0 ~~~~~~~ti B L I C I' O 1, I C A F O R 'r 1f E SEP9TF.NfIBER 109'- Privatesector ' D>:zm uSt z t| |1 8956 7 The Restructurin anc Pivaizain of thet ILK Elecriit SU_______________ \NWIs It Vorthi It- David IM.Neweiu a Jlicbael G. Pollf 11 A Retrospectixv on tht Mexi.ln Toll Road 1'rogr ( 1989 94) 1 icfRzits/er 19 The Private Sectir in Watcr and Sanitation-I osP\ to Get Started L Peteknefoe Brook, Cinena 23 Privatization and Restructuring in Central and EalStern Europe RKobert E AS ijderslim, Sim12 emi ~ Dj/zitkoi, (GerIird Pobl. (attc. St/jil C'lesseos 27 The Drivers of the Information Revolution-Cost, C(omputing Poxver, and Coilnvergence fumes 1ou 31 Telecoummunication-i Is I)ead. Li ng Live Nettorking A Jamies Boor!. 35 Tcleciomrnunicatiiins Refot im- r- FlOx to SLCCeelrd B/br,za We/eo izns [~6 *'557 39 Lilberalizing TeILreoFIIntWnicationns andf the Roil of the NXorll Trade Organiz.ation Cr2rlos, - Primo Brguta 47 W1hat the TIrYansforimation ofn 4 Telecrom Mlarkets Means for- R,gUilatitiOn 51 The Pr' ate S,ector and the r7?1TR ~ Itiiternet (Cad/s -A Pi*iii rimofi.(Ca 611d Carx/no Fink The World Bank Group * Finianice, Private Sector, nmd Infrastructure Net,,\irlk Private Sector is an open forum intended to encourage dissemination of and debate on ideas, innovations, and best practices for ex- panding the private sector. The views pub- lished are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the World Bank or any of its affiliated organizations. Nor do any of the con- clusions represent official policy of the World Bank or of its Executive Directors or the coun- tries they represent. Private Sectoris a quarterly publication distrib- uted free of charge. To subscribe, please send your name, mailing address, telephone num- ber, and fax number to the editor (Suzanne Smith, Room F6P-188, The World Bank, 1818 H Street, NW, Washington, D.C. 20433, email: ssmith7@worldbank.org, fax: 202 522 2961, telephone: 202 458 1111). Most Notes from Private Sector are also avail- able on-line. There is full text in HTML format for on-screen viewing or a downloadable file in Adobe's PDF format (http://www.worldbank. org/html/fpd/notes/notelist.html). Mn, Private sector Quarterly No.1I1, September 1997 The Restructuring and Privatization of the U.K. Electricity Supply-Was It Worth It? 7 David M. Newbery and Michael G. Pollitt report on a studcy that assesses the costs and benefits of the Frestrcturing and pri- atization of the electricity supplv sector in England and -\Vales. Since privatization, real unit costs haxe fallen by ahout 50 percent and real pool prices by 20 percent, and a switch from coal to gas hals ConltrihLuteCd to a dIop in polluting emilissions. But sorme of the positive changes can he attributed to external cfators socIh as the development of high-efficiency combined cycle turhines and the fall in coal prices. So the authors estimate the net henefits of privLtizLtion over the period 1995-2010 ly comparing the historical and projected path of the privatized incdustry Nwitlh what miglht have happened had the assets stavecl uncler public ow\ nership. They estimate the overall net henefits from privaltization at Al 1.9 billion. Costs fall. hut mucil of the benefit goes to the generators-because prices in the wholesale market fall muchL less. The authors suggest that | more competition may help to reduce these prices. A Retrospective on the Mexican Toll Road Program (1989-94) 11 In 1989. Mexico initiatecl a private toll road program of fifty-three concessions inv olving an inivestment of al)out 5I bSS i 3illion in limited reCourse financing over the period 1989-94. The program more than doubled the size of the national toll road network. but miscalculations of inv estment costs and overoptimistic forecasts of operating 0| Cincom1e uncdermiiiined the viahility of the toll ioads. An already bad situation xw as made wkorse b)y the Mexican Currency criSis of Deeemlher 1994 and the private toll road initiative came to a \irtual standstill. Local commiler- cial hianks \vere saddled w ith nonperforming loans estimzatecd at USS4.5 billion to USS5.5 billion. Concession- airCs and their- affiliates have been faced with w,\r iting off large portions of their investmtients. Ancl users w-ere left 4i | i Nwitl som1e of the highoest tolls in the world. Jeff Ruster diagnoses the fla s in the clesign of the program and showvs howN the failure was manifested in the implemenitation of clifferent phases of the projects. The Private Sector in Water and Sanitation-How to Get Started 19 T'ihe moie risk and responsibility a government hands over to the private sector in water and sanitation, the i:| more powNerful the incentives for better perforimanice-but also the moie clemands on the government in cormimtitment and preparation. So a governmient about to enter into a long partnershiip foi a water concession or b| uildl-operate-trainsfer arrangemient-typically for twenty-five to thirtv years-needs to he suLe that it does not ov erlook cletails that \ill later land it in messy renegotiations. A lease is less demandling, but offers smaller gains and wvill not fix sulIC problems as chroniC underinvestiment. It will, however, give the goverrnment time to ipreplie Li longer-terim option. In this Note. hased on toolkits recently published by the Wo'rld Bank. Penelope J. Brook Cowen sets out the range of options for involving the private sectoir in wxate and sanitation and reviews the lessons oni -viat can make ot break a private participation process. Privatization and Restructuring in Central and Eastern Europe 23 One of the Ilost imilportant policy questions in the transitioIn economilies is x hat go\ ernioments can clo to speed the restruCturing of firms and thus hasten the transitioni to a mature market economiy. Robert E. Anderson, Simeon Djankov, Gerhard Pohl, LincI Stijn Claessens report on) a study that pi-ovides some answers. l'rivat- ization encouLrages restructuring if it is rapid andl comprelhensive and leads to concentraLted ownership. Irivat- izLition also pi-omotes restruiCtLiring hecause privatized firmiis are more likely tball state-owned enterprises to exercise waige restraint-and wLage restraint is vital to free up the necessary internal finance. Btit policies that increase banik lencling to firiis, suLch as debt forgiveness aLind recapitalization. mav clo more harm than good. The sLifest course is to recapitillize banks only as part of privLitization ancl to encourLige negotiLitions for finan- - ciail restruCturinig only aifter the bLinks are privaLtizedl. The Drivers of the Information Revolution-Cost, Computing Power, and Convergence 27 James Bond explains the drivers of the information revolution-the decline in the cost of transmitting informa- tion, the increase in the power of computing. and the shift from analog to digital information teclnologies that has joined the telecommunications and computing industries and merged segments of the information industry. F Over the past twenty years. the cost of voice transmission circuits and the computing power per dollar invested . have both fallen by a factor of 10.000. Prices have not fallen nearly as fast-they have been set hy a cartel-like I system of international agreements hetveen incumbent monopolies. But as convergence restructures the tele- commUnications industry. new operators are arbitraging the difference between costs and the old tariff strmc- tures, putting pressure on incumbent telecommunications operators. 4 Telecommunications Is Dead, Long Live Networking 31 James Bond looks at hov the drivers of the information revolution are transforming the structure of the telecommunications industry. The end of natural monopoly, the breakdo-wn of the old pricing mechanisms, the increasing competition from new operators and new products, and the globalization of the industry are forcing radical change. This spells trouble for incumbent telecommunications operators-most of wvhose assets are holes in the ground. Many incumbents are responding by forming global alliances. But this trend imay have more to do wvith their desire to recreate in international markets the oligarchies they are used to at home than _ - . with the underlying market forces. Where is the industry heading? One view of the future sees transmission capacity and bandwidth becoming tradable comm)odities, with the industry fragmenting into wvholesalers in- Telecommunications Reform-How to Succeed 35 _ ; Telecommunications reform-privatization and opening markets to competition-can he a positiVe-SUMII gamCe in wlhich all stakeholders gain: customers, existing and new^- operators, employees, domestic and foreign inves- tors, and government. But the extent and timing of benefits vary from one case to another. Bjbrn Wellenius . I r . sets out some rules for reform that w-ill enhance those benefits: Get support at the higlhest level of political U authority. Sort out conflicting objectives early-especially the conflict between maximizing revenue and delis - ering more, better. and cheaper services. tIse market mechanismns rather than individual negotiations to select . partners and determine the right sale price. Establish and follow clearly defined processes for sale and regul.l- tion that are open to participation and reviev by all interested parties. And respect and trust the general public ! 4 ; and keep it informeld. Although miajor transactions suclh as a privatization or the issuance of new licenses drive "A the reform agenda, clhange continues wevll beyond them. Following the rules and hlonoring commiiiiitmcnts help X . I consolidate an environment for sustainahle development of telecommunications. Liberalizing Telecommunications and the Role of the World Trade Organization 39 In Febriary 1997, sixty-nine governments of high-income and developing countries agreed to liberalize their basic telecommunications services under an agreement negotiated through the Norld Trade Organization. Most participants in the agreement have subscribed to procompetitive regulatory principles, including independent regulators, competitive safeguards, measures to ensure interconnection, universal service obligations, and trans- parent and nondiscriminatory practices in licensing. The markets affected by the arrangement represent more than 90 percent of the w-orld market for telecommunications. Carlos A. Primo Braga reviews the evolution of the agreement and argues that the cr-itical issues novy are ensuring the quality of implementation and setting up . a procompetitive regulatory environment. .. -.. "0 -'" What the Transformation of Telecom Markets Means for Regulation 47 Peter Smith looks at the impact of the changes in the telecommunications industry on regulation. As demand changes, services converge, and new players emerge, the key issue for regulators is promoting competition. The work of regulators is becolmiing increasingly complex at the same time that convergence and the common principles estahlished in regional and international trade agreements are reducing their discretion. One way for regulators to deal with the complexity is to privatize aspects of regulation-for example. hy creating property rights to the spectrum and by outsourcing some regulatory tasks. But the specialized telecommunications regulatory agency is probably a transitory entity that may eventually find itself merged into a multisectoral antitrust agency. The Private Sector and the Internet 51 Carlos A. Primo Braga and Carsten Fink look at the rise of the Internet as the main application behind the emerging global information infrastructure. Many now believe that the Internet provides a window into a futLre in whiclh access to information will be inclependent of geographic location and interactivity in a multimedia environment will be ubiquitous. The authors review the need for a regulatory framework for the Internet in three critical areas: provision of backbone access, Internet service providers, and information services. They also explore the problem of the appropriability of content, discussing intellectual property rights in the digital era and other remedies to the cost recovery problem. For developing countries, however, the critical bottleneck is still their weak information infrastructure. 4.1 m C~~~ S; >~~~~~~~~ 5 THREE WAYS TO ORDER 0, For a free sabscription to Private sector Fill oGlt and miail this card to SLtzanne Smith, Ec itor, or I x it to 202 522 29(i FIRSI NANIE Nil iASS \NAMF Topics of interest JOB IITLE :IO'SPANS 3 Banking and capitail markeE' STREET ADDRESS 3 Priv,ttization El CotQprct,tiun CIII >TATlE POSTAL C()lk and regulation El Thiccolrns and COt \ITBSy ENLAIL techt lnaogy =Encrgy WVORK PHO\E FN 3 Transport 2 Call 202 458 1111 to record this information LJNYater 3 Email this information to ssmith7@worldhank.org H1l Netscape: 99Estach.pdf % I tGQt$i - �_ ()II Rt o a d ConcE ss n s :vW*? VM.' ' ts *.1 Kaac*4 *1 ''ct ?*trnrg $$. t:0 are t; ';' Lcssons fl rii Argentina ._ .,ut. 1. . . . 0 tSt'.1.,.1 ; = ;: 01 41>11. 0>0 1 4 WI I," A I _ _ @ w ' J tz X v } v s T .1 .. ' la S F~~~~~~~~~~~'V"6 t'h I I~~~~1 i., x IIII''II Most Notes are now available on-line in full-text HTML format or in downloadable Adobe PDF format (http://www.worldbank.org/html/fpd/notes/notelist.html). g' 1 7 ~~~~~Editor: A Suizanne Smith Roomn F6P-188 The World flank 1818 H Street, NW Washington, D.C. 20433 Telephone: 202 458 7281 Facsimile: 202 522 2961 Email: ssmith7@worldbank.org Cover illustration by Ruth Sofair Ketler. Photos on pages 1, 2. 3, 4, and 6 provided by FPG International. The entire contents of Private Sector �)1997 World Bank. You are authorized to reproduce, duplicate, and disseminate all or part of this publication so long as yotu include the name of the publication and the name of the respec- tive author. You may not, however, modify, p e g I as alter, or otherwise change any part of this pub- lication or sell, transfer, or otherwise dissemi- nate any part of the publication for profit. w � Printed on recycled paper. 7 The Restructuring and Privatization of the U.K. Electricity Supply-Was It Worth It? David MI. Xiubeilu andffi Mcbael G Pollitt The electricity supply industry in England and Significant changes followed. In the first six years Wales was under public ownership from 1948 after restructuring, labor productivity in the stuc- to 1990. For most of this period, a single com- cessor companies more than doubled. There w as pany, the Central Electricity Generating Board a marked shift away from coal and toward natu- (CEGB), operated all generation and transmis- ral gas. At privatization, generation hased on sion as a -ertically integrated statutory mo- fossil fuel used 92 percent coal, 7 percent oil. nopoly, while twelve area boards acted as and only 1 percent gas. In the next fiv-e years. regional distribution monopolies. The CEGB purchases of British coal fell from 74 million during this time was a classic example of a cost- metric tons to 30 million, and by August 1996, of-service regulated public utility-wvith exces- gas accounted for 23 percent of generation. In siv-e capital costs, overdependence on high-cost the meantime, the price of coal delivered to indigenous coal and nuclear power, low pro- power stations fell by 20 percent in real terms. ductivity growth, and low return on assets. The switch from coal and the dash for gas contributed to a substantial drop in emissions In 1990, the CEGB vas restructuLred and priva- of sulfur dioxide and nitrogen oxides, hoth tized. What xvere the costs and henefits? The sources of acid rain, and of carbon dioxide, the question is important not only because the cause of global warming. CEGB accounted for such a significant share of economic activity-vith value added equal The pover generation sector added 9.5 mega- to about 1 percent of GDP-but also because watts of capacity in combined cycle gas turbines its restructuring was a key part of the British (nearly 20 percent of peak demand) in 1990-96, electricity experiment,' wlhich has provided a while demand rose less than 6.5 percent: of the model for power sector reform around the new capacity, half was installed by new entrants. world. This Note reports the results of a social Fossil fuel costs per kilow att-hour (kWh) of elec- cost-benefit analysis of the restructuring and tricity generated fell by -r percent in real terms privatization of the CEGB. as a result of fuel switching and efficiency in- creases, wvhile nuclear fuel costs per kWhI fell The reform by 60 percent. Overall. real unit costs fell by about 50 percent, while real pool prices fell by The restructuring of the CEGB involved divid- a more modest 20 percent, \vith the difference ing it into four successor companies on Mlarch betwN-een the two figures reflecting the lack of 31, 1990-three of which were soon sold to competition among generating companies. the general public-creating a power pool, and liberalizing entry into the generation market. Some of these positive changes could be at- The three privatized companies are National tributed to external factors. The timely devel- Power and PoxverGen, w hich took the thermal opment of high-efficiency combined cycle gas generating plant, and National Grid, which was turbines, the lifting of the European Union (EU) allocated the high-voltage transmission net- ban on burning gas to generate electricity, and work. Nuclear Electric took the nuclear power tighter EU limits on sulfur emissions all encour- stations. aged the sxvitch to gas, and the decline in 8 The Restructuring and Privatization of the U.K. Electricity Supply-Was It Worth It? international coal and oil prices and in the the future, so the method involves projecting domestic price of gas contributed to the re- into the future hoth the actual outcomes and duction in unit costs. the counterfactual. The restructuring and privatization were not The social cost-benefit analysis of the CEGB's without costs. The 'dash for gas" greatly accel- restructturing and privatization proceeds in two erated the decline of the coal industry. Em- stages: first the net benefits of the restructur- ployment fell from nearly 250,000 miners at ing and privatization are calculated, then these the time of the 1984-85 coal miners strike to benefits are apportioned among shareholders, only 7,000 by 1994. The collapse of the British the government, and the power purchasers in coal market was the subject of a Parliamentary the pool or wholesale market (the distribution inquiry. Partly in response to that inquiry, policy companies and the supply businesses of the toward the still publicly owned nuclear gen- generating companies) to see how the gains eration industry was reviewed, plans to build are distributed. The first stage of the analysis more nuclear power stations were abandoned values four areas of net benefits and costs sepa- in early 1996, and the nuclear industry was re- rately: the efficiency savings, the investment structured. The more modern nuclear power and fuel use effects, the costs of reorganiza- stations were sold as British Energy in June tion, and the environmental benefits. In each 1996, leaving only the ruLmp of aging first- area, it establishes a set of counterfactuals with generation Magnox stations and the fuel re- which data or projections for the actual indus- processing facilities in the public sector. The try are compared. The start date from which coal industry was privatized at the end of 1994. the effects of restructuLring and privatization are evaluated is a weighted average of the years A social cost-benefit analysis 1985-88. Actual data are available until March 1996, and projections are made to 2010. Studies have used several methods to assess the economic effects of privatization on formerly To allow some sensitivity analysis for the more state-owned companies. including financial debatable issues, two counterfactuals are used. performance analysis, labor and total factor One is labeled proprivatization because the un- productivity analysis, frontier efficiency measure- derlying assumptions about the industry under ment. and social cost-benefit analysis. Although continued public ownership are more pessi- all these methods are of interest, only a full so- mistic than under the other counterfacttual and cial cost-benefit analysis identifies who gained, so it suggests greater net benefits from privati- who lost, and by how much-by comparing the zation. The other counterfacttual is labeled pro- historical and predicted future course of an in- CEGB because its more optimistic assumptions dustry after privatization with a counterfactual about the industry under continued public in which the industry remains unprivatized. ownership point to smaller net benefits from Jones, Tandon, and Vogelsang (1990) set out privatization. The counterfactLals incorporate this method, and Galal and others (1994) apply three key items: Productivity growth is lower it to twelve privatizations, two of which involved in both counterfactuals compared with the ac- Chilean electricity companies. tual, but slightly higher under pro-CEGB than under proprivatization. Gas and coal prices are In simple terms, the analysis reduces to a project the same as actual under pro-CEGB but higher appraisal, in which restructuring and privatiza- under proprivatization. And under both tion are an investment project that has associ- counterfactuals, the CEGB invests in uneco- ated costs (redundancy payments, brokers fees) nomic nuclear capacity and retrofitting of some and creates a stream of net benefits arising from coal plant with flue-gas desulfurization units, the evaluated differences between the privatized but under proprivatization it builds more industry and a counterfactual publicly owned nuclear and coal plant and does morc retrofit- industry. The costs and benefits continue into ting. The counterfactuals are based on reports The World Bank Group 9 TABLE 1 THE NET BENEFITS OF PRIVATIZING THE CEGB RELATIVE TO TWO COUNTERFACTUALS, 1995-2010 (f billions at 1994-95 prices; at a 6 percent discount rate, of the CEGB before privatization and an analy- discounted to April 1995) sis of the CEGB's performance in the decade before restructuring. The proprivatization Relative to Relative to counterfactual is probably closer to what wooulcl proprivatization pro-CEGB have happened in the absence of privatization. counterfactual counterfactual The results Fuel and investment effects End of nuclear expansion program 3.3 2.8 What does the analysis show abotut the net ben- Effect on price of French imports -2.6 -1.5 efits? The fuel and investment effects of the privatization range from gains of �3.6 billion Netfossit fuel costs 2.9 -2.1 to losses of f0.7 billion (at the U.K. putblic sec- Total 3.6 4.7 tor's preferred 6 percent discount rate),' de- pending on assurmptions about hov a utility Externality benefits under continued public owvnership xxould have Reductions in sulfur dioxide emissions invested in new capacity (table 1). The net gains (�125 per metric ton) 1.0 0.7 from privatization are higher relative to the Reductions in carbon dioxide emissions proprivatization counterfactual; the oains conme 1~~~~~~~~~ (f�12 per metric ton of carbon) 1.4 1.2 from the ending of the expensive nuclear ex- pansion program that mighlt have seen tw-o new Total 2.3 1.9 nuclear power stations built and the sharp switch from expensive British coal to cheaper Restructuring natural gas for electricity generation. Costs -2.8 -2.8 Cost savings 8.8 7.6 Regardless of the counterfactual Used, some of Total 6.0 4.8 the benefits of privatization are dissipated in higher payments to Electricite de France (EdF), Total net benefits 11.9 6.0 the French utility, for its cheap electricity im- ports. This happens because before privatiza- Total net benefits (pence per kWh) 0.21 8.09 tion EdF had received a price equal to the average of the marginal costs of the two sys- Sorrce-Authiors'estimates. tems (a price lower than the system nmarginal cost in England and Wales), while since privati- zation it has received the pool price (which is at or above system marginal cost) plus a share nients in nitrogen oxide emissions and ben- of the fossil fuel levy paid to non-fossil fuel efits from reduced coal burning. generators (introduced at the time of privatiza- tion to finance decommissioning at Nluclear Elec- The restructuring and privatization haxve high tric). If privatization had not occurred in the clirect costs, �2.8 billion. This figtire includes all United Kingdom, the paytnent terms would not the restructuring costs of the successor compa- have changed to the benefit of EdF. nies. including substantial redundancy and early retirement payments. But the restructuring and Against both counterfactuals, privatization privatization deliver unambiguous benefits in yields substantial environmental benefits as lower operating costs (08.8 billion relative to cleaner gas generation replaces older coal-fired proprivatization. �07.6 billion relative to pro- plant and thermal efficiencies rise at thie re- CEGB). The difference reflects the lower labor maining fossil fuel plant, leading to sharply and materials andcservices costs that the restruc- reduced emissions. The figures in table 1 are turing and privatization deliver-gains difficult conservative estimates of the environmental to imagine under a counterfactual publicly benefits, whichi include unmeasured inmprove- owned CEGB. 10 The Restructuring and Privatization of the U.K. Electricity Supply-Was It Worth It? TABLE 2 DISTRIBUTION OF THE NET BENEFITS OF PRIVATIZING THE CEGB, WITH PRICES CONVERGING IN 2000 try and the counterfactual publicly owned firm (� billions at 1994-95 prices; discounted to April 1995; converge in 2000. The study assumes that regu- excludes externalities) lation would ensure long-run convergence of precdicted and counterfactual prices. The results Relative to Relative to of the calculation show the perverse nature of Beneficiary proprivatization pro-CEGB the distributional effects of the privatization. The government's substantial sales revenue Powerpurchasers -1.3 4.4 (X9.7 billion) up to March 1996 is at least par- Govemment (including sales proceeds) 1.2 0.4 tially offset by loss of flow revenue, because Shareholders (less sales proceeds) 9.7 8.1 tax revenue from the successor companies falls below the public sector dividend target. As a Source: Authors' estimates. result, the government is �1.2 billion better off relative to proprivatization if prices converge in 2000. Relative to both counterfactuals, the The overall net benefit of the privatization is shareholders benefit by more than the total net substantially positive relative to both counter- benefit, even after the sales proceeds paid to factuals: �11.9 billion and �6.0 billion. These acquire the assets are subtracted. figures may be converted to permianent savings in the unit cost of electricity of 0.21 and 0.09 Conclusion pence per kWh at a time that electricity prices were about 2.8 pence per kWh. Thus, privatiza- Was it worth it? Yes. but the analysis suggests tion delivers a permanent cost reduction equiva- two major areas for improvement in the pro- lent to about 3.2 to 7.5 percent of prices, or an cess of the restructuring and privatization. First. extra 40 percent return on assets. about a quarter of the net gains were transferred out of the country because of the change in How has this net benefit been distributed among payment arrangements for French electricity. If shareholders, purchasers in the wholesale mar- more attention had been paid to this possibility ket, and the government? Examination of price at the time of restructuring, sonme arrangement trends shows that wholesale prices have not could probably have been found to prevent it. fallen nearly as fast as costs and that profits have Second. introducing more competition in gen- risen sharply in the successor companies: com- eration (by creating more successor companies) bined profits (before taxes and exceptionals) would have reduced excess entry and lowered rose from �.2.0 billion in 1991-92 to �3.5 billion prices, improving the distribution of the net in 1995-96. The share prices of National Power benefits and increasing social welfare. and PowerGen have approximately tripled since flotation, outperforming the stock market by Thi Note is ahort version of an aticle hv the authors dui to appear more than 100 percent. Thus, the companies in Jolto'al oJ tInditu'stnl Ecotnomics (Siptletifner 199T). seem to have unambiguously gained from the RcstrUctutring and pninatiz.ttion .are ., pUbliC sector project and so privatization. Power purchasers seem to be pay- hutd le es alutted at an approprte pUbtiC sctot discount rate. ing higher prices than they would have uncler References continued public ownership (higher company profit margins offset lower costs). And the gov- Galal Alimed, Lcov Jones, PFank.j Ta.ndon. and ingt Vogelsang. 1994. ernment has gained from sales revenue, higher Co//nre (onu'qtuettce.s oSetltling IPliblic ELtetprnses: An Littpitlcal taxes on profits, and dividend income, though Ana4tsis. Ness Ytrk: Oxford U nieisitv Ilr-ess. Jones. Lerty, Pank.j Tatndon, and Ingo Vogelsang. 1990. Setling Putblic it has lost the revenue associated with the pub- Entte)ptpsnc: A Cost-Benefit.Atethbdologt. Cambridge. Mass.: MIT P'ress. lic sector dividend target for the CEGB. David M. ,VNeubery anzd Micbael G. Pollitt, Table 2 shows one possible calculation of the Department of Applied Economics and Faculty distribution of the net benefits of privatizing of Economics, University of Cambridge, the CEGB. In it prices in the privatized indus- Cambridge, UK. 11 A Retrospective on the Mexican Toll Road Program (1989-94) Jejf Raister Mexico's private toll road program more than In retrospect, some industry observers lhave char- doubled the national toll road network-from acterized the toll road program as a ruslhed and 4,500 kilometers in 1989 to 9.900 kilometers in poorly designed effort to develop the infrastruc- 1994. Fifty-three concessions were awrardcd for tture the country needed to compete effectively the approximately 5.500 kilometers of roads, in an era of free trade. Others have simply la- and by the first quarter of 1995 forty-four wTere beled it a mechanism to lift the construction in- in full or partial operation, represenrtingp 5,120 dLustry Otut of the economic depression of the kilometers. The investment of approximately 1980s. Whatever the diagnosis for the poor per- US$13 billion in the program over the period fortnance of the sector. from a private investment 1989-94 was sourced from local commnercial perspective the impact wvas to shut off capital bank debt, concessionaire equity, and federal flowvs to the sector anci to add to the Mexican and state government grants ancI equity con- banking system's nonperforming loan portfolio. tributions (figure 1).' This Note presents a diagnostic of key policy However, gross miscalculation of investment regulatory, and institutional gaps that under- costs and operating inconme led to an unsus- mined the- financial equilibrium of the sector. tainable set of operating conditions for these A checklist of recurrent problems illustrates limited recourse financings. The financial eqcui- hoxy the failure to address these issues mani- librium of the sector xvas fturtlher undermined fested itself in the course of implementation. by the Mexican currency crisis of D)eceinher 1994. The combination of macroeconomic and project-level factors brouglht new project de- velopment to a virtual standstill, despite gov- FIGURE 1 SOURCES OF FUNDING FOR THE TOLL ROAD ernment estimates that another 6(500 kilometers CONCESSIONS of roads are needed by 2000. Restructuring of both project debt and equity investments has Concessionaire been the main focus of recent efforts.' equity Domestic commercial banks The financial and economic repercussions have been widespread. Local cormmercial banks were saddled with nonperforming toll road loans cs- timated at US$4.5 billion to tS$5.5 hillion. Con- cessionaires and their affiliates were facedith (US$2.5wt writing off significant portions of their invest- billion) ments. Moreover, the government has been un- Federal and state able to unclog the road construction progrtm government grants and has been under severe pressure to inject and equity scarce financial resources to rescue investors. Source:Author'scompilation. Users, in the meantime, were left with socme of the most expensive road tolls in the xvorld. 12 A Retrospective on the Mexican Toll Road Program (1989-94) BOX 1 THE TOLL ROAD CONCESSIONS Legal framework. Under the program, the Secretary of Communica- tions and Transport granted concessions to special-purpose entities, Major issues and sector performance which in almost all cases were either directly owned by or were affiliates of one or more local construction companies. The conces- Although the program attracted significant pri- sion agreements were issued under the federal law of General vate investment, well-puLblicized problems Means of Communication, which governs, among other things, roads negatively affected sector performance. These revolved around the following issues: that connect two or more Mexican states and bridges along any such * Inadequate tendering process and concession road. Under this legal framework, concessions could not exceed design. The prequalification standard was not fifteen years, though this was later extended to thirty years, and a rigorous enough (for example, bidders were free, parallel alternative to each highway was required.3 not required to submit a detailed financing plan). Also, the project award criteria lim- Concession party responsibilities. The concessionaire was respon- ited the pool of potential candidates (and sibleforfinancing, building, operating, and maintainingthetoll road thus haotential competition for themariket) to a handful of local construiction compainies subject to government regulation for a specified period of time in that were more interested in the construc- exchangefortherighttoreceivetollrevenuesgeneratedbythe tion work than in the long-term financial vi- project. The role of the Secretary of Communications and Transport ability of the projects. (See box 1 for an centered on project definition, including highway path, location of outline of the concessions.) interchanges and toll booths, and number of lanes, establishment of * Inadequate financial discipline in government- design and construction standards; design and implementation of owned commercial banks. This led to large tendering procedures; and supervision of the concessionaire. or nod iece unaking was not or no due diligence undertaking. It wvas not uncommon for lenders to waive important Concession design. The concession specified the duration of the conditions precedent to initial and subsequent agreement, the work to be undertaken, operational and maintenance funding (insurance and bonding requirements, standards, govemment supervision, required maintenance reserve securing permits and rights of way, satisfac- funds, concessionaire reporting requirements, certain fees payable to tory review of traffic studies, geotechnical and the government, and the tolls to be charged. On termination of the environmental studies, and the like). As the concession, the right to operate the highway and to collect toll story goes, such behavior was guided by an implicit understanding that even if the projects revenues reverted to the govemment The government was to remain proved commercially nonviable, ultimate re- the owner of the project throughout the term of the concession. course was indeed to the government. Underdeveloped local financial markets. Le- Tariff and adjustment mechanism. Each concession set forth a gal and regulatory limitations combined with schedule of tolls by category of vehicle. Tolls were allowed to poor macroeconomic fundamentals inhibited increase semiannually in accordance with the consumer price index the capacity of local markets to provide long- CPI) or whenever the CPI increased by 5 percent or more since the term fixed rate financing. Peso-denominated debt featured very short maturities rarely ex- previous adjustment. All other toll adjustments beyond the levels set tending beyond five years, with interest rates forth in the concession required the govementfs written approval. often 1,000 to 1,500 basis points above those paid by the government. This situation was Guarantees. Each concession also contained guarantees of traffic exacerbated by the currency crisis of Decem- volumes by category of vehicle. Most concessions provided that if the ber 1994, when all-in interest rates rose to actual traffic volumes on the highway fell short of those specified in more than 100 percent a year for most the concession, the concessionaire would be entitled to request an projects, which were already strapped to meet their debt service obligations. extension of the term of the concession to permit recovery of its Underdeveloped institutional capability. The investment above three issues were aggravated by the fact that the program's scope simply ex- The World Bank Group 13 ceeded the technical and administrative ca- given concurrent plans to privatize the rail, pacity of the local constrLction industry, the port, and airport sectors. liquidity of domestic financial markets, the * Understaffing and limited institutional capa- project finance experience of most financial bilities within the Secretariat of Communica- intermediaries involved, and the institutional tions and Transport often led to problems in capabilities of regulatory officials. Conse- obtaining permits or approvals for change quently, the control mechanisms needed to orders on a timely basis and to inadequate develop the roads within suchi a shlort time enforcement of the concession requirements were never adequately acldressed. regardin(g construction and maintenance qual- it- control standards. A summary follows of how these four prob- u In addition to the problems relating to hid lems manifested themselves in project imple- selection criteria, there was no efficient pre- mentation-in the regulatory and institutionial selection process to screen out potential bid- framework for the concessions, the operative ders that lackeed the capacity to assume the period, and the financial and legal arrangements essential risks of construction design and man- of the projects. agement, completion of large projects, and commercial management of toll road opera- The regulatory and institutional framework tions. While operating a toll road is fairly simple (nostly consisting of collecting tolls Problems relating to the regulatoryv and institu- from passing vehicles), managing a toll road tional framework for the concessions included program is much more complex. It includes vsaguie project selection criteria stemming in large estimating deniand in the face of competition part from the lacki of an intermodal strategy and from toll-free roads or other forms of trans- inadequate planning criteria at the fecleral and port, adjusting tolls to optimize revenues, plan- state level, inadequate prequalification and ning maintenance to minimize long-term costs, award criteria, uncertain tariff adjustment pro a'ndi managing short- and long-term financial cedures. and lack of an independent regulatory commitments. Ideally, the hidding consortia authority to supervise the contractual arrange- slhould be able to demonstrate that these sklills ments. The major recurring issues includced the are available to them. The lack of a good following: screening process led, for e\iample, to the * This greenfield program sought to establish selection of mecdium-size concessionaires that five main road corridors, three of which >were financed their equity contributions throtugh to run between the main industrial centers in commercial loans. NXWhen projects began to suf- Mexico and the principal border crossings into fer financial difficulties, these concessionaires the United States.' Nonetheless, some high- wAere often unable to meet their equity infu- priority segments were never concessioned, sion requirements. Others did not have the while others that were constructecd lacked con- necessary technical c apabilities, inclucding spe- tiguous sections that would integrate them into cialized machinery, skilled labor, and adequate the network. This piecemeal pattern of coln- quality control procedures. Even some of the tracting reduced the near-term attractiveness larger companies xxvere stretched too thin, of the toll roads to long-distance traffic, par- given the speed at which different conces- ticularly to truck-ers, xvho pay the higlhest tolls. sions were awarcled to the same firm. * Somewlhat related is the lack of an intermodal * Formal mechanisms were never established development strategy. Thus, project devel- for soliciting or channeling inquiries or re- opment in the various transport sectors often quests from private sector participants before, occurred without due coordination. Conse- dcuring, or aftcr the bidding process. Thus, the quently, investors were unable to determine relationship that developed between the pub- whether a project fit well into the long-term lic and private sectors often lacked transpar- development plans of a region. especially ency and was at times adversarial. 14 A Retrospective on the Mexican Toll Road Program (1989-94) Project cost structure at all. This, combined w ith the fact that lend- ers only rarely hired an independent engi- Cost overruns and delays frequently arose be- neer to assist them with their due diligence cause of information deficiencies, problems investigation before financial closing or with with securing rights of way, lack of effective supervision of the contractors' efforts, cre- turnkey construction arrangements, unantici- ated a void in terms of monitoring quality pated design changes, local community resis- control programs, permitting issues, and the tance, and permitting issues. As a result, the progress of construction budgets, critical path average cost per kilometer of new highway rose activities, and the like. to about US$2.6 million to US$2.8 million, com- * In some projects, construction came to a vir- pared with the original estimated cost of USSI.7 tual standstill because of poorly defined pro- million. This figure does not reveal the full cedures and bureaucratic delays regarding extent of the overruns associated with the "hard the issuance of permits for purchase and use costs" of construction, that is, the costs associ- of chemicals or dangerous substances. In one ated with required equipment, material, and project, time delays resulting from problems labor, and as opposed to 'soft costs" (interest in securing permits for dynamite directly re- payments during construction, cost escalation sulted in cost increases of nearly 30 percent. due to inflation, advisory services, and the like). The dramatic drop during 1990-94 in both in- Project revenue structure flation and interest rates offset in part the real increases in hard costs. Cash flow generated by the sector has been far below base-case expectations as a result of Reasons for the cost overruns included the traffic shortfalls and higher-than-expected following: operations and maintenance expenditures. The * Projects often broke ground with only very December 1994 currency crisis led to a sharp preliminary engineering and design work. In decline in disposable income and thus road the case of the 267 kilometer Cuernavaca- usage. along with a drop in economic activity Acapulco toll road, for example, this led to that resulted in a marked decrease in commer- cost overruns of 200 percent and time de- cial activity ancd freight transportation. As a lays of thirty months. result, of the thirty-two projects for which op- � Construction often began without first secur- crating data \vere available in March 1995, less ing the right of way. This failure was often than five could meet their base-case revenue exacerbated by mounting resistance from lo- projections. On average, actual project revenues cal farmers and community groups, environ- were 30 percent below original projections. mentalists, and historical conservationists, and resulted in delays and even rerouting of Important factors leading to this situation in- some projects. As problems occurred, ma- cluded the following: chinery and material sat idle while mobiliza- * Shortcomings in the traffic studies reflected a tion and interest costs mounted. general lack of expertise by the concession- * One of the most frequently recurring problems aires, the lenders, and their consultants in related to supervision and unilaterally man- developing adequate methodologies (box 2). dated change orders by the Secretary of Com- On only five of the thirty-two toll roads for munications and Transport. In a project in which traffic data are available has the aver- which four pedestrian bridges were expected, age daily traffic been above base-case expec- the final number reached almost sixty as a re- tations (table 1). sult of government-mandated change orders, * In some projects, trucks were expected to ac- often required to appease local interest groups. count for 20 to 45 percent of users. In reality, * Many projects were financed under very loose trucks were less than 5 percent of the traffic cost-plus construction arrangements or none on many roads, leading to a weighted aver- The World Bank Group 15 BOX 2 TRAFFIC STUDIES Traffic study methodologies often suffered from the following: age tariff much lower than originally expectedl. Lack of analysis of specific traffic characteristics, including time In some cases, the existence of a black mar- ket for toll tickets contributed to this outcome. and seasonal variations by type of vehicle, trip origins and Despite obvious time and cost advantages destinations, and purpose and frequency of trips. of the new roads, many potentiual users were . Failure in projections to identify key economic parameters that simply unw illing to pay the toll. Aside froim would affect road usage, such as population, employment, per the extremely high tariff's, this unw illingness capita auto ownership, per capita and disposable income, and was also duie to the fact that the conicession- performance of key industrial indicators. aires did little to market the time ancd cost savings of the roads (for examiiple. through Unrealisticgrowth rate assumptionsforextended periodsthat, if monthly passes, volurme discounts, and cli- realized, would have exceeded the capacity of the road. rect negotiations with high-volume uscrs such l Failure to include an end-user learning curve or differences in as trucking or passenger bus companics). tariff elasticity between end users. In all but a few concession agreements, the Overreliance on increased demand due to the opening of intercon- concessionaire could adjust the tariffs only withepriornappreoval byjt the S etarioff Coinl necting roads, the construction of which was often delayed or wTith prior approval hy the Secretary of Comi- munications and Transport (even for down- neverundertaken. ward adjustments). This greatly reduced the Underestimation of the congestion relief thatthe opening of the flexibility of the concessioniaire in efforts to new toll road would bring for the toll-free option, and thus maximize cash flow. overestimation of the actual time savings of the new road. Minimal attention was paid to the develop- * Insufficient attention to general conditions of alternative and mnent of suich auxilkiarV SerxTiCeS as gas sta- feeder routes and the identification of factors influencing the tions, rest stops, hospitals, tow truck services, and restaurants. (For most projects, conces- traffic-carryingcapacityofkeysections. sionaires were uranted the right to operate - Inadequate and at times not readily accessible data from the these services for two years beyond the con- Secretary of Communications and Transport for traffic studies. cession term.) A toll bridge expected to - Though investors sometimes employed their own independent handle ',)00 trucks a day mov ing through a consultants, actual fieldworkwas limited toonetotwoweeks of U.S. border crossing captured only 200 users traffic surveys. This was often the result of insufficient time a dav. This shortfall wAas in large part clue to inadequate attention to access roads and to allotted to bidders and financiers between the date of release of installation of customs clearing facilities. the bid documents and the deadline for delivery of bids. The government faced great resistance from the trucking industry in implementing and enforcing technical measurenment and axle- weiglht standards. Truckers for the most part X Inadequate toll collection operations and sys- continued to use the toll-free option, espe- teimis, poorly designecd fiduciary structures, cially in light of the very hig,h tolls. and the inexperience of the trustees and com- Operations and maintenance budgets often mercial banks responsible for super-vising the were not heavily scrutinized by the conces- flowv of project funds led to less than strict sionaire or its lenders, and in many cases controls over collection and proper applica- extraordinary maintenance costs xx ere grosslv tion of road revenues. underestimated. Though provisions for ma- jor maintenance reserve funcls were incluclecl Project financial structure in most concession agreements, enforcement of these provisions by the Secretary of Com- Lack of liquidity in the local financial markets, munications andl Transport and credlitors xv as use of short-term, high-cost. floating rate dlebt. often lacking, especially' as concessionaires currencv risk (both devaluation and convert- began to experience financial difficulties. ibility) faced by international investors, and the 16 A Retrospective on the Mexican Toll Road Program (1989-94) high cost and limited availability of surety and * The only source of local debt financing was insurance coverage severely hampered sector the commercial banking sector. But the ten- performance. ors for such debt often extended only through Concessionaires' financial contributions were the construction period, with the expecta- in the form of 'sweat equity" provided tion that once the project was in operation, through the retention of work from construc- cash flows would be securitized through lo- tion affiliates. These contributions originally cal or international debt offerings. However, amounted to 25 to 30 percent of investment as roads incurred cost overruns and the debt costs, but as lenders demanded higher eq- servicing ability of the projects proved far uity cushions and debt service coverage ra- less than had been expected, these construc- tios, the contributions increased to about 50 tion lenders soon were forced to restructure percent of project costs. This led to inflated and extend the terms of their bridge financ- construction budgets (and hence toll levels), ing. In addition, the loans were character- with some projects effectively financed with ized by high floating interest rates, often 1,000 100 percent or more leverage. Estimates of basis points higher than the local market ref- the average gross margins in the road builcl- erence rate. This combination of high inter- ing program range from 35 percent to 50 per- est rates and short maturities resulted in cent of total costs. Like the distortions arising prohibitively high tariffs. from the bid selection criteria, these exces- * As many projects became increasingly un- sive margins in no small part were the result able to meet their debt service obligations, of a lack of competition among the limited lenders' appetite for new toll road invest- number of project bidders. ments declined. Consequently, many banks The concession agreements contained an that had underwritten huge amounts for adjustment clause to shorten the concession projects were later unable to syndicate or term if traffic exceeded guaranteed levels. refinance the loans, and liquidity quickly Because of the lack of any upside potential, dried up in the market. Once word spread this clause led to significant disincentives to about the actual financial situation of many apply true risk capital. projects, other, untapped sources of funding (such as international institutional investors) quickly turned their attention to other invest- ment opportunities, both within and outside the country. Likewise, in the few international TABLE 1 DAILY TRAFFIC HAS NOT offerings, market liquidity and resulting pric- MET EXPECTATIONS ing were adversely affected by the presence of currency risk, in the form of both exchange Average dailytraffic rate depreciation and convertibility or trans- as a percentage of ferability concerns.' guaranteed traffic Number of roadsfeaitycnrs. * Local commercial banks were lacking in credit analysis, loan documentation, internal Above 100 5 controls, and risk and liquidity management. 75-100 2 Thus, the skills needed for limited recourse 50-74 8 financing-to analyze project credit, security 25-49 8 arrangements, and operative agreements- 6-24 9 simply were not adequate for the complex- ity of the projects and the huge demand for Note: As of December 1994. credit. Source:Author's compilation. * Performance, advance payment, and hidden defects bonds, as well as insurance for prop- erty damage, third-party liability, force ma- The World Bank Group 17 jeure, and delayed opening, were high cost ing power at the negotiating table with both and very scarce. Where coverage was se- the borrower and the government. cured, significant problems arose in collec- x Some concessionaires wxere not single-purpose tion. These problems resulted as much from entities. In these cases, it was impossible for lenders' inexperience in negotiating the terms lenders to isolate specific cash flowxs by project, of such policies as fi-om cuinhbersome and and borrowersNwith multiple concessions were vague collection procedures. able to apply the cash flow from some projects to .support the financial needs of related but Legal considerations separately financed ventures. Under manv trust agreeiiients, local banks Legal aspects of the projects that weakened allowed the concessionaire the final word in financial discipline included issues associated technical decisions on such matters as change with lender security and enforcement rights, orders, change of material subcontractors, dispute resolution mechanisms, tax treatment, and toll collection procedures. This led to and procedures for securing government capi- major problems relating to construction and tal contributions. Key problems included the operating costs as wxell as quality control. following: -Certain tax aspects affected the financial vi- L Legal disputes in Mexico arising between a ability of the projects. Changes to the tax code private party and the governmnent were to be wN ere required regarding the 2 percent tax resolved within the constraints of the Mexi- on assets, application and calculation of cle- can court system and were not subject to in- preciation and tax credits, and payment of ternational arbitration. Being subject to the value added taxes. But these modifications local court system represented a significant Nvere made only after nearly twenty-five risk to international investors because of their projects had been concessioned, and in many lack of familiarity with the legal system. cases they required annual approval and thus � State governments were expected to providle subjected financiers to nonrenexwal risk. graimLs or cash equity or to dedicate toll rev- enues from existing roads for certain projects Policy conclusions as part of the construction financing, as con- tingent obligations to cover cost overruns, or Policies to address such issues will vary de- to cover costs related to securing the right of pending on sector objectives, the current sta- way. But there were often delays or actual tus of the legal and regulatory framework, and defaults in the fulfillment of these financial the technical and financial capability of the obligations, in part because the contributions public and private sector participants. Of the were to be sourced from annual budget ap- many lessons to be learned from the Mexican propriations, a process subject to tremendous program, however, perhaps the most impor- uncertainty and discretion. As a result, state tant for governments developing a sector pro- governments were often left without any gram based on private investment is the means for meeting their obligations. Other necessity of devising systems of regulation and problems arose because of the lack of a clear support that provide the encouragemilent and registration process for public debt, wxThich left room for maneuver that the private sector lenders witlh no clear understanding of where needs, while minimizing the government's ex- they stood relative to other state creditors. posure to the host of commercial and financial * Lenders were not allowed a collateral assign- risk-s surrounding projects. The sector strategy ment of the concession agreement. Conse- must include sound and explicit incentives to quently, they could neither secure revenue select worthwlbile projects. Prices should be generated by the project nor exercise bor- set to ensure the viability of privatized enter- rower substitution rights in the event of a prises without protecting private parties from default. This greatly diminished their bargain- bankruptcy. Prices should also be allox-ed to 18 A Retrospective on the Mexican Toll Road Program (1989-94) reflect actual demand-in this respect, the need stith an expected payotit in five and a half years and a targeted to develop congestion pricing is of fundamen- average life nf tiree and a third Nears). The issue receised a local CuLTrencv-hased "A" rating front Standard & Poor's. The tal importance. The regulatory framework deal stas initially placed at abotit 350 basis points over US. should check the abuse of market power and Treasuries. ensure adequate services. Besides protecting A fourth financing of ahoit US5300 itillion for the Tepic Guadala;ara ensure adequate ~~~~~~~~~~~~toll roadl wsta canceledi at the last minuite hecause of the onset of investors, an appropriate regulatory and market the December 1994- cuirrency crisis. structure protects the government and eventu- ally taxpayers from bearing ultimate responsi- Jeff Ruster (jruster@avorldbank.org), Private bility for the financial performance of privatized Sector Development Department enterprises. Feder.al funding also inicluded contributions by Petroleos Mslexicanos (Peinex) and by Canminos V I'PlenLe Federales de Ingreso N Serticio Conexo (Cipute). the federal higiwsays and bridge operator. for niore than 1.100 kilometers (kmr) of public toll roads. Recent government estimates shosN that 26 billion net pesos (US53 billion) will be recluired to restructure existing concessions. The Wcirld BaRik's Operations Evaltiation Department reports that by earlv 1997 nearly forty projects. accounting for LiSS11.5 billion of debt and equitN investmients, haie submitted requests to the gov etinment for finiancial restrcictciring. Thie gosernments of several Mexican states also granted conces- sions incler local l.iAs to build and operate higItays; these saNe generally been modeled on tbose granted by the Secretary of Comr mtinications and Transport cinder federal last The fi e major axis links aire Nog.lles -Liliacan Tepic-Guadalajara- TICtlcis.i-Mlexico Citn ('21 krn) Nuet o Laredo-Revrtosa-Monterres- San LLiis Potosi Qcueretarc-Mexico Citn t480 kin): Citidacl Jciarez- Mcxico Cinv-lt'cebla-Oaxaca (340 kin): Mexico Cinv-Veracruz Savula Ocozocoaultla Arriaga-PuLerto Madero (428 km): and Tixpan- liachuca-.Mexico Cin- (222 kin). Thiee projects alrecdy in operation swere nevertheless able to re- finance fiy tapping the international capital markets prior to the December 1994 Ciurrencv crisis. This was duLe in large part to ex- pectations that Mexico xx ould receis e an ins estment-gra.de rating. These three projects are as follows: * Tie ten veai. US5207 million placenisent ftr the Toluca toll road in Jcine 1992. The deal initially s-as not *tell received despite repr icing cif about 700 basis points over U.S. Treasciries. Inves tor concerns centered on tight debt sen ice coserage r.itios of 1.25 tci 1. combined stwith the existence of cLirrency risk, a par- tiCsIlarlv sensitive issuLe at the time because the peso ssas esti matecd to le abouit 20 percent over.lcied. * The 1SS1 10 imsillion placenment for the Fecatepec-Piramicles and Mtlanzanillo-Airneria toll roads, which v-ere jointlv secciritized. The proposecd financing and secciripn strcicture stas percei-ed as mcich simpler than th.it in the Tolcica placeniemii. andl it pr'O- vided for a clual amortization process. The target amortization is based on a twelve year final matLiritv. Thie alternative schedule reqLlires payNment (with a 1 percent added premicim for inives- tors) in eighteen years if project revencies are impaired, whether becatisc of insufficient traffic flos , ctirrencv fluctuations. or similar risks. The deal s-as priced at abocit 500 basis points over UIJS Treasuries at the time cif closing. * The Mexico Citv Ciernataca toll road. ostned and ciperated bty Capcife. The placenment of exchange rate-linked bonds in Ati- gtist 1994 stas originally planned as a USS625 millionn stents- tear final isiaturinv tiansaction. Bcit because of investor con cerns afiotis ccirrency risk ancI long-terisi interest rate volatility. the isscie swas cut back to a seven sear. I2ss265 million 144A placenment (ttioLigli also featurinig a dLial atmortization scliedcile 19 . The Private Sector in Water and Sanitation- How to Get Started PenelopeJ BTook Couien The henefits from private participation in wa- itecd areas as building capacity and providing ter and sanitation depend on the level of rislk plumlibing services, it is difficult to achieve in and responsibility the government handcs over distribution and collection, core activities in to the private sector. But strong government water and sanitation (table 1). So governments commitment and careful preparation are re- wNanting to involve the private sector have quired if the private sector is to take on signifi- been atble to rely little on competition to assure cant risks and responsibilities. A g,ov-ernment g,ood outcomes for consumers and have in- about to cnter into a concession contract for steadh ad to devise regulatory systems for this twenty-five or thirty years, for example, needs purpose. to be sure that it does not, in haste, gloss over details that will later land it in messy renego- tiations. wvith loss of face to all concerned and reduced benefits to consumers. But govern- BOX 1 TOOLKITS FOR PRIVATE SECTOR PARTICIPATION ments often worry that detailed preparations IN WATER AND SANITATION take too much time. This Note, based on a set of'KWorld Bank toolkits compiled from experi- The World Bank has recently published a set of toolkits to guide gov- ences in involving the private sector in water ernments in designing and implementing private sector arrangements and s.,nitation, reviewrs the essential factors In anchosingtatn privatizaio optioessentian fargus that for water and sanitation. The toolkits focus on three sets of issues: prepsing rat paysrdivatizatidends.tionandargiestt How to choose a private sector participation option. What are the preparation pavs divildends. options? What might you have to do to make your preferred option What makes the business special? practicable? What are the risks? * How to design the process for refining and implementing the The activities of urban whater and sanitation chosen option. What might a critical path look like? How do you utilities range from impounding and treating set up a government unit to run the privatization process? What raw water, to distributing water and collecting can you expect from legal, financial, economic, and engineering sewage, to treating sewage. In many w ays. advisers-and how do you go about hiring them? How do you decisions about how to involve the private sec- design a bidding process? What can you do to keep the contract on tor in these operations resemble decisions track once you've chosen a private partner? about privatization in any other utility sector. * How to ensure that contracts cover all the issues. What should a All such privatizations. for example. require management, build-operate-transfer (BOT), or concession contract decisions on how to set up an independent cover? In writing or reviewing contractual documents for a con- regulator anid how to set and enforce service standards. Buit wuater ancl sanitation hlve special cession, a BOT arrangement, or a management contract, how do features that governments must take into ac- you know if you've covered everything? What are your options for count in choosing and clesigning a contract and allocating and managing the many risks that go with the contract? in designing a supporting policy framework: Vater and sanitation systems are clharacter- Infermation on how to obtain copies of the toolkits can be found at the World Bank's ized by a high degree of natural monopoly. Website lhttp://www.worldbank.org). Although competition is feasible in such lim- 20 The Private Sector in Water and Sanitation-How to Get Started TABLE 1 COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY IN WATER AND SANITATION Activity Characteristics of competition ficient use. In India, for example, many cities go short of water while farmers continue to Allocation of water resources Natural monopoly in each receive subsidized water for irrigation. and regulation of use hydrogeographical unit * Water and sanitation are well suited to local (such as a river basin) management, and in many countries, respon- Capacity construction Competitive (but may depend on sibility for service provision is decentralized accessto water resources) to the provincial or municipal level. As a re- sult, complex interjurisdictional issues often Bulk supply generation Small number of possible need tombe rsledibeforth ivate sec suppliers (often only one) nced to be resolved before the private sec- tor can be brought in. Water trea*ment* Local monopoly Many of the assets of water and sanitation Localdisthibution* Local monopoly systems are buried, so obtaining accurate in- Local sewerage network* Local monopoly formation about them is costly-increasing the cost of preparing for private sector par- SEwagpent and appliaence s LocalComonopolye ticipation, and the chance of surprises after Equipment and appliance sales. Competitive the contract is signed. plumbing services Broad access to water and sanitation yields - Core activities of traditional water and sanitation utilities. important public health and environmental benefits. Government interventions to pro- mote these benefits are likely to remain after privatization. Water is essential to life, and access to it must be ensured for all. Guaranteeing access for the None of these issues is a barrier to private sector poor will sometimes require designing subsi- participation-all arise under both public and dies or schemes for reducing the cost of deliv- private provision. But governments often sys- ering services to the very poor. A complicating tematically confront their implications only factor for reformers is that existing systems for when they begin to contemplate private sector allocating scarce raw water resources among involvement. Failure to adequiately address alternative uses-urban consumption, irriga- these issues increases the risk that a government tion, industry-are often incompatible with ef- will be unable to find a partner for its pre- TABLE 2 THE MAIN OPTIONS FOR PRIVATE SECTOR PARTICIPATION AND THEIR ALLOCATION OF RESPONSIBILITIES Asset Operations and Capital Commercial Option ownership maintenance investmnent risk Duration Examples Service Public Public and private Public Public 1-2 years Chile (Santiago) contract India (Madras) Management Public Public Public 3-5 years Gaza contract Trinidad and Tobago Lease Public Public Shared 1-15 years Guinea (17 cities) Poland (Gdansk) Build-operate- P$$20-30 years Malaysia (Johor) transfer Australia (Sydney) Concession Pbi <>25-3 years Argentina (Buenos Aires) ~~4~~~< - - ~~~~Coite d Ivoire Philippines (Manila) Divestiture ~ sIndefinite England and Wales The World Bank Group 21 ferred form of private sector participation or proving efficiency, constructing large-scale that a private sector arr-angemiient will fall short projects, cutting the cost of public subsidies or of its broad policy objectives. redirecting them to the poor. and making the sector more responsive to customers. All forms The main private sector options-and of private sector participation can be designed who's doing what to improve technical and managerial capacity. But whether the other objectives can be met Different countries have adopted different op- depends on whiclh option is chosen and whether tions for private sector participation. Trinidad the government can do a good job on the en- and Tobago is using a management contract abling and regulatory environment. A poor job for water and sewerage services and plans to can lead to dissatisfied customers and difficult replace it with a concession. Guinea has a lease renegotiations with the private partner. Under- arrangement for water treatment and supply in the Guinea lease, for example, consumers have seventeen cities. Buenos Aires and several other lost out because disputes over the division of Argentine provinces have concessions for va- responsibilities between the government and the ter and sewerage. And England and Wales hax-e operator have hampered new connections and divested their water and sanitation utilities. service improvements. The Buenos Aires con- cession has led to better service, but there have The main options can be clearly distinguished been costly disputes over the definition of the by how they allocate responsibility for such func- regulator s role (for example, in determining in- tions as asset ownership and capital investment vestment requirements) and the handling of ad- between the public and private sectors (table 2). justments in tariff levels and structure. The more risk and responsibility are passed to the private sector, the more powerful are its in- To determine wvhich private sector options are centives to improve services. Service contracts, feasible-or what must be done to make a pre- which confer little risk and responsibility on the ferred option possible-a government needs private sector, offer commensurately small gains to undertake a range of analyses: -and are simply not designed to address mana- * An analysis of the state of the utility-looking gerial inefficiency or chronic underinvestment. at the current level and standard of service, Concessions and divestitures are well suited to the condition ancd serviceability of assets, the tackling these problems-but demand more from human resources, and the financial perfor- government in commitment and preparation. mance. Is information about the utility's assets good enough to serve as a base for long- In practice, private sector arrangements are of- term contracts? If not, can better informnation ten hybrids of these models. For example. be produced rapidly? Where information leases may pass some responsibility for small- about the quality of underground pipes, for scale investment to the private sector, and example, is partial or inaccurate, revelations management contracts may, like leases, have about the true state of the system that come revenue-sharing provisions that pass on some after a concession contract has been signed commercial risk. Options can also be used in may lead to costly renegotiations. combination-for example. a build-operate- i An analysis of the existing regulatory frame- transfer contract for bulk water supply might work-both general laws that might affect be combined with a management or lease private participation in the sector and sector- contract for operating the distribution system. specific laws and institutions focusing on pric- ing and quality standards. Does the existing Key factors in choosing an option regulatory framework provide sufficient sup- port for the private sector so that it will take Governments seeking to involve the private sec- on commercial risk? If not, can the necessary tor in water and sanitation may have a range of changes be made fairly easily'? And if not, can objectives-introducing greater technical and parts of the regulatory function be simplified managerial expertise and new technology, im- or contracted out in the short term? Where 22 The Private Sector in Water and Sanitation-How to Get Started TABLE 3 PREREQUISITES FOR SUCCESSFUL IMPLEMENTATION OF DIFFERENT PRIVATE SECTOR OPTIONS Stakeholder sup- Potential port and political Cost-recovering Good information Developed regulatory Good country benefits Option commitment tariffs about the system framework credit rating of the option Service Unimportant Not necessary Possible to proceed Minimal monitoring Not necessary Low contract in the short term with only limited capacity needed information Management Low to moderate Preferred but not Sufficient infornation Moderate monitoring Not necessary contract levels needed necessary in the required to set capacity needed short term incentives Lease Not necessary Build-operate- fllitsn mlSnl transferC! G Concession Divestiture It!]l W'" = - 1 Slmfu'iatisi.ws_ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~High Note: The shading signals the degree of importance: 0 not significant * moderate El low * high regulatory capacity is weak, for example, col- analysis can sometimes lead to redefinition of lection of information on the utility's techni- a private sector project-for example, re- cal and financial performance could be balancing planned investment expenditures contracted out to a private auditing company. between new production capacity and the re- * An analysis of which stakeholders (employees. habilitation of existing distribution systems. consumers, environmentalists, government agencies) support private participation and As table 3 shows, in a very simplified way, the which oppose it. Can processes and policies results of these analyses can point the govern- be put in place to meet stakeholder concerns? ment to an appropriate choice of private sec- Can the risk of political interference be mini- tor option. If regulatory capacity is weak and mized? Often, a key factor in the success of a political commitment is low, for example, a con- private sector project is identifying the con- cession will be difficult to implement. Even with cerns of employees early on and finding con- strong political commitment to a concession structive ways of addressing them-rather than or divestiture, however, countries that lack a allowing those concerns to derail the reform good business climate or a strong track record process later. of successful private investment may not im- * An analysis of the financial viability of alter- mediately be able to attract large-scale private native options. Do current tariffs cover costs? financing for infrastructure projects. These Can the private sector reasonably be expected couLntries may need to start out with a man- to boost efficiency enough to meet the pro- agement contract and work up to options that posed service objectives without increasing demancl more of the private sector. tariffs? If not, will consumers be willing to pay higher tariffs? And if not, can grant finance Penelopej Brook Couwen (pbrookcoweng (or subsidies to needy households) support worldhank.org), Private SectorDevelopment service improvements? This kind of financial Specialist, Private SectorDevelopment Department 23 Privatization and Restructuring in Central and Eastern Europe Robert E. Anderson, Siunzeon Djankov, Gecbcv cl Pobl aind Stdn ClaGessens This Note reports on the first comprehensive analysis of the industrial restructuring that has taken place since 1992 in Central and Eastern Europe. The study, covering more than 6,000 industrial firms in seven countries, looks at which government policies have been most effective in speeding enterprise restructuring. The results show that privatization is the single most important factor in restructuring. The method of privatization has been less important: management buyouts and massive giveaways of firms through voucher privatization have led to results similar to those of case-by-case sales to foreign or domestic investors. The study also shows that privatizing industrial and commercial firms is the most effective way to improve the solvency of the banking sector-more effective than bank recapitalization or debt forgiveness. The approach policies from the effects of such other factors as size, sector, and initial productivity levels. The study compares the extent of restructuring by firnis in seveni CenLral and Eastern European The measures of restructuring used in the study countries: Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Hun- include profitability, proportion of firms with a gary, Poland, Romania, the Slovak Republic, and positive operating cash flow, average operating Slovenia. The number of firms in the sample for cash flowv as a percentage of revenue, grow"th each country ranges from 700 to 1,000, and the firms account for 40 to 90 percent of employ- ment in manufacturincg (table 1).' The govern- ments in the seven countries have used different TABLE 1 FEATURES OF THE DATABASE policies to encourage restructuring, and com- paring enterprise performance among the coun- Employees as a tries should shed light on which have been most percentage of total effective. The study tests the restructuring data Employees manufacturing for the effect of such policies as rapid privatiza- Country Firms 1992 employment tion, concentrated outside ownership (for bet- ter governance), wage growth restraint (to Bulgaria 828 314,042 48 improve cash flow and fund restructuring), fi- Czech Republic 706 829,312 64 nancial discipline (firms may be more likely to Hungary 1,044 428,645 41 restructure if neither the government nor banks Poland 1,066 1,338,645 45 finance their losses), and maintaining debt obli- Romania 1,092 2,121,102 91 gations (firms may have a greater incentive to SlovakRepublic 905 578,737 93 restructure if banks do not forgive or reduce debts). The data are subjected to econometric analysis to separate the impact of government 24 Privatization and Restructuring in Central and Eastern Europe TABLE 2 PROGRESS IN PRIVATIZATION, 1995 (percentage privatized) in labor productivity, growth in total factor pro- Mnfcuinfirms ductivity, and growth in exports. The data show that for each firm these measures tend to be Country firms weighted by output highly correlated. The econometric analysis fo- cuses on the two most reliable indicators of re- Bulgaria 8 7 structuring: growth in labor productivity and Czech Republic 89 93 growth in total factor productivity.2 Hungary 67 65 Poland 61 60 The study defines a 'privatized' firm as one Romania 15 12 for which more than a third of shares have been transferred to private investors. It mea- Slovak Republic 79 83sures the extent of privatization in a country Slovenia 41 41 by using both a simple count of the firms clas- sified as privatized and a count weighted by output to reflect differences in size. On both measures, the Czech Republic, Hungary, and the Slovak Republic come out ahead, while Bul- TABLE 3 ANNUAL LABOR PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH, 1992-95 gai Sloa Rbein hain m ade litle rgrs garia lags behind, having made little progress (percent) in privatization (table 2). Country Privatizedfirmso State-owned firms All firms Impact of privatization Bulgaria 12.4 -1.4 -1.4 The data show that labor productivity growth Czech Republic 8.6 -2.6 6.8 across the seven countries averaged 7.3 percent Hungary 6.0 3.2 4.8 a year for privatized firms during 1992-95, but Poland 7.5 1.4 5.4 -0.2 percent for state-owned firms (table 3). The econometric analysis indicates that privatization *omania 1.0 accounts for almost all this productivity growth. Slovak Republic 7.8 -4.1 5.1 The only exception to this pattern is Hungary, Slovenia 7.2 1.8 3.6 where state-owned firms achieved half the pro- ductivity gains of privatized firms. In Bulgaria Average 7.3 -0.2 3.6 and Romania, where privatization has been in- significant, productivity in state-owned firms is a. Firms privatized by 1995. declining, pulling down labor productivity for Source: Autors' estimates. the manufacturing sector as a whole. FIGURE 1 TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH Results are similar for the productivity of all factors of production. The cumulative gains in (percent. cumulative) total factor productivity for privatized firms far 15 exceed those for state-owned firms in the 12 sample (figure 1). The analysis shows that pri- vatization has increased total factor productiv- 9 ivatizedfirns ity growth by about 4 percentage points a year. 6 The data also show that even a credible threat of privatization promotes restructuring. For ex- 3 ample, in Poland, where the government's com- 0, State-ownedfirms mitment to privatization was perceived as 0 1 2 3 credible, the firms included in the mass privatiza- Years since privatization tion program began to show rapid improvement Source: Authors estimates. in profitability in 1994 and 1995-long before they were formally privatized in November 1995. The World Bank Group 25 FIGURE 2 ANNUAL GROWTH IN LABOR PRODUCTIVITY AND REAL WAGES FOR PRIVATIZED AND One possible explanation for this is that man- STATE-OWNED FIRMS, 1992-95 agers, improved their performance because they (percent) expected to be held accountable by the ftiture LSabor productivity * Privatized fiitms new owners. Government plans for large-scale 15 D State-owned firms privatization programs appear to boost produc- 12 Bulgaria * tivity in state-owned firms, probably because of similar anticipation and signaling effects. 9 Slovak Republic z R 6 ~~~~~~Poland-111 *Si-ovenia 6 Hungary * Method of privatization 3 Hungary O Rormania a Slovenia Poland Real Many foreign advisers to the governments of Bulgaria Ro ania wages transition economies initially believed that mass -3 Slovak Republic Czech Republic privatization and insider buvouts wTould lead to -6 wveak pressures to restructure and that the pre- X -2 0 2 4 6 8 10 ferred strategcy should be sale to strategic inves- Source:Authors' estimates. tors. But the study findls no significant differences in the effectiveness of privatization methlods. TABLE4 AVERAGE ANNUAL INVESTMENT PER WORKER, Productivity growth for privatized firms in the 1992-95 Czech and Slovak Republics, which chose mass privatization. is similar to that in Hungary and Poland, which have relied more on case-by-case privatization (table 3). Also in the Czech Re- Country Privatizedfirms State-ownedfirns public, where data on the results of different privatization methods are available for a suffi- Bulgaria 2790 90 ciently long period, the study finds onlv mintor Czech Republic 3,290 470 differences amocng the methods. But it finds Hungary 2,990 460 strong effects of ownership concentration on Poland 1,880 410 the speed of restructuring. Romania 590 110 The role of wage restraint Slovak Republic 3,340 230 Slovenia 1,690 310 Restructuring is likely to be encouraged if the Source:Authors estimates. workforce does not initially absorh all the pro- ductivity gains through higher wages. Firms tmuhst FIGURE 3 SHARE OF NONPERFORMING LOANS TO finance much of their investment with retained INDUSTRIAL FIRMS, 1992 AND 1995 earnings from current cash flow, especially when 9 the financial system is weak. But this demands Bulgaria _ 1995 new habits. While firms in industrial countries CzechRepublic have relied mostly on internal cash flow to fi- nance working capital or new investment, firms Hungary in the formerly socialist economies have relied heavily on loans from state-owned banks. Poland Romania The study finds that privatized firms have re- tained most of their large productivity gains to Slovak Repubiic finance productivity-enhancing investments. In all the countries, labor productivity has grown Slovenia faster than real wages in privatized firns (as _ shown by their position above the diagonal in 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 10 figure 2). That does not mean that real wages in Percent these firms did not also grow rapidly. Blut sincc Soorce:Authors'estimates. the firms maintained a large margin between 26 Privatization and Restructuring in Central and Eastern Europe labor productivity and wages, they were able to than expected, making government interven- sustain high levels of investment per worker tion in the banks unnecessary. By contrast, in (table 4). By contrast, real wage growth in state- countries that have done little or no privatiza- owned enterprises has exceeded labor produc- tion, firms' financial conditions did not improve tivity gains, eroding internal financing. and the banks' bad-loan problems are worse than the pessimists expected (figure 3). The The analysis shows that privatization has had a speed of privatization of the industrial and com- greater effect on wage restraint than have gov- mercial sectors has proved to be the most im- ernment wage policies. Most of the seven coun- portant policy issue for the financial sector. tries had a policy of limiting wage increases (though by 1995, all countries had market- Conclusion determined wages). For example, the Czech Re- public, Hungary, and Poland each introduced an One of the most important policy questions in excess wage tax during 1991-94. But even though the transition economies is what governments government-led wage restraint applied primarily can do to speed the restructuring of firms and (or exclusively) to state-owned firms, wages grew thus hasten the transition to a mature market faster in the state sector than in the private sector economy. The study provides some answers. in both Hungary and Poland. And in Bulgaria Rapid and comprehensive privatization lead- and the Slovak Republic, which pursued more ing to concentrated ownership encourages vigorous wage restraint in the state sector, real restructuring. Privatization also promotes re- wages still outstripped productivity in state-owned structuring because privatized firms are more firms-but not in the private sector. likely than state-owned enterprises to exercise wage restraint-and wage restraint is vital to Financial restructuring and the role of free up internal finance. Policies that increase banks bank lending to firms, such as debt forgive- ness and recapitalization, may do more harm What actions, if any, should governments in the than good. The safest course is to recapitalize region take to encourage the financial restruc- banks only as part of privatization and to en- turing of overindebted firms? In industrial coun- courage negotiations for financial restructur- tries, most financial restructuring takes place ing only after the banks are privatized. through private negotiations between private lenders (mostly banks) and private firms. But in This Note is based on a paper bv the authors of the same title (World transition economies, most banks and many Bank Tecihital Paper 368, Washington, D.C., 1997) firms are still under state ownership, so the in- To ensore conitparability. the stoidy adjustecd the data to reflect centives to negotiate are different. Many banks ditferences in accotinting standards both over time and among cenive bas coLuntries and excluded otilit, banking, and agricultural firms and in the region inherited large portfolios of nco private companies. The distribution of firms among nonperforming loans when state enterprises, suhsectors-mosttv food, textiles, chemtials, nsetals, machinery. suddenly exposed to competition, started run- tnd transport equtipment-is similar across the cotintries. -Lahor prt)durttvttv (valoce added per nosan-lhoort does not take ning big losses. Audits done in accordance with into account depreciation. debt service, and taxes, which are more international accounting standards showed that liket to cliffer frotTi countrv- to countrv because of differences in up to 60 percent of the banks' loans were con- Set Sticn Ciaessens, Simeon Dan k or accoting standards. sidered irrecoverable. The usual advice at this shiip and Corporate Governminent-Evidence fromii the Czech Re- point was for the government to take over the public (Pnvatte Sector. June 1997) bad loans and recapitalize the banks (usually through an asset swap). Robert E. Anderson (anderson9@worldbank. orgy), Simeon Djankov (sdjankov@worldbank. The study's analysis shows that this course was org), and Gerhard Pohl, Europe and Central premature. In countries that pursued large and Asia, and Middle East and North Africa rapid privatization programs, privatized firms Technical Department, and Stijn Claessens, have improved their profitability much more East Asia and Pacific Vice Presidency 27 The Drivers of the Information Revolution- Cost, Computing Power, and Convergence alatm(es Bon(id In the past few years, there has been a technological phase-shift as computers have become ubiquitous, communications technologies have multiplied, and the Internet has become a widely used means of doing business. The three most powerful trends driving these developments are the decline in the cost of transmitting information, the increase in the power of computing, and the shift from analog to digital information technologies that has joined the telecommunications and computing industries and merged market segments of the information industry. This Note explains these three trends. Cost of communicating chmnging the industryvs cost structure, moving it awN ay from existing tariff setting mechanisms. The cost of communicating has declined dra- matically in the past twenty years. The cost of Cheap electronics. A key part of the telephone a voice transmission circuit, for example, has infrastructure is network exchanges, made up fallen by a factor of 10,000 as a result of the of switching equipment. Automatic switches development of fiber optics, cheap electron- were originally electromechanical, but the ics, and smart wireless (figure 1). sw,itches installed today are electronic- essentially specialized computers. The advent Fiber optics. First produced commercially by of cheap, pow erfiul, microprocessor-based com- Corning Glass in 1970. fiber-optic cahle has puting has alter-ed the economics of switching. become the increasingly dominant means of reducing costs and increasing reliability while signal transmission in telephonysince the mid- also delivering new value added services for 1980s. replacing copper cables, microwave the user (such as call wT-aiting and caller ID). transmission, and satellite. Optical fiber has ecx- Cheap electronics are also at the heart of celltn- tremely high capacity (bandwidth) because of lar telephony and personal communications the light it transports. The high frequency of services, which use electronmagnetic spectrum light allows higher information density than more efficiently than conventional wrireless. And conventional cable: a fiber thinner than a single cotmputing power now, makes it possible to run hair can carry a laser signal combining many existing telecommunications infrastructure as an thousands of telephone conversations, so that intelligent network,' improving capacity utili- the cost per voice circuit becomes almost in- zation, lowering the cost of maintaining sw>;itches, finitesimal. Because fiber optics reduces the and creating new services, such as virtual pri- cost of signal transmission so much. ancd be- vate networks. cause this cost is increasingly fixed (with main- tenance costs much lower than for conventional Smart wireless. Wireless technology is evolving cable, the cost is mostlv in installation), the toward I higher frequencies (inherently more generalization of fiber optics is profoundlv information dense), vwith a range of clever 28 The Drivers of the Information Revolution-Cost, Computing Power, and Convergence FIGURE 1 COST TRENDS IN OPTICAL FIBER TRANSMISSION Index of transmission cost per bits per second per kilometer (log scale) * - compression algorithms to squeeze many con- 1000 bransmision osts have fallen versations into a given frequency (such as Time 45Mbps Division Multiple Access, or TDMA, and Code 100 e 90135MIPS Division Multiple Access, or CDMA). This de- 0 40D OMbpvelopment, coupled with cheap electronics, ^ 12-1J Gbps permits mobility for the user-in some situa- 1 2anwidps tions, wireless has become an alternative to 10 lGbps conventional wireline technology for basic ser- 0.1 - bps vices. Cellular telephony is growing rapidly, 0.01 more than doubling worldvvide every two years, 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 while fixed wireless is increasingly being de- Note: Mbpsis megabits persecond- Gbps is gigabits per second. ployed for the "local loop," or local access net- Source:AT&T data. work-that part of the network providing FIGURE 2 PRICE TRENDS IN INFORMATION PROCESSING access to the end user. So, besides bringing overall costs down, fixed wireless has also in- Index of investment cost troduced real opportunities for competing pro- per instruction per second viders of local services an area earlier deemed (100 scale) Computing power per to be a natural monopoly. Finally, the cost of IBM mainframe dollar invested has isen bya deploying wireless is much less sensitive to factor of 10,OOOin 20 years subscriber density (the number of customers 10 . Digital VAX in a given area) than that of installing wireline, Cray1 I so wireless is of great interest to developing I countries, particularly for rural areas. , IBM PC > Sun Microsystems 2 These three developments have necessarily been 0.1 accompanied by a move away from analog to digital technology, in which signals are trans- 0.01 Pentium mitted as binary code. Digital telephone net- 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 works ensure better quality and allow the use of packing protocols for data transmission, such Source: World Bank compilafton based on industry data. o as frame relay, Asynchronous Transfer Mode FIGURE 3 TRENDS IN TRANSISTORS PER MICROPROCESSOR (ATM), and the Internet protocol TCP/IP. (log scale) Pentium II Power of computing The number of transistors (7.5inillion) 1,000,000 on a microchip doubles Pentium Pro The second important driver of the information every 2 years (f5 millon revolution has been the relentless increase in 1,000,000 48fi / Pentium the power of computing. Computing power per 4,000 (3.1 million) dollar invested has risen by a factor of 10,000 in 386iu twenty years (figure 2). Power has increased 100,000 2 / and costs have fallen because of the develop- Motorola 68000 a ment of integrated circuits and microchips, be- Intel * a Sun SPARC cause of increasing transistor density on /0,000 microchips, and because of economies of scale 10,000 / in production. Intel 8080 , Intel4004 Integrated circuits, miniaturization, and micro- 1,001' (23 ) chips. The modern electronics era began with 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 the invention of the integrated circuit in a Texas Source:WorldBankcompilationbasedonindustrydata. Instruments laboratory in Dallas in 1958. The integrated circuit, which groups transistors and The World Bank Group 29 other electronic circuits on a tiny piece of semi- began penetrating the business environment conductor, is a breakthrough in product design aroun(l 1981, they were used mainly as stand- because of its enormous potential for miniatur- alone workstations. Independent mainframe ization and for reducing unit costs. The micro- computers, accessed by "dumb" terminals, con- chip, essentially an entire computer on a chip. tinued to handle much of the heavy process- was developed by Intel (as the four-bit 4004 ing. Today's business computers are connected processor) in 1971. Its 2,300 transistors provide to one another in local area networks (LANs), all the essential functions of a computer. and increasingly, these private netvworks are interconnected through the Internet, the inter- Increasing transistor density. The density of national "network of networks," which is dou- transistors has been rising exponentially-a hling in size every year. Because of the growing phenomenon sometimes characterized as interconnection, PCs' primary fuLnction has Moore's law. In the 1960s. Gordon Moore. an shifted from document and spreadsheet man- electrical engineer and a cofounder of Intel, agement to communication and information observed that the number of transistors on a processing. 'T he growth of the Internet illus- microchip doubles every one to two years. Be- trates Metcalfe's law (Metcalfe was the co- cause computing power is roughly proportional founder of modern computer networking), to the number of transistors, or "gates," on the which states that the value of a netwvork equals microprocessor, this would translate into a the square of the number of interconnected doubling of computing power per microchip nodes. As new users join the Internet, its value every eighteen months or so. And because the for all users increases geometrically. Metcalfe's cost of a microchip rises only slowlIy from one law illustrates how, networking PCs radically generation to the next and represents onlv increases their value as a knowlIedge tool. about 5 to 15 percent of the cost of the com- puter, Moore's law woould translate into a near Convergence doubling of computing power for a given in vestment every eighteen months. In fact, the As costs have f'allen and digitalization has re- growth in power over twenty-four years-from placed analog technologies in telecommunica- the Intel 4004 (2,300 transistors) of 1971 to the tions, the telecommunications, information Pentium II (7.5 million) of 1997-averaged technology, and media industries are merging nearly 40 percent a 'ear, corresponding to a into a ibit industry" that manipulates voice, doubling every twenty-five and a half months- image, video, and computer data in binary form. close enough to Moore's estimate (figure 3). This convergence has profound implications for the industries involved. Economies of scale. Computing has also become n Communications and information services are far cheaper and more powerful because of econo- being delinked from their underlying deliv- mies of scale in production, not only of micro- elr infrastructure: telephone services can be chips but of such essential ancillary equipment delivered through coaxial cable, data services as mass storage (disk drives), removable stor- and Internet access through telephone lines, age, and computer network equipment. The and cahle TV through direct broadcast satellite. emergence of a set of de facto industry standards u Accompanying the delinking is increasing -based on the first IBM personal computer (PC) overlap between the two primary components of 1981. the Intel microprocessor instruction set, of the communications industry, which have and the Microsoft operating systems (DOS and traditionally been segregated: common car- Windows)-has also enabled producers to stan- rier conduit systems and networks designed dardize equipment and sofm' are and encouraged to transmit signals anonymously (telephony) price competition. and content-based information sources and technologies (broadcasting). One result of the increase in the powver of com- puting and the decline in the cost of commu- Thus. it is nowx possible to receive radio nicating is the rise of networks. When PCs broadcasts over the Internet (using telephone 30 The Drivers of the Information Revolution-Cost, Computing Power, and Convergence FIGURE 4 THE CHANGING INFORMATION INFRASTRUCTURE UNDER CONVERGENCE Before convergence After convergence _ Ei 1 R_ networks), and telephone services can be pro- legal sanctions (throuigh the courts). Telecom- vided by companies in cable TV (a broadcast- mnunications content has been largely tinregui- ing medium). Broadcasting (from one to many) lated, because it is not technically possible to now shadies fromn narrow-casting (custom- do so uising existing content regulation mecha- tailored infor-mation) to one-to-one communi- nisms. But, convergence opens new r-ealms of cation like telephony (figure 4). communications where traditional content regu- lation cannot be applied. In this context, what Convergence has important implications for do) policymakers do about decency, privacy, policymakers. First, it has made existing models and intellectual property righits? for the telecommunications industry obsolete. Those models have assumed that telecommu- Convergence also opens up huige opportuni- nications is a puiblic service, delivered through ties for developing couintries to accelerate the a network that is a natural monopoly. Buit these rolOLout of connectivity to their populationS uISing models are negated by the competition now innovative technologies and private sector-led possible between segments of the delivery investment in a competitiv e mode. Cheaper infrastructure (intermodal competition) and, commuLnications are offering new possibilities increasingly, within segments (intram-odal for couintries to be internationally competitive competition). Convergence thus means that and to "plug in" to the global economy-and governments must lower barriers to entry and providing much more cost-effective ways to overhaul telecommujnications regulatory sys- dleliver essential puiblic services to the poor. tem--s to promote competition, moving away from utility-type regulation.' See Petty >miitl. XWhUt the Tratnsformtation of Telecom Marrkets M\ie.n'I for Regulatito (page -4 to tii', 'sir Second, convergence raises serious issues re- lating to content reguilation. In broadcasting, J/ames Bond (/bond@worldbank.org), Divisioni countries have applied standards of decency. Chief, Telecommunications a/id DInbrmatics privacy, and protection of intellectual property rights using different mnechanisms, buit usually relying on a combination of self-reguilation and ;31 Telecommunications Is Dead, Long Live Networking The effect of the information revolution on the telecom industry Jamzes Bondl Economic history teaches us that no industrv structures, and the increasing competition and is imrnuine to chanige. Canals gave way to rail- globalization in the induLstry are forcing radi- roads, which in turn bowed to road transport cal change. when the cost of motor vehicles fell enough to make it more cost-effective. Banks are scram- The end of scale and natural monopoly bling to adjust to a world in which debt can be raised on bond markets and consumers can In a conventional wired network, most of the obtain many traditional banking services on- investment goes to establish the local loop, par- line. And the telecommunications giants, which ticularly the civil works needed to extend the have reigned supreme for the past fifty years, network to the end user. About two-thirds of are being besieged in their turn as the infor- the assets on the balance sheet of telecommu- mation revolution overturns the certainties on nications operators are `holes in the ground"- which their strength is based. the trenches needed to lay the cables. Thus, in a traditional netwTork, 70 to 85 percent of the The threat to the giants arises from the huge de- cost of a call, even an international one. con- cline in the cost of communicating. the increase sists of the cost of the low-technology link cov- in the power of computing, and the shift to digi- ering only the last couple of miles. tal technology. These forces have led to indus- trial convergence as communications and information services (such as basic telephone service and cable TV) have been delinked from BOX 1 WHAT IS THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS INDUSTRY? their delivery infrastructures (the telecommuni- cations and cable networks). With the delinking ' TELECOMMUNIcATIONS INFRASTRUCTURE has three main components: has come increasing overlap between the two terminal equipment, such as telephones and fax machines in main components of the communications indus- users' homes and businesses, the local loop, generally a pair of try: common carrier conduit systems (delivering copper wires connecting the tenninal equipment to switching telephonyv) and content-based information sources and technologies (broadcasting). As a equipment in the local exchange; and long-distance or interna- result of these changes. new competitors are tional transmission networks, made up of fiber-optic cables, emerging from unexpected directions, and the microwave links, and satellites. market domination on which telecommunications * TELECOMMUNICATIONS SERvicES have focused on calling services: local companies base their strength is melting away. calls (within the local exchange network) and long-distance or The economics of telecommunications international calls. Increasingly, however, these basic services have been augmented by the transmission of data in binary form and by New technology has profoundly altered the value added services (such as call waiting and Internet access), industry's cost structure, and as a result, the which increasefunctionalityforthe end userand generate structure of the industry and its pricing meth- supplementary income for the telecommunications operator. ods have become incoherent. The end of natu- ral monopoly, the trend toward new pricing 32 Telecommunications Is Dead, Long Live Networking FIGURE 1 BURIED COPPER WIRE GIVES WAY TO WIRELESS IN LOCAL LOOP AS TECHNOLOGY DRIVES COST DOWN Because in the conventional local loop based Annual lifetime cost (U.S. dollars) on copper wires the marginal cost of each new 1200 Buried copperwire subscriber declines no matter how many 1,000 existing subscribers there are, the telecommu- 800 \ nications sector-or at least its local loop 600 \ portion-has been considered a natural mo- I1E I nopoly. Economic theory suggests that the best 400 111i_ 8 f ) fway to manage a natural monopoly is to cre- 200 ate a regulated utility, granting it a franchise to O Wireless deliver the service in exchange for certain ob- 0.1 1 10 100 1,000 ligations (such as nondiscriminatory treatment Subscriber density (lines per square kilometer) of consumers) and regulating the prices it can (log scale) charge for the end product. This explains the Source: Coopers & Lybrand data; European Bank for Reconstruction and Development nearly universal model for the telecommuni- data. cations sector: a local monopoly company, of- ten a public enterprise, with regulated prices. FIGURE 2 WORLDWIDE EXPLOSION OF NEW SERVICES But wireless, cable TV, and other technologies Index (1990 100) are now challenging the conventional local loop 1,500 based on wireline technology and buried cop- Internet subscribers (94^20/) per (figure 1). In many cases, wireless is already 1,000 I cheaper per new subscriber than wireline. And the much flatter cost curves of wireless show that size no longer brings any real cost advan- 500 Cellularphones(51.5%) tage. It is possible to have several competing providers of local service without raising the Tele hone 5. n8%(5.8%) network's overall costs much. The implications 0 are considerable: the best way to deliver service to customers is no longer through a utility but Note:Figures in parentheses are annual growth rates overthe period shown. through competing providers of local telecom- Source: World Bank and International Telcommunication Union data. munications services. The prevailing model for the telecommunications sector in most of the FIGURE 3 EXPLOSION OF NEW TECHNOLOGIES world is simply wrong. Furthermore, the tele- communications reforms sweeping the world 19974Voicepager should focus more on the structure of the sec- 1996 Networked PC 199 Fixed wireless tor-providing as much potential for competi- Digital TVina osbl-hno h Asynchronous Transfe 1980 Pesonal computer tion as possible-than on the transfer of the 1993 /Mode 1918 Compact disc monopoly telecommunications company from 9 system 1971 Chip the public to the private sector. In many cases, 1987 Internet exposion 1 Laser however, the reverse is happening. 1986 Local area networks 1969 Computer network 1985 J Cellular telephone 1960 Satellite _190 nTransistor The move to bandwidth-based pricing 1t45 <Computer t95 Television 19 2 -Facsimele Almost universally, how much you pay for a 1906 Radio telephone call depends on how long you talk 1876-0 _ Telephone and how far away your correspondent is. If you ____ ___ ___ ___ ___ ___ ___ ___ ___ ___ ___ ___ ___ ___ ___ Telegraph 185D 190D 1950 2DOD are in Paris, it is much more expensive to call Source:World Bank compilation. New York than Toulouse, and the price you pay (beyond the monthly rental fee for the line) is proportional to the time you talk. But that is not The World Bank Group 33 BOX 2 THE IMPENDING COLLAPSE OF THE INTERNATIONAL ACCOUNTING RATE SYSTEM how costs aLre huilt up for telecomniunicationis operators. For example, tariffs for international International tariffs fortelecommunications services are based on the calls, based on the outdated accounting rate sv s- accounting rate system, which was developed as part of a regulatory temn, nearlv alwiays far exceed the cost of pro- tradition holding that international services are supplied through a viding the service (boX 2). bilateral correspondent relationship between national monopoly A second problem relates to new services. The carriers. An accounting rate is the price the two national carriers (or new communications services that custolmers their governments) negotiate for handling one minute of international increasingly demancl send varying amnounts of telephone service. Revenues are shared between the two carriers. The information per second down the transmission accounting rate system was originally intended to allow each carrier line. Paging, for examople. reqtuires narrow to recover its costs for handling an international call. bandwidthi (a small am-iount of information per The main problem with the accounting rate system is that for second), while new multimcdia services (such as teleconferencing ) require a huge amount of nearly every country the cost of transmitting a call has fallen bxandwidth because transmitting video sends dramatically over the past twenty years, but the fall in price has much more information dowx n the line than lagged this decline. As a result, the rate greatly exceeds the cost of does transmitting sound alone. Btit most tele- providing the service, so accounting rates, which still assume that communications operators dlo not offer chioice the sector is a monopoly, generate huge economic rents for tele- in bandwvidth: cuistomiers get a standard tele- phone companies handling international calls. In some cases, phone line, accommodating (64 kilobits per internationalcallsaccountlortheentireprofitofthesectorandeven second (kbps) in Europe and 56 khps in the lnited States. generate foreign exchange for the government This system is showing signs of imminent collapse. New possibili- To an increasing degree, the costs borne by ties for competition in international services make the sector a fertile telecommunications operators are mtade up of area for arbitrage-and so we are seeing significant activity in call- thiree elemients: ai fixed monthly7 aMoUnt, X\ 'hich back services, calling cards, Internet telephony, and the like. These corresponds to the capital costs of the local loop) a one-timc cost for ach connectin, cor- new sources of competition undercut the hugely inflated accounting responding to the cost of swvitching that call; rates and eat into the income of telecommunications operators- and a transmission cost, which is proportional especially those offering the lowest prices. As a result, the U.S. to the bandw idth. But actual ctistomir charges regulator, the Federal Communications Commission, is seeking to are quite different. And because it is increas- replace international accounting rates with a new benchmark inglv possible to compete for customers, nese agile operators arc emerging that take advan- system based more closely on actual costs. tage of the possibilities for arbitrage between tariffs and actual costs. Much of the new, activ - ity is in international service. But nexw plaVers e\en for international calls (in addition to the are also emerging in other areas, such as Inter- montlily rental for local access). net setAvice providers, w hich enable customers to place long-distance calls for the price of the Intermodal competition, globalization, local loop connection (figure 2). and the WTO negotiations It is safe to predict that competition andn mar Policvnmakers increasingly accept that competi- ket forces will drive tariffs closer to long run tion in the local loop is both possible and desir incremental costs. both in level and in struc able. But competition is also bringing changes ture. And within a couple of years. consumers that policvmiiakers are much less knowvledgeable will probably be able to but the bandwidth ahbout-in the explosion iof new techniologies. capacity thev need for a given connection, products, and services competing with one an wxhich, because of declining transmission costs, other to deliver connectivitx to the end user (fig- wvill cost no more than a few cents per hour utre 3). NeN- technologies increase arbitrage 34 Telecommunications Is Dead, Long Live Networking possibilities for new operators, and they compli- thing from bulk transmission to value added cate the work of regulators. But above all, they services, in such a world. Instead, the world challenge existing operators, which are often slow would segment into wholesalers, which would in responding to new customer demands. invest in and sell capacity; retailers, which would be in contact with the final consumer; Also changing is the geographic service area in and traders and brokers, which would inter- which end users are interested-increasingly not mediate supply and demand for capacity. only national but international. International traf- fic is growing by 12.4 percent a year, compared Globalization goes beyond the actions of na- with 5.9 percent for domestic calls. Thus, as com- tional telecommunications operators. As the petition in domestic markets becomes the norm, World Trade Organization (WTO) focuses in- ternational attention on liberalizing trade in ser- vices, policymakers are beginning to realize that The trend toward global alliances may opening telecommunications markets to foreign the desire investors and operators has important benefits stem morefjrom the desire offormer both locally and globally. The WTO has placed telecommunications at the top of its agenda monopoly players to re-create at the for multilateral trade liberalization (page 39). As markets open to foreign participation, and internati'onal level the oligarchaes to as technology creates new markets, we can expect to see an entirely new cast of players which they are accustomed in their investing in markets that are new not only tech- domesti'c markets thanfrom the nologically but also geographically. underlying marketforces in the industry. The old monopoly telecommunications sector is fast disappearing. National telecommunica- consumers will find operators that can offer tions markets are fragmenting into a multiplicity packaged services on an international scale in- of niche markets at the same time that trade creasingly attractive. The growing demand for barriers are falling. Many new operators are international services helps explain the trend emerging, each targeting the segment that best toward global alliances among telecommunica- corresponds to its comparative advantage. In tions operators. But this trend may stem more this new networked bit industry, offering a huge from the desire of former monopoly players to range of competing technologies and services, re-create at the international level the oligar- the future for the incumbent telecommunica- chies to which they are accustomed in their do- tions companies looks increasingly bleak. Over mestic markets than from the underlying market the next decade, as the market shifts from un- forces in the industry. der their feet and as new, more nimble actors emerge, we can expect the dominance of the In an alternative future, transmission capacity telecommunications operators over their tradi- and bandwidth might become tradable com- tional markets to erode spectacularly. Some modities, with a spot market on which capac- countries are likely to see their major telecom- ity is bought and sold in half-hour slices and munications operators fail as new players ap- megabit-per-second tranches. The spot market pear that quickly become household names could be associated with a ftitures market on around the world. which contracts would allow operators to hedge future positions. It is difficult to imagine today's James Bond (fbond@worldbank.org), Division mastodon operators, which now cover every- Chief Telecommunications and Informatics 35 Telecommunications Reform-How to Succeed B/dirn W1lZenius Today, more than sixty emerging economies- services. Pressures from interest groups-incum- some twenty-five in Sub-Saharan Africa alone bcnts wanting continuLed protection. new en- -are at some stage of transformation fromn a trants seeking special deals, treasury officials state telecommunications monopoly to private- expecting to use sale revenues to reduce budget led, competitive markets. WX7hen wvell done, such deficits, financial advisers earning success fees reforms can be positive sum games in wrhich all tied to transaction prices-can steer reform off stakeholders gain-customers, existing and new this track. In particular, sale strategies that drive operators, employees, domestic and foreign in- up the prices for existingJ companies or new vestors, and the government. Faster market licenses can repress growth, recluce the fund- growath, new and better services, loxver costs, ing availahle to invest in the companies, or re- and, eventually. lower prices followv. This Note suit in high tariffs. The Mcxican government, outlines the key factors in successful telecom- for example, concluded that the six-year long- munications reform. distance monopoly granted to Telmex in 1990 had led to higher consumer prices and slower Get support at the top growth thani would have resulted under coin- petition. So, in 1996. it chose to forgo the high Reform is most likely to succeed if it is led at fees it could have obtained by tendering one or the highest level of political authority. That is two new licenses and instead opted for unre- usually the head of government, wvho then allo- stricted entry. In India, the exorbitant prices bid cates responsibility for the reform to a single for second fixed operator licenses in 1996. com- person with direct access to senior government bined with modest revenue projections (based officials, freedom to cut red tape, and resources on the low per capita income), are making it to assemble a small support team and hire the difficult to raise debt financing for investment. necessary experts. Such was the case in the BY contrast, the government of Bolivia priva- privatization of Mexico's telecommunications tized Entel in 1996 by issuing new shares for company, Telmex. The president announced the which the xvinning bidder paid US$600 million- reform in August 1989, appointed the minister flunds immediatelv available for investment in of finance chairman of the board and gave him the company. In Brazil, the consortium that won overall responsibility for the privatization, and the cellular license in Sao Paulo in 1997 with a handed over the chief executive's job to an ex- US$2.5 billion bid-fotir timnes the government's perienced public administrator syith a clear re- asking price and 60 percent more tlhan the sec- form mandate. Privatization wTas cormpleted in ond-highest bid-is likely to pass on the cost to December 1990. By contrast. Brazil's attempts customaiers through munch higher tariffs than those at reform begyinning in the early 1980s did not proposed by rival bidders. muster the necessary political muscle. Not until 1997 has real progress been made. Sale strategies that place less emphasis on cash up front can, moreover, yield substantially more Sort out conflicting objectives early cash to the government later. For example, axvarding a cellular license to the bidder that The primary purpose of reform is to get con- offers the largest build-out plan-rather than sumers more, better, new, andc less costly the one offering the highest license fee-can 36 Telecommunications Reform-How to Succeed increase tax revenue for years to come by cre- The interconnection olligation of the dominant ating more business. And initially selling only operators, the principles under whichi terms of the minimuLm number of government shares interconnection will be negotiated, and the pro- needed to effectively transfer control of the state cess and timetable for a regulatory decision if company to the new owners (usually 20 to 30 the parties fail to reach agreement must be percent) allows the government to float the hal- clearly spelled out. A new operator's ability to ance later and obtain much higher prices, once reach (and be reached by) customers of the the company appreciates uncler private man- existing operator and to use parts of existing agement. In the Telmex privatization, for ex- networks on reasonable technical and price ample, the government initiaLly sold 20 percent terms (rather than building complete new fa- of the shares to a strategic investor in 1990 for cilities) plays a big part in determining not only US$1.8 billion, then sold 31 percent more its own viability but also the economic efficiency through public offerings in 1991 and 1992 for of the sector. In Ploland, failure to sort out inter- US$4.5 billion-70 percent more per share. connection with the incumbent meant that of some 200 licenses issued to independent op- Set clear policies, rules, and erators since 1990, only about twelve were in procedures use in 1996. Licensees cited the main iinpedi- ments as unfavorable terms for sharing revenues T he business offered to investors must be with the dominant state operator. limited access clearly defined in the laws, regulations, and to its network, slow negotiation of interconnec- main transaction documents (licenses, contracts tion agreements. and a prohibition on setting of sale). The most critical policy issues relate up their own transmission facilities. to pricing, competition, and interconnection. In pricing, governments most bite the bullet Reforms should follow clearly definec processes early and rebalance tariffs. The price an op- that are open to participation and review by all erator is allowed to charge its customers is the interested parties. The public should be kept most important determinant of profitability and informed. Market mechanisms. not individual ability to finance growth. Existing tariffs are negotiations, should be usedc to select partners often way out of line witlh costs-far too high and cletermine the right sale prices. And the for international calls, too low for local calls award of licenses and contracts should strictly and fixed charges, and somewhere in between adhere to the evaluation criteria announced at for domestic long-distance calls and initial con- the outset. Once a window of political opportu- nection (sometimes tariffs are also too low nitv for reform opens, time is of the essence- overall). Including rebalancing plans in licenses but that shotuld not be used as an excuse to cut or contracts often delays further reforms; new corners or strike deals behind closed doors. owners tend to defer raising some prices to avoid the public fallout, yet later expect the Clear rules and processes must also be applied licensing of competitors to be delayed because to the regulatory function. The loCcus and func- tariffs remain unbalanced. In setting new tariff tions of regulatory authority and the basic pro- structures, calculating the actual costs of each ceclures that will govern its relationships with operator is seldoni a viable method. Rather, operators and customers must he defined, pref- tariffs observed in competitive markets proh- erably by law. That does not mean that a ftull ably offer the best guidance on efficient prices. regulatory capability must be in place before Some cost elements (land, labor, taxes) vary major reform steps can be undertaken. Initial considerably among countries, but the main regulatory decisions can be written into licenses costs (equipment, capital) are determined in and contracts of sale. A core decisionmaking global markets and international benchmarks capability in the form of a commission, say. are thus relevant. As the market becomes more and a secretariat with processing capability, competitive, pricing can increasingly be left to supported by outsourcing of expertise, can the operators. handle essential tasks in the first two or three The World Bank Group 37 TABLE 1 FASTER GROWTH IN OPEN, PRIVATIZED MARKETS (annual percentage growth in main telephone lines) years, such as issuing licenses, marnaginyg coni 1984-89 1989-94 flicting dcemands on the radlio spectrum, and resolving interconnection disagreements. Other Brazil, Colombia,7.0 7.8 areas of competence can he gradually devel Ecuador,Peru,Uruguay oped as needed. Chances are that successive Argentina, Mexico, Venezuela 6.7 t1.3 problems will arise, peak. and then decline to a low simmer, so that a permanent. comilpre- Chile hensive in-house capability may never he needed. Moreover, in most emerging econo- mies, anvthi regulatory ~~~~~~~state monopolies mies, anvthing heyondl a minimalist reglatory ivatized monopolies institution* is not feasihle. open, privatized market Source: Pyramid Research data; World Bank data. Open all markets to competition Without competition, the benefits from increased tions companies. failed shortly before closing private participationi will not he fully realized. when tlhe winning hidder realized that the gov- In Latin Anmerica, for example. countries that eirnent did not intend to grant Svyazinvest a granted monopoly privileges of six to ten years license to builcl its ov,-n long distance netwxork. to privatized state enterprises saw connections grow at 1.5 times the rate under st.te monopolies Enhance credibility and stability -but at onlv lhalf the rate in Chile. wxhere the government retained the right to issue comrPt- Even if a government gets all the policies, rules ing licenses at any timc (table 1). Rural areas, and procedures right, operators and investors too. can become an attractive business undler vxill c)rmne and remaiin only if they believe that liheral entry and pricing policies. In Chile, gov- the government will stay the course. Govern- ernment subsidies equivalent to less than 0.5 iments can do several things to enhance cred- percent of total telecorninunication.s rev enue. al- ibilitv and stability. To safCguard rcforms against locatedl through competitive h-idding in 1995, political changes. governmnents slhould develop mobilized twenty times as much private invest- the reforms wvith the support of maior stake- ment to extend hasic telephone access to rural holders-various branches of government, areas. The program bromught service to ahout a public and private sector users, chambers of thircl of the rural population lackinig it. commerce, consumcr groups, largc cnterprises (inclutcling state-ow ned firms) that could become Contrary to views often expressed by financial alternative network providers. local banks and advisers, investors are not opposCd to com- investors, and the staft and management of ex- petition-as long as they are inot also burdened isting operating comnlpaniies. with regulatory uncertainity, unrealistic service obligations. and rigid tariffs and employvment In cmerging economies, most with strong growth rules. This is true even in small, low'-income potential. the concerns of labor can be readily markets. Ghana Telecotmv was stuccessfullv accommodated. MIost workers stand to gain from privatized in late 1996 at the saiiie time that a higher salaries, improved career prospects, and license was awvarded for a second full-service new opportunities as employees or entrepre- national operator and three other cellular comIl- neurs in a rapidly expanding market. Groxxth panies xvere already in place-and the price alloiws major gains in labor productivity with per line was similar to that paid for the mo little reduction in personnel. As Ghana Telecom nopoly in neighboring C6te cl'Ivoire. Btut lack prepared to privatize in 1996, some 500 wsork- of clarity regarding competition policy does ers (14 percent of the telecomiimunications and drive ixrestors away. Partial privatization in postal xxworkforce) agreed to leave xxith sever- 1996 of Svyazinvest, the Russian holding com- ance packages that cost the government less pany of eighty-five regional telecormmnunica than 3 percent of the initial proceeds from pri- Telecommunications Reform-How to Succeed vatization. After privatization, potential labor the country's own reform targets, abide by a problems largely disappeared as a result of common set of regulatory principles, and rec- managements promises of no forced redundan- ognize the WTO as an instance of intergovern- cies, the introduction of training programs, and mental appeal (see page 39). All this is likely expectations of growth. By contrast, labor unions to provide comfort to investors worried about whose concerns-and political clout-had been regulatory risk. Similarly, loans, credits, and ignored brought Sri Lanka's reform program to guarantees from multilateral agencies such as a halt in the mid-1980s. In the restructuring of the World Bank Group involve government ob- state telecommunications enterprises in Latin ligations that can be tailored to help offset such America, an additional enticement has been of- risks as failure of the government to abide by fered-employee stock option plans that trans- the terms of licenses (on pricing, for example) fer about 5 percent of shares to employees on or ensure access to foreign exchange for debt favorable terms. service or dividend payments. A 1993 invest- ment of USS90 million by the International Fi- Essential for reducing investor risk is limiting nance Corporation and the European Bank for the opportunity for discretionary government Reconstruction and Development in the Hun- or regulatory intervention in business, espe- garian state telecommunications company mo- cially in the early years. In Uganda, initial de- bilized US$1.2 billion in foreign funds at the cisions on tariffs, service obligations, and time of privatization. default interconnection terms are being writ- ten into licenses and contracts (as was also done Investors, operators, and customers will be re- in Ghana). Numbers that will remain firm for, assured by a telecommunications law that es- say, five years-subject if necessary to auto- tablishes broad principles and rules governing matic adjustment, based on simple formulas, the sector. But a law with a narrower objec- for inflation, foreign exchange, or other fac- tive, such as establishing a regulatory author- tors-are more effective at reducing risk than ity, may suffice. The timing of amending or are rules for calculating these numbers. replacing a dated law must weigh the poten- tial delays and political cost. Telmex was priva- Telecommunications reforms gain credibility tized in 1990 in the framework of a 1938 when coupled with broader programs in which transport and communications law-but pas- the government has a large stake. The privati- sage of a new law in 1995 was essential to zation of ENTel in Argentina was the flagship of open the market for competition in 1996. President Menem's multisectoral public enter- prise reform program in the early 1990s, and Conclusion everyone knew that a failure by the govern- ment to stick to the rules it had set for telecom- Major transactions such as a privatization or the munications would have undermined the whole issuance of new licenses tend to drive the re- program. More generally, telecommunications form agenda, but change continues well beyond reforms benefit from a healthy overall business these transactions. Following the rules and hon- climate-political stability, sound macro- oring commitments help consolidate an envi- economic management, and policies favoring a ronment for sustainable growth. Also critical are private-led, competitive, open economy. to build a regulatory capability to suit changing needs, take every opportunity to enhance com- Anchoring key elements of reform in interna- petition, and address any persistent gaps be- tional frameworks also adds credibility. Every tween development and commercial objectives. World Trade Organization (WTO) member country that subscribes to the telecommunica- Bjorn Wellenius (bu.ellenius@n'orldbanpk.org), tions agreement of 1997 enters a binding inter- TelecommunicationsAdOiser, Telecommunica- national commitment to implement aspects of tions and Informatics Division 39 Liberalizing Telecommunications and the Role of the World Trade Organization Carlos A. Porino Braga Februarv 15, 1997, will be remembered as a land- on the best way to proceed. Developing coun- mark date in the history of the multilateral trade tries, for example, opposed the negotiations system. On that day, sixuv-nine governments for- either because they believed that they did not malized commitments to liberalize their basic enjoy comparative advantage in the relevant telecommunications services under the General industries or because they feared that these Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS). The negotiations would intrude into other areas, resulting Decision on Commitments in Basic such as foreign direct investment policies and Telecommunications has both symbolic and national regulatory regimes. Needless to say. practical meaning. The final act of the Uruguay other topics-for example, agriculture and Round in Marrakech in 1994-giving birth to textiles-were much more prominent on the the World Trade Organization (WTO 1-was de- negotiating agenda of developing countries. scribed by many as the beginning of a new era in international trade rtules. The agreement on For telecommunications, resistance to trade basic telecommunications can be characterized negotiations also came from major players in as the first major accomplishment of this new the industry. After all, state-owned enterprises era. Moreover, it will foster the liberalization of were the suppliers of telecommunications ser- telecommunications, bringing significant benefits vices in all but a handful of countries, and inter- for industrial and developing countries alike. national telephony was conducted like a cartel, with transactions closely regulated under rules This Note reviews the evolution of the services negotiated under the International Telecommu- and telecommunications negotiations, the scope nication Union (ITU). Using trade negotiations of the new set of multilateral disciplines, and to promote the liberalization of telecommuni- the implications of the agreement for WTO cations was an alien concept to most of this meimbers, particularly developing countries. community. It was also perceived as a threat The basic message is that the agreemenit is a to national regulators, and in some countries, major accomplishment. but implementing the it was even portrayed as a threat to national commitments it contains will pose a significant sovereignty. challenge for many of the developing country WTO members. But the potential benefits of Despite the opposition, the services negotia- following through with these commitments are tions progressed more smoothly than most not trivial, and policymakers should maintain analysts had predicted at the beginning of the the focus on the liberalization agenda. build- Uruguay Round. The internationalization of ing on the commitments already made. services is at the very core of the process of economic globalization. Service industries (for A clash of worlds example, telecommunications, transport, finan- cial services) provide critical links among In the early 1980s, when the trade community, geographically dispersed markets. Efficient, under the leadership of the United States, began high-quality links are fundamental for trans- to discuss the inclusion of selvices in the multi- national corporations-the most dynamic actors lateral trade regime. there was no consensus in globalization-and this critical need explains 40 Liberalizing Telecommunications and the Role of the World Trade Organization their strong interest in the establishment of to publish anci make available to the public multilateral disciplines in services trade. Pushed the laws and regulations that affect trade in by these powerful interests anci the growing services. recognition of the potential benefits of liberal- izing services, the negotiating agenda evolved Market access ancd national treatment are spe- gradually, and by 1993, the basic architecture cific obligations under the GATS. They apply of the GATS had been agreed on. only to the sen vice industries and activities listed by a country in its schedule of commitments. The GATS in a nutshell' These obligations are specified at the level of eaclh of the four modes of supply and subject The GATS comprises the framework agreement to the limits made explicit in the offer. The (with its twenty-nine articles and eight annexes) GATS adopts a positive list" approach with as well as the schedules of specific commit- respect to sectoral coverage of service indus- ments and the lists of exemptions to most tries-that is, only the industries and activities favored-nation (MFN) treatment submitted by scheduled in the commitments are subject to member countries. It covers four modes of the GATS's specific obligations. international delivery of services: cross-border supply (for example, international telephony), The treatment of telecommunications consumption abroad (tourism), commercial in the GATS presence (provision of services abroad throughl a branch, agency, or subsidiary), and the pres- The definition of telecommunications services ence of natural persons (entry and temporary for GATS purposes is comprehensive, encom- stay of foreign individuals in order to supply a passing both basic services-those that involve service). simiiply end-to-end transmiiission of voice or data-and value addled services-those that It broadly follows the tradition of its counter- modify the form or content of the messages part for trade in goods-the General Agreement relayed through the networks.' By the end of on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)-emphasizing the tJruguay Round, forty-eight schedules nondiscrimination and imposing limits on the (representing 59 of the 125 governments parti- tise of quantitative restrictions on trade. But it cipating in the negotiations) contained com- introduces innovations, covering transactions mitments in telecommunications. BIut almost all associated with commercial presence and intro- of these commitments covered only value ducing a concept of market access that goes added services, reflecting the resistance still beyond border restrictions (for example, in facing this novel approach to telecommuinica- principle, it proscribes restrictions on the type tions negotiations. In short, most of the rel- of organization under which foreign providers evant markets for communications continued can establish commercial presence). to operate otitsicde multilateral disciplines. Unconditional MFN treatment is a basic obli- The Uruguay Round accomplished some impor- gation of signatories that applies to all services, tant results for the sector, however. First, it raised an obligation that bars a WTO member from awarencss about the potential role of trade ne- treating other members less favorably than any g,otiations in fostering the liberalization of tele- other country. BLit the GATS allows MFN ex- communications. Second, it helpecl to diminish emptions as long as the member country icden- the gap in understanding between the trade and tifies them explicitly. The list of exemptions is teleconmmunications communities by promoting supposed to be time-bound and, in principle, a dialogue on their distinct approaches to regu- shoulci not last more than ten years. Another lation. Thircl, it established that access to tele- basic obligation of members is a commitment communications services was critical for trade to transparency, which requires governments in services and that users were entitled to fair The World Bank Group 41 terms of access (as outlined in the Annex on cess commitments would be greatly reduced Telecommunications of the GATS). unless a procompetitive rcgulatory framew ork was also put in place. A draft reference paper But the limited progress in effective liberaliza- describing regulatory disciplines supportive of tion of basic telecommunications led WTO market entry was negotiated. and most coun- members to agree to continue the negotiations tries became signatories to this text (partially beyond the date of the Round's completion or in its entirety) in the context of additional (April 15, 1994). Basic telecommunications commitments made in their offers (expanding joined maritime transport, financial services, on their market access and national treatment and the movement of natural persons as topics for sectoral negotiations. The Negotiating Group on Basic Telecommunications (NGBT) 7ThiS Ccn be charactePlzedt as was created in Mav 1994, with a deadline of April 30. 1996, for completing the talks. thefirst undltilateral eJfort to deal From the NGBT to the GBT explicitly with su bstantive aspects of Participation in the NGBT was voluntary. Ini- coimpetition policy. Even though limitect tially, fifty-three WTO members decided to par- ticipate in the negotiations, with twenty-four to teleconmmunications, it w as a major other governments attending the meetings as observers. The attitude of most participating achiev)emWenJt, and it paves th wae Ivyjor countries about the usefulness of engaging in these negotiations had shifted significantly by fiatture multilateral disc'Alines a d then. In part, this simply reflected a better understanding of the potential benefits of lib- international harmonization. eralizing telecommunications. More funda- mentally, however, it reflected the growing recognition that the industry faces a paradigm commitments). This can be characterized as the shift. Technological progress is rapidly erod- first multilateral effort to deal explicitly with ing the sustainability of old practices based on substantive aspects of competition policy. Even monopolistic behavior, state control, and thouglh limited to telecommunications, it was protected markets for local providers. Callback a major achievement, and it paves the way for systems, virtual private networks, the Internet. future multilateral disciplines and international and the growing promise of modern satellite harmonization. communications are multiplying the opportu- nities for bypassing telecommunications mo- By April 1996, thirty-four offers ('encompass- nopolies. At the same time, the increasing ing forty-eight governments. with the European information intensiveness of transnational cor- Union's submission counting as one) were on porations and the dramatic reductions in the the table. Still, some countries-particularly the cost of communications create additional in- United States-- were dissatisfied with the qual centives for customers to actively explore by- ity and coverage of the offers. Moreover, in passing alternatives. the final phase of the talks, the issue of satel- lite services-that is, to wlhat extent explicit In the NGBT, the focus of the debate rapidly provision for these services needed to be made mio\ved oIn froii "wlhy to liberalize" to '-how to in the offers-added noise" to the negotia- liberalize." Important conceptual progress was tions. As a result, no deal was attained by the made as participants recognized that for tele- deadline of April 30. 1996. Given the progress communications, the value of the market ac- already achieved. however, there was broad 42 Liberalizing Telecommunications and the Role of the World Trade Organization FIGURE 1 COUNTRIES MAKING BASIC TELECOMMUNICATIONS COMMITMENTS Voice telephony Local Domestic long distance International Resale Data transmission Private leased circuit services Terrestre mobile Other terrestre mobile services Mobile satellite services Fixed satellite services Trunked radio Reference paper (additional commitments) 0 10 20 30 40 50 s0 70 * Developing countries * High-income countries Source: World Trade Organization data. support for continuing the negotiations. Seiz- give rise to anticompetitive practices by for- ing this opportunity, Renato Ruggiero, Director- eign monopolistic carriers), on satellite services, General of the WTO, suggested that countries and on what constituted an adequate "critical should be given a chance to improve on their mass" for a deal. Other controversial issues offers, and February 15, 1997, was established included how to avoid discriminatory practices as the new deadline for the negotiations. A new in the allocation of spectrum and how to draw body-the Group on Basic Telecommunica- the line between telecommunications and au- tions (GBT)-was created to carry on with the diovisual services given the growing techno- negotiations, replacing the NGBT, and the rules logical convergence in these areas. of participation were changed to make all WTO members full participants. Gradually, however, technical and political solutions began to emerge. With respect to The negotiations restarted in July 1996, and by international services, the United States unilat- the WTO Ministerial Conference in Singapore erally announced a new policy toward inter- in December 1996, several countries had al- national settlement rates in December 1996, ready tabled improved offers, signaling support creating a mechanism for addressing the con- for a successful conclusion of the negotiations. cerns of its own carriers about the distortions Still, some thorny issues remained. Lively dis- of the accounting rates system outside the WTO cussions continued on international services framework. This helped deflate opposition to (for example, countries with more liberal the agreement based on concerns that it could regimes were concerned that an MFN commit- foster anticompetitive practices (for example, ment to liberalize international services could through one-way accounting rate bypass). Also The World Bank Group 43 FIGURE 2 DISTRIBUTION OF WORLD TELECOMMUNICATIONS REVENUES BETWEEN PARTICIPATING AND NONPARTICIPATING COUNTRIES United States (29.70) European Union (28.27) Japan (15.59) Australia (1.89) Canada (1.78) Switzerland (1.48) Republic of Korea (1.45) Brazil (1.43) Mexico (1.08) Argentina (1.00) Other countries that made commitments (7.44) Countries not participating in the telecommunications agreement (8.56) 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 Percentage share Note:Warld revenues from telecommunications services amounted to US$602 billion in 1995. Source: World Trade Organization data. helping to pave the way to the final agreement the final stages of the negotiations.' By early were the adoption of a technologically neutral 1997, it became clear that a "critical mass' of approach to scheduling (that is, unless other- offer,s would be achieved. On February 15, wise noted, the commitments would cover all 1997, the telecommunications talks were suc- transmission possibilities including satellite ser- cessftilly concluded. vices) and the acceptance of the concepts that frequency and spectrum management should The scope of the agreement not be used to undermine market access cotim- mitments and that MFN exemptions cotild temn- Sixty-nine WXrTO members tabled commitments porarily be used to address the differences in by FebrtLary 1z, 1997f These schedtiles will treatment of audiovisual services. become formally binding by January 1, 1998. Not only were several new offers added to In a parallel effort, governments, the WTO, and those available in April 1996, but thirty-two of several other multilateral organizations worked the thirty-four original offers wxere revised, typi- to raise awareness of the importance of the cally leading to more substantive commitments. negotiations for developing cotintries and to Commitments were made in all basic telecom- help these cotuntries prepare their own offers. mtnications services by both high-income and The World Bank. for example, through its In- developing countries (figure 1). Moreover, most formation for Development (injh)Dev) program participants made commitments either to all or and in close cooperation with the WTO, spon- to parts of the reference paper, subscribing to sored a project to provide technical assistance procompetitive regulatory principles (for ex- to more than twenty developing cotintries in ample, the establishment of independent regu- 44 Liberalizing Telecommunications and the Role of the World Trade Organization FIGURE 3 COUNTRIES WITH LOWEST TELEDENSITY LESS ACTIVE IN WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION NEGOTIATIONS Teledensity in 1995 Main telephone lines per 100 inhabitants *>25 * 10-25 0] 1-10x WTO offers (February 1997) _ * Countries making offers The boundaries, colors, denominations, and any other information shown on this map do not imply, on the part of the World Bank Group, any judgment on the legal status of any territory or any endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Source: international Telecommunication UnijO and World Trade Organization data. lators, the adoption of competitive safeguards, The exact implications of the agreement for a measures to ensure interconnection, transpar- particular country can only be assessed by a ent and nondiscriminatory practices with careful analysis of its schedule of commitments, respect to licensing, and universal service including phasing considerations, list of quali- obligations). fications by activity and mode of delivery, and The World Bank Group 45 eventual recourse to MFN exemiiptions (nine driver of the paradigm shift in telecommunica- governments claimed such exemaiptions for cer- tions, and it explains to a large extent the chang- tain activities). It is fair to say, hoV ever, that in ing attitude in the industry on the desirability contrast with the GATS's results in 1994, xvhen (and inevitability) of competition. But credible most schedules were characterized by status rules relating to market access, constraints on quo commitments (that is, governments basi- discrimination, and a procompetitive regula- cally bound themselves not to adopt more tory environment play an important part in restrictive policies). the outcome of the basic shaping the outcome of this revolution." par- telecommunications negotiations w-ill foster ticularly in influencing the distribution of its significant additional liberalization.' In this benefits. sense, the agreement proved wrong those ana- lysts who were skeptical of the role of sectoral Private capital is expected to take the lead in negotiations in fostering liberalization at the funding investments in telecommunications in multilateral level. the developing world. In the early 1990s. 65 percent of the financing for basic wireline tele- The markets affected by the agreement repre- comnmunications in the developing world came sent more than 90 percent of the world market for telecommunications (figure 2). Dev eloping countries account for less than 20 percent of 7The utaikets affected by the agreement the global revenues from telecommunications services, but they are the fastest-growing markets represet wore than 90 percent of the for these sernvices. Their participation in the WTO process is thus important not only for develop- w'orld zarket Ibr telecommu inications. mental reasons, but also because these markets are bound to increase in relative importance. The countries with the weakest telecommuni- from internal sources (,profits), with commer- cations infrastructure (such as in Sub-Saharan cial funds (20 percent) and official sources (15 Africa) are also those that participated less active- percent) playing a more limited role. By the ly in the WTO negotiations (figure 3). Assistance end of this decade, it is estimated that private to help bring these countries into the system capital flows will finance a much greater share should be a priority for the donor community. of the investments in the sector (55 percent), with internal ( O percent) and official sources The road ahead (5 percent) reducing their relative participation. Analyses of the importance of the basic tele- But private investors wxill be willing to invest communications agreement tend to cluster in modernizing the teleconmmunications infra- around two extreme positions. Most analysts structure of developing countries only if they have been extremnely enthusiastic and present can count on fair and stable rules of the game. the agreement as delivering swx ift liberalization Accordingly, developing countries able to sig- of participating markets. Others are more skep- nal their commitment to liberalization and to tical, pointing out that the multilateral regime adopt a procompetitive regulatory environment and the regulatory authorities are being over- will he in a better position to attract the capital taken by the velocity of technological change flows required for these investments. WTO in the industry. According to these skeptics, commitments can play an important part in this. the agreement plays at best a secondary role in this process of change. Benefits for developing countries are not lim- ited to attracting foreign direct investment. Lib- Reality is somewhere in between. It is true that eralization will also improve local firms access fast teclnological change has been the main to efficient telecommunications service provid- 46 Liberalizing Telecommunications and the Role of the World Trade Organization ers. This will increase their competitiveness- and thus their ability to explore the dynamism of international trade in information-intensive products and services. Last but not least, com- petition will improve the price-quality mix of the telecommunications services available to consumers. The critical remaining issue is the quality of the implementation of the commit- ments. Many developing countries are entering uncharted territory, particularly with respect to procompetitive regulatory disciplines. Those able to meet these challenges will be much better positioned to benefit from the information age." This section relies on lPrinio Blraga (1996). For fuirther details on the -.ition.ile for liheralizing services and on the ,Irrhitectore of the GAIS, see tI'NCTAD and World Bank (1994) and Hoekmaln (1996). IBasic sen ices coser noice telephony, telex. telegraph, facsimile. dalta transmission, pr ivate leased circuit ser ices. fixe(d and mttohile satellite cysterns and sets ites, cellular telephons mobile data ser 'iices. paging. atnd pei sonal commusnic.tion selts iC cV altLie added ser ices incluide email, oice mail. on line dat.i processing. on line dat.uihse storige and retries al. and electonic d.itai interctange. hFor tirtiher details on this project, fhich sas executed hN the Internaitional Institcite of Cotninunic ations. isit the in/heDs \ c-bsitse at http: \s'N'. Ntorldh)ank.org/html intfdes inriodlex lhtul. Antignia and Barbocla, Argentina. AUstralia. Brngladesh. Belize, Bolisxia. Brazil. Brujiei I)artissalar. Brilgaria. Canadcl. (thile, Colotbhia, Cote dIsoircr Czech Republic. Doiitinica. Doittinican Rephhlic. Ecuadiior. El Salt aidor, Etniopean COmntltUnitics and its Meriher States. Ghana. Gienada. Gciatemiala, Hong Kong. Hcingars, Iceland, India.z Incdonesia. Israel. Janmaica. Japan, the Repcublic of Korea. Malaxsia, Matiritiris. Nlexicr, M,orocco. Nes Zealand, N or.ss, Pitkistan, PapcLi Ness Gcuinea. Perci, Philippines. Tioland. Romania, Senegil, Singapore, Sri Lbaitka, Six itzerlandc Slosak Repuhlic, SoLitih Africa. Thailand. Trinidad and Tolvigr. 'i Tinisia. Turkev. tJnited States, and Nenezecela. Foir a clisctisssion of the rescilts of the GATS in pronitoting sel ices tiber.lization. see Hoekm.n and Pirinmo Braga (1996). References Hoekinan. Bernird. 1996. "Assessing the General Agreement on Trade in Ser ices." In Will Martin and L. Alan Winters. eds.. The tlugitorl, Ronit ii aotd the Deetlopintg Coii nries. Cambridge: ('ambridge t'ni- s ersit Pi- ess. Hoekinan. Bernard. and C.A. Primo Braga. 1996. 'Irade in Sernices.: The GATS and Asi.` Asia Pac'u/ic L-cotwntittic Ret iei' 2 (Apt il ): 5-20. Inrino Braga C. A. 1996. "The Impact of the Intetnation.alization of Set' ices on Des eloping Cointries.'' Fi'naoce no!d Detvelopment( (March): 34-37 UNCTAD and WXorld Bank, 1994. Liber/alizing IJnterniationial Trans- actionts itt Ser ics e: A Hatndbook. Ness York: I Inite(i Nations. Carlos A. PRino Braga (cbraga@n orldbank.org) Principal Economist Telecommunications and InJormatics Division 47 What the Transformation of Telecom Markets Means for Regulation Peter Smith In most countries, telecommunications regulators no longer regulate a static, monopolistic industry that provides essentially a single product, telephone service, but a dynamic, multi- product, multioperator industry. In this respect, the telecommunications regulator is way ahead of its peers in other utility sectors in moving from a monopolistic to a competitive market. This environment is a fast-changing and increasingly complex one in which regulators face reduced scope for discretionary decisions. This Note explores the implications for the regulatory agenda. The transformation of telecommunications lular mobile telephony is now a substitute markets is occurring in several dimensionis- for conventional local telephone service for in the changing structure of demand, in the many customers; the distinction between lo- convergence of services, and in the changing cal and long-clistance calling or, with the structure of the industry. The transformation is pending introduction of global personal nio- driven mainly by technological developments. But competitive pressures resulting from the long globalization of the world economy and the ideology and results of reform policies in the distance calling or, with thepending sector are also important forces. � Changing demand structure. Only ten years i ' " ' " ago, conventional 'fixed" voice telephony v onale dominated the revenues of all telephone companies. Today. unprecedented growth in stellite service, between domestic and demand for nevw= services-facsimile. mobile i telephony, and Internet-is fundamentally interntional senke iS becoming less a) d changing the overall structure of demand in less relevant the sector. For example, in Thailand recently, 24 percent of all telephones wvere mobile. The exponential growth in the number of Internet bile satellite service, between domestic and servers and users, and consequently in the international service is becoming less and less demand for bandwidth to carry graphics-rich relevant; and paging and cellular telephony data files, is intensifying the demanld for na- are nov sometimes bundled as a single ser- tional and international transmission links. vice delivered through the same handset. � Convergence of services. Convergence is oc- * Changing industry structure. There has been curring not only between telecommunica- a fundamental shift in the industry structure tions, broadcasting, cable television, and the in many countries toward a multioperator Internet, but also within segments of the tele- environment. Several factors are driving this communications market. For example, cel- shift. New operators are entering the market 48 What the Transformation of Telecom Markets Means for Regulation from other utility sectors (in the United setting the terms of entry-and thus creating Kingdom, for example, electric utilities and market forces. cable TV companies both provide telephony Adopting processes for the award of licenses services). Service suppliers are going inter- to service providers. (These may include bid- national as the era of national monopolies ding processes in which the evaluation cri- passes. And the resale of network services is teria are clear and easily measured, as in price becoming an increasingly important business bids, or "beauty contests," in which the bid as separating network ownership from ser- evaluation criteria are subjective and the se- vice delivery becomes operationally and lection process is less transparent.) commercially viable. * Resolving network interconnection issues and managing numbering plans to promote the The future of telecommunications emergence of a multioperator environment. regulation * Authorizing rate rebalancing (whereby prices are moved closer to costs by reducing prices These trends in telecommunications markets for international and long-distance services mean that regulators will operate in a rapidly and increasing them for local and network changing environment characterized by in- access service) in order to reduce economic creased complexity, reduced scope for discre- rents and cross-subsidies. Applying new approaches to cross-subsidies, The resale of network services is becoming such as improved targeting of beneficiaries, bidding for minimum subsidies, and the ad- an increasingly important business as ministration of subsidies in a way that does not favor one operator over another. s,eparating network ownershipfrom separatig networ n hp fromA task of new signifigance is spectrum manage- service delivery becomes operationally ment. The wireless revolution, reflected in the rapid growth of cellular telephony, the increasing and commercially viable. significance of wireless local loop systems, and the planned deployment of several new-gen- eration global personal mobile satellite systems, tionary decisions, increasing privatization of demands that regulators respond to the increased some aspects of regulation, and the conver- need to manage radio spectrum. Typically, this gence of regulation of different sectors and of task involves allocating portions of the radio regulation within the sector. spectrum to different uses, assigning frequen- cies and authorizing transmission power levels Managing the transition to transmitters at specified locations, maintain- ing standards to ensure that transmitters make In contrast to such utilities as power and wa- optimum use of the radio spectrum, and imple- ter, telecommunications is now clearly a menting measures to control unauthorized use. multiproduct sector with several alternative ser- vice delivery mechanisms that permit compe- While the emphasis shifts to managing the tran- tition in service provision. Thus, the regulatory sition to competition, the fundamental reasons agenda has shifted from minimizing the price for regulation of the sector-the need to pro- of subscribing to local telephone service or tect customers from potential monopoly abuses maintaining cross-subsidy to managing multiple and to allocate the scarce radio spectrum-have issues related to competition, entry, pricing, not gone away. Voice telephony remains widely and cross-subsidies: regarded as an essential public service, and the * Determining whether entry in different mar- sector is still a potential monopoly in which ket segments should be limited or open and operators could adopt strategic behavior with The World Bank Group 49 respect to network interconnection, numbering tion with a major operator on nondiscrimina- plans, allocation of radio spectrum, and the use tory terms, and allocating scarce resources such of cross-subsidies. Regulators are still gate- as radio frequencies and telephone numbers.' keepers of the transformation of the telecom- munications market-they influence the speed, Privatizing regulation conditions, and areas of change, and they arbi- trate conflicts that arise between winners and With the increased complexity, the option of losers in that change. Consequently. regulators privatizing some aspects of telecommunications often must keep an eye on politically accept- regulation is increasingly attractive. Two main able limits to change (for example, to the struc- approaches are possible. One is to create pri- ture of cross-subsidies in the sector) wxhile vate property rights over the radio spectrum, steering a course toward regulatory reform. which has been implemented to some extent in the United States and other countries through Increased complexity and reduced discretion radio spectrum auctions. Once such property rights are established, the new owners of the The transformation of telecommunications mar- spectrum tnay wish to take an increased role in kets has made the job of regulating the sector sublicensing to other users and in policing the much more complex. At the same time, it has use of the spectrum. Establishing property rights reduced the scope for discretionary decisions. Market transformation is reducing the scopc for Witb the inicr-eased conmplexity the regulators to maintain cross-subsidy, for -J example, as a result of the convergence of ser- ohtiou ofpritizi rig some aspects vices within the sector. Traditionally, the clear 17e Of segmentation of the market enabled regulators telecomn'umications regulation is to treat different categories of customers and service providers differently, influencing the iticreasingly altracti2ve profitability of services and the flow of cross- subsidies. Thus, mobile telephone service prices were typically unregulated, wxhile fixed tele- increases the commercial value of the spectrum phone service prices were regulated. And mo- and tlhus provides incentives for more efficient nopoly international telephone service prices use. An important extension of this approach, could be set very high in order to generate a proposed by advisers to the government of El pool of funds for cross-subsidy. But the conver- Salvador in 1996, calls for creating rights over gence of services-reflected in the increasing designated commercial radio spectrum bands substitutability of mobile and fixed services, the not just for specific uses, but for any use. This increasing ease with which high-priced interna- gives owners of designated commercial bands tional telephone service can be bypassed an incentive to assign frequencv to the most through private networks, the introduction of profitable (or highest-value) use. callback services, and the pending introduction of global personal mobile satellite services-cre- Creating property rights thus substitutes a mar- ates pressures to reduce differential regulatory ket process for the government role in assign- treatment and to push prices closer to costs. ing radio spectrum for specific uses such as broadcasting, cellular telephony, or private tele- In addition. the involvement of the World Trade communications networks. The government Organization (NTO) in setting rules for regulat- role could he limited to managing the initial ing basic telecommunications services further sale of spectrum, ensuring compliance with in- reduces regulators' scope for discretionary ternational agreements on spectrum use, and decisions relating to. for example, preventing ensuring that ownership of the radio spectrum anticompetitive practices, providing interconnec- is not monopolized. 50 What the Transformation of Telecom Markets Means for Regulation The second approach for privatizing regula- of procompetition policies in telecommunica- tion is outsourcing. While regulatory authority tions is sector-specific (or in some cases, spe- would remain with a government agency, many cific to network industries) in important ways, functions could be contracted out, such as the policy itself is essentially competition policy. auditing the performance of operators, pre- This pressure for regulatory convergence is an paring public consultation documents, or outcome not only of the changing technology implementing alternative dispute resolution and market structures, but also of the increas- mechanisms. The multioperator environment ing role of international agreements on tele- emerging in most countries promises a heavy communications regulation. And as a result, workload for regulators in adjudicating billing, telecommunications regulatory agencies will in- numbering plan, and interconnection issues. creasingly become specialized competition Alternative dispute resolution mechanisms and policy agencies. other forms of outsourcing are important options for reducing that workload as well as Fourth, the high level of insularity or compart- the budgetary burden on telecommunications mentalization that has been possible at the na- regulators. tional and international level as well as the sectoral level is being eroded. Until recently, Convergence of regulation for example, France could have a completely different regulatory approach than the United Multisector public utility boards have been around Kingdom. But the recent completion of the for many years in the United States. These utility WTO agreements setting out commitments for boards often have a mandate over telecommuni- regulating basic telecommunications services cations, natural gas, and electric power supply. is a step toward international harmonization And in some jurisdictions, communications regu- of regulation in the sector. And in the Euro- lators have a mandate over transport or broad- pean Union, the application of European casting as well as telecommunications. competition policy has played a key role in liberalizing basic telecommunications. These Now, new pressures for convergence in regu- recent EU and WTO initiatives, though not com- lation are arising from four main sources. First, prehensive, are important steps in harmoniz- the overlap between regulation of carriage (tele- ing national approaches to telecommunications communications) and regulation of content regulation. (broadcasting) will increase as both telephone companies and cable TV operators begin to Conclusion provide services previously provided only by the other and as the Internet's capability to Regulation is profoundly changing the telecom- deliver video improves. munications sector. But change in the sector is also driving the agenda for regulation. In time, Second, the substitutability of services across it is not inconceivable that telecommunications subsectors or market segments, particularly regulatory agencies will eventually disappear, between telecommunications and cable TV, absorbed into multisector antitrust agencies. broadcasting, satellite broadcasting, or Inter- net, also creates pressures for harmonizing SeeCar1osA,PrinoBrg, Ller.ilizinglTelcommuniAtiorsand regulation across communications subsectors. tfhc Role of the World Trade Organization' (page 39 in this issue) Third, the critical issues that are emerging in PeterSmith 6psmith2fworldbank.org), Principal telecommunications relate to promoting com- Telecommuinications Policy Specialist, Telecom- petition: interconnection arrangements, revenue munications and Informatics Division settlement, numbering plans, number portabil- ity, and the like. Although the implementation 51 The Private Sector and the Internet Carlos A. Prniom Braga mul Carsten Fink? Advances in telecommunications and infor- archiitecture typically used for voice telephony. matics have transformed the Internet from an it does not require an opcn, or point-to-point, academic experiment into a householdl n ame connection. Packet-switching allows many users in most industrial countries. The number of to share a circuit, with no particular connection computers connected to the Internet grew from dedicated for a given communication session. 535,000 in Tuly 1991 to close to 16 million by MIoreov7er it increases the network's reliability, January 1997 (figure 1), and it is estimated that allowing it to operate even under catastrophic the numlnber of Internet users has already ex- conditions (for example, amid a nuclear war). ceeded 50 million. Althoughi still concentrated in industrial countries, this network of net- The resulting network, Arpanet. began opera- works'" is rapidly expanding in the developing tion in 1969. linking four sites. In the 1970s. world. Many now be]ieve that it provides a win- other governme nt-supported networks emerged dow into a future in vwhich access to informa- in the tUnited States, but access remained tion wvill he independlent of geographic location restricted to the research community connected and interactivity in a multimedia environment with the Department of Defense and other will be ubiquitous. This Note briefly reviews the history of the In- ternet and its evolution from an academic ex- perimcnt into the main application behind the IGUre 1 GRoW T E emerging global inform ation infrastructure. It I t 16 discusses the role of the private sector in these 14 developments ancl the regulatory envTironment A Domain names required for the Internet to fulfill its proimiise. 12 Other It concludes with some lessons for expancling 10 edu the Internet in developing countries. 8 com 6 neMot The rise of the Internet 4 2 The origins of the Internet can he tracecl to the o- 1960s, when the U.S. Departmcnt of Defense Jul Jul Jul Jul Jul Jul Jan decided to fund the development of a packet- 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 switching data network that wvould allow net- w c r s a Ilfote:An Internet host is a computer that acts as an information and communications nTorlSel coptr ltpCs server and has a direct connectionto the Internet. Top-level domain names identify to comiimunicate efficiently. In packet-switching hosts by type or origin-for example, .com Icommercial) .edu (educational), and .net netwrorkis cdata files are br-oken into small pack- (network), the three most frequently used. Others include .org (organization, .gov (U.S. government), and country domains such as .uk (United Kingdom) and de (Germany). ages that are sent independently over the But top-level domain names can be misleading: a host might not be located in the network and then reassembled at the final desti- country indicated or might be either a public or a private institution. nation. This permits efficient use of commutnica- Source:NetworkWizards(http://wwnwcom). tions lines because, unlike circuit-switching, an 52 The Private Sector and the Internet government agencies. This changed in 1986 with been the rapidly evolving network architecture the creation of the NSFNet, also subsidized by and user interfaces. This technology has ben- the U.S. government. The idea of the NSFNet efited from the decline in computing costs rela- was to provide high-speed backbone services tive to transmission costs. On the user side, the connecting regional networks as well as cam- growth of the Internet has been promoted by puses and research centers. The network of net- the appearance of powerful programming lan- works communicating through the Internet guages, new network "tools," and user-friendly protocol began to expand rapidly. interfaces. The World Wide Web, a sophisticated application that allows users to access any kind In the early 1990s, the management of the of digitized information (text, picture, sound, NSFNet backbone was subcontracted to private vileo) and configure it for display with a mouse firms, which were allowed to route commer- click, has given multimedia capabilities to the cial traffic through the Internet. The explosive Internet. The growth of the Web has been as- demand for network service in the 1990s- tounding: betweenJune 1993 andJanuary 1997, mainly from the private sector-led to the the number of Websites leapt from 130 to emergence of several commercial Internet back- roughly 200,000. Fostered by the improving bone networks (such as Alternet, PSNet, and multimedia capabilities, commercial use of the SprintLink), and in October 1995, the NSFNet Internet overtook research and educational use backbone was shut down. U.S. government and has been growing exponentially in the 1990s subsidies for the Internet have fallen to an in- (see figure 1). ByJanuary 1997, there were close significant amount, and almost all the costs of to 4 million hosts in the .com domain.' The pri- the Internet are now borne by its users. vate sector has clearly taken the driver's seat in providing both the Internet's infrastructure and Supporting the explosive growth of the Internet its content in the United States. and of the demand for Internet services have Regulation The Internet has blossomed in a relatively regulation-free environment. Most regulatory FIGURE 2 MONOPOLY VERSUS COMPETITION- activity has concentrated on defining standards AND THE GROWTH OF THE INTERNET for the formats and protocols necessary to operate the network. But as the commercial Inteet hostsper1,000inhabitants presence on the Net increases, regulatory is- sues relating to the provision of the network's 14 1 OECD markets with infrastructure monopoly infrastructure and services become increasingly 1Z * OECD average important. The development of a regulatory 12 *OECDmarkets withinfrastructur competition framework is critical in three areas: provision 10 of Internet backbone access; Internet service 8 - : - providers (ISPs); and information services. 6 4 | * - The Internet backbone servers are the highest- level network servers-those to which ISPs pay 2 connection charges. The basic regulatory options 0 are to provide public support for backbone Jul 91 Jul92 Jul 93 Jul:94 Jul 95 Jan 96 access to promote connectivity or to leave back- Soure: OECD, "nformation infrastructure Convergence and Pricing: Tme Internet bone service provision to the market. As men- (Paris, 1996). tioned, the original backbone in the United States, NSFNet, was government-funded until rapid growth in networking demand led to the The World Bank Group 53 emergence of commercial backbones. A similar pattern can be found in other industrial coun- tries. In Germany, for example, the first Internet BOX 1 INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY IN CYBERSPACE backbone-UNIDO, for Universitat Dortmund- was run by the university and later replaced by The rise of the Internet gives new relevance to the issue of extra- commercial backbones. territorialiy and increases the demand for convergence among ISPs provide Internet services to the end tisers. national intellectual property rights regimes. The Intemet not only In the United States, ISPs are competing private opens new possibilities for dissemination of information; it also firms. In other countries, the major ISP is the expands the scope for activities that may infringe on someone's state-owned telecommunications operator. of- intellectual property rights. With a few keystrokes, an Intemet user ten a monopoly. Regulatory options for ISPs can anonymously download copyrighted material in bulletin boards depend on the market structure in telecommu- around the world. Prosecuting Internet service providers can nications. In many cases, the telecommunica- nicationsoperators mare wsell pitined tcom vide discourage infringement, but it may inhibit the expansion of the value tions operators are wTell positioned to provide Internet services. But it is worth pointing out addedservicesthatmakethelnternetsopowerful. that OECD countries with more competitive tele- The most important international treaty on copyright protection is communications sectors tend to have greater theBemeConventionfortheProtectionofLiteraryandArtisticWorks Internet connectivity than countries with a mo- of 1886, which provides for national treatment of domestic and nopoly (figure 2). foreign copyright holders and sets minimum standards for copyright Policymakers have to decide w,vhether telecom- protection. The World Intellectual Property Organization (WlPO)-a munications network operators should be per- specialized United Nations agency that administers the Brne mitted to offer information services in direct Convention-held a diplomatic conference in December 1996to competition with independent information ser- revise the convention and to clarify the scope of copyright protection vice providers. As a rule of thumib, if a telecom- in the digital environment. The main outcome of this conference was munications operator has market power in the the WIPO Copyright Treaty. This treaty makes clear that the reproduc- transport network, structural or at least account- iangseparatione hor, .uldub r to avoi nt- tion rights of copyright owners encompass the right to make digital ing separation should be required to avoid anti- competitive cross-subsidization. In other words, copies. But its language is broad enough to allow national legislation the Internet services unit of the operator should to limit (or remove) liability at the level of network providers with be required to buy access to the transport net- respect to, for example, temporary digital storage. The treaty thus work on an arm's-length" basis. Another, very achieves a balance between the concerns of content providers and sensitive issue is voice telephony over the In- those of contentcarriers. ternet. which may become a serious threat to the traditional circuit-switched network. Note: For discussion of the economics of intellectual propert riglas in cyberspace. see Appropriability of contentGCA Primo Braa and C. Fink, "The Economic Justification for the Grant of Intellectual Property Rights: Patems of Convergence and Coafficf," in E Abbt and D. Gerber. ads. Public Policy and Global Technological lnregrdtoo (London: Kluwer, lU9117. Digitized information can be easily reproduced and redistributed on the Internet, and providers of information find it difficult to charge users directly. Most private content providers recover costs indirectly-by providing information to But the conventional remedy for the cost recov- potential customers about other goods and ser- ery problem is intellectual property rights pro- vices. The indirect incentive structure is strong tection. Copyright, for example, protects an given the low cost of disseminating information author's work-whether a book, a performance, on the Internet relative to the number of users a recording, or a computer program-from unli- and the bright future prospects of the Internet. censed copying. In principle, traditional copyright 54 The Private Sector and the Internet law applies to the Internet environment. But such provide digital protection across national major industrial economies as the United States boundaries. Incrcasingly sophisticated digital and those in the European Union have revised rights management technologies are becoming or are now revising their intellectual property available on the World Wide Web. But national rights laws to address specific needs of electronic security reasons have been invoked to limit networks. Moreover, the global character of the the dissemination of cryptographic capabilities. Internet demands international legal governance The United States has been trying to address (box 1). the national security issue by promoting data encryption standards that can be broken by An important problem in legal protection for intelligence agencies and by controlling the ex- copyright holders on the Internet is enforce- port of encryption technology, restrictive mea- ment, given the speed and magnitude of data sures that may inhibit widespread commercial transmission. This is an area where digital rights use of these technologies. management technologies can be of help. These hardware and software devices control A third way to recover costs is through the sale access to information and the ability to use and of advertising space on information pages. further distribute it. In principle, these "encryp- Commercial advertisements first appeared on tion" technologies are attractive because, un- the Web in 1994. Although this step toward like intellectual property rights, they can pure commercial use of the Internet initially FIGURE 3 GLOBAL INTERNET DENSITY, 1996 Internet hosts per 10,000 inhabitants * More than 100 E 1-10-l E Less than 1 The boundaries, colors, denominations, and any other information shown on this map do not imply, on the part of the World Bank Group, any judgment on the legal status of any territory or any endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Source: Network Wizards (http:/www.nw.conVzone/WWW/top.html). The World Bank Group 55 met with strong resistance from the researclh telecommunications operator. Recognizing the and education communities, growth has been economic benefits of electronic networking, the rapid, and advertising revenues are estimated Brazilian government supports an Internet to have exceeded US$250 million in 1996. backbone open to commercial connectivity and traffic while limiting the dominant carrier's ac- Internationalization tivity in the direct provision of Internet ser- vices to the public. The number of Internet Although the Internet is still most widely used in the United States, the 1990s have been marked by its rapid internationalizationi. The By the niid-1990s, Br-azil had a hiuher share of non-U.S. hosts increased from 20 per- cent in July 1991 to 36 percent in July 1996. ratio of Internet hosts to PCs than such But most non-U.S. hosts still reside in indus- trial countries, and in July 1996, roughly 96 econo/zies as France, Germany, Hong percent of all Internet hosts were in OECD countries. Kon?7g, and Sitngapore. Most developing countries are connected to the Internet-if only through email-though pen- hosts in Brazil (br domain) grew from 300 in etration is still low7 (figure 3). In 1996. there January 1992 to more than 50,000 in July 1996, was on average only 0.5 Internet host per of which some 20.000 are commercial ('.com.br 10,000 inhabitants in developing countries, domain). By the niid-1990s, Brazil had a higher compared with 101 in industrial countries. The ratio of Internet hosts to PCs than such econo- low pcnctration is due mainly to the poor in- llies as Francc, Germany, Hong Kong, and formation infrastructure in developing coun- Singapore. tries-the roads and ports that carry and process digitized information. Average teledensity (tele- There are, of course, many obstacles to the phone lines per person) is thirteen times lower, diffusion of the Internet in developing coun- and average PC density thirty-eight times lowTer. tries. National laws regarding privacy and in- than in industrial countries. tellectual property rights protection must be refined. And the predominance of English- For developing countries, establishing the right language content may deter local researchers regulatory environment is as critical as it is for or local firms that could use the Internet to industrial countries-though the relevance of add value to their goods and services. the regulatory experience of industrial econo- mies discussed above is open to debate for coun- The critical bottleneck, however, continues to tries with poor telecommunications networks, be the weak information infiastructure of de- low computer penetration, and incfficient, state- vcloping countries. Government activism to owned telecommunications monopolies. But a promote Internet connectivity at the level of few developing countries have managed to rap- the research and education communities may idly expand Internet connectivity despite weeak help jump-start the national information infra- information infrastructure, such as Brazil, Chile, structure. And governments should support the Czech Republic, Malaysia, Mexico, and community access in public libraries and com- South Africa. munity centers. But an increasingly important role for governments in fostering the Internet Brazil, for example, successfully adopted a revolution is that in the regulatory arena. Most model of public-private partnership to diffuse important here is to promote a competitive en- the Internet, and it has increased Internet vironment for Internet service providers, es- connectivity despite its dominant state-ovwned tablish adequate rules of the game for electronic 56 The Private Sector and the Internet commerce, and ensure effective incentives for the provision of content-essential measures for attracting private investment in the infra- structure and in content generation. Those countries able to attract such investment will be better positioned to benefit from the emerg- ing global information infrastructure. This understates the nuLmber of comniercial hosts, since the net domain (with more than 1.5 million hosts) and some of the country domains also include commercial hosts. Carlos A. Primo Braga (cbraga@worldbank. org, Principal Economist, and Carsten Fink, Consultant, Telecommunications and Informatics Division