70909 A WORLD BANK STUDY Design and Performance of Policy Instruments to Promote the Development of Renewable Energy EMERGING EXPERIENCE IN SELECTED DEVELOPING COUNTRIES Gabriela Elizondo Azuela with Luiz Augusto Barroso A WO R L D B A N K S T U DY Design and Performance of Policy Instruments to Promote the Development of Renewable Energy Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries Gabriela Elizondo Azuela with Luiz Augusto Barroso Washington, D.C. © 2012 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000; Internet: www.worldbank.org Some rights reserved 1234 15 14 13 12 World Bank Studies are published to communicate the results of the Bank’s work to the development com- munity with the least possible delay. The manuscript of this paper therefore has not been prepared in accordance with the procedures appropriate to formally edited texts. This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. Note that The World Bank does not necessarily own each component of the content included in the work. The World Bank there- fore does not warrant that the use of the content contained in the work will not infringe on the rights of third parties. The risk of claims resulting from such infringement rests solely with you. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this work do not necessarily reflect the views of The World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Nothing herein shall constitute or be considered to be a limitation upon or waiver of the privileges and immunities of The World Bank, all of which are specifically reserved. Rights and Permissions This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 Unported license (CC BY 3.0) http:// creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0. Under the Creative Commons Attribution license, you are free to copy, distribute, transmit, and adapt this work, including for commercial purposes, under the following conditions: Attribution—Please cite the work as follows: Azuela, Gabriela Elizondo with Luiz Augusto Barroso. 2012. Design and Performance of Policy Instruments to Promote the Development of Renewable Energy: Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213- 9602-5. License: Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0 Translations—If you create a translation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the attribution: This translation was not created by The World Bank and should not be considered an official World Bank translation. The World Bank shall not be liable for any content or error in this translation. All queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to the Office of the Publisher, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2625; e-mail: pubrights@worldbank.org. ISBN (paper): 978-0-8213-9602-5 ISBN (electronic): 978-0-8213-9603-2 DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-9602-5 Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Elizondo Azuela, Gabriela. Design and performance of policy instruments to promote the development of renewable energy: emerg- ing experience in selected developing countries / Gabriela Elizondo Azuela, with support from Luiz Augusto Barroso. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references. ISBN 978-0-8213-9602-5; 978-0-8213-9603-2 1. Energy development—Developing countries. 2. Renewable energy sources—Developing countries. 3. Energy policy—Developing countries. I. Barroso, Luiz A. II. World Bank. III. Title. HD9502.D442E45 2012 333.79’4091724—dc23 2012024070 Contents Foreword vi Acknowledgments vii Acronyms and Abbreviations viii Units of Measure ix Chapter 1 Introduction 1 Summary of Key Findings 1 Note 2 Reference 2 Chapter 2 Background 3 The Growing Importance of RE Development 3 Use of RE Policy Tools to Support RE in Developed and Developing Countries 4 Experience with the Use of RE Policy Mechanisms in Developed Countries 5 Policy Choice and Trends in Developing Countries 6 Notes 9 References 9 Chapter 3 Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries 11 Objectives of the Review and Characterization of the Sample 11 Emerging Experience with Designing and Implementing Price-Setting Policies 13 Emerging Experience with Designing and Implementing Quantity-Setting Policies 18 Policy Interactions and Instrument Compatibility 24 Notes 27 References 29 Chapter 4 Policy Performance 31 Attainment of Targets 31 Effectiveness of Policy Package in Sample Countries 32 iii iv Contents Alignment of Exhibited Trends in RE Deployment to Future Committed Targets 39 Economic Efficiency of RE Policy in Sample Countries 40 Notes 43 References 44 Chapter 5 Policy Trends and Market Structure 47 Market Structure and Types of Policy Instruments 47 Market Structure and Types of Procurement Methods 47 Market Structure and Policy Performance 48 Use of RE Policy Instruments in Different Market and System Structures 48 Notes 50 Reference 50 Chapter 6 Key Findings 51 Emerging Experience with Feed-in Tariff Policies 51 Emerging Experience with Competitive Schemes 52 Emerging Trends on the Use of Price and Quota-Based Mechanisms 54 General Lessons of Experience 54 Final Remarks 55 Notes 56 Appendix A Types of Renewable Energy (RE) Policy Mechanisms and Incentives 57 References 58 Appendix B Policy Package of Sample Countries as of Last Reform, 2009–10 59 Appendix C Instrument Comparison 61 Appendix D Data Sources 63 Glossary 64 Boxes Box 3.1: Feed-in Tariff Policy in Brazil 15 Figures Figure 2.1: Use of Renewable Energy Policy Instruments 7 Figure 2.2: Choice of Policy Instruments to Deploy RE in the Developing World (Number of Countries Introducing Instrument Per Period) 8 Figure 3.1: Mapping the Sample 12 Figure 3.2: Options for Renewable Energy Procurement in Sample Countries 20 Contents v Figure 3.3: Capacity Factor vs. Winning Auctioned Prices for On-Shore Wind (Auction 2009) 22 Figure 3.4: Remuneration Level Efficiency On-Shore Wind 23 Figure 3.5: Evolution of Wind Capacity and Aggregated Capacity Factor, India 25 Figure 4.1: Degree to Which Official Targets on Renewable Energy Have Been Attained 32 Figure 4.2: Evolution of Renewable Energy Capacity and Share in Power System, India 33 Figure 4.3: Evolution of Renewable Energy Capacity and Share in Power System, Brazil 33 Figure 4.4: Effectiveness as Average Annual Growth, India 34 Figure 4.5: Evolution of Renewable Energy Capacity and Share in Power System, Turkey 36 Figure 4.6: Evolution of Renewable Energy Capacity and Share in Power System, Sri Lanka 37 Figure 4.7: Evolution of Renewable Energy Capacity and Share in Power System, Indonesia 38 Figure 4.8: Evolution of Renewable Energy Capacity and Share in Power System, Nicaragua 39 Figure 4.9: Evolution of Average Annual Growth vis-à-vis Average Annual Growth Required for Reaching Targets for All Renewable Energy 40 Figure 4.10: Estimated Cost and Impact of Meeting Renewable Energy Target, Sri Lanka 42 Tables Table 2.1: Renewable Energy Policy Instruments: Adoption and Policy Shifts 8 Table 3.1: Policy Mix in Selected Countries as of the Last Reform, 2010 13 Table 3.2: Feed-in Tariff Design in Sample Countries as of the Last Reform, 2010 16 Table 3.3: Compliance with Renewable Purchase Obligations in India, 2009 17 Table 3.4: Formal and Indicative Targets in Sample Countries 19 Table 3.5: Final Bid in Brazil Auctions and Feed-in Tariffs for On-Shore Wind 21 Table 3.6: Efficiency Comparison: PROINFA and Auctions 23 Table 4.1: Subsidy Required for Meeting Renewable Energy Targets, India and Sri Lanka 41 Table 4.2: Incremental Cost Recovery Mechanisms 43 Table A.1: Types of Renewable Energy (RE) Policy Mechanisms and Incentives 57 Table B.1: Policy Package of Sample Countries as of Last Reform, 2009–10 59 Table C.1: Instrument Comparison 61 Foreword In the early 1990s, developing countries started to introduce different incentives to promote renewable energy investments, especially feed-in tariff policies. Today, more than 30 developing countries have introduced some type of price- or quantity-setting instrument to increase the share of renewable energy in their energy mix. There is an increasing interest among World Bank client countries to learn more about the experience with the design and performance of these policy instruments, especially lessons learned and the degree to which they are succeed- ing in creating sustainable renewable energy markets in developing countries. In response to these client needs, and given the wealth of experience that has emerged over the last few years, the Energy Anchor has started to analyze the effects and performance of renewable energy policies. To this end, this paper discusses the lessons on policy design, implementation, and performance emerg- ing from the experience in six developing countries that introduced renewable energy policy tools before 2005. We hope that this paper serves to disseminate knowledge about some of the important issues and options confronting the implementation and adoption of renewable energy policies. It is also our hope that the analysis set out in this paper proves useful to World Bank Group staff, as well as the authorities and stakeholders of our client countries. Lucio Monari Manager, Energy Anchor Unit (SEGEN) Sustainable Energy Department vi Acknowledgments The main report was produced by the Sustainable Energy Department, Energy Unit (SEGEN) and written by Gabriela Elizondo Azuela (SEGEN), with contri- butions by Luiz Augusto Barroso. Gabriela Elizondo Azuela is a senior energy specialist in the World Bank’s Energy Anchor Unit of the Sustainable Energy Department (SEGEN), and Luiz Augusto Barroso is the technical director of Brazilian consultant company PSR. Maria Shkaratan and Federico Querio (con- sultants), Victor Loksha (ESMAP), and Ashaya Basnyat (SEGEN) also contrib- uted to this report. The editing was conducted by Rebecca Kary. This paper has benefitted from valuable advice, suggestions and clarifications from peer reviewers, country focal points and World Bank colleagues, including: David Reinstein, Demetrios Papathanasiou, Kwawu Gaba, Leopoldo Montanez, Saamer Shukla, Fan Zhang, Xiaoping Wang, Migara Jayawardena, Abdulaziz Faghi, Beatriz Arizu, Luiz Maurer, and Venkata Ramana Putti. The analytical work has been developed under the guidance of Lucio Monari (SEGEN). The work was partially financed with resources granted by the Energy Sector Management Assistance Program (ESMAP). This paper is available online at www.worldbank.org/energy/ vii Acronyms and Abbreviations AAG average annual growth ANEEL Brazilian Electricity Regulatory Agency Agência Nacional de Energia Elétrica BNDES Brazilian Development Bank O Banco Nacional de Desenvolvimento BRIC The countries of Brazil, Russia, India, and China, all of which are deemed to be at a similar stage of newly advanced economic development CDM Clean Development Mechanism Disco distribution company EU ETS EU Emissions Trading System FEC Firm Energy Certificate FIT feed-in tariff FITP feed-in tariff policy GBI generation-based incentive Genco generation company IPP independent power producer MME Ministry of Mines and Energy MNRE Ministry of New and Renewable Energy NAPCC National Action Plan on Climate Change (India) NFFO Non-Fossil Fuel Obligation (United Kingdom) OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development ONS National Power System Operator (Brazil) Operador Nacional do Sistema Elétrico PPA Power Purchase Agreement PROINFA Programme of Incentives for Alternative Electricity Sources (Brazil) Programa de Incentivo a Fontes Alternativas de Energia Elétrica viii Acronyms and Abbreviations ix PURPA Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act (United States) RD&D Research, Development, and Demonstration RE renewable energy REC Renewable Energy Certificate RPO renewable purchase obligation RPS Renewable Portfolio Standard SHP small hydropower SPPA Standardized Power Purchase Agreement SPPDF Special Purpose Debt Facility T&D transmission and distribution TGC Tradable Green Certificate Transco transmission company Units of Measure GW gigawatt GWh gigawatt-hour MW megawatt CHAPTER 1 Introduction This report summarizes the results of a recent review of the emerging experience with the design and implementation of policy instruments to promote the devel- opment of renewable energy (RE) in a sample of six representative developing countries and transition economies (“developing countries�) (World Bank 2010). The review focused mainly on price- and quantity-setting policies, but it also covered fiscal and financial incentives, as well as relevant market facilitation measures. The lessons learned were taken from the rapidly growing literature and reports that analyze and discuss RE policy instruments in the context of different types of power market structures. The analysis considered all types of grid-connected RE options except large hydropower: wind (on-shore and off-shore), solar (photovoltaic and concentrated solar power), small hydropower (SHP) (with capacities below 30 megawatts), biomass, bioelectricity (cogeneration), landfill gas, and geothermal.1 The six coun- tries selected for the review included Brazil, India, Indonesia, Nicaragua, Sri Lanka, and Turkey. Summary of Key Findings In the sample countries analyzed, different types of policy instruments and incentives have been introduced either sequentially or in parallel. The diversity of these policy packages and their effect on renewable energy (RE) scale-up and market sustainability is the subject of the analysis presented in this chapter. The review suggests the following general lessons of experience. A tailor-made approach is necessary: Choice of policy instruments, policy design, and complexity of the policy package (or regulatory regime) should be tailored to the actual conditions of the system in the type of market, supply or demand volume, and nature and level of risks, as well as institutional and administrative capacity. Policy sequencing is critical for policy effectiveness: Policy sequencing, the exis- tence of basic legal and regulatory preconditions, as well as institutional and administrative efficiency are crucial to the effectiveness of RE policy. For example, legal and regulatory frameworks for grid connection and integration, 1 2 A World Bank Study resource and land use and/or the allocation of permits and rights must be in place before RE policy is introduced, and the process for granting permits should not create bottlenecks. Policies that successfully lead to the scale-up of renewable energy may not neces- sarily be efficient: Even if the policy mix succeeds in triggering investments that achieve RE capacity targets, its overall economic efficiency (cost per unit of benefits) may be poor. Policy interaction and compatibility need to be considered: The coexistence of policy instruments has the potential to result in complex interactions and unin- tended effects. Thus, policy makers need to assess the compatibility among policy and regulatory mechanisms or incentives—that is, their combined impact may result in inefficient outcomes. It is also vital that individual policies are coordinated with the wider set of conditions that impact the energy market in a specific setting. Policy and regulatory design is a dynamic process: Developing countries have tested different types of instruments to support RE development (policy shifts) and many are now using both price and quantity setting instruments to support different segments of the RE market. In the sample countries, feed-in tariff poli- cies (FITPs) have required successive adjustments (the challenge has been attracting private investment while at the same time minimizing inframarginal rents). However, policy adjustments should be controlled through mechanisms— perhaps embedded in the policy design per se—that allow stakeholders to man- age the risks in order to maintain a certain level of regulatory certainty (for example, programmed reviews, thresholds on adjustments, and adjustments that affect only new projects). RE policy performance (effectiveness/efficiency) depends on a number of key factors: Even policies with a sound design do not result in effective and efficient develop- ment of RE if other critical aspects are not considered in parallel, including the existence of a sustainable incremental cost recovery mechanism (paid through sustainable subsidy sources or a surcharge on consumer tariffs) and the existence of transmission infrastructure capable for RE integration, as well as clear rules on transmission access and connection. Note 1. The focus is on RE technologies that are not yet fully competitive and that, when compared to conventional sources, exhibit an incremental cost (that is, in the context of systems where externality pricing has not been introduced). Reference World Bank. 2010. “Design and Performance of Policy Instruments to Promote the Development of Renewable Energy: Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries.� Final Report, Energy Anchor Unit, Sustainable Energy Department, World Bank, Washington, DC. CHAPTER 2 Background This chapter discusses the emerging trends and general experience with the use of various policy tools to support renewable energy (RE) deployment in the developed and developing world. A general classification of main policy instru- ments and incentives is provided in appendix A of this chapter. The Growing Importance of RE Development RE plays an important role in contributing to the transition toward low-carbon development growth (to reduce greenhouse gas emissions), in enhancing tech- nology diversification and hedging against fuel price volatility (to increase sup- ply adequacy), in strengthening economic growth (to promote industrial development and employment generation), and in facilitating access to electric- ity (to promote rural development and reduce poverty). The global trends indicate a growing commitment to RE development from developed and developing countries in both the introduction of specific policy levers and investment flows. Although RE technologies still represent a tiny share of the world’s generation capacity mix (about 7 percent, excluding large hydropower), their share in total new capacity additions, considering all tech- nologies, is gradually increasing (from 10 percent in 2004 to 36 percent in 2009). In 2009, investment in RE (excluding large hydropower) was compara- ble to that in fossil fuel–based generation capacity, at around US$100 billion each (UNEP, SEFI, and Bloomberg New Energy Finance 2010). In particular, the growth of RE capacity in developing countries has been remarkable, and associated services and equipment manufacturing industries have already started to boom. For instance, Brazil, China, and India today are among the top 10 countries in the world in the volume of new financing attracted for investments in sustainable energy (with a combined US$44.2 bil- lion in 2009, representing 37 percent of global financial investment in clean energy) (UNEP, SEFI, and Bloomberg New Energy Finance 2010). In 2009 the RE industry in these three countries created almost 1 million jobs, and China alone became one of the largest suppliers of solar photovoltaics, batteries for electric vehicles, wind turbines, and solar hot water collectors (REN21 2010). 3 4 A World Bank Study Upper and lower middle-income countries are also quickly progressing in the development of their RE markets. For instance, developing countries in Asia and Oceania, the Middle East and Africa, and South America (excluding Brazil, China, and India) received almost US$11 billion of new financial investment for both RE and energy efficiency in 2009 (9 percent of the global total) (UNEP, SEFI, and Bloomberg New Energy Finance 2010). Today, more than 50 percent of the existing RE capacity in the world is oper- ating in developing nations. In addition, about half the countries that have issued some type of RE promotion policy are now in the developing world (REN21 2010). Use of RE Policy Tools to Support RE in Developed and Developing Countries Developed and developing countries have accumulated a long history with the implementation of different types of policy tools to support RE development. The RE market is to a large extent a policy-driven market. Developed coun- tries have been designing and implementing diverse types of price- and quota- based mechanisms to promote RE development from the late 1970s. For instance, the United States implemented its first feed-in tariff policy (FITP) in 1978 (Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act, PURPA) and a quota mechanism known as Renewable Portfolio Standard (RPS) from 1983 so that today 31 of 50 states have these obligations in place; in 1990 Germany was the first European country to introduce a feed-in tariff (FIT), and since then many European countries have experimented with either price- or quota-based mechanisms (REN21 2010).1 The United Kingdom, in particular, introduced competitive tenders to fulfill specific RE quotas during the 1990s (the Non- Fossil Fuel Obligation, NFFO), but the scheme was later substituted for a type of RPS mechanism with tradable certificates (known as Renewables Obligation Certificates, from 1998) (Butler and Neuhoff 2004). Developing countries also have a long history of designing and implementing specific regulatory instruments to promote RE. The first four countries to intro- duce some type of preferential tariff or FIT were India (from 1993), Sri Lanka (from 1997), and Brazil and Indonesia (from 2002) (REN21 2010). Quota mechanisms, however, have been less popular in the developing world. For instance, a rigorous RPS—in which a quota or target is specified, a proportional obligation is imposed on utilities or retail companies, and the price is competi- tively determined by the market—has only been introduced as such by a few countries, including Chile (from 2008), Poland (from 2005), and Romania (from 2004).2 Although the use of competitive schemes or auctions to deploy RE in the developing world is less common, some countries have or are now testing their effectiveness (for example, Argentina, Brazil, China, Peru, Thailand, and Uruguay).3 Today, FITPs are being implemented in about 49 countries around Background 5 the world and are often cited as the most effective policy for attracting private investment in RE. Yet, many developed and developing countries still use quota- based mechanisms, including RPSs and auctions (for example, Brazil, Chile, China, France, Poland, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the United States). A range of other supplementary measures is in use that directly stimulates investments in RE, including fiscal and financial incentives, and voluntary mea- sures. These have been adopted in parallel to price- and quantity-setting instru- ments in both developed and developing countries. A significant and growing category of policies that indirectly promote the development of RE are known as cap-and-trade programs. The cap-and-trade mechanism sets a ceiling on the emissions of covered entities, issues allowances or emission certificates, and promotes their trading to generate a market price for emissions. Emissions pricing can also be implemented through a tax policy (for example, a carbon tax). Cap-and-trade schemes are being implemented in many developed countries. In the United States the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative operates across many states, and in the European Union the Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) is active now in 30 European nations. A few developed countries have also been applying carbon taxes since the beginning of the 1990s (the Netherlands and Scandinavian countries), and oth- ers have only recently started to apply them (Canadian Province of British Columbia). As of today, no developing country has formally implemented a greenhouse gas cap-and-trade scheme or a carbon tax. Experience with the Use of RE Policy Mechanisms in Developed Countries There is a large body of literature analyzing the experience of developed coun- tries with the use of different types of policy and regulatory instruments to promote RE development. The literature concentrates mainly on the experience in Europe and the United States. In particular, a long and ongoing debate throughout the literature has focused on what policies are more effective and efficient in driving the sus- tainable least-cost development of RE markets. The debate has centered on the relative advantages and disadvantages between price- and quota-based mecha- nisms, focused mostly on FITs (German and Spanish models), RPSs (United Kingdom, Renewables Obligation Model; United States, Texan RPS model), and auctions (United Kingdom, Non-Fossil Fuel Obligation model or NFFO). In most recent analyses, a general consensus has emerged that FITs are more effective at lowering investors’ risks than RPS or quota instruments (that is, when considering price, volume, and balancing risks). However, some studies indicate that quota mechanisms (an RPS-REC scheme) can be relatively less expensive than price-based mechanisms, considering that FITPs typically offer high subsidy rates (to mature technologies in the case of technology-neutral FITs, and to less mature, expensive technologies in the case of technology-specific 6 A World Bank Study FITs), while RPS-REC systems encourage competition among technologies (and therefore promote the most mature technologies).4 In general, developed countries have made successive adjustments to their RE policies and associated regulatory instruments in response to unexpected feedback effects (for example, effects on electricity or gas prices), difficulties in their implementation, and/or poor performance. Indeed, legal and regulatory frameworks for RE are constantly evolving. Also, some developed countries have made important policy shifts (that is, from price to quantity setting, or vice versa). For instance, the United States made a major policy shift from an early FITP (PURPA, introduced in the late 1970s) to a quota mechanism with tradable RECs (RPS-REC scheme), which became widely used in many states. Likewise, Italy went from an FITP (estab- lished in 1992) to an RPS policy (from 1999). However, Italy has recently reintroduced an FIT for small-scale PV installations (from 2007) and for RE projects with capacities below 1 megawatt (from 2008). Similarly, many states in the United States are starting to consider or experiment with FITs again, especially to support small-scale RE (for example, California from 2006).5 In particular, the United Kingdom abandoned its auction mechanism to pro- mote the deployment of mature RE technologies (NFFO) and moved to a quota system, known as Renewables Obligation, in which the government specifies the proportion of RE that must be supplied by distribution utilities as in the U.S. RPS mechanism (that is, the obligation can be fulfilled through either the util- ity’s own RE generation, the purchase of tradable certificates, or a fixed pen- alty). In 2010, the United Kingdom also introduced an FITP for RE projects with capacities lower than 5 megawatts. The analysis of the recent literature thus shows that developed countries have not only made policy shifts to test the performance of different policy tools, but also that FITs are being offered in combination with either auctions or RPS-REC schemes to support less mature RE technologies or small-scale RE projects. In terms of policy performance, the IEA and OECD (2008) found that high levels of policy effectiveness are linked to three factors coexisting at the same time: (a) a country’s level of policy ambition (for example, level of targets), (b) the presence of a well-designed incentive scheme, and (c) the capacity of the system for overcoming noneconomic barriers that may prevent the proper func- tioning of the market (such as administrative hurdles and obstacles to grid access). Policy Choice and Trends in Developing Countries As of today, about 31 developing countries have introduced some type of price- or quantity-setting instrument to increase the share of RE in the electricity generation capacity mix. Of these, at least 28 have opted for an FITP, and only a few have introduced an RPS or use auctions to deploy RE (for example, Brazil, Chile, China, Poland, and Romania) (REN21 2010). Background 7 Developing countries—especially emergent economies—have also made impor- tant policy shifts, and many are now also using both price- and quota-based instru- ments in parallel to support different segments of the RE market. For instance, Brazil moved from an FITP (known as Programme of Incentives for Alternative Electricity Sources (Brazil), PROINFA and introduced in 2002) to the use of auc- tions (from 2007). Conversely, China moved from the use of auctions (on-shore wind) to an FITP in 2005 (which ultimately applied only to biomass-based gen- eration). Most recently (May 2010), however, China launched an auction to deploy off-shore wind-based capacity. The Philippines is also trying to implement a regime that includes both an RPS-REC system (with a target for mature technologies) and an FITP for less mature technologies (such as solar or tidal). In addition to its FITP and REC market, which support all types of RE technologies, at the end of 2010 India also began to launch auctions to deploy solar capacity. Figure 2.1 shows the policy instrument of choice of various developed and developing countries today, and table 2.1 illustrates the increasing adoption of RE policy mechanisms by some of these countries as well as policy shifts. Although developing countries—especially middle income economies—have gradually adopted economic incentives such as FITPs, the most recent trends indi- cate that upper-middle income countries have started to introduce competitive mechanisms including renewable portfolio standards and auctions (see figure 2.2). Figure 2.1 Use of Renewable Energy Policy Instruments Feed-in tariff 20 European Countries Auction RPS / RO (Spain, Germany) 25 developing France countries China Argentina Brazil Peru UK Uruguay Many USA Argentina European Italy India Thailand Countries Philippines (Netherlands) India Belgium Sweden Chile Poland Romania TGC/REC Market Source: Prepared by authors. Note: Almost all countries apply some type of fiscal or financial incentive in parallel to price or quota-based mechanisms. 8 A World Bank Study Table 2.1 Renewable Energy Policy Instruments: Adoption and Policy Shifts Year FITP RPS/REC Auction 1970s United States (PURPA)(1978) 1980s United States (first in Iowa) Germany (1990) Italy (1992) United Kingdom 1990s Italy (1999) Many European Countries (NFFO) (1990) Indiaa (1993), Sri Lanka (1997) Brazil, Indonesia (2002) United Kingdom (RO) (2002) 2000–05 Nicaragua (2004) Belgium, Austria, Japan, China (2003) Sweden, Canada, Poland Turkey, Ecuador, China (2005) United Statesb (from 2006) Argentina (2006) Brazil (2007) Philippines, Kenya, South Africa Peru (2008), Chile, Romania, 2006–10 (2008) Uruguay, Thailand Philippines (2008) +11 developing countries China (2010) Italy (2007–2008) India (2010) United Kingdom (2010) Sources: Barroso and Maurer 2010; REN 21, 2010. Note: In bold: Countries that have shifted from one mechanism to another or that are using them in parallel. a. Indian states introduced feed-in tariff policies (FITPs) gradually in the period 1993–2008. b. Different U.S. states have started to introduce FITPs from 2006. Figure 2.2 Choice of Policy Instruments to Deploy RE in the Developing World (Number of Countries Introducing Instrument Per Period) 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 1990–2000 2001–2005 2006–2010 1990–2000 2001–2005 2006–2010 FITP RPS/Auctions Low Income Lower Middle Income Upper Middle Income Source: Prepared by authors. Background 9 Notes 1. It is important to note that although the PURPA’s tariff was based on avoided cost, the Act did not exclude the possibility of setting tariffs through competitive schemes. 2. In general, RPS policies use tradable and/or nontradable Renewable Energy Certificates (RECs) to create a market of environmental attributes. The use of RECs has emerged as a market-based tool to facilitate compliance with the purchase obliga- tions (quotas) mandated under the RPS. 3. Even though auctions do not represent a renewable energy policy per se, they are used as mechanisms to promote the development of RE on a competitive basis. 4. FITP can, however, deliver the same results as an RPS-REC or Tradable Green Certificate (TGC) schemes when offering uniform rates across all types of RE tech- nologies (thereby eliminating special provisions for solar or other expensive technolo- gies) (Fischer and Preonas 2010). 5. FIT policies are being experimented with in the United States, though at a smaller scale and less comprehensively than in a number of European countries. To date, several utilities in California, Florida, Oregon, Vermont, Washington, and Wisconsin have implemented different variations of FIT policies (Couture and Cory 2009). References Butler, Lucy, and Karsten Neuhoff. 2004. “Comparison of Feed-in Tariff, Quota and Auction Mechanisms to Support Wind Power Development.� Cambridge Working Papers in Economics 0503, MIT Institute, Cambridge, MA. Couture, Toby D., and Karleen Cory. 2009. “State Clean Energy Policies Analysis (SCEPA) Project: An Analysis of Renewable Energy Feed-in Tariffs in the United States.� NREL. http://www.nrel.gov/analysis/pdfs/45551.pdf. Fischer, Carolyne, and Luis Preonas. 2010. “Combining Policies for Renewable Energy: Is the Whole Less Than the Sum of Its Parts?� Resources for the Future. http://www.rff. org. IEA (International Energy Agency) and OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2008. Deploying Renewables: Principles for Effective Policies. Paris: IEA/OECD. REN21 (Renewable Energy Policy Network for the 21stl Century). 2010. “Renewables 2010 Global Status Report.� REN21 Secretariat, Paris. http://www.ren21.net/ REN21Activities/Publications/GlobalStatusReport/tabid/5434/Default.aspx. UNEP, SEFI (United Nations Environment Program, Sustainable Energy Finance Initiative), and Bloomberg New Energy Finance. 2010. “Global Trends in Sustainable Energy Investment 2010.� UNEP DTIE, Paris. http://www.rona.unep.org/.../news/ GlobalTrendsInSustainableEnergyInvestment2010_en_full.pdf. CHAPTER 3 Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries This chapter establishes the rationale for the need to investigate further the experience with the design and performance of price- and quantity-setting instruments in the developing world and describes the characteristics of the sample of countries subject to the review. Objectives of the Review and Characterization of the Sample A growing body of analytical work is now reporting on the experience of devel- oping countries with the design and implementation of different types of renew- able energy (RE) policies and regulations, especially on a country-by-country basis. However, the general experience and the degree to which these policies are succeeding in creating sustainable domestic markets in the context of differ- ent power sector structures has been less analyzed. Thus, the review was set at identifying the main lessons learned, as well as best practice associated with the design, implementation, and performance of RE policy tools through the experience in six developing countries. The work was limited to a desk review; thus, the conclusions must be eventually confirmed through other more formal quantitative assessments (for example, statistical analyses or appropriate modeling to more accurately assess causality between policies and their impacts). The sample was chosen among the 12 developing countries that introduced specific instruments of regulation to promote RE before 2005 (as indicated by REN21 2010). The selection of countries covers a broad spectrum of economic and power sector sizes, as well as the degree of market liberalization, while at the same time exhibiting the common energy-security problems characteristic of electricity- supply industries across the developing world: fuel dependence and/or reduced or negative reserve margins (that is, peak deficits). In the sample countries, RE policy—or its adjustments—has been stream- lined primarily through legal frameworks associated with the reform and the liberalization of their power sectors (Brazil, India, and Turkey) or through legal 11 12 A World Bank Study Figure 3.1 Mapping the Sample India +10 Peak deficit (%) Indonesia Turkey Brazil Sri Lanka Nicaragua −10 Monopoly±IPP Single purchaser Liberalized market Dependence on coal Dependence on diesel Dependence on natural gas Source: Prepared by authors. Note: Bubble size indicates high, moderate, or low fossil fuel dependence (relative to country demand). provisions specifically addressing security of supply concerns (Indonesia, Nicaragua, Sri Lanka, and Turkey), or both. Figure 3.1 maps the sample in terms of the peak deficit that is exhibited today and the current power supply struc- ture (that is, degree of market liberalization).1 In the sample of countries chosen for the review, all countries except for Brazil and Nicaragua are committed to official targets for RE capacity additions in the system.2 Also, all countries in the sample offer some sort of price-based incentive (for example, feed-in tariffs (FITs), preferential tariff in standardized or small power purchase agreements, reduction in transmission and distribution (T&D) charges, generation-based incentives or premiums), but none of them has commit- ted to a formal Renewable Portfolio Standard (RPS). In particular, India has recently introduced the use of Renewable Energy Certificates (RECs), but this market is not set to function in combination with an RPS, as in the developed countries that have introduced them (United Kingdom and United States); rather, it will operate in combination with state feed-in tariff policies (FITPs) and other supplementary incentives. The competitive route to RE procurement is being used at present in Brazil and India (through auctions), and in Indonesia, Sri Lanka, and Turkey through conventional bidding processes.3 Auctions in India, however, have only been recently launched to deploy solar-based generation (from December 2010). Finally, all countries in the sample offer some sort of fiscal or financial incentive. Table 3.1 shows the composition of the policy package applied today in the sample countries (a more detailed list of incentives is given in appendix B). Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries 13 Table 3.1 Policy Mix in Selected Countries as of the Last Reform, 2010 Policy Instrument IN BR TK INDO NI SRL Targets Formal / official NCRE targets � � � � Price-based instruments Feed-in policies and premiums � � � SPPA (fixed term and preferential price or FIT) � � Reduced T&D costs � � Net metering / banking � � � Carbon market / CDM transactions � � � � � Quantity-based instruments and procurement mechanisms Renewable Portfolio Standard (RPS) Competitive bidding / auction � � � � Investment cost reduction / financial incentives Accelerated depreciation � � Green funds (for example, soft loans, grants) � � � � Capital subsidy / equity participation � Fiscal incentives Tax exemptions � � � � � � Grid connection and dispatch Prioritized dispatch � � � � � � Other measures Green power / retail tariff � R&D funds / subsidies � � � Single window clearance systems � Exempted / reduced licensing fees � � Source: Prepared by authors. Note: Reduced transmission charges may include discounts on wheeling prices or connection costs. IN = India, SRL = Sri Lanka, BR = Brazil, INDO = Indonesia, NI = Nicaragua, TK = Turkey. In the sample, the countries with the lower gross national income and smaller power sector in terms of installed generating capacity (Indonesia, Nicaragua, and Sri Lanka) are the countries with the less-diverse policy package. Emergent economies (BRIC countries) and/or upper middle-income countries exhibit a rich variety of mechanisms for increasing the use of RE. Emerging Experience with Designing and Implementing Price-Setting Policies Price-setting policies reduce cost and pricing-related barriers by establishing favorable price regimes for RE relative to other sources of power generation (World Bank 2008). This section focuses on FITPs, given their importance and effectiveness in driving investments and scaling up RE. The design of FITPs typically involves three key incentives: (a) a preferential tariff, (b) guaranteed purchase of the electricity produced for a specified period, 14 A World Bank Study and (c) guaranteed access to the grid. In general, FITPs impose a purchase obli- gation on national or regional utilities (renewables purchase obligation, RPO) and, in some countries, the obligation to purchase or share the revenues associ- ated with tradable environmental attributes (such as certified emission reduc- tions). FITPs may also offer additional incentives to entities purchasing RE supply, such as reduced cross-subsidy surcharges or reduced wheeling charges. Experience with the design and implementation of FITPs in the sample countries can be summarized as follows. First, except for Indonesia, all countries in the sample have experimented with FITPs, and in all cases the tariffs per se have evolved from simple to more sophisticated formulations (the experience with the Brazilian FITP is described in box 3.1).4 Also, all these countries have made successive adjustments to their FITs, either to increase their performance (effectiveness and efficiency) or to adapt to new system or market conditions (in order to maintain the incentive for invest- ments in RE). In the former case, FITs have evolved from technology-neutral flat tariffs (based on either levelized or avoided costs) to technology-specific stepped tar- iffs (designed to lower inframarginal rents and the overall cost of FIT subsidies) and/or to tariffs with degression factors (designed to account for technology improvement, innovation, and learning). These adjustments are aligned to what has been identified by leading sources as best practice with FIT design in Europe and other developed countries (that is, tariffs differentiated by technology, size, resource intensity, and degree of technological maturity improve the overall economic efficiency of the policy).5 In systems that exhibit a high vulnerability to oil price fluctuations or fuel oil dependence, the FIT structure has been adjusted to maintain the incentive for investments in RE (for example, FITs pegged to international oil prices, or shifts from avoided-cost tariffs to technology-specific, levelized cost-based FITs when the avoided cost of power generation is expected to fall as a result of planned substitutions from expensive to cheaper fossil fuels in the generation mix). In general, all sample countries applying FITPs have successively increased the level of FITs and adjusted the periods of support. However, in some specific cases, frequent FIT design adjustments, especially those that are applied in response to unexpected shocks (fuel price fluctuations or spikes) or system instabilities (volatile spot prices) have lowered policy predictability, increased risks, and rendered the FITPs ineffectual. The analysis of successive policy adjustments and their effectiveness for the countries under consideration suggests that cost-based FITs (that is, not linked to market fluctuations in fuel and electricity prices) are more effective at pro- moting RE market development than those linked to wholesale or fuel prices. Table 3.2 below shows the type of tariffs used to promote RE in the sample countries. Second, all countries applying FITPs offer guaranteed, nondiscriminatory access to the grid and impose a purchase obligation on utilities, retail providers, Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries 15 Box 3.1 Feed-in Tariff Policy in Brazil Programme of Incentives for Alternative Electricity Sources (Brazil) (PROINFA) was the first step toward developing RE on a larger scale in Brazil. However, the initial design of the pro- gram imposed rules and specific constraints that created bottlenecks and affected the overall economic efficiency of RE deployment. The first issue was the allocation of the targeted amount of 3,300 megawatts in equal shares of 1,100 megawatts to wind, small hydropower (SHP), and biomass projects, despite their different costs (that is, the mechanism did not promote the least-cost expansion of RE capacity in the system). Project selection—within the technology specific quotas—was also not based on a least- cost approach. Projects were selected based on the dates that relevant environmental permits were issued (that is, the older the permit, the closer the project was in the merit order for con- tracting). This process ended up creating a “black market� for environmental licenses. In fact, the issue of permitting and licensing in Brazil became a bottleneck to the introduction of new capacity in general, creating serious economic distortions, high transaction costs, and even court cases. In addition, the minimum national business participation rate (that is, equipment and ser- vices of national origin) of 60 percent required by PROINFA became a bottleneck to wind generation development, given that Brazil had only one local wind manufacturer at the time. As a result, not all technologies could reach their quotas, and eventually some volumes of capacity had to be transferred from one technology to the other in order to achieve the total target of 3,300 megawatts. The deadlines for the initiation of commercial operation of different plants were also post- poned several times, and the lack of market confidence in the continuity of PROINFA was considered a “stop and go� situation. In addition, there is no evidence that PROINFA was effective in its management of Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) revenues. Under PROINFA, Eletrobras was responsible for managing carbon revenues to reduce program costs (and hence the “uplift� on consumer tariffs). However, there is no information on whether projects were registered under the CDM or on the use of carbon revenues to lower program costs and reduce consumer tariffs. In general, PROINFA was criticized for failing to provide economic signals for efficiency and technological improvement. Source: Barroso 2010. and large consumers. This is also aligned with international best practice. However, the actual compliance with purchase obligations has been generally poor for two reasons. On one hand, many distribution companies (Discos) (especially those operating in India, Nicaragua, and Turkey) exhibit weak or unsustainable financial balances, and the purchase obligation has become an 16 A World Bank Study Table 3.2 Feed-in Tariff Design in Sample Countries as of the Last Reform, 2010 Fixed price Purchase Country obligation Stepped tariff Tariff degression Flat tariff Premium price Sample countries Turkey X Xa Nicaragua X Xb India X X (wind, solar, X (wind) Xc SHP) Indonesia X Xd Sri Lanka X Xe Xe Some European countries Denmark Xf X X (wind) France X X X (wind) Germany X X X (wind) Italy X X X (PV) Spain Xg X X Sources: Data on European countries come from Klein and others 2008, data on the five sample countries come from a variety of sources (see main report, World Bank 2010). a. The previous scheme (fixed feed-in tariff [FIT] with upper and lower limits, in which renewable energy [RE] generators could opt for the wholesale electricity price) was substituted for a flat fixed FIT (amendments to Renewable Energy Law of December 2010). RE producers can also sell their energy in the “free market.� b. Tariff level is a function of marginal costs and varies with oil prices. c. The generation-based incentives (GBIs) recently introduced for solar and wind are a premium in practice. d. Tariff in Standardized Power Purchase Agreements is fixed at 80–85 percent of avoided cost of power generation (not a FIT in strict sense). e. Independent power producers can choose between a flat and a three-tier stepped tariff; stepped tariff applies to all RE-eligible technologies. f. Except for wind onshore. g. Only in combination with fixed (stepped) tariff. additional burden, especially in cases where the FIT subsidy is not passed on to consumer tariffs (or when the transfer is incomplete or subject to government approvals) (this point is illustrated in table 3.3 for the case of India). On the other hand, the actual design of purchase obligations has—in some cases— lacked penalty mechanisms and realistic escalation schedules or has imposed ambitious targets not aligned with lag times required for the construction of new plants. In particular, different states across India are working toward strengthening the design of RPOs. Third, an important factor in determining the success of FITPs is the exis- tence of a formal incremental cost recovery mechanism. This mechanism must be viable, transparent, explicit, and sustainable in the long term. The lack of a viable and sustainable funding source is indeed a limiting factor to compliance with RPOs and ultimate RE deployment. In systems where FIT subsidies are not passed through to consumer tariffs, FITPs need to be tied to a realistic strategy that outlines the short- and long-term options for the financing of incremental costs (for example, if the funding source is the state budget, tranches to cover FIT policies must be formally approved at the beginning of the fiscal cycle). In India, for instance, fiscal transfers to cover Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries 17 Table 3.3 Compliance with Renewable Purchase Obligations in India, 2009 Targets (introduced Extent to which the target State from 2006) Achievement 2009 has been achieved (%) RPO Andhra Pradesh 5% (1% from wind) 4.52% (target on wind 90 not met) RPO Gujarat 2 2.10 105 RPO Haryana 3 0.01 ~0 RPO Karnataka 7–10 9.47 95–135 RPO Kerala 5 1.22 24 RPO Madhya Pradesh 10 0.11 1 RPO Maharashtra 5 3.17 63 RPO Rajasthan 6.5–6.75 7.49 111–115 RPO Punjab 1 1.8 180 RPO Tamil Nadu 10 n.a. n.a. RPO Uttarakhand 5 1.32 26 RPO Chhattisgarh 10 3.77 38 RPO Himachal Pradesh 20 — — Sources: ESMAP 2010; World Bank 2009, States’ Regulation on RPO (Maharashtra, Andhra Pradesh, Haryana). Note: — = not available, n.a. = not applicable. FIT subsidies have been incomplete, and utilities have been expected to partially cover the subsidy with their own revenues. In Sri Lanka, invoices from the Ceylon Electricity Board to cover the incre- mental costs associated with the existing five SHP facilities (which have been commissioned under the new FIT system) are accumulating at the Sustainable Energy Authority, which has been unable to pay them (Meier 2010). Thus, without a sustainable mechanism for covering incremental costs, the mobilization of financing for new RE investments is implausible, even in the presence of attractive FITs. The implementation of a transparent mechanism to share the incremental costs associated with RE policies (including grid integra- tion and balancing costs) has been identified as best practice across the devel- oped world. This has been achieved in Brazil, but remains a challenge for most of the countries in the review. In particular, the FITPs of Brazil, India, and Sri Lanka have included rules that determine the allocation of carbon revenues to explicitly reduce the impact of FIT subsidies on consumers or tax payers. This measure was not completely successful under PROINFA in Brazil (as described in box 3.1), but it has proven successful in other countries (as long as the additionality criterion is met in the presence of an FITP).6 Fourth, developing countries have learned that some requirements or precon- ditions embedded in the design of FITPs have the potential to constraint the actual use of the incentive and development of RE. For example, the design of PROINFA established the requirement of a minimum business participation rate (that is, 60 percent of services and equipment associated with RE projects had 18 A World Bank Study to be produced or manufactured locally), which seriously constrained the devel- opment of wind-based capacity. In contrast, Turkey recently approved the use of premiums over the actual FIT to promote the use of equipment manufactured locally (proposal approved on December 2010). Other typical constraints affecting the performance of FITPs—and ultimately RE deployment—are related to bottlenecks in the administrative process for granting the required licenses and permits. This has been especially notable in Brazil and India, although both countries have made major efforts to improve the efficiency of administrative procedures. Finally, one important lesson learned concerning the effectiveness of FITPs is that policy sequencing is crucial and that some key preconditions have to be met before incentives to promote RE are introduced. The existence of specific legal and regulatory provisions addressing the issues of land use, resource use, and allocation of rights is also necessary to avoid bottlenecks in RE development. Emerging Experience with Designing and Implementing Quantity- Setting Policies Quota-based or quantity-setting mechanisms (also known as market share poli- cies) mandate the introduction of a certain percentage or absolute quantity of RE capacity or generation at unspecified prices (World Bank 2008). This section focuses on the experience with the use of different procurement mechanisms in the sample countries, especially with the use of auctions in Brazil. None of the sample countries has implemented a formal RPS.7 Formal RE Targets Except for Brazil and Nicaragua, all other countries subject to the review are committed to formal targets on RE (see table 3.4). The extent to which these targets are attainable is discussed below. Procurement Mechanisms As mentioned before, the competitive route to RE procurement is only being used at present in Brazil and India (through auctions) and in Indonesia and Sri Lanka through conventional bidding processes. However, none of the countries in the sample has committed to a formal RPS. In fact, the only developing country that had introduced a formal RPS before 2005 was Poland. In 2008, both Chile and Romania implemented a type of RPS mechanism. The procurement of RE in the sample countries varies from direct contract- ing (cost-plus, fixed-fee contracts) to competitive mechanisms (such as biddings, auctions, and transactions in the wholesale market). In India, Indonesia, Nicaragua, Sri Lanka, and Turkey, the bulk of RE capacity has been procured through cost-plus, fixed-fee contracts. In particular, Indonesia and Sri Lanka have used Standardized Power Purchase Agreements (SPPAs) to Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries 19 Table 3.4 Formal and Indicative Targets in Sample Countries Issued Size of target / share Deadline Official targets India 2008 1% annual increase, about 20% share (NAPCC) 2020 2009 54 GW, approx. 12.7% share (13th Plan) 2022 2010 1 GW, solar capacity (National Solar Mission) 2013 Turkey 2009 30% 2023 Indonesia 2006 10% 2025 2004 2,700 MW geothermal capacity 2010 2008 4 GW geothermal capacity 2015 2008 9.5 GW geothermal capacity 2020 Sri Lanka 2006 10% 2015 European Union 2007 20% 2020 Indicative expansion plans Brazil 2010 Add 10.7 GW, approx. 19% share 2019 Nicaragua 2007 37% share 2014 Source: Prepared by authors. Note: All targets exclude large hydroelectric capacity. procure small-scale RE. In fact, the use of SPPAs in Sri Lanka has been notori- ously successful for rapidly increasing SHP capacity. This has not been the case in Indonesia, however. Figure 3.2 illustrates the options for RE procurement in sample countries. Turkey has recently allowed the use of competitive bidding to procure wind- based generation when there are multiple available projects in the same region. The country also allows RE developers to sell in the wholesale energy market. Also India has recently introduced auctions to procure solar installations. The procurement of RE in Brazil is carried out through auctions, but devel- opers are also allowed to sell directly through bilateral contracts in the free unregulated market. In both, Brazil and Turkey selling in the wholesale market (especially through bilateral contracts) has been a real possibility to RE develop- ers. In the case of Turkey, the spot market prices were well above the FIT in place until the formal approval of new technology-specific FITs in December 2010, and in Brazil, other incentives in place have leveraged the feasibility of bilateral contracts between small-scale RE developers (less than 30 megawatts) and large consumers (that is, discounts on T&D tariffs). Both Indonesia and Sri Lanka now allow the use of competitive biddings for small-scale RE and geo- thermal initiatives, respectively. Experience with Auctions in Brazil Brazil has launched two types of auctions to deploy RE: technology-specific auctions and reserve energy auctions.8 Technology- or project-specific auctions are carried out within the frame- work of the regular auctions to deploy new capacity and supply the regulated market. This type of auction has been used to support specific energy policy decisions or the introduction of special projects (such as large hydroelectric 20 A World Bank Study Figure 3.2 Options for Renewable Energy Procurement in Sample Countries Wholesale market Brazil Turkey spot/contracts (market forces) Sri Lanka India Brazil Turkey Competitive bidding auction (quota set) Indonesia Sri Lanka India Nicaragua Turkey Direct single source Indonesia contracting (price set) Monopoly±IPP Single purchaser Liberalized market All NCRE Only geothermal Only in wind Only solar Plants higher than 10 MW Source: Prepared by authors. Note: IPP = independent power producer, MW = megawatt, NCRE = non-conventional renewable energy. plants). In this case, contracts have to be covered with Firm Energy Certificates (FECs) to ensure that new generation is added to maintain minimum adequacy and reliability levels at the system level.9 Reserve energy auctions, by contrast, are carried out to directly increase the system’s reserve margin. In this case, contracts do not have to be covered by FECs, and the auctioned quantity is independent of the demand forecasts issued by Discos. The experience with the use of auctions to deploy RE capacity in Brazil can be summarized as follows. First, the procurement of RE through auctions has been so far more successful with reserve energy auctions than with technology- specific auctions. In 2007 the Government of Brazil launched the first technol- ogy-specific auction to supply the regulated market where only RE could participate, although participation in the auction was unexpectedly low. This lack of interest has been attributed to the following factors: (a) RE developers have obtained higher prices in the free market because of the attractiveness of the T&D discount (which is offered only to RE of less than 30 megawatts); (b) it is often more difficult for RE to comply with the FEC coverage obligation, since intermittent generation faces a higher risk of penalization; and (c) the upper limit for the remuneration level in the auction was set at a rate lower than the FITs previously offered by PROINFA (Barroso 2010; de la Torre, Fajnzylber, and Nash 2008; IEA and OECD 2008). Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries 21 Indeed, one of the main challenges of auction mechanisms is to attract suffi- cient bidders and ensure that competition is established (for example, it is impor- tant to mitigate the barriers to entry for new players and lower information asymmetries as much as possible). As of today, three “reserve energy� auctions for RE have been launched (August 2008, December 2009, and August 2010), awarding an aggregated capacity of about 6.2 gigawatts in SHP, sugarcane bagasse cogeneration, and wind-based generation for delivery dates between 2008 and 2015, with contract terms ranging from 15 to 30 years. Second, the auctioning of RE in Brazil has resulted so far in low prices (in the lower bound, but not outside the range of international FITs), raising concerns as to the extent to which auction winners will be able to construct and profit from the plants (see table 3.5). Although the auction system in Brazil includes a number of prerequisites and mitigation measures10 to avoid speculative behavior among participants and lower the risk of construction delays or no construction of facilities at all (deployment risk), the actual enforcement and payment of project completion guarantees is an issue of concern (for example, potential lengthy court cases that may then discourage other investors). In general, to ensure that auction winners will deliver the awarded projects it is important to pre-qualify bidders to discourage speculators or financially insol- vent companies from participating and to include ad hoc mitigation measures and requirements (for example, projects with granted environmental licenses and relevant permits, bids that include audited historical records of hydrology or wind velocities, as well as grid access studies that demonstrates the feasibility of the connection point). In addition, the proper design of project completion guarantees and penalties to avoid construction delays and underperformance are crucial for ensuring deployment and operational efficiency. In particular, the low prices that resulted from the reserve energy auctions to deploy wind-based generation carried out in December 2009 and August Table 3.5 Final Bid in Brazil Auctions and Feed-in Tariffs for On-Shore Wind Data 2009–10 (US$ in cents/kWh) Country Tariff level Remuneration period India FIT (CERC levelized tariff 2010–11) 7.4–11.05 India (Maharashtra) 9.92 with annual escalations 6 India (Guajarat) 7.76, 25 years 25 Sri Lanka 20.5, 20 years 20 Turkey (proposed FIT) 11.1, 10 years 10 Nicaragua (Amayo plant) 8.6, 20 years 20 Germany 9.2, 20 years 20 France 8.2, 15 years 15 Brazil Auction December 2009 8, 20 years 20 Brazil Auction August 2010 7.5, 20 years 20 Source: Prepared by authors. 22 A World Bank Study Figure 3.3 Capacity Factor vs. Winning Auctioned Prices for On-Shore Wind (Auction 2009) 55 50 Capacity factor (%) 45 40 35 30 25 7.0 7.2 7.4 7.6 7.8 8.0 8.2 8.4 US$ (in cents)/kWh Source: Prepared by authors. 2010 have raised the fear of no-implementation of projects because of financial insolvency.11 The 2009 auction for wind-based generation did not result in a clear correla- tion between capacity factors and prices, confirming to some extent the influence of strategic behavior in bidding results (that is, win the bid, then adjust) (see figure 3.3). However, this behavior may also be associated with the lack of a good record of historical data on wind velocities. When comparing Brazil’s auction prices for on-shore wind with other coun- tries, it can be observed that the bid rounds have delivered prices in the lower bound, but not outside the international range (as shown in table 3.6). Yet the costs of debt and capital, as well as the types and level of risks exhibited in a country like Brazil, are different to those exhibited in developed countries. A comparison of the remuneration levels using common assumptions for a 30 megawatts wind-based plant again shows that the auctions in Brazil delivered prices within the range of other countries (France, Germany, Nicaragua, and Turkey), although well below FITs provided in India and Sri Lanka (see figure 3.4). The effectiveness of the auction system to procure RE in Brazil will only be discovered with time; their potential to deliver least-cost RE capacity has already been proven. A comparison between the costs of PROINFA and the costs of RE delivered through auctions is provided in table 3.6, showing that auctions are delivering a more economically efficient output than the previous FITP (PROINFA). Third, the auctions for wind-based capacity additions in Brazil have rapidly attracted the participation of new equipment suppliers to the market. In addi- tion to Wobben Wind Power, which has been present in the market for many years (a subsidiary of German company Enercon), IMPSA (Argentinean), Suzlon (Indian), Vestas (Danish), Siemens (German), and GE (United States) Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries 23 Table 3.6 Efficiency Comparison: PROINFA and Auctions Technology-specific auction PROINFA (“reserve energy� auction) 2009 MW GWh/year US$/MWh MW GWh/year US$/MWh Wind 1,423 3,740 154 1,800 6,596 80 Small Hydro 1,191 6,260 96 — — — Bioelectricitya 779 2,661 77 2,379 4,800 84 Impact on costs Total capacity (MW)b 3,393 4,179 Total energy (GWh/year) 12,661 11,397 Average cost (US$/MWh) 109 80 Total cost (million 1,381 911 US$/year)c Net impact on tariffs 3.8 1.6 (US$/MWh)d Source: Barroso 2010. a. Values of April 2010, prices include taxes. Exchange rate: 1.85 USD/BRL. b. Installed capacity includes self-consumption. In the auction case, energy values correspond to the excess energy sold to the grid at the auction. More excess energy from the new plants is available to be sold to the free market of at future auctions. c. Gross cost, that is, total (fixed) cost paid by the consumers. d. For the auction case, it is the net cost, that is, includes estimates of yearly spot revenues collected by consumers. Figure 3.4 Remuneration Level Efficiency On-Shore Wind 30 25 20 US$ (in cents)/kWh 15 10 5 0 Turkey (FIT) France (FIT) Brazil Brazil Peru India Nicaragua Germany Brazil Sri Lanka auction auction auction Gujarat (Amayo (FIT) PROINFA (FIT) August December February (FIT) Plant) 2010 2009 2010 Source: Prepared by authors. Note: Annualized net present value of remuneration levels, under similar assumptions, not adjusted to inflation. are now operating—or in the process of starting operations—in the country. Many private developers have also emerged to participate in auctions (for example, in the auction launched in December 2009, 14 companies were awarded a portion of the auctioned quota). 24 A World Bank Study Fourth, environmental licensing issues are still creating a bottleneck to the development of RE projects in Brazil. For instance, many projects have been severely delayed, large cost overruns have been incurred, and some have even given up altogether, because of environmental impediments. Although there is an established sequence of environmental licenses to be obtained at each step of the project, with each license being more detailed than the preceding one, requirements sometimes change significantly from one license to the next, and licenses are frequently challenged by public attorneys on various grounds, resulting in unpredictability and long-drawn-out lawsuits. Finally, several other issues have generated strong debate among market participants and different stakeholders. One area of concern is the role of the public sector as both auctioneer and power purchaser, which creates a conflict of interest. For instance, there has been frequent interference of the govern- ment in technical functions, such as dispatch, the selection of projects for capacity expansion, and even in the decisions on what public enterprises can participate in auctions. Also, the type of technology and contract volume can be discretionary (that is, the government has the prerogative to call an auction to contract a given volume of energy even if it is not contemplated in the demand forecasts prepared by Discos). In fact, debate among auction participants has been strong concerning some of the technical parameters included in the auction scheme (which may favor specific projects or technologies and, indirectly, specific companies). In addition, private participants have expressed concern with regard to the different percep- tion of risks of public and private enterprises and its effect on competition (such as different hurdle rates or costs of capital). Policy Interactions and Instrument Compatibility A growing body of literature suggests that the compatibility among coexisting policy or regulatory instruments and fiscal or financial incentives is critical to the success of RE policy. In particular, many studies have focused on the interac- tion among different RE policy instruments, concluding that (a) some instru- ments are more effective when combined with other supporting schemes and (b) the effect of policy overlapping may produce counterintuitive effects that create substantial excess costs. In developed countries, the focus has been on the effects of investment tax credits on operational efficiency (in the absence of technology standards) and the interactions between RE policies and emissions trading systems, especially in European countries. Other studies have analyzed the effect of RE deploy- ment on electricity and gas prices, especially in the context of liberalized mar- kets.12 In the review, a few examples that illustrate the issue of policy interactions and compatibility were identified. Two of these examples are briefly described below. Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries 25 Investment Tax Credits and Feed-in Tariff Policies In 1994–95 India introduced accelerated depreciation to trigger investments in wind-based generation through adjustments to the Income Tax Act. The original incentive allowed 100 percent depreciation within the first year on a written-down value basis. In 2002 the incentive was reduced to 80 percent depreciation, also within the first year. To some extent, however, the incentive attracted diversified profit-making companies with high tax liabilities—as opposed to wind developers— seeking to use accelerated depreciation as a tax shield against profits on the entire company balance sheet. At the same time, these companies had a marked prefer- ence for the use of turnkey project packages sold by equipment vendors. Investors have profited from the use of accelerated depreciation in addition to the FIT. The combination of these two instruments has resulted in unintended effects, in both the operational efficiency of wind installations and the costs of equipment. First, contrary to world market trends, technology improvements and economies of scale have not reduced the costs of the wind generation industry. In fact, the average costs of equipment increased from about US$880,000 to US$1.3 million per megawatt between 2003 and 2008 (ESMAP 2010; World Bank 2009). Second, wind-based installations in India have exhibited very low operational efficiencies (as shown in figure 3.5).13 Third, the lack of harmoniza- tion among FITPs across different states has driven investments to the regions where these policies are more attractive, and not necessarily to the locations with the highest wind or resource potential. Figure 3.5 Evolution of Wind Capacity and Aggregated Capacity Factor, India 12,000 20 19 10,000 18 17 8,000 16 Megawatts Percent 6,000 15 14 4,000 13 12 2,000 11 0 10 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Years Capacity factor (%) Installed capacity (MW) Source: EIA 2009; Ministry of Power India 2010. 26 A World Bank Study This suggests that the types of instruments chosen to support RE and the policy mix per se have an effect not only on deployment but also on operational efficiency14. In response, the Government of India has introduced generation-based incen- tives (GBIs), which are designed to shift the incentive from installations to pro- duction and facilitate the entry of independent power producers (IPPs). These incentives have been offered since 2008 for solar- and wind-based capacity addi- tions in an attempt to improve their technical and operational efficiency. In addi- tion, the government has also recently introduced an REC market, mainly as an equalization mechanism to improve the overall economic efficiency of RE deployment. However, as of today the accelerated depreciation incentive has not been phased out, and it is being offered in parallel with generation-based incen- tives (in this case, a premium over the FIT). The dynamic resulting from this type of policy mix has also been exhibited in other countries (for example, investment tax credits for RE in California and for biofuels across the United States have also resulted in unintended effects) (de la Torre, Fajnzylber, and Nash 2008; Sawin 2004). Firm Capacity Incentives and Obligations Many power markets have developed financial instruments or incentives to stimulate investment in new capacity and maintain an adequate reserve margin. These incentives, generally termed “reliability payments� or “firm capacity charges� have been offered either as price premiums to technologies capable of delivering “firm energy,� or auctioned as incentives to achieve prespecified levels of adequacy and reliability. In general, capacity payments compensate investors for higher capital costs arising from regulatory risk and the failure of market design to accommodate for long-term contracts with domestic consumer franchises to allow hedging of investment decisions. Thus, these mechanisms compensate for market failures, rather than removing them (Neuhoff and Twomey in Grubb, Tooraj, and Pollit 2008). In hydropower-based systems, capacity payments are provided to help mitigate price spikes and encourage investments in flexible and backup plants (that is, peaking generation receives capacity payments to anticipate and receive a certain level of scarcity rents over time). The issue of firm capacity also arises when an important volume of RE is expected to be deployed. As intermittent generation is added in a system, addi- tional reserve capacity is necessary to maintain minimum levels of supply ade- quacy (for example, Germany, Portugal, and Spain require about 250–300 megawatts of additional reserve for every 1 gigawatt of wind capacity added to the system (Bakovic 2010). The “stand-by� plants can only recover their invest- ments if the spot price allows price spikes or if a capacity payment is offered. In some systems, the need for “firm energy� is addressed through an obligation. As discussed before, in Brazil all energy loads (regulated and unregulated con- sumers) are required to cover 100 percent of their energy needs with contracts; Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries 27 at the same time, all contracts have to be covered by FECs. The FEC coverage requirement ensures that new generation is added on time to cover the growing future load. Nicaragua, by contrast, offers capacity payments (a price premium) to generators capable of supplying firm energy, but has imposed an obligation on all generators (including RE) to provide a capacity reserve equal to 5 percent of installed capacity. In general, however, firm energy incentives and obligations have not been designed to acknowledge the capacity of intermittent RE to also provide “firm energy services� (for example, RE can be dispatched in base load when hydro- power reservoirs are low or in between biomass harvesting seasons). In fact, RE is generally excluded from the incentives (payments or premiums), but not from the obligations (as in Nicaragua). As they are designed, firm capacity instruments tend to reward or simply favor conventional technologies, but directly or indirectly undermine the finan- cial viability and competitiveness of intermittent sources of power supply, given their specific characteristics and the greater uncertainty associated with their annual output delivery. The existence of firm capacity obligations also has the potential to affect the effectiveness of regulatory instruments or measures to promote RE development. In Brazil for instance, RE developers have not par- ticipated in the so-called technology-specific auctions specifically aimed at deploying RE in part because of the FEC obligation. The use of “reserve energy auctions� to deploy RE, by contrast, has attracted more participation, mostly because in this type of auction, FECs are not required. However, the use of reserve energy auctions to deploy RE is limited. In a system where the price of RE is discovered through auctions, the FEC obligation may prove a limiting fac- tor to the scale-up of RE. Thus, the existence of firm capacity payments and obligations may have two effects: (a) reduce the capacity of RE to compete on an equal footing with ther- mal generation in some markets; and (b) undermine their financial viability as firm capacity and reserve obligations impose a greater financial burden on RE, given their operational characteristics. The introduction of FITs in systems that also offer firm capacity instruments need to consider this aspect because it may change the way RE is priced. How “stand-by� plants and RE are priced to appropriately pay for the value of “firm energy services� needs to be explored on a case-by-case basis (or at least until externality pricing is introduced). Already in Colombia, an innovative mecha- nism is being explored by the regulator to allow intermittent RE to compete in “firm energy� auctions (see Vergara et al. 2010). Notes 1. From a vertically integrated monopoly (with or without IPP participation), to a single buyer (that is, as a national generation company (Genco), transmission company (Transco), or Disco, or a combined national Genco-Transco or Transco-Disco and 28 A World Bank Study IPPs), to a structure with many Discos, Gencos, and a Transco as a single buyer (with third-party access), to a power market of Gencos, Discos, large users, Transco, and an independent system operator. In Brazil, the model established after the enactment of Law 10.848 (2004) relies on a combination of competition and strong government planning with centralized procurement (auctions). In this sense, the Brazilian model can be considered a hybrid model, where the public and private sectors coexist (and compete) in a contracts market, but where state-owned enterprises still dominate the market and the government still exercises considerable control. 2. In the past, however, Brazil did commit to a formal target on RE through its official program to stimulate RE development (PROINFA); this program has been cancelled. 3. Although competitive biddings and auctions do not represent RE policy instruments per se, they can be used as mechanisms to convey RE policy. For this reason, they are generally classified as incentives under “mandated market policies� (see World Bank 2008). 4. In Indonesia and Sri Lanka, a “preferential� tariff has been channeled through SPPAs. This arrangement has also included a guaranteed purchase for a multiyear period and a guaranteed access to the grid. In both countries, the “preferential tariff� was originally designed as a function of avoided costs of power generation (in 2008 Sri Lanka moved to a technology specific FIT, also provided through SPPAs); however, in the case of Indonesia the tariff was set at a level below avoided costs. The arrangement was quite successful in Sri Lanka, but largely unsuccessful in Indonesia, as explained later in this chapter. 5. See Couture et al. (2010), Mercados—Energy Markets International (2009), and Klein et al. (2008). 6. A CDM project activity is considered additional if anthropogenic emissions of green- house gases by sources are reduced below those that would have occurred in the absence of the registered CDM project activity. Probing additionality in the presence of FITPs is therefore more challenging. For instance, in December 2009 the CDM Executive Board rejected 10 wind projects located in China for failing to prove that projects could not achieve financial closure even in the presence of existing FITPs (PCF 2010). In this case, the concern was focused on the FIT design (that is, determi- nation of actual level of payments). The additionality criterion is also more difficult to justify when RE projects participate in REC markets. 7. With the recent introduction of auctions to deploy solar-based capacity, India now has the elements typical of an RPS (only for the case of solar initiatives): (a) targets and purchase obligations; (b) a REC market with solar-specific RECs; and (c) use of a competitive mechanism to determine the price. Yet, the purchase obligations are mandated under the FITP framework. 8. The experience with auctions to deploy solar-based capacity in India is too recent, and thus it is not analyzed in this review. 9. FECs (denominated in gigawatt-hour per year) are issued by the Ministry of Mines and Energy (MME). The methodology for their calculation is fairly complex. In prac- tice, FECs reflect the sustainable energy production of each generator when intercon- nected to the grid. For instance, to sign a contract of 100 “average MW,� a generator or trader must also acquire an equivalent amount of FECs (in gigawatt-hour per year). The FEC of a plant is also the “maximum amount of energy that it can sell through contracts.� Any shortfall is penalized at a price that mirrors the cost of new energy. Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries 29 10. These include the requirement of granted environmental licenses prior to participa- tion in auctions, deposit of bid bonds (equal to 1 percent of a reference investment, deposited before the auction and returned after the contract is signed), and project completion guarantees (10 percent of a reference investment value deposited after the contract is signed and released as the project completes construction), as well as the existence of grid access studies showing that a connection point is feasible and avail- able. In addition, investors can be severely penalized for not delivering the project. In the case of wind power, new wind turbines must be used (machines could not have been used before for prototype testing) and a historical record of wind speed and direction for a period of at least 12 months issued by a third party is required. 11. On average, offered capacity factors reached 45 percent, and in a few cases even more than 50 percent. 12. The literature on “policy interactions� is rapidly evolving. See, for instance, Jensen and Skytte (2002), De Jonghe et al. (2009) Blyth et al. (2009) Fischer and Preonas (2010). 13. The lowering of this aggregated factor may also be attributed to dispatch dynamics and grid limitations. Thus, further investigation is necessary to differentiate between the impacts of policy and grid and dispatch constraints. 14. In the literature a few authors have emphasized that FITPs can have a negative effect on cost reductions, as they induce generators to choose high cost-sites and provide fewer incentives for cost cuts (Soderholm and Klaassen 2007). References Bakovic, Tonci. 2010. “Integrating Renewables into Electricity Markets.� Presentation given in September 2010 at the International Finance Corporation, Washington, DC. Barroso, Luiz. 2010. “Implementation of Renewable Energy Market Development Policies in Brazil.� Consultant report, World Bank, Washington, DC. Blyth, William, Derek Bunn, Janne Kettunen, and Tom Wilson. 2009. “Policy Interactions, Risk and Price Formation in Carbon Markets.� Energy Policy 37: 5192–207. Couture, Toby D., Karlynn Cory, Claire Kreycik, and Emily Williams. 2010. “A Policymaker’s Guide to Feed-in Tariff Policy Design.� Technical Report NREL/ TP-6A2-44849, NREL, Golden, CO. http://www.energy.eu/publications/A_ Policymakers_Guide_to_Feed-in_Tariffs_NREL.pdf. De Jonghe, Cedric, Erik Delarue, Ronnie Belmans, and William D’haeseleer. 2009. “Interactions between Measures for the Support of Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources and CO2 Mitigation.� Energy Policy 37: 4743–52. de la Torre, Augusto, Pablo Fajnzylber, and John Nash. 2008. Low Carbon, High Growth: Latin American Responses to Climate Change. World Bank Latin American and Caribbean Studies. Washington, DC: World Bank. EIA (U.S. Energy Information Administration). 2009. “Data Obtained from the Energy Intelligence Unit (EIU).� EIA, Washington, DC. http://www.eia.doe.gov. ESMAP (Energy Sector Management Assistance Program). 2010. “Food for Thought: Unleashing the Potential of Renewable Energy in India.� Sustainable Development Unit, World Bank, Washington, DC. Fischer, Carolyne, and Luis Preonas. 2010. “Combining Policies for Renewable Energy: Is the Whole Less Than the Sum of Its Parts?� Resources for the Future. http://www.rff.org. 30 A World Bank Study Grubb, Michael, Jamasb Tooraj, and Michael J. Pollit. 2008. “Delivering a Low Carbon Electricity System: Technologies, Economics and Policy.� Department of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. IEA (International Energy Agency) and OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2008. Deploying Renewables: Principles for Effective Policies. Paris: IEA/OECD. Jensen, Stine G., and Klaus Skytte. 2002. “Interactions between the Power and Green Certificate Markets.� Energy Policy 30: 425–35. Klein, Arne, Benjamin Pfluger, Ragwitz Held, Gustav Resch, and Thomas Faber. 2008. “Evaluation of Different Feed-in Tariff Design Options: Best Practice Paper for the International Feed-in Cooperation.� Fraunhofer Institute Systems and Innovation Research, Energy Economics Group, Karlsruhe, Germany. Meier, Peter. 2010. “Sri Lanka: Energy Sector Infrastructure Assessment.� Draft report, World Bank, Washington, DC. Mercados—Energy Markets International. 2009. “Pricing and Contracting Mechanisms for Renewable Energy Development in the Philippines.� Consultant report, World Bank, Washington, DC. Ministry of Power India. 2010. http://www.powermin.nic.in/JSP_SERVLETS/internal. jsp. PCF (Prototype Carbon Fund). 2010. “The EB 51 Decision on Chinese Wind Projects: What Are the Implications?� Information Note for PCF Participants, World Bank, Washington, DC. January 27. REN21 (Renewable Energy Policy Network for the 21st Century). 2010. “Renewables 2010 Global Status Report.� REN21 Secretariat, Paris. http://www.ren21.net/ REN21Activities/Publications/GlobalStatusReport/tabid/5434/Default.aspx. Sawin, Janet L. 2004. “National Policy Instruments: Policy Lessons for the Advancement and Diffusion of Renewable Energy Technologies around the World.� Thematic Background Paper, International Conference for Renewables, Bonn, Germany. Soderholm, Patrik, and Ger Klaassen. 2007. “Wind Power in Europe: A Simultaneous Innovation-Diffusion Model.� Environmental and Resource Economics 36 (2): 163–90. Vergara, Walter, Alejandro Deeb, Natsuko Toba, Peter Cramton, and Irene Leino. 2010. Wind Energy in Colombia: A Framework for Market Entry. Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank. 2008. “REToolkit: A Resources for Renewable Energy Development.� http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTRENENERGYTK/Resources/REToolkit_ issues_note.pdf. ———. 2009. “Strengthening Investment Climate for Renewable Energy in India.� South Asia Sustainable Development Energy (SASDE), World Bank, Washington, DC. June. ———. 2010. “Design and Performance of Policy Instruments to Promote the Development of Renewable Energy: Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries.� Final Report, Energy Anchor Unit, Sustainable Energy Department, World Bank, Washington, DC. CHAPTER 4 Policy Performance The performance of renewable energy (RE) policy depends on a number of factors, including macroeconomic conditions, institutional structure and capac- ity, governance (regulatory quality, rule of law, control of corruption, political stability, and government effectiveness), fuels and electricity market dynamics, and infrastructure capacity (for example, capacity of the grid to evacuate inter- mittent generation). Thus, the review of the design and performance of RE policy cannot be decoupled from the analysis of the prevailing system and market conditions. Indeed, the successive reforms of key regulatory incentives respond to feedback effects between design and implementation experience in the context of a dynamic system (that is, a dynamic legal, institutional, economic, financial, and technical system). This chapter briefly discusses the effectiveness of policy packages in the sample countries in terms of market growth.1 In this exercise, it is implicitly assumed that policy design and implementation have a direct link with the intended outcome (that is, RE market growth).2 Attainment of Targets Except for Nicaragua, all countries in the sample have committed to targets on RE. Figure 4.1 depicts the degree to which passed targets have been attained, as well as the degree to which new targets are being met. In particular, India has a very good record in achieving targets, especially those offered in the 9th (1997–2001), 10th (2002–06), and 11th (2007–12) five-year plans. Also, the target introduced in the Indian National Action Plan on Climate Change (NAPCC) for increasing the share of RE by 1 percent annually was met in its first year (2008/09). Brazil, by contrast, did not meet the Programme of Incentives for Alternative Electricity Sources (Brazil) (PROINFA) target offered in 2002 (an additional 1,100 megawatts for each RE technology type, including wind, biomass, and small hydropower, SHP, by 2006); however, the country managed to reach the target for wind in 2009 and has progressed substantially with biomass and SHP. 31 32 A World Bank Study Figure 4.1 Degree to Which Official Targets on Renewable Energy Have Been Attained 2004–09 All NCRE 2006–2025 2006–2025 2008–09 Geothermal 2005–2025 2004–10 Technologies Biomass 2002–06 2002–06 2007–12 2002–09 2002–09 SHP 2005–2025 2002–06 2002–06 2007–12 2002–09 Wind 2007–12 2002–06 2002–06 0 50 75 Above 100 Percent Passed targets India Indonesia Sri Lanka Brazil Turkey Target in progress India Indonesia Sri Lanka Source: Prepared by authors. Note: NCRE = non-conventional renewable energy, SHP = small hydropower. At the other end of the spectrum, Indonesia could not attain the target on geothermal capacity offered in its Geothermal Road Map of 2004 (2,700 mega- watts by 2010) and targets offered in its National Energy Management Blueprint of 2005 have also not progressed substantially. The new targets offered by Sri Lanka and Turkey are fairly recent. Thus, it is too soon to report progress. However, in 2004 the Government of Turkey set up a Special Purpose Debt Facility (SPPDF) to promote RE development with the support of a World Bank loan. Under this initiative, the targets on RE were in fact surpassed by 2009. Effectiveness of Policy Package in Sample Countries This section briefly discusses the effectiveness of policy packages in the sample countries in terms of market growth. Brazil and India Of the sample countries under review, Brazil and India have exhibited sustained RE market growth that started soon after the introduction of a feed-in tariff policy (FITP) (as depicted in figures 4.2 and 4.3).3 India started introducing Policy Performance 33 Figure 4.2 Evolution of Renewable Energy Capacity and Share in Power System, India GBIs State SHP FIT policies 16,000 12 National tariff policy 14,000 & state biomass FIT policies 10 12,000 SERC preferential tariff regime (SHP) 8 10,000 Electricity Act 2003 Megawatts Percent FIT policy 8,000 6 SERC preferential tariff regime (wind) 6,000 4 4,000 2 2,000 0 0 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Years Biomass Grid connected solar PV Small-scale hydro Wind Sources: EIA 2009; Ministry of Power India 2010. Note: India introduced a renewable energy certificate (REC) market and the use of auctions from 2010. SERC = State Energy Regulatory Commission, FIT = feed-in tariff, SHP = small hydropower, GBIs = generation-based incentives. Figure 4.3 Evolution of Renewable Energy Capacity and Share in Power System, Brazil 12,000 12.0 10,000 Reserve energy auctions 10.0 Tax incentives 8,000 8.0 Megawatts T&D tariff discounts Percent (adjustments) 6,000 6.0 Adjustments to PROINFA and BNDES financing incentives 4,000 4.0 PROINFA 2,000 2.0 0 0.0 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Years Biomass SHP Wind Source: EPE 2009. Note: Data for the years 2009 and 2010 are “expected deployments� (actual data still not officially released). SHP = small hydropower. 34 A World Bank Study incentives to promote the development of RE as early as 1993 when the newly created Ministry of New and Renewable Energy (MNRE, previously Department of Non-Conventional Energy Sources) issued tariff guidelines that offered a national preferential rate to all types of RE. Today, the Government of India offers a complex combination of policy incentives that includes FITPs, fiscal and financial incentives, generation-based incentives (GBIs), and competitive mecha- nisms (for example, auctions to deploy solar-based capacity and a market of solar and nonsolar Renewable Energy Certificates, RECs, from 2010) (see matrix in appendix B). Brazil introduced an FITP (PROINFA) in 2002 for a relatively short period and moved to the use of auctions from 2007. The policy package to support RE deployment in Brazil is less diverse and includes only discounts on transmission and distribution (T&D), fiscal and financial incentives, and the use of auctions to support the introduction of a predefined quota of RE (as shown in appendix B). Many factors have contributed to the sustained RE market growth in both Brazil and India: (a) strong government commitment (most notably in India); (b) the creation of institutions exclusively focused on RE development at the central and state levels (India); (c) the existence of a growing domestic equip- ment manufacturing industry (in India, but also emerging in Brazil); (d) a sus- tained effort toward attracting private sector participation (Brazil and India); and (e) the existence of either a tight reserve margin or a large supply-demand gap, which has signaled the need for new capacity investments, among others (Brazil and India). In India, the use of FITPs in combination with fiscal and financial incentives has effectively promoted the deployment of different types of RE capacity, especially on-shore wind (as seen in figure 4.4 below). Yet, this sustained mar- Figure 4.4 Effectiveness as Average Annual Growth, India 1,400 Average annual growth (MW/year) 1,200 1,000 800 600 400 200 0 Wind SHP Biomass Solar 9th Plan 233 50.8 71.6 10th Plan 1,039 96.4 148.8 0.2 11th Plan 1,277 218 206.8 1.4 Sources: Ministry of New and Renewable Energy 2006; Planning Commission 2001a, 2001b. Note: Periods of the 9th, 10th, and 11th Plans are 1997–2001, 2002–06, and 2007–12, respectively. SHP = small hydropower. Policy Performance 35 ket growth has not been accompanied by acceptable levels of operational efficiency—especially in wind-based generation—partly because of unintended or perverse incentives driven by the policy mix per se, as explained before. In 2010 the Government of India introduced specific policy mechanisms to address this issue (generation-based incentives, REC market), but their capacity to improve the overall operational and economic efficiency of the RE market is yet to be seen. Thus, the case of India suggests that the design of policy mecha- nisms and the composition of the policy mix can have a positive effect on mar- ket growth, but a negative effect on efficiency and the overall costs of RE deployment. By contrast, the case of Brazil suggests that an emphasis on policy efficiency through the use of competitive auction mechanisms (in terms of low policy costs and least-cost expansion), may not necessarily lead to a sustained RE deployment. In this case, the proper design of project completion guarantees, as well as penalties to avoid construction delays and underperformance, are crucial for ensuring deployment and operational efficiency. The reserve energy auctions launched in 2008, 2009, and 2010 have already awarded a total of 6,199 mega- watts of new least-cost RE capacity to be deployed before 2012. The effective- ness of the auction mechanism in terms of actual market growth is yet to be seen, although the construction of some of the first scheduled new RE plants is already delayed (ANEEL 2011). Since the first successful auction for RE in Brazil was carried out recently (August 2008), the deployment of RE before that date can only be partially attrib- uted to the combination of other existing incentives, including the FITP (PROINFA), the reduced T&D tariff, tax incentives, and the preferential financing conditions offered by Brazilian Development Bank (BNDES). Even though the PROINFA target was not reached by 2006 as originally established, adjustments to policy design and the introduction of new incentives allowed Brazil to reach the quota of 3,300 megawatts before the end of 2010.4 Investments in small-scale RE to supply the free or nonregulated market (lower than 30 megawatts) have also increased, mainly because of a discount—generally on the order of 50 percent—on T&D charges offered by the government to support RE development. Turkey and Sri Lanka Although on a more modest scale than in Brazil and India, RE capacity has also gradually increased over the last decade in Turkey and Sri Lanka. In Turkey, the sustained growth of on-shore wind capacity additions are largely attributed to the introduction of an FITP in 2005 (see figure 4.5). The policy package for the promotion of RE-based capacity in Turkey includes an FITP that offers technology-specific fixed feed-in tariffs (FITs), green funds (which offer preferential loans under a Special Purpose Debt Facility), and reduced or exempted licensing and land use fees, as well as funds to support Research, Development, and Demonstration (RD&D) activities.5 Turkey has also established an official target on RE—30 percent by 2023. 36 A World Bank Study Figure 4.5 Evolution of Renewable Energy Capacity and Share in Power System, Turkey 600 7.0 6.0 500 5.0 400 Geothermal law & Megawatts 4.0 Percent adjustments to FIT 300 Feed-in tariff policy 3.0 Green concessional 200 funds (SPDB) 2.0 Incentives licensing connection priority 100 1.0 0 0.0 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Years Biomass Geothermal Wind Sources: Global Wind Energy Council 2009; TEIAS 2009. Note: The graph excludes small hydropower (SHP) to illustrate capacity additions of other types of renewable energy (RE). SHP accounted for 2,000 MW at the end of 2009 (including a net addition of 335 MW during the period 2002–09). The line representing the share of RE in the system includes SHP. Many other contributing factors may explain the initial takeoff of RE in Turkey: (a) the financing leverage achieved under the Special Purpose Debt Facility, which triggered 620 megawatts of new privately owned additions in RE capacity, especially in SHP (that is, equity-to-debt ratio on the order of 2.6); (b) the demonstration and replication effect resulting from this facility, which induced the emergence of new financing programs for RE in local commercial banks and the additional deployment of new SHP capacity; (c) the existence of a strong regulatory agency; (d) the consistent effort toward the establishment of a dynamic wholesale market and cost-reflective tariffs; and (e) the tight balance in supply and demand in the system, which provides a strong signal for the need of new investments. However, to reach the committed targets and significantly scale up RE, Turkey will need to revise the effectiveness of the policy mix. For instance, it may be necessary to adjust the FIT levels—which are perhaps too low to attract private sector investments—and to ensure that the utilities or retail companies subject to the purchase obligation are able to guarantee the purchase.6 In Sri Lanka, the sustained market growth of SHP can be attributed to the introduction of Standardized Power Purchase Agreements (SPPAs) from 1998, which offered a 15-year purchase guarantee and an attractive tariff (based on avoided costs of power generation), as well as to the provision of fiscal and Policy Performance 37 Figure 4.6 Evolution of Renewable Energy Capacity and Share in Power System, Sri Lanka SPPAs based on technology-specific FITs (RE plants < 10 MW) 160 6 Competitive bidding plants > 10 MW 140 5 120 4 100 From 1998: Megawatts SPPAs (based on avoided Percent cost, for RE plants < 10 MW) 80 3 60 CDM 2 40 1 20 0 0 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Years Small-scale hydro Wind Source: Central Bank of Sri Lanka 2010. Note: SPPA = standardized power purchase agreement, RE = renewable energy, CDM = clean development mechanism, FIT = feed-in tariffs. financial incentives (see figure 4.6). In 2008, the Government of Sri Lanka modified the scheme to the use of 20-year SPPAs based on technology-specific FITs (with the choice of stepped or flat FITs for on-shore wind, SHP, and solid biomass). In particular, the Government of Sri Lanka has recently committed to ambitious RE targets that will require the ramp-up of previous market growth trends. However, the new FIT levels are high—when compared to the interna- tional range—and given the legal limitations to pass incremental costs on to consumer tariffs, the fiscal sustainability of the scheme may prove a limiting factor to RE deployment.7 Indonesia and Nicaragua By contrast, Indonesia has not been able to develop its RE market consistently or sustainably (as shown in figure 4.7). In this country, SPPAs were offered from 1993, but it was not until after 2002 that they actually started to attract invest- ments. This has been largely attributed to contextual factors (such as the effect of the Asian financial crisis and governance issues, among others). In practice, the use of SPPAs based on tariffs levels below avoided costs of power generation has been largely unsuccessful. Also, although competitive 38 A World Bank Study Figure 4.7 Evolution of Renewable Energy Capacity and Share in Power System, Indonesia 2009: Competitive biddings allowed for geothermal (with tariff ceiling) Tax incentives introduced Reforms to ministerial Geothermal law decree on SPPA 1,200 Ministerial decree 4.5 SPPA for RE 4.0 1,000 3.5 800 3.0 Megawatts 2.5 Percent 600 2.0 400 1.5 1.0 200 0.5 0 0.0 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Years Geothermal Small-scale hydro Wind Source: Ministry of Energy and Mineral Resources Indonesia 2008. Note: SPPA = standardized power purchase agreement, RE = renewable energy. biddings (with a tariff ceiling) have been recently allowed for geothermal capac- ity, the existing concessions have been so far negotiated directly. Three issues affect the scale-up of RE in Indonesia: (a) high levels of regula- tory uncertainty in the power sector; (b) lowering avoided costs of power generation, especially in the islands that have switched from oil- to coal-based generation (and thus the existing policy is becoming even more ineffective); and (c) lack of clarity as to how the government will cover incremental costs (there is a high off-take risk). In Nicaragua, the FITP has also been largely ineffective. Yet, the system is fairly small in terms of installed capacity (about 974 megawatts as of 2009) and thus, RE capacity additions represent a high share of the total system’s capacity. Nicaragua introduced its first FITP in 2002 through Presidential Decree 279 to stimulate the addition of SHP and wind-based generation. However, the policy had no effect on either SHP or wind-based capacity additions. With the enact- ment of the Renewable Energy Promotion Law in 2005, the Government of Nicaragua then introduced a second FIT scheme (successively adjusted in 2007 and 2009). However, the scheme did not lead to new investments in RE either (except perhaps for a 1 megawatt SHP facility added in 2007) (see figure 4.8).8 Policy Performance 39 Figure 4.8 Evolution of Renewable Energy Capacity and Share in Power System, Nicaragua Feed-in tariff policy all NCRE 300 & 40 tax exemptions 35 250 Geothermal law (concessions) & 30 200 premium over spot price to SHP and wind 25 Megawatts Percent 150 20 15 100 10 50 5 0 0 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Years Biomass Geothermal Small-scale hydro Wind Source: CEPAL 2009. Note: SHP = small hydropower, NCRE = non-conventional renewable energy. The lack of investments in RE despite the existence of an FITP—and other fiscal incentives—in Nicaragua has been attributed to a number of factors: (a) a generalized legal and regulatory uncertainty; (b) the lack of a critical water rights law; (c) the existence of legislation that converted geothermal resource-rich areas into national parks; and (d) lack of clarity in the design of the FITP of 2002 (the pricing formula was not clearly defined in the regulation) (Mostert 2007, 2009). In the sample countries, as indicated before, RE policy—or its adjustments— has been streamlined primarily through legal frameworks associated with the reform and the liberalization of their power sectors (Brazil, India, and Turkey) or through legal provisions specifically addressing security of supply concerns (Indonesia, Nicaragua, Sri Lanka, and Turkey), or both. Alignment of Exhibited Trends in RE Deployment to Future Committed Targets Figure 4.9 depicts the evolution of average annual growth (average annual growth, AAG, megawatt per year) for RE in the four sample countries that have a formal target on RE today. In the case of India, the country has experienced sustained growth through the 9th (1997–2001), 10th (2002–06), and 11th (2007–12) five-year plans. However, to reach its target on RE (54 gigawatts by 2022), India will have to almost double its present AAG.9 This is even more acute in Indonesia, Sri Lanka, and Turkey, which will have to ramp up their efforts considerably if they are to attain the targets they are committed to (increasing their AAGs by 3-, 7-, and 12-fold, respectively). 40 A World Bank Study Figure 4.9 Evolution of Average Annual Growth vis-à-vis Average Annual Growth Required for Reaching Targets for All Renewable Energy a. India b. Turkey 4,000 2,000 3,000 1,500 Megawatts Megawatts 2,000 x 1.9 1,000 x7 1,000 500 0 0 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 Years Years c. Sri Lanka d. Indonesia 60 800 50 600 Megawatts 40 Megawatts 30 400 x3 20 x 12 200 10 0 0 1998 2003 2008 2013 2018 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 Years Years Average market growth required to reach target Evolution of average market growth Source: Prepared by authors. Note: Average annual growth (AAG) is in megawatts per year. Economic Efficiency of RE Policy in Sample Countries This section provides a general discussion of the costs and impacts of RE policy, the implications of policy design on efficiency, and the sustainability of cost recovery mechanisms. Costs and Impacts of RE Policy There is a general lack of analytical work that would provide estimates on the subsidy volume required to reach the targets committed on RE across develop- ing countries, and/or on the impact of RE supporting policies on consumer tariffs or fiscal accounts. An indication of the subsidy volume required to cover the incremental costs associated with RE additions in relation to targets has been found for India and Sri Lanka (as shown in table 4.1). In the case of Sri Lanka, the FIT subsidy could have an important impact on consumer tariffs if the incremental costs were passed through to electricity tar- iffs, as shown in figure 4.10. In Brazil, as shown earlier in table 3.6, the total annual cost originating from RE generation triggered by both PROINFA and auctions is estimated at US$1.38 billion per year and US$911 million per year, respectively. The impact on Policy Performance 41 Table 4.1 Subsidy Required for Meeting Renewable Energy Targets, India and Sri Lanka Subsidy required Target (incremental cost) Country Expansion scenarios Volume Year Total (US$) Per Year (US$) India Scenario 1: diversified mix (all 45 GW 2020 68 billion 6.8 billion types of NCRE) Scenario 2: only wind and SHP 45 GW 2020 12 billion 1.2 billion (least cost) Sri Lanka Diversified mix (SHP, wind, 366 MW 2015 116 million 23.2 million biomass) 851 MW 2025 258 million 17.2 million Sources: ESMAP 2010; Meier 2010. Figure 4.10 Estimated Cost and Impact of Meeting Renewable Energy Target, Sri Lanka a. Incremental costs of NCRE target a 350 300 250 US$, millions 200 150 100 50 0 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 2027 b. Impact of meeting NCRE target on electricity tariff b 16 14 12 10 Rs/kWh 8 6 4 2 0 2009 2014 2019 2024 2029 NCRE scenario Tariff Thermal fuel cost Source: Meier 2010. Note: NCRE = nonconventional renewable energy. 42 A World Bank Study consumer tariffs today, however, is negligible, given the size of the market (that is, 1.35 percent from PROINFA and 0.6 percent from auctioned RE capacity). Economic Efficiency in Policy Design Although the scope of this review did not include an assessment of the eco- nomic efficiency associated with the policy mix of sample countries, a few observations on efficiency were made during the course of the review. First, FITs designed to minimize producers’ inframarginal rents and the over- all costs of FIT subsidies are only being used in India and Sri Lanka (that is, technology-specific stepped FITs and/or FITs with degression rates).10 In Sri Lanka, however, as shown earlier in figure 3.4, the initial value of FITs for on- shore wind has been set at very high levels (the remuneration level is one of the highest in the world). In India on the other hand, despite the efforts in designing and introducing FITs that encourage economic efficiency, other factors seem to have signifi- cantly affected the overall economic efficiency of FITPs and RE development (especially in wind): (a) the lack of consistency across state FITPs seems to have driven investments to the states with the most attractive policies, as opposed to the areas with the best resource potential (thus, the expansion has not neces- sarily been least-cost); and (b) the provision of accelerated depreciation, together with the FIT, has induced the installation of wind-based plants with low operational efficiencies (as discussed previously). Thus, the actual design features of the FITPs are not sufficient to ensure an economically efficient expansion of RE-generating capacity. Second, Brazil, India, Indonesia, Sri Lanka, and Turkey use competitive mechanisms to procure RE development (as shown in figure 3.2). In this case, competition is expected to induce the least-cost installation of RE (that is, for one or all types of RE, depending on the policy and procurement rules). In particular, the auction mechanism used in Brazil to add RE capacity has already delivered an efficient outcome (projects have been awarded based on lowest price, and the prices delivered are in the lower bound when compared to international levels), although its effectiveness in project completion rate is yet to be seen (in general, there is a high deployment risk associated with auctions in RE). Sustainability of Incremental Cost Recovery Mechanisms Brazil, Nicaragua, and Turkey allow the pass-through of incremental costs asso- ciated with RE generation to consumer tariffs, while India, Indonesia, and Sri Lanka transfer fiscal resources to utilities to cover these costs (see table 4.2). In the case of India, other contributing sources are carbon revenues (Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) proceedings should be shared between the developers and the consumers for the case of solar initiatives) and utility revenues (which indeed are expected to partially cover the costs of FITPs). In Brazil, depending on the type of auction, incremental costs are passed through Policy Performance 43 Table 4.2 Incremental Cost Recovery Mechanisms Incremental cost recovery IN BR TK INDO NI SRL Pass-through to consumer tariff Equal burden sharing � � Differentiated burden sharing � � Fiscal transfer & other Fiscal transfer (national/central � � � or state level) Utility revenue � CDM revenues � � Grants Source: Prepared by authors. Note: IN = India, SRL = Sri Lanka, BR = Brazil, INDO = Indonesia, NI = Nicaragua, TK = Turkey. to either regulated users (technology specific auctions) or both regulated and nonregulated consumers (reserve energy auctions) as a fixed charge or uplift. In Sri Lanka, the 2006 Energy Strategy proposed the establishment of a fund to be supported through “an energy cess, grants received from donors, well wishers and CDM revenues.� As of today, however, the fund has not been established. In practice, the success or failure of RE policy is largely dependent on the sustainability of proposed mechanisms for the recovery of incremental costs. Notes 1. Trends in RE market growth are compared to the growth required for attaining official targets in the case of sample countries that have officially established them. 2. Clearly, it is necessary to control for a number of factors to more accurately assess causality between policies and their intended outcomes or empirical performance. In the absence of a formal impact evaluation or appropriate modeling of the system, attribution cannot be rigorously assessed. However, the simple analysis of market growth as a first step in the discussion of RE policy performance is thought to be appropriate in the context of a case-study approach. 3. The adjustments to PROINFA in Brazil included changes in the financing conditions offered by the BNDES to PROINFA projects. 4. For instance, the financing conditions offered by BNDES under PROINFA were adjusted after 2006, allowing higher debt-to-equity ratios, longer amortization peri- ods, and lower interest rates. Also, from 2007, new tax incentives were introduced to promote RE development. 5. Other actions aimed at facilitating the introduction of RE include the release of a wind energy grid code. 6. One issue of concern in Turkey is that RE generators must approach retail companies in addition to distribution companies (Discos), given the low purchase obligations imposed on Discos (on the order of 4 percent). However, unlike Discos, most retail companies have no sizeable assets in their balance sheet to guarantee the purchase. 44 A World Bank Study 7. Today, the invoices from the Ceylon Electricity Board (CEB, the largest vertically integrated utility in the country) to cover the incremental cost of RE capacity intro- duced under the new FITP are accumulating at the Sustainable Energy Authority (SEA), which has no ability to pay. Incremental costs are estimated to reach US$116 million by 2015 (Meier 2010). 8. Neither was the introduction of a 40 megawatts wind-based generating plant in 2009 triggered by the FITP; rather, it was the result of a direct single-source contracting in which the negotiated price was set above the FIT established in the regulation. 9. The extent to which India will be able to maintain this sustained growth will be chal- lenged by the existence of sites with good resource potential (in the case of wind) and the actual installation of solar-based projects. 10. In 2009, a new FITP that included technology-specific FITs with two-step degression rates was proposed in Turkey. However, the proposal was rejected and instead the government approved technology-specific flat tariffs with characteristically low levels in December 2010 (as shown in figure 3.4 before). References ANEEL (Agência Nacional de Energia Elétrica). 2011. “Chronogram of New Auctioned RE Plants’ Construction and Deployments.� http://www.aneel.gov.br/arquivos/zip/ Cronograma_Eventos_EOL_abr_2011.zip. Central Bank of Sri Lanka. 2010. “Economic and Social Statistics of Sri Lanka 2010.� http:// www.cbsl.gov.lk/pics_n_docs/10_pub/_docs/statistics/other/Pub_E&SS_2010.pdf. CEPAL (Banco Centroamericano de Integración Económica). 2009. “Análisis del Mercado Nicaragüense de Energía Renovable.� Tegucigalpa, Honduras. EIA (U.S. Energy Information Administration). 2009. “Data Obtained from the Energy Intelligence Unit (EIU).� EIA, Washington, DC. http://www.eia.doe.gov. EPE (Empresa de Pesquisa Energética). 2009. “Database for ONS National Power System Operator (Brazil).� http://www.ons.org.br/biblioteca_virtual/publicacoes_operacao_ sin.aspx. ESMAP (Energy Sector Management Assistance Program). 2010. “Food for Thought: Unleashing the Potential of Renewable Energy in India.� Sustainable Development Unit, World Bank, Washington, DC. Global Wind Energy Council. 2009. “Turkey Total Installed Capacity.� Brussels. http:// www.gwec.net/index.php?id=133&L=0. Meier, Peter. 2010. “Sri Lanka: Energy Sector Infrastructure Assessment.� Draft report, World Bank, Washington, DC. Ministry of Energy and Mineral Resources Indonesia. 2008. http://www.esdm.go.id/ publikasi/statistik.html. Ministry of New and Renewable Energy. 2006. “XIth Plan Proposals for New and Renewable Energy.� http://www.mnre.gov.in. Ministry of Power India. 2010. http://www.powermin.nic.in/JSP_SERVLETS/internal.jsp. Mostert, Wolfgang. 2007. “Unlocking Potential, Reducing Risk: Renewable Energy Policies for Nicaragua.� ESMAP, World Bank, Washington, DC. Policy Performance 45 ———. 2009. “Easing Investment Barriers: Nicaragua’s Renewable Energy Potential.� ESMAP Knowledge Exchange Series No. 12, World Bank, Washington, DC. Planning Commission Government of India. 2001a. “Approach Paper to 10th Five Year Plan.� http://planningcommission.nic.in/. ———. 2001b. “9th Five Year Plan.� http://planningcommission.nic.in/. TEIAS (Turkish Electricity Transmission Corporation). 2009. “Turkish Electrical Energy 10-Year Generation Capacity Projection 2009–2018.� http://www.teias.gov.tr/eng/ ApkProjectionCAPACITY%20PROJECTION%202009-2018.pdf. CHAPTER 5 Policy Trends and Market Structure The chapter briefly discusses the links and compatibility between market structure and types of policy instruments, procurement methods, and policy performance. Market Structure and Types of Policy Instruments The review did not find any relevant association between the type of market structure and the type of renewable energy (RE) policy instruments being applied in the sample countries. However, there seems to be a distinction between large and medium-size countries (that is, gross national income and size of power sector) in the diver- sity of instruments included in the policy package. For instance, Brazil, India, and Turkey are using a more diverse set of mechanisms to advance RE than Indonesia, Nicaragua, and Sri Lanka (as shown in appendix B). Also, BRIC coun- tries Brazil and India are applying the most complex types of instruments (com- plex FIT design, REC market, and auctions). Market Structure and Types of Procurement Methods Surprisingly, no links can be identified between the type of market structure and the degree of competition in the RE market. In Nicaragua and Turkey (markets in transition to full liberalization), as well as in India (single purchaser), the bulk of RE supply has been contracted through direct single-source procurement. In Nicaragua, however, although feed-in tariff policies (FITPs) have been designed as a function of wholesale electricity price, they have been largely ineffective, considering the size of the market and its vulnerability to oil price shocks. In Turkey, RE developers are allowed to sell directly in the wholesale market, but there is a high price risk associated with this possibility in the long term, and investors have not responded to the incentive (the amendments of December 2010 to the Renewable Energy Law in Turkey introduced technology-specific, cost-based feed-in tariffs, FITs). Brazil (wholesale market with strong government control), by contrast, is now using auctions to attract investment in RE and has successfully promoted 47 48 A World Bank Study competition among developers, since auctions have attracted numerous com- panies and resulted in very low prices. Most recently (December 2010), India introduced auctions to deploy solar-based capacity. Both Indonesia and Sri Lanka (monopolies that allow independent power producer, IPP participation) are now promoting competitive solicitations to attract RE (for geothermal capacity and plants higher than 10 megawatts, respectively). Market Structure and Policy Performance The review did not find any relevant association between the type of market structure and the performance of the policy mix in the sample countries. The policy pathway to support RE seems to have been more effective in the higher-income countries (Brazil, India, and Turkey). This is also associated with other factors, such as investment climate, economic and political stability, and governance issues. As discussed before, low RE market growth was exhibited in both Indonesia and Nicaragua for reasons related to policy or contract design in combination with other external or contextual factors (such as regional financial crises, gov- ernance issues, or regulatory uncertainty). With regard to economic efficiency, the two countries that have explicitly tried to attract least-cost RE generation are Brazil (through auctions) and Turkey (with a low FIT set at about wholesale market levels—subsequently substituted for technology-specific flat FITs with higher levels, but still in the lower bound when compared to those offered in the sample countries).1 Both the Indian policy package and Brazil’s Programme of Incentives for Alternative Electricity Sources (PROINFA) are believed to have delivered RE generation at very high costs, either because of a high FIT (Brazil, as shown in figure 3.4 and table 3.6) or because of a low operational efficiency (India, as shown in figure 3.5).2 In particular, the levels of the FITP issued in Sri Lanka in 2007 are among the highest in the world for on-shore wind and small hydro- power (SHP), allowing producers a higher rent given the level of other risks exhibited in the country. Use of RE Policy Instruments in Different Market and System Structures The review suggests that FITPs can be very effective in attracting private invest- ment for RE development in the context of markets in transition, where the institutional structure and legal and regulatory frameworks are evolving, and where players are still learning and gaining experience on competition practice and rules. In this case, the FIT provides the degree of price certainty necessary to counterbalance the other set of risks (such as regulatory uncertainty or off- take risk). For instance, countries with no record of sound regulation face Policy Trends and Market Structure 49 greater lending constraints, and the FITP plays a critical role in increasing the debt-to-equity ratio.3 However, FITP—which directly addresses price risks—can be unsuccessful when the other set of risks is too high or when unusual external factors hit the sector or the economy (such as regional financial crises; fuel price shocks that affect the financial health of the industry; and a track record of frequent or unpredictable regulatory changes, governance issues, such as corruption, and of course grid constraints). The literature suggests that an RPS or quota system can only be implemented effectively where the electricity market is more mature: institutions are experi- enced, legal and regulatory frameworks and the process for amending them are strong and predictable, competition practices and rules have been established, and players are both experienced and financially strong (such as in countries with large sophisticated utilities). In other words, quota mechanisms are more appropriate for systems where price uncertainty can be accommodated, given the low level of other types of risks. As discussed in this review, none of the sample countries has implemented an RPS. The use of auctions can also be more successful in systems where the markets are mature and relatively stable, where the rules are not evolving, and where there are a sufficient number of players and scope for market growth to achieve competition. For instance, developed power markets with a large number of buyers and sellers in sound financial standing are generally more conducive to competition; but even in systems where competition is modest and markets are small, countries can benefit from the use of competitive auction mechanisms (Maurer and Barroso 2010). However, effective auctions require a sophisticated level of regulatory and administrative capacity as well as a robust rule of law (for example, existence of independent regulators with the oversight capacity, enforcement of contracts). Nevertheless, auctions can be seen as a very good mechanism for FIT-level determination (for example, they help lower information asymmetries between the government and RE suppliers right from the beginning). Indeed, auctions for long-term contracts may result in the same Power Purchase Agreement (PPA) and risk allocation as that provided in FITPs. In smaller vertically integrated power sectors, where private sector participa- tion in RE development is more difficult to attract and where there are no balancing markets, state-owned utilities have played an anchoring role in smoothing out some of the risks through take-on contracts (for example, price volatility and intermittency risks are better addressed). This model has been successful in some countries only when the PPAs are sustainable and the off- take risks are low. The evidence in developed countries shows that the type, complexity, and sequencing of RE policy are crucial for creating sustainable RE markets. For instance, introducing simple technology-neutral FITs—although expensive— helps pave the way for attracting investors and lowering uncertainties in an 50 A World Bank Study initial stage or before a quota mechanism is introduced. The importance of policy sequencing is also reflected in the need to introduce legal and regulatory frameworks for resource and land use, before RE policy is introduced. The review of the experience of sample developing countries shows that the design of policy instruments aimed at creating sustainable RE markets is a dynamic process, which requires frequent adjustments and the introduction of complementary mechanisms to leverage the overall effectiveness of the policy mix. Clearly, along the way, regulators need to establish a solid track record of decisions that consider and involve the various stakeholders participating in the market. Appendix C of this paper provides a relative comparison of most important price and quantity setting instruments. Notes 1. Turkey recently (as of the end of 2010) introduced a new FIT regime, based on technology-specific fixed FITs whose level is in fact higher than the previous fixed technology-neutral FIT (that is, to increase the producer rent and hence the policy effectiveness). In the new amendments, however, RE firms are still allowed to par- ticipate in the free unregulated market. 2. Of course, RE capacity additions provide additional services related to enhanced secu- rity of supply, which need to be estimated and compared to a business-as-usual sce- nario to formally assess economic efficiency. 3. The effectiveness of the FITP can be enhanced if combined with partial risk guaran- tees or other types of financial mechanism. Reference Maurer, Luiz T. A., and Luiz Barroso. 2010. A Strategic Overview on Efficient Energy Procurement and Best Practices in Electricity Auctions. Washington, DC: World Bank. CHAPTER 6 Key Findings Emerging Experience with Feed-in Tariff Policies In the sample analyzed, all countries have implemented some type of feed-in tariff policy (FITP). The experience with the use of FITPs can be summarized as follows. FITPs can effectively promote the sustained deployment of renewable energy (RE) capacity, especially when other key policy and regulatory instruments are also in place, including (a) clear rules on transmission connection and RE inte- gration, (b) a sustainable incremental cost recovery mechanism, and (c) fiscal and financial incentives.1 FITPs have been particularly effective in India and Turkey, but largely ineffective in Indonesia and Nicaragua. In all cases, the design of FITPs has required successive adjustments, either to improve policy perfor- mance (that is, lower inframarginal rents) or to adapt to new system or market conditions (for example, oil price fluctuations, decarbonization of generation mix, and market liberalization). However, policy adjustments should be con- trolled—perhaps through a mechanism embedded in the policy design per se—that allows stakeholders to manage the risks in order to maintain a certain level of regulatory certainty (for example, programmed reviews, thresholds on adjustments, and adjustments that affect only new projects). Also in the countries analyzed—except for the case of Indonesia—feed-in tariffs (FITs) have evolved from simple to more sophisticated formulations (for example, as information asymmetries between policy makers and RE producers diminish). However, compliance with the renewable purchase obligations (RPOs) imposed by FITPs has been poor in systems where off-takers exhibit weak or unsustainable financial balances or where schemes have lacked penalty mechanisms or realistic escalation schedules (that is, an RPO becomes an addi- tional burden, especially in systems where incremental costs or the subsidy per se is not passed through to consumer tariffs or where the fiscal transfer is incom- plete or unsustainable). Indeed, the effectiveness of FITPs seems to be strongly linked to the existence of fiscal and financial incentives. This is particularly important for developing countries where uncertainties are higher and risks are more diverse. In particular, FITPs have been less effective when the FIT design is structured as a function of 51 52 A World Bank Study wholesale electricity markets or pegged to oil prices, given that this type of pref- erential tariff does not provide the minimum level of certainty on revenue flows required to attract private investment. Nevertheless, the lack of policy effective- ness is also linked to other factors, including overall investment climate in the country and sector risks (off-take risks, regulatory uncertainty, governance issues), as well as other external factors (such as global or regional financial crises). Despite the relative success of FITPs in some of the sample countries ana- lyzed, the analysis suggests that effective FITPs have not necessarily led to efficient outcomes (that is, in overall costs and operational efficiency). Poor economic efficiency may be attributed to one or more of the following three factors: (a) use of a complex policy package that provides multiple sources of incentives (expensive policy package); (b) a driving policy mechanism that allows high producer rents (that is, poor FIT design); and (c) policy interac- tions that introduce unintended economic distortions (such as the use of FITPs in combination with accelerated depreciation or tax breaks in the absence of technology standards). Of course, grid access (connection) and the capacity of the system to absorb RE (integration) are critical to the delivery of green electrons.2 Expensive FITPs can have a direct impact on the poor when incremental costs are passed through to consumer tariffs, especially when there is no differ- entiated burden sharing.3 The potential impact of FITP on poorest consumers needs to be considered and properly assessed by policy markers when designing FITPs. In this review, information on the impact of FITPs on consumer tariffs was only found for the case of Sri Lanka. Ultimately, an FITP can only be successful if—in combination with other policy levers—it leads to the deployment of RE capacity, as well as to the sus- tainable and efficient delivery of green electrons. Emerging Experience with Competitive Schemes None of the sample countries analyzed has experience with the implementation of Renewable Portfolio Standards (RPSs) or with the use of Renewable Energy Certificates (RECs). The use of RPSs has actually been less common in the developing world—with only Poland, Romania, and most recently Chile imple- menting this scheme. The review, however, provides an analysis of this type of regime because India recently introduced an REC market (mainly as an equalization mechanism to improve the overall economic efficiency of RE deployment). With time, the use of RECs may become more common, especially in systems where many distri- bution companies (Discos) or retail companies operate and where the potential for RE scale-up is high and distributed across a large geographic area. The review was, therefore, more focused on the experience with auctions for RE in Brazil and on the use of competitive mechanisms in other sample countries. Key Findings 53 The experience with auctions to deploy RE in Brazil can be summarized as follows: (a) auctions have been a useful tool for ensuring the economic effi- ciency of RE deployment, although the resulting low prices have raised con- cerns as to the extent to which bid winners will be able to construct and profit from the plants (this has been the experience with RE auctions in other coun- tries in the past, for example, the United Kingdom and China); and (b) it is possible that these low prices may be the result of speculative behavior from bidders (low correlation between capacity factors and offered prices), although low prices may also be associated with the lack of a good record of historical data on resource potential (for example, wind velocities). The auction design and process is complex, and requires a sophisticated level of regulatory and administrative capacity. For instance, the auctions in Brazil have included a number of prerequisites to avoid speculative behavior and lower the risk of construction delays or no construction of facilities at all, but the actual enforcement of project completion guarantees remains an issue of concern (for example, potential court cases, which may then discourage future private investment). The effectiveness of auctions can be affected by other external or sector issues (such as environmental licensing as a bottleneck to the development of projects, or the multiple roles of the public sector as a planner, dispatcher, auc- tioneer, and power purchaser, introducing potential conflicts of interest). Nevertheless, auctions can also be seen as a very good mechanism for FIT level determination (helps lower information asymmetries between policy makers and RE producers, right from the beginning). As with FITPs, the provision of fiscal and financial incentives—as well as the existence of clear rules on transmission connection and RE integration—is cru- cial to the effectiveness of quota-based mechanisms. In Brazil, for instance, the Brazilian Development Bank (BNDES) provides very cheap financing with long amortization periods to RE-based projects, and the regulator has designed inno- vative mechanisms on grid connection based on a cooperative planning approach. In sum, auctions can deliver a very efficient outcome but their effectiveness depends on a number of other important preconditions. As of November 2010, except for India and Nicaragua, all other countries encourage the use of competitive schemes (biddings and auctions) to procure a specific segment of the RE market (Indonesia, Sri Lanka, and Turkey), but the use of competitive schemes has been allowed only recently in these countries. Both India and Nicaragua use only direct contracting or cost-plus fixed FIT contracts for all types and scales of RE. Concerning RE targets, except for the case of India, the analysis suggests a significant disconnection between committed quotas and historical trends, espe- cially in Indonesia, Sri Lanka, and Turkey (these countries would have to ramp up their RE deployment rate 3-, 7-, and 12-fold, respectively, in order to reach committed targets). 54 A World Bank Study Emerging Trends on the Use of Price and Quota-Based Mechanisms There is a large body of literature analyzing the experience with the use of dif- ferent types of policy and regulatory instruments to promote RE development. The leading reports concentrate mainly on the experience in Europe and the United States. In particular, a long and ongoing debate throughout the literature focuses on what policies are more effective and efficient in driving the sustain- able least-cost development of RE markets. In most recent analyses, the general consensus seems to be that FITPs are more effective at lowering investors’ risks than RPS or quota instruments (that is, when considering price, volume, and balancing risks). However, some studies indicate that quota mechanisms (such as the RPS-REC scheme) can be rela- tively less expensive than price-based mechanisms, considering that FITP typi- cally offers high subsidy rates. The analysis of the recent literature shows that developed countries have not only made policy shifts to test the performance of different policy tools, but also that FITPs are being offered in combination with either auctions or RPS-REC schemes to support less mature RE technologies or small-scale RE projects (hybrid regimes). Developing countries—especially emergent economies—have also made important policy shifts, and many are now also using both price- and quota- based instruments in parallel to support different segments of the RE market. Future analysis should depart from the previous debate on the relative effec- tiveness of price- and quota-based mechanisms (in practice, this depends very much on country-specific factors, institutional and administrative capacity, and the types and nature of risks) and focus more on the complementarities between different types of price- and quota-based instruments, as well as on the issue of policy interactions and their effects on overall policy efficiency. General Lessons of Experience The review suggests the following general lessons of experience. A tailor-made approach is necessary: Choice of policy instruments, policy design, and complexity of the policy package (or regulatory regime) should be tailored to the actual conditions of the system in the type of market, supply or demand volume, and nature and level of risks, as well as institutional and administrative capacity. Policy sequencing is critical for policy effectiveness: Policy sequencing, the exis- tence of basic legal and regulatory preconditions, as well as institutional and administrative efficiency are crucial to the effectiveness of RE policy. For example, legal and regulatory frameworks for grid connection and integration, resource and land use, and/or the allocation of permits and rights must be in place before RE policy is introduced, and the process for granting permits should not create bottlenecks. Key Findings 55 Policies that successfully lead to the scale-up of renewable energy may not necessar- ily be efficient: Even if the policy mix succeeds in triggering investments that achieve RE capacity targets, its overall economic efficiency (cost per unit of benefits) may be poor. Policy interaction and compatibility need to be considered: The coexistence of policy instruments has the potential to result in complex interactions and unintended effects. Thus, policy makers need to assess the compatibility among policy and regulatory mechanisms or incentives—that is, their combined impact may result in inefficient outcomes. It is also vital that individual poli- cies are coordinated with the wider set of conditions that impact the energy market in a specific setting. Policy and regulatory design is a dynamic process: Developing countries have tested different types of instruments to support RE development (policy shifts) and many are now using both price and quantity setting instruments to support different segments of the RE market. In the sample countries, FITPs have required successive adjustments (the challenge has been attracting pri- vate investment while at the same time minimizing inframarginal rents). How- ever, policy adjustments should be controlled through mechanisms—perhaps embedded in the policy design per se—that allow stakeholders to manage the risks in order to maintain a certain level of regulatory certainty (for example, programmed reviews, thresholds on adjustments, and adjustments that affect only new projects). RE policy performance (effectiveness/efficiency) depends on a number of key factors: Even policies with a sound design do not result in effective and efficient devel- opment of RE if other critical aspects are not considered in parallel, including the existence of a sustainable incremental cost recovery mechanism (paid through sustainable subsidy sources or a surcharge on consumer tariffs) and the existence of transmission infrastructure capable for RE integration, as well as clear rules on transmission access and connection. Final Remarks Ultimately, a low carbon development growth in the developing world depends on the availability of resources to finance the solutions that exhibit incremental costs. The volume of financing resources required and the sources are an issue of great concern. While green growth in the developing world is necessary to minimize climate change impacts on a global level, other more pressing devel- opmental priorities compete for the use of budgetary resources, concessional finance, and official development assistance. The pass-through of incremental costs to consumer tariffs is also an issue of concern, given the huge implications on affordability and potential impacts on the poor. Moreover, the use of budgetary resources—or the issuing of debt—to 56 A World Bank Study support RE development displaces other present and future competing priorities. For this reason, policies to support RE development should be designed and introduced in combination with strategies that clearly identify sources of finance and establish a sustainable incremental cost recovery mechanism (for example, using concessional financial flows from developed countries to leverage private financing, strengthening the performance of utilities and Discos, or allowing the partial pass-through of incremental costs to consumer tariffs with a differenti- ated burden sharing that protects the poor). Without question, policy makers will have to ensure that the design of differ- ent policy mechanisms and the policy mix per se deliver RE targets with the lowest possible incremental costs and volume of subsidies. Notes 1. Of course, RE policy effectiveness is also subject to the capacity of the grid to absorb renewables. 2. This has been an issue of concern in the cases analyzed when the grid evacuation infrastructure is weak or when the regulations on connection and dispatch are not clear. 3. These incremental costs may include not only the cost associated with the production of RE, but also the cost associated with FITPs that promote the use of local equipment manufacturing. APPENDIX A Types of Renewable Energy (RE) Policy Mechanisms and Incentives Table A.1 Types of Renewable Energy (RE) Policy Mechanisms and Incentives Classification Type of instrument/incentive I Direct Price-based incentives Feed-in policies (FITs or premiums over spot price) Other premiums: generation-based incentives (GBIs), premiums for use of domestic equip- ment or services Reduced T&D costs Quantity-based incentives or quota obligations Targets on RE penetration Renewable Portfolio Standards (RPS) in combina- tion with Renewable Energy Certificate or Credit (REC) markets (also known as Tradable Green Certificates, TGC markets) RE policy (quota) through competitive procure- ment mechanisms (competitive biddings, auctions) Fiscal and financial incentives Tax credits/incentives and fiscal exemptions (such as accelerated depreciation) Grants/capital subsidies Preferential loans and loan guarantees Carbon financing (through CDM) R&D grants, loans or subsidies Voluntary measures Green tariffs Investment focused (shareholder/contribution programs) II Indirect Pricing of environmental externalities Carbon tax Cap-and-trade or emissions trading schemes (ETS) Environmental standards Performance standards: penalize high emitting sources Voluntary measures Voluntary agreements Sources: Adapted from Fischer and Preonas 2010; Klein et al. 2008; Menanteau, Finon, and Lam 2003; World Bank 2010. 57 58 A World Bank Study References Fischer, Carolyne, and Luis Preonas. 2010. “Combining Policies for Renewable Energy: Is the Whole Less Than the Sum of Its Parts?� Resources for the Future. http://www. rff.org. Klein, Arne, Benjamin Pfluger, Ragwitz Held, Gustav Resch, and Thomas Faber. 2008. “Evaluation of Different Feed-in Tariff Design Options: Best Practice Paper for the International Feed-in Cooperation.� Fraunhofer Institute Systems and Innovation Research, Energy Economics Group, Karlsruhe, Germany. Menanteau, Philippe, Dominique Finon, and Marie-Laure Lamy. 2003. “Price versus Quantities: Choosing Policies for Promoting the Development of Renewable Energy.� Energy Policy 31: 799–812. World Bank. 2010. “Design and Performance of Policy Instruments to Promote the Development of Renewable Energy: Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries.� Final Report, Energy Anchor Unit, Sustainable Energy Department, World Bank, Washington, DC. APPENDIX B Policy Package of Sample Countries as of Last Reform, 2009–10 Table B.1 Policy Package of Sample Countries as of Last Reform, 2009–10 Instruments deployed (1990–2010) IN BR TK INDO NI SRL Targets RE targets � Indicative � � Indicative � Technology specific targets � � � � Price based instruments Feed-in tariff/premium � � � � Premium for use of domestic equipment � � Generation-based incentive (GBI) � Reduced transmission cost (wheeling price � � and/or connection cost) Net metering/banking � � � Carbon market/CDM transactions � � � � � Quantity based instruments and procurement mechanisms Renewable Portfolio Standard (RPS) REC market � Competitive bidding/auction � � � � � Investment Cost Reduction/Financial Incentives Accelerated depreciation � � Green funds (for example; soft loans, � � � � grants) Capital subsidy/equity participation � 100% FDI equipment manufacturing � Fiscal incentives Value added tax exemption � � � �(1) Income tax exemption/reduction � � � Property/turn-over tax exemption � Import duty/customs tax exemption � � � � Excise duty exemption � (table continues on next page) 59 60 A World Bank Study Table B.1 Policy Package of Sample Countries as of Last Reform, 2009–10 (continued) Instruments deployed (1990–2010) IN BR TK INDO NI SRL Entry tax exemption � Electricity duty exemption � Corporate tax exemption (10 years) � Municipal taxes exemption � Tax on financial operations exemption � Corporate tax credit on R&D expenses � Other Prioritized dispatch � � Specific connection alternative for RE � Grid code to facilitate RE integration � � Voluntary measures and other market facilitation measured Green power/retail tariff � Voluntary carbon trading � Reduced or exempted water charges � Biddings for the use of resources � R&D funds/subsidies � � � Single window clearance systems/special � � processing environ licensing Exempted/reduced licensing fees � Exempted/reduced land use fees � � Source: Prepared by authors. Note: IN = India, SRL = Sri Lanka, BR = Brazil, INDO = Indonesia, NI = Nicaragua, TK = Turkey. APPENDIX C Instrument Comparison Table C.1 Instrument Comparison Investment risks Effectiveness/efficiency Complexity Feed in tariff policy (FITP) • Low price, volume and balancing risks • Effectiveness in terms of market • In general complexity is low, but • In spot market transactions, growth is high (subject to compli- depends on type of FIT (trade-offs balancing risk may arise (this risk can ance with RPO) between simplicity and complexity) be minimized introducing a “per • Sophisticated FIT design can reduce • Fixing prices, not quantities requires area� mechanism) inframarginal rents calibration and successive adjust- • Designed to create stable investment • Allows for strategic support of differ- ments (to avoid insufficient or exces- environment (although succes- ent types of RE sive output) sive FITP design adjustments may • No incentive for cost reductions • Depending on design complexity, decrease investors’ confidence) (entire supply chain) calibration may require a complex • Predictable revenue streams • Overall cost of FITP may be high administrative process • Help increase debt financing (depends on FITP design and market conditions) RPS-REC • Moderate to high price risk (value of • Effectiveness in terms of market • REC market design and the periodic REC depends on market dynamics) growth depends on actual setting or targets/quotas may be • Moderate to high volume risks (once compliance with quotas complex targets are met, suppliers do not (market share) • REC market requires high institutional have an incentive to purchase RE • Market-based instrument, fosters and administrative capacity generation) competition among RE suppliers • Balancing risk may be high (depends (least-cost RE introduced first) on market rules and support • Favors mature technologies mechanisms) • Less predictable revenue streams require higher IRRs • Participation in bids may entail high transaction costs • More difficult to secure financing (table continues on next page) 61 62 A World Bank Study Table C.1 Instrument Comparison (continued) Investment risks Effectiveness/efficiency Complexity Competitive procurement (auctions, biddings) • Moderate to high price risk (depends • If competition is effectively fostered, • Design of auction mechanism may on contract design, market rules) delivers low prices (entire supply be complex (depends on type of • Stop-and-go nature creates chain) market and market conditions) uncertainty • Allows for strategic support of • Requires high institutional and • Less predictable revenue streams different types of RE administrative capacity require higher IRRs • High deployment risk (project delays • Requires robust rule of law, • Awarded contracts provide or no implementation at all due enforcement of contracts predictable revenue streams to difficulties in financial closure, • Regulatory stability is crucial (stable administrative or licensing barriers, auction rules) • Participation in bids may entail high weak rule of law or weak enforce- transaction costs • Requires proper design of project ment of contracts or project comple- • More difficult to secure financing completion guarantees and penalties tion guarantees) for delays and underperformance. Source: Prepared by authors. APPENDIX D Data Sources Brazil Operador Nacional do Sistema Elétrico, www.ons.org.br http://www.ons.org.br/resultados_operacao/boletim_mensal_geracao_eolica/ index.aspx India Ministry of Power, www.powermin.nic.in Ministry of New and Renewable Energy, www.mnre.gov.in Planning Commission, www.planningcommission.nic.in Indonesia Ministry of Energy and Mineral Resources, www.esdm.go.id Asian Development Bank, www.adb.org Nicaragua CEPAL, www.cepal.org Instituto Nicaraguense de Energia, www.ine.gob.ni Sri Lanka Central Bank of Sri Lanka, Economic and Social Statistics of Sri Lanka 2010 http://www.cbsl.gov.lk/pics_n_docs/10_pub/_docs/statistics/other/Pub_E&SS_ 2010.pdf Turkey Turkish Electricity Transmission Company, www.teias.gov.tr International Energy Agency, http://www.iea.org/ General U.S. Energy Information Administration, www.eia.doe.gov Global Wind Energy Council, www.gwec.net 63 Glossary Accelerated depreciation: refers to the accelerated amortization of fixed assets, such as plant and equipment (that is, faster recovery of capital costs and ear- lier tax advantages). For tax purposes, accelerated depreciation provides a way of deferring corporate income taxes by reducing taxable income in cur- rent years, in exchange for increased taxable income in future years. This is a valuable tax incentive that encourages businesses to purchase new assets. Additionality criterion: applies to projects considered under the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM). A CDM project activity is additional if anthropogenic emissions of greenhouse gases by sources are reduced below those that would have occurred in the absence of the registered CDM project activity. The baseline for a CDM project activity is the scenario that reason- ably represents the anthropogenic emissions by sources of greenhouse gases that would occur in the absence of the proposed project activity (UNFCCC 2008). Auction: a selection process designed to procure (or allocate) goods and services competitively, where the award is made to a prequalified bidder and is based on a financial offer. In the most common type of auction, potential buyers bid for a product and the highest bid price wins. In most cases involving electric- ity auctions, the sellers, such as generators, are the ones bidding their prod- ucts, since they are interested in selling power contracts to large consumers or distribution companies, with the bidding process designed in part to select the lowest price. This is the so-called “reverse auction,� where the lowest offer is the winner (Maurer and Barroso 2010). Capacity payment: a payment that compensates investors for higher capital costs arising from regulatory risk and the failure of market design to accommodate for long-term contracts with domestic consumer franchises to allow hedging of investment decisions (Grubb et al. 2008). In hydropower-based systems, capacity payments are provided to help mitigate price spikes and encourage investments in flexible and backup plants (that is, peaking generation receives capacity payments to anticipate and receives a certain level of scarcity rents over time). Clean Development Mechanism (CDM): a mechanism established by Article 12 of the Kyoto Protocol for project-based emissions reduction activities in developing countries. The CDM allows emissions emission reduction (or emissions removal) projects in developing countries to earn certified 64 Glossary 65 emissions reductions (CERs), each equivalent to one tone of carbon diox- ide. These CERs can be traded and sold, and used by industrialized coun- tries to meet a part of their emissions reduction targets under the Kyoto Protocol (UNFCCC 2010). Feed-in tariff (FIT): a special tariff paid to renewable energy generators. The pay- ment levels for each kilowatt-hour can be differentiated by technology type, project size, resource quality, and project location to reflect actual project costs better. FITs are categorized as fixed tariffs or premiums. Fixed FITs are paid to generators as guaranteed remuneration independent from the elec- tricity market price (different types include stepped tariffs, tariffs with degression rates, and flat tariffs). Premiums are paid to renewable energy generators on top of the electricity market price; for this reason, they are considered a market-based support instrument. Feed-in tariff policy (FITP): an energy supply policy focused on supporting the development of renewable energy projects by offering three key provisions: (a) guaranteed access to the grid; (b) stable long-term purchase agreements or an arrangement that ensures a stable revenue stream for a prespecified period (for example, in multiple-buyer power markets, renewable energy suppliers are paid a preferential tariff or premium for a prespecified number of years from the market operator; in this case the market operator imposes a surcharge on consumer tariffs to cover the incremental cost); and (c) payment levels, usually above market price, based on the cost of renewable energy generation (that is, a feed-in tariff). FITPs also typically mandate a renewables purchase obligation (RPO) on utilities or retail companies (for example, in the form of market share or minimum percent of electricity purchase from renewable energy, RE suppliers). Firm Energy Certificate (FEC): in the Brazilian regulation, a FEC is a certificate (denominated in gigawatt hour per year) for the maximum amount of energy that a power plant can sell annually through contracts. Any shortfall is penal- ized at a price mirroring the cost of new energy (Barroso 2010). Generation-based incentive (GBI): a premium paid over the FIT or electricity price to shift the incentive from renewable energy installations (MW) to production (GWh). By rewarding the actual generation, GBIs encourage the higher output efficiency of renewable energy plants. Price-setting policies: price-setting policies reduce cost and pricing-related barri- ers by establishing favorable price regimes for renewable energy relative to other sources of power generation. The most common price-based policy is known as FITP (World Bank 2008). Quantity-setting policies: quota-based or quantity-setting mechanisms (also known as market share policies) mandate the introduction of a certain per- centage or absolute quantity of RE capacity or generation at unspecified prices. The government sets a target and lets the market determine the price. 66 A World Bank Study The most common quota-based mechanisms for promoting RE deployment are the RPS and auctions (World Bank 2008). REC market: a platform or legal framework for the trading of RECs. The use of RECs has emerged as a market-based tool to facilitate compliance with pur- chase obligations under the RPS mechanism. The obligated entities under the standard (utilities, retail suppliers) can either own generating capacity or buy RECs. Suppliers can also exercise a “buy-out� option by paying a fixed pen- alty, which theoretically caps the price of credits. Renewable Energy Certificate (REC): represents renewable and environmental attributes associated with energy production. For instance, a REC—for California RPS purposes—is a certificate of proof, issued through the appro- priate accounting system, that one unit of electricity was generated and delivered by an eligible renewable energy source. A REC includes all renew- able and environmental attributes associated with the production of electric- ity from the eligible energy resource, except for emissions reduction credits. RECs can be used not only as a unit of account for compliance purposes, but they can also be traded separately from the energy produced. RECs are also known as Tradable Green Certificates (TGCs). Renewable Portfolio Standard (RPS): a quota-based policy that mandates that electricity suppliers source a given proportion or share of their electricity from renewable energy. An RPS can be phased, with incrementally increasing targets, over a number of years. Assuming there is sufficient capacity to meet the requirement, and assuming ideal operation of the market, eligible renew- able generating sources will “stack themselves� into a merit order of increas- ing cost of generation. These sources then compete to supply renewable electricity to meet market demand, which is determined by the policy target or quota. Typically, generators of eligible electricity receive a Renewable Energy Certificate or Credit (REC, also known as Tradable Green Certificates or TGCs), an official record certifying that a specified amount of renewable electricity has been generated (Grubb et al. 2008). Renewable purchase obligation (RPO): an obligation imposed on utilities or retail companies to source a given proportion or share of their electricity from renewable energy. In this case, the RPO is a component of the FITP. Standardized Power Purchase Agreement (SPPA): a legally binding standardized contractual agreement by which an entity, such as single buyer or a distribu- tion company, undertakes to purchase the power generated by an indepen- dent or affiliated small-scale renewable energy power producer under specified terms for a multiyear period. ECO-AUDIT Environmental Benefits Statement The World Bank is committed to preserving In 2010, the printing of endangered forests and natural resources. this book on recycled paper The Office of the Publisher has chosen to saved the following: print World Bank Studies and Working • 11 trees* Papers on recycled paper with 30 percent • 3 million Btu of total postconsumer fiber in accordance with the energy recommended standards for paper usage • 1,045 lb. of net greenhouse set by the Green Press Initiative, a non- gases profit program supporting publishers in • 5,035 gal. of waste water using fiber that is not sourced from endan- • 306 lb. of solid waste gered forests. For more information, visit www.greenpressinitiative.org. * 40 feet in height and 6–8 inches in diameter D esign and Performance of Policy Instruments to Promote the Development of Renewable Energy: Emerging Experience in Selected Developing Countries is part of the World Bank Studies series. These papers are published to communicate the results of the Bank’s ongoing research and to stimulate public discussion. Renewable energy plays an important role in contributing to the transition toward low-carbon development growth, in enhancing technology diversification and hedging against fuel price volatility, in strengthening economic growth, and in facilitating access to electricity. Global trends indicate a growing commitment to renewable energy development from developed and developing countries in both the introduction of specific policy levers and investment flows. Developing countries have a long history of designing and implementing specific policy and regulatory instruments to promote renewable energy. Today, feed-in tariff policies are being implemented in about 25 developing countries, and quantity-based instruments, most notably auction mechanisms, are increasingly being adopted by upper-middle-income countries. This report summarizes the results of a recent review of the emerging experience with the design and implementation of price- and quota-based instruments to promote renewable energy in a sample of six representative developing countries and transition economies. It also discusses the importance of a tailor-made approach to policy design and identifies the basic elements that have proved instrumental to policy effectiveness, including adequate tariff levels, long-term policy or contractual commitments, mandatory access to the grid, and incremental cost pass-through. Ultimately, low-carbon development growth in the developing world depends on the availability of resources to finance the solutions that exhibit incremental costs. Policies that support renewable energy development should be designed and introduced in combination with strategies that clearly identify sources of finance and establish a sustainable incremental cost recovery mechanism. Without question, policy makers will have to ensure that the design of different policy mechanisms and the policy mix deliver renewable energy targets with the lowest possible incremental costs and volume of subsidies. World Bank Studies are available individually or on standing order. This World Bank Studies series is also available online through the World Bank e-library (www.worldbank.org/elibrary). Energy and Mining ISBN 978-0-8213-9602-5 Sector Board SKU 19602