GUATEMALA POVERTY ASSESSMENT (GUAPA) PROGRAM TECHNICAL PAPER NO. 7 POVERTY AND MODERN UTILITY SERVICES IN GUATEMALA VIVIEN FOSTER1 AND CARIDAD ARAUJO2 December 13, 2001 This paper was prepared under the Guatemala Poverty Assessment Program (GUAPA) of the World Bank. The GUAPA is a multi-year program of technical assistance and analytical work. This is one of many working papers being prepared under the GUAPA. For more information, please contact: Kathy Lindert, Task Manager, LCSHD, The World Bank, KLINDERT@WORLDBANK.ORG. The views presented are those of the authors and need not represent those of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. 1Vivien Foster is an Economist with the Finance, Private Sector and Infrastructure Department of the Latin America and Caribbean Region of the World Bank. VFOSTER@WORLDBANK.ORG 2María Caridad Araujo is a Doctoral student in the Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics at the University of California at Berkeley. araujo@are.Berkeley.EDU 1 Acknowledgements The authors are particularly grateful to Kathy Lindert (Task Manager of the Guatemala Poverty Assessment) for excellent guidance and undying support, and to fellow team members Michele Gragnoloti and Alessandra Marini for close collaboration on the health section of this paper. Extremely helpful comments on an earlier draft were received by the following participants at a World Bank internal seminar: Kulsum Ahmed, Ana María Ibañez, Masami Kojima, Alessandra Marini, Maurizia Tovo, Jean-Philippe Tré, and Renos Vakis. The following people played the invaluable role of providing the background information needed for the study: Tofic Abularach (Unidad Nacional para Acueductos Rurales); Carlos Becerra (INE); Franz Drees (World Bank); José Luis Guasch (World Bank); Ada Karina Izaguirre (World Bank); Chris Jennings (Inter-American Development Bank); Francisco Marroquín (Fondo Nacional para la Paz); Jose Romeo Orellana (Superintendencia de Telecomunicaciones); Kilian Reiche (World Bank); Amalia Sandoval (GUATEL); Marina Segastume (Fondo de Inversión Social); Maurizia Tovo (World Bank); Ricardo Velado (Instituto Nacional de Electricidad); Sergio Velásquez (Comisión Nacional de Energía Eléctrica); Harris Whitbeck (Fondo de Solidaridad y Desarrollo Comunitario); Eduardo Zolezzi (World Bank). 2 Executive Summary Context 1. The 1996 Peace Accords acknowledged the pivotal importance of modern utility services in the Guatemalan development process, and made a commitment to expanding coverage to disadvantaged groups in order to make-up for historic neglect. This commitment was not an empty one and has indeed given rise to very significant and tangible changes in the utilities sectors in Guatemala. This paper uses data from the recent Guatemala Living Standards Measurement Survey (LSMS) 2000 to explore how these changes have affected the lives of poor households. 2. As part of the wider infrastructure sector reform movement in Latin America, Guatemala took major steps to allow private sector participation and promote the development of competition. · The national telecommunications operator TELGUA was privatized in 1998, three new cellular licenses were issued, and the local and long distance markets were opened-up to immediate competition, in one of the most radical liberalization processes witnessed in Latin America. · The three main electricity distribution companies EEGSA, DEORSA and DEOCSA were also privatized, and the generation market opened-up to competition, although the state-owned enterprise INDE continues to hold half of the generation capacity and to control the transmission network. · Water and sanitationwas the only sector where reform measures did not prove to be possible. Thus service continues to be provided by municipal utilities in urban areas, and community-based organizations in rural areas. The metropolitan region is partly served by the state-owned enterprise EMPAGUA, but small-scale private sector operators also play an important role. 3. At the same time, the volume of resources channeled towards rural service expansion has increased substantially through a variety of new and existing institutional mechanisms. First, the investments made by the three main social funds (FIS, FONAPAZ and FSDC) in rural electrification, water and sanitation rose from US$17 million in the period 1993/96 to US$152 million in the period 1997/01. Second, a part of the sales proceeds from the privatization process were earmarked to finance rural service expansions. Thus, the US$110 million raised from the sale of the electricity distribution companies will be used to cover one third of the cost of the new Programa de Electrificación Rural which aims to connect 2,633 communities to the national grid during the period 2000/05. While USS$7.5 million raised from spectrum auctions has been used to provide investment subsidies for private sector construction and operation of 1,600 rural public telephones via the new FONDETEL program. Benefits 4. Evidence from the Guatemala LSMS 2000 shows that households that have access to modern utility services obtain important advantages. · First, the cost of modern utility services is often considerably lower than the corresponding traditional alternative. The clearest example is that of households without electricity who pay implicit prices of more than US$11 per kilowatt-hour (more than 80 times the price of electricity) to illuminate with candles and wick lamps and power appliances with dry cell batteries. 3 · Second, access to modern services can substantially enhance the productivity of households and household-based micro-enterprise. Rural households with access to piped water and liquid propane gas for cooking save around six man-hours per week compared with households who must go out to collect water and fuel wood. Furthermore, micro-enterprises with access to water and electricity are twice as profitable than comparable enterprises without access to these services, and the effect of a cellular telephone on micro-enterprise profitability is even larger. · Third, some traditional substitutes for modern utility services are associated with adverse health impacts and may contribute to infant mortality. Although it is difficult to isolate the underlying causality, children from households with access to piped water and adequate sanitation are significantly less likely to suffer from diarrhea and overall physical stunting. Access 5. Sector by sector coverage rates conceal significant overlaps in the population covered by different services. Overall about 70% of Guatemalan households have water and electricity. These services are close to universal in urban areas, but reach little more than half of rural households. Almost 90% have some kind of basic sanitation, though fewer than half of these have sewerage. About 20% subscribe to either a fixed line and/or a cellular telephone service. Around 17% of Guatemalan households do not have access to any kind of modern network utility service, leading a completely traditional lifestyle. This proportion rises to 33% in rural areas, and 40% among households in the lowest consumption quintile. Middle-income households tend to have only water and electricity services; while only among households in the highest consumption quintile do a majority also have sewerage and telephone. Interestingly, households who only have one utility service (23% in all) are most likely to choose electricity, even when other services (such as piped water) are available in their communities. 6. Coverage has accelerated considerably in recent years reflecting increased levels of investment in the utilities sector. The coverage indices for electricity, water and sanitation increased by about 14 percentage points from 1997/00 versus about 11 percentage points for the period 1993/96. Given the effects of population growth, this represents a substantial increase in the rate of new connections from around 80,000 per year in the years prior to the Peace Accords to around 115,000 per year in the years following the Peace Accords. Moreover, the probability that a household without access received a water or electricity connection rose from 0.19 in the years 1993/96 to 0.35 in the years 1999/00. Notwithstanding these improvements, coverage rates in Guatemala are still only about average for the Central American region. 7. While access to modern utility services in Guatemala remains highly inequitable, there are at least some signs that these inequities are reducing. Relative to the poorest 20%, the richest 20% of households are twice as likely to have a water or electricity connection, and four times as likely to have sewerage. This degree of inequity in access to services is typical of other countries in the Central American region. Fortunately, the most disadvantaged poor, rural and indigenous households have seen their probability of receiving service more than double following the Peace Accords, increasing more than for any other group in society. However, even this substantial improvement has not been enough to offset their traditional disadvantage, so that in absolute terms these groups still remain the least likely to receive services. 4 8. The overall teledensity index for Guatemala has risen almost fivefold from 4.2 to 19.7 over the period 1997/01. An important reason for this has been the explosion of cellular telephony. Although about half of the new cellular subscriptions are second telephones for the richest 20% of the population, there is evidence that cellular telephones are also having a wider social impact. In rural areas, cellular telephones are as common as fixed lines and two thirds of them represent first telephones for households that lack a fixed line service. Moreover, there is considerable anecdotal evidence that these are used to provide an informal public telephone service for the surrounding population. Although less than one percent of households in the poorest 20% of the population own a telephone line, access to telecommunications has improved substantially, with the number of rural public telephones increasing by 80% since the Peace Accords. Thus, 50% of rural households now have a public telephone in their community, and 80% of rural households live within 6 kilometers (or about half an hour) of a public telephone. 9. Notwithstanding substantial progress since the Peace Accords, a significant coverage gap remains. Over half a million households lack access to electricity and piped water, some 200,000 households are without any form of sanitation, and another 200,000 households in the largest cities are still relying on in situ sanitation as opposed to sewerage. Even if currenthistorically highlevels of expenditure and effort are sustained, with population growth of 2.6% per annum it will still take around 10 years to reach universal coverage for water, sewerage and electricity, and five for basic sanitation. The overall cost to the country is estimated at around US$1 billion. 10. However, achieving universal coverage is not merely about building infrastructure networks. The evidence shows that about a third of households without electricity and water live in neighborhoods where these services are available, but simply fail to make a connection. Reasons may include high connection charges, cultural priorities, and the responsiveness of utilities to customer requests. Affordability 11. In Guatemala there has been a conscious policy decision to keep water and electricity tariffs artificially low. To some extent this is understandable given that providing access to utilities services is only ultimately meaningful if these are affordable for poor households to use. However, the evidence suggests that this has not always had the desired consequences, and that the disadvantages of this policy are quite substantial. 12. In the electricity sector, the `tarifa social' introduced following privatization of the distribution companies largely fails to reach poor households. The objective of this policy is to keep domestic tariffs for those consuming up to 300 kilowatt-hours per month capped at US$0.08 per kilowatt-hour. However, the evidence suggests that this measure has only a very modest impact on poor households. Owing to relatively low connection rates among poor households and to the relatively high consumption threshold for the `tarifa social', about 65% of the beneficiaries are non-poor households who together capture 90% of the total value of the subsidy, while 60% of poor households receive no benefits from the scheme at all since they do not have an electricity connection. Lowering the threshold from 300 to 100 kilowatt-hours per month would improve matters somewhat by lowering the number of non-poor beneficiaries to 55% and the leakage rate to 75%, and reducing the annual costs of the policy by 80%. However, even this still leaves a great deal to be desired. 5 13. A much more pro-poor policy would be to channel these resources towards expanding coverage of electricity to unserved households. It is important to recall that thelargely poorhouseholds without access to electricity pay an estimated US$11 per kWh, compared with full cost electricity tariffs of US$0.11 to US$0.15 per kWh. From this perspective, it would appear to make much more sense to channel the US$50 million annual cost of the `tarifa social' towards increasing connections to unserved households. It is estimated that an additional 50,000 new connections each year could be financed in this way. Moreover, given that over 70% of households without electricity belong to the poorest segments of the population, such a policy would be very effective at reaching the poor. 14. In the water and sanitation sector, tariffs are well below true economic costs and international parameters of willingness to pay. Households pay bills of less than US$2 per month in Guatemala City, and less than US$1 per month in other urban areas. The underlying tariffs are barely US$0.10 per cubic meter compared with typical costs of around US$0.40 per cubic meter for the Latin American region. In spite of these low tariffs, as many as 30% of households with piped water reported that they did not pay for the service in the last month, compared with only 8% for electricity. As a result, households spend barely 0.5% of their budgets on water and sanitation services, which is a fraction of the 3%-5% World Health Organization guideline for what households are typically willing to pay. Moreover, many households spend three times as much on bottled water as on piped water. 15. While low water tariffs may seem attractive, there is substantial evidence that the precarious financial position of water utilities is contributing to a very poor quality of service. Three quarters of households with piped water feel it necessary to either buy bottled water or perform some kind of self-treatment. It is particularly striking that the practice regular boiling drinking water is equally prevalent among households with and without piped water (some 40% of both groups). Moreover, households report that on average they receive only 17 hours of water per day and face 3.6 days per month without water. Policy Recommendations 16. In conclusion, the key policy recommendations that emerge from the assessment are as follows. · To maintain and, if possible, increase the current level of resources channeled towards the expansion of modern utility services so as to reach universal coverage within a 10-year horizon. · To try and improve further the ability of service expansion programs to target traditionally disadvantaged groups, in particular, poor, rural and indigenous households. · To develop a strategy for removing the barriers that prevent a significant proportion of excluded households from making connections to services even when these are available in their communities. · To find new financial resources for the FONDETEL rural telephony program and to consider using these to subsidize the extension of cellular networks into commercially marginal areas. · To reform the `tarifa social' policy by at least reducing the eligibility threshold to 100 kilowatt-hours per month, and preferably replacing it with a program to fund 50,000 new connections per year. · To allow water tariffs to rise to a level that allows water utilities to become financially sustainable and thereby improve the quality of service that they offer to the public. · To complement expansion of water and sanitation programs with measures to improve household hygiene practices so as to reap the full health benefits of the service. · To complement expansion of electricity and telecommunications coverage in rural areas with measures to promote the productive use of these services by micro-enterprises. 6 Table of Contents 1. Introduction......................................................................................................................................... 8 2. Recent Developments in the Utilities Sector ...................................................................................... 9 2.1 Sector Reform............................................................................................................................. 9 2.2 Peace Accords........................................................................................................................... 13 3. Impact on Service Coverage ............................................................................................................. 16 3.1 The coverage situation.............................................................................................................. 16 3.2 International context ................................................................................................................. 18 3.3 Historical context ...................................................................................................................... 20 3.4 The remaining deficit................................................................................................................ 26 3.5 Obstacles to expanding coverage .............................................................................................. 28 4. Affordability of Modern utilities ............................................................................................... 31 4.1 Electricity.................................................................................................................................. 32 4.2 Water......................................................................................................................................... 37 5. Benefits of Access to Modern Utilities.......................................................................................... 39 5.1 Productivity benefits................................................................................................................. 39 5.2 Health benefits .......................................................................................................................... 48 6. Conclusions and Recommendations ............................................................................................ 52 Data Annex............................................................................................................................................... 57 A. Summary Statistics for Regressions................................................................................................ 57 B. Summary Statistics Underlying Figures Presented in Text............................................................. 63 C. Standard Summary Tables .............................................................................................................. 68 D. Explanations of Coverage, Take-Up and Availability.....................................................................78 7 1. Introduction `Para [el desarrollo] es imprescindible la infraestructura básica, de comunicación, electrificación y la productiva. La inversión pública se deberá orientar prioritariamente con ese propósito y se establecerá un marco de incentivos a la inversión para el desarrollo rural en las áreas consideradas.' Acuerdos de Paz, 1996. The 1996 Peace Accords acknowledged the pivotal importance of modern utility services3 in the Guatemalan development process, and made a commitment to expanding coverage to disadvantaged groups in order to make-up for historic neglect. This commitment has given rise to substantial changes in the utilities sectors in Guatemala. On the one hand, the electricity and telecommunications sectors have undergone profound structural transformation, through an ambitious program of privatization and market liberalization. At the same time, the volume of resources channeled towards rural service expansion has been tripled through a variety of new and existing institutional mechanisms. Poor households typically have much lower rates of access to modern utility services than the rest of society. As a result, they often rely primarily on traditional substitutes, consuming water from local rivers, meeting their sanitation needs in the open air, lighting their homes with candles, cooking with fuel wood collected from local forests, and traveling personally over long distances to pass on messages to distant relatives or business associates. There a number of barriers that explain why many low income households remain uncovered by modern utility networks. They include inadequate development of physical infrastructure, prohibitively high capital costs of access, or in some cases lack of cultural familiarity or information about the services in question and their advantages. As a result of this exclusion, poor households suffer a number of handicaps. First, the unit cost of some traditional substitutes is often considerably higher than the corresponding modern alternatives. For example, lighting with candles is very much more expensive per kilowatt-hour than lighting with electricity. Similarly traveling to a distant town to relay a message is often much more expensive than making a telephone call. Again, time spent collecting and storing water may be costly in relation to the price of a piped service. Where costs are high, households may consume too little of the service to satisfy subsistence requirements. For example, households may not be able to afford enough water to meet basic hygiene needs. Second, access to modern services can substantially enhance the productivity of households and household-based micro-enterprises. Many of the traditional substitutes for modern services are time intensive to use (for example, collecting water and fuel-wood, or relaying messages). Time liberated from these tasks can potentially be reallocated to income generating activities, or in the case ofchildren to education. Furthermore, electricity makes possible the use of appliances that substantially increase productivity and hence income generating potential of micro-enterprises (pumps, sewing machines, power tools), while information and communication technologies enhance the availability of market information and the possibility of social and political participation. 3 For the purposes of this discussion, modern utility services are defined to include water, sanitation, energy, and telecommunications. Water is defined as having piped water in the dwelling or yard. Sanitation is defined to include latrines, septic tanks and sewerage. 8 Third, some traditional substitutes for modern utility service are associated with adverse health impacts and may contribute to infant mortality. Inadequate water and sanitation may give rise to waterborne diseases, while cooking with biomass fuels has often been linked to respiratory ailments. In this sense, infrastructure could be regarded as an input into the health production function that complements hygiene practices and health care interventions. This paper explores how the important policy changes experienced in the utilities sector in Guatemala since the Peace Accords have affected the lives of poor households. First, Section 2 examines to what extent service expansion programs have succeeded in reversing the inequities that have traditionally existed in access to modern utility services, and the barriers that remain in achieving universal coverage. Second, Section 3 looks at how tariff reforms and related subsidy policies have affected the affordability of modern utility services for the poor. Finally, Section 4 attempts to quantify the broader benefits that such services bring to poor households, in terms of improved health and productivity. A Data Annex provides a set of standard cross-tabulations of all of the basic variables of interest by geographical, ethnic and economic categories. It also gives the descriptive statistics for each of the regressions reported in the paper, as well as tabulations of the numbers underlying each of the graphics. The analysis draws primarily on household level data collected during the ENCOVI 2000 Survey; the first survey ever to be conducted in Guatemala in accordance with the Living Standards Measurement Survey methodology. The ENCOVI covered 7,276 households, drawn from 745 census clusters of UPM (Unidad Primaria de Muestreo), and is designed to be statistically representative at the national level, and of a number of strata including urban and rural areas, the country's eight geographical regions, and the main ethnic groups established in the 1994 census4. In some areas, it is possible to match-up the results of the quantitative analysis against subjective perceptions of poverty recorded in aparallel Qualitative Poverty and Exclusion Study (QPES), which conducted in-depth focus group interviews in nine communities selected to represent a broad ethnic cross-section of Guatemalan society. The survey data is complemented by sectoral statistics collected directly from the key policy-making and regulatory bodies, as well as a number of donor agencies active in the country5. 2. Recent Developments in the Utilities Sector This section provides a brief overview of the policy context each in the three utilities sectors: telecommunications, energy, and water and sanitation services. Two important developments are documented. First, the sector reform movement that has led to a complete transformation of the telecommunications and electricity sectors, but has yet to make any impact on the water and sanitation sector. Second, the various policies that were established to promote expansion of service coverage in rural areas. 2.1 Sector Reform Electricity Prior to reform, electricity was provided by two state-owned companies: EEGSA, which was responsible for electricity distribution in the metropolitan region; and INDE, which controlled the remaining generation, transmission and distribution assets nationwide. The Electricity Law of 1996 4Kiche, K'aqchikel, Mam, Q'eqchi, `other Maya' and `other indigenous'. 5Throughout the study, quintiles are based on per capita household consumption.. 9 (Decreto 93-96) sought to increase investment and improve efficiency in the sector by introducing competition in electricity generation, and privatizing the distribution networks. A regulatory agency, the Comisión Nacional de Energía Eléctrica (CNEE), was created to oversee the new system. Table 2.1: Summary of structural changes in Guatemala telecommunications sector Pre Reform Post Reform Generation INDE monopoly 50%INDE (hydroelectric) and 50% Independent Power Producers (thermal) Transmission INDE monopoly INDE monopoly Distribution EEGSA, DEORSA, DEOCSA Privatized EEGSA, DEORSA, DEOCSA In 1998, an 80% stake in EEGSA was sold to Iberdrola of Spain. While the distribution assets of INDE were broken down into two regional distribution companies, DEORSA and DEOCSA (serving the east and west of the country respectively), which were also privatized in 1998. One investor purchased both companies: Unión Fenosa of Spain. Notwithstanding the reforms, the state-owned enterprise INDE retains a dominant position in the system. It controls about half of the country's (mainly hydroelectric) generating plants, but competes with independent power producers that control the rest of the (primarily thermal) capacity. Furthermore, INDE continues to own and operate the national transmission grid. An important benefit of the electricity sector reform has been the rapid increase in coverage, from 53% in 1996 to 70% in 19996. However, prices have also risen substantially. Under the new regulatory framework, the privatized distribution companies are allowed to pass on to the customers the variations in the purchase cost of energy. Due to the fact that the current Power Purchase Agreements signed between generators and distributors are indexed to the US dollar and the price of oil, prices have risen substantially since 1998, between 60%-80% depending on the company. Another issue that remains problematic in the electricity sector is that of illegal connections. As reported in the ENCOVI survey, while 73% of the households report to be connected to the electricity network (95% in the urban and 56% in the rural areas), only 62% have an electricity meter (78% in the urban and 50% in the rural areas). The lack of a meter suggests that these households are illegally connected, or at best, that the amounts they pay for the service are not proportional to their monthly consumption. Telecommunications7 Until 1996, telecommunications services in Guatemala were the monopoly of GUATEL; a state-owned enterprise created in 1971. By the mid-1990s, there was growing dissatisfaction with the performance of GUATEL. Not only was the company comparatively inefficient (around 60 mainlines per 1,000 employees), but it was failing to satisfy mounting demand for telecommunications services. In 1996, Guatemala had one of the lowest teledensity ratios in Latin America with only 4.2 (fixed plus cellular) lines per 100 inhabitants. With only 350,000 fixed telephone lines in the country, unsatisfied demand was estimated at 1,000,000 lines. 6 Official national coverage statistics provided by the regulatory agency, Comisión Nacional de Energía Eléctrica (CNEE). They are consistent with the coverage trends inferred from ENCOVI 2000 (see Section 3 below). 7 The factual information reported in this section is either drawn from a number of World Bank Aide Memoires for the Guatemala Private Participation in Infrastructure Technical Assistance Project (Loan 4149-GU) or supplied directly by the Superintendencia de Telecomunicaciones. 10 The Telecommunications Law of 1996 (Decreto 94-96) paved the way for one of the most radical market liberalizations witnessed in the region (Table 2.1). All barriers to competition were removed with immediate effect, as were all regulatory restrictions on prices and quality of service. This stands in contrast to most other reforming countries in Latin America, which have tended to pass through a transitional exclusivity periodduring which the historical incumbent retains much of its monopoly powerand which have tended to retain regulatory safeguards on price and quality of service even after the introduction of competition. Table 2.2: Summary of structural changes in Guatemala telecommunications sector Pre Reform Post Reform Fixed telephony · Local calls GUATEL monopoly Privatized TELGUA plus 15 new entrants. · Long distance calls GUATEL monopoly Privatized TELGUA plus 13 new entrants. Cellular telephony One private operator. Three new entrants The 1996 law also created a new regulatory agency, the Superintendencia de Telecomunicaciones (SIT). However, given the extent of deregulation in the sector, the functions of the SIT are limited to licensing and monitoring the use of the radio spectrum and resolving disputes involving telecommunications operators. Although the privatization of GUATEL was an integral part of the reform strategy, this was delayed until 1998 owing to a variety of political and legal obstacles. In the end, due to legal obstacles, it proved necessary to transfer most of the assets of GUATEL (except for the network of rural public telephones) to a new company, TELGUA. The government then sold off a 95% stake in TELGUA via auction to the private sector; the successful (and in fact only interested) bidder being TELMEX. An important consequence of liberalization has been the need to rebalance call charges, to remove the cross-subsidy that previously existed from long distance to local calls. As a result, local call charges increased tenfold from $0.51 per month (for the basic subscription including 200 free minutes; equivalent to $0.003 per minute), to $5.64 per month (equivalent to $0.028 per minute). However, even this falls below the estimated economic cost of around $0.030 to $0.033 per minute. There are now more than 250 companies involved in providing the full range of telecommunications services in Guatemala. These include a number of major international investors such as Bell South, Telefónica, TELMEX, and Millicom International. Although the local telephony market continues to be dominated by TELGUA, with 95% of all fixed line subscribers, sixteen other companies have entered the market competing primarily in the most lucrative market niches, such as Guatemala City. Competition for long distance services has been more vigorous, with fourteen players in all, and four major players. The combination of tariff-rebalancing and competition has led to dramatic reductions in long distance charges, from US$1.50 per minute to the United States in 1996, to around US$0.30 per minute in 1998. More recently, charges have fallen to around US$0.15 per minute as a result of the introduction of the possibility of teleselection of the long distance operator8. 8The lower cost of international calls is an important consideration for the approximately 10% of households in Guatemala who obtain about 10% of their income from international remittances. 11 In addition, four licenses have been issued for mobile telephony services. Calls are charged at around $0.14 per minute, with some calling plans costing less than $10 per month. The reform has had a major impact on the performance of the telecommunications sector in Guatemala. The efficiency of the sector improved markedly, with the number of mainlines per 1,000 employees rising from 60 in 1996 to 130 in 1999. While, at the same time there have been massive gains in coverage. According to SIT data, the total number of fixed plus cellular telephone lines rose almost fivefold from around 350,000 to over 1,600,000 between 1996-01, raising the teledensity index from 4.2 to 19.7. Much of this growth came from new cellular lines, which now represent more than half of the total (57%). The development of the cellular network has been less concentrated in the capital city. Whereas in 2001, 70% of the country's fixed lines were located in the Department of Guatemala, only 43% of the cells of the mobile telephony network were located in that Department. Water and sanitation Although sector reforms have been under discussion for some years in the water sector, it has not been possible to reach a political consensus on this issue. At present, the provision of water and sanitation services in the metropolitan region remains the responsibility of the state-owned enterprise EMPAGUA. EMPAGUA serves about 70% of the market in the central city area (falling to 50% if the surrounding municipalities are taken into account). More than 200 private companies meet the shortfall in demand, of which the largest are Aguas de Mariscal and San Cristóbal, but the majority are small-scale operations serving a specific neighborhood or housing estate. A recent study (Solo, 1999) found that whereas charges by the main utility fell in the range $0.09-$0.42 per cubic meter depending on the consumption group, charges applied by alternative suppliers were substantially higher at between $0.25-$2.70 per cubic meter. Table 2.3: Summary of the structure of the Guatemala water and sanitation sector Metropolitan area 50% EMPAGUA, 50% small scale private operators Non-metropolitan urban areas Municipal utilities Rural areas Community Based Organization with support from central government UNEPAR Outside of the metropolitan region, the country's 240 municipalities are responsible for providing water and sanitation services, at least in urban areas. However, they do not tend to reach isolated rural areas, where community-based organizations typically take charge of services, often with some financial support from central government via the Unidad Ejecutora del Programa de Acueducto Rural (UNEPAR) or from the various social investment funds. A number of recent sector reviews9 comment on the precarious financial position of many of the service providers, due to the relatively low level of water tariffs and the political unwillingness to raise them closer to cost recovery levels. According to the ENCOVI survey, 69% of households have piped water and 87% of the households have some form of sanitation; although only 38% are connected to the sewerage network. 9See for example CEPIS, 2000 and IDB, 2001. 12 2.2 Peace Accords The 1996 Peace Accords acknowledged the pivotal importance of modern utilities in the development process, and the historical neglect of the infrastructure needs of rural and disadvantaged urban communities. Although no quantitative targets were set, the Peace Accords made concrete commitments to expanding coverage of electricity, water and sanitation, as well as public telephones. Following the Peace Accords, two main mechanisms were used to channel greater volumes of finance into (particularly rural) infrastructure. First, both in the electricity and telecommunications sectors, some of the proceeds of privatization were earmarked to finance rural expansion programs. In the electricity sector10, the net sale revenues from the privatization of the two non-metropolitan distribution companies (DEORSA and DEOCSA), totaling US$110 million, were placed in a trust fund to be used to finance a five-year rural electrification program (PER). The fact that the government was willing to sacrifice such a significant sum of potential fiscal revenue to support rural service expansion is unusual within the Latin American experience of privatization, and indicates the degree of commitment that exists to rural electrification. The objective of the PER is to connect 2,633 communities to the national grid during the period 2000-05, at a total cost of US$333 million. The two distribution companies DEORSA and DEOCSA are contractually responsible for executing the investments. Since the program became active in 1999, almost US$55 million have been disbursed. As a result, about 23% of the coverage target has been met, with a further 5% in the pipeline. The projects executed to date suggest that the average cost of electrifying a rural household is of the order of US$1,000, which is not unusual by international standards. In the telecommunications sector11, 70% of the proceeds of the spectrum auctions held for mobile telephony services (up to an annual ceiling of US$5 million) were allocated to a special fund (FONDETEL) designed to support the expansion of public telephones in rural areas. In line with best practice in a number of other Latin American countries (notably, Chile, Colombia and Peru), FONDETEL bid out the construction and operation of public telephones to the private operator requesting the minimum subsidy. Between 1998/99, FONDETEL disbursed US$7.5 million of subsidies for the installation of some 1,600 public telephones. Each US$1 of subsidy leveraged between US$2-4 of private investment, so that the total subsidy cost per town was US$4,400. However, unfortunately, the revenues from spectrum auctions have now been exhausted and no additional funding source has been identified for FONDETEL. While GUATEL - the state-owned company that continues to hold the rural telephone assets that were created prior to 1998 - has also lacked the financial resources to make any further investments. Second, in addition to these privatization related initiatives, the existing social fundsprincipally FSDC, FIS and FONAPAZincreased their investments efforts in the infrastructure sectors (Figure 2.1). Overall, the investments of these three funds in energy, water and sanitation services more than quadrupled between 1996 and 1998. However, this reflected an overall increase in social fund 10Information provided directly by INDE. 11Information provided directly by FONDETEL. 13 expenditure; rather than a shift in the portfolio of projects towards infrastructure sectors. Moreover, there is evidence that the water, sanitation and electricity investments of social funds have begun to tail- off since 1999. Figure 2.1: Total social fund investments in rural infrastructure since 1993 50 45 40 year 35 per 30 Electricity 25 Water and sanitation million 20 US$15 10 5 0 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Sources: FIS, FONAPAZ, FSDC It is interesting to explore the relative importance of resources generated by the privatization process, those channeled via the social funds, and other sources of finance for rural expansion of utility services (Table 2.4). By far the largest volume of resources has gone to water and sanitation, US$153 million, versus US$99 million for electricity and US$7.5 million for public telephones. In electricity, the volume of resources devoted to rural electrification tripled in the years before and after the Peace Accords. As well as this overall increase, the composition of financing has changed substantially. Up until 1996, about two thirds of the investment in rural electrification came from the state-owned operator INDE, whose program has since been dramatically reduced in scale. This reduction has been more than offset by a quadrupling of social fund investments, and by the beginning of the PER. The latter, which has only disbursed about 20% of its programmed expenditure to date, will become increasingly important over time as social fund investments appear to be tailing-off. In telecommunications, the rural investment activities of GUATEL were substantial prior to the Peace Accords but came to a halt following the privatization and sector restructuring exercise that divested the state-owned company of all its assets except for the rural telephones, thereby curtailing its ability to finance further projects. While GUATEL continued to operate existing rural telephones, FONDETEL became responsible for constructing further rural telephones, which it did by contracting with private sector operators. The FONDETEL program rapidly succeeded in almost doubling the number of rural public telephones (from 2,000 to 3,600) in a very short period, with a fraction of the resources absorbed by GUATEL in the earlier period (US$7.5 million versus US$46.0 million), largely due to its ability to leverage private capital. Table 2.4: Summary of rural infrastructure initiatives since 1996 Sector Initiative Description Funds Funds Invested Invested (US$ million) (US$ million) 1993-1996 1997-2000 Electricity 32.6 99.0 PER · Programa de Electrificación Rural: A program incorporated 0.0 36.1 into the concession contracts of the two non-metropolitan distribution companies (DEORSA and DEOCSA). The two companies are required to extend grid access to 280,000 households in 2,700 communities over the period 2000/05. The property of the assets financed by PER will revert to the state. 14 property of the assets financed by PER will revert to the state. INDE will be responsible for operating transmission assets, and DEORSA and DEOCSA for the distribution assets. About a quarter of the target communities are in the department of Quiche, and the average size of the communities is around 500 inhabitants. The total cost of US$333 million, will be financed in part by the net proceeds of privatizing DEORSA and DEOCSA (US$110 million). FSDC · Fondo de Solidaridad para el Desarrollo Comunitario : The 12.2 57.3 largest of the country's three main social funds, financed primarily financed by central government, and providing a range of services requested by communities including electrification. Covers mainly rural communities. INDE · Instituto Nacional de Electrificación. The statutes of the 20.4 5.6 company require that it devotes any operating surplus to rural electrification projects. These have tended to involve mini-grid projects and grid extensions for communities close to the Mexican border. Telephony 46.0 7.5 FONDETEL · Fondo de Telecomunicaciones: A fund established from the 0.0 7.5 proceeds of spectrum license auctions. Bids out minimum subsidy concessions for private operators to build and operate public telephones in rural communities. GUATEL · Guatemala Telecom. The state-owned enterprise that owns 46.0 0.0 and operates the state's network of rural public telephones. During the period 1993-96, the company invested $46 million with finance from IDB and EXIMBANK to provide services to 1,150 rural communities. Lack of investment finance has prevented further progress since privatization, although a new project for 1,324 rural communities is in process to be financed by FONAPAZ and BCIE. Water and NA. 153.1 Sanitation FIS · Fondo de Inversión Social: One of the country's largest three 0.4 29.6 social funds, financed predominantly by international donors, providing a range of services requested by communities including water and sanitation. Covers primarily rural communities. FONAPAZ · Fondo Nacional para la Paz: One of the country's largest three 4.1 7.8 social funds, financed predominantly by international donors, providing a range of services requested by communities including water and sanitation. Focuses on areas that were most affected by the armed conflict. FSDC · Fondo de Solidaridad para el Desarrollo Comunitario. 0.0 64.4 UNEPAR · Unidad de Proyectos de Acueductos Rurales:The public entity NA. 51.3 responsible for finance and TA to rural water projects.In1997, was transfered from the Ministry of Health to the Instituto de Fomento Municipal (INFOM). Finance comes from IDB and KFW among others. 15 In water and sanitation, the investments made by the social funds since the Peace Accords represented about two thirds of the total, with the remainder being supplied by the central government's rural water program UNEPAR. The total value of UNEPAR's investments in the years prior to the Peace Accords is not known, however they are unlikely to have been as high as those currently allocated by the social funds, and hence overall it seems likely that the volume of resources devoted to rural water and sanitation project has increased substantially. 3. Impact on Service Coverage 3.1 The coverage situation12 The current coverage situation in Guatemala, as portrayed by the ENCOVI survey, is summarized in Table 3.1. Sanitation (broadly defined to include latrines, septic tanks and sewerage) is the service with the highest level of coverage, followed by electricity, water, sewerage and telephony. The gaps between urban and rural coverage are lowest for sanitation, and highest for sewerage and telephony. Water and sanitation are those with the most egalitarian distribution, while sewerage and telephony are the least egalitarian. Table 3.1: Coverage of utilities (service by service) (Proportion of households) National By area By quintile Urban Rural 1 2 3 4 5 Electricity .73 .95 .56 .39 .64 .78 .90 .95 Water .69 .88 .54 .50 .62 .63 .76 .92 Sanitation .87 .97 .79 .73 .80 .88 .95 .98 Sewerage .38 .76 .09 .06 .18 .32 .54 .81 Fixed telephone .15 .31 .03 .003 .01 .03 .14 .58 Cellular telephone .10 .18 .03 .001 .01 .03 .11 .34 Community public telephone .64 .89 .44 .37 .53 .65 .79 .83 No service = lack of all network services and latrine. Network services = electricity, piped water in dwelling or field, telephone (fixed or cellular), and toilet connected to sewerage. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística - Guatemala While it is conventional to report separate statistics on the coverage of different services, in terms of understanding quality of life, it is informative to consider the combinations of utilities services that people have access to (Table 3.2). The results show that one in six Guatemalan households has no access to any modern network services (electricity, piped water, sewerage or telephony). In rural areas the proportion rises to almost one in three; while in the lowest consumption quintile it is as high as two in five. At the other end of the spectrum, one in six Guatemalan households has access to all four network services, with the ratio rising to one in three for urban areas. It is interesting to question which is the first service to reach those Guatemalan households that only have access to one of the network services (Table 3.3). The statistics show that in about 60% of cases the only service available in the household is electricity, and in the other 40% of cases water. The greater prevalence of electricity services holds good for almost every sub-category of the population except for the poorest. Where only two services are available, they are invariably water and electricity, while households with only three services most typically have electricity, water and sewerage. 12See Annex D for definitions of coverage, takeup, and availability. 16 Table 3.2: Coverage of utilities (in combination) (Proportion of households) National By area By quintile Urban Rural 1 2 3 4 5 No network service .16 .02 .27 .39 .21 .15 .06 .02 One network service .23 .09 .34 .33 .32 .29 .27 .04 Two network services .28 .22 .32 .26 .37 .34 .32 .11 Three network services .18 .34 .06 .02 .09 .20 .31 .27 Four network services .15 .32 .01 .001 .01 .03 .14 .56 No service = lack of all network services and latrine. Network services = electricity, piped water in dwelling or field, telephone (fixed or cellular), and toilet connected to sewerage. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística - Guatemala Table 3.3: Specific combinations of utility services (Proportion of households) National By area By quintil Urban Rural 1 2 3 4 5 One network service 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Electricity .57 .79 .53 .34 .52 .75 .78 .69 Water .42 .19 .47 .65 .47 .25 .22 .25 Phone .004 .01 .003 0 .01 0 0 .06 Sewerage .001 .01 0 .001 .002 .002 0 0 Two network services 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Electricity and water .93 .88 .95 .99 .97 .97 .84 .72 Electricity and phone .04 .07 .02 0 .002 .004 .10 .14 Electricity and sewerage .02 .03 .01 0 .01 .01 .04 .04 Water and phone .01 0 .01 0 .01 .001 .01 .07 Water and sewerage .01 .02 .001 .01 .004 .01 .01 .03 Phone and sewerage 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Three network services 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Electricity, water and phone .19 .14 .44 .11 .06 .13 .16 .31 Electricity, water and sewerage .80 .85 .53 .89 .94 .87 .81 .66 Electricity, phone and sewerage .01 .01 .03 0 0 0 .02 .02 Water, phone and sewerage .005 .004 .01 0 0 0 .004 .01 Network services are electricity, piped water in dwelling or field, telephone (fixed or cellular), and toilet connected to sewerage. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística - Guatemala From the previous figures, it is not possible to say whether the higher prevalence of electricity rather than water in single-service households reflects a preference on the part of the household or simply greater success in rolling out electricity networks versus water networks. In order to shed some light on this question, attention is focused on that subset of the population that live in communities where both services are available (Table 3.4). The results show that such households are twice as likely to choose an electricity connection than a water connection, and that this relationship holds across almost all sub- categories, except the first quintile where households are a little more likely to choose the water service. A possible explanation for this is that electricity connections are free of charge, at least in urban areas, whereas water connections entail paying a significant connection fee (see Table 3.14 below). Table 3.4: Choice between electricity and water (Proportion of households, among with only one service and in census tract where both water and electricity are available) National By area By quintile Urban Rural 1 2 3 4 5 Electricity .63 .69 .60 .44 .59 .76 .79 .63 Water .31 .31 .40 .56 .41 .24 .21 .37 Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala 17 Another way of exploring the relative value that households place on different services is to consider how much extra they are willing to pay to rent a dwelling thatother things being equalhas access to utilities. This rental premium can be estimated using a hedonic function that models rental payments (or estimated rental payments in the case of owner-occupied housing) as a function of the availability of utilities and of a wide range of variables that affect the price of housing (geographical location, quality of construction, size and age of dwelling, facilities). For full details of the model see Table A5 of the Data Annex. The results show that utility services attract statistically significant rental premia, which represent a substantial percentage of the rent. Although the results vary by geographical zone, telephone services typically attract the highest rental premium, followed by electricity and water. Table 3.5: Rental value of access to modern utility services Metropolitan Urban Rural (urban and rural) (non-Metropolitan) (non-Metropolitan) Predicted rent in Quetzales 794 379 159 Value as a % of rent Water 48%*** 0.3% -1% Drainage 2% 9%* 17%** Electricity 9% 31%*** 18%*** Telephone 56%*** 22%*** 32%*** Value in Quetzales Water 379*** 1 -2 Drainage 16 32* 27** Electricity 72 118*** 29*** Telephone 447*** 82*** 51*** Notes: Values calculated from the regional-specific hedonic price function estimations. Significance level of corresponding variables in the hedonic mo del: ***99% level.**95% level,* 90% level. Metropolitan includes urban and rural in this region, while urban and rural exclude the Metropolitan region. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala 3.2 International context To put these findings in an international context, comparable figures are presented for three neighboring Central American countries: El Salvador, Nicaragua and Panama (Table 3.6). Coverage levels in Guatemala lie towards the middle of the range for this peer group; in general, they are somewhat better than those in Nicaragua and El Salvador, but not as good as those in Panama. Finally, the pattern of access to modern utilities across consumption quintiles in Guatemala is very similar to that found in neighboring Central American countries (Figure 3.1). This illustrates that the degree of inequity in access to basic services found in Guatemala is typical of the Central American region. Table 3.6: Central American comparisons of urban and rural coverage (Percentage of households) Electricity Piped water Basic sanitation Telephone Nat'l Urban Rural Nat'l Urban Rural Nat'l Urban Rural Nat'l Urban Rural Guatemala 70 92 54 69 88 54 87 97 79 20 40 5 El Salvador 80 95 55 52 69 25 81 85 74 20 32 1 Nicaragua 69 91 40 61 95 74 84 95 70 16 16 1 Panamá 79 98 52 86 95 74 93 99 86 41 62 11 Notes: Piped water in dwelling or yard. Includes toilets and latrines. El Salvador and Honduras quintiles based on income aggregate. Sources: El Salvador (Encuesta de Hogares de Propósitos Múltiples 1997); Guatemala (ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística - Guatemala); Honduras (Encuesta Nacional de Ingresos y Gastos de los Hogares, 1999); Nicaragua (LSMS 1998-99); Panama (LSMS 1997). 18 Figure 3.1: Central American comparisons for equity of coverage (a) Electricity 100 90 80 70 Guatemala households 60 Nicaragua of 50 Panama 40 El Salvador 30 20 Percentage 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 Consumption quintile (b) Water 100 90 80 70 Guatemala households 60 El Salvador of 50 Nicaragua 40 Panama 30 20 Percentage 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 Consumption quintile (c) Sanitation 100 90 80 70 Guatemala households 60 El Salvador of 50 Nicaragua 40 Panama 30 20 Percentage 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 Consumption quintile (d) Telephone 100 90 80 70 Guatemala households 60 El Salvador of 50 Nicaragua 40 Panama 30 20 Percentage 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 Consumption quintile Sources: El Salvador (Encuesta de Hogares de Propósitos Múltiples 1997); Guatemala (ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística- Guatemala); Honduras (Encuesta Nacional de Ingresos y Gastos de los Hogares, 1999); Nicaragua (LSMS 1998-99); Panama (LSMS 1997). 19 3.3 Historical context It is important to understand how current levels of coverage have been reached, an in particular the extent to which the greater volume of resources devoted to service expansion following the Peace Accords is reflected as faster growth of coverage. Expansion of electricity, water and sanitation Historical trends show that the rate of increase of coverage accelerated after the major policy changes introduced in 199613 (Figure 3.2). For all three services (electricity, water and sanitation), coverage improved by close to 15 percentage points over the subsequent four years (1997-00) compared with just over 10 percentage points over the previous four years (1993-96)14. Clearly, it is difficult to attribute the causality for this acceleration to the Peace Accords and to the structural reforms introduced at that time. Other factorsnotably economic growth and urbanizationcould equally have been at work. Nonetheless, the fact that neither GDP per capita nor urbanization rates increased substantially over this period makes it more likely that the observed improvements were at least partially attributable to changes in the policy environment and increases in public investment15. However, coverage statistics can be misleading because they confound growing numbers of connections with growing population. To disentangle these effects, Table 3.7 reports the absolute number of new connections made in the period before and after the Peace Accords. The results confirm that the rate of service expansion was in general about 50% higher in the years following the Peace Accords, and that these differences are statistically significant (in most cases at the 99% level). Furthermore, the acceleration of coverage was quite generalized affecting both urban and rural areas, as well as poor and non-poor populations. Moreover, the changes in the number of new connections per year were largest (in percentage terms) and most significant in the case of poor and rural populations. On reflection, it is not entirely surprising that new connections went disproportionately to traditionally disadvantaged groups, since most other groups in society were already being served. Therefore, in order to detect whether there has really been an improvement in targeting of services towards socially excluded groups, it is necessary to normalize the number of new connections they received against the size of the corresponding unserved population in each group. In other words, it is necessary to compare the probability that an unserved household in any particular category would become connected during the period immediate preceding and following the Peace Accords (Table 3.8). 13 It is important to explain how this historical series was derived. Due to the paucity of earlier household surveys in Guatemala, the historical series is based on a question in the ENCOVI 2000 survey that asked households to recall the year in which they had first received these services. Hence, the accuracy of the historical trend is contingent on the accuracy of households' recollection. It has been noted in the literature that respondent recall in household surveys can sometimes be affected by a phenomenon known as `telescoping' whereby events are recalled as being more recent than they actually were. Such a phenomenon, if present, would create the impression that coverage growth had been more rapid in recent years. 14 Where possible coverage rates derived from the ENCOVI have been compared with official figures. In the case of electricity, the current estimated coverage of 70% coincides precisely with that reported by the Ministry of Energy. While rural water coverage of 54% is almost identical to that reported by UNEPAR. 15Average GDP per capita was US$1,449 for 1993/96 and US$1,532 for 1997/00. While urbanization stood at an average of 38.6% for 1993/96 and 39.4% for 1997/00. 20 Table 3.7: New connections in a three year period before and after the Peace Accord (Number of new connections) Electricity Piped Sanitation water National 1993-1996 208,518 240,069 281,106 1997-2000 329,734*** 352,336*** 350,418** % change 58% 47% 25% Urban 1993-1996 92,823 109,453 134,692 1997-2000 105,009 128,593 109,792 % change 13% 17% -18% Rural 1993-1996 115,695 130,616 146,414 1997-2000 224,725*** 223,743*** 240,626*** % change 94% 71% 64% Extreme poor 1993-1996 13,662 24,253 27,979 1997-2000 33,135*** 43,091** 38,674* % change 143% 78% 38% All Poor 1993-1996 95,296 108,754 132,815 1997-2000 180,842*** 184,682*** 176,028** % change 90% 70% 33% Non-poor 1993-1996 113,222 131,315 148,255 1997-2000 148,892* 167,654* 174,390 % change 32% 28% 18% Indigenous 1993-1996 87,785 105,547 114,052 1997-2000 142,414*** 153,789*** 137,572 % change 62% 46% 21% Non-indigenous 1993-1996 117,976 133,965 166,007 1997-2000 186,392*** 195,611*** 209,926* % change 58% 46% 26% Notes: Based on household recall of the year in which they were first connected The null hypothesis of equality of thenumber of users before and after Peace Accord is rejected at: ***99% level. **95% level,* 90% level. Piped water in dwelling or yard.Includes toilets and latrines. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística - Guatemala 21 Figure 3.2: Historical coverage trends (a) Electricity 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 TOTAL 0.5 URBAN population of 0.4 RURAL % 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 year (b) Water 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 TOTAL 0.5 URBAN population of 0.4 RURAL % 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 year (c) Sanitation 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 TOTAL 0.5 URBAN population of 0.4 RURAL % 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 year Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística- Guatemala 22 Table 3.8: Probability that an unserved household was connected (Proportion of unserved households receiving a connection) Electricity Piped water Sanitary services National 1993-1996 .19*** .19*** .31*** 1997-2000 .36 .34 .55 % change 89% 79% 77% Urban 1993-1996 .38*** .31*** .50*** 1997-2000 .70 .53 .82 % change 84% 71% 64% Rural 1993-1996 .13*** .14*** .22*** 1997-2000 .29 .28 .48 % change 123% 100% 118% Extreme poor 1993-1996 .06*** .13*** .21*** 1997-2000 .17 .26 .37 % change 183% 100% 76% All Poor 1993-1996 .13*** .15*** .25*** 1997-2000 .28 .29 .44 % change 115% 93% 76% Non-poor 1993-1996 .29*** .24*** .38*** 1997-2000 .55 .41 .72 % change 90% 71% 89% Indigenous 1993-1996 .16*** .18*** .30*** 1997-2000 .30 .32 .52 % change 88% 78% 73% Non-indigenous 1993-1996 .21*** .19*** .31*** 1997-2000 .42 .35 .57 % change 100% 84% 84% Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística- Guatemala Notes: The null hypothesis of equality of the probability of coverage before and after Peace Accord is rejected at: ***99% level. **95% level,* 90% level. Piped water in dwelling or yard. Includes toilets and latrines. At a national level, the probability of an unserved household receiving a connection increased by approximately 80% for electricity, piped water and basic sanitation. All types of households, irrespective of location, poverty or ethnicity experienced a statistically significant increase in the probability of being connected. Moreover, traditionally disadvantaged groups gained disproportionately, increasing their probability of being connected by well over 100% in most cases. For example, the probability of being connected increased by 183% for the extreme poor, 115% for the poor, and 90% for the non-poor. However, this disproportionate gain has not been enough to compensate for the lower initial probability of being connected for members of traditionally disadvantaged groups. Thus, notwithstanding the large percentage gains, in absolute terms the probability that a family in extreme poverty receives an electricity connection (at 0.17) is still lower than the probability for a family in poverty (at 0.28), and substantially lower than that for a non-poor household (0.55). Some indigenous groups also still have a relatively low probability of being connected, in particular the Q'eqchi (for electricity and water). However, other indigenous groups actually have a higher probability than average of receiving a connection, in particular the Ki'che and Kaqchikel (for electricity). 23 Expansion of telecommunications The ENCOVI survey does not provide information on historical coverage trends for telecommunications at the household level. However, it is possible to trace the evolution of rural public telephones. As of 1996, GUATEL was operating some 2,000 rural public telephones, while FONDETEL added a further 1,600 between 1998/9. Although, only about a third of the country's 19,000 rural towns have a public telephone service16, the ENCOVI reveals that 50% of rural households have a public telephone in their community. This reflects the fact that the larger rural communities tend to be the first to receive a public telephone. For those living in unserved communities, the average distance to the nearest public telephone was 7.2 km (or about a 45 minute trip). Figure 3.3: Distance to public telephone for rural households 100 90 80 households 70 of 60 50 40 percentage 30 20 10 Cumulative 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Distance to nearest public telephone (kms) >10 Within community Outside community Overall Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala Overall, 80% of rural households in Guatemala live within 6 km of a telephone (Figure 3.3). However, the pattern differs significantly by region (Figure 3.4). The North and Northwest of the country, together with Petén, have the worst levels of access to public telephones with average distances of 6-12 km and average journey times of around 50 minutes. By contrast, in all other regions the average distance to a public telephone is less than 5 km representing typically a half hour trip. Fewer than 10% of rural households claimed to have spent money on making a public telephone call the day before the survey17. 16Information supplied by FONDET EL. 17Unfortunately, the ENCOVI survey groups together expenditure on public telephone calls, faxes and postal services. The percentage reported relates to the number of people who registered non-zero expenditure in this category. Hence, it is very much an upper bound estimate for the proportion of rural households that are using public telephones. However, given the relatively scarce availability of facsimile and postal services in rural areas, it seems probable that quite a high proportion of these expenditures relate to public telephone calls. 24 Figure 3.4: Accessibility of public telephones for rural households by region 14 60 (kms) 12 (mins.) 50 10 40 telephone 8 telephone Kilometers 30 6 Minutes public 20 public to 4 to 2 10 Distance 0 0 Distance Central NorthPeten MetropolitanNortheast SouthwestSoutheast Northwest Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística - Guatemala As of 2000, 20% of households in Guatemala claimed to have access to either a fixed line and/or a cellular telephone, although coverage rates differ substantially between urban areas (40%) and rural areas (5%). About 74% of Guatemala households continue to obtain their telephone service from TELGUA. With 16% of the household market, COMCEL is the most significant competitor to TELGUA; it has the second largest fixed lines business in the country, as well as a substantial presence in the cellular market. Moreover, it has developed a particular presence in the rural areas where it is the primary service provider for 29% of households. There is a widespread anecdotal perception, not only in Guatemala, but throughout Latin America, that the advent of cellular telephony has helped to `democratize' the telephone. However, to date, very few household surveys make it possible to distinguish between fixed and cellular telephone ownership. The ENCOVI is unusual in this respect, and hence it is interesting to examine ownership patterns across consumption quintiles (Figure 3.5). The results appear to indicate a high degree of concentration of cellular telephones in higher consumption quintiles, with more than 80% being held by the top two quintiles. Indeed, about half of all cellular telephones in Guatemala are second telephones belonging to households in the highest consumption quintiles. However, on closer inspection, cellular telephones have become a very important phenomenon for certain other groups. For example, in the second and third quintiles, although cellular telephones are only held by a small minority, there are in fact equal numbers of households with fixed and cellular telephones. The same is true in rural areas, where there are equal numbers of fixed and cellular subscribers, and where two thirds of the households with cellular telephones have no other telephone service and are hence using the device as a substitute for a fixed line service. This is in contrast to urban areas where fixed telephones still outnumber cellular ones by 1.7 to 1.0. Finally, this data may understate the full importance of cellular telephony in rural areas. Onan anecdotal basis, the interview teams for the ENCOVI survey reported that cellular telephones are quite widely used to provide an informal public telephone service in rural areas, with the owner of the telephone allowing his neighbors to make calls on a charged out basis. However, unfortunately, it is not possible to corroborate this phenomenon with the ENCOVI data. 25 Figure 3.5: Access to fixed and cellular telephones 80 70 60 Both fixed and cellular 50 lines households of 40 Cellular line only 30 Fixed line only 20 Percentage10 0 1 2 3 4 5 Consumption quintile Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacionalde Estadística- Guatemala 3.4 The remaining deficit Notwithstanding this progress, a significant coverage gap remains (Table 3.9). Well over half a million households are still without electricity and piped water. Some 200,000 are without any form of sanitation, while about 1.3 million rely on latrines as opposed to conventional sewerage. The households that remain unserved are predominantly rural and predominantly poor. Table 3.9: Coverage gap for modern utilities (Number of unserved households) Electricity Piped water Basic sanitation Improved sanitation Total no. of households National 585,933 686,893 288,807 1,353,895 2,191,451 By area Urban 45,189 113,235 24,156 224,291 951,654 Rural 540,744 573,658 264,651 1,129,604 1,239,797 By quintile 1 266,931 220,182 116,340 411,318 438,437 2 155,116 163,797 84,249 349,173 427,908 3 98,428 164,199 52,064 304,708 446,068 4 44,513 104,894 25,003 203,850 442,583 5 20,945 33,821 10,161 84,846 436,455 Notes: piped water in dwelling or yard;includes toilets and latrines. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala From Table 3.7 it can be inferred that the typical annual rate of service expansion at present rates was around 115,000 new connections for electricity, water and sanitation. Given current levels of population growth of around 2.6% per annum, with this rate of expansion it will take more than eight years to reach universal coverage for all services except for basic sanitation (Table 3.10). Only a doubling of current rates of expansion, or a stabilization of population, would permit universal coverage to be reached in the medium term; that is between 3 to 12 years depending on the service. 26 Table 3.10: How far away is universal coverage? (Anticipated date of universal coverage) Present effort levels Present effort sustained levels doubled Electricity 2006 2003 Water 2007 2004 Basic sanitation 2003 2002 Improved sanitation 2014 2007 Note: It is assumed that population growth remains at historically observed rates of 2.6% per annum and that household size remains constant. Based on typical unit costs for service expansion, the total cost of meeting universal coverage across the electricity, water and sanitation services is estimated at US$1.5 billion (Table 3.11). The electricity service, owing to its relatively high unit cost of US$1,000 per household, accounts for over 40% of this total expenditure, compared with 25% for piped water. In the case of sanitation, two levels of universal service are defined. The first level is universal basic sanitation, which basically entails providing latrines to the 288,807 households that currently have no form of sanitation, and would cost less than US$15 million to achieve. The second level is universal improved sanitation. This entails providing sewerage to all households in conurbations with greater than 50,000 population (notably the Metropolitan area, Quetzaltenango, and Escuintla)18, and upgrading all other households to a flush toilet with a septic tank. This is a very much more expensive proposition, accounting for almost a third of the overall expansion costs. Table 3.11: Cost of reaching universal coverage Coverage gap Unit cost Total cost Share of (connections) (US$ per connection) (US$) total cost Electricity 585,933 1,000 585,933,000 40.1% Water 686,893 500 343,446,500 23.5% Basic sanitation 288,807 100 28,880,700 2.0% Improved sanitation 1,148,702 250 287,175,500 19.6% · Large cities 205,193 750 153,894,750 10.5% · Elsewhere 585,933 1,000 585,933,000 40.1% Public telephones 12,730 5,000 63,650,000 4.4% Total 1,462,980,450 100.0% Estimates provided by Kilian Reiche (electricity) and Franz Drees (water and sanitation) from the Finance, Private Sector and Infrastructure Division of the Latin America and Caribbean Region of the World Bank 18For the purposes of this analysis it was only possible to estimate the coverage deficit for the Metropolitan region. 27 In the case of water and sewerage services, international experience suggests that the costs of universalizing access could be reduced by as much as 40% if innovative `condominial' designs are adopted and implemented through community participation (Foster, 2001). The `condominial' approach to water and sewerage networks was pioneered in Brazil in the 1980s and has recently been applied with some success in Bolivia. The approach involves altering the engineering design of the water or sewerage network so that instead of providing a separate branch from the main network to each household, a single branch is provided to a whole block (or `condominium') of households, who then make their connections along this common branch. This saves costs by reducing the length, diameter and depth of the network needed to serve a given community, costs are further reduced by relying on community volunteer labor to construct the systems. 3.5 Obstacles to expanding coverage19 In order to develop a strategy for reaching unserved households, it is important to understand the reasons why these households remain unconnected at present. Broadly speaking, there are two possible explanations. The first explanation is that the service is simply not available in the communities where they live; this is essentially a supply-side problem that requires increased investment in infrastructure expansion. The second explanation is that the households fail to take-up the service even when it is available in the community; this is essentially a demand-side problem that may be less costly to overcome in investment terms, but is perhaps more complex to deal with requiring a careful diagnosis and considered policy response. It is possible to capture this difference by comparing two indices (Table 3.12). The availability index gives the percentage of households that live in communities where the service is available, while the uptake index shows the percentage of households who live in communities where the service is available who actually connect to the service20. The results show that electricity has the highest uptake index of any of the services at 88%, followed by water, sewerage and fixed telephone. Not only are services more likely to be available in urban areas, but urban households are substantially more likely to take-up these services when they are available. Table 3.12: Comparison of availability and uptake of services (Percentage of households) Electricity Piped water Sewerage Fixed telephone Nat'l Urban Rural Nat'l Urban Rural Nat'l Urban Rural Nat'l Urban Rural Availability 83 100 70 81 95 70 51 91 20 36 68 11 Uptake 88 95 81 85 92 76 75 85 44 42 46 24 Coverage 73 95 56 69 88 54 38 76 09 15 31 03 Notes: Piped water in dwelling or yard. See Annex D for definitions and calculations of Availability, Uptake, and Coverage. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala Using these indices it is possible to calculate what proportion of the coverage deficit currently observed in Guatemala is attributable to supply-side or demand-side factors (Figure 3.7)21. The results indicate 19See Annex D for an explanation of the definitions of coverage, take-up, and availability. 20 It is important to clarify the definition of `community'. The sampling frame of the ENCOVI 2000 was based on `unidades primarias de muestro', which are blocks of 50 contiguous households from which 10-12 households were sampled by the survey. 21This breakdown is undertaken as follows. Households who live in communities where the service is available but who do not connect are counted as a demand-side only problem. For communities where the service is not currently available, the 28 that, depending on the service, 20% to 40% of the coverage gap is related to purely demand-side factors and could be resolved without major investments in network expansion. Between 10% and 50% of the coverage gap, depending on service, would require both physical expansion and demand-side measures. It is important to note that the cost estimates for universal coverage that were presented above were based on the assumption that new infrastructure investments would be needed to reach all households that are currently unserved. (Table 3.11). The analysis of the coverage deficit suggests that this is not in fact the case, and that a significant part of the coverage gap could be bridged by removing barriers that prevent households connecting to existing networks. Overall, it is estimated that this factor could reduce the cost of meeting universal access by as much as 30%, from US $1.4 billion to US$ 1.0 billion. average take-up rate observed elsewhere in the country is applied to determine how many of these households could be expected to connect if the service were made available. These households are counted as a supply side only problem. All remaining households are counted as both a demand-side and a supply-side problem. 29 Figure 3.7: Decomposition of coverage deficit Notes: Piped water in dwelling or yard. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala In order to understand the correlations between specific household characteristics and the decision of 100% 90% 80% 70% households 60% of 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% Percentage 0% Demand side problem only water Electricity Both supply and Piped Seweragetelephone telephone demand side problem line Cellular Fixed Supply side problem only whether to connect to a utility service that is already available in the community, a probit regression is used to control for other economic, cultural and geographic variables that may be related with the decision to connect to a service (Table 3.13). Table 3.13: Take-up of modern utilities and household characteristics (Marginal effects from probit regression are reported) Variable Electricity Water Sanitation Sewerage Fixed Phone Cell Phone Household head characteristics Male -.021** -.027** -.003 -.081*** -.047 .047 Age 5x10-4* .001*** 7x10-4*** .001 .011*** -.002** Years of school .011*** .013*** .008*** .015*** .035*** .021*** Indigenous -.016 -.004 .018** -.067** -.079* -.046 Speaks Spanish .026 .010 .016 .010 -.214* .027 Household characteristics Business in dwelling .035*** .004 .009 .009 .085** .026 Income .003 .007*** .007*** .013*** .025*** .007*** Urban area .056*** .052*** .063*** .280*** -.015 -.071*** Regional dummies Metropolitan .043* .024 .007 .022 -.064 .042 North -.041* -.038 .031*** -.059 -.160*** -.039 Northeast .031* -.064 -.054** -.106 -.034 -.010 Southeast .021 -.024 -.059*** -.011 -.033 -.032 Central .019 -.027 .008 .081*** -.080 -.020 Southwest .023 .013 .002 .083** -.035 -.016 Petén -.070** .020 -.080*** -.595*** -.065 .009 F (15,1043) 15.05 10.60 13.79 12.73 34.09 13.08 Observations 6,058 6,034 7,144 3,796 2,761 2,592 Population size 1,802,063 1,764,457 2,137,789 1,098,917 781,336 826,134 Results of probit regressions where the dependant variable is 1 if the household uses the service and 0 if it is does not even though available. Significant at: *90% level, ** 95% level, *** 99% level. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala The model suggests that households headed by men are significantly less likely to connect to electricity, water, and sewerage services. The propensity to connect to all services increases significantly with years of education of the head of household. Furthermore, households headed by an indigenous person are substantially less likely to be connected to sewerage and fixed telephony services. The presence of a 30 business in the dwelling is significantly correlated to being connected to the electricity network, and particularly to having fixed line telephone service, where there is an impact of 8.5 percentage points. Monthly household expenditure also is significantly correlated with the take-up of all modern utilities, with the exception of electricity. This finding suggests that connection charges for all services may represent a barrier for lower income households. Indeed, the charges levied for connection to all services, except for electricity in urban areas, represent a substantial proportion of the monthly poverty line (Table 3.14). Furthermore, it is important to note that the cost of connecting to utility services goes beyond the connection charge. There is often a substantial complementary investment that must be made in adapting the dwelling to the new service. For example, internal wiring for electricity can cost around US$100, while internal plumbing for water and sewerage can cost several hundred dollars. Table 3.14: Affordability of connection charges Electricity Piped water Sewerage Fixed telephone Connection charge (US$) Urban: None EMPAGUA TELGUA 250 350 Rural: varies Rural areas Rural areas by project <100 <25 but can be substantial Connection charge as a percentage 0 EMPAGUA TELGUA of the budget of a 5 person 104 146 household living exactly on the Rural areas Rural areas poverty line (%) <42 <10 Source: CNE, TELGUA, IADB Finally, people living in urban areas are significantly more likely to be connected to all, except fixed phone services. This difference is exceptionally high in the case of sewerage. There are two possible explanations for this. The first is that utilities may find it particularly easy to respond to connection requests in the urban areas, and specifically the capital city, than in remote areas. The second is that the greater prevalence of services in urban areas, and especially the metropolitan area, may create other types of neighborhood effects that will lead households to connect (e.g. social pressure, lower information costs, free riding from neighbors' lobbying efforts, etc.). 4. Affordability of Modern utilities Evidently, there is little value in having access to a utility service if a household is unable to meet the corresponding bills. The Guatemalan government has been very conscious of the potential political and social ramifications of the tariff increases that typically result from private sector participation and sector reform. In the electricity sector, this has meant introducing socially motivated ceilings on residential tariffs. While, in the water sector, the unwillingness to raise tariffs to anything approaching cost recovery levels has been a significant barrier to reform. However well-intentioned these policies may have been, there is significant evidence that they are not particularly successful in protecting poor households, and that they can have undesirable consequences. To put these matters into context, households in Guatemala spend around 10% of their household budget on water, energy and telecommunications services. Over 50% of this expenditure goes on energy for cooking and heating, and over 25% goes on energy for lighting and powering appliances, while barely 0.5% of income is spent on water services. The overall budget share is relatively constant across 31 consumption quintiles, although the composition of the budget shifts away from cooking fuels and towards telecommunications for richer households (Figure 4.1). Although only a tiny fraction of the poorest households have access to telephones, those that do so spend as much as 5% of their income on the service. Figure 4.1: Expenditure on modern utilities as a percentage of consumption 14 12 consumption 10 Cooking and heating 8 Lighting and appliances Water household 6 of Telecoms 4 2 Percentage 0 1 2 3 4 5 Total Consumption quintile Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala 4.1 Electricity As a consequence of the electricity reforms, the newly privatized distribution companies were allowed to pass on to customers the changes in the cost of purchasing energy. Since Power Purchase Agreements signed between generators and distributors were indexed to the US$ and the price of oil, prices began to rise substantially from the end of 1998 (Figure 4.2). EEGSA experienced the steepest rises, with tariffs increasing 85% over the three year period 1998/01. While for DEORSA and DEOCSA the increases were somewhat lower at 55%-60%. In order to protect domestic consumers from rising electricity prices, the government introduced a social tariff (`tarifa social'), which held the price of electricity at around US$0.08 per kWh for all residential customers consuming up to 500 kWh. The cost of this subsidy, estimated at over US$57 million per year, was met by INDE on the basis of state transfers. It is noteworthy that even with the social tariff, about a quarter of all complaints received from consumers by the regulatory agency CNEE during 2000 are about tariffs being excessively high. 32 Figure 4.2: Evolution of electricity tariffs following reform 0.18 0.16 0.14 0.12 0.1 EEGSA 0.08 DEOCSA US$/kWh 0.06 DEORSA 0.04 Tarifa social 0.02 0 Mar-98 Jul-98 Nov-98 Mar-99 Jul-99 Nov-99 Mar-00 Jul-00 Nov-00 Mar-01 Source: CNE A new law passed in January 2001 made a number of changes to the social tariff, designed to reduce the associated fiscal burden and provide a more objective basis for determining and revising the level of the tariff. The new law reduced the threshold of eligibility from 500 kWh per month to 300 kWh per month, leading to an estimated cost saving of US$7.1 million annually. It also obliged distributors to tender out the purchase of power for the express purpose of meeting this `social demand'. The idea is to allocate supply from the lowest marginal cost power plants (typically hydroelectric) to this category of domestic customers, while leaving more expensive power from mid-merit thermal plants to cover demand from largest domestic, as well as commercial and industrial, customers. Effectively, this approach has done away with the need for direct government finance of the subsidy, by creating a cross-subsidy between customer categories. The thresholds that have been set for social tariffs are very high in relation to typical residential consumption (Figure 4.3). The average household consumes 102 kWh per month, with poor households consuming 48 kWh per month on average and non-poor households consuming 128 kWh per month. As a result, 99% of residential customers qualified for the social tariff under the original scheme. Following the recent reforms, this percentage fell only slightly to 94%, reflecting the fact that relatively few households consume in the bracket 300-500 kWh per month. In terms of affordability, the effect of the current social tariff is to reduce the proportion of the household budget devoted to electricity from 3.7% to 2.7% for poor households, and from 4.1% to 2.6% for non-poor households22. 22In practice, this is an over-estimate since it assumes zero price elasticity. If households, who currently benefit from the social tariff were faced with the true cost of electricity, they would presumably adjust by reducing their level of demand and hence the proportion of budget allocated to electricity would be somewhat lower than indicated. 33 Figure 4.3: Cumulative density of electricity consumption of 100 80 60 percentage 40 20 households 0 50 Cumulative 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500 >500 Subsidy threshold (kWh/mo.) Poor customers Non-poor customers Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala Table 4.1: Comparison of electricity consumption Poor Non-Poor Connection rate 46 76 Average consumption (kWh/mo.) 48 128 Electricity expenditure ($/mo.) · With social tariff 5.1 14.4 · Without social tariff 7.2 21.9 Electricity expenditure as percentage of monthly budget · With social tariff 2.7 2.6 · Without social tariff 3.7 4.1 Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala It is important to question who benefits from the current social tariff policy, and in particular how effective is it at protecting the most vulnerable households. Owing to the high level of the consumption threshold, the social tariff evidently benefits a considerable number of households who live above the poverty line. Indeed, about 65% of the beneficiaries of both the old and the new schemes are not poor (errors of inclusion23), and given that their consumption is relatively high they absorb an even larger percentage of the resources devoted to the subsidy (leakage rate24), 90% in all (Figure 4.4). The subsidy reaches 100% of poor households with electricity connections (that is there are no errors of exclusion25), but only 40% of poor households enjoy these connections and hence benefit from the subsidy. Given that poor households consume substantially less electricity than non-poor households, the cost- effectiveness of the social tariff could be significantly improved if the consumption threshold was reduced. In order to explore this possibility, a simulation exercise was performed to calculate the errors of inclusion and exclusion, as well as leakage rates, for a series of different consumption thresholds (Figure 4.4). There is an underlying assumption in this exercise that electricity consumption will remain constant despite the changes in the tariff structure by moving the consumption thresholds. The results show that the targeting performance of the subsidy could be significantly improved with an eligibility threshold of 100 kWh per month. Errors of inclusion would fall from 75% to 65%, and the leakage rate from 90% to 75%. At the same, time errors of exclusion would rise only 0% to 8%, while the overall cost of the subsidy would fall to almost a quarter of its current level, from $48.9 to $13.2 million per year. 23Errors of inclusion are defined as the percentage of subsidy beneficiaries who are not poor. 24The leakage rate refers to the proportion of the total subsidy expenditure that flows to the non-poor. 25Errors of exclusion are defined as the percentage of the poor who are not subsidy beneficiaries. 34 Figure 4.4: Simulation of inclusion and exclusion errors 1 0.9 0.8 Errors of exclusion 0.7 (connected poor) error 0.6 Errors of exclusion (all poor) 0.5 Errors of inclusion 0.4 Percentage0.3 Leakage rates 0.2 0.1 0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500 Consumption threshold (kWh/mo.) Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala Figure 4.5: Simulation of subsidy cost 70.0 60.0 50.0 (US$m) 40.0 cost 30.0 20.0 Annual 10.0 0.0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 Subsidy threshold (kWh/mo.) Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala Notwithstanding the considerable policy attention that has gone into subsidies for electricity consumers, the empirical evidence suggests that households that lack access to electricity are in a much worse position in terms of their ability to afford basic energy requirements. The reason is that traditional substitutes for electricity, such as candles and kerosene lamps are extremely inefficient at delivering usable energy (Table 4.2). In particular, electric light bulbs give out 50 times more luminosity per kWh of raw energy used than do candles, and 100 times more than primitive kerosene wick lamps. These differences in efficiency need to be taken into account when comparing the prices of these different sources of energy. In the table below, the gross price reports the standard unadjusted market price, while the net price corrects for differences between the efficiency of electricity and alternative energy sources. The results indicate that households without electricity pay 75 to 150 times more per kWh of light, and 5 to 30 times more per kWh to power home appliances using dry cell or car batteries. Table 4.2: Relative efficiency and luminous efficacy factors used to adjust from gross to net energy consumption 35 Lighting Appliances Fuel Relative luminous Fuel Relative efficiency efficacy Electricity 1.00 Electricity 1.00 Kerosene 0.01 Batteries 0.90 Candles 0.02 Car batteries 0.90 Source: Foster and Tre, 2000. Table 4.3: Gross and net unit prices for different fuels (US$ per kWh) Lighting Appliances Gross Net Gross Net Electricity 0.08 0.08 Electricity 0.08 0.08 Kerosene 0.05 5.87 Batteries 0.59 0.53 Candles 0.26 13.00 Car batteries 2.57 2.31 Notes: The unit price is based on the assumption that the batteries are used to power a 16 watt radio. The unit price is based on the assumption that the batteries are used to power a 16W black and white television set. Source: Foster and Tre, 2000 The much higher implicit energy prices faced by households without electricity translate into very low levels of energy consumption. For example, households in the lowest consumption quintile without access to electricity consume only 1.4 net kilowatt-hours of energy per month on lighting and appliances compared with 40.0 kilowatt-hours per month consumed by households in the lowest consumption quintile who have electricity (Table 4.4). Interestingly, both of these groups of households spend a very similar monthly amount on energy for lighting and appliances; just over Qz.30 (US$4) per month. Table 4.4: Energy consumption patterns of those with and without electricity National By area By quintile Urban Rural 1 2 3 4 5 Electricity coverage 73 94 57 40 64 77 89 95 rate (%) Connected to Y N Y N Y N Y N Y N Y N Y N Y N electricity Energy 90*** 33 119*** 31 52*** 34 37 31 41*** 33 60*** 38 82*** 36 174*** 40 expenditure(Q/mo.) Percentage of budget 3 3 3 2 3 3 3 3 3 3 3* 3 3*** 2 3*** 2 (%) Energy consumption · Gross kwh/mo. 101*** 21 132*** 58 11*** 23 40*** 22 46*** 23 71*** 23 100*** 15 182*** 15 · Net kwh cons 101*** 2.1 132*** .81 11*** 2.2 40*** 1.4 46*** 2.0 71*** 2.6 100*** 2.4 182*** 7.6 Implicit energy price · Q/gross kwh/mo. 1.0*** 5.5 .94*** 9.1 1.1*** 5.1 1.1*** 4.5 1.1*** 5.5 1.0*** 6.1 .95*** 7.9 .92*** 8.9 · Q/net kwh cons 1.0*** 85 .94*** 233 1.1*** 69 1.1*** 69 1.1*** 84 1.0*** 89 .95*** 153 .92*** 121 Notes: For those with electricity, energy refers to electricity and for those wit hout electricity, energy refers to electricity substitutes (i.e. candles, kerosene and batteries). The averages for expenditure and prices excluded households that are connected to the electricity network but did not pay for the service. If significantly different from those without electricity at: * 90%, ** 95%, *** 99%. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala To give a concrete idea of what such low levels of energy consumption mean in terms of quality of life, it is helpful to think of a subsistence package of energy requirements that can be used to define a `fuel poverty' line. Based on consultation with local energy experts about the energy needs of low income households, this subsistence package provides enough energy to run two 60 watt light bulbs and one 16 36 watt radio for four hours each day, and incorporates a cooking requirement of ten kilograms of fuel wood each day. The survey indicates that 92% of households without access to electricity have energy consumption levels that fall below the `fuel poverty' line, compared to only 35% of households with access to electricity (Table 4.5). It is estimated that if these households had access to electricity they would be able to substantially increase their energy consumption, so that the fuel poverty rate would fall from 92% to between 37% and 73%, depending on what assumption is made about the price elasticity of demand. Table 4.5: Fuel poverty estimates with and without access to electricity Households without access to electricity Households with access Current After gaining access, for different price situation elasticities of demand for energy to electricity e = -0.5 e = -1 e = -1.5 Price per effective kwh (Q) 1.7 39.3 1.8 1.8 1.8 Net consumption (kwh/month) 67.5 .98 16.2 21.6 32.4 Fuel poverty Headcount .27 1.00 .68 .55 .33 Poverty gap .12 .94 .34 .24 .14 Squared poverty gap .08 .89 .21 .14 .08 Note: Refers only to energy used for lighting and appliances, based on a poverty line of 200 kwh/year Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala 4.2 Water The typical tariff structure for water in Guatemala comprises a flat payment up to a relatively high consumption threshold, and a linear unit charge for consumption above this level. This kind of tariff structure has the disadvantage that it does not provide any incentive for households to control consumption below this threshold level. A recent survey of water tariffs found that in the larger citiesGuatemala and Quetzaltenangothe flat rate charge of $1 to $2 per month entitled households to consume between 15 and 25 cubic meters per month, while further consumption was charged at a rising rate of between $0.10 and $0.30 per cubic meter (Figure 4.6) (ESA Consultores, 2001). The same survey found that water charges in the smaller towns of the interior were substantially lower, with a flat charge of around $0.50 per month entitling the household to around 30 to 40 cubic meters per month, and subsequent consumption being charged at less than $0.10 per cubic meter (Figure 4.6). The implication is that for a typical monthly consumption of 20 cubic meters, households in the larger cities would be paying an implicit tariff of less than $0.10 per cubic meter, while households in the smaller cities would be paying less than $0.05 per cubic meter. Figure 4.6: Typical structure of water bills (a) Large cities (b) Small towns 10 10 9 9 San Sebastian (Retalheuleu) 8 8 7 EMPAGUA 7 San Martin 6 (domestic) 6 (Retalheuleu) (US$/mo.) 37 5 EMPAGUA (US$/mo.) 5 bill (social) bill San Agustin 4 Quetzaltenango 4 Acasaguastian water 3 (El Progreso) water 3 Source: IADB Not only are water tariffs very low, but survey evidence suggests that revenue collection rates are also extremely low. On average, as many as 30% of those with piped water reported that they did not pay for the service during the last month, compared with only 8% for the electricity service in spite of the fact that average monthly electricity bills are almost 10 times as high as average water bills (US$12.97 versus US$1.48). Among the poorest, non-payment rate rises to 46%. As a result, water utility revenues are extremely low, both with respect to the likely cost of providing water and sanitation services, and with respect to the likely willingness and ability to pay of the population. Although there is no available information about the cost of potable water in Guatemala, international benchmarks would suggest a full cost of around $0.30 to $0.40 per cubic meter, exclusive of sewerage. This suggests that at current tariff levels, water utilities are unlikely to be covering their operating costs, let alone their capital costs. Table 4.6: Comparison of expenditures on piped and bottled water National By area By consumption quintile Urban Rural 1 2 3 4 5 % of households that bought bottled water1 .17 .33 .04 .02 .03 .08 .23 .47 Among those who bought bottled water Quetzales spent on piped water 16 24 5 1 5 7 12 34 Quetzales spent on bottled water 47 50 30 10 30 30 39 56 Expenditure on piped water as % of consumption .004 .005 .002 .001 .003 .003 .004 .006 Expenditure on bottled water as % of consumption .01 .01 .01 .01 .01 .01 .01 .01 1: Refers to last two weeks before the survey. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística - Guatemala In terms of willingness to pay, the WHO has traditionally recommended an affordability threshold of 5% of income for water and sanitation services, about 10 times as high as what households in Guatemala currently spend. Recent research in Central Americainvolving willingness to pay surveys in Nicaragua, Panama, and El Salvadorhas provided empirical confirmation of the WHO threshold (Walker et al., 2000). Further confirmation of willingness to pay for water in Guatemala comes from expenditure on bottled water. The ENCOVI survey shows that 20% of households purchase bottled water at a price of $0.50 per liter (equivalent to $500 per cubic meter). Moreover, households who use both piped and bottled water, spend three times more on bottled water than on piped water. 38 Table 4.7: Water treatment practices (proportion of households) National By area By consumption quintile Urban Rural 1 2 3 4 5 Among those with water in dwelling or yard Buys bottled water only .13 .22 .02 .002 .01 .04 .13 .35 Buys bottled water and also treats .08 .13 .03 .02 .03 .05 .12 .15 Boils water .38 .29 .50 .55 .51 .47 .32 .20 Filters water .02 .02 .01 .001 .004 .003 .01 .04 Puts chlorine .12 .12 .12 .07 .10 .16 .18 .09 Other strategy .01 .01 .003 .001 .01 .003 .01 .01 No treatment .26 .20 .32 .36 .34 .27 .24 .15 Among those without water in dwelling or yard Buys bottled water only .03 .11 .01 0 .02 .02 .11 .07 Buys bottled water and also treats .02 .05 .02 .005 .02 .03 .04 .09 Boils water .42 .43 .41 .51 .39 .42 .32 .16 Filters water .002 .001 .002 .0003 .0004 .005 .002 .003 Puts chlorine .17 .15 .17 .09 .17 .23 .19 .37 Other strategy .01 .0005 .01 .002 .0003 .001 .03 .05 No treatment .35 .25 .37 .40 .40 .30 .31 .26 Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala The shortage of resources going into the sector probably goes some way towards explaining the relatively low quality of service provided. Households surveyed in the ENCOVI received water on average only 17 hours per day and faced 3.6 days each month without water. The fact that as many as 74% of households with piped water, either buy bottled water or perform some kind of self-treatment, suggests that they are not confident about the potability of public water supply (Table 4.7). Boiling is the most popular form of self-treatment, particularly among low-income households and in rural areas. While higher income urban households are more likely to rely on bottled water. It is very striking that the prevalence of water boiling is about the same for households who have piped water as for households without the service, around 40% in both cases. 5. Benefits of Access to Modern Utilities It is often argued that access to modern utility services brings benefits to households in terms of improved productivity and health. While these arguments are intuitively persuasive, there is relatively limited rigorous empirical evidence to document the link and quantify the magnitude of the associated effects. Therefore, this section uses the ENCOVI survey data to try and shed some light on the nature of these relationships. 5.1 Productivity benefits Use of household time endowment It is anecdotally well-known that the collection of fuel wood and water for household use, particularly in rural areas, can be very time consuming and it is often suggested that these activities come at the cost of more productive pursuits, such as paid employment or education of children (Table 5.1). Table 5.1: Anecdotal evidence on time use from qualitative poverty study `A los niños los ponen a trabajar, a traer leña, a acarrear agua.' School Teacher, Ladino Community, Qualitative Poverty Study. 39 In the ENCOVI, households who collect water on a regular basis report that on average they travel around nine minutes to reach their nearest water source (Table 5.2). The equivalent distance for fuel wood collection was a 50 minute walk in urban areas and a 70 minute in rural areas. The average number of persons per household involved in such a trip is around 1.50 in urban areas and 1.85 in rural areas. Moreover, the survey demonstrates clear gender specialization in collection activities, with men and boys accounting for 65% of the labor devoted to the collection of fuel wood, and women and girls accounting for 74% of the labor devoted to the collection of water (Figure 5.1). Table 5.2: Distance to source of wood and water (Among those who collect water and buy or collect wood) National By area By consumption quintile Urban Rural 1 2 3 4 5 Water collection Minutes 12.5 13.2 12.3 14.5 12.8 10.6 12.6 7.0 Meters 242 111 267 351 216 222 136 72 Wood collection or purchase Minutes 63.4 51.0 67.2 66.9 67.2 63.3 54.8 47.9 Meters 1,336 1,032 1,448 1,611 1,511 1,236 961 917 Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala Figure 5.1: Intra-Household Allocation of Fuel Wood and Water Collection Tasks (individuals who collected wood and water on the day before the survey) (a) Fuel wood (b) Water 11% 13% 41% Men 13% Women 24% Boys Girls Women 50% Men Girls Boys 24% 24% Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala 40 Table 5.3: Time devoted to collection of fuel wood and water according to whether or not the household has access to modern water and energy services National By area Urban Rural Access to modern services Y N Y N Y N Proportion of households who collected yesterday · Fuel wood .04 .18 .01 .11 .08 .19 · Water .03 .33 .02 .22 .05 .35 No. of minutes spent collecting yesterday · Fuel wood 102 162*** 77 173*** 121 161*** · Water 63 96*** 62 75*** 64 99*** Expected no. of minutes per week spent collecting · Fuel wood 29 204*** 5 133*** 68 214*** · Water 13 221*** 9 116*** 22 243*** By quintile 1 2 3 4 5 Access to modern services Y N Y N Y N Y N Y N Proportion of households who collected yesterday · Fuel wood .16 .19 .06 .18 .09 .18 .04 .14 .01 .10 · Water .03 .35 .04 .37 .06 .35 .02 .31 .01 .24 No. of minutes spent collecting yesterday · Fuel wood na 202 154 165 94 99 72 107 na 86 · Water 82 127** 65 93** 70 76 50 57 21 84 Expected no. of minutes per week spent collecting · Fuel wood na 268 208 65*** 59 124*** 20 105*** na 62 · Water 17 311*** 18 242*** 29 185*** 7 124*** 1 141*** na: Less than 30 observations were available. Notes: A modern water service is defined as having piped water in the dwelling or yard. A modern energy service is defined as having access to propane. Percentage of households with and without service are significantly different at: *** 99%, **95% and 90%. * Expected minutes = 7 * proportion who collected yesterday * minutes spent collecting. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala Clearly, one of the potential benefits of providing households with access to piped water and modern energy sources, such as propane, is that they can save the time that would otherwise be devoted to collection activities. Using the ENCOVI data, it is possible to estimate the number of minutes per week that households spend on average collecting fuel wood and water, and to compare this between households that have access to modern alternatives and those that do not (Table 5.9). In urban areas, households without access to modern utilities spend on average two man-hours per week on each of the two collection activities, while those who have access spend less than ten minutes per week on each. In rural areas, households with access spend closer to four man-hours per week on each activity. However, even those with services spend a significant amount of time collecting fuel wood and water. This may be a reflection of the lower reliability of these services in rural areas. Consequently, the time saving for rural households who gain access to modern services is 2.5 hours per week for fuel wood and 3.5 hours per week for water. Although it is difficult to place an economic value on these time savings, an approximate indication can be obtained from the average hourly earnings of rural workers in the agricultural sector, which are of the order of Q.3-4 (US$0.50) (Vakis, 2001). This would suggest that the value of weekly time savings associated with piped water could be around Q.12 (US$1.75), compared with a typical weekly piped water bill of Q.3 nationwide, or less than Q.1 in rural areas. The implication is that households who are not cash constrained would find it attractive to switch to a piped service. Although, the benefits are 41 exaggerated due to artificially depressed current water tariffs, the difference is significantly large that piped water would continue to remain attractive, even if water tariffs increased substantially. In the case of propane, the comparison is not so favorable, with a weekly value of time savings of around Q.9 (US$1.25), compared with a typical weekly energy bill of around Q.18. Table 5.4 Time allocation and wood collection (Number of minutes spent yesterday in each activity among those who spent time on them) Urban Rural Female Male Female Male 7-15 >15 7-15 >15 7-15 >15 7-15 >15 Paid work Did not collect 33 167 34 360 19 85 55 342 Collected 0 82 50 275 9 47 34 263 Difference *** *** *** * *** ** *** Unpaid work Did not collect 39 57 49 81 75 74 172 159 Collected 48 43 103 164 75 82 165 216 Difference * ** *** Study Did not collect 312 314 296 299 302 282 311 296 Collected 382 368 302 178 285 313 299 243 Difference ** ** Housework Did not collect 136 373 44 58 194 448 34 33 Collected 263 416 48 73 251 466 62 43 Difference *** *** *** *** Errands/shopping Did not collect 10 23 9 12 7 15 6 10 Collected 34 29 6 14 10 20 9 11 Difference ** Leisure and other Did not collect 913 750 951 778 916 763 945 799 Collected 781 658 940 777 846 709 903 776 Difference *** *** *** *** ** ** Notes: Means of those who collected and did not collect wood are significantly different at: *** 99%, ** 95% and * 90%. Minutes spent collecting wood among those who did it. The symbols describe cells that are significantly different from the one to the right at:^^^99%, ^^95%, 90%. ^ Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala Those devoting such significant amounts of time to wood and water collection activities must presumably do so at the expense of other activities. It is therefore interesting to explore which types of activities households who engage in wood and water collection (Tables 5.4 and 5.5) curtail. Paid work and leisure (including sleep) seem to be the activities that are cut back the most in order to accommodate wood and water collection. Interestingly, the amount of time devoted to study by children who do and do not engage in these activities is not significantly different in most cases. 42 Table 5.5 Time allocation and water collection (Number of minutes spent yesterday in each activity among those who spent time on them) Urban Rural Female Male Female Male 7-15 >15 7-15 >15 7-15 >15 7-15 >15 Paid work Did not collect 34 168 36 355 20 94 55 330 Collected 13 104 16 368 14 42 16 254 Difference *** *** *** *** Unpaid work Did not collect 38 57 53 85 76 79 179 172 Collected 59 44 39 79 71 61 112 165 Difference ** *** Study Did not collect 315 317 296 300 305 308 309 288 Collected 278 236 320 202 286 168 306 300 Difference ** *** Housework Did not collect 127 368 50 60 174 417 54 49 Collected 252 468 124 95 262 526 97 110 Difference *** *** ** *** *** *** *** *** Errands/shopping Did not collect 11 23 9 12 8 17 7 10 Collected 5 26 6 12 7 15 6 12 Difference ** Leisure and other Did not collect 909 751 953 781 929 769 938 796 Collected 903 678 892 686 843 720 920 769 Difference *** * *** *** *** * Notes: Means of those who collected and did not collect water are significantly different at:***99%, **95% and 90%. * Minutes spent collecting water among those who did it. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala Micro-enterprise productivity Modern utilities, in particular electricity and telecommunications, have the potential to improve the productivity of household based micro-enterprises. The electrification of household enterprises lengthens the potential working day, and permits the substitution of manual labor with more efficient power-assisted tools. Telecommunications improve links between enterprises and downstream buyers, as well as upstream suppliers, thereby helping entrepreneurs to expand sales and reduce supply costs. While these arguments are convincing at an anecdotal level, there is limited rigorous empirical evidence to back them up. Using the data provided by the ENCOVI, this section explores firstly, whether households in areas where modern utilities are available are more likely to have household enterprises, and secondly, whether household enterprises that have access to modern utilities are significantly more profitable than those enterprises that do not. An important caveat is that all of the analysis in this section refers exclusively to households that own a micro-enterprise that operates in the dwelling. As a preliminary step, the proportion of households with micro-enterprises is tabulated against the various indices of access to modern utilities developed above (Table 5.6). The results show that the probability of having a micro-enterprise is significantly higher among households with coverage of modern utilities. However, within communities that have access to modern utilities, households that 43 take-up a connection are no more likely to be entrepreneurs than those that do not (except in the case of fixed telephones). Table 5.6: Cross-tabulation of household enterprise against access to modern utilities (Proportion of households) Has an enterprise Wald Yes No Test2 Availability Electricity .85 .82 Piped water .85 .80 ** Fixed phone .42 .34 *** Cellular phone .42 .37 ** Takeup Electricity .98 .98 Piped water .95 .95 Fixed phone .57 .46 *** Cellular phone .33 .29 Coverage *** Electricity .81 .72 *** Piped water .76 .67 *** Fixed phone .22 .14 ** Cellular phone .12 .09 *** Public phone 18 23 Population size 459,347 1,731,720 Notes: Refers only to enterprises that operate in dwelling. Null hypothesis (equality of enterprise owners and non-owners) is rejected at: ***99%, ** 95%, 90%. * Pubic phone variable refers to minutes to closest public phone in census tract. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala However, it is not possible to draw any inferences from cross-tabulations of this kind, because they do not control for many other factors that influence the disposition to form a business. In order to address this issue, a probit model is estimated that looks at the correlation between a variety of factors including characteristics of the households and the head of household, availability of modern utilities and geographical variables. Separate models are estimated for urban and rural enterprises (Table 5.7). An important methodological issue that arises is the potential endogeneity of access to modern utilities. The model is estimated on the statistical assumption that access to modern utilities affects the probability of forming a micro-enterprise, but not vice versa. However, it could equally be argued that the presence of a micro-enterprise influences the choice of whether or not to connect to modern utilities. In order to avoid the resulting bias in the statistical estimates, it is necessary to find an instrumental variable that is related to the variable of interest but which has a greater claim of exogeneity. In this case, the community availability of the basic service is used as an instrument; that is to say, that instead of looking at whether or not the household has access to the service, the model looks at whether or not the household lives in a neighborhood26 that has access to the service. It can be argued that local availability is somehow more likely to be exogenous to enterprise formation than household connection. 26As explained earlier, we use the word community in this context to describe clusters of contiguous households on which the survey design was based. 44 Table 5.7: Results of probit model for probability of having a micro-enterprise (Coefficients are marginal effects) Everyone Urban Rural F/x F/x F/x Household head characteristics Male -.009 .038 -.073** Age .002*** .002** .001* Years of school .003 .003 .005 Speaks Spanish .039 .135*** .024 Indigenous .077*** .059 .077** Household characteristics Number of adults .021*** .017** .022*** Urban area .008 Population in locality -.0001 -.0002 .002 Availability of utilities Electricity .008 .028 -.011 Water .028 .067 -.003 Fixed phone .036 .035 .031 Cellular phone .001 -.017 .011 Minutes to public phone -.0003 -.0009** -.0001 Population size 1,553,028 735,373 817,655 F (19,869) (18, 870) (18, 870) 4.76 4.38 3.92 Notes: Region-level fixed effects were included. Significant at:***90%, **95%, 90%. * Refers only to enterprises that operate in dwelling. The results report the marginal effects from the probit model, that is to say how much a 1% change on each continuous variable would affect the probability that a household enterprise is formed (for binary variables, we observe the effect of the change from 0 to 1). Enterprises are significantly more likely to be formed in larger households, with older heads of household. There is evidence of a small but significant effect from being located relatively close to a public telephone, but only in urban areas. In the discussion that follows, attention is limited to those households that have a micro-enterprise, and turns to the question of how their profitability is affected by access to utilities. While the estimations so far have included expansion factors to have a sample that is representative at the national level, in the exercise that follows, attention is limited to the sample of households that have a micro-enterprise that operates in the dwelling and uses no expansion factors. The cross-tabulation of net income per worker-hour indicates that households covered by modern utilities have significantly more profitable enterprises. The differences in profitability are very substantial: almost double for water, more than double for electricity, more than three times as high for fixed telephones and almost four times as high for cellular telephones. Moreover, within communities that have access to services, enterprises that take-up connections to electricity and telecommunications services are significantly and substantially more profitable than those that do not. 45 Table 5.8: Cross-tabulation of enterprise profitability against access to modern utilities (Net income of owner in Quetzales per worker-hour) Basic service Wald Yes No Test Coverage Electricity 8.0 3.4 *** Piped water 7.9 4.7 ** Fixed phone 15.9 4.6 *** Cellular phone 20.2 5.2 *** Public phone 7.5 7.0 Takeup Electricity 7.8 3.2 *** Piped water 7.9 4.2 Fixed phone 15.9 6.2 *** Cellular phone 20.2 6.8 *** Availability Electricity 7.7 3.5 *** Piped water 7.4 5.0 *** Fixed phone 11.2 4.0 *** Cellular phone 10.6 4.4 *** Population size 459,347 Notes: Refers only to enterprises that operate in dwelling. Null hypothesis (equality of profits between enterprises covered and not) is rejected at:***90%, **95%, 90%. * Public phone variable refers to availability of public phone in census tract. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala However, as before, it is necessary to control for other factors affecting enterprise profitability before reaching conclusions about the role of basic infrastructure services. In addition to the variables used above, a set of variables describing the characteristics of the business is introduced. These include measures of capital and labor input, sector of activity, source of finance, and type of premises. Once again, there are potential endogeneity problems with access variables, since it seems likely that not only does access improve profitability, but also profitability may increase the likelihood of access. This problem is addressed byinstrumenting each of the utility access variables, in a series of first-stage regressions using the community availability of the service as an instrument. As noted above, it can be argued that local availability is more likely to be exogenous than household availability. It could however be argued that local availability is correlated with unobserved characteristics of the local market. In order to control for this potential effect, a series of municipality specific dummies (or fixed effects) were included in the regressions. As might be expected, the results indicate that enterprise profitability is significantly related to the magnitude of labor and capital inputs and the type of financing facilities that are available. Utility coverage variables do not prove to be statistically significant in urban areas, perhaps because coverage of services is close to universal, and hence there is little variation from which to estimate the coefficient. In rural areason the other handcoverage of electricity, water and cellular telephones are all statistically significant with sizable coefficients. Moreover, the overall explanatory power of this model is much higher than the urban one, with an R-squared coefficient of 55% versus 15%. 46 Table 5.9: Results for regression model of profitability of the household micro-enterprise Urban Rural Household head characteristics Male .437* .026 Age -.011 -.011** Years of school -.035 .018 Speaks Spanish .634 .037 Indigenous -.139 .247 Household characteristics Number of adults -.101 .063 Population in locality -.003 .0001* Coverage of utilities Electricity -2.14 .503** Water .931 1.0*** Fixed phone 1.73 -1.04 Cellular phone 2.36 2.7** Minutes to closest public phone .0008 -.001 Business characteristics Capital (Q) 6x10-8 1x10-5* Labor (man-hours) .001*** .001*** Age of business (years) -.001 -.004 Months worked last year (#) .092*** .105*** Economic activity Manufacture .283 -.144 Services -.124 .281 Provider Large firm .254 .080 Small firm .030 .013 Source of finance Bank / cooperative / NGO .898* .460 Family / friends .720* .836** Providers -.113 1.45** Savings / assets / inheritance 1.02** .660* Type of dwelling House .507 -.458* Constant 3.66 5.13*** Observations 634 478 Pseudo R-squared .1537 .5553 Chi 2 332.59 671.08 Notes: Results reported are those of second-stage regression. Coverage of basic services for electricity, water, fixed and cellular phone were instrumented using availability of these services in census tract as instrument. Estimations include a municipality-level fixed effect. Significant at: *** 90%, ** 95%, 90%. * Refers only to enterprises that operate in dwelling. Table 5.10: Estimated change in profits due to connection to modern utilities Urban Rural In Quetzales per month Electricity -1,445 399** Water2 2,518 1,062*** Fixed phone 7,585 -395 Cellular phone 15,644 8,663** As proportion of profits Electricity -.88 .65** Water 1.5 1.7*** Fixed phone 4.6 -.65 Cellular phone 9.6 14.2** Observations 634 478 Notes: Refers only to enterprises that operate in dwelling. 47 From the regression model coefficients, it is possible to estimate the average impact that each of the utility services has on the profitability of the micro-enterprise (Table 5.10). Perhaps of greatest interest are the figures which express the additional profit attributable to utility services as a percentage of the average profit of micro-enterprises that do not enjoy access to the corresponding services. These show that the value of these services to micro-enterprises is very large indeed. For example, micro-enterprises without electricity in the rural areas have profits that are 65% higher on average than micro-enterprises with electricity. The corresponding figure for water is 170%. By far the largest effect is that of the cellular telephone, which raises profitability by 1420%. This effect appears implausibly large, and it is possible that the cellular telephone is picking-up some other unobserved variable that is important for profitability and which may not be captured either by the locality population or by the municipality fixed-effect; for example, proximity to a markets. 5.2 Health benefits It is widely believed that modern infrastructure services have an important link with household health. Safe water and basic sanitation reduce exposure to waterborne diseases such as diarrhea and cholera. Garbage collection improves hygiene and reduces the presence of parasites. Use of modern cooking fuels, such as propane gas, reduces exposure to indoor air pollution. Women participating in the qualitative poverty study, seemed to be particularly aware of the health benefits that had come about as a result of receiving access to water and sanitation services (Table 5.11). Table 5.11: Impressions of water and sanitation health linkages from qualitative poverty study `Nosotros...antes íbamos a traer agua en los pozos que hay en los barrancos. El agua era sucia y estaba lejos, nos costaba mucho, sufrimos con el acarreo del agua... Ahora el agua llega a la casa y es limpia, eso nos ha ayudado en la salud de la familia... Ahora hay muy pocas enfermedades pero es por descuido de la gente... también hay letrinas, todo eso nos ha ayudado en nuestra salud.' K'iche Woman, Qualitative Poverty Study. `[Tener agua] ha mejorado la salud de la familia porque no hay muchas enfermedades del estómago (diarrea)... ahora las mujeres ya no sufren... ya no van al barranco a traer agua.' K'iche Woman, Qualitative Poverty Study `El río queda lejos y se seca durante el verano... cuando no había agua se iban las mujeres por día a acarrear agua de los ríos... Antes, cuando no teníamos agua, era un sacrificio, peligroso y debajo de la lluvia. Ahora estamos mejor, antes nos bañábamos a veces hasta cada tres días y esto produce enfermedad, había mucho olor feo... Las mujeres lavan los trastos porque si no se hace esto trae enfermedad, sirve para la higiene.' Q'eqchi Woman, Qualitative Poverty Study. `[Con el agua entubada] ha mejorado el problema de tomar agua del río crudo y hay menos niños que se enferman... en la casa cloran el agua de tomar.' Ladina Woman, Qualitative Poverty Study. To gain an initial impression of the extent of the correlation between health and access to modern utilities, a series of cross-tabulations are performed. The cross-tabulations distinguish between children and infants as well as between urban and rural areas. The first of these relates to the relationship between access to piped water and sanitation and the incidence of diarrhea among children (Table 5.12). In urban areas, no significant correlation was found between access to water and sanitation and incidence to diarrhea. In rural areas, however, two variables are found to be statistically significant both for children and infants, namely possession of a toilet 48 collected to drainage and purchase of bottled water. Interesting, self-treatment of piped water supply does not show a significant correlation with the incidence of diarrhea. The presence of piped water in the community (though not in the dwelling) is also correlated with the incidence of diarrhea in the case of children but not of infants. However this is expected in that infants tend to be breastfed and are hence less exposed to impurities in water. Table 5.12: Cross-tabulation of incidence of diarrhea and access to water and sanitation (Proportion of children who had diarrhea) Urban Rural Service Pearson Service Pearson Yes No Test Yes No Test Infants: 0-12 months old Piped water in dwelling or yard .26 .50 .33 .30 Community covered by piped water .50 .50 .27 .31 Dwelling connected to sewerage .25 .40 .33 .32 Toilet connected to drainage .24 .40 .17 .31 * Latrine .32 .40 .33 .31 Excusado lavable .43 .40 .31 .31 Only treats water .33 .32 .33 .31 Only buys bottled water .23 .32 .05 .31 ** Treats and buys bottled water .29 .32 .33 .31 Children: 13-59 months old Piped water in dwelling or yard .27 .29 .37 .20 Community covered by piped water .35 .21 .32 .44 ** Dwelling connected to sewerage .25 .31 .30 .39 Toilet connected to drainage .24 .33 .16 .35 ** Latrine .32 .33 .40 .35 Excusado lavable .29 .33 .40 .35 Only treats water .27 .26 .39 .37 Only buys bottled water .22 .26 .14 .37 *** Treats and buys bottled water .36 .26 .43 .37 Notes: Refers to illness during the month previous to the survey. Null hypothesis (homogeneity of users and non-users) is rejected at: ***99%,** 95%,*90%. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala The same exercise is performed for the incidence of respiratory illnesses, cross-tabulated against use of fuel wood for cooking (Table 5.13). Those households that do use fuel wood are further sub-divided according to whether or not they have some kind of chimney for ventilation of the kitchen. It is important to note that the definition of `respiratory illnesses' used in the ENCOVI questionnaire is rather vague, identifying whether or not children had suffered from a very broad range of complaintsincluding cold, cough, bronchitis, chokes or respiratory infectionsduring the previous month. The results show that (in most cases) the use of fuel wood in the home is not significantly correlated with the incidence of respiratory disease. However, what does seem to matter quite significantly is whether households burning fuel wood have a smoke escape in the kitchen. 49 Table 5.13: Cross-tabulation of incidence of respiratory illness and access to basic services (Proportion of children) Urban Rural Service Pearson Service Pearson Yes No Test2 Yes No Test2 Infants: 0-12 months old Use of fuel wood at home .53 .37 * .46 .46 Kitchen has a escape for smoke .22 .57 ** .35 .48 ** Children: 13-59 months old Use of fuel wood at home .41 .47 .53 .49 Kitchen has a escape for smoke .39 .39 .47 .55 ** Notes: Refers to illness during the month previous to the survey. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala It is interesting to compare these results with those from a second source of data on this issue: the National Maternal and Infant Health Survey 1998/9. This survey, which falls into the broad category of Demographic and Health Surveys, has a much tighter definition of what constitutes an acute respiratory illness. This is defined as a child manifesting at least two of the following three symptoms simultaneously: coughing, fever and breathing in quick short breaths. Given the more stringent definition, the proportion of children reporting respiratory illness in the DHS (at around 20%) is substantially lower than in the ENCOVI (at around 40%). Moreover, the equivalent cross-tabulation for the DHS data, shows a significant correlation between cooking with fuel wood and incidence of respiratory illness. The correlation is particularly strong in the case of infants, who (due to their lack of mobility) tend to spend more time close to the mother while she is cooking (Table 5.14). Unfortunately, the DHS does not include questions about kitchen ventilation and hence it is not possible to make that comparison with the ENCOVI data. Table 5.14: Cross-tabulation of incidence of acute respiratory illness and access to modern fuels (Proportion of children) Service Pearson Yes No Test Infants: 0-15 months old Use of fuel wood at home .30 .21 *** Children: >15-60 months old Use of fuel wood at home .22 .19 * Notes: Refers to illness during the two weeks previous to the survey. Null hypothesis (homogeneity of users and non-users) is rejected at: *** 99%, * 90%. Source: Torres, (2001) based on Guatemala National Maternal and Infant Health Survey 1998/9. As well as looking at links between specific types of services and specific types of illnesses, it is interesting to consider the overall impact of modern utilities on the production of health at the household level. In the health literature, stunting (or the ratio of height for age in children) is considered a good stock measure of the accumulated health experiences of the child throughout life. Simple cross- tabulations of stunting rate against a range of access variables show that children living in households with modern services are significantly less likely to experience stunting. The differences are up to a factor of two in the case of some services. 50 Table 5.16: Cross tabulation of stunting rate against access to modern utilities (Proportion of children) Urban Rural Service Pearson Service Pearson Yes No Test Yes No Test Infants: 0-12 months old Piped water in dwelling or yard .16 .10 .24 .22 Community covered by piped water na 0na ** .28 .20 Dwelling connected to sewerage .17 .11 .18 .24 Toilet connected to drainage .17 .03 ** .05 .25 ** Latrine .17 .03 ** .24 .25 Excusado lavable .12 .03 .13 .25 Only treats water .15 .21 .22 .25 Only buys bottled water .08 .21 * 0 .25 Treats and buys bottled water .19 .21 .33 .25 Children: 13-59 months old Piped water in dwelling or yard .32 .59 *** .60 .60 Community covered by piped water .57 .62 .66 .57 * Dwelling connected to sewerage .30 .51 *** .36 .62 *** Toilet connected to drainage .28 .61 *** .23 .65 Latrine .46 .61 ** .62 .65 Excusado lavable .43 .61 * .30 .65 *** Only treats water .44 .37 .62 .59 Only buys bottled water .19 .37 *** .30 .59 ** Treats and buys bottled water .27 .37 .40 .59 * Notes: Null hypothesis (homogeneity of users and non-users) is rejected at: ***99%,** 95%,*90%. na: not enough observations were available in this subgroup. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala However, such cross-tabulations are at best inconclusive since they do not control for the impact of many other health-related variables that are likely to be correlated with access to utility services, such as household income, geographical location, educational attainment, and a variety of other socioeconomic and demographic factors. While in principle it would seem relatively straightforward to control for these in a multivariate regression framework, there are a number of more serious methodological problems that lend caution to modeling the impact of modern utility services on health outcomes. First, in the case of parentally-reported incidence of disease (such as whether or not children had diarrhea or respiratory illnesses) there may be serious reporting bias, with health-conscious parents being more likely to detect and report the presence of these problems among their children. In this sense, the stunting variable, based on anthropometric measurements, provides a more objective indicator of health status. Second, there is the serious issue of the potential endogeneity of access to modern utilities in the health production function. That is to say that not only do modern utilities contribute to health, but households with unobserved preferences for health are also more likely to connect to modern utilities. Failure to take this into account could be expected to lead to biased coefficient estimates. The analysis of micro- enterprise profitability already illustrated how it can be possible to overcome endogeneity problems by using two stage instrumental variables techniques, with the community availability variable acting as an instrument. However, in the case of health production functions, the endogeneity problem affects not only the modern utility coverage variables but also many of the other key explanatory variables, such as 51 family demographics and hygiene behavior. The shear number of potentially endogenous variables complicates the search for instruments and can make the estimation process computationally intractable. For both of these reasons, no further modeling is attempted here. However, the health chapter of the Guatemala Poverty Assessment incorporates a reduced form health production function estimation that incorporates coverage of modern utility services (with appropriate instrumentation). The reader is referred to the corresponding paper for more details (Marini and Gragnolati, 2001). In brief, the main finding of interest is that access to piped water and use to bottled water are both found to make a positive and significant contribution to the height of children in urban areas, but not rural areas. While use of propane gas in the household is found to have a positive and significant effect on height overall. 6. Conclusions and Recommendations Evidence from the Guatemala LSMS 2000 shows that households that have access to modern utility services obtain important benefits. · First, the cost of modern utility services is often considerably lower than the corresponding traditional alternative. The clearest example is that of households without electricity who pay implicit prices of more than US$11 per kilowatt-hour (more than 80 times the price of electricity) to illuminate with candles and wick lamps and power appliances with dry cell batteries. · Second, access to modern services can substantially enhance the productivity of households and household-based micro-enterprise. Rural households with access to piped water and liquid propane gas for cooking, save around six man-hours per week compared with households who must go out to collect water and fuel wood. Furthermore, micro-enterprises with access to water and electricity are twice as profitable than comparable enterprises without access to these services, and the effect of a cellular telephone on micro-enterprise profitability is even larger. · Third, some traditional substitutes for modern utility service are associated with adverse health impacts and may contribute to infant mortality. Although it is difficult to isolate the underlying causality, children from households with access to piped water and adequate sanitation are significantly less likely to suffer from diarrhea and overall physical stunting. These benefits serve to highlight the importance of the commitments made by the Government of Guatemala at the time of the Peace Accords: to improve access of modern utilities services to traditionally disadvantaged groups. The events of recent years demonstrate that the commitments made in the Peace Accords have been honored. Since 1996, there have been major structural reforms in the electricity and telecommunications sectors designed to improve efficiency and promote investment. Furthermore, resources channeled towards rural expansion of electricity, water, and sanitation infrastructure have approximately tripled; both as a result of earmarking privatization revenues and due to an overall increase in the resources allocated to social funds. Overall about 70% of Guatemalan households now have water and electricity. These services are close to universal in urban areas, but reach little more than half of rural households. Almost 90% of households have some kind of basic sanitation, though fewer than half of these have sewerage. About 20% of households subscribe to either a fixed line and/or a cellular telephone service. Around 17% of 52 Guatemalan households do not have access to any kind of modern network utility service, leading a completely traditional lifestyle. This proportion rises to 33% in rural areas, an 40% among households in the lowest consumption quintile. Middle-income households tend to have only water and electricity services, while only among households in the highest consumption quintile do a majority also have sewerage and telephone. Interestingly, households who only have one utility service (23% in all) are most likely to choose electricity, even when other services (such as piped water) are available in their communities. As a result there has been an appreciable acceleration in the rate of expansion of service coverage. The coverage indices for electricity, water and sanitation increased by about 14 percentage points from 1997/00 versus about 11 percentage points for the period 1993/96. Given the effects of population growth, this represents a substantial increase in the rate of new connections from around 80,000 per year in the years prior to the Peace Accords to around 115,000 per year in the years following the Peace Accords. Moreover, the probability that a household without access received a water or electricity connection rose from 0.19 in the years 1993/96 to 0.35 in the years 1999/00. These increases in service coverage have begun to reverse traditional inequities in access to services. It is noteworthy that poor, rural and indigenous households have all seen their probability of receiving service more than double following the Peace Accords, increasing more than for any other group in society. However, even this substantial improvement has not been enough to offset their traditional disadvantage, so that in absolute terms these groups still remain the least likely to receive services. Aided by the rapid expansion of cellular telephony, the overall teledensity index for Guatemala has risen almost fivefold from 4.2 to 19.7 over the period 1997/01. Although about half of the new cellular subscriptions are second telephones for the richest 20% of the population, they are also playing an important role in rural areas where they have become as common as fixed line telephones and have begun to be used to provide informal public telephone services. The network of formal public telephones in rural areas has increased by 80% since the Peace Accords. As a result, 50% of rural households now have a public telephone in their community, and 80% of rural households live within 6 kilometers (or about half an hour) of a public telephone. Notwithstanding these improvements, coverage rates in Guatemala are still only about average for the Central American region, and a significant coverage gap remains. Over half a million households lack access to electricity and piped water, some 200,000 households are without any form of sanitation, and another 200,000 households in the largest cities are still relying on in situ sanitation as opposed to sewerage. Even if currenthistorically highlevels of expenditure and effort are sustained, with population growth of 2.6% per annum it will still take around 10 years to reach universal coverage for electricity, water, and sewerage. The overall cost to the country is estimated at around US$1 billion. However, achieving universal coverage is not merely about building infrastructure networks. The evidence shows that about a third of households without electricity and water live in neighborhoods where these services are available, but simply fail to make a connection. Reasons appear to include high connection charges, cultural priorities, and the responsiveness of utilities to customer requests. Complementary policy measures are therefore required to encourage these households to connect to existing networks. 53 There has been a conscious government policy decision to keep water and electricity tariffs artificially low. To some extent this is understandable given that providing access to utilities services is only ultimately meaningful if these are affordable for poor households to use. However, the evidence suggests that this has not always had the desired consequences, and that the disadvantages of this policy are quite substantial. In the electricity sector, the `tarifa social' introduced following privatization of the distribution companies largely fails to reach poor households. This policy keeps domestic tariffs for those consuming up to 300 kilowatt-hours per month capped at US$0.08 per kilowatt-hour. However, the evidence suggests that this measure has only a very modest impact on poor households. Owing to relatively low connection rates among poor households and to the relatively high consumption threshold for the `tarifa social', about 65% of the beneficiaries are non-poor households who together capture 90% of the total value of the subsidy, while 60% of poor households receive no benefits from the scheme at all since they do not have an electricity connection. Lowering the threshold from 300 to 100 kilowatt- hours per month would improve matters somewhat by lowering the number of non-poor beneficiaries to 55% and the leakage rate to 75%, and reducing the annual costs of the policy by 80%. However, even this still leaves a great deal to be desired. A much more pro-poor policy would be to channel these resources towards expanding coverage of electricity to unserved households. It is important to recall that thelargely poorhouseholds without access to electricity pay an estimated US$11 per kWh, compared with full cost electricity tariffs of US$0.11 to US$0.15 per kWh. From this perspective, it would appear to make much more sense to channel the US$50 million annual cost of the `tarifa social' towards increasing connections to unserved households. It is estimated that an additional 50,000 new connections each year could be financed in this way. Moreover, given that over 70% of households without electricity belong to the poorest segments of the population, such a policy would be very effective at reaching the poor. In the water and sanitation sector, tariffs are well below true economic costs and international parameters of willingness to pay. Households pay bills of less than US$2 per month in Guatemala City, and less than US$1 per month in other urban areas. The underlying tariffs are barely US$0.10 per cubic meter compared with typical costs of around US$0.40 per cubic meter for the Latin American region. In spite of these low tariffs, as many as 30% of households with piped water reported that they did not pay for the service in the last month, compared with only 8% for electricity. As a result, households spend barely 0.5% of their budgets on water and sanitation services, which is a fraction of the 3%-5% World Health Organization guideline for what households are typically willing to pay. Moreover, many households spend three times as much on bottled water as on piped water. While low water tariffs may seem attractive, there is substantial evidence that the precarious financial position of water utilities is contributing to a very poor quality of service. Three quarters of households with piped water feel it necessary to either buy bottled water or perform some kind of self-treatment. It is particularly striking that the practice regular boiling drinking water is equally prevalent among households with and without piped water (some 40% of both groups). Moreover, households report that on average they receive only 17 hours of water per day and face 3.6 days per month without water. In conclusion, the key policy recommendations that emerge from the assessment are as follows. 54 · To maintain and, if possible, increase the current level of resources channeled towards the expansion of modern utility services so as to reach universal coverage within a 10 year horizon. · To try and improve further the ability of service expansion programs to target traditionally disadvantaged groups, in particular, poor, rural and indigenous households. · To develop a strategy for removing the barriers that prevent a significant proportion of excluded households from making connections to services even when these are available in their communities. · To find new financial resources for the FONDETEL rural telephony program and to consider using these to subsidize the extension of cellular networks into commercially marginal areas. · To reform the `tarifa social' policy by at least reducing the eligibility threshold to 100 kilowatt-hours per month, and preferably replacing it with a program to fund 50,000 new connections per year. · To allow water tariffs to rise to a level that allows water utilities to become financial sustainable and thereby improve the quality of service that they offer to the public. · To complement expansion of water and sanitation programs with measures to improve household hygiene practices so as to reap the full health benefits of the service. · To complement expansion of electricity and telecommunications coverage in rural areas with measures to promote the productive use of these services by micro-enterprises. 55 Bibliography Centro de Investigaciones Económicas Nacionales (CIEN), 1998, Revisión del Programa de Inversión Pública de Mediano Plazo : Sector InfraestructuraElectricidad y Telecomunicaciones, Mimeo, The World Bank, Washington DC. Centro Pan-Americano de Ingenieria Sanitaria (CEPIS), 2000, Evaluación de los Servicios de Agua Potable y Saneamiento 2000 en las Américas: Informe Analítico de Guatemala, Mimeo, Pan-American Health Organization, Washington DC. Comisión Nacional de Energía Eléctrica (CNEE), 2001, www.cnee.gob.gt. ESA Consultores, 2001, Guatemala Agua y Saneamiento: Apuntos para la Preparación de una Nota Sectorial, Mimeo, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington DC. Foster, 2001 Condominial Water and Sewerage Systems: Costs of Implementation of the Model. El Alto-Bolivia Pilot Project. Economic and Financial Evaluation, Water and Sanitation Program, Lima, Perú. Foster, V. and Tre, J.P., 2000, `Measuring the impact of energy interventions on the poor: an illustration from Guatemala.' Conference Volume `Infrastructure for Development: Private Solutions and the Poor', Private Provision of Infrastructure Advisory Facility (PPIAF), Department for International Development (DIFD) and the World Bank, London, United Kingdom Instituto Nacional de Electrificación (INDE), 2001, Plan de Electrificación Rural: Gerencia de Electrificación Rural y Obras: Informe de Avance, Mimeo, Ciudad de Guatemala. Marini, A. and Gragnolati, M. (2001) `Nutrition and Poverty in Guatemala', Background Paper for the Guatemala Poverty Assessment, The World Bank Group, Washington DC (forthcoming). Solo, T., 1999, `Guatemala's Medley of Water Providers: Los Aguateros no Tienen Quien les Regule', Chapter 7 from The Other Private Participation in Water and Sanitation: Tales of Small Independent Providers in Latin American Cities, Mimeo, The World Bank Group, Washington DC. Torres, J., Infant mortality and morbidity from exposure to indoor air pollution in Guatemala, Consulting Report to the World Bank, July 2001. Vakis, R. (2001) `Guatemala: Livelihoods, Labor Markets and Rural Poverty', Background Paper for Guatemala Poverty Assessment, The World Bank Group, Washington DC (forthcoming). Walker, I., Ordoñez, F., Serrano, P. and Halpern, J., 2000, Potable Water Pricing and Poor: Evidence from Central America on the Distribution of Subsidies and the Demand for Improved Services, Policy Research Working Paper No. 2468, The World Bank Group, Washington DC. World Bank, 1999, Ayuda Memoria de la Misión de Supervisión del Proyecto de Asistencia Técnica para la Participación Privada en Infraestructura (Préstamo 4149-GU), Mimeo, Washington DC. Zúñiga, A., 1999, Análisis de los Fondos de Inversión Social, Mimeo, The World Bank, Washington DC. 56 Data Annex A. Summary Statistics for Regressions Table A1: Summary statistics for the regression of determinants of the price per efficient kilowatt-hour National Urban Rural Difference Quetzales per net kwh consumed 10.8 11.9 9.9 Household head characteristics Sex (1 if male) 0.82 0.77 0.85 *** Age (years) 44.29 44.49 44.14 Ethnicity (1 if indigenous) 0.39 0.26 0.49 *** Language (1 if speaks Spanish) 0.92 0.98 0.88 *** Education (# of years) 4.06 6.47 2.22 *** Household size (# of adults) 2.90 2.85 2.94 * Expenditure (thousands of Quetzales) 7.72 12.13 4.35 *** Area (1 if urban) 0.43 Micro enterprise (1 if operates in dwelling) 0.21 0.23 0.20 * Use of electricity 0.73 0.95 0.56 *** Use of kerosene 0.25 0.04 0.40 *** Use of propane 0.46 0.78 0.20 *** Use of fuel wood 0.74 0.46 0.96 *** Population size 2,183,071 947,643 1,235,428 Significantly different (urban from rural) at: * 90% level, ** 95% level, *** 99% level. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala Table A2: Regression of determinants of the price per efficient kilowatt-hour National Urban Rural Household head characteristics Sex (1 if male) -0.015 -0.005 -0.046 Age (years) 0.0001 -0.001 0.001 Ethnicity (1 if indigenous) -0.181*** -0.100** -0.254** Language (1 if speaks Spanish) 0.147 0.283 0.148 Education (# of years) 0.002 0.003 0.002 Household size (# of adults) 0.002 0.010 -0.004 Expenditure (thousands of Quetzales) 0.0004 0.002* -0.004 Area (1 if urban) 0.078 Micro enterprise (1 if operates in dwelling) 0.032 0.122*** -0.042 Use of electricity -0.833*** -1.059*** -0.817*** Use of kerosene -0.173* 0.014 -0.181 Use of propane -0.285*** -0.248*** -0.295*** Use of fuel wood -0.225*** -0.159*** -0.621*** Constant 0.773*** 0.673** 1.282*** R2 .0931 .1301 .0962 Population size 2,169,354 937,759 1,231,596 OLS estimation where dependent variable is log of price of net kilowatts-hour consumed. Regional dummies were included in the estimation. Significant at: 90% level, * **95% level, ***99% level. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala 57 Table A3: Summary statistics for regression on take-up of modern utilities Variable Electricity Water Sanitation N Y N Y N Y Household head % of male .85** .80 .85*** .80 .84* .81 Age in years 44 44 43** 45 43 44 Years of school 1.6*** 5.0 2.0*** 5.0 1.6*** 4.4 % of indigenous .56*** .33 .51*** .35 .41 .38 % who speaks Spanish .88*** .96 .89 .95 .89** .93 Household characteristics % with business in dwelling .11*** .18 .15 .18 .12*** .18 Per capita income1 3.9*** 9.2 4.2*** 9.3 3.6*** 8.4 % in urban area .20*** .56 .25*** .56 .09*** .49 Regional dummies % in Metropolitan .09*** .33 .10*** .31 .06*** .28 % in North .08*** .03 .10** .05 .06 .08 % in Northeast .05 .07 .14* .08 .15* .08 % in Southeast .09 .08 .12 .08 .18*** .07 % in Central .13 .13 .12 .11 .08** .12 % in Southwest .32 .26 .24 .24 .26 .25 % in Petén .03** .01 .01 .02 .06*** .02 Population size 210,677 1,593,209 272,554 1,494,239 249,168 1,890,371 Variable Sewerage Fixed Phone Cell Phone N Y N Y N Y Household head % of male .85*** .76 .80 .77 .76*** .84 Age in years 44 45 42*** 48 45*** 42 Years of school 3.1*** 6.8 5.1*** 9.8 5.3*** 10.4 % of indigenous .42*** .23 .28*** .11 .25*** .11 % who speaks Spanish .96*** .99 .985* .994 .986** .997 Household characteristics % with business in dwelling .16 .19 .17** .22 .19 .19 Per capita income1 5.6*** 12.9 8.4*** 21.0 10.2*** 20.9 % in urban area .48*** .87 .76*** .90 .70*** .83 Regional dummies % in Metropolitan .23*** .46 .37*** .58 .49*** .67 % in North .04 .02 .03** .02 .02*** .01 % in Northeast .12* .06 .09 .07 .12*** .08 % in Southeast .07 .05 .05 .04 .06*** .03 % in Central .12 .14 .13*** .08 .09** .06 % in Southwest .28 .23 .26*** .18 .17*** .12 % in Petén .02*** .001 .01 .01 .01 .01 Population size 271,823 828,331 454,470 328,104 617,354 209,711 1: Household consumption aggregate, in thousand of Quetzales per capita per year. If significantly different from those who use service at:***99%,***95%, 90%. * Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística - Guatemala 58 Table A4: Summary statistics for hedonic rental model Variable / Region Metropolitan Urban Rural (urban and rural) (non-Metropolitan) (non-Metropolitan) Monthly rent (quetzales) 888 431 190 Proportion in urban area .86 Proportion with walls made of Block .60 .55 .29 Adobe .10 .24 .37 Wood .07 .10 .20 Proportion with roofs made of Concreto .33 .15 .02 Metal .62 .72 .77 Tile .005 .09 .18 Straw or palm 0 .001 .01 Proportion with floors made of Cement or clay bricks .27 .17 .05 Cement .32 .45 .38 Ceramic or granite .22 .15 .03 Soil or sand .19 .22 .53 Connection to Water .85 .89 .59 Drainage .67 .74 .10 Electricity .95 .91 .59 Telephone .42 .27 .03 Number of rooms 3.0 2.5 1.7 Number of rooms for business .13 .22 .10 Exclusive use of Kitchen .96 .96 .97 Water .68 .71 .48 Sanitary service .83 .80 .70 Age of dwelling (years) 17.4 18.3 16.3 Really rented dwellings .13 .15 .02 Metropolitan includes urban and rural in this region, while urban and rural exclude the Metropolitan region. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala 59 Table A5: Regression results for hedonic rental model Variable / Region Metropolitan Urban Rural (urban and rural) (non-Metropolitan) (non-Metropolitan) Urban area -.39* Walls made of Block .13 .17** .28*** Adobe .004 .12* .10 Wood .09 -.10 .03 Roofs made of Concreto .31** .03 .03 Metal .11 -.15** -.10 Tile -.07 -.26*** -.10 Straw or palm - -.20 -.15 Floors made of Cement/ clay bricks .02 .10 -.16 Cement -.13 -.04 -.17 Ceramic or granite .08 .04 -.17 Soil or sand -.38** -.25** -.36* Connection to Water .39*** .003 -.01 Drainage .02 .08* .16** Electricity .09 .27*** .17*** Telephone .45*** .20*** .28*** # of rooms .09*** .14*** .13*** # of rooms for business -.10* .06* .02 Exclusive use of Kitchen -.07 .02 .07 Water -.04 -.01 .11** Sanitary service .27** .15*** .07* Age of dwelling -.003 .0002 -.0001 Rented -.19*** -.30*** -.38*** Constant 5.28*** 4.36*** 4.20*** R2 .7694 .6527 .5375 Population size 446,882 429,432 1,029,361 Results of OLS regressions where the dependant variable is the logarithm of the monthly rent for the dwelling. Census-tract fixed-effects were included in each of the estimations. Metropolitan includes urban and rural in this region, while urban and rural exclude the Metropolitan region. Significant at: 90% level, * **95% level, ***99% level. Source: World Bank calculations using th e ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística ­ Guatemala 60 Table A6: Summary statistics for model of probability of having a micro-enterprise No enterprise Enterprise Wald test3 Household head characteristics Male .77 .81 Age 44 47 *** Years of school 6.5 6.6 * Speaks Spanish .98 .99 Indigenous .26 .29 Household characteristics Number of adults 2.8 3.2 *** Urban area .43 .48 ** Rural area .57 .52 ** Modern utilities availability Electricity 1 1 Water2 .94 .97 ** Fixed phone .68 .73 *** Cellular phone .66 .63 * Modern utilities coverage Expenditure in electricity4 (Q) .43 27 *** Electricity .95 .97 *** Water2 .87 .90 *** Fixed phone .29 .39 *** Cellular phone .19 .19 ** Minutes to closest public phone 11 8 *** Region Metropolitan .50 .44 North .03 .03 ** Northeast .06 .05 Southeast .05 .06 *** Central .12 .14 Southwest .18 .19 Northwest .05 .06 Petén .02 .02 ** Population size 1,721,709 455,641 1: Refers only to enterprises that operate in dwelling. 2: In dwelling or yard. 3: Null hypothesis (equality of enterprise owners and non-owners) is rejected at: *** 90%, ** 95%, 90%. * 4: For business purposes, only. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala 61 Table A7: Summary statistics for characteristics of households with micro-enterprises National Rural Urban Household head characteristics Male 0.81 0.82 0.81 Age 46.90 46.10 47.54 Years of school 4.54 2.50 6.16 Speaks Spanish 0.93 0.87 0.98 Indigenous 0.40 0.52 0.31 Household characteristics Number of adults 3.19 3.15 3.22 Urban area 0.56 0.00 1.00 Modern utilities coverage Electricity 0.84 0.68 0.97 Water2 0.79 0.63 0.91 Fixed phone 0.24 0.06 0.39 Cellular phone 0.10 0.05 0.15 Minutes to closest public phone 16.10 27.64 7.00 Business characteristics Capital (Q) 1,0645 4,401 15,573 Labor (man-hours) 249 207 283 Age of business (years) 10.43 10.27 10.56 Months worked last year (#) 10.75 10.63 10.85 Economic activity Manufacture 0.33 0.35 0.31 Services 0.63 0.64 0.63 Provider Large firm 0.21 0.15 0.27 Small firm 0.32 0.34 0.31 Source of finance Bank / cooperative / NGO 0.05 0.03 0.07 Family / friends 0.10 0.09 0.12 Providers 0.01 0.01 0.02 Savings / assets / inheritance 0.85 0.89 0.82 Type of dwelling House 0.94 0.92 0.96 Modern utilities availability Fixed phone 0.46 0.16 0.71 Cellular phone 0.41 0.20 0.58 Water2 0.88 0.74 0.99 Electricity 0.89 0.75 1.00 Observations 1,299 726 573 1: Refers only to enterprises that operate in dwelling. 2: In dwelling or yard. 62 B. Summary Statistics Underlying Figures Presented in Text Table B1: Total social fund investments in rural infrastructure since 1993 (US$ million per year) Electricity Water and Sanitation FIS FONAPAZ FSDC Total FIS FONAPAZ FSDC Total 1993 0 0 0 0 0 1.0 0 1.1 1994 0 0 0 0 0 1.0 0 1.0 1995 0 0 4.0 4.0 0 1.0 0 5.0 1996 0 0 8.2 8.2 7.3 0.9 7.3 9.5 1997 0 0 13.9 13.9 15.9 1.9 15.9 23.2 1998 0 0 23.5 23.5 16.9 1.0 16.9 43.4 1999 0 0 16.6 16.6 7.9 3.9 7.9 40.8 2000 0 0 3.3 3.3 23.6 1.0 23.6 26.2 Total 0 0 69.5 69.5 31.1 12.8 71.7 114.5 Table B2: Central American comparison for equity of coverage (percentage of households) Guatemala Nicaragua Panama El Salvador Electricity · 1st quintile 37 54 27 27 · 2nd quintile 60 69 51 72 · 3rd quintile 74 77 74 86 · 4th quintile 87 85 83 93 · 5th quintile 93 96 93 98 Water · 1st quintile 50 29 22 58 · 2nd quintile 62 33 45 82 · 3rd quintile 63 45 63 89 · 4th quintile 76 54 73 94 · 5th quintile 92 76 86 98 Sanitation · 1st quintile 73 72 64 71 · 2nd quintile 80 76 73 92 · 3rd quintile 88 79 86 97 · 4th quintile 94 81 92 99 · 5th quintile 98 88 97 100 Telephone · 1st quintile 0 1 1 4 · 2nd quintile 2 4 1 14 · 3rd quintile 6 10 3 32 · 4th quintile 24 19 6 55 · 5th quintile 68 46 31 78 63 Table B3: Historical coverage trends (percentage of households) Electricity Water Sanitation Total Urban Rural Total Urban Rural Total Urban Rural 1990 46 72 27 38 60 22 55 68 45 1991 47 73 28 39 61 23 55 69 45 1992 49 74 29 42 63 25 58 72 47 1993 50 76 30 44 65 27 60 75 49 1994 52 78 33 46 68 29 63 78 52 1995 55 81 36 50 73 32 67 82 56 1996 58 84 38 53 75 36 71 86 59 1997 61 87 42 57 78 40 75 89 63 1998 65 89 46 61 82 45 79 92 69 1999 67 91 49 65 85 49 83 95 74 2000 73 95 56 69 88 54 87 97 79 Table B4: Distance to public telephone for rural households (cumulative percentage of households who live with the distance indicated) Within community Outside community Overall 1km 86 17 48 2km 94 32 60 3km 96 40 66 4km 97 51 72 5km 98 61 78 6km 98 65 80 7km 98 69 82 8km 98 76 86 9km 98 78 87 10km 98 83 90 >10km 100 100 100 Table B5: Accessibility of public telephones for rural households by region (average distance faced by households) Physical distance Temporal distance (kilometers) (minutes) Metropolitan 2.7 28 Northeast 3.2 22 Southwest 3.6 24 Southeast 3.7 33 Central 4.9 24 Northwest 7.2 46 North 9.1 48 Peten 12.4 48 64 Table B6: Access to fixed and cellular telephones (percentage of households) Consumption quintile 1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th Fixed line only .2 1 3 13 34 Cellular line only .1 1 3 10 10 Both fixed and cellular lines 0 .1 0 1 24 Total .3 2 6 24 68 Table B7: Decomposition of coverage deficit (percentage of households who lack coverage) Demand side Both supply side and Supply side Total problem only demand side problem only problem Electricity 37 7 56 100 Water 39 10 52 100 Sewerage 21 19 60 100 Fixed telephone 25 44 32 100 Cellular telephone 31 51 18 100 Table B8: Expenditure on basic services (percentage of consumption aggregate) Consumption Quintiles 1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th Total Telecommunications 0.12 0.53 0.65 1.79 3.69 1.4 Cooking and heating 0.15 0.29 0.46 0.72 1.01 0.5 Lighting and appliances 3.58 3.15 3.1 3.08 2.58 3.1 Water and sanitation 7.87 6.86 5.62 4.19 2.21 5.3 Total 11.72 10.83 9.83 9.78 9.49 10.3 Table B9: Evolution of electricity tariffs following reform (US$ per kWh) EEGSA DEOCSA DEORSA Tarifa Social 1998 March 0.0835 0.0750 July 0.0856 0.0750 November 0.0856 0.0750 1999 March 0.0856 0.0685 0.0685 0.0750 July 0.1033 0.0698 0.0595 0.0750 November 0.1063 0.0750 0.0740 0.0750 2000 March 0.1063 0.0791 0.0772 0.0750 July 0.1063 0.0870 0.0849 0.0750 November 0.1415 0.0915 0.0892 0.0750 2001 March 0.1519 0.0962 0.0940 0.0750 65 Table B10: Cumulative density of electricity consumption (cumulative percentage of households) Electricity consumption Poor Non-poor (kWh per month) customers customers 50 70 29 100 91 54 150 96 69 200 99 79 250 100 84 300 100 90 350 100 93 400 100 95 450 100 96 500 100 97 <500 100 100 Table B11: Simulation of inclusion and exclusion errors and subsidy cost (various performance variables) Electricity consumption Targeting errors Subsidy Cost (kWh per month) (percentage) (US$m pa) Exclusion Exclusion Inclusion Leakage (connected (all poor) (non- (subsidy poor) poor) cost) 50 30 72 47 61 4.1 100 8 64 56 75 13.2 150 4 62 61 82 22.7 200 2 61 63 85 32.0 250 1 61 65 87 38.6 300 0 61 66 89 48.9 350 0 61 67 90 54.0 400 0 60 67 91 58.7 450 0 60 67 91 60.2 500 0 60 67 92 62.9 <500 30 72 47 61 4.1 66 Table B12: Typical structure of water bills (US$ per month) m3 per EMPAGUA Quetazal San San San San month domestic social -tenango Sebastian Martin Agustin Cristobal 5 0.66 1.32 1.81 0.33 0.33 0.39 0.66 10 0.66 1.32 1.81 0.33 0.33 0.39 0.66 15 0.66 1.32 1.81 0.33 0.33 0.39 0.66 20 1.67 1.32 1.81 0.33 0.33 0.39 0.66 25 2.02 1.32 2.11 0.33 0.33 0.39 0.66 30 2.57 3.67 2.41 0.33 0.33 0.39 0.66 35 3.12 5.32 3.62 0.33 0.33 0.39 0.66 40 3.67 6.97 3.92 0.33 0.68 0.74 1.01 45 4.22 8.62 4.52 0.33 1.03 1.09 1.36 50 4.87 10.27 5.42 0.33 1.38 1.44 1.71 55 6.17 11.92 6.62 0.33 1.73 1.79 2.06 60 8.12 13.57 8.12 0.33 2.08 2.14 2.41 65 10.72 15.22 9.92 0.33 2.43 2.49 2.76 70 12.02 16.87 12.02 0.33 2.78 2.84 3.11 75 13.32 18.52 14.42 0.33 3.13 3.19 3.46 80 14.62 20.17 17.12 0.33 3.48 3.54 3.81 85 15.92 21.82 20.12 0.33 3.83 3.89 4.16 90 17.22 23.47 23.42 0.33 4.18 4.24 4.51 95 18.52 25.12 27.02 0.33 4.53 4.59 4.86 100 19.82 26.77 30.92 0.33 4.88 4.94 5.21 Table B13 : Intra-household allocation of water and fuel wood collection tasks (percentage of man-hours devoted yesterday by different groups) Fuel wood Water Men 41 13 Boys 24 13 Women 24 50 Girls 11 24 Total 100 100 67 C. Standard Summary Tables Table C1: Availability, Take-up and Coverage Piped water1 Electricity Propane Sewerage Availability Take-up Coverage Availability Take-up Coverage Availability Take-up Coverage Availability Take-up Coverage National 0.81 0.85 0.69 0.83 0.88 0.73 0.74 0.61 0.45 0.44 0.68 0.30 Urban 0.95 0.92 0.87 1.00 0.95 0.95 0.98 0.79 0.77 0.85 0.74 0.63 Rural 0.70 0.76 0.53 0.70 0.81 0.57 0.55 0.37 0.20 0.13 0.39 0.05 Region Metropolitan 0.91 0.94 0.86 1.00 0.97 0.97 0.96 0.86 0.83 0.77 0.81 0.62 North 0.65 0.74 0.48 0.43 0.75 0.32 0.44 0.35 0.15 0.18 0.43 0.08 Northeast 0.85 0.77 0.65 0.65 0.91 0.59 0.86 0.53 0.46 0.29 0.61 0.18 Southeast 0.82 0.79 0.65 0.78 0.87 0.68 0.71 0.45 0.32 0.27 0.57 0.15 Central 0.82 0.83 0.68 0.95 0.88 0.84 0.87 0.57 0.50 0.49 0.60 0.29 Southwest 0.77 0.84 0.65 0.89 0.86 0.77 0.72 0.50 0.36 0.42 0.61 0.26 Northwest 0.85 0.78 0.66 0.74 0.76 0.56 0.30 0.46 0.14 0.23 0.58 0.13 Peten 0.46 0.89 0.41 0.46 0.78 0.36 0.60 0.38 0.23 0.04 0.19 0.01 Poverty Non-poor 0.87 0.91 0.79 0.94 0.95 0.89 0.91 0.79 0.72 0.64 0.77 0.49 All poor 0.74 0.75 0.56 0.70 0.77 0.54 0.53 0.25 0.13 0.21 0.36 0.08 Extreme poor 0.71 0.67 0.48 0.53 0.58 0.31 0.33 0.04 0.01 0.09 0.17 0.02 Quintile 1 (poorest) 0.71 0.71 0.50 0.59 0.66 0.39 0.38 0.06 0.02 0.11 0.20 0.02 2.00 0.78 0.79 0.62 0.77 0.82 0.63 0.61 0.29 0.18 0.27 0.38 0.10 3.00 0.77 0.82 0.63 0.86 0.90 0.77 0.80 0.55 0.44 0.38 0.56 0.21 4.00 0.85 0.90 0.77 0.95 0.95 0.90 0.92 0.80 0.74 0.60 0.69 0.41 5 (richest) 0.96 0.97 0.93 0.97 0.98 0.95 0.98 0.90 0.88 0.84 0.90 0.76 Ethnicity Non-indigenous 0.83 0.88 0.73 0.88 0.92 0.81 0.85 0.69 0.59 0.54 0.74 0.40 Indigenous 0.78 0.79 0.62 0.75 0.81 0.61 0.56 0.42 0.24 0.28 0.51 0.14 Quiche 0.89 0.82 0.73 0.91 0.88 0.80 0.73 0.52 0.38 0.45 0.54 0.24 Q'eqchi 0.47 0.69 0.32 0.35 0.76 0.27 0.45 0.30 0.14 0.11 0.42 0.05 Kaqchiqel 0.81 0.82 0.66 0.98 0.87 0.85 0.80 0.46 0.37 0.38 0.50 0.19 Mam 0.84 0.80 0.67 0.72 0.70 0.50 0.32 0.28 0.09 0.17 0.45 0.08 Other ind 0.79 0.76 0.60 0.64 0.76 0.49 0.39 0.34 0.13 0.19 0.52 0.10 1: Piped water in dwelling or field. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística- Guatemala 68 Table C1: Availability, Take-up and Coverage (continued) Sanitation Fixed phone Cell phone Availability Take-up Coverage Availability Take-up Coverage Availability Take-up Coverage National 0.98 0.88 0.86 0.36 0.42 0.15 0.38 0.25 0.10 Urban 1.00 0.98 0.98 0.68 0.46 0.31 0.65 0.29 0.19 Rural 0.97 0.81 0.79 0.11 0.24 0.03 0.18 0.16 0.03 Region Metropolitan 1.00 0.97 0.97 0.66 0.53 0.35 0.81 0.32 0.26 North 1.00 0.91 0.91 0.13 0.26 0.03 0.09 0.14 0.01 Northeast 0.96 0.80 0.77 0.34 0.36 0.12 0.48 0.18 0.09 Southeast 0.96 0.75 0.72 0.19 0.34 0.06 0.23 0.15 0.03 Central 0.99 0.92 0.91 0.36 0.29 0.10 0.29 0.19 0.06 Southwest 0.99 0.88 0.87 0.32 0.33 0.11 0.24 0.19 0.05 Northwest 0.95 0.84 0.80 0.12 0.37 0.04 0.11 0.18 0.02 Peten 0.93 0.74 0.69 0.15 0.37 0.06 0.15 0.21 0.03 Poverty Non-poor 0.99 0.95 0.94 0.57 0.48 0.27 0.57 0.30 0.17 All poor 0.97 0.81 0.79 0.11 0.06 0.01 0.15 0.06 0.01 Extreme poor 0.95 0.75 0.71 0.03 0.14 0.00 0.07 0.00 0.00 Quintile 1 (poorest) 0.96 0.77 0.74 0.04 0.06 0.00 0.08 0.01 0.00 2.00 0.98 0.82 0.80 0.14 0.05 0.01 0.18 0.06 0.01 3.00 0.99 0.90 0.89 0.27 0.11 0.03 0.34 0.08 0.03 4.00 1.00 0.95 0.95 0.50 0.28 0.14 0.50 0.21 0.11 5 (richest) 1.00 0.98 0.98 0.84 0.69 0.58 0.81 0.42 0.34 Ethnicity Non-indigenous 0.99 0.89 0.88 0.47 0.47 0.22 0.49 0.29 0.14 Indigenous 0.97 0.87 0.84 0.19 0.22 0.04 0.21 0.13 0.03 Quiche 0.98 0.85 0.83 0.36 0.18 0.06 0.31 0.11 0.03 Q'eqchi 1.00 0.88 0.88 0.10 0.14 0.01 0.19 0.08 0.02 Kaqchiqel 1.00 0.93 0.93 0.26 0.25 0.07 0.36 0.11 0.04 Mam 0.97 0.87 0.84 0.06 0.25 0.02 0.05 0.30 0.02 Other ind 0.91 0.83 0.76 0.10 0.30 0.03 0.09 0.34 0.03 Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística- Guatemala 69 Table C2: Coverage gap Number of households without access to Proportion of total gap in each group Piped water1 Electricity Propane Sewerage 2 Sanitation3 Fixed Phone Cellular phone Piped water1 Electricity Propane Sewerage 2 Sanitation3 Fixed Phone Cellular phone National 683,111 584,141 1,190,928 1,521,984 286,980 1,747,331 1,967,640 Urban 111,843 44,468 206,408 346,951 23,478 574,821 767,760 0.16 0.08 0.17 0.23 0.08 0.33 0.39 Rural 571,268 539,673 984,520 1,175,033 263,502 1,172,510 1,199,879 0.84 0.92 0.83 0.77 0.92 0.67 0.61 Region Metropolitan 77,394 18,440 93,685 205,153 15,197 296,145 402,422 0.11 0.03 0.08 0.13 0.05 0.17 0.20 North 83,226 107,895 134,736 146,897 14,276 152,605 157,320 0.12 0.18 0.11 0.10 0.05 0.09 0.08 Northeast 66,432 79,395 104,240 158,207 45,275 156,070 176,092 0.10 0.14 0.09 0.10 0.16 0.09 0.09 Southeast 65,489 59,547 127,687 159,727 54,029 171,986 181,781 0.10 0.10 0.11 0.10 0.19 0.10 0.09 Central 75,934 39,508 122,526 171,028 20,684 208,283 228,082 0.11 0.07 0.10 0.11 0.07 0.12 0.12 Southwest 193,415 130,057 347,995 404,460 68,189 471,506 519,875 0.28 0.22 0.29 0.27 0.24 0.27 0.26 Northwest 82,838 107,566 209,848 212,135 49,090 230,098 239,224 0.12 0.18 0.18 0.14 0.17 0.13 0.12 Peten 38,383 41,734 50,211 64,377 20,241 60,640 62,844 0.06 0.07 0.04 0.04 0.07 0.03 0.03 Poverty Non-poor 240,705 124,009 324,404 598,060 68,169 762,763 976,921 0.35 0.21 0.27 0.39 0.24 0.44 0.50 All poor 442,406 460,132 866,525 923,924 218,810 984,568 990,719 0.65 0.79 0.73 0.61 0.76 0.56 0.50 Extreme poor 123,338 163,615 232,740 232,105 66,678 234,580 235,678 0.18 0.28 0.20 0.15 0.23 0.13 0.12 Quintile 1 (poorest) 219,573 266,303 426,486 427,226 116,259 435,668 436,766 0.32 0.46 0.36 0.28 0.41 0.25 0.22 2 161,818 154,008 349,745 381,385 82,959 417,626 420,242 0.24 0.26 0.29 0.25 0.29 0.24 0.21 3 163,691 98,389 248,703 350,730 51,775 419,808 433,129 0.24 0.17 0.21 0.23 0.18 0.24 0.22 4 104,376 44,496 115,959 254,855 25,993 333,828 391,852 0.15 0.08 0.10 0.17 0.09 0.19 0.20 5 (richest) 33,653 20,945 50,035 107,789 9,993 140,401 285,650 0.05 0.04 0.04 0.07 0.03 0.08 0.15 Ethnicity Non-indigenous 359,148 255,024 543,016 794,063 158,100 952,527 1,143,277 0.53 0.44 0.46 0.52 0.55 0.55 0.58 Indigenous 323,963 329,117 647,913 727,921 128,879 794,804 824,363 0.47 0.56 0.54 0.48 0.45 0.45 0.42 Quiche 51,165 39,063 119,419 145,941 32,437 175,736 186,896 0.07 0.07 0.10 0.10 0.11 0.10 0.09 Q'eqchi 84,929 92,404 108,948 120,188 15,017 122,897 124,301 0.12 0.16 0.09 0.08 0.05 0.07 0.06 Kaqchiqel 65,097 29,162 120,929 154,483 13,444 173,358 183,755 0.10 0.05 0.10 0.10 0.05 0.10 0.09 Mam 52,676 78,102 144,693 147,139 25,416 154,325 156,707 0.08 0.13 0.12 0.10 0.09 0.09 0.08 Other ind 70,097 90,386 153,924 160,170 42,565 168,488 172,704 0.10 0.15 0.13 0.11 0.15 0.10 0.09 1: Piped water in dwelling or field. 2: Toilet connected to drainage. 3: Includes toilets and latrines. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000,Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala 70 Table C3: Quality of services Among those with electricity Among those with piped water1 # of blackouts days without hours/day days without hours/day proportion who proportion who Service2 with service3 Service2 with service3 treat water buy bottled water National 2.90 0.69 23.4 3.58 16.7 0.61 0.22 Urban 2.20 0.34 23.5 3.54 15.2 0.57 0.35 Rural 3.79 1.14 23.4 3.62 18.5 0.66 0.05 Region Metropolitan 0.75 0.22 23.8 3.76 13.1 0.47 0.43 North 3.36 0.56 23.4 3.98 20.1 0.64 0.07 Northeast 3.75 0.87 23.3 3.29 17.4 0.50 0.15 Southeast 4.25 1.30 22.5 4.66 17.8 0.49 0.06 Central 2.30 0.51 23.5 4.67 15.1 0.60 0.18 Southwest 3.65 0.90 23.4 2.76 19.1 0.83 0.12 Northwest 7.42 1.52 23.1 2.91 20.6 0.78 0.06 Peten 4.06 0.34 23.4 3.82 14.6 0.46 0.18 Poverty Non-poor 2.44 0.51 23.5 3.39 15.6 0.59 0.33 All poor 3.79 1.03 23.4 3.89 18.5 0.65 0.03 Extreme poor 4.89 1.30 23.3 * * 0.64 0.03 Quintile 1 (poorest) 4.56 1.19 23.3 3.79 19.8 0.64 0.02 2 3.64 1.06 23.3 3.91 17.8 0.66 0.03 3 2.87 0.74 23.5 4.33 16.2 0.69 0.10 4 2.52 0.59 23.4 3.76 15.7 0.64 0.24 5 (richest) 2.09 0.29 23.5 2.56 15.3 0.50 0.50 Ethnicity Non-indigenous 2.48 0.60 23.4 3.51 15.9 0.55 0.28 Indigenous 3.75 0.88 23.4 3.71 18.1 0.74 0.09 Quiche 3.38 0.60 23.4 3.06 19.2 0.78 0.13 Q'eqchi 2.44 1.00 23.3 5.41 18.7 0.76 0.06 Kaqchiqel 2.33 0.62 23.5 5.67 13.2 0.60 0.11 Mam 4.28 1.18 23.3 2.95 20.0 0.82 0.04 Other ind 7.03 1.50 23.4 2.37 20.1 0.75 0.06 *: No observations available. 1: Piped water in dwelling or field. 2: Consecutive days without service in previous month. 3: Consecutive hours-per-day with service in previous month. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala 71 Table C4: Consumption Energy for lighting and appliances Energy for cooking Energy for cooking, lighting and appliances Gross kwh Net kwh Price of gkw Price of nkw Efficiency Gross kwh Net kwh Price of gkw Price of nkw Efficiency Gross kwh Net kwh Price of gkw Price of nkw Efficiency National 69.1 61.6 3.15 33.5 9.9 1,268 236 0.21 0.51 4.51 1,341 298 8.0 1.69 5.67 Urban 108.5 105.0 2.30 27.0 4.0 759 194 0.34 0.59 2.88 870 300 4.4 1.50 3.02 Rural 39.1 28.6 3.79 38.4 14.3 1,656 268 0.10 0.45 5.89 1,699 297 10.7 1.84 7.70 Region Metropolitan 130.3 128.5 2.16 24.2 3.8 342 138 0.40 0.67 0.16 36 267 2.2 1.26 2.14 North 39.7 19.7 2.94 48.7 23.7 1,176 190 0.12 0.50 0.10 105 210 8.4 1.39 11.07 Northeast 50.5 42.1 4.50 43.3 13.0 1,500 268 0.19 0.49 0.28 224 312 9.8 1.96 5.65 Southeast 45.1 37.9 3.65 50.0 12.9 1,817 302 0.12 0.37 0.15 213 341 11.3 2.05 7.77 Central 68.3 60.4 2.82 27.5 6.2 1,264 238 0.19 0.50 0.15 95 301 8.0 1.75 5.10 Southwest 50.7 43.7 3.14 27.5 8.8 1,569 271 0.13 0.44 0.13 133 315 10.0 1.88 5.69 Northwest 31.9 22.8 4.35 39.3 12.6 1,812 286 0.10 0.47 0.09 177 308 10.2 1.71 7.80 Peten 51.2 31.2 3.25 46.4 20.3 2,408 380 0.11 0.36 0.15 292 411 14.3 2.36 9.93 Poverty Non-poor 99.1 94.5 2.60 22.7 4.7 973 220 0.30 0.56 3.29 1,076 315 5.4 1.56 3.49 All poor 33.7 22.8 3.80 46.1 15.9 1,616 255 0.09 0.44 6.10 1,653 278 11.0 1.85 8.24 Extreme poor 26.2 11.9 3.95 55.6 24.5 1,460 221 0.06 0.40 6.57 1,486 233 11.6 1.79 10.59 Quintile 1 (poorest) 27.6 13.9 3.73 51.3 20.9 1,548 235 0.07 0.41 6.52 1,577 249 11.7 1.84 9.86 2 35.5 26.2 3.77 40.7 12.1 1,695 271 0.10 0.45 5.96 1,736 298 10.9 1.88 7.27 3 53.0 46.3 3.31 36.0 9.1 1,472 260 0.17 0.50 4.91 1,527 306 8.6 1.78 5.44 4 84.1 79.3 2.77 25.3 4.5 1,133 237 0.26 0.55 3.55 1,220 317 5.8 1.60 3.63 5 (richest) 145.5 142.4 2.16 13.8 2.5 493 176 0.42 0.63 2.05 641 320 2.8 1.36 2.17 Ethnicity Non-indigenous 86.0 80.3 3.17 31.2 7.4 1,040 216 0.27 0.54 3.73 1,130 298 6.5 1.62 4.59 Indigenous 42.6 32.2 3.13 37.1 13.8 1,626 266 0.12 0.47 5.75 1,671 298 10.3 1.81 7.37 Quiche 44.9 40.2 3.31 28.8 8.9 1,187 213 0.14 0.53 5.34 1,232 254 7.7 1.55 5.53 Q'eqchi 41.7 19.6 2.29 35.0 22.3 1,446 229 0.11 0.50 6.01 1,488 248 9.5 1.54 9.10 Kaqchiqel 59.6 55.3 2.39 41.9 7.5 1,724 295 0.15 0.49 5.27 1,792 352 10.0 1.94 5.53 Mam 29.6 16.9 2.66 27.3 17.2 1,878 290 0.07 0.38 6.35 1,907 307 13.7 2.19 7.83 Other ind 33.9 21.5 4.78 51.7 16.6 1,902 297 0.10 0.46 6.03 1,936 318 10.9 1.81 9.72 Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instit uto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala 72 Table C5: Expenditure In Quetzales per month As a percentage of consumption expenditure Piped water1 Energy Energy for Telecom. Piped water1 Energy Energy for Telecom. for cooking lighting and applianes for cooking lighting and applianes National 11 74 96 69 0.33% 3.09% 5.35% 1.36% Urban 20 109 98 130 0.52% 3.08% 3.81% 2.20% Rural 3 48 94 22 0.18% 3.10% 6.53% 0.72% Region Metropolitan 26 133 92 171 0.58% 3.13% 2.99% 2.48% North 2 45 85 12 0.11% 3.50% 6.89% 0.29% Northeast 6 57 88 48 0.26% 2.85% 4.92% 1.42% Southeast 5 54 88 27 0.26% 3.22% 5.92% 0.90% Central 12 70 98 36 0.48% 3.39% 5.43% 0.89% Southwest 5 55 103 39 0.23% 2.91% 6.17% 1.06% Northwest 2 43 105 34 0.09% 2.98% 7.66% 1.17% Peten 6 56 91 34 0.25% 2.92% 5.17% 0.92% Poverty Non-poor 17 102 101 120 0.44% 2.91% 3.75% 2.18% All poor 3 42 90 8 0.20% 3.31% 7.24% 0.40% Extreme poor 1 35 74 1 0.13% 3.87% 8.54% 0.07% Quintile 1 (poorest) 1 36 78 2 0.14% 3.57% 7.86% 0.12% 2 4 44 95 11 0.23% 3.16% 6.87% 0.58% 3 6 59 103 17 0.30% 3.08% 5.63% 0.64% 4 12 81 103 60 0.41% 3.08% 4.20% 1.79% 5 (richest) 31 151 99 256 0.56% 2.58% 2.22% 3.68% Ethnicity Non-indigenous 15 90 93 99 0.40% 2.99% 4.13% 1.76% Indigenous 4 49 101 21 0.21% 3.26% 7.27% 0.73% Quiche 7 51 103 23 0.34% 2.87% 6.49% 0.72% Q'eqchi 2 48 88 8 0.13% 3.81% 7.33% 0.26% Kaqchiqel 6 64 115 19 0.29% 3.58% 7.35% 0.69% Mam 2 36 92 19 0.15% 3.14% 8.09% 0.91% Other ind 2 44 100 31 0.11% 3.04% 7.26% 0.98% 1: Piped water in dwelling or field. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala 73 Table C6: Cost recovery Piped water1 Electricity Proportion of Monthly Quetzales paid Proportion of Monthly Quetzales paid hh with service Everyone Only those who hh with service Everyone Only those who who do not pay pay an amount >0 who do notpay pay an amount >0 National 0.30 11 22 0.08 60 89 Urban 0.22 20 29 0.07 103 118 Rural 0.40 3 11 0.09 26 51 Region Metropolitan 0.24 26 40 0.09 132 151 North 0.24 2 6 0.10 18 61 Northeast 0.28 6 12 0.12 39 76 Southeast 0.27 5 9 0.12 34 57 Central 0.28 12 24 0.07 55 71 Southwest 0.36 5 13 0.06 38 54 Northwest 0.49 2 5 0.07 21 41 Peten 0.14 6 17 0.06 30 91 Poverty Non-poor 0.25 17 29 0.07 93 112 All poor 0.39 3 8 0.10 21 42 Extreme poor 0.46 1 5 0.13 11 41 Quintile 1 (poorest) 0.46 1 5 0.10 13 37 2 0.35 4 9 0.09 24 41 3 0.36 6 15 0.10 41 59 4 0.28 12 21 0.06 68 81 5 (richest) 0.17 31 40 0.06 152 173 Ethnicity Non-indigenous 0.26 15 28 0.09 79 107 Indigenous 0.38 4 11 0.07 29 52 Quiche 0.34 7 15 0.08 39 53 Q'eqchi 0.21 2 9 0.09 16 67 Kaqchiqel 0.30 6 12 0.04 50 62 Mam 0.56 2 8 0.04 16 32 Other ind 0.39 2 6 0.09 19 44 1: Piped water in dwelling or field. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala 74 Table C7: Social tariff Connection rate Consumption1 Exp. in Quetzales Exp. as prop. of consumption Avg. subsidy Number of hh Total subsidy Share of (proporiton of hh) (kwh/month) With tariff No tariff With tariff No tariff (Quetzales) beneficiaries (US$) total subsidy National 0.73 102 88 134 0.03 0.04 39 1,190,384 6,485,975 100% Urban 0.95 135 119 183 0.03 0.04 57 652,726 5,280,061 81% Rural 0.57 60 50 71 0.02 0.03 17 537,657 1,205,914 19% Region Metropolitan 0.97 168 156 257 0.03 0.05 91 340,619 4,555,958 70% North 0.32 80 61 81 0.03 0.04 13 38,831 68,183 1% Northeast 0.59 96 74 95 0.03 0.03 15 86,141 180,050 3% Southeast 0.68 71 54 72 0.03 0.03 12 100,019 162,700 3% Central 0.84 88 73 112 0.03 0.05 35 153,292 732,674 11% Southwest 0.77 67 54 71 0.02 0.03 13 334,862 599,038 9% Northwest 0.56 46 39 51 0.02 0.03 9 117,064 142,250 2% Peten 0.36 115 92 112 0.03 0.04 17 19,556 45,122 1% Poverty Non-poor 0.89 128 112 171 0.03 0.04 52 794,359 5,807,678 90% All poor 0.54 48 39 56 0.03 0.04 13 396,024 678,298 10% Extreme poor 0.31 47 39 52 0.04 0.05 7 189 181 0% Quintile 1 (poorest) 0.39 42 35 48 0.03 0.04 8 127,889 142,763 2% 2 0.63 48 40 56 0.02 0.03 13 205,107 373,094 6% 3 0.77 63 51 76 0.03 0.04 21 242,727 698,583 11% 4 0.9 100 79 127 0.03 0.04 44 295,368 1,747,755 27% 5 (richest) 0.95 184 171 255 0.03 0.04 74 319,293 3,523,779 54% Ethnicity Non-indigenous 0.81 123 107 164 0.03 0.04 50 791,990 5,534,813 85% Indigenous 0.61 59 49 70 0.03 0.03 18 398,394 951,163 15% Quiche 0.8 66 52 72 0.03 0.03 15 112,427 229,753 4% Q'eqchi 0.27 69 52 74 0.03 0.04 15 21,797 44,463 1% Kaqchiqel 0.85 72 61 91 0.03 0.04 28 116,886 440,690 7% Mam 0.5 34 31 40 0.02 0.03 8 73,524 76,684 1% Other ind 0.49 52 42 62 0.02 0.03 16 73,759 159,574 2% 1: From this column on (i.e. to the right), the analysis focuses only on households that have an electricity meter. Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística­ Guatemala 75 Table C8: Probability that an unservedhousehold was connected Electricity Piped water§ Sanitary services¨ 1993-1996 1997-2000 % change 1993-1996 1997-2000 % change 1993-1996 1997-2000 % change National .18*** 0.36 89% .19*** 0.34 79% .31*** 0.55 77% Urban .38*** 0.7 84% .31*** 0.53 71% .50*** 0.82 64% Rural .13*** 0.29 123% .14*** 0.28 100% .22*** 0.48 118% Region Metropolitan 0.45*** 0.73 63% 0.33*** 0.46 41% 0.60*** 0.73 22% North 0.03*** 0.15 335% 0.09*** 0.23 149% 0.28*** 0.5 78% Northeast 0.06*** 0.2 247% 0.07*** 0.38 431% 0.16*** 0.47 198% Southeast 0.13*** 0.34 167% 0.19*** 0.38 103% 0.18*** 0.39 118% Central 0.23*** 0.54 132% 0.15*** 0.31 110% 0.30*** 0.63 107% Southwest 0.20*** 0.46 127% 0.18*** 0.33 79% 0.29*** 0.64 122% Northwest 0.20*** 0.3 50% 0.24*** 0.33 38% 0.30*** 0.49 64% Peten 0.05*** 0.15 186% 0.08*** 0.19 121% 0.15*** 0.41 166% Poverty Non-poor .06*** 0.17 183% .13*** 0.26 100% .21*** 0.37 76% All poor .13*** 0.28 115% .15*** 0.29 93% .25*** 0.44 76% Extreme poor .29*** 0.55 90% .24*** 0.41 71% .38*** 0.72 89% Quintile 1 (poorest) 0.08*** 0.22 191% 0.13*** 0.27 104% 0.22*** 0.38 71% 2.00 0.20*** 0.34 74% 0.18*** 0.34 87% 0.26*** 0.48 83% 3.00 0.21*** 0.44 110% 0.18*** 0.29 61% 0.33*** 0.62 87% 4.00 0.33*** 0.54 62% 0.22*** 0.39 76% 0.41*** 0.73 76% 5 (richest) 0.28*** 0.68 140% 0.32*** 0.61 93% 0.38*** 0.82 113% Ethnicity Non-indigenous .21*** 0.42 100% .19*** 0.35 84% .31*** 0.57 84% Indigenous .16*** 0.3 88% .18*** 0.32 78% .30*** 0.52 73% Quiche 0.22*** 0.53 138% 0.23*** 0.41 77% 0.30*** 0.46 51% Q'eqchi 0.02*** 0.09 368% 0.07*** 0.19 181% 0.20*** 0.58 199% Kaqchiqel 0.23*** 0.56 144% 0.16*** 0.32 100% 0.41*** 0.64 53% Mam 0.17*** 0.25 51% 0.26*** 0.39 49% 0.33*** 0.59 81% Other ind 0.16*** 0.22 43% 0.18*** 0.33 79% 0.24*** 0.4 66% Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística- Guatemala 76 Table C9: Number of new connections in a three year before and after the Peace Accord Electricity Piped water§ Sanitary services¨ 1993-1996 1997-2000 % change 1993-1996 1997-2000 % change 1993-1996 1997-2000 % change National 208,518.00 329,734*** 58% 240,069.00 352,336*** 47% 281,106.00 350,418** 25% Urban 92,823.00 105009 13% 109,453.00 128,593.00 17% 134,692.00 109,792.00 -18% Rural 115,695.00 224,725*** 94% 130,616.00 223,743*** 71% 146,414.00 240,626*** 64% Region Metropolitan 54,521.00 49430 -9% 68,785.00 65,250** -5% 86,176.00 41,926* -51% North 4,518.00 18,977*** 320% 11,244.00 25,361** 126% 11,043.00 14,194.00 29% Northeast 6,007.00 19,642** 227% 8,157.00 40,250.00 393% 15,711.00 39,447*** 151% Southeast 13,307.00 39,944** 200% 24,129.00 39,809*** 65% 19,052.00 34,175*** 79% Central 25,794.00 46,023*** 78% 19,129.00 34,249.00 79% 24,577.00 35,354* 44% Southwest 61,419.00 111,103*** 81% 65,222.00 95,398** 46% 76,948.00 121,819*** 58% Northwest 37,470.00 45246 21% 38,528.00 40,355.00 5% 40,353.00 46,521.00 15% Peten 2,726.00 7,390** 171% 4,317.00 8,737** 102% 6,199.00 13,960*** 125% Poverty Non-poor 13,662.00 33,135*** 143% 24,253.00 43,091** 78% 27,979.00 38,674* 38% All poor 95,296.00 180,842*** 90% 108,754.00 184,682*** 70% 132,815.00 176,028** 33% Extreme poor 113,222.00 148,892* 32% 131,315.00 167,654* 28% 148,255.00 174,390.00 18% Quintile 1 (poorest) 27,646.00 74,446*** 169% 45,018.00 79,644*** 77% 53,797.00 71,506** 33% 2 56,845.00 79,690* 40% 54,036.00 82,664** 53% 56,963.00 76,914* 35% 3 47,313.00 78,562*** 66% 50,301.00 66,279* 32% 67,856.00 85,001.00 25% 4 48,566.00 52267 8% 49,883.00 67,898* 36% 67,271.00 69,273.00 3% 5 (richest) 25,391.00 43840 73% 20,273.00 52,924.00 161% 34,173.00 44,704.00 31% Ethnicity Non-indigenous 117,976.00 186,392*** 58% 133,965.00 195,611*** 46% 166,007.00 209,926* 26% Indigenous 87,785.00 142,414*** 62% 105,547.00 153,789*** 46% 114,052.00 137,572.00 21% Quiche 24,287.00 44,912** 85% 25,581.00 34,880.00 36% 26,347.00 27,645.00 5% Q'eqchi 1,945.00 8,928*** 359% 7,760.00 20,327.00 162% 8,734.00 21,000* 140% Kaqchiqel 19,417.00 36,647** 89% 18,406.00 30,914** 68% 26,123.00 23,484.00 -10% Mam 20,817.00 26214 26% 30,730.00 33,853.00 10% 30,249.00 36,923.00 22% Other ind 21,319.00 25713 21% 23,070.00 33,824.00 47% 22,599.00 28,519.00 26% Source: World Bank calculations using the ENCOVI 2000, Instituto Nacional de Estadística- Guatemala 77 Annex D: Understanding whether coverage deficits are due to demand or supply side factors Coverage is the traditional indicator of access to services. However, the drawback of this indicator is that it doesn't allow you to distinguish whether people don't use the service (a) because it is not available in their community, or (b) because they choose not to use it even if it is available. These two alternative supply-side and demand-side explanations have very different policy implications and hence it is useful to be able to distinguish between them. As a first step it is helpful to calculate coverage, availability and take-up indicators as follows. Coverage rate = No. of households using the service/Total no. of households Availability rate = No. of households living in communities where the service is available/Total no.of households Take-up rate = No. of households using the service/No. of households living in communities where the service is available It is easy to show that: Coverage rate= Take-up rate * Availability rate Using these indicators, it is straightforward to decompose the coverage gap between demand-side and supply-side factors. Unserved population = 100 - Coverage rate Pure demand side gap = Availability rate - Coverage rate Supply side gap = Unserved population - Pure demand side gap Pure supply side gap = supply side gap * take-up rate Mixed demand and supply side gap = supply side gap* (100-take-up rate) These indicators can be normalized in the following way to show the actual proportion of any service deficit that is attributable to supply side factors, demand-side factors or both. Proportion of deficit attributable to demand side factors only = Pure demand side gap / Unserved population Proportion of deficit attributable to supply side factors only = Pure supply side gap / Unserved population Proportion of deficit attributable to both demand and supply side factors only = Mixed demand and supply side gap / Unserved population An example, may help to illustrate the methodology. Availability rate = 80% Take-up rate = 50% Coverage rate = 80% * 50% = 40% 78 Unserved population = 100%-40%=60% Pure demand-side gap = 80%-40% = 40% Supply side gap = 60%-40% = 20% Pure supply-side gap = 20% * 50% = 10% Mixed demand and supply-side gap = 20% * (100%-50%) = 10% Proportion of deficit attributable to demand side factors only = 40%/60% = 66% Proportion of deficit attributable to supply side factors only = =10%/60% = 17% Proportion of deficit attributable to both demand and supply side factors only = 10%/60% = 17% 79