£4P5 a 3 70 POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 2370 A New Model for Market- To bring fiscal discipline to state and municipal Based Regulation of govemments. Mexico's Subnational Borrowing federal government has established a rwo-pillar framework that explicitly The Mexican Approach renounces federal bail-outs and establishes a Basel- consistent link between the Marcelo Giugale capital-risk weighting of bank Adam Korobow loans to subnational Steven Webb governments and the borrower's credit rating. Whether the framework succeeds will depend partly on market assessments of the government's commitment to enforce bank capital rules and refrain from bailing out defaulting subnational governments. The World Bank Latin America and the Caribbean Region Mexico Country Department and Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Sector Unit July 2000 POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 2370 Summary findings Faced with weak subnational finances that pose a risk to municipal clients; differentiate interest rates on the basis macroeconomic stability, Mexico's federal government in of the borrowers' creditworthiness; and elicit a strong April 2000 established an innovative incentive demand for institutional development at the subnational framework to bring fiscal discipline to state and level. municipal governments. But its success will depend on three factors critical to That framework is based on two pillars: an explicit implementation: renunciation of federal bail-outs and a Basel-consistent * Whether markets find the federal commitment not link between the capital-risk weighting of bank loans to to bail out defaulting subnational governments credible. subnational governments and the borrower's credit * Whether subnational governments have access to rating. financing other than bank loans. In theory, this new regulatory arrangement should * How well bank capital rules are enforced. reduce moral hazard among banks and their state and This paper - a product of the Mexico Country Department and Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Sector Unit, Latin America and the Caribbean Region - is part of a larger effort in the region to understand the subnational underpinnings of sustainable, national economic framework. Copies of the paper are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Please contact Michael Geller, room I4-142, telephone 202-458-5155, fax 202-522-2093, email address mgeller@worldbank.org. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at www.worldbank.org/research/workingpapers. The authors may be contacted at mgiugale@worldbank.org, akorobow@worldbank.org, or swebbaworldbank.org. July 2000. (25 pages) The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the view of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. Produced by the Policy Research Dissemination Center COMMENTS WELCOME A New Model for Market-based Regulation of Subnational Borrowing: The Mexican Approach Marcelo Giugale, Adam Korobow, and Steven Webb JEL Classification: H74 1/ Giugale is the Lead Economist of the World Bank's Mexico Country Department. Korobow is a Research Associate at the same department. Webb is a Senior Decentralization Specialist at the World Bank's Vice-Presidency for Latin America and the Caribbean. A New Model for Market-based Regulation of Subnational Borrowing: The Mexican Approach Introduction Much as defaults on commercial banks' liabilities (in particular, deposits) carry systemic costs that far out-weigh private considerations, the liabilities of sub-national governments in federal systems can also generate large, negative externalities for the country as a whole. While those governments have a constitutional right to manage their own finances, including borrowing decisions, the cost of their financial performance is spread to other states, to the federal government and, sometimes, even to other countries. The experience of the Brazilian state of Minas Gerais in January 1999 is a clear example of the wedge between a single state's private cost of default and the economy- and region- wide social cost of that default.' There is, in other words, a public good case for regulating sub-national borrowing. While the externalities involved in commercial banking have led to a well- developed regulatory practice (and literature), relatively less is known or commonly accepted about sub-national borrowing regulation, especially in developing countries.2 This dearth of knowledge is odd as, in those countries, the bulk of the sub-national borrowing is financed by domestic banks, leading to an important second-order externality implicit in state defaults. In principle, a large state's reneging from its bank debt 1 See for example, "Brazil's Government Pays Foreign Debt Owed by One of Its States," The New York Times, February 11, 1999, Thursday. 2.Taken together, Ter-Minassian and Craig (1997), Freire and Huertas (1999), and Dillinger and Webb (1999) provide a good sampler of development-country oriented literature available in this area. 2 obligations compromises not only the market access of other states and, internationally, of the federal government, but also the banks' ability to service their deposits. Those first- and second-order externalities make federal bail-outs of defaulting states virtually inevitable (effectively distributing the cost of the state's default among the tax-payers of all the states in the federation). This, ex-ante, generates moral hazard of two types-it fosters irresponsible borrowing by the states and irresponsible lending by their bankers. The danger of irresistible pressure for federal bailouts, and thus of both types of moral hazard, is increased when the borrowers are sub-national governments with service provision responsibilities that are important to the national government, such as primary schooling and police protection. This is typical of developing countries, like Mexico, where political expediency hastened expenditure decentralization without prior establishment of an adequate regulatory framework for state and municipal borrowing. This paper describes and analyzes Mexico's innovative approach to regulating sub- national bank borrowing. It starts by presenting the context in which that approach was introduced in April 2000 as well as the regulatory regime's main policy components. A theoretical model is then developed to examine the economic underpinnings of the regime, and is simulated under various parametric structures. This helps identify the main conditions for Mexico's sub-national bank borrowing regulation to achieve its core objective, namely, to minimize the cost of federal bail-outs while fostering efficiency- enhancing, risk-based interest rate differentiation across sub-national borrowers. Three such conditions are shown to be critical: (i) the market credibility of the federal commitment not to bail-out defaulting sub-nationals; (ii) the sub-nationals' access to 3 financing other than bank loans; and (iii) the quality of the enforcement of bank capital rules. Sub-national Borrowing in Mexico: The Initial Position Sub-national debt in Mexico has so far not been a national macroeconomic problem (as it has in Brazil for example), but it could rapidly become one. In 1997, the recorded stock of state and municipal debt was equivalent to about 2 percent of Mexico's GDP (and about 6 percent of total public debt).3 By comparison, sub-national debt amounts to 5 percent of GDP in Argentina, almost 20 percent in Canada, and somewhat above that level in Brazil. In addition, the Mexican constitution prohibits states from borrowing in foreign exchange or from foreign creditors. Behind Mexico's relatively comfortable sub-national debt statistics, however, lie three potential destabilizing factors-moral hazard, limited actual servicing capacity, and contingent liabilities. Prior to the 1990s the federal government, through the governing party's infrastructure, had control over the state governments, and thus ultimately over any state borrowing decisions Over the course of the 1990s, rapid democratization ended much of this federal political control, which allowed states to take advantage of the federal government's concern for both the banking system (which, following its 1995 crisis, had 3. Most Mexican states have much less disposable income to service debt than usual accounting would suggest, since much of their current expenditures is "tied" to defacto inflexible commitments (notably salaries). The ratio of debt stock to disposable revenue, the latter defined as own taxes plus untied transfers, ranges from a maximum of 1.8 (in Sonora) to a minimum of 0.02 (in Hidalgo). By that measure, the eight most indebted states are Sonora, Nuevo Le6n, Mdxico, Queretaro, Quintana Roo, Baja California Sur, Jalisco, and Sinaloa, all with a ratio of debt stock to disposable revenue greater than 1 (Hemandez and Oliveira, 2000). 4 problems of its own) and for the ability of states to continue delivering important public services which had been decentralized. Indeed, both states and banks in Mexico had witnessed many federal bailouts in the past and had come to expect them, thus making borrowing a means through which states could obtain extra federal resources transferred to them directly or through their creditors. The federal government's capacity to deliver those transfers was embedded in its annual budget through a special and often large line-item to be allocated at the Executive's discretion (especially within Ramo 23). All states received bailouts in the wake of the 1995 crisis, and a few states have received bailouts since then when guarantees came due on large infrastructure projects. Perhaps more importantly, the federal government's practice of accepting state mandatos (mandates) to act as a trustee in servicing state debt that had been collateralized withparticipaciones (revenue sharing) became a defacto pre-condition for states to have access to credit markets, not just because of the value of the collateral but because of the perceived blessing and guarantee by the federal government. Legally, a mandato became a perfect "intercept" for the lenders, whereby the federation would automatically pay back bank loans out of the participaciones that would otherwise correspond to the debtor state, before the monies could reach that state and, thus, without violating its constitutional jurisdiction. Not surprisingly, few commercial banks developed their institutional capacity to assess sub-national lending, even though they have been active in this market. Structural problems in the financial markets that were exposed in the aftermath of the 1995 banking crisis (e.g., weak commercial guarantee and bankruptcy laws; limited judicial capacity) 5 drove banks away from private borrowers and toward secured lending possibilities with federal and state government entities. The existence of a regimen de excepci6n, whereby usual regulatory limits to single-customer exposure (concentration limits) did not apply to loans given to sub-national governments made those possibilities all the more attractive. In sum, the combination of sovereign states ability to make independent borrowing decisions along with increasing expenditure responsibilities, banks with a need for secured lending options, and a federal government with a track record of acting as last-resort lender put Mexico in an uncomfortable position with regard to sub-national liabilities and their potential impact on the country's macroeconomic stability. A New Approach to Sub-national Borrowing Regulation To reverse the situation, Mexico's federal government faced the challenge of both imposing ex-ante, market-based mechanisms that would prevent excessive sub-national borrowing and at the same time convey a credible signal that it would not, ex-post, bail- out the parties involved in such borrowing. In response to this challenge, it introduced in late 1999 (with full effect as of April 2000) a new regulatory framework for debt management by the states and municipalities. This framework is made up of the following six components: 1. A renunciation, and ensuing removal from the federal budget for 2000, of the Executive's power for discretionary transfer. Naturally, this policy proved uncontroversial with the opposition-dominated Congress. 2. The abolition of the mandatos. This left the states and their creditors to make their own fideicomiso (trust) arrangements for the collateralization of debt with 6 parficipaciones or other revenue flows, assuming the legal risks involved and without recourse to the federation. 3. The elirnination of the so-called regimen de excepci6n to single-customer exposure ceilings. This limits the extent of financial-sector damage that one single state can cause and signals that state debt must be evaluated on a basis similar with other debt. 4. The establishment of a link between the capital risk weighting of bank loans to sub- national governments and those governments' credit rating. In particular, two, current, published, global-scale local-currency credit ratings performed by internationally reputable credit rating agencies are to be used by bank regulators to assign capital risk weightings (between 20 and 115 percent) to loans given to state and municipalities. The rules for assigning these weights are fully specified by regulation. This innovative scheme, which is in line with the Basle Committee's recommendations of June 1999, is based on the distance between the rating obtained by the sub-national borrower in question and the rating of the local-currency debt of the federal government. To control for agency shopping, two ratings are called for by the regulation and, in case of large discrepancies (more than two grades of distance), the capital weighting of the worse rating applies. The purpose of these regulations is, of course, to make the pricing of bank loans a function of the underlying risk of the sub-national borrower, especially in the new framework characterized by the absence of federal intervention. Financially weaker states are likely to be priced or rationed out of the market (and become conditional 7 clients of the development banks-see below), while stronger states would see the price of loans fall. 5. Registration of sub-national loans with the federal government was made conditional upon the borrowing state or municipality being current on its publication of debt and associated fiscal statistics from the preceding year's final accounts, and on all of its debt service obligations toward the Government's development banks. At the same time, and to make that registration appealing, unregistered loans are automatically risk weighted by the regulators at 150 percent. This additional incentive to achieve transparency has the purpose of ensuring that private contracting between the sub- national borrowing and the credit rating agencies does not lead to the withholding of a minimum of quantitative information on borrower finances. Ultimately, the discipline on these governments will arise only if voters and opposition parties have access to full information about the fiscal behavior of the administration in office. 6. Finally, and as a matter of corporate policy, federally-owned development banks are to make new loans to states and municipalities only when the loan in question qualifies for registration and its corresponding capital risk weighting is less than 100 percent. This policy, coupled with the previously mentioned conditions for registration, makes the development banks part of the rigor of the new regulatory scheme, rather than allowing them to function as a potential loophole. Lending to weaker sub-nationals is not forbidden, after all, these are the clients whom the development banks are mandated to assist. Instead, sub-national loans with risk weightings of more than 100 percent are allowed if the loan package 8 contains a technical assistance component funded by an international development bank. This latter arrangement conveys the signal that, when the loan is particularly risky (and correspondingly expensive), its origination and supervision is subject to a neutral, independent party. The Theory Behind the Rules How does Mexico's regulatory environment for sub-national bank borrowing work, that is, provide incentive for interest rates to reflect the creditworthiness of the borrowers and reduce the expected cost of federal bail-outs? This section addresses that question by developing and simulating a simple, one-period model of interest rate determination in the sub-national loan market. Rational, profit-maximizing banks operating in competition will be shown to generate interest and bail-out cost outcomes that critically depend on the perceived (not necessarily the declared) attitude of the federation toward bail-outs; the existence of alternate means of financing for sub-national governrnents; and the quality of banking supervision. This sets up the stage for simulating the effect of Mexico's new regulations under various parametric structures. The model will assume that, at the beginning of the period, the representative bank ignores what the repayment capacity or asset value, A, of the sub-national borrower will be at the end of the period, when the loan must be repaid. It knows, however, that there are two possible outcomes for A: a high value, AH, and a low value, AL, which is some proportion, p, of the high value, so that AL = p AH, where 0 < p < 1. For simplification, and with no loss of generality, AH is here normalized so that AH1 and AL=p. Thus, A = {AL, A, 3 = {p, 1}. The probability of a low outcome, o- e [0,1], is also known to the 9 bank. In practice, A can be thought of as the ex-post capacity of a borrowing state or municipality to repay its debts, a variable usually associated with, among others, local business cycles and fiscal efforts. Three other factors will play a critical role in the bank's sub-national lending decision: a) the portion of the loan's service that the federal government is expected to bail out, m E [0,1]; b) the capital risk weighting, w E [0,+oo), required by the regulations for bank loans to states and municipalities; and c) the quality of banking supervision, denoted here by q E [0,1], i.e., the resulting effectiveness with which capital risk weighting regulations are enforced. The three factors are at the core of Mexico's new regulatory system for sub-national borrowing. By renouncing its powers to execute discretionary transfers in its budget for the year 2000 (and, supposedly, thereafter), the federal government vastly reduced, if not eliminated, the perception that it would bail-out sub- nationals that default on their debt. By linking capital risk weights to credit ratings, the value of w varies across states and municipalities, rather than being uniform for all loans to sub-national governrments. Finally, through a package of reforms put in motion in September 1999, rules for bank capital formation and accounting were brought up to internationally accepted standards and are gradually being enforced4. Given these framework conditions, a form for the supply of bank loans to sub- national governments, L', can be developed. Equation (1) and (2) below, define the expected revenue and expected cost of the representative bank in the one-period sub- national loan market: 4For a description of the September 1999 banking reforms, see the website of La Comisi6n Nacional Bancariay de Valores http://www.cnbv.gob.mx/index.htm. 10 E[R]=(1-o-).P i,+ o-m-L'S i (1) E[C]=Ls id +q.w.p.L'+a-c(l-m)-(Ji -AL) (2) where i,, id, and pE(-oo,+oo) are the loan interest rate, the deposit interest rate and the return on the bank's equity (or opportunity cost of capital), respectively. Equation (1) states that the expected revenue of the bank is not only a function of the risk of default by the sub-national borrower, but also of the portion, m, of the loan that the federal government is expected to bailout if default takes place. As m approaches 1, the moral hazard inherent in the market increases, and thus it is more likely that the lenders will receive their due revenue in full, or simply E[R] = il . Similarly, Equation (2) argues that the expected cost of the loan depends on the cost of funds, the cost of fulfilling capital risk weighting regulations (given the quality of enforcement)5 and, in the event of default, the portion of the unpaid balance (that is, the loan's principal minus the low asset value, AL) not bailed out by the federal government.6 If there is close to perfect moral hazard, m-)l, and no capital risk weighting requirements exist, w -O, or the quality of their enforcement is poor, q->O, the expected per unit cost of the loan approaches the deposit interest rate, E[C] - 'd. Assuming that the market for loans is competitive, i.e., equilibrium is characterized by no supra-nornal profits and E[JR] = E[Cj, the following implicit function for the supply of loans obtains from equations (1) and (2): 5 We adapt the middle tenn of Equation (2) from LUvy-Garboua (1993). 6Note that E[ A] = a - AL + (1 - a-) AH . However, since the bank would never lend more thanAH (net of interest), it will, in the event of a high outcome, recover its principal and make its return on the loan, L i l, in full. Thus only AL factors into the expected cost function. 11 i= id +qwp+ lC.(1-m){(I + _ ) (3) In addition to the cost of funds and the cost of fulfilling the regulatory requirements, the supply price of a one-dollar loan is implicitly determined by the portion of the loan's gross revenue that the bank does not expect to recover per dollar lent. Equation (3) can be rearranged into the following: il = 1 * id + wp( + l(l -m)I- AL (4) where a = 1 - a(1 - m) >0. It can then be shown that: <0 , 0 , - < 0, all 0 ac 'aAL reasonable characteristics of a supply function for sub-national loans. States and municipalities will pay less for their loans the higher the chances that the federation will bail them out, the lower the probability of bad asset outcome, and the higher their asset value when a bad outcome materializes. 7 To complete the model, the demand for sub-national loans is assumed as a simple linear function of the interest rate: LD = a -,Bi (5) The additional restriction, a = AH, is added to the model as a sub-national government can borrow no more than the high value of its asset.' 'Note that the usual marginal cost equal marginal revenue condition for profit maximization yields the following solutionfortheinterestrate, i, = I + qwp + o-(l _ m)Iwhlchisthesameastotal revenue equal total cost approach solution above as L'. 8 Another way to rationalize that restriction is as follows. Sub-national goveniments are not able to borrow more than the expected value of their asset. At the same time, for interest rates to be zero, a necessary condition is that risk be zero. In that case, E[A] = a - AL + (1 - a) . AH , and since AH=1, then a = E[A] = 1, when a--o. 12 Equating supply (4) and demand (5), and after some rearrangement, the following quadratic function for the equilibrium interest rate is: i2,#6-i,(6a +± 0) +a0-r=O (6) where y = a(1- m) AL and 0 = id + q op P + cr (I m) .9 The solution for (6) yields two distinct real roots'0. The analysis here is confined to the root which yields positive interest rates and loan quantities. This root and, thus, the equilibrium interest rate solution is given by: il = g3- (ax + 60 - [4Pi(.r- a) + (-a - I5f)P) (7) Simulating the Effect of the New Rules This section employs Equation (7) to simulate the effect of changes in demand and policy parameters on the equilibrium interest rate, quantity of loans, and expected cost of bail-outs by (and to) the federal government. This expected cost is determined by: E[C] = M (L (1 + ij) -AL). C- (8) 9 The existence of an interior solution in quadrant I, and hence, an equilibrium for the supply and demand for funds requires that a > r . This is found by noting that lim LS = r, which is the 0 il >Oo 0 horizontal intercept of the supply function, must be less than c. This condition is necessary and sufficient for an equilibrium with positive i and L, and implies that the interest rate never exceeds the positive asymptote,-. 1 The condition for the existence of two distinct real roots is op = [(5a + fi0)]2 + 4,/B{v - a °)> 0 13 That is, the federal government expects to pay a portion, m, of the difference between the loan repayment amount and the state's low-value asset, with probability o-. If the high asset value materializes, no federal outlay is required. Alternative regulatory regimes enter the expected bail-out cost via their effect on interest rates, yet, changes in interest rates have an ambiguous effect on the expected cost, which is shown to depend on the elasticity of the demand for loans." For example, higher capital risk weighting requirements, assuming q>O and p>O, will increase equilibrium interest rates, and for a demand curve with non-zero elasticity, reduce the loan quantities. The combined effect, in terms of expected bail-out, hinges on the parametric values of the capital risk weighting variable, w, the elasticity of the demand for loans, - , and a -,B the moral hazard proxy, m. Four basic policy scenarios are simulated here: (i) banking regulations which require no capital risk weighting of sub-national loans, so that w = 0 (an arrangement not uncommon in countries where the federation is perceived as the guarantor of state and municipal borrowing and, thus, sub-national loans are considered riskless); (ii) a uniform, but low capital risk weighting scheme for all sub-national loans independent of their risk; " The ambiguous interest rate effect on expected cost can be seen by differentiating (9) with respect to the rate of interest: WE[C] = af m [a - 6(2i, + 1)] (9') oil If P31, the impact of higher interest rates on the expected cost of federal bail-outs is unambiguously negative. If ,B<1, the sign of (9) becomes ambiguous. Letting C(iQJ) denote a set of interest rate and P pairs, for 0<1, then plainly, there are an infinite number of C(i,,) which could either make (9') negative or positive. The sign on (9) is determined by whether il dominates a given value of l3 thus making the expected marginal cost of interest changes negative. On the other hand, a 0<1 may dominate any value of i,, so that [a -,6(2 i, + 1)] > 0, leaving (9') positive and increasing the expected cost of the government when interest rates rise. 14 (iii) a similarly uniform but high capital risk weighting scenario called for by regulation; and (iv) regulation which makes capital risk weightings a function of the underlying risk as measured, for example, by independent credit rating agencies (this is the essence of Mexico's new regulatory system). 12 For each regulatory scenario (that is, for each value of w), three different levels of moral hazard are simulated (m=l, m=O.S and m=O. 05), each reflecting a different perceived federal attitude toward bail-outs. 3 Finally, two varying degrees of demand elasticity are employed (embedded in the value of j3), implying either a relatively inelastic or a relatively elastic demand for sub-national loans. Table 1 shows the exact values (or, when relevant, functional form) given to w, m, ,8 and the other parameters in the simulations. Figures 1 through 6 illustrate how the various combinations of parametric structures interplay to determine changes in interest rate and expected bail-out cost as the underlying borrower risk, a-, varies. The figures express expected bail-out cost as a proportion of the loan's principal-plus-interest, measured in basis point units over the corresponding cost when zero capital risk weighting is required'4. In other words, the figures show the basis point differential cost of any given regulatory regime over an arrangement in which sub-national bank borrowing is, for regulatory purposes, automatically considered risk-free. Thus, when a differential cost series slopes upward, 2 For the simulations in scenario (iv), the Basel Committee's recommendations for the level of capital risk weighting according to risk of default are employed. For a detailed description of the weightings, see the Basel Committee's Report, A New CapitalAdequacy Framework-, p. 29-32. 13 m=0.05, rather than m= 0, is use here as a proxy for a no-bail-outs situation, since the case of m=O is trivial in that, there are by definition zero expected costs to the federal government. C4cost as a percent of the loan and interest is given by: c a m[l - eL( i,)1 15 Table 1 Parameter Values for Simulations Parameter Value AL, low asset value 0.5 id, cost of funds 0.05 q, quality of supervision 0.9 w, capital risk weight None 0.0 Uniformly Low 0.08x0.2 Uniformly High 0.08x 1.15 Function of Risk 0.08x (0.2+cr) p, bank's return on equity 0.1 m, moral hazard High (perfect) 1.0 Intermediate 0.5 Low 0.05 ,B, elasticity parameter Inelastic 0.5 Elastic 5.0 c-, risk (0,1) this is to be interpreted as a regime which, for a given level of risk, is more costly to the federal government than no risk weighting requirements. Similarly, interest rates are shown as the basis point difference between the interest rate prevailing in a given regulatory regime over the interest rate that applies under zero capital risk weighting. 15 i) Inelastic Demand As shown in Figure 1-a and l-b, a relatively inelastic demand for loans and high moral hazard are the worst possible combination from the point of view of federal government. In that scenario, introducing regulations that seek to penalize uncreditworthy (risky) sub-national borrowers is, in effect, self-defeating. This is because the increase in interest rates caused by a tighter link between capital risk weighting and underlying risk does not generate a large enough contraction in the equilibrium quantity of 16 loans. Although stricter regulation makes credit more expensive, states and municipalities do not reduce the quantity demanded of loans sufficiently and the moral-hazard-prone federal government faces a large expected bail-out bill. The riskier the sub-national in question, the larger that expected cost. Why does credit become more expensive in the first place? The reason is that the introduction of capital risk weighting requirement increases the cost of lending to the banks and, in competitive markets, they pass the higher per unit cost to their borrowers. Notice that, when compared to the non-weighted scenario, the increase in interest rates occurs even though there is 'perfect' moral hazard (that is, m = 1) and the federal government is expected to bail out in full. However, risk-based interest rate differentiation only occurs when the regulatory link between capital risk weighting and risk assessments (that is, credit ratings) is enforced. As moral hazard shrinks (that is, the value of m falls), the differential cost of introducing positive capital risk weighting decreases across possible regulatory regimes (Figures 2a and 2b). Now that the federal government is less willing to pick up the expected cost of defaults, banks do not expect a full bail-out and subsequently increase interest rates more steeply in line with risk. But, given the inelastic demand for funds by states and municipalities this increase in interest rates results in a relatively smali contraction in the quantity demanded for funds. Partial federal willingness to bail out (m < 1) also achieves another important result -banks begin to differentiate interest rates across borrowers even in the case when capital risk weighting coefficients are constant. 15Notethat: ilw < ilw, since qnw =id +cr(1-m)