WPS7600 Policy Research Working Paper 7600 Taxation, Information, and Withholding Evidence from Costa Rica Anne Brockmeyer Marco Hernandez Macroeconomics and Fiscal Management Global Practice Group March 2016 Policy Research Working Paper 7600 Abstract This paper studies tax withholding on business sales, a widely compliance shows that firms are relatively compliant with used compliance mechanism which is ignored by public third-party information on the extensive, intensive and pay- finance theory. A withholding scheme, whereby the payer ment margin. An event study then shows that coverage by in a transaction collects tax from the payee, is introduced third-party reporting leads to a 20–50 percent increase in in a standard evasion model with third-party reporting. If reported taxable income. Finally, a difference-in-difference the taxpayer can fully reclaim the tax withheld, withhold- and regression discontinuity estimation of a withholding ing is irrelevant to her evasion decision. However, in the rate increase isolates the impact of withholding. A doubling presence of costly reclaim, low salience of enforcement or of the withholding rate leads to a 33 percent increase in extensive margin compliance gaps, withholding can raise sales tax payment among treated firms and an 8 percent tax payment. To show this empirically, the study exploits increase in aggregate sales tax revenue. The mechanisms a ten-year panel of income tax and sales tax records from are reduced misreporting and incomplete reclaim of the 400,000 firms in Costa Rica, and over 20 million third-party tax withheld. The large compliance impact of withholding information and withholding reports. First, an anatomy of rationalizes its widespread use in low compliance contexts. This paper is a product of the Macroeconomics and Fiscal Management Global Practice Group. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted at abrockmeyer@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team Taxation, Information, and Withholding: * Evidence from Costa Rica Anne Brockmeyer, Marco Hernandez The World Bank September 9, 2016 * Corresponding author: Anne Brockmeyer, abrockmeyer@worldbank.org. Marco Hernandez: marcohernan- dez@worldbank.org. This is an update of World Bank Policy Research Working paper 7600 (March 2016). The last version of this paper can found at https://sites.google.com/site/annebrockmeyerworldbank/. We are exceed- ingly grateful to the Ministry of Finance and the General Directory for Taxation of Costa Rica for outstanding collaboration. In particular, we are indebted to Fernando Rodriguez Garro and Carlos Vargas Duran, as well as to Laura Badilla Castro, Lorena Chacon Sanchez, Jenny Delgado Monge, Graciela Garcia Santamaria, Jorge Richard Muñoz Núñez, Mercedes Padilla Delgado, Manuel Enrique Ramos Campos, Karla Salas Corrales, Ronald Solorzano Vega, Giovanni Tencio Pereira and Marvin Zárate Muñoz. We thank François Gérard, Henrik Kleven, Aart Kraay, David McKenzie, Joana Naritomi, Steven Pennings, Eleanor Wilking and conference/seminar participants at LSE STICERD, NTA, PEUK, PacDev, ABCDE, IIPF, Oxford CBT and the World Bank for helpful comments. Juliana Londoño Vélez, Spencer Smith, Corinne Stephenson and Gabriel Tourek provided excellent research assistance. All errors are our own. 1 Introduction Developing economies are characterized by low tax-to-GDP ratios and a dierent mix of tax instru- ments than high income countries (Besley & Persson 2013, Best et al. 2015). Withholding on rms' sales is a tax instrument that is extensively used in developing countries and in low compliance sectors in high income countries (Samanamud 2013, Soos 1990, OECD 2009). 1 In a sample of 118 countries, 66 countries were found to use some form of withholding on rms' sales, and per capita income in these countries was on average 40% lower than the per capita income in countries without withholding. 2 In the typical withholding scheme, the payer in a transaction withholds tax from the payee, remitting the tax to the government as an advance tax payment for the payee. 3 The payer cum withholding agent can be a state agency, nancial institution, or another rm. The widespread use of withholding stands in contrast to the theoretical prediction that with- holding should be irrelevant to evasion. If withholding applies to transactions that are already third-party reported, and the taxpayer can claim full credit for tax withheld, withholding is merely a dierent method of tax collection. It shifts the collection task from the tax authorities to the withholding agent, with no direct relevance for evasion decisions. In a typical withholding scheme, the tax withheld is fully creditable against a taxpayer's income or sales tax liability and can give rise to a cash refund if the amount withheld exceeds the liability. In practice, however, taxpayers incur an administrative cost to make a reclaim and they can reclaim only if they are compliant on the extensive margin. Withholding may also increase the salience of tax enforcement, if the withholding agent regularly informs the taxpayer of the amount of tax withheld. 4 For these reasons, withholding can establish a compliance default, increasing total tax payment. This paper studies the compliance impact of withholding conceptually and empirically. We extend a simple evasion model with third-party reporting based on Allingham & Sandmo (1972), allowing the third party to both report a taxpayer's sale and withhold a share of the transaction amount as advance tax payment for the taxpayer. Third-party reporting puts a lower bound on reported sales. Adding withholding does not aect the taxpayer's evasion decision if she can fully reclaim the tax withheld. If reclaim is costly, however, only a fraction of taxpayers reclaim the tax withheld and an increase in the withholding rate may increase reported taxable income. To test the predictions of our model empirically, we exploit various sources of quasi-experimental 1 This is distinct from withholding on wages, a tax compliance mechanism that is applied almost universally and well understood (Kleven et al. 2011). 2 See Figure I for an analysis of the use of withholding on business sales by country income levels. 3 In some countries, the payee also withholds from the payer, adding tax to the invoice. 4 Note that salience in this context refers to the salience of tax enforcement as perceived by tax paying rms, rather than to the salience of tax rates as perceived by consumers, which has featured prominently in the literature (Chetty et al. 2009, Finkelstein 2009). 2 variation in the income and sales tax system in Costa Rica, and a ten-year panel of administrative tax records. We construct the Costa Rican tax register from the universe of registration and deregistration records since 2006. We match the register with income and sales tax records from the universe of rms, including both self-employed and corporations. We further match these data with over 20 million third-party and withholding records from rms' transaction partners, nancial institutions and state institutions. Our analysis is divided into three parts. In the rst part, we leverage the data to conduct a detailled anatomy of compliance. 5 To our knowledge, this is the rst study to use population- wide third-party and withholding data from a developing country, and to analyze all compliance margins, including the extensive, intensive and payment margin. On the extensive margin, we nd that about 50% of tax-liable rms fail to le their income tax declaration. The vast majority of these non-lers are identied through third-party reports, and thus denitely economically active. However, non-lers are disproportionately small. We estimate that total income tax revenue could be increased by at most 10% if all non-lers were made to le. However, a companion paper by Brockmeyer et al. (2015) shows that the gains from a communication intervention to non-lers are actually orders of magnitude smaller. On the intensive margin, we nd that 14-17% of rms under- report their sales, while 30-50% of them under-utilize their costs compared to third-party reports. The potential revenue gains from perfectly enforcing tax liabilities on third-party reported sales are again approximately 10% of income tax revenue. However, evidence from the impact of desk audits shows that realized revenue gains are orders of magnitude smaller. On the payment margin, we nd that 5-25% of small rms pay their taxes with signicant delay. After accounting for theses delays, however, payment is above 95% of liabilities for both the income tax and the sales tax. We interprete this as evidence that a country like Costa Rica, with relatively high institutional capacity, achieves a satisfactory level of tax compliance on third-party reported margins. Some administrative follow-up interventions on detectable compliance gaps are necessary as deterrence, to maintain the level of compliance, but increasing investments in these administrative interventions is unlikely to yield substantial revenue gains. This does not mean that tax compliance in Costa Rica is near perfect. The Ministry of Finance estimates, based on macro data, that 30% of sales tax liabilities and 70% of corporate income tax liabilities are evaded or avoided (Hacienda 2015). A large part of these liabilities are simply not observable to the government. We thus investigate whether expanding the coverage of third-party information reporting, and of associated withholding mechanisms, holds more promises to increase tax revenues substantially. We turn to analyze the impact of information reporting in the second part. We begin by showing 5 We borrow the term from Kleven et al. (2011) who conduct an anatomy of compliance for wage earners and the self-employed in Denmark. 3 that bunching at the rst bracket threshold in the income tax schedule - a proxy for misreporting 6 - is large and sharp in the full sample, but signicantly smaller among rms covered by information- reporting from other rms. Bunching is even smaller among rms covered by reporting by state institutions or credit/debit card companies, the two reporting mechanisms which are also associated with withholding. We then exploit within-rm changes over time in the coverage by information reporting in an event study. We nd that reported tax liability increases by up to 50% after rms are reported for the rst time by another rm, by 22% after the rst report from a state institution and by 25% after the rst report from a credit/debit card company. These eects emerge suddenly at event time and can thus not be reconciled with a pure growth eect. Finally, we isolate the impact of withholding by exploiting a quasi-experimental increase in the withholding rate applied by credit/debit card companies to rms' card sales. As all card sales were already reported to the tax authorities and credit card usage hardly responds to the reform, this rate change did not aect the information environment. Applying a dierence-in-dierence estimation, we nd that a doubling of the withholding rate leads to a 33% increase in sales tax payment among taxpayers subject to withholding. In aggregate, the withholding rate reform increased sales tax payments by about 8%. 7 This eect is driven by incomplete reclaim of the tax withheld, and an increase in reported taxable income among rms subject to withholding. We argue that this reporting response is due to a salience of enforcement eect. Indeed, the response is driven by rms for whom the withholding rate changes from zero to a positive rate (as opposed to rms experiencing a similarly-sized change from a positive to a larger rate), and which are thus informed of the amount of tax withheld for the rst time on their credit/debit card machine statement. We also conrm that only a tiny fraction of taxpayers reclaim the tax withheld through other channels, for instance by requesting a cash refund. Our paper contributes to several strands of literature. First, our work contributes to the litera- ture on taxation and development, as reviewed in Besley & Persson 2013. Theoretical contributions in this literature have discussed why tax systems in developing countries dier from those in high income countries (Keen 2008, Gordon & Li 2009, Best et al. 2015). Our results rationalize the preva- lence of withholding schemes for rms as an enforcement tool in low compliance environments. Our results are also consistent with Kopczuk et al. (2016) and Slemrod (2008) who argue that the tax remittance arrangement aects compliance, an argument for which we propose a new mechanism. More generally, our evidence highlights the important role of rms in enforcing taxes (here as infor- 6 Previous studies have shown that bunching is largely driven by misreporting rather than real responses (e.g. Best et al. 2015 for the mininum tax kink in Pakistan, Almunia & Rodriguez 2015 for an enforcement notch in the Spanish corporation tax). 7 Overall, withholding agents collected 10% of corporate income tax revenue and 20% of sales tax revenue in 2014. 4 mation reporting and withholding agents), as suggested theoretically by Kopczuk & Slemrod (2006) and Kleven et al. (2016), and demonstrated empirically by Best (2014) in the context of employer reporting on employees' earnings. In addition, our results contribute to the empirical literature on third-party reporting and compliance. Consistent with Naritomi 2015 and Pomeranz 2015, we show that expanding the coverage of information reporting increases reported taxable income substan- tially. We can also reconcile these ndings with Carrillo et al. 2016 and Slemrod et al. 2015, who provide evidence of evasion shifting to the cost margin. Indeed, our analysis suggests that most rms are responsive to the presence of third-party reporting when they are aware of such reporting ex ante, but the remaining misreporters are not responsive to requests to correct their reports ex post. Put dierently, most rms voluntarily comply on third-party reported margins, but enforcing compliance among the remaining non-compliers is dicult. Second, our study extends the literatures on tax withholding and the impact of defaults. A large literature has analyzed withholding for the personal income tax, focusing mostly on the United States (Barr & Dokko 2008, Gandhi & Kuehlwein 2014, White et al. 1993, Highll et al. 1998). Aside from descriptive policy reports (Samanamud 2013, OECD 2009) and legal writing (Soos 1990), the only study analyzing withholding on rms is Carillo et al. (2012). They show that rms bunch at a withholding rate kink, and interpret this as evidence for a (perceived) discontinuity in the audit function. Our paper is the rst to quantify the tax revenue impact of withholding for rms, and identify the impact mechanisms. By showing that witholding establishes a compliance default, we contribute to the behavioral literature on defaults, which shows that defaults increase organ donation (Johnson & Goldstein 2003) and retirement savings (Chetty et al. 2014, Thaler & Benartzi 2004, Madrian & Shea 2001). We show that a default can also be used to induce people into a behavior such as tax compliance that even rational agents may not display. Finally, we draw on methodological contributions from two literatures. We follow the lead of Fisman & Wei (2004) in identifying misreporting by comparing two data reports on the same tax base. This approach is also used in Zucman (2013), Kumler et al. (2015), Best (2014) and Rijkers et al. (2015). Using the approach, we show that rms under-report sales as well as costs, consistent with Carrillo et al. (2016). We also construct novel estimates of compliance gaps on the extensive and payment margin. Shedding light on payment delays, we highlight the importance of analyzing payment data in addition to tax liability data, which previous studies have focused on. We also draw on the bunching literature in public nance, initiated by Saez (2010), Chetty et al. (2011) and Kleven & Waseem (2013), and summarized in Kleven (2016). This literature provides the techniques to estimate taxpayers' behavioral responses to discontinuities in the tax schedule, and translate them into income elasticities. 5 The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. We start by describing a simple conceptual framework in Section 2. Section 3 presents the Costa Rican tax system and administrative data. Sections 4, 5 and 5 present the anatomy of compliance, the impact of information reporting and the impact of withholding. Section 7 concludes. 2 Conceptual Framework This section presents a simple conceptual framework to analyze behavioral responses to withhold- ing. The framework is based on the canonical tax evasion model by Allingham & Sandmo (1972), extended by Kleven et al. (2011) and Carrillo et al. (2016) to include third-party reporting for individuals and rms respectively. We rst present the basic setup of the model, then introduce withholding with full reclaim and with costly reclaim, and nally consider salience eects. 2.1 A Tax Evasion Model with Third-Party Reporting The basic setup of our model follows Carrillo et al. (2016). Firms have revenue R = RT + RS , where revenue can be either third-party reported or self-reported, indexed by T and S, and rms declare ˆ R. Firms have costs C = Cs , which we assume for simplicity to be fully self-reported, and rms chose to report ˆ C. The government levies tax at rate τ on declared prots ˆ =R π ˆ−C ˆ. The tax liability is ˆ. T = τπ With probability p, rms are audited, in which case any evasion is certain to be detected, and evaders pay a ne θ which is proportional to the evaded liability. Firms maximize expected utility 8 over after-tax income in the audited and non-audited state of the world, YA and YN : EU = (1 − p)U (YN ) + pU (YA ) ˆ ) + pU (π − τ π − θτ (π − π = (1 − p)U (π − τ π ˆ )). To take into account the tax authorities' use of risk scores to target audits (or enforcement interventions in general), we further follow Carrillo et al. (2016) by assuming that the audit proba- bility is decreasing in the reported prot rate, p = p((ˆ ˆ) π + )/R with p < 0. Mis-reporting against third-party information leads to certain detection: ˆ < R T .9 p = 1 if R With these assumption, rms choose to report ˆ ∗ ≥ RT , R and choose ˆ∗ ≷ C C to satisfy the rst-order condition. 8 As Carrillo et al. (2016), we consider that modeling rms in a developing country context as risk-averse is reasonable, since more than half of the rms in our sample are unincorporated, and most rms are vulnerable to income volatility. 9 The inclusion of , a small positive number, ensures that rms declaring zero prots on a large revenue base incur a higher audit probability than rms declaring zero prots on a small revenue base, thus dierentiating the two corner cases where ˆ = 0. π Assuming p=1 instead of the more realistic specication p=p ¯ = max(p) if ˆ < RT R simplies the exposure, but results are similar in the latter case. 6 To ensure that the government always prefers less evasion, i.e. ˆ>0 ∂R/∂ π , we assume that θ and p are small, which are reasonable assumptions in most countries. As is also standard in the literature, we assume that the second-order condition is met and avoid non-concavities by imposing p ≥ 0. 2.2 Withholding with Full Reclaim We introduce withholding into the model by assuming that tax is witheld at a rate µ on third-party reported revenue RT . The information reporting agent thus also becomes the withholding agent. As rms are already chosing to report revenue larger than or equal to third-party reported revenue, the introduction of withholding leaves the information environment unchanged. In a rst step, we assume that the tax withheld can be fully reclaimed, as is technically the case in most withholding systems. This means that rms' net tax liability and hence payment is P = T − µRT , where the tax withheld is deducted from the gross tax liability. There are no restrictions on the sign of P, P ≷ 0, so that rms can request a refund if the reported tax liability is smaller than the tax withheld. In this model, rms' after-tax income in the audited and non-audited state of the world are ¯N = π − µRT − [τ π Y ˆ − µRT ] = π − τ π ˆ = YN , ¯A = π − µRT − [τ π − µRT ] − θ[(τ π − µRT ) − (τ π Y ˆ − µRT )] = π − τ π − θτ (π − π ˆ ) = YA . After-tax income in both states is exactly equal to after-tax income in the model without with- holding. Withholding is thus irrelevant to rms' evasion decisions. This trivial result obviously relies on the assumption of full and costless reclaim, which we relax in the next section. It is also obvious that withholding would mechanically increase tax payment in the case of compliance gaps on the extensive margin or payment margin. 2.3 Withholding with Costly Reclaim To bring the model closer to reality, we assume that rms pay a rm-specic xed cost fi , distributed according to the cumulative distribution function H (f ), to reclaim the tax withheld µRT .10 This xed cost can represent the cost of collecting withholding receipts for each transaction and adding up the amounts when preparing the tax return. 11 The presence of the xed cost generates a cut-o ¯ < µRT f such that rms with ¯ do not reclaim.12 ¯ reclaim the tax withheld and rms with fi ≥ f fi < f 10 We are also currently extending the model to allow the salience of tax enforcement (information reporting) to vary with the withholding rate. 11 It can also capture, albeit in a crude way, the monetary cost of an increase in the monitoring or audit probability that rms may face when reclaiming tax withheld. The latter mechanism could also be modeled more explicitely as a discontinuous increase in the audit probability p for reclaimers, e.g. p=1 for rms reclaiming ˆ, µRT > τ π which would generate bunching at the threshold where the reported tax liability equals the tax withheld, for suciently risk averse rms, as show in Carillo et al. (2012). 12 ¯ = µRT , Note that the f as taxpayers also consider the audited state, in which non-reclaimers get the tax that withheld accredited against their liability, without having made a reclaim. 7 A rst testable prediction of the model is thus that reclaim of the tax withheld is incomplete, ¯) < 1, H (f and that the share of reclaimers increases in the withholding rate, ¯)/∂µ > 0. ∂H (f Comparative Statics for Firms Absent any behavioral response, reclaimers experience a de- crease in their after-tax income of fi < µRT in both the audited and non-audited state, and non-reclaimers experience a decrease of their after-tax income of µRT in the non-audited state only. In the case of an audit, the tax withheld is recredited by the tax authorities against any outstanding liability and nes. Taxpayers adjust their reporting behavior in response to the decrease in after- tax income. Under decreasing absolute risk aversion, as in Allingham & Sandmo (1972), one can show that reclaimers declare π ˆR and non-reclaimers declare π ˆN R with ˆR >π π ˆ∗ > π ˆN R , where ˆ∗ π is the taxpayers' optimum in the baseline model without withholding. Intuitively, the decrease in after-tax income hurts reclaimers more in the audited state, and thus induces them to become more compliant. This simultaneously reduces the likelihood of detection and increases after-tax income in the case of detection. The opposite is true for non-reclaimers. 13 It is trivial to see that ˆR /∂f > 0 ∂π for reclaimers, with µ being irrelevant, and ˆN R /∂µ < 0 ∂π for non-reclaimers. However, an increase in the withholding rate also pushes some non-reclaimers to become reclaimers. The impact of a withholding rate increase on total reported prots is thus ambiguous. Comparative Statics for the Government Government revenue G is equal to total tax pay- ment by all rms. Assume a continuum of rms of measure 1 with xed costs distributed according to H (f ). Then government revenue is the weighted average of revenue across the audited and non- audited state of the world, where in each state, a fraction ¯) H (f of rms are reclaimers who pay exactly the declared (or true) tax liability and the remaining fraction ¯)) (1 − H (f of rms are non- reclaimers from whom the government collects the reported tax liability plus the tax withheld in the non-audited state, and the true tax liability in the audited state: ¯)[τ π G = (1 − p) H (f ¯))[τ π ˆR ] + (1 − H (f ˆN R + µRT ] ¯)θτ (π − π +p τ π + H (f ¯))[θτ (π − π ˆR ) + (1 − H (f ˆN R )] . On the one hand, a higher withholding rate pushes a larger share of rms to become reclaimers, who report higher prots and accordingly pay a higher liability. On the other hand, non-reclaimers reduce their reported prots, but by less than the amount of tax withheld, and thus pay more tax 13 As has been shown in the referenced papers, ˆ π also increases in p, θ and RT . 8 than they otherwise would. Assuming that p and/or θ is small, a withholding rate increase raises total tax revenue. 2.4 Withholding and Salience of Enforcement If taxpayers are not fully aware of third-party reporting about them (i.e. misperceive RT ), the withholding system may aect their behavior through a salience channel. Third-party reporting mechanisms usually require information reports to be submitted by the reporting agent to the tax authorities, but not necessarily to the taxpayer. Withholding mechanism, however, normally require the withholding agent to inform both the tax authorities and the taxpayer about the amount of tax withheld, so as to enable the taxpayer to make a reclaim. 14 For taxpayers unaware of third-party reporting, the introduction of withholding thus raises (their perception of ) third-party reported sales from 0 to RT and moves reported prots from ˆ ∗ (0) π to ˆ ∗ (RT ) π with ˆ ∗ (RT ) > π π ˆ ∗ (0) if p = 0. Furthermore, the introduction of withholding and the associated communication of the amount of tax withheld to the taxpayer by the withholding agent may increase the salience of tax enforcement in general, captured by the audit probability p in our simple framework. For instance, taxpayers may react to a perceived audit probability ˜ which p is a function of the number of times they have witnessed tax enforcement in practice (e.g. have observed an audit or received a communication from the tax authorities). Being confronted with the tax withholding mechanism (another form of enforcement) may then lead taxpayers to revise p ˆ .15 ˜ upwards and increase π We proceed to estimate the impact of third-party reporting and withholding empirically using policy variation in Costa Rica. 3 Context and Data Costa Rica's tax system relies predominantly on the income tax for rms and the sales tax. Firms in Costa Rica register either as persona física (unincorporated rm, i.e. self-employed individuals) or as persona jurídica (corporation), using the D140 registration form. There are no size thresholds or other requirements obliging rms to chose one rm type or the other, but the governance structure and income tax schedule for the two rm types dier. 16 This section presents rst the income and sales tax system in Costa Rica, and then the compliance mechanisms used to enforce taxes, and nally the administrative data used in this study. 14 See Figure XII for an illustration of the type of information provided by card processing companies in Costa Rica to aliated businesses. 15 Note however that a model as in Finkelstein (2009), in which salience merely increases the link between the perceived and actual tax rate, but without moving the misperception in a particular direction, a change in salience has an ambigious eect on taxpayer behavior. 16 Wage earners are taxed according to yet another tax schedule, which features three tax brackets with marginal rates of 0, 10 and 15% respectively. The highest kink for wage earners is below the lowest kink for the self-employed. 9 3.1 Income Tax For all rms, income tax is levied on taxable prots, and led annually by December 15, with three quarterly advance payments made in March, June and September. 17 The self-employed face a kinked tax schedule on prots, with ve tax brackets. As Table I shows, the location of all the kinks is adjusted annually for expected ination. The new kink locations are announced by decree each year in the early fall, before the begining of the new scal year. The marginal tax rates which apply to incomes in the ve brackets are 0, 10, 15, 20 and 25% respectively. These rates do not change over the period 2006-2014. The rst kink is the largest kink, representing a 10-percentage-point jump in the marginal tax rate, and the most salient one, as crossing the kink generates a payment obligations. Chetty et al. (2011) suggest that larger kinks generate stronger bunching, as the size of the tax incentive allows some taxpayers to overcome optimization frictions that would otherwise prevent them from bunching. Corporations face a notched tax schedule on revenue, with three tax brackets and no exempt amount. 18 A rm's revenue determines its average tax rate, which is then applied to prots. The notch locations are again ination-adjusted annually, and the average tax rates of 10, 20 and 30% have not changed during the period we study. Note that the annual adjustment of kink and notch locations generates 54 dierent thresholds over 2006-2014. Out of these, only two are at a round number (kink 1 in 2011, and kink 2 in 2009). This means that persistent bunching at the thresholds cannot be driven by round-number bunching. 19 3.2 Sales Tax Costa Rica does not have a fully-edged VAT, but levies a sales tax which rms need to declare monthly by the tenth working day of the following month. The base for the sales tax is the sale of goods and certain specied services, which includes for example hotels, tailors, and orists, but excludes most professional services, for instance those provided by lawyers and doctors. The standard rate has been constant at 13% for the entire period of our study, and reduced rates of 10% and 5% respectively are levied on wood and residential electricity. Sales tax paid on inputs can be claimed as credit, which makes the sales tax eectively a VAT with a narrow base. Any 17 Fiscal year t in Costa Rica starts on October 1 in year t−1 and ends on September 30 in year t. Taxpayers can request to pay taxes according to a dierent scal period, which we take into account in our analysis. The quarterly advance payment is a quarter of either the previous year's tax liability, or the average liability over the last three years, whichever is higher. 18 Corporations also claim a dierent set of deductions than unincorproated rms. 19 Retailers in certain sectors and below certain size thresholds (annual purchases less than 150 base salaries, xed assets less than 350 base salaries, less than six employees) can opt into a simplied regime. In this regime, tax is levied on input at sector-specic rates that vary from 3% to 9.8%. Firms in this regime declare and present quarterly, and can claim credit for withholding by state institutions for the income tax, but not for withholding by credit card institutions for the sales tax. Firms can opt out of the regime by submitting a D140 modication form. For details, see United Nations (2014). 10 sales taxpayer is liable for the income tax, but the reverse is not necessarily true. In our sample, approximately 15% of income tax compliant rms also le sales tax. 3.3 Compliance Mechanisms To enhance tax compliance among rms, the tax authorities in Costa Rica make use of third-party information and tax withholding from dierent sources. The relevant informative declarations, submitted by public or private sector agents about the economic activities of tax-liable rms and individuals, are listed in Table III. An informant submits one informative declaration for each customer/provider, specifying the tax identication number of the informant and the taxpayer, the transaction amount, the tax withheld if applicable, and the income/transaction type. All information reporting and withholding mechanisms apply in the same way to the self-employed and corporations. Unlike in the United States, taxpayers are not provided with the informative declarations at the time they le their declaration, and are not notied about the existence of an informative record. However, given the structure of reporting requirements explained below, the tax authorities expect rms to be aware of any third-party records about them. 20 The authorities use all informative declarations, combined with customs declarations D166 and D167 on imports and exports, to automatically cross-check all income tax declarations. Taxpayers with strong discrepancies between the third-party information and the self-assessment declaration are then selected for intensive margin controls or audits. 3.3.1 Information Reporting Declarations D151 and D158 are pure reporting declarations, not involving any withholding. Dec- laration D151 must be led by all rms conducting purchases or sales above a certain threshold. Purchases and sales must be reported if the accumulated annual amount of transactions with a single transaction partner reaches  2.5 mio. The payment of rent, commissions, professional ser- vice fees or interests must be reported if the annual transaction amount with a single transaction partner reaches  50,000. These transactions must be reported by both the seller and the purchaser. Declaration D158 must be led by the organizers of agricultural auctions, and covers all sales and purchases at the auction. Each transactions must be reported only once, either by the seller or the buyer. 20 In the rare case that a taxpayer inquires with the tax authorities about the information held about her economic activities, the authorities are legally obliged to provide the information to the taxpayer. 11 3.3.2 Withholding System Declarations D150 and D153 are led by withholding agents, and are accompanied by remittance of the tax withheld to the tax authorities. Declaration D150 is led by state institutions making purchases from rms, and by rms purchasing certain specied services (e.g. transport, communica- tions) from non-resident rms. State institutions withhold tax at a rate of 2% on all purchases, and rms withhold at a rate of 3% on the specied purchases. This withholding applies to the income tax only. Declaration D153 is led for the purpose of sales tax withholding by companies processing credit/debit card payments. The companies report all sales that their sales-tax-liable customers conduct through card transactions. On this base, they withhold sales tax at a rm-specic rate varying between 0 and 6% of the transaction value. The sales tax withholding rate schedule is displayed in Table II. Prior to August 2011, the withholding rate was determined by a notched schedule on value-added. Value-added is dened as the ratio of taxed sales over taxed purchases and imports reported on the sales tax declaration. The notches are located at 5, 20, 30, 40, 55, and 75% of value-added. All notches are associated with a one percentage point increase in the withholding rate. Prior to August 2011, 40.3% of rms subject to D153 reporting beneted from the zero-withholding rate, and only 21.8% were subject to the 6% rate. To increase the extent of withholding, a reform announced by decree in July 2011 and eective since August 2011 consolidated the withholding rate schedule to three rates of 0, 3 and 6% and changed the rate determination. The rates are now based on the share of local sales in total sales, with notches at 0 and 50%. Since the reform, 68.7% of D153-covered rms are subject to a withholding rate of 6%. For the entire period of our study, withholding rates are determined each semester t with ref- erence to the value-added/share of local sales in semester t − 2. The tax authorities determine the withholding rate based on rms' tax returns, using sector averages for rms with no tax history, and communicate the withholding rate to the withholding agent. In special circumstances, rms can request the tax authorities to change the withholding rate before the end of the semester. In this case, the realized withholding rate may dier from the rate predicted by value-added or share of local sales in semester t − 2. The taxpayer whose tax payment has been (partially) withheld can deduct the corresponding amount on the relevant tax declaration (income or sales tax) for the same scal period (henceforth called reclaim), or in future scal periods (through the tax return box compensation request). If the taxpayer has a tax liability of zero in three consecutive months, and can thus not make 12 use of these deduction options, the taxpayer can make a refund request through form 402. This form requires detailled information on the withholding agent, amount of tax withheld and timing of withholding, and asks the taxpayer to certify that she has no outstanding liabilities in any other tax. 3.4 Data Our analysis combines anonymized tax return data and third-party and withholding declarations from the General Directory for Taxation in Costa Rica. The tax return data contains the universe of income tax declarations (D101) for 2006-2014 and sales tax declarations (D104) for 2008-2014, as well as the corresponding payment returns (D110) for the income and sales tax. Since 2006, all tax returns have been digitzed, and electronic ling has gradually been introduced for the dierent declarations, ensuring that the data have nearly complete coverage and a high degree of acurracy. The ling software EDDI-7 conducts automatic validation checks to ensure the internal consistency of led returns. The data contain all line items of the tax return, including rm type and sector, income sources, cost items, deductions, gross and net liability and payment.The nal data set contains 112,000 to 250,000 self-employed per year, 90,000 to 150,000 corporations and 58,000 to 70,000 sales tax lers per month. 21 We merge the tax records with the informative declarations D150, D151, D153 and D158, also for the period 2006-2014. These data have been led eletronically through the DECLAR@7 system, which conducts similar validation checks as EDDI-7. Table III provides an overview of the number of records and their coverage for each of the informative declarations. Declaration D151 registers both the largest number of observations, and the widest coverage, being available for approximately half of all rms. The coverage is similar for the self-employed and corporations. The ling of informative declarations is more concentrated than the coverage, meaning that an even small share of rms act as informants (results available upon request). Note that information reporters are slightly more likely to report their own costs rather than their own sales, as evidence by the fact that 54.3% of the D151 records represent sales records. Declaration D158 is similar to D151 in that sense, but has much lower coverage, given the specic nature of the transactions it covers (agricultural auctions). In our analysis, we thus use the sum of third-party information on sales/costs from D151 and D158. We henceforth refer to these reports as information reports by other rms or D151 reports. Withholding by state institutions and nancial institutions, as reported in D150 and D153, has a 21 Only the tax records for 2012-2014, and a small share of records for 2010 and 2011 have rm type indicators (self- employed or corporation). During this period, we observe only a handful of rms switching rm type. We therefore use the 2010-2014 tax return data and the tax register to assign a rm type to the tax returns for 2006-2011. We drop returns for which we cannot determine the rm type with this strategy. 13 much lower coverage among rms than pure information reporting, especially for the self-employed. D150 and D153 records are available for only 5.0% and 5.8% of the self-employed and 8.4% and 11.% of corporations respectively. 22 98.5% of D150 records are submitted by state institutions, mean- ing that withholding by private non-nancial rms is minimal. A signicant share of informative declarations cannot be matched with income tax records, suggesting that a large number of rms covered by third-party information or withholding are incompliant on the extensive margin. In addition to the tax returns and informative declarations, we use the D140 and D141 regis- tration and deregistration records for 2006-2014 to construct snapshots of the tax register for each scal period. Firms use the D140 form both for registration purposes, as well as for modication and deregistration. If the government deregisters a rm de ocio, which happens if a rm has not led taxes for at least three years, a D141 form is used. 4 Anatomy of Compliance This section presents the anatomy of tax compliance in Costa Rica, identifying mis-reporting through discrepancies between two data reports on the same tax base, as applied by Fisman & Wei (2004). We start with the extensive margin, estimating the share of non-lers by matching tax declarations led to the set of tax liable rms as constructed from the tax register and available third-party reports. We then consider the intensive margin, estimating misreporting by comparing third-party reported and self-reported sales and costs. Finally, we estimate compliance with the payment obligation, comparing tax returns with payment receipts. We compare compliance by the self-employed and by corporations, as the two groups face dierent tax schedules and the self- employed have been identied in the literature as a particularly evasion-prone segment of taxpayers. 4.1 Extensive Margin Compliance To examine compliance on the extensive margin, we construct the set of tax liable rms and compare it to the self-assessment declarations led for the income tax and the sales tax. A rm is considered income tax liable for scal year t if it fullls at least one of the following conditions: (i) the rm is in the tax register in year t, (ii) has led income tax in t, (iii) is covered by at least one third-party informative declaration in t,23 (iv) has led income tax in t−1 and has not deregistered since, or (v) has registered in the last year and has not deregistered since. For the sales tax, we consider only rms that have either (i) led sales tax between month m and m − 4, (ii) registered as liable for the 22 As indicated by the percentages in squared brackets in Table III, the coverage of D153 declarations among sales-tax-liable rms is higher, since they constitute only a small subsample of income taxpayers. 23 We exclude information from D151 cost reports, which could pertain to wage-earning individuals who purchased goods from a rm. 14 sales tax in the last four months and have not changed their registration status since, or (iii) are subject to withholding by credit/debit card providers for the purpose of sales tax compliance. 24 Table IV reports the share of non-lers for dierent taxes and subsamples. The overall share of non-lers for the income tax is substantial in all years, having increased from 38% to 55% of tax liable rms from 2010 to 2013 (panel A, column 1). It seems that non-ling for the sales tax is less prevalent, with a non-ling share of about 20%, which is consistent with the self-enforcing nature of the VAT. However, the fact that only a subsample of income taxpayers are liable for the sales tax lowers our estimates. Non-lers that are identied only through third-party reports, and are not subjet to withholding, need to be dropped from the pool as it is not possible to determine whether they are sales tax liable. The majority of sales tax non-lers are thus registered rms which le only intermittently. In contrast, the majority of income tax non-lers are identied through third-party information (column 2). This suggests that, though third-party information helps to identify taxable activities, it does not necessarily induce the reportees to comply with their tax ling obligations. An analysis of ling behavior across rm types shows that non-ling rates are generally lower for registered rms (panel B, column 1), and lower for registered corporations than for registered self-employed (columns 2 and 4). 25 Besides, there is a positive correlation between coverage by information reporting and ling, as theory would predict (columns 3 and 5). This correlation is stronger for corporations, where non-ling rates fall from around 7% for all corporations to 3.5% for corporations covered by third-party information. Distinguishing dierent sources of third-party information, panel C shows that rms reported by state institutions or credit/debit card companies display signicantly lower non-ling rates than rms reported only by their suppliers or clients. This suggests that reporting mechanisms which are accompanied by withholding may have a stronger compliance impact. The estimated share of undeclared sales represents 16-23% of declared sales, and the estimated share of unreported liabilities represents 7-10% of reported liabilities for the income tax (panel A, columns 4 and 5). The estimates rely on non-lers' third-party reported sales or their most recent available tax return, the assumption that the distribution of prots rates by rms size is similar for non-lers and lers and that the tax schedule is applied as per the law (see the notes to Table IV 24 This algorithm is described in more detail in appendix section 8.1. Note that our algorithm is more conservative than the tax authorities' own algorithm, which consider rms that led in the past three years and have not deregis- tered since as tax liable. We report estimates using a more lenient algorithm (going back three years for the income tax and 12 months for the sales tax) in appendix table VIII. The estimates are marginallly higher for the income tax, and about one third higher for the sales tax. The three-year window reects the tax authorities' practice of deregistering a rm de ocio if it has not led for three years. According to the codigo de normas y procedimientos tributarios, the period until a taxpayer gets deregistered de ocio is three years until September 2012 (when the relevant article was amended), and four years from then on. 25 Note that column 1 in panel B is not the average of columns 2 and 4, as column 1 also includes rms for which the rm type indicator, identifying self-employed and corporations, is missing. 15 for details). The numbers suggest that even if the tax authorities were able to perfectly enforce the tax ling obligation at no cost, income tax revenue would increase by 10% at most. Given the incomplete nature of the third-party information trail, these estimates are a weak lower bound of extensive margin compliance gaps. Our algorithm does not capture rms that are fully informal and do not transact with any withholding or information reporting agents. However, we consider that our estimates capture the policy-relevant subsample of extensive margin non-compliers. Indeed, while several studies nd that formalizing fully informal rms is dicult and costly (de Mel et al. 2013, Bruhn & McKenzie 2014), a companion paper by Brockmeyer et al. (2015) shows that ling rates among rms known to the tax authorities can be increased signicantly through low- cost deterrence messages. Nonetheless, ling rates still remain below 40% in the sample of initial late-lers, and revenue gains from increased ling are very marginal (below .1% of initial income tax revenue). 4.2 Intensive Margin Compliance To examine compliance on the intensive margin, we rst compare self-reports and third-party re- ports, for sales and costs respectively. We construct a taxpayer's third-party reported sales as the sum of sales reported by other rms (the taxpayer's clients, D151 sales), state institutions (D150), debit/credit card companies (D153) and exports. While inter-rm sales could technically be conducted through a card transaction and would thus appear both on the D151 and on the D153 delaration, in which case our measure would over-estimate third-party reported sales, the tax authorities consider this is unlikely. A taxpayer's third-party reported costs are the sum of sales re- ported by the taxpayer's suppliers (D151 costs). Underreporters (overreporters) are rms reporting an amount at least 0.25% smaller (larger) than the relevant comparison amount. Table V shows the estimates of under-reporting for tax year 2010, distinguishing sales reports and cost reports, and reports by the self-employed and corporations respectively. Panel A focuses on under-reporting for the income tax, panel B on estimating the under-reported income tax liability, and panel C on internal consistency between the dierent declarations submitted by a taxpayer. Estimating under-reporting for the sales tax is more challenging, given its narrow base and the fact that third-party reports do not distinguish between sales tax liable and non-liable sales. While 17% of the self-employed and 14% of corporations under-report sales compared to third- party reports, the share of rms under-reporting their costs is even higher, 50% and 30% respectively for the self-employed and corporations (row 1). Firms thus under-report not just sales but scale, as shown also in Carrillo et al. (2016). The higher share of cost under-reporters among self-employed can be explained by the presence of an exempt tax bracket in the self-employed tax schedule. The 16 under-reported amounts are substantial as a share of under-reporters' own third-party reports (30- 40%, row 5), but a smaller share of total third-party reports. The share of un-reported sales in total third-party reported sales is just slightly smaller than the share of sales under-reporters, suggesting that under-reporters are not disproportionately small rms. The share of under-reported costs in total third-party reported costs is signicantly smaller than the share of cost under-reporters (row 6). This suggests that marginal cost under-utilization is widespread, but substantial under-utilization is not. With a few assumptions, it is possible to translate the unreported sales amounts into unreported tax liability. We assume that under-reporters declare all third-party reported sales, apply the intially reported prot rate to their intially unreported sales, and then apply the tax schedule. This means we allow under-reporters to oset additional reported sales with additional reported costs, proportionately to the initial declared prot rate. This is a realistic assumption, given the evidence in Carrillo et al. (2016) and Slemrod et al. (2015), and consistent with rms' response to desk audits discussed further below. We estimate that reported tax liabilities would increase by 9% for corporations and by 48% for the self-employed if all third-party reported sales were declared (row 11). This large increase for the self-employed is driven by their high initial reported prot rates, given the exempt tax bracket. However, as the self-employed's tax liabilities represents only 3% of corporate tax liabilities, the general conclusion still is that the tax authorities could increase income tax revenue from rms by 10% at most if they were able to perfectly enforce all third-party reported sales. Evidence from the impact of desk audits further supports the conclusion that simply improv- ing enforcement on third-party reported margins cannot increase tax revenue substantially. The tax authorities systematically cross-check third-party reports and self-assessment declarations, and conduct periodic desk audits for rms that exhibit discrepancies. A desk audit entails a one-day examination of the case by a tax ocer and a phone call to the taxpayer. Figure II displays the results of desk audits for the income tax (panel A) and the sales tax (panel B). Comparing a rm's initial tax return to the post-audit revised return, the gure plots the change in reported costs against the change in reported revenue for panel A, and the change in reported input tax credit against the change in sales tax collected in panel B. The gures focus on the small share of rms that actually revise their declaration in response to the phone call: 19% of desk-audited rms for the income tax and 16% for the sales tax. Revisers clearly oset revenue increases by cost increases, by almost 100% for the income tax and by about two-thirds for the sales tax. The revisers' reported tax liability more than doubles nonetheless, as the initial base is extremely low. The interventions are also highly cost-eective, considering the daily salary of a tax ocer, and the load of one case 17 per day. However, the number of revisers and their scale is so small that the revisions increase total revenue by less than .5%. 26 The low response rate, osetting cost adjustments and marginal tax revenue gains of these desk audits are all consistent with the fact that the under-reporting rates in Table V are very similar when considering rms' initial returns rather than their nal returns, or earlier or later scal years. This analysis has thus shown that, although misreporting compared to third-party information is present, its levels are moderate, probably due the deterrence eect of routine cross-checks, desk audits and other compliance interventions by the tax authorities. Perfectly enforcing reporting of third-party reported margins could increase income tax revenue by 10% in theory, but the realized eect of desk audits is orders of magnitude smaller. 4.3 Payment Compliance To examine taxpayers' compliance with the obligation to pay their net tax liability, we match the income and sales tax returns with payment records from the D110 payment receipts. Importantly, the payment receipts display both the payment date and the tax period and taxpayer to which the payment corresponds, allowing us to exactly match payments with liabilities. To our knowledge, this is the rst attempt at estimating payment compliance for the income and sales tax, testing the previously implicit assumption that declared tax liabilities automatically translate into payments. 27 The relevant liability is the taxpayer's nal tax liability to be paid as per the nal (revised) tax returns, after deductions, advance payments and tax withheld have been subtracted. 28 We compare this liability to the tax payment that the taxpayer makes herself, excluding payments made by withholding agents and advance payments made by the taxpayer. 29 We then take the share of payment over liability for each taxpayer, and average this share across all taxpayers in each scal period. The results are displayed in Figure III, where panel A corresponds to the income tax and panel B correspond to the sales tax, and red and blue lines correspond to corporations and self-employed respectively. In both panels, the average payment share is below 100% in all scal periods, and decreases as we consider more recent tax periods, dropping to 70% for the income tax and 85% 26 Whether the desk audits improve reporting behavior in future tax periods is an open question that we currently study. More generally, whether it is optimal for the tax authorities to invest in desk audits rather than full audits or follow-up communications with non-lers or late-payers depends on the relative revenue elasticities of these dierent enforcement activities, in the spirit of Keen & Slemrod (2016). 27 Del Carpio (2014) provides estimates of property tax compliance in Peru, which are conceptually dierent from our estimates as property taxes are assessed by the government and thus have no misreporting margin. 28 Note that we use the net liability as derived on the rm's tax return, and taking into account only the amount of advance tax payments and tax withheld that the taxpayer chose to reclaim on her tax declaration. 29 Including payments that are enforced retroactively by the tax authorities through administrative or judicial procedures makes little dierence to the results. 18 for the sales tax in the most recent period considered (solid lines). This is despite the fact that we consider payments made until April 2015, the payment deadline for scal year 2014. There are two potential explanations for this downward sloping prole of the average payment rate: a fall in payment compliance over time, and the presence of late-payers. If taxpayers service their tax obligations with substantial delays, then more recent periods will display lower payment compliance than earlier periods, for which a longer series of payment data is available. To distinguish these two explanations, we add the average payment proles based on payments made until April 2013 and April 2011 respectively (dashed and dotted lines). These payment proles are similarly downward sloping and shifted to the left, suggesting that payment delays are indeed at play. For instance, while the income tax payment share for 2010 is about 88% when measured by April 2011, it is above 95% when measured in April 2015. A small share of taxpayers thus pay with large delays. This is consistant with anedotal evidence that cash-constrained rms make tax payments when they are liquid rather than when the payment is due, as nes and interest fees are small. 30 At the same time, the payment share, as measured by the period-specic payment deadline, is also decreasing over time, from 88% for the income tax in 2010 to 81% in 2014. This suggests that payment compliance has also fallen over time. Overall, however, payment compliance is relatively high, not only across rms, but especially in the aggregate. As non-payers and late-payers are disproportionately small, the aggregate payment rate, that is the sum of payments divided by the sum of nal liabilities, is close to 100% soon after the payment deadline and stable over time. 31 Although the enforcement of outstanding payments through administrative and judicial procedures is part of the regular activities of the tax authorities in Costa Rica, and important from a deterrence perspective, increasing enforcement on this margin is unlikely to increase tax revenue substantially. To summarize, the anatomy of compliance allows the following conclusions. First, a substan- tial share of rms fail to le their taxes, and there are limits to the extent to which third-party information induces compliance on the extensive margin. Second, a non-neglegible share of rms under-report sales compared to third-party reports, despite the fact that the authorities systemati- cally cross-check tax returns and informative declarations and request corrections of discrepancies. Finally, a group of predominantly small rms pay their outstanding liabilities with several years of delay. While compliance gaps are present on all margins, they are relatively modest compared to to- tal tax revenue. As evidence from a ling intervention and desk audits show, increased enforcement 30 The payment rate seems to be lower for corporations than for the self-employed, but this is likely driven by a small number of missing payment records. Our current data does not contain payments led through a special online platform which is mainly used by large taxpayers. To ensure that our main results on the causal impact of withholding are not driven by gaps in the payment data, we conduct a series of robustness checks explained below and displayed in the appendix. 31 Results available upon request. 19 on third-party reported margins is unlikely to yield large revenue gains. In such an environment, expanding the coverage of third-party information, and the application of withholding mechanisms to third-party reported sales, may be a much higher-return investment than increased enforcement, a question that we turn to in the next two sections. 5 Impact of Information Reporting This section examines the compliance impact of information reporting while section 6 isolates the impact of withholding. We rst analyze the heterogeneity of bunching, as a proxy for misreporting, across subsamples of rms with dierent degrees of information reporting coverage, and then conduct an event study of the response to information reporting. 5.1 Heterogeneity in Bunching Bunching at kinks or notches in the tax schedule has been used in numerous studies to estimate the response of reported taxable income to the tax rate, and bunching is usually shown to be driven by an evasion/avoidance response rather than a real response (e.g. Bachas & Soto 2016,Almunia & Rodriguez 2015, Seim 2015). Consistent with this, we observe large and sharp bunching at the rst kink in the self-employed tax schedule and at the rst notch in the corporate tax schedule. 32 Taking the example of the self-employed (results are similar for corporations), Figure IV shows that bunching moves every single year with the location of the kink. There is rarely any excess mass at the previous year's kink, suggesting that rms adjust almost immediately and fully to the new kink location. The consistent and speedy adjustment supports the interpretation of bunching as a reporting response rather than a real production change. 33 We thus use bunching as a proxy for misreporting. To examine the heterogeneity of bunching with coverage by information reporting, we pool the data for 2006 to 2015 and display the distribution as percentage dierence from the year-specic 32 The rst threshold in each schedule is the most salient one, and also the largest in terms of the tax rate change for teh self-employed. Bunching is also present but smaller at the other thresholds. 33 Strikingly, the excess mass is always concentrated to the left of the kink. For the years 2010 to 2014, the distribution also displays a clear missing mass to the right of the kink, which is at odds with the prediction of standard utility theory. This theory predicts that kinks generate symmetric bunching around the threshold, and notches generate asymmetric bunching below the threshold and a missing mass in a dominated range above the threshold Kleven & Waseem (2013). However, as discussed in Kleven (2016), several studies have found asymmetric bunching also at kink points, suggesting that taxpayers may perceive a kink as a notch. One possible explation is that crossing the kink may be associated with a xed cost, such as having to make a payment, as is the case for the rst kink in the self-employed tax schedule in Costa Rica. However, tax payments can be done online and should generate little transaction cost in Costa Rica. Another explanation is that the threshold creates a reference point, which constitutes a notch in the rm's utility function, so that bunching is driven by reference point dependence rather than the traditionally assumed response to the nancial incentive change at the kink. This warrents caution when using bunching to estimate the elasticity of taxable income, but does not prevent us from interpreting bunching as a measure of misreporting which generates a revenue loss for the government. 20 threshold location in 1% bins. To estimate the size of bunching, we t a exible polynomial to the observed distribution, excluding a range around the thresholds, as is standard in the bunching literature (Chetty et al. 2011, Kleven & Waseem 2013). Given the asymmetric nature of bunching, we estimate bunching to the left of the kink and the missing mass to the right of the kink. As the missing mass does not seem to be the same size as the excess mass, at least for the self-employed, we apply the estimation strategy suggested by Best & Kleven (2015) rather than the covergence method. We choose the lower bound of the excluded range as the point where bunching starts and the upper bound as the point where the derivative of the observed distribution shifts from positive to negative. 34 The convergence method would require the missing mass and the excess mass to be of the same size and assumes that there are no extensive margin responses, which is unlikely in a context with high shares of non-lers even among registered rms. Figure V displays the observed distribution (dotted blue line), the estimated counterfactual (solid red line) and excess mass and missing mass estimates for dierent subsamples. The top row (A) shows the distribution of taxable income for the self-employed around the rst kink; the bottom row (B) shows the distribution of revenue for corporations around the rst notch. In each row, panel 1 reects the rm-year observations not covered by any information reporting or withholding mechanisms, panel 2 reects observations that are subject to information reporting by other rms only (declaration D151 by suppliers and clients), and panels 3 and 4 reect observations subject to reporting by state institutions and credit/debit card companies respectively (declarations D150 and D153). While several papers have analyzed the heterogeneity in bunching by proxies of evasion propensity (e.g. Best 2014, Almunia & Rodriguez 2015), this is to our knowledge the rst exercise of estimating the heterogeneity of bunching by actual third-party information coverage. Among both rm types, the largest excess mass is found in the sample of rms not subject to information reporting (panel 1). The subsample of rms subject to information reporting by other rms (panel 2) still exhibits a large excess mass around both the kink and the notch, but in both cases, the excess mass estimate is signicantly smaller than the estimate for rms not subject to information reporting. The excess mass drops from 4.5 to 2.08 for the self-employed and from 4.49 to 3.17 for corporations, and those drops are statistically signicant at the 1% level. 35 The fact that bunching is smaller but still highly signicant among information-covered rms is consistent with the fact that bunching can be partly driven by legal avoidance, and that the information trail 34 The location of the upper bound is less clear from visual inspection. In a forthcoming appendix table, we provide robustness checks varying the degree of the polynomial and the size of the excluded range below and above the kink. 35 Note that the change in the missing mass estimate is driven by a change in the counterfactual density which scales the excess mass, rather than by a change in the absolute size of the excess mass. The missing mass drops for corporations, but increases for the self-employed. In fact, the missing mass for the self-employed is clearly visible only in panels 2 and 3. This suggests that the threshold may be perceived as a kink by some self-employed in the subsample not covered by information reporting. 21 is incomplete, covering only large transactions. Firms can still manipulate their taxable income by misreporting small and cash transactions and sales to the nal consumer, or inating costs, deductions and exemptions. 36 Information reporting by state institutions and credit/debit card companies, which also act as withholding agents, is associated with a further reduction in misreporting behavior (panels 3 and 4). For the self-employed, the excess mass among rms subject to state reporting is similar to the excess mass among rms subject only to information reporting by other rms, but the excess mass drops to .52 for rms subject to credit/debit card reporting. For corporations, the excess mass drops from 3.17 among rms subject to information reporting by other rms to 1.44 and 1.35 respectively for rms subject to state reporting and credit/debit card reporting. These drops are again highly statistically signicant. The heterogeneity of bunching across subsamples is thus consistent with a compliance impact of information reporting, and an even stronger impact of withholding. Our results are also consistent with estimates from the United States, where the Internal Revenue Service reports tax evasion rates of 56%, 8% and 1% respectively on income covered by little information reporting, income covered by substantial information reporting and income subject to withholding (IRS 2012). However, just like the IRS estimates, our estimates do not capture a pure causal eect. Firms subject to information reporting, and especially rms subject to withholding, are on average larger, more urban and probably equipped with more sophisticated management and accounting systems. It is possible that these characteristics, rather than coverage by the tax compliance mechanisms, explain at least part of the heterogeneity in bunching. In addition, the dierent reporting mechanisms apply to dierent types of transactions, rm-to-rm, rm-to-state and card transactions respectively, so that the corresponding informative declarations and the rms covered by them are not strictly comparable. 37 5.2 Event Study To move a step further towards estimating a causal eect of information reporting, we exploit within- rm variation across time in the coverage by information reporting. Each year, over a thousand rms switch from not being reported to the tax authorities by any third party to being reported by at least one transaction partner. If third-party reporting of transactions to the tax authorities forces rms to declare a larger share of their transactions on their self-assessment declarations, coverage by information reporting should be associated with an increase in reported taxable sales and income. 36 Bunching is also present in all economic sectors and relatively homogenous across sectors. 37 For example, managers of rms deciding to sell their output to a state institution may have higher tax morale, or be more committed to public goods provision, than managers transacting only with other private sector rms. 22 This prediction is motivated by the fact that the tax authorities regularly follow up on rms with discrepancies between third-party and self-reports, leading most rms to report sales weakly larger than the third-party reported amounts (section V). We thus conduct an event study of reported taxable income around the time of the rst informa- tion report about a rm, distinguishing reports by the dierent informing agents (other rms, state institutions, credit/debit card companies). 38 Of course, whether or not a rm becomes subject to information reporting is partly under the rm's control. A rm is nearly certain to be reported to the tax authorities if it sells to a state institution or conductes sales via a credit/debit card termi- nal, as state institutions and card companies are considered highly compliant with their reporting obligations. Conducting transactions with another rm above the relevant annual threshold amount should also trigger information reporting, although rms may be less compliant with their report- ing obligations, and transacting partners may collude not report their transactions. An additional concern is that the event of becoming subject to information reporting may increase not only the share of true taxable income that is reported to the tax authorities, but also the level of true taxable income and hence of reported taxable income, even if the share of income that is reported remains unchanged. For instance, securing a government contract has been shown to increase rm growth (Ferraz et al 2016), and oering consumers the opportunity to pay by credit/debit card may allow rms to attract additional customers. While there are no credible estimates of the potential size of these demand eects, we discuss below why our estimates are unlikely to be fully driven by them. To adress the identication concerns, we consider the event group E of rms that switch into information reporting coverage for the rst time at event time k = 0, and the event control group C of rms which have not switched into coverage by k = 0. As a careful precaution, but without substantively modifying the core results, we follow Hilger (2014) and Naritomi (2015) in reweighting the control group to resemble the treatment group pre-event trend. For each event period, we estimate the rms' propensity score of switching into information reporting coverage. 39 Following DiNardo et al. (1996), we re-weight the control group by quintile bins of the propensity score to match the distribution of the event group. We consider the event's impact on income tax declarations and sales tax declarations. For the income tax, we consider a balanced panel of rms that we can 38 The Costa Rican tax authorities, unlike the Internal Revenue Service in the United States, do not notify taxpayers about the informative reports received about them. However, given the structure of reporting requirements, each rm should be aware of the informative declarations held by the tax authorities about its business activities. Each inter- rm transaction above the relevant threshold amount needs to be reported by both the seller and buyer (declaration D151). State institutions and credit/debit card companies acting as withholding agents are obliged by law to provide taxpayers with a receipt stating the amount of tax withheld. Compliance with this information requiremetn is considered to be high. 39 The propensity score of a rm receiving its rst informative declaration is estimated separately for each declaration type and event year, using rm type and tax administration dummies, and the two lags of a third-order polynomial of total income and taxable income. See also Yagan (2015) for a detailled description of the reweighting procedure. 23 observe for at least four years before and three years after the event, allowing us to evaluate events happening in event periods p = {2010, 2011, 2012}. For the sales tax, we consider a balanced panel of rms that we can observe for at least ve months before and after the event, allowing us to evaluate events happening in event periods between February 2009 and August 2014. 40 Each panel in Figure VI displays the trend in (real) reported taxable income for the event group (orange dots) and the control group (blue crosses), scaled by the pre-event average, along with the dierence-in-dierence coecient obtained from estimating yip k = γk + αip + β · I {k ≥ 0, g = E } + uip k . (1) The unit of observation in this estimation is a rm i in event period p at event time k . For instance, a rm may be in the control group group for events happening in 2010 and 2011, but in the treatment group for event happening in 2012. Each rm-year observation for this rm will thus appear in the event dataset three times, for event years 2010, 2011 and 2012. We estimate the rm's reported taxable income as a function of event-time dummies γk , rm-event-period xed eects α ip , and the post-event and treatment group dummy I {k ≥ 0, g = E }.41 Outcomes are in levels rather than logs, to include the large number of rms with zero values, and winsorized at the 95th percentile to limit the inuence of outliers. Panels on the left side of gure VI correspond to the self-employed, and panels on the right side correspond to corporations. For most rms, the rst transacting partner reporting to the tax authorities is a supplier, leading to a D151 cost report about the rm's purchase. As panels A1 and B1 show, receipt of this rst information report is associated with a 26% increase in reported taxable income for the self-employed and a 49% increase for corporations. This large eect emerges precisely at event time, after otherwise identical trends in the event and control group, which means it is unlikely to be driven purely by true income growth. Over time, rms gradually become covered by more information reports, such as reports from their clients (D151 sales). This event, which happens on average a year after the rst cost report, is considered in panels A2 and B2. The rst sales report is associated with a much smaller increase in taxable income than the rst cost report, possibly because part of the relevant transactions have already been reported to the tax authorities in response to the rst cost report. The eect size is again larger for corporations than for the self-employed. Consistent with the fact that rms under- 40 Results are robust to considering fewer or more event periods, or omitting the propensity score reweighting. 41 Contrary to Naritomi (2015), we conduct the estimation at the rm level rather than on the collapsed data, to estimate the standard errors. The results are qualitatively similar in a simple event study without control group, in which we estimate coecients for each event time. However, limited statistical power makes the point estimates signicantly more noisy. Firm-event-period xed eects and clustering of standard errors at the rm level account for potentially repeated appearance of rm-year/rm-month observations. 24 report both sales and costs, the taxable income response to all events is driven by a similarly-sized increase in reported sales and reported costs, as the numbers is squared brackets demonstrate. Reporting by state institutions or credit/debit card companies (panels A3-B4) has a relatively homogenous eect on the self-employed and corporations, leading to a 21-26% increase in reported taxable income in both samples. 42 Although most rms are already subject to reporting by other rms when being rst reported by a state institution or card company, these new reports enforce a dierent margin - sales to state institutions and nal consumers, as opposed to inter-rm trans- actions - and may thus have an additional eect on reporting. 43 However, the result could also be driven by the fact that information reporting mechanism that are associated with withholding have a stronger compliance impact than pure reporting mechanisms. The next section will show that withholding indeed increases reported taxable income even when information reporting requirements are held constant. In all gures, the event and control group follow similar, almost identical trends until the event, and then diverge precisely at event time k = 044 , until the dierence between the two groups stabilizes at approximately k = 1. In the monthly sales tax data, the event group has a slightly higher pre-event growth rate than the control group, but the sudden divergence in the event month still supports a causal interpretation of the eect. Although oering consumers the possibility to pay by credit/debit card may increase sales, this eect is unlikley to materialize immediately, as consumers need to acquire the new information and adjust their purchasing behavior. We thus conclude that the size and timing of the eect is hard to reconcile with a pure growth eect, and must be at least partly driven by a compliance response to information reporting. 6 Impact of Withholding Having show that information reporting increases reported taxable income, this section studies whether withholding has an impact on compliance beyond the impact generated by information reporting. We use the August 2011 reform of the sales tax withholding rate schedule to isolate the impact of withholding, holding the information environment constant. We start by analyzing the rst stage impact of the reform on realized witholding rates and card use, then conduct a 42 Note also that the increase in reported taxable income (reported tax liability for the sales tax) is associated with an increase in the reported prot rate (reported value-added rate for the sales tax). 43 For the event of credit/debit card reporting (last two gures) we use the reported tax liability (rather than reported taxable income) as outcome variable, and sales tax collected and input tax credits deducted (rather than sales and costs) for the decomposition, as these variables are available on the monthly sales tax declarations. The results are similar when conducting the analysis at the annual level with reported taxable income for the income tax as outcome. However, the event is less sharp in this case, as the rst credit card report may be led in the middle of a tax year rather than at the beginning of the year. 44 This is true except in the case of corporations receiving a rst sales report from other rms (fourth panel), whose trend diverges from the control group at k = −1 rather than k = 0. 25 dierence-in-dierence estimation of the payment response to the withholding rate increase, and nally examine the mechanisms of the withholding impact. 6.1 First Stage and Impact on Card Use As discussed in section 3.3.2, a reform in August 2011 revised the sales tax withholding rate schedule. Panel A in Figure VII shows that the reform lead to a large increase (approxiately a doubling) of the average withholding rate, as intended. This also conrms the high compliance of card companies with the government-assigned withholding rates. The graph displays small jumps every semester, when the withholding rates are revised by the tax authorities and communicated to the withholding agents. The graph also displays a gradual decrease in the withholding rate after the initial post- reform jump, suggesting that a number of rms obtained a lowering of their withholding rate, probably by making a revision request to the tax authorities. 45 To understand the extent of deviation between the assigned and realized withholding rate, we predict each rm's withholding rate based on its past tax returns and the withholding rate schedule in Table II. As panel B shows, the predicted rate tracks the realized rate closely, for rms for which we can observe both rates, but the realized withholding rate is always slightly higher. This is consistent with the fact that rms can request a lowering of the withholding rate from the tax authorities, for instance if they have losses for several consecutive months. Panel C and D investigate the possibility that the reform may have discouraged rms from ling their sales declaration, or using their credit/debit card machine, which would have limited information reporting and withholding by card companies. Both the number of sales tax declarations and of credit/debit card reports (D153 informative declaration by card processing companies) led with the tax authorities is steadily increasing and smooth at reform time. Similarly, the share of sales tax declarations that can be matched with at least one credit/debit card report and vice-versa does not display a discontinuity at reform time. In fact, the share of credit/debit card reportees that le sales tax was decreasing prior to the reform (driven by an increase in the number of credit/debit card reportees), but then stagnated after the reform. The possibility of reclaiming the tax withheld may have increased withholdee's propensity to le sales tax. Overall, we conclude that the reform did not reduce tax ling and credit/debit card marchine usage on the extensive margin. A remaining concern is that the reform may have decreased the intensity of card marchine usage. However, as panels E and F show for rms using a card machine (i.e. reported by at least one credit/debit card company), neither the sum of card sales over total sales nor the average 45 There is only a weak behavioral response to the withholding rate notches in reported value-added and the share of local sales, suggesting that few rms, if any, can manipulate the withholding rates by manipulating the relevant line items on their sales tax declaration. 26 over the rm-specic share of card sales changes discontinuously at reform time. While both series display a small drop at reform time, this drop is statistically signicant only when considering the average share of card sales, suggesting it is driven by rms with a relatively small sales volume. The size of the drop is economically insignicant even in this sample - one percentage point of an average share of 50%. This suggests that most rms have not attempted or do not have the market power to refuse card transactions with the objective of avoiding the withholding rate increase or reducing its scope of application. We can thus consider the information reporting environment constant around the reform, and use the reform to isolate the eect of withholding. 46 6.2 Dierence-in-Dierence Estimation To estimate the impact of the withholding rate increase on total tax payment and other intermediate outcomes, we conduct a dierence-in-dierence estimation on the balanced panel of rms which consistently submitted sales tax declarations during a 30-months window around the reform. Only rms that experienced an increase in the predicted withholding rate between July and August 2011 are considered treated. The control group consists of rms that experienced no rate increase or are not subject to withholding. 47 Note that we condition on the predicted rather than the realized increase in the withholding rate, as the latter may be aected by a rm-specic request or connection to the tax authority which allowed the rm to obtain a lower withholding rate. 48 The predicted rate change depends on value added and the share of local sales in the second semester of 2010, long before the reform decree was designed in July 2011, so that rms could not possibly have gamed the system to avoid an increase in the predicted withholding rate. 49 We estimate the eect of the rate increase using the specication yit = αi + γt + µi · t + β · T reati · P ostt + it , (2) where yit is the outcome reported by rm i in month t; αi and γt are rm and month xed eects and µi is a rm-specic linear time trend; and T reati and P ostt are dummies indicating the treatment group and post-reform period. it is the error term. We consider as outcomes all main line items 46 Any reduction in credit/debit card usage would simply downward bias our diernece-in-dierence estimates below. Similarly, if the (small number of ) rms that reduced card usage after the withholding rate reform were the rms with the largest potential evasion rents, our estimates would constitute a lower bound on the true compliance impact of withholding. 47 Results are similar but more noisy when excluding rms that are not subject to withholding. We always exclude rms that experience a reduction in their withholding rate, as the small size of this sample does not allow for separately estimating the impact of a rate reduction. 48 We consider collusion between the withholding agent and the rm unlikely, given the small number of withholding agents and the high monitoring intensity they are subject to. 49 We do not observe rms starting to revise tax returns for 2010 after the reform was announced. 27 on the roughlysales tax return, as shown in table VI. The table reports the pre-reform mean in the treatment group, and the coecient β for dierent specications, either using the raw data, or winsorizing by the 99.9th, 99th and 95th percentile, in addition to the rst percentile. As several outcome variables take value zero for a large share of observations, we use levels rather than logs, and report the treatment eect as marginal eect on the pre-reform average. However, the results are qualitively similar when using log(outcome+1) or a dummy variable indicating if the outcome is non-zero. To visualize the identifying assumption and treatment eect on total tax payment, Figure VIII plots the month-on-month change in total tax payment for the treatment and control group, together with the DiD coecient estimates from Equation 2. For the purpose of this gure, the data is winsorized by the 99th percentile. Total tax payment is the sum of the tax withheld and the taxpayer's payment. Despite seasonal uctuations with peaks during the December shopping season, the two groups exhibit parallel pre-reform trends, which conrms the suitability of the control group. At the time of the reform, tax payments in the treatment group increase sharply by about 33% and remain at this higher level for the next 15 months. 50 As there is no corresponding decrease in tax payment in the control group, and the treatment group represents a substantial share of total sales, the withholding rate reform increased aggregate sales tax revenue by 8.4%. Figure IX illustrates this results, using a simple linear regression discontinuity design on demeaned semester-wise revenue data (from ocial government statistics). We display the evolution of revenue from the quarterly simplied regime tax as a counterfactual, to show that the discontiuity at reform time is not driven by business cycle uctuations. 51 A concern is that taxpayers may have countered the eect of the withholding rate reform by changing their behavior on other margins. The last three rows in table VI show that this is not the case. Where tax has been withheld in excess of liabilities, taxpayers can either request a refund of the excess amount, or substract it as compensation from their income tax liability. However, this applies to a very small number of taxpayers. 52 We nd that the main treatment eect barely changes when considering as outcome total sales tax payments net of any refunds requests and income tax compensations. Furthermore, the last row shows that the withholding rate reform was not met by a decrease in income tax payment. When using the sum of total income and sales tax 50 There is an additional increase over time during the post-reform period, but this parallels a qualitatively similar development in the control group. 51 The results are similar when running the estimation on the un-demeaned data, or aggregating at the quarter or month-level. See footnote 19 for details on the simplied tax regime. 52 In the raw data, the number and total amount of the refund requests increased slightly at the time of the reform (results available upon request). However, there are usually less than 300 refund requests per month, compared to about 6000 treated rms in our balanced panel, and less than half of the refund requests are led by sales tax payers. The delay in receiving a refund is reportedly several months, and the request procedure is cumbersome and thus undertaken primarily by large and sophisticated rms. 28 payments minus refunds as dependent variable (dividing annual income tax payments equally across months of the relevant scal year for estimation purposes), we estimate that the reform increased tax payment by 22.5% (column 5). Given that annual sales tax payments are on average almost twice as high as income tax payments, this is consistent with the demonstrated increase of sales tax payments by 33% and even a slight increase of income tax payments. Indeed, to the extent that taxpayers are internally consistent, i.e. report the same tax base on the income and sales tax declaration, an increase in sales tax compliance would spillover to the income tax. 6.3 Mechanisms of Withholding Impact One potential mechanism is the default mechanism, by which incomplete reclaim of the tax withheld, ceteris paribus, leads to an increase in total tax payment. Panel A and B of Figure X show evidence for this. The share of withholdees making a reclaim on their sales tax declaration, conditional on having a non-zero gross tax liability, is only around 50% before the reform, and drops close to 40% at the time of the reform. This drop occurs because the reform increases the number of taxpayers subject to withholding, and many of the new withholdees might not be familiar with the reclaim procedure, or might not even realize that they are suject to withholding. As these new withholdees start to reclaim the tax gradually, the share of withholdees making a reclaim increases, and eventually surpases the pre-reform share of reclaimers by approximately 10 percentage points. The average share of withheld tax reclaimed, as displayed in the second panel, follows a similar pattern. The share uctuates between 80% and 95% before the reform, then drops sharply at the time of the reform, and recovers gradually. However, the share of withheld tax reclaimed is much higher than the share of reclaimers. This provides evidence that incomplete reclaim is indeed a mechanism through which withholding increases total tax payment, but mostly for small rms. Indeed, columns 1 and 2 in table VII show that the withholding rate increase generates a larger payment increase for the self-employed than for corporations. 53 This suggests that a second mechanism must be at play, which is analyzed in the bottom panels of Figure X. The gures display results from estimating Equation VIII, as in Figure VIII, with dierent outcome variables, as indicated in the panel titles. The gures conrm that the reform did not aect the amount of sales tax collected (nor the amount of total reported sales), suggesting that production has not decreased as a result of the reform. Yet the reform led to a 3% reduction in reported input tax credits in the treatment group. Combining these two results means that the reported gross tax liability in the treatment group increased by 17%. This is consistent with a world in which rms evaded sales tax by over-reporting input tax credits, but report more accurately after 53 We chose the rm type division as it is based on a time-invariant characteristics that is unlikely to be misreported. Results are similar when splitting the sample by median pre-reform revenue. 29 the withholding rate is increased. We also nd a similar increase in reported taxable income after the introduction of tax withholding by credit/debit card companies for the purpose of income tax compliance in 2015 (a reform which again maintained the information environment constant). The results are shown in Appendix Figure XI. The ndings raise the question of what drives the improvment in reporting, given that enforce- ment by the tax authorities has not increased, as evidence in panel F by the relatively constant audits rates. One possibility is that rms increase reported taxable income when reclaiming the tax withheld, in anticipation of a higher probability of cross-checks or monitoring. However, columns 3 and 4 of table VII show that rms which never make any reclaim experience a similar increase in reported tax liability as rms making a reclaim. This shows that the reporting eect is not driven by reclaimers. Another possibility is that a withholding rate increase raises the salience and hence the perceived but not the true intensity of enforcement for some taxpayers. To see this, it is important to know that rms learn from their daily (or occassionally monthly) credit/debit card machine statements the volumne of card sales processed, any commissions applied by the card processors, and the amount of tax withheld and transmitted to the tax authorities. 54 Firms experiencing an increase in the withholding rate from a positive rate to a larger rate would notice the rate increase on their card machine statement only if they pay close attention to the amount of transactions processed and the amount of tax withheld, to back out the withholding rate applied. Firms experiencing an increase in the withholding rate from zero, however, are much more likely to notice the rate increase, as the box for tax withheld on their card machine statement switches from being blank to carrying a number. Noticing the application of withholding for the rst time may raise the salience of possible enforcement interventions like desk audits, and lead rms to increase compliance. Consistent with this, columns 5 and 6 show that rms experiencing a withholding rate increase from zero exhibit a larger increase both in their reported tax liability and in their total tax paid than rms experiencing a similarly-sized rate increase from a positive to a larger rate. 55 This signicant interaction does not disappear when additionally interacting with the self-employed and reclaimer indicator, and is always larger than the latter. We thus label the increase in reported tax liability among treated rms the salience of enforcement eect, as per the panel title in Figure X. 56 54 See Figure XII for an illustration of the type of information provided by card processing companies in Costa Rica to aliated businesses. 55 We exclude from the From-Zero Rate Increase group all rms that experience the maximum rate increase of six percentage points, to ensure that the average rate increase in this group is not larger than the average rate increase among other treated rms. 56 An alternative explanation might posit that rms are unaware of their true tax liability and thus report with error, but start to report more correctly after the withholding rate reform, as the withholding system provides them with information of their true tax liability. However, this explanation would be consistent with our results only if rms systematically (but non-strategically) underestimated their tax liability. 30 To quantitatively decompose the impact of the withholding rate increase into the default eect, the salience of enforcement eect, and a possible reduction in under-payment, we are currently awaiting a new payment dataset that contains payments by all taxpayers, including the large rms paying through a special online platform. 7 Conclusion Although withholding schemes for rms are widespread in low income countries, and in low com- pliance sectors in high income countries, they have been largely ignored by the public nance literature. This paper proposes an explanation for the attractiveness of withholding schemes. In a simple Allingham-Sandmo model with third-party reporting, withholding can create a compliance default if reclaiming the tax withheld is costly, and can enhance the salience of tax enforcement. Exploiting a unique ten-year panel of tax declarations and third-party information and withhold- ing reports for the universe of rms in Costa Rica, we estimate compliance gaps on the extensive, intensive and payment margin. The estimates suggest that compliance is satisfactory on third-party reported margins, and expanding the coverage of information reporting leads to substantial increases in reported taxable income. An event study nds that rms increase their reported taxable income by 20-50% when being information-reported for the rst time by a trading partner. Withholding further enhances compliance. A doubling in the sales tax withholding rate increases tax payments by 33% among rms subject to withholding and by 8% in aggregate. This eect is driven by incom- plete reclaim of the tax withheld, and reduced misreporting. We nd no evidence that withholding reduces output, which suggests that the liquidity costs associated with the regime are neglegible. As withholding has the largest impact on small rms, analyzing the distributional consequences of withholding is an important avenue for future research. 31 Table I: Income Tax Schedule 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Panel A: Self-Employed Kink 1 1,858 2,074 2,252 2,599 2,747 2,890 3,042 3,171 3,339 3,522 Kink 2 2,775 3,097 3,362 3,880 4,102 4,316 4,543 4,735 4,986 5,259 Kink 3 4,629 5,167 5,609 6,473 6,843 7,199 7,577 7,898 8,317 8,773 Kink 4 9,276 10,354 11,241 12,972 13,713 14,427 15,185 15,827 16,667 17,581 Panel B: Corporations Notch 1 27,811 31,043 33,701 38,891 41,112 43,253 45,525 47,451 49,969 52,710 Notch 2 55,943 62,444 67,791 78,231 82,698 87,004 91,573 95,447 100,513 106,026 Notes: The table shows the income tax schedule for the years 2006 to 2015. Amounts are in tousands of Costa Rican colones (CRC, ). Panel A shows the location of the kinks on taxable income that separate the ve tax brackets for the self-employed. The tax is applied to taxable income at marginales rates of 0, 10, 15, 20 and 25% respectively for the rst to fth tax bracket. Panel B shows the location of the notches on revenue that separate the three tax brackets for corporations. The tax is applied to taxable income at average rates of 10, 20 and 30% respectively for the rst to third tax bracket. For more information on the tax base, tax schedule and the ling procedure, see http://www.hacienda.go.cr/contenido/12994-regimen-tradicional. Table II: Withholding Rate Schedule for Sales Tax Withholding Rate 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Base before 08/2011: Value-Added Rate ≤ 5 20 30 40 55 75 ∞ Base since 08/2011: Share of Local Sales ≤ 0 - - 50 - - 100 Notes: The table shows the withholding rate which credit/debit card companies apply to the sales of their sales-tax-liable clients. Prior to August 2011, the average withholding rate was determined by a notched schedule on value-added, with notches at value-added rates of 5, 20, 30, 40, 55 and 75%, and resulting withholding rates between 0 and 6%. Since August 2011, the schedule has been consolidated to three withholding rates of 0, 3 and 6%. The rates are determined by a notched schedule on the share of local sales, with a notch at 50%. 32 Table III: Informative Declarations to Tax Authorities (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Form Purpose Record Type Coverage of Coverage of % Matched With Corporations Self-Employed Income Tax Records D151 Reporting of rm-rm transactions Sales 46.5 38.9 37.0 N=17,125,017 (54.3% sales) Purchases 49.3 54.1 65.5 D158 Reporting of transactions at auctions Sales 0.5 1.7 16.4 N=369,002 (71.0% sales) Purchases 0.3 0.9 23.5 D150 Withholding on purchases State purchases 8.4 5.0 78.7 N=759,391 (98.5% state purchase) Private purchases 0.22 0.08 39.9 D153 Withholding on card transactions for GST Sales 11.5 [26.7] 5.8 [18.4] 67.8 [48.7] N=4,198,384 33 Notes: This table provides information about the nature and coverage of third-party informative declarations used by the tax authorities in Costa Rica, for 2006 to 2014. Columns 1-3 provide the form number, its purpose, the number of observations and the record type. Columns 4 and 5 display the share of income tax lers covered by the dierent third-party declarations, distinguishing corporations and the self-employed. Column 6 displays the share of informative declarations which are matched with an income tax declaration. In the last row, the shares in brackets refer to the match rate with the monthly sales tax declarations for 2008-2014. The shares are calculated on the pooled data for all years/months. All declarations identify the reporter and taxpayer by their administration-internal anonymous tax ID, and provide information on the transaction amount, and (where applicable) the amount of the tax withheld. Amounts are accrued. Since January 2012, all declarations must be prepared using the DECLAR@7 software. Sanctions for non- compliance with the obligation to submit informative declarations are specied in the Codigo de Normas y Procedimientos Tributarios. All declarations are annual, except D153, which is monthly. D151 requires reporting of transactions >2.5 mio  annually with a transaction partner, and transactions of >50,000  annually for rent, commissions, professional services or interests. For D150, the withholding rate is 2% and 3% respectively for state and private purchases. For D153, the withholding rate is rm specic, following the schedule in Table II. For more information on the ling of informative declarations, see http://www.hacienda.go.cr/contenido/12997-declaraciones-informativas. Table IV: Non-Filing Panel A: Non-ling among all tax-liable rms (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Non-lers' Unreported Of which Undeclared TPI sales as % liability as % % Non-lers registered sales as % of of declared of declared non-lers declared sales TPI sales liability Income Tax 2010 0.384 0.185 0.155 0.211 0.071 Income Tax 2011 0.485 0.125 0.195 0.230 0.069 Income Tax 2012 0.528 0.116 0.115 0.168 0.071 Income Tax 2013 0.556 0.121 0.114 0.181 0.099 Sales Tax 2011 0.196 0.894 . . . Sales Tax 2012 0.185 0.884 . . . Sales Tax 2013 0.198 0.891 . . . Panel B: Non-ling among registered rms Self-Employed Corporations All Self-Employed Corporations with TPI with TPI Income Tax 2010 0.104 0.095 0.082 0.081 0.045 Income Tax 2011 0.105 0.090 0.078 0.061 0.033 Income Tax 2012 0.115 0.080 0.070 0.065 0.028 Income Tax 2013 0.131 0.128 0.094 0.137 0.043 Sales Tax 2011 0.180 0.263 0.122 0.094 0.060 Sales Tax 2012 0.168 0.247 0.103 0.085 0.045 Sales Tax 2013 0.181 0.269 0.079 0.085 0.034 Panel C: Non-ling among rms covered by information reporting Reported by Reported by Reported by All card rms state companies Income Tax 2010 0.574 0.579 0.235 0.293 . Income Tax 2011 0.653 0.659 0.202 0.297 . Income Tax 2012 0.673 0.679 0.186 0.308 . Income Tax 2013 0.677 0.682 0.177 0.319 . Notes: These three panels show the share of non-lers for the income tax (rows 1-4) and the sales tax (rows 5-7). Non-lers are tax liabile rms which have not submitted their own tax declaration for the relevant scal period. The algorithm used to construct the share of non-lers is explained in appendix section 8.1. The share of non-lers for the sales tax is an average across months in a scal year. Panel A shows the share of non-lers among all tax liable rms (column 1), the share of non-lers that a registered (2), non-lers' third-party reported sales as share of lers' reported sales (3), non-lers' estimates sales as share of declared sales (4), and non-lers' estimated tax liability as share of declared tax liability (5). TPI stands for third- party information, and TPI sales is the sum of all third-party reports except cost reports. A non-ling rm's estimated sales in in period t are the maximum of its third-party reported sales in t and its self-reported sales in the most recent prior reporting period. A non-lers' tax liability is estimated using its estimated sales, applying the average prot rate of lers in the corresponding decile of the sales distribution of lers, and the applying the tax schedule. Panel B reports the share of non-lers among all registered rms (1), and among subsamples and registered rms as indicated by the column headings (2-5). Panel C reports the share of non-lers among all rms covered by information reporting (1), and among subsamples of rms reported by dierent informing agents, as indicated by the column headings (2-4). 34 Table V: Misreporting (1) (2) (3) (4) Sales Reports Cost Reports Self-Employed Corporations Self-Employed Corporations Panel A: Underreporting IT 1) % Underreporters IT vs TPI 16.9 14.2 50.6 29.8 2) Unreported Amount 270.6 2799.7 271.1 1021.1 3) Underreporters' TPI 652.9 7010.6 953.2 3603.3 4) Total TPI 1859.8 20664.1 1507.5 16421.4 5) Unreported Amount(% UR TPI) 41.4 39.9 28.4 28.3 6) Unreported Amount(% TPI) 14.5 13.5 18 6.2 Panel B: Underreported Liability 7) Unreported Tax IT 12.7 71.1 8) Underreporters' Reported Tax 3.3 51.8 9) Total Reported Tax 26.6 800.1 10) Unreported Tax (% UR Tax) 385.6 137.4 11) Unreported Tax (% Tax) 47.7 8.9 Panel C: Internal Consistency 12) % Underreporters IT vs OTPI 3.6 5.3 17 8.3 13) % Overreporters IT vs OTPI 43.5 62.9 81.1 90.2 14) % Underreporters IT vs ST 9.4 9.6 14 5.9 15) % Overreporters IT vs ST 53.8 61.6 83.5 93.6 Notes: This table displays estimates of compliance gaps between third-party reports and self-reports for the income tax. Third-party reported sales for the income tax is the sum of sales reported under D150, D151, D158, D153, and exports. Third-party reported costs for the income tax is the sum of costs reported under D151 and D158. Third-party reported sales for the sales tax is the sum of sales reported on D153 declarations. Columns 1-2 are for sales reports, and columns 3-4 for cost reports. In both analyses, we consider separately the self-employed (columns 1 and 3) and corporations (columns 2 and 4). All gures in this table are either in percent (as indicated), or in billions of constant 2015 colones. Underreporters (overreporters) are rms reporting an amount at least 0.25% smaller (larger) than the relevant comparison amount. Rows 1-6 examine underreporting of third-party reported sales/costs. They show the share of under-reporters among rms subject to third-party reporting for the income tax (1), the amount unreported (as compared to third- party reports) (2), the total third-party reports for under-reporters (3), the total third-party reports for the full sample (4), and the unreported amount as a share of the underreporters third-party reports (5), and as a share of total third-party reports (6). Rows 7-11 convert unreported sales into tax liabilities. They show an estimate of the unreported tax liability (7), the underreporters' reported tax liability (8), and the total reported tax liability (9), and the unreported tax as share of the underreporters' reported tax (10), and as a share of the total reported tax (11). The estimation of the unreported (gross) tax liability assumes that the prot rate on unreported sales is the same as the prot rate on reported sales (capped at 100%), and applies the tax schedule as displayed in Table I. Rows 12-15 analyze internal constency in ling. Rows 12 and 13 compare self-reports for the income tax to a rm's own third-party reports (third-party reports submitted by the rm itsself about transactions with other rms), and rows 14 and 15 compare income tax reports to sales tax reports. All calculations are based on 2010 data. Results are similar for other years, and when focusing only on rms that le according to the regular scal period. 35 Table VI: Impact of Withholding Rate Increase (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Pre-Reform Mean Pre-Reform Mean Basline Winsorized Winsorized Winsorized Treated, 99.9th pctile Treated, 99th pctile Raw Data 99.9th pctile 99th pctile 95th pctile Total Sales Reported 71560.380 51664.220 0.200 0.042 ∗ 0.002 0.003 (996.541) (329.431) (0.293) (0.018) (0.008) (0.006) Sales Tax Collected 5114.702 3782.567 0.030 -0.008 -0.012 0.011 (59.499) (19.500) (0.023) (0.019) (0.008) (0.006) Input Tax Credits 4309.865 3192.292 -0.087 ∗ -0.068 ∗∗ -0.038 ∗∗∗ -0.036 ∗∗∗ (43.137) (14.898) (0.041) (0.022) (0.010) (0.006) Import Credits 1509.174 882.316 -0.196 ∗ -0.120 ∗∗∗ -0.024 -0.076 ∗∗∗ (22.230) (7.134) (0.081) (0.036) (0.020) (0.017) Local Purchase Credits 2752.913 2064.536 -0.559 -0.055 ∗ -0.029 ∗∗ -0.031 ∗∗∗ (27.976) (8.237) (0.546) (0.023) (0.010) (0.006) Gross Tax Liability 844.611 548.881 0.096 0.160 ∗∗∗ 0.167 ∗∗∗ 0.216 ∗∗∗ (21.245) (5.437) (0.061) (0.030) (0.021) (0.015) Withholding Base 10827.196 7293.079 -0.032 0.018 0.017 -0.031 ∗∗∗ (146.869) (37.665) (0.035) (0.021) (0.010) (0.008) Withheld Tax 146.758 78.916 1.419 ∗∗∗ 1.872 ∗∗∗ 2.423 ∗∗∗ 2.667 ∗∗∗ (5.691) (1.222) (0.375) (0.191) (0.093) (0.063) Withheld Tax Reclaims 137.523 67.647 1.464 ∗∗ 1.533 ∗∗∗ 2.141 ∗∗∗ 2.309 ∗∗∗ (4.965) (1.055) (0.543) (0.172) (0.109) (0.075) Net Tax Liability 703.196 458.880 -0.191 -0.068 -0.049 ∗ -0.048 ∗∗ (18.402) (4.549) (0.161) (0.043) (0.023) (0.015) Compensation Requests 15.696 5.116 0.763 ∗∗ 0.476 ∗ 0.123 0.000 (0.508) (0.108) (0.281) (0.208) (0.163) (.) Final Tax To Pay 664.067 419.057 -0.222 -0.094 ∗ -0.115 ∗∗∗ -0.111 ∗∗∗ (17.415) (4.084) (0.182) (0.047) (0.024) (0.015) Taxpayer Sales Tax Payment 646.775 423.248 -0.251 -0.108 ∗ -0.098 ∗∗∗ -0.100 ∗∗∗ (17.431) (4.144) (0.195) (0.047) (0.024) (0.016) Total Sales Tax Payment 802.957 528.147 0.158 0.254 ∗∗∗ 0.326 ∗∗∗ 0.519 ∗∗∗ (20.679) (5.215) (0.083) (0.034) (0.022) (0.018) Tot. Payment - Refund 802.576 527.766 0.160 0.253 ∗∗∗ 0.327 ∗∗∗ 0.518 ∗∗∗ (20.672) (5.212) (0.084) (0.034) (0.022) (0.018) Tot. Payment - Refund - IT Comp. 784.958 512.144 0.174 ∗ 0.257 ∗∗∗ 0.327 ∗∗∗ 0.546 ∗∗∗ (20.600) (5.179) (0.079) (0.034) (0.023) (0.019) ST + IT - Refund 1237.233 813.674 0.090 0.145 ∗∗∗ 0.225 ∗∗∗ 0.347 ∗∗∗ (31.134) (8.589) (0.060) (0.026) (0.016) (0.013) Observations 1069680 1069680 1069680 1069680 1069680 1069680 R2 0.001 0.008 0.962 0.916 0.899 0.880 Notes: This table displays pre-reform means in the treatment group (columns 1 and 2) and OLS estimates of the impact of the withholding rate increase on rms in the treatment group (rms with a predicted rate increase at reform time), as per equation 2 (columns 3-6). The rows reect dierent outcome variables, the columns reect dierent specications, as per the row and column titles. For columns 1 and 2, the data is winsorized at the 99.9th and 99th percentile respectively. Columns 3-6 allow for year and rm FE and a rm-specic linear time trend. Point estimates are marginal eects compared to the pre-reform average. Standard errors, clustered at the taxpayer level, are in parantheses. All amounts are in '000 CRC, deated with base in 01/2015 (1USD=530CRC). All outcome variables correspond to boxes on the sales tax return form, except the variables in the last three rows. Compensation requests are used to deduct any net credits or unreclaimed tax withheld from previous tax periods or from other taxes. Taxpayer payment is the payment made by the taxpayer at the end of each month. Total payment is the sum of taxpayer payment and any tax withheld. Total payment - refund subtracts any refund that taxpayers may have claimed on a separate form (refund request form 402). Total tpayment - refund - IT compensation additionally subtracts any compensation requests that the taxpayer requested on her income tax declaration. ST + IT - refund is the sum of total sales tax and total income tax payment (including tax withheld) minus any refund requested. 36 Table VII: Heterogeneity of Withholding Rate Impact (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Payment Liability Payment Liability Payment Liability Treat 0.290 ∗∗∗ 0.137 ∗∗∗ ∗∗∗ 0.328 0.188 ∗∗∗ ∗∗∗ 0.231 0.116 ∗∗∗ (0.021) (0.018) (0.021) (0.017) (0.018) (0.015) Treat x Self-Employed 0.554 ∗∗∗ 0.256 ∗∗∗ (0.042) (0.042) Treat x Never-Reclaimer ∗∗∗ 0.261 -0.059 (0.078) (0.072) Treat x From-Zero WHR Increase ∗∗∗ 1.681 0.400 ∗∗∗ (0.167) (0.135) Observations 1069680 1069680 1069680 1069680 1010120 1010120 R2 0.757 0.743 0.730 0.737 0.750 0.743 Notes: This table displays OLS estimates of the impact of the withholding rate increase on rms in the treatment group (rms with a predicted rate increase at reform time), as per equation 2. The columns denote the outcome variables, which are winsorized at the 99th percentile. Payment is total tax payment (constructed) and liability is gross tax liability, as in table VI. All amounts are in '000 CRC, deated with base in 01/2015 (1USD=530CRC). The treatment and control group are specied as in table VI. Never- Reclaimers are treated rms that do not make any reclaim, compensation request or refund request during the post-reform period. The label From-Zero Withholding Rate Increase indicates that rms experience an increase of the predicted withholding rate from zero to a positive rate at reform time, as opposed to other treated rms that were already subject to a non-zero withholding rate prior to reform time. We exclude from the former group all rms that experience that maximum rate increase of six percentage points, to ensure that the average rate increase in this group is not larger than the average rate increase among other treated rms. 37 Figure I: Withholding Systems and GDP per capita 40 30 ** ** * GDP pc 20 ** 10 0 N=31 N=35 N=53 N=60 N=19 N=10 N=36 N=16 H H H H d d d ed oa te oa W W W W et ge Br Br T T IT IT rg r VA VA Ta Ta H H o N W W o H H N T IT W W VA T IT VA Mean GDP pc Median GDP pc 95% CI Notes: This gure displays the mean and median GDP per capita, and the 95% condence interval of the mean, for dierent subsamples of countries. GDP per capita is measured in thousands of current USD from the World Development Indicators for 2013. The number below each bar displays the sample size. The stars reect the signicance levels of the mean dierence between two adjacent bars. The rst and second bar refer to countries that use and do not use withholding on the VAT/sales tax respectively. The third and fourth bar refer to countries that use and do not use withholding on business income taxes (i.e. income taxes on corporations and the self-employed/unincorporated businesses) respectively. The fth and sixth (seventh and eight) bar further divide the subsample of countries with VAT (income tax) withholding into countries that use a broad withholding regime (that applies across sectors), and those that use a targeted withholding regime, applicable only to certain sectors (e.g. construction, shing). The analysis is based on a sample of 118 countries for which data was available from the PKF International Worldwide Tax Guide 2015, recent EY International Tax Alerts, PWC Tax Summaries, or the secondary sources referenced in the introduction. The results are robust to using dierent denitions of GDP (e.g. purchasing power parity), limiting the sample to the 109 countries for which information was available from the PKF Guide, coding countries for which the guide does not specically mention withholding either as missing or as not having withholding, and dierent ways of dening targeted withholding systems. 38 Figure II: Impact of Desk Audits A: Income Tax 500 Share of revisers: 19% Initial tax declared: 759 mio CRC Increase post revision: 1335 mio CRC (+.12% of total revenue) 400 Cost: 5138*36,700 = 188 mio CRC Cost change (mio CRC) 100 200 300 0 0 100 200 300 400 500 Revenue change (mio CRC) Taxpayer-Year 45 degree line Linear fit B: Sales Tax 5 Share of revisers: 16% Initial tax declared: 165 mio CRC Change in Input Tax Credit (mio CRC) Increase post revision: 224 mio CRC (+.02% of total revenue) Cost: 2000*36,700 = 73 mio CRC 1 2 0 3 4 0 1 2 3 4 5 Change in Tax Collected (mio CRC) Taxpayer-Month 45 degree line Linear fit Notes: The gure shows the revenue and cost adjustments made by rms contacted via phone calls by tax ocers, after a desk audit uncovered a discrepancy between self-reported and third-party reported sales. The desk audits are for income tax returns for 2013 and 2014, and for sales tax returns for 2013. The gures focus on rms submitting a revised tax return, and display the change in revenue and costs (sales tax collected and input tax credit deducted in panel B), comparing the initial return with the revised return. The text displays the share of revisers, the initial tax declared by revisers, the dierence between their nal tax paid after revision and the initial tax declared, this dierence as a share of initial total tax revenue for the relevant tax and scal year, and the cost of the desk audit intervention. The cost is calculated by multiplying the number of cases by the daily wage of a tax ocer, accounting for the fact that tax ocers are asked to handle one case per day. 39 Figure III: Payment of Tax Liabilities A: Income Tax Average Payment Share of Net Liability, Income Tax 1 Average Payment Share .85 .9 .8 .95 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 Year Self-Employed, cut 04-2015 Corporations, cut 04-2015 Self-Employed, cut 04-2013 Corporations, cut 04-2013 Self-Employed, cut 04-2011 Corporations, cut 04-2011 B: Sales Tax Average Payment Share of Net Liability, Sales Tax 1.05 .8 .85 .9 .95 1 Average Payment Share .75 2009m1 2010m7 2012m1 2013m7 2015m1 Month Self-Employed, cut 04-2015 Corporations, cut 04-2015 Self-Employed, cut 04-2013 Corporations, cut 04-2013 Self-Employed, cut 04-2011 Corporations, cut 04-2011 Notes: This gure shows the average of the payment share, dened as the total payment made by the taxpayer for a specic tax period, divided by the nal tax liability to be paid for that period. The average is an unweighted average across all taxpayers with an positive nal liability for each scal period. The nal tax liability is net of any deduction made for tax withheld, and the payment data does not include tax withheld. The income tax data includes all declarations led and payments made by June 2015. The sales tax data includes all declarations led and payments made by October 2015. The blue series correspond to the self-employed and the red series corresponds to corporations. We show the series for three dierent cuts in the paymen data, taking into account all payments made before the cut date. 40 Figure IV: Bunching At First Income Tax Kink for Self-Employed 2006 2007 2008 1500 2000 1500 1500 Number of Taxpayers Number of Taxpayers Number of Taxpayers 1000 1000 1000 500 500 500 0 0 0 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 Taxable Income (in '000 colones) Taxable Income (in '000 colones) Taxable Income (in '000 colones) 2009 2010 2011 1500 2000 2000 1500 1500 Number of Taxpayers Number of Taxpayers Number of Taxpayers 1000 1000 1000 500 500 41 500 0 0 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 Taxable Income (in '000 colones) Taxable Income (in '000 colones) Taxable Income (in '000 colones) 2012 2013 2014 2000 1200 2500 1000 2000 1500 Number of Taxpayers Number of Taxpayers Number of Taxpayers 1500 800 1000 1000 600 500 500 400 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 Taxable Income (in '000 colones) Taxable Income (in '000 colones) Taxable Income (in '000 colones) Notes: The gures show the frequency distribution of taxable income of the self-employed (personas sicas con actividad lucrativa) around the rst kink in the income tax schedule, for the years 2006-2014. The data is aggregated in bins of  20,000. The black solid line marks the kink in year t (as per the gure title), the black dashed line marks the kink in year t − 1. Figure V: Bunching, Information Reporting and Withholding A: Self-Employed A1: No Information Reporting A2: Reporting by Firms A3: Reporting by State A4: Reporting by Credit/Debit Card .008 .008 .008 .008 .006 .006 .006 .006 Excess mass b=4.5(.3) Missing mass m=-.14(.07) Excess mass b=2.08(.18) Missing mass m=.75(.09) Excess mass b=2.17(.3) Missing mass m=.7(.16) Excess mass b=.52(.24) Missing mass m=.07(.07) Density Density Density Density .004 .004 .004 .004 .002 .002 .002 .002 0 0 0 0 50 100 150 50 100 150 50 100 150 50 100 150 Taxable Income/Kink (%) Taxable Income/Kink (%) Taxable Income/Kink (%) Taxable Income/Kink (%) Observed distribution Counterfactual Observed distribution Counterfactual Observed distribution Counterfactual Observed distribution Counterfactual B: Corporations B1: No Information Reporting B2: Reporting by Firms B3: Reporting by State B4: Reporting by Credit/Debit Card .0008 .002 .002 .002 Excess mass b=4.49(.48) Missing mass m=3.65(.97) Excess mass b=3.17(.22) Missing mass m=1.07(.21) Excess mass b=1.44(.39) Missing mass m=1.29(.44) Excess mass b=1.35(.33) Missing mass m=.37(.25) 42 .0006 .0015 .0015 .0015 Density Density Density Density .0004 .001 .001 .001 .0002 .0005 .0005 .0005 0 0 0 0 50 100 150 50 100 150 50 100 150 50 100 150 Total Revenue/Notch (%) Total Revenue/Notch (%) Total Revenue/Notch (%) Total Revenue/Notch (%) Observed distribution Counterfactual Observed distribution Counterfactual Observed distribution Counterfactual Observed distribution Counterfactual Notes: The gure shows the density distribution of taxable income for the self-employed around the rst kink in the income tax schedule (top row, A), and the density distribution of total revenue for corporations around the rst notch in the corporation tax schedule (bottom row, B). The data is pooled for years 2006-2015, represented as percentage distance from the kink, and aggregated in taxable income bins of 1%. The panels show the distribution for dierent subsamples, as per the panel titles that indicate whether and by what type of information reporting rms in the subsample are covered.. The blue dotted line marks the empirical distribution, the red solid line marks the counterfactual, tted as a exible polynomial to the observed distribution outside the excluded range. We use an tenth-degree polynomial for self-employed and a sixth-degree polynomial for corporations. The excluded range above the threshold covers four and seven bins respectively in the two groups of rms. The excess mass b and missing mass m are estimated as the dierence between the observed and estimated density, weighted by the height of the counterfactual density. The standard errors are bootstrapped. Figure VI: Event Study of Compliance After First Information Report A: Self-Employed A1: Report by Supplier A2: Report by Client A3: Report by State A4: Report by Credit/Debit Card 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.4 Change in Real Taxable Income Change in Real Taxable Income Change in Real Taxable Income [Sales DD=.17 (.01)] [Sales DD=.18 (.01)] [Sales DD=.17 (.01)] [Tax Collected DD=.12 (.01)] 1.3 [Costs DD=.14 (.01)] [Costs DD=.21 (.01)] [Costs DD=.15 (.01)] [Input Credit DD=.09 (.01)] 1.2 Change in Liability DD=.25 (.02) Income DD=.26 (.01) Income DD=.09 (.01) Income DD=.21 (.01) VA Rate DD=.14 (.01) 1.1 Profit Rate DD=.15 (.01) Profit Rate DD=-.03 (.01) Profit Rate DD=.07 (.01) 1 .9 .9 .9 .9 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 Event Time Event Time Event Time Event Time Control Group Event Group Control Group Event Group Control Group Event Group Control Group Event Group 6927 event group firms, 40266 control firms 21922 event group firms, 73177 control firms 3360 event group firms, 206071 control firms 4257 event group firms, 1089915 control firms . . . . B: Corporations B1: Report by Supplier B2: Report by Client B3: Report by State B4: Report by Credit/Debit Card 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.4 Change in Real Taxable Income Change in Real Taxable Income Change in Real Taxable Income [Sales DD=.3 (.03)] [Sales DD=.55 (.03)] [Sales DD=.14 (.01)] [Tax Collected DD=.19 (.01)] 1.3 43 [Costs DD=.28 (.03)] [Costs DD=.570 (.04)] [Costs DD=.14 (.01)] [Input Credit DD=.13 (.01)] 1.2 Change in Liability DD=.26 (.02) Income DD=.49 (.04) Income DD=.25 (.02) Income DD=.23 (.03) VA Rate DD=.2 (.01) 1.1 Profit Rate DD=.39 (.03) Profit Rate DD=.08 (.01) Profit Rate DD=.06 (.03) 1 .9 .9 .9 .9 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 Event Time Event Time Event Time Event Time Control Group Event Group Control Group Event Group Control Group Event Group Control Group Event Group 4574 event group firms, 38321 control firms 7620 event group firms, 43705 control firms 2303 event group firms, 139817 control firms 4259 event group firms, 1128297 control firms . . . . Notes: This gure displays event studies for dierent events, as indicated by the panel titles (rst information report led by the relevant reporting agent). The top row (A) is for the self-employed and the bottom row (B) for corporations. Each panel displays the year-on-year change (month-on-month change for credit/debit card reporting) in real reported taxable income (tax liability) for an event group (orange doted line) and an event control group (blue crossed line). The black solid line marks event time 0, when rms in the event group are reported to the tax authorities for the rst time by the reporting agent indicated in the panel title. The control group is reweighted by its propensity score of experiencing the event (cf. section 5.2, especially footnote 39, for details). Each group consists of a balanced panel of rms that can be observed for the entire period displayed. Panels A1-A3 and B1-B3 consider events happening in 2010-2012. Panels A4 and B4 consider events happening in 02/2009-08/2014. The text dispays the dierence-in-dierence coecient from estimating equation 1, for dierent outcomes variables as noted. VA stands for value-added rate. Figure VII: Withholding Rate Reform A: Withholding Rate (Full Sample) B: Withholding Rate (Prediction Sample) 5 5 Average Rate (%) 4 4 Average Rate 3 3 2 2010m8 2011m8 2012m8 2013m8 2014m8 Month 2 2008m8 2009m8 2010m8 2011m8 2012m8 2013m8 2014m8 Month Realized Rate Predicted Rate C: Number of Declarations D: Number of Declarations Matched 90000 40000 .27 .52 .26 85000 .51 Share Withholding 35000 Share Sales Tax .25 N Withholding N Sales Tax 80000 .5 .24 30000 .49 75000 .23 .22 .48 70000 25000 2008m8 2009m8 2010m8 2011m8 2012m8 2008m8 2009m8 2010m8 2011m8 2012m8 Month Month Share Sales Tax Declarations Matched With Withholding N Sales Tax Declarations N Withholding Declarations Share Withholding Declarations Matched With Tax Declaration E: Total Share of Card Sales F: Average Share of Card Sales .85 .6 .8 Slope= .004 (.002) ∆ Slope= 0.000 (0.000) Slope= .004 (.005) ∆ Slope= 0.000 (0.000) .55 .6 .65 .7 .75 ∆ Constant= -.01 (.013) .55 ∆ Constant= -.01 (.005) Share of Card Sales Share of Card Sales .45 .5 .5 .45 .4 .4 2008m8 2009m8 2010m8 2011m8 2012m8 2013m8 2014m8 2008m8 2009m8 2010m8 2011m8 2012m8 2013m8 2014m8 Month Month Share Linear Fit Share Linear Fit Notes: The gure displays the rst stage of the withholding rate reform and analyzes the reform's eect on credit/credit card use. Panel A shows the average realized withholding rate among all rms subject to withholding. Panel B shows the average realized and predicted withholding rate among rms for whom we can predict the withholding rate based on previous semester's tax returns and the withholding rate schedule in Table II. Panel C shows the number of sales tax declarations and credit/debit card withholding declarations presented to the tax authorities, correcting for revisions and duplicates. Panel D shows the share of sales tax declarations matched with at least one withholding declaration and vice-versa. Panel E shows the share of card sales in total sales among rms with a credit/debit card machine, and panel E shows the average over the rm-specic shares of card sales among rms with a credit/debit card machine. The black solid line in all panels marks 08/2011, when the increase in the withholding rate for the sales tax entered into eect. Panel E and F show a linear t that allows for a dierent trend and constant after the reform. The text displays the pre-reform slope of the linear t, and the change in slope and constant after the reform, along with standard errors in parantheses. 44 Figure VIII: Impact of Withholding Rate Increase DD=.326 (.022) 2.2 2 Change 1.5 1 .7 2010m1 2011m1 2012m1 2013m1 Month Treatment Group (Rate Increase) Control Group Notes: The gure displays the results of the dierence-in-dierence estimation of Equation 2, with total tax payment as outcome variable. It considers the overall impact of the reform, pooling all rms with a predicted rate increase in the treatment group. The control group includes rms experiencing no increase in the predicted withholding rate and rms not subject to withholding. The black solid line marks 08/2011, when the increase in withholding rates entered into eect. The data is winsorized by the 99th percentile, and scaled by the pre-reform average. The text displays the coecient β (marginal eect compared to pre-reform average) from estimating Equation 2. Figure IX: Aggregate Impact of Withholding Rate Increase Aggregate Sales Tax Revenue Aggregate Simplified Regime Tax Revenue 50 .5 Pre-Reform Mean: RD: 24.9 (3.19) ~ 8.4% Increase Pre-Reform Mean: RD: .026 (.053) 294.838 Bio. CRC .5 Bio. CRC Revenue Demeaned (Bio. Col) Revenue Demeaned (Bio. Col) .4 40 .3 30 .2 20 .1 10 0 -5 0 -.1 2008h2 2009h2 2010h2 2011h2 2012h2 2013h2 2008h2 2009h2 2010h2 2011h2 2012h2 2013h2 Semester Semester Tax Revenue Linear Fit Tax Revenue Linear Fit Notes: This gure shows the impact of the withholding rate reform in August 2011 on aggregate sales tax revenue (upper panel), and on aggregate revenue from the quarterly simplied regime tax, as a counterfactual (bottom panel). The sales tax data is based on ocial statistics from the Ministry of Finance, and the simplied regime data is based on rm-level tax declarations. The dots represent semester-wise tax revenue in billions of Costa Rican colones demeaned by the pre-reform semster-level means. For the upper panel, semesters are dened to t exactly around the time of the reform. For each year, the rst semester includes February to July, and the second semester includes August to December, and January of the following year. The red line is a linear t, allowing for a discontinuity at the time of the reform. The text displays the pre-reform semester-level mean revenue from the tax (in blue), and the coecient and standard error on the post-reform dummy (in red). The results are robust to running the analysis on monthly or quarterly data, using shorter or longer time series, and adding controls for the months of December and January (in the monthly data). 45 Figure X: Mechanisms of Withholding Rate Impact Default Mechanism: Incomplete Reclaim A: Share of Reclaimers B: Share of Withheld Tax Reclaimed Reclaimers over Withholdees Share of Withheld Tax Reclaimed 1.2 .7 .65 1.1 .6 1 Share Share .55 .9 .5 .45 .8 .4 2010m1 2011m1 2012m1 2013m1 2010m1 2011m1 2012m1 2013m1 Date Date Salience of Enforcement Mechanism: Increased Reporting C: Sales Tax Collected D: Input Tax Credit Deducted 1.3 1.3 DD=-.01 (.008) 1.2 1.2 DD=-.03 (.01) 1.1 1.1 Change Change 1 1 .9 .9 .8 .8 .7 .7 2010m1 2011m1 2012m1 2013m1 2010m1 2011m1 2012m1 2013m1 Month Date Treatment Group (Rate Increase) Control Group Treatment Group (Rate Increase) Control Group E: Gross Tax Liability F: Number of Audits 1000 DD=.167 (.021) 1.8 900 1.6 Number of Audits 800 Change 1.4 700 1.2 600 1 500 .8 2010m1 2011m1 2012m1 2013m1 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 Month Year Treatment Group (Rate Increase) Control Group N planned audits N planned (non-LTU firms) Notes: The gure displays evidence on the mechanisms for the withholding rate impact. In all panels, the black solid line marks 08/2011, when the increase in withholding rates entered into eect. Panels A and B display, for all rms subject to withholding in a given month, the share of rms making a reclaim, and the average share of withheld tax reclaimed. The shares are winsorized by the 99.9th percentile. Panels C, D and E show results of the dierence-in-dierence estimation of Equation 2, with dierent outcome variables, as indicated by the gure titles. The treatment group includes rms experiencing an increase in the predicted withholding rate in 08/2011, the control group includes rms experiencing no increase in the predicted withholding rate and rms not subject to withholding. The data is winsorized by the 99th percentile, and scaled by the pre-09/2011 average. The text displays the coecient β (marginal eect compared to pre- reform average) from estimating Equation 2. Panel F shows the evolution over time of the number of planned audits for all taxpayers and for taxpayers who are part of the large taxpayer unit, as per the annual work programs of the audit department. 46 8 Appendix 8.1 Algorithm to Estimate Non-Filing: Income Tax This section describes the procedure by which the pool of income tax-liable taxpayers is constructed for each year between 2010 and 2013. This pool forms the sample for Tables IV and VIII. The following algorithm is used to identify tax-liable rms: ˆ Income tax ling: Firms that declare income tax in current scal year t and are not found to have deregistered or switched to a simplied (non-tax-liable) regime by year t are included in the pool of income tax-liable taxpayers. Additionally, rms that led in the previous year t − 1 and did not deregister or switch regimes in the interim are included to capture taxpayers who were previously identied as income tax-liable and then do not le in subsequent years. This condition is applied to generate the sample used in Table IV; for the sample used in Table VIII, the rule is extended to include rms that declared income tax in any year between t−1 and t−3 for years 2011 and later and between t−1 and t−4 for years prior to 2011, which are the historical rules ocially applied by the tax authority for determining income tax liability, though in practice this condition may not have been systematically applied. ˆ Registration: Firms that are found to have registered with the tax authority in any of the previous three years prior to the current scal year t but did not le income tax returns in the current scal year are included. This step identies rms that are ocially registered as tax-liable but which did not le for the years during which these rms were registered, which step 1 does not capture as it relies only on the records of lings. ˆ Subsequent deregistration: In addition to identifying rms that are registered but do not le for income tax in prior years in step 2, rms that deregister in years following the current scal year t but are not found to have registered in year t or the previous three years are classied as having been income tax-liable despite not appearing on the ocial registration roster. ˆ Declaring sales tax in current scal year: Firms that declare sales tax in any of the months of the current scal year t - which spans from October of year t−1 to September of year t - are included in the pool of income tax-liable taxpayers. This rule corresponds to the tax authority's ocial regulation that rms liable for sales tax are also deemed liable for paying income tax (though the reverse is not true). ˆ Informative declarations: Records of transactions between rms or between rm and the government provide information on the sales and costs of individual rms that can be used to 47 identify income tax-liable taxpayers. Firms that report or are reported as having tax-liable sales in the current scal through the third-party reporting mechanisms described above are included in the pool of income tax-liable rms. 8.2 Algorithm to Estimate Non-Filing: Sales Tax This section describes the procedure by which the pool of sales tax-liable taxpayers are constructed for each month of scal years 2011 to 2013. This pool forms the sample for Tables IV and VIII, which reports the average of the monthly values for each measure in corresponding scal year. The following algorithm, which is similar to the method used to identify income tax-liable rms, is used to identify sales tax-liable rms: ˆ Income tax ling: Firms that declare sales tax in month m of the current scal year t and are not found to have deregistered or switched to a simplied (non-tax-liable) regime by month m in year t are included in the pool of sales tax-liable taxpayers. Additionally, rms that led in the previous four months - m−4 to m−1 - and did not deregister or switch regimes in the interim are included to capture taxpayers who were previously identied as sales tax-liable and then do not le in subsequent months. This could include rms that either declare sales tax in previous months within the same scal year or in months falling within the previous scal year t − 1, depending on the month. This condition is applied to generate the sample used in Table IV; for the sample used in Table VIII, the rule is extended to include rms that declared sales tax in months between m − 12 and m − 1. ˆ Registration: Firms that are found to have registered with the tax authority in any of the previous thirty six months (three years) prior to the current month m of scal year t but did not declare sales tax in month m are included. This step identies rms that are ocially registered as tax-liable but which did not le for the years during which these rms were registered, which step 1 does not capture as it relies only on the records of lings. ˆ Subsequent deregistration: In addition to identifying rms that are registered but do not le for income tax in prior years in step 2, rms that deregister in months following the current month m but are not found to have registered within the previous thirty six months are classied as having been income tax-liable despite not appearing on the ocial registration roster. ˆ Informative declarations: Firms that are reported as having been subject to withholding by credit/debit card companies are considered tax-liable for the sales tax. 48 Table VIII: Non-Filing [Less Conservative Estimates] Panel A: Non-ling among all tax-liable rms (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Non-lers' Unreported Of which Undeclared TPI sales as % liability as % % Non-lers registered sales as % of of declared of declared non-lers declared sales TPI sales liability Income Tax 2010 0.420 0.335 0.154 0.225 0.081 Income Tax 2011 0.509 0.239 0.195 0.246 0.077 Income Tax 2012 0.547 0.218 0.114 0.189 0.076 Income Tax 2013 0.586 0.266 0.112 0.203 0.104 Sales Tax 2011 0.335 0.960 . . . Sales Tax 2012 0.325 0.955 . . . Sales Tax 2013 0.372 0.962 . . . Panel B: Non-ling among registered rms Self-Employed Corporations All Self-Employed Corporations with TPI with TPI Income Tax 2010 0.195 0.158 0.131 0.155 0.073 Income Tax 2011 0.198 0.161 0.134 0.143 0.071 Income Tax 2012 0.209 0.153 0.126 0.128 0.051 Income Tax 2013 0.273 0.215 0.158 0.216 0.067 Sales Tax 2011 0.326 0.439 0.155 0.192 0.073 Sales Tax 2012 0.315 0.423 0.126 0.185 0.054 Sales Tax 2013 0.363 0.478 0.101 0.185 0.040 Panel C: Non-ling among rms covered by information reporting Reported by Reported by Reported by All card rms state companies Income Tax 2010 0.573 0.578 0.235 0.293 . Income Tax 2011 0.652 0.658 0.202 0.297 . Income Tax 2012 0.672 0.678 0.186 0.308 . Income Tax 2013 0.676 0.681 0.177 0.320 . Notes: These three panels show the share of non-lers for the income tax (rows 1-4) and the sales tax (rows 5-7). Non-lers are tax liabile rms which have not submitted their own tax declaration for the relevant scal period. The algorithm used to construct the share of non-lers is explained in appendix section 8.1. The share of non-lers for the sales tax is an average across months in a scal year. Panel A shows the share of non-lers among all tax liable rms (column 1), the share of non-lers that a registered (2), non-lers' third-party reported sales as share of lers' reported sales (3), non-lers' estimates sales as share of declared sales (4), and non-lers' estimated tax liability as share of declared tax liability (5). TPI stands for third- party information, and TPI sales is the sum of all third-party reports except cost reports. A non-ling rm's estimated sales in in period t are the maximum of its third-party reported sales in t and its self-reported sales in the most recent prior reporting period. A non-lers' tax liability is estimated using its estimated sales, applying the average prot rate of lers in the corresponding decile of the sales distribution of lers, and the applying the tax schedule. Panel B reports the share of non-lers among all registered rms (1), and among subsamples and registered rms as indicated by the column headings (2-5). Panel C reports the share of non-lers among all rms covered by information reporting (1), and among subsamples of rms reported by dierent informing agents, as indicated by the column headings (2-4). 49 Figure XI: Impact of Income Tax Withholding for Firms Gross Tax Liability 1.4 DD=.237 (.018) Year-on-Year Change 1 1.2 Introduction of CIT WH .8 2008 2010 2012 2014 2015 Year Treatment Group (Withholdees) Control Group Notes: This gure shows the impact of the introduction on withholding for the income tax in 2015 (corpo- ration and self-employed) on reported gross tax liability, using a dierence-in-dierence estimation similar to equation 2, but on annual data. The treatment group contains rms that are subject to income tax withholding for the rst time in scal year 2015. 50 Figure XII: Card Machine Statement Notes: This gure shows an example of the credit/debit card marchine statement, that card processing companies provide to their aliated businesses (clients) on a daily or monthly basis. The statement lists transaction amounts, withholding for the income tax and the sales tax remitted to the tax authorities and commissions to the card processing company. 51 References Allingham, Michael G., & Sandmo, Agnar . 1972. Income Tax Evasion: A Theoretical Anal- ysis. Journal of Public Economics, 1, 323338. Almunia, Miguel, & Rodriguez, David Lopez . 2015. Under the Radar: The Eects of Moni- toring Firms on Tax Compliance. Social Science Research Network, August. Bachas, Pierre, & Soto, Mauricio . 2016. Not(ch) Your Average Tax System: Corporate Taxation Under Weak Enforcement. Mimeo. Barr, Michael S., & Dokko, Jane K. 2008. Paying to save: tax withholding and asset allocation among low- and moderate-income taxpayers. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2008-11. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.). Besley, Timothy J., & Persson, Torsten . 2013 (Jan.). Taxation and Development. CEPR Discussion Papers 9307. C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers. Best, Michael, Brockmeyer, Anne, Kleven, Henrik, Spinnewijn, Johannes, & Waseem, Mazhar . 2015. Production vs Revenue Eciency with Low Tax Compliance: Theory and Evidence from Pakistan. Journal of Political Economy, 123(6), 13111355. Best, Michael Carlos . 2014. Salary Misreporting and the Role of Firms in Workers' Responses to Taxes: Evidence from Pakistan. Mimeo. Best, Michael Carlos, & Kleven, Henrik Jacobsen . 2015. Housing Market Responses to Transaction Taxes: Evidence from Notches and Stimulus in the UK. Mimeo. Brockmeyer, Anne, Hernandez, Marco, Smith, Spencer, & Kettle, Stewart . 2015. Casting the Tax Net Wider: Experimental Evidence from Costa Rica. Mimeo. Bruhn, Miriam, & McKenzie, David . 2014. Entry Regulation and the Formalization of Mi- croenterprises in Developing Countries. World Bank Research Observer, 29(2), 186201. Carillo, Paul, Emran, Shahe, & Rivadeneira, Anita . 2012. Do cheaters bunch together? Prot taxes, withholding rates and tax evasion. Mimeo. Carrillo, Paul, Pomeranz, Dina, & Singhal, Monica . 2016. Dodging the Taxman: Firm Misreporting and Limits to Tax Enforcement. Chetty, Raj, Looney, Adam, & Kroft, Kory . 2009. Salience and Taxation: Theory and Evidence. American Economic Review, 99(4), 114577. 52 Chetty, Raj, Friedman, John, Olsen, Tore, & Pistaferri, Luigi . 2011. Adjustment Costs, Firm Responses, and Micro vs. Macro Labor Supply Elasticities: Evidence from Danish Tax Records. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126, 749804. Chetty, Raj, Friedman, John N., Leth-Petersen, Súren, Nielsen, Torben Heien, & Olsen, Tore . 2014. Active vs. Passive Decisions and Crowd-Out in Retirement Savings Accounts: Evidence from Denmark. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(3), 11411219. de Mel, Suresh, McKenzie, David, & Woodruff, Christopher . 2013. The Demand for, and Consequences of, Formalization among Informal Firms in Sri Lanka. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 5(2), 12250. Del Carpio, Lucia . 2014. Are the Neighbors Cheating? Evidence from Social Norm Experiment on Property Taxes in Peru. Mimeo. DiNardo, John, Fortin, Nicole M., & Lemieux, Thomas . 1996. Labor Market Institutions and the Distributoin of Wages, 1973-1992: A Semiparametric Approach. Econometrica, 64(5), 10011044. Finkelstein, Amy . 2009. E-ztax: Tax Salience and Tax Rates. The Quarterly Journal of Eco- nomics, 124(3), 9691010. Fisman, Raymond, & Wei, Shang-Jin . 2004. Tax Rates and Tax Evasion: Evidence from "Missing Imports" in China. Journal of Political Economy, 112(2), 471500. Gandhi, Ashvin, & Kuehlwein, Michael . 2014. Reexamining Income Tax Overwithholding as a Response to Uncertainty. Public Finance Review. Gordon, Roger, & Li, Wei . 2009. Tax structures in developing countries: Many puzzles and a possible explanation. Journal of Public Economics, 93(7-8), 855866. Hacienda . 2015. Incumplimiento Tributario en Impuestos sobre la Renta y Ventas, 2010-2013. Tech. rept. Ministerio de Hacienda, Costa Rica. Highfill, Jannett, Thorson, Douglas, & Weber, William V. 1998. Tax Overwithholding as a Response To Uncertainty. Public Finance Review, 26(4), 376391. Hilger, Nathaniel G. 2014. Parental Job Loss and Children's Long-Term Outcomes: Evidence from 7 Million Fathers' Layos. Mimeo. IRS . 2012. Tax Year 2006 Tax Gap Estimates. Tech. rept. Internal Revenue Service. FS-2012-6. 53 Johnson, Eric J., & Goldstein, Daniel . 2003. Do Defaults Save Lives? Science, 302(5649), 13381339. Keen, Michael . 2008. VAT, taris, and withholding: Border taxes and informality in developing countries. Journal of Public Economics, 92(10-11), 18921906. Keen, Michael, & Slemrod, Joel . 2016 (July). Optimal Tax Administration. Working Paper 22408. National Bureau of Economic Research. Kleven, Henrik . 2016. Bunching. Annual Review of Economics, forthcoming, 8. Kleven, Henrik J., & Waseem, Mazhar . 2013. Using Notches to Uncover Optimization Fric- tions and Structural Elasticities: Theory and Evidence from Pakistan. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128, 669723. Kleven, Henrik Jacobsen, Knudsen, Martin B., Kreiner, Claus Thustrup, Pedersen, Søren, & Saez, Emmanuel . 2011. Unwilling or Unable to Cheat? Evidence From a Tax Audit Experiment in Denmark. Econometrica, 79(3), 651692. Kleven, Henrik Jacobsen, Kreiner, Claus Thustrup, & Saez, Emmanuel . 2016. Why Can Modern Governments Tax So Much? An Agency Model of Firms as Fiscal Intermediaries. Economica, 83(330), 219246. Kopczuk, Wojciech, & Slemrod, Joel . 2006. Putting Firms into Optimal Tax Theory. Amer- ican Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 96(2), 130134. Kopczuk, Wojciech, Marion, Justin, Muehlegger, Erich, & Slemrod, Joel . 2016. Does Tax-Collection Invariance Hold? Evasion and the Pass-Through of State Diesel Taxes. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 8(2), 25186. Kumler, Todd, Verhoogen, Eric, & Frías, Judith A. 2015. Enlisting Workers in Improving Payroll-Tax Compliance: Evidence from Mexico. NBER Working Paper 19385. Madrian, Brigitte C., & Shea, Dennis F. 2001. The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) Participation and Savings Behavior. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(4), 11491187. Naritomi, Joana . 2015. Consumers as Tax Auditors. Mimeo. OECD . 2009. Withholding and information reporting regimes for small or medium-sized businesses and self-employed taxpayers, Information Note. Tech. rept. OECD. 54 Pomeranz, Dina . 2015. No Taxation without Information: Deterrence and Self-Enforcement in the Value Added Tax. American Economic Review, 105(8), 25392569. Rijkers, Bob, Baghdadi, Leila, & Raballand, Gael J. R. F. 2015 (June). Political con- nections and tari evasion : evidence from Tunisia. Policy Research Working Paper Series 7336. The World Bank. Saez, Emmanuel . 2010. Do Taxpayers Bunch at Kink Points? American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2(3), 180212. Samanamud, Enrique . 2013. Estudio comparado de los regimenes de retenciones y percepciones del IVA e impuesto a la renta en America Latina y el Caribe. Tech. rept. Inter-American Centre of Tax Administrations. Seim, David . 2015. Behavioral Responses to an Annual Wealth Tax: Evidence from Sweden. Mimeo. Slemrod, Joel . 2008. Does It Matter Who Writes the Check to the Government? The Economics of Tax Remittance. National Tax Journal, 61(2), 25175. Slemrod, Joel B., Collins, Brett, Hoopes, Jeffrey L., Reck, Daniel H., & Sebas- tiani, Michael Does Credit-Card Information Reporting Improve Small-Business Tax . 2015. Compliance? Mimeo. Soos, Pirosko . 1990. Self-employed evasion and tax withholding: a comparative study and analysis of the issues. UC Davis Law Review, 24(107), 107193. Thaler, Richard, & Benartzi, Shlomo . 2004. Save more tomorrow: Using behavioral eco- nomics to increase employee saving. The Journal of Political Economy, 112(1), 164187. United Nations . 2014. Measuring Tax Transactions Costs in Small and Median Enterprises. Tech. rept. United Nations and Inter-American Centre of Tax Administrations. White, Richard A., Harrison, Paul D., & Harrell, Adrian . 1993. The Impact of Income Tax Withholding on Taxpayer Compliance: Further Empirical Evidence. Journal of the American Taxation Associationl, May, 6378. Yagan, Danny . 2015. Capital Tax Reform and the Real Economy: The Eects of the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut. American Economic Review, forthcoming. Zucman, Gabriel . 2013. The Missing Wealth of Nations: Are Europe and the U.S. net Debtors or net Creditors?*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(3), 13211364. 55