S~~~\~~ 1253) POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 13 3 1 The Myth of Monopoly V largefinnsaremore prevalent in the United States A New View of Industrial Structure than in Ria.And there'is in Russia little evidence in Russia of in RUSSia industrial concentration in Nnational narkets. lnstead - Annette N. Browrz ', barriers to competion in Ba-rry W. Ickes Razndi Ryterman Russ'ia arise as a resulc of highy segmented product marke. Corequently. traditional policy remedies. a'appropriate for problems of concentration (such as antitrust policy and import competition) may be Hi- advised or inadequate for addressing problems of imperft compeition in the Russian econory. The. presciption for healthier competion: improve Russia's distributon systen and fa-cilitate the entry of new: - firrns- The World Bank Policy Research Department Transition Eoonomics Division August 1994 POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 1331 Summary findings Discussions of economic reform in the Russian Instead, barriers to competition in Russia arise as a Federation arc colored by the conventional view of result of highbly segmented product markets. In large part, Russia's industrial strucrurc. Both in Russia and in the this segmentation can bc viewed as a legacy of central Wesr, Russian industry is characterized as very large planning. Under the prior regime, enterprises were enterprises operating in highly concentrated industries. highly isolated, divided along both ministerial and Brown, Icke and Ryterman challenge the geographic lines. Presently, these barriers are reinforced conventional view. They assess Russian industrial by some fe&tures of the transitional environment that concentration by comparing the Russian industrial continue to undermine the efficient distribution of structure (as revealed in the 1989 Soviet Census of goods. Industry) with that in the United States and other Brown, Ickes, and Ryterman conclude that the countries. traditional policy remedies appropriate for problems of They find that very large firms are more prevalent in concentration (snxch as antitrust policy and import the United States than in Russia. This empirical fact compedtion) may be ill-advised or inadequate for suggests that planners economized on the costs of central addressing problems of imperfect competition in the economic coordination not by building unusually large Russian economy. enterprises, but by not building very small enteprises. They argue instead that improving the distrbution Their most important finding: That there is little system and other market infrastructure that supports aggregate or industry concentration at the national level trade and facliting the entry of new finns should be the in Russia. Monopolies and oligopolics actually account most critical elements of competition policy in Russia. for only a small share of national employment and production. This paper-a producr of the Transition Economics Division, Policy Research Department-is parr of a larger effort in the deparmnent to understand the adjustment of enterprises in economies in transition. Copies of the paper are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Please contact Maxine Berg, room N11-054, extension 36969 (68 pages). August 1994. Tec Policy Rearch Working Paper Sris dsemnates the fmdiw of wait as progres to encoure the exchacng of ide about dnudopmensue Anobceah,e of thesfies is toga thefns outquickly, even tife presemman rekss thanfudfl polishe& The papers carry the names of the auors anddsbd be usd and cid accordingly. The flding, iterpretatknt and condusions are the adtors' own and sbold not beatątibsaed to the World Bank its Execsate Board of Dirtrs, or any of is menmbr countries. Produced by the Policy Research Dissemination Center The Myth of Monopoly: A New View of Industrial Structure in Russia* Annette N. Brown Department of Economics University of Michigan Ann Arbor, MI 48109 (313) 994-0440 anbrown@umich.edu Barry W. Ickes Deparment of Economics The Pennsylvania State University University Park, PA 16802 (814) 863-2652 i04@psuvm.psu.edu Randi Ryterman The World Bank 1818 H Street, NW Washington, D.C. 20433 (202) 473-7037 nryterman@worldbank.org Correspondence to: Barry W. Ickes, Department of Economics, The Peansylvania State University, University Park, PA 16802 Slhe authors thank Abram Bergson, Joseph Berliner, Abe Becker, Rick Ericson, Gregory Grossman, Gur Ofer, Rughvir Khemani, Bryan Roberts, Alan Gelb, and workshop participants at Indiana, Michigan, Penn State, RAND, and the World Bank for helpful comments. We also thank Yvonne Ying and Miodrag Deric for research assistance. Barry Ickes and Randi Ryterman are grateful to the National Council for Soviet and East European Research for its support This work was completed while Annett Brown was a visitor at the World Bank and she is grateful for its support. The Myth of Monopoly: A New View of Industrial Structure in Russia 1. Introduction Discussions of economic reform in the Russian Federation are colored by the conventional view of Russian industrial structure. This view, held both in Russia and in the west, is that Russian industry is characterized by very large enterprises operating in highly concentrated industries. This perception of industrial structure has important implications for policy, and for the interpretation of developments in Russia.' For example, based on the view that Russian industry is dominated by monopoly enterprises, Russian policymakers have reintroduced price controls on a wide variety of commodities. The conventional wisdom about Russian industrial structure is based on a generation of research on the Soviet system of central planning, research that appeared to be supported by available evidence. According to this view, planners econoinized on the costs of central planning by creating a highly concentrated industrial sector with a small number of very large enterprises in each industry. Before transition, the conventional costs associated with imperfect competition - higher prices and restricted output - could be overcome by the control of prices and the setting of output targets by central planners. Now, however, as the Russian economy adopts the market system, problems of industrial structure become important and affect the design of econoric reftbmL Consequently, it is crucial that the conventional wisdom be re-examined. In this paper, we challenge the conventional wisdom. We estimate Russian industrial concentradon by examining the Soviet Industrial Census of 1989, and by comparing the Russian industrial structure to that in the United States and other countries. We find that the conventional wisdom about Russian industrial structure is seriously misleading. We find, for example, that very large firms are more prevalent in the United States than in Russia, as are very small firms. Our analysis suggests that planners economized on the costs of central economic coordinauion, not by buiding wwsually large enterprises, but by not buiding very small enterprises. Because innovation was centrally directed, small firms did not play the role they play in a market economy, and thus industry evolved under a completely different process of economic selection. Our most important finding is that there is little aggregate or industry concentration at the national level in Russia. Monopolies and oligopolies actually account for a very small share of national employment and production. Our analysis suggests instead that the barriers to comperition in 'A frequently offered explanation of the output drop that fbllowed price liberalizatipn is that monopolies reduced output to raise prices. ThduaWd Concamtraooa Russia arise as the result ofproduct markets ta are highly segmente'J? In large part, this segmentation can be viewed. as a legacy of the system of central planning. Nevertheless, some features of the transition environment continue to undermine the efficient distribution of goods, reinforcing these barriers. Based on our finding, we conclude that the traditional policy remedies appropriate for problems of concentration, such as anti-trust policy and import competition, may be ill-advised or inadequate for addressing problems of imperfect competition in the economy. We argue instead that imwroving the disbution system and fiacilitating the entry of new firms are the most critical elements of competition policy in Russia. The remainder of the paper is as follows. In the rest of section 1, we focus on the process of industrial evolution under central planning. We also discuss the conventional wisdom, and explain why we think a further examination is warranted. Section 2 discusses data and methodology. In section 3, we present our findings in the form of a series of "myths" and wrealities." We then turn, in section 4, to analyze the barriers to competition that do exist in Russia today. Section 5 discusses the implications of our findings for economic reform in Russia. Section 6 concludes the paper. 1.1 Industril Evolution Under Central Planning The industrial structure that exists in the Russian Federation today was crealid mostly as a consequence of decisions made during the prior economic regime. Therefore, we begin our discussion of industrial concentration in Russia by considering the process of industrial evolution under central planning. Some of the onfusion that arises over the present industrial structure is a direct consequence of differences in views over the important features of this process. We present these two views below. Much of the convenlonal view about industrial evolution under central planning arises from a particular folk model (the 'cookie cutter" model) of planner or ministerial decision making. In this model, a Stalinist minister is assigned the responsibility of building a new industry. The minister. studies the set of technologies available to produce the product to identify the efficient scale of production within a centrally planned sewing. After this efficient scale is identified, the mirister uses the cookie cutter to carve a set of identical factories at this scale to satisfy industrial development needs. 'Mhe predominant source of monopoly power under central planning was the sellers' market created by price controls. Price liberalization then is perhaps the most important element of competition policy in Russia and other countries of the former socialist world. 2 Indusud Co_wmn__n_ Clearly, the conventional model supports the view that Russian industry is very homogeneous. Each industry is populated by identical firms: . Also, the model is often interpreted to suggest that industry is highly concentrated and dominated by very large firms. It is generally believed that, by building fewer and, thus, larger enterprises; the administaive costs of central planning could be economized.' Moreover, Stalinist ministers are generally believed to have identified scales of production that were quite large, a phenomenon known as- gigantomania.' Eva Ehrlich [1985: 293] relates this bias quite simply, 'In the socialist countries, large size and economic efficiency were thought to be synonymous." Stalin, especially, preferred large scales of production because such enterprises stood out as impressive examples of Soviet industrialization.5 An alternative view of industrial evolution under central planning is implicit in the more recent literature on ministerial decision-making under central planning. The older literature emphasizes the similarity of technologies within an industry among firms when they are first built; the newer literature emphasizes the differences between firms that become more pronounced as they age. This newer literature presents models that stress the role of hidden information and hidden action in the behavior of decision makers under planning. In these models, industrial ministers must allocate production targets to enterprises with imperfect knowledge of their true productivity. To elicit information from enterprises about their potential productivity, the minister must provide enterprise directors with sufficient incentives to meet their targets. These models provide several insights into the type of industrial structure that evolves as a consequence of this system of incentives. First, implicit in the model is the belief that enterprises in each industry are heterogeneous. They differ in productive potential, possibly because of differences in managerial skills or behavior, location, access to suppliers, or even technology. Second, over time, these differences may not be fully revealed. When the incentives directors face do not adequately reward them for fully revealing inforrnation, the directors of higher productivity 'Fewer enterprises makes it easier to construct the plan and also reduces the costs of monitoring its implementation. 'See, for example, Gregory and Stuart [1986: 143]. We note that, in early research on Soviet enterprises, gigantomania referred to the tendency of the Soviet ministers to built gigantic plants. More recently, however, this concept has been used to describe enterprise size. 'Discussing the fixation with large enterprises, Peter Wiles 11962: 3041 writes: "There is something 'socialist' and 'progressive' about mere size, even if unaccompanied by lower costs. Gigantomania as such, then, reinforces the view that large capital expenditures are a good thing, even where smaller ones will do." 3 ladueria Concgaden enterprises will choose to conceal the true potential of their enteririses, precisely because they lbow that ministers will use this information against them in designing fiture production targets. This dynamic incentives problem, the "ratchet effect,' impairs economic performance because the treat of higher targets causes enterprise directors to demand greater rewards in return for full revelation. This makes it more costly for planners to obtain important information.' Ickes and Ryterman [19931 use these observations to develop a model of industrial evolution under central planning. In most of the literature on managerial decision making, the number of enterprises is given. The problem considered in the Ickes-Ryterman model is the determination, by the relevant mi ister, of how many enterprises should be built in a given industry. In this model, planners provide industrial ministers with a stream of aggregate output targets to be met over time. The industrial minister, in turn, must disaggregate these targets and award them to specific enterprises in the ministry, building new enterprises and expanding existing enterprises to meet this goal. The minister cannot, however, shut down enterprises that are observed to be high cost because the absence of exit is one of the distinguishing features of centrally planned economies. Of course, the productive potential of new enterprises is learned only over time as the ministers observe the ability of enterprise directors to consistenty meet production targets at low cost. This model also provides important insights into the evolution of industry under central planning. Again, the model stresses the presence of heterogeneity within industry. Over time, as ministers observe the performance of enterprises, they naturally award larger targets to enterprises with a demonstrated ability to meet their production goals. Thus, the model predicts that a mature industry will be populated by a mixture of enterprises - larger more productive enterprises and smaller less productive ones. Thus, this and other more recent models raise the possibility that industry, in fact, is not dominated by very large enterprises and, consequently, may not be highly concentrated. Ickes and Ryterman suggest that the maximum and minimum scales of enterprises in a centrally planned industry were determined by an interplay of technology and the costs of centrally planned production. All else equal, these administrative costs increase with the number of levels of hierarchy as well as well as the span of control at each level. Therefore, these costs are viewed as favoring the creation of fewer larger enterprises than would be created in a market setting. We believe that diseconomies of scale that are created in very large enterprises quickly outweighed the administrative advantages of very large firms. Larger firms require more layers of hierarchy to 'Mhe cassic reference is Berliner [1957]. Keren [19931 provides a survey of this literature. 4 monitor production, quickldy adding to costs. Moreover, small firms were not required to play the important role - in fostering innovation - tat they play.in market economies. In market economies, small firms enter the market, experiment with a new product or process, then grow or fail based on their success. Under central planning, a different process of economic selection was implemented, one in which product innovation was typically produced in larger science-production associations. Therefore, we believe that ministers economized on coordination costs predominantly by choosing not to build very small enterprises. Industrial concentration, in turn, is determined by the interplay of technology and the costs of centrally planned production, on the one hand, and demand, measured by the size of output targets, on the other. For a given technology and costs of coordination, industrial concentration will be higher in industries that were presented with lower aggregate output targets. This feature suggests that, to some extent, important industries for which product demand was high are less likely to be concentrated than less important industries.7 More importantly, given the large size of the former Soviet Union, this feature suggests that industrial concentration in national markets is unlikely to exist. 1.2 Problems with the Conventional Wisdom In par-, the conventional view has been so compelling historically because some empirical evidence does appear to support it. In this section, we explain why we believe this evidence is misleading. Heidi Kroll, in recent work [19911, presents some evidence for bodt large firm sizes and industrial concentration in the Soviet Union. Concerning enterprise size, she states that, since the :960's, the size of Soviet enterprises has been increasing, The average number of employees per enterprise rose to 813 in 1987-88, and 73.4 percent of the labor force now work in enterprises employing more than 1000 workers; indeed, enterprises with 10,000 workers or more employ 21.6 percent of the labor force, while those with 500 workers or fewer employ only 14.9 percent of the labor force...3 7However, we do recognize that some small industries may have strategic importance to an economy. Kroll [1991: 147]. Induarld Cencrntraion She gives many of the conventional reasons to expLain why Soviet enterprises were so large. While these numbers seem compelling, they are haed if not impossible to interpret without comparison with other countries. Eva Ehrlich [1985: 267-295] does compare enterprise and establishment sizes between capitalist and socialist economies. While her survey does not include data from the Soviet Union, her methodology and conclusions are relevant to our study. She employs two measures to describe industrial structure: average employment and size distribution of firms. Her tables show quite clearly that average enterprise sizes in the socialist economies, especially Poland and Hungary, are greater than in even the 'large-type' capitalist economies. The tables also show that size distributions of firms vary distinctly between the two types of economies: the socialist economies have a greater percentage of employment in the large firms and a lower percentage in the small firms than the capitalist countries do. Ehrlich relates the following metaphor for socialist industrial structure, A Hungarian economist compares the size structure of the Hungarian economic system to a pyramid turned upside down, characterized not by large enterprises relying on a broad base of small- and medium-size firms but, on the contrary, by a preponderance of big enterprises and a sirnificant lack of small and medium ones.2 Given their understanding of the distinct size distributions, what Ehrlich and Kroll fail to do is to weight or correct the averages they use according to the different size distributions and ihe different overall numbers of firms in these economies. We can illustrate this problem with a simple example. Consider two economies, each with 10 firms of different sizes, but distributed equally -across the two economies so that the average firm size is the same. Now, give one economy, A, 10 more firms all of which are smaller than the smallest original firm, and leave economy B the same. The average firm size in A is now much smaller, but that does not mean that economy B has more large firms than A. In. other words, this change does not winvert" B's pyramid, but rather just builds to the bottom of A's. In this paper, we try to draw a clear picture of size structure both by using country comparisons and by correcting or explaining our measures in terms of size distribution. Kroll also provides evidence of industrial concentration. According to Goskomstat SSSR, more than one-third of the most important types of machine- building products are produced by a single enterprise, and approximately the same share is produced by only two enterprises.. .According to Gossnab, 80 percent of the volume of output in machine building is manufactured by monopolists, and 77 percent of machine-building 'Ehrlich [1985: 294]. 6 Industdn Ciucantnadon enterprises are monopolists.. .Another statistic from Gossnab is that about 2,000 eniterprises in the country are the sole producers of.a specific type of product... The World Bank [1992: 82] provides even more startling statistics. Under the former regime, the State Conunittee for Material Technical Supply, Gossnab, organized the delivery of 7,664 distinct product groups. According to the World Bank, 77 percent of these products were produced by single enterprises." These stsics measure a specific type of concentration-product concentration-that is, they measure concentration in terms of the ability of the consumer to find alternative suppliers of the exact same product. Due to central planning, however, product categories in the former Soviet Union were defined very narrowly. In order for the plinners to ensure that the input needs of each producer would be met. they (or the appropriate industrial minister) assigned very specific targets for each intermediate good. For example, in principle, the output target for one centimeter nails would be distinct from the target for two centimeter nails. As a consequence, the number of different product categories used by planners in the former Soviet Union was enormous. Moreover, enterprises specialized in production more highly than in the West.12 Under central planning, there was no incentive, let alone authority, for the enterprise to diversify its production. Thus, while concentration measured in terms of products will naturally appear greater than concentration measured at a more aggregated level, this disaggregation effect is exaggerated in the Soviet case." In this context, the statistics quoted above are not all that surprising. "Kroll [1991: 144-145]. "Kahn and Peck [1991; 62-67] also discuss the prevalence of monopoly in Soviet industry. '2Granick [19671 is the classic reference on the forces that went into the design of enterprises and factories in the Soviet metal fabricating industry. One of his important insights was the link between product specialization and scale (1967: 361: "If each plant were to limit its output to a single product - - or to a small range of products if its output of one item would exceed the total planned consumption of the entire USSR - and concentrate all its facilities on such production, then each plant could gain economies of scale." "This point is illustrated, albeit unwittingly, by the IMF-World Bank-OECD-EBRD joint study on the Soviet economy [1991: 16]: "Industrial production in most sectors tends to be highly concentrated in one or a few enterprises. For example, in almost two-thirds of the 38 product groups included under sledge-press machines, the largest enterprise accounted for 75 percent ore more of total production in 1988..." The key point, however, is that with the demise of central planning enterprises that produce different types of sledge-press machines can compete against each other. 7 lgddrd Cohwiado The other type of concentration one can measure is tndusty concentration, that is, concentration measured in terms of the ability of the producer to supply substitute or directly competing products in the short term. This measure is a broader measure than the one abve, requiring enterprises to be classified and compared based on their industry rather than the specific, products they produce. It is based on the assumption that enterprises compete by producing the same products, producing substitute products, or by being able to easily alter production in order to make the same or substitute products. In a market seting, where an enterprise's choice of product mix is not centrally determined, this approach more correcty measures potential competiftion between firms that produce similar types of products. Potential competition is an important feature of an industrial structure. In a decentralized enviromnent, the threat of entry, most easily from other firms producing similar products, often serves to discipline existing firms in a particular product market. If existing firms set prices too high (or quantities too low), the incentive for near competitors to enter the product market and share in oligopoly rents is raised. Thus, if a market is contestable, competitive conditions may exist even if only one or a few firms produce a product. The question, then, is which measure is most appropriate for this analysis. During the Soviet period, there was no competition and little opportunity for enterprise directors to choose their product mix. Now, with enterprise reform, decisions about product mix are decentralized, and there is the potential for competition. In fact, evidence from an assortment of surveys on enterprise behavior suggests that some enterprises, both state-owned and privatized, are adapting their product mix in order to survive. Thus, we believe that measures of industry concentration more accurately reflect the incentives related to competition in the economy. Furthermore, from a practical perspective, studies of market economies typically use industry measures rather than product measures to discuss concentration and competition. Not only does this suggest that industry measures are more appropriate; it means that by using industry measures, we are able to compare Russia to other countries. Kahn and Peck [19911 also find that measures of product concentration exaggerate the role of monopoly and oligopoly in the Russian economy. They provide data on the number of industries in Russia that appear to be concentrated, and compare these statistics to similar ones for the United States. They find, as we do, that a larger number of industries in Russia appear to be concentrated. The problem with their analysis, however, is that it fails to take into account the importance of these B laraatlh CoImCmraUo industries."' As we) demonstrate, below, this correction is critical to understanding the degree of industrial concentr;ition that actually exists i the Russian economy. 2. Data and Methodology We compile statistics on industrial concentration in the Russian Federation using data collected for the 1989 Soviet Census of Industry. This data set includes all civilian enterprises engaged in production activities defined by the Soviets as industrial. For a summary of the characteristics of enterprises in the data set, see Table 1. The enterprises in this data set are classified based on the primary conunodity they produce and, correspondingly, are assigned a U.S. Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) code." As our primary concern is industrial concentration, we focus our attention at the four-digit SIC level."' Further disaggregation would take us into the realm of product concentration which, as we have argued above, is of less interest. Typically, in studies such as ours, sales are used as the principal measure of a firm's size. Unfortunately, in countries such as the former Soviet Union, data measured in value terms do not provide useful measures of a firm's activity. Aggregate measuves of economic behavior that are expressed in value terms have ambiguous meaning because prices were determiined by administrative flat, and not by market interactions. Thus, although we provide some statistics based on sales, we primarily use employment to measure the market position of firms within an industry. Our choice of 1989 was dictated by circumstance; that is the year for which we have the data. There are, however, some distinct advantages to this year. The survey methodology used by "4Kahn and Peck [1991: 65] acknowledge this problem, but did not have the data needed to properly weight industries according to their importance in the economy. "Unfbrtunately, we do not know the industrial code assigned to the enterprises by Goskomstat (the State Statistical Office). Consequently, we cannot aggregate our data into the standard branch divisions used in Soviet publications, which are quoted often in western analyses. Thus, for example, we are not able to look at machine building as a separate branch. "Although many enterprises are assigned codes at the five-digit level, we use four-digit codes in our analysis. We base our decision on two factors. First, comparison at the four-digit level reveals evidence of competition and potential competition within an industry, while comparison at the five- digit lcvel would reveal information about product competition only. Moreover, this type of analysis is nearly always conducted at the four-digit level for the U.S. and other western countries. Thus, analysis at the four-digit level allows us to evaluate industrial concentration in the Russian Federation in a broader context. 9 lnad uifa Coucmatmtfou Goskomstar (the State Statistical Office) was based on central planning institutions. As those institutions began to deteriorate, the quality ;f the survey frame and data also began to deteriorate. Analysts are thus faced with a tradeoff. Earlier years most likely orovide more accurate data, but are of less interest for their implications about the transition. In our assessment, 1989 was the last year in which Goskomstat was able to conduct a survey at an sufficient level of quality for this analysis. Fortnately, 1989 constiutes a good base year to assess the initial conditions of reform. The staistics for the Russian Federion are presentea in context of statistics for the U.S. and, to a lesser extent, for the O.E.C.D. We chose the U.S. as tie dominant country for comparison because of its size and level of industrial development. The statistics on industrial structure in the U.S. are based on U.S. Census Bureau data1, usually from 1987, although we do make some comparisons which use other years; we specify when 1987 is not the comparator. 2.1 The Unit of Analysis Conducting comparisons of industrial structure between the Russia and the United States raises issues of the proper unit of comparison. The U.S. Census Bureau collects data at the company and establishment levels, where an establishment is defined as all plants owned by a company that are engaged in similar activities at one location. Russian data, however, are collected at the enterprise level. Technically, an enterprise is a company. However, it differs from a western company in an important way. Unlike companies, enterprises are seldom multi-divisional firms in the western sense. Although they may produce several products for sale, these products are typically in closely related product groups. However, in addition, many enterprises produce products that do not reach the market. Often, enterprises are vertically integrated, producing output that they consume as inputs. Also, many enterprises engage in side activities such as farming to provide food for workers. Thus, in practice, Russian enterprises might be quite diversified."' Many enterprises are made up of several "We use data from both the Census of Manufacturers, Concentration Ratios in Manufacturing, 1987 and the 1987 Enterprise Statistics. "'A good example is the production of machinery. According to Hewett [1988: 172]: 'Some departments in nonmachinebuilding enterprises also produce machinery. Forty-five percent of all metalworking equipment in the Soviet Union can be found there, a stock that by itself exceeds in value the entire capital stock of the U.S. machinebuilding sector." 10 radutd Coceutwie plants (zawd), often in different cities (and, during the Soviet period, even in different republics). Hence, in certain respects, an enterprise is ldss than a company, but more than an establishment.' For evaluating firm size and aggregate concentration, we compare Russian enterprises to U.S. companies, where U.S. companies are measured by their domesic employment. Very large enterprises in Russia are almost always multi-plant enterprises and, consequiently, are more like companies than estdblishments. Moreover, for the discussion of policy implications related to firm size and aggregate concentration, company is a more insightful measure. In contrast, for evaluating industry concentration, we compare Russian enterprises to U.S. establishment-groups. Establishment- groups are all domestic establishments in a single company that are classified with the same 4-digit SIC code.?° The U.S. Bureau of the Census uses this unit to partition the company and allocate its activities to different industries. This partition enables Census to compute concentration statistics that reflect the ability of domestic producers to supply substitute or direcdy competing products in the short term. To the extent that Russian enterprises are like establishments (in that their priniary products for sale are closely related), this comparison is direct. To the extent that Russian enterprises are, in fact, diversified companies, concentration measures will overstate the level of concentration in the Russian economy. Consequently, using the enterprise data actually biases the Russian statistics against our case. The use of enterprise data does raise an important issue, however. Beginning with a decree of Brezhnev in 1973, Soviet enterprises were organized into associations (obyedineniya).2 The enterprises that comprise an obyedineniye were operated under a single management22 Hence, when 1"he extreme vertical integration of enterprises presents an important additional source of potential competition in the Russian economy. In our analysis, we measure concentration based on the industry to which the enterprise belongs. To the extent that the enterpr.se produces products that belong to a different SIC code, we are understaing the potential for competition. 2Ihese statistics are based on establishment level data which are then aggregated into the establishment-group unit of measure. The concenation ratios that we present at the two-dgit level are based on company data with company as the unit of measure. The bias is not great here since few companies will have establishments in two different two-digit industries. 2'The primary purpose of the reform was to reduce the administrative burdens on the planners, as discussed above. 'According to Conyngham [1982: 228] the average number Of enterprises in an obyedinemiye varied across sectors: "in the machine-building industries, the ptoduction unions average five or six enterprises. In light industry, the average is nine... in the chemical, coal, and other extractive industries, however, (associations) usually incorporate twenty-five or more enterprises." 11 lisdEsgrfo Concemnidon we examine enterprise data, we may be treating units that belong to a single, larger structure as if they were independent units. It is important to keep in mind, however, that our purpose in this paper is to examine industrial strmcture&in Russia as it pertains to the development of a market economy. In this context, enterprises seem to be the appropriate unit of analysis, because these are the units that are typically being privatized. 2.2 The Military Industrial Complex (MIC) The primary difference between the Russian and the U.S. data sets is the fact that the Russian data set includes data on the civilian sector only. The military-industrial complex (MIC) in Russia is very important Consequently, we cannot simply ignore its presence in our analysis. To deal with this problem, we have assumed that the industrial structure of the MIC closely resembles that of heavy industry in the civilian sector. We then use the observed distributions of heavy industry in the civilian sector to produce esimates of the industrial structure of the MIC. We base our choice on the observation that the process of industrial evolution in the MIC closely resembled the process of evolution of heavy industry in the civilian sector. In fact, our calculations suggests that the mean size of firms in the military-industrial sector is smaller than the mean size of firms in civilian heavy industry?. In our analysis, we estimate the total number of firms in the military-industrial complex?' and assume the distribution of these firms by size resembles the distribution in civilian heavy industry. Although this process produces an upward bias in the distribution of firms in the military- industrial complex (toward larger firns than is statistically evident), we feel this more conservative approach is necessary to persuade readers to our point of view. Specifically, to estimate the size distribution of enterprises in the military-industrial complex, we computed the size distribution of enterprises in the following civilian branches: chemicals,. industrial machinery and equipment, electronics, transport equipment, and instruments. We selected these branches based on our belief that enterprises in the military-industrial complex produce similar 2'The average firm size for our proxy group of branches (chemicals, industrial machinery and equipment, electronics, transport equipment, and instruments) is 1,750. We know that adding the MIC to our data would add 5,309 enterprises and 7,979,161 workers. This implies an average firm size of 1,503 for the MIC. The largest enterprise in Russia, for example, is Autovaz, a civilian, not a military enterprise. 'Including fuels and energy production. 12 Inasdd ncenwtean types of products.2? Then, we applied this distribution to the number of enterprises that are kmown to exist in the miliary-ipdistrial sector.' See Table 2 for more detailed information. Although this method is useful in correcting biases inrroduced in estimates of enterprise size, we do not use it in calculations of industry concentration. While omission of enterprises that are part of the military-industrial complex may bias statistics related to firm size downward (for example, the average size of the 100 largest firms), it is unlikely to do so in the case of measures of industrial concentration. Enterprises in the military-industrial complex are of two types. Some produce products that compete with those produced by enterprises in the civilian sector. In these cases, our (unadjusted) statistics overstate the level of concentration in Russia, a bias that only strengthens the force of our conclusions Alternatively, some enterprises in the military-industrial complex produce products that are not produced in the civilian sector. In these cases, we suggest the reader look to levels of concentration that are measured in heavy civilian industry for a prediction of the levels of concentration in these industries. 3. Myths and Reality In this section, we discuss some of the most commonly held myths concerning firm size and concentration in the Russian economy. We begin with a discussion of the size distribution of enterprises. We then turn to industrial concentration at the national level, and finally to concentration at the industry level. 3.1 Size Distribution of Enterprises The conventional view of industrial evolution in Russia emphasizes the dominant role played by very large firms in the economy. As a result, it views Russian industry as highly concentrated. In 2'We did not adjust the implicit weights assigned to any of the civilian branches in the computation of the size distribution. We base this decision on the observation that the military- industrial complex may have beer. fairly autarkic; as a consequence, its structure should reflect an industrial balance not unlike that observed in the remainder of the economy. 'We note that the mean size of enterprises in heavy civilian industry is larger than the mean size of enterprises in the military-industrial complex. As a consequence, when we use the size distribution of firms in heavy civilian industry to approximate the size distribution of the military-industrial complex, we unavoidably inflate the number of workers employed in this sector. Specifically; official data suggests that 7,979,161 workers are employed in the military-industrial complex; however, when we use the distribution of employment in heavy civilian industry to estimate the size of firms in the military-industrial complex, we estimate that 9,289,726 workers are employed in the sector. 13 lnduadagr C.ace&ubiea. contrast, the more recent work on industrial evolution suggests that Russian industry is fairly heterogeneous in terms of size, opening the possibility that industry is not dominated by very large firms and, in fact, may not be highly concentrated. Clearly, then, the size distribution of enterprises is at the very heart of our discussion of industrial concentration in Russia. Thus, we begin by presenting evidence related to the size distribution of firms. Myth 1: Many Russian enterprises are very large. The Russian economy suffers from gigantomania. Reality 1: In fact, Russia's largest enterprises are actually smaller than the largest finns in many O.E.C.D. countries. In Table 3, we compare the size of the largest finrs in O.E.C.D countries with that of Russia. The ten largest civflian firms in Russia employed an average of 62,649 workers. We estimate that the ten largest firms, including those in the military-industrial complex, employed an average of approximatly 92,698 workers (table 8).27 We can compare these average-employment statistics to those for the top ten firms in a sample of other countries using 1985 statistics found in Scherer and Ross [1990: 63j. Table 3 shows that these statistics for Russia are notably smaller than. those for the United States, Japan, West Germany, the United Kingdom, and France, and, on average, about the same as that for Holland. The result is similar when one compares the average firm sizes of the top 20 firms in these countries; that is, the average-employment of the top 20 Russian enterprises is notably smaller. In fact, there are only 113 civilian and approximately 217 total industrial enterprises in Russia that have 10,000 workers or more. These findings are actually not that surprising. Most of the very large companies in the O.E.C.D. countries are multinational enterprises that have both multinational labor markets - they 2tTo estimate the number of enterprises in the military-industrial complex that employ 10,000 workers or more, we calculated the percent of civilian enterprises in heavy industry that employed 10,000 to 19,999 workers, 20,000 to 29,000 workers, ..., 90,000 to 100,000 workers, and more than 100,000 workers and applied these percents to the number of enterprises in the military-industrial complex. To estimate the size of the enterprises in the military-industrial complex, we calculated the mean size of civilian enterprises in each size class and assigned the mean to all the non-civilian enterprises widiin the class. We note hiat, due to the small number of firms involved in the calculation of the ten largest finns in the economy (cited above), the particular estimate is subject to large potential error. 14 J'udIL&WI Cmeawuauude employ people at home and abroad - as well as multinational product markets for their goods. They tend to operate in environments in which communication and other infrastructure facilitating large- scale organization is good. Thus, their large size can represent an efficient scale of production. Large Russian enterprises, on the other hand, cannot be considered conventional multi-national firms. While they were often built to serve the C.M.E.A. market, they rarely located production outside national boundaries. But, there is no reason to conclude a priori that their sizes are too large for their national and regional markets. The conventional belief, or myth, that Russian firms are unnaturally large is often used to suggest that they must, in fact, be inefficiently large. This conclusion then supports the position of those who favor breaking up Russian enterprises during transition. Our evidence shows, however, that it is incorrect to assume that Russian enterprises are inefficient based on size alone. If Russian enterprises are inefficient, their inefficiency likely comes from internal organization rather than from scale of production. The inernal organization of many Russian firms reflects historic circumstances, rather than market conditions. The assertion that Russian enterprises are "too large' is really an assertion about the shape of the cost functions of these units. Without such data one cannot really address the issue. But the comparison with other O.E.C.D. countres does provide some perspective on the size of Russian enterprises. Organizational inefficiencies can be found in firms of all sizes and require a much different set of remedies tan simply breaking up large firms into their constituent plants. Myth 2: The size distribution of Russian enterprises can be represented by an inverted pyramid. There are many large enterprises and very few medium or small enterprises. Reality 2: The size distnrbution is better represented by an uprightpyramid. The significant difference between the industrial structure of market economies and that of Russia is that Russia lacks the myriad of very small firms found in market economies. 15 Indartlol Coacentradon Tables 4, 5, and 6 show the distributions of Russian and U.S. manufacturing enterprise?s by enterprise employment.' In table 4, we see that, while Russia does have more large finns and the U.S. has dramatically more small firms, for both countries the number of firms as a percentage of total firms in a size class decreases as the size of firms in the class increases. Thus, the image created by the industrial structure in both Russia and the U.S. is an upright pyramid, in which many smaller finns support fewer larger firms. In table 5, we see that an inverted pyramid is present in the Russian case, but it describes the distribution of small firms only. That is, the number of firms as a percentage of total small firms in a size class increases with the size of firms in the class in the case of Russia, but decreases in the case of the U.S. We consider this observation very important. It supports the conclusion from the historical evidence that there was, in effect, a lower bound on enterprise size in the former Soviet Union. The relative absence of small enterprises in Russian industry suggests that comparing Russia and the United States by looking at average firms size for industry as a whole may be misleading If -we take the arithmetic mean, for example, we find that manufacturing firms in Russia employ an average of 670 workers in the.civilian sector and an estimated average of 925 workers when firms in the military-industrial complex also are considered. In contrast, manufacturng firms in the U.S. enploy an average of 70 workers. We can correct for the small-frm bias by computing average emnployment per firm for all manufacturing firms employing above a lower bound of 249 employees. In Russia, these firms employ an average of 1,297 workers in the civilian sector and an estimated average of 1,621 workers in both sectors, while, in the U.S., these manufacturing firms employ 2Manufacturing enterprises are a subset of industrial enterprises. See table-l for a breakdown of all industrial enterprises in the Census into one-digit SIC codes. 2-We base the size categories on the current Russian definitions, with one exception. In tables 4 through 6, we define small enterprises based on the U.S. definition of 1 to 249 workers.. (Consequently, medium firms begin with 250 workers.) The 'very small' categories are based on the categories in U-S. tables. In further tables which just present Russian data, small is 1 to 199 employees. To- estimate the number of non-civilian firms in each size class, we calculated the share of enterprises in heavy civilian industry in each size class and applied these shares to the total number of firms in the military-industrial complex. Similarly, we used mean employment by enterprises in heavy civilian industry in each size class as the approximate employment of non-civilian firms assigned to the class. 16 lndWd Cancuantles 2,103 workers.30 Average employment by manufacturing firms with 50 workers or more is 761 workers in the civilian sector in Russia, an estimated 1,025 workers in both sectors, and 498 workers in the U.S?1 The distribution of employment (rather than firms) across size categories presents a more striking difference between the two countries (the lower panel of table 4). In Russia 91.5 percent of civilian employment and an estimated 94.5 percent of total employment in manufacturing is provided by enterprises with employment of 250 or greater, while only 73.1 percent of U.S. manufacturing employment is provided by similar firms. But, these statistics obscure the dominant role of extra- large firms in the provision of employment in the U.S. A closer examination of the size distribution of firms in the two countries reveals this role. Three-fourths of Russian manufacturing employment falls in the middle of the distribution, that is, in medium and large enterprises. In contrast, two-thirds of U.S. manufacturng employment falls in the tails, in sinall and extra-large firms. Strikingly, 40.2 percent of the U.S. employment is provided by extra-large firms, while only 15.3 percent of Russian civilian employment and an estimated 20.5 percent of total manufacturing employment are provided by similar firms. Thus, in comparison with the U.S., the Russian economy is not dominated by gigantic firms and Russian employment is not dominated by employment in very large firms. The importance of medium and large enterprises in Russian industry is also evident in table 7, where we break down the size distribution of firms for separate branches of civilian industry in Russia.32 This table also snows that production by very large firms is mostly concentrated in a few industrial branches. Just four branches contain 84 of the 113 extra-large enterprises in the civilian sector, and one of these, mining, is a non-manufacturing branch. The other three are industrial machinery and equipment, primary metals, and transportation equipment. These branches not only have a large share of their employment in extra-large enterprises - an average of 45 percent - they also represent a large share of industrial employment - an average of 8.7 percent each. The results from table 7 suggest that, for some branches, restructuring, especially reorganization of the large enterprises, will have a significant effect on their relevant labor markets. But" this is clearly not true 'Mhe total numbers of firms used for these calculations are 8,131 for civilian manufacturing in Russia, 12,131 for total manufacturing, and 7,454 for the U.S. '"The total numbers of firms used for these calculations are 15,066 for civilian and 20,233 for total manufacturing in Russia, and 37,604 for manufacturing in the U.S. 2The branch distinctions for the manufacturing enterprises are 2-digit SIC categories. The other branches are 1-digit groups, except for construction and mining which have been divided into two. 17 IndaadL ConecatnmIon for all branches of industry, nor even for branches with large shares of industrial employment. The other branches with high shares of national ihdustrial employment - Food and Kindred Products, Lumber and Wood Products, Stone, Clay, and Glass, and Textile Mill Products - have zero to little employment in extra-large firms. Thus, while restructuring in the industries in these branches will significantly impact the economy, the issues involved will be somewhat different. 3.2 Industrial Concentration There are several measures of industrial concentration that are commonly utilized. Ownership concentration measures how diffuse is the ownership of industry. Russian industry in 1989 was entirely state-owned, leaving little to study?' Product concentration measures the degree to which products are produced by few or many enterprises. This measure, however, says very little about potential competition, because it disaggregates markets too finely, especially given the very distinct product categories used in Soviet planning. Moreover, given the fact that central planners deternined the assortment plans of enterprises, product concentration says very little about what enterprises can produce. Rather, it is more a measure of the assortment planners and ministers chose. Consequently, we focus our attention on measures of concentration both in the aggregate and by industrial branch. The former essentially measures how large enterprises are relative to the size of the economy. The latter is a measure of market power. We consider these in turn. 3.2.1 Aggregate Concentration Perhaps the most salient component of the conventional wisdom is the belief that the Russian economy is dominated by large enterprises. Myth 3: The largest Russian enterprises account for an unusually large share of national production and employnrent. Reality 3: The largest enterprises account for only a moderate share of national production and employment. 3The Russian privatization plan, since it gives advantages to insiders, wil most likely lead to a rather diffuse ownership at least in the first stages. It will be interesting to study what happens to ownership concentration in the faure. 18 Indua1 Concahude Table 8 presents statistics describing the role, of the largest enterprises in industrial employment and production. The ten largest enterprises by employment account for 4.6 percent of national civilian employment; the top 100, 16.3 percent. Our estimates suggest, that if enterprises in the military-industrial complex were included in our sample, the top 100 enterprises in the entire economy would account for a smaller share, approximately 14.3 percent of total employment. Scherer and Ross present aggregate concentration shares for the United States for 1982r; table 9 is a supplemented version of their table. They show that, in the U.S., the largest 100 manufacturing corporations accounted for 23.8 percent of total U.S. employment. In Russia, sales of the largest 100 civilian firms accounted for 21.6 percent of total sales, while sales of the largest 100.firms in the U.S. accounted for 31.8 percent of total sales of civilian goods. The comparisons for the largest 200 firms offer the same conclusions. Table 10 compares aggregate concentration in the U.S. and Russia at higher level&. In spite of the fact that Russia has 1118 the number of manufacturing 'irms as the U.S., the manufacturing four-firn concentration ratio for Russia is three percentage points lower than for the U.S., and this margin persists in the other groupings as well. Thus, aggregate concentration in Russia is less than in the market economy of the U.S. These results relate to those above which show that enterprises are not as gigantic as we once presumed. Table 8 also shows how aggregate civilian coricentration is distributed across industries and regions. The top 10 civilian firms only represent four branches; in fact, these firms represent only four industries at the 4-digit S.I.C. level. This concentration of Russia's major enterprises in a few number of branches and industries is also true when examining the top 25, 50, or 100 civilian enterprises. These major enterprises seem to be rather broadly distributed across oblasts (provinces), however. Seven different oblasts have enterprises in the top 10, and these fall in six different economic regions. Thirty-nine out of the 78 oblasts in Russia contain enterprises with 10,000 workers or more, and these fall in all 12 of the economic regions. Thus, the major enterprises are not geographically concentrated. Only one oblast, Kemerovskaya, stands out as having a large share 'Scherer and Ross [1990: 591. Scherer and Ross explain that aggregate concentration in the U.S., in terms of domestic manufacturing activities alone, has risen insignificantly since the 1960's. Thus, the use of 1982 data for the U.S. in comparison with 1989 data for Russia does not present a significant problem. 19 IndusUla Cacentraai of the major civilian enterprises. It has six of the top 25 civilian firms and seven of the top 50 civilian firms. 3.3 Industry Concentration Prior to presenting our evidence, we should say a few words about measuring, comparing,and thinking about industry concentration Any comparison of concentration between the U.S. and Russia is tricky because the U.S. has both many more industries and many more firms than Russia. In manufacturing alone, the U.S. has 448 industries at tde 4-digit S.I.C. level, while Russia has only 350 4-digit industries.6 Even when using percentages of concentrated industries versus actual numbers, the comparison could be biased by the type of industries that Russia does not have. The U.S. also has almost 18 times as many firms. In terms of firms per industry, the U.S. has an average of 685.5 firms per industry in manufacturing, while Russia's average is only 49.1. In these simple terms, Russia's production is clearly more concentrated. This does not mean, however, that Russia's industrial markets are necessarily non-competitive. We employ three measures of industry concentration. The most well known is the four-firm concentration ratio (CR4). This is a ratio of the sum of the measure for the largest four firms (according to the same measure) to the sum of the measure over all firms in the industry. More specifically, we usually calculate the sum of employment in the four firms with the most employment in the industry as a percent of the sum of employment in all the firms in the industry. We calculate CRB's in the same manner for the largest eight firms in an industry?' We also classify enterprises according to how many enterprises there are in that industry, that is, we identify monopolists, duopolists, oligopolists, and others which fall into larger categories. Finally, we use the Russian measure of a 'domidant' firm; a dominant firm is one which accounts for a 35 percent or greater share of its industry's market in terms of employment or sales. In the tables 35Kemerovskaya oblst is located on the east border of Western Siberia in the south. MThis number for the U.S. does include military production and thus likely includes industries which are not counted in the Russian number. "Without information about costs we cannot calculate Lerner Indices. We calculate concentration ratios rather than Herfindahl-Hirschman Indices (HHI's). As Scherer and Ross explain, CR4's and HHI's are highly correlated (Scherer and Ross 11990: 74]), and the analysis we do is not precise enough to warrant the more complicated statistic. 20 Indaad CoMceanden looking at Russia alone; and unless otherwise specified, all measures are calculated at the four-digit industry level. That means we report the highest possible measure of industry concentration. We therefore implicitly define the relev;ant market for competition as the four-digit industry level. This assumption is no more than a guess or a proxy. For some industries, the relevant markets are more distinct, for some more aggregated.? As we explain earlier in the paper, we intentionally measure industry concentration instead of product concentration. The four-digit level is then the most disaggregated market we can choose. In the case where the relevant markets are larger, we actually overstate concentration. We try to con;rol for this problem in the U.S.-Russia comparisons by calculating the statistics at the same level in each country. Myth 4: Russian industry is highly monopolized. These monopolies are very large enterprises. Reaity 4 When measured at the national level, there are very few monopolistic enterprises in Russia, and most of these firms are relatively small. Table 11 shows that only 43 of the 21,391 civilian Russian enterprises are monopolies in their four-digit industries at the national level. While this represents 10.6 percent of all industries, it only represents 0.2 percent of civilian firms, 0.2 percent of civilian employment, and 0.2 percent of civilian output This measure of industy concentration and, thus, potential competition is much lower than the statistics often quoted, for example the ones from Koll [19911 above, which is that around 80 percent of Russian products are produced by monopolies. Table 11 also shows that, while the mean size of a monopoly is 726 workers, the median is only 285 workers. Even 726 workers is less than the means in all other competition classes, except the class with the most number of finms. Looking at table 12, we see that there are no extra-large firms that are monopolies, or duopolies for that matter. In fact, 32 of the 43 monopolies have less than 1,000 employees. If we define oligopoly quite liberally to mean four or fewer firms in an industry, we see in table 11 that, while 26.4 percent of industries in this sample are oligopolies, they only account for 1.1 percent of all these firms and 1.9 percent of all this employment. At the same time, 70.3 percent of firms and 41.8 percent of employment falls in enterprises in industries which have more than 100 'Scherer and Ross [1990: 73] offer a good discussion of defining markets according to SIC codes. 21 liadarld CDnecaindo firms. The highest employment mean is in the industry category with five to ten firms, and table 12 shows that the plurality (and one-third of allj extra-large firms are in industries with 21 to 50 firms. Mammoth monopolies simply do not dominate the civilian industrial sector. Myth 5: Russian industry is heavily concentrated. Reality 5.1: Measured at the two-digit level, U.S. manufacturing is at least as concentrated as Russian manufacturing. Table 13 lists CR4's and CR8's by employment for companies in two-digit manufacturing branches in the U.S. and Russia." If one took the argument seriously that the industrial structure of Russia was arbitrary, then one would expect there to be no correlation between the concentr.tion ratios in Russia and the United States. In fact, however, the Pearson correlations between the U.S. and Russia for the two sets are .72 and .82 respectively. These results suggest that, in terms of the larger firms in these branches, the U.S. and Russian industrial structures are actually quite similar - a surprising result if one believes that the Russian industrial structure should appear artificial or unnatural as a consequence of central planning. Further, the mean CR4 and CR8 for the U.S. are both greater than those for Russia; the hypothesis that they are equal is rejected with 97 percent confidence or better. Table 14 presents similar information, but with the CR4's and CR8's calculated by sales rather than employment. Here again, the Pearson statistic shows positive correlation with values of .67 and .77. While the mean ratios for the U.S. are greater than those for Russia, in this case one cannot reject the null that they are equal. This is still a surprising result when one expects Russian manufacturing to be much more concentrated. These tables present another interesting comparison - that between the CR's calculated in terms of employment and those calculated in terms of sales within the two countries. In all four comparisons, U.S. and Russia for four-firm and eight-firm, the concentration ratios calculated in terms of sales are higher than those for employment. But, this difference is much greater for Russia than for the U.S. The null hypothesis that the U.S. four-firm concentration ratios for employment 'Comparisons of the U.S. and Russia are potentially biased in favor of the result that the U.S. is less concentrated. The reason is that the U.S. Census Bureau does not publish concentration ratios when those numbers might reveal information about specific enterprises in an industry. These missing data then are concentration ratios that are quite high; six such observations are deleted from this analysis. This bias causes the analysis to understate concentration in the U.S. 22 lndaltu CenwaulXn and sales have equal means cannot be rejected, but the null for the other three sets can be rejected, and for the Russian numbers, the confidence level is greater than 99 percent. The mean concentration ratios calculated by sales in the Russian series are at least six percentage points higher than those calculated in terms of employment, while for the U.S. the difference is only 1.8 points. This finding implies that, relative to the U.S., the large firms in Russian manufacturing represent a larger percentage of output than they do of labor. This conclusion continues to hold if we look at industry as a whole. Extra-large enterprises in civilian manufacturing account for 25.6 percent of manufacturing output and only 15.3 percent of manufacturing labor; extra-large enterprises in all of civilian industry account for 22.9 percent of industrial output and just 17.3 percent of industrial labor. The small and .nedium-sized firms, on the other hand, account for a greater percentage of labor than of output. Reality 5.2: Measured at the four-digit level, the industrial structures of the U.S. and Russian manufacturing sectors are quite different, and the Russian sector appears more concentrated. Comparing CR4's across 331 observations of matching U.S. and Russian four-digit industries, we find that the Pearson Correlation is only .06. The mean CR4 for Russian manufacturing is 69 while the mean for the U.S. is 36, and, not surprisingly, the null that the means are equal is rejected with 100 percent probability. It is interesting that the structures of two economies seem to diverge so much when viewed at a lower level of aggregation. Upon examination of the data, we discover that, in striking contrast to the U.S. industrial structure, many industries in Russia, are in fact, very small. Thus, a more meaningful way to compute the Pearson correlations is to weight the comparisons of industrial concentration by industry size. One simple way of weighting is to compare only the predominant industries in Russia with the same industries in the United States. Comparing the ratios for the top 25 percent of industries in Russia in terms of employment, we find that the means are not significantly different; both are about 40. As we take larger groupings of the major industries, the mean CR4 for Russia increases while that for the U.S. remains about the same. Even for the top 75 percent of industries though, the Russian mean is still under 60, that is, on average, concentration is not high enough to be considered a barrier. 23 iadaur Conmman 'Reality 5.3: At the four-digit industry level, many more Russian industries are concentrated than U.S. industries; however these industries account for a minority share of Russian industrial activity. When one thinks about the above analysis, it may not seem significant that the concentration levels are roughly similar between the U.S. and Russia for only the top 25 percent of industries in Russia. Further analysis reveals, however, that the top 25 percent of industries accounts for almost ., 80 percent of employment in the 331-industry sample. The top 75 percent, whose mean CR4 is less than 60, accounts for over 99 percent of the employment. Table 15 presents more statistics on industrial concentration in Russia using the full sample of Russian industries and grouping industries by concentration ratios instead of ordering by employment From this table, we see that 55.2 percent of four-digit industries in all Russian industry have fc z'r- firm concentration ratios of employment of 61 percent or more; 62.1 percent have four-firm ratios of sales of 61 percent or more. This 55.2 percent of industries in the top half of the table represents only 17.5 percent of industrial employment and 17.4 percent of industrial sales. To provide a context for these statistics, we compare them to those for the U.S. Table 16 offers a comparison of U.S. and Russian four-digit industry concentration in manufacturing using categories of four-firm concentration ratios.' Here we see that, in the U.S., only 17.6 percent of industries have CR4's of 60 percent or greater, while in Russia, 64.8 percent do. There is little doubt that more Russian manufacturing industries are concentrated. However, the 17.6 percent of industries in the U.S. account for 19.8 percent otvalue added, while the 64.8 percent in.Russia account for only 30.9 percent of sales and 25.0 percent of employment. In other words, the percentage of industries in the U.S. that are concentrated is much more indicative of shares of economic activity than in Russia. Thus, the statistics describing the number of concentrated industriec are misleading whtn assessing the importance of concentration to the economy. Rea5Lty 5A: Concentrated industries in Russia have a different industrial structure than industry in general. 'We use calculations from Scherer and Ross [1990: 83J which are based on 1982 establishment data and use establishment groups as the unit of measure. 24 IaduaI Cwacen-wes Concentrated industries in Russia have proportionately more medium, large, and extra-large enterprises and fewer small ones than in industry in general. This demonstrates that the problem of * very few smalf firms is even more important in concentrated industries. Concentrated industries (defined, for example, as industries with CR4's of over 40 percent) are thus different from other industries, not only in terms of the industries' top enterprises, but also in the overall distribution of enterprises within the industries. This is evident from the data in the bottom half of table 12. In addition, note from table 16 that concentrated industries account for a larger share of output than employment, while in other industries just the opposite is tue. This seems to suggest that enterprises in highly concentrated industries have higher labor productivity than in industry in general. One must be careful about such inferences, however, since they are based on data generated under the system of regulated prices and planned outputs. Reality 5.5: In the set of industries that are highly concentrated, concentration is mostly due to having few firms in the industry rather than to having principal firms in the industry. When industries are arranged by CR4's, into deciles for example, one might expect that the share of total industries in a decile would be roughly similar to the share of total value added or nationa employment in that decile. This is in fact the case for the US. For Russia, on the other hand, while the top decile represents the lowest share of output and employment, it accounts for more four-digit industries than the other three combined.on the top four deciles of industries by concentration ratios (table 15). Table 16 shows a similar distribution - almost half of all industries fall in t.e top category of the CR4 ranges. If we arranged the data in table 16 from quintiles into deciles of concentration ratios, we would find that most of the 45 percent would indeed fall in the 90 to 100 category, but account for a small share of employment and sales. The very high CR4's suggest one of two things: either production in these industries is highly concentrated in the largest firms, or these industries have very few firms. Table 17 shows that the latter is true. One hundred seven of the 125 industries in the 91 to 100 percent decile have four or fewer firms, and none of these industries has more than 10 firms. There is, in fact, a triangle of zeros in the lower left portion of the table - concentrated industries have few firms. No industry with an employment CR4 greater than 60 percent has more than 50 firms. It may seem obvious that this latter explanation is true. But, limited evidence on the U.S. suggests that the opposite is true, Xt is, that high CR4's in the U.S. indicate a high concentration of 25 IuduArts CeizeWung production in the larger firms, but do not necessarily indicate a very small number of firms. Table 18 presents comparisons of sales CR4's and'CRB's for selected four-digit industries in the U.S. and Russia.4' In this selected sample alone, there are two four-digit industries in the top decile wit far more than ten firms - one has 352 firms. Of the 16 industries with CR4's of 60 percent or greater, there are nine with more than 50 firms. Thus, based on this sample evidence alone, we know that a table 17 for the U.S. would not have zeros in the lower left triangle. In all of the 350 industries, of the 53 U.S. industries with CR4's of 60 or greater, there are 19 industries with more than 50 firms, and of the 10 in the top decile (including those with undisclosed ratios), six of them have more than 10 firms-the average is 121 firms. The Russian evidence points to three explanations. The first is that the industries in our data set with few firms have parallel four-digit industries in the defense sector. We know that many civilian goods were produced by enterprises in the military-industrial complex and, thus, are not represented in our data.'2 Where this is the case then, the industries actually have many more firms and are likely less concentrated than our data show. If we had these finms in our data, then, not only would we find fewer concentrated industries, but we would also see that the match up between industries and shares of both employment and output is more even. In other words, it is not that these industries have such a small share of employment and output relative to th- others in our data, but rather we just do not see how much they actually account for. Looking at uble 18, we guess that the exclusion of finns in the military-industrial complex probably explains the high concentration and low firm numbers for household television receivers, semiconductors, and even possibly screw machine products. However, it probably does not explain the concentration in the women's and misses' dresses industry. 'As it is not feasible to include a table with all 350 manufacturing industries, we present a selected sample in 18. To create a "random" sample for comparing the U.S. and Russia, we adopt the selected industries which Scherer and Ross [1990: 77J, with no intention of comparing to Russia, present in their text. The U.S. numbers in our table are updated to 1987, however, and a we change a few of the industries up or down a category in order to exactly match as many industries as possible. We also reordered the listing so that the 1987 CR4's for the U.S. industries are in descending order. '2Another reason why some firms may be missing is that some of these products are consumed by the enterprises that produce them. Therefore, these products never reach the market. This explanation is especially important for critical inputs whose delivery was very uncertain under central planning. To eliminate the uncertainty, enterprises often. developed the internal capacity to produce their inputs ("universalism"). 26 The second explanation is that some industries there were some industries which, Soviet planners intentionally kept smnal. These industries were probably low priority sectors - light industry and consumer goods. This explains both the low mimber of firms and the low share of output and employment. For these industries, then, the conventional wisdom about Russian industrial concentra- tion does hold, although the high concentration is probably just a consequence of low priority, and thus low output and few firms, rather than the explicit intent of the planners. The final explanation is that some industries are smnall because they are relatively new industries. As of 1989, the planners had not had the chance to build many enterprises in these industries, plus, with new technologies, they may have been reluctant to invest large amounts initially. For example, plastic pipe and plastic foam products are two industries that have very few firms and thus are very concentrated in Russia, but have many firns and low concentration ratios in the U.S. The closely related four-digit industry, plastic bottles, did not even exist in Russia in 1989. Here, high concentration is a consequence of youth and, thus, low output and few firms, rather than the explicit intent of the planners. Understanding these three explanations is very important. When we can identify the reasons why an industry has a small number of firms, we can then predict which industries might indeed suffer from oligopolistic behavior after price liberalization. The new industries likely have good incentives for entry and sLould not present a problem, but the others, especially those that produce intermediate goods, likely represent bo'. "anecks in the new economy. For these, the impact of their concentrto will be greater than their share of economic activity in general. In sum, there is, in fact, a group of industries which resemble the conventional wisdom about concentration in the Russian economy. They represent, however, a small share of the economy. There is another group which appears highly concentrated in our data, but in fact these industries art augmented by production of civilian goods in the military-industrial complex. Apart from these industries, and even including those augmented by production in the military-industrial complex, Russian industry is not highly concentrated when measured at the national level. The vast majority of industries have enough firms that, with a national market, competition should exist. Although this seems to contradict the historical evidence, one feature of the command economy does indeed suggest this result. As we explain later, ministers preferred to keep entire chains of production within their ministry to minimize reliance on firms outside of their direct control. Thus, for many intermediate goods, each ministry wanted its own enterprise. For these industries, we should find at least as many enterprises as there were ministries that used the products. 27 lndasiL Concentrution Reality 5.6: The-difference between Russian and U.S. concentration arises not in the largest firms in each industry, but, rather, in the secondary firms in bach industry. Here we use table 18 to look at specific comparisons between four-digit industries. For many industries, the U.S. and Russia have very similar concentration ratios, but Russia has only a fraction of the firms that the U.S. does. For example, the CR4 and CR8 for the Russian storage-batteries industry are only slightly different while Russia has one tenth as many firms - 13 where the U.S. has 125. For farm machinery and equipment, Russia also has similar concentration ratios, but only has 147 enterprises where the U.S. has 1,576. The U.S. and Russian ratios are about similar for the metal-cutting machine tools industry, but there are 381 such firms in the U.S. and only 51 in Russia. Thus, while Russia does have fewer firms in each industry in general, that does not mean that industries are controlled by oligopolies any more so than in a market economy like the U.S. Rather, for industries with similar concentration of large firms, the big differences appear in the secondary finns. In the last example, each secondary (ninth largest or smaller) firm in the U.S. accounts for an average of .16 percent of sales, whie each in Russia accounts fbr 1.26 percent These findings are the logical conclusion of the results of the analysis on enterprise size. Russia is characterized by medium and large firms, while the U.S. is characterized by very small and extra-large firms. So, we find that, while the large firms in Russia may represent the same share of their industry that the extra-large firms in the U.S. rpresent of theirs, the remainder of the industry's production in Russia is filled by a small number of medium-sized firms while that in the U.S. is filled by a myriad of very small firms. In terms of price competition, these medium-sized firns are probably more likely to compete with the primary firms given a national market in Russia than the small ones do with the manmmoth ones in the U.S. This is good news for short-term monopoly concerns in Russia. The small firms in the U.S., however, offer dynamic advantages to the whole industrial structure as we discuss above. Myth 6: The Russian economy is controlled by a large number of dominant enterprises. Reality 6: Dominant enterprises do not, in fact, dominate the national economy. 28 Anadzarfa Concenradon In table 19, we present the results of analysis using the Russian definition of dominant enterprise. This definition was created in thf context of anti-monopoly policy. An enterprise is dominant if it commands a 35 percent or greater share of its market. For the purposes of policy, markets are defined differently for different industries. Here, we start by looking at the national market. We find that less than 1 percent of all enterprises and less than 4 percent of all employment are accounted for by finns with 35 percent or greater market shares at the national level. The results are similar when measured using sales except that dominant fiim sales as a percentage of total is 7.6 percent. Some of these industries have more than one dominant firm. While such industries would be considered concentrated in the analysis above, these individual firms have less market power than if only one were dominant. The table shows that, if we ignore industries with two dominant firms, the share of industries with dominant firms is somewhat diminished. Table 20 shows dominant firms and dominated industries across branches of production. Four manufacturing branches seem to cover much of the dominance: electronics, fabricated metal, instruments, and paper. Mining also exhibits a high proportion of dominant firms and dominated industries. 4. Barriers to Competition In the preceding section we have presented evidence that supports our view that, at.the national level, industrial concentration - the presence of too few firms or of powerful firms - is not responsible for problems of imperfect competition in Russia. This still leaves open the question of whether there are structural impediments to competition in Russia. In this section, we argue that important barriers to competition do exit in Russia. These barriers, however, are not the result of industrial concentaon, but rather are primarily the result of markets that are highly segmented.43 Under the prior regime, enterprises were highly isolated, divided along both ministerial and, often, geographic lines." In part, this segmentation can be viewed as a legacy of central planning. Unfortunately, certain features of the transition environment strengthen these divisions, undermining 3As Ofer [1992: 91] points out "...inertia in distribution links and in supply and marketing routes, and the remaining main core of production according to ministerial flat may preserve monopolistic power and produce monopolistic prices." Kahn and Peck [1991: 66-67] also emphasizes that problems in distribution may create local monopolies. MTis point was noted in the IMF-World Bank-OECD-EBRD joint study: "Even where more than one enterprise exists, the national aggregates hide a high degree of regional monopoly power that is protected by generally poor communications and transportation and by administered marketing channels which, in turn, are insulated from one another by ministerial lines of responsibility [1991: 16]. 29 lwdased Cenceizron the efficient distribution of goods. In this section, we discuss the nature of these segmentations, both ministerial and geographic, in more detail. 4.1 Ministerial Segmentation The success of central planning relied on the ability of planners and industrial ministers to retain control over the important decisions of enterprises. The roles of Gosplan (the State Planning Committee) and the industrial ministries in guiding production and investnent decision making are well known." Under central planning, the distribution of goods was also coordinated centrally, by Gossnab (the State Committee for Material Technical Supply). Gossnab was responsible for creating and managing the wholesale trade system, including identifying appropriate trading partners, setting the contractual terms of delivery, and arranging for the transportation of goods. This system was designed to allow planners at Gossnab to control the system of distribution. Preventing enterprises from developing their own trading links was an important element in limiting enterprise autonomy and forcing adherence to the plan. Given the sheer size of the task of supply control, Gossnab planners relied heavily on historic linkages between enterprises when designing their distribution plans. In many cases, this inertia meant that enterprises were forced to remain in relationships that, over time, become obsolete due to the creation of alternative and potentially more appropriate partners. Moreover, many enterprises were assigned trading partners that were unable tp fulfill their contractual obligations on a timely basis. This uncertainty undermined the ability of enterprise directors to meet their production targets and, consequendy, to receive adequate financial rewards. Unfortunately, the economic and legal structure provided little recourse for the director, pressing him or her to find alternative sources for important inputs." In some cases, the director independently developed the internal capacity to produce the needed inputs. In other cases, the industrial minister took the initiative and established the capacity to produce important inputs, particularly when so doing '5For more infornation, see Gregory and Stuart [1986]. "One important direction this effort took is the development of informal distribution lines between enterprises. Most enteprises employed a tolach (expediter) whose job it was to procure inputs through informal channels. Although these efforts were widespread, they were formally illegal, and inhibited the development of economy-wide supply information. For more on informal aspects of plan fulfillment, see Powell [1979]. 30 laduri ConcenrtIon reduced his or her reliance on enterprises outside the ministry.' This latter feature of central planning alone suggests that, for important commodities, there must be at least as many firms as there are industrial ministries. The dominant feature of this system of distribution was the absence of institutions to provide enterprises with the information they would require to establish links with other firms on a decentralized basis. In effect, Gossnab and the industrial ministries created a barrier to insulate enterprises from their trading partners. As a consequence, enterprises tended to become highly isolated, without knowledge of national and, in some cases, local market structure. Vertical dependence among enterprises is, to a great extent, the consequence of the arbitrary demarcation between processes in Soviet industry. Enterprises within an industrial ministry can usefiully be thought of as processes aiong an assembly line. While there are logical ways of dividing of an assembly line into its constituent parts, ministers made divisions for reasons of control, rather than economic rationality. This is of little consequence when the enterprises are subordinate to a ministry that fits them together. With the collapse of the industrial ministries enterprises are now free to seek out new customers and new suppliers, but this ability is checked by the arbitrary ways in which the assembly line is divided. Enterprise directors suppose that they are tied to a vertical chain that it is very difficult to escape from. Thus, an important legacy of central planning is an industrial structure that is highly segmented based on historic trading relationships. We call this type of segmentation ministerial because it arose out of the ministerial system that included both Gossnab and the industrial ministries. Unfortunately, the information problem that arose out of the ministerial system continues to persist today. Currently, much of distribution is organized by wholesale organizations, many of which are vestiges of the system of central planning. They continue to distribute for the supply organizations and industrial ministries to which they previously corresponded even when the latter have been privatized or decentralized. Thus, they act to maintain and reinforce the ministerial distinctions that arose prior to the introduction of markets. Until new wholesale firms are created to compete with these firms, old patterns of production and distribution are likely to persist. "7An extreme example of this "ministerial autarky" occurs with respect to timber. As described in Hewett [1988: 173]: "Minergo (Energy and Electrification), for example, ships sawn timber produced by construction firms at the Bratsk and Krasnoiarsk hydroelectric stations in Siberia 3,000-5,000 kilometers away to its enterprises in the European USSR. Simultaneously Minlesbumprom (timber, pulp, paper, and wood) ships sawn timber to Siberia from its enterprises in the European USSR.' 31 Industri Cencentraton Ministerial segmentation has important implications for industrial concentration in the Russian economy. It has produced well-defined and persistent vertical linkages between enterprises, linkages which, in some sense, can be considered a form of vertical integration. As enterprises re-create the vertical chains of the assembly line, they represent both fewer and larger producers in the economy. However, the vertical integration that we observe in the Russian Federation is quite distinct from vertical integration in western countries. In the Russian Federation, the integration does not take a legal form nor is it motivated by conventional economic interests." Rather, it is created by a lack of knowledge of alternative trading partners. In the extreme, one could view the Russian economy as segmented along historically determined chains of production, in which each firm in the chain may be acting as both a monopsonist and a monopolist.4'' Once fims become better informed about their trading alternatives, we can expect some of the more inefficient chains of production to break down.5 4.2 Geographic Segmentation Many markets in the Russian Federation, which one would naturally expect to be national, are, in fact, regional or local. In part, this geographic segmentation is a vestige of the system of central planning. In the prior regime, the production of many commodities of lesser importance, such as clothing or footwear, was planned by regional, not national, authorities, and thus these enterprises are only experienced in selling within local markets. Moreover, currentlv the distribution of these 'In the Williamsonian tradition the primary explanation of vertical integration is the reduction in transactions costs that occur when asset specificity is present. In the case of Russia, however, it is not asset specificity, but the lack of knowledge of alternative suppliers and customers that creates the potential for integration. "Rughvir Khemani suggests that this type of market segmentation offers another reason for heterogeneity of firm size within industries, that is, a firm in a given industry was established or maintained at the size necessary for its vertical, or ministerial, market regardle$s of the sizes of other firms in the same industry. 'CEd Hewett [1988: 170-174] discusses the reasons for strong vertical linkages as well as physical vertical integration. He concludes, "As a consequence, the successful enterprise is the vertically integrated enterprise, and the successful ministry, the vertically integrated ministry." 5"To date most of the evidence supporting the presence of ministerial segmentation is anecdotal, but non-contradicting. in fall 1992, we interviewed 75 firms across western Russia The survey was conducted by the authors in collaboration with Alan Gelb and I.J. Singh from the World Bank and Valeriy Makarov and other economists from the Central Economics and Mathematics Institute in Moscow. These interviews revealed that enterprise directors were often not aware of alternative trading partners, even when they were known (by the interviewers) to exist. 32 Indual Concentradox and other goods is arranged by the wholesale trade organizations that we discuss above. In certain areas, many of these wholesale trade organizations have only single outlets that act as regional monopolies. As a consequence, the markets for certain goods are highly localized.'2 Naturally, one expects that after liberalization, the size of the markets for these types of goods will expand quickly. However, certain features of the transition environment suggest that some barriers to this expansion do exist. Specifically, some regional or oblasr governments have implemented restrictions on the free flow of irater-oblast trade. Such restrictions have historic precedents in both legal and illegal activity. Under the prior regime, the transpormtion of goods between cities required special permits. Any official could stop a truck and inspect its load to determine whether the delivery was authorized or not. And, if the delivery was, in fact, unauthorized, the truck driver may have offered the official a bribe to ignore the transgression. The use of licenses and other regulations to restrict the free flow of trade between oblasts appears to persist during the transition, although in ways that are presently umneasurable- Much of the evidence is anecdotal. Many obMast governments have introduced explicit controls restricting the export of important goods from their region. Typically, these governments still control the local prices of important consumer commodities and therefore require export restrictions in order to prevent the flow of these conunodities into neighboring, high-price regions. Private entrepreneurs often complain that, in addition to these export restrictions, they encounter the extra cost of formnal and informal tariffs when transporting good across oblast borders. However, the extent to which these added costs are the consequence of explicit policy is unknown. The failure of the federal government to invalidate old laws and the activation of new, often conflicting, laws provide local officials with wide discretion in the enforcement of policy. To some extent, local officials appear to be using this lack of clarity to collect bribes from firms engaged in the transportation of goods, although, again, the pervasiveness o. this phenomenon is not known. Barriers to inter-oblast commerce also are created by problems in the system of transportation. Unfortunately, the present trasportation system in the Russian Federation was designed to support the unique institutions of central planning. Certain types of transportation infrastructure, such as roadways, are presently underdeveloped because they threatened the ability of govermment authorities to maintain central control over economic behavior.3 For example, nearly all '2Kahn and Peck [1991: 66] emphasize the importance of regional, as opposed to national, markets as a barrier to competition. "Gregory and Stuart [1986]. 33 IaduaSd Cenesan transport in terms of tonkilometers is served by trains and not by trucks. Trains are easier to administer and control centrally, while trucks require roads. Roads complicate enforcement of restrictions on internal travel. Moreover, the present system of incentives prevents the efficient use of available transportation. For example, central control over rail transportation (and the absence of freight-forwarding institutions) has led to conditions where freight must be scheduled at least six months in advance. How important are these barriers in creating local monopolies and oligopolies? Unfortunately, we do not have direct evidence that enables us to identify which markets have become localized. Nor do we precisely know the level of localization - the economic region, the oblast, or the city or town. However, we have prepared some tables to indicate the potential impact of local markets on the presence of imperfect competition in Russia based on the assumption that geographic segmentation in Russia is present. To begin, refer to table 21. Table 21 introduces the reader to the twelve economic regions and describes each of them in terms of their dependence on particular branches of the civilian economy. Table 19 shows that, if markets are segmented based on the twelve economic regions, a larger share of industries have dominant firms. They account for about 10 percent of firms and about one-third of employment and sales. Ib table 22, we calculate the number of monopolies and oligopolies that would be present, again based on the assumption that markets are largely contained within economic regions. )We find that in three major economic regions - Chernozem, Northwest, and Volgo-Vyatka - regional monopolies and oligopolies may employ nearly half of all civilian workers or more. It is, of course, not surprising that as we disaggregate on a geographical level that concentration should increase because, in the Soviet period, industrial location decisions generally were made on ministerial, not regional lines.? Much of the anecdotal evidence suggests that markets may even be segmented to a finer geographic level, to the oblasT level or, in some cases, to the level of the city or town. Clearly, the smaller the geographic market, the greater the potential for imperfect competition. Unfortunately, high levels of industrial concentration in localized markets not only lead to higher prices and lower output, they also exacerbate the existing probiems of highly localized labor markets. During the Soviet period, the government severely restricted internal migration. Citizens were issued domestic passports and not permitted free travel outside of their city of residence. Thus labor markets were "The exception, of course, was the sovnarkhoz - regional planning ministries - that were implemented by Khrushchev. This experiment ended in 1964. 34 Indi&al Concugrenon limited to cities or towns except in the cases where the government wanted workers to move, for example when it enticed workers to the Far East with higher wages. Currently, although the migration laws have changed, the shortage of housing at current prices and other factors continue to restrict labor mobility. As a consequence, firms that may be monopolists or oligopolists in their local goods markets may also be monopsonists or oligopsonists in their local labor markets. Table 23 presents statistics that describe the average number of civilian firms and industries in both oblasts and in cities or towns. This table suggests that, while oblasts contain many firms, they also contain many industries. Thus, although oblasts may be industrially diverse, the presence of barriers to free trade suggests that many of these industries may be local monopolies or oligopolies. This feature has mixed implications for reform. With industrial diversity, oblasts are relatively insulated from economic shocks that affect particular .ndustries, such as shocks to certain types of heavy industry. On the other hand, the presence of local concentration raises political pressure for price controls, regulations, and other forms anti-monopoly policy that may impede the progress of economic reform. A potentially more important problem is the number of towns in Russia with very few industries or enterprises. More than 90 percent of all cities and towns in Russia have nine or fewer civilian firms or industies. Further, as shown in table 24, almost one-half of all cities have only one firm and more than three-quarters have four firms or fewer. In an ervironment with labor mobility and little market segmentation, the particular spatial distribution of firms would not pose a serious threat to reform. Under such conditions, even if the only employer in the town shuts down, workers can -find employment elsewhere. However, when labor is highly immobile,55 entire cities and towns are open to potentially large unemployment shocks, if the dominant local industry experiences a downturn. Under these conditions, workers in these firms are likely to pressure their local govermnents to intervene and try to find them subsidies, undermining the process of micro- adjustment. Although there are many cities with four firms or fewer, these cities accodnt for only 12.2 percent of all civilian employment in industry. Typically, these cities are small towns that predominantly host small firms. In table 25, we observe that the largest firms are not in cities with four finms or less. They tend to be in cities with a moderate number of other firms, suggesting that 55The issue, of course, is whether observed low mobility of labor in Russia is due to a lack of inter-regional employment that resulted from the absence of enterprise failure under the old regime, or whether this is due to impediments to labor mobility, such as lack of housing. The latter effect seems to be very important in Russia. 35 IndutarL Conuudou either larger firms require complementary goods to be produced or the local work force requires a sufficiently diversified local economy.m We emphasize that local monopolies and oligopolies in these cities and towns exist only as a consequence of segmented markets, not as a consequence of having too few firms in their particular industries. In table 26, we present statistics on the potential competitiveness of industries in cities of different sizes. We find that very few firms in cities with four firms or fewer are in industries that are highly concentrated when measured at the national level. In fact, most of the firms in cities and towns with few firms are in industries with many firms. This fact suggests either that these firms are in industries that naturally serve only local markets (such as bakeries), or that these firms are in industries that, with improvements in the system of distribution, are potentially very competitive. S. Implications for Economic Reform The hct that barriers to competition in Russia arise, not from industrial concentration at the national level, but from ministerial and geographic segmentation of markets, has important' implications for economic reform. We now turn to the implications of our findings for competition policy and economic reform. With respect to competition policy, a whole set of issues arises surrounding the relative importance and appropriate timing of anti-trust policies. Contestable markets theory argues that the facilitation of free entry and exit alone should induce competitive behavior in firms 'through the threat of entry. Even when monopoly power is exercised, many would contend that, in the Russian case, the conventionally measured welfare losses are less than the benefits from faster privatization due to the attractiveness of owning monopolies and oligopolies. Moreover, if the threat of entry does not inhibit monopoly profits, these profits will attract new entry into the market. Thus, the govermnent should keep its hands off enterprises. Although entry and the threat of entry are important mechanisms for eliminating the concentration problems imposed by highly segmented markets, there are nonetheless good reasons for considering the role of an active competition policy in Russia. Three features of the current environment suggest that enterprise directors will not perceive a threat for entry or will not care. Thus, the persistence of non-competitive behavior may warrant competition policy. First, the S6 It should be noted that'in some of these small cities there may be military enterprises that are not included in our data set. Such additional firms as do exist would mitigate the vulnerability of those towns to potentially volatile local markets. 36 indafll Cenmavwitou enviroment is very uncertain. 'This uncertainty.tends to shrink the time horizon for decisionmakers. In this case, enterprise directors will substantially discount the future fall in profits which could be the result of attracting entry or regulation in the current period. Second, directors realize that the lejal and administrative complexity of starting a new firm acts as an effective barrier against many potential entrants into their markets. Third, the high cost of capital (to agents not in the state sector) and the difficulties in acquiring facilities make it very difficult to start up new businesses!, In certain cases then, an active competition policy may be warranted. It then becomes important to design the policy appropriately. This clearly depends on the causes of imperfect competition. We argue that traditional anti-trust policies are inappropriate when the sources of imperfect competition are ministerial and geographic segmentation. Anti-trust policy in Russia includes two types of distinct actions. First, the Russian government has established anti-monopoly committees at regional and local levels. These committees use product categories and current relevant market sizes to identify "monopolies" - those firms with a 35 percent or more market share - to be regulated. Anti-monopoly price regulations are based on the belief that this market power comes from industrial stmcture. However, as we have emphasized, the dominant cause of market power is market segmentation. Not only do price regulations fail to address the real problern then, they probably exacerbate it by eliminating gains from inter-regional trade and therefore reinforcing the segmentation. This type of regulation is also vulnerable to a degree of mismanagement and corruption which could pose a real threat to the process of enterprise reform in Russia. Any flexibility that local officials have in defining markets provides them with wide discretion in identifying firms and thus, provides them with a tool to potentially punish any firm that pursues its own, rather than the government's, objectives. Second, anti-trust activity often involves breaking up lar!,er firms into smaller ones. In the case of Russia, this type of action is often discussed in the context of privatization. The idea that monopolistic or oligopolistic firms should bebroken apart into smaller enterprises is partly based on the conventional belief that these firns are inefficiently large. Fawever, as we show above, the evidence does not support this belief. Thus, we question the ability of the government to determine, ex ante, the appropriate size for firms in an industry. We also question whether the government has sufficient information to be able to determine, ex ante, whether a particular organizational structure is suited for market competition. "7Iis factor is clearly more important in sectors where the minimum efficient scale of the firm is large. Hence new entry in the retail sector has been quite dramatic. 37 Induafi Cevacanudon Moreover, when the real probWen is market segmentation, it is not at all clear that breaking up enterprises will add to the effective number of potential competitors in the market. The breakup of a large enterprise will not produce several identical small enterprises. In most cases, it will involve the breakup of an integrated enterprise into its parts. If the market is segmented, this policy will merely reproduce vertical dependence, as the former constituents of the enterprise will have still rely heavily on each other. The optimal policy under such conditions must involve measures that reduce the segmentation of markets (we discuss these types of measures below). Moreover, both types of anti-trust policies often target specific sectors, in which the effects of high prices create important economic or political consequences. For example, these policies may target finns in one part of a chain of production only, such as in light industry. If this is the case, then anti-trust policy runs the risk of creating worse market structures than those that are currendy in place. For example, in most cases, firms are engaged in trade relationships which can be characterized as bilateral monopolies. They purchase inputs from a limited number of firms that, in urn, sell to only a limited number of customers. Thus, there is a mutual dependency between the supplier and the customer. If, say, the limited number of customers are divided into many direct competitors, then a power asymmetry is created, in which many downstream firms compete for a limited number of upstream supplies. In this case, the relative bargaining power of the upstream producer is increased and the costs of imperfect competition may be increased. Ignoring the role of market segmentation in creating imperfect competition can thus lead to anti-trust pblicies that exacerbate the situation. The effectiveness of import competition as a remedy for market power depends on two features of the economy. First, the economy must be open. Second, the economy must have a good distribution system. Imported goods cannot easily flow into countries lacking seaports, airports, train stations, and other centers of trade. The absence of such a system in Russia is at the center of our discussion of imperfect competition. In our view, ministerial and geographic segmentation forces trading relationships to be backward looking, promoting the maintenance of relationships developed under central planning, rather than new ones. To promote enterprise-adjustment, a distribution system must exist that is forward looking. This requires no unnecessary restrictions on the flow of domestic trade; a good network of wholesale and retail enterprises to link producers with customers; a good information system to allow firms to identify potential suppliers and customers; and a good transportation system to move goods from the place of production to the place of consumption; a good storage system to hold goods, to separate the time of production from the time of consumption; a good communication system to allow firms to negotiate and modify contracts as needs change; a 38 I dutrc Concentradon rapid payments and settlements system to facilitate financial compensation for products or services provided; and, a system of enforceable contract law to enable firms with no history of relations to contract with one another. Unfortunately, the Russian economy is faced with oblast-level restrictions on commerce; wholesale- and retail-trade monopolies (and barriers to entry in wholesale and retail trade); poor infrastructure and poor incentives in infrastructure (information, transportation, communication, storage); long delays in the payment and settements system; and the absence of an enforceable system of contract law. Improvements in the system of distribution would require a combination of investment in public infrastructure, improvements in the legal system, some privatization, and, most importantly, elimination of all barriers to free internal trade and free entry.' Moreover, by improving distribution, the creation of small trading firms will facilitate the entry of new industrial firms." We would expect that these new firms will become an important source of innovation in the economy.Y As more small new firms enter, we also anticipate that the size distribution of industrial finms will change to reflect a more-market-oriented industrial structure. 6. Conclusion In this paper, we have presented evidence that calls into question the conventional wisdom that Russia suffers from excessive industrial concentration. Concentration, measured at the national level, is not significantly (in an economic sense) greater in Russia than in the United States. While this indicates that Russia does not suffer from the problem of gigantomania - that is, production concentrated in a few very large enterprises - national comparisons may obscure important issues when distribution is costly and information is poor. Indeed, we have argued that the major barriers to competition that do exist in Russia, arise from market and geographic segmentation. 5' Free entry, to the extent that it leads to the expansion of previously repressed sectors of the economy - such as services and communications - may also play an important role in mitigating the consequences of reductions in employment in industry that are associated with restructuring. 54One potential source of new entrants that could play an important role is the MIC. The decline in orders for MIC output provides incentives for entry into civilian industry. Moreover, the natural industries to enter are those where profits are high. This suggests that the MIC will be a dynamic source of competition in Russia. 1DDearden, Ickes, and Samuelson (1990] show that the cost of inducing innovation is increasing in the amount of hierarchy, and use this to explain the slow rate of innovation adoption in Soviet industry. 39 laduarful Concamentoo Analysis of market structure in Russia is important for understanding economic refrmn. Market segmeniation has created a situation where enterprise directors believe that they are dependent on a small number of customers and suppliers. This makes the transition environment much more uncertain, and thus inhibits adjustment to the market. It is often argued, that privatization of state-owned enterprises will lead to improved economic performance solely because ownership will provide the proper incentives. It seems unlikely, however, that without competitive pressures, ownership alone will be sufficient to change behavior. Enterprises bent on survival will minimize changes that entail significant risks. Consequently, it will be critical to remove the barriers to competition that exist in Russia. This means that it is crucial to know the sources of these barriers. Our analysis strongly suggests that marker infrastrucrure - communication, distribution, and information - is the most important element of a competition policy in Russia. 40 indusrial Cncaooen References Berliner, Joseph, Factory and Manager in the USSR, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1957. Conynghan, William J., The Modernization of Soviet Industrial Management, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982. Cooper, Julian, "Defence Industry Conversion in the East The Relevance of Western Experience," working paper, May 1991. Dearden, James, Barry W. Ickes, and Larry Samuelson, "To Innovate or Not to Innovate: Incentives for Innovation in ZI'r,rarchies," American Economic Review, 80, 5, December 1990. Erhlich, Eva, "The Size Structure of Manufacturing Establishments and Enterprises: An International Comparison," Journal of Compararive Economics, vol. 9, 1985. Granick, David, Soviet Metal-Fabricating and Economic Development, Madison, University of Wisconsin Press, 1967. Gregory, Paul and Robert C. Stuart, Soviet Economic Structure and Performance, 3rd edL, New York: Harper & Row, Publishers, 1986. Hewett, Ed A., Reforming the Soviet Economyy: Equality versus Efficiency, Washington, D.C.: rhe Brooldngs Institution, 1988. Hurwitz, Elliott., 'Concentration of Russian Defense Industrial Employment by Economic Region and Oblast, memorandum, May 20, 1992. Ickes, Barry W., and Randi Ryterman, "Entry Without Exit: Economic Selection Under Socialism," working paper, 1993. International Monetary Fund, The World Bank, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, and European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, A Study of the Sovet Economy, volume 2. Paris, 1991. Kahn, Alfted and Merton J. Peck, "Price Deregulation, Corporatization, and Competition," in Whw is To Be Done? Proposals fr the Soviet Transition to the Marker, M. J. Peck and T. Richardson, eds. (New Haven, CT and London, England: Yale University Press), 1991. Kered, Michael, "Optimal Tautness and the Economics of Incentives in Bureaucracies," Comparative Economic Studies, 35, 1, Spring 1993: 85-117. Kroll, Heidi, "Monopoly and Transition to the Market," Soviet Economy, 1991, 7, 2, pp. 14-174. 41 InduiWda Coxatrutfan. Ofer, Gur, 'Stabilizing and Restructuring the Former Soviet Economy: Big-Bang or Gradual Sequencing?" in Vials of Transition, M. KeFen and G. Ofer, eds. (Boulder, CO; San Francisco, CA; Oxford, England: Westview Press), 1992. Scherer, F.M., and David Ross, Industrial Market Stuwre and Economic Performance, Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company, 1990. U.S. Department of Commerce, 1987 Census of Manufactures: Concentration Ratios in Mwuifaatring, MC87-S-6, February 1992. U.S. Department of Commerce, 1987 Enterprise Statistics: Company Swimay, ES87-3, June 1991. The World Bank, Rssian Economic Reforn: Crossing the Threshold of Structural Change, Washington, 1992. Wiles, PJ.D., The Political Economy of Communism, Oxford, Basil Blackwell, 1962. 42 Table' 1989 densus of Manufacturers Nuinher.ct.. hCliuracteftics of.irm .Industrial Hrms Epvmn - S |921.391 Mean 643 2 Digit 39 TotaLl Eniploynmnt . Median 211 3 Digit 180 In Industrial Fimr . Minimum 1 4 Digit 406 13,751,839 Maximum 100,605 5 Digit 489 Range 100,604 4374 Variance 4,578,015 t_4m 0hlas I Coef of Var 332.82 78 ! * - .. |I .: Fum Sazfe ., * .* .-:. 9IDigit.SIC. : . Smail :MbdiuIm .:z argw.. lotai. Agriculture 1411 122 15 3 1551 Mining & Canstruction 307 259 140 25 731 Manufacturing: food, textiles, wood, print, chemicals 6518 4049 . 1082 14 11663 ManufacturinT. rubber, leather glass, metals, M&E 1410 2750 1304 69 5533 Transpart and Util.'s 238 572 84 1 895 Trade 1 0 0 0 1 Fire, Insurance, Real Estate 0 0 0 0 0 Services: business, repair 430 515 65 1 1011 Services, health, education 2 1 0 0 3 Public Administration 2 1 0 0 3 Total 10319 8269 2690 113 21391 Table prepared by A. Brown, B. Ickes, and R. Ryterman. 43 Table 2. Estimates of Mean Employment by Finns in the Military-lndustrial Complex in Russia for 1989 Number of Mean Employ- Sector Employment Enterprses mnent Per Finn Civilian Industry 13,751,839 21,391 643 of which Heavy Civilian Industry 4,250,750 2,429 1,750 MIC 7,979,161 5,309 1,503 Estimated MIC 9,289,726 5,309 1,750 All Industry 21,731,000 26,700 814 Sources: Goskomstat Ecnoamic Yearbook for 1990 and PlanEcon data. 44 Table 3. Aggegate Industrial Concentration Pattems in 1985 Average Size of Leading Fi;ms Leading Company Employment INumber of Employeesl as a Percent of Total Industrial E_nployment fin %) Top 10 Top 20 Top 10 Top 20 Nation United States 310,554 219,748 13.1 18.6 Japan 107,106 72,240 7.3 9.9 West Germany 177,173 114,542 20.1 26.0 United Kingdom 141,156 '108.010 23.1 35.3 France 116,049 81,381 23.2 32.5 South Korea 54,416 n.a. 14.9 n.a. Canada 36,990 26,414 15.3 21.9 Switzerland 60,039 36,602 49.4 60.2 Holland 84,884 47,783 84.5 95.1 Sweden 48,538 32,893 49.4 66.9 Russia (1989) 62,649 48,133 4.6 7.0 U.S. statistics based on company data. Sources: Scherer and Ross (1990, p. 631 and PlanEcon data. Table prepared by A. Brown, B. Ickes, and R. Ryterman 45 Table 4. Comparison of the Size Distibutions of Russian and U.S. Manufacturing Finns Size dam by employment Small Medium Large Ex-large Total Caurnry Statistic 1-249 250-959 lOUD- 1000 _ 9999 or mar Russia Number of firms 9,065 5,662 2,386 83 17,196 Witho &mat&edHMC` 10.374 7,651 4,292 188 22,505 As a percent of total number af firms 52.7 32.9 13.9 0.5 100.O in manaucturin* *Wth estdatedŁfIC 46.1 34.0 19.1 0.8 100.0 US. Number of firms 299.666 5.530 1,657 267 307.120 As a percent of totl number of firms 97.6 1.0 0.5 0.1 100.0 in mandacturing Russia Numberof workers 974.721 2.874,640 5911.370 1.758.320 11.519,051 with estimatedMtC 1,151.649 3.959.560 11,440,500 4.257.068 20,808,777 As . percent of tatl number of workers 8.5 25.0 51.3 15.3 100.0 in mnmufacturing with esanstagd MIC 5.5 19.0 55.0 205 100.0 U.S. Number of workers 5,777.592 2519.572 4,518.667 8.632.159 21.447.990 As a percent of total number df workers 26.9 11.7 21.1 40.2 100.0 in mnufacturig Rusia Avg.#ofworkes 100 - 508 2.478 21.185 670 U.S. Avg. Xof workers 19 456 2.727 32.330 70 'U.S. data are fronm U.S. Census 1987 Enterprise Statistcs and are company data. "See Table 2 and the text for explanation Table prepared by A.Brown, B. Ickes, and R. Byterman 46 7 ble 5. Com.parison of the Size Distribution of Russian and U.S. Small Manufacturing Firms Sbe cion by employment ountry Statistic 14 5 9 10-19 20149 50 99 100-249 Total ussia Number af firms 27 205 512 1.386 2A476 4A459 9.065 with xtifiat;dMIC` 27 207 521 1,517 2762 5,340 10.374 As a porcent of tobl number of small firnm 0.3 2.3 5.6 15.3 27.3 49.2 100.0 in manufacturing bwth esdmated MIC 0.3 2.0 50 14.6 26.6 51.5 10;0. .S. Numberof firns 112,926 58S598 32,158 65.834 18.661 11.489 299.666 As a percent of total number of small firms 37.7 19.6 10.7 22.0 62 3.8 100.0 in manufacturing_ usia Number of worker 76 1,513 7,435 48,645 180,81E 736.237 974.721 i,tb estimafifdAC 76 1,533 7,576 53,336 202.165 88963 1,151.649 As a prment of total number of workers 0.0 0.2 0.8 5.0 18.6 75.5 100.0 in manufacturing small firms * with estizatidiC 0.0 0.1 0.7 4.6 17.6 77.0 100.0 .S. Number of worker 215.443 394,067 378,180 1,750.874 1.289.853 1,749,175 5.777,592 As a percent of total number of workrs 3.7 68 6.5 30.3 22.3 - 30.3 100.0 in manufaturing small finm -Issia Avg.#eof workers 3 7 15 35 73 165 108 .S. Avg. # of wrken 2 7 12 27 . .69 152 19 J.S. data are from the U.S. Cansus 1987 Entepripse Statistics and aro company data. 'See Table 2 and the text far explanation. 3b1s prepared by A. Brown, B. lcides, and R. Rytarman 47 Table 6. Comparison of the Size Distribution of Russian and U.S. Manufacturing Firnns Size dm by employmeit Country Statiodo 148 501699 1009249 2S0.99 1000. ioaao Total 9999 or more fluei. Numbar of firms 2,130 2,476 4,459 5,662 2,386 83 17,196 witFt extjaadNX"e 2,Z72 Z782 5,340 7,651 4 4,292 188 272505 As a percnt of total numbr of firm 12.4 14.4 25.9 32.9 13.9 0.5 100.0 in manufacturing M*tk4w&tad Mx 10.1 12.3 23.7 34.0 19.1 0.8 1O0.0 US. Number of finmn 269.516 18,661 11,489 5,530 1,657 267 307.120 As * percent of htol numler of firmn 87.5 8.1 3.7 1.8 0.5 0.1 100.G in manufacturinng Renem Humbwrofwmrkwe 57,669 180.815 736,237 2.074,640 5,911,370 1,758.320 11.519,051 w M A: estiwatdMiC 62szZi 202,165 886,963 3.959,560 11.440,50a 4,257,068 20.808,777 As a pernt of tol number af merka 0.5 1.9 6.4 25.0 51.3 15.3 100.0 in manufactnring firms with aujavatad ifX 0.3 1.0 4.3 19.0 55.0 205 100.0 U.S. Number of workes 2,73B.564 1,28.853 1,749,175 2.S19,572 4,518,667 8,63Z,159 21,447,990 An a percet of total number of wrker 12.8 LO 8.2 11-7 21.1 40.2 1W.0 in m ufacturing firms nue.a Avg.Dof workser 27 73 165 508 2475 21185 670 U.S. Avg.fofw wrke 10 6a 152 456 2727 32330 70 US. data an fom U.S. C 1987 Eueiesa Stabis an - cunpan daa *'Se Tdd 2 and t test fr mnIaiaueL Tabl ppad by A.Drown, B. ldwks, m R. Ryutmn n 48 Table 7. Size Characteristics of Firms by Industrial Branch.s In Russia In 1989 Number of Firms hr Employment I e Shari o1 Share of Drench Employmauth bSIzr' Share of Branch Small Medium Large Ex-Large NFirms Total Fitm. Small Madlum Large Ex-Lurge Total Em Agricullura' 1411 122 t5 3 1551 7.3 39.7 19.9 25.4 15.0 1.6 Apparel 225 445 144 0 814 3.8 5.0 .38.2 56.9 0.0 3.8 Chemicals 103 188 150 5 454 2.1 1.9 14.2 75.0 8.9 4.9 Construction' 40 25 3 0 68 . 0.3 21.6 55.3 23.2 0.0 0.1 Electronics 37 100 118 3 256 1.2 1.1 11.1 78.8 9.0 . 3.2 Fabricated Metal 13 305 72 3 553 2.6 5.9 36.7 44.0 13.4 2.8 .2' 9 # a i,w,, 3 09.c t furnitulre 110 218 62 0 390 1.8 6.7 42.5 51.8 0.0 1.7 K ...... :idT 5.4.Y . w a§fr' ;..TWTh ,.., 1;- .4.S. .. Yi~A Instfuments 117 95 69 1 252 1.3 3.4 . 17.9 74.6 4.0 2.0 Leather 64 123 73 0 260 1.2 3.4 24.6 72.0 0.0 1.7 Al.t. . -ffV ,.&IVt Minlng" 2j7 234 137 25 683 3.1 2.3 9.4 37.8 50.5 8.0 Miscellmneous 96 217 43 0 356 1.7 6.8 54.2 39.0 0.0 1.3 Paper 38 62 57 0 157 0.7 2.4 14.7 . 82.9 0.0 1.4 Petroleum 20 35 25 2 82 0.4 2.0 - 13.6 62.1 22.3 1.0 Printing 1256 146 22 0 1424 6.7 29.2 42.8 28.0 0.0 1.0 Rubber 24 89 50 3 176 0.8 1.2 16.9 68.7 ' 13.2 2.0 Servicesc 430 GIs 65 . 1011 4.7 11.3 56.2 29.8 3.0 2.8 .. ;2P: : . r ; . 421.7;, . > Tgri'6 r ; 4 r 94; 24> :2i2 r. ;[c i. ? J 601 15ii :" .62 78 .r;:{ .3 -* 8. Tobacco 3 22 3 0 28 0.1 1.2 72.8 26.0 0.0 0.1 Transportation' 238 572 84 1 895 4.2 5.0 54.4 37.5 3.1 3.6 Others? 5 2 0 a 7 0 31.6 60.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 Total 10319 8269 2690 113 21391 100 6.6 27.5 48.7 17.3 100.0 *Small: Employ < 200, Medium: 200< -Employ < 1000, Large: 1000< -Employ c 10,000. Large: 10,000< -Employ. 'Non-manufacturing branches. able prepared by A. Brown, 0. Ickae. and R. Ryrerman. Table 8. Characteristics of the Largest Firms by Employment in Russia in 1989 Characteristic Statistic To 10 Top 25 Top 50 ToP 100 All Ex-large- Separate Oblasts Number 7 14 26 37 39 Separata Branches Number 4 4 8 15 15 Separate 4-digit Industries Number 4 9 22 40 46 Employment % of Total 4.6 8.0 11.6 ti6.3 17.3 Mean 62,649 43,966 31,958 22,421 21,027 Employment with % of Total 4.0 7.1 10.2 14.3 20.8 est rimtedMlC Mean 92,698 65,561 46,899 33,001 22,073 Employment Share of Total Sample', Mean 15.8 17.3 17.5 15.5 15.8 Employment Share of Regional Sample Mean 50.0 53.2 54.1 53.7 55.0 Output % of Total 4.2 9.8 14.4 21.6 22.9 Mean 1860.7 1734.9 1273.3 952.9 895.2 Output Share of Total Sample Mean 16.9 .19.0 18.8 16.0 16.7 Output Share of Regional Sample Mean 51.3 52.6 55.1 54.5 55.9 'Exlarge refers to enterprises with greater than 10,000 employees, of which there are 1 13 in the PlanEcon sample and 217 in the sample with the estimated MIC-. See Table 2 and the text for explanation. -The share statistics are the means over enterprises of each enterprise's market share within its 4-digit industry as measured by the given variable far the given market. Notes: 46 of the top 50 enterprises represent only four branches. The other four enterprises are each from separate branches making the total branches represented eight. In the top 50 there are only six enterprises which are dominant nationally, that is only six with greater than or equal to 35% employment share of the sample. There are only eight which are dominant in terms of sales. In the top 50, 35 enterprises are dominant in terms of employment in their regional market, and 33 are doaiinant in terms of sales in their regional market. The biggest drip in employment size is between the third and fouth enterprises going from 88969 to 58379. Only one-third of the extra-large enterprises have employment between 20,000 and 100,605, while the other two-thirds have employment between 10,000 and 20,000. Kemerovskaya Oblast has the largest share of very big enterprses; it contains six of the top 25 and seven uf the top 50.. Table prepared by A. Brown, B. Ickes, and R. Ryterman. 50 Table 9. Aggregate Concenration Shares in the U.S. and Russia Shr of f100 Sere of 200 Larvgot Larpxt Manu_ming Manufnuti'no Nation Siz Meumre Cepeaden An %I Cepuudu tin%) United Stat.s Domdic vlw uedded 32 43.2 tl9U21 1nDesde plant suln 31.1 44.0 Enloymimt in the U.S 23.8 32. Ru#ia Emnplynwnt in nmnufacturin 15.7 23.4 (1919) U.S. data are astablishment data. Sources Scherer and Ross [1990, p. 591 and PlanEcon data. Table prepared by A. Brown, B. Ickes, and IL RytenMan. 5L 51 Table 1 0. Aggregate Concentration in Russian and U.S. Manufacturing Perent of manufacturing sales accounted for by- lumber of 4 largest 8 largest 20 largest 50 largest Nation Companies companies companies companies companies Russia 17,196 6 9 15 24 (1989) United States 310,341 9 12 18 27 (1987) .v - . __. U.S. data is company data. Sources U.S. Census Bureau 1987 Concentration Ratios in Manufacturing and PlanEcon data. Table prepared by A. Brown, B. Ickes, and R. Ryterman. 52 Table 11. Measures of Industrial Concentration of Firms in Russia In 1909 Value of Statfstic for Industries * with the FollowingNumher of firms Measure of mor Concentration Statlslti 1 3 4 6to 10 it la20 2ItO50 51to 100 than 100 Number of Industiies 43 24 1 .: 21. . 80 75 63 34 - 472 Percent of all Industries Frequency 1'1.11 6.9 4.7 8.2 19.7 18.5 15.5 8.4:. Cumulative 10.6 1G.5 21.2 :25. 48.1 64.8 80.0 88.5 1EB.O. Number of Firms 43 48 57' .B4 598 1134 2014 2382 .lE3i. Percent of all Firms Frequency n.2 0.? 0- 3-- 0.4 2.8 5.3 9.4 11.1 7.3.3 cumulative . .2 0.4 0 . 0.71d:. 3.9 9.2 18.B 29.7 c.0 - Labor Force Percent of Labor Employed Inumber of workers) by Industries: Frequency D.23 0.38 0.49? . 0.03 10.52 13.27 18.53 13.94 41982 Cumulative 0 22; 0.60 10 9 2 1,92 12.44 25.71 44.24 58.18. 100iO. Charecteristics of Employment in Firms in Industries: Mean 720 1091 1181,., 1556 2420 1609 1265 805 s - Median 255 481 271' .422 694 505 432 3011 Minimum ~2 10 7~1 > Maximum 7.e0 9421 10278 4 100605 48905 ' 45904 20845 !. 546 Range 7'E0 9411 10271 E 100597 48904 45898 20841 8454ts Industries are measured at Ihe 4-digil SIC level. Table prepared by A. Brown, B. Ickes, and R. Ryterman. Table 12. Frequency of Firms by Size In Industrial Concentration Classes Size by Frequency of Firms in Industries with the Following Number of Firms Employment 1 2 3 4 5to10 11to20 21to5051tolIOU >100 Total Small IE < 200) 15 11 24 27 101 203 514 904 8460 10319 Medium (200< -E< 10001 1 7 25 16 30 258 489 048 1022 5468 8269 Large 11000< -E< 10,000) 11 12 1B 28 210 354 510 448 I0B7 2690 Extra Large (E>-10,000) 0 0 1 20 28 35 10 18 113 Total 43 48 67 84 598 1134 2014 2382 15031 21391 Un size by Frequency of Firms in Industries with the Following Four*Firm Concentration Ratios (mployment 91-100% 81-90% 71-80% 61-70% 51-60% 41-150% 31-40% 21-30% 11-20% 0 10% Total Small I(E<200) 97 58 g0 133 127 184 284 912 1i29 6699 10319 Medium (200 < -E < 1000_ 138 87 187 220 277 338 484 1032 1946 3582 8269 Large (1000< -E <10,0I0) 92 58 151 118 254 187 314 531 513 472 2690 Extra Large (E> -1I0,IJO) 8 9 8 14 25 6 32 a 5 0 113 Total 333 212 422 485 883 713 1114 2483 4193 10753 21391 The four-firm concentration ratio Is the employment of the four largest flirms as a percent of total employment in the Industry. Tablp prepared by A. Brown, B. Ickes, and R. Ryterman. Table 13. U.S. and Russian Concentration Ratios Based on SALES Twu.diglt Fmur.finu Eight.fin Industry U.S. Rush U.S. Ru.i. Industry _ Code (19971 (19138 (15975 il989 FODO ANO KINDRED PRODUCTS 20 la 11 19 15 TOBACCO PROOUCTS 21 92 42 97 61 TEXTILE MILL PRODUCTS 22 17 a 29 13 APPAREL AND OTHER TEXTILE PRODUCTS 23 10 6 13 11 LUMBER AND WOOD PRODUCTS 24 10 4 14 7 FURNITURE AND FIXTURES 25 20 11 25 18 PAPER AND ALUED PRODUCTS 25 25 34 39 53 PUBLISHING AND PRINTING 21 a 16 14 23 CHEMICALS AND ALLIEO PRODUCTS 28 19 13 26 22 PETROLEUM ANO COAL PRODUCTS 29 29 41 61 62 RUBBER AND MISCELLANEOUS PLASTCS PROD. 30 16 25 22 36 LEATHER ANO LEATHER PRODUCTS 31 11 21 16 31 STONE. CLAY. AND GLASS PRODUCTS 32 17 3 26 6 PRIMARY METAL INDUSTRIES 33 25 30 36 46 FABRICATED METAL PRODUCTS 34 9 24 13 32 INDUSTRIAL MACHINERY AND EQUIPMENT 35 22 12 28 1a ELECTRICAL AND OTHER ELECTRONIC EQUIP. 36 19 11 29 19 TRANSPORTATION EQUIPMENT 37 46 46 60 55 INSTRUMENTS ANO RELATED PRODUCTS 38 29 24 44 34 MISCELLANEOUS MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 39 7 10O 10 17 Sources U.S. Bureau at die Caom Company Summary (19871 and PhoEcan data Table prepared by A. Brown, B. Icbas and R. Rylhmu Tahle 14. U.S. and Russian Concentration Ratios Based on EMPLOYMENT Tw.digit Four-firm E_ghft-irm tndutuy U.S. Russ U.S. RuB h Industry Cade (18971 (18389 (19871 (19891 FOOD AND KINDRED PRODUCTS 20 9 4 1i 6 TOBACCO PRODUCTS 21 92 33 91 53 TEXTILE MILL PRODUCTS 22 19 5 29 9 APPAREL AND OTHER TEXTILE PRODUCTS 23 10 6 13 10 LUMBER AND WOOD PRODUCTS 24 7 2 10 4 FURNITURE AND FIXTURES 25 15 9 24 15 PAPER ANO AWED PRODUCTS 26 20 18 31 29 PUBUSHING AND PRINTING 27 7 9 12 15 CHEMICALS AND ALLIEO PROOUCTS 28 19 7 27 13- PETROLEUM AND COAL PRODUCTS 29 38 34 66 53 RUBBER AND MISCELLANEOUS PLASTICS PROD. 39 13 17 Ia 28 LEATHER AND LEATHER PRODUCTS 31 12 13 18 20 STONE. CLAY, AND GLASS PRODUCTS 32 19 2 27 4 PRIMARY METAL INDUSTRIES 33 20 10 30 30 FABRICATED METAL PRODUCTS 34 6 16 10 23 INDUSTRIAL MACHINERY AND EQUIPMENT 35 18 9 24 14 ELECTRICAL AND OTHER ELECTRONIC EQUIP. 36 19 11 27 19 TRANSPORTATION EQUIPMENT 37 38 35 52 43 INSTRUMENTS AND RELATEO PROOUCTS 30 23 14 40 25 MISCELLANEOUS MANUFACTURING INOUSTRIES 39 4 7 7 12 SOurces U.S. Census Bureau Company Summary (19171 and PlanEcon datL Table prepared by A. Brawn, S. Ickes. and R. Ryterman. 55 Table 15. Measures of Industrial Concentration of Finms in Russia fOr 1989 Value of Statistic for lndusides I in the Following Decilas of Faur-rirm Concantrarion Ratios of EA&PLOYMENT Afeasure of Concentraton SOafista 1solS0 111020% 21 to30% 311o 40% 41 to 505 51 to 60% 61 to 70% 711io 60% 81 to 90% St to 100% Total Number el Industries 20 31 37 27 31 36 33 38 28 125 406 Percent of Frequency 4.9 7.8 L.1 6.7 7.6 8.9 9.1 9.4 6.9 30.8 all Industiles Cumulative 4.0 12.6 21.7 28.3 36.0 44.e 53.0 62.3 69.2 100.0 llumber of Firms 10153 4193 2483 1114 713 663 405 422 212 333 21319 Percent of Frequienicy 50.3 19.6 11.6 5.2 3.3 3.2 2.3 2.0 1.0 1.8 all Firms Cumulative 50.3 69.9 81.5 __ 13.7 90.0 93.2 95.5 97.5 96.4 100.0 Number of Employees 2944198 2232027 2033250 1868026 741955 1530517 628866 662479 666221 444240 13751839 Percent of Frequency 21.4 16.2 14.8 13.6 5.4 11.1 4.6 4.0 4.8 3.2 all Employees Cumulative 21.4 37.6 52.4 65.0 71.4 62.5 67.1 91.9 96.6 100.0 Percent of Frequency 11.2 19.6 7.7 27.9 6.0 10.2 4.0 6.1 4.2 2.9 441320.4 all Sales . Cumulative 11.2 30.8 30.5 66.4 72.4 82.6 86.6 92.7 96.9 100.0 LA Value of Staltistic for Indusiries ' n the following Deciles ol Fourfirm Concentration Ratios of SALES Aleasuy, of Concentration Stallstic 0 to 10% II to20% 21 o130% 311040% 41 to E0% 511060% 61 to 70% 71aO 80% 811090% Sito 100% Total Number of lodusltles 14 19 34 29 30 28 31 41 43 137 406 Percent of Frequency 3.4 4.7 9.4 7.1 7.4 6.9 7.6 10.1 10.6 33.7 all Industries Cumulative 3.4 8.1 16.5 23.0 31.0 31.9 45.6 55'7 66.3 100.0 Number of Firnis 0576 4515 2691 1484 1419 603 516 726 442 419 21319 Percent of Frequency 40.1 21.1 12.6 6.9 6.8 2.8 2.4 3.4 2.1 2.0 all Firms Cumulalive 40.1 61.2 73.8 80.7 97.3 90.2 92.8 96.0 98.0 100.0 Number of Employees 2664951 1476631 1902195 1270028 2126020 65241l 1051921 901732 1005634 500268 13751839 Petcent of Frequency 19.4 10.7 13.8 9.Z 15.5 6.2 7.6 6.6 7.3 3.8 all Employees Cumulative 12.4 30.1 43.9 53.1 68.6 74.6 82.5 89.1 95.4 100.0 Percent of Frequency 21.3 5.0 6.4 21.0 16.4 5:3 7.1 5.4 8.9 3.1 441320.4 all Sales Cumulative 21.3 26.3 32.7 53.1 70.1 75.4 82.5 87.9 96.8 100.0 'Indusities are measured at the 4-diglt SIC level. Four-lirm concentration altiOs ere the sum of the statistic for the four largest firms as a percent of the total of the stalislic for the industry. Table prepared 4y A. Brown, B. Ickes. and n. Ryterman. Table 16. Distribution of U.S. and Russian Manufacturing Industries by Four-Firm Ratias All Ratiosby Sales Four *Firm Concentration Percentage of all Percentap of Percentae Perantp of Ratio Range Number of Industries Industries Tota value added of Output Employment U.S. Russia U.S. Russio U.S. Russi Rusia 0.19 86 25 19.2 7.1 21.7 18.7 28.8 20-39 163 52 36.4 14.9 38.8 17.2 24.0 40459 120 46 26.8 13.1 19.7 33.3 222 60-79 56 68 12.5 1rq.4 14.9 16.3 13.2 80.100 23 159 5.1 45.4 4.9 14.6 11.8 Total 448 350 100 100 100 100 100 Bassian Ratios by Employment Four -Firm Concentration Pecenage of Ill Percentage of Percentage Percentage of Raio Range Number of Industries Industries Tal value added of Output Employment U.S. Russia U.S. Russia US. Russia Russia 0-19 86 39 19.2 11.1 21.7 24.1 37.0 20-39 163 56 36.4 16.0 38.8 35.7 30.5 40-59 120 56 20.8 16.0 19.7 lS.0 13.4 50.79 56 63 12.5 19.0 14.9 11.3 9.8 800100 23 136 5.1 38.9 4.9 10.9 9.2 TotaI 448 350 100 100 100 100 100 U.S. data are for 1982 and ara establishment data. Sources: Scherer and Ross 11990, p.831 and PlanEcon data Table prepared by A. Brown. 8. Ilckes, and R. Rytenman 57 Table 17. Frequency of Firms by Firm-Indusury and Concentration Ratlo Number of Firms Incidence of Firms in Indus_ties with the Following Four-Firm Concentration Ratios of Employment in industry 0lto 100% 81 to 90% 71 to 80% B1 to 70% 61 to 80% 41 to 50% 31 to 40% 21 to 30% 11 to 20% 0 to OV% Total 1 43 a a 0 0 U a 0 0 0 43 2 48 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 48 3 57 0 0 0 O O O .0 0 0 57 3 __________ ______________________ . ____ 4 84 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 84 Ln _ 5 to 10 101 175 181 72 69 0 a 0 0 0 598 lto2O 0 37 212 204 239 282 60 0 0 0 1134 21 to50 0 0 29 .119 286 421 671 498 so 0 2014 51 to iOO- 0 0 0 0 89 0 338 1335 528 96 2382 > 10.0 0 0 0 0 0 0 147 650 3577 10657 15031 Total 333 212 422 485 683 713 1114 2483 4193 10753 21391 1ndustries are measured at the 4.diglt SIC level. Thealour*lirm concentration ratio is the employment In the four largest firms as a percont of total employment in the Industry. Table prepared by A. Brown, B. Ickos, and R. Ryterman. Table 18. Sales Concentration Ratios for Representative Industries for the United States (1987) and Russia.(1989) 4&Firm bEe 8 irm Ratio |Nubsr of Firm. S1C Code Industry Descriptien U.S. Ruia I U.S. Susie lU.. Rusio 2067 Chewing gum 96 10o 8 33310 Ptimary copper' 92 54 120 85 7 12 2111 Cigarenes 92 30 IDI 59 9 24 3641 Electric lamps S1 77 94 94 93 12 3711 Passengercars 90 84 95 90 352 10 2043 Cereal breakfast foods 17 99 33 2082 BOr and malt beverages 07 13 98 22 101 237 3632 Household frif eortors and freezers i5 98 40 3211 Ratcans 82 63 (DI 74 65 29 3511 Turbines and tumibe generators 90 91 35 99 68 10 3221 Glass containers 7 33 u9 53 35 36 3334 Primry aluminum 74 66 95 92 34 11 3721 Aircraft 72 92 137 3011 Tres and inner tubes 69 60 87 92 114 10 2841 Soap and detergents E5 76 76 95 683 11 3691 Storage batteries 64 57 78 81 125 13 3562 Ball and roller bearings 59 53 69 84 113 19 3411 MetaI cans 54 100 70 100 161 2 2822 Synthetic rubber 50 65 76 92 55 10 3144 Women's footwear, excpt athledic 50 61 123 (3140) Footwear 25 37 111 3523 Farm machinery and equipment 45 42 52 59 1576 147 3312 BlasxfumaacesandsteelniUls 44 46 63 71 271 36 2041 Rour and other grain mils 44 14 63 23 237 235 n11 Cotton weaving niuls 42 18 59 28 246 122 3574 Seniconductors 40 100 59 100i 755 2 3651 Household audio and video equip. 39 1WO 59 100 360 1 3621 Motors nd generators 36 30 49 49 349 48 2051 Bread. cake, and related products 34 8 47 11 1948 1467 3965 Fasteners buttons. etc. 33 80 43 92 247 16 2873 Nitrigenous ferlizer 33 49 55 79 117 13 2911 Petroleum refining 32 42 52 65 200 , 31 3541 Metal-cutting machine tools 31 28 41 46 381 51 2066 Bottled and canned soft drinks 30 33 40 45 646 76 3241 Portland cement 28 24 47 **40 123 42 2851 Paints and allied products 27 74 40 84 1121 .61 2653 Corrugated and sold fiber boxes 26 10D 41 100 952 4 2711 Newspapers 25 54 39 65 7473 32 2834 Pharmaceutical preparations 22 33 36 52 640 63 2026 Fluid ilk * 21 10 32 15 652 472 3552 Textile machinery 20 57 30 81 475 17 3452 Screw machine products 16 99 24 100 834 5 2421 Sawmills nd planning nils is 210 21 32 5252 199 3273 Ready-mixed concrete 8 28 11 45 3749 40 2335 _Wmensandmisses' dresses 6 100 10 100 5398 3 U.S. da are establishment dna. IDI Withheld to avoid discDsing data for individual cnvt anies. *U.S. statistics are for 1982 from Scherer and Ross Sources Scherer and Ross 11990. p. 771. U.S. Burmau of Census 1987 Concentration Ratios in Manufacturing, and PlanEcon date Table Oreoared by A. Brown. B. Ickes. and R. Rvternan 59 'Table 19. Frequency of Dominant Firms within Industies in Russia in 1989 #as % of su as % of Measured in employmert # of fimns nat'l total nat'l sum National Fimrs with > -35% of market in their industry . 173 0.81 3.8 Of those, firms in industries where only ons firm has more than 35% 135 0.63 3.5 Regional Finns with > -35% of market in their industry 2122 9.92 34.9 Of those, firms in industries where only one firm has more than 35% 1634 7.64 27.8 Measured in sales National Firms with > - 35% of market in their industry 203 0.95 7.6 Of those, finms in industries where only one firm has mare than 35% 163 0.76 6.7 Regional Firms with > -35% of market in their industry 2189 10.23 37.9 Of those, fims in industries where only one firm has more than 35% 1751 8.19 30.8 *Industry is measured at the four-digit SIC level. Table prepared by A. Brown, B. Ickes, and R. Ryteman. 60 Table 20. Concentration Characteristics of Firms by Industrial Branches in Russia In 1989 FIRMS with > - 35%; Employment Share In their 4dig1t Int, INDUSTRIES wlth firms with > -35% Employment Shares As ftarof As Sharo1 of In Ind #of 4digit As Shaerof #firms In AiShaerof As Share of Branch #Fi rms Branch irs BaeEm wt only I Indusre #lofInd Bronch Ind theso Ind Branch Firms Branch Em Agricultuie' 5 0.3 0.4 3 8 4 50.0 is 1.2 0.5 Apparel 10 12 3,3 8 19 a 421 26 31 4.6 Chemicals 5 11 50 6 27 5 I 35 77 113 Construction' 0 0.0 0.0 a I a 0.0 0 0.0 0.0 Food 7 011 0 5 B 35 B 17.1 10 0.2 0.6 Furniture 4 1.0 0.4 P 9 4 44.4 6 1.5 0.5 Ind M&E Is 1.5 6.2 14 44 Is 34.1 93 8.5 11.2 Lumber 4 0.2 0.3 2 14 3 21.4 4 0.2 0.3 Mining' 12 1.8 10.9 12 27 12 44.4 94 14.2 22.9 Miscellanuour 8 2.2 5.1 a 16 a 50.0 31 8.7 8.7 Petruleum 2 2.4 1 2 2 5 2 40.0 11 13.4 2.5 Primary Metal 10 4.4 3.3 8 19 9 47.4 25 11.1 5.3 Printino 9 0.6 4.0 7 13 a 61.5 30 2.1 8.8 Rubber 4 2.3 1.1 2 10 3 30.0 a 3.4 1.2 Services' 0 0.0 0.0 0 11 0 0.0 0 0.0 0.0 Sltone C&G , 0.3 1.5 4 26 5 19.2 40 2.0 3.5 Textile 10 1.7 2.5 6 21 6 39.1 27 4.5 4.3 Tobacco 2 7.1 3.4 2 3 2 69.7 4 14.3 4.5 Transpart Equip 3 0.9 1.7 3 9 3 33.3 10 2.9 3.2 Trinspattatian' I 0.1 0.1 1 a 1 16.7 1 0.1 0.1 Others 3 42.9 77.9 3 3 3 100.0 7 100.0 100.0 'Non-manufaclur ing branches. Ta bI prepared by A. Brown, 9. Ickes, and R. Rytermen. Table 21. Concentratlon of Employment In Brenches Across Regions for Enterprlsns In flussla In 199 llow %I Crlumn %len Share ol irantec Central Chernotem E Siberia Far East Kaliningrad N Caucasus North Northwest Urtals Velga Vyatka W Siberis Total E Agriolturst* i0.9. 3.3 6.9 18.3 8.? 4.5 17.0 2.6 10.2 5.7 5.8 5.3 0.E 1.1 1.9 7.1 23.7 0.9 5.6 0.9 1.1 0.8 1.5 0.9 1.6 Apparel '29.6 4.2 3.9 3.6 0.5 13.7 . 2.4 6.8 10.7 10.3 7.6 6.6 4.7 3.2 2.5 3.1 2.9 6.9 1.8 4.9 2.7 3.5 4.4 2.7 3.8 Chamicahs 21.6 5.9 5.5 0.D 0.0 1.7 1.4 4.8 13.0 19.5 9.4 10.5 4.5 6.6 4.5 1.0 0.2 4.3 1.4 4.3 4.3 8.51 7.1 __ 5.5 4.9 Construction' 16.8 4.2 3.8 4.1 0.5 3.0 14.3 6.0 8.2 4.1 3.5 31.3 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.4 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.4 0.1 Eleelroriles 24.1 9.5 4.1 1.2 1.0 8.5 0.1 8,6 13.3 9.3 11.6 10.6 3.3 8.1 2.2 0.9 5.4 2.4 0.0 5.3 2.9 2.7 5.0 3.7 3.2 Fabricated Metal 21.6 7,2 3.9 3.2 0.0 10.1 0.9 12.4 15.4 9,2 9.4 6.8 _______ __ 2.6 4.0 1.9 2.0 0.0 _ 3.2 0.5 6.6 2.9 2.3 4.0 2.0 * 2.8 Food 17.3 8.8 4.7 8.7 0.8 14.5 3.6 4.6 10.5 11.3 5.3 9.6 _______________ 7.1 16.9 7.6 19.3 12.6 15.9 7.4 8.4 6.7 9.7 7.9 9.5 9.6 Furniture 25.1 3.6 5.1 3.7 0.6 17.6 3.3 5.1 8.4 9.0 6.6 8.8 1.8 1.2 1.4 1.4 2.1 3.4 1.1 2.8 0.9 . 1.4 1.7 1.6 1.7 Ind M&E . 27.3 6.7 2.8 1.6 0.4 10.5 2.1 5.9 15.5 13.4 5.4 8.4 15.8 18.2 6.4 4.9 6.2 16.3 5.8 15.3 14.1 16.3 11.3 12.2 13.6 Instruments 43.0 1.8 1.7 0.5 0.6 8.8 0.1 8.5 8.9 14.3 6.2 5.71 3.7 0.7 0.0 0.2 1.9 2.0 0.0 3.3 1.2 2.6 1.9 1.2 2.0 Leathar 2S,8 5.6 2.8 2.3 0 .4 13.3 1.0 9.3 13.86 11.6 6.4 6.0 1.EI 1.9 0.6 0.9 1.2 _ 2.0 0.3 3.0 1.6 1.0 2.2 1.1 I.7 Lumbar 11.7 0.9 16.7 6.1 0.3 2.6 19.2 4.5 14.6 4.4 7.7 9.1 3.4 1.3 19.1 12.5 3.7 2.0 26.1 5.9 6.6 2.7 5.0 6.6 6.8 Mining 6.8 3.4 9.5 7.6 0.2 IIA 10.6 2.2 18.3 3.7 0.8 25.6 2.3 5.4 12.8 14.1 3.0 10.5 17.1 3.4 9.9 2.61 1.0 22.1 8.0 Miscellaneous 37.1 2.2 2.1 1.0 0.0 10.3 4.1 10.0 11.4 4.5 14.2 3.1 2.1 0.6 0.5 0.3 0.0 1.5 1.1 ! 2.5 1.0 0.5 2.8 0.4 1.3 a.,~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 1.3 Table 21 Cant. Shari o1 Otanvh Cenlral Chernozem E Sibetla Far East Kallningrad N Caucasus North Northwest Urals Vel Vyatka W Siheria Total E Paper 14.1 0.7 11.4 6.9 4.6 1.8 25.0 12.5 11.8 4.4 6.2 0.6 -- __________O.9 _0.2 _2.7 2.1 10.9 0.3 7.2 3.4 1.1 0.6 1.4 0.1 _1.4| Petroleum 14.2. 0.1 14.5 1.8 0.0 8.3 0.8 3.2 28A4 14.8 5.1 8.8 0.l -0.0 2.4 0.4 0.0 0.9 0.1 0.6 1.9 1.3 0.8 0.9 1.0 Primary Metal 15.0 6.8 4.3 1.5 0.0 3.1 5.8 1.5 43.3 5.1 4.3 9.4 ___________ 3.9 6.3 4,5 _2.1 0.4 2.2 _ _7.1 _ 1.; 17.7 2.1 4.1 6.2 _ 6.1 Plinliiig 41.3 3.3 3.1 3.2 0.5 6.7 2.7 9.6 10.6 8.6 3.6 8.3 1.8 0.7 0.5 0.8 0.9 0.8 0.1 1.9 0.8 0.8 0.6 0.7 1.0 Rubber 29.0 8.1 2.8 0.5 0.0 5.9 0.2 68.8 .2 20.0 5.9 10.9 ___________2.E 3.2 0.9 0.2 0.0 1.3 0.1 3.4 1.1 3.6 1.8 2.3 2.0 Serwice., 25.6 4.3 6.8 5.0 OA .10.5 2.1 5.3 15.9 10.1: 4.6 9.4 3.1 2.4 3.3 3.3 1.8 3.4 1.2 2.9 3.0 _ 2.6 2.0 2.8 2.8 Slone C&C 26.5 5.7 8.0 4.8 0.3 9.1 3.3 6.7 14.5 . 11.6 4.6 8.9 __________ _8.1 8.5 7.8 6.3 4.0 7.e 4.9 8.1 7.3 7.8 5.3 7.2 7.5 TextIl e 55.2 3.2 4.0 0.7 0.3 7.3 1.3 5.3 6.5 7.8 4.1 4.2 .14. 3.9 4.2 1.1 3.2 5.2 1.8 6.3 2.7 4.3 4.0 2.8 8.2 Tobacco 23.7 10.5 2.2 0.0 0.0 18.2 0.0 13.5 8.1 7.8' 0.2 7.7 0.1 0.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.01 0.3 0.1 O.1 0.0 0.1 0.1 Transport Equip 25.5 1.9 3.6 3.7. 0.9 4.8 2.2 1.7 1OA 47.1 15.7 2.6 7.9 2.7 4.4 6.1 11,3 4.0 3.2 2.4 5.0 17.6 17.5 2.0 7.2 Transportation 15.2 4.3 11.9 9.1 0.4 6.7 7.4 '3.5 14.6 10.2 5.1 11.7 2.3 3.1 7.2 7.5 2.2 2.6. 5.4 2.4 3.5 3.3 2.8 4.5 3.6 Othets 38.1 0 .0 0. 0. 0.0 . 30.2 0.0 .0 0 68. 13.8 0.0 8.5 ___________0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.a 0 .0 _ 0.0 D.0 0.O 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Share of total E 23.4 5.0 6.9 4.3 0.6 897 5.0 5.2 14.9 11.2 6.5 9.3 IOO.D 'Non-manulacturlng branches. Table prapated by A. Brown, S. Ickes, and R. Rytorman. a'~~ w Table 22. Measures of Industrial Concentration Across Regions In Russia for 1989 Firm-lndustries' Firm-lndustries Region StalTistic 1 <-4 Region Statistic 1 <-4 Central % of Industiles 19.0 49A North % of IndustrIes 39.2 68.4 Yof Firms 1.4 7.6 % of Firms 4.7 14.2 % of Employment 1.7 19.9 % of Employment 19.8 36.9 Chernozem % of Indusities 38.8 71.3 Northwest % of industries 37.0 77.2 % of Firms 5.9 19.1 % of Firms 8.5 30.9 % of Employment 15.5 49.0 % of Employment 17A 52.0 E. Siberia % of Industries 40.1 73.1 UralS % of Industries 27.1 61.0 X of Firms 4.R 15.1 Y of Firms 3.0 13.2 % of Employment 10.7 38.7 % of Employment 8.2 29.5 Fat East X of Industiies 42.1 70.1 Volga % of Industries* 27.5 63.0 X of Firms 5.6 15.0 X of Firms 3.0 14.1 X of Enployment 12.4 24.3 X of Employment 7.3 41.1 Keliningrad % of Industries 62.1 84.8 V Vyatka X of Industries 38.8 71.1 X of Firms 27.0 62.8 X of Firms 5.3 18.6 X of Employment 26.3 70.5 X of Employment 15.1 52.5 N. Caucasus X of Industries 33.1 55.7 W. Siberia % of Indusiries 32.2 65.2 X of Firms 3.9 14.1 X of Firms 3.7 13.9 X of Employment B.9 25.3 % of Employment 8.5 29.5 Column lists the value of the statistic for industries with the given number oa firms in that industry in that region. Industries are measured at the 4-digit SIC level. Table prepared by A. Brown, B. Ickes, and R. Ryterman. Table 23. Geographic Distribution of Firms and Industries in Russia fot 1989 Value of Statistic for OBLAST$ fn Each of the Foalowing Decfils' Unit Statistic 1 2 3 4 6 a 7 8 9 10 Total Firma Mean 67.6 129.3 177.0 203.5 232.3 263.7 304.8 379.9 439.4 655.3 Minimum 27 98 157 l8e 221 247 288 340 404 517 27 Maximum 97 155 187 217 244 277 328 402 507 898 898 Range 70 57 30 29 23 30 40 62 103 381 871 Industries Mean 33.5 55.5 63.1 69.8 81.6 85.7 95.0 114.5 128.6 179.8 Minimum 18 44 60 07 77 89 91 106 125 135 18 Maximum 41 B0 B8 74 85 91 103 123 132 234 234 Range 23 16 a 7 a .5 12 17 7 99 216 Value of Siatlstif forCIT/ESin Ehch of the Following oDed11s Unlt StatIstin 1 2 3 4 5 0 7 9 9 10 Total Firma Mean 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.3 2.0 3.0 4.5 7.2 105.0 Minimum 1 1 I 1 1 2 Z 4 5 9 1 Maximum 1 1 I 1 2 2 4 5 9 768 788 Range 0 0 0 0 1 0 2 1 4 759 767 Industries Mean 1 1 1 1 1.2 2 2.9 4.4 0.9 54.1 Minlmum 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 4 5. 9 1 Maximum 1 1 1 1 2 2 4 5 9 234 234 Range 0 0 0 0 1 0 2. 1 4 225 233 Industries are measured at the 4-diglt SIC level. Each decile contaTns 10 percent of Russian cities or ablasts ranging from smallest to largest based on the unit of observation being analysed. For example, when analyzing the geographic distribution oa firms In cities, cities are ranked based an their totil number oa firms. Table prepared by A. Brown, B. Iekes. and R. Ryterman. Table 24. Characteristics of Firms in Russian Cities by Firm and Industry Concentration for 1989 Value of St tittic for Cilia. wiih the Foliowing lNmter of FIRMS Attrliute Statistil 1 2 3 4 6tol 11 ta 20 2Itc 90 61to 100 101 to 200 >200 Nwnmbr 4f Total Clik . Number 2097 576 356 292 693 228 92 33 15 2 Poment of Total Citles Frequercy 47.9 13.2 9.1 8.4 15.8 6.2 2.1 0.8 0.3 0 Cumulative 47.9 81.1 69.3 75.7 91.6 96.9 98.9 99.6 I00 100 Number ofloslFlmim Numbef 2097 1152 1069 1128 4660 3246 2760 2334 1632 1114 Poecent of Toltl Firma Frequency 9.9 6.4 6.0 5.3 21.8 15.2 12.9 I0.9 98. 5.2 Cuniuf liv. 9.8 16.2 20.2 25.5 47.2 82.4 75.3 96.2 94.9 tOO EmploymentbyFrlms Men 335.9 319.2 286.7 274.3 361.2 659.3 1030.8 940.0 1108.B 1051.2 (numbeor) Median 179 90 64 62 76 122 148 128 213 645 Minimum I 1 3 1 1 1 2 4 5 9 Meximum 7157 6511 17784 40960 25525 30t92 99980 33235 10605 59379 Reng 7156 8510 17781 40959 25524 30091 99959 33231 100600 58371 Varilane 209203 424810 959389 1919212 1014338 2890801 13736589 U95489 12880984 5450188 Caef Var 138.2 204,2 341.6 491.8 278.9 267.9 359.8 226.8 320.9 222.1 Ori Peceint of Total Frequeney 6.1 2.7 2.2 22 12.2 i 15.6 20.7 IC.0 14.8 8.5 Employment Cumulative 5.1 7.8 10.0 12.2 24.4 40.0 60.7 78.7 91.5 108.0 Value of Sfo tutu for Citl J H'th th Folo Wing Numberof INDUSTRIES Attribute Statitle 1 2 3 4 to 10 11to20 21to60 S1 to 100 OlOto200 >200 Numbor of Tatil Cilhs Number 2125 573 359 291 690 228 el 36 1 1 Percent of Total Ciltie Frequency 48.8 13 8.2 8.4 15.9 5.2 1.9 0.8 0 0 Cumulative 48.6 61.7 69.9 78.3 92.1 97.3 99.1 100 100 100 Number of TolFinmn Number 215S 1169 1105 1151 4791 3499 2947 3470 348 769 Percent of Total Firms Froquency 10.1 5.5 5.2 5.4 22.4 16.3 13.8 16.2 1.0 3.6 Cumulaltlv 10.1 15.5 20.7 28.1 49.5 64.9 73.8 94.9 96.4 100 Employment by Flims Mean 336.7 338.4 283.7 276.0 370.0 693.6 101?.9 1055.0 1115.9 1022.1 (number) Medlin 182 65 82 61 78 123 123 178 1047 242 Minimum I 1 3 .1 1 1 2 4 10 8 Maximum 7157 16930 17784 40960 25525 32348 99960 100605 13354 59379 Ringo 7159 18929 17781 40959 25524 32347 99959 100601 13344 59371 Vauiance 205945 701343 638042 1805830 1013561 3289613 12741143 9147E80 2622892 8726288 Coalf Vr 134.8 247.5 302.9 489.9 272.9 261.9 350.7 286.6 145.1 253.7 Poercnt of Total Frequency 6.3 2.9 2.1 2.3 12.9 17.8 21.8 26.6 2.9 5.7 Employment Cumulative 5.3 8.2 10.3 12.6 26.5 43.1 64.9 91.6 94.3 100.0 Table prupared by A. Brown, B. Ickes, and R. Ryterman. Table 25. Employment Size of Firms In Cities by Firm Concentration ir Russia for 1989 Value of tho Statistic for Cities with tho following Numher ofFirms 1 2 3 4 Sto 11 11 to20 21to50 51tol0 101tto200 >200 Total Number of Cities 2097 578 356 282 693 228 92 33 15 2 4374 Number Size by of Firma Employment Small 1105 737 802 962 3105 1465 986 728 447 204 10319 IE < 2001 Medium 866 340 215 217 1215 1335 1392 1129 968 592 8269 (200<-E< 10001 Large 126 75 49 48 330 421 469 460 400 312 2690 11000< -E< 100001 Extra Large 0 0 2 1 10 25 33 19 17 6 113 (E < - 100001 Total 2097 1152 1066 1128 4660 3248 2760 2334 1932 1114 21391 Tabl prepared by A. Brown, B. Ickes, and R. Ryterman. Table 26. Frequency of Firms by Industrial Concentration Classes in Cities By Firm Concentration Classes Number of firms Firm Frequency In Cities with the Following Number of Firms in industry 1 2 3 4 to 10 Ill to20 21 to 50 61 to 100 101 to 200 > 200 Total 1 3 2 1 0 6 a 5 6 4 10 43 2 4 1 0 2 1 11 6 3 7 13 48 3 2 1 0 0 6 7 13 4 9 15 57 4 7 0 3 2 16 13 14 9 6 14 84 5to lo 43 14 15 9 67 83 89 85 78 115 598 11to20 93 43 24 24 148 166 182 149 173 134 1134 21 to 50 147 69 43 47 270 288 306 349 311 194 2014 51 to 100 231 99 78 88 381 310 364 376 282 173 2382 > 100 1687 933 904 958 3767 2362 1781 1353 962 445 15031 > Total 2097 1152 1068 1128 4660 3248 2760 2334 1832 1114 21391 4*Firm Concen Firm frequency in Cities with the Following Number of Firms tration Ratio 1 2 3 4 5tolO llto20 21to50 Sito 100 lOlto200 >200 Total 91 to lOO% 23 B 5 5 33 51 48 37 42 85 333 81 to90% 17 12 B 6 28 24 32 30 t28 31 212 71 to 80% 29 11 7 6 G8 55 68 51 55 72 422 G1 to 70% 43 13 17 13 63 78 62 71 67 58 485 51 to60% 50 24 18 19 79 108 117 110 87 73 683 41 to50% 65 34 16 12 g0 87 112 105 125 68 713 31 to40% 109 34 25 42 173 171 182 167 161 70 1114 21 to30% 176 58 el 45 309 323 422 469 383 237 2483 11 to20% 384 184 120 147 732 745 684 596 411 194 4193 Oto 10% 1191 798 788 833 3087 160B 1055 698 473 226 10753 Total 2097 1152 1068 1128 4660 3245 2760 2334 1832 1114 21391 the four-firm concentration ratio Is the employment in the four largest firms as a percent of total employment in the industry. Table prepared by A. Brown, B. Ickes, and R. Ryterman. Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Dale for paper WPS1319 The Financial Systemn and Public Astl Demirgflg-Kunt July 1994 B. Moore Enterprise Reform: Concepts and Ross Levine 35261 Cases WPS1320 Capital Structures in Developlng Asil DemirgOu-Kunt July 1994 B. Moore Countries: Evidence from Ten Vojislav Maksimovic 35261 Countries WPS1321 Institutions and the East Asian Jose Edgardo Campos July 1994 B. Moore Miracle: Asymmetric Information, Donald Lien 35261 Rent-Seeking, and the Deliberation Council WPS1322 Reducing Regulatory Barriers to Barbara Richard July 1994 M. Dhokai Private-Sector Participation in Latin Thelma Triche 33970 America's Water and Sanitation Services WPS1323 Energy Pricng and Air Pollution: Gunnar S. Eskeland July 1994 C. Jones Econometric Evidence from Emmanuel Jimenez 37699 Manufacturing in Chile and Indonesia UU Liu WP51324 Voucher Funds in Transitional Robert E. Anderson July 1994 F. Hatab Economies: The Czech and Slovak 35835 Experience WPS1325 The Economics of Research and Anwar Shah July 1994 C. Jones Development: How Research and 37699 Development Capital Affects Production and Markets and Is Affected by Tax Incentives WPS1326 Banks, Capital Markets, and Gerhard Pohl July 1994 L Hovsepian Corporate Govemrance: Lessors Stijn Claessens 37297 from Russia for Eastem Europe WPS1327 Is the Debt Crisis History? Recent Michael Dooley July 1994 S. King-Watson Private Caphal Inflows to Developing Eduardo Fernandez-Arias 31047 Countries Kenneth Kietzer WPS1328 The Use of New York Cotton Futures Panos Varangis July 1994 D. Gustafson Contracts to Hedge Cotton Price Risk Elton Thigpen 33714 in Developing Countries Sudhakar Satyanarayan WPS1329 The Regulation and Supervision of David H. Scott August 1994 K. Waelti Domestic Financial Conglomerates 37655 WPS1330 Revenue Uncertainty and the Choice DelHin S. Go August 1994 C. Jones of Tax Instrument during the Transition 37699 in Eastem Europe Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS1331The Myth ol Monopoly: A New View Annette N. Brown August 1994 M. Berg of Industrial Structure In Russia Barry W. Ickes 36969 Randl Ryterman