World Bank Reprint Series: Number 307 Mateen Thobani A Nested Logit Model of Travel Mode to VVork and Auto Ownership Reprinted with permission from Journal of Urban Economics, vol. 15 (1984), pp. 287-301. Copyrighted by Academic Press. World Bank Reprints No. 267. Dipak Mazumdar, "Segmented Labor Markets in LDCs," American Economic Review No, 268. Stephen P. Heyneman and William A. Loxley, "The Effect of Primary-School Quality on Academic Achievement across Twenty-nine High- and Low-Income Countries," The American Journwl of Sociology No. 269. James R. Follain, Jr., Gill-Chin Lim, and Bertrand Renaud, "Housing Crowding in Developing Countries and Willingness to Pay for Additional Space: The Case of Korea," Journal of Development Economics No. 270. Bela Balassa, "Policy Responses to External Shocks in Sub-Saharan African Countries," Journal of Policy Modeling No. 271. Jaime de Melo and Sherman Robinson, 'Trade Adjustment Policies and Income Distribution in Three Archetype Developing Economies," Journal of Development Economics No. 272. J. B. Knight and R. H. Sabot, 'The Role of the Firm in Wage Determination: An African Case Study," Oxford Economic Papers No. 273. William G. Tyler, 'The Anti-Export Bias in Commercial Policies and Export Perfor- mance: Some Evidence from Recent Brazilian Experience," Welfwirtsclaftliches Archiv No. 274. Ron Duncan and Ernst Lutz, "Penetration of Industrial Country Markets by Agricul- tural Products from Developing Countries,' World Development No. 275. Malcolm D. Bale, "Food Prospects in the Developing Countries: A Qualified Optimistic View," The American Economic Review (with Ronald C. Duncan) and 'World Agricultural Trade and Food Security: Emerging Patterns and Policy Directions," Wisconsin International Law Journal (with V. Roy Southworth) No. 276. Sweder van Wijnbergen, "Interest Rate Management in LDCs," Journal of Monetary Economics No. 277. Oli Havrylyshyn and Iradj Alikhani, "Is There Cause for Export Optmism? An Inquiry into the Existence of a Second Generation of Successful Exporters," Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv No. 278. Oli Havrylyshyn and Martin Wolf, "Recent Trends in Trade among Developing Countries," European Economic Review No. 279. Nancy Birdsall, "Fertility and Econornic Change in Eighteenth ard Nineteenth Century Europe: A Comment," Population and Development Review No. 280. Walter Schaefer-Kehnert and John D. Von Pischke, "Agricultural Credit Policy in Developing Countries," translated from Handbuch der Landwirtschaft und Erniihrung in den Entwicklungsliindern (includes original German text) No. 281. Bela Balassa, "Trade Policy in Mexico," World Development No. 28Ia. Bela Balassa, "La politica de comercio exterior de M6xico," Comercio Exterior No. 282. Clive Bell and Shantayanan Devarajan, "Shadow Prices for Project Evaluation under Alternative Macroeconomic Specifications," The Quarterly Journal of Economics No. 283. Anne 0. Krueger, "Trade Policies in Developing Countries," Handbook of International Economics No. 284. Anne 0. Krueger and Baran Tuncer, "An Empirical Test of the Infant Industry Argument," American Economic Review No. 285. Bela Balassa, "Economic Policies in Portugal," Economia No. 286. F. Bourguignon, G. Michel, and D. Miqueu, "Short-run Rigidities and Long-run Adjustments in a Computable General Equilibrium Model of Income Distribution and Development,' Journal of Development Economics JOURNAL OF URBAN ECONOMCS 15, 287-301 (1984) A Nested Logit Model of Travel Mode to Work and Auto Ownership1 MATlEEN Th1OBANI The World Bank, 1818 H Street, N. W., Washington, D. C. 20433 Received April 23, 1982; revised August 24, 1982 INTRODUCTION Estimating the demand for urban passenger travel is useful in transport planning. An appropriately specified model may be used not only to predict the demand for various travel models but also to examine the effect of policy changes on the welfare of individuals. Such policies may include changing the public transport fare structure, changing the tax on petrol, adding more buses to the existing fleet, or making a certain travel mode accessible to more people. When the choice of mode to work and auto ownership is jointly modeled, the effect of, say, an increase in bus fares on the demand for various travel modes, as well as the effect on the demand for car ownership, can be predicted. This paper estimates a probabilistic joint choice model of travel mode to work and auto ownership. The probabilistic models consider the probability that an individual makes a certain choice (e.g., the choice of mode to work) as a function of attributes of the choice and socioeconomic characteristics of the individual. Such models are behavioral, based on disaggregated data, and policy oriented in that they are sensitive to changes in policy variables. An important advantage of the probabilistic models is that under certain assumptions, they can be derived from a theory of stochastic utility maximi- zation. Further the decision set may include several modes and allows for joint decisions such as buying a car and going to work in a bus. If the joint nature of a decision is ignored it may bias coefficient estimates in addition to decreasing their efficiency. Decisions such as whether to make a trip or the time of day to make the trip can also be handled although they are usually difficult to model and data are often unavailable. 'This paper is a refinement of the author's Ph.D. thesis at Yale University. He is grateful to his advisors John Quigley and T. N. Srinivasan for guidance. Support for data collection was provided by the International Labour Office, Geneva. Office space and research assistance during the data collection period were kindly provided by the Applied Economics Research Centre, Karachi University. The author thanks Valerie Kozel who suggested many of the refinements in this paper and Eric Swanson with whom he has had many useful discussions, He is also grateful to a reference for pointing out an important error and making useful suggestions. 287 0094-1190/84 $3.00 Copyright © 1984 by Acadermic Prcss, Inc. All rights of reproduction in any form reserved. 288 MATEEN THOBANI While the probabilistic models are typicaly laid out within a framework which allows for elaborate joint decisions, few studies estimate the joint decisions. Studies of the latter sort include Adler's and Ben-Akiva's [1] study on shopping trips and Lerman's [6] study on choice of residential location, type of housing, automobile ownership, and mode to work. More recently Train [12] estimates a joint choice model of auto ownership and mode to work 'Lased on a sample of households in the San Francisco area. Using Train's -pproach, this paper estimates a joint choice model of auto owner.6i4' and; mode to work based on household survey data from Karachi. There are several reasons for choosing to model this set of joint decisions. The trip to work is a large percentage of total trips made by the household and the primary use of public transport is for work trips. It is made to a fixed destiation at a relatively fixed time of day and demand for the trip is inelastic. This allows one to ignore the effect of a price change on the decision to go to an alternate location or not make the ftip at all. One would expect that the decision to buy a car or motorcycle is determined simultaneously with the decision to choose a particular mode to work. If so, and the simultaneity is ignored, coefficient estimates are biased. By correctly modeling the joint decision it is possible to see the effect, for example, of an increase in petrol price not only on demand for a mode to work, but also on demand for car ownership. Fitting the model to household data from Karachi is interesting because Karachi has a rich variety of modes. Further, it is relevant because all fares in Karachi and the petrol prices are regulated by the govermment so that policy instruments are readily available. It is instructive to compare travel behavior in a city in a developed country (San Francisco) with Karachi. Are values of time and price and time elasticities different between these cities? This paper extends Tra's paper in that it explicitly shows how one could use such a model to make welfare comparisons under different policies. THE NESTED LOGIT MODEL The nested logit model is a generalized version of the multinomial logit model.2 An outline of the model as it applies to the problem at hand is given below. The consumer is assumed to face a joint decision of choice of auto ownership indexed c = 1,... C and mode to work indexed n = 1,... Nc.' The consumer derives utility Ucn which is a function of the attributes of the alternative cn. The attributes may be variables related to the consumer, such as family size and household income; auto ownership, such as maintenance 2See Domencich and McFadden [4] and McFadden [10]. 3The set Nc will vary according to c since it is assumed that a person cannot decide not to own a car but to go to work in one, MODE TO WORK AND AUTO OWNERSHP 289 and depreciation; the choice of mode to work such as commuting time; or interaction variables, such as cost of the mode divided by the individual's wage rate. The consumer then chooses the alternative that gives the highest utility. All consumers are assumed to have the same stochastic utility function. Not all attributes of the utility function are observed. Unobserved vari- ables have some probability distribution conditioned on the values of the observed variables. If the observer knows the foim of the utility function and the probability distribution of the unobserved variables, he can make a probabilistic statement of the expected choice, namely Pr,, = Prob[ U,, > Ubm for bm ¢ cn] (1) where Prcn denotes the probability of choosing cn. The joint probability above may be estimated by specifying a functional form for Uc,, and by using the identity Pr,, = Prc (2) where Prcn is the joint probability that the individual chooses mode n to work and the household choses the auto ownership category c, Prnlc is the conditional probability of the worker choosing mode n given auto owner- ship c, and Pr, is the marginal probability of the household choosing auto ownership category c. The utility function Uc,, can be decomposed into three components as shown below Uc. = Ax + (xaYc + X;cn (3) where xn is a vector of observed attributes which vary with mode attributes of the work' trip4 (e.g., in-transit time), y, is a vector of observed attributes which vary only with auto ownership (e.g., depreciation cost), and /3' and a' are vectors that may be estimated using maximum likelihood methods by specifying a structure for the stochastic error term Xck. If the A?, are identically and independently distributed having a Weibull distribuition, then Prc, is multinomial logit. However, McFadden [10] has shown that if the Ac, have a particular generalized extreme value distribu- tion, then the conditional and marginal probabilities described above are 4We have assumed that the nonstochastic compnnent of the utility function is linear in parameters. In addition, whereas the general model allows for x,, to vary with both mode ownership and mode to work attributes, in this model xe,, equals x, since the variables such as in-transit time by bus are independent of whether the household owns a car. 290 MATEEN THOBANI given by ,Be'xA/(l-c) (4) elc and Pr y