem to be subject ­ to higher levels of scrutiny than members of the board. Thirty percent of executive directors are not assessed based on particular criteria. Arrangements to ­ evaluate the performance of the CEO range from informal, ad hoc mechanisms to more detailed systems. At most utilities, the board approves the CEO’s ­ performance. At some utilities, specific criteria are established; other utilities lack procedures to evaluate CEO performance. The most detailed mechanisms include memorandums of understanding between the government and the executive director or the assessment of performance against the performance agreement or other mechanism through which the company is evaluated (such as the balance scorecard). Corporate Governance and Performance This section explores the relations between various dimensions of corporate governance and the operational performance of utilities in the water and electricity distribution sectors of LAC. The dimensions described in the previous ­ section are correlated with the level and growth rates of the main performance indicators. Appendix G presents the detailed results. Legal Framework A legal arrangement in which companies are corporatized and subject to similar standards as other private companies receives a higher score. Results suggest that greater legal soundness is associated with low distributional losses, low coverage, high labor productivity, and high tariffs. The stronger the legal framework, the lower the average quality of service and the higher the average tariffs. For water utilities, greater soundness is associated with higher labor productivity; in electricity distribution, the opposite trend is observed. The main other results ­ hold for both sectors. Board of Directors and Chief Executive Officer A higher score is given to companies in which political discretion over the board of directors is low, board members are selected based on predefined criteria, and member performance is assessed based on different governance arrangements. The results suggest that the higher the scores on these dimensions, the lower the distributional losses and the lower the service coverage. The higher the qualifica- tions of the board, the higher the level of average tariffs. Growth rates of these Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 109 performance indicators seem not to be significantly affected by the competitive- ness of the board or the CEO; however, when the sectors are analyzed separately, the change in performance in the water sector seems to be more sensitive to these dimensions. In the water sector, these dimensions are associated with greater continuity of service. The measure of CEO competitiveness is more closely correlated with positive changes in coverage and lower average tariffs; board competitiveness is more closely correlated with positive changes in labor productivity and micrometering. For the electricity sector, the results were not significantly different from zero. Management/Staff For the sample as a whole, only labor productivity is correlated with good management. In the water sector, better management is also associated with ­ lower distributional losses and better continuity of service, sewerage coverage, and micrometering. Transparency and Disclosure The transparency index measures the existence of mechanisms that allow for publication of the company’s financial and nonfinancial information, the involvement of civil society in decision making, disclosure of financial ­ information, and independent auditing of accounts. Utilities with greater trans- ­ parency and disclosure standards are associated with higher levels of service coverage and lower average tariffs. In the electricity sector, utilities with higher transparency indexes have higher coverage and lower tariffs. The results are stronger in the water sector, where transparency is correlated with greater efficiency; lower v ­ ­ olumes of nonrevenue water; and higher potability, metering, and coverage. Performance Orientation The performance orientation index measures the existence of internal and exter- nal mechanisms for evaluating performance. As expected, this index is highly correlated with labor productivity and (low) distributional losses, as well as significant changes in coverage. Most of these results hold when each sector is ­ assessed separately. Aggregated Corporate Governance The aggregated measure of corporate governance presents the overall results for the region in terms of the ranking of companies according to the five components of the framework. The index is highly correlated with high levels of labor productivity and tariffs and low distributional losses. Positive correlations are also ­ evident in service coverage. The correlation results are stronger for water utilities than electricity providers. For water companies, overall corporate governance is associated with low volumes of nonrevenue water and high quality standards, coverage, labor productivity, and average tariffs. The evidence shows that aggre- gate corporate governance is positively correlated with continuity of service, Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 110 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises labor productivity, metering, and sewerage coverage and negatively correlated with average tariffs. Some of the components of the aggregate index probably behave similarly. Hence, a principal component approach (PCA) was applied in order to include six indicators, thus minimizing the loss of information.6 The first principal component factor accounts for 36 percent of the variance of the indexes. The other two component factors account for 23 percent and 17 percent of the variance. Together the three factors account for 76 of the total variance.7 Appendix table G.8 presents the factor loading. Factor 1 is associated with the professional management and the performance orientation ­ dimensions. Factor 2 reflects the board competitiveness aspects. Factor 3 is related to legal soundness and transparency and disclosure. The correlation between the aggre- gated index as a weighted average of these factors and the aggregated corporate governance index presented earlier is significant (0.87). The ranking of countries presents some changes in the relative position for each country, but the story told earlier still holds. Conclusion Governance arrangements in SOEs in water and electricity distribution pres- ent a wide spectrum of designs. In contrast to private enterprises, which are characterized by the adoption of standard corporate strategies, SOE standards vary depending on countries’ institutional systems and the characteristics of the service. The variety of arrangements calls for the systematization of gover- nance practices and the identification of successful experiences. SOE perfor- mance is directly or indirectly related to the overall governance of countries or provinces. This chapter emphasizes the need for a corporate structure that prevents political intervention, rewards performance, and is subject to public scrutiny. It focuses on the qualifications of the staff of the enterprises. Although it tries to capture as many variables from state enterprises as possible, the focus is on the design, not the effectiveness, of governance procedures. As in a private enterprise, the organizational structure and decision making of an SOE reflects the interests and involvement of its shareholders and, hence, their strengths and weaknesses. Because these enterprises are part of the public administration and thus subject to its governance schemes and leadership, they can benefit (or suffer) from the performance of its bureaucracy. SOEs remain a complex and unique organizational mode, caught between the norms of public sector governance and corporate governance (Whincop 2005). Hence, although mimicking private enterprise arrangements might improve SOE management, it could also contribute to the consolidation of corruption and the lack of account- ability in enterprises with few controls and few governing stakeholders with vested interests. The focus on five components of design highlights the major pitfalls related to performance orientation and the selection and composition of the board of Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 111 directors. SOEs plan their strategies, but it is not clear how they set objectives or monitor and enforce them. Generally, SOEs are subject to influences of different authorities, particularly during their planning process. The major difference in staff selection in private companies and SOEs is the way in which managers are selected. From low-level employees to members of the board of directors, a significant percentage of managers are hired internally or with limited competition. Hiring from within is common among private enterprises; SOEs, however, provide more room for collusion between stakeholders. Measures need to be taken to prevent low levels of professionalism ­ and political appointees. Management of SOEs presents government bureaucrats with unique ­ challenges. First—and most important—SOEs face conflicting goals, which affect their business strategy. Several departments usually compete to move their agenda to the top of the company’s priorities. Interference in the companies’ business is often done informally, preventing the company from making the costs of interference explicit. Second, the lack of profit orientation prevents SOEs from identifying ways to improve efficiency and performance. Because low ­ revenues can be compensated for by government subsidies, making the company sustainable is not the top priority. Third, poor accountability systems (at the regulatory or management levels) prevent the development of an ownership structure that incentivizes senior management to behave in ways that promote efficiency. Although it is too early to formulate policy recommendations, some potential actions emerge from both the literature and practices in the region. Considering public enterprises as private companies can in some cases lead to wrong d ­ iagnoses and, hence, inappropriate reforms. Some, if not the majority of, SOEs in water and electricity distribution are not profit driven, which makes the corporate incentives on which private enterprises are based questionable. As Whincop (2005) notes, it makes sense to design governance appropriate to the form rather than to emulate the incentive structure of alternatives. Doing so calls for the identification of governance schemes that focus on the factors that may spur efficiency, reducing the space for corruption and capture by vested interests. It is in this context that accountability emerges as the main governance aspect of SOEs. At utilities with high levels of corruption and inefficiency, a ­ ccountability systems should be put in place that prevent discretional management (both from management and political authorities) and create incentives for good ­performance. Regulation and performance-based management are complementary ways of achieving these goals, although care needs to be taken in creating checks and balances, such as parliamentary oversight and state auditing. ­ A governance design reflecting the incentives of private enterprises seems more appropriate for utilities with partial rather than full state ownership, ­ ompanies ­particularly companies with significant private sector participation. For c with significant gaps in both performance and management, transparent accountability mechanisms should be considered. At companies that are fully ­ state owned and characterized by good performance, management need to strike Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 112 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises a balance between private sector orientation and public accountability. Governance design needs to take into consideration sector differences. Technology and sector dynamics also determine management. This assessment is the first of its kind. The results suggest that good corporate governance is associated with better performance and higher growth rates. As expected, performance orientation and professional management characteristics seem to be the most important contributors to performance; all the other characteristics are associated with some performance indicators. Results ­ stronger in the water sector than the electricity sector, presumably because of are ­ the larger number of utilities included in the sample. Further analysis should include more disaggregated data and a larger sample. It is also important to explore ­political economy approaches that address issues of causality, ­sequencing, and complex interaction effects that contribute to SOE governance and to complement the analysis with detailed case studies to improve the knowledge of the internal mechanisms affecting performance. Notes 1. In Argentina, the ownership policies of Aguas Rionegrinas S.A. are determined by the Secretary of Management and Control of SOEs of the government of Rio Negro. In Paraguay, some SOEs are subject to the Oversight Council of SOEs, which is also in charge of signing and enforcing performance contracts with SOEs. 2. FONFAE, in Peru, developed guidelines regulating the appointment, payment, and obligations of directors of companies in which the state has any ownership. Its direc- professional tive asserts that only directors with a university degree and five years of ­ experience can be appointed. They are not employees of the enterprise but hired under a professional services contract (locación de servicios). The regulation also establishes their obligations and responsibilities. Empresas Públicas de Medellín ­ (EPM), in Colombia, has a corporate governance code that addresses, among other issues, the criteria for appointing directors to the board. Board members must have a university degree and relevant professional experience, and five of the nine directors must be independent from the government. EPM is one of the few state enterprises in LAC that requires independence as a criterion for appointment. 3. The survey defines operational workers in the following way: Operational “qualified” workers are employees (permanent and nonpermanent) that do not have a university degree but perform tasks that require a special knowledge and practice. Operational “nonqualified” workers are employees (permanent and nonpermanent) that do not have a university degree and perform tasks that do not require special knowledge or practices. 4. ElectroSureste (Peru), SABESP, and EPM have well-designed websites with useful information for consumers, investors, and the general public. ElectroSureste’s website includes an e-procurement system that provides bidding guidelines, deadlines, and results. It also publishes the projected time, responsible authorities, and purpose of the different types of claims users can pursue. It provides consumers with a virtual office to answer their questions and address their concerns. 5. State-owned electrical utilities in the Dominican Republic are under the authority of the DR Corporation of Electricity Companies. ELECTROSUR, a Dominican Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises 113 SOE, for instance, discusses objectives related to coverage and quality of service with the government. It discusses efficiency and revenues issues with the holding company and issues related to work-related accidents, environment protection, and so forth within the company. A different approach to the setting of objectives is used in Colombia, where the control agency (Superintendencia de Servicios Publicos Domiciliarios) requires utilities to prepare plans based on preselected criteria and indicators. The evaluation of financial and nonfinancial performance of ­ SOEs takes place through an independent audit by a private firm. The assessment focuses on corporate and social aspects. The first evaluation is related to financial indicators; the second is related to administrative and technical parameters and quality standards. Another set of ­ companies coordinates policy goals and objectives through performance agreements. Some companies in Brazil and Paraguay sign performance contracts with government authorities through which they set objec- ­ tive and monitoring strategies. In Paraguay, ANDE signs a performance agreement with the line minister and the ownership unit (Consejo Supervisor de Empresas del Estado). The agreement is enforced by the o ­wnership unit through periodical reports stating the level of achievement of targets. Grupo CEEE and CAESB in Brazil sign performance contracts with policy formulation authorities. Other state utilities establish objectives that are linked to development plans. Together with the sector minister, SOEs in Costa Rica set development goals, which are monitored in the context of the national evaluation system. Some utilities (ANDE in Paraguay, ERSSA and CentroSur in Peru) use scorecard methodologies. 6. The principal component approach was used to jointly take into account the informa- tion provided by the six main governance indicators ratios (appendix table G.8) and generate orthogonal indexes to measure corporate governance. Factor scores were then calculated for each of the utilities. As a first step, the number of factors in the analysis was determined. Appendix table G.7 reports the estimated factors and their eigenvalues. Only factors accounting for more than 10 percent of the variance ­ (eigenvalues >1) were kept in the analysis (the first three factors). 7. These factors allow a factor score coefficient matrix to be computed. The varimax factor rotation method was used to reduce the number of variables that have high loadings on a factor. This method makes it the most likely to identify each variable with a single factor. This approach greatly enhances the ability to make substantive interpretation of the main factors. Appendix table G.8 presents the factor loadings; variables with large loadings (N > 0.4) for a given factor are highlighted in bold. References Andrés, L. A., J. L. Guasch, and S. L. Azumendi. 2011. “Governance in State-Owned Enterprises Revisited: The Cases of Water and Electricity in Latin America and the Caribbean.” Policy Research Working Paper 5747, World Bank, Washington, DC. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2005. Guidelines of Corporate Governance in SOEs. Paris: OECD. Schwartz, K. 2006. Managing Public Water Utilities: An Assessment of Bureaucratic and New Public Management Models in the Water Supply and Sanitation Sectors in Low- and Middle-Income Countries. UNESCO–IHE Institute for Water Education, Delft, the Netherlands. Vagliasindi, M. 2008. Governance Arrangements for State-Owned Enterprises. London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 114 Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises ———. 2009. The Links between Internal and External Governance and the Performance of Infrastructure Service Providers. World Bank, Washington, DC. Whincop, M. J. 2005. Corporate Governance in Government Corporations. Aldershot, U.K.: Ashgate. World Bank. 2009. LAC SOE Governance Database. Washington, DC. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Chapter 6 Other Determinants of Sector Performance This chapter briefly summarizes a number of additional factors that may affect sector performance and examines the interaction of some of them. It reviews and summarizes the results of previous empirical analyses of factors that affect utilities’ decision-making process. These decisions have an impact that can be ­ measured through the indicators proposed in this study. Researchers have modeled and empirically tested the impact of such issues as corruption, market structure, economies of scope and density, renegotiation, and reputation. Some have proposed that other issues—such as subsidy mechanisms, cost recovery, and the political economy and social accountability of the sector— also affect performance. Few econometric studies exist on this connection; most analyses rely on comprehensive analytical case studies. Corruption Corruption can have a destructive effect on sector performance. As previous research suggests, it affects the pace and nature of private sector participation in infrastructure service, affecting competitive bidding and resulting in unequal allocation of bids that can lead to monopoly rents instead of efficiency gains (Andrés, Diop, and Guasch 2008). Corruption directly affects sector performance through multiple transmission mechanisms. Various studies have linked corruption not only with lower levels of investments but also with types of investments, service quality, access, and prices.1 Dal Bó and Rossi (2007) show that corruption diverts managerial effort away from the productive process, forcing firms to use a different (suboptimal) combination of inputs to meet their service obligations. Their model shows that more corrupt countries have less efficient (lower labor productivity) firms. By measuring the impact of corruption on performance and the interaction between reforms (introducing private participation, an independent regulatory agency, or both) and corruption, Estache, Goicoechea, and Trujillo (2009) test Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   115   116 Other Determinants of Sector Performance the extent to which “reform policies have managed to reinforce or offset the impacts of corruption and, vice versa, the extent to which corruption reinforces or offsets the impacts of the policies” (p. 194). Their results show that in ­ electricity distribution, corruption offsets the impact of reforms. An increase in the corruption index results in a decrease in energy use. In countries with state- owned enterprises, an increase in corruption is associated with lower residential prices and deterioration of access and quality. For water, the model is less conclusive, possibly because of the poor quality of the data. ­ In the electricity and telecommunications sectors, the negative interaction between corruption and the introduction of an independent regulatory agency suggests that the presence of these agencies offsets the effects of corruption. Clarke and Xu (2004) provide evidence for the effects of petty corruption at the utility level and the impact on service provision and sector performance.2 They show that corruption increases the constraints on utility capacity and reduces competition among utilities. Cost Recovery Cost recovery is considered the most significant policy aspect explaining water policy performance. Among the seven policy aspects Saleth and Dinar (1999) consider, cost recovery ranks as the most significant in explaining water policy performance.3 They evaluate the overall performance of water institutions and their ultimate impact on performance by studying the linkages between ­ institutions and performance. For example, better water sector performance in China, Mexico, and other countries suggests that macroeconomic policies condition the effectiveness of water policy. Traditionally, utilities have charged ­ tariffs that are far below cost-recovery levels; failure to recover costs was one of the fundamental reasons for promoting private sector participation in fixed ­ telecommunications, electricity distribution, and water distribution during the 1990s in Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC). Low tariffs led to lack of network expansion, low coverage rates, and poor service quality. As poor customers could not (and cannot) afford service at higher prices, subsidy ­ ­ mechanisms were (and remain) part of the price structure in electricity and water. Some studies suggest a link between the type of subsidy mechanism and sector performance, as the mechanism creates incentives for particular behavior from customers that hinders the utility’s ability to maximize its profits and perform efficiently (Komives and others 2005). ­ Role of Civil Society The voice of users is often ignored. The lack of a mechanism for incorporating users’ priorities and preferences into the decision-making processes of the service provider may lead to service deterioration and client estrangement. Muller, Simpson, and van Ginneken (2008) explore innovative approaches to public management that hold service providers more directly accountable to their users Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Other Determinants of Sector Performance 117 for the outcomes of their work. Accountability in this context is about directly channeling users to service providers. A study by the Asian Development Bank (2004) looks at the role of civil society in water provider accountability in 18 Asian cities. It explores priority areas for both users and service providers, such as improving governance and reducing corruption, and suggests that this overlap of priorities may be a power- ful determinant of improved sector performance. Contract Arrangements Investment levels and contract arrangements are significant determinants of effective and equitable public services. Various studies have assessed the ­ challenges, opportunities, and options for public-private partnerships and their impact on sector performance. According to Ogunbiyi (2004), several schemes have had a “negative impact on the poorest of the poor by restricting their access to clean supplies because of high tariffs” (p. 4). Ogunbiyi asserts that public- private partnership schemes involving management contracts—which combine public finance and private management of technical and commercial o ­ perations— could be the best type of contractual arrangement for water supply and s ­ anitation in Africa. In Senegal, for example, the choice of an affermage contract, which was enhanced by the addition of strong financial incentives to reduce leakage and improve billing and collection efficiency, was innovative.4 The contract addressed the needs of the government, kept the assets in the government’s hands, and clearly defined operations and maintenance functions. The nature of the contract fostered a partnership between the government and the private operator. Private Sector Participation and Renegotiation Although renegotiation may be the inevitable consequence of contract incompleteness—and sometimes the solution to some of the inefficiencies ­ caused by it—several authors have identified negative practical consequences. Engel, Fischer, and Galetovic (1997) study the effects of government guaran- tees and renegotiation on the efficiency of the public-private partnership contracts. They find that renegotiations increase the discretion of the govern- ­ ment, reduce the incentives for efficiency, and encourage firms to lowball their bids for the ­projects, especially if they have experience lobbying. Guasch (2004) notes that lowball strategies in the bidding process undermine the effi- ­ llocation—and as a consequence reduce consumer welfare and ciency of the a sector performance. The most relevant research on the relation between renegotiation and ­ lowballing bidding strategies is by Guasch, Kartasheva, and Quesada (2001); Estache and Quesada (2001); Guasch (2004); and others who develop ­ theoretical models in which lowballing is an equilibrium strategy for rational bidders. Guasch and others (2001) provide a quantitative measure of the lowballing Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 118 Other Determinants of Sector Performance effect of the expectations of future renegotiation over bidding strategies. They conclude that renegotiation expectations appear to significantly affect the competitive bidding of public-private partnership infrastructure projects. ­ Disaggregating by the party requesting the renegotiation, they find evidence of a positive effect if the requesting party is the winning firm; the evidence is slightly less clear if the government is the requesting party. Private Sector Participation and Reputation Bajari, Houghton, and Tadelis (2011) develop a structural auction model in which they use data on characteristics of a project to construct highways in California, including the size of ex post adjustments to the original construc- tion budgets, as a measure of the expected extra revenues the firm may obtain after requesting contract renegotiation. As the extra revenues affect the bids at the auction stage less than proportionally, the authors conclude that there is a sizable transaction cost from the renegotiation process. To measure ex ante expectations, Andrés, Diaz, and Guasch (2009) consider the ex post outcome (the occurrence of renegotiation). They model the ­ expectations of renegotiation using ex post occurrences of renegotiation for a given country. Their framework allows them to use more information and eliminate possible bias from the estimation. The results suggest that bidders ­ (especially bidders with the highest valuations for the project) adjust their ­ investment offer upward when renegotiation is a plausible outcome after the concession is awarded. Economies of Scope, Scale, and Density Research to determine the optimal size of utilities focuses on estimating cost or production functions in which firms either minimize costs or maximize profits. Through the use of these types of models, a number of studies have been able to establish the optimal size of a given utility firm and determine the existence or nonexistence of economies of scale and scope in different sectors.5 Additional research has focused on trying to measure the existence of economies of density in electricity and water. Using frontier analysis estimation ­ methods, a number of studies have examined the factors that affect productivity and efficiency at individual firms. These models consider structural variables to account for the potential existence of economies of scale and density. In some cases, the results suggest that settlement density; urban versus rural location (Cullmann, Crespo, and Plagnet 2008); and consumer structure affect the productivity of utilities (von Hirschhausen and Kappeler 2004). By estimating ­ cost functions, several studies show the existence of economies of density and economies of scale for small and medium-size electric utilities. As smaller utilities do not operate at an optimal service level, costs can be reduced by merging and increasing their service area (Filippini 1998; Filippini and Wild 2001). Performance can suffer in low population density service areas, where it is Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Other Determinants of Sector Performance 119 difficult to exploit economies of scale in management and physical plants (Gómez-Ibáñez 2007). Using total factor productivity analysis for a set of utili- ties in Southern Africa, Estache, Tovar, and Trujillo (2007) find a correlation between performance on the one hand and market structure, the existence of a private actor, dependence on the water source, the degree of vertical integration, and the existence of an independent regulator on the other. Under certain conditions, economies or diseconomies of scale and density exist. Models show that there are diseconomies of scale for residential service and economies of scale for nonresidential service. Economies of scale achieved in water treatment are largely lost in the distribution of water; however, utilities experience economies of scope associated with joint production of water and sanitation (Kim and Clark 1988). In a study of four developing countries, Nauges and Van den Berg (2008) show that there are economies of scope in areas where utilities provide both water and sewerage services. Competition in the Telecommunication Sector During the 1990s, both privatization and the introduction of competition in the telecommunications sector were recommended in Latin America. There is broad agreement among academics and practitioners that competition is the most effective method of promoting investments in the telecom sector. A monopoly ­ provider, whether a state-owned enterprise or a private operator, faces fewer incentives to improve service and reduce prices than enterprises operating in a competitive environment (Wallsten 2001). In most countries, liberalization of the long-distance market took place a few years after privatization (Andrés Diop, and Guasch 2008). To identify the effects of competition on performance, the literature uses two proxies for competition: liberalization of long-distance fixed-line telephone service and the existence and coverage of cellular phone providers (as a ­ ­ competitive threat to fixed-line operators). Petrazzini and Clark (1996) find that service coverage is higher in competitive markets. Wallsten (2001) finds that competition is associated with deeper mainline penetration, a larger number of pay phones, greater connectivity capacity, and lower prices for local calls. Andrés, Diop, and Guasch (2008) find that the main driver for sector performance in these markets is private sector participation. When a control variable for private sector participation is included in their model, introducing competition in the market is associated with a reduction in prices. Conclusion This chapter attempts to understand sector performance by examining the ­ performance of individual utilities in Latin American and the Caribbean. By themselves, the factors studied—corruption; cost recovery; civil society; contracts arrangements and their renegotiation; reputation; economies of scope, scale, and density; and competition—may not affect the performance indicators examined in this volume. But direct links (such as subsidy mechanisms that result in tariffs Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 120 Other Determinants of Sector Performance that are below cost-recovery levels, restricting the utility’s financial ability to expand coverage and provide adequate service quality) and indirect links (such as improving social accountability by introducing a mechanism that can hold service providers more directly accountable to users for the outcomes of their work) management and interact to create the incentive framework utilities use to make ­ operation decisions. The objective of this chapter was not to fully explain sector performance but to recognize and acknowledge issues that may affect utility behavior and the type of incentives they have to perform efficiently. Notes 1. For a comprehensive review of recent studies on corruption and infrastructure, see Estache (2008). 2. Clarke and Xu (2004) use a unique dataset for 21 Eastern European countries that includes information about bribes paid to utilities for service provision. 3. These policy aspects are the project selection criteria, the cost-recovery status, the effectiveness of interregional/sectoral water transfer policy, the extent of the impact of government policy toward private sector and user participation, the effects of other economic policies on water policy, and the extent of linkage between water law and water policy. 4. In an affermage contract, the private utility operates a publicly owned system and ­ collects revenues that it then shares with the public owner, who remains in charge of investment. 5. For water supply, Kim and Clark (1988) study the effects of economies of scale and scope in a multiproduct utility, using a translog multiproduct joint cost function. For electricity, Hjalmarsson and Veiderpass (1992) use data envelope analysis to examine productivity growth and the effects of economies of density in retail ­ distribution in Sweden. electricity ­ References ADB (Asian Development Bank). 2004. Water in Asian Cities: Utilities Performance and Civil Society Views. Water for All Series No. 10, Manila: ADB. Andrés, L., J. G. Diaz, and J. L. Guasch. 2009. An Empirical Study of the Effects of Renegotiations over the Auctioning of PPP Concessions. World Bank, Washington, DC. Andrés, L., M. Diop, and J. L. Guasch. 2008. “Achievements and Challenges of Private Participation in Infrastructure in Latin America: Evaluation and Future Prospects.” In  Euromoney Infrastructure Financing, edited by H. Davis. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. Bajari, P., S. Houghton, and S. Tadelis. 2011. “Bidding for Incomplete Contracts: An Empirical Analysis of Adaptation Costs.” Working Paper, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis. Clarke, G. R. G., and L. C. Xu. 2004. “Privatization, Competition, and Corruption: How Characteristics of Bribe Takers and Payers Affect Bribes to Utilities.” Journal of Public Economics 88: 2067–2097. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Other Determinants of Sector Performance 121 Cullmann, A., H. Crespo, and M. Plagnet. 2008. “International Benchmarking in Electricity Distribution: A Comparison of French and German Utilities.” DIW Discussion Paper 830, German Institute for Economic Research, Berlin. Dal Bó, E., and M. A. Rossi. 2007. “Corruption and Inefficiency: Theory and Evidence from Electric Utilities.” Journal of Public Economics 91 (5–6): 939–62. Engel, E., R. Fischer, and A. Galetovic. 1997. “Infrastructure Franchising and Government Guarantees.” In Dealing with Public Risk in Private Infrastructure, edited by T. Irwin, M. Klein, G. Perry, and M. Thobani, 89–118. Washington, DC: World Bank. Estache, A. 2008. “Infrastructure and Development: A Survey of Recent and Upcoming Issues.” In Rethinking Infrastructure for Development: Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, edited by F. Bourguignon and B. Pleskovic, 47–82. Washington, DC: World Bank. Estache, A., A. Goicoechea, and L. Trujillo. 2009. “Utilities Reforms and Corruption in Developing Countries.” Utilities Policy 17 (2): 191–202. Estache, A., and L. Quesada. 2001. “Concession Contract Renegotiations: Some Efficiency versus Equity Dilemmas.” Policy Research Working Paper 2705, World Bank, Washington, DC. Estache A., B. Tovar, and L. Trujillo. 2007. “Are African Electricity Distribution Companies Efficient? Evidence of Southern African Countries.” Discussion Paper, Department of Economics, City University, London. Filippini, M. 1998. “Are Municipal Electricity Distribution Utilities Natural Monopolies?” Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 69 (2): 157–74. Filippini, M., and J. Wild. 2001. “Regional Differences in Electricity Distribution Costs and Their Consequences for Yardstick Regulation of Access Prices.” Energy Economics 23 (4): 477–88. Gómez-Ibáñez, A. J. 2007. “Private Infrastructure in Developing Countries: Lessons from Recent Experience.” Paper presented to the Commission on Growth and Development, “Workshop on Global Trends and Challenges,” Yale Center for the Study of Globalization, New Haven, CT, September 28–29. Guasch, J. L. 2004. Granting and Renegotiating Infrastructure Concessions: Doing it Right. Washington, DC: World Bank. Guasch, J. L., A. Kartasheva, and L. Quesada. 2001. “Concession Contracts in Latin America and Caribbean Region: An Economic Analysis and Empirical Evidence.” Working Paper, World Bank, Washington, DC. Hjalmarsson, L., and A. Veiderpass. 1992. “Productivity in Swedish Electricity Retail Distribution.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 94 (Supplement): 193–205. Kim, H. Y., and M. R. Clark. 1988. “Economies of Scale and Scope in Water Supply.” Regional Science and Urban Economics 18 (4): 479–502. Komives, K., V. Foster, J. Halpern, and Q. Wodon. 2005. Water, Electricity and the Poor: Who Benefits from Utility Subsidies? Directions in Development. Washington, DC: World Bank. Muller, M., R. Simpson, and M. van Ginneken. 2008. “Ways to Improve Water Services by Making Utilities More Accountable to Their Users: A Review.” Water Working Notes, World Bank, Washington, DC. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 122 Other Determinants of Sector Performance Nauges, C., and C. van den Berg. 2008. “Economies of Density, Scale and Scope in the Water Supply and Sewerage Sector: A Study of Four Developing and Transition Economies.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 34: 144–63. Ogunbiyi, C. 2004. “PPPs: Fad or Good for SADC?” SADC PPP Pathway, SADC Banking Association PPP Capacity Building Programme, Newsletter No. 1, July. Petrazzini, B. A., and T. H. Clark. 1996. “Costs and Benefits of Telecommunications Liberalization in Developing Countries.” Paper presented at Institute for International Economics, “Liberalizing Telecommunications,” Washington, DC, January 29. Saleth, R. M., and A. Dinar. 1999. “Evaluating Water Institutions and Water Sector Performance.” Technical Paper 447, World Bank, Washington, DC. von Hirschhausen, C., and A. Kappeler. 2004. “Productivity Analysis of German Electricity Distribution Utilities.” DIW Discussion Paper 418, German Institute for Economic Research, Berlin. Wallsten, S. 2001. Reverse Auctions and Universal Telecommunications Service: Lessons from Global Experience. Technology Policy Institute, Stanford University, Stanford, CA. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Chapter 7 Conclusions As a result of reforms, Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC) witnessed significant improvements in the performance of the electricity distribution, ­ water and sanitation, and fixed telecommunications sectors. In the early 2000s, however, public and private investment declined significantly, dissatisfaction with some of the policies implemented during the 1990s rose, and poor people found it difficult to secure access to affordable services. Against this backdrop, the analysis examined several determinants that affected sector performance between 1990 and 2006. By analyzing trends in ­ sector perfor- mance and several of its determinants, this analysis provides the empirical knowl- edge and foundation necessary for meeting the infrastructure challenges the region currently faces. Understanding the various interventions and conditions that explain sector performance is critical to reducing the region’s infrastructure gap. The results of this book can be summarized in three main messages:1 1. Performance in all three sectors improved significantly, but there is still much room for improvement. Between 1990 and 2006, coverage, service quality, and labor productivity in all three sectors improved. • Coverage for the utilities covered in the databases increased to 95 percent in electricity, 97 percent in water, and 62 percent in fixed telecommunica- tions by 2005. • The quality of service also improved: the frequency of electricity interrup- percent, tions fell nearly by half, the continuity of water service increased 8 ­ and the number of annual telephone faults declined from 23 to 8. • Private sector participation had a positive effect on labor productivity, efficiency, and quality. ­ • Introducing Independent Regulatory Agencies in the electricity and water promoted gradual improvements in performance. sectors ­ • Service provision improved in both private and public companies. Although the average top private performer outperformed the top public utility, some top public utilities ­ outperformed average private utilities. • Smaller companies outperformed larger companies. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   123   124 Conclusions • Some countries were top performers in electricity, others in water. • The differences in performance across utilities suggest that different approaches and variables contribute to good performance. The results usually depend on initial ­ ­ conditions and implementation mechanisms. Part of the heterogeneity in performance is explained by regulatory governance arrangements, the degree of private sector participation, and the ­governance design of state-owned enterprises (SOEs). 2. Both the government (as a regulator and a service provider) and the private sector (as a service provider) can play active roles in enhancing sector performance. Introducing private sector participation alone was not the answer to better sector performance. Although the government continues to be at the heart of infrastructure service delivery, private sector participation was an important partner in improving sector performance. However, the manner in which private sector participation was developed determined the extent of its impact ­ on performance. By promoting transparent and accountable r ­ egulatory gover- nance design, the government can make positive contributions to sector per- formance. An independent regulatory agency free of political interference and accountable for its decisions significantly improves utility performance, even for SOEs. SOEs that have a corporate governance structure that reduces politi- cal interference, rewards performance, and opens decisions to public scrutiny perform better than SOEs that allow politics to influence decision making. 3. Improving sector performance requires a holistic and case-based approach that goes beyond conducting a comprehensive assessment of a key determinant and proposing specific designs that address issues related to that determinant. It entails an approach that integrates policies that address a wide range of issues. By acknowl- edging and determining the differences among service providers and the environments in which they operate, policy makers can design ­ ­ comprehensive solutions to complex problems in infrastructure service provision. This book describes and benchmarks the region’s good and poor utility ­ performers. It calls on further analytical work to explain how the various determinants interact and affect specific performance indicators and why there ­ are such large differences across countries and utilities. An in-depth analysis of the facts presented here would allow additional conclusions to be drawn about the trends and changes that characterize the region. A thorough understanding of how and why regional, country, and utility performance improved or worsened will allow countries to share their ­ experiences and learn from one another by assessing what has worked and what ­ has not. By doing so, stakeholders can work together to establish the strongest possible foundation for efficient and reliable sectors in the future. Future ­ analytical work can target potential audiences, such as the private sector, utility managers, political decision makers, policy makers, and regulators, among others, providing potential users with the knowledge and tools to move ahead and providing policy makers with the impetus for future reform. ­ Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Conclusions 125 To move ahead, it is also important to maintain, update, and improve the ­ uality of the data on infrastructure, so that they remain an ongoing resource for q the World Bank and the community at large. Efforts to continue data collection and analysis are crucial if the Bank is to provide a resource that remains useful for LAC and other regions. Utility sector performance encompasses a variety of dimensions. Impacts on each of these dimensions are not necessarily straightforward, with differences determined by sector and internal and external environments. Policy makers considering sector reforms should first prioritize their performance objectives. Once the objectives are identified, the detailed results presented by the analysis can be mined to determine the circumstances in which the objectives can be achieved. For instance, if a utility prioritizes quality and efficiency over retaining employees, private sector participation would be an attractive option. If reducing distributional losses in an SOE is a key objective, a sound design of the ­enterprise’s corporate governance with well-designed performance orientation rules could be considered. The results presented in this book highlight pitfalls in sector reform programs. Identifying in advance problems associated with poor design and faulty implementation—problems that explain many of the shortcomings in reform ­ processes—can help policy makers design proactive counter measures. Consider the case of an electricity distribution policy maker who has prioritized improving quality and reducing distributional losses—and hence decided to move ahead with private sector participation. By drawing lessons from the experience detailed in this analysis, policy makers could design a public relations campaign emphasizing expected benefits and warning consumers of potential price increases and reductions in sector employment. The analysis in this book can help policy makers make informed decisions and well-designed change strategies, allowing them to maximize both technical and political objectives. The analysis indicates that programs and reforms could have been i ­ mplemented better. Overall results were quite positive, but perceptions appear quite negative. To achieve greater benefits and higher popular approval, in some countries the process of introducing private sector participation could have been better prepared and communicated. The context in which the programs of private ­ sector participation were developed in the region was one of excessive optimism, ­ a belief in quick positive profits, too many promises, a lack of realism, poor ­ handling of expectations, and a constant breach in contractual agreements by both parties. Social distribution and lack of transparency throughout the process appear as common denominators. By creating an environment that maximizes the benefits of reform and promotes a broad consensus, reform programs in the infrastructure sectors can be ­ successfully implemented. In moving forward, the lessons from the past need to be accounted for and corrected. The ultimate objective is to improve sector performance and long-term efficiency; reduce poverty, through better concession ­ design and regulation; and foster compliance with the terms agreed to by both the government and the operator. To ensure that these objectives are met, concession Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 126 Conclusions laws and contracts should focus on securing long-term sector efficiency and proper risk assignments and mitigation, as well as discouraging opportunistic bidding and renegotiation; be embedded in regulations that foster transparency ­ and predictability, support incentives for efficient behavior, impede opportunistic renegotiation, and force contract compliance; address social ­concerns and focus on poverty; and promote accountability as the main g ­ overnance aspect of SOEs. Governments remain at the heart of infrastructure service delivery. SOEs that have a corporate governance structure that reduces political interference, rewards performance, and opens decisions to public scrutiny perform better than SOEs that have a structure that allows politics to influence decision making. Furthermore, even with private sector participation, there may be a need for public involvement. Governments need to regulate infrastructure provision as well as contribute a significant share of investment. They must leverage their resources to attract complementary financing. They are also responsible for setting distributional objectives and ensuring that resources and policies are ­ ­ available to increase access for the poor. Infrastructure service provision requires well-performing SOEs and private companies that can disseminate good practices and, with the government, finance capital investments. Raising private sector participation to previous levels requires addressing past problems and building on lessons learned. Under the current environment, in which infrastructure competes with other investments for financial resources, increasing transparency and improving the risk profile for projects rise as necessary conditions for further development. Regulatory risk must fall, and better risk mitigation mechanisms need to be developed for private perceptions participation in infrastructure. In some countries, very negative public ­ of private participation in infrastructure represent a serious constraint on further participation that needs to be addressed. Changing these perceptions requires greater transparency, improved transaction design and oversight to reduce renegotiations and poor performance, and better management of providers that ­ stand to lose out. Making new reforms sustainable requires that not only the technical and financial aspects but also the social aspects most responsible for the backlash be addressed. Better communication is critical to create popular support. It is ­ essential to promote programs’ infrastructure improvements, publicize i ­ nitiatives, explain the impact of failing to improve the status quo, and realistically present the program’s cost-benefit tradeoff. The communication strategy must not only justify programs but also periodically inform on their progress as well as any changes or problems. It is not enough that reforms be successful: their success must be communicated. Experiences in the region show that the key elements of a successful program must include the following: • Improved institutional context. Projects generally should be selected by the sectoral ministry, based on the country’s strategic planning program and ­ objectives. An interministerial group should be led by the finance minister Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Conclusions 127 to evaluate and approve the projects (accompanied by the appropriate economic and financial analysis) identified by the sectors. ­ • Improved contract and concession design. Concession contracts should be awarded competitively—rather than through direct adjudication or bilateral negotiation—and designed to avoid ambiguities as much as possible. Contracts should be carefully designed and reviewed, and the qualifications of bidders should be screened. Outcome targets (regulation by objectives or service levels) rather than investment obligations (regulation by means) should be ­ the norm. Contracts should clearly define the treatment of assets, evaluation of investments, outcome indicators, procedures and guidelines to adjust and review tariffs, and criteria and penalties for early termination of concessions and procedures for resolution of conflicts. The sanctity of the bid is essential. For private sector participation to be successful and achieve the desired objectives, contracts and regulations need to be designed and enforced ­ ­ appropriately. The key objective should be to ensure that the contracting parties comply with the agreed conditions. ­ • Stronger regulatory framework. An appropriate regulatory framework and agency should be in place, with sufficient autonomy and implementation capacity to ensure high-quality enforcement and deter political opportunism. In addition, the tradeoffs between types of regulation—price cap and rate of return—should be well understood, including their different allocations of risk and implications for renegotiation. Technical regulation should fit information requirements and existing risks, and regulation should be by ­ objectives, not by means. Performance objectives should be used instead of investment obligations. • Proper regulatory instruments. Proper regulatory accounting of all assets and liabilities should be in place to avoid any ambiguity about the valuation of assets and liabilities and the regulatory treatment and allocation of cost, investments, the asset base, revenues, transactions with related parties, management fees, and operational and financial variables. Cost and financial ­ models of the regulated utility should be standard regulatory instruments to assess performance, with emphasis on the evaluation of the cost of capital. Extensive use of benchmarking should be common best practice of regulatory agencies; it is critical to assess the efficiency of operations and conduct ordinary five-year tariff reviews. ­ • Better corporate governance. Accountability emerges as the main governance aspect of SOEs. In companies with high levels of corruption and inefficiency, accountability systems should prevent discretional management (both from management and political authorities) and create incentives for good performance. Regulation and performance-based management could be ­ considered complementary ways of achieving these goals, although care needs ­ Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 128 Conclusions to be taken in creating checks and balances such as parliamentary oversight and tailoring state auditing. An important observation is related to the importance of ­ governance strategies to companies’ realities. For utilities with partial state ownership, particularly utilities with significant private sector ­ participation, a governance design reflecting the incentives of private e ­nterprises seems appropriate. For companies with significant gaps in p ­ erformance and manage- ment, transparent accountability mechanisms should be considered. Fully state- owned utilities characterized by good sector performance and management need to strike a balance between private ­ sector orientation and public accountability. Governance design needs to take sector differences into ­ consideration. Technology and sector dynamics also ­ ­ determine management. • Inclusion of social tariffs. Social tariffs should be a standard component of all programs. Programs that subsidize access for the poor should be a part of all relevant projects, and programs and policies should be implemented to support adversely affected workers. Involving affected communities from the ­ start, at least in a consultative process, should be an integral part of any reform. Initiatives should be launched and supported from the bottom up in areas and locations where the benefits and costs will be incurred. • Greater transparency and better communications. Communication serves as a safeguard against corruption at all levels and as a tool for garnering popular support. Better communication is also essential to promote the program’s infrastructure improvements, publicize the initiative, explain the likely impact and the consequences of maintaining the status quo, and realistically describe the program’s cost-benefit tradeoff. The communication must not only justify the programs, it must also periodically inform on the program’s progress, as well as any changes or problems. The success of reforms must be communi- cated. Greater transparency in the overall process, financing, and use of funds critical to safeguard against corruption at all levels and obtain greater p is ­ ­ opular support. • Evaluation and monitoring. It is essential to periodically evaluate the ­ accomplishments to improve efficiency and achieve the expected results, and broadly communicate advances and pitfalls. Sector performance should play a major role in defining sectoral reforms. Modalities of private sector participation beyond strict privatization and proper corporate governance design for SOEs offer significant potential for improving sector performance. In particular, chances of success will be increased for ­ programs that comply with the above-listed elements. Improvements in infrastructure for growth and poverty cannot be delayed. There are significant threats and opportunities. Most countries, including in LAC, are at a crossroads on how to improve sector performance. Success may require some form of private sector involvement and financing. If obstacles such as poor Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Conclusions 129 perception of private sector participation are not removed, the significant gains and the very necessary modernization of the sector might fail, and private financing will prove costly if not difficult. Conversely, opportunity exists to refine ­ the model, by attacking the problems and deficiencies of the past, through second-generation reforms that are constructive and broadly participatory. ­ New reform processes that incorporate lessons learned with the clear p ­ articipation of all stakeholders and a key role for the public sector are crucial. Note 1. Other determinants also affect sector performance, but their interactions have not yet been thoroughly evaluated. These factors include corruption, market structure, the potential for contract renegotiation and reputation, the type of contract arrangements for service provision, and the existence of social accountability ­ ­ mechanisms. Because the main objective of this book is to provide a factual descrip- ­ olicies that could be empirically tested and analyzed, its scope tion of changes and p was restricted to some of the potential policies that could be developed within the sectors. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Appendix A Empirical Approach We will follow a similar approach to econometric method proposed by Andrés and others (2008). The main difference is that we will build dummies for each characteristic and we will interact them with the ownership dummies both methodologies. In order to identify the effects of the characteristics we will modify (1’) and (2’) as follows: In( yijt ) = d T DUM_ TRAN ijt * X ijt + d P DUM_ POSTijt * Xijt ∑f D + v (1”) + ij ij ijt ij In( yijt ) = d T DUM_ TRAN ijt * X ijt + d P DUM_ POSTijt * Xijt (2”) + ∑f D + ∑q t ij ij ij ij ij ij + v ijt where 1 if s ijt ≥ −1  DUM_TRAN ijt  0 otherwise  and 1 if s ijt ≥ 2  DUM_POSTijt  0 otherwise  where sijt is a time trend that has a value equal to zero for the past year when the company had a public owner. Now, d   T, that was a scalar number in our previous specifications, became a vector with the coefficients for each charac- teristic of the vector Xijt than is of the form 1, x1 N ( ) ijt ,..., x ijt with N as the total number of characteristics evaluated. Note that the specifications used by Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   131   132 Empirical Approach Andrés and others (2008) were a particular case when we use a vector Xijt equal to (1,0,...,0). In this case, the first coefficient will identify the average effect of change in ownership during the transitional period on a given ­ indicator. As soon as we use the specification proposed in this appendix, the first coefficient of the vector d   T will become the average effect of change in ownership during the t ­ ­ ransitional period on a given indicator for a firm without the characteristics evaluated in the other elements of the vector Xijt. Equivalently, the vector d  P will contain the coefficients for the different characteristics of vector Xijt, but for the posttransitional years. ­ As suggested by Andrés and others (2008), there are some indicators that present time trends. For this reason, firm-specific time trend analysis, as shown in equation (2") is a better indicator. Again, this relies on the assumption that trends between the three periods of analysis are the same. In order to relax this assump- tion, we run a second set of equations (1”) but using the (log) annual growth in each indicator. In this case, it will identify average changes in growth between the periods. Given the fact that we are using a semilogarithmic functional form of these models for each of the indicators, when interpreting the coefficient estimates of the dummy, it should be remembered that the percentage impact in each indicator is given by ed − 1 (Halvorsen and Palmquist 1980). ­ In order to correct for potential nonspherical errors, a Generalized Least Square (GLS) approach will be more adequate. But, the GLS estimation requires the knowledge of the unconditional variance matrix of vijt, Ω, up to scale. Hence, we must be able to write Ω = s  2C, where C is a known G×G positive definite matrix. But, in our case, as this matrix is not known, our second set of estimators will be a Feasible GLS (FGLS) that replaces the unknown matrix Ω with consistent estimator. a ­ References Andrés, L., J. L. Guasch, T. Haven, and V. Foster. 2008. The Impact of Private Sector Participation in Infrastructure: Lights, Shadows, and the Road Ahead. Washington, DC: World Bank. Halvorsen, R., and R. Palmquist. 1980. “The Interpretation of Dummy Variables in Semilogarithmic Equations.” American Economic Review 70: 474–75. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Appendix B Data Sets Seven data sets were used and merged to provide a comprehensive analysis in this analysis. The performance indicators data set developed for this analysis is unique because of the comprehensiveness of the indicators and sectoral coverage. The data also have a relatively long time span, starting in 1995 and continuing until 2005–07, depending on the sector. Data were collected from a variety of sources and was cross-checked, when possible. A particular effort was made in corroborating the company data with several public sources and with data of the firms provided by different government offices. In addition, the research was particularly cautious about the consistency and comparability of the data. In order to ensure high data quality and consistency, appropriate calculations and approximations were made to construct missing data points. For example, through the method of interpolation, data were constructed for the earlier years of certain variables, such as number of connections, number of employees, and so on. However, interpolation and other means of constructing data were the excep- tion, and when used, were based on already concrete data and time trends. Specific methodologies were designed according to the variables at hand to ensure their comparability and consistency across time and utilities.1 The data sets are the following: Performance Indicators Data Set The performance indicators data set developed for Andrés and others (2008) is unique because of the comprehensiveness of the indicators and sectoral coverage. It covers 181 infrastructure firms in Latin America that changed from public to private ownership during the 1990s. Many studies look only at the financial performance of privatized companies, which is just part of the story; this analysis ­ coverage, considers changes in output, labor, efficiency, labor productivity, quality, ­ and prices. In terms of sectors, the analysis includes the often-neglected water and electricity distribution sectors, in addition to fixed telecommunications. The analysis focuses on these sectors because of data availability and because they present similar characteristics (in the sense that they all have monopolistic fea- tures and are networking markets, allowing for similar interpretations of such Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   133   134 Data Sets indicators as labor productivity, coverage, and distributional losses), a feature that allows for cross-sectoral comparison. For these reasons, other sectors, such as transport, mobile telecommunications, and generation and transmission of elec- tricity, among others, were excluded from the analysis. The data also have a relatively long time span, starting five years before the change in ownership and continuing five years after that. The time span allows for the separation of short-run or transitional effects from long-run results. How short- and long-run effects are separated is discussed in the following ­methodology sections. The database targeted utilities privatized mainly in the period from 1990 to 2003—the main private sector participation wave in the region. The database also includes a few companies changed ownership during the 1980s (in cases in which data from the period before private sector participation were available). Data were gathered from a variety of sources and was cross-checked, when possible. This research required the construction of an unbalanced panel data set of key indicators for utilities in Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC). For this, official data reported to investors by the firms and statistical reports of the regu- latory agencies of each country was used. Information was requested from each of the companies, as well as from each regulatory office. Furthermore, additional sources were used, such as ITU (International Telecommunication Union) and OLADE (Organización Latinoamericana de Energía, Latin American Organization of Energy). A particular effort was made in corroborating the company data with several public sources and with data of the firms provided by different govern- ment offices. In addition, the research was particularly cautious about the consis- tency and comparability of the data across time and across countries.2 The analysis focused on several indicators of outcomes, employment, labor productivity, efficiency, quality, coverage, and prices. Some of these variables have been used by other authors in other samples, such as Ros (1999), who used equivalent indicators for coverage, labor productivity, quality, and prices, but did so for the telecommunications sector. Ramamurti (1996) used analogous indicators in output, coverage, and labor productivity for the four Latin American telecom- munications firms of his study. Saal and Parker (2001) used similar indicators for output, employment, quality, and prices, but did so for water and sewerage compa- nies of England and Wales. The countries analyzed in electricity distribution were Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, El Salvador, Guatemala, Nicaragua, Panama, and Peru. The sample consists of unbalanced panel data that includes 116 firms and 1,103 firm-year observations. Each of the firms included in the sample contains at least one year of data from the period before private sector participation. In fact, 98 of the 116 firms have information for at least the previous three years. For water and sewerage, the paper reviewed companies in Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, and Trinidad and Tobago. The sample consists of unbalanced panel data that includes 49 firms and 515 firm-year observations. Each of the firms included in the sample contains at least one year of data from the period before private sector participation, and 35 of the 49 firms have infor- mation for at least the previous two years. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Data Sets 135 The countries studied for the telecommunication sector were Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, El Salvador, Guatemala, Guyana, Jamaica, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Peru, Trinidad and Tobago, and República Bolivariana de Venezuela. The sample consists of unbalanced panel data that includes 16 firms and 267 firm-year observations. Each of the firms included in the ­sample contains at least four years of data from the period before private sector participation, and 17 out of the 18 firms have information for at least the previous four years. Table 2.1 presents the definitions of the variables used in the present analysis. LAC Electricity Distribution Benchmarking Database The LAC electricity distribution benchmarking database was built by the World Bank (Andrés and Dragoiu 2008) and contains annual information of 250 private and state-owned utilities using 26 variables indicating coverage, output, input, labor productivity, operating performance, quality and customer ­ services, and prices. The time frame covers data from as early as 1990, but the main focus is the period from 1995 to 2005. Data availability and data sources vary by country, often times depending on their ownership and means of regula- tion. Although the benchmarking study uses a homogenous set of variables to collect data and measure performance, each country represents a special case and therefore efforts were made to ensure consistency of the data across time and utility. This database is representative of 89 percent of the electrification in the region (see table B.1). Furthermore, we argue that there is no significant self- selection in this database due the high data coverage. More precisely, most of the countries in the region were covered with at least 75 percent of the electricity connections in the ­ country. The only countries not covered were Cuba, Guyana, Haiti, Trinidad and Tobago, and some other islands in the Caribbean. The primary means of conducting research was field data collection and in- house data collection. A standard template and set of variables were used by both field and in-house consultants. Field consultants collected data to complement the information in some of the countries. Because of limited information available on the Web for these countries, local consultants were the most ­ resourceful. For these selected countries and utilities, a preliminary feasibility screening was conducted to determine which countries would be likely to pro- vide information. Although field workers had direct access to the respective util- ity and government, the process of data collection was often hindered by unexpected factors, such as political affairs, bureaucracy, un-systematized data, and confidentiality issues, among other elements. The main sources for the in-house data collection were the World Wide Web, information collected by World Bank staff for other projects, and the internal World Bank databases (Development Data Platform, Integrated Records and Information System [IRIS], and so on). The main sources of information on the Internet were the utilities’ Web sites. For some countries, the following sources proved to be useful: regulators, ministries, partnerships, central banks, online financial journals, papers, loan reports, financial reports, annual reports, monthly Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 136 Table B.1 Electricity Coverage and Data Coverage (Base Year = 2005) Electricity coverage LAC Electricity Benchmarking Households with power (census dara; several sources) Population (source: WDI & ITU) Database connection % Urban % Rural % Total Total % Urban Total HH (own calculation) Residential CXs % Total CXs Argentina 70 95.4 38,747,148 9140.0 10,530,123 10,045,737 9,252,165 92 Bolivia 85 28 64.4 9,182,015 6420.0 2,135,003 1,374,942 942,805 69 Brazil 96.5 186,830,759 8420.0 54,223,593 52,325,767 49,600,000 95 Chile 90 98.6 16,295,102 8760.0 4,791,755 4,724,670 4,486,053 95 Colombia 93 55 86.1 42,889,000 7360.0 9,028,323 7,773,386 7,773,386 100 Costa Rica 100 87 98.5 4,327,228 6170.0 1,006,053 990,962 990,962 100 Cuba 11,259,905 7560.0 3,188,425 – Dominican Republic 40 82.5 9,469,601 6680.0 2,704,434 2,231,158 844,613 38 Ecuador 96 54 90.3 13,060,993 6360.0 2,902,443 2,620,906 2,620,906 100 El Salvador 97 72 79.5 6,668,356 5980.0 1,531,173 1,217,283 1,191,459 98 Guatemala 78.6 12,709,564 4720.0 2,955,713 2,323,190 1,583,268 68 Guyana 739,472 2820.0 198,842 – Haiti 45 36.0 9,296,291 4270.0 2,067,902 744,445 – 0 Honduras 94 45 69.0 6,834,110 4650.0 1,558,640 1,075,462 809,843 75 Jamaica 92.0 2,650,400 5270.0 764,827 703,641 491,452 70 Mexico 100 95 96.0 103,089,133 7630.0 24,703,635 23,715,490 23,715,490 100 Nicaragua 90 40 69.3 5,462,539 5590.0 974,652 675,434 534,886 79 Panama 85.2 3,231,502 7080.0 787,808 671,213 606,127 90 Paraguay 85.8 5,898,651 5850.0 1,453,110 1,246,769 871,717 70 Trinidad and Tobago 1,323,722 1220.0 351,709 – Uruguay 95.4 3,305,723 9200.0 1,322,289 1,261,464 1,091,523 87 Venezuela, RB 98.6 26,577,000 9230.0 5,945,522 5,862,285 4,802,261 82 Othersa 90 6,303,557 83.6 1,969,846 1,772,861 230,707 LAC 91.6 553,426,037 77.1 143,019,699 131,006,044 116,036,948 89 a. Antigua and Barbuda, Aruba, The Bahamas, Barbados, Belize, Cayman Islands, Dominica, Grenada, the Netherlands Antilles, Puerto Rico, St. Kitts and Nevis, St. Lucia, St. Vincent and the Grenadines, Suriname, and Virgin Islands (U.S.). Data Sets 137 bulletins, statistics offices, and contacts with the companies and regulators. In addition, the following associations and organizations provided valuable statistics for the region: ARIAE (Asociación Iberoamericana de Entidades Reguladores de Energía), ECLAC (Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean), IEA (International Energy Agency), and CIER (Comisión de Integración Energética Regional). Because regulators, international organizations, and commissions often cover the electricity distribution of the entire region, most of the information provided was aggregated at the country level and not disaggregated by utility. One of the challenges of data collection was the inconsistency between the data provided by utilities or regulators in annual and financial reports. To best describe the efficiency of the distribution sector of LAC, indicators were selected to determine utility-level performance. The utility-level indicators reflect relevant and feasible measurements in depicting the distribution segment of the electricity sector. The utility-level indicators were computed to measure such factors as technical efficiency, operating efficiency, cost-efficiency, quality of service, and so on. Technical efficiency is defined as the capacity of the utility to achieve maximum output from a given set of inputs. To compute the technical efficiency of a utility, output and input indicators reflecting operating- and cost- efficiency were aggregated. Table B.2 is a statistics summary for the datasets used in this analysis. We have calculated the number of observations, mean, standard deviation, minimum, and maximum, for the main indicators. The statistics show the heterogeneity and comprehensiveness of the data. The LAC Electricity benchmarking dataset includes information for 250 utili- ties in 26 countries. The size of the utilities varies between over 17 million con- nections and as little as 289 connections. The dataset includes the information Table B.2 LAC Electricity Distribution Benchmarking Database—Summary Statistics Electricity Observations Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum Number of utilities 250 Total connections (millions) 247 432,697 1,308,686 289 17,900,000 Total residential connections 247 377,889 1,147,699 251 15,800,000 Total energy sold (GWh) 248 2,605.0 8,997.4 4.1 111,000.0 Employees 235 1,244 3,062 13 36,942 Distribution losses (%) 221 16.1 8.6 1.6 49.8 Average duration of interruptions per subscriber 149 26.1 33.2 0.5 209.2 Frequency of interruptions per subscriber 137 27.6 47.7 1.0 285.2 Coverage (%) 151 78.8 17.0 28.1 100.0 Residential connection per worker 231 392.9 273.5 58.3 2,694.1 Average GWh sold per worker 230 1.8 1.4 0.14 11.8 Note: Each observation in this table corresponds to the simple average (across all the years with available information) for each utility. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 138 Data Sets for most of the largest companies in the region, and some of the smaller compa- nies. Evidence of this also is the difference in the energy sold yearly by each company. The utility with the lowest total energy sold sells 4.1 GWh a year, while the utility with the largest total energy sold sells 111,000 GWh a year. Distributional losses range between 1.6 and almost 50 percent of the energy produced. In terms of quality, the indicators that show the differences among the observations in the sample are average duration of interruptions per sub- scriber, and frequency of interruptions per subscriber. The minimum and maxi- mum for these indicators are respectively 0.5 and 209 minutes and 1.0 and 285.2 times. Labor productivity varies between 58.3 and 2,694 connections per employee, and 0.14 and 11.8 GWh sold per employee. Average number of employees varies between 13 and 36,942. LAC Water and Sanitation Benchmarking Database The LAC Water and Sanitation benchmarking database was built by the World Bank (World Bank 2009) and contains annual information for 1,700 ­private and state-owned utilities using 34 variables indicating coverage, output, input, labor productivity, operating performance, quality and customer services, and prices. The time frame covers data as early as 1990, but the main focus is the period from 1995 to 2006. Data availability and data sources vary by country, often times depending on their ownership and means of regulation. Although the benchmarking study uses a homogenous set of variables to collect data and mea- sure performance, each country represents a special case and therefore efforts were made to ensure consistency of the data across time and utility. This data- base is representative of 59 percent of the water connections in the region (see table B.3). Furthermore, most of the main utilities in the region covering urban areas were included in this database. The only countries not covered were Cuba, the Dominican Republic, Guatemala, Guyana, Haiti, Jamaica, República Bolivariana de Venezuela, and some other islands in the Caribbean. The primary means of conducting research was in-house and direct data collection. A standard template and set of variables were used to collect the ­ information. Because of limited information available on the Web for these coun- tries, where feasible the information was requested directly from regulatory and sectoral agencies. In some cases, the utilities provided the information directly by ­ completing the template. The main sources for the in-house data collection were the World Wide Web, information collected by World Bank staff for other projects, and the internal World Bank databases (Development Data Platform, IRIS, and so on). The main sources of information on the Internet were the utilities’ Web sites. For some countries, the following sources proved to be useful: regulators, ministries, part- nerships, journals, papers, loan reports, financial reports, annual reports, monthly bulletins, statistics offices, and contacts with the companies and regulators. In addition, the following associations and organizations provided valuable statistics for the region: ADERASA (Asociación de Entes Reguladores de Agua Potable y Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Table B.3  Water Coverage and Data Coverage (Base Year = 2004) LAC Water Benchmarking Households with Water coverage (source: JMP) Population (source: WDI & ITU) Database water connection % Urban % Rural % Total Total % Urban Total HH (own calculation) Residential CXs % Total CXs Argentina 83 45 79.6 38,371,527 91.1 10,419,503 8,297,383 4,669,379 56 Bolivia 90 44 73.3 9,009,045 63.7 2,086,000 1,529,272 1,227,044 80 Brazil 91 17 78.9 184,317,696 83.6 51,939,168 40,961,306 37,100,000 91 Chile 99 38 91.2 16,123,815 87.3 4,741,622 4,325,715 3,555,960 82 Colombia 96 51 84.0 42,306,000 73.3 8,733,700 7,334,998 4,344,921 59 Costa Rica 99 81 92.0 4,253,037 61.2 989,172 910,125 397,902 44 Cuba 82 49 73.9 11,246,670 75.6 3,181,522 2,352,672 – 0 Dominican Republic 92 62 81.8 9,324,633 65.9 2,663,357 2,177,986 – 0 Ecuador 82 45 68.3 12,917,362 62.9 2,870,525 1,960,218 617,605 32 El Salvador 81 38 63.6 6,576,008 59.5 1,542,091 980,671 545,223 56 Guatemala 89 65 76.2 12,396,581 46.8 2,817,405 2,147,629 – 0 Guyana 66 45 50.9 738,992 28.3 197,004 100,351 – 0 Haiti 24 3 11.7 9,149,270 41.3 2,008,392 234,355 – 0 Honduras 91 62 75.4 6,702,291 46.1 1,532,907 1,155,248 301,916 26 Jamaica 92 46 70.2 2,638,100 52.5 750,222 526,350 – 0 Mexico 96 72 90.2 102,049,758 76.0 24,626,697 22,221,949 8,241,126 37 Nicaragua 84 27 58.7 5,393,597 55.7 964,143 566,205 566,205 100 Panama 96 72 88.8 3,175,354 69.8 777,133 689,721 409,673 59 Paraguay 82 25 58.0 5,788,088 57.9 1,422,496 824,766 237,847 29 Peru 82 39 69.5 26,958,549 71.0 6,068,751 4,220,125 2,354,301 56 Trinidad and Tobago 80 67 68.5 1,319,139 11.9 350,223 240,076 240,076 100 Uruguay 97 84 95.9 3,301,732 91.9 1,303,720 1,250,813 715,563 57 Venezuela, RB 84 61 82.1 26,127,000 91.8 5,743,930 4,716,306 – 0 Othersa n.a. n.a. n.a. 6,255,641 83.2 1,955,934 – LAC 90 42 79.2 546,439,884 77.1 139,392,648 110,336,799 65,524,741 59 a. Antigua and Barbuda, Aruba, The Bahamas, Barbados, Belize, Cayman Islands, Dominica, Grenada, the Netherlands Antilles, Puerto Rico, St. Kitts and Nevis, St. Lucia, St. Vincent and the Grenadines, Suriname, and Virgin Islands (U.S.). 139 140 Data Sets Saneamiento de las Américas) and IBNET (International Benchmarking Network for Water and Sanitation Utilities). The information collected is for specific utility companies. In some cases, the existing data were at the municipal level. For those cases, we considered that the data for the municipality were that of the utility operator.3 In cases where the data were at the Municipal level and we were able to establish that the same operator serviced several municipalities, the data were aggregated at the utility level. One of the challenges of data collection was the inconsistency between the data provided by utilities or regulators and the annual and financial reports. Considering this, appropriate calculations and approxima- tions were made to construct missing data points. For example, through the method of interpolation, data were constructed for the earlier years of certain variables, such as number of connections, number of employees, and so on. Interpolation and other means of constructing data were the exception based on already concrete data and time trends. Specific methodologies were designed according to the variables at hand to ensure their comparability and consistency across time and utilities. To best describe the efficiency of the distribution sector of LAC, indicators were selected to determine utility-level performance. The utility-level indicators reflect relevant and feasible measurements in depicting the distribution segment of the water and sanitation sector. The utility-level indicators were computed to measure such factors as technical efficiency, operating efficiency, cost-efficiency, quality of service, and so on. Technical efficiency is defined as the capacity of the utility to achieve maximum output from a given set of inputs. To compute the technical efficiency of a utility, output and input indicators reflecting operating- and cost-efficiency were aggregated. Table B.4 summarizes the statistics for the datasets used in this analysis. As we presented for the LAC Electricity Distribution Benchmarking Database, we have calculated the number of observations, mean, standard deviation, minimum, and maximum, for the main indicators. The LAC Water and Sanitation Benchmarking dataset includes information for 1,708 utilities in 16 countries. The size of the utilities varies between over 6 ­million connections and as little as 110 connections. Coverage in the service area of the utilities in the sample varies between less than 10 and 100 percent. The dataset includes the information for most of the largest companies in the region, and some of the smaller companies. Evidence of this also is the difference in the volume of water produced by each utility. The utility with the lowest total volume of water produced 20,000 cubic meters a year, while the utility with the largest total volume of water produced 2.6 billion cubic meters a year. For sewer- age collection, the wastewater collection varies between 0 and 420 ­ million cubic meters. In terms of efficiency of service provision, the utility with the lowest col- lection rates, collect 16.4 percent of what they bill yearly, while the best collect 100 percent. Metered connections vary between those that have no meters, and those that have all connection with meters. Labor productivity, measured as num- ber of connections per employee ranges between 38 and over 1,700 connections per employee. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Data Sets 141 Table B.4 LAC Water and Sanitation Benchmarking Database—Summary Statistics Water Observations Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum Number of utilities 1,708 Total water connections 927 75,109 329,216 110 6,843,391 Total residential water connections 927 68,652 300,203 100 6,247,583 Total sewerage connections 612 67,769 271,620 10 5,271,316 Total residential sewerage connections 612 61,638 246,481 10 4,783,496 Total volume of water produced (millions cubic meter) 1,200 24.5 122.0 0.00002 2,610.0 Total volume of water sold (millions cubic meter) 859 19.2 86.6 0.00021 1,720.0 Total volume of wastewater collected (millions cubic meter) 722 6.3 31.6 0.0 420.0 Number of employees 938 258 950 1 18,291 Unaccounted for water (%) 803 35.4 17.3 0.0 99.9 Collection rate (%) 1,006 89.5 15.0 16.4 100.0 Continuity of service (hrs) 523 22.7 3.7 1.9 24.0 Potability (%) 621 95.2 9.5 16.1 100.0 Water coverage (%) 1,214 92.5 13.1 2.4 100.0 Sewerage coverage (%) 1,073 79.3 25.9 1.2 100.0 Number of customer complaints 778 8,362 42,622 1 1,017,398 Labor productivity (connections per employee) 869 262.5 162.2 37.8 1,787.9 Metered (%) 699 72.2 31.7 0.0 100.0 Note: Each observation in this table corresponds to the simple average (across all the years with available information) for each utility. ITU World Telecommunication/ICT Indicators Database This database contains annual time series from 1975–2007 for about 100 sets of telecommunication statistics covering telephone network size and dimension, mobile services, quality of service, traffic, staff, tariffs, revenue, and investment. Data for over 200 economies are available. The data is collected through an annual questionnaire sent out by the Telecommunication Development Bureau (BDT) of the ITU. The questionnaire is sent to the government agency in charge of the telecommunications sector, usually a line ministry or the regulator. The ITU’s Market Information and Statistics (STAT) unit verifies, harmonizes, carries out additional research, and collects missing information from government web- sites, and operator’s annual reports, particularly for those countries that do not provide answers to the questionnaire. Market research data is used to cross-check the data and complement missing values. In some cases, estimates are made by the ITU staff. For telecom, the ITU data includes information of 32 countries in LAC for most indicators. The sample includes small and large countries, as seen through the minimum and maximum statistics for telecom penetration and coverage. Furthermore, full-time staff varies between 188 and 90,576 employees. Quality also varies among the countries in the sample, from countries with 3.4 to 133 Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 142 Data Sets Table B.5 ITU Database—Summary Statistics (for LAC) Telecommunications Observations Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum Main (fixed) lines in operation (millions) 32 2.0 4.9 0.2 24.9 Main (fixed) telephone lines per 100 inhabitants 32 16.7 15.3 1.0 79.6 Mobile cellular telephone subscribers per 100 inhabitants 32 30.0 22.3 2.2 109.4 % Households with a main line 27 41.4 26.0 4.3 90.0 % Residential main lines 32 73.2 5.7 59.3 85.0 % Digital main lines 32 83.5 16.3 38.3 100.0 Number of local (fixed) telephone calls (billions of calls) 17 1.9 2.9 0.0005 9.5 Number of local (fixed) telephone minutes 24 12.1 30.5 0.0009 133.0 (billions of minutes) % of telephone faults cleared by next working day 29 58.2 20.7 19.7 95.0 Faults per 100 main (fixed) lines a year 29 42.9 30.9 3.4 133.2 Residential telephone connection charge (US$) 32 8.02 5.21 1.11 24.50 Price of a 3-minute fixed telephone local call (off-peak US$) 29 0.06 0.04 0.00 0.19 Price of a 3-minute fixed telephone local call (peak-US$) 30 0.10 0.11 0.00 0.64 Staff (full-time telecommunications) 32 10,960 20,037 188 90,576 Waiting list for main (fixed) lines 30 146,816 242,245 615 980,262 Note: Each observation in this table corresponds to the simple average (across all the years with available information) for each utility. faults per 100 main (fixed) lines a year. Also, the percentage of telephone faults cleared by the next working day varies from 20 to 95 percent. Table B.5 gives the reader a better idea of the diversity of countries in the data. Contract and Regulatory Characteristics Data Set The performance indicators data set was matched to a novel data set built by the World Bank that describes the characteristics of nearly 1,000 infrastructure projects awarded in Latin American and Caribbean countries from 1989 to 2002 ­ (see Guasch 2004). The data set provides details on the private sector participa- tion process, including how many bidders participated, the contract process,4 the award ­criterion,5 and the type of concession.6 The data set covers the regulatory framework, including how the legal framework was established,7 how tariffs are ­regulated,8 if there was a possibility of renegotiation of the contract, and if so, who might be the initiator of the renegotiation (table B.6).9 The data set captures additional private sector participation contract details, including information about termination clauses, the arbitration process, claim- solving institutions, universal service obligations, contract duration, contract renewal, government guarantees, government subsidies, frequency of tariff review, and how the exchange and commercial risk were borne. If the contract was Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Data Sets 143 Table B.6 Contract and Regulatory Variables Variable Description Private sector participation process Auction Dummy with value 1 if the concession was awarded through an auction process. Award: highest price Dummy with value 1 if the concession was awarded according to the highest price. Award: best investment plan Dummy with value 1 if the concession was awarded according to the best investment plan. Regulatory board Full autonomy Dummy with value 1 if the regulatory board was fully autonomous. Partial autonomy Dummy with value 1 if the regulatory board was partially autonomous. Duration Dummy with value 1 if the duration of appointments to the regulatory board was five or more years. Investors Investors: foreign Dummy with value 1 if the investors were foreign. Investors: mixed Dummy with value 1 if some of the investors were foreign. Tariff regulation Tariffs: rate of return Dummy with value 1 if the tariffs were regulated according to the rate of return. Tariffs: price cap Dummy with value 1 if the tariffs were regulated according to price cap. Source: Andrés and others 2008c. renegotiated, the reason given and the renegotiation outcome are also known. Characteristics of the regulator—such as an index of the regulator’s autonomy, its budget source, the duration of the regulatory board member mandate, and the year of the regulatory board’s inceptions—are captured in the data set. For this book’s analysis, not all of the aforementioned variables could be used because of data constraints. Only the variables that had sufficient variation across firms were employed, making it possible to measure the effect of different con- tract and regulatory characteristics on performance outcomes. This database contains annual time series from 1975–2007 for about 100 sets of telecommunication statistics covering telephone network size and dimension, mobile services, quality of service, traffic, staff, tariffs, revenue, and investment. Regulatory Governance In order to assess the governance of electricity regulators in LAC, we designed a survey that was distributed to all electricity regulatory agencies in the region, including not only national but also provincial or state regulators (particularly in the cases of Argentina and Brazil). All LAC countries that are members of the World Bank Group and have an electricity or water regulatory agency were included. The database comprises data from 43 electricity and 28 water regulatory agencies, whose coverage in terms of consumers exceeds 90 percent of the region. Each country was represented by its own regulatory agency, with the exception of Colombia and Chile, for which we assigned unique values since they each have two different entities with regulatory functions. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 144 Data Sets In both Colombia and Chile, for instance, regulatory responsibilities are shared between a National Energy Commission in charge of the main regulatory aspects (tariffs, approval of contracts) and an Oversight Electricity Agency (in the case of Chile, the Superintendencia de Electricidad y Combustibles and in the case of Colombia, the Superintendencia de Servicios Públicos) in charge of the sector’s oversight (service quality, sanctions’ enforcing, consumer complaints). Considering that both agencies perform different tasks that in other countries are undertaken by only one regulator, the database “merged” both administrative bodies and assigned a unique value for the country. For those institutional aspects that should be reflected in both agencies, such as the independence of their decision-making (for example. the appointment of directors) or the transparency of their manage- ment (for example account audits), the data assigned the country an average score calculated from both agencies’ scores on the same question. For instance, if the Comisión Nacional de Energía of Chile was assigned 0 for not auditing its accounts and the Superintendencia de Electricidad y Combustibles was assigned 1 for auditing its accounts, then Chile would obtain 0.5 for that question. In those aspects where the agencies had separate responsibilities (for example the regula- tion of tariffs by the Comisión Reguladora de la Energía of Colombia and the reception of consumers’ claims by the Superintendencia de Servicios Públicos), the data assigned the country the score achieved by the agency with responsibility in that issue, regardless of the score obtained by the other agency for the same issue. The questionnaire is composed of 97 questions (for the full version of the survey, see Andrés and others 2007) reflecting the four variables of agencies’ governance and both formal and informal aspects of their functioning. The data also included a general section aimed at capturing characteristics of electricity markets such as the methodology for tariff calculation, the degree of market liberalization, and social tariffs. Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises These data were collected through surveys sent to 110 different utilities of the region in both the electricity distribution and water sectors. Final respondents were 45 SOEs. The initiative included both public companies with full state ownership and companies where, even though there is private investment, state ownership is at least 51 percent of total shares (only a few in this category). This database compresses detailed information on the governance of SOEs in infrastructure through six indexes. The Corporate Governance Index (CGI) is the main index and is the result of the aggregation of the other five. Other indexes include: the Legal Soundness Index, the Board Competitiveness Index, the Professional Management Index, the Performance-Oriented Index, and the Transparency and Disclosure Index. Indexes are composed of different variables representing various aspects of the management of SOEs. Questions were valued between 0 (worst) and 1 (best). In selecting the questions and in giving values, the data uses as a main bench- mark a public enterprise that is corporatized and subject to the same conditions, Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Data Sets 145 in terms of access to finance and auditing, than any other private enterprise. The data adjusted the benchmark to sector specificities such as the mechanisms to appoint the Board of Directors, economic regulation, and performance-based orientation. Different from other approaches to the governance of SOEs, it also included the study of the selection, appointment, salary, and educational levels of the staff. Previous approaches have only emphasized the role of the Board and its relationship with the shareholder/s. The data considered that in the infrastruc- ture sector, the role of the staff of a state enterprise is a vital aspect of good management. Because most of these enterprises are not profit-oriented, we were not able to focus on revenues as parameters of good performance, and also because a good bureaucracy is a good filter to political intervention, we believe that an index that reflects the professionalism (given by educational levels, hiring criteria, and rewards) of the staff might give us a good proxy of the performance of the enterprise. Notes 1. This is the case, for instance, of the variable that measures number of employees in the case of utilities that were formerly vertically integrated. We compare the total number of employees of the different vertically disintegrated units and we compare with the total number of employees before the change. We assumed that this change was proportionally similar to all the new units and then we use the growth rates for the previous years. 2. As quality indexes vary across countries, the most similar indexes were collected to compare their evolution across time, rather than absolute quality levels. 3. For Mexico, the data submitted by the Consejo Nacional de Agua was at the municipal level. According to their description, the data for each Municipality corresponds to the data of the utility operator in the municipality area. For the few private operators, in Mexico, we were able to get data directly from the operator. 4. Bid, direct adjudication, invitation, petition, or request. 5. Highest cannon, highest price, tariff, lowest government subsidy, investment plan, shorter duration of the concession, or multiple criteria. 6. Operation, BOT, BOO, privatization, and so on. 7. Law, decree, contract, or license. 8. Revenue cap, price cap, rate of return, or no regulation. 9. The government, the concessionaire, both, or nobody. References Andrés, L., and G. Dragoiu. 2008. “Benchmarking Electricity distribution Report 1995–2005.” World Bank, Washington, DC. Andrés, L., J. L. Guasch, M. Diop, and S. L. Azumendi. 2007. “Assessing the Governance of Electricity Regulatory Agencies in the Latin American and the Caribbean Region: A Benchmarking Analysis.” Policy Research Working Paper 4380, World Bank, Washington, DC. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 146 Data Sets Andrés, L., J. L. Guasch, T. Haven, and V. Foster. 2008. The Impact of Private Sector Participation in Infrastructure: Lights, Shadows, and the Road Ahead. Washington, DC: World Bank. Guasch, J. L. 2004. Granting and Renegotiating Infrastructure Concessions: Doing it Right. Washington, DC: World Bank. Ramamurti, R. 1996. Privatizing Monopolies: Lessons from the Telecommunications and Transport Sector in Latin America. Baltimore, MD: The Hopkins University Press. Ros, A. 1999. “Does Ownership or Competition Matter? The Effects of Telecommunications Reform on the Network Expansion and Efficiency.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 15 (1): 65–92. Saal, D. S., and D. Parker. 2001. “Productivity and Price Performance in the Privatized Water and Sewerage Companies of England and Wales.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 20 (1): 61–90. World Bank. 2009, “Understanding Sector Performance: The Case of Utilities in Latin America and the Caribbean.” Sustainable Development Department, Economics Unit, Latin America and the Caribbean Region, World Bank, Washington, DC. June. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Appendix C Benchmarking Analysis Electricity Distribution Regional Benchmarking Assessment Figure C.1 Regional Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Output, Coverage, and Labor Productivity a. Energy sold per connection per year 5.8 5.7 5.6 MWh/yr 5.5 5.4 5.3 1995 2000 2005 Year b. Coverage 0.95 Percentage 0.90 0.85 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   147   148 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.1  Regional Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Output, Coverage, and Labor Productivity (continued) c. Residential connections per employee 700 Number of connections 600 500 400 1995 2000 2005 Year d. Energy sold per employee 4,000 3,500 MWh 3,000 2,500 2,000 1995 2000 2005 Year e. Number of employees 65,000 Number of employees 60,000 55,000 50,000 45,000 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 149 Figure C.1  Regional Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Output, Coverage, and Labor Productivity (continued) f. Private sector participation 0.6 Share of total connections 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 1995 2000 2005 Year Source: LAC Electricity Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2007. Figure C.2 Regional Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Distributional Losses and Quality of the Service a. Distributional losses 0.150 0.145 Percentage 0.140 0.135 0.130 1995 2000 2005 Year b. Frequency of interruptions per connection 20 18 Number 16 14 12 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 150 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.2  Regional Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Distributional Losses and Quality of the Service (continued) c. Duration of interruptions per connection 20 18 Hours 16 14 12 1995 2000 2005 Year Source: LAC Electricity Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2007. Figure C.3 Regional Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Tariffs and Expenses a. Average residential tari s 110 100 Dollars/MWh 90 80 70 60 1995 2000 2005 Year b. Average industrial tari s 90 80 Dollars/MWh 70 60 50 40 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 151 Figure C.3  Regional Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Tariffs and Expenses (continued) c. OPEX per connection 160 150 140 Dollars 130 120 110 1995 2000 2005 Year d. OPEX per energy sold 34 32 30 Dollars 28 26 24 1995 2000 2005 Year Source: LAC Electricity Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2007. Utility-Level Benchmarking Assessment Figure C.4  Utility Level Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Coverage, Output, and Labor Productivity a. Electricity coverage 1.0 0.8 Percentage 0.6 0.4 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 152 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.4  Utility Level Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Coverage, Output, and Labor Productivity (continued) b. Energy sold per connection per year 8 6 MWh 4 2 1995 2000 2005 Year c. Residential connections per employee 1,500 Number of connections 1,000 500 0 1995 2000 2005 Year d. Energy sold per employee 6,000 4,000 MWh 2,000 0 1995 2000 2005 Year Top 10% Mean Bottom 10% Source: LAC Electricity Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2007. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 153 Figure C.5  Utility Level Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Distributional Losses and Quality of the Service a. Distributional losses 0.4 0.3 Percentage 0.2 0.1 0 1995 2000 2005 Year b. Average frequency of interruptions per connection 150 100 Number/yr 50 0 1995 2000 2005 Year c. Average duration of interruptions per connection 150 100 Number/yr 50 0 1995 2000 2005 Year Bottom 10% Mean Top 10% Source: LAC Electricity Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2007. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 154 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.6  Utility Level Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Tariffs and Expenses a. Average residential tari s 200 Dollars/MWh 150 100 50 1995 2000 2005 Year b. Average industrial tari s 140 120 Dollars/MWh 100 80 60 40 1995 2000 2005 Year c. OPEX per connection 800 600 Dollars 400 200 0 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 155 Figure C.6  Utility Level Benchmarking—Electricity Distribution: Tariffs and Expenses (continued) d. OPEX per MWh sold 300 200 Dollars 100 0 1995 2000 2005 Year e. TOTEX per connection 1,000 Dollars 500 0 1995 2000 2005 Year f. TOTEX per MWh sold 400 300 Dollars 200 100 0 1995 2000 2005 Year Top 10% Mean Bottom 10% Source: LAC Electricity Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2007. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 156 Benchmarking Analysis Water and Sanitation Sector Regional-Level Benchmarking Assessment Figure C.7 Regional Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Coverage, Output, and Labor Productivity a. Coverage (in the sample) 100 90 80 Percentage 70 60 50 40 1995 2000 2005 Year Water coverage Sewerage coverage b. Coverage (standarized) 80 70 Percentage 60 50 40 1995 2000 2005 Year Water coverage Sewerage coverage c. Number of connections (in this sample) 70 60 50 Millions 40 30 20 10 0 1995 2000 2005 Year Total water connections Residential water connections Total sewerage connections Residential sewerage connections figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 157 Figure C.7  Regional Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Coverage, Output, and Labor Productivity (continued) d. Number of connections (standarized) 120 100 80 Millions 60 40 20 0 1995 2000 2005 Year Residential water connections Residential sewerage connections e. Total water 30 25 Billions of m3 20 15 10 5 0 1995 2000 2005 Year Total water produced Total water sold f. Water sold per inhabitant 160 155 Liters per day 150 145 140 135 1995 2000 2005 Year Source: LAC Water Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2009. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 158 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.8 Regional Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Efficiency, Labor Productivity, and Quality of the Service a. E ciency indicators (within this sample) 100 80 Percentage 60 40 20 0 1995 2000 2005 Year Collection Micrometering Non-revenue ratio water (%) b. Total water connections per employee 450 400 Ratio 350 300 250 1995 2000 2005 Year c. Continuity of the service 24 23 Hours per day 22 21 20 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 159 Figure C.8  Regional Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Efficiency, Labor Productivity, and Quality of the Service (continued) d. Potability 100 98 Percentage 96 94 92 90 1995 2000 2005 Year Source: LAC Water Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2009. Figure C.9 Regional Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Tariffs and Expenses a. Average residential tari 0.8 0.6 US$/m3 0.4 0.2 0 1995 2000 2005 Year Water average tari Sewerage average tari b. Expenditures per cubic meter sold 1.0 0.8 0.6 US$/m3 0.4 0.2 0 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 160 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.9 Regional Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Tariffs and Expenses (continued) c. Expenditures per connection 140 120 100 US$/m3 80 60 40 20 0 1995 2000 2005 Year Total expenditures Operational expenditures Source: LAC Water Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2009. Utility-Level Benchmarking Assessment Figure C.10  Utility Level Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Coverage and Output a. Water coverage 100 90 Percentage 80 70 60 1995 2000 2005 Year b. Sewerage coverage 100 80 Percentage 60 40 20 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 161 Figure C.10  Utility Level Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Coverage and Output (continued) c. Water sold per connection 600 500 400 m3/yr 300 200 100 1995 2000 2005 Year d. Water sold per inhabitant 400 300 Liter/day 200 100 1995 2000 2005 Year Top 10% Mean Bottom 10% Source: LAC Water Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2009. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 162 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.11  Utility Level Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Labor Productivity, Efficiency, and Quality of the Service a. Labor productivity 800 Number of connections per employee 600 400 200 0 1995 2000 2005 Year b. Non-revenue water 80 60 Percentage 40 20 0 1995 2000 2005 Year c. Collection ratio 100 90 Percentage 80 70 60 50 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 163 Figure C.11  Utility Level Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Labor Productivity, Efficiency, and Quality of the Service (continued) d. Water connection micrometered 100 80 Percentage 60 40 20 1995 2000 2005 Year e. Continuity of the service 24 21 18 Hours per day 15 12 9 6 1995 2000 2005 Year f. Potability 100 95 Percentage 90 85 80 75 1995 2000 2005 Year Bottom 10% Mean Top 10% Source: LAC Water Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2009. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 164 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.12  Utility Level Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Tariffs and Expenses a. Average residential water tari 1.5 US$/m3 1.0 0.5 0 1995 2000 2005 Year b. Average industrial sewerage tari 1.0 0.8 0.6 US$/m3 0.4 0.2 0 1995 2000 2005 Year c. Operational expenditures per connection 150 100 US$/year 50 0 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 165 Figure C.12  Utility Level Benchmarking—Water and Sanitation: Tariffs and Expenses (continued) d. Operational expenditures per cubic meter sold 1.0 US$/m3 0.5 0 1995 2000 2005 Year e. Total expenditures per connection 150 100 US$/year 50 0 1995 2000 2005 Year f. Total expenditures per cubic meter sold 1.5 1.0 US$/m3 0.5 0 1995 2000 2005 Year Highest 10% Mean Lowest 10% Source: LAC Water Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2009. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 166 Benchmarking Analysis Telecommunications Sector Figure C.13  Fixed Telecommunications Sector a. Household with fixed telephone 60 50 40 Percent 30 20 10 0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year b. Subscribers per 100 inhabitants 60 Number of subscribers 40 20 0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year Fixed Lines Mobile Lines c. Main (fixed) telephone lines in operation 100 80 Millions of lines 60 40 20 0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 167 Figure C.13  Fixed Telecommunications Sector (continued) d. Number of local (fixed) telephone minutes 350 300 Billions of minutes 250 200 150 100 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year e. Number of national (fixed) long distance telephone minutes 80 70 Billions of minutes 60 50 40 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year f. Total minutes per operational line 400 360 320 Minutes 280 240 200 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 168 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.13  Fixed Telecommunications Sector (continued) g. Total full-time telecommunications staff 400 350 Thousands 300 250 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year h. Total labor productivity 1,500 Fixed and mobile connections per employee 1,000 500 0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year i. Digital main lines 100 90 Percent 80 70 60 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 169 Figure C.13  Fixed Telecommunications Sector (continued) j. Faults per 100 main (fixed) lines per year 25 20 Number of faults 15 10 5 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year k. Percentage of telephone faults cleared by next working day 80 60 Percentage 40 20 0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year l. Waiting list for main (fixed) lines 2.0 1.5 Millions of lines 1.0 0.5 0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 170 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.13  Fixed Telecommunications Sector (continued) m. Price of 3-minute local call (off-peak US$) 0.08 0.06 US$ 0.04 0.02 0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year n. Price of 3-minute local call (peak US$) 0.12 0.10 0.08 US$ 0.06 0.04 0.02 0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year o. Residential monthly telephone subscription 12 10 8 US$ 6 4 2 0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 171 Figure C.13  Fixed Telecommunications Sector (continued) p. Business telephone monthly subscription 18 15 12 US$ 9 6 3 0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year q. Business telephone connection charge 400 300 US$ 200 100 0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year r. Residential telephone connection charge 200 150 US$ 100 50 0 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year Source: International Telecommunication Union 2008. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 172 Benchmarking Analysis Public versus Private Benchmarking Assessment Figure C.14 Public versus Private Benchmarking Assessment a. Electricity coverage 0.90 0.85 Percentage 0.80 0.75 0.70 1995 2000 2005 Year Private utilities Public utilities b. Electricity coverage 0.95 0.90 Percentage 0.85 0.80 0.75 0.70 1995 2000 2005 Year Privatized before 1995 Privatized after 1995 Public utilities c. Energy sold per connection per year 4.6 4.4 4.2 MWh 4.0 3.8 3.6 1995 2000 2005 Year Private utilities Public utilities figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 173 Figure C.14  Public versus Private Benchmarking Assessment (continued) d. Energy sold per connection per year 4.6 4.4 4.2 MWh 4.0 3.8 3.6 1995 2000 2005 Year Privatized after 1995 Privatized before 1995 Public utilities e. Residential connections per employee 600 Number of connections 500 400 300 200 1995 2000 2005 Year Private utilities Public utilities f. Residential connections per employee 700 Number of connections 600 500 400 300 200 1995 2000 2005 Year Privatized before 1995 Privatized after 1995 Public utilities figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 174 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.14  Public versus Private Benchmarking Assessment (continued) g. Energy sold per employee 3,000 2,500 MWh 2,000 1,500 1,000 1995 2000 2005 Year Private utilities Public utilities h. Energy sold per employee 3,000 2,500 MWh 2,000 1,500 1,000 1995 2000 2005 Year Privatized before 1995 Privatized after 1995 Public utilities i. OPEX per connection 350 300 Dollars 250 200 150 1995 2000 2005 Year Private utilities Public utilities figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 175 Figure C.14  Public versus Private Benchmarking Assessment (continued) j. OPEX per connection 350 300 250 Dollars 200 150 100 1995 2000 2005 Year Privatized before 1995 Privatized after 1995 Public utilities k. OPEX per MWh sold 100 80 Dollars 60 40 1995 2000 2005 Year Private utilities Public utilities l. OPEX per MWh sold 100 80 Dollars 60 40 20 1995 2000 2005 Year Privatized before 1995 Public utilities Privatized after 1995 figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 176 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.14  Public versus Private Benchmarking Assessment (continued) m. Average residential tariffs 110 100 Dollars/MWh 90 80 70 60 1995 2000 2005 Year Private utilities Public utilities n. Average residential tariffs 120 100 Dollars/MWh 80 60 1995 2000 2005 Year Privatized after 1995 Privatized before 1995 Public utilities o. Average industrial tariffs 90 80 Dollars/MWh 70 60 1995 2000 2005 Year Private utilities Public utilities figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 177 Figure C.14  Public versus Private Benchmarking Assessment (continued) p. Average industrial tariffs 110 100 Dollars/MWh 90 80 70 60 1995 2000 2005 Year Privatized before 1995 Public utilities Privatized after 1995 q. Distributional losses 0.20 0.18 Percentage 0.16 0.14 0.12 1995 2000 2005 Year Public utilities Private utilities r. Distributional losses 0.20 0.18 Percentage 0.16 0.14 0.12 0.10 1995 2000 2005 Year Public utilities Privatized after 1995 Privatized before 1995 figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 178 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.14  Public versus Private Benchmarking Assessment (continued) s. Average frequency of interruptions per connection 25 20 Number/yr 15 10 1995 2000 2005 Year Public utilities Private utilities t. Average frequency of interruptions per connection 25 20 Number/yr 15 10 5 1995 2000 2005 Year Public utilities Privatized after 1995 Privatized before 1995 u. Average duration of interruptions per connection 40 35 Number/yr 30 25 20 15 1995 2000 2005 Year Public utilities Private utilities figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 179 Figure C.14  Public versus Private Benchmarking Assessment (continued) v. Average duration of interruptions per connection 40 30 Number/yr 20 10 1995 2000 2005 Year Public utilities Privatized before 1995 Privatized after 1995 Source: LAC Electricity Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2007. Figure C.15 Top Ten and Bottom Ten Percent Performers a. Public—energy sold per connection per year 10 8 6 MWh 4 2 1995 2000 2005 Year b. Private—energy sold per connection per year 10 8 6 MWh 4 2 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 180 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.15  Top Ten and Bottom Ten Percent Performers (continued) c. Public—residential connections per employee 1,500 Number of connections 1,000 500 0 1995 2000 2005 Year d. Private—residential connections per employee 1,500 Number of connections 1,000 500 0 1995 2000 2005 Year e. Public—energy sold per employee 6,000 4,000 MWh 2,000 0 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Benchmarking Analysis 181 Figure C.15  Top Ten and Bottom Ten Percent Performers (continued) f. Private—energy sold per employee 6,000 4,000 MWh 2,000 0 1995 2000 2005 Year g. Public—distributional losses 0.5 0.4 Percentage 0.3 0.2 0.1 1995 2000 2005 Year h. Private—distributional losses 0.5 0.4 Percentage 0.3 0.2 0.1 1995 2000 2005 Year figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 182 Benchmarking Analysis Figure C.15  Top Ten and Bottom Ten Percent Performers (continued) i. Public—average frequency of interruptions per connection 250 Number/yr 200 150 100 50 0 1995 2000 2005 Year j. Private—average frequency of interruptions per connection 250 200 Number/yr 150 100 50 0 1995 2000 2005 Year Top 10% Mean Bottom 10% Source: LAC Electricity Benchmarking Database, World Bank, 2007. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Appendix D Detailed Results of the Empirical Analysis Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   183   184 Table D.1 Means and Medians Analysis in Levels—Electricity Distribution T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Mean Difference in levels in means (medians) in levels Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Outputs Residential connections mean 85.83 102.26 120.48 17.32 17.11 35.16 −16.209*** −17.493*** −16.809*** p50 85.94 102.00 119.59 17.11 16.55 34.33 −7.843*** −7.306*** −7.459*** sd 9.20 2.53 10.04 9.68 8.76 16.94 N 82 116 74 82 74 71 MWh sold per year mean 82.29 102.67 119.22 20.82 15.60 36.74 −13.119*** −11.882*** −7.554*** p50 82.59 101.20 117.13 19.88 15.17 34.60 −7.399*** −6.945*** −6.128*** sd 14.11 6.44 21.12 14.28 17.77 25.69 N 81 116 74 81 74 69 Inputs Number of employees mean 162.71 100.65 86.59 −61.37 −14.27 −78.19 8.949*** 8.678*** 5.432*** p50 147.46 100.00 86.17 −48.38 −14.76 −63.63 6.252*** 5.903*** 5.057*** sd 54.42 6.76 23.63 52.22 20.18 63.71 N 58 116 59 58 59 50 Efficiency Connections per employee mean 60.24 103.33 147.42 45.38 40.83 88.62 14.738*** 13.344*** 9.334*** p50 59.90 100.00 135.26 44.65 32.10 88.86 −6.543*** −6.093*** −6.438*** sd 18.65 9.86 42.10 23.25 33.31 46.49 N 57 116 58 57 58 49 table continues next page Table D.1  Means and Medians Analysis in Levels—Electricity Distribution (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Mean Difference in levels in means (medians) in levels Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) GWh per employee mean 58.56 103.97 145.09 47.50 37.64 86.27 −17.097*** −11.362*** −6.901*** p50 59.68 100.00 129.76 46.04 26.76 71.15 −6.567*** −6.093*** −6.182*** sd 18.58 11.98 53.86 20.98 41.54 53.15 N 57 116 58 57 58 49 Distributional losses mean 112.19 98.73 87.78 −12.92 −9.75 −25.14 3.658*** 4.657*** 3.515*** p50 104.37 100.00 85.34 −6.13 −11.06 −19.93 3.268*** 4.272*** 3.341*** sd 26.96 7.33 26.03 27.14 21.12 37.79 N 59 116 58 59 58 49 Quality Duration of interruptions per year per mean 134.49 100.34 72.42 −30.61 −25.32 −41.34 3.250*** 2.687*** 3.782*** consumer p50 123.37 100.00 65.42 −24.11 −30.41 −34.37 3.477*** 3.143*** 4.019*** sd 67.57 20.00 42.58 57.28 41.80 75.35 N 37 116 39 37 39 24 Frequency of interruptions per year per mean 132.59 98.63 82.71 −34.90 −13.65 −31.66 4.256*** 1.300 1.078 consumer p50 119.54 100.00 67.96 −21.20 −29.20 −32.86 3.809*** 3.571*** 4.326*** sd 57.83 13.77 93.00 49.88 79.05 119.29 N 37 116 39 37 39 24 table continues next page 185 186 Table D.1  Means and Medians Analysis in Levels—Electricity Distribution (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Mean Difference in levels in means  (medians) in levels Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Coverage Residential connections per 100 HHs mean 94.93 101.17 110.66 6.93 8.67 16.46 −6.886*** −8.162*** −8.333*** p50 95.35 100.00 108.92 5.60 7.62 14.16 −6.016*** −6.110*** −6.323*** sd 7.91 2.22 10.09 8.42 8.26 15.09 N 70 116 63 70 63 56 Prices Average tariff per residential GWh mean 106.24 98.48 94.87 −9.49 −2.88 −9.91 3.305*** 2.808*** 1.313* (in dollars) p50 97.85 100.00 95.61 −0.09 −1.38 −16.37 2.437** 2.690*** 1.702* sd 23.68 7.52 24.63 23.85 18.73 26.18 N 69 116 73 69 73 55 Average tariff per residential GWh mean 91.77 100.81 109.61 9.21 8.46 17.90 −5.164*** −5.143*** −5.067*** (in real local currency) p50 88.27 100.00 107.07 15.25 4.64 24.26 −4.774*** −4.181*** −4.643*** sd 12.83 4.97 18.59 14.81 14.27 25.81 N 69 116 73 69 73 55 Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: GWh = gigawatt hours; HH = household; MWh = megawatt hours. * significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; *** significant at 1 percent. Table D.2 Means and Medians Analysis in Growth—Electricity Distribution T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Average annual growth Annual difference in growth in means (medians) in growth Preprivate Transition Postprivate (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Outputs Residential mean 4.3% 5.5% 3.4% 1.3% −2.8% −0.8% −1.787** 3.590*** 1.976** connections p50 4.4% 4.7% 3.2% 0.4% −1.7% −1.0% −1.456 5.116*** 2.366** sd 2.6% 5.5% 2.0% N 79 84 60 79 60 56 MWh sold per mean 6.7% 6.7% 3.2% −0.5% −5.0% −3.2% 0.616 3.085*** 3.362*** year p50 6.6% 5.9% 2.8% −0.7% −2.9% −2.7% 0.708 4.096*** 3.159*** sd 4.5% 8.7% 4.7% N 74 85 57 74 57 51 Inputs Number of mean −6.6% −9.9% −2.1% −3.2% 9.7% 2.1% 2.056* −5.398*** −1.519* employees p50 −6.1% −9.0% −1.8% −3.8% 8.7% 4.0% 2.306** −4.505*** −1.776* sd 8.1% 10.0% 4.8% N 53 69 44 53 44 32 Efficiency Connections per mean 13.4% 18.4% 5.5% 4.2% −16.4% −4.2% −1.813** 5.691*** 2.183** employee p50 11.1% 14.0% 5.6% 4.5% −10.6% −3.5% 2.333** 4.975*** 2.300** sd 12.6% 16.8% 5.1% N 53 66 43 53 43 32 table continues next page 187 188 Table D.2  Means and Medians Analysis in Growth—Electricity Distribution (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Average annual growth Annual difference in growth in means (medians) in growth Preprivate Transition Postprivate (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) GWh per mean 15.1% 20.3% 5.5% 3.7% −19.9% −6.7% 1.426* 6.539*** 2.826*** employee p50 12.8% 15.0% 4.0% 3.0% −16.4% −6.3% −1.624 5.084*** 3.011*** sd 13.5% 16.9% 7.6% N 53 66 43 53 43 32 Distributional mean 0.6% −5.5% −1.3% −4.7% 6.4% −2.0% 3.301*** −3.474*** 0.960 losses p50 0.1% −4.9% −0.1% −4.5% 6.5% −1.5% 3.317*** −2.944*** 0.786 sd 7.8% 10.2% 9.6% N 57 73 46 57 46 36 Quality Duration of mean 4.1% −9.8% −3.8% −11.2% 3.4% −10.5% 1.788* 4.476*** 5.122*** interruptions p50 −5.2% −12.9% −3.2% −7.0% 8.5% −5.1% 2.132** −0.749 0.711 per year per sd 31.6% 25.7% 24.8% consumer N 32 51 26 32 26 11 Frequency of mean 2.7% −10.6% −11.4% −11.1% −2.9% −17.8% 1.653* 0.378 3.093*** interruptions p50 −5.0% −10.8% −6.6% −2.8% −2.4% −14.4% 1.664* −0.165 2.490** per year per sd 29.0% 20.3% 20.5% consumer N 32 51 26 32 26 11 table continues next page Table D.2  Means and Medians Analysis in Growth—Electricity Distribution (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Average annual growth Annual difference in growth in means (medians) in growth Preprivate Transition Postprivate (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Coverage Residential mean 2.0% 2.2% 1.9% 0.4% −1.0% −0.6% −0.903 1.702** 0.780 connections p50 1.5% 1.9% 1.3% 0.4% −0.9% −0.3% −1.408 3.186*** 0.619 per 100 HHs sd 3.9% 3.0% 3.6% N 65 76 50 65 50 42 Prices Average tariff per mean 9.3% −3.3% 2.0% −15.2% 4.3% −11.4% 6.251*** −1.821** 3.172*** residential p50 9.7% −6.3% 0.1% −15.1% 1.3% −13.1% 5.329*** −1.442 2.785*** GWh (in dollars) sd 16.0% 9.0% 14.1% N 59 86 57 59 57 35 Average tariff per mean 10.2% 2.0% 0.6% −7.8% 0.2% −12.3% 4.744*** −0.172 4.899*** residential p50 5.9% 2.3% 1.8% −5.3% 0.9% −9.7% 4.454*** −0.734 4.063*** GWh (in real sd 12.6% 7.3% 7.9% local currency) N 59 86 56 59 56 35 Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: GWh = gigawatt hours; HH = household; MWh = megawatt hours. * significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; *** significant at 1 percent. 189 190 Table D.3 Econometric Analysis—Electricity Distribution (11) Average (10) price per Average MWh (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) price per (in real Number of Energy sold Number of Connections Energy per Distributional Duration of Frequency of (9) MWh local connections per year employees per employee employee losses interruptions interruptions Coverage (in dollars) currency) Model 1: Log levels without firm-specific time trend Transition 0.150*** 0.201*** −0.307*** 0.442*** 0.474*** −0.031** −0.144*** −0.107*** 0.053*** −0.013 0.105*** (t >= −1) (0.005) (0.007) (0.016) (0.019) (0.021) (0.013) (0.028) (0.025) (0.004) (0.018) (0.008) Post-transition 0.176*** 0.169*** −0.193*** 0.368*** 0.346*** −0.141*** −0.344*** −0.308*** 0.077*** −0.028*** 0.071*** (t >= 2) (0.005) (0.007) (0.016) (0.019) (0.021) (0.013) (0.026) (0.022) (0.004) (0.010) (0.007) Observations 823 808 586 575 570 614 376 377 698 687 685 Model 2: Log levels with firm-specific time trend Transition −0.002 0.040*** −0.054*** 0.049*** 0.086*** 0.021 0.068** 0.076*** −0.007*** 0.078*** 0.034*** (t >= −1) (0.002) (0.005) (0.013) (0.012) (0.017) (0.013) (0.033) (0.029) (0.002) (0.012) (0.008) Post-transition 0.009*** −0.014*** 0.047*** −0.037*** −0.080*** −0.040*** −0.115*** −0.120*** 0.009*** 0.036*** 0.007 (t >= 2) (0.002) (0.005) (0.013) (0.013) (0.017) (0.013) (0.031) (0.027) (0.002) (0.009) (0.007) Observations 823 808 586 575 570 614 376 377 698 687 685 Model 3: Growth Transition 0.001 −0.002 −0.050*** 0.048*** 0.046*** −0.042*** −0.063*** −0.050** −0.000 −0.117*** −0.082*** (t >= −1) (0.001) (0.003) (0.008) (0.008) (0.010) (0.010) (0.023) (0.024) (0.001) (0.011) (0.007) Post-transition −0.003*** −0.027*** 0.064*** −0.065*** −0.092*** 0.015 0.001 −0.048** −0.000 0.023*** 0.009 (t >= 2) (0.001) (0.003) (0.008) (0.008) (0.010) (0.010) (0.021) (0.021) (0.000) (0.008) (0.006) Observations 803 783 566 557 554 592 339 341 669 633 631 Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: Standard errors are in parentheses. The Transition and Post-transition variables are dummy independent variables in regressions where the dependent variable is given by the column heading (Number of Connections). Transition = 1 starting two years before the privatization or concession was awarded and continuing for all years after. Post-transition = 1 for all years after the transition period, that is, starting one year after the privatization was awarded. MWh = megawatt hours. * significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; *** significant at 1 percent. Table D.4 Means and Medians Analysis in Levels—Fixed Telecommunications T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Mean Difference in levels in means (medians) in levels Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Outputs Total number of mean 78.98 115.39 181.31 36.41 65.70 102.77 −10.022*** −8.627*** −6.742*** lines p50 76.93 112.16 178.47 33.90 67.92 93.40 −3.516*** −3.408*** −3.408*** sd 12.55 13.76 48.91 14.53 37.74 46.14 N 16 16 15 16 15 15 Total number of mean 107.32 103.05 146.89 0.82 41.13 69.57 −0.049 −3.973* −19.420** minutes p50 97.39 100.00 146.89 9.05 41.13 69.57 0.105 −1.342 −1.342 sd 41.60 5.04 8.32 40.84 3.00 24.76 N 6 16 2 6 2 2 Inputs Number of mean 117.88 100.72 82.02 −17.12 −18.37 −37.18 2.213** 2.671*** 2.675*** employees p50 111.71 100.28 81.31 −22.64 −20.05 −50.94 1.761* 2.166** 2.291** sd 30.44 7.88 29.61 29.96 25.70 52.09 N 15 16 14 15 14 14 Efficiency Total number mean 72.98 119.54 262.84 47.86 140.97 191.73 −4.972*** −5.262*** −4.957*** of lines per p50 70.13 110.66 217.38 38.93 102.05 154.59 −3.237*** −3.233*** −3.233*** employee sd 24.63 26.54 126.18 37.28 106.41 136.35 N 15 16 14 15 14 14 table continues next page 191 192 Table D.4  Means and Medians Analysis in Levels—Fixed Telecommunications (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Mean Difference in levels in means (medians) in levels Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Total number of mean 79.81 105.38 238.94 34.53 123.54 172.50 −2.879** −2.059 −1.486 minutes per p50 76.03 100.00 238.94 44.60 123.54 172.50 −1.782* −1.342 −1.342 employee sd 22.83 12.63 135.73 29.38 117.59 118.47 N 6 16 2 6 2 2 Percentage of mean 580.77 141.09 101.20 −368.95 −93.78 −472.93 1.050 1.098 1.378 incomplete p50 111.56 100.00 74.51 −17.23 −27.47 −37.37 1.782* 2.201** 2.366** calls sd 1,133.58 167.34 74.92 860.92 180.06 1,055.53 N 6 16 7 6 7 6 Quality Percentage of mean 68.64 116.56 199.92 51.75 81.00 138.97 −4.407*** −2.964*** −2.339** digitalized p50 70.82 107.27 136.01 41.82 29.26 78.72 −3.180*** −3.180*** −3.129*** network sd 22.80 31.58 161.58 42.33 129.55 169.03 N 13 16 14 13 14 13 Coverage Number of lines mean 83.65 113.47 167.28 29.82 53.25 84.53 −7.573*** −7.708*** −6.025*** per 100 HHs p50 80.18 109.18 169.15 28.25 56.28 68.99 −3.516*** −3.408*** −3.351*** sd 12.73 13.75 45.46 15.75 34.23 42.48 N 16 16 15 16 15 15 table continues next page Table D.4  Means and Medians Analysis in Levels—Fixed Telecommunications (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Mean Difference in levels in means (medians) in levels Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Prices Average price for mean 144.83 100.45 99.89 −46.64 −1.03 −58.79 0.718 0.710 0.05 a 3-minute call p50 57.48 99.98 91.72 34.44 −11.25 1.74 −0.866 −0.178 1.255 (in dollars) sd 219.85 15.00 63.61 205.46 61.29 248.59 N 10 16 12 10 12 9 Average monthly mean 55.46 101.25 143.43 39.02 41.60 105.49 −2.983*** −2.083** −1.295 charge for p50 41.00 100.00 120.51 53.32 15.16 43.43 −2.293** −2.073** −0.804 residential sd 36.35 19.28 124.99 41.36 115.87 151.92 service (in dollars) N 10 16 13 10 13 9 Average charge mean 634.94 123.11 100.51 −502.46 −25.83 −256.72 1.814* 0.777 1.122 for the p50 95.78 101.06 77.29 11.18 −39.79 8.92 0.051 −0.314 1.376 installation of a sd 887.73 40.50 108.31 875.99 72.80 808.89 residential line (in dollars) N 10 16 10 10 10 6 Average price for mean 84.40 100.65 97.58 12.63 −3.46 16.28 −0.711 −0.599 0.250 a 3-minute call p50 64.40 100.00 87.14 30.96 −14.01 25.78 −0.980 −1.120 1.478 (in real local sd 50.71 7.71 44.03 50.24 43.72 76.87 currency) N 8 16 10 8 10 8 table continues next page 193 194 Table D.4  Means and Medians Analysis in Levels—Fixed Telecommunications (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Mean Difference in levels in means (medians) in levels Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Average monthly mean 60.42 100.26 135.11 36.59 34.54 88.96 −2.782** −2.750** −1.654* charge for p50 49.78 100.00 115.76 49.77 16.83 79.48 −2.191** −2.310** −1.334 residential sd 35.69 12.69 77.55 41.60 69.27 97.05 service (in real local currency) N 10 16 11 10 11 9 Average charge mean 842.23 122.99 132.07 −699.77 1.25 −252.68 1.915** 0.692 −0.028 for the p50 108.37 100.00 58.62 −6.06 −31.83 1.91 0.700 −0.105 0.420 installation of sd 1,045.40 41.81 152.59 1,033.62 126.57 894.37 a residential line (in real N 8 16 8 8 8 6 local currency) Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: HH = household. * significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; *** significant at 1 percent. Table D.5 Means and Medians Analysis in Growth—Fixed Telecommunications T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference in Average annual growth Annual difference in growth means (medians) in growth Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Outputs Total number of mean 6.9% 12.7% 7.2% 5.8% −6.5% 0.4% −2.546** 1.917** −0.152 lines p50 7.2% 11.7% 6.6% 3.8% −12.0% −2.1% −2.223** 1.852* −0.157 sd 6.2% 6.3% 8.2% 9.1% 12.8% 10.7% N 16 16 14 16 14 14 Total number of mean 4.1% 2.1% 3.8% −6.7% 3.2% −0.8% 1.158 – – minutes p50 4.6% 1.7% 3.8% −4.1% 3.2% −0.8% 1.219 – – sd 1.9% 15.3% . 12.9% . . N 5 6 1 5 1 1 Inputs Number of mean −0.5% −3.1% −6.9% −2.6% −3.4% −6.5% 0.916 1.258 2.861*** employees p50 −0.8% −4.5% −7.7% −1.5% −1.3% −3.9% 0.909 0.785 2.291** sd 6.9% 9.8% 9.0% 11.1% 10.0% 8.4% N 15 15 14 15 14 14 Efficiency Total number mean 7.8% 17.6% 16.0% 9.8% −3.1% 8.0% −2.452** 0.610 −1.791** of lines per p50 6.6% 21.3% 15.7% 10.9% −9.9% 9.4% −2.101** 0.659 −1.726* employee sd 11.6% 15.3% 11.5% 15.5% 18.9% 16.7% N 15 15 14 15 14 14 table continues next page 195 196 Table D.5  Means and Medians Analysis in Growth—Fixed Telecommunications (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Average annual growth Annual difference in growth in means (medians) in growth Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Total number of mean 5.2% 13.2% 28.6% 5.5% 11.9% 19.1% −3.000** – – minutes per p50 9.5% 16.3% 28.6% 4.4% 11.9% 19.1% −2.023** – – employee sd 9.6% 11.7% . 4.1% . . N 5 6 1 5 1 1 Percentage of mean −1.5% −16.4% −14.3% −13.9% −0.2% −13.7% 1.293 0.046 2.145** incomplete calls p50 −1.5% −7.8% −9.3% −5.1% 0.0% −8.8% 1.363 0.000 2.201** sd 1.0% 23.4% 14.7% 26.4% 14.0% 15.6% N 6 8 7 6 7 6 Quality Percentage of mean 51.5% 17.1% 4.9% −33.1% −13.5% −50.1% 1.085 3.602*** 1.434* digitalized p50 22.1% 14.2% 0.9% −4.4% −12.0% −11.9% 1.293 2.734*** 2.824*** network sd 116.3% 15.9% 6.8% 110.1% 13.5% 121.1% N 13 14 13 13 13 12 Coverage Number of lines mean 4.9% 11.0% 6.0% 6.1% −5.9% 1.2% −3.001*** 2.040** −0.438 per 100 HHs p50 4.4% 9.4% 4.9% 4.5% −8.0% −0.1% −2.637*** 1.852* −0.471 sd 5.9% 6.2% 7.8% 8.1% 10.8% 10.0% N 16 16 14 16 14 14 table continues next page Table D.5  Means and Medians Analysis in Growth—Fixed Telecommunications (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Average annual growth Annual difference in growth in means (medians) in growth  Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Prices Average price for a mean 46.7% −3.1% −5.7% −44.4% −2.3% −60.8% 1.981** 0.295 1.788* 3-minute call (in p50 40.9% −1.3% −0.4% −41.4% −7.9% −52.5% 1.820* 0.459 1.572 dollars) sd 69.0% 16.8% 12.4% 63.5% 25.1% 83.3% N 8 13 10 8 10 6 Average monthly mean 42.8% 13.9% 5.2% −21.9% −10.5% −45.8% 1.088 0.830 1.785* charge for p50 15.7% 6.0% 0.0% −33.1% −3.3% −28.4% 1.007 0.978 1.272 residential sd 54.6% 31.0% 28.1% 60.4% 41.9% 67.9% service (in dollars) N 9 14 11 9 11 7 Average charge for mean −1.9% −14.7% −13.7% −9.6% −5.7% −32.6% 0.785 0.381 1.626 the installation p50 −1.8% −2.3% −29.3% −5.2% −2.6% −18.2% 1.008 0.533 1.826* of a residential sd 25.8% 38.7% 33.7% 36.5% 44.6% 40.1% line (in dollars) N 9 14 9 9 9 4 Average price for mean 35.7% −2.5% −0.6% −30.5% 2.7% −36.7% 1.696* −0.389 1.549* a 3-minute call p50 44.3% 4.3% 0.6% −32.1% −5.2% −21.2% 1.352 0.178 1.153 (in real local sd 55.4% 19.1% 4.9% 47.6% 21.1% 58.0% currency) N 7 10 9 7 9 6 table continues next page 197 198 Table D.5  Means and Medians Analysis in Growth—Fixed Telecommunications (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Average annual growth Annual difference in growth in means (medians) in growth Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Average monthly mean 35.6% 16.5% 7.1% −12.7% −9.4% −29.4% 0.721 0.959 1.426 charge for p50 −0.9% 15.6% 3.2% −32.9% −1.9% 0.6% 0.770 0.866 0.676 residential sd 50.1% 32.1% 13.1% 52.9% 30.9% 54.6% service (in real local currency) N 9 12 10 9 10 7 Average charge for mean –8.6% −16.1% −11.6% −4.7% −6.7% −19.1% 0.289 0.370 0.789 the installation p50 −26.3% −20.0% −30.5% −35.0% −2.0% 1.4% 0.000 0.845 −0.365 of a residential sd 32.3% 46.4% 40.4% 43.5% 48.0% 48.4% line (in real local currency) N 7 10 7 7 7 4 Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: HH = household. * significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; *** significant at 1 percent. Table D.6 Econometric Analysis—Fixed Telecommunications (9) (12) (2) (5) Cost of (10) (11) Cost of (13) (14) (1) Number (3) (4) Minutes (6) (7) 3-minute Monthly Connection 3-minute Monthly Connection Number of of Number of Connections per Incomplete Network (8) local call charge charge local call charge charge connections minutes employees per worker worker calls digitization Coverage (dollars) (dollars) (dollars) (r.l.c.) (r.l.c.) (r.l.c.) Model 1: Log levels without firm-specific time trend Transition 0.253*** 0.079** −0.097*** 0.301*** 0.278*** −0.133 0.310*** 0.168*** 0.384*** 0.565*** 0.095 0.371*** 0.486*** −0.178 (t >= −1) (0.030) (0.035) (0.033) (0.054) (0.059) (0.083) (0.053) (0.025) (0.080) (0.118) (0.114) (0.081) (0.113) (0.171) Post- transition 0.494*** 0.319*** −0.264*** 0.727*** 0.657*** −0.353*** 0.458*** 0.421*** −0.014 0.209*** −0.310*** −0.090 0.197** −0.286* (t >= 2) (0.028) (0.032) (0.033) (0.054) (0.084) (0.057) (0.046) (0.026) (0.053) (0.049) (0.108) (0.063) (0.086) (0.153) Observations 168 71 161 162 69 70 131 165 104 114 107 91 110 87 Model 2: Log levels with firm-specific time trend Transition −0.050** 0.002 0.031 −0.101*** −0.010 0.142*** 0.048** −0.065*** 0.523*** 0.281*** 0.300*** 0.358*** 0.067 0.118 (t >= −1) (0.024) (0.038) (0.026) (0.038) (0.044) (0.042) (0.024) (0.019) (0.104) (0.100) (0.063) (0.082) (0.092) (0.154) Post- transition 0.113*** 0.133*** −0.069** 0.185*** 0.173*** 0.006 0.024 0.091*** 0.051 −0.067 0.222*** −0.168** −0.099 0.244** (t >= 2) (0.025) (0.041) (0.027) (0.041) (0.060) (0.044) (0.026) (0.021) (0.091) (0.087) (0.082) (0.082) (0.080) (0.097) Observations 168 71 161 162 69 70 131 165 104 114 107 91 110 87 Model 3: Growth Transition 0.027** 0.069*** −0.041*** 0.070*** 0.085** −0.062 −0.008 0.037*** −0.052 −0.101 −0.003 −0.056 −0.047 −0.140 (t >= −1) (0.011) (0.012) (0.015) (0.021) (0.042) (0.041) (0.026) (0.010) (0.077) (0.097) (0.048) (0.065) (0.067) (0.107) Post- transition −0.002 0.053* −0.026* 0.033* 0.083 −0.035 −0.056*** 0.001 0.019 −0.034 −0.019 −0.025 0.001 0.036 (t >= 2) (0.010) (0.031) (0.015) (0.020) (0.052) (0.028) (0.022) (0.010) (0.048) (0.056) (0.056) (0.046) (0.059) (0.073) Observations 165 60 158 158 59 64 122 162 93 105 98 82 102 79 Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: Standard errors are in parentheses. The Transition and Post-transition variables are dummy independent variables in regressions where the dependent variable is given by the column heading (Number of Connections). Transition = 1 starting two years before the privatization or concession was awarded and continuing for all years after. Post-transition = 1 for all years after the transition period, that is, starting one year after the privatization was awarded. r.l.c. = real local currency. * significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; *** significant at 1 percent. 199 200 Table D.7 Econometric Analysis—Fixed Telecommunications, Liberalization (9) (12) (2) (3) (5) Cost of (10) (11) Cost of (13) (14) (1) Number Number (4) Minutes (6) (7) 3-minute Monthly Connection 3-minute Monthly Connection Number of of of Connections per Incomplete Network (8) local call charge charge local call charge charge connections minutes employees per worker worker calls digitization Coverage (dollars) (dollars) (dollars) (r.l.c.) (r.l.c.) (r.l.c.) Model 1: Log levels without firm-specific time trend Transition 0.232*** 0.064* −0.046 0.272*** 0.232*** −0.140* 0.307*** 0.166*** 0.422*** 0.558*** 0.033 0.359*** 0.398*** −0.107 (t >= −1) (0.027) (0.036) (0.030) (0.049) (0.050) (0.081) (0.057) (0.025) (0.088) (0.131) (0.073) (0.085) (0.112) (0.191) Post- transition 0.432*** 0.279*** −0.151*** 0.602*** 0.432*** −0.335*** 0.446*** 0.364*** 0.011 0.220*** −0.151* −0.162** 0.102 −0.131 (t >= 2) (0.028) (0.043) (0.031) (0.051) (0.078) (0.076) (0.055) (0.025) (0.057) (0.058) (0.083) (0.073) (0.086) (0.163) Liberalization 0.275*** 0.065 −0.361*** 0.673*** 0.487*** −0.027 0.023 0.230*** −0.097 0.001 −0.491*** 0.150* 0.443*** −0.529** Dummy (0.037) (0.046) (0.047) (0.083) (0.082) (0.088) (0.069) (0.035) (0.088) (0.144) (0.171) (0.091) (0.155) (0.221) Observations 168 71 161 162 69 70 131 165 104 114 107 91 110 87 Model 2: Log levels with firm-specific time trend Transition −0.050** 0.001 0.026 −0.089** −0.006 0.133*** 0.044* −0.066*** 0.441*** 0.192 0.245*** 0.296*** −0.007 0.130 (t >= −1) (0.024) (0.043) (0.026) (0.038) (0.049) (0.043) (0.025) (0.020) (0.109) (0.136) (0.083) (0.082) (0.087) (0.165) Post- transition 0.116*** 0.127*** −0.066** 0.192*** 0.164*** 0.009 0.023 0.091*** −0.011 −0.111 0.197** −0.193** −0.135* 0.246** (t >= 2) (0.025) (0.041) (0.027) (0.041) (0.060) (0.043) (0.026) (0.021) (0.091) (0.093) (0.081) (0.078) (0.076) (0.097) Liberalization 0.002 0.037 −0.046 0.117** 0.108 −0.041 −0.016 −0.007 −0.356*** −0.410*** −0.030 −0.240*** −0.500*** 0.035 Dummy (0.032) (0.063) (0.042) (0.049) (0.090) (0.053) (0.028) (0.025) (0.116) (0.147) (0.092) (0.090) (0.136) (0.169) Observations 168 71 161 162 69 70 131 165 104 114 107 91 110 87 table continues next page Table D.7  Econometric Analysis—Fixed Telecommunications, Liberalization (continued) (9) (12) (2) (3) (5) Cost of (10) (11) Cost of (13) (14) (1) Number Number (4) Minutes (6) (7) 3-minute Monthly Connection 3-minute Monthly Connection Number of of of Connections per Incomplete Network (8) local call charge charge local call charge charge connections minutes employees per worker worker calls digitization Coverage (dollars) (dollars) (dollars) (r.l.c.) (r.l.c.) (r.l.c.) Model 3: Growth Transition 0.028** 0.066*** −0.041*** 0.075*** 0.073* −0.059 0.006 0.036*** 0.006 0.072 −0.021 −0.038 −0.004 −0.253* (t >= −1) (0.011) (0.013) (0.015) (0.020) (0.040) (0.040) (0.028) (0.011) (0.077) (0.095) (0.066) (0.065) (0.047) (0.138) Post- transition 0.010 0.030 −0.027* 0.047** −0.006 −0.011 −0.046* 0.008 0.142*** 0.038 −0.022 0.012 0.053 0.003 (t >= 2) (0.011) (0.041) (0.016) (0.021) (0.058) (0.033) (0.025) (0.010) (0.053) (0.059) (0.067) (0.053) (0.049) (0.085) Liberalization −0.053*** 0.037 0.007 −0.075** 0.183*** −0.037 −0.044 −0.027 −0.451*** −0.428*** 0.002 −0.161** −0.387*** 0.251* Dummy (0.019) (0.039) (0.029) (0.034) (0.067) (0.039) (0.031) (0.017) (0.080) (0.111) (0.098) (0.070) (0.108) (0.132) Observations 165 60 158 158 59 64 122 162 93 105 98 82 102 79 Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: Standard errors are in parentheses. The Transition and Post-transition variables are dummy independent variables in regressions where the dependent variable is given by the column heading (Number of Connections). Transition = 1 starting two years before the privatization or concession was awarded and continuing for all years after. Post-transition = 1 for all years after the transition period, that is, starting one year after the privatization was awarded. The Liberalization dummy = 1 for those years that the long-distance telecommunications market was liberalized. r.l.c. = real local currency. * significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; *** significant at 1 percent. 201 202 Table D.8 Econometric Analysis—Fixed Telecommunications, Mobile Competition (9) (12) (2) (3) (5) Cost of (10) (11) Cost of (13) (14) (1) Number Number (4) Minutes (6) (7) 3-minute Monthly Connection 3-minute Monthly Connection Number of of of Connections per Incomplete Network (8) local call charge charge local call charge charge connections minutes employees per worker worker calls digitization Coverage (dollars) (dollars) (dollars) (r.l.c.) (r.l.c.) (r.l.c.) Model 1: Log levels without firm-specific time trend Transition 0.247*** 0.047 −0.059** 0.291*** 0.178*** −0.143* 0.313*** 0.171*** 0.432*** 0.506*** −0.030 0.311*** 0.365*** −0.165 (t >= −1) (0.027) (0.037) (0.027) (0.043) (0.050) (0.077) (0.053) (0.022) (0.079) (0.120) (0.021) (0.075) (0.102) (0.106) Post-transition 0.413*** 0.221*** −0.089*** 0.500*** 0.269*** −0.337*** 0.442*** 0.342*** 0.038 0.189*** 0.032 −0.221*** 0.003 0.031 (t >= 2) (0.027) (0.050) (0.030) (0.046) (0.085) (0.089) (0.053) (0.025) (0.053) (0.046) (0.030) (0.067) (0.077) (0.110) Mobile 0.013*** 0.005** −0.025*** 0.037*** 0.030*** −0.000 0.001 0.014*** −0.015*** 0.013 −0.151*** 0.017*** 0.042*** −0.132*** subscribers (0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.002) (0.006) (0.010) (0.017) (0.004) (0.009) (0.017) Observations 168 71 161 162 69 70 131 165 104 114 107 91 110 87 Model 2: Log levels with firm-specific time trend Transition −0.064*** 0.019 0.008 −0.070* 0.029 0.111** 0.017 −0.068*** 0.166*** −0.056 0.327*** 0.201*** −0.043 0.349** (t >= −1) (0.025) (0.051) (0.025) (0.039) (0.063) (0.045) (0.022) (0.021) (0.063) (0.105) (0.073) (0.047) (0.044) (0.161) Post-transition 0.120*** 0.112*** −0.044* 0.176*** 0.061 0.022 0.042* 0.099*** 0.293*** 0.055 0.195** 0.083* −0.005 0.225** (t >= 2) (0.025) (0.034) (0.026) (0.041) (0.048) (0.046) (0.023) (0.022) (0.060) (0.061) (0.088) (0.049) (0.041) (0.090) Mobile −0.006* 0.010** −0.017*** 0.010** 0.032*** −0.004 −0.021*** −0.003 −0.117*** −0.148*** 0.039* −0.063*** −0.105*** 0.076*** subscribers (0.003) (0.005) (0.003) (0.005) (0.006) (0.005) (0.003) (0.003) (0.007) (0.015) (0.024) (0.005) (0.011) (0.025) Observations 168 71 161 162 69 70 131 165 104 114 107 91 110 87 table continues next page Table D.8  Econometric Analysis—Fixed Telecommunications, Mobile Competition (continued) (9) (12) (2) (3) (5) Cost of (10) (11) Cost of (13) (14) (1) Number Number (4) Minutes (6) (7) 3-minute Monthly Connection 3-minute Monthly Connection Number of of of Connections per Incomplete Network (8) local call charge charge local call charge charge connections minutes employees per worker worker calls digitization Coverage (dollars) (dollars) (dollars) (r.l.c.) (r.l.c.) (r.l.c.) Model 3: Growth Transition 0.023** 0.068*** −0.043*** 0.068*** 0.075* −0.062 0.006 0.035*** −0.005 −0.076 −0.031 −0.023 −0.043 −0.175* (t >= −1) (0.011) (0.014) (0.015) (0.021) (0.040) (0.042) (0.025) (0.011) (0.063) (0.090) (0.054) (0.059) (0.059) (0.093) Post- transition 0.011 0.068 −0.017 0.039* −0.004 −0.033 −0.030 0.004 0.117*** 0.051 −0.063 0.051 0.071 −0.039 (t >= 2) (0.011) (0.053) (0.016) (0.022) (0.064) (0.040) (0.024) (0.011) (0.042) (0.062) (0.060) (0.047) (0.056) (0.076) Mobile −0.002** −0.001 −0.002 −0.001 0.006* −0.000 −0.005*** −0.001 −0.026*** −0.032*** 0.018* −0.014*** −0.025*** 0.028*** subscribers (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.004) (0.008) (0.011) (0.004) (0.007) (0.011) Observations 165 60 158 158 59 64 122 162 93 105 98 82 102 79 Number of firms 16 11 16 16 11 8 14 16 12 13 13 11 13 11 Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: Standard errors are in parentheses. The Transition and Post-transition variables are dummy independent variables in regressions where the dependent variable is given by the column heading (Number of Connections). Transition = 1 starting two years before the privatization or concession was awarded and continuing for all years after. Post-transition = 1 for all years after the transition period, that is, starting one year after the privatization was awarded. Mobile subscribers is an independent variable measuring millions of mobile subscribers. r.l.c. = real local currency. * significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; *** significant at 1 percent. 203 204 Table D.9 Econometric Analysis—Fixed Telecommunications, Instrumental Variables (9) (12) (2) (3) (5) Cost of (10) (11) Cost of (13) (14) (1) Number Number (4) Minutes (6) (7) 3-minute Monthly Connection 3-minute Monthly Connection Number of of of Connections per Incomplete Network (8) local call charge charge local call charge charge connections minutes employees per worker worker calls digitization Coverage (dollars) (dollars) (dollars) (r.l.c.) (r.l.c.) (r.l.c.) Model 1: Log levels without firm-specific time trend Transition 0.462*** 0.326*** −0.198*** 0.646*** 0.717*** −0.086 0.490*** 0.377*** 0.877*** 1.041*** −0.692** 0.754*** 0.910*** −1.060*** (t >= −1) (0.052) (0.109) (0.070) (0.111) (0.135) (0.079) (0.105) (0.046) (0.147) (0.221) (0.300) (0.136) (0.209) (0.355) Post- transition 0.436*** 0.364*** −0.222*** 0.674*** 0.724*** −0.262*** 0.363*** 0.371*** −0.069 0.331* −0.204 0.012 0.332** 0.035 (t >= 2) (0.043) (0.097) (0.059) (0.094) (0.120) (0.060) (0.084) (0.039) (0.111) (0.174) (0.260) (0.097) (0.163) (0.283) Observations 121 54 114 115 52 42 107 120 79 90 93 71 90 77 Model 2: Log levels with firm-specific time trend Transition 0.003 0.229* 0.160* −0.126 0.204 0.109** 0.129 0.027 1.370*** 0.982*** 0.912*** 0.837*** 0.507 0.862** (t >= −1) (0.063) (0.134) (0.087) (0.103) (0.153) (0.042) (0.199) (0.060) (0.278) (0.350) (0.309) (0.213) (0.304) (0.375) Post- transition 0.115** 0.114 0.057 0.095 0.173 −0.018 0.014 0.108** 0.099 −0.147 0.593*** −0.022 −0.209 0.723** (t >= 2) (0.046) (0.138) (0.064) (0.077) (0.151) (0.042) (0.150) (0.045) (0.226) (0.264) (0.220) (0.176) (0.213) (0.271) Observations 121 54 114 115 52 42 107 120 79 90 93 71 90 77 Model 3: Growth Transition 0.035 0.056 −0.024 0.062 0.084 −0.049 0.243* 0.050** −0.559*** −0.477*** −0.197 −0.470*** −0.313** −0.095 (t >= −1) (0.024) (0.141) (0.031) (0.038) (0.152) (0.046) (0.124) (0.022) (0.170) (0.173) (0.144) (0.151) (0.150) (0.202) Post- transition 0.028 −0.049 −0.054** 0.023 −0.037 −0.036 −0.146* −0.038** −0.147 -0.116 0.043 −0.088 −0.088 0.046 (t >= 2) (0.019) (0.113) (0.025) (0.030) (0.123) (0.028) (0.087) (0.018) (0.107) (0.118) (0.111) (0.085) (0.103) (0.140) Observations 118 45 111 112 44 37 101 117 72 84 87 64 84 71 Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: Standard errors are in parentheses. The Transition and Post-transition variables are dummy independent variables in regressions where the dependent variable is given by the column heading (Number of Connections). Transition = 1 starting two years before the privatization or concession was awarded and continuing for all years after. Post-transition = 1 for all years after the transition period, that is, starting one year after the privatization was awarded. r.l.c. = real local currency. * significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; *** significant at 1 percent. Table D.10 Means and Medians Analysis in Levels—Water and Sewerage T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Mean Difference in levels in means (medians) in levels Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Outputs Residential water mean 85.85 103.15 119.74 16.20 16.31 29.43 −10.988*** −8.762*** −12.059*** connections p50 87.37 102.61 117.09 15.18 13.88 28.10 −4.197*** −5.086*** −3.724*** sd 6.32 3.72 13.17 7.07 10.85 10.35 N 23 49 34 23 34 18 Residential sewer mean 84.88 102.75 122.59 18.83 19.43 32.90 7.932*** 8.950*** 9.735*** connections p50 85.48 101.89 119.62 18.62 17.46 29.38 −3.883*** −4.937*** −3.408*** sd 11.21 5.02 15.08 10.62 12.28 13.09 N 20 49 32 20 32 15 Cubic meter of mean 99.98 103.62 97.27 2.21 −2.91 −1.33 −0.745 1.416* 0.299 produced water p50 100.99 100.00 99.04 1.95 −0.72 3.15 −0.879 1.078 −0.973 sd 8.89 22.20 14.80 11.88 11.45 16.60 N 16 49 31 16 31 14 Inputs Number of mean 141.43 103.97 92.35 −37.20 −12.18 −57.36 3.961*** 3.668*** 4.766*** employees p50 125.11 100.00 97.04 −21.34 −8.36 −52.01 3.527*** 3.339*** 3.237*** sd 49.22 14.22 23.85 38.72 17.26 46.62 N 17 49 27 17 27 15 table continues next page 205 206 Table D.10  Means and Medians Analysis in Levels—Water and Sewerage (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Mean Difference in levels in means (medians) in levels Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Efficiency Water connections mean 70.50 103.34 144.11 36.53 38.73 83.86 −9.979*** −4.201*** −5.177*** per employee p50 68.46 100.00 125.05 36.39 20.71 69.30 −3.621*** −4.532*** −3.408*** sd 18.93 12.65 59.84 15.09 48.79 62.73 N 17 49 28 17 28 15 Distributional Mean 107.22 100.02 82.08 −8.70 −18.26 −23.18 2.577** 3.755*** 3.110*** losses p50 106.01 100.00 81.64 −8.33 −16.63 −20.12 2.327** 3.254*** 2.605*** sd 16.43 7.42 21.22 13.51 23.33 27.88 N 16 49 23 16 23 14 Quality Continuity (hs per mean 78.34 101.01 116.79 21.81 14.94 21.66 −1.781* −2.748*** −1.330 day) p50 97.11 100.00 104.35 2.48 2.17 4.05 −2.192** −2.774*** −1.971** sd 37.52 4.68 24.68 36.74 21.06 46.07 N 9 49 15 9 15 8 % of the samples mean 88.35 100.30 103.89 11.55 2.58 4.94 −1.250 −2.088** −1.682* that passed the p50 99.50 100.00 100.51 0.58 0.46 1.08 −1.630 −2.603*** −1.941* potability test sd 27.92 1.53 6.87 26.14 4.62 7.20 N 8 49 14 8 14 6 Coverage Residential water mean 94.25 101.84 111.12 6.52 8.71 10.37 −4.498*** −4.379*** −4.478*** connections per p50 95.13 100.00 106.88 4.86 5.26 8.76 −4.107*** −4.584*** −3.823*** 100 HHs sd 5.70 3.96 14.11 6.80 10.71 10.10 N 22 49 29 22 29 19 table continues next page Table D.10  Means and Medians Analysis in Levels—Water and Sewerage (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference in Mean Difference in levels means (medians) in levels Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) (2)−(1) (3)−(2) (3)−(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Residential sewer mean 91.47 101.77 110.03 10.23 8.67 13.59 −4.539*** −3.981*** −5.277*** connections per p50 91.72 100.00 106.87 8.02 5.76 8.98 −3.479*** −3.920*** −3.180*** 100 HHs sd 8.76 6.88 11.55 9.29 9.74 9.29 N 17 49 20 17 20 13 Prices Average price per mean 93.62 101.39 106.70 10.43 1.46 40.24 −0.635 −0.173 −2.261** cubic meter of p50 87.95 100.00 98.60 11.81 3.27 32.70 −1.274 −0.314 −2.240** water (in dollars) sd 43.54 9.53 37.16 51.89 30.57 50.34 N 10 49 13 10 13 8 Average price per mean 84.00 103.53 130.09 25.70 17.68 57.87 −2.478** −2.903*** −4.150*** cubic meter of p50 82.76 100.00 121.21 22.22 19.65 44.80 −1.988** −0.411** −2.521** water (in real sd 23.18 11.71 32.81 32.80 21.96 39.44 local currency) N 10 49 13 10 13 8 Average price per mean 114.61 100.53 107.79 −19.43 0.03 44.29 0.375 0.001 −0.835 cubic meter of p50 79.43 100.00 107.68 16.46 −12.60 44.29 0.000 0.365 −0.447 sewer (in dollars) sd 89.74 6.94 32.73 89.77 35.56 75.05 N 3 49 4 3 4 2 Average price per mean 93.06 101.80 152.44 13.26 32.25 53.34 −0.512 −3.012** −37.266*** cubic meter of p50 74.75 100.00 135.93 30.91 33.12 53.34 −0.535 −1.826* −1.342 sewer (in real sd 45.93 10.88 51.26 44.86 21.42 2.02 local currency) N 3 49 4 3 4 2 Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: HH = household. * significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; *** significant at 1 percent. 207 208 Table D.11 Means and Medians Analysis in Growth—Water and Sewerage T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference in Average annual growth Annual difference in growth means (medians) in growth Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)–(1) (3)–(2) (3)–(1) (2)–(1) (3)–(2) (3)–(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Outputs Residential water mean 4.4% 6.5% 4.7% 0.9% −1.9% 1.5% −1.095 1.649* −1.113 connections p50 4.1% 5.2% 3.8% −0.1% −1.8% 1.2% −0.923 2.229** −0.943 sd 3.0% 4.4% 4.6% 3.5% 5.6% 3.2% N 17 43 24 17 24 6 Residential sewer mean 3.8% 6.7% 7.4% 3.1% 1.5% 0.0% −1.222 −0.569 0.009 connections p50 4.3% 5.5% 3.6% 2.1% −1.4% 0.1% −0.966 0.693 −0.135 sd 5.9% 6.8% 10.7% 9.8% 12.3% 3.2% N 15 40 23 15 23 5 Cubic meter of mean 2.1% 7.5% 0.5% −0.9% −1.8% 1.6% 0.741 1.117 −0.718 produced water p50 1.6% 1.0% 0.9% 0.0% 0.0% 1.5% 0.000 0.817 −0.674 sd 4.6% 38.6% 5.0% 4.1% 7.3% 5.0% N 12 38 21 12 21 5 Inputs Number of employees mean −0.4% −10.0% −1.5% −9.6% 7.5% −1.0% 3.425*** −3.460*** 0.309 p50 0.1% −8.3% −1.0% −9.8% 7.8% −1.4% 2.432*** −2.765*** 0.135 sd 4.2% 10.2% 7.2% 9.7% 9.2% 7.4% N 12 32 18 12 18 5 Efficiency Water connections per mean 5.5% 17.5% 7.3% 11.6% −9.6% 1.2% −3.068*** 2.939*** −0.348 employee p50 4.9% 15.8% 4.5% 9.9% −7.8% 0.1% 2.551** 2.656 0.105 sd 5.4% 13.5% 10.1% 13.7% 14.3% 8.3% N 13 32 19 13 19 6 table continues next page Table D.11  Means and Medians Analysis in Growth—Water and Sewerage (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference in Average annual growth Annual difference in growth means (medians) in growth Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)–(1) (3)–(2) (3)–(1) (2)–(1) (3)–(2) (3)–(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Distributional losses Mean −3.1% −0.6% −5.5% 0.5% 0.5% 0.6% −0.297 −0.310 −0.363 p50 −2.6% −2.0% −5.1% −0.1% 0.3% 0.8% −0.267 −0.450 −0.843 sd 3.8% 21.5% 9.1% 5.3% 6.2% 4.0% N 11 26 17 11 17 6 Quality Continuity (hs per day) mean 0.0% 7.2% 4.6% 22.4% −0.1% 0.0% −1.000 0.057 − p50 0.0% 0.0% 0.9% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% –1.000 0.075 − sd 0.0% 16.0% 8.7% 38.7% 6.0% N 3 18 11 3 11 1 % of the samples that mean 0.8% 5.2% 0.4% 18.6% −0.5% −1.0% −1.074 1.273 1.000 passed the potability p50 0.6% 0.2% 0.0% 2.2% 0.0% −1.0% −0.928 1.315 1.000 test sd 1.0% 16.4% 0.7% 34.6% 1.2% 1.4% N 4 18 9 4 9 2 Coverage Residential water mean 1.0% 4.1% 3.3% 1.1% −1.3% 0.4% −2.050** 0.914 −0.570 connections per 100 p50 0.3% 2.8% 1.6% 0.2% −1.3% 0.1% −1.448 1.690* −0.944 HHs sd 1.7% 5.0% 4.4% 2.1% 6.1% 1.7% N 16 34 19 16 19 5 Residential sewer mean 1.6% 8.0% 2.8% 2.9% −0.9% −1.6% −1.815 0.529 2.735** connections per p50 1.4% 2.9% 0.6% 0.1% −1.6% −0.9% −1.036 1.601 2.023** 100 HHs sd 17.9% 17.9% 6.1% 6.0% 6.2% 1.3% N 14 25 14 14 14 5 table continues next page 209 210 Table D.11  Means and Medians Analysis in Growth—Water and Sewerage (continued) T-statistics (Z-statistics) for difference Average annual growth Annual difference in growth in means (medians) in growth Pre-private Transition Post-private (2)–(1) (3)–(2) (3)–(1) (2)–(1) (3)–(2) (3)–(1) Variable Statistics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Prices Average price per mean 12.2% 1.9% −3.4% −12.1% −7.2% −3.9% 2.493** 0.835 0.666 cubic meter of p50 10.9% –2.2% –1.1% –13.8% −3.3% −2.1% 1.820* 0.889 0.535 water (in dollars) sd 10.4% 22.2% 20.0% 13.8% 26.0% 10.1% N 8 17 9 8 9 3 Average price per cubic mean 10.1% 9.4% 4.5% −6.0% −8.9% −0.8% 2.078** 1.060 0.346 meter of water (in p50 10.1% 5.4% 2.6% −4.3% −6.5% −2.5% 1.540 1.007 0.000 real local currency) sd 6.7% 18.4% 10.0% 8.1% 25.1% 4.0% N 8 17 9 8 9 3 Average price per cubic mean −0.6% −5.1% −7.9% 2.3% −6.4% −7.7% −0.298 0.799 − meter of sewer (in p50 −0.6% −8.7% −7.9% 2.3% −10.8% −7.7% −0.447 1.069 − dollars) sd 17.1% 16.1% 11.6% 10.8% 13.9% N 2 5 3 2 3 1 Average price per mean −1.1% 7.0% 9.7% 5.0% −4.3% −15.1% 3.881* 0.302 cubic meter of p50 −1.1% 1.4% 9.8% 5.0% −18.4% −15.1% −1.342 0.000 sewer (in real local sd 13.9% 13.5% 16.0% 1.8% 24.7% currency) N 2 5 3 2 3 1 Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: HH = household. * significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; *** significant at 1 percent. Table D.12 Econometric Analysis—Water Distribution and Sewerage (11) Coverage (12) (13) (14) (5) Average Average Average Average (1) (2) (3) (4) Water (7) price per price per price per price per Number of Number of Cubic Number connections (6) Continuity (9) m3 of m3 of m3 for m3 for water sewerage meters of per Distributional of the (8) Water (10) water water sewerage sewerage connections connections per year employees employee losses service Potability coverage Sewerage (in dollars) (in r.l.c.) (in dollars) (in r.l.c.) Model 1: Log levels without firm-specific time trend Transition 0.141*** 0.174*** 0.040*** −0.180*** 0.268*** −0.039** 0.038 0.059* 0.025*** 0.053*** 0.055 0.146*** −0.014 0.104 (t > = −1) (0.010) (0.016) (0.009) (0.030) (0.034) (0.017) (0.064) (0.034) (0.007) (0.009) (0.041) (0.026) (0.142) (0.083) Post-transition 0.139*** 0.173*** 0.015*** −0.194*** 0.354*** −0.155*** 0.074*** 0.012** 0.049*** 0.065*** 0.097** 0.213*** −0.096 0.222*** (t > = 2) (0.008) (0.011) (0.006) (0.024) (0.027) (0.015) (0.015) (0.005) (0.005) (0.007) (0.038) (0.027) (0.110) (0.077) Observations 259 239 195 201 199 179 97 90 243 198 112 112 37 37 Model 2: Log levels with firm-specific time trend Transition 0.006 −0.006 −0.007 0.083*** −0.076*** −0.014 0.000 −0.002 −0.000 −0.005 0.003 −0.048 0.026 0.017 (t > = −1) (0.004) (0.009) (0.010) (0.026) (0.023) (0.012) (0.006) (0.005) (0.001) (0.006) (0.050) (0.034) (0.093) (0.082) Post-transition −0.002 −0.005 −0.013* 0.069*** −0.027 0.000 0.000 −0.002 −0.001 −0.008 −0.047 −0.024 0.013 0.045 (t > = 2) (0.003) (0.005) (0.007) (0.017) (0.019) (0.001) (0.002) (0.009) (0.001) (0.005) (0.031) (0.020) (0.088) (0.078) Observations 259 239 195 201 199 179 97 90 243 198 112 112 37 37 Model 3: Growth Transition 0.001 0.006 −0.008 −0.048*** 0.047*** −0.000 0.002 0.009 0.001 0.003 −0.203*** −0.099*** −0.054 0.007 (t > = −1) (0.004) (0.006) (0.009) (0.018) (0.018) (0.012) (0.020) (0.013) (0.002) (0.004) (0.034) (0.027) (0.080) (0.059) Post-transition −0.010*** −0.011*** −0.025*** 0.048*** −0.037*** −0.012* −0.001 −0.005 −0.004*** −0.008** −0.018 −0.011 −0.005 0.006 (t > = 2) (0.002) (0.002) (0.007) (0.012) (0.012) (0.007) (0.005) (0.005) (0.002) (0.004) (0.021) (0.019) (0.076) (0.065) Observations 235 216 172 176 178 160 81 77 217 180 101 101 31 31 Source: Andrés and others 2008. Note: Standard errors are in parentheses. The Transition and Post-transition variables are dummy independent variables in regressions where the dependent variable is given by the column heading (Number of Connections). Transition = 1 starting two years before the privatization or concession was awarded and continuing for all years after. Post-transition = 1 for all years after the transition period, that is, starting one year after the privatization was awarded. r.l.c. = real local currency. * significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; *** significant at 1 percent. 211 212 Detailed Results of the Empirical Analysis Reference Andrés, L., J. L. Guasch, T. Haven, and V. Foster. 2008. The Impact of Private Sector Participation in Infrastructure: Lights, Shadows, and the Road Ahead. Washington, DC: World Bank. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Appendix E Dimensions of Regulatory Governance Figure E.1 Electricity Regulatory Agencies a. Regulatory autonomy 1.0 0.8 0.6 Index (0–1) 0.4 0.2 0 Ho aica go a ia Re ina Ba ala ico a ic in rge s a M s To u at r Co dor Ja ay T1 T2 Ec ica Bo l Gu ado A do gu a bi m i r liv bl az ur a n Pe ba u em ex nt m aR na m pu ba ua ra ug Br nd lv lo ca Pa st r Ur Sa Ni Co d n El ica ad id m in Do Tr figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   213   214 Index (0–1) Index (0–1) 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Ja 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Do m Gu ai m T1 at ca in ica em n Bra al a Re zil Tr p in id Ar az Br Ni ubli ad g il ca c an ent ra gu d ina To Bo a ba liv go ia Do m P e Co Per in Bar ru st u a ica ba n d El Ric Re os Sa a pu lv b ad or Pa lic na Ar T2 Ni m ge ca a Figure E.1  Electricity Regulatory Agencies (continued) n El ragu Ur tina Sa ug lv a ua ad Tr M y Ec or in ex ua id Co do ad Pa ico st r an na c. Political autonomy aR b. Managerial autonomy d ma ica To Bo Gu bag liv at o ia em al Ur T1 Ja a m ug Ho aic ua nd a M y ex Ba uras ico rb ad Ec os Ho T ua nd 2 Co do u Co ra lo r lo s m m bi a bi a figure continues next page Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Dimensions of Regulatory Governance Tr in id ad Index (0–1) Tr Index (0–1) an in d id 0.8 1.0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.2 0.6 0 0.4 To ad b an Pe Co ag d lo o To ru Do m ba m bi go in a ica n T1 T1 Re pu Br bl az ic Bo il El P liv Sa eru M ia lv El exi ad Sa co o Dimensions of Regulatory Governance lva Bo r Ar ivi l Co dor lo ge a m nt b Ja ia Ur ina m ug Ba ica a u rb Pa ay Figure E.1  Electricity Regulatory Agencies (continued) Gu am n Co ado st s at a aR e ica Ni mal ca a Ar ra ge T2 gu Do M a m nt ex in Ur ina e. Social transparency ic d. Institutional transparency ica ug Ec o n ua Re uay do p r Gu ub Br at lic Ho az e nd il Ni mal ca a ra Co uras g st a Pa ua na Ba Ric Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 rb a Ho m ad nd a os u Ec ras ua T2 do Ja m r ai ca figure continues next page 215 216 Index (0–1) Index (0–1) Gu 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 at em 1.0 al Gu Pe a at ru Br em Ar a z El Sa ala ge il lv nt ad i or Ja na m Tr in B ai id r a ca ad Ur zil Pe an ugu ru d Bo To ay liv b ia Ar ag Tr ge o in nt id i adUr T1 Ja na an ugu m d Co aic To ay st a b aR Co ago ica Figure E.1  Electricity Regulatory Agencies (continued) lo El mb Co T1 Sa ia lv lo m Ni ado bi ca r Bo a Do ra m C gu l in os a Ba ivia f. Regulatory tools rb g. Institutional tools ica ta n Ri ad Re ca Pa os pu Do na bl m m M ic in Hon a ica d ex Ba ico n ura rb Re s ad pu os Ni bli ca c ra g Pa T2 Ec ua na ua m do Ec a r ua Ho do T2 nd r M ur ex as ico Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 figure continues next page Dimensions of Regulatory Governance Index (0–1) Index (0–1) 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0 Ur Do m 0.6 0.8 ug 0 1.0 0.4 0.2 ua in ica y n P Do Bo Re eru m Ni liv pu in c ia Ni bli ica ara ca c n g ra Re ua gu pu Co bli Bo a El li st c Sa via a lv Ar Ric ad ge a or Gu ntin Br at a az Dimensions of Regulatory Governance Tr em Pa il in na id al a m ad a an Bra d z Ba T To il rb 1 ba ad go Ar ge os Figure E.1  Electricity Regulatory Agencies (continued) nt T1 i Ec na ua Pe ru d Ba Tr Ja or rb in m El ad id C aic Sa os ad os a h. Formal autonomy lv i. Informal autonomy ad an ta R d ic Pa or To a na ba m g M o M a Gu exic ex i at o Ja co em m al Ho icaa a nd u Co T2 Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 lo Co ras lo m m Ur a bi bi ug a Ho uay T2 nd Ec ur ua as do r figure continues next page 217 218 Tr in id ad Index (0–1) an Tr d 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 in To id ba ad Index (0–1) go an d 0.6 0.8 1.0 0 0.2 0.4 To Pe Gu ba ru at go M em ex El ico al Sa Do a lv m ad in T1 Co or ica lo n Bra m Re zi bi pu l Ba rb a b ad Bo lic o Ur livia Bo s u Ba liv i Ba gua rb a rb y ad El ad os Sa os Figure E.1  Electricity Regulatory Agencies (continued) lv Co ado Ni T1 lo r ca ra Ar mb ge ia Co ua g nt st in aR a i Ni Pa ca ca T2 na ra Gu m gu at a a em j. Formal accountability k. Informal accountability Pe a M r u Ec la ex ua Ja ico Ar do m ge r Co ai Do nt st ca m in a aR in Ec ica ica ua n T Ho d Re 2 pu nd or u b Pa ras Ja lic na m m Ho aica a nd ur Ur as ug ua y Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 figure continues next page Dimensions of Regulatory Governance Tr Index (0–1) in id ad an Index (0–1) 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Bo d 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Tr in liv ia To ba 1.0 id P er M go Do ad m an u El ex in d Sa ic ica To T1 lv o n ba Co ad lo or Re go m El pub bi Sa li c Br a az Gu lva il at dor em T1 Dimensions of Regulatory Governance M ala Co Pe Co exic st ru lo o Ni a Ri ca ca Ar mb ra ge ia Ur gu nt ug a in Br a Ba ua rb y Figure E.1  Electricity Regulatory Agencies (continued) Ba az a rb il a Ja dos Source: LAC Electricity Regulatory Governance Database, World Bank, 2008. Ja dos Ar ma m ge ica Ur aic nt a i m. Informal transparency Do m Bo na l. Formal transparency Co ugu st ay in l aR ica Pa ivia Ho ic n na nd a Re m ur pu a as Ec blic Ni ua ca 2 T do ra r Pa gua Ho na Gu du n T2 Ec ma at ras ua em do Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 r al a 219 220 Tr in Pe Index (0–1) id r ad Index (0–1) 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 a Br Br u–S az UN 0.8 1.0 0 0.6 0.2 0.4 Ho nd T azil Ar il– A nd ob –A ge A S ur ag RC nt Br GER S a o E Co in az S Ar B s–E –RI Tr st a– il– A ge ra RS C in a R ER AT nt zil AP id i S R in – S ad B ca– PyO Ba a–E AGE an ra ERS C rb R R d zil– A T A P Pe ado SAC Pa oba MAS ru s T na go E Co Pa –SU –FT n m – st am N C Ar Br a– RIC aR a AS ge azi AS Co ica– –AS S nt l–A EP in R Figure E.2  Water Regulatory Agencies lo ER EP Pa Bra a–E SA B m SA ra zi RS L Br raz bia PS gu l–A A az il– –C ay D C il A R – A Ar –AG GE A g R Br ERS SA az S Ar en EN SA ge tin ER Br il–A AN nt a– SA a in ER Br zil– RC a– A az A E ER S Ar il– GE Br SA ge AG R az C nt ES i l Br in az a– C Pa Br –A T1 ra az RS il– EN T1 gu il– A A Ba GE RES ay AR M rb NE S –E SA ad R Br RSS L Ho os SA a. Regulatory autonomy Br az AN nd –F az il– ur TC b. Managerial autonomy Br il–A ATR as az RS Br –ER T2 il– A az S E il– AP Br Bra AM A S az zil AE Co Bra RS Ar B il– –A lo zil– AE ge ra AG GR Br mb AG n z E az ia R Ar tin il–A RG i – ge a– D S Ar Bra l–AG CRA nt ER AS ge zi E in SP A n l– RG a– yO Ar tina ARS S EN C ge –E A RE nt RS M Br SS in A az a– CT il– T ER AG 2 AS ES C Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 figure continues next page Dimensions of Regulatory Governance Tr in Br az Index (0–1) id a il– 0.8 1.0 0 0.6 0.2 Index (0–1) 0.4 d AD an Bra AS Co Pe d zil A 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 To –A st ru– ba R a C Br Ri SU T1 az ca N Br go– E il– –E AS Pe az RI ru il– C AG RS S –S AG EN AP UN R ER S Br AS Br SA Co azil S Br azi Br lo –A T1 az l–A T2 az m RS il il– bia A Pa B –AG RSA AG –C L ra ra ER L Ho gu zil– G Br EN RA nd ay– AG S az ER Dimensions of Regulatory Governance il– SA ur ER ER B A Ar as SS – Co Bra raz GE ge Br ERS AN st zil– il– R nt azi AP a R A AT in l–A S i G R a– R Ba ca– ERG E C rb ER S Figure E.2  Water Regulatory Agencies (continued) Br NRE E Br ado SAP Br az SS az s– S az il– il– F Br il–A AGR AD TC Ho ra B AS Tr Ar Br azil– GES in ge az A C nd zil– A id n il– M Pa ur AG T ad tin A A ra as E 2 an a– GE E gu –E RS d ER RS a R A To SP A Br y–E SAP Br ba yO a g C c. Political autonomy az RS S i S Ba zil– o–R Br l–AR AN rb AR IC az S a S B il A Ar Bra dos AM d. Institutional transparency Ar raz –AM M ge zi –F ge il– A nt l–A TC nt AR E i Pa ina– RSA Ar Bra na– SAE na ER E ge zi ER m SA nt l–A AS a in G Co Bra –AS C Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Ar Pan a– ES l A om zil– EP Ar gen am ERS C Ar rgen bia ATR ge tin a– AC ge ti –C n a A nt na R Ar tina –EN SEP in –E A ge –E R a– R nt RS ES ER AS in P S SA a– yO CT ER C SA CT figure continues next page 221 222 Co Index (0–1) Br Index (0–1) lo Ar azil m 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 b ge –A 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Br ia– nt GE Tr az C in RS a– A in il– RA ER id B AR Pe ad ra CE AS an zil Co ru– d –A T lo SU T1 To G 1 m NA P ba ER Br Bra bia SS Ar eru go GS az zi –C Ho gen –SU –RI il– l–A RA AG R nd tin NA C Tr in S ur a– SS a E id Br ENE AL az R ad i Co Bra s–E RAS B an ra l–A SA st zil RSA Ho d T zil– RC a R –A P ica GE S nd ob AM E ur ag AE Br Br –ER RSA as o– az az SA –E RI il– il– P A A S Br RSA C a Figure E.2  Water Regulatory Agencies (continued) Br GE GE B zi PS az NE R Br raz l–A il– R az il– TR A S i Br RS A Br l–A AGR Br azi AM az GE a l– il R Br zil– AT Br –AR GS az AR R i Co Br azil SAM Br l–A SAL st azi –A az DA a R l– GE il S B –A A ica AD R –E AS Br razi MA a l E Ar Ba RS A AP Ba zil– –AG r f. Institutional tools S e. Social transparency rb AG R ge ba ad E n Pa ti o T2 d os SC ra na s– –F Ar Pa TC Ar gua –EN FTC ge a n ge y– RE Pa nti ma T nt ER SS ra na –A 2 Ar in S g ge Bra a–E SAN Ar ua –EN SEP nt zi RS ge y– RE Ar in l– A nt ER SS ge a– AG C Ar in SS nt ER ES ge Bra a–E AN in SP C n Ar tin zil– RSA Pa a–E yO ge a– AR C na RS C nt ER SA m A in SP E Br a– CT a– y az AS ER OC il– EP SA AR CT SA E Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 figure continues next page Dimensions of Regulatory Governance Index (0–1) Br a Index (0–1) Br Br az az Br zil– 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 il– il– Br az AG A A az il– E il– A RS Br GEN GER az E A G A Co Br il–A RS Pe GEN ERG st azi G A ru E S a R l– ES Ho –S RS ic AD C nd UN A Co u AS Ar Br a–E AS ge az RS A st as r S Ho nti il–A AP a R –E T1 nd na– RS S ica RS Tr –E AP in ur EN AL id as R Co Bra RSA S ad –E ES z an RS S Ar lom il–A PS d AP ge b G To S nt ia– R Dimensions of Regulatory Governance ba in CR Br go T1 a Br –ER A Ba azi –R B Pa r azi AS r l– IC ra azi l–A Br bad AR az os CE Ar gua l–A TR Tr ge y– GE Pe il–A –FT in nt ER SC id Figure E.2  Water Regulatory Agencies (continued) ru G C ad in SS Br –SU ERS a az N A an Bra –E AN d zil RS Pa Braz il–A ASS To –A AC ra il– RS Ba bag MA gu A A a G M rb o– E a Pa y–E ERG Br dos RIC na RS S az – m S Br il– FTC B a AN az AR Co razi –AS i g. Regulatory tools h. Informal autonomy lo l–A EP Br l–A SAL m M Ar B az RS b A ge ra il– AE Br ia–C E nt zil AG B Ar ra zil RA a in –A ER ge zi –A a– R ER SA nt l–A GR SP M in R Pa yO a– SA na C Ar Br ERS E Ar B a T m ge az A ge raz –A 2 nt il– C Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 nt il– SE in AT in A P A – a R a D Ar rge ER T Ar B –EN AS ge nt P 2 S ge ra R A nt ina yO nt zil ES in – C in –A S a– R a– ER ER AS ER CE SA SA CT CT figure continues next page 223 224 Tr Tr in in id id ad ad an an d Index (0–1) d Index (0–1) T To 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Br oba 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 az g Br bag az o Co il– o– il– –R lo AG RIC AD IC m ER Co e P AS Br bia– SA st ru– A a C aR S Br zil– RA ica UN T1 az AR i C Br –E AS az RS S Br l–A E Br a zil GER Ar Br il–A APS az –A ge az RS Pa n il– A il– GR AG ra tin AM L gu a– A Br EN T a 1 a E E Ba zil– ERS Pa y–E RSA rb A A na RS C Br m SA Pe ado RSA az a– N ru s– L il– A –S F A SE T Figure E.2  Water Regulatory Agencies (continued) Br Br UNA C az Br GER P Co az S il– az S st il– S AG il– A aR AT A ica R Br ENE TR az R Br –E T az R 2 B il– SA Pa B il–A SAP Ba razi AG ra raz RS S rb l–A ER gu il A ad R ay –A M os CE Ho Br –E MA –F TC nd azil RSS E B ur –A AN Br raz T az il– 2 Pa as– DAS i. Formal autonomy Ho Col il–A AG na ER A S Ar nd om RS R j. Informal accountability Br ma AP ge ur bia AM Ar az –A S n a ge il– SE Ar tin s–E –CR nt AG P ge a– RS A B ina ES nt ER AP in SP S Ar B razi –ER C a ge raz l–A A Br –E yO S B az RS C Ar ntin il–A RSA Ar ra il– AC ge a– GE E ge zi AG T nt l–A ES Ar ntin ERS RGS in G C g P a E Ar en a–E yO Br –EN RG ge tin RS C Ar azi RE S nt a– AC ge l–A S in ER T nt R S a– S in SA EN AC a– E RE ER SS AS Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 figure continues next page Dimensions of Regulatory Governance Tr in Pe Index (0–1) id r ad u– an Index (0–1) 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Ho SU d nd NA To ba 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 ur SS Co as– g lo ER T1 Ba Braz o–R rb il– IC Br mb SA ad A P Co os GR Ar azil– ia–C S st –F ge A R aR nt GE A i TC in RS Co ca– a Br lo R T1 E Tr Br –ER A a m S in az A Pa zil– bi AP id B Br il– S ra A a– S ad ra az AT gu GE CR an zil il– R a N A d –A AG Pa y– ER Dimensions of Regulatory Governance na ER SA To G R b E S Br ma– SAN Br ag RGS az o– a Br il– RI Br zil– ASE az AR C az AR P il– S il– S AD AL Figure E.2  Water Regulatory Agencies (continued) Br AD AL AS az A A Br il–A SA B a Pe raz Co Bra zil– RC ru il– T2 st zil AG E – A a R –A E B SU TR i R R Br razi NA az l– SS Ba ca– SA il– AM rb ER M a S Br AG AE Br dos APS B Ar ra azil ERS az –F ge zil –A A Br il– T nt –A GE az AM C in GE R il– AE a– R A Ho E G l. Informal transparency Pa GE T nd Bra RSA S k. Formal accountability na NE 2 ur zil– C a T Pa Br ma– RSA Br s–E ARC r az A az R E Ar agu il–A SE i S ge ay G P B l– A – E Ar raz ARS PS Ar ntin ER SC A ge il– A Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 ge a– SS Ar rge nti AG M nt EN AN ge n na ES Ar in R nt tin –E C ge Br a–E ESS in a– RA n a R a– ER S Ar tin zil– SA Ar Br ERS SA ge a– AR C ge az Py C nt ER SA nt il– O in SP E in AR C a– y a– S ER OC EN AE SA RE CT SS figure continues next page 225 Tr 226 in id ad an d Index (0–1) To ba 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Br go az –R il I Co Bra –AR C lo zil CE Pe mb –AG ru ia– R Co –S CR st UN A aR AS ica S Br –E T az R 1 S Source: LAC Water Database, World Bank, 2009. Br il–A AP az D S i A Br l–A SA az RS i A Br l–A L Br azi GER Figure E.2  Water Regulatory Agencies (continued) B az l– Br raz il–A ATR az il– M Ar il–A AG AE ge G ER nt EN SA in E Pa Bra a– RS ra zil– ER A gu A SA a G C Ba y–E ERG rb RS S ad SA os N Ho an P –F TC nd am m. Formal transparency ur a– T2 a A Br s–E SE az RS P Ar B il– AP Ar gen razi AGE S ge ti l–A SC nt na RS i – Ar na– ENR AE ge ER E nt SP SS Ar Bra ina– yOC ge zi ER nt l–A A in R S a– SA ER M SA CT Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Dimensions of Regulatory Governance Appendix F Regulatory Governance and Performance Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   227   228 Table F.1 Regulatory Governance and Performance—Existence of Regulatory Agency Average Average Residential Energy Energy OPEX per OPEX per residential industrial Cost connection per sold per Distributional sold per Duration of Frequency of connection MWh sold tariff (in tariff (in recovery employee employee losses Coverage connection interrupt’s interrupt’s (in dollars) (in dollars) dollars) dollars) ratio (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Dummy transition 0.131*** 0.169*** 0.043*** −0.011*** 0.065*** −0.014 0.032 −0.314 −0.352 0.042** 0.064*** −0.005 of PSP (0.012) (0.014) (0.013) (0.002) (0.003) (0.032) (0.037) (0.223) (0.224) (0.019) (0.023) (0.059) Dummy post- transition 0.045*** 0.015 −0.131*** 0.003* 0.003 −0.295*** −0.348*** −0.142*** −0.089** −0.019** −0.031 0.192*** of PSP (0.008) (0.010) (0.012) (0.002) (0.005) (0.024) (0.023) (0.034) (0.036) (0.009) (0.021) (0.050) Existence of regulatory 0.177*** 0.167*** −0.045*** 0.004* −0.031*** −0.210*** −0.190*** −0.387*** −0.320*** 0.145*** −0.047** 0.125*** agency (0.010) (0.012) (0.009) (0.002) (0.005) (0.028) (0.029) (0.051) (0.056) (0.016) (0.021) (0.032) Utility FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Utility specific time trend Yes Yes No Yes No No No No No No No No Observations 2000 1981 2073 1323 2515 1056 947 864 873 1728 840 669 Number of utilities 199 198 190 144 213 144 132 131 131 175 90 103 Standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Table F.2 Regulatory Governance and Performance—Existence of Regulatory Agency with Interactions Average Average Residential Energy Energy OPEX per OPEX per residential industrial Cost connection sold per Distributional sold per Duration of Frequency connection MWh sold tariff (in tariff (in recovery per employee employee losses Coverage connection interrupt’s of interrupt’s (in dollars) (in dollars) dollars) dollars) ratio (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Dummy transition 0.121*** 0.170*** 0.125*** −0.012*** 0.057*** −0.018 0.059 −0.278 −0.230 0.164*** 0.055 −0.053 of PSP (0.014) (0.016) (0.018) (0.003) (0.008) (0.040) (0.046) (0.228) (0.229) (0.024) (0.039) (0.107) Dummy post- transition 0.018 −0.020 −0.123*** 0.006 0.095*** −0.561*** −0.429*** −0.110 −0.116 −0.087*** 0.123 0.308*** of PSP (0.015) (0.025) (0.035) (0.004) (0.015) (0.074) (0.064) (0.102) (0.099) (0.018) (0.100) (0.116) Existence of regulatory 0.162*** 0.175*** −0.008 0.002 −0.023*** −0.239*** −0.176*** −0.351*** −0.233*** 0.286*** −0.039 0.146*** agency (0.014) (0.017) (0.010) (0.002) (0.006) (0.038) (0.044) (0.069) (0.078) (0.024) (0.026) (0.042) Transition* 0.026 −0.012 −0.144*** 0.004 0.005 0.019 −0.061 −0.016 −0.150 −0.315*** 0.000 0.045 existence (0.018) (0.022) (0.022) (0.004) (0.011) (0.054) (0.059) (0.121) (0.129) (0.033) (0.045) (0.114) Post trans.* 0.032* 0.041 0.020 −0.005 −0.102*** 0.284*** 0.107 −0.071 0.006 0.138*** −0.158 −0.123 existence (0.017) (0.026) (0.037) (0.005) (0.016) (0.078) (0.069) (0.109) (0.108) (0.021) (0.102) (0.121) Utility FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Utility specific time trend Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 2000 1981 2073 1323 2515 1056 947 864 873 1728 840 669 Number of utilities 199 198 190 144 213 144 132 131 131 175 90 103 Standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 229 230 Table F.3 Regulatory Governance and Performance—Duration of the Regulatory Agency Average Average Residential Energy OPEX per OPEX per residential industrial Cost connection Distributional sold per Duration of Frequency of connection MWh sold tariff (in tariff (in recovery per employee losses Coverage connection interrupt’s interrupt’s (in dollars) (in dollars) dollars) dollars) ratio (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) Dummy transition of 0.175*** 0.030*** −0.013*** 0.062*** −0.022 0.044 −0.463** −0.451** 0.053*** 0.027 0.043 PSP (0.014) (0.011) (0.002) (0.005) (0.027) (0.033) (0.220) (0.228) (0.016) (0.019) (0.059) Dummy post- transition of 0.101*** −0.091*** 0.006*** 0.024*** −0.112*** −0.167*** −0.152*** −0.158*** −0.089*** −0.058*** 0.157*** PSP (0.008) (0.012) (0.002) (0.006) (0.025) (0.024) (0.036) (0.046) (0.011) (0.021) (0.049) Duration of the regulatory −0.014*** −0.018*** 0.004*** −0.018*** −0.094*** −0.094*** −0.057*** −0.016*** 0.026*** −0.013*** 0.040*** agency (0.003) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.008) (0.007) (0.005) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.005) Duration of the regulatory −0.000 0.001*** −0.001*** 0.001*** 0.004*** 0.004*** 0.003*** 0.001*** 0.001*** 0.002*** −0.001*** agency (Sq.) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Utility FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Utility specific time trend Yes No Yes No No No No No No No No Observations 2000 2073 1323 2515 1056 947 864 873 1728 840 669 Number of utilities 199 190 144 213 144 132 131 131 175 90 103 Standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Table F.4 Regulatory Governance and Performance—Regulatory Governance Index OPEX per Average Average Residential Energy Energy Duration Frequency OPEX per MWh sold residential industrial Cost connection sold per Distributional sold per of of connection (in tariff (in tariff (in recovery per employee employee losses Coverage connection interrupt’s interrupt’s (in dollars) dollars) dollars) dollars) ratio (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Dummy transition of 0.124*** 0.159*** 0.045*** −0.012*** 0.054*** −0.010 0.031 −0.269 −0.293 0.041** 0.070*** −0.006 PSP (0.012) (0.014) (0.013) (0.003) (0.005) (0.033) (0.038) (0.225) (0.227) (0.018) (0.022) (0.060) Dummy post- transition of 0.062*** 0.030*** −0.118*** 0.001 −0.007 −0.276*** −0.332*** −0.213*** −0.179*** 0.019 −0.027 0.194*** PSP (0.009) (0.011) (0.012) (0.002) (0.005) (0.024) (0.023) (0.036) (0.044) (0.012) (0.021) (0.050) Regulatory governance 0.236*** 0.226*** −0.077*** 0.005* −0.029*** −0.274*** −0.248*** −0.495*** −0.373*** 0.154*** −0.074*** 0.150*** index (ERGI) (0.013) (0.016) (0.013) (0.003) (0.007) (0.036) (0.038) (0.069) (0.076) (0.021) (0.028) (0.042) Utility FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Utility specific time trend Yes Yes No Yes No No No No No No No No Observations 1859 1840 1983 1247 2337 1030 924 841 850 1655 831 660 Number of utilities 181 180 175 137 195 139 127 126 126 159 85 98 Standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 231 232 Table F.5 Regulatory Governance and Performance—Principal Component Analysis Average Average Residential Energy OPEX per OPEX per residential industrial Cost connection Distributional sold per Duration of Frequency of connection MWh sold tariff (in tariff (in recovery per employee losses Coverage connection interrupt’s interrupt’s (in dollars) (in dollars) dollars) dollars) ratio (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) Dummy transition of 0.122*** 0.027** −0.014*** 0.059*** −0.043 0.046 −0.730* −0.808** 0.147*** 0.087*** 0.068 PSP (0.012) (0.013) (0.003) (0.004) (0.037) (0.044) (0.397) (0.400) (0.019) (0.021) (0.062) Dummy post- transition of 0.084*** −0.124*** 0.002 −0.008 −0.358*** −0.366*** −0.193*** −0.137*** 0.049*** −0.016 0.176*** PSP (0.008) (0.013) (0.002) (0.005) (0.025) (0.024) (0.039) (0.049) (0.013) (0.021) (0.053) PCA 1 -Informal 0.001 −0.027*** −0.001 −0.048*** 0.014 0.010 0.046 0.053 0.087*** 0.010 −0.003 (0.007) (0.007) (0.001) (0.004) (0.018) (0.018) (0.042) (0.050) (0.010) (0.021) (0.018) PCA 2 -Formal 0.107*** −0.006 0.004* 0.037*** −0.024 −0.103*** 0.050 0.092 −0.145*** −0.051*** −0.071* (0.008) (0.006) (0.002) (0.004) (0.026) (0.028) (0.084) (0.085) (0.014) (0.016) (0.037) PCA 3 -Formal autonomy 0.085*** −0.069*** 0.012*** −0.009 −0.144*** −0.080 −0.405*** −0.339** −0.036* −0.030 0.266*** and tariffs (0.015) (0.012) (0.004) (0.009) (0.053) (0.049) (0.111) (0.132) (0.020) (0.029) (0.068) Utility FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Utility specific time trend Yes No Yes No No No No No No No No Observations 1782 1917 1190 2253 974 882 800 809 1596 820 619 Number of utilities 175 169 131 189 134 123 121 121 153 84 93 Standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Appendix G Corporate Governance and Performance Table G.1 Correlation between Corporate Governance Indexes and Performance—Water and Electricity Distribution Sectors (in Levels) Distributional Quality of Labor Residential losses the service Coverage productivity tariffs Legal soundness −0.41 0.05 −0.26 0.29 0.39 CEO competitiveness −0.39 0.08 −0.33 0.08 0.36 Board competitiveness −0.22 −0.14 −0.12 0.10 0.14 Professional management −0.24 0.13 −0.08 0.34 0.22 Transparency and disclosure 0.14 −0.16 0.37 0.24 −0.31 Performance orientation −0.25 0.28 −0.09 0.26 0.22 Corporate governance −0.44 0.09 −0.20 0.40 0.37 Table G.2 Correlation between Corporate Governance Indexes and Performance—Water and Electricity Distribution Sectors (in Growth Rates) Distributional Quality of Labor Residential losses the service Coverage productivity tariffs Legal soundness 0.04 −0.31 0.14 −0.10 0.26 CEO competitiveness 0.05 −0.10 0.35 0.01 0.06 Board competitiveness −0.06 −0.10 −0.08 0.18 0.00 Professional management 0.03 −0.11 0.07 0.12 0.01 Transparency and disclosure −0.02 −0.04 0.15 0.10 −0.37 Performance orientation 0.18 0.09 0.30 0.13 0.01 Corporate governance 0.07 −0.20 0.31 0.12 0.02 Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5   233   234 Corporate Governance and Performance Table G.3 Correlation between Corporate Governance Indexes and Performance—Electricity Distribution Sector (in Levels) Distributional Duration of Frequency of Labor Residential Industrial losses interruptions interruptions Coverage productivity tariifs tariffs Legal soundness 0.02 0.39 0.32 −0.32 −0.41 0.42 0.42 CEO competitiveness 0.17 0.28 0.41 −0.02 −0.51 −0.19 0.22 Board competitiveness −0.01 0.47 0.44 −0.03 −0.23 0.09 0.50 Professional management 0.08 0.21 0.10 0.05 −0.07 0.40 0.18 Transparency and disclosure −0.19 −0.18 0.00 −0.07 0.20 0.09 −0.23 Performance orientation 0.06 −0.15 −0.04 0.14 0.31 0.23 −0.26 Corporate governance 0.06 0.37 0.44 −0.11 −0.30 0.38 0.31 Table G.4 Correlation between Corporate Governance Indexes and Performance—Electricity Distribution Sector (in Growth Rates) Distributional Duration of Frequency of Labor Residential Industrial losses interruptions interruptions Coverage productivity tariifs tariffs Legal soundness −0.10 0.36 0.30 0.19 −0.10 0.15 −0.01 CEO competitiveness −0.01 0.09 0.01 0.02 −0.19 −0.08 −0.26 Board competitiveness −0.09 0.10 0.05 0.00 0.07 0.00 0.02 Professional management 0.24 0.09 0.13 −0.15 −0.31 0.02 −0.30 Transparency and disclosure −0.03 −0.03 0.16 0.32 0.17 −0.28 −0.49 Performance orientation 0.28 −0.20 −0.14 0.03 0.04 −0.34 −0.16 Corporate governance 0.09 0.16 0.18 0.17 −0.11 −0.18 −0.40 Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Table G.5 Correlation between Corporate Governance Indexes and Performance—Water Sector (in Levels) Non-revenue Continuity of Water Sewerage Residential Residential Labor water the service Potability coverage coverage water tariffs sewerage tariffs productivity Metering Legal soundness −0.33 0.34 −0.05 −0.08 0.09 0.29 −0.01 0.54 −0.48 CEO competitiveness −0.02 −0.52 −0.12 −0.13 0.26 0.23 −0.23 0.07 −0.02 Board competitiveness −0.23 −0.12 0.31 0.29 −0.04 0.01 0.12 0.15 0.03 Professional management −0.27 −0.13 0.24 0.23 −0.07 0.31 0.11 0.53 −0.09 Transparency and disclosure −0.29 0.09 0.31 0.39 0.17 −0.11 0.32 0.26 0.26 Performance orientation −0.37 −0.23 0.62 0.35 0.18 0.17 0.03 0.46 0.21 Corporate governance −0.42 −0.14 0.41 0.32 0.17 0.30 0.10 0.59 −0.04 235 236 Table G.6 Correlation between Corporate Governance Indexes and Performance—Water Sector (in Growth Rates) Non-revenue Continuity of Water Sewerage Residential Residential Labor water the service Potability coverage coverage water tariffs sewerage tariffs productivity Metering Legal soundness 0.11 −0.37 0.25 −0.24 0.13 −0.04 0.17 −0.05 −0.03 CEO competitiveness −0.04 0.70 0.17 0.24 0.33 −0.52 −0.38 0.01 −0.17 Board competitiveness −0.10 0.36 0.22 0.02 −0.21 −0.03 −0.32 0.32 0.28 Professional management −0.21 0.27 0.16 −0.23 0.25 −0.23 −0.20 0.29 0.36 Transparency and disclosure 0.09 0.32 −0.01 0.28 0.20 −0.13 −0.09 0.08 0.32 Performance orientation −0.05 0.42 −0.73 −0.11 0.55 0.13 0.37 0.41 0.51 Corporate governance −0.06 0.48 0.05 −0.04 0.39 −0.25 −0.13 0.30 0.41 Corporate Governance and Performance 237 Table G.7 Principal Component Analysis—Eigenvalues of Factors Component Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative 1 2.173 0.810 0.362 0.362 2 1.362 0.357 0.227 0.589 3 1.006 0.289 0.168 0.757 4 0.717 0.271 0.119 0.876 5 0.445 0.148 0.074 0.950 6 0.297 n.a. 0.050 1.000 Note: n.a. = not applicable. Table G.8 Principal Component Analysis—Factor Loadings of Indexes after Varimax Rotation Variable Component 1 Component 2 Component 3 Unexplained Performance orientation 0.678 −0.327 −0.128 0.128 Legal soundness 0.217 0.151 0.624 0.328 Transparency and disclosure 0.277 0.223 −0.692 0.157 Board competitiveness −0.067 0.859 −0.050 0.076 CEO competitiveness 0.374 0.162 0.335 0.485 Professional management 0.522 0.236 0.028 0.287 Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 Environmental Benefits Statement The World Bank is committed to reducing its environmental footprint. In sup- port of this commitment, the Office of the Publisher leverages electronic pub- lishing options and print-on-demand technology, which is located in regional hubs worldwide. Together, these initiatives enable print runs to be lowered and shipping distances decreased, resulting in reduced paper consumption, chemical use, greenhouse gas emissions, and waste. The Office of the Publisher follows the recommended standards for paper use set by the Green Press Initiative. Whenever possible, books are printed on 50% to 100% postconsumer recycled paper, and at least 50% of the fiber in our book paper is either unbleached or bleached using Totally Chlorine Free (TCF), Processed Chlorine Free (PCF), or Enhanced Elemental Chlorine Free (EECF) processes. More information about the Bank’s environmental philosophy can be found at http://crinfo.worldbank.org/crinfo/environmental_responsibility/index.html. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance  •  http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-9660-5 For the past three decades, infrastructure economics has been preoccupied with the business of answering the question, “How?” in various contexts and settings. When public ownership of utilities appeared to be the sole cause of massive debts and poor services throughout Latin America and the Caribbean, economists were brought in to figure out how to privatize state-owned enterprises. When the capture of utility operators became a concern, the question evolved into, “How should public services be regulated?” And when, in recent years, the public’s patience with private operators began to wear thin, the questions became, “How do we rebalance risks?”“How do we best design public-private partnerships?” and “How do we take account of the rise of populism, of volatility in financial markets, of the flight of capital to safety?” The primary purpose of Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance is to step back from the carpentry of “How?” and answer the underlying question, “Why?” Why do some utilities perform well while others ­perform poorly? This book provides insights into infrastructure sector performance by focusing on the links connecting key indicators for private and public utilities, as well as on changes in ownership, regulatory agency governance, and corporate governance, among other dimensions. By linking inputs and outputs over the past 15 years, the analysis is able to uncover key determinants that have impacted performance in infrastructure s ­ ectors in Latin America and the Caribbean, and help one understand why the effects of such variables result in significant changes in the performance of infrastructure service provision. The book focuses on the distribution segment of basic infrastructure services: electricity, water and sewerage, and fixed telecommunications. It uses previously unavailable data on the performance of utility ­ companies; in addition to private service providers, data were collected through surveys sent to regulatory agencies and state-owned enterprises throughout the region. The entire analysis undertaken for Uncovering the Drivers is based on a dataset specifically constructed for this purpose. For most of the analysis, the data collected are original and are used here for the first time. The wealth of information pulled together through this exercise lends itself to further far-reaching analysis. By making this information available to a broader audience, the authors hope that such benchmarking efforts provide a regional- and utility-level frame of reference for sector performance, good or poor, in the region. ISBN 978-0-8213-9660-5 SKU 19660