Drivers of Entrepreneurship and Post-entry Performance of Newborn Firms in Developing Countries Francesco Quatraro and Marco Vivarelli The aim of this paper is to provide an updated survey of the “state of the art” in entrepre- neurial studies with a particular focus on developing countries (DCs). In particular, the concept of “entrepreneurship” is critically discussed, followed by a discussion of the institu- tional, macroeconomic, and microeconomic conditions that affect the entry of new firms and the post-entry performance of newborn firms. The reviewed literature bears some policy implications for the support of the creation new firms, such as the targeting of policy measures to prospective entrepreneurs who possess high education levels, long previ- ous job experience, and innovative skills. Specifically, for DCs, tailored subsidies and support should be coupled with framework and infrastructural policies that are able to improve the business environment such that new ventures can start and grow. JEL Codes: L26, O12 According to Schumpeter (1934), entrepreneurship is a driving force of innovation and, more generally, an engine for economic development (Audretsch, Keilbach and Lehmann 2006; Koellinger and Thurik 2012; for a comprehensive survey, see Van Praag and Versloot 2007). As detailed by Wennekers and Thurik (1999) and Dejardin (2011), new firm formation may play a crucial role in fostering competi- tion, inducing innovation and supporting the emergence of new sectors. Ultimately, new firms may substantially contribute to job creation provided that the net effect of new entrants brings about overall market growth (Malchow-Møller, Schjerning, and Sørensen 2011). The relationship between the rate of new firm creation and economic development is, however, heterogeneous across countries. The distinction between advanced and The World Bank Research Observer # The Author 2014. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / THE WORLD BANK. All rights reserved. For permissions, please e-mail: journals.permissions@oup.com doi:10.1093/wbro/lku012 Advance Access publication November 4, 2014 30:277–305 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 developing countries (DCs) is particularly important in this respect. Wennekers et al. (2005) showed that the link between entrepreneurial dynamics and economic perfor- mance is not monotonic. On the contrary, they found evidence of a U-shaped rela- tionship between the level of development and the rate of entrepreneurship (see also Ligthelm 2011, 163). This finding suggests that entrepreneurship does not yield the same effects in every place. Based on this contribution, Amoro ` s and Cristi (2008) analyzed the Latin American evidence by adopting an interpretative frame- work based on Porter’s (1990) scheme of country economic development, which identifies three stages: factor-driven, efficiency-driven and innovative-driven. These authors provided further support for the U-shaped hypothesis. In particular, they showed that Latin American countries are clustered in the downward part of the curve. Such heterogeneous evidence at the aggregate level can be better understood when the focus is shifted to the micro foundations of entrepreneurship. Since the seminal contribution by Baumol (1990), we have known that “Schumpeterian” in- novative entrepreneurs coexist with “defensive and necessity entrepreneurs.” The latter are those who enter a new business because of market opportunities and in- novative ideas but merely because they need income to survive.1 For obvious reasons, this type of “survival-driven” self-employment is particularly diffused in DCs (Naude ´ 2009, 2010; Desai 2009), where poverty and a lack of formal opportu- nities in the wage sector often push a large number of people into “entrepreneurial” activities ranging from street vending to traditional and personal services (in most cases, within the informal sector of the economy; see Ihrig and Moe 2004; Maloney 2004; Sonobe, Akoten, and Otsuka 2011). The prevalence of survival-driven entre- preneurs in DCs is often associated with the choice to stay small and informal rather than participating in the formal sector of the economy (Desai 2009; Klapper, Amit, and Guille ´ n 2010). This is one of the reasons why the effects of entrepreneur- ship on the economic performance of DCs appear to be problematic. However, Amoro ` s and Cristi (2011) study the relationship between entrepreneurship and human development indicators and provide empirical evidence for the hypothesis that although this type of entrepreneurship is rarely able to trigger the economic performance of DCs, it nonetheless contributes to the reduction of inequalities by affecting the wealth distribution in the society. On similar grounds, Naude ` , Amoros, and Cristi (2011) posit that the effects of entrepreneurship in DCs should be ana- lyzed by looking at broader and more non-material and subjective measures of human well-being. Their findings suggest that entrepreneurship in DCs may matter for individual and societal development beyond the mere increase of GDP . The emphasis on the development stage of countries calls for a special attention to the evolution of their industrial structure. Since the seminal contributions by Marshall (1919) and Kuznets (1930), we have known that a country’s economic performance is related to the main sectors in which it shows a comparative 278 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 advantage. The fortunes of countries as well as the dynamics of entry, exit, and growth are therefore closely related to the relative stage of the lifecycle of their in- dustries (Klepper 1997). In this respect, the empirical evidence concerning industrial dynamics casts doubt on the progressive potentialities of business start-ups. First, the survival rates of new firms are strikingly low: the available econometric evidence shows that more than 50 percent of new firms exit the market within the first five years of activity (Dunne, Roberts, and Samuelson 1989; Reid 1991; Geroski 1995; Mata, Portugal, and Guimaraes 1995; Audretsch and Mahmood 1995; Audretsch, Santarelli, and Vivarelli 1999a; Johnson 2005). Second, entry and exit rates are significantly correlated (called “turbulence”; Beesley and Hamilton 1984). This is one of the uncontroversial “stylized facts” of the entry process according to Geroski (1995, 424), who noted that the “mecha- nism of displacement, which seems to be the most palpable consequence of entry, affects young, new firms more severely” (see also Baldwin and Gorecki 1987, 1991). Indeed, entry and exit rates have been found to be positively correlated across industries in OECD countries (Bartelsman, Scarpetta, and Schivardi 2005) and in DCs (Bartelsman, Haltinwanger, and Scarpetta 20042). This evidence opens the way to considerations regarding the alleged role of entry as a vehicle for technological upgrading, productivity growth and employment gen- eration. One should be very cautious in seeing entrepreneurship measured as new firm formation as the main driver of development for a DC. If entry were indeed driven mainly by technological opportunities, growing sales, and profit expecta- tions, a negative cross-sectional correlation would be observed between entry and exit rates, particularly over short time intervals. By the same token, new firm formation may be more or less conducive to techno- logical upgrading and industry growth according to the different sectors in which it occurs. For instance, new technology-based firms (NTBFs; see Acs and Audretsch 1990; Colombo, Delmastro, and Grilli 2004) in advanced manufacturing and ICT services play a different role than small-sized start-ups play in traditional sectors. These considerations concerning the role of the industrial structure are particularly relevant for DCs, where the dominant role of traditional and low-tech sectors renders turbulence more likely and the presence of progressive/innovative entrepre- neurs an exception. Within this context, the rest of the paper is organized as follows. The next section is devoted to the institutional context (which is often the main deterrent to entrepreneurship in the DCs). Subsequently, we move to the microeconomic and personal drivers of entrepreneurship. Then, we discuss the link between ex ante characteristics and post-entry performance of newborn firms, and finally, we briefly conclude. Quatraro and Vivarelli 279 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 Contextual Factors and Institutional Constraints Together with industrial characteristics, as noted above, the growth of a newborn firm is affected by a larger set of variables that involve the general macroeconomic business climate and with a wide range of institutional factors (Acs and Audretsch 1990; Geroski and Schwalbach 1991; Audretsch 1995). Overall, previous research has proven that market failures, the infrastructure endowment, and regulatory and legal conditions are important determinants of the post-entry performance of newborn firms. Although this is true even for the developed countries, a fortiori, these institutional constraints may play a crucial role in developing countries, with a larger impact moving from the middle-income to the low-income DCs. At a general level, the growth of small entrepreneurial firms is obviously con- strained by the overall state of the economy, and the economic cycle is important for the availability of exploitable business opportunities (Nichter and Goldmark 2009). However, the various entrepreneurial dynamics introduced in the previous section engender a composite response to business cycles. Indeed, in recession phases, the reduction of opportunity-driven Schumpeterian entrepreneurs may well be accom- panied by the expansion of necessity-driven ones (Pisani and Pagan 2004). DCs are also characterized by several market failures that severely hamper the post-entry growth potentialities of entrepreneurial activities. As extensively dis- cussed by Tybout (2000), Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page ´ s (2009), and Vivarelli (2012), imperfections in the credit and financial markets, a non-transpar- ent regulatory environment, the lack of infrastructure and the high incidence of bribing are important factors that hinder firms’ growth in DCs. Starting with capital markets, Rajan and Zingales (1998) and Beck et al. (2008) clearly show that firms in financially dependent industries grow much faster in financially developed countries. In contrast, new small firms in DCs are credit and equity rationed in the vast majority of cases because their financial markets are un- derdeveloped (Ayyagari, Demirgu ¸ -Kunt, and Maksimovic 2008; Lian, Sepehri, and ¨c Foley 2011; and below). In fact, capital markets in DCs are characterized by 1) a lower depth (measured, for instance, by a low ratio of bank deposits to GDP; see Paravisini (2008) for the case of Argentina and Banerjee and Duflo (2004) for the case of India); 2) a lower level of competition between financial intermediaries, gener- ating the misallocation of funds (see Banerjee, Duflo, and Munshi (2003), studying the misallocation of capital in India, and Cole (2009), discussing agricultural credit in India); and 3) higher information asymmetries due to institutional and infrastruc- tural underdevelopment (see Klapper and Love (2011) for a general discussion; Canales and Nanda (2008) discuss lending to small businesses in Mexico). Similarly, a non-transparent regulatory environment with regard to labor market rules, taxation, red tape procedures, property rights and bankruptcy laws is particu- larly harmful to firms’ growth in DCs and may be fatal for young entrepreneurial 280 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 activities (Goedhuys and Sleuwaegen 1999; Sleuwaegen and Goedhuys 2002; Beck, Demirgu ¸ -Kunt, and Maksimovic 2005; Lee et al. 2011). For instance, in a ¨c recent study, Ardagna and Lusardi (2010) worked with GEM microdata from 37 countries, including eight DCs, and showed that stringent entry regulation, soft contract enforcement rules, and labor market rigidities play an important role in hindering entrepreneurship and strengthening the adverse impact of risk aversion. Moreover, inefficient regulation may hinder the growth of small firms in DCs because they may fear the effects of red tape and higher taxes (De Soto 1989). The regulatory framework often involves counterproductive policy measures that were originally intended to support small firms but actually prevent firms’ growth. Indeed, the presence of subsidies addressed to SMEs may push entrepreneurs to keep the size of the firm unchanged - or at least below a given threshold - to main- tain eligibility for government funding (Little, Mazumdar, and Page 1987; Mitra and Pingali 1999). In a developing country context, a prominent role is played by the wide diffusion of bribing, which may abort any chance of growth of a fragile new entrepreneurial activity3. For instance, Fisman and Svensson (2007), using data collected from 126 Ugandan firms, show that a 1 percent increase in the bribery rate implies a reduc- tion of 3 percent in firm sales growth. Obviously, corruption may amplify the ham- pering role of credit constraints (see above) when it involves bank officials who are ¨c responsible for screening the entrepreneurial initiatives (Beck, Demirgu ¸ -Kunt, and 4 Maksimovic 2005). Finally, the lack of an adequate infrastructural endowment including roads and railways, basic utilities such as electricity and water supply, and ICT networks is singled out by the literature as a significant shortcoming that prevents young and small firms in DCs from growing (Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page ´ s 2009; 5 Goedhuys and Sleuwaegen 2010 ; Ghani, Kerr, and O’Connell 2011). Having discussed the role of the macroeconomic and institutional conditions, we now move the focus of this study to the microeconomic and personal characteristics that may play a role in determining the entry and post-entry performance of new firms in DCs. The Microeconomic Determinants of Entry In the traditional microeconomic textbook narrative, the creation of new firms is driven by profit expectations, economic growth, and technological opportunities (Mansfield 1962; Acs and Audretsch 1989a,b; Geroski 1995), and it is deterred by both exogenous and endogenous entry barriers (Geroski and Schwalbach 1991; Sutton 1991; Arauzo-Carod and Segarra-Blasco 2005). However, the main limitation of the textbook approach is that it focuses on market mechanisms (“pull factors”) and Quatraro and Vivarelli 281 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 may obscure the decision-making process at the level of the individual,6 thus underes- timating the factors behind an entrepreneur’s motivation to start a new business. Indeed, some 20th-century authors such as Knight (1921), Schumpeter (1934, 1939), and Oxenfeldt (1943) drew attention to the characteristics of the founder of a new firm. Following their contributions, we are aware that important individual determinants may act as push factors and may be related both to environmental circumstances and to the potential founder’s personal characteristics. For instance, the specific local/sectoral labor market plays an important role given that the vast majority of new founders (approximately two-thirds of them) were previ- ously employed or located in the same geographical area and the same sector. The rest were young people starting their first job experience, ex-entrepreneurs, or foun- ders moving in from an outside region (Vivarelli 1991; Storey 1994; Cressy 1996; Arrighetti and Vivarelli 1999; Shane 2000; Stam 2007). Therefore, entrepreneur- ship is strongly characterized by sectoral and locational inertia, and this phenomenon is affected by significant persistence (Fritsch and Mueller 2007). Within this framework, new firm formation can be modeled as an income choice based on a comparison between the wage earned in the previous job and the expected profit as an entrepreneur starting a new business in the same sector and in the same geographical area (Creedy and Johnson 1983; Vivarelli 1991; Foti and Vivarelli 1994; Audretsch 1995; Geroski 1995; Vivarelli 2004; for DCs, see Le ´ vesque and Shepherd 2004). This means that entry may have a counter-cyclical component and may be induced by industrial restructuring and decreasing real wages rather than by buoyant demand expectations and an appropriate endowment of entrepreneurial capabilities (Highfield and Smiley 1987; Hamilton 1989). Pushing this argument further, found- ing a new firm may be an alternative to uncertain future career prospects or may even represent an “escape from unemployment” (Oxenfeldt 1943; Evans and Leighton 1990; Storey 1991, 1994; Premand et al. 2012). Thus, entry may be determined by a set of different environmental factors, includ- ing some “progressive” determinants, such as profitability and promising technologi- cal opportunities, and “regressive” determinants, such as low wages and the actual condition of being (or the fear of becoming) unemployed (the latter conditions are particularly likely in a DC context). Moreover, in determining new firm formation, these environmental drivers interact with the potential entrepreneur’s personal traits. Indeed, new firm founders differ with regard to characteristics such as previous work experience, family tradition, financial status, and personal motivation. The founder of a new firm is heavily influenced by his/her own background, with particu- lar reference to his/her previous job experience (Evans and Leighton 1989; Reynolds et al. 2001; Chlosta et al. 2012). The role of the family background in fostering entre- preneurship has been demonstrated in DCs as well. For instance, Djankov et al. (2006a,b, 2007) have shown that entrepreneurs in China, Russia, and Brazil are 282 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 much more likely to have family members who are entrepreneurs as well as childhood friends who became entrepreneurs, suggesting that the family and the social environ- ment play an important role in entrepreneurship. Another important stream of literature has investigated the impact of financial constraints on business start-ups, mostly following the work of Fazzari, Hubbard, and Petersen (1988). The fact that wealth, inheritance, and windfall gains spur en- trepreneurship suggests that business start-ups are often underfinanced (Parker 2004). Because most new companies need external capital, differences in the ability of capital markets to select and finance the most promising entrepreneurial projects may lead to important differences in the level and quality of entrepreneurship across countries, with DCs obviously suffering a disadvantage in this respect (Kerr and Nanda 2011; Klapper, Amit, and Guille ´ n 2010). Other studies show that non-economic personal factors may be even more impor- tant than environmental variables. For instance, potential entrepreneurs seem to be strongly influenced by specific psychological attitudes, such as a desire to be independent, a search for autonomy in the workplace, an aspiration to fully exploit previous job experience and acquired ability, and a desire to be socially useful and to acquire improved social status (Creedy and Johnson 1983; Evans and Leighton 1990; Vivarelli 1991, 2004; Zacharakis, Bygrave, and Shepherd 2000). If one considers the (often dominant) psychological attitudes discussed above, entry mistakes and excess entry can be further justified. In fact, the observed occur- rence of these entry mistakes suggests an attitude that can be defined as a “try and see” bet. Accordingly, market churning, turbulence, and early failure observed at a more aggregate level of analysis emerge as normal and expected features of industrial dynamics. These findings lead to the conclusion that several heterogeneous entry processes are simultaneously at play in the economy and that opportunity entrepreneurs, who bring about innovation and economic growth, should be distinguished from “revolving door” start-ups, which are doomed to early failure and generate only precarious and temporary jobs (Baumol 1990, 2010). Obviously, this distinction is a fortiori crucial when we focus on DCs, where entre- preneurship and self-employment often generate informal and transient activities that are not very different from “disguised unemployment.” Drivers of the Post-entry Performance of Newborn Firms Because entrepreneurs are embedded in different institutional contexts and are driven by both progressive and regressive determinants, the post-entry performance of newborn firms and their eventual contribution to economic development may also be diverse. From an empirical perspective, a relatively recent stream of literature has Quatraro and Vivarelli 283 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 focused on the drivers of survival (or early exit) and growth of newborn firms (among the early studies, see Reid 1991; Boeri and Cramer 1992; Baldwin and Rafiquzzaman 1995). Within this field of research, it is possible to analyze the relationship between the ex ante features of entry, on the one hand, and both survival and (conditional on survival) the post-entry performance of newborn firms, on the other hand. The following subsections are devoted to investigating what have been found to be the most important ex ante characteristics that affect the post-entry performance of new businesses. Size and Age Many studies have identified a positive relationship between start-up size and survival (Audretsch and Mahmood 1995; Mata, Portugal, and Guimaraes 1995; Agarval and Audretsch 2001; for more controversial results, see Audretsch, Santarelli, and Vivarelli 1999a,b7). Because entry implies sunk costs (Sutton 1991) and generally occurs at a scale that is lower than the minimum efficient scale (MES), a larger entry size is a signal of commitment and self-confidence and makes both the occurrence of wrong entry decisions and the risk of failure due to diseconomies of scale less likely. Moreover, a larger start-up size is positively correlated with other factors, such as lower credit constraints and a higher technological capability, which are predictors of a higher likelihood of survival and better post-entry performance. Therefore, a larger start-up size can be considered a reliable indicator of better chances of sur- vival of a newborn firm. In contrast, a vast number of papers have found (conditional on survival) a negative relationship between start-up size and post-entry growth, thus rejecting Gibrat’s Law8 (Gibrat 1931; Hall 1987; Hart and Oulton 1996; Sutton 1997; Lotti, Santarelli, and Vivarelli 2003, 2009). This evidence means that smaller entrants with a sub-optimal entry size and with a higher risk of early failure (see above) must grow to survive and reach the MES as soon as possible. However, it is worth emphasizing that the (nega- tive) relationship between size and growth has been found to be significant within the sub-sample of new entrants that struggle to survive (Lotti, Santarelli, Vivarelli 2003). Once market selection is accounted for, long run analyses have shown that a conver- gence towards Gibrat-like behavior can be detected among the surviving most efficient firms (Lotti, Santarelli, and Vivarelli 2006, 2009; Daunfeldt and Elert 2013). In other words, once small entrants have succeeded in approaching an efficient scale of produc- tion, their growth dynamics increasingly resemble a stochastic process in which size and growth are independent. A firm’s age consistently turns out to be positively correlated with survival (that is, the hazard rate is decreasing with age; see Fackler, Schnabel, and Wagner 2013) and negatively with growth (Evans 1987; Dunne and Hughes 1994; Calvo 2006; Coad, 284 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 Segarra, and Teurel 2013). Experienced, mature firms are more able to address market dynamics and thus are more likely to stay in the market. However, once they have reached (or are very close to) the MES, they do not need to grow very fast.9 Although all of the studies cited so far concern developed countries, the evidence from DCs is similar. For instance, Das (1995), examining the Indian computer indus- try, found a significant negative relationship between firm growth and initial firm size. McPherson’s (1996) study of five southern African countries detected a signifi- cant negative link between firm growth and both the firm’s size and age. Goedhuys and Sleuwaegen (2000) and Sleuwaegen and Goedhuys (2002) analyzed 141 and 129 manufacturing firms in Co ˆ te d’Ivoire, respectively, and found negative correla- tions between firm growth and both firm size and age. Finally, Bigsten and Gebreeyesus (2007) ran GMM-SYS panel estimates covering census-based Ethiopian manufacturing firms over the 1996–2003 period and showed that the negative relationship between size and age, on the one hand, and firms’ employment growth, on the other, is significant and robust to sample selection and unobserved firm heterogeneity.10 In summary, a larger start-up size is reassuring in terms of the likelihood of sur- vival and ensuring that job creation linked to the newborn firm is not transitory. In contrast, to survive, smaller new entrants must grow rapidly so they can contribute to employment growth. However, in the latter case, the job creation effect related to the surviving and fast-growing small entrants must be compared with the massive job losses due to the early failure of most small newborn firms. Entrepreneurial Learning From a theoretical point of view, Lucas (1978) was the first to propose a theory of the size distribution of firms based on the relative endowment of entrepreneurial talents. However, the first author to represent the post-entry evolution of newborn firms formally was Jovanovic (1982), who proposed a Bayesian model of noisy selec- tion in which efficient firms grow and survive, whereas inefficient ones decline and fail. Jovanovic’s model of entrepreneurial learning is perfectly consistent with a world in which founders are quite heterogeneous in terms of both general and spe- cific characteristics, entry mistakes can easily occur, entry can be originated by a “try and see” bet and early failures are rather common (see previous sections; Hopenhayn 1992; Ericson and Pakes 1995). If entrepreneurial learning is crucial and entry is often tentative, both spinoffs (entrepreneurs leaving a mother firm to found a new business) and “serial entrepre- neurs” (founders who have previously run other businesses) may have an advan- tage compared with “de novo” entrepreneurs.11 For example, Hirakawa, Muendler, and Rauch (2010), using microdata from Brazil over the 1995 –2001 period, found that spinoffs are characterized by larger entry sizes and lower exit rates than are Quatraro and Vivarelli 285 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 new firms that are not generated by a parent company. Similarly, the role of past ex- perience and path-dependence is confirmed by the fact that serial entrepreneurs are more likely to replicate the success of their past companies than single venture en- trepreneurs or serial entrepreneurs who failed in their prior business (Gompers et al. 2006). Empirical studies on DCs provide support for the importance of entrepreneurial learning for the post-entry performances of newborn firms either by observing the direct effect between experience and survival (Parker 1997) or by showing that in contexts characterized by a substantial absence of learning opportunities, the average survival is quite short (Barr 1998). McPherson (1996) found a positive re- lationship between annual employment growth and the previous experience of the founder in similar economic activities for entrepreneurial firms in Swaziland and Botswana, whereas Vijverberg (1991) and Goedhuys and Sleuwaegen (2000), in studies of Co ˆ te d’Ivoire, found that job experience previously acquired in the same industry both increases the likelihood of founding a new business and contributes to a firm’s better performance. Nichter and Goldmark (2009) noted an additional channel by which learning on the job may positively affect the survival rate of newborn firms: previous work experi- ence may expand entrepreneurs’ social network, which, in turn, can positively affect post-entry performance (see also Barr 1998; Kantis, Angelli, and Koenig 2004). However, the authors stress the differences between DCs and advanced countries with regard to this link, and the evidence about DCs is quite controversial.12 Finally, turning our attention to a managerial and organizational perspective, new founders who had previously been employed as top managers in the same sector and who have better access to relevant information are expected to exhibit better post- entry business performance due to their better ability to run and organize complex activities (for an empirical validation of these relationships, see Cooper, Gimeno- Gascon, and Woo 1994; Cressy 1996; Arrighetti and Vivarelli 1999; Shane 2001; Vivarelli 2004). Financial Constraints Credit constraints and a lack of financial capital in general should limit the rate of entry of new businesses as well as their likelihood of survival and rate of growth (Becchetti and Trovato 2002; Carpenter and Petersen 2002; Aghion, Fally, and Scarpetta 2007). However, some recent microeconometric studies have shown that the role of credit rationing has been somewhat over-emphasized and that entrepre- neurial saving plans may be able to overcome borrowing constraints (Cressy 1996, 2000; Parker 2000; Hurst and Lusardi 2004).13 At any rate, new entrepreneurial initiatives in DCs are credit-rationed in the vast majority of cases due to a lack of collateral, informational asymmetries, and largely 286 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 imperfect local capital markets. For this reason, micro and small firms in DCs rarely apply for and receive formal bank loans. Instead, they rely on other sources of credit, such as trade credit, overdrafts, and informal loans (Bigsten et al. 2003). Indeed, the lack of credit represents a severe impediment to the growth of small firms in the early years of activity. For instance, Goedhuys and Sleuwaegen (2010), in a study investigating 947 small and medium entrepreneurial firms in several manufacturing industries in 11 Sub-Saharan African countries,14 report that financial constraints are singled out as the major obstacle (from 11 alternatives) to a firm’s growth in five of 11 countries. In the previously cited paper on Co ˆ te d’Ivoire, the authors consistently find that a lack of collateral significantly hampers firms’ growth (Goedhuys and Sleuwaegen 2000, 139). In this framework, the suc- cessful diffusion of microfinance in DCs can be seen as a way of reducing informa- tion and transaction costs in screening and financing small and new businesses (Yunus 1999; Fogel, Lee, and McCumber 2011). A somewhat more skeptical position is proposed by Akoten, Sawada, and Otsuka (2006), who conducted an econometric test of the effects of credit rationing on the growth of 225 micro and small garment firms in Nairobi. Their results show that credit access does not affect significantly firms’ growth and that the factors that affect credit access are clearly different from those that affect firms’ growth. Education Not surprisingly, it has been demonstrated that education and human capital have an important role in increasing the likelihood of survival of new firms and in im- proving their post-entry economic performance (Bates 1990; Gimeno et al. 1997; Acs, Armington, and Zhang 2007). In particular, human capital aspects are partic- ularly important in fostering entrepreneurship in the high-tech sectors. For in- stance, Baptista and Mendonc ¸ a (2010) show that local access to knowledge and human capital significantly affect entry by knowledge-based firms, whereas Colombo and Grilli (2010) note that the founder’s human capital is a key driver of post-entry growth of high-tech start-ups. Turning our attention to DCs and taking into account that entrepreneurship and self-employment are often carried out within the informal sector of the economy in this context, the impact of education is controversial. In fact, higher education aug- ments the managerial capabilities necessary to run a business enterprise, but it also increases the outside option for salaried employment in the formal sector of the economy. This is most likely the reason why van der Sluis, van Praag, and Vijverberg (2005), in their comprehensive survey, found that in the majority of DCs, education reduces the likelihood of entering self-employment as contrasted with wage-earning employment. Quatraro and Vivarelli 287 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 In contrast, Goedhuys and Sleuwaegen (2000) ran logit estimations on data con- cerning the owners of 141 manufacturing firms in Co ˆ te d’Ivoire and found that the probability of being an entrepreneur is strongly stimulated by both apprenticeship and formal education, with the positive effect of education steadily increasing from lower to higher levels of education. Similarly, Ghani, Kerr, and O’Connell (2011), using cross-sectional establishment-level surveys of manufacturing and services companies in Indian districts, conclude that higher education in a local area signifi- cantly increases the supply of entrepreneurs. However, this relationship becomes non-significant when the informal manufacturing sector is taken into account. This is an interesting outcome that confirms that education may render the choice of being a wage earner preferable to entering self-employment in the informal sector (often characterized by “defensive entrepreneurship”).15 The evidence concerning the relationship between education and the post-entry performance of new businesses in DCs may also appear controversial on the surface. For example, Kantis, Angelli, and Koenig (2004) show that secondary school attain- ment yields no discernible impact on firm growth in Latin America. On the contrary, other studies, such as van der Sluis, van Praag, and Vijverberg (2005), conclude that an additional year of schooling raises entrepreneurial income by an average of 5.5 percent. Similarly, McPherson (1996) found that in Botswana and Zimbabwe, business owners who have completed secondary school run faster-growing firms than do those proprietors with no schooling. Finally, Goedhuys and Sleuwaegen (2000, 2010), using data from Co ˆ te d’Ivoire and from 11 Sub-Saharan African coun- tries, respectively, found unequivocal evidence that formal education of an entrepre- neur positively affects a firm’s growth performance, measured in terms of the growth rates of sales and employment, respectively (in both studies, the greatest effect on growth is found for entrepreneurs who hold a university degree).16 Nichter and Goldmark (2009) maintain that such apparent contradictions disap- pear if one takes into account a sort of “threshold effect” of education. Small firms with more educated owners are more likely to experience faster growth rates, but a country-specific threshold should be reached for this effect to take place. For example, whereas the threshold enabling faster growth appears to be secondary school in African countries, in Latin America, one can observe a higher threshold at the university level. Finally, it is worth noting the potential harmful effects of higher education, which may divert the attention of firms’ owners to other business opportunities, leading these owners to pay little attention to the workings of their actual business (Alvarez and Crespi 2003). Technological Change If the underlying motivation to start a new firm is linked to innovative projects, then better post-entry performance should be expected.17 Empirically, this seems to 288 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 be the case. In fact, a propensity for innovation emerges generally as a firm’s growth driver (see, for instance, Coad and Rao 2008; Altindag, Zehir, and Acar 2011; Colombelli, Krafft, and Quatraro 2014) and specifically as a positive pre- dictor of survival and an above-average post-entry performance of newborn firms (Esteve-Pe` rez, Sanchis, and Sanchis 2004; Raspe and Van Oort 2008; Colombelli, Krafft, and Quatraro 2013).18 Consistent with the discussion above, Cefis and Marsili (2006) found convincing evidence of an “innovation premium” in survival time. Using Pavitt’s (1984) taxon- omy, they showed that young firms (less than four years old) in the “science-based” and “specialized supplier” sectors were characterized by significantly higher chances of survival than firms in other sectors. More specifically, Cefis and Marsili (2005) showed that being an innovator enhanced the expected time of survival by 11 percent compared with non-innovator counterparts. However, the impact of innovation on the post-entry performance of newborn firms is strictly related to sectoral differences and ultimately to the differential pat- terns of specialization of countries discussed above. In fact, entrepreneurial dynam- ics in DCs are more likely to occur in sectors that are far from the technological frontier. Therefore, the prevalence of traditional and mature sectors makes these contexts less fertile for innovation-driven entrepreneurship. According to Siqueira and Bruton (2010), high-technology entrepreneurship in emerging economies is subject to greater resource constraints and higher levels of informality than in ad- vanced countries. These two factors are likely to mitigate any possible positive effect of technology investments on firm performance. Moreover, as far as technological change is concerned, a distinction must be made between low-income and middle-income DCs. Middle-income DCs primarily import innovation produced elsewhere in the global economy, whereas low-income DCs are often completely excluded from any innovative process (see Robbins and Gindling 1999; Robbins 2003; Lall 2004; Lee and Vivarelli 2006; Srholec 2011). Finally, the international diffusion of technologies is likely to be grounded in crea- tive rather than passive adoption (Antonelli 2006). Technological congruence, in- stitutional setting and governmental arrangements shape a country’s capacity to absorb knowledge and technologies produced elsewhere (Dosi and Nelson 2013). Social capabilities represent the set of cultural, political, commercial, industrial and financial institutions that create the conditions for catching-up countries to absorb and exploit the technologies developed elsewhere (Abramovitz 1986). For example, a study conducted on Brazil, Russia, India, and China (the so-called BRIC) con- firmed that their institutional specificities play a major role in shaping their rapidly growing economies (da Rocha, Ferreira da Silva, and Carneiro 2012; Kim, Park, and Lee 2013; Gupta et al. 2014). Nevertheless, in most DCs and even in BRIC, the role of R&D-driven new firms and domestic NTBFs19 is extremely limited. Therefore, Quatraro and Vivarelli 289 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 it is not surprising that very few studies attempt to link innovation with entrepre- neurship within a DC context. Santarelli and Tran (2011) studied entrepreneurship in Vietnam using a panel of regional-level data for 61 provinces over the 2000 – 8 period. Among other out- comes, the authors found that an innovative climate ( proxied by the share of tech- nical/R&D personnel in the province) significantly and positively affects the regional net entry rate. As for post-entry performance, in the previously cited study by Goedhuys and Sleuwaegen (2010) on Africa, the innovative capability ( proxied by a dummy for the introduction of new products) was found to increase a firm’s annual employment growth by 2 percent on average. Unemployment Regarding unemployment (or the fear of becoming unemployed), the literature notes two stylized facts: 1) those who start a new business as an escape from unemploy- ment exit to a higher extent than those who enter from paid employment (see Carrasco 1999; Pfeiffer and Reize 2000; for slightly more optimistic evidence, Caliendo and Kritikos 2010); 2) new founders who were formerly unemployed have, on average, lower economic outcomes and a lower propensity to contribute positively to job creation. For instance, Arrighetti and Vivarelli (1999, 936) found that defensive motiva- tions, such as concern about future career developments and the fear of becoming unemployed, were predictors of below-average post-entry evolution. Similarly, Andersson and Wadensjo ¨ (2007), using a large sample of Swedish-born men who were self-employed in the 1999–2002 period and who were wage-earners, unem- ployed or inactive in 1998, showed that those who were previously unemployed had systematically lower incomes compared to those who were previously wage earners. Moreover, they found that income from self-employment declined with the number of days spent in unemployment and that previously unemployed entrepreneurs were significantly more likely to be “solo” entrepreneurs (i.e., to have no employees). With regard to DCs, the literature is extremely scarce.20 However, Wang (2006) found convincing evidence that unemployment fostered start-ups in Taiwan (China) over the 1986–2001 period. In contrast, in the previously cited work by Santarelli and Tran (2011), no significant impact of the unemployment rate on new firm for- mation in Vietnam was found. Alien Minorities A particular driver of new firm formation in DCs is the role played by ethnic minorities in generating above-average rates of entry and better post-entry performance among newborn firms. The basic hypothesis is that alien minorities may have an 290 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 entrepreneurial advantage based on their opportunity to exploit their minority com- munity networks to overcome important hindrances to entrepreneurship, such as regulatory drawbacks, credit constraints, and difficulties accessing available inputs and technologies (Kilby 1983; Biggs and Shah 2006). In addition, from a sociological point of view, an ethnic minority, which is characterized by common traits such as language, culture, and religion, generates trust, social cohesion, and emulation, which are all factors that favor entrepreneurial behavior (Greif 1993; Hobday 1995; Iyer and Schoar 2010). Finally, a minority group may be affected by a feeling of inse- curity and frustration (in comparison with a dominant group), which encourages members to seek economic success and better social status (Elkan 1988).21 Empirical evidence is generally consistent with the hypotheses just discussed. For instance, Ramachandran and Shah (1999), using firm-level data from Kenya, Tanzania, Zambia, and Zimbabwe and after controlling for firm size and age, various personal characteristics of the entrepreneurs, and sector and country differ- ences, found that Asian and European firms start larger and grow faster than do in- digenously owned African firms. Similarly, Hewitt and Wield (1997) show that Asian businesses in the Tanzanian manufacturing sector have better access to sources of technology than do indigenous companies. In the previously cited study by Goedhuys and Sleuwaegen (2000), the consistent finding is that the dummy var- iable “non-African” significantly and positively affects the likelihood of becoming an entrepreneur in Co ˆ te d’Ivoire. When analyzing a randomly selected sample of 296 Ethiopian SMEs, Mengistae (2001) finds that companies owned by the indigenous minority group of the Gurage perform better than average in the country; in partic- ular, new businesses start larger and then grow faster. More recently, Goedhuys and Sleuwaegen (2010) show that the Asian dummy (equal to 1 for entrepreneurs of Lebanese, Indian, Middle Eastern, or other Asian origin) turns out to be positive and significant in affecting firms’ growth in Sub-Saharan Africa. Main Findings and Some Policy Suggestions If one conclusion can be drawn from this study, it is that “entrepreneurship” is per- formed by very different “animals”. From a macroeconomic point of view, progres- sive new firm formation can generate permanent economic growth, whereas defensive and regressive start-ups generate only temporary positive effects and, ulti- mately, market turbulence. From a microeconomic point of view, far from solely being the result of the entrepreneurial “creative destruction” process proposed by Schumpeterian advocates (Schumpeter 1943), any set of entrepreneurial ventures can be seen as a rather heterogeneous aggregate where real and innovative entre- preneurs are found together with passive followers, over-optimistic gamblers and Quatraro and Vivarelli 291 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 even escapees from unemployment. Therefore, both scholars and policy makers should bear some important caveats in mind. First, because founders are heterogeneous and may make entry mistakes, most new firms are doomed to early failure. This type of entry is not conducive to techno- logical renewal and economic growth but simply to an excess of entries, market churning and turbulence. In both developed and developing countries, policy makers should discourage this type of venture. Second, ex ante features may be predictors of survival chances and post-entry business performance. For instance, larger size, previous experience, the absence of credit constraints, higher education, and innovation can be considered positive pre- dictors of a higher likelihood of survival, whereas infrastructural and institutional drawbacks, the absence of an adequate incubator background and a previous state of unemployment can be seen as predictors of early failure. The implementation of policy measures supporting the creation of new firms should consider these factors. Policy makers could, for example, target potentially successful entrepreneurs by shaping eligibility criteria to gain access to specific funds or tax credits. Although this process cannot ensure the success of new ven- tures, it would help minimize the risk of wasting public resources by supporting en- trepreneurs who have low ex ante probabilities of survival (see Santarelli and Vivarelli 2002, 2007; Mason and Brown 2013). In the specific case of DCs, in addi- tion to having a larger start-up size, higher education, longer previous job experi- ence, and innovative capabilities, belonging to an entrepreneurial ethnic minority can be seen as a preferential trait when deciding how to target a policy addressed at sustaining progressive new firm formation. However, on average, DCs appear to be strongly affected by regressive factors that induce “defensive” and “necessity” start-ups, which are often concentrated in the informal sectors and doomed to early failure. In this context, the widespread diffu- sion of general, “erga-omnes” entry subsidies as policy instruments in developing countries is unfortunate22 because they are very likely affected by standard policy failures, such as deadweight and substitution effects (Vivarelli 2012, 2013). Indeed, umbrella subsidies should be discarded in favor of selective and targeted measures addressed at more promising potential entrepreneurs, such as those char- acterized by superior human capital or by interesting and feasible innovative ideas. Examples of targeted policy measures may include 1) public financial aid to inno- vative projects that are otherwise neglected by a conservative and short-run-orient- ed capital market (for instance, the Korean government credit guarantee offered to technology-based SMEs suffering from funding problems; see Sohn and Kim 2013); 2) the already mentioned microcredit support, which is intended to be a way of reducing the information and transaction costs that are so common in DCs and that affect both the screening and the financing of new promising businesses 292 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 (Yunus 1999); and 3) public support for innovative start-ups generated by universi- ty spin-offs (for recent analyses of this perspective, see Bonaccorsi et al. 2013). In DCs, more general market failures and regulatory constraints are obvious and severe, ranging from extreme financial rationing to a lack of property rights and bribing. In this context, any entrepreneurial policy should consider it a priority to remove the market, institutional and informational constraints that prevent poten- tial entrepreneurs from starting a new business (Acs and Virgill 2009). In this respect, tailored subsidies and supports, such as those briefly discussed above, should be coupled with framework and infrastructural policies that are able to improve the business climate where new ventures can find a proper environment to start and grow. In summary, a proper entrepreneurial policy in the DCs should be able to combine a comprehensive macroeconomic approach to release the major institutional con- straints to entrepreneurship with selective microeconomic support for the most prom- ising potential entrepreneurs. Notes Francesco Quatraro is affiliated with GREDEG, CNRS et Universite ´ de Nice Sophia Antipolis, Nice, France, and with BRICK, Collegio Carlo Alberto, Torino. Marco Vivarelli is affiliated with Universita ` Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Milano and Piacenza, Italy, SPRU, University of Sussex, and Institute for the Study of Labour (IZA), Bonn. Correspondence can be addressed to Prof. Marco Vivarelli, Facolta ` di Economia Universita ` Cattolica, Via Emilia Parmense 84, 29122 Piacenza; marco.vivarelli@unicatt.it. 1. The identification of necessity entrepreneurs is a non-trivial task. In the recent literature, the distinction between necessity- and opportunity-driven entrepreneurs is established by using the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) data. The GEM measures ‘necessity-driven’ entrepreneurship by in- cluding the question ‘Are you involved in this start-up [this firm] to take advantage of a business oppor- tunity or because you have no better choices of work?’ (Naude ´ , Amoros, and Cristi 2011). In more general terms, empirical studies single out ‘necessity entrepreneurs’ either as those who come from un- employment status or as those who answer ad-hoc questionnaires revealing that they are pushed into ‘entrepreneurship’ by a concern about future career developments or by the fear of becoming unem- ployed (see also Section 4.6). 2. The authors used a sample of 22 countries (14 European, six Latin American, the US and Canada) and found that the correlation between entry and exit rates across industries in 1990 was positive and significant in the vast majority of cases (Bartelsman, Haltinwanger, and Scarpetta 2004, 21, Table 6). 3. Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page ´ s (2009, 10), using evidence from the World Bank Enterprise Surveys, show that 42 percent of firms declare that they have paid bribes, with an average amount paid of 1.5 percent of sales. 4. Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page ´ s (2009) provide a slightly different picture, showing that the effect of corruption on growth is different across different size classes. In particular, corruption seems to have no effect on medium-sized firms and some negative effects on small firms, whereas it may help micro firms grow. This phenomenon can be explained by the fact that often, very small firms in DCs do not comply with all prescriptions of business regulation, and they stay persistently in the Quatraro and Vivarelli 293 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 informal sector. Paying bribes may therefore be less costly than compliance (see also Vial and Hanoteau 2010). 5. The authors, using data from the World Bank Investment Climate Survey covering 947 manu- facturing SMEs in 11 Sub-Saharan countries, show that firms with their own transport facilities and their own websites exhibit higher growth rates, measured in terms of employment creation. 6. In the conventional approach, entrepreneurship is generally measured as the number of new firms relative to the size of the existing population of businesses in a given industry. In contrast, if the individual ‘push factors’ are fully considered, new firms must be related to the labor force (for further discussion, see Santarelli, Carree, and Verheul 2009; Vivarelli 2007). 7. However, as clarified by the authors, these results, in contrast to previous studies, may be due to the peculiarities of the Italian manufacturing sample used, which is dominated by micro-firms well below the minimum efficient scale. In this context, which is characterized by a limited size variability, the positive impact of a larger scale might have been underestimated. 8. Gibrat (1931), proposed that firm growth is predominantly a random process. This amounts to say that firm growth is independent of firm size. 9. Moreover, recent literature has shown that firms’ age may play a crucial role in shaping the rela- tionship between size and firms’ growth. In particular, Haltiwanger, Jarmin, and Miranda (2013), using data from the Census Bureau’s Business Dynamics Statistics and Longitudinal Business Database, show that once one controls for firm age, the negative relationship between size and growth either disappears or reverses the sign due to the large share of exit among the smallest firms. As far as age is concerned, young firms are found to grow more rapidly than mature ones. From this perspective, start-ups are likely to play a key role in the job creation process. However, Haltiwanger, Jarmin, and Miranda (2013) do not focus on start-ups; most of their firms are established incumbents (for an anal- ysis of the link between age and firm’s performance, see Coad, Segarra, and Teruel 2013). 10. Consistent econometric outcomes in studies devoted to DCs can also be found in the studies by Mead and Liedholm (1998), Gunning and Mengistae (2001), Bigsten and So ¨ derbom (2006), and Coad and Tamvada (2012). 11. For instance, Sørensen and Phillips (2011) argue that work experience in the prior firm shapes both the entrepreneur’s competence and his/her commitment to the entrepreneurial role. However, al- though the competence and information inherited from the mother firm provide an initial advantage, parental influence may generate inertia and resistance to change unless the new company is able to create a unique competitive identity (see Ferriani, Garnsey, and Lorenzoni 2012). 12. A recent article by Frankish et al. (2013) questions the idea that previous work experience affects firms’ performances. They propose that there are good reasons to expect no significant effects of work experience, such as the importance of chance, entrepreneurs’ propensity toward optimism, and the unlikely event that two business situations are identical. They use UK data to show that there is no significant evidence about entrepreneurial learning. It must be noted, however, that such results could, to some extent, be due to the peculiarity of the sample they use due to institutional specificities of the UK business environment. 13. The risk of overstating the hindering role of credit constraints is particularly high in question- naire analyses where nascent or newborn entrepreneurs are asked to list their main difficulties in starting and/or running a new firm. In fact, they have the self-indulgent tendency to indicate a lack of external financial support as the main cause of their problems, whereas in most cases, this is only a symptom of more fundamental deficiencies that are internal to the firm. 14. The authors extracted their firm-level data from the World Bank Investment Climate Survey. 15. Nafziger and Terrell (1996), using evidence from India, found that higher education of the founding entrepreneur reduces firm survival, indicating the importance of outside opportunities in paid wage employment within the formal sector. 16. Ligthelm (2011) found that business management skills are one of the strongest predictors of survival among small informal firms in South Africa. 17. For an updated survey on the vast available micro-evidence on the link between innovation and productivity, see Mohnen and Hall (2013). For a discussion of the key role of innovation and R&D 294 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 in young firms and SMEs in general, see Ortega-Argile ´ s, Vivarelli, and Voigt (2009) and Voigt and Moncada-Paterno ` -Castello (2012). 18. For instance, Arrighetti and Vivarelli (1999), after applying a factor analysis to a sample of 147 Italian spinoffs, found that innovative factors (related both to the innovative motivations of the founder and to his/her previous innovative experience in the mother firm) were significantly correlated with post-entry performance. Their subsequent cluster analysis also revealed that the innovative group was more likely to have better post-entry performance (see also Vivarelli and Audretsch 1998). 19. Rather, R&D-based initiatives in DCs are often the outcome of the outsourcing by US, European, and Japanese multinationals; see Moncada-Paterno ` -Castello, Vivarelli, and Voigt 2011. 20. This is unfortunate because, as discussed above, “defensive and necessity entrepreneurs” appear to make up the bulk of self-employment in DCs, with activities ranging from street vending and small retailing to traditional personal services. 21. This mechanism can work up to a given threshold. Belonging to a socioeconomically excluded group may decrease the likelihood of successfully founding a new firm (this is the case, for instance, for the caste system in India; see Monsen, Mahagaonkar, and Dienes 2012). 22. As correctly noted by Shane (2009, 41), “Policy makers believe a dangerous myth. They think that start-up companies are a magic bullet that will transform depressed economic regions, generate innovation, create jobs. This belief is flawed because the typical start-up is not innovative, creates few jobs, and generates little wealth”. References Abramovitz, M. 1986. “Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind.” The Journal of Economic History 46 (2) : 385– 406. Acs, Z. J., C. Armington, and T. Zhang. 2007. “The Determinants of New-firm Survival across Regional Economies: The Role of Human Capital Stock and Knowledge Spillover.” Papers in Regional Science 86 (3) : 367– 91. Acs, Z. J., and D. B. Audretsch. 1989a. “Small-firm Entry in US Manufacturing.” Economica 56 (222) : 255–65. . 1989b. “Births and Firm Size.” Southern Economic Journal 56 (2) : 467 –75. . 1990. Innovation and Small Firms. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Acs, Z., and N. Virgill. 2009. “Entrepreneurship in the Developing Countries.” Jena Economic Research Paper n. 2009–23. Max Planck Institute of Economics, Jena, Germany. Agarval, R., and D. B. Audretsch. 2001. “Does Entry Size Matter? The Impact of the Life Cycle and Technology on Firm Survival.” Journal of Industrial Economics 49 (1) : 21 – 43. Aghion, P., T. Fally, and S. Scarpetta. 2007. “Credit Constraints as a Barrier to the Entry and Post-entry Growth of Firms.” Economic Policy 22 (52) : 731 –79. Akoten, J. E., Y. Sawada, and K. Otsuka. 2006. “The determinants of credit access and its impacts on micro and small enterprises: The case of garment producers in Kenya.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 54 (4) : 927 –44. Altindag, E., C. Zehir, and A. Z. Acar. 2011. “Strategic Orientations and their Effects on Firm Performance in Turkish Family Owned Firms.” Eurasian Business Review 1 (1) : 18 –36. Alvarez, R., and G. Crespi. 2003. “Determinants of technical efficiency in small firms.” Small Business Economics 20 (3) : 233–44. ´ s, J. E., and O. Cristi. 2008. “Longitudinal analysis of entrepreneurship and competitiveness dy- Amoro namics in Latin America.” International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal 4 (4) : 381–99. Quatraro and Vivarelli 295 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 . 2011. “Poverty, human development and entrepreneurship.” In M. Minniti, ed,) The Dynamics of Entrepreneurship: Theory and Evidence. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Andersson, P ., and E. Wadensjo ¨ . 2007. “Do the Unemployed Become Successful Entrepreneurs?” International Journal of Manpower 28 (7) : 604–26. Antonelli, C. 2006. “Diffusion as a process of creative adoption.” Journal of Technology Transfer 31 (2) : 211 –26. Arauzo-Carod, J. M., and A. Segarra-Blasco. 2005. “The Determinants of Entry are not Independent of Start-up Size: Some Evidence from Spanish Manufacturing.” Review of Industrial Organization 27 (2) : 147– 65. Ardagna, S., and A. M. Lusardi. 2010. “Explaining International Differences in Entrepreneurship: The Role of Individual Characteristics and Regulatory Constraints.” In J. Lerner, and A. Schoar, eds., International Differences in Entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Arrighetti, A., and M. Vivarelli. 1999. “The Role of Innovation in the Postentry Performance of New Small Firms: Evidence from Italy.” Southern Economic Journal 65 (4) : 927 –39. ´ s. 2009. “Big Constraints to Small Firms’ Growth? Aterido, R., M. Hallward-Driemeier, and C. Page Business Environment and Employment Growth Across Firms.” Policy Research Working Paper 5032. World Bank, Policy Research Department, Washington, DC. Audretsch, D. B. 1995. Innovation and Industry Evolution. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Audretsch, D. B., M. C. Keilbach, and E. E. Lehmann. 2006. Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Audretsch, D. B., and T. Mahmood. 1995. “New Firm Survival: New Results Using a Hazard Function.” Review of Economics and Statistics 77 (1) : 97 –103. Audretsch, D. B., E. Santarelli, and M. Vivarelli. 1999a. “Start Up Size and Industrial Dynamics: Some Evidence from Italian Manufacturing.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 17 (7) : 965 –83. . 1999b. “Does Start Up Size Influence the Likelihood of Survival?” In D. Audretsch, and R. Thurik, eds., Innovation, Industry Evolution and Employment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ayyagari, M., A. Demirgu ¨c¸ -Kunt, and V. Maksimovic. 2008. “How Important Are Financing Constraints? The Role of Finance in the Business Environment.” The World Bank Economic Review 22 (3) : 483– 516. Baldwin, J. R., and P. K. Gorecki. 1987. “Plant Creation Versus Plant Acquisition: The Entry Process in Canadian Manufacturing.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 5 (1) : 27– 41. . 1991. “Firm Entry and Exit in the Canadian Manufacturing Sector.” Canadian Journal of Economics 24 (2) : 300 –23. Baldwin, J. R., and M. Rafiquzzaman. 1995. “Selection Versus Evolutionary Adaptation Learning and Post-entry Performance.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 13 (4) : 501–22. Banerjee, A., and E. Duflo. 2004. “Do Firms Want to Borrow More? Testing Credit Constraints Using a Directed Lending Program.” CEPR Discussion Papers n. 4681. CEPR, London. Banerjee, A., E. Duflo, and K. Munshi. 2003. “The (Mis)allocation of Capital.” Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (2-3) : 484 –94. ¸ a. 2010. “Proximity to Knowledge Sources and the Location of Baptista, R., and J. Mendonc Knowledge-based Start-ups.” Annals of Regional Science 45 (1) : 5– 29. Barr, A. M. 1998. “Enterprise performance and the functional diversity of social capital.” Working paper number 65. Centre for the Study of African Economies, University of Oxford. 296 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 Bartelsman, E., J. Haltiwanger, and S. Scarpetta. 2004. “Microeconomic Evidence of Creative Destruction in Industrial and Developing Countries.” Policy Research Working Paper 3464. World Bank, Policy Research Department, Washington, DC. Bartelsman, E., S. Scarpetta, and F. Schivardi. 2005. “Comparative Analysis of Firm Demographics and Survival: Evidence from Micro-level Sources in OECD Countries.” Industrial and Corporate Change 14 (3) : 365–91. Bates, T. 1990. “Entrepreneur Human Capital Inputs and Small Business Longevity.” Review of Economics and Statistics 72 (4) : 551–9. Baumol, W. J. 1990. “Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive and Destructive.” Journal of Political Economy 98 (5) : 893 –921. . 2010. The Microtheory of Innovative Entrepreneurship. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Becchetti, L., and G. Trovato. 2002. “The Determinants of Growth for Small and Medium Sized Firms. The Role of Availability of External Finance.” Small Business Economics 19 (4) : 291–306. Beck, T., A. Demirgu ¸ -Kunt, L. Laeven, and R. Levine. 2008. “Finance, Firm Size and Growth.” Journal ¨c of Money, Credit and Banking 40 (7) : 1379– 405. ¨c Beck, T., A. Demirgu ¸ -Kunt, and V. Maksimovic. 2005. “Financial and Legal Constraints to Growth: Does Firm Size Matter?” Journal of Finance 60 (1) : 131–77. Beesley, M. E., and R. T. Hamilton. 1984. “Small Firms’ Seedbed Role and the Concept of Turbulence.” Journal of Industrial Economics 33 (2) : 217–31. Biggs, T., and M. K. Shah. 2006. “African SMEs, Networks and Manufacturing Performance.” Journal of Banking and Finance 30 (11) : 3043– 66. Bigsten, A., and M. Gebreeyesus. 2007. “The Small, the Young and the Productive: Determinants of Manufacturing Firm Growth in Ethiopia.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 55 : 813–40. Bigsten, A., and M. So ¨ derbom. 2006. “What Have We Learned from a Decade of Manufacturing Enterprise Surveys in Africa.” World Bank Research Observer 21 (2) : 241–65. Bigsten, A., P. Collier, S. Dercon, M. Fafchamps, B. Gauthier, J. W. Gunning, and M. So ¨ derbomet al. 2003. “Credit constraints in manufacturing enterprises in Africa.” Journal of African Economies 12 (1) : 104 –25. Boeri, T., and U. Cramer. 1992. “Employment Growth, Incumbents and Entrants: Evidence from Germany.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 10 (4) : 545 –66. Bonaccorsi, A., M. G. Colombo, M. Guerini, and C. Rossi-Lamastra. 2013. “University Specialization and New Firm Creation across Industries.” Small Business Economics 41 (4) : 837–63. Caliendo, M., and A. Kritikos. 2010. “Start-ups by the Unemployed: Characteristics, Survival and Direct Employment Effects.” Small Business Economics 35 (1) : 71 –92. Calvo, J. L. 2006. “Testing Gibrat’s Law for Small, Young and Innovating Firms.” Small Business Economics 26 (2) : 117–23. Canales, R., and R. Nanda. 2008. “A Darker Side to Decentralized Banks: Market Power and Credit Rationing in SME Lending.” Harvard Business School Working Papers 08-101. Harvard Business School, Cambridge, MA. Carpenter, R. E., and B. C. Petersen. 2002. “Is the Growth of Small Firms Constrained by Internal Finance?” Review of Economics and Statistics 84 (2) : 298–309. Carrasco, R. 1999. “Transitions to and from Self-employment in Spain.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 61 (3) : 315–41. Cefis, E., and O. Marsili. 2005. “A Matter of Life and Death: Innovation and Firm Survival.” Industrial and Corporate Change 14 (6) : 1167–92. . 2006. “Survivor: The Role of Innovation in Firm’s Survival.” Research Policy 35 (5) : 626–41. Quatraro and Vivarelli 297 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 Chlosta, S., H. Patzelt, S. B. Klein, and C. Dormann. 2012. “Parental Role Models and the Decision to Become Self-employed: The Moderating Effect of Personality.” Small Business Economics 38 (1) : 121 –38. Coad, A., and R. Rao. 2008. “Innovation and Firm Growth in High-tech Sectors: A Quantile Regression Approach.” Research Policy 37 (4) : 633–48. Coad, A., A. Segarra, and M. Teurel. 2013. “Like milk or wine: Does firm performance improve with age?” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 24 : 173–89. Coad, A., and J. P. Tamvada. 2012. “Firm Growth and Barriers to Growth among Small Firms in India.” Small Business Economics 39 (2) : 383– 400. Cole, S. 2009. “Fixing Market Failures or Fixing Elections? Agricultural Credit in India.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 1 (1) : 219 –50. Colombelli, A., J. Krafft, and F. Quatraro. 2013. “Properties of knowledge base and firm survival: Evidence from a sample of French manufacturing firms.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 80 (8) : 1469–84. . 2014. “High-growth firms and technological knowledge: Do gazelles follow exploration or ex- ploitation strategies?” Industrial and Corporate Change forthcoming. doi:10.1093/icc/dtt053. Colombo, M. G., M. Delmastro, and L. Grilli. 2004. “Entrepreneurs’ Human Capital and the Start-up Size of New Technology-based Firms.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 22 (8-9) : 1183–211. Colombo, M. G., and L. Grilli. 2010. “On Growth Drivers of High-tech Start-ups: Exploring the Role of Founders’Human Capital and Venture Capital.” Journal of Business Venturing 25 (6) : 610–26. Cooper, A. C., F. J. Gimeno-Gascon, and C. Y. Woo. 1994. “Initial Human Capital and Financial Capital as Predictors of New Venture Performance.” Journal of Business Venturing 9 (5) : 371– 96. Creedy, J., and P. S. Johnson. 1983. “Firm Formation in Manufacturing Industry.” Applied Economics 15 (2) : 177 –85. Cressy, R. 1996. “Are Business Start-ups Debt-rationed?” Economic Journal 106 (438) : 1253–70. . 2000. “Credit Rationing or Entrepreneurial Risk Aversion? An Alternative Explanations for the Evans and Jovanovic Finding.” Economics Letters 66 (2) : 235 –40. da Rocha, A., J. Ferreira da Silva, and J. Carneiro. 2012. “Entrepreneurship: The role of strategy and the institutional environment.” In E. R. Brenes, and J. Haar, eds., The future of entrepreneurship in Latin America. London: Palgrave MacMillan. Das, S. 1995. “Size, Age and Firm Growth in an Infant Industry: The Computer Hardware Industry in India.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 13 (1) : 111–26. Daunfeldt, S., and N. Elert. 2013. “When is Gibrat’s Law a Law?” Small Business Economics 41 (1) : 133 –47. Dejardin, M. 2011. “Linking Net Entry to Regional Economic Growth.” Small Business Economics 36 (4) : 443 –60. Desai, S. 2009. “Measuring Entrepreneurship in Developing Countries.” Research paper, No. 2009.10. United Nations University – World Institute for Development Economics Research, Helsinki, Finland. De Soto, H. 1989. The other path: The invisible revolution in the Third World. New York: Harper and Row. Djankov, S., Y. Qian, G. Roland, and E. Zhuravskaya. 2006a. “Entrepreneurship in China and Russia Compared.” Journal of the European Economic Association 4 (2-3) : 352– 65. . 2006b. “Who Are China’s Entrepreneurs?” American Economic Review 96 (2) : 348–52. . 2007. “What Makes a Successful Entrepreneur? Evidence from Brazil.” Working Paper w0104, Center for Economic and Financial Research, Moscow, Russia. 298 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 Dosi, G., and R. R. Nelson. 2013. “The Evolution of Technologies: An Assessment of the State-of-the- Art.” Eurasian Business Review 3 (1) : 3–46. Dunne, P., and A. Hughes. 1994. “Age, Size, Growth and Survival: UK Companies in the 1980s.” Journal of Industrial Economics 42 (2) : 115–40. Dunne, T., M. J. Roberts, and L. Samuelson. 1989. “The Growth and Failure of US Manufacturing Plants.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (4) : 671–98. Elkan, W. 1988. “Entrepreneurs and Entrepreneurship in Africa.” World Bank Research Observer 3 (2) : 171–88. Ericson, R., and A. Pakes. 1995. “Markov-Perfect Industry Dynamics: a Framework for Empirical Work.” Review of Economic Studies 62 (1) : 53 –82. ´ rez, S., A. Sanchis, and J. A. Sanchis. 2004. “The Determinants of Survival of Spanish Esteve-Pe Manufacturing Firms.” Review of Industrial Organization 25 (3) : 251–73. Evans, D. S. 1987. “The Relationship Between Firm Growth, Size, and Age: Estimates for 100 Manufacturing Industries.” Journal of Industrial Economics 35 (4) : 567–81. Evans, D. S., and L. S. Leighton. 1989. “Some Empirical Aspects of Entrepreneurship.” American Economic Review 79 (3) : 519–35. . 1990. “Small Business Formation by Unemployed and Employed Workers.” Small Business Economics 2 (4) : 319 –30. Fackler, D., C. Schnabel, and J. Wagner. 2013. “Establishment Exits in Germany: The Role of Size and Age.” Small Business Economics 41 (3) : 683–700. Fazzari, S. M., R. G. Hubbard, and B. C. Petersen. 1988. “Financing Constraints and Corporate Investment.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 115 : 695– 713. Ferriani, S., E. Garnsey, and G. Lorenzoni. 2012. “Continuity and Change in a Spin-off Venture: The Process of Reimprinting.” Industrial and Corporate Change 21 (4) : 1011–48. Fisman, R., and J. Svensson. 2007. “ Are Corruption and Taxation Really Harmful to Growth? Firm Level Evidence.” Journal of Development Economics 83 (1) : 63 –75. Fogel, K., K. Lee, and W. McCumber. 2011. “Institutional Impact on the Outreach and Profitability of Microfinance Organizations.” In D. B. Audretsch, O. Falck, S. Heblich, and A. Lederer, eds., Handbook of Research on Innovation and Entrepreneurship. Cheltenham, UK: Elgar. Foti, A., and M. Vivarelli. 1994. “An Econometric Test of the Self-employment Model: The case of Italy.” Small Business Economics 6 (2) : 81 –93. Frankish, J. S., R. G. Roberts, A. Coad, T. C. Spears, and D. J. Storey. 2013. “Do entrepreneurs really learn? Or do they just tell us that they do?” Industrial and Corporate Change 22 (1) : 73 –106. Fritsch, M., and P. Mueller. 2007. “The Persistence of Regional New Business Formation Activity Over Time. Assessing the Potential of Policy Promotion Programs.” Journal of Evolutionary Economics 17 (3) : 299 –315. Geroski, P. A. 1995. “What do We know about Entry?” International Journal of Industrial Organization 13 (4) : 421–40. P. A. Geroski, and J. Schwalbach, eds. 1991. Entry and Market Contestability: An International Comparison. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Ghani, E., W. R. Kerr, and S. D. O’Connell. 2011. “Spatial Determinants of Entrepreneurship in India.” NBER Working Paper 17514. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Gibrat, R. 1931. Les Inegalites Economiques. Paris: Librairie du Recueil Sirey. Gimeno, J., T. Folta, A. Cooper, and C. Woo. 1997. “Survival of the Fittest? Entrepreneurial Human Capital and the Persistence of Underperforming Firms.” Administrative Science Quarterly 42 (4) : 750–83. Quatraro and Vivarelli 299 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 Goedhuys, M., and L. Sleuwaegen. 1999. “Barriers to Growth of Firms in Developing Countries, Evidence from Burundi.” In D. Audretsch, and R. Thurik, eds., Innovation, Industry Evolution and Employment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ˆ te d’Ivoire.” The Journal of . 2000. “Entrepreneurship and Growth of Entrepreneurial Firms in Co Development Studies 36 (3) : 123– 45. . 2010. “High-growth Entrepreneurial Firms in Africa: A Quantile Regression Approach.” Small Business Economics 34 (1) : 31 –51. Gompers, A., A. Kovner, J. Lerner, and D. Scharfstein. 2006. “Skill vs. Luck in Entrepreneurship and Venture Capital: Evidence from Serial Entrepreneurs.” NBER Working Paper 12592. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Greif, A. 1993. “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders’ Coalition.” American Economic Review 83 (3) : 525 –48. Gunning, J. W., and T. Mengistae. 2001. “Determinants of African Manufacturing Investments: The Microeconomic Evidence.” Journal of African Economies 10 (Suppl 2) : 48 –80. Gupta, V. K., C. Guo, M. Canever, Y. R. Yim, G. K Sraw, and M. Liu. 2014. “Institutional environment for entrepreneurship in rapidly emerging major economies: the case of Brazil, China, India, and Korea.” International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal 10 (2) : 367–84. Hall, B. 1987. “The Relationship Between Firm Size and Firm Growth in the US Manufacturing Sector.” Journal of Industrial Economics 35 (4) : 583– 606. Haltiwanger, J., R. S. Jarmin, and J. Miranda. 2013. “Who Creates Jobs? Small versus Large versus Young.” Review of Economics and Statistics 95 (2) : 347 –61. Hamilton, R. T. 1989. “Unemployment and Business Formation Rates: Reconciling Time-series and Cross-section Evidence.” Environment and Planning 21 (2) : 249–55. Hart, P. E., and N. Oulton. 1996. “Growth and Size of Firms.” Economic Journal 106 (438) : 1242–52. Hewitt, T., and D. Wield. 1997. “Tanzanian Networks, Networks in Tanzanian Industrialization.” Science and Public Policy 24 (6) : 395–404. Highfield, R., and R. Smiley. 1987. “New Business Starts and Economic Activity: An Empirical Investigation.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 5 (1) : 51 –66. Hirakawa, O., M. A. Muendler, and J. E. Rauch. 2010. “Employee Spinoffs and Other Entrants: Stylized Facts from Brazil.” International Growth Centre Working Paper 10/0879. London School of Economics, London. Hobday, M. 1995. Innovation in East Asia: The Challenge to Japan. Cheltenham: Elgar. Hopenhayn, H. 1992. “Entry, Exit and Firm Dynamics in Long Run Equilibrium.” Econometrica 60 (5) : 1127–50. Hurst, E., and A. Lusardi. 2004. “Liquidity Constraints, Household Wealth and Entrepreneurship.” Journal of Political Economy 112 (2) : 319–47. Ihrig, J., and K. S. Moe. 2004. “Lurking in the Shadows: The Informal Sector and Government Policy.” Journal of Development Economics 73 (2) : 541– 57. Iyer, R., and A. Schoar. 2010. “Are there Cultural Determinants of Entrepreneurship?” In J. Lerner, and A. Schoar, eds., International Differences in Entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Johnson, P. S. 2005. “Targeting Firm Births and Economic Regeneration in a Lagging Region.” Small Business Economics 24 (5) : 451–64. Jovanovic, B. 1982. “Selection and Evolution of Industry.” Econometrica 50 (3) : 649 –70. Kantis, H., P. Angelli, and V ´rica Latina y la experiencia . M. Koenig. 2004. Desarrollo emprendedor - Ame internacional. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. 300 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 Kerr, W. R., and R. Nanda. 2011. “Financing Constraints and Entrepreneurship.” In D. B. Audretsch, O. Falck, S. Heblich, and A. Lederer, eds., Handbook of Research on Innovation and Entrepreneurship. Cheltenham: Elgar. Kilby, P. 1983. “The Role of Alien Entrepreneurs in Economic Development, an Entrepreneurial Problem.” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 73 (2) : 107–11. Kim, J. Y., T. Y. Park, and K. Lee. 2013. “Catch-up by Indigenous Firms in the Software Industry and the Role of the Government in China: A Sectoral System of Innovation (SSI) Perspective.” Eurasian Business Review 3 (2) : 100– 20. Klapper, L., R. Amit, and M. F. Guille ´ n. 2010. “Entrepreneurship and Firm Formation across Countries.” In J. Lerner, and A. Schoar, eds., International Differences in Entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Klapper, L., and I. Love. 2011. “Entrepreneurship and Development: The Role of Information Asymmetries.” The World Bank Economic Review 25 (3) : 1–8. Klepper, S. 1997. “Industry Life Cycles.” Industrial and Corporate Change 6 (1) : 145–81. Knight, F. H. 1921. Uncertainty and Profit. New York: Houghton Mifflin. Koellinger, P., and A. R. Thurik. 2012. “Entrepreneurship and the Business Cycle.” Review of Economics and Statistics 94 (4) : 1143–56. Kuznets, S. 1930. Secular Movements in Production and Prices. Boston: Houghton Mifflin. Lall, S. 2004. “The Employment Impact of Globalization in Developing Countries.” In E. Lee, and M. Vivarelli, eds., Understanding Globalization, Employment and Poverty Reduction. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Lee, E., and M. Vivarelli. 2006. “The Social Impact of Globalization in Developing Countries.” International Labour Review 145 (3) : 167–84. Lee, S-H., Y. Yamakawa, M. W . Peng, and J. B. Barney. 2011. “How Do Bankruptcy Laws Affect Entrepreneurship Development Around the World?” Journal of Business Venturing 26 (5) : 505 –20. ´ vesque, M., and D. A. Shepherd. 2004. “Entrepreneurs’ Choice of Entry Strategy in Emerging and Le Developed Markets.” Journal of Business Venturing 19 (1) : 29 –54. Lian, Y., M. Sepehri, and M. Foley. 2011. “Corporate Cash Holdings and Financial Crisis: An Empirical Study of Chinese Companies.” Eurasian Business Review 1 (2) : 112 –24. Ligthelm, A. 2011. “Survival Analysis of Small Informal Businesses in South Africa, 2007-2010.” Eurasian Business Review 1 (2) : 160–79. Little, I. M. D., D. Mazumdar, and , JrJ. W . Page. 1987. Small manufacturing enterprises: A comparative analysis of India and other economies. New York: Oxford University Press. Lotti, F., E. Santarelli, and M. Vivarelli. 2003. “Does Gibrat’s Law Hold Among Young, Small Firms?” Journal of Evolutionary Economics 13 (3) : 213 –35. . 2006. “Gibrat’s Law in a Medium-Technology Industry: Empirical Evidence for Italy.” In E. Santarelli, ed., Entrepreneurship, Growth and Innovation: The Dynamics of Firms and Industries. New York: Springer. . 2009. “Defending Gibrat’s Law as a Long-Run Regularity.” Small Business Economics 32 (1) : 31 –44. Lucas, R. E. Jr. 1978. “On the Size Distribution of Business Firms.” Bell Journal of Economics 9 (2) : 508–23. Malchow-Møller, N., B. Schjerning, and A. Sørensen. 2011. “Entrepreneurship, Job Creation and Wage Growth.” Small Business Economics 36 (1) : 15– 32. Maloney, W. 2004. “Informality Revisited.” World Development 32 (7) : 1159– 78. Quatraro and Vivarelli 301 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 Mansfield, E. 1962. “Entry, Gibrat’s Law, Innovation and the Growth of Firms.” American Economic Review 52 (5) : 1023–51. Marshall, A. 1919. Industry and Trade. A Study of industrial technique and business organization; and of their influences on the condition of various classes and nations. London: Macmillan and Co., Ltd. Mason, C., and R. Brown. 2013. “Creating Good Public Policy to Support High-growth Firms.” Small Business Economics 40 (2) : 211–25. Mata, J., P. Portugal, and P. Guimaraes. 1995. “The Survival of New Plants: Start-up Conditions and Post-entry Evolution.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 13 (4) : 459– 82. McPherson, M. A. 1996. “Growth of Micro and small enterprises in Southern Africa.” Journal of Development Economics 48 (2) : 253–77. Mead, D. C., and C. Liedholm. 1998. “The Dynamics of Micro and Small Enterprises in Developing Countries.” World Development 26 (1) : 61 –74. Mengistae, T. 2001. “Indigenous Ethnicity and Entrepreneurial Success in Africa: Some Evidence from Ethiopia.” Policy Research Working Paper 2534. World Bank, Policy Research Department, Washington, DC. Mitra, R., and V . Pingali. 1999. “Analysis of growth stages in small firms: A case study of automobile ancillaries in India.” Journal of Small Business Management 37 (3) : 62 –76. Mohnen, P ., and B. J. Hall. 2013. “Innovation and Productivity: An Update.” Eurasian Business Review 3 (1) : 47 – 65. Moncada-Paterno ` -Castello, P., M. Vivarelli, and P. Voigt. 2011. “Drivers and Impacts in the Globalization of Corporate R&D: An Introduction Based on the European Experience.” Industrial and Corporate Change 20 (2) : 585 –603. Monsen, E., P. Mahagaonkar, and C. Dienes. 2012. “Entrepreneurship in India: The Question of Occupational Transition.” Small Business Economics 39 (2) : 359– 82. Nafziger, E. W., and D. Terrell. 1996. “Entrepreneurial Human Capital and the Long-Run Survival of Firms in India.” World Development 24 (4) : 689 –96. ´, W Naude . A. 2009. “Out With the Sleaze, in With the Ease: Insufficient for Entrepreneurial Development?” Research Paper no. 2009/01. United Nations University – World Institute for Development Economics Research, Helsinki, Finland. . 2010. “Entrepreneurship, Developing Countries, and Development Economics: New Approaches and Insights.” Small Business Economics 34 (1) : 1–12. ´, W Naude ´ s, and O. Cristi. 2011. “‘Surfeiting, The Appetite May Sicken’: Entrepreneurship ., J. E. Amoro and the Happiness of Nations.” Working Paper No. 2011/07. Maastricht School of Management, Maastricht, Netherlands. Nichter, S., and L. Goldmark. 2009. “Small Firm Growth in Developing Countries.” World Development 37 (9) : 1453–64. ´ s, R., M. Vivarelli, and P Ortega-Argile . Voigt. 2009. “R&D in SMEs: A Paradox?” Small Business Economics 33 (1) : 3– 11. Oxenfeldt, A. R. 1943. New Firms and Free Enterprise: Pre-War and Post-War Aspects. Washington, DC: American Council on Public Affairs. Paravisini, D. 2008. “Local Bank Financial Constraints and Firm Access to External Finance.” Journal of Finance 63 (5) : 2161– 93. Parker, S. C. 1997. “The Effects of Risk on Self-employment.” Small Business Economics 9 (6) : 515–22. . 2000. “Saving to Overcome Borrowing Constraints: Implications for Small Business Entry and Exit.” Small Business Economics 15 (3) : 223 –32. 302 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 . 2004. The Economics of Self-Employment and Entrepreneurship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Pavitt, K. 1984. “Sectoral Patterns of Technical Change: Towards a Taxonomy and a Theory.” Research Policy 13 (6) : 343 –73. Pfeiffer, F., and F. Reize. 2000. “Business Start-ups by the Unemployed – An Econometric Analysis Based on Firm Data.” Labour Economics 7 (5) : 629–63. Pisani, M. J., and J. A. Pagan. 2004. “Self-employment in the era of the new economic model in Latin America: A case study from Nicaragua.” Entrepreneurship & Regional Development 16 (4) : 335 –50. Porter, M. 1990. The competitive advantage of nations. New York: The Free Press. Premand, P ., S. Brodmann, R. Almeida, R. Grun, and M. Barouni. 2012. “Entrepreneurship Training and Self-Employment among University Graduates. Evidence from a Randomized Trial In Tunisia.” Policy Research Working Paper 6285. World Bank, Policy Research Department, Washington, DC. Rajan, R. G., and L. Zingales. 1998. “Financial Dependence and Growth.” American Economic Review 88 (3) : 559–86. Ramachandran, V ., and M. K. Shah. 1999. “Minority Entrepreneurs and Firm Performance in Sub- Saharan Africa.” Journal of Development Studies 36 (2) : 71 –87. Raspe, O., and F. G. Oort Van. 2008. “Firm Growth and Localized Knowledge Externalities.” Journal of Regional Analysis and Policy 38 (2) : 100–16. Reid, G. C. 1991. “Staying in Business.” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 9 (4) : 545–56. Reynolds, P . D., M. S. Camp, W. D. Bygrave, E. Autio, and M. Hay. 2001. Global Entrepreneurship Monitor. 2001 Summary Report. London: London Business School and Babson College. Robbins, D. 2003. “The Impact of Trade Liberalization upon Inequality in Developing Countries - A review of Theory and Evidence.” ILO Working Paper n.13. International Labour Organization, Geneva, Switzerland. Robbins, D., and T. H. Gindling. 1999. “Trade Liberalization and the Relative Wages for More-Skilled Workers in Costa Rica.” Review of Development Economics 3 (2) : 140 –54. Santarelli, E., M. Carree, and I. Verheul. 2009. “Unemployment and Firm Entry and Exit: An Update on a Controversial Relationship.” Regional Studies 43 (8) : 1061–73. Santarelli, E., and H. T. Tran. 2011. “Growth of Incumbent Firms and Entrepreneurship in Vietnam.” Working Papers DSE n. 785. Dipartimento Scienze Economiche - Universita’ di Bologna, Bologna, Italy. Santarelli, E., and M. Vivarelli. 2002. “Is Subsidizing Entry an Optimal Policy?” Industrial and Corporate Change 11 (1) : 39 –52. . 2007. “Entrepreneurship and the Process of Firms’ Entry, Survival and Growth.” Industrial and Corporate Change 16 (3) : 455–88. Schumpeter, J. A. 1934. The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. . 1939. Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process. New York: McGraw-Hill. . 1943. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: Harper. Shane, S. 2000. “Prior Knowledge and the Discovery of Entrepreneurial Opportunities.” Organization Science 11 (4) : 448– 69. . 2001. “Technological Opportunities and New Firm Creation.” Management Science 47 (2) : 205–20. . 2009. “Why Encouraging More People To Become Entrepreneurs Is Bad Public Policy.” Small Business Economics 33 (2) : 141 –9. Quatraro and Vivarelli 303 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 Siqueira, A., and G. D. Bruton. 2010. “High-technology entrepreneurship in emerging economies: Firm informality and contextualization of resource-based theory.” IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management 57 (1) : 39 –50. Sleuwaegen, L., and M. Goedhuys. 2002. “Growth of Firms in Developing Countries, Evidence from ˆ te d’Ivoire.” Journal of Development Economics 68 (1) : 117 –35. Co Sohn, S. Y., and Y. S. Kim. 2013. “Behavioral Credit Scoring Model for Technology-based Firms that Considers Uncertain Financial Ratios Obtained from Relationship Banking.” Small Business Economics 41 (4) : 931 –43. Sonobe, T., J. E. Akoten, and K. Otsuka. 2011. “The Growth Process of Informal Enterprises in Sub- Saharan Africa: A Case Study of a Metalworking Cluster in Nairobi.” Small Business Economics 36 (3) : 323 –35. Sørensen, J. B., and D. J. Phillips. 2011. “Competence and Commitment: Employer Size and Entrepreneurial Endurance.” Industrial and Corporate Change 20 (5) : 1277–304. Srholec, M. 2011. “ A Multilevel Analysis of Innovation in Developing Countries.” Industrial and Corporate Change 20 (6) : 1539– 69. Stam, E. 2007. “Why Butterflies Don’t Leave. Locational Behavior of Entrepreneurial Firms.” Economic Geography 83 (1) : 27 –50. Storey, D. J. 1991. “The Birth of New Firms – Does Unemployment Matter? A Review of the Evidence.” Small Business Economics 3 (3) : 167–78. . 1994. Understanding the Small Business Sector. London: Routledge. Sutton, J. 1991. Sunk Costs and Market Structure. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. . 1997. “Gibrat’s Legacy.” Journal of Economic Literature 35 (1) : 40 –59. Tybout, J. R. 2000. “Manufacturing Firms in Developing Countries: How Well Do They Do and Why?” Journal of Economic Literature 38 (1) : 11 – 44. van der Sluis, J., M. van Praag, and W . Vijverberg. 2005. “Entrepreneurship Selection and Performance: A Meta-analysis of the Impact of Education in Developing Economies.” World Bank Economic Review 19 (2) : 225– 61. van Praag, M. C., and P. H. Versloot. 2007. “What Is the Value of Entrepreneurship?, A Review of Recent Research.” Small Business Economics 29 (4) : 351 –82. Vial, V., and J. Hanoteau. 2010. “Corruption, Manufacturing Plant Growth, and the Asian Paradox: Indonesian Evidence.” World Development 38 (5) : 693–705. Vijverberg, W ˆ te d’Ivoire.” World Development 19 . 1991. “Profits from Self-Employment: The Case of Co (6) : 683 –96. Vivarelli, M. 1991. “The Birth of New Enterprises.” Small Business Economics 3 (3) : 215–23. . 2004. “Are All the Potential Entrepreneurs So Good?” Small Business Economics 23 (1) : 41 –9. Vivarelli, M. 2007. Entry and Post-Entry Performance of Newborn Firms. London: Routledge. . 2012. “Drivers of Entrepreneurship and Post-Entry Performance.” Policy Research Working Paper 6245. World Bank, Policy Research Department, Washington, DC. Vivarelli, M. 2013. “Is Entrepreneurship Necessarily Good? Microeconomic Evidence from Developed and Developing Countries.” Industrial and Corporate Change 22 (6) : 1453–95. Vivarelli, M., and D. B. Audretsch. 1998. “The Link between the Entry Decision and Post-entry Performance: Evidence from Italy.” Industrial and Corporate Change 7 (3) : 485 –500. Voigt, P., and P ` -Castello. 2012. “Can Fast Growing R&D-Intensive SMEs Affect the . Moncada-Paterno Economic Structure of the EU Economy? A Projection to the Year 2020.” Eurasian Business Review 2 (2) : 96 – 128. 304 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 30, no. 2 (August 2015) Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017 Wang, S. 2006. “Determinants of New Firm Formation in Taiwan.” Small Business Economics 27 (4-5) : 313–23. Wennekers, S., and A. R. Thurik. 1999. “Linking Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth.” Small Business Economics 13 (1) : 27 – 55. Wennekers, S., A. J. van Stel, A. R. Thurik, and P. D. Reynolds. 2005. “Nascent Entrepreneurship and the Level of Economic Development.” Small Business Economics 24 (3) : 293 –309. Yunus, M. 1999. Banker to the Poor. London: Aurum Press. Zacharakis, A. L., W . D. Bygrave, and D. A. Shepherd. 2000. Global Entrepreneurship Monitor. National Entrepreneurship Assessment: United States of America, 2000 Executive Report. Babson College, Babson Park, MA. Quatraro and Vivarelli 305 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article-abstract/30/2/277/1653524/Drivers-of-Entrepreneurship-and-Post-entry by Sectoral Library Rm MC-C3-220 user on 06 October 2017