Human Capital Development HCD Working Papers Equitable Allocation of Ceilings on Public Investment: A General Formula and a Brazilian Example in the Health Sector Philip Musgrove August 1996 HCDWP 69 Papers in this series are not formal publications of the World Bank. They present preliminary and unpolished results of analysis that are circulated to encourage discussion and comment; citation and the use of such a paper should take account of its provisional character. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirelv those of the author(s) and should not be attributed in any manner to the World Bank, to its affiliated organizations, or to members of its Board of Executive Directors or the countries they represent. Equitable Allocation of Ceilings on Public Investment: a General Formula and a Brazilian Example in the Health Sector by Philip Musgrove Abstract Funds for investment (or recurrent expenditure) should often be pre-allocated among competing entities-territorial units, sub-national governments or others-to give substantial weight to population but also to recognize greater per capita needs in some entities than in others. Such ceilings prevent better-prepared entities from acquiring all the resources, and thereby protect weaker claimants. A general class of simple linear formulas can be used for this purpose: it minimizes arbitrary adjustments, allows for transparent and politically acceptable calculations, and guards against unreasonable extreme values. The procedure is illustrated with allocation of health investment funds among Brazilian states. Contents Introduction ..................,..,,,,,,.....,,,,,,,......,,,,,,,.....,,,..,.,..,,,,.,,.,,.....,., 1 The Formula .,..,,,,..,,,,,..,,...2 The Brazilian Case .5 Complications . 10 Concluding Comment .13 Introduction Not only are resources always limited, but often there are a number of entities- territorial units, sub-national governments, ministries, or other potential recipients- competing for a more-or-less fixed amount to be spent, invested or otherwise applied. When the market cannot be relied on to allocate the funds; and when it is desired to keep the distribution equitable in some sense, which often means keeping it partly proportional to the beneficiary population, it is desirable to 'pre-allocate" the total fund among entities-that is, to set ceilings on how much each of them can receive, subject perhaps to subsequent revision in the light of how funds are actually invested or spent. This note sets out a simple general formula for such pre-allocation and discusses some of the requirements for its application. A specific example of a situation calling for pre-allocation of a fixed fund is provided by the REFORSUS health sector reform and investment project in Brazil, approved in June 1996. It will finance investments under a decentralized, competitive arrangement in which states, municipalities and philanthropic providers submit proposals for sub-projects. This procedure runs the risk that some states, with a greater capacity to generate proposals, would end up getting too large a share of the funds, leaving too little for states which were slower to submit proposals. To avoid this, the total fund available for investment will be pre-allocated among the states, establishing an initial ceiling for each state. A state will not automatically receive that much money; instead the ceiling will 2 reserve those funds to be invested if there are enough acceptable sub-project proposals to absorb them. If the ceiling for a particular state is not reached during the life of the project, despite technical assistance from the Ministry of Health in preparing sub-projects, the unused funds can be reallocated to other states which still have acceptable proposals pending. The Formula The formula for the state-by-state pre-allocation of investment funds has to meet a number of conditions which are likely to recur, perhaps in slightly modified form, in similar situations. The formula must: . Allocate not less than half the total investment fund in proportion to population, in order to be consistent with the rule that at least 50 percent of recurrent expenditures by the Ministry for the purchase of health care be allocated by population. More generally, the share to be assigned according to population-the weight of population in the decision on how to distribute funds-is one of the major choices to be made in these circumstances. Allocating part of a fund by head-count is often regarded as a first, crude approximation to an equitable distribution, to be ' a > 0.5); and X is an indicator of need for additional or excess investment, beyond that associated with population alone. This may be a single variable or a function of several variables. Obviously the construction of X involves all the allocation choices other than the relative weight of population versus all other factors. In order for the formula never to take away from a state or entity, any part of the ceiling distributed according to population, Xe must be non-negative. A zero value implies that the state gets no more funds than it is entitled to on the basis of population alone-that is, it is already a favored state. In addition, in order for the formula to allocate all of F exactly, it is necessary for the national value of X to be the sum of the Xe across all the states, just as P is the sum of the state populations, Pe. With this condition, summing the formula across entities makes it clear that a is exactly the share of the total fund allocated according to population, and (1-a) is the share allocated according to X. This restriction has the great advantage that no other arbitrary parameters are needed in order to ' 0 for every other state e (So no state has any money taken away, that was already assigned according to population); and The sum of the Xe is equal to X, which is the total shortfall in the whole country, or the amount of additional expenditure that would be needed in order to raise per capita spending everywhere to the level in the state (Parana) where it is highest now. The final formula is then Fe/F = a(Pe/P) + (1-a)(Gem - Ge)/(Gm - G) which is linear in Ge and therefore avoids the risks of non-linearity referred to earlier. Complications Several possible and reasonable-sounding complications to this formula were debated and discarded. For example, the need for medical care is not simply proportional 11 to population but depends on the age (and sex) distribution, so it is arguable that Pe should somehow be adjusted for these factors. However, this would make the formula for investment allocation differ from the pure population basis on which part of recurrent spending is assigned. And since there is no one way to '"djust" for age and sex distribution, this would cause more argument over the formula and make it harder to accept politically. Similarly, Ge might be complicated by including state or municipal as well as federal expenditures. But that would take the variable out of the control of the Ministry, would make it less transparent, and might even create a perverse incentive for a state to spend less of its own resources in order to claim a larger share of the investment funds. None of the possible subtleties or complications to the formula appeared to improve it sufficiently in technical terms, to justify the consequent ambiguities and political difficulties. In general, apparent refinements can easily make things worse. The parameter a is necessarily arbitrary, since the only requirement is that it lie between 0.5 and 1.0 The Banks and the Ministry of Health agreed that it should fall somewhere in the middle of that range, so that Xe, the expenditure-related indicator, can actually have some impact on the allocation of funds, but not so much as to make the allocation depart greatly from proportionality to population. In the circumstances of Brazil, a value of a = 0.7 appears satisfactory: 70 percent of the ceiling allocated according to population and 30 percent according to expenditure shortfall. In general, the arbitrary nature of the parameter a is not entirely a bad thing, because it focuses the discussion on the relative importance of population versus everything else, rather than 12 trying to decide on the specific weight of each of a number of variables. Having only one arbitrary number in the decision rule may be the best situation possible: no arbitrariness at all is probably infeasible in many situations, whereas having several unrestrained parameters could make it impossible to reach consensus on the formula or to understand how it would work. Table 1 shows the share of population Pe/P which determines 70 percent of the allocation, the per capita recurrent spending Ge/Pe which determines the other 30 percent, and the resulting investment ceilings, as shares of the total, Fe/F and in per capita terms, Fe/Pe. States are in alphabetical order by two-letter abbreviations; shares are shown as percentages. The formula does reward the states where per capita federal health expenditure is low, particularly those in the North (Acre, Amapa, Amazonas, Para) and some in the Northeast (Bahia, Sergipe) at the expense of the South and Southeast (Rio de Janeiro, Sao Paulo, Parana, Rio Grande do Sul). But since population weighs heavily in the allocation, the range of per capita ceilings is only 2.2:1 (from 2.4 to 5.3), and the need-based allocation never adds more than about half as much as a state would receive on the basis of population alone. (The share of investment is about 1.5 times the share of population, for Acre, Amapa, Para, Rondonia and Roraima, all very small states whose populations have grown by migration faster than health facilities have expanded, so that per capita spending is low and there is a need for public investment to keep up with demographic 13 growth.) The largest absolute gain from basing part of the allocation on current per capita spending occurs in Bahia, because it includes a large share of the population (8.12 percent) with much lower expenditure per head than the maximum in Parana (32.46 versus 58.09). In the other large states (Minas Gerais, Rio de Janeiro and Sao Paulo) the per capita expenditure gap is much smaller and so the impact on investment ceilings is less. Concluding Comment It remains to be seen how these proposed ceilings will be accepted politically, and then whether the states will all be able to propose enough good investment sub-projects to use up all the funds reserved for them. The final distribution of investments may differ from this proposal; but the changes will probably not be very large. The formula provides a simple and transparent basis not only for the calculations shown in the table, but for the discussion and negotiation that will be integral to the project. The same logic, using different variables to construct the second term of the formula, can be applied to many similar situations in which resources need to be assigned in advance on a mixed basis of population size and some measure of additional needs. 14 Table 1: Distribution of Population, Per Capita Recurrent Federal Health Expenditure and Investment Ceilings by State in Brazil Population Per Capita Investment Per Capita Share Spending Share Ceiling State (Pe/P) (Ge/Pe) (Fe/F) (Fe/Pe) Acre 0.29 24.46 0.44 5.3 Alagoas 1.72 35.93 2.17 4.3 Amazonas 1.49 29.37 2.08 4.9 Amapa 0.21 20.94 0.33 5.5 Bahia 8.12 32.46 11.12 4.8 Ceara 4.31 43.31 4.60 3.7 Distrito Federal 1.12 52.66 0.93 2.9 Espirito Santo 1.79 38.39 2.28 4.4 Goias 2.76 48.16 2.71 3.4 Maranhao 3.36 39.29 3.91 4.0 Minas Gerais 10.59 43.92 10.12 3.3 Mato Grosso do 1.23 39.64 1.39 3.9 Sul Mato Grosso 1.48 38.68 1.72 4.0 Para 3.50 23.16 5.37 5.3 Paraiba 2.14 43.06 2.28 3.7 Pernambuco 4.78 42.64 5.13 3.7 Piaui 1.75 42.49 1.87 3.7 Parana 5.59 58.09 3.91 2.4 Rio de Janeiro 8.53 52.58 7.23 2.9 Rio Grande do 1.66 36.34 2.06 4.3 Norte Rondonia 0.86 31.51 1.22 4.9 Roraima 0.17 28.94 0.24 5.0 Rio Grande do Sul 6.15 53.08 5.43 3.1 Santa Catarina 3.10 43.14 3.34 3.7 Sergipe 1.03 32.42 1.39 4.7 Sao Paulo 21.63 57.97 15.93 2.6 Tocantins 0.66 33.57 0.82 4.4 Total or Average 100.00 46.15 100.00 3.5 Human Capital Development Working Paper Series Contact for Title Author Date paper HROWP38 Procurement of Denis Broun September 1994 0. Shoffner Pharmaceuticals in World 37023 Bank Projects HROWP39 Notes on Education and Harry Anthony Patrinos September 1994 I. Conachy Economic Growth: Theory and 33669 Evidence HROWP40 Integrated Early Child Mary Eming Young October 1994 0. Shoffner Development: Challenges and 37023 Opportunities HROWP41 Labor Market Insurance and Deepak Lal October 1994 M. Espinosa Social Safety Nets 37599 HROWP42 Institutional Development in Alberto de Capitani October 1994 S. Howard Third World Countries: The Douglass C. North 30877 Role of the World Bank HROWP43 Public and Private Secondary Marlaine E. Lockheed November 1994 M. Verbeeck Schools in Developing Emmanuel Jimenez 34821 Countries HROWP44 Integrated Approaches to T. Paul Schultz November 1994 M. Espinosa Human Resource Development 37599 HROWP45 The Costs of Discrimination in Harry Anthony Patrinos November 1994 I. Conachy Latin America 33669 HROWP46 Physician Behavioral Nguyen X. Nguyen December 1994 M. Espinosa Response to Price Control 37599 HROWP47 Evaluation of Integrated T. Paul Schultz January 1995 M. Espinosa Human Resource Programs 37599 HROWP48 Cost-Effectiveness and Health Philip Musgrove January 1995 0. Shoffner Sector Reform 37023 HROWP49 Egypt: Recent Changes in Susan H. Cochrane February 1995 0. Shoffner Population Growth Ernest E. Massiah 37023 HROWP50 Literacy and Primary Kowsar P. Chowdhury February 1995 M. Espinosa Education 37599 HROWP51 Incentives and Provider Howard Barnum March 1995 0. Shoffner Payment Methods Joseph Kutzin 37023 Helen Saxenian HROWP52 Human Capital and Poverty Gary S. Becker March 1995 M. Espinosa Alleviation 37599 HROWP53 Technology, Development, and Carl Dahlman April 1995 M. Espinosa the Role of the World Bank 37599 HROWP54 International Migration: Sharon Stanton Russell May 1995 0. Shoffner Implications for the World 37023 Bank HROWP55 Swimming Against the Tide: Nancy Birdsall May 1995 A. Colbert Strategies for Improving Equity Robert Hecht 34479 in Health Human Capital Development Working Paper Series Contact for Title Author Date paper HROWP56 Child Labor: Issues, Causes Faraaz Siddiqi June 1995 I Conachy and Interventions Harry Anthony Patrinos 33669 HCOWP57 A Successful Approach to Roberto Gonzales July 1995 K. Schrader Partcipation: The World Bank's Cofino 82736 Relationship with South Africa HCOWP58 Protecting the Poor During K. Subbarao July 1995 K. Labrie Adjustment and Transitions Jeanine Braithwaite 31001 Jyotsna Jalan HCOWP59 Mismatch of Need, Demand Philip Musgrove August 1995 Y. Attkins and Supply of Services: 35558 Picturing Different Ways Health Systems can go Wrong HCOWP60 An Incomplete Educational Armando Montenegro August 1995 M. Bennet Reform: The Case of 80086 Colombia HCOWP61 Education with and with out the Edwin G. West September, 1995 M. Espinosa State. 37599 HCOWP62 Interactive Technology and Michael Crawford October 1995 P. Warrick Electronic Networks in Higher Thomas Eisemon 34181 Education and Research: Lauritz Holm-Nielsen Issues & Innovations HCOWP63 The Profitability of Investment George Psacharopoulos December 1995 M. Espinosa in Education: Concepts and 37599 Methods HCDWP64 Education Vouchers in Practice Edwin G. West February 1996 M. Espinosa and Principle: A World Survey 37599 HCDWP65 Is There a Case for Antonio Zabalza March 1996 M. Espinosa Government Intervention in 37599 Training? HCDWP66 Voucher Program for Alberto Calder6n Z. May 1996 M. Espinosa Secondary Schools: The 37599 Colombian Experience HCDWP67 NGO-World Bank Toshiko Hino June 1996 A. Thomas Partnerships: A Tale of Two 31151 Projects HCDWP68 The Disability-Adjusted Life Nuria Homedes July 1996 L. Arias Year (DALY): Definition, 35743 Measurement and Potential Use HCDWP69 Equitable Allocation of Ceilings Philip Musgrove August 1996 Y. Attkins on Public Investment: A 35558 General Formula and a Brazilian example in the Health Sector