66469 ECONOM IC AND SECTOR WOR K HIDDEN HARVEST The Global Contribution of Capture Fisheries M AY 2 0 1 2 REPORT NUMBER 66469-GLB ECONOMIC AND SECTOR WORK HIDDEN HARVEST The Global Contribution of Capture Fisheries REPORT NO. 66469-GLB © 2012 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / International Development Association or The World Bank 1818 H Street NW Washington DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000 Internet: www.worldbank.org This volume is a product of the staff of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank. The ï¬?ndings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect the views of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Rights and Permissions The material in this work is subject to copyright. Because The World Bank encourages dissemination of its knowledge, this work may be reproduced, in whole or in part, for noncommercial purposes as long as full attribution to this work is given. Any queries on rights and licenses, including subsidiary rights, should be addressed to the Ofï¬?ce of the Publisher, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2422; e-mail: pubrights@worldbank.org. Cover Photo: Michael Arbuckle CONTENTS III Table of CONTENTS List of Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . v List of Boxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vii List of Figures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vii Abbreviations and Acronyms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ix Foreword . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xi Acknowledgments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xiii Terminology as Used in This Report. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xv Executive Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xvii Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xvii Key Findings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xviii Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xix Chapter 1: Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 Chapter 2: Estimating the Economic Contribution of Global Capture Fisheries . . . . . . . . . . 3 2.1 Disaggregating Small- and Large-Scale Commercial Capture Fisheries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 2.2 Case Study Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 2.3 Uncovering the Hidden Harvests of Subsistence Fisheries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 2.4 Estimating the Economic Contribution of Recreational Fisheries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12 2.5 Estimating the Extended Global GDP Contribution of Commercial Capture Fisheries along the Value Chain . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 Chapter 3: Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 3.1 The Global Proï¬?les of Small- and Large-Scale Commercial Fisheries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 3.2 Small- and Large-Scale Fisheries in the Sampled Countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25 3.3 Supplementary Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34 3.4 The Hidden Harvest of Subsistence Fisheries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35 3.5 Recreational Fisheries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38 3.6 The Contribution of Commercial Fisheries to GDP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39 Chapter 4: Implications for Decision Makers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43 4.1 Recommendations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45 Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47 Annex: Data Sources and Notes for GDP Calculations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55 A.1 Notes on Data Sources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55 EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK LI S T O F TA B L E S V List of TABLES Table 2.1: Example Deï¬?nitions of Small-Scale Marine Fisheries from Developing Country Case Studies . . . 4 Table 2.2: Generic Characteristics of Categories of Fisheries. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 Table 2.3: Estimated Expenditures on Fishing Tackle in Relation to Total Angler Expenditures . . . . . . . . 13 Table 2.4: Recreational Fishing Gear Trade Classiï¬?cation Code . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 Table 2.5: Estimated Global Number of Anglers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 Table 2.6: Global Expenditures on Recreational Fishing Tackle . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 Table 2.7: U.S. Expenditures on Fishing Equipment by Type, 2006 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 Table 2.8: Selected Information Sources for Recreational Fisheries Contribution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 Table 2.9: Summary of Information Sources for Fisheries GDP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20 Table 3.1: Global Proï¬?le of Small- and Large-Scale Fisheries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22 Table 3.2: Small- and Large-Scale Fisheries in Developing Countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22 Table 3.3: Small- and Large-Scale Fisheries in Developed Countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 Table 3.4: Employment in Capture Fisheries in Developing Countries, by Continent (thousands) . . . . . . 23 Table 3.5: Results from Developed Countries (thousands) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 Table 3.6: Catch Used for Local Human Consumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 Table 3.7: Discard Rates in Developing and Developed Countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 Table 3.8: Summary of Developing Country Case Studies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25 Table 3.9: Summary of Developed Country Sample . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26 Table 3.10: Full- and Part-Time Fishing and Postharvest Employment in the Case Study Developing Countries (thousands) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27 Table 3.11: Estimated Employment in Developed Countries (thousands). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 Table 3.12: Women in Fisheries Workforce in Developing Countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 Table 3.13: Women in Fisheries Workforce in Developed Countries. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29 Table 3.14: Reported and Estimated Catches in Inland Capture Fisheries (thousand tons) . . . . . . . . . . 29 Table 3.15: Fish Production in the Sampled Countries (million tons) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30 Table 3.16: Comparison of Apparent per Capita Fish Consumption in the Lower Mekong Basin (kg/capita/yr) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30 EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK VI LIST OF TA B LES Table 3.17: Catch per Ton of Fuel . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 Table 3.18: Fuel Efï¬?ciency Estimates: Examples from Developing Country Marine Fisheries . . . . . . . . . 32 Table 3.19: Catch per Ton of Fuel Consumed in Fisheries in the Northeast United States . . . . . . . . . . . 33 Table 3.20: Fuel Costs as Share of Revenue from Fish Landed . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33 Table 3.21: Proï¬?le of World Fisheries in 1980: The Thomson Table . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34 Table 3.22: Comparative Results of Previous Studies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35 Table 3.23: Comparison of Vietnam Fish Production Case Studies (million tons) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38 Table 3.24: Estimated Participation in Vietnam Inland Fisheries under Alternative Scenarios (millions) . . . 38 Table 3.25: Estimated Total Expenditures on Recreational Fishing for 2009 ($ million) . . . . . . . . . . . . 39 Table 3.26: Contribution from the Fisheries Harvest Subsector to National GDP (%) . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40 Table 3.27: VARs for Fisheries Subsectors in Developing Countries in the Paciï¬?c . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41 Table 3.28: Value Chain Analysis for Lake Victoria Nile Perch . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41 Table A.1: Postharvest Share of Fisheries GDP for 21 Sample Countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57 Table A.2: Calculation of Mean and Median Fisheries Sector GDPs Based on 128 Countries . . . . . . . . . 57 Table A.3: Base Data and Data Sources Used to Estimate Extended Fisheries Sector GDP . . . . . . . . . . 58 Table A.4: Estimated Extended Fisheries Sector GDP (proportion and $ millions) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64 Table A.5: Fisheries Sector Multipliers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 Table A.6: Examples of Supply-Driven Multipliers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69 H ID D EN H A RV ES T LI S T O F B O X E S V II List of : BOXES Box 2.1: The Case for Separate Consideration of Small-Scale Fisheries. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 Box 2.2: The Code of Conduct and Small-Scale Fisheries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 Box 2.3: Key Features of Case Study Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 Box 2.4: Subsistence Fishing in Bangladesh. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12 Box 2.5: Calculation of GDP. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16 Box 2.6: Classiï¬?cation of Fisheries-Related Activities in the System of National Accounts . . . . . . . . . . 17 Box 3.1: Inland Fisheries in Cambodia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27 Box 3.2: Deï¬?ning Bycatch and Discards . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34 Box 3.3: Bycatch Collection in Mozambique . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34 Box 3.4: Subsistence Fishing in Thailand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35 List of : FIGURES Figure 3.1: Income from Fisheries in Bangladesh by Income Group . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36 Figure 3.2: Bangladesh Fish Consumption by Rural and Urban Poor and Nonpoor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37 EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK ABB R E V I AT I O N S A ND ACRONYMS IX ABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMS DANIDA Danish International Development Agency MRC Mekong River Commission EU European Union NAS National Accounts Statistics FAO Food and Agriculture Organization of the NMFS National Marine Fisheries Service United Nations NZ New Zealand FCP Fishery Country Proï¬?le (FAO publication) OECD Organization for Economic Cooperation and GDP Gross domestic product Development GGP Gross geographical product PROFISH Global Partnership on Fisheries GPP Gross provincial product SFLP Sustainable Fisheries Livelihoods Programme GT Gross tonnage SINTEF Stiftelsen for industriell og teknisk forskning; The Norwegian Foundation for Scientiï¬?c and HIES Household Income and Expenditure Survey Industrial Research HP Horsepower SNA Systems of National Accounts IFAD International Fund for Agricultural SUMA Support for Brackish Water and Marine Development Aquaculture project (DANIDA, Vietnam) IFREMER L’Institut Français de Recherche pour UK United Kingdom l’Exploitation de la Mer UN United Nations ISIC International Standard Industrial Classiï¬?cation of All Industrial Activities U.S. United States of America IUU Illegal, unreported and unregulated (ï¬?shing) VAR Value-added ratio UNITS OF MEASURE $ U.S. dollar ton(s) metric ton(s) NOK Norwegian kroner TT$ Trinidad dollar EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK FO R E W O R D XI FOREWORD The important contribution of ï¬?sheries to human well-being is frequently underestimated. This report highlights that contribution. Not only do ï¬?sheries generate employment for millions, but ï¬?sh provides vital nutrition to billions of people and is essential to the diet of the poor in many countries. About half of those working in the ï¬?sheries sector are women, mostly engaged in marketing and processing. However, the foundations of this natural bounty, this inï¬?nite cash flow, are threatened by overex- ploitation, pollution, and habitat loss. This study strengthens the case for investment in sustainable ï¬?sheries and improvement of ï¬?sheries and aquatic environmental governance. The report focuses on small-scale ï¬?sheries and developing countries because the livelihoods of 90 percent of the 120 million employed in ï¬?sheries are in the small-scale ï¬?sheries, and almost all of those workers, 97 percent, live in developing countries. Many small-scale ï¬?shing communities have high levels of poverty, and poverty reduction is a core focus of the contributing partners to the report. Raising awareness of the importance of small-scale ï¬?sheries is particularly relevant, not only because these livelihoods de- pend on sustainable use of the natural resource base, but also because these ï¬?sheries provide vital local nutritious food and a safety net for many poor households in coastal communities in developing countries. In developing countries, these ï¬?sheries also underpin the social fabric of many communities. Because of their concentrated and largely urban base and their visibility as an important earner of foreign exchange, large- scale ï¬?sheries have been the target of considerable management efforts. Because of their variety, dispersion, and social complexity, small-scale ï¬?sheries are often poorly documented and poorly regulated, and many of the complex management issues remain largely unresolved. At a time when ï¬?sheries resources are increasingly depleted and climate change poses a growing threat, failure to effectively address the issues confronting small-scale ï¬?sheries places the livelihoods of millions of people at risk. By quantifying the global economic and social footprint of ï¬?sheries, this study calls for increased attention to issues facing both large- and small-scale ï¬?sheries. The report compiles information from case studies on countries representing over half of the world’s ï¬?sh workers and draws on a range of published information to provide a global picture of capture ï¬?sheries from a largely social and economic perspec- tive. It presents an estimate of the contribution of the ï¬?sheries sector to the gross domestic product, including recreational ï¬?shing and postharvest activities, and highlights the importance of subsistence ï¬?shing. The report is the result of a collaborative effort by Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO), the WorldFish Center, and the World Bank’s Global Program on Sustainable Fisheries (PROFISH). EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK ACK N O W L E D G ME NT S X III ACKNOWLEDGMENTS This report was made possible through the contributions and support of many experts. Kieran Kelleher is the former Fisheries Team Leader at the World Bank. He prepared the overall terms of reference for the study, proposed the methodology for raising the gross domestic product (GDP) estimates to the global level, prepared the recreational ï¬?sheries component, and drafted the report. Lena Westlund (World Bank and Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations [FAO] consultant) synthesized the country case study materials, drafted the background study on the relative contributions of large- and small-scale ï¬?sheries, and undertook the initial estimates of their respective global contributions. Eriko Hoshino (World Bank consultant) assisted by Glen-Marie Lange (Senior Environmental Economist, World Bank), Kieran Kelleher, and Petter Jern (FAO), prepared the background study to estimate the contribution of capture ï¬?sheries to global GDP. David Mills (WorldFish Center), a member of the initial study design team, prepared the background study on subsistence ï¬?sheries and coordinated the country case studies prepared by WorldFish, supported by Yumiko Kura and David Walfoort. David Mills applied the term hidden harvest to ï¬?sheries in the context of the subsistence case studies. Rolf Willmann and Gejan de Graaf were members of the initial study design team; they coordinated the preparation of FAO- executed case studies and were supported by Felix Marttin, Daniela Kalikoski, Marc Taconet, and Shunji Sugiyama. Randall Brummett, Senior Fisheries Specialist at the World Bank, edited the text. The authors wish to thank and acknowledge the valuable contributions to the developing country case studies made by the following individuals and their organizations: I. Adikwu (Nigeria); L. I. Braimah (Ghana); M. Démé (Senegal); L. Garces and N. Salayo (Philippines); D. Lymer, S. Funge-Smith, P. Khemakorn, and N. Sukumasavin (Thailand); S. Koeshendrajana, L. Adrianto, T. Trihartono, and E. Anggraini (Indonesia); J. Kurien (India); A. M. Menezes (Mozambique); N. V. Nghia, B. V. Hanh, and P. G. Hai (Vietnam); M. G. Mustafa and H. Bose (Bangladesh); N. Thuok, P. Somany, S. Kao, and D. Thomson (Cambodia); M. van der Knaap (Lake Victoria–Kenya, Tanzania, and Uganda); G. Velasco Canziani (Brazil); and X. Yingliang (China). The extensive research and data analysis on developed country ï¬?sheries by Pavel Salz (FAO consultant) is gratefully acknowledged, and the authors wish to thank the following experts for assistance with data collection and interpretation of information for speciï¬?c countries and subject matters: L. Sonsini (Department of Fisheries and Oceans, Canada), M. Boudreau (Statistics, Canada), R. Gillett (Asian Development Bank consultant), A. Kitts (National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration United States [NOAA]), M. Sandberg (Stiftelsen for industriell og teknisk forskning; The Norwegian Foundation for Scientiï¬?c and Industrial Research (SINTEF), Norway), and S. Vannuccini (FAO). The invaluable advice and inputs provided by the following people are gratefully acknowledged: C. Barlow (Mekong River Commission [MRC]), S. Funge-Smith (FAO), M. Akester (Danish International Development Agency [DANIDA] Support for Brackish Water and Marine Aquaculture project), A. Poulsen (DANIDA Strengthening of Capture Fisheries Management Project), K. Hortle (consultant/MRC), H. BÃ¥ge (FAO), F. Chopin (FAO), B. Kuemlangan (FAO), S. Siar (FAO), M.-C. Badjeck (WorldFish Center). Participants at the side event of the Global Conference on Small-Scale Fisheries: Bringing Together Responsible Fisheries and Social Development (Bangkok, Thailand, October 13–17, 2008) offered constructive advice and comments on EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK XI V A CK NOWL ED GM ENTS the preliminary report “Small-Scale Capture Fisheries: A Global Overview with Emphasis on Developing Countriesâ€?;1 their contribution is gratefully acknowledged. Grateful thanks are extended to the peer reviewers and commentators: R. Volk (USAID); S. Garcia (consultant); J. Ward (National Marine Fisheries Service [NMFS] National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration); and C. de Haan, J. Virdin, X. Vincent, and M.-A. Bromhead (World Bank). The study is the result of a joint activity with FAO and WorldFish Center, both of which are partners in Global Partnership on Fisheries (PROFISH). This study is one of a series of knowledge products produced by PROFISH.2 Complementary PROFISH knowledge products include The Sunken Billions: The Economic Justiï¬?cation for Fisheries Reform; Changing the Face of the Waters: The Promise and Challenge of Sustainable Aquaculture; and Rising to Depletion? Towards a Dialogue on the State of National Marine Fisheries (publications are available at http://www.worldbank.org/ï¬?sh). A background study for this report was also prepared to inform policymakers and decision makers participating in the 28th Session of the FAO Committee on Fisheries. The term hidden harvest is not original. It has been used by several authors and for several different purposes. These are some examples: Employment and food recovery. Hidden Harvest is a produce recovery program in Coachella Valley, California, that em- ploys low-income farm workers to “rescueâ€? produce that is left behind in the ï¬?elds and orchards after harvest (http:// www.hiddenharvest.org) Food rescue. Hidden Harvest is a surplus food rescue program that strives to alleviate hunger and end food waste in the Bay, Midland, and Saginaw, Michigan, regions by providing a safe and coordinated system of rescuing surplus food and redistributing it to feed people in need (http://www.hiddenharvest.com) Food policy report. Hidden Harvest: U.S. Beneï¬?ts from International Research Aid, Philip G. Pardey, Julian M. Alston, Jason E. Christian, and Shenggen Fan (Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute, 1996) Integrated farming services. Paciï¬?c Ag Solutions (The Hidden Harvestâ„¢) provides a full range of integrated farming services (http://www.pacagsol.com) Forests. Uncovering the Hidden Harvest: Valuation Methods for Woodland and Forest Resources, B. M. Campbell and Martin Karl Luckert (London: Earthscan Publications, 2001) Wild foods. The Hidden Harvest: Wild Foods and Agricultural Systems: A Literature Review and Annotated Bibliography, Ian Scoones, Mary Melnyk, and Jules N. Pretty (London; Sustainable Agriculture Programme, International Institute for Environment and Development, 1992) Wild resources. Valuing the Hidden Harvest: Methodological Approaches for Local-Level Economic Analysis of Wild Resources, International Institute for Environment and Development (London: Sustainable Agriculture Programme Research Series 3:4. International Institute of Environment and Development, 1997) Garments. The Swedish company, Our Legacy’s SS10, Hidden Harvest collection features garments of naturally grown fabrics and “personal identityâ€? Poetry. “Hidden Harvest,â€? in Platform, Rodrigo Toscano (Berkeley, CA: Atelos, 2003) 1 The preliminary report of “Small-Scale Capture Fisheries: A Global Overview with Emphasis on Developing Countriesâ€? is available at http://www.4ssf.org. 2 Donors to the PROFISH Partnership have included UK Department for International Development; Ministry Foreign Affairs, Iceland, Nor- way, and Finland; Ministry of Fisheries New Zealand; and Agence Française de Développement. PROFISH also beneï¬?ted from the support of FAO, WorldFish Center, and the International Union for Conservation of Nature. H ID D E N H A RV ES T TER M I N O L O G Y A S USE D IN T HIS RE P ORT XV TERMINOLOGY AS USED IN THIS REPORT Commercial includes both large- and small-scale ï¬?sheries subsectors aimed at generating cash revenues. The ï¬?sheries sector includes all stakeholders and economic activities associated with the capture ï¬?sheries value chain, including preharvest and postharvest. Industrial, commercial, inland, recreational, small-scale, large-scale, and artisanal are subsectors. Except in the case of recreational ï¬?sheries for which ï¬?shing equipment data were available, preharvest inputs to other subsectors are not included in calculations due to lack of disaggregated data. The footprint of an activity is the collective economic, social, and environmental impacts of its undertaking. Full-time ï¬?shers receive at least 90 percent of their livelihood from or spend at least 90 percent of their working time at ï¬?shing. Part-time ï¬?shers receive at least 30 percent, but less than 90 percent, of their livelihood from ï¬?shing or spend at least 30 percent, but less than 90 percent, of their working time in that occupation. Occasional ï¬?shers receive less than 30 percent of their income from ï¬?shing or spend less than 30 percent of their working time at ï¬?shing. Industrial represents the large-scale, commercial ï¬?shery subsector most often conducted from motorized vessels greater than 20 meters in length operating inshore and/or on open oceans. Inland ï¬?sheries are operated in (mostly) freshwater marshes, swamps, rivers, lakes, and reservoirs. Postharvest activities take place after the capture and landing of ï¬?sh and include cleaning, storing, wholesaling, retailing, and other processing before consumption. Recreational ï¬?shers in both high- and low-income countries catch ï¬?sh for pleasure and home consumption. Few, if any, of the ï¬?sh are sold. Small scale generally refers to the commercial ï¬?shery subsector conducted without boats and/or from motorized or nonmo- torized vessels of less than 20 meters in length. The concept of small scale is discussed in greater detail in the text. In this report, artisanal is the same as small scale. Subsistence ï¬?sheries comprise the subsector in which the majority of ï¬?shers are poor and captures are primarily consumed by local households without entering the value chain. Only surpluses are sold. The value chain comprises all economic activities and subsectors that directly or indirectly contribute to capture and post- harvest processing and marketing of ï¬?sh. In this report, the value chain does not include activities that occur before ï¬?sh capture, such as boatbuilding and net fabrication. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK EX E C U T I V E S U MMARY X V II EXECUTIVE SUMMARY This study provides a disaggregated proï¬?le of the world’s small- and large-scale ï¬?sheries and an estimate of their direct and indirect contributions to the gross domestic product (GDP), food security, and rural livelihoods. The study is directed at deci- sion makers, the development community, and professionals to uncover the hidden importance of the ï¬?sheries sector with a view to increasing its economic and environmental contributions in a sustainable manner. APPROACH Key indicators on production, employment, productivity, and economic contributions were compiled from 17 developing country3 and region case studies supplemented with recent sector studies from other developing countries and published information from Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) member states. Case study data were compiled and extrapolated to the global level using available global ï¬?sheries statistical information. The primary raising fac- tors were statistical information, most importantly from the national catch reports submitted to the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO). Developing and developed countries and marine and inland ï¬?sheries were treated separately. Rather than being a random sample, the case study countries ensure coverage of countries where approximately 80 percent of the world’s ï¬?shers live. Speciï¬?c case studies on subsistence ï¬?sheries were undertaken in Bangladesh, Vietnam, and the Philippines to complement and extend the case studies described previously. Estimates of recreational ï¬?sheries’ contribution to GDP and estimates of numbers of recreational ï¬?shers (anglers) were compiled from the published literature. Because most countries report the value of recreational ï¬?shing tackle sold but do not report the number of anglers and their other nontackle expenses (such as for licenses, ice, bait, accommodation, boat hire, travel costs, etc.), the percentage of expenditures attributable to ï¬?shing equipment in the (mostly OECD) countries that do disaggregate these data was used to ascertain the aggregate value of expenditures made by anglers globally. Most studies acknowledge some overlap and possible double accounting with the tourism sector. Available national ï¬?sheries sector GDP estimates were compiled and examined to ensure consistency and to establish wheth- er postharvest or aquaculture segments were included or excluded. For most countries, postharvest economic activities are considered as “manufacturingâ€? under the System of National Accounts and generally are not included in reported GDP contribution of the ï¬?sheries sector. However, recent studies of some countries in West Africa, the Paciï¬?c Islands, and OECD member states have included disaggregated estimates of the postharvest contribution of ï¬?sheries to GDP where available. This sample was used to correct estimated GDP from ï¬?shing alone (available for more than 120 countries) to include the postharvest value chain. Available data did not permit the disaggregation and/or extrapolation of the preharvest value chain contributions to GDP. 3 Bangladesh, Brazil, Cambodia, China, Ghana, India, Indonesia, Lake Victoria (Kenya, Uganda, Tanzania), Mozambique, Myanmar, Nigeria, Philippines, Senegal, Thailand, and Vietnam. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK XV I I I EX ECUTIV E S UM M A RY Methodological Issues No standard deï¬?nition allows for easy disaggregation of small- and large-scale ï¬?shery subsectors from national capture ï¬?shery reports. Many countries do not even report these subsectors as separate economic activities. To the extent possible in this analysis, the deï¬?nitions of small scale and large scale used by each case study country was respected. Consequently, at the aggregate or global level, the dividing line between small and large scale is inevitably blurred, as are distinctions among commercial, recreational, and subsistence ï¬?shing. The lack of data for some countries, or the lack of disaggregated data, required assumptions to ï¬?ll these data gaps. The major gaps encountered related to (1) deï¬?ciencies in the ofï¬?cial records of the numbers and production of small-scale ï¬?shers, particularly in inland ï¬?sheries; (2) records or estimates of postharvest labor in small-scale ï¬?sheries; (3) information to assess the scale and importance of subsistence ï¬?sheries; and (4) the basis for national ï¬?sheries GDP estimates. The nonrandomness of the case study samples improved overall data richness but created problems for accurate extrapola- tion. For example, in terms of catch, the Brazil case study does not reflect the dominance of large-scale ï¬?sheries in other Latin American countries such as Peru and Chile. Similarly, the global postharvest GDP contribution is extrapolated on the basis of the limited number of GDP estimates, which disaggregate aquaculture, capture ï¬?sheries harvesting, and capture ï¬?sheries postharvesting activities. Because of these issues, the results should be treated with due caution and critically evaluated in light of new information or additional precision obtained from further studies. KEY FINDINGS Approximately 120 million full-time and part-time workers are directly dependent on commercial capture ï¬?sheries value chains for their livelihoods. Ninety-seven percent (116 million) of these people live in developing countries. Among them, • more than 90 percent (including almost 32 million ï¬?shers) work in the small-scale ï¬?sheries subsector, • 47 percent of the total workforce is women, which in developing countries equates to 56 million jobs, • over half (60 million) of those employed in ï¬?sheries value chains in developing countries work in small-scale inland ï¬?sheries, and • 73 percent (approximately 23 million) of developing country ï¬?shers and ï¬?sh workers live in Asia. Over half of the catch in developing countries is produced by the small-scale subsector, and 90 to 95 percent of the small-scale landings are destined for local human consumption. Commercial capture ï¬?sheries, including postharvest activities, are conservatively estimated to have contributed $274 billion to the global GDP in 2007. This is slightly less than 1 percent of the total global GDP. The preharvest value chain (including such activities as boatbuilding and equipment manufacture and sale) may add a further $160 billion to the GDP estimate. Global estimated expenditures by approximately 220 million recreational ï¬?shers are about $190 billion annually. Recreational ï¬?sheries can be of greater economic importance than commercial ï¬?sheries in some countries, and they contribute about $70 billion to global GDP. An estimated 5.8 million ï¬?shers in the world earn less than $1 per day. Fish is a vital source of nutrition and feeds more than 1 billion consumers to whom ï¬?sh is a key component of their diets. Subsistence ï¬?sheries are a large economic activity and livelihood component of rural communities, but the numbers of subsistence ï¬?shers at the global level and the importance of ï¬?sh to such households are poorly quantiï¬?ed. The role of women in ï¬?sheries is not limited to processing and marketing; women are also investors, sources of credit, managers of household ï¬?shing receipts, and consumers who make important decisions on family nutrition. Small-scale ï¬?shing communities are among the poorest and most afflicted with social ills and may be further marginal- ized by a failure to recognize the importance of ï¬?sheries. H ID D E N H A RV ES T EX E C U T I V E S U MMARY X IX Large-scale ï¬?sheries land more ï¬?sh, but small-scale ï¬?sheries produce more ï¬?sh for domestic human consumption. National reported capture ï¬?sheries production statistics seem to underestimate overall commercial catches by about 10 percent and small-scale inland captures by as much as 70 percent. Employment in small-scale ï¬?sheries is several times higher per ton of harvest than in large-scale ï¬?sheries. Small-scale ï¬?sheries generate less waste in the form of discards (unwanted catch dumped at sea). Like other primary production sectors, ï¬?sheries tend to be more important in developing economies than in developed economies. CONCLUSIONS The study compiles estimates for key indicators and highlights numerous limitations at local, national, and global levels regarding data availability, data use, and data interpretation. The study reveals serious information deï¬?ciencies that undermine decision makers’ understanding of the importance of the ï¬?sheries sector. In particular, there is a lack of accurate and acces- sible information on the social and economic performance of ï¬?sheries, such as their importance for employment and food supply, their role in poverty reduction, and as a source of wealth and economic growth. The economic and social importance of the capture ï¬?sheries value chain is frequently underappreciated, and the contribution of small-scale and inland ï¬?sheries to livelihoods and food security is often poorly recognized. Undervaluation of this sector is both a cause and a result of having weak data on how ï¬?sheries interact with the greater society and economy. These knowledge gaps may in part explain why policymakers tend to neglect comprehensive efforts to manage this complex and politically sensitive sector. What little is known about the contribution of ï¬?sheries focuses on the industrial subsector, partly because it is urban based and produces the bulk of the ï¬?sh entering international trade and because data from this sector are easier to collect. Even in the case of large-scale ï¬?sheries, however, available information rarely identiï¬?es key trends in proï¬?tability and sustainability. The case studies show that standard ï¬?shery production statistics frequently fail to consider employment and other socioeco- nomic contributions of small-scale, subsistence, and recreational ï¬?sheries. As a result, the real economic importance of these ï¬?sheries often remains hidden, the pressure on ï¬?sh resources is often underestimated, and the sector is often neglected in national, regional, and local policies and plans. Despite a focus of this study on GDP, GDP values are but one indicator of the economic contribution of ï¬?sheries. GDP values do not necessarily reflect the potential of the sector to create net beneï¬?ts, or economic rents, or to contribute to employ- ment and food security. An increase in ï¬?sheries GDP may simply mean increased costs of ï¬?shing rather than increased productivity, or net beneï¬?ts. Consequently, increases in sector GDP or employment need to be complemented by indicators of the productivity of the sector and its economic and environmental sustainability, such as the state of ï¬?sh stocks, long-term proï¬?tability, and governance.4 There is a general understanding that capture ï¬?sheries need to be broadly reformed to optimize their economic performance and environmental sustainability. Such an overhaul will require an inventory of users and use patterns. National and regional ï¬?sheries policy and planning need to be informed by an accurate characterization of the economic performance of ï¬?sheries, their social contribution, and their sustainability. In an era of volatile fuel and food prices, changing climatic conditions, overï¬?shing, and growing environmental stresses, the declining economic and environmental efï¬?ciency of both small- and large-scale ï¬?sheries evokes the need for a clearer under- standing of the sector’s vulnerability and threats to sustainability. Small-scale ï¬?sheries are often part of diverse and complex livelihoods—at times a livelihood of last resort—and a vital nutritional safety net, and they are highly vulnerable to external and internal threats. Accurately characterizing their role and contribution is a ï¬?rst step toward improved management of these ï¬?sheries and building political will for reform. 4 See, for example, the World Bank’s reports The Sunken Billions and Rising to Depletion? and its Worldwide Governance Indicators project (http://info.worldbank.org). EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK XX EX ECUTIV E S UM M A RY Overall, the contribution of the world’s ï¬?sheries to national and global economies is greater than that generally recognized by decision makers. Commercial ï¬?shing constitutes the economic base for an extended value chain through processing, market- ing, retailing, and the food service industry. Subsistence ï¬?sheries are important for food security and rural livelihoods. In some countries, recreational ï¬?sheries are of greater economic importance than commercial capture ï¬?sheries. Recommendations 1. Critically review the results presented here with a view to improving the underlying data, rendering deï¬?nitions and data sets more compatible, and enhancing the basis for assessing the economic contribution of capture ï¬?sheries with the overall objective of improving ï¬?sheries management and laying a robust foundation for reform. 2. National and international ï¬?sheries agencies and nongovernmental organizations should alert policymakers and decision makers to the value of capture ï¬?sheries as a primary industry that underpins the economic activities of an extended value chain and can make an economic contribution several times the landed value of the catch. 3. National ï¬?sheries authorities, specialists, and statistics agencies should collaborate to improve estimates of the ï¬?sh- eries sector’s contribution to GDP, including the entire value chain. GDP estimates need to be complemented with disaggregated social and environmental indicators reflecting employment, direct contributions to poverty reduction and food security, and trends in the economic performance and environmental sustainability of the various capture ï¬?sheries subsectors. 4. The development community should consider collaboration in the following: • Elaboration of guidelines to evaluate the contribution of subsistence ï¬?sheries, including guidance on the use of household and nutrition surveys and poverty proï¬?ling to characterize subsistence ï¬?sheries • Development of procedures to estimate the extended GDP of the ï¬?sheries sector (consistent with existing United Nations guidance [UN and FAO 2004]), including a typology of sector-speciï¬?c multipliers and value chain analyses, especially for developing countries • Building consensus on the preparation of estimates of economic rents and associated indicators of ï¬?sheries sec- tor performance (Anderson and Anderson 2010) • Improving human resource and other capacity in ï¬?sheries data collection, analysis, and management • Further development of ï¬?sheries governance indicators. 5. Work with the formal mechanisms of the FAO5 to improve collection and interpretation of statistical data on ï¬?sheries at national, regional, and global levels, including validation and improvement of the results presented, and enhance linkages between ï¬?sheries data sets and social and economic data sets. 5 In particular, the Coordinating Working Party on Fishery Statistics (http://www.fao.org/ï¬?shery/cwp/en) with strengthened links to the Global Strategy to Improve Agricultural and Rural Statistics. H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 1 — I N T RODUCT ION 1 Chapter 1: INTRODUCTION The importance of ï¬?sheries as a source of nutrition, em- Because of this lack of data, the relative contributions of the ployment, and income for many of the world’s coastal and different ï¬?sheries subsectors, both harvest and postharvest, rural poor is often not fully appreciated by policymakers. In have not been systematically appraised to inform policy and particular, the contributions of small-scale ï¬?shing to the liveli- management. hood strategies of millions of households in coastal and rural communities in developing countries and the role they play This data deï¬?cit can be attributed to several causes. Catching in food security and poverty alleviation are often ignored in operations are highly dispersed, making collection of com- ï¬?sheries planning. The growing threat to sustainable ï¬?sher- prehensive catch information challenging, particularly in de- ies represented by overcapitalization, overï¬?shing, and envi- veloping countries. The variety of species and products and ronmental degradation is often a matter of survival for the the means of counting or measuring production at point of many millions of workers in the capture ï¬?shery value chain. harvest or ï¬?rst sale present substantial technical problems (such as shell on/off, gutted, whole, dried, or salted). Illegal Disaggregated information and separate analysis of large- and deliberately unreported ï¬?shing is ubiquitous. Waste scale, small-scale, artisanal, recreational, marine, and inland and discarding can account for over half of a catch. The ï¬?sheries creates a better understanding of their respective relationships between catches and economic returns are roles and social and economic importance. The analysis can nonlinear and complex. Although difï¬?cult to collect, these inform the trade-offs between objectives—between poverty basic production and economic information requirements reduction and employment, foreign exchange and food sup- are essential for policy and planning. The deï¬?ciencies are an ply—and it can inform the policies underpinning effective important contributor to underinvestment in management ï¬?sheries management. A disaggregated analysis can under- and policy support to, especially small-scale and subsistence pin investment in reforms and in the capacity to develop and ï¬?sheries. implement governance systems adapted to the local context of small-scale ï¬?sheries. It can also help build political will for This study attempts to address these critical knowledge reforms founded on a greater understanding of the social, gaps with a focus on small-scale ï¬?sheries in developing economic, nutritional, and cultural importance of these differ- countries to direct the efforts by policymakers and planners ent sector segments. The diversity within each subsector, or to address core tenure, allocation, and valuation issues and industry segment, is enormous, with multiple areas of over- to raise awareness of communities and authorities on the lap between the subsectors providing a continuum, or spec- economic and social value of their ï¬?sheries. trum, of production and marketing systems from shoreline The speciï¬?c objectives of the study are the following: collection of shellï¬?sh to electronic auctions and recreational ï¬?sheries. To provide a disaggregated proï¬?le of the world’s small- Unfortunately, disaggregated data showing the characteris- and large-scale ï¬?sheries, including subsistence and tics of the various capture ï¬?sheries subsectors are gener- recreational subsectors ally lacking. Sector proï¬?les distinguishing between marine To provide an estimate of the national and global and inland ï¬?sheries, harvest and postharvest employment, economic importance of the ï¬?sheries sector and value and their respective economic contributions seldom exist. chains. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK C H A P T E R 2 — E S T IMAT ING T HE E CONOMIC CONT RIB UTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES 3 Chapter 2: ESTIMATING THE ECONOMIC CONTRIBUTION OF GLOBAL CAPTURE FISHERIES This study addresses the knowledge gaps in our understand- and large-scale ï¬?sheries, but the respective deï¬?nitions differ ing of the importance of the various capture ï¬?sheries subsec- greatly among countries. Nevertheless, several general attri- tors. The characteristics and contributions of the small- and butes distinguish them. Large-scale ï¬?sheries are often asso- large-scale commercial capture ï¬?sheries are compared and ciated with high capital costs and sophisticated technologies. contrasted with a particular emphasis on small-scale ï¬?sher- They tend to substitute labor with technology and tend to ies in developing countries. The study draws on information have an urban rather than rural or community base. Large, from 17 case studies in developing countries, represent- concentrated landings tend to require specialized catch pres- ing over half of the world’s people who are related to the ervation and distribution, and the economic beneï¬?ts accrue ï¬?shing industry. This information is supplemented with directly through labor and indirectly through proï¬?t distribution additional data drawn from recently completed reviews of and taxation. the sector. Analyses of ï¬?sheries in developed countries are then compared with the developing country proï¬?les to build Small-scale ï¬?shing uses smaller (or no) ï¬?shing vessels and a global picture of small- and large-scale ï¬?sheries. Overall, relatively low-technology ï¬?shing methods. Small-scale ï¬?sh- the sample of developing and developed countries accounts eries tend to be more labor intensive. Small-scale ï¬?sher- for 88 percent of reported marine catches and 74 percent of ies are often seen as an activity of low productivity, with reported inland catches. low yield rates and low-value products directed mainly to local consumption. However, modern small-scale ï¬?sher- The fundamental differences between large-scale and small- ies can be economically efï¬?cient and produce high-value scale ï¬?sheries call for different approaches and perhaps dif- products for international markets. Technological develop- ferent values to be applied in these coupled segments of a ments—particularly motorization, modern navigation, and primary industry. In this report, ï¬?sheries are disaggregated as communication equipment; globalization; and food safety commercial, subsistence, and recreational. Commercial ï¬?sh- requirements—have changed the way many small-scale eries are further disaggregated according to scale. Fisheries ï¬?sheries operate. that target species that will be rendered for ï¬?shmeal or ï¬?sh oil, often called industrial or reduction ï¬?sheries,6 are not in- cluded in this analysis. 2.1.1 What Are Small-Scale Fisheries? Many countries classify their small-scale ï¬?sheries as a dis- tinct category. However, the terminology varies and can 2.1 DISAGGREGATING SMALL- AND LARGE- include a wider range of categories such as artisanal, tradi- SCALE COMMERCIAL CAPTURE FISHERIES tional, subsistence, or recreational. Some countries, such as Capture ï¬?sheries is an extremely diverse sector that uses a Norway, use the category “coastal ï¬?sheries,â€? implying ï¬?sh- wide variety of ï¬?shing techniques and technologies to har- ing closer to the shore and with relatively small boats. vest wild living aquatic resources. These techniques range from ï¬?shing with handheld rods and spears to using trawls Artisanal ï¬?shery commonly describes a traditional ï¬?shery. or purse seines over a kilometer long operated by industrial Artisanal implies a simple, individual (self-employed) or fam- ï¬?shing vessels longer than a football ï¬?eld. ily type of enterprise most often operated by the owner. It also implies the use of low levels of technology rather than Within this great diversity are vast differences in scale. describing the scale of the activity. However, artisanal ï¬?sher- Commonly, the sector is divided into small-scale ï¬?sheries ies and small-scale ï¬?sheries are often used interchangeably, and in this report, artisanal ï¬?sheries is used synonymously 6 In particular, the Coordinating Working Party on Fishery Statistics. with small-scale ï¬?sheries. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 4 CHAP T E R 2 — E STIMATING TH E EC ONOMIC CONTR IBUTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES TABLE 2.1: Example Deï¬?nitions of Small-Scale Marine Fisheries from Developing Country Case Studies COUNTRY SIZE OF VESSEL/ NO. OF (AREA) ENGINE OTHER CRITERIA SUBCATEGORIES VESSELS Brazil <18 m “Small boatsâ€? <12 m (with and without engines); “middle- 99,100 sized boatsâ€? 12–18 m Cambodia <10 HP Largely subsistence ï¬?shing Motorized; nonmotorized 5,400 Ghana Canoes Low level of mechanization According to gear types: Ali/Poli/Watsa, set net, hook and 11,200 line, drift gillnet, beach seine India Nonmechanized Motorized; nonmotorized and type of boat: catamarans, 179,000 plank-built craft, ï¬?ber-reinforced polymer and other craft, ring seiners, dugouts Philippines <3 GT Operating in coastal area <15 km and Motorized and nonmotorized bancas (an outrigger boat) 469,800 under management of local municipalities Source: Developing country case studies. Notes: HP = horsepower; GT = gross tonnage. Small-scale ï¬?sheries are often classiï¬?ed on the basis of tech- registration at the municipal government level and are nical attributes (table 2.1). Chuenpagdee et al. (2006) found allowed to ï¬?sh in the 0- to 15-kilometer coastal area. that vessel size was the key criterion in marine small-scale They are called municipal ï¬?sheries and are consid- ï¬?sheries in 65 percent of 140 countries studied. In 2002, ered small scale, and management responsibility is the world ï¬?shing fleet consisted of about 4 million vessels. devolved to the municipality level Large-scale vessels over 24 meters (or larger than 100 gross Conceptual considerations: According to the tons) represent only about 1 percent of the total ï¬?shing fleet Indonesian National Act No. 31/2004 concerning ï¬?sh- (FAO 2007a). About two-thirds of the fleet were undecked eries, small-scale ï¬?shers are deï¬?ned as those who do (and generally less than 10 meters), of which 65 percent, or ï¬?shing for their daily life or daily necessity. approximately 1.8 million, were nonmotorized vessels oper- ated by small-scale ï¬?shers. The European Union (EU) has no harmonized deï¬?nition of small-scale ï¬?sheries, although member countries use the The type of ï¬?shing gear type is another important deter- term generally to describe fleet segments of smaller boats minant, and ï¬?shing grounds and operational distance from ï¬?shing in national coastal waters. Small-scale ï¬?sheries are shore can be a criterion, especially where different manage- considered particularly important to employment and as hav- ment regulations apply for the different subsectors. Many ing a relatively lower impact on resources. A 2007 study co- countries consider all inland water ï¬?shing operations to be ordinated by the French Research Institute for Exploration of small-scale. The large-scale ï¬?sheries tend to be the primary the Sea (IFREMER) suggests that the EU bases its operational focus of monitoring and management efforts, and because deï¬?nition of small-scale ï¬?sheries on three criteria: vessel size, fewer restrictions generally are placed on small-scale ï¬?shing, gear used, and geographic range of activities. Accordingly, operators of relatively large vessels may be motivated to try small-scale coastal ï¬?shing would generally include vessels of to remain classiï¬?ed as small scale, as reported in Nicaragua less than 12 meters but possibly up to 18 meters for vessels (FAO/FishCode-STF 2008). The following examples of criteria using predominately passive gear and operating in inshore and characteristics for small-scale ï¬?sheries were found in the areas. The study concludes that the importance of this indus- developing country case studies: try segment, in terms of both production and employment, is often underestimated and that more knowledge on the struc- Technical criteria: Vessels of less than 5 gross tons in ture and functioning of the small-scale ï¬?sheries is necessary Thailand and less than 50 horsepower in Cambodia are for its efï¬?cient management (IFREMER 2007). classiï¬?ed as small scale. In Senegal, the vessel type is the decisive criterion, and all canoes, or pirogues, are The FAO Working Group on Small-Scale Fisheries concluded considered to be artisanal, although some can be over that it is not possible or useful to formulate a universal deï¬?ni- 15 meters with more than 20 crew tion of small-scale ï¬?sheries considering their diversity and Fishing ground and management responsibility: In the dynamism. Accordingly, the following description of small- Philippines, vessels smaller than 3 gross tons require scale ï¬?sheries was agreed upon: H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 2 — E S T IMAT ING T HE E CONOMIC CONT RIB UTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES 5 Small-scale ï¬?sheries can be broadly characterized as a levels ranging from self-employed single operators dynamic and evolving sector employing labour intensive through informal micro-enterprises to formal sector busi- harvesting, processing and distribution technologies to nesses. This subsector, therefore, is not homogenous exploit marine and inland water ï¬?shery resources. The within and across countries and regions and attention activities of this subsector, conducted full-time or part- to this fact is warranted when formulating strategies time, or just seasonally, are often targeted on supplying and policies for enhancing its contribution to food secu- ï¬?sh and ï¬?shery products to local and domestic markets, rity and poverty alleviation (FAO/Advisory Committee on and for subsistence consumption. Export-oriented pro- Fisheries Research 2004, p. 2). duction, however, has increased in many small-scale The diversity of attributes in small-scale ï¬?sheries sug- ï¬?sheries during the last one to two decades because gests that a multidimensional approach is required to cat- of greater market integration and globalization. While egorize small- and large-scale ï¬?sheries and ï¬?shery systems. typically men are engaged in ï¬?shing and women in ï¬?sh Table 2.2 gives an overview of some of these attributes. processing and marketing, women are also known to engage in near shore harvesting activities and men are A general evolution from small scale toward large scale is known to engage in ï¬?sh marketing and distribution. Oth- taking place, but this trend is neither linear nor irreversible er ancillary activities such as net-making, boatbuilding, (Berkes et al. 2001; Johnson 2006). Béné, Macfadyen, and engine repair and maintenance, etc., can provide addi- Allison (2007) make a case for the separate consideration tional ï¬?shery-related employment and income opportu- of small-scale ï¬?sheries (box 2.1), and small-scale ï¬?sheries nities in marine and inland ï¬?shing communities. Small- is now a permanent agenda item on the FAO Committee scale ï¬?sheries operate at widely differing organizational on Fisheries agenda. In conclusion, their differentiating TABLE 2.2: Generic Characteristics of Categories of Fisheries SMALL-SCALE CHARACTERISTICS SUBSISTENCE OTHER LARGE-SCALE Size of ï¬?shing vessel and engine Nonmotorized or small (5–7 m, <10 GT Small (<24 m, <50 GT) with low-power Large (>24m, >50 GT) with high-power engine (<400 HP) engine (>400 HP) Type of craft/vessel Canoes, dinghies, wooden boats, undecked vessels Steel/glass-reinforced plastic–hulled vessel, trawlers, factory vessels Fishing unit Individuals or family or community Small groups; some specialization and Smaller and larger groups; specializa- groups division of labor; importance of house- tion and division of labor hold and community Ownership Craft/gear owner operated Usually owned and operated by senior Concentration of ownership, often operator; some absentee ownership by nonoperators; some cooperative ownership Time commitment Mostly part time/occasional Full time or part time Usually full time or seasonal Fishing grounds Inshore or inland Inshore/coastal; inland or marine All marine areas, very few inland Disposal of catch Primarily household consumption but Sales to local, national, and internation- Primarily sale to organized markets some local barter and sale al markets; household consumption Utilization of catch Fresh or traditionally processed for Fresh or processed, often traditionally, Mostly processed; large share for human consumption for human consumption reduction to ï¬?shmeal Knowledge and technology Premium on skills and local knowledge; High skills and knowledge needs; Skills and experience important but sup- manual gear manual and mechanized gear; some ported by technology; mechanized gear; electronic equipment automation and electronic equipment Integration into economy Informal, not integrated Partially integrated Formal, fully integrated Base Rural/periurban Rural/periurban Urban/corporate Value added Low/local Household/local level Throughout economy Beneï¬?ts Direct consumption Direct sale and employment Some direct and through proï¬?ts and taxes Factors of production Labor intensive Labor intensive Capital intensive Source: Authors; adapted from Berkes et al. 2001; Chuenpagdee et al. 2006; Johnson 2006. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 6 CHAP T E R 2 — E STIMATING TH E EC ONOMIC CONTR IBUTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES BOX 2.1: The Case for Separate Consideration of The dividing line between small- and large-scale land-based Small-Scale Fisheries postharvest activities may be blurred. Small-scale ï¬?shers may supply ï¬?sh to industrial processing plants, allowing Small-scale ï¬?sheries are often part of diverse and com- them to indirectly participate in markets to which they might plex livelihoods nested in a local ï¬?shery economy that not otherwise have access. In some countries, canoe ï¬?sh- underpins the social, economic, and cultural cohesion ers collect and market bycatch from industrial trawlers. For of isolated communities; are essential for food security example, in the Gambia, ï¬?shers who were effectively dis- and as social safety nets; are frequently dispersed over placed by shrimp trawlers worked out informal agreements large areas with multiple landing points; require different and made a business of collecting and marketing bycatch management approaches and knowledge pathways and (Clucas 1997). However, large- and small-scale ï¬?shers often more discursive than coercive enforcement; are highly compete directly for access and control over ï¬?sh resources vulnerable to threats, including overï¬?shing in inshore and markets (FAO 2003). and inland areas, competition from large-scale ï¬?shing, and exposure to natural disasters such as typhoons and Vertical integration of the large-scale ï¬?shing and processing floods; and are subject to increased prevalence of HIV/ industry has become common during the last few decades in AIDS, particularly in ï¬?shing communities in Africa and many countries, such as Iceland, New Zealand, Namibia, and Southeast Asia. Peru (FAO 2011). In small-scale ï¬?sheries, vertical organiza- tion tends to be informal; for example, ï¬?sh traders ï¬?nance Stakeholders in small-scale ï¬?sheries (in developing ï¬?shing operations in exchange for a guaranteed supply of countries) generally have a weak political voice because ï¬?sh. In Bangladesh, the dadandar, or the ï¬?sh trader/money they live in remote areas in communities with low liter- lender, is the traditional source of credit for ï¬?shers. The credit acy that may be marginalized on the basis of race, tribe, conditions vary from one location to another, but generally, caste, or ethnicity. the borrower is obliged to sell his ï¬?sh to the dadandar at a Because the production is caught for domestic use or price below the market price (Kleih et al. 2003). sold onshore directly to end consumers, the economic While many countries reserve inshore marine areas and in- and nutritional contribution of small-scale ï¬?sheries is in- land waters for small-scale operators, in many ï¬?sheries, both adequately captured in national accounts and food bal- fleet segments compete for the same ï¬?shery resources ance sheets. (FAO/RAP/FIPL 2004; Jacquet and Pauly 2008), and indus- Many small-scale ï¬?sheries are effectively unregulated trial trawlers frequently encroach on reserved inshore ï¬?shing and poorly monitored, especially in developing countries grounds (Kelleher 2002). In addition to affecting the resource and inland waters. base available for small-scale ï¬?sheries, encroachment on Source: Béné et al. 2007; Garcia et al. 2008. inshore ï¬?shing grounds may increase the risk of accidents and collisions. Incidents of large-scale vessels getting their trawls entangled in small-scale ï¬?shing nets and dragging attributes are sufï¬?cient to treat small- and large-scale ï¬?sher- them away were among the main causes for accidents at ies as two distinct categories in global data and policy discus- sea in seven West African countries (Gallène 1995). In the sions (Chuenpagdee et al. 2006; Jacquet and Pauly 2008). Republic of the Congo, Guinea, and Gabon, infractions by larger vessels in areas reserved for small-scale ï¬?shers and safety at sea were major concerns among small-scale ï¬?shers 2.1.2 The Small-Scale Fisheries Value Chain (Njock 2007). The FAO Code of Conduct calls for preferential Fishing operations are part of an extended value chain in treatment of small-scale ï¬?sheries (box 2.2). which ï¬?sh processing and marketing are of major impor- tance. In general, small-scale processing is labor intensive and uses a minimum of technology to preserve the ï¬?sh, ex- 2.2 CASE STUDY METHODS tend its shelf life, or add value. Drying, salting, fermenting, Case studies on 17 developing countries formed the quan- and smoking are extensively used. In large-scale ï¬?sheries, titative basis for the developing country part of the global processing takes place at sea and/or at shore-based plants. study. The case studies were executed in full collaboration Freezing and canning are the most important methods of with the national authorities with a view to progressively processing. Frozen ï¬?sh is the most common ï¬?sh commodity securing greater inclusion of previously unaccounted ï¬?shing exported from developing countries (FAO 2007a). activities. The selected countries were not a random sample H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 2 — E S T IMAT ING T HE E CONOMIC CONT RIB UTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES 7 BOX 2.2: The Code of Conduct and Small-Scale Information of the ï¬?sheries was compiled on the following Fisheries characteristics: The Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries was 1. Production adopted in 1995 by FAO members in response to the Catch growing concerns regarding the sustainability of global Catch for human consumption ï¬?shery resources. The Code recognizes the importance Waste and discards of small-scale ï¬?sheries in poverty alleviation and food 2. Employment security. One of the objectives of the Code is to “pro- Numbers of harvesters mote the contribution of ï¬?sheries to food security and Numbers of postharvest workers by gender food quality, giving priority to the nutritional needs of 3. Employment per ton of catch local communitiesâ€? (FAO 1995a, Article 2[f]). It also ac- knowledges that the context of ï¬?sheries management 4. Efï¬?ciency includes “food security, poverty alleviation and sustain- Catch per ï¬?sher able developmentâ€? (Article 6.2). The Code directly ref- Catch per ton of fuel erences ï¬?shers and ï¬?sh workers in the “subsistence, 5. Economic contribution small-scale and artisanal ï¬?sheriesâ€? and their right to “a Harvest GDP secure and just livelihood, as well as preferential ac- Postharvest GDP cess, where appropriate, to traditional ï¬?shing grounds Recreational GDP. and resources in the waters under their national jurisdic- tionâ€? (Article 6.18). The FAO (2005) also issued technical The information provided in the case studies is based on the guidelines for “increasing the contribution of small-scale latest available data and generally refers to a year during the ï¬?sheries to poverty alleviation and food securityâ€? to ac- period 2004 through 2007, although for some values, older company the Code. data have been used. This study does not standardize the values from the different country case studies to a base year. Rather, it assumes that the orders of magnitude of the calculated values and the relationships between different in- dicators are sufï¬?ciently precise given the level of aggregation but included countries home to 70 percent of the world’s and indicative nature of the study estimates. ï¬?sh workers and that account for 40 percent of the global The case studies relied to a large extent on secondary data and 56 percent of developing countries’ reported catches.7 in the form of ofï¬?cial statistics, published data, and “gray lit- The group of case study countries did not include any of the eratureâ€? (such as information from project reports and stud- major ï¬?shmeal-producing countries in Latin America, which ies). In some cases, this information was complemented and makes the results less representative for a wider group of conï¬?rmed by primary data collection. This primary research developing countries with regard to estimates of the use took place via interviews with key informants in Cambodia of catches (e.g., the share of production used for domestic and Ghana; through focus group discussions or expert meet- human consumption). The case studies were undertaken on ings in Brazil, Cambodia, and China; and through interviews the following developing countries: with a sample of operators to collect vessel-speciï¬?c infor- Asia—Bangladesh, Cambodia, China, India, Indonesia, mation in Bangladesh and China. The reanalysis of existing Myanmar, Thailand, Vietnam, and the Philippines household survey data constitutes an important input into Africa—Ghana, Mozambique, Nigeria, Senegal, and the assessment of production and consumption in Thailand three countries around Lake Victoria (Kenya, Tanzania, and Vietnam. Uganda) Although every effort was made to standardize in the Latin America—Brazil. case study approaches, each was tuned to local circum- stances and data availability to obtain best estimates for the 7 Calculated using averages of 2004–06 based on data from FAO selected indicators. Box 2.3 provides further details of the FishStat Plus. The developing countries grouping is deï¬?ned as approaches. Data are most complete for employment, pro- listed in FAO FishStat Plus (FAO 2008a) with one exception: Cyprus has been removed from developing countries (and now duction quantities, and the share for local human consump- belongs to developed countries in Europe). tion. For some of the case study countries, information was EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 8 CHAP T E R 2 — E STIMATING TH E EC ONOMIC CONTR IBUTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES not available on all the selected indicators, and available infor- on each case study country (and Lake Victoria) are available mation was used as a basis for extrapolation to complete the (FAO and WorldFish Center 2009). Macroeconomic aspects analyses. Case study results were also complemented and were not explicitly addressed in the developing country case cross-checked with information available from other sourc- studies, but a separate study was undertaken by a team led es, particularly from the database of FAO Fishery Country by Eriko Hoshino on the contribution of ï¬?sheries to GDP and Proï¬?les (FCPs). Summary tables of the information available related economic multiplier effects. BOX 2.3: Key Features of Case Study Methods China: Estimates were based on ofï¬?cial ï¬?sheries statis- as the share for domestic human consumption) was not tics and an unpublished frame survey conducted in 2007 available. and on interviews with wholesale markets’ managers Philippines: Data were sourced from ofï¬?cial ï¬?sheries sta- and vessel captains in selected locations in Guangdong tistics, censuses, and research studies. The ofï¬?cial infor- and Zhejiang provinces for marine ï¬?sheries and in Hubei mation was disaggregated into marine or inland and munic- province for inland ï¬?sheries. The results for the marine ipal (small scale) and commercial (large scale). Information subsector in Guangdong and Zhejiang provinces were on the share for domestic human consumption, separated extrapolated to the entire marine ï¬?sheries based on of- into small- and large-scale production, was not available. ï¬?cial landings data. The results for Hubei province were extrapolated to the rest of the country in consultation Thailand: Estimates for the marine subsector were with local experts and using ofï¬?cial statistics on ï¬?shing based on data sourced from ofï¬?cial ï¬?sheries statistics. vessel and ï¬?shery resources distribution in inland wa- Production was recalculated assuming the following: ters to guide the raising factors. Large-scale catches included an additional 1 percent because of discards at sea. Ghana: Estimates for the marine ï¬?sheries were based on data sourced from ofï¬?cial ï¬?sheries statistics comple- Small-scale catches included 1 additional mented by a questionnaire survey on auxiliary employ- kilogram (at $1/kg) per ï¬?sher and day for own ment. Information on cost and earnings was collected in consumption. semistructured discussions with key informants. Data Only the large-scale ï¬?sheries produce for export. on the inland ï¬?sheries were partly sourced from ofï¬?- Estimates of inland production and employment cial statistics and project and research reports. In addi- were made using 2003 census data giving an tion, a market survey was conducted, and landings for estimate of the total number of inland ï¬?sh- Lake Volta were recalculated using market information ing households accompanied by survey data from Yeji together with lakewide catch assessment data for 2,215 sampled households. Distinguishing from 2000 as a basis for extrapolation. Employment es- between small, medium, and commercial ï¬?shing, timates were based on earlier (2007) survey data. For the survey results were extrapolated to all house- regions other than Lake Volta, data and estimates for holds according to the census data. Assumptions Lake Volta were used, taking known differences be- made included that inland production was valued tween these other areas and Lake Volta into consider- at $1 per kilogram, the number of boats was 1.4 ation. The number of ï¬?sh processors was obtained from per square kilometer of water area, and all inland government ofï¬?cials in the different regions. production was for domestic local consumption. Vietnam: Data were mainly sourced from ofï¬?cial sta- Indonesia: Aggregate data separating marine from inland tistics and project reports. Estimates of inland ï¬?sher- ï¬?sheries were sourced from ofï¬?cial estimates from dif- ies production were calculated by reanalyzing existing ferent government agencies. The numbers of small- and household consumption survey data. Data sources and large-scale ï¬?shers was estimated using a ratio derived disaggregation deï¬?nitions were discussed and validated from earlier sample surveys. Small- and large-scale produc- with local ofï¬?cials and experts. tion was calculated according to estimates by an expert panel. Information on the disposition of catches (such Source: Authors. H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 2 — E S T IMAT ING T HE E CONOMIC CONT RIB UTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES 9 2.2.1 Developed Country Sample attempt was made to harmonize the deï¬?nition of small-scale The quantiï¬?ed proï¬?le of large- and small-scale ï¬?sheries from and large-scale ï¬?sheries across countries (see Annex for the developing country case studies was complemented more a detailed discussion of deï¬?nitions). with existing information from OECD countries and others Throughout the study, the term catch is considered as where recent studies have been executed, such as for the equivalent to landings. However, the two terms are not Paciï¬?c Islands. Information was compiled from a sample of equivalent, and discards are generally not included when 11 developed countries, representing about 14 percent of referring to catch. Quantities of all aquatic animals are given global reported catches and 47 percent of developed coun- as live weight equivalents, which is the weight of the catch try catches.8 These countries included eight EU members before gutting, heading, or similar treatment. Seaweed and (Denmark, France, Greece, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal, other aquatic plants, pearls, and marine mammals are gener- Spain, and the United Kingdom) and Canada, Japan, and ally excluded from the study. Reference to the catch of a Norway. Data were sourced from ofï¬?cial statistics and re- country or region means the catch of the fleets registered search study reports, and the most recent values available in that country or region rather than the catch taken from its were used. Most data are from the 2005–2007 period, but waters. Catches from recreational ï¬?sheries are generally not some earlier data were used as necessary. included in the disaggregated proï¬?les because the estimates An approach similar to that used for the developing coun- represent only commercial ï¬?sheries and include subsistence try case studies was applied to the deï¬?nitions of small- and and recreational ï¬?sheries only to the extent that they are in- large-scale ï¬?sheries in developed countries. However, cluded in ofï¬?cial ï¬?sheries statistics. information on the share of the catch for domestic human consumption and on discards was not available by subsector 2.2.3 Extrapolating the Sample Data to the Global Level in the sample countries. Most of the information on ï¬?sher and postharvest employment was expressed in full-time 2.2.3.1 Developing Countries equivalents. The postharvest jobs referred mainly to employ- The results of the case studies were used to estimate key ment in ï¬?sh processing and include employment related to indicators for all developing countries as a group. Because processing of ï¬?sh originating not only from domestic capture important ï¬?shmeal-producing countries were not represent- ï¬?sheries, but also from aquaculture production and imported ed in the developing country case study sample, the share ï¬?sh. In general, jobs in marketing and sales, particularly at of production for domestic human consumption was not the retail level, are not captured in the analysis. Employment included in this exercise. Estimates of discards in the devel- in upstream and support activities (such as boatbuilding, gear oping country case studies were largely based on ancillary repair, and fuel provision) is likewise not included. information, so no attempt was made to assess discards on the basis of those estimates. 2.2.2 Use of Statistical Data The developing and developed country data were disag- To obtain the aggregate employment values, the number of gregated to separate small- from large-scale ï¬?sheries on ï¬?shers and ï¬?sh workers by subsector, or industry segment, the basis of the deï¬?nitions used by the countries studied, in case study countries was included as per-case-study esti- to separate marine from inland (freshwater) ï¬?sheries, and mates. For non–case study countries, the case studies’ aver- to separate harvest from postharvest activities. The studies age catch-per-ï¬?sher ratio and reestimated catch quantities assessed employment, catches, food ï¬?sh supply, and invest- were used to calculate the number of ï¬?shers in each sub- ment and operation costs including fuel consumption. These sector. Catches were reestimated on the basis of the differ- variables—mainly focusing on food security at the household ence between case study data on catches by subsector and level—were selected largely because they had also been marine and inland production averages for 2004 to 2006 from included in earlier analyses (see Annex). FAO FishStat Plus data (2008a). For all case study countries excluding China,9 the case study data showed, on average, Several of the case study countries did not have formal deï¬?- catches to be 10 percent higher in the marine subsector and nitions of small- and large-scale ï¬?sheries, but a classiï¬?cation was agreed upon with national experts and government ofï¬?cials for the purpose of these case studies. However, no 9 The Chinese case study provided catch estimates that were about 10 percent lower than ofï¬?cially reported catches (com- pared to the FAO FishStat Plus data) both for marine and inland production. While these estimates were considered valid for 8 (http://www.fao.org/ï¬?shery/cwp/en) with strengthened links to China, it was deemed incorrect to allow this particular case to the Global Strategy to Improve Agricultural and Rural Statistics. influence the reestimation of catches for other countries. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 10 CHAP T E R 2 — E STIMATING TH E EC ONOMIC CONTR IBUTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES 70 percent higher for inland ï¬?sheries, reflecting assumed un- total marine catch at 13 percent higher than reported catches derreporting. The production of all other developing countries according to the FAO FishStat Plus data.11 Comprehensive was raised proportionately, dividing the difference between information on inland ï¬?sheries was not available for most small- and large-scale ï¬?sheries according to the averages ob- of the sample of developed countries. The division of catches tained in the case study countries. Small-scale ï¬?sheries rep- between small- and large-scale ï¬?sheries in the marine sector resented 64 percent of total marine catches and 96 percent was based on the average proportions of the sample coun- of inland catches. Adjustments based on complementary tries. On this basis, 23 percent of marine catches were as- data (e.g., FAO FCPs) were made for known anomalies. By sessed as small-scale production. All inland catches were dividing these reestimated catch quantities by the catch-per- considered to be small scale. The reestimated catches ï¬?sher ratios from the case studies, estimates of the number were divided by the average catch-per-ï¬?sher values obtained of ï¬?shers by country were obtained. These estimates were from the sample of developed countries to derive at an ag- cross-checked with other available information and adjusted gregate number of ï¬?shers for all developed countries. as and when required. Postharvest employment was calculated according to the 2.2.4 Assumptions and Issues average multiplier (number of postharvest jobs divided by Despite the global diversity of ï¬?sheries and ï¬?shery systems, number of ï¬?shers) of the case studies. Likewise, the number there are sufï¬?cient common features to distinguish small- of women involved in the ï¬?sheries sector was calculated us- and large-scale ï¬?sheries as two principal segments for the ing the average proportion of women in total employment as purposes of global policy discussions or country-level moni- derived from case studies. toring efforts. The deï¬?nitions of large- and small-scale ï¬?shing used in this report are those speciï¬?ed in the respective na- 2.2.3.2 Developed Countries tional or regional (in the case of the EU) statistical systems. To arrive at employment numbers for developed countries Summing these categories across countries presents certain as a group, the same principles and methods were used to difï¬?culties, and every effort was made to standardize the extrapolate sample country data as were used for developing units. Ofï¬?cial ï¬?sheries data on catches and employment at countries. The number of ï¬?shers by subsector, or segment, these different scales are not always reliable. This is the case in the non-EU sample countries was included as given. For for all types of ï¬?sheries, but it is of particular concern with the 25 member states of the EU, data were available on total regard to small-scale ï¬?sheries. Because of their informal and full-time and part-time employment.10 For other developed dispersed characteristics, catches of and employment in in- countries, the sample countries’ average catch-per-ï¬?sher land ï¬?sheries tend to be greatly underreported. In particular, ratio and the recalculated catch volumes were used to calcu- estimates of the importance and extent of subsistence ï¬?sh- late the number of ï¬?shers in each subsector. ing are deï¬?cient. This study addresses this gap, but for a limited number of countries. For the reestimate of catches, data from the sample of devel- oped countries were combined with FAO FishStat Plus data Because the disparate information has been compiled and (averages of catches for 2004 to 2006 in marine and inland synthesized across highly diverse ï¬?sheries and countries, the waters) for nonsampled countries to provide totals for marine results must be treated with due caution. For example, there and inland catches by all developed countries. Using the ï¬?nd- is no universally accepted deï¬?nition of small-scale ï¬?sheries, ings from the developing country case studies and considering and as already noted, statistical information on small-scale estimates of illegal, unreported, and unregulated (IUU) ï¬?sh- ï¬?sheries can be deï¬?cient or nonexistent. ing (Agnew et al. 2008), the total marine production was then The sample data are extrapolated to the global level using raised by 10 percent overall and that of the large-scale marine a variety of multipliers, the most important of which is the ï¬?sheries by another 5 percent, resulting in a reestimate of the 11 According to Agnew et al. (2008), key IUU ï¬?sheries include large- 10 From Salz et al. 2006. Unlike the information in the sample coun- scale international ï¬?sheries, and IUU catches amounted to be- try data compilation that was generally expressed as full-time tween 11 and 26 million tons in 2003, representing between 13 equivalents, employment information in Salz et al. is presented and 32 percent of total global landings when compared to the in total full-time and part-time employment ï¬?gures. These data reported catch ï¬?gure of 81.5 million tons (FAO 2007a). The Big were adjusted for assumed decreases in employment from the Numbers Project (BNP) study applies the lower range of this es- year of the study (2005) to present-day (2008) levels (based on timate to the reestimation of catches by the developed country personal communication, P. Salz). group. H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 2 — E S T IMAT ING T HE E CONOMIC CONT RIB UTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES 11 country-level catch as reported to FAO. In the absence of generally not readily available. Census or national employ- evidence to the contrary, inland ï¬?sheries catches were as- ment surveys often record only primary occupational catego- sumed to be from small-scale ï¬?sheries, although some inland ries, not secondary or tertiary occupations, misrepresenting waters, such as the Caspian Sea and North America’s Great the diversity of rural livelihoods that combine many income- Lakes, are known to have signiï¬?cant large-scale ï¬?sheries. It generating activities (Keskinen 2003). Subsistence and oc- is assumed that the sample reflects the global disaggrega- casional ï¬?shing is the subject of separate case studies (Mills tion of small- and large-scale ï¬?sheries. 2010). Disparities exist between ofï¬?cial statistics (such as numbers Employment in postharvest and auxiliary ï¬?sheries activities of ï¬?shers) and the values obtained through the case studies. also raises issues about deï¬?nitions. These employment val- Consequently, a global estimate, such as global catch, based ues in the case studies refer mostly to postharvest process- on the case study results is higher than that estimated by ing and include marketing jobs. Employment values could FAO on the basis of the aggregate of the ofï¬?cially reported also include employment related to processing of imported catches. The values presented are not intended to substitute ï¬?sh and ï¬?sh from aquaculture, as employment data gener- for the ofï¬?cial national or FAO values. Rather, the anomalies ally do not distinguish between the sources of ï¬?sh supply. demand that additional effort and resources are directed to Employment in upstream and support activities, such as resolve the differences and that such resources are justiï¬?ed boatbuilding, gear repair, and provision of fuel, were esti- given that the contribution of capture ï¬?sheries to economies mated in some of the countries, but these values were not is considerably greater than portrayed by the ofï¬?cial statis- included in the ï¬?nal compilation of data for the developing tics. The study complements ofï¬?cial statistics, allowing for country case studies. a better understanding of the contributions and roles of small- and large-scale capture ï¬?sheries and the people they support. 2.3 UNCOVERING THE HIDDEN HARVESTS OF SUBSISTENCE FISHERIES In some countries, separating statistical information on aqua- culture from the information on capture ï¬?sheries presents A subsistence ï¬?shery is “a ï¬?shery where the ï¬?sh caught are particular challenges, and a variety of cross-checks were shared and consumed directly by the families and kin of the used to ensure consistency within and across countries. The ï¬?shers rather than being bought by intermediaries and sold results can be considered as best estimates to which future at the next larger marketâ€? (FAO n.d.[c]). Pure subsistence studies can add precision. ï¬?sheries are rare because excess production is sold or ex- changed for other products or services even in the smallest There is a spectrum of ï¬?shing activities that are often not ï¬?shery. In this respect, subsistence ï¬?sheries are partly a com- readily distinguishable from one another. Conscious of this ponent of small-scale commercial ï¬?sheries. With the pos- spectrum for the purposes of quantifying the ï¬?shing activi- sible exception of recreational ï¬?sheries, all ï¬?sheries are likely ties, the case studies followed the classiï¬?cation used by FAO: to have some commercial component. Recreational, subsis- tence, and commercial ï¬?sheries may overlap. Nevertheless, Full-time ï¬?shers, receiving at least 90 percent of their subsistence ï¬?shing implies a more household-centered than livelihood from or spending at least 90 percent of their commercial activity. working time ï¬?shing Part-time ï¬?shers, receiving at least 30 percent, but Under the FAO deï¬?nition, where ï¬?sh are sold, ï¬?shing can no less than 90 percent, of their livelihood from ï¬?shing or longer be deemed subsistence, which does not accommo- spending at least 30 percent but less than 90 percent date well the inherent variability in ï¬?sh supply that moderates of their working time in that occupation ï¬?shers’ disposal of catch. In practice, “pureâ€? noncommercial Occasional ï¬?shers, receiving less than 30 percent ï¬?shing as described here is rare, and ï¬?shers remain oppor- of their income from ï¬?shing or spending less than tunistic, so where ï¬?sh surplus to household requirements 30 percent of their working time ï¬?shing. are captured, often during peak seasons, this catch is sold (box 2.4). This deï¬?nition also leaves a gray area where catch Occasional ï¬?shing can make a major contribution to local sold directly by ï¬?shers or family members of ï¬?shers is nei- food supplies and nutrition for communities living near inland ther included nor excluded from the proposed subsistence and marine waters. However, this category of ï¬?shing was group. Recreational ï¬?sheries, with the exception of catch- not used in the case studies because separate data were and-release ï¬?sheries, also fall within this deï¬?nition. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 12 CHAP T E R 2 — E STIMATING TH E EC ONOMIC CONTR IBUTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES BOX 2.4: Subsistence Fishing in Bangladesh balance sheet to reassess the likely magnitude of capture ï¬?shery activities, including subsistence ï¬?shing. These es- Subsistence ï¬?shers are those who ï¬?sh for consumption timates were compared to alternative estimates for total and for whom any income from ï¬?shing is more a mat- supply. A series of detailed provincial case studies provided ter of chance than intent. Opportunistic is perhaps the data on ï¬?shery participation and laid a basis for scenarios most appropriate descriptor for subsistence ï¬?shing in extrapolating these data to the national level. Bangladesh. The patterns of activity by subsistence ï¬?sh- ers are seen to be highly dependent on natural variability The Bangladesh study is considered the more robust, and in available resources, and making meaningful distinc- the Vietnam results are considered to provide reasonable tions between subsistence ï¬?shing and ï¬?shing for income estimates given the weakness of the underlying data. The can be a futile exercise. The designation of subsistence data gaps mean that the Vietnam estimates do not include ï¬?sher may largely be a matter of convenience. When the marine sector for which additional ï¬?eldwork would be ï¬?shers outside professional ï¬?shing communities want of beneï¬?t. Additional details of the case study analyses are to understate the level of ï¬?shing, it is often described as provided in the Annex. ï¬?shing for consumption, although they may be ï¬?shing at commercial scale. Children’s ï¬?shing is almost always 2.4 ESTIMATING THE ECONOMIC CONTRIBUTION said to be just for consumption, even though many may OF RECREATIONAL FISHERIES sell some of their catch to supplement family income. The degree to which what is caught is sold for income Recreational ï¬?sheries may be considered a special form of small- also varies in accordance with seasonal fluctuations in scale ï¬?sheries. To some extent, they overlap with subsistence the ï¬?sh biomass and the area of water bodies. When ï¬?sheries because part of the catch is consumed by the ï¬?sher, ï¬?sh are plentiful and concentrated in small areas where the ï¬?sher’s family, or associates. In some cases, some or all of they are easily caught, self-described subsistence ï¬?sh- the catch may be sold to offset the costs of the sport or small- ers can catch more ï¬?sh than the family can consume. scale commercial ï¬?shing may masquerade as recreational. Source: FAP 1994. The ï¬?sh caught by recreational ï¬?shers are not part of a market transaction, so the economic contribution of the recreational ï¬?sheries requires alternative approaches to valuation. The ap- The process of preparing the developing country case studies proach taken in available national assessments is to estimate indicated that the contribution of subsistence ï¬?sheries was either the economic welfare or the total expenditures made considerably more important than anticipated. Consequently, by anglers. The economic welfare measure includes not only detailed studies on subsistence ï¬?sheries were undertaken the aggregate market transactions (total purchases made by for Bangladesh, Vietnam, and the Philippines, in each case us- anglers), but also an estimate of their willingness to pay. For ing available data (that is, no ï¬?eld surveys were undertaken). example, an angler may be willing to pay more than the cost of the ï¬?shing license for the authorization to ï¬?sh. The approach The methods used differed substantially in Bangladesh and taken in this study is to determine the aggregate value of the Vietnam because of the nature, perceived reliability, and cov- purchases made by anglers; that is, expenditure on registration erage of the available data. A failure to satisfactorily complete fees, ice, bait, accommodation, boat hire, ï¬?shing equipment, the Philippines study indicates the complexity and difï¬?culty and travel costs. Most studies acknowledge some overlap and in assessing the subsistence ï¬?sheries. possible double accounting with the tourism sector. In the case of Bangladesh, detailed studies, prepared over Expenditures made by anglers, estimates of recreational a 10-year period as part of the Flood Action Plan, were re- ï¬?sheries’ contribution to GDP (total expenditure and/or value analyzed. The outputs from 34 districts were extrapolated added), and estimates of numbers of recreational ï¬?shers to the national level using a neighbor-influence model and (anglers) were compiled from available literature. From the updated using the 2001 population census values. The available studies (tables 2.3 through 2.8), the percentage of Compartmentalization Pilot Project was used to calibrate expenditures attributable to ï¬?shing equipment was derived. changes resulting from flood control measures. The sample value (mostly from OECD countries) was raised to The Vietnamese case study took separate approaches to the global level using available regional and global estimates assessing the magnitude of and involvement in ï¬?shing ac- of the sales of recreational ï¬?shing equipment. The numbers tivities. Direct and indirect data were used in a production of recreational ï¬?shers were estimated in the same manner. H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 2 — E S T IMAT ING T HE E CONOMIC CONT RIB UTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES 13 TABLE 2.3: Estimated Expenditures on Fishing Tackle in Relation to Total Angler Expenditures LOCATION YEAR RATIO STUDY South Australia 2000 0.09 Jones and Doonan 2005 Australia 2003 0.08 Henry and Lyle 2003 United States 2001 0.06 Dean 2007 United States (Lake Erie) 2003 0.20 Murray and Shields 2004 United States 2006 0.10 Southwick Associates 2007 United States 2008 0.10 ASA 2002 United States 2004 0.10 Steinback, Gentner, and Castle 2004 United States (Washington) 2006 0.15 TCW Economics 2008 United States (Washington) 2008 0.22 Washington Department of Fish and Wildlife Canada 2005 0.08 DFO 2007 Germany 2000 0.38 Hilge 1998; Wedekind, Hilge, and Steffens 2001 Germany — 0.03 Toivonen 2004 England and Wales (inland) 2007 0.43 Radford, Riddington, and Gibson 2009 Austria 2000 0.25 Kohl 2000 Ireland (indirect est.) 2003 0.24 The Marine Institute 2004 Ireland (foreign) 2001 0.04 Indecon 2003 Ireland (local) 2001 0.08 Indecon 2003 Wales (salmon/trout) 1999 0.06 Radford et al. 2009 Wales (trout) 2000 0.31 Nautilus 2000 Scotland 2009 0.13 Glasgow Caledonian University 2009 Brazil (Pantanal) 1994 0.33 Moraes and Seidl 2000 Mexico (Los Cabos) 2007/08 0.02 Southwick et al. 2008 Mean 0.16 Median 0.10 Source: Findings of the authors’ review of the studies listed on the right. TABLE 2.4: Recreational Fishing Gear Trade Classiï¬?cation Code THE NORTH AMERICAN INDUSTRY CLASSIFICATION SYSTEM CODE FOR FISHING TACKLE AND EQUIPMENT IS 3399201. THE AGGREGATE LATENT DEMAND ESTIMATES ARE DERIVED FOR THIS DEFINITION OF FISHING TACKLE AND EQUIPMENT. “FISHING TACKLE AND EQUIPMENTâ€? IS SPECIFICALLY DEFINED AS FOLLOWS: 3399201 Fishing tackle and equipment 33992011 Fishing tackle and equipment 3399201101 Fishing rods, excluding ï¬?shing rod and reel combinations 3399201106 Fishing reels, excluding ï¬?shing rod and reel combinations 3399201111 Fishing rod and reel combinations 3399201116 Fish hooks, including snelled hooks 3399201121 Artiï¬?cial ï¬?shing bait, including flies, lures, casting plugs, spinners, and spoons 3399201126 Fishing tackle boxes 3399201131 Other ï¬?shing equipment, including bait and ï¬?sh buckets, creels, floats, furnished lines, sinkers, and snap swivels Source: http://www.icongrouponline.com/codes/NAICS.html. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 14 CHAP T E R 2 — E STIMATING TH E EC ONOMIC CONTR IBUTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES TABLE 2.5: Estimated Global Number of Anglers ANGLERS COUNTRY SOURCE (MILLIONS) Australia 3.360 Austria 0.410 EAA 2003 Belgium 0.300 EAA 2003 Brazil (Pantanal only) 0.059 Shrestha, Seidl, and Moraes 2002 Bulgaria 0.180 EAA 2003 Canada 2.800 Fisheries and Oceans Canada 2005 China 90.000 Min 2006 Cyprus 0.003 EAA 2003 Czech Republic 0.263 EAA 2003 Denmark 0.650 Roth and Jensen 2003 Estonia 0.050 EAA 2003 Finland 1.900 Finnish Game and Fisheries Research Institute 2009 France 4.000 EAA 2003 Germany 3.300 EAA 2003 Hungary 0.325 EAA 2003 Iceland 0.650 EAA 2003 Ireland 0.200 EAA 2003 Italy 0.900 EAA 2003 Japana 10.200 Latvia 0.200 EAA 2003 Luxembourg 0.004 EAA 2003 Macedonia 0.000 EAA 2003 Netherlands 1.500 EAA 2003 Norway 1.800 EAA 2003 Poland 4.400 BizAcumen 2009 Portugal 0.230 EAA 2003 b Rest of Asia and Latin America 41.800 Rumania 0.200 EAA 2003 Russia 14.700 BizAcumen 2009 Slovakia 0.069 EAA 2003 South Africa (marine) 0.496 Grifï¬?th and Lamberth 2002 Spain (Mediterranean licenses only) 0.133 Franquesa et al. 2004 Sweden 2.500 EAA 2003 Switzerland 0.350 EAA 2003 Turkey 4.900 BizAcumen 2009 England and Wales 4.200 Nautilus 2000 United States 29.400 BizAcumen 2009 Total number of anglers 226.431 Sources: http://www.eaa-europe.org/index.php?id=14 and see table references. a Assuming Japan spends the same per person as other OECD countries spend. b Assuming the rest of Asia and Latin America spend 75 percent of what OECD countries spend per person (includes Argentina with separate estimate of 3 million anglers). Note that if these anglers spend less than 75 percent of what OECD anglers spend, the number of anglers rises proportionately. H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 2 — E S T IMAT ING T HE E CONOMIC CONT RIB UTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES 15 TABLE 2.6: Global Expenditures on Recreational TABLE 2.7: U.S. Expenditures on Fishing Equipment by Fishing Tackle Type, 2006 REGION/COUNTRY 2009 FISHING TYPE SHARE United States 29.13% Freshwater 63.87% Canada 2.41% Saltwater 20.41% Japan 9.02% Nonspeciï¬?c 15.72% Europe 39.17% Total 100% Asia-Paciï¬?c 11.65% Source: BizAcumen 2009. Latin America 8.62% Total 100% Source: BizAcumen 2009. TABLE 2.8: Selected Information Sources for Recreational Fisheries Contribution SOURCE COUNTRIES/ REGIONS DATA SOURCE METHOD Steinback et al. 2004 United States, excluding A series of marine angler expenditure surveys in Input-output model MPLAN; value- Alaska, Texas, and Hawaii the coastal regions in 1998–2000; two-part survey added impacts not provided involving a random sample of saltwater trips through an intercept creel survey and a random-digit-dial telephone survey of coastal households Peterson 2005 Hawaii Surveys Multipliers generated using RIMS II NMFS 2007 United States No detail; this document is a national overview No detail on methods Cowx 1998 22 European countries n.a. n.a. Henry and Lyle 2003 Australia National recreational and indigenous ï¬?shing survey Exploratory analysis of survey data implemented in 2000; used a remote (telephone/diary) (i.e., variance estimation); input-output survey technique in conjunction with a number of analysis not provided validation/calibration surveys to minimize nonresponse and behavioral biases Canada 2007 Canada 2005 survey on angler proï¬?les, catch volumes and Major purchases or investments attrib- species, trip, and expenditure; questionnaires were utable to ï¬?shing activities; value added mailed to residents and nonresidents impacts not provided Barnes et al. 2002 Namibia Series of surveys conducted in 1996–1997 Expenditure, travel cost, and contingent valuation analysis McGrath et al. 1997; South Africa Expenditure and income surveys in 1995–1996 Input-output analysis Brouwer et al. 1997 Mike and Cowx 1996 Trinidad Socioeconomic survey in 1992 Travel cost analysis Source: Authors. 2.5 ESTIMATING THE EXTENDED GLOBAL GDP other important economic indicators were not included in CONTRIBUTION OF COMMERCIAL CAPTURE the scope of this study. The term commercial is used es- FISHERIES ALONG THE VALUE CHAIN sentially to distinguish the segment from recreational or This part of the study provides an estimate of the commer- subsistence ï¬?sheries, and there may be overlap with these cial capture ï¬?sheries sector’s contribution to global GDP. A segments. country’s GDP is a key indicator of the role of ï¬?sheries in the national economy and complements the estimates of capture ï¬?sheries employment addressed in a previous part 2.5.1 Approaches to the Calculation of Fisheries GDP of the study. Fisheries sector trade balance,12 rents, and The published values for ï¬?sheries GDP are commonly created through national accounts in accordance with the internation- 12 The global supply and demand for ï¬?sh is being addressed in a al standard for Systems of National Accounts (SNA) and the separate study. International Standard Industrial Classiï¬?cation of All Industrial EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 16 CHAP T E R 2 — E STIMATING TH E EC ONOMIC CONTR IBUTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES BOX 2.5: Calculation of GDP then compile GDP statistics based on the data provided by these line ministries and agencies. According to the Handbook of National Accounting, there are three approaches to calculate GDP: To produce internationally comparable statistics, most coun- tries adopt International Standard Industrial Classiï¬?cation 1. Total value added generated by all producers (ISIC) of all industrial activities classiï¬?cation systems and the (production approach) Central Product Classiï¬?cation, both developed by the UN, 2. Sum of private and government consumption, although some countries have developed their own classiï¬?- capital formation, and net exports (expenditure cation systems or adopted regional systems. ISIC classiï¬?ca- approach) tions are structured according to the type of economic activity 3. Sum of compensation of employees, taxes rather than the type of product produced by each sector. The on production and imports, consumption of current ISIC (Revision 4.0, released on August 11, 2008) has ï¬?xed capital, and the operating surplus (cost or four levels: sections, divisions, groups, and classes. Sections income approach). are used to group similar activities and are identiï¬?ed by a letter. The division is represented by a two-digit code and Ideally, the three approaches should be used simulta- further subdivided into groups (three-digit code) and classes neously and independently from each other so that (four-digit code). the data resulting from each approach can be used as checks to evaluate the data obtained from the other two If a particular sector is economically of great importance, the approaches. In practice, however, this ideal situation is relevant part of the classiï¬?cation can be further disaggregat- rarely encountered: Some countries do not reconcile ed, and less economically important activities can be treated their estimates at all, and statistical discrepancies re- at a more aggregated level (UN 2008). Ideally, a country can main in the published results. Other countries do not provide data at all levels of ISIC classiï¬?cation, but in reality, use the three approaches independently. not all detailed categories of the classiï¬?cation are reported. Countries often estimate GDP using only one or two ap- Fisheries-related activities are most often reported at an ag- proaches. Most often, GDP is estimated by the produc- gregated level under “Agriculture, forestry, and ï¬?shing,â€? and tion approach. In most cases, the income approach is it is often not possible to isolate the economic values of ï¬?sh- not used because it is generally regarded to be the most ing activities from the other agricultural subsectors. difï¬?cult to implement. In most countries where disaggregated data are available, Source: UN 1999. ï¬?sheries-related activities are often reported under “Fishing and aquaculture.â€?14 This means that the values of capture Activities (ISIC)13 followed by the SNA. The SNA is based on a ï¬?shing and ï¬?sh farming to the point of ï¬?rst sale, the harvest set of internationally agreed concepts, deï¬?nitions, classiï¬?ca- subsector, are included, whereas the economic contributions tions, and accounting rules. It deï¬?nes some major statistics of related or dependent activities such as ï¬?sh processing that are widely used as indicators of economic activity, in- and marketing or ï¬?shing vessel construction are not included cluding GDP. Three main methods are used to calculate GDP but are counted under manufacturing or other sectors in the (box 2.5). The production approach (also called value added or national accounts. Countries usually do not report these con- output approach), which calculates GDP by taking the value nected activities in detail, or they lump information under a of goods and services produced (gross output) less the cost general category such as food processing. Thus, the ï¬?sheries of goods and services used in the production process (inter- GDP values generally include only value added created in pri- mediate consumption), is the most common approach. mary production activities—the catching and farming of ï¬?sh. In most countries, macroeconomic statistics such as GDP are compiled by national statistical ofï¬?ces rather than the 2.5.1.1 Classiï¬?cation of Fisheries Activities in the ï¬?sheries agency. Fisheries sector–speciï¬?c data are most of- System of National Accounts ten compiled by the relevant ministries, such as the Ministry Fishing and aquaculture appears as a separate economic of Fisheries, and the required ï¬?sheries-related statistics are activity at the division level in the ISIC Rev. 4 (box 2.6). sent to national statistical ofï¬?ces. National statistical ofï¬?ces 14 In the previous revision (ISIC Rev.3.1), ï¬?shing is classiï¬?ed under 13 http://unstats.un.org/unsd/cr/registry/regct.asp?Lg=1. “Fishing, operation of ï¬?sh hatcheries and ï¬?sh farms.â€? H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 2 — E S T IMAT ING T HE E CONOMIC CONT RIB UTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES 17 BOX 2.6: Classiï¬?cation of Fisheries-Related Activities in the System of National Accounts Section A: Agriculture, forestry, and ï¬?shing Class 4630: Wholesale of food, includes egg, meat, Division 03: Fishing and aquaculture ï¬?shery products, etc. Group 031: Fishing Division 47: Retail trade, except of motor vehicles and Class 0311: Marine ï¬?shing motorcycles Class 0312: Freshwater ï¬?shing Group: 472: Retail sale of food, beverages, and tobac- Section C: Manufacturing co in specialized stores Division 10: Manufacture of food products Class 4721: Retail sale of food in specialized stores, includes ï¬?sh and seafood Group 102: Processing and preserving of ï¬?sh, crusta- ceans, and molluscs Section R: Arts, entertainment, and recreation Class 1020: Processing and preserving of ï¬?sh, crus- Division 93: Sports activities and amusement and recre- taceans, and molluscs ation activities Division 33: Repair and installation of machinery and Class 9319: Other sports activities, including opera- equipment tion of sport ï¬?shing Group 331: Repair of fabricated metal products, ma- Section T: Activities of households as employers chinery and equipment Division 98: Undifferentiated goods- and services- Class 3315: Repair of transport equipment, except producing activities of private households for motor vehicles, includes repair and main- own use tenance of ships and pleasure boats Group 981: Undifferentiated goods-producing activi- Section G: Wholesale and retail trade; repair of motor ties of private households for own use, in- vehicles and motorcycles cludes hunting, gathering, and farming of goods produced by the household for its Division 46: Wholesale trade, except of motor vehicles own subsistence and motorcycles Group: 463: Wholesale of food, beverages, and Source: UN Online Statistical Database: Detail Structure and Explanatory tobacco Notes, ISIC Rev. 4. http://unstats.un.org/unsd/cr/registry/regcst.asp?Cl=27. However, processing and marketing of ï¬?sh and ï¬?shery 1. Available GDP estimates were compiled for 129 products are located under Section C, Manufacturing, and countries, for 26 of which GDP information disaggre- Section G, Wholesale and retail trade, respectively. In addi- gated into harvest and postharvest subsectors was tion to these divisions, ï¬?sheries-related activities, such as available. recreational ï¬?shing and subsistence goods producing (such 2. A GDP postharvest multiplier (ratio of harvest-to- as subsistence ï¬?shery for own consumption), also appear as postharvest GDP) was derived based on these a part of other divisions or classes. 26 countries (value = 1.76, with a range of 1.55 to 2.04). Within the SNA, the contribution of the ï¬?sheries sector to GDP is generally recorded in terms of the value at the point 3. The GDP postharvest multiplier was applied to the of harvest, or ï¬?rst sale. This means that, for example, the reported harvest GDP for those countries for which economic value of associated and dependent economic ac- postharvest GDP was not available (103 countries). tivities, such as boatbuilding or ï¬?sh processing, are recorded 4. The percentage contribution of both harvest and as part of the manufacturing sector. This study considers not postharvest subsectors to total national GDP for each only the economic activities to the point of ï¬?rst sale but also of the 129 countries was calculated. the downstream economic activities in the estimate of the 5. The percentage contribution was converted into global economic contribution of capture ï¬?sheries, monetary value, using the reported national GDP data15 (measured in current U.S. dollars in 2007) from This metric is called the extended GDP contribution and was estimated as follows (details of the data sources are provided 15 http://siteresources.worldbank.org/DATASTATISTICS/Resources/ in the Annex). GDP.pdf. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 18 CHAP T E R 2 — E STIMATING TH E EC ONOMIC CONTR IBUTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES the World Development Indicator database (World 40 percent is generated by the secondary and tertiary sec- Bank 2011). tors. The small-scale ï¬?sheries made the most important 6. The extended global GDP contribution of commer- contribution to the value added created along the value cial capture ï¬?sheries is the sum of these monetary chain in most of these countries: in Mauritania, about values. 45 percent of the overall value added is attributed to the 7. Lack of GDP data, weak speciï¬?cation, or disaggrega- small-scale ï¬?sheries; in Senegal, 80 percent of total land- tion of the available GDP data precluded isolation ings and 60 percent of the export volume are attributed to of the aquaculture subsector (aquaculture GDP small-scale ï¬?sheries. data were available for only 18 countries, repre- senting 7 percent of global production) and of the Value-added ratios (VARs) were used in a study on Paciï¬?c upstream economic activities (such as ï¬?shing vessel Island countries, which focused on harvesting operations construction). rather than on the entire value chain. VARs are the proportion of the gross output attributable to value added. The VARs Based on available literature and online sources, efforts were were based on (1) published estimates of VARs, (2) the ratios made to separate the contribution of the capture from the used in calculating national accounts in various countries, (3) culture subsectors for these 18 countries. In the absence of reported income and expenditure data for some activities, evidence to the contrary, the GDP values for other countries (4) discussions with people involved in the industry, and (5) were assumed to include aquaculture and were adjusted us- author knowledge and experience. The value added was es- ing the proportion of the harvest contributed by aquaculture timated by multiplying the value of production (gross output) as per the FAO FishStat (n.d.[a]) production values. by the VARs. The study showed that their reestimated aver- age ï¬?shing GDP for the region was approximately 30 percent 2.5.1.2 Alternative Approaches higher than the ofï¬?cial ï¬?gure, or 7.0 percent compared to A large body of recent work underlines the high potential 5.4 percent of GDP across all countries. The increased esti- of small-scale ï¬?shing activities for economic development mates were primarily attributable to the omission of noncom- but systematically highlights how poorly the true economic mercial subsistence ï¬?shing, differences in the estimate of value of this sector is reflected in ofï¬?cial statistics and dis- production, and differences in the method used to calculate cussions of food security and livelihoods (Cowx et al. 2004). the GDP contribution. An updated study (Gillett 2009) on 22 Some studies have attempted to recalculate ï¬?sheries GDP Paciï¬?c Island countries and territories found that GDP ranged considering the wider social and economic contributions between 4.5 percent (Niue) and 63 percent (Palau) higher of the sector; for example, input-output analysis has been than the ofï¬?cial ï¬?gure. used to estimate the contribution of ocean ï¬?sh to the global economy at $380 billion (Dyke and Sumaila 2009). These alternative approaches can be used to cross-check the results presented in this study. For example, the eco- The Sustainable Fisheries Livelihoods Programme (SFLP) nomic impacts arising from the ï¬?sheries production and considered a wider range of economic and social impacts recreational ï¬?sheries could be estimated through a meta- in case studies in 15 participating countries.16 The GDP es- analysis on multipliers, such as output, value added, and em- timates included the whole ï¬?sh value chain, from ï¬?shing ployment multipliers obtained from the existing input-output and ï¬?sh farming to trade and retail marketing. Two other analyses in ï¬?sheries. By structuring the available data into indicators, annual investment in ï¬?sheries and the contri- groups with similar multipliers (based on deï¬?ned criteria), it bution of the sector to national budgets, were used as a would be possible to estimate wider economic contributions proxy for national wealth created by the ï¬?sheries sector. (rather than harvest and postharvest subsectors alone) to The results showed that the value added generated by the global economy and understand any intergroup differences ï¬?sh harvesting operations to the point of ï¬?rst sale repre- quantitatively. However, multiplier beneï¬?ts may be subject sented, on average, 60 to 70 percent of the total value to double counting. Another possible approach is to use generated by the sector (Kébé 2008). The remaining 30 to VARs in conjunction with the landed value of capture and aquaculture production to determine the contributions of the ï¬?sheries sector to national GDP. Currently, VARs for ï¬?sher- 16 Benin, Burkina Faso, Côte d’Ivoire, Ghana, Mali, Congo, Gabon, Guinea, Mauritania, Cameroon, Chad, Gambia, Senegal, Cape ies are available for only a limited number of countries, and Verde, and Sao Tome and Principe. improved estimates of the contribution of ï¬?sheries to GDP H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 2 — E S T IMAT ING T HE E CONOMIC CONT RIB UTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES 19 will beneï¬?t from additional case studies such as those for 2.5.3 Information Sources the Paciï¬?c Islands. The NAS compiled each year by the UN are the primary source of information on GDP and value added by industry. 2.5.2 Methodological Challenges These include statistics on value added by industry for all Several issues and challenges were identiï¬?ed during the es- reporting countries but generally provide insufï¬?cient detail to timation exercise. identify ï¬?sheries sector activities. For example, data are pre- sented as an aggregated value such as “Agriculture, hunting, 1. Many countries do not publish these GDP estimates forestry and ï¬?shingâ€? (see Annex). Consequently, it is difï¬?cult or statistics on value added in the ï¬?shery sector. to estimate the value added from the ï¬?sheries sector at the Where such data exist, the basis for the estimates is global scale solely by drawing on relatively consistent data often insufï¬?ciently clear to enable the values to be such as those in the NAS. compared or compiled across countries. 2. Informal ï¬?sheries sector activities, such as non- Values provided through the NAS need to be complemented commercial subsistence ï¬?shing, are generally not and interpreted using other information sources. The study recorded in ofï¬?cial catch or economic statistics. In compiled data on ï¬?sheries/ï¬?shing GDP contributions for addition, where signiï¬?cant levels of illegal ï¬?shing 129 countries, including 101 developing and 28 developed exist, the related economic activity may not be fully countries. Further details of the sources of information are captured in available estimates of GDP. provided in the Annex. 3. Other important economic activities that can be at- tributed to the ï¬?sheries sector, such as recreational Fisheries and Aquaculture Country Proï¬?les, produced by the ï¬?shing, are rarely included in the estimates of the FAO (2011), were a primary information source, providing economic contribution of the ï¬?sheries sector. ï¬?sheries GDP ï¬?gures for 69 countries across all geographic regions. However, in many country proï¬?les examined, the 4. “The compilers of national accounts do not appear to method used to estimate the reported GDP value was not have consulted the relevant ï¬?sheries agencies or the speciï¬?ed, and it was unclear whether the value referred industry when preparing their estimatesâ€? (Gillett and to the primary sector alone or included processing and re- Lightfoot 2002). lated activities. In many country proï¬?les, it was also unclear 5. The year for which individual country harvest GDP whether the values for primary production included aqua- estimates were available varies between 1990 and culture. The exceptions were Belize, Fiji, Madagascar, and 2007. However, the majority of data referred to the Norway, where aquaculture production was speciï¬?cally in- 2000 to 2007 period (speciï¬?cation of the year was cluded. Unless otherwise speciï¬?ed, the data were assumed deï¬?cient for 14 countries). to refer to the primary (harvest) sector alone. 6. Where there is extensive vertical integration in the ï¬?shing industry (for example, if the ï¬?rst sale is by a GDP values were also obtained from the ofï¬?cial economic processing plant that owns a ï¬?shing fleet), primary and ï¬?sheries reports produced by individual countries production (harvesting) may not be fully reflected in and from online sources. As in the FAO proï¬?les, in many the harvest-level GDP estimates. cases, the method used to estimate GDP and the data 7. GDP estimates are not derived using a common sources were not sufï¬?ciently speciï¬?ed. For the developing methodology across countries. countries, the values available for the South Paciï¬?c Islands countries (Gillett and Lightfoot 2001; Gillett 2009) and for For these reasons, a consistent method, such as a simple West and Central Africa (various SFLP project reports; compilation of National Accounts Statistics (NAS), to es- for more information, see http://www.fao.org/ï¬?shery/en) timate the value added from the ï¬?sheries sector at the are notable exceptions, stating clearly how the values global scale was not possible. The approach assumed that were obtained and the economic activities included in the the harvest-postharvest ratio derived from the 26 sample estimates. countries represents the universe of harvest-postharvest GDP ratios. However, the extended GDP estimate can 2.5.4 GDP Data Sources clearly be improved when more comprehensive, clearly Table 2.9 summarizes the data sources used for the GDP speciï¬?ed, and disaggregated ï¬?sheries sector GDP data data. Tables A.1 through A.6 (in the Annex) display the data become available. upon which the estimates were based. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 20 CHAP T E R 2 — E STIMATING TH E EC ONOMIC CONTR IBUTION OF GLOBA L CA PTURE FIS H ER IES TABLE 2.9: Summary of Information Sources for Fisheries GDP SOURCE COUNTRIES DATA SOURCE METHOD ISSUES/NOTES FAO 2011 69 countries across all regions In most cases, the data source In most cases, the method is Appear to be ï¬?shing activities is not speciï¬?ed not speciï¬?ed only; aquaculture is included in some countries (not speciï¬?ed in most cases) Gillett and Lightfoot 2001 14 Paciï¬?c Island countries Published estimates of VAR; Used VAR to estimate different Harvest activities only (ï¬?shing (10 used in our analysis) national accounts in various ï¬?shing activities; for sub- and farming) countries; reported income sistence ï¬?shing, farm pricing and expenditure data; personal method was used contact with industry Gillett 2009 22 Paciï¬?c Island countries Various; see annex for detail VAR Catching and farming and territories (19 countries available) SFLP documents (http://www 15 West and Central African Various, including ofï¬?cial Using a common method that Sum of added values in produc- .fao.org/ï¬?shery/en) countries statistics, household surveys, follows SFLP Methodological tion, processing, and marketing and expert contacts Guidelines of fresh products and in processing and marketing of processed products Sugiyama, Staples, and Funge- Bangladesh, China, Indonesia, GDP values in 2001 calcu- Production values of capture Figures are indicative, as the Smith 2004 Malaysia, Philippines, Lao PDR, lated from the ESCAP ofï¬?cial ï¬?sheries and aquaculture; no data to quantify the value of Thailand, Vietnam statistics further detail capture production is not read- ily available for many states Salz et al. 2006; Eurostat 2006 Netherlands, Italy, France, Data mainly from Eurostat data Eurostat data do not include United Kingdom, Denmark, in 2006 marketing and other post- Spain, Ghana, Uganda harvest activities other than processing; aquaculture not included Expert contacts (case study Cambodia, China, Ghana Various ofï¬?cial statistics Production and postharvest coordinators) included; further detail not available Individual country reports Canada, New Zealand, Japan, Ofï¬?cial statistics Limited number of original Iceland, Maldives, Seychelles documents accessed Source: SFLP (http://www.fao.org/ï¬?shery/en); Gillett and Lightfoot 2001; Gillett 2009. H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 3 — R E S ULT S 21 Chapter 3: RESULTS The results are presented in the following order: Almost half of the ï¬?sheries value chain workforce is female. 1. The global proï¬?les of small- and large-scale commer- Almost half of the workforce is employed in inland cial ï¬?sheries ï¬?sheries. 2. Results of the developing country case studies and Small-scale ï¬?sheries generate less wastage in the sampled developed countries form of discards; that is, catch that is not landed but 3. Results of the subsistence ï¬?sheries case studies disposed of at sea. 4. Estimate of economic importance of recreational ï¬?sheries If the level of engagement of government in ï¬?sheries man- 5. Estimate of the contribution of commercial capture agement reflects the perceived importance of this subsector ï¬?sheries to global GDP. to national economies, the importance of ï¬?sheries, especially small-scale ï¬?sheries, as a source of nutrition, employment, and income for many of the world’s coastal and rural poor is 3.1 THE GLOBAL PROFILES OF SMALL- AND generally underestimated. In particular, small-scale ï¬?shing is LARGE-SCALE COMMERCIAL FISHERIES a key livelihood strategy for millions of households in coastal The sample of developing and developed country ï¬?sheries and rural communities in developing countries and plays an proï¬?les were extrapolated to the global level. Tables 3.1, 3.2, important part in food security and poverty alleviation. and 3.3 quantify selected characteristics of the global cap- ture ï¬?sheries. Key points include the following: Fish is the world’s most traded food—about 37 percent of reported production is traded (FAO 2006). Large-scale An estimated 35 million commercial ï¬?shers are ï¬?sheries account for a substantial proportion of the trade engaged in harvesting operations in developing and in capture ï¬?shery products. In many countries, large-scale developed countries combined. ï¬?sheries provide important foreign exchange earnings. Trade Adding employment in the postharvest subsector in the products of large-scale ï¬?sheries (particularly small pe- brings the total ï¬?sheries workforce to approximately lagic ï¬?sh such as sardines and mackerel) is vital to ï¬?sh food 119 million people who are directly dependent on security in a number of developing countries, particularly in capture ï¬?sheries for their livelihoods as full-time or sub-Saharan Africa where ï¬?sh consumption is about half the part-time workers. global average. Ninety-six percent of these people live in developing countries (116 million). Tables 3.1 through 3.4 summarize the proï¬?les of small- and large-scale ï¬?sheries at the global level and in developing Over 90 percent of ï¬?shers and ï¬?sh workers are em- and developed countries. The tables are based on devel- ployed in small-scale ï¬?sheries. oping country case studies and the sample of developed Over half (60 million) of those employed in ï¬?sheries countries and raised to the global level as described in the in developing countries work in small-scale inland methodology. ï¬?sheries. Fisheries are more important to national economies in In the developing country case studies, small-scale ï¬?sheries developing countries than in developed countries. land more ï¬?sh than large-scale ï¬?sheries, but at the global Large-scale ï¬?sheries land more ï¬?sh in total, but small- level—when taking developed countries and major ï¬?shmeal scale ï¬?sheries produce more ï¬?sh for domestic human producers into account—large-scale ï¬?sheries account for consumption. the majority of the landings. However, small-scale ï¬?sheries EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 22 C H A PTER 3 — R ES ULTS TABLE 3.1: Global Proï¬?le of Small- and Large-Scale Fisheries SMALL-SCALE FISHERIES LARGE-SCALE FISHERIES MARINE INLAND TOTAL MARINE INLAND TOTAL TOTAL Production and utilization Total annual catch (million tons) 34 14 48 56 1 57 105 Value (billions) $37 $9 $46 $49 $0 $50 $96 a Discards (% of total catch) 4% 0% 3% 13% 3% 13% 8% Employment (full time and part time) Number of ï¬?shers (millions) 14 18 32 2 1 3 35 Number of postharvest jobs (millions) 38 38 76 7 0.5 8 84 Total workforce (millions) 52 56 108 9 2 11 119 Women in total workforce (%) 36% 54% 46% 64% 28% 60% 47% Efï¬?ciency Catch per ï¬?sher (tons) 2.5 0.8 1.5 25.7 0.6 18.3 3.0 Catch per ton of fuel (tons) 1–3 n.a. n.a. 1–4 n.a. n.a. n.a. Source: Authors. Notes: a Refers to catch that does not go to nonfood uses or that is exported. TABLE 3.2: Small- and Large-Scale Fisheries in Developing Countries SMALL-SCALE FISHERIES LARGE-SCALE FISHERIES MARINE INLAND TOTAL MARINE INLAND TOTAL TOTAL Production and utilization Total annual catch (million tons) 28 13 41 34 0.5 35 76 Value of catch (billions) $28 $8 $37 $35 $0.5 $35 $72 Discards (% of total catch) 1% 0% 1% 5% 2% 5% 3% Employment Number of ï¬?shers (millions) 13 18 31 2 1 3 34 Number of jobs in postharvest (millions) 37 38 75 7 0.5 7.5 82.5 Total workforce 50 56 106 9 1.5 10.5 116.5 Women in total workforce (%) 36% 54% 46% 66% 28% 62% 47% Efï¬?ciency Catch per ï¬?sher (tons) 2.1 0.7 1.3 18.3 0.6 13.4 2.2 Catch per ton of fuel (tons) 0.5–4 n.a. n.a. 1–5 n.a. n.a. n.a. Source: Authors. Note: Developing countries are deï¬?ned according to the FAO FishStat Plus database (FAO 2008). produce more ï¬?sh for domestic human consumption, and in consumption (table 3.6). In developed countries, inland ï¬?sh- developing countries, over half of the catch for domestic hu- eries are far less important, and accurate data on catches, man consumption is produced by the small-scale ï¬?sheries. including recreational and subsistence ï¬?shing, are often deï¬?cient. Based on the developing country case studies, inland ï¬?sh- eries account for 23 percent of the total catch, and about The following sections provide additional details of these 90 percent of this production is used for domestic human proï¬?les. H ID D EN H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 3 — R E S ULT S 23 TABLE 3.3: Small- and Large-Scale Fisheries in Developed Countries SMALL-SCALE FISHERIES LARGE-SCALE FISHERIES MARINE INLAND TOTAL MARINE INLAND TOTAL TOTAL Production and utilization Total annual catch (million tons) 6 1 7 22 <1 22 29 Value of catch (billions) $9 $0.5 $9 $15 <1 $15 $24 Discards (% of total catch) 15% 1% 13% 25% n.a. 25% 22% Employment Number of ï¬?shers (millions) 1 <1 1 0.5 <1 0.5 1.5 Number of jobs in postharvest (millions) 1 <1 1 0.5 <1 0.5 1.5 Total workforce (millions) 2 <1 2 1 <1 1 3 Women in total workforce (%) 43% 44% 43% 38% n.a. 38% 42% Efï¬?ciency Catch per ï¬?sher (tons) 9.5 8.6 9.4 67.8 n.a. 67.5 26.9 Catch per ton of fuel (tons) 1–2 n.a. n.a. 2–4 n.a. n.a. n.a. Source: Authors. TABLE 3.4: Employment in Capture Fisheries in Developing Countries, by Continent (thousands) SMALL-SCALE TOTAL FISHERS POSTHARVEST TOTAL ALL DEVELOPING CONTINENT FISHERS EMPLOYMENT EMPLOYMENT COUNTRIES Africa 7,389 7,827 17,640 25,467 22% America 1,156 1,523 4,086 5,609 5% Asia 22,920 24,723 59,736 84,459 73% Oceania 126 137 387 524 <1% TOTAL 31,951 34,210 81,849 116,059 100% Source: Authors. 3.1.1 Employment or complementary source of food and income along with Extrapolating the case study results to all developing coun- other livelihood strategies. tries (using catch-per-ï¬?sher ratios and reestimated catch In developed countries, employment in ï¬?sheries has general- quantities, as described earlier), the total employment in ly declined (FAO 2009b). Employment in the sector still totals developing countries is estimated at 116 million, of which about 3 million—about 1 million in harvest and 2 million in almost 32 million are small-scale ï¬?shers. Most of the ï¬?shers postharvest activities. The small-scale ï¬?sheries account for and ï¬?sh workers—almost 23 million or 73 percent—live in 74 percent of all jobs and are the most important employer Asia. (table 3.5). Other estimates have been made of the total number of people employed in ï¬?sheries. FAO suggests there may be 3.1.2 Production and Utilization as many as 170 million people in full- and part-time employ- At the global level, large-scale ï¬?sheries produce about 11 mil- ment in the whole ï¬?shery industry (including aquaculture). lion tons more than small-scale ï¬?sheries, though it should be Because those employed generally provide for dependents noted that global ï¬?shmeal supply is based largely on harvests and household members, the ï¬?sheries sector may support of about 17 million tons by industrial reduction ï¬?sheries. over half a billion people, or almost 8 percent of the world’s population (FAO 2009b). This ï¬?gure does not include all those In the developing country case studies, small-scale who depend on ï¬?shing and related activities as an occasional fisheries land more than large-scale fisheries, and EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 24 C H A PTER 3 — R ES ULTS TABLE 3.5: Results from Developed Countries (thousands) SMALL-SCALE FISHERIES LARGE-SCALE FISHERIES MARINE INLAND TOTAL MARINE INLAND TOTAL TOTAL Number of ï¬?shers 663 98 761 326 2 328 1,089 Postharvest employment 1,259 206 1,465 457 1 458 1,923 Total employment 1,922 304 2,226 783 3 786 3,012 Women in total workforce 43% 44% 43% 38% 29% 38% 41% Source: Authors. TABLE 3.6: Catch Used for Local Human Consumption SMALL-SCALE FISHERIES LARGE-SCALE FISHERIES REGION/COUNTRY MARINE INLAND TOTAL MARINE INLAND TOTAL TOTAL Lake Victoria, Bangladesh, Brazil, China, 77% 91% 81% 56% n.a. 57% 77% Ghana, Nigeria, Senegal, Thailand Excluding China 88% 97% 93% 44% n.a. 46% 75% Source: Authors; case studies. TABLE 3.7: Discard Rates in Developing and Developed Countries SMALL-SCALE FISHERIES LARGE-SCALE FISHERIES MARINE INLAND TOTAL MARINE INLAND TOTAL TOTAL Developing countries Catch (tons) 30 12 42 34 — 34 76 Discard rate (%) 1% 0% 0.8% 5% 2% 5% 3% Developed countries Catch (tons) 6 1 7 22 0 22 29 Discard rate (%) 15% 1% 13% 25% 25% 25% 22% Total tons 36 13 49 56 0 56 105 % 3% 0% 3% 13% 25% 13% 8% Source: Authors; case studies; Kelleher 2005. Note: Rates according to case studies and Kelleher (2005) and adjusted to match total estimates made in Kelleher—namely, discards are 8% of the global marine catch and 3.7% of small-scale marine catches. The sample of ï¬?sheries in Kelleher is biased toward ï¬?sheries with high discard rates, which tends to increase the discard rate for small-scale ï¬?sheries in developed countries. small-scale fisheries generally produce more fish for do- Ofï¬?cially reported catches from inland ï¬?sheries represent mestic human consumption. In developing countries, it is less than 1 percent of the total.17 estimated that over half of the catch for domestic human consumption is produced by the small-scale fisheries. The case study information on the percentage of the catch In the developing country case studies, inland fisheries used for direct local consumption (not used for animal feed account for 23 percent of the total catch, and about 90 or exported) is summarized in table 3.6. Although it is not percent of this production is used for domestic human possible to extrapolate the case studies to the global level, consumption. the available data suggest that about 45 percent of the global The total annual capture ï¬?sheries production of the 11 devel- 17 With a few exceptions, inland ï¬?sheries’ catch quantities for the oped sample countries amounts to 11.8 million tons. Small- sample countries were compiled from FAO FishStat Plus (2008a) scale ï¬?sheries account for 24 percent of this production. averages for 2004–06. H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 3 — R E S ULT S 25 TABLE 3.8: Summary of Developing Country Case Studies DEVELOPING COUNTRY SMALL-SCALE FISHERIES LARGE-SCALE FISHERIES FISHERIES MARINE INLAND MARINE INLAND TOTAL Number of ï¬?shers (million tons) 23.3 1.5 24.7 (percentage of total) 40% 54% 4% 2% Postharvest employment (millions) 56.1 3.6 59.7 Total employment (millions) 79.3 5.1 84.4 (percentage of total) 45% 49% 5% 1% Number of women in total workforce 36.6 3.1 39.7 (millions) (percentage of total) 36% 55% 67% 31% 47% Total catch (million tons) 28.9 11.4 40.3 (percentage of total) 50% 22% 27% 1% Catch for domestic human consump- 23.5 6.2 29.7 tion (million tons) (percentage of total) 77% 91% 56% n.a. 74% Discards (% of total catch) 0.5% 5% 2% 0.5% 0 5% 2% Source: Authors; case studies; Kelleher 2005. catch may be used for direct local human consumption. The Small-scale ï¬?sheries produce more ï¬?sh for domestic discard rates shown in table 3.7 should be interpreted with human consumption than do large-scale ï¬?sheries. caution because the source data (Kelleher 2005) were com- In inland ï¬?sheries, which are mainly small scale, 90 piled on the basis of ï¬?shing gears and not with a view to percent of the production is used for domestic human disaggregating small- and large-scale ï¬?sheries. consumption. Small-scale ï¬?sheries generate less wastage in the form 3.2 SMALL- AND LARGE-SCALE FISHERIES IN of discards, or catch that is not landed but disposed of THE SAMPLED COUNTRIES at sea (expressed as a proportion to landed catch). The results of the developing country case studies are sum- marized in table 3.8 and of the developed country samples The following sections further explore these results and in table 3.9. The tables divide ï¬?sheries into quadrants: small- discuss related issues, including production estimates, ï¬?sh scale and large-scale ï¬?sheries in marine waters and in inland consumption and trade, and fuel consumption and costs. waters. In summary: Almost 25 million ï¬?shers are represented in the case 3.2.1 The People in Commercial Fisheries study countries. Including postharvest activities, there 3.2.1.1 Developing Countries are over 84 million full-time and part-time ï¬?shers and In the developing country case studies, close to 25 million ï¬?sh workers.18 ï¬?shers are represented. However, while ï¬?shing itself is clear- Forty-seven percent of the total workforce is women. ly an important source for employment, the bulk of ï¬?sheries The vast majority of ï¬?shers and ï¬?sh workers are employment is in the postharvest subsector such as ï¬?sh employed in small-scale ï¬?sheries; only 6 percent are processing and marketing. The case studies indicate that for employed in large-scale activities. each person employed as a ï¬?sher, on average, between two In small-scale ï¬?sheries, over half work in inland to three people are employed in postharvest activities. When waters. postharvest activities are included, over 84 million full-time and part-time ï¬?shers and ï¬?sh workers are represented in the 18 For Kenya, Tanzania, and Uganda, only employment on and case study countries. Over 90 percent of this total workforce around Lake Victoria is included. is employed in the small-scale ï¬?sheries, and over half work EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 26 C H A PTER 3 — R ES ULTS TABLE 3.9: Summary of Developed Country Sample SMALL-SCALE FISHERIES LARGE-SCALE FISHERIES MARINE INLAND TOTAL MARINE INLAND TOTAL TOTAL Employment Number of ï¬?shers 268,351 7,108 275,459 148,341 1,200 149,541 425,000 % of total 63.1% 1.7% 64.8% 34.9% 0.3% 35.2% 100.0% Number of other jobs 507,853 14,724 522,577 211,925 510 212,435 735,012 Ratio 1.9 2.1 1.9 1.4 0.4 1.4 1.7 Total 776,204 21,832 798,036 360,266 1,710 361,976 1,160,012 Total adjusteda 763,301 21,745 785,046 350,537 1,710 352,247 1,137,293 a Women in workforce 324,721 9,479 334,200 134,135 504 134,639 468,839 Womena (%) 43% 44% 43% 38% 29% 38% 41% Production and utilization Total annual catch (tons) 2,746,912 82,064 2,828,976 8,989,268 22,612 9,011,880 11,840,856 % of total 23.2% 0.7% 23.9% 75.9% 0.2% 76.1% 100.0% Value of catch ($ million) $9,196 $642 $9,838 $14,297 $28 $14,325 $24,163 Average value ($/ton) $3,348 $7,823 $3,477 $1,591 $1,237 $1,590 $2,041 Contribution to domestic animal 12% protein intakeb % of catch used for local human 75% 92% 75% 58% 58% 58% 62% consumptionc Catch per ï¬?sher (tons) 10.2 11.5 10.3 60.6 18.8 60.3 27.9 d Catch per ton of fuel 1.9 1.9 3.5 3.5 3.3 e Discards (% landings) 11.1% Source: Authors; sample country studies. a Excluding Norway. b Only EU countries excluding France and the United Kingdom. c Same proportions among subsectors as in developing countries assumed. d Marine ï¬?sheries in EU countries only. e Only Norway, Canada, Japan, and France in inland waters such as lake, river, flood plain, and wetland 3.2.1.2 Developed Countries ï¬?sheries (see table 3.10 and box 3.1). In addition, there are Although employment in ï¬?sheries has generally declined in many millions of occasional, or subsistence, ï¬?shers, although developed countries (FAO 2009b), the sector still provides the importance of ï¬?sh to their complex livelihood strategies about 3 million jobs (table 3.11). About 1 million are ï¬?shers, is poorly quantiï¬?ed (see section 3.4). and the remaining two-thirds are employed in postharvest activities. Seventy-four percent of all jobs are in small-scale The sector also generates employment upstream, supplying activities. inputs such as boatbuilding and engine and gear manufactur- ing and providing various support services in harbors, at land- While employment in developed country ï¬?sheries may ap- ing sites, and in dry docks and repair and maintenance work- pear relatively low, especially compared with the developing shops. These jobs are not as numerous as in the postharvest country estimates, ï¬?sheries can be far more important at subsector, but these workers still constitute a substantial the local level than national aggregate employment values workforce. Case study information from Ghana and Senegal may indicate. In addition, the employment ï¬?gures for many indicate that employment in these backward linkages add developed countries are expressed in a full-time equivalent, another 5 to 10 percent to the total number of full-time and so the actual number of people receiving income from ï¬?sher- part-time people employed in ï¬?sheries. ies is considerably higher. Moreover, employment multiplier H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 3 — R E S ULT S 27 TABLE 3.10: Full- and Part-Time Fishing and Postharvest Employment in the Case Study Developing Countries (thousands) NUMBER OF POSTHARVEST TOTAL PERCENTAGE IN PERCENTAGE COUNTRY FISHERS FISH WORKERS EMPLOYMENT SMALL-SCALE INLAND WATERS Bangladesh 1,576 1,677 3,253 97 67 Brazil 391 102 493 82 48a Cambodia 624 1,000 1,624 90 96a China 3,522 8,556 12,078 99 10 Ghana 205 167 372 97 31 India 2,063 8,254 10,317 82 57 Indonesia 2,397 n.a. n.a. 94b 23b Mozambique 230 35 265 98 35 b Myanmar 3,751 n.a. n.a. 88 40a,b Nigeria 1,230 5,270 6,500 95 26 Philippines 1,500 n.a. n.a. 99b 48b Senegal 85 45 130 92 34 Thailand 3,300 391 3,691 87 85 c b Vietnam 3,653 n.a. n.a. 96 83b Lake Victoria (Kenya, Tanzania, 196 30 226 89 100 Uganda) Total 24,723 24,528 38,949 92 42 Source: Authors; developing country case studies. a Includes ï¬?shers and ï¬?sh workers in the large-scale ï¬?sheries. b Fishers only. c See section 3.4 on subsistence ï¬?sheries. BOX 3.1: Inland Fisheries in Cambodia effects can be important. Estimates from the United States indicate an employment multiplier of up to 27 percent. That The extensive inland capture ï¬?sheries of Cambodia are means that if output increased so that 100 new jobs were based on two systems: the Mekong River and the Tonle created in commercial ï¬?shing, 27 jobs would also be gener- Sap Great Lake. Small-scale ï¬?shing commonly involves ated in other sectors supplying inputs (U.S. BEA 2008). In the family labor, using nonmotorized small vessels or no United Kingdom, a multiplier analysis, encompassing both boats, and operating in flood plains or rice ï¬?elds. Fishing indirect and induced impacts,19 estimated that the removal and related activities are generally integrated with other of sea ï¬?shing and ï¬?sh processing, which account for direct livelihood activities. An estimated 496,000 full-time and employment of about 22,000, would result in the loss of part-time inland ï¬?shers, some of whom are subsistence 138,000 U.K. jobs (Seaï¬?sh 2007).20 ï¬?shers, operate in Cambodia. In addition, more than 920,000 people are involved in small-scale processing of inland catches. This activity takes place during the peak 19 An employment multiplier indicates these direct and indirect ef- ï¬?shing period after the rainy season, and employment fects. An induced effect occurs because employees get wages is mainly part time and often organized on a household that they spend, thereby increasing demand for other products basis. and services and requiring additional employment in the sectors producing these goods (Scottish Government 2008). Source: Thouk et al. 2008 (Cambodia case study). 20 Full-time equivalent (sample country table for the United King- dom). EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 28 C H A PTER 3 — R ES ULTS TABLE 3.11: Estimated Employment in Developed Countries (thousands) SMALL-SCALE FISHERIES LARGE-SCALE FISHERIES MARINE INLAND TOTAL MARINE INLAND TOTAL TOTAL Number of ï¬?shers 663 98 761 326 2 328 1,089 Postharvest employment 1,259 206 1,465 457 1 458 1,923 Total employment 1,922 304 2,226 783 3 786 3,012 Women in total workforce (%) 43% 44% 43% 38% 29% 38% 41% Source: Authors; compiled from sample of developed countries. 3.2.2 The Role of Women TABLE 3.12: Women in Fisheries Workforce in Women account for 47 percent of the workforce, indicating Developing Countries that about 56 million jobs in the harvest and postharvest COUNTRY/CASE TOTAL WORKFORCE subsectors are held by women. The World Bank, FAO, and STUDY (THOUSANDS)* PERCENTAGE WOMEN International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD) have Nigeria 6,500 73% already addressed this gender in ï¬?sheries and aquaculture, India 10,316 72% but considerable additional efforts are required, including Cambodia 1,624 57% on empowerment, health, education and access to ï¬?nance (World Bank, FAO, and IFAD 2007). Ghana 372 40% Senegal 129 32% Gender roles in ï¬?sheries commonly portray men as ï¬?sh- Brazil 493 30% ers going out on boats to catch the ï¬?sh and women as ï¬?sh China 12,078 19% sellers and processors on land. While this generalization is largely correct, an examination of gender in ï¬?sheries reveals Bangladesh 3,253 5% a more complex array of roles according to country and cul- Mozambique 265 4% tural contexts. For example, in Benin, Cambodia, Republic Source: Authors; Developing country case studies. * Full- and part-time; ï¬?shing and postharvest activities of the Congo, Mali, and Thailand, women ï¬?sh or collect ï¬?sh on lakes using their own boats. In Uganda, it is taboo for women to be on board a ï¬?shing vessel, but they can own boats and hire men as crew. As ï¬?sh buyers, it is common for women to ï¬?nance the working capital for ï¬?shing trips large-scale ï¬?sheries but with somewhat higher numbers of against a guaranteed supply of ï¬?sh when the catch is landed women in marine than in the inland ï¬?sheries. Surveys in (Holvoet 2009; Westlund 2009a). In Bangladesh, ï¬?shing is the Lower Mekong Basin show that women are often heav- traditionally a low-caste Hindu occupation, and only men ily engaged in subsistence ï¬?shing and collection of aquatic in ï¬?shing communities normally engage in catching ï¬?sh. animals and plants in inland waters. However, as with other Although relatively few women work in ï¬?sheries today—an data on inland ï¬?sheries, this is not always adequately re- estimated 3 percent of the total female workforce is in- ported (FAO/RAP 2003). The conventional division of labor volved in harvesting—signiï¬?cant numbers of poor women is also often less strict than in marine ï¬?sheries with more are catching shrimp fry in coastal areas regardless of their women and children involved in small-scale ï¬?shing (ODI religion, age, or marital status (Mustafa 2008 [Bangladesh 2002). case study]). Data on ï¬?sheries employment in Europe shows that very Estimates of women’s participation in the ï¬?sheries work- few women work onboard vessels. Nevertheless, they rep- force in the developing country case studies varied consid- resent a third of the total sector workforce of about 400,000 erably (table 3.12). On average, however, almost as many people (full and part time), although important differences women as men are employed in the ï¬?sheries sector when exist among countries (Salz et al. 2006). In the sample, in postharvest activities are included. If China is excluded, the developed countries, women represented an average of 41 average proportion of women ï¬?shers and ï¬?sh workers ap- percent of the total employment, mostly employed in the proaches 60 percent. This is true both for the small- and ï¬?sh-processing industry (table 3.13). H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 3 — R E S ULT S 29 TABLE 3.13: Women in Fisheries Workforce in TABLE 3.14: Reported and Estimated Catches in Inland Developed Countries Capture Fisheries (thousand tons) COUNTRY/CASE TOTAL WORKFORCE PERCENTAGE RATIO YEAR STUDY (THOUSANDS)* WOMEN OFFICIALLY CASE ESTIMATE/ OF CASE Japan 864 46 REPORTED STUDY OFFICIALLY STUDY COUNTRY LANDINGS ESTIMATES REPORTED DATA Portugal 20 30 Bangladesh 849 985 1.2 2005/2006 Canada 75 29 Cambodia 332 438 1.3 2006 Spain 54 29 Ghana 75 398 5.3 2006 Netherlands 7 29 Mozambique 16 24 1.5 2007 Denmark 7 29 Myanmar 530 741 1.4 2005 United Kingdom 22 28 Senegal 50 64 1.3 1999/2000 France 27 23 Thailand 200 1,060 5.3 2004 Italy 33 20 Viet Nam 203 1,191 5.9 2003 Greece 27 4 Source: Authors; FAO 2008 (FISHSTAT Plus, average 2004 to 2006); Source: Authors; compiled from sample of developed countries. developing country case studies. * Full- and part-time; ï¬?shing and postharvest activities. 3.2.3 Production Estimates production. Ofï¬?cially reported catches23 from inland ï¬?sheries The case studies show important differences between ofï¬?- represent less than 1 percent of the total.24 cially reported inland catches and the estimates made in the context of the studies. For example, ofï¬?cial inland catches 3.2.4 Utilization of Catches in Ghana averaged 75,000 tons per year in 2004 to 2006 3.2.4.1 Fish Consumption (FAO 2008a), but the Ghana case study estimated catches Based on the FAO Food Balance Sheets derived from data from Lake Volta alone to be 346,000 tons on the basis of ofï¬?cially reported by member countries (FAO 2009b), the information from Yeji ï¬?sh market surveys. The most impor- average global apparent per capita ï¬?sh consumption was tant cases of underreported inland water catches described 16.7 kilograms in 2006.25 For 2005, the average reported in the developing country case studies are summarized in per capita ï¬?sh consumption in all developing countries as table 3.14.21 Inland water catches appeared to be under- a group was estimated at 14.4 kilograms per person, com- reported by an average of 70 percent in all the case study pared to 23.9 kilograms in developed countries (Laurenti countries. Marine catches also showed variations but not 2007). to the same extent as the inland production—on average, about 10 percent.22 The Food Balance Sheets show great variations among countries. For example, apparent per capita consumption in The total annual production by capture ï¬?sheries in the 11 developing country case studies ranged from 4.6 kilograms developed countries in the sample is 11.8 million tons (table 3.15). Small-scale ï¬?sheries account for 24 percent of this 23 Among 22 countries that submitted inland ï¬?shery catch data to FAO, 6 reported both commercial and recreational data, 11 only commercial catches, and 5 only recreational catches (Garibaldi 2007). 21 The table includes all case study countries showing a difference 24 With a few exceptions, inland ï¬?sheries catch quantities for the greater than 10 percent (smaller differences may be due to differ- sample countries were compiled from FAO FishStat Plus aver- ences in reporting years). The China case study indicated inland ages for 2004–06 (FAO 2008a). catches to be 10 percent less than the ofï¬?cially reported ï¬?gure 25 Apparent per capita consumption equals the per capita food ï¬?sh (not included in the table). supply in the Food Balance Sheets calculated on a country-by- 22 These averages exclude China because it is considered a special country basis: (production – nonfood uses + imports – exports case. If China is included, the average level of underreporting +/− stock variations)/population. The calculation includes produc- is 40 percent in inland waters and is not notable for the marine tion from both capture ï¬?sheries and aquaculture and is based on sector. the live weight equivalent of ï¬?shery products. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 30 C H A PTER 3 — R ES ULTS TABLE 3.15: Fish Production in the Sampled Countries (million tons) SMALL-SCALE FISHERIES LARGE-SCALE FISHERIES MARINE INLAND TOTAL MARINE INLAND TOTAL TOTAL Developed countries 2.747 0.082 2.829 8.989 0.023 9.012 11.841 Developing countries 19.956 8.991 28.948 11.035 0.329 11.364 40.311 Total 22.703 9.073 31.777 20.024 0.351 20.376 52.152 Source: Authors; case studies. TABLE 3.16: Comparison of Apparent per Capita Fish Consumption in the Lower Mekong Basin (kg/capita/yr) CAMBODIA LAO PDR THAILAND VIETNAM TOTAL/AVERAGE MRC consumption study (Cambodia and Lao PDR) and estimates 52.4 43.5 53.8 48.7 49.6 based on case study catch data (Thailand and Vietnam) FAO Food Balance Sheets (average 2003–05) 23.4 18.7 32.6 25.4 27.7 Sources: Authors; Hortle 2007; Laurenti 2007; Lymer et al. 2008; Nguyen, Bach, and Mills 2008; case studies for Thailand and Vietnam. in Mozambique to 32.6 kilograms in the Philippines (in 2005) Even relatively low annual ï¬?sh consumption levels can be (Laurenti 2007). In-country variations are not reflected in of vital importance for nutrition and health. Because of its these national averages, and ï¬?sh consumption is consider- high nutritional content—including proteins, micronutrients, ably more important in some areas. Given the underreported and essential fatty acids—ï¬?sh often constitutes a vital landings previously described, consumption is likely to be supplement to low-quality diets. Moreover, per-capita food substantially greater than the estimates based on production ï¬?sh supplies data do not explain the relative importance of statistics, particularly where small-scale inland capture ï¬?sh- ï¬?sh in animal protein intakes. It is estimated that ï¬?sh globally eries are prevalent. provides more than 1.5 billion people with almost 20 percent of their average per capita intake of animal proteins (FAO Studies on ï¬?sh consumption in the Lower Mekong Basin 2009b). In some small-island developing states, as well as show that the average per capita consumption of ï¬?sh and oth- in, for example, Bangladesh and Ghana, ï¬?sh provides at least er aquatic animals (inland and marine) is about 50 kilograms half of the total animal protein intake (FAO 2007a; Laurenti (Hortle 2007). This contrasts with a value of 28 kilograms, the 2007). In the Lower Mekong River Basin, the contribution total average apparent per capita ï¬?sh consumption for the of ï¬?sh to the nutritional level of the average diet is high: in- four countries concerned, as calculated in the Food Balance land ï¬?sh and other aquatic animals alone contribute 47 to 80 Sheets (Laurenti 2007). However, these numbers are not percent of animal protein consumption in the four countries entirely comparable because only part of each country forms (Hortle 2007). part of the Lower Mekong River Basin. The differences in catch estimates arising from recorded production and con- sumption surveys are further addressed in section 3.3. The 3.2.4.2 Different Uses of Small- and Large-Scale apparent per capita ï¬?sh consumption derived from the Food Production Balance Sheets for Thailand and Vietnam was recalculated Small-scale inland ï¬?sheries production tends to be used using the higher catch estimates provided in case studies. Per almost entirely for local human consumption (91 percent) capita consumption ï¬?gures for Cambodia and Lao PDR are and plays an important direct role in food security. Although included in table 3.16 (as estimated by Hortle 2007) because important differences exist at the local level, the develop- 95 and 93 percent of the populations of Cambodia and Lao ing country case studies show that at the aggregate level, PDR, respectively, are residents of the Lower Mekong River small- and large-scale ï¬?sh production have signiï¬?cantly dif- Basin. The differences in apparent consumption compared ferent patterns in utilization of the catch. Generally, a higher to the FAO Food Balance Sheets estimates are considerable proportion of small-scale than of large-scale marine produc- (table 3.16). It should be noted, however, that the Mekong tion is used for direct domestic human consumption. In other River Commission (MRC) consumption study includes some words, it is not exported or used for reduction into ï¬?shmeal supply from subsistence ï¬?sheries. or as animal feed. H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 3 — R E S ULT S 31 With the exceptions of China, Thailand, and Vietnam, ï¬?sh pro- 3.2.5 Fueling Fisheries duction in the case study countries is generally used directly Fish-catching operations are heavily dependent on fossil fuel. as food, either locally or for exports. In China, a major part The global ï¬?shing fleet consumes 42 to 45 million tons of of the large-scale ï¬?sheries production is used for ï¬?shmeal fuel per year (Tyedmers 2004; Tyedmers, Watson, and Pauly and other nonfood purposes, whereas only 18 percent of 2005), which means that, on average, the fleet catches the catch of the small-scale ï¬?sheries is used for animal feed. somewhat less than 2 tons of ï¬?sh per ton of fuel consumed In Thailand and Vietnam, 20 to 30 percent of the total ï¬?sh (based on catches reported to FAO).28 Active demersal ï¬?sh- production is destined for nonfood uses (Laurenti 2007; Xie ing activities, such as dredging, bottom trawling, beam trawl- 2008; Lymer et al. 2008; Nguyen et al. 2008). ing, and Danish seining, represent energy-intense ï¬?shing methods, whereas passive ï¬?shing (such as using hook and 3.2.4.3 Trade line, gill nets, or raps) requires less energy. Active pelagic ï¬?shing with, for example, midwater trawls, purse seines, and Fish and ï¬?shery products are among the world’s most traded ring nets tends to be moderately energy intense. food products—37 percent of the total production enters in- ternational trade (FAO 2009b). About 25 percent of this quan- Large-scale marine ï¬?sheries use about 10 times more fuel tity is produced through aquaculture, and the rest, about 40 per ton of catch than do small-scale ï¬?sheries (table 3.17). million tons,26 is capture ï¬?sheries production. The economic Developing country ï¬?sheries and small-scale ï¬?sheries show importance of ï¬?sh trade varies among countries. Developing signiï¬?cantly greater fuel efï¬?ciency, largely because many countries have increased their share in food ï¬?sh exports small-scale and inland ï¬?sheries in developing countries do and, as a group, account for 51 percent of world exports by not use motorized vessels. The poor fuel efï¬?ciency in the volume.27 Most export products are from marine waters, but large-scale marine ï¬?sheries in developing countries is partly there are notable exceptions. Among the case study coun- attributable to aging and poorly maintained fleets, wide- tries, Nile perch exports from Lake Victoria, freshwater ï¬?sh spread tropic shrimp trawl ï¬?sheries with a low retained catch and prawn exports from Cambodia, and kapenta (Tanganyika per unit of fuel, and fleet overcapacity. sardine) exports from Mozambique are of note (Menezes 2008; Thuok et al. 2008; van der Knaap 2008). 3.2.5.1 Developing Countries The impact of international trade on the poor and food Small-scale ï¬?sheries use passive gear more often and are security is complex. Although trade generally stimulates generally more fuel efï¬?cient than the large-scale ï¬?sheries. economic growth—and trade in food is essential for food Because of the wide diversity in ï¬?shing operations, the aver- deï¬?cit countries, international trade is not an unqualiï¬?ed age estimated fuel-efï¬?ciency rates calculated from the devel- remedy for poverty reduction or food security because food oping countries case studies29 varied greatly (table 3.18) and, security depends both on domestic production and foreign in some cases, showed similar levels of fuel efï¬?ciency for exchange availability (for food-importing countries). Trade small- and large-scale marine ï¬?shing. Small-scale ï¬?shing in liberalization may reduce food security if it removes protec- inland waters, on the other hand, appears to be less energy tion for domestic producers, and small-scale producers are intense, although data are particularly limited.30 heavily affected if imports capture market share from tradi- tional products. Declining ï¬?sh export prices combined with Nonmotorized vessels are an important part of the small- rising prices for imported fuel and ï¬?shing gear pose growing scale ï¬?sheries, and ï¬?shing with nonmotorized craft or with threats. Economic slowdown, changes in the composition handheld gear is obviously fuel efï¬?cient. However, vessels of consumers’ shopping baskets, and vulnerability of the global food supply system to trade disruption pose additional 28 Based on catches from 2000, the estimation is 80.4 million tons. threats (Kelleher 2008). High export prices are beneï¬?cial for Only direct fuel consumption (i.e., not accounting for indirect ï¬?shers, but if sustainable resource management practices energy use related to input supplies, boat building, etc.) and re- ported marine ï¬?shing (freshwater ï¬?sheries and IUU ï¬?shing) are are absent, international market demand may foster overex- not considered (Tyedmers et al. 2005). ploitation (FAO 2005; Kurien 2005). 29 Data on selected fleet segments were provided in the Big Num- bers Project case studies from Ghana, Bangladesh, Cambodia, China, and Senegal. 30 The China case study gave an average of 10.9 tons caught per ton of fuel consumed in inland waters of Hubei province. In Lake 26 Live weight equivalent (FAO 2009b). Volta in Ghana, the average rate was 6.1 tons of ï¬?sh per ton of 27 In 2004; including aquaculture products (FAO 2007). fuel. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 32 C H A PTER 3 — R ES ULTS TABLE 3.17: Catch per Ton of Fuel SMALL-SCALE FISHERIES LARGE-SCALE FISHERIES MARINE INLAND TOTAL MARINE INLAND TOTAL TOTAL (TONS) Developing countries 2.2 0.7 1.3 18.3 0.6 13.0 2.2 Developed countries 1.9 3.5 3.2 Source: Authors. TABLE 3.18: Fuel Efï¬?ciency Estimates: Examples from Developing Country Marine Fisheries COUNTRY TYPE OF VESSEL/FISHING FISH CATCH (TONS) PER TON OF FUEL Senegal Small-scale: Average pirogues, different gear 4.2 Cambodia Small-scale: <10 HP 3.1 Ghana Small-scale: Ali/poli/watsa 1.4 China Small-scale: Gillnetters and stow boats in East China Sea (Zhejiang province) 0.9 Bangladesh Small-scale: Average motorized vessels 0.3 Ghana Large-scale: Tuna purse seiners 4.8 Senegal Large-scale: Offshore tuna 3.9 China Large-scale: Purse seiners, trawlers, and hooking boats in East China Sea (Zhejiang 1.7 province) Bangladesh Large-scale: Vessels <150 GT 1.4 Cambodia Large-scale: Average trawlers, seiners, and other offshore boats 1.2 Source: Authors; developing country case studies. ï¬?shing in inland waters in Cambodia and shore-operated efï¬?cient ï¬?shing methods both for small and large vessels lift nets, common in some Asian countries, have become with average catches of 1.5 tons per ton of fuel consumed. increasingly mechanized. Most artisanal canoe ï¬?sheries in developing countries now include some motorized vessels. 3.2.5.3 Historical Trends in Fuel Use Evidence shows that some ï¬?sheries are using an increasing 3.2.5.2 Developed Countries quantity of fuel to catch the same amount of ï¬?sh because Data from the EU sample countries showed that large- of the declining state of many ï¬?sh stocks, an expanding scale vessels were more fuel efï¬?cient than the small-scale fleet, and increasing vessel horsepower driven by the “race fleet—3.5 tons of ï¬?sh per ton of fuel consumed compared to ï¬?shâ€? (Tydemers 2004). A comparison with fuel-efï¬?ciency to 1.9 tons of ï¬?sh per ton of fuel, respectively. Based on rates calculated in 1980 (Thomson 1980) shows a clear de- observer data, however, ï¬?sheries in the northeast United cline in volume of ï¬?sh caught per unit of fuel used. In 1980, States show greater differences in fuel efï¬?ciency between small-scale ï¬?sheries were estimated to catch 10 to 20 tons gear types than between vessel sizes. Overall, large vessels per ton of fuel, and large-scale ï¬?sheries, 2 to 5 tons. By 2006, (longer than 24 meters) appeared twice as fuel efï¬?cient as these values had decreased to 4 to 8 tons and 1 to 2 tons for medium (12 to 24 meters) and small (less than 12 meters) small- and large-scale ï¬?shing, respectively (see Annex). vessels. However, if midwater pair trawling and purse sein- ing for herring and mackerel (high volume, lower value spe- The historical trend suggests a likely continued decline in cies) are excluded, the smaller vessels as a group landed fuel efï¬?ciency in small-scale ï¬?sheries. The available data do more ï¬?sh per ton of fuel used than did medium and large not show small-scale ï¬?sheries to be more fuel efï¬?cient than boats (table 3.19). This ï¬?nding is consistent with other obser- their large-scale counterparts. However, these estimates are vations that purse seine ï¬?sheries for small pelagic species based on a limited sample, particularly for developing coun- often destined for reduction (ï¬?shmeal and oil) are more fuel tries, and this conclusion refers only to motorized ï¬?shing be- efï¬?cient than ï¬?shing for high-value (food) ï¬?sh (Tyedmers et cause ï¬?shing from nonmotorized boats or by handheld gear al. 2005). Otter and scallop trawling are by far the least fuel- is not included in the sample. H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 3 — R E S ULT S 33 TABLE 3.19: Catch per Ton of Fuel Consumed in Fisheries in the Northeast United States FLEET SEGMENTS/ OTTER MIDWATER PURSE SCALLOP SCALLOP GEAR TYPES GILLNET LONG-LINE TRAWL PAIR TRAWL SEINE DREDGE TRAWL TOTAL Large vessels (>24 m) (all values in metric tons) Fish landed 14,441 35,237 — 15,106 46 64,830 Fuel consumed 8,925 2,519 — 4,236 35 15,715 Landings per ton of fuel 1.6 14.0 — 3.6 1.3 4.1 Medium vessels (12–24 m) (all values in metric tons) Fish landed 2,619 325 16,193 1,862 4,599 5,673 282 28,934 Fuel consumed 682 136 11,828 233 97 1,919 190 14,402 Landings per ton of fuel 3.8 2.4 1.4 8.0 47.6 3.0 1.5 2.0 Small vessels (<24 m) (all values in metric tons) Fish landed 716 375 104 — — 22 282 783 Fuel consumed 173 94 74 — — 7 190 364 Landings per ton of fuel 4.1 4.0 1.4 — — 3.2 1.5 2.2 Average for all vessels (all values in metric tons) Fish landed 3,335 700 30,738 37,099 4,599 20,801 328 94,265 Fuel consumed 855 229 20,827 2,751 97 6,162 225 30,291 Landings per ton of fuel 3.9 3.1 1.5 13.5 47.6 3.4 1.5 3.1 Source: Kitts, Schneider, and Lent 2008; A. Kitts (personal communication). 3.2.5.4 Fuel as a Proportion of Total Harvesting Costs TABLE 3.20: Fuel Costs as Share of Revenue from Fish The price of fuel for ï¬?shing generally does not vary among Landed countries as much as it varies for the transport sector be- 1995– 1999– 2002– 2005 cause taxes on fuel for ï¬?shing tend to be lower. However, 1997 2000 2003 (ESTIMATED) studies on the economic performance of marine capture ï¬?sh- Global average (%) 15 17 19 37 ery fleets31 show that ï¬?shing vessels in developing countries Developed countries (%) 11 10 10 20 have relatively higher fuel costs than do vessels in developed Developing countries (%) 19 21 22 43 countries (Le Rey, Prado, and Tietze 1999; Tietze et al. 2001; Source: FAO 2007a. Tietze et al. 2005; FAO 2007a).32 When expressed as a per- centage of the revenue of the ï¬?sh landed, fuel costs were almost twice as high in developing countries as in developed countries. This difference was even more pronounced for the extensive use of outboard motors in the canoe ï¬?sheries. vessels using passive gear; the studies showed that devel- Overall, the relative importance of fuel costs has increased oping country ï¬?shers using passive gear spend three times and is estimated to represent 37 percent of gross revenues as much as their counterparts in developed countries spend globally and 20 percent and 43 percent in developed and de- on fuel. The cost differential may be largely attributable to veloping countries, respectively (table 3.20). The developing country case studies also provided informa- 31 See Le Rey et al. 1999; Tietze et al. 2001; Tietze et al. 2005. tion on the relative weight of fuel in the cost structure of ï¬?sh- The studies included both developed and developing countries ing. Although the data are insufï¬?cient for calculating exact and covered small- and large-scale ï¬?sheries. In the most recent proportions, the studies indicate that fuel represents a larger study (Tietze et al. 2005), fleets in Antigua, Argentina, Barbados, France, Germany, India, Norway, Peru, Republic of Korea, Sen- percentage of gross revenues in marine small-scale than in egal, South Africa, Thailand, and Trinidad were surveyed. marine large-scale ï¬?sheries. Considering the current volatil- 32 This situation is not speciï¬?c for the ï¬?sheries sector but is general ity of fuel prices, this could be of signiï¬?cant concern for the for all industries. The energy intensity, measured as the amount of energy needed to produce a unit of GDP, tends to decrease in future viability of small-scale ï¬?sheries and related livelihoods maturing economies (FAO 2007a). in some of these countries. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 34 C H A PTER 3 — R ES ULTS BOX 3.2: Deï¬?ning Bycatch and Discards BOX 3.3: Bycatch Collection in Mozambique Bycatch includes, in its broadest sense, “all non-target In Mozambique, artisanal ï¬?shers have collected bycatch animals and non-living material (debris) which are caught from shrimp trawlers since the 1970s. In Nampula and while ï¬?shingâ€? and can also include “animals and non- Zambezia provinces, artisanal ï¬?shers exchange their living material that interact with the ï¬?shing gear but do shrimp catch for bycatch with the semi-industrial or in- not make it to the deck of the ï¬?shing boatâ€? (Eayrs 2007). dustrial vessels. The ï¬?sh is sold fresh for local consump- More commonly, bycatch is the total catch of nontarget tion or dried for more distant markets. Many ï¬?shers in animals (Kelleher 2005). the two provinces believe that the activity is more proï¬?t- able than ï¬?shing. “Discards, or discarded catch, is that portion of the total organic material of animal origin in the catch, which is Source: Menezes 2008 (Mozambique case study). thrown away, or dumped in the sea for whatever rea- son. It does not include plant materials and post harvest sea by small-scale operators takes place in many countries, waste such as offal. The discards may be dead, or aliveâ€? such as Ghana, India, Mozambique, Nigeria, Senegal, and (Kelleher 2005). Thailand (Béné et al. 2007). “The discard rate is the proportion (percentage) of the total catch that is discarded.â€? It should be noted that 3.3 SUPPLEMENTARY DATA discards are not a subset of bycatch because target spe- cies may be discarded as well (Kelleher 2005). Table 3.21, adapted from Thomson (1980), gives an overview of the marine capture ï¬?sheries in 1980. Thomson’s study in- Source: Eayrs 2007; Kelleher 2005. cluded global estimates of employment, catches, and fuel consumption in small- and large-scale marine ï¬?sheries. It argued for the relative importance of small-scale ï¬?sheries 3.2.6 Bycatch and Discards and the need to protect inshore ï¬?shing grounds and support Globally, the quantity of ï¬?sh discarded at sea (box 3.2) has small-scale ï¬?shers. declined in recent years. Increased utilization of bycatch (par- ticularly in Asia), use of more selective gear, reduced ï¬?shing The Thomson table has been updated on several occasions if there are high levels of unwanted bycatch, and more ef- (Lindquist 1988; Berkes et al. 2001; Pauly 2006), and the dif- ï¬?cient bycatch management have all contributed to reduced ferent versions are summarized in tables 3.21 and 3.22. Of discards. However, global discards are around 7 million tons these, only Berkes et al. (2001) includes inland ï¬?sheries. The annually—effectively 8 percent of catch is dumped before values in these tables are often cited as representing global landing. Tropical shrimp trawl ï¬?sheries have the highest dis- ï¬?sheries despite the omission of inland ï¬?sheries. card rates, followed by other shrimp and ï¬?nï¬?sh trawl ï¬?sher- ies. Small-scale ï¬?sheries tend to have lower discard rates TABLE 3.21: Proï¬?le of World Fisheries in 1980: The than large-scale ï¬?sheries. Purse seine, handline, jig, trap, and Thomson Table pot ï¬?sheries have relatively low discard rates (Kelleher 2005). LARGE-SCALE, The developing country case studies countries showed low COMPANY SMALL-SCALE, discard rates—an estimated average of 0.5 percent in the OWNED ARTISANAL small-scale ï¬?sheries and 5 percent for large-scale ï¬?sheries Number of ï¬?shers employed 450,000 Over 8,000,000 (Kelleher 2005).33 Small-scale inland ï¬?sheries showed almost Marine ï¬?sh caught annually for ~24 million ~20 million human consumption (tons) no discards, but tropical shrimp-trawl ï¬?sheries in some countries (such as Indonesia, Mozambique (box 3.3), Nigeria, Capital cost of each job ($) $10,000–100,000 $100–1,000 and Senegal) influenced the higher discard rates noted for Marine ï¬?sh caught for industrial ~19 million tons .. reduction (ï¬?shmeal and oil) the large-scale ï¬?sheries in general. In Asia, including China, discards are negligible because bycatch is used either for hu- Fuel oil consumption (tons/year) 10–14 million 1–2 million man consumption or as animal feed. Bycatch collection at Fish caught per ton of fuel consumed 2–5 tons 10–20 tons Fishers employed for each $1 million 10–100 1,000–10, 000 invested 33 Based on case study data and the FAO discards database (Kelle- her 2005). Source: Adapted from Thomson 1980. H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 3 — R E S ULT S 35 TABLE 3.22: Comparative Results of Previous Studies THOMSON 1980 LINDQUIST 1988 BERKES ET AL. 2001 PAULY 2006 SMALL- LARGE- SMALL- LARGE- SMALL- LARGE- SMALL- LARGE- BENEFITS SCALE SCALE SCALE SCALE SCALE SCALE SCALE SCALE Annual catch for human consumption 20 24 24 29 20–30 15–40 ~30 ~30 (million tons) Annual catch reduced to meals/oils .. ~19 n.a. ~22 n.a. n.a. .. 20–30 (million tons) Fish and other sea life discarded at sea n.a. n.a. 0 6–16 n.a. n.a. .. 8–20 (million tons) Number of ï¬?shers employed (million) <8 ~0.45 >12 0.5 50 0.5 >12 ~0.5 Annual fuel consumption (tons) 1–2 10–14 1–2.5 14–19 1–2.5 14–19 ~5 ~37 Catch (tons) per ton of fuel consumed 10–20 2–5 10–20 2–5 10–20 2–5 4–8 1–2 Source: Compiled from cited sources. Note: All studies refer to marine ï¬?sheries only except Berkes et al. 2001, which includes both marine and inland ï¬?sheries. 3.4 THE HIDDEN HARVEST OF SUBSISTENCE in excess of 80 percent of the rural population engage FISHERIES in ï¬?shing activities (Shams 2007; Sjorslev 2000). During the preparation of the developing country case stud- Households switch from no-ï¬?shing to subsistence ies, it became evident that the important contribution from ï¬?shing to commercial ï¬?shing in accordance with the subsistence ï¬?sheries was not adequately reflected in ofï¬?- cial ï¬?sheries production values and only partly captured in BOX 3.4: Subsistence Fishing in Thailand the 17 case studies undertaken. Three detailed studies on The Thai case study included a recalculation of inland subsistence ï¬?sheries were commissioned—on Vietnam, capture ï¬?sheries production. Datasets used included Bangladesh, and the Philippines (Mills 2010). The results of the National Agricultural Census and the Gross Provincial two of these studies follow. In the case of the Philippines, Product (GPP) survey. In the GPP survey, 2,215 house- subsistence ï¬?shing could not be satisfactorily disaggregated holds reporting ï¬?sh production were identiï¬?ed, and sur- from small-scale commercial ï¬?shing. vey returns were examined in detail. Of these, 75 per- The subsistence ï¬?shing case studies present a complex cent of households reported production of less than 281 picture of an activity that is only partially captured in ofï¬?cial kilograms per year, with a mean production of 102 kilo- ï¬?sheries or household survey statistics (box 3.4). A number grams per year. These households were designated to of key points emerge: be low-production households. Remaining ï¬?shing house- holds had an average catch of 1,306 kilograms per year. If production is primarily for household consumption, The National Agricultural Census identiï¬?ed 2,639,582 production volumes per household are low, as borne ï¬?shing households. Assuming a distribution of high- out by the proï¬?les of subsistence and commercial production and low-production ï¬?shing households simi- ï¬?shers in the case studies. Where production is far lar to that identiï¬?ed in the GPP survey, and attributing to higher than required by the immediate kin of ï¬?shers, these the average catches of such households as cal- ï¬?shing has moved beyond subsistence into the com- culated in the GPP survey, total inland production was mercial realm. estimated at 1,062,696 tons in 2005. Subsistence ï¬?shing is difï¬?cult to deï¬?ne and can be highly seasonal such that one-off surveys may not This value represents about ï¬?ve times the ofï¬?cial inland indentify its importance. For example, in studies in capture ï¬?shery production for the same year. Ofï¬?cial the Mekong Delta, all communities were dominated data are collected via the direct monitoring of landings by those identifying themselves as rice farmers, yet at major landing sites in a number of larger reservoirs up to 83 percent of the population engaged in ï¬?shing throughout Thailand. at some time of the year. This is also consistent with Source: Lymer et al. 2008. studies of riverine areas in adjacent countries where EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 36 C H A PTER 3 — R ES ULTS seasonality of livelihood opportunities and household 40 percent the number of people engaged in ï¬?sh division of labor. production. Conventional ï¬?sheries statistics do not capture the Capture ï¬?sheries constitute a greater proportion of extent or importance of subsistence ï¬?sheries, and household income for poor than for nonpoor house- household income and expenditure surveys may not holds (see ï¬?gures 3.1 and 3.2). capture its importance if conducted in a nonï¬?shing Seasonality and interannual variability in ï¬?shing yields season. and participation are high. Snapshot (single-sample) Food consumption surveys and food balance sheets data collection systems fail to capture the diversity of can indicate a substantially greater level of depen- ï¬?shing activities and ultimately the value of the ï¬?sher- dence on subsistence ï¬?sheries than is shown by the ies sector. other approaches. However, the design of the survey The discrepancy between estimates from these two requires some sensitivity to the nature of subsistence data systems relates at least in part to the changing ï¬?sheries. nature of ï¬?sh production in Bangladesh as well as to a mismatch between temporal and spatial scales of 3.4.1 Bangladesh sampling in the HIES and the nonrandom temporal The following are some key ï¬?ndings of the Bangladesh study: and spatial distribution of ï¬?shing activities. As well as providing a direct measure of the nutritional Reanalysis of data collected from the 1980s and importance of ï¬?sh, consumption data proved a sub- 1990s indicated up to 15.2 million households (inhab- stantially better indicator of ï¬?sh supply than did direct ited by 68 million people) directly engaged in capture household measures of ï¬?sh production. The value of ï¬?shery activities at a subsistence or commercial level consumption as an averaging device to remove biases for at least part of the year. in production estimates should not be overlooked. The more recent Household Income and Expenditure The relative importance of subsistence and com- Survey (HIES) from 2005 provides an estimate of 13 mercial ï¬?shing at a district level cannot be predicted million households (inhabited by 63 million people) on the basis of yield estimates, nor can the amount involved in ï¬?sh production, both ï¬?sheries and aquacul- of subsistence ï¬?shing be determined on the basis of ture subsectors. commercial ï¬?shing estimates. A far more complex Direct questions in the HIES regarding household set of drivers, including geography and hydrology, ï¬?sh production underestimated by a minimum of urbanization, and social issues, act to negate simple FIGURE 3.1: Income from Fisheries in Bangladesh by Income Group Share of fisheries in total income (%) 10.0 Rural culture 9.0 8.0 Rural capture 7.0 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 Bottom 10% 10–20% 20–30% 30–40% 40–50% 50–60% 60–70% 70–80% 80–90% Top 10% Per capita income decile group Source: HIES 2005. H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 3 — R E S ULT S 37 FIGURE 3.2: Bangladesh Fish Consumption by Rural and Urban Poor and Nonpoor 30.0 Rural: nonpoor 25.0 Rural: poor Urban: nonpoor 20.0 %Households Urban: poor 15.0 10.0 5.0 0.0 >45 kg <= 5kg 5–10 10–15 15–20 20–25 25–30 30–35 35–40 40–45 Per capita fish consumption (kg/year) Source: HIES 2005. correlation. Therefore, data on commercial ï¬?shing, households from which 2.5 million people are actively which dominates ï¬?sheries data systems, are often a engaged in ï¬?shing. poor indicator of the importance of ï¬?shing at a district Stakeholders in Vietnam acknowledge that existing and ultimately at a national level. data systems do not provide an adequate picture of the entire ï¬?sheries sector and that data on subsis- 3.4.2 Vietnam tence ï¬?shing are largely absent. Fish consumption The following are some key ï¬?ndings of the Vietnam study: studies were of considerable value in detecting ï¬?sh production not captured by direct sampling methods. Studies of ï¬?sh consumption in the Mekong Delta The study adopted a balance sheet methodology for indicate that inland capture ï¬?sheries production is calculating ï¬?sh supply per capita under a range of ï¬?sh more than ï¬?ve times that reported in ofï¬?cial statistics. production scenarios developed from alternative data Extrapolation to the country level indicates inland ï¬?sh- sources. The importance of ï¬?sheries to livelihoods eries production in excess of 1 million tons per year. in the Mekong Delta has resulted in comprehensive Alternative estimates of both inland and marine studies being conducted in recent years. Data on capture ï¬?sheries suggest national supply of ï¬?sh per participation and production of inland ï¬?sheries outside capita may be as high as 40 kilograms per year (table the Mekong Delta are deï¬?cient. 3.16). This is about 40 percent higher than the ofï¬?cial Studies of inland provinces tended to provide detailed estimate for ï¬?sh consumption. statistics on participation in ï¬?sheries by the general The study suggests that a minimum of 15 million population, and those of marine provinces concen- household members rely directly on 4 million ï¬?shers trate on data collection from ï¬?shing households only, to fulï¬?ll part of their nutritional requirements at some creating difï¬?culty in characterizing the importance of stage during the year. This number could be as high subsistence ï¬?shing in coastal provinces. as 25 million household members and 8 million ï¬?sh- ers. This extrapolation, however, involves signiï¬?cant A comparison of (1) the ofï¬?cial production and consumption assumptions because key characteristics of ï¬?sheries estimates with (2) results of the ï¬?rst case study (which had differ among regions. the objective of disaggregating small- and large-scale ï¬?sher- In 10 provinces adjacent to the Mekong Delta, an esti- ies) and (3) the second case study (which focused on sub- mated 8.13 million people rely directly on the capture sistence ï¬?sheries) is presented in tables 3.23 and 3.24. The of ï¬?sh and aquatic animals to meet part of their nutri- comparison illustrates that the ofï¬?cial values may underesti- tional requirements. These people live in 1.82 million mate ï¬?sh production and consumption by about 40 percent. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 38 C H A PTER 3 — R ES ULTS TABLE 3.23: Comparison of Vietnam Fish Production Case Studies (million tons) OFFICIAL DISAGGREGATION SUBSISTENCE PRODUCTION AND TRADE ESTIMATES CASE STUDY CASE STUDY Marine capture 1,647,482 1,647,482 2,584,313 Inland capture 208,872 1,129,298 1,129,298 Brackish/marine culture 443,135 443,135 443,135 Inland culture 559,960 559,960 559,960 Total production 2,859,449 3,779,875 4,716,706 Less marine trash for feedstock 411,870 411,870 933,183 Less exports 544,159 544,159 544,159 Plus imports 29,420 29,420 29,420 Available for local human consumption 1,932,840 2,853,226 3,268,784 Equivalent to (kg/person/year) 23.89 35.26 40.41 Source: Mills 2010. TABLE 3.24: Estimated Participation in Vietnam Inland Fisheries under Alternative Scenarios (millions) INLAND FISHING HOUSEHOLD SCENARIO/ASSUMPTIONS HOUSEHOLDS INLAND FISHERS TOTAL FISHERS MEMBERS 1. Same catch for non-Mekong households 2,820 4,090 4,720 14,450 2. Half catch for non-Mekong households 4,990 7,240 7,910 23,910 3. Thirty percent of rural households outside 4,970 7,200 7,880 23,810 Mekong Delta ï¬?sh Source: Mills 2010. Note: Scenario 1 is based on an assumption that households outside of the case study area catch the same quantity of ï¬?sh as those within the immediate delta area. Scenario 2 is based on a more conservative assumption that households outside this highly productive area catch, on average, half the quantity of ï¬?sh of those within the study area. Scenario 3 is based on a similar conservative assumption that 30 percent of rural households outside of the study area are engaged in ï¬?shing. 3.5 RECREATIONAL FISHERIES marine recreational ï¬?sheries is more than three times that of There is no standard method of estimating the value of recre- the commercial ï¬?sheries. In Iceland, the value of a commer- ational ï¬?shing. The wide variety of studies often target either cially netted salmon was found to be about 1/35 of the value inland or marine angling but rarely both. Different studies in- of a salmon netted in an angling ï¬?shery ($600–1,000 per clude or exclude different costs, such as exclusion of capital angled salmon) (Isaksson and Oskarsson 2002). The employ- costs, which may also exclude ï¬?shing tackle. ment generated by recreational ï¬?shing is signiï¬?cant, almost three times the number employed in commercial ï¬?sheries in The subsector tends to be sublimated into the tourism sec- the United States, and the economic contribution of angling tor, and its economic contribution often receives limited at- in Wales is more than twice that of commercial ï¬?shing and tention. The sector is also closely aligned with subsistence aquaculture combined (Nautilus 2007). China has an esti- ï¬?shing because many “weekend anglersâ€? ï¬?sh expressly to mated 90 million recreational ï¬?shers. Angling is promoted as provide food. The activity is also closely linked to marine and part of the National Healthy Exercise Plan, and based on an aquatic recreation. Neither of these activities is addressed in annual per capita consumption of $35 per recreational angler, this study. the Chinese market for recreational ï¬?shing is about $3.5 bil- lion (Min Guo 2006). There are an estimated 225 million recreational ï¬?shers, or anglers, worldwide—almost twice the numbers of commer- The total annual expenditure on recreational ï¬?sheries is con- cial ï¬?shers (see Annex). In the United States, 18 out of 22 servatively estimated at over $190 billion (table 3.25). The es- maritime states derive greater economic impacts from rec- timated annual global demand for recreational ï¬?shing equip- reational ï¬?sheries, and the aggregate economic impact from ment is $15.66 billion (BizAcumen 2009). A number of studies H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 3 — R E S ULT S 39 TABLE 3.25: Estimated Total Expenditures on Recreational Fishing for 2009 ($ million) INDEPENDENT EXPENDITURES ON TACKLE AS % OF TOTAL ESTIMATED TOTAL ESTIMATES OF COUNTRY/REGION FISHING TACKLE EXPENDITURE EXPENDITURE EXPENDITURES France 850 0.075 11,333 Germany 508 0.075 6,773 Italy 653 0.075 8,701 United Kingdom 1,122 0.075 14,960 £2.89 billion Spain 162 0.075 2,161 Russia 245 0.1 2,448 Rest of Europe 2,554 0.1 25,540 United States 4,532 0.075 60,423 $82 billion Canada 376 0.075 5,008 Japan 1,403 0.075 18,711 Australia 146 0.075 1,947 A$1.9 billion China n.a. n.a. n.a. $3.5 billion Rest of Asia-Paciï¬?c 1,667 0.1 16,672 Latin America 1,341 0.075 17,880 Total 15,558 192,556 Source: BizAcumen 2009; authors. of expenditures on recreational ï¬?shing (Annex, table 2.8) and BVA 2002). In South Africa, the commercial lineï¬?sh indicate that 10 percent (median value; average 12 percent) ï¬?shery accounts for 79 percent of the catch, whereas the of expenditures can be attributed to ï¬?shing equipment. The recreational component generates over 80 percent of the value of $190 billion is derived on the basis of a conservative employment and revenue (Grifï¬?ths and Lambeth 2002). assumption that 7 percent of angler expenditure is used for equipment in developed countries and 10 percent is used in developing countries. The higher proportion for developing 3.6 THE CONTRIBUTION OF COMMERCIAL countries is based on the perception that a greater proportion FISHERIES TO GDP of developing country angler expenditure is on equipment. The contribution of a sector to national GDP is a key macro- The different approaches used in the available recreational economic indicator frequently referred to by decision makers ï¬?sheries case studies complicate estimates of average value and donors when highlighting the particular sector’s impor- added and multipliers. Studies from the United States and tance to a national economy. Information on the contribution the United Kingdom both indicate that income value added of a natural resource sector to GDP is useful as one of many is about 0.37 percent for each unit of angler expenditure, so indicators, not only to monitor the progress of sustainable total value added would be in excess of this value. If total resource management, but also to gain the attention of deci- value added is assumed to be 40 percent, the contribution sion makers and to highlight the contribution of the sector to of recreational ï¬?sheries to GDP is about $70 billion annually. poverty alleviation (FAO 2004b). This value is a conservative estimate because recreational ï¬?sheries in seven countries contribute an estimated $74 bil- The total ï¬?sheries sector’s contribution, including the marine, lion per year to the global economy when direct and indirect inland, and postharvest subsectors, to the global economy impacts are taken into account. was estimated at $274 billion in 2007, with a 95-percent con- ï¬?dence interval of between $252 and 303 billion. If a conser- The impact of recreational ï¬?shing on ï¬?sh stocks can be con- vative upstream multiplier of 1.3 is applied (a limited number siderable. In France, sea angling (including collection of shell- of studies suggest a multiplier of 1.6), there is an additional ï¬?sh) is estimated to harvest 30,000 tons annually (Fremer contribution to GDP of about $90 billion. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 40 C H A PTER 3 — R ES ULTS The global capture ï¬?sheries GDP estimate is based on infor- Of these, 10 countries used estimates prepared by the SFLP mation from 129 countries for which further details of the for sub-Saharan countries (see Annex), which included not estimate are itemized in table A.3. The estimates included only the postharvest subsector (marketing, processing, ï¬?sh only the direct impacts from commercial ï¬?sheries (primary handling), but also the sale and repair of ï¬?shing boats and production of harvest and postharvest subsectors). Indirect, equipment. For the remaining 11 countries, the precise ac- induced economic impacts were not included, nor was the tivities included in the nonharvest subsector were not fully aquaculture subsector. The available GDP values underesti- speciï¬?ed. mate the economic contribution from subsistence ï¬?sheries because the majority of the countries did not include these In the 26 countries, the nonharvest contribution varies be- activities or did so marginally. The exceptions include some tween 10.3 percent (Sao Tome and Principe) and 75 percent Paciï¬?c Island countries and some estimates prepared in (Uganda) of the total ï¬?sheries contribution to GDP, with an West and Central Africa. Future analyses can signiï¬?cantly average contribution of about 41.3 percent. This means that, improve the accuracy of the estimate when further country- on average, harvest subsector alone captures just over half level postharvest GDP values become available. of the actual contribution from the ï¬?sheries sector. The con- tribution of nonharvest activities appears slightly higher in developing countries (44.7 percent) than in developed coun- 3.6.1 Summary Statistics tries (40.7 percent), although the difference is not statistically 3.6.1.1 Harvest Subsector signiï¬?cant. Out of 129 countries where the ï¬?sheries-related GDP data were available, the contribution from the harvest (catching) The nonharvest share of total ï¬?sheries GDP is not signiï¬?- subsector was identiï¬?ed for 111 countries (see table 3.26). cantly correlated with other factors, such as country eco- The remaining 18 countries reported the combined contribu- nomic status, ï¬?sh production, or the species composition tion of catching and farming (aquaculture) of ï¬?shery products (demersal, shellï¬?sh, pelagic, and freshwater) of landings. The (primary production) to national GDP. postharvest contribution tends to have a lower share of GDP in European countries, whereas the postharvest contribution The contribution from the harvest subsector to national GDP tends to have a higher share in countries with high demersal varies between almost zero and 30 percent with a median and freshwater landings (inland production in general). The contribution of 1.28 percent. The contribution is signiï¬?cantly correlations are not statistically signiï¬?cant. higher for developing countries, with a median contribution of 1.8 percent compared to a median of 0.2 percent for de- Information on value added generated from the recreational veloped countries. With a median contribution of 4.6 percent, ï¬?sheries subsector, including marine and inland tourism, countries in Oceania tend to have higher harvest subsector was compiled for seven countries (Australia, Belize, Canada, contributions to GDP than do other regions. The average val- Namibia, New Zealand, Northwest Trinidad, and the United ues are sensitive to the presence of outliers (some countries States). Together, these countries directly contributed ap- with extremely high GDP contribution), and median value is a proximately $49 billion per year to the global economy and, if more appropriate indicator of the central tendency. indirect impacts are included, about $74 billion per year. 3.6.1.2 Postharvest and Nonharvest Subsectors 3.6.2 VARs, Value Chain Analyses, and Input-Output Analyses Out of 129 countries, the contributions of the postharvest and nonharvest subsectors were identiï¬?ed for 26 countries. Studies in 15 sub-Saharan countries show that the harvest subsector accounts for 60 to 70 percent of the value generat- ed by the sector (table 3.27). The remaining 30 to 40 percent TABLE 3.26: Contribution from the Fisheries Harvest is generated largely by postharvest marketing and process- Subsector to National GDP (%) ing activities (Kébé 2008). Studies using a VAR approach in RANGE AVERAGE MEDIAN Paciï¬?c Island developing economies estimate the revised Global 0–30 2.8 1.3 ï¬?sheries sector GDP (including nonharvest activities) to be Developing countries 3.5 1.8 from 4 percent to 63 percent higher than the “ofï¬?cialâ€? esti- Developed countries 0.4 0.2 mates, which generally refer to the harvest subsector only, and on average 30 percent higher (Gillet 2009, Gillett and Oceania 8.5 4.6 Lightfoot 2002). Other studies in the U.S. Paciï¬?c Territories Source: Gillett 2010; Kébé 2008. H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 3 — R E S ULT S 41 TABLE 3.27. VARs for Fisheries Subsectors in TABLE 3.28: Value Chain Analysis for Lake Victoria Nile Developing Countries in the Paciï¬?c Perch SUBSECTOR VAR (%) EURO/KG % OF VALUE Large-scale offshore ï¬?shing 40–55 Boat owners 0.58 9 Small-scale commercial ï¬?shing 55–70 Middlemen 0.71 2 Subsistence ï¬?shing: motorized 65–75 Agents 0.89 3 Subsistence ï¬?shing: nonmotorized 90 Processing factories 1.48 9 Nonvessel ï¬?shing 89–92 Exporters 2.72 19 Aquaculture 21–72 Wholesale 3.60 14 Source: Gillett and Lightfoot 2002. Retail 6.40 44 Source: Authors; case studies. and in Uganda indicate that revised ï¬?sheries sector GDP is The economic impact of marine capture ï¬?sheries to the glob- about twice the ofï¬?cial estimates (Yaron and Moyini 2004; al economy has been estimated at about US$380 billion per Zeller, Booth and Pauly 2006). year using an input-output analysis (table 3.28). This is 4.5 times greater than the ï¬?rst sale value of the ï¬?sh produced The distribution of value added along the value chain var- (Dyck and Sumaila 2009). ies widely. A value chain study from Nigeria indicates that approximately three times the farm gate value of farmed In Canada, the seafood sector (commercial ï¬?shing, aquacul- catï¬?sh is generated postharvest in marketing and special- ture, and ï¬?sh processing) created the equivalent of 37,255 ized ï¬?sh restaurants. Approximately 80 percent of the ex- full-time direct jobs and another 25,200 in spin-off (second- port value of processed Indonesian blue swimming crab is ary) activities, generating a household income of approxi- generated postharvest. Other studies report value added mately US$2.2 billion,in 2006 (Pinfold 2009). The GDP impact at the harvesting level accounted for between 4 percent of the sector was estimated at $3.7 billion when direct plus (Moroccan anchovy ï¬?shery) and 18 percent (Icelandic cod) secondary activities were accounted for, and the ï¬?nal prod- of the retail value, and the retail sector captured about uct value of the seafood industry overall was just under $4.8 60 percent of the retail value (Gudmundsson, Asche, and billion. A 2008 study in Norway34 showed that the ï¬?shing and Nielsen 2006). Nile perch ï¬?shers in Lake Victoria receive aquaculture industry in Norway contributed NOK38.9 billion less than 10 percent of the retail value, and about 60 per- to GDP, approximately 1.8 percent of both Norway’s GDP cent of the retail value is captured in the European market and total employment in the country in 2006. Further details (table 3.28). of sector economic multipliers are provided in the Annex. 34 http://www.regjeringen.no/en/dep/md/documents-and-publi- cations/government-propositions-and-reports-/Reports-to-the- Storting-white-papers-2/2008-2009/report-no-37-2008-2009-to- the-storting/4/1.html?id=577903#note3. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK C H A P T E R 4 — I MP L ICAT IONS F OR DE CISION MAKE RS 43 Chapter 4: IMPLICATIONS FOR DECISION MAKERS The study is an effort to compile and interpret disparate in- attention from policymakers. The substantial underreporting dicators of global capture ï¬?sheries. It should be seen as one of small-scale catches constrains conventional approaches to step in a process of building knowledge of the importance ï¬?sheries management and undermines the social and eco- of capture ï¬?sheries to economies, livelihoods, food security, nomic valuation of these activities. In particular, these small- and environmental sustainability. scale and community ï¬?sheries require increased attention to their assessment and governance. The methodologies and their results form a coherent and valuable baseline for ï¬?sheries policymaking and governance. Small- and large-scale commercial ï¬?sheries merit sepa- The results should be seen as best estimates rather than rate consideration not only in developing countries but also deï¬?nitive values, given that the underlying data and assump- in many developed countries. The underestimated social, tions should be open to constructive criticism and improve- economic, and nutritional contributions of small-scale ï¬?sher- ment. The results highlight a number of key considerations. ies tend to undermine decisions and policies that may favor ï¬?shing communities. Fisheries managers and economic The economic and social importance of capture ï¬?sher- planners have tended to focus on the large-scale ï¬?sheries, ies is substantially underestimated. The importance of and marginalized small-scale ï¬?shing communities may not capture ï¬?sheries, particularly in developing countries, is sub- receive equitable beneï¬?t from public investment in roads, stantially underestimated in conventional reporting, namely water transport, schools, and other social infrastructure. through national ï¬?sheries statistics and national accounts. There is also a growing consensus that small-scale ï¬?sher- Effective policymaking must move beyond GDP and its basis ies assessment and governance approaches need to be in recorded production, or landing statistics, to consideration fundamentally different from those used in large-scale in- of the extended value chain and to recreational and subsis- dustrial ï¬?sheries. The approaches must address not only the tence ï¬?sheries. In developing countries, the contribution of particular vulnerability of the small-scale sector, but how to ï¬?sheries to poverty alleviation and rural community stability use science to inform community-level decisions. Some of and its role in environmental sustainability and adaptation to these approaches are outlined in the Code of Conduct for climate change needs to be highlighted to policymakers. Responsible Fisheries (see box 2.2) and its relevant Technical Hidden harvests mean that the sector is undervalued in terms Guidelines (FAO 2005) and by other authors (Andrew et al. of its perceived economic contribution. This translates to in- 2007; Béné et al. 2007; Berkes et al. 2001; Garcia et al. 2008). adequate weight in policy development, poverty reduction Subsistence ï¬?sheries and poverty require explicit atten- strategies, and allocation of public resources. Decisions that tion. The two subsistence case studies indicate substantial compromise the integrity and productivity of the concerned underreporting of subsistence ï¬?sheries. As a result, the sub- ecosystems may follow, for example, in relation to water sector’s contribution to food security and poverty alleviation extraction, drainage of wetlands, offshore oil extraction, or in developing countries is not sufï¬?ciently recognized. This tourism. Already marginalized communities may become undervaluation implies that the subsector is already margin- further disadvantaged. alized despite its likely high importance to the lives of the Healthy small-scale ï¬?sheries are vital for employment, rural poor. Effective assessment of subsistence ï¬?sheries pro-poor ï¬?sheries policies, food security, and for rural live- requires active collaboration with nonï¬?sheries information lihoods in many communities. The relative contributions of systems, such as nutrition and household income surveys. large- and small-scale ï¬?sheries and their interactions in terms The studies did not speciï¬?cally assess the poverty level of of competition for shared ï¬?sh resources need increased the subsistence ï¬?sher, although the notion that subsistence EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 44 C H A PTER 4 — IMPLIC ATIONS FOR D ECISIO N M A K ER S ï¬?shers are poor also provides a measurable characteristic. and (5) only direct impacts were included—spin-off (indirect It is clear, however, that subsistence ï¬?shers generally have and induced) impacts were not. limited capital and assets available to provide alternatives if access to ï¬?sh supply is curtailed. This has important policy If provisional estimates of these additional economic activi- implications for design of rights-based management regimes ties are included, the estimated contribution to GDP would and makes a case for speciï¬?c consideration of subsistence be considerably greater. For example: ï¬?shing activities in any measures to limit access. Including, on a pro-rata basis, the countries accounting Recreational ï¬?sheries deliver substantial economic ben- for 10 percent of reported production and for which eï¬?ts. Per kilogram of ï¬?sh, recreational ï¬?sheries yield orders GDP values are unavailable increase the estimate by of magnitude more economic value. They can also generate $27 billion dollars to a total of $301 billion dollars. substantial employment. Studies indicate that society attrib- If a conservative provision for upstream economic utes additional nonmarket values to recreational ï¬?sheries activities—a multiplier of 1.3—is applied to this value, (Toivonen 2004). Although recreational ï¬?sheries tend to have the estimate increases by an additional $90 billion. a relatively greater importance in developed countries, ris- If a conservative provision of 5 percent is made for ing incomes in developing countries provide opportunities to unrecorded catches, including subsistence ï¬?shing, the develop and sustain these ï¬?sheries and build on the links value increases by an additional $15 billion. to tourism and other aquatic recreational activities. The food If a conservative estimate of the value added by recre- value of recreational ï¬?sheries should not be ignored—it ex- ational ï¬?shing is included ($70 billion), the contribution tends into subsistence ï¬?sheries. of the sector to global GDP rises to $476 billion. By their nature, recreational ï¬?sheries overlap with both The global estimate is within the range of an estimated $380 subsistence and commercial ï¬?sheries. They may compete billion per year derived from input-output analyses (Dyck and with both and can exert signiï¬?cant pressure on the ï¬?shery Sumaila 2009). However, this estimate is not directly compa- resources, giving rise to conflicts and policy issues. It means rable because it refers to the marine ï¬?sheries subsector only that all three activities must be responsibly managed and and includes marine tourism. The simpliï¬?ed approach suffers that the governance regime and allocation processes must from a large degree of uncertainties given the data-limited balance the competing needs of the interest groups and environment. The estimates provided can be substantially society. The rents generated by recreational ï¬?sheries can improved when further country-level data become available, be signiï¬?cant and are not captured in a recent estimate of when the scope of estimated GDPs are more rigorously the global loss of rents in marine capture ï¬?sheries (World deï¬?ned, and when the determinants of harvest/processing Bank 2009). Recreational ï¬?sheries provide a rich array of multipliers can be more clearly quantiï¬?ed. examples of ï¬?sheries governance arrangements with appli- cation beyond these ï¬?sheries. These arrangements include Accounting for the contribution of the ï¬?sheries sector to indigenous people’s rights over these ï¬?sheries, separation of national GDP (and by extension to global GDP) exposes com- angling and land rights, community leasing of water bodies, mon methodological challenges and pitfalls in obtaining a stock enhancement, licensing and levies, catch reporting, consistent measure of ï¬?sheries GDP. Improvement of the management cost recovery approaches, and payments for national-level data through documenting a clear description ecosystem services. of what is included in the GDP estimate is the initial step to address these challenges. Ideally, national statistics ofï¬?ces Fisheries contribute importantly to GDP. Based on the and relevant ï¬?sheries agencies should work together for available data, the commercial ï¬?sheries sector’s contribution improved data collection and reporting of ï¬?sheries-related to global GDP is very conservatively estimated at $274 billion economic activities. Knowledge of the ï¬?sheries sector’s in 2007, including marine and inland harvest and postharvest contribution to national economies can help governments subsectors. The estimate is considered conservative for sev- address their economy’s dependence on ï¬?shery resources eral reasons: (1) the analysis omitted several countries for and improve future planning for sustainable management of which GDP data were not available and that, in aggregate, ac- the sector. count for about 10 percent of global seafood production; (2) the contribution from recreational ï¬?sheries subsectors was Fisheries are highly vulnerable to internal and external not included; (3) subsistence ï¬?sheries remain largely unac- threats. Dam construction, water extraction, oil and mining counted; (4) upstream economic activities are not included; activities, wetland conversion, deforestation, pollution, and H ID D E N H A RV ES T C H A P T E R 4 — I MP L ICAT IONS F OR DE CISION MAKE RS 45 coastal development degrade environments and habitats sector-speciï¬?c multipliers and value chain analyses, critical to aquatic ecosystem function and ï¬?sheries. Ensuring including for developing countries that the economic value of the ï¬?sheries sector is adequately Consensus guidelines on the preparation of estimates reflected at the national level builds arguments to take due of economic rents and associated indicators of eco- account of the sector in environmental decision making. nomic performance of ï¬?sheries Further development of actionable ï¬?sheries gover- Investment in good ï¬?sheries governance is justiï¬?ed by nance indicators (Anderson and Anderson 2010). their value. The economic losses attributable to weak ï¬?sh- eries governance—estimated at over $50 billion annually— provide ample justiï¬?cation for investments in good sector National ï¬?sheries specialists coordinate efforts to charac- governance to build future economic rents. Sustaining rural terize subsistence and small-scale ï¬?sheries with agencies livelihoods can offset the growing costs of urban migration. undertaking studies on household income and expenditure, Control of industrial fleets in coastal areas combined with nutrition, and rural economy in developing countries to responsible practices by small-scale ï¬?shing communities can provide policy-relevant information for the development of recover these economic rents and maintain the integrity of pro-poor ï¬?sheries governance approaches. National ï¬?sheries ï¬?shery-dependent communities. authorities reinforce collaboration with tourism authorities and angler associations to evaluate and manage recreational ï¬?sheries. 4.1 RECOMMENDATIONS National statistic ofï¬?ces and ï¬?sheries agencies in asso- National and international ï¬?sheries agencies and nongov- ciation with the development community collaborate to ernmental organizations direct the attention of policymakers improve data collection and reporting of ï¬?sheries-related and decision makers to the value of capture ï¬?sheries as a economic activities, including speciï¬?c attention to subsis- primary industry that underpins the economic activities of an tence and recreational ï¬?sheries. These efforts may include extended-value chain that can have an economic contribution the following: several times the landed value of the catch. Concise policy briefs can highlight the contribution to poverty reduction, Disaggregation of ï¬?sheries statistical information at nutrition, and employment and emphasize that, with good the country level into large- and small-scale in relation governance, sustainable ï¬?sheries can substantially increase to speciï¬?c policy issues such as access rights, food economic wealth. security, and economic growth based on sustainable ï¬?sheries National ï¬?sheries authorities direct increased attention to Development of ï¬?sheries satellite accounts in national the knowledge gaps exposed by the study. These include accounts improved estimates of contribution of the entire sector to GDP, including postharvest and upstream activities. While Incorporation of ï¬?sheries-speciï¬?c data collection into important to economic planners, the GDP values need to existing information tools, such as household income be complemented with social and environmental indicators, and expenditure surveys, to include ï¬?sheries infor- reflecting employment along the entire value chain, contribu- mation in the broader context of national economic tions to poverty reduction and food security, and the eco- growth, poverty reduction, and well-being nomic performance of different ï¬?sheries. Ensuring effective use of limited resources by engag- ing with survey agencies (bureaus of statistics, agricul- The development community considers collaboration in ture and nutrition departments) to provide advice and preparation of the following: training on question design as well as speciï¬?cities of the sampling frames required to capture the diversity Guidelines to evaluate the contribution of subsistence of ï¬?shing activities and livelihoods and subsistence ï¬?sheries, including guidance on the use of household ï¬?sheries in particular and nutrition surveys and poverty proï¬?ling to charac- Agree on key indicators for the different segments of terize subsistence ï¬?sheries the ï¬?sheries sector to enable effective policy formula- Guidelines consistent with the existing UN guid- tion and tracking of progress and trends. Make provi- ance (UN and FAO 2004) to estimate the extended sions for regular collection, compilation, and dissemi- GDP of the ï¬?sheries sector, including a typology of nation of this key information EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 46 C H A PTER 4 — IMPLIC ATIONS FOR D ECISIO N M A K ER S Develop partnership arrangements at the regional or Use the formal mechanisms of the FAO35 to improve collec- global level to improve quality and availability of key in- tion and interpretation of statistical data on ï¬?sheries, includ- formation on small scale ï¬?sheries and to support and ing validation and improvement of the results presented, at improve the capacity for appropriate data collection national, regional, and global levels. and analysis, particularly in developing countries. Critically review the results presented in this study with a The development community considers development of view to improving the underlying data, rendering deï¬?nitions partnerships or programs to make ï¬?sheries statistics and and data sets more compatible and enhancing the basis for knowledge more relevant and useful for decision making assessing the economic contribution for capture ï¬?sheries and to ensure that project-level monitoring is streamed into with the overall objective of improving ï¬?sheries management country knowledge-management systems. and laying a robust foundation for reforms. 35 In particular, the Coordinating Working Party on Fishery Statistics (CWP), http://www.fao.org/ï¬?shery/cwp/en, with strengthened links to the Global Strategy to Improve Agricultural and Rural Sta- tistics. H ID D E N H A RV ES T BIBLIOGRAPHY 47 BIBLIOGRAPHY ABS (Australian Bureau of Statistics). 2008. Australian National Béné, C., Macfadyen, G., and Allison, E. H. 2007. Increasing the Accounts: Tourism Satellite Account, 2006–07, ABS cat. no. Contribution of Small-Scale Fisheries to Poverty Alleviation and 5249.0. Canberra: Australian Bureau of Statistics. Food Security. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper No. 481. Rome: FAO. Adikwu, I. 2008. “Project Big Numbers Nigeria.â€? Unpublished BNP working document. Berkes, F. 2003. Alternatives to conventional management: Lessons from small-scale ï¬?sheries. Environments 31(1): 5–19. Agnew, D., Pearce, J., Peatman, T., Pitcher, T. J., and Pramod, G. 2008. The Global Extent of Illegal Fishing. Marine Resources Berkes, F., Mahon, R., McConney, P., Pollnac, R., and Pomeroy, R. and Fisheries Consultants Ltd., London, UK, and Fisheries 2001. Managing Small-Scale Fisheries. Alternative Directions Ecosystems Restoration Research, Fisheries Centre, University and Methods. Ottawa: International Development Research of British Columbia, Vancouver, Canada. Centre. Ainsworth, C. H., and Pitcher, T. J. 2005. Estimating illegal, unreport- BizAcumen. 2009. Fishing equipment—a market perspective. http:// ed and unregulated catch in British Columbia’s marine ï¬?sheries. www.bizacumen.com. Fisheries Research 75(1–3): 40–55. Braimah, L. I. 2008. “Assessment of the Inland Fisheries of Ghana Alfredsson, F. 2010. To the Boards of the Blue Swimming Crab for the Big Numbers Project.â€? Unpublished BNP working Councils in Indonesia—APRI—and in the Philippines—PACPI. document. Unpublished Internal PROFISH report. Agricultural and Rural Brouwer, R., I. H. Langford, I. J.. Bateman, T. C. Crowards and R. K. Development Department. Washington, DC: World Bank. Turner (1997), A Meta-Analysis of Wetland Contingent Valuation The Allen Consulting Group. 2004. The Economic Contribution of Studies. GEC Working Paper 97-20, CSERGE, University of East Australia’s Marine Industries, 1995–96 to 2002–03. Report to the Anglia and University College London. National Oceans Ofï¬?ce. Cai, J., Leung, P.-S., Pan, M., Pooley, S. G., Pelagic Fisheries Research Anderson, J. L., and Anderson, C. M. 2010. Fishery Performance Program, et al. 2005. Linkage of Fisheries Sectors to Hawaii’s Indicators. Prepared for the International Coalition of Fisheries Economy and Economic Impacts of Longline Fishing Regulations. Associations (ICFA) as part of the World Bank’s public/private Honolulu: University of Hawaii–NOAA Joint Institute for Marine partnership, Alliance for Responsible Fisheries. and Atmospheric Research. Andrew, N. L., Béné, C., Hall, S. J., Allison, E. H., Heck, S., and Catella, A. C. 2004. Reflexões sobre a pesca esportiva no Pantanal Ratner, B. D. 2007. Diagnosis and management of small-scale Sul: Crise e perspctivas. EMBRAPA/CPAP. http://www.agronline ï¬?sheries in developing countries. Fish and Fisheries 8(3): 227–40. .com.br/artigos/artigo.php?id=147. ASA (American Sportï¬?shing Association). 2002. “Sportï¬?shing Chuenpagdee, R., Liguori, L., Palomares, M. L. D., and Pauly, D. in America: Values of Our Traditional Pastime.â€? American 2006. “Bottom-Up, Global Estimates of Small-Scale Marine Sportï¬?shing Association. http://www.asaï¬?shing.org/images/ Fisheries Catches.â€? Fisheries Centre Research Reports 14(8). statistics/participation/sportï¬?shing_america/ï¬?sh_eco_impact.pdf. Vancouver: University of British Columbia. Bahiigwa, G., Mugambe, K., and Keizire, B. B. 2003. Fiscal Reforms Cisneros-Montemayor, A. M., and Sumaila, U. R. 2009. “A Global in Fisheries in Uganda. http://p15166578.pureserver.info/ilm/ Valuation of Ecosystem-Based Marine Recreation.â€? Working pa- docs/finance/Fiscal%20Reforms%20in%20Fisheries%20in% per # 2009-09. Vancouver: Fisheries Centre, University of British 20Uganda.pdf. Columbia. Bank of Namibia. 2007. Quarterly Report, September 2007, http:// Clucas, I. 1997. “A Study of the Options for Utilisation of Bycatch www.tradedirectory.com.na/documents/sbn5.pdf. and Discards from Marine Capture Fisheries.â€? FAO Fisheries Circular No C928. Rome: FAO. Banks, R. 2003. Business Plan for the Uganda Fisheries Authority. Entebbe: MAAIF. Coates, D. 1995. “Inland Capture Fisheries and Enhancement: Status, Constraints and Prospects for Food Security.â€? KC/FI/95/ Barnes, J. I., Zeybrandt, F., Kirchner, C., and Sakko, A. 2002. The TECH/3. Contribution to the International Conference on the Economic Value of Namibia’s Recreational Shore Fishery: Sustainable Contribution of Fisheries to Food Security, Kyoto, A Review. DEA Research Discussion Paper 50. Windhoek: Japan, December 4–9, 1995. Rome: FAO. Directorate of Environmental Affairs, Ministry of Environment and Tourism. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 48 BIBLIOGR A PH Y ———. 2002. Inland Capture Fishery Statistics of Southeast Asia: Canada. 2007. Survey of Recreational Fishing in Canada 2005. Current Status and Information Needs. RAP Publication No. Ottawa: Fisheries and Oceans Canada, Economic Analysis and 2002/11. Bangkok: Asia-Paciï¬?c Fishery Commission. Statistics, Policy. Cooke, S. J., and Cowx, I. G. 2004. “The Role of Recreational Eurostat. 2006. Statistics. http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/ Fisheries in Global Fish Crises.â€? Bioscience 54(9): 857–59. page/portal/statistics/search_database. ———. 2006. “Contrasting Recreational and Commercial Fishing: FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations). Searching for Common Issues to Promote Uniï¬?ed Conservation 1995a. Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries. Rome: of Fisheries Resources and Aquatic Environments.â€? Biological FAO. Conservation 228(1): 93–108. ———. 1995b. “The Coordinating Working Party on Fishery Cowx, I. G. 1998. “Aquatic Resource Management Planning for Statistics: Its Origin, Role and Structure.â€? FAO Fisheries Circular Resolution of Fisheries Management Issues.â€? In Recreational No. 903. Rome: FAO. Fisheries: Social, Economic and Management Aspects, P. Hickley ———. 1996. Technical Consultation on Reduction of Wastage in and H. Tompkins, eds. Oxford: Blackwell Science, pp. 97–105. Fisheries. Tokyo, October 28–November 1, 1996. FAO Fisheries Cowx I. G., Almeida, O., Béné, C., Brummett R., Bush S., Darwall Report No. 547. Rome: FAO. W., Pittock J., and van Brakel M. 2004. “Value of River Fisheries.â€? ———. 1999. “Numbers of Fishers 1970–1997.â€? FAO Fisheries In Proceedings of the Second International Symposium on the Circular No 929, Rev. 2. FAO Fisheries and Aquaculture Management of Large Rivers for Fisheries, Volume 1, RAP Department, Information and Statistics Service. Rome: FAO. Publication 2004/16. R. Welcomme and T. Petr, eds. Bangkok: FAO Regional Ofï¬?ce for Asia and the Paciï¬?c, pp. 1–20. ———. 2002. The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture 2002. Rome: FAO. De Young, C. (ed.). 2006. Review of the State of World Marine Capture Fisheries Management: Indian Ocean. FAO Fisheries ———. 2003. “Strategies for Increasing the Sustainable Contribution Technical Paper. No 488. Rome: FAO. fo Small-Scale Fisheries to Food Security and Poverty Alleviation.â€? Background paper No COFI/2003/9. Committee on Dean, J. 2007. “Economic Impact of Sportï¬?shing.â€? http:// Fisheries, 25th session, February 24–28. Rome: FAO. EzineArticles.com/?expert=Jeff_Dean. ———. 2004a. “Report on the Expert Consultation on Fishing Vessels Démé, M. 2008. “Revue sectorielle des statistiques de pêche et des Operating under Open Registries and Their Impact on Illegal, systèmes de collecte de l’information au Sénégal.â€? Unpublished Unreported and Unregulated Fishing.â€? Miami, Florida, September BNP working document. 23–25, 2003. FAO Fisheries Report No 722. Rome: FAO. DFO (Department of Fisheries and Oceans Canada). 2007. “Canadian ———. 2004b. Trends and Current Status of the Contribution of the Fisheries Statistics 2005.â€? Economic Analysis and Statistics. Forestry. Rome: FAO. Policy Sector. Ottawa, Ontario. http://www.dfo-mpo.gc.ca/com- munic/statistics/publications/commercial/cfs/2005/CFS2005_e ———. 2005. Increasing the Contribution of Small-Scale Fisheries to .pdf. Poverty Alleviation and Food Security. FAO Technical Guidelines for Responsible Fisheries, No. 10. Rome: FAO. ———. n.d. Statistical Services. Information and data from Department of Fisheries and Oceans Canada website. http:// ———. 2006. “Country Review Paper on Inland Capture Fisheries www.dfo-mpo.gc.ca. Information—Union of Myanmar. Addressing the Quality of Information in Inland Fisheries.â€? Prepared by National Consultant Drammeh, O. K. L. 2000. “Illegal, Unreported and Unregulated for AQUIIF and Department of Fisheries, Union of Myanmar. Fishing in Small-Scale Marine and Inland Capture Fisheries.â€? Field Document 9. FI: TCP/RAS/3013. Bangkok: FAO. Document AUS: IUU/2000/7. Report presented at the Expert Consultation on Illegal, Unreported and Unregulated Fishing, ———. 2007a. The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture 2006. Sydney, Australia, May 15–19. FAO Fisheries Report No. R666. Rome: FAO. Rome: FAO. ———. 2007b. Report of the Twenty-Seventh Session of the Dyck, A. J., and U. R. Sumaila. 2009. Contribution of Ocean Fish Committee on Fisheries. March 5–9. Rome: FAO. Populations to the World Economy. Vancouver: Fisheries Centre, ———. 2008a. “Capture Production 1950–2006.â€? FishStat Plus University of British Columbia. [online or CD-ROM]. Dataset: FAO Fisheries and Aquaculture EAA (European Anglers Alliance). 2003. Number of anglers in Europe. Department, Information and Statistics Service. Rome: FAO. Availabel on-line at: http://www.eaa-europe.org/index.php?id=14 http://www.fao.org/ï¬?/statist/FISOFT/FISHPLUS.asp. (Accessed 23 April 2012). ———. 2008b. The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture 2008. Eayrs, S. 2007. A Guide to Bycatch Reduction in Tropical Shrimp-Trawl Rome: FAO. Fisheries, Rev. ed. Rome: FAO. ———. 2009a. “Combating Illegal, Unreported and Unregulated EC (European Commission). 2009. GDP and Beyond. Measuring Fishing, including through a Legally Binding Instrument on Port Progress in a Changing World. Communication from the State Measures and the Establishment of a Global Record of Commission to the Council and the European Parliament. Fishing Vessels.â€? Committee on Fisheries, 28th Session. Rome, Brussels, 20.8.2009. COM(2009) 433 ï¬?nal. Luxembourg: Italy, March 2–6, 2009. Meeting document COFI/2009/6. ftp:// Publications Ofï¬?ce. ftp.fao.org/docrep/fao/meeting/015/k3898e.pdf. H ID D E N H A RV ES T BIBLIOGRAPHY 49 ———. 2009b. The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture: 2008. Fedler, A. J., and Hayes, C. 2008. “Economic Impact of Recreational Rome: FAO. http://www.fao.org/ï¬?shery/soï¬?a/en. Fishing for Boneï¬?sh, Permit and Tarpon in Belize for 2007.â€? Report prepared for the Teneffe Atoll Trust, Belize City. ———. 2011. Fishery Country Proï¬?les. http://www.fao.org/ï¬?shery/ countryproï¬?les/search. Finnish Game and Fisheries Research Institute. 2009. “Recreational Fishing 2008.â€? Riistaja kalatalous—Tilastoja 6/2009. Ofï¬?cial ———. n.d.(a) FishStat databases. http://www.fao.org/ï¬?shery/ Statistics of Finland—Agriculture, Forestry and Fishery. Helsinki: statistics/software/ï¬?shstat/en. Finnish Game and Fisheries Research Institute. ———. n.d.(b). Fisheries Glossary. http://www.fao.org/ï¬?/glossary/ Fisheries and Oceans Canada. 2005. “Survey of Recreational Fishing default.asp. in Canada 2005.â€? Economic Analysis and Statistics Policy Sector. ———. n.d.(c). Types of Fisheries. http://www.fao.org/ï¬?shery/ Fisheries and Oceans Canada. http://www.dfo-mpo.gc.ca/stats/ topic/14831/en. rec/can/2005/index-eng.htm. FAO/Advisory Committee on Fisheries Research. 2004. Report of the Franquesa, R., Gordoa, A., Mina, T., Nuss, S., and Borrego, J. R. 2004. Second Session of the Working Party on Small-Scale Fisheries. “The Recreational Fishing in the Central and Western European Bangkok, Thailand, November 18–21, 2003. FAO Fisheries Report Mediterranean Frame.â€? Gabinete de Economía del Mar, Universidad No. 735. Rome: FAO. de Barcelona and Centro de Estudios Avanzados de Blanes. FAO and WorldFish Center. 2009. Small-Scale Capture Fisheries—A FSN Forum. 2007. Glossary. Global Forum on Food Security and Global Overview with Emphasis on Developing Countries. Nutrition Policies and Strategies. http://km.fao.org/fsn/resourc- Prepared for World Bank, PROFISH. Penang: FAO and WorldFish. es/glossary.html. FAO/FAD (Fisheries and Aquaculture Department). 2009. The State Gallène, J. 1995. Data Compendium on Safety at Sea for Seven of World Fisheries and Aquaculture: 2008. FAO, Rome. West African Countries: Mauritania, Senegal, the Gambia, Guinea-Bissau, Guinea, Sierra-Leone and Cape Verde, 1991–94. FAO/FishCode-STF. 2008. Incremento del perfil de la pesca arte- Programme for Integrated Development of Artisanal Fisheries in sanal en las políticas nacionales de Nicaragua, Actas del taller West Africa (IDAF). Technical Report No 71. Danida and FAO. nacional INPESCA, INEDE, FENIPESCA, GRAAN, GRAAS, Rome: FAO. BICU, MARENA, SERENA. El manejo de los recursos acuáti- cos, la seguridad alimentaria y la pobreza en el sector arte- Garces, L. 2008. “Small-Scale Fisheries (Philippines).â€? Unpublished sanal de Nicaragua, FAO FishCode STF—OSPESCA, Programa BNP working document. FAO de Asociación de Países Bajos (FNPP) and Programa FAO Garcia, S. M., Allison, E. H., Andrew, N. J., Béné, C., Bianchi, G., de Noruega (FNOP), Managua, Nicaragua, 29–31 Enero 2008, Graaf, G. J., Kalikoski, D., Mahon, R., and Orensanz, J. M. 2008. Volume 1: Informe del Taller, FishCode-STF-NIC/WP2008/1. Towards Integrated Assessment and Advice in Small-Scale FAO/RAP. 2003. “Myanmar Aquaculture and Inland Fisheries.â€? FAO Fisheries: Principles and Processes. FAO Fisheries Technical Regional Ofï¬?ce for Asia and the Paciï¬?c (RAP). Bangkok, Thailand. Paper No. 515. Rome: FAO. http://www.fao.org/docrep/004/ad497e/ad497e00.htm. Garibaldi, L. 2007. “Summary on Inland Water Catch Statistics in ———. 2003. New Approaches for the Improvement of Inland European Countries and EIFAC Members.â€? Brieï¬?ng note on the Capture Fishery Statistics in the Mekong Basin. Ad-hoc Expert website of the European Inland Fisheries Advisory Commission Consultation. FAO Regional Ofï¬?ce for Asia and Paciï¬?c (RAP) pub- (EIFAC). ftp://ftp.fao.org/FI/DOCUMENT/eifac/summ_2007/ lication No. 2003/01. Bangkok: FAO. SummaryEIFACstats.pdf. FAO/RAP/FIPL. 2004. A Research Agenda for Small-Scale Fisheries. Gillett, R. 2009. Fisheries in the Economies of Paciï¬?c Island Countries FAO Regional Ofï¬?ce for Asia and the Paciï¬?c, Bangkok, Thailand. and Territories. Paciï¬?c Studies Series, Asian Development FAO Regional Ofï¬?ce for Asia and Paciï¬?c (RAP) publication No. Bank, World Bank, Forum Fisheries Agency, Secretariat of the 2004/21 and FIPL/C 10009 (En). Bangkok: FAO. Paciï¬?c Community, and Australian Agency for International Development. Mandaluyong City, Metro Manila, Philippines: FAO-FIES. 2008. (FAO Fisheries and Aquaculture Information and Asian Development Bank. Statistics Service). Food Balance Sheets. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome. Available on-line at: http:// Gillett, R., and C. Lightfoot (2002). The Contribution of Fisheries to faostat.fao.org/site/368/default.aspx#ancor (accessed 23 April the Economies of Paciï¬?c Island Countries. Paciï¬?c Studies Series, 2012). Asian Development Bank, World Bank, Forum Fisheries Agency, Secretariat of the Paciï¬?c Community. Mandaluyong City, Metro FAO-SEAFDEC. 2005. “Improvement of Fishery Data and Information Manila, Philippines: Asian Development Bank. Collection Systems in Southeast Asia.â€? In Proceedings of the FAO/SEAFDEC Regional Workshop on the Improvement Glasgow Caledonian University, Grid Economics, Cogent Research of Fishery Data and Information Collection Systems, Bali, International Ltd. 2009. Economic Impact of Recreational Sea Indonesia, February 15–18, 2005, Vol. 1: Report of the Workshop. Angling in Scotland: Technical Report. Edinburgh: Scottish FishCode-STF-WP2005/1. Government. FAP (Flood Action Plan) 17. 1994. “Fisheries Studies Draft Main Grifï¬?ths, M. H., and Lamberth, S. J. 2002. “Evaluating the Marine Report.â€? Dhaka: Flood Plan Coordination Organisation, Ministry Recreational Fishery in South Africa.â€? In Recreational Fisheries: of Irrigation, Water Development, and Flood Control (prepared Ecological, Economic and Social Evaluation, T. J. Pitcher and C. for Overseas Development Agency). E. Hollingsworth, eds. Oxford: Blackwell Science. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 50 BIBLIOGR A PH Y Gudmundsson, E., Asche, F., and Nielsen, M. 2006. “Revenue Kébé, M. 2008. “Reassessing the Economic and Social Contribution Distribution through the Seafood Value Chain.â€? FAO Fisheries of Fisheries in Developing Countries.â€? In Achieving Poverty Circular No. 1019 FIIU/C1019 (En). Rome: FAO. Reduction through Responsible Fisheries. Lessons from West and Central Africa, L. Westlund, K. Holvoet, and M. Kébé, eds. Henry, G. W., and Lyle, J. M. 2003. The National Recreational and Rome: FAO. Indigenous Fishing Survey. Project No. 1999/158. NSW Fisheries Final Report Series No. 48. ISSN 1440-3544. Cronulla, NSW: Kébé, M., and Tallec, F. 2006. Contribution of Fisheries to National NSW Fisheries. Economies. Rome: FAO. Hilge, V. 1998. “Data on Recreational Fisheries in the Federal Republic Kelleher, K. 2002. “Robbers, Reefers and Ramasseurs. A Review of Germany.â€? In Recreational Fisheries: Social, Economic, and of Selected Aspects of Fisheries MCS in Seven West African Management Aspects, P. H. Hickley and H. Tompkins, eds. Countries.â€? Prepared for the Sub-Regional Fisheries Commission. Malden, MA: Blackwell Science, pp 10–14. Project FAO/GCP/INT/722/LUX (AFR/013) July 2002. http:// www.imcsnet.org/imcs/docs/robbers_reefers_ramasseurs.pdf. Holvoet, K. 2009. “Mainstreaming Gender in Fisheries.â€? In Achieving Poverty Reduction through Responsible Fisheries: ———. 2005. Discards in the World’s Marine Fisheries. An Update. Strategies and Lessons from the West and Central Africa FAO Fisheries Technical Paper No 470. Rome: FAO. Sustainable Fisheries Livelihoods Programme, L. Westlund, K. ———. 2008. “International Trade, Small-Scale Fisheries and Food Holvoet, and M. Kébé, eds. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper No Security.â€? Keynote presentation to Global Conference on Small- 513. Rome: FAO. Scale Fisheries, Bangkok, October 2008. Hortle, K.G. 2007. Consumption and the Yield of Fish and Other Keskinen, M. 2003. “Socio-Economic Survey of the Tonle Sap Lake, Aquatic Animals from the Lower Mekong Basin. MRC Technical Cambodia.â€? Master’s thesis. Helsinki University of Technology. Paper No. 16, Mekong River Commission, Vientiane. http://www .mrcmekong.org. Kirchner, C. H., and Stage, J. 2005. “An Economic Comparison of the Commercial and Recreational Line Fisheries in Namibia.â€? IFREMER (French Research Institute for Exploration of the Sea) DEA Research Discussion Paper, Number 71. Directorate of (coord.). 2007. “Small-Scale Coastal Fisheries in Europe.â€? Final Environmental Affairs, Ministry of Environment and Tourism. report of the contract No. FISH/2005/10. http://archimer.ifremer Private Bag 13306, Windhoek, Namibia. .fr/doc/2007/rapport-6348.pdf. Kitts, A., Schneider, G., and Lent, R. 2008. “Carbon Footprint of IFREMER et BVA. 2009. Enquête relative à la pêche de loisir Commercial Fishing in the Northeast United States.â€? Paper pre- (récréative et sportive) en mer en Métropole et dans les DOM. sented at the International Institute of Fisheries Economics and Synthèse des résultats ï¬?naux. IFOP, IFREMER et Direction des Trade (IIFET) Conference in Vietnam. Pêches Maritimes et de l’Aquaculture, Ministère de l’Agriculture et de la Pêche. Avril 2009. Kleih, U., Alam, K., Dastidar, R., Dutta, U., Oudwater, N., and Ward, A. 2003. “Livelihoods in Coastal Fishing Communities and the Indecon (International Economic Consultants). 2003. An Economic/ Marine Fish Marketing System of Bangladesh, Synthesis of Socio-Economic Evaluation of Wild Salmon in Ireland. Dublin: Participatory Rural Appraisals in Six Villages, and Assessment Central Fisheries Board. of the Marketing System.â€? Report of Project Fish Distribution Isaksson, A., and Oskarsson, S. 2002. “Economic Value of from Coastal Communities—Market and Credit Access Issues. Icelandic Salmon (Salmo salar L.) in Angling and Net Fisheries.â€? Report No 2712, Project A1004, January. NRI (National Research Prepared for the Technical Workshop on Social and Economic Institute). http://www.nri.org/projects/ï¬?shtrade/issues-market- Values of Atlantic Salmon, NASCO. Directorate of Freshwater credit.pdf. Fisheries. Koeshendrajana, S., Adrianto, L., Trihartono, T. Anggraini, E., and Jacquet, J., and Pauly, D. 2008. “Funding Priorities: Big Barriers to Kura, Y. 2008. “Big Numbers Project Indonesia.â€? Unpublished Small-Scale Fisheries.â€? Conservation Biology 22(4): 832–35. BNP working document. Jensen, M. E., and Bourgeron, P. S. 2001. A Guidebook for Integrated Kohl, Dr. 2000. “Soziale und ökonomische Bedeutung der Ecological Assessments, 13th ed. New York: Springer. Angelï¬?scherei in Österreich.â€? Auftrag des ÖKF. Johnson, D. S. 2006. “Category, Narrative and Value in the Kurien, J. 2005. Responsible Fish Trade and Food Security. FAO Governance of Small-Scale Fisheries.â€? Marine Policy 30 (6): Fisheries Technical Paper No. 456. Rome: FAO. 747–56. ———. 2008. Big Numbers Project India (Marine). Unpublished BNP Jones, K., and Doonan, A. M. 2005. 2000–01 National Recreational working document. and Indigenous Fishing Survey: South Australian Regional Laurenti, G. (comp.). 2007. 1961–2003 Fish and Fishery Products: Information. Fisheries Management Series, Paper No. 46. World Apparent Consumption Statistics Based on Food Adelaide: Primary Industries and Resources SA. Balance Sheets. FAO Fisheries Circular No. i821, rev. 9. Rome: Kaplinsky, R. 2000. Spreading the Gains from Globalisation: What FAO. Can Be Learned from Value Chain Analysis? Brighton, UK: Le Rey, J.-M., Prado, J., and Tietze, U. 1999. Economic Viability of Institute of Development Studies. Marine Capture Fisheries. Findings of a Global Study and an Kaplinsky, R., and Morris, M. 2001. A Handbook of Value Chain Interregional Workshop. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper No 377. Research. Brighton, UK: Institute of Development Studies. Rome: FAO. H ID D E N H A RV ES T BIBLIOGRAPHY 51 Lem, A., and Nghia, N. 2002. “Economic Modeling and Fish Murray, C., and Shields, M. 2004. “Creel Analysis and Economic Consumption.â€? In Fish Marketing and Credit in Viet Nam, A. Lem Impact of Pennsylvania’s Lake Erie Tributary Fisheries in Erie and FAO, eds. Rome: FAO. pp. 123–34. County, Pennsylvania, with Special Emphasis on Landlocked Steelhead Trout (Oncorhynchus mykiss), October 1, 2003–April Leung, P. S., and S. Pooley. “Regional Economic Impacts of 30, 2004.â€? http://seagrant.psu.edu/publications/study_results/ Reductions in Fisheries Production: A Supply-Driven Approach.â€? SteelheadStudy.pdf Marine Resource Economics 16(2002): 251–62. Mustafa, M. G. 2008. Bangladesh Case study—Capture ï¬?sheries: cur- Lindquist, A. 1988. “The World’s Two Marine Fishing Industries— rent status of Bangladesh. Unpublished BNP working document. How They Compare.â€? NAGA, ICLARM Quarterly 11: 16–17. Myanmar Department of Fisheries. 2006. “Fisheries Statistics Lymer, D., Funge-Smith, S., Khemakorn, P., Naruepon, S., and 2005–2006.â€? Myanmar: Department of Fisheries. Ubolratana, S. 2008. “A Review and Synthesis of Capture Fisheries Data in Thailand. Large versus Small-Scale Fisheries.â€? Myanmar Fisheries Industry Directory website. Fisheries in Myanmar. RAP Publication 2008/17. FAO Regional Ofï¬?ce for Asia and the Myanmar Fisheries Federation, Department of Fisheries. http:// Paciï¬?c. www.myanmarï¬?sheriesindustry.com/ï¬?sheries-in-myanmar.htm. The Marine Institute. 2004. “A National Survey of Water-Based National Fisheries Development Board. 2007. About Indian Fisheries. Leisure Activities in Ireland 2003.â€? http://www.marine.ie/NR/ http://nfdb.org.in/html/aboutus.htm. rdonlyres/2A571A28-486D-4CA5-B697-7D796AD31AAA/0/ SurveyofWaterBasedLeisure.pdf. Nautilus Consultants Ltd. and EKOS Economic Consultants Ltd. 2000. “Study into Inland and Sea Fisheries in Wales.â€? Final Matsuoka, T. 1996. “Discards in Japanese Marine Capture Fisheries Report August 2000. Prepared for National Assembly for Wales. and Their Estimation.â€? In Report on the Technical Consultation http://www.nautilus-consultants.co.uk/pdfs/wales.pdf. on Reduction of Wastage in Fisheries, I. J. Clucas and D. James, eds. Rome, FAO, 1996. Nguyen, N., Bach, H., and Mills, D. 2008. “Big Numbers Project Vietnam Country Case Study.â€? Unpublished BNP working McGrath, M. D., Horner, C. C. M., Brouwer, S. L., Lamberth, S. document. J., Mann, B. Q., Sauer, W. H. H., and Erasmus, C. 1997. “An Economic Valuation of the South African Lineï¬?shery.â€? South Njock, J. C. 2007. “Projet Pilote Aménagement participatif des African Journal of Marine Science 18: 203–11. pêches en zone côtière au Congo, au Gabon, en Guinée et en Mauritanie.â€? Rapport Terminal, May 2005. Sustainable Fisheries Menezes, A. 2008. “Mozambique: Fishery Country Review—Big Livelihoods Programme (SFLP) Report. http://www.sflp.org. Number.â€? Unpublished BNP working document. NMFS (National Marine Fisheries Service). “Fisheries Economics of Mike, A., and Cowx, I. G. 1996. “A Preliminary Appraisal of the the U.S., 2006.â€? Department of Commerce, National Oceanic Contribution of Recreational Fishing to the Fisheries Sector in and Atmospheric Administration, National Marine Fisheries Northwest Trinidad.â€? Fisheries Management and Ecology 3(3): Service. http://www.st.nmfs.noaa.gov/st5/publication/ï¬?sheries_ 219–28. economics_2006.html. Mills, D. 2010. “Fisheries Hidden Harvests. Case Studies of Data NRC (National Research Council) Committee on Fishing Vessel Safety. Collection for Subsistence and Household-Level Fisheries.â€? 1991. “Fishing Vessels Safety: Blueprint for National Program.â€? WorldFish Center/PROFISH 2010, unpublished report. http://www.nap.edu/catalog.php?record_id=1622#orgs. Min, G. 2006. “Three Ways to Develop Recreational Fishing.â€? China ODI (Overseas Development Institute). 2002. Inland Fisheries. Key Fisheries Report (translation courtesy of J. Chu, PROFISH). http:// Sheets for Sustainable Livelihoods: Resource Management. www.chinabreed.com/ï¬?shery/develop/2006/05/2006053160863 http://www.odi.org.uk/Publications/keysheets.html. .shtml. OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development). Mitchell, C. L., Roger A. Stacey Consultants Ltd., Canada Dept. n.d. OECD.Stats. http://lysander.sourceoecd.org/vl=617597/ of Fisheries and Oceans. 2003. Canada’s Ocean Industries: cl=12/nw=1/rpsv/dotstat.htm. Contribution to the Economy, 1988–2000. Ottawa: Roger A. Stacey Consultants Ltd. http://www.dfo-mpo.gc.ca/communic/statistics/ Pauly, D. 2006. “Major Trends in Small-Scale Marine Fisheries, with oceans/economy/contribution/OCEAN%20INDUSTRIES%20 Emphasis on Developing Countries, and Some Implications for 1988%20-%202000%20FINAL%20Report%20-%20English.pdf. the Social Sciences.â€? MAST 2006 4(2):7–22. Mitchell, K., ACNielsen, and Blue Water Marine Research. n.d. “The Peterson, A. 2005. “1997 Hawaii Fishery Input-Output Model and Economic Contribution of New Zealand Recreational Billï¬?sh Methodology.â€? SOEST Publication 05-02, JIMAR Contribution Fishing.â€?http://bluewatermarine.co.nz/index.php?option=com_ 05-356. http://www.soest.hawaii.edu/PFRP/soest_jimar_rpts/ content&view=article&id=62:the-economic-contribution-of-new- peterson_input_output.pdf. zealand-recreational-billï¬?sh-ï¬?shing&catid=35:projects&Itemid=55. Pinfold, G. 2009. Economic Impact of Marine Related Activities in Moraes, A. S., and Seidl, A. F. 2000. “Perï¬?l dos pescadores es- Canada. Ottawa: Fisheries and Oceans Canada. portivos do sul do Pantanal. Corumbá: Embrapa Pantanal, 2000.â€? Pitcher, T. J., Watson, R., Forrest, R., Valtýsson, H., and Guénette, Embrapa Pantanal. Circular Técnica, 24. ISSN 1517-1965. S. 2002. “Estimating Illegal and Unreported Catches from Marine Ecosystems: A Basis for Change.â€? Fish and Fisheries 3(4): 317–39. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 52 BIBLIOGR A PH Y Pramod, G., Pitcher, T., Pearce, J., and Agnew, D. 2008. “Sources Southwick Associates. 2007. “Sportï¬?shing in America: An of Information Supporting Estimates of Unreported Fishery Economic Engine and Conservation Powerhouse.â€? Produced Catches (IUU) for 59 Countries and the High Seas.â€? Fisheries for the American Sportï¬?shing Association with funding from the Centre Research Reports 16(4). The Fisheries Centre, University Multistate Conservation Grant Program. of British Colombia, Canada. http://www.ï¬?sheries.ubc.ca/ Southwick Associates, Nelson Resources Consulting, and FIRMUS publications/reports/fcrr.php. Consulting. 2008. “Contribución económica de la pesca deporti- Radford, A., Riddington, G., and Gibson, H. 2009. Executive va a la economía de Los Cabos.â€? Fernandina Beach, FL, Oakland Summary: Economic Impact of Recreational Sea Angling in Park, FL, Ciudad de México. Scotland. Edinburgh: Scottish Government. Statistics Canada. 2005. “Vista on the Agri-Food Industry and the Roth, E., and Jensen, S. 2003. “Impact of Recreational Fishery on Farm Community.â€? Catalogue no. 21-004-XIE. http://www.stat- the Formal Danish Economy, October 2003.â€? IME Working Paper can.gc.ca/pub/21-004-x/21-004-x2005005-eng.pdf. 48/03. Department of Environmental and Business Economics. Statistics New Zealand. “New Zealand’s Marine Economy 1997 University of Southern Denmark, Esbjerg. to 2002. An Experimental Series Report by Statistics.â€? http:// Rudd, M. A., Folmer, H., and van Kooten, G. C. 2002. “Economic www.stats.govt.nz/NR/rdonlyres/531099BF-67DC-42C2-A6A8- Evaluation of Recreational Fishery Policies.â€? In Recreational 7723F3A0D33D/0/NewZealandMarineEconomy19972002.pdf. Fisheries: Ecological, and Economic, and Social Evaluation, T. J. Statistics Norway. 2008. NOS D 404: Fishery Statistics 2006. http:// Pitcher and C. E. Hollingsworth, eds. Oxford: Blackwell Science. www.ssb.no/english/subjects/10/05/nos_ï¬?skeri_en/. Salz, P., Buisman, E., Smit, J., and de Vos, B. 2006. “Employment STECF-SGECA. 2008. “Annual Economic Report 2008, European in the Fisheries Sector: Current Situation, Final report.â€? Commission. Scientiï¬?c, Technical and Economic Committee FISH/2004/4. LEI BV. Framian BV. European Commission. for Fisheries (STECF), Subgroup on Economic Assessment Seaï¬?sh. 2007. “The Economic Impacts of the UK Sea Fishing and (SGECA), 02-08. Copenhagen, Denmark, April 21–25. Fish Processing Sectors: An Input-Output Analysis.â€? Final report Steinback, S., Gentner, B., and Castle, J. 2004. “The Economic March 2007. Project sponsored by Seaï¬?sh, SEERAD, Defra, Importance of Marine Angler Expenditures in the U.S.â€? U.S. DARDNI, and the Welsh Assembly. http://www.seaï¬?sh.org/ Department of Commerce. NOAA Prof. Paper NMFS 2. upload/file/economics/FINAL-%20Input%20output%20 report%20%20,full%20report.pdf. Storey, D. A., and Allen, P. G. 1993. “Economic Impact of Marine Recreational Fishing in Massachusetts.â€? North American Journal Seung, C. K., and Waters, E. C. 2006. “A Review of Regional of Fisheries Management 13(4):698–708. Economic Models for Fisheries Management in the U.S.â€? Marine Resource Economics 21(1): 101. Sugiyama, S., Staples, D., and Funge-Smith, S. 2004. Status and Potential of Fisheries and Aquaculture in Asia and the Paciï¬?c. Bangkok: FAO. Shams, N. 2007. “Contribution of Rice Field Ecosystems to Food Security Strategies in Northwest Cambodia.â€? Journal of Sutinen, J. G., and Johnston, R. J. 2003. “Angling Management Sustainable Agriculture 29:4, 109–133. Organizations: Integrating the Recreational Sector into Fishery Management.â€? Marine Policy 27(6): 471–87. Shrestha, R. K., Seidl, A. F., and Moraes, A. S. 2002. “Value of Recreational Fishing in the Brazilian Pantanal: A Travel Cost TCW Economics. 2008. Economic Analysis of the Non-Treaty Analysis Using Count Data Models.â€? Ecological Economics 42 Commercial and Recreational Fisheries in Washington State. (1/2): 289–99. Olympia: Washington Department of Fish and Wildlife. Sjorslev, J. G. (ed.). 2000. “Fisheries Survey Luangprabang Province, Thomson, D. 1980. “Conflict within the Fishing Industry.â€? ICLARM Lao PDR.â€? Vientiane: AMFC/MRC and LARReC/NAFRI. http://ns1 Newsletter3: 3–4. .mrcmekong.org/download/programmes/ï¬?sheries/LP-report.pdf. Thuok, N., Somany, P., Kao, S., and Thomson, D. 2008. Big Numbers Smit, J., and Taal, C. 2007. Socio-economic Indicators of the Dutch Project—Cambodia: Fishery Country Review. Unpublished BNP Fisheries Sector.â€? Report no. 5.07.07. The Hague: LEI. working document. Smit, M., de Vos, B., and de Wilde, J. W. 2004. “De economische Tietze, U., Prado, J., Le Rey, J.-M., and Lasch, R. 2001. Techno- betekenis van de sportvisserij in Nederland.â€? Project code economic Performance of Marine Capture Fisheries. FAO 30123. Rapport 2.04.05. The Hague: LEI. Fisheries Technical Paper No 421.Rome: FAO. Soe, K.M. 2008. “Trends of Development of Myanmar Fisheries: Tietze, U., Thiele, W., Lasch, R., Thomsen, B., and Rihan, D. 2005. With Reference to Japanese Experiences.â€? V.R.F. Series No Economic Performance and Fishing Efï¬?ciency of Marine Capture 433. February 2008. Institute of Developing Economies Japan Fisheries. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper No 482. Rome: FAO. External Trade Organization. http://www.ide.go.jp/English/ Publish/Download/Vrf/pdf/433.pdf. Toivonen, A.-L., Roth E., Navrud S., Gudbergsson, G., Appelblad, H., Bengtsson, B., and Tuunainen, P. 2004. “The Economic South Australian Fisheries Management Series. “National Recreational Value of Recreational Fisheries in Nordic Countries.â€? Fisheries and Indigenous Fishing Survey.â€? Paper No. 46. 2000–01 South Management & Ecology 11(1):1–14. Australian Information. ISBN 0 7590 1362 4, ISSN 1322-8072. Tyedmers, P. H. 2004. “Fisheries and Energy Use.â€? In Encyclopedia Southwick Associates. 2006. “The Relative Economic Contributions of Energy, Vol. 2, C. J. Cleveland and R. U. Ayres, eds. Boston: of U.S. Recreational and Commercial Fisheries.â€? Prepared for Elsevier, pp. 683–93. the Theodore Roosevelt Conservation Partnership. H ID D E N H A RV ES T BIBLIOGRAPHY 53 Tyedmers, P. H., Watson, R., and Pauly, D. 2005. “Fueling Global Westlund, L. 2009a. “More Than Credit: Synergies between Fishing Fleets.â€? Ambio 34(8): 635–38. Microï¬?nance Service Delivery, Capacity Building and Livelihoods Diversiï¬?cation.â€? In Achieving Poverty Reduction through UN (United Nations). Handbook of National Accounting. New York: Responsible Fisheries: Strategies and Lessons from the West United Nations. and Central Africa Sustainable Fisheries Livelihoods Programme, ———. 2008. “International Standard Industrial Classiï¬?cation of All L. Westlund, K. Holvoet, and M. Kébé, eds. FAO Fisheries Economic Activities (ISIC) (Statistical Papers).â€? Department of Technical Paper No 513. Rome: FAO. Economic and Social Affairs. Statistics Division. ———. 2009b. “Rescaling the Contribution of Capture Fisheries. An UN Economic and Social Council. 2010. “Global Strategy to Improve Overview with a Focus on Developing Country Case Studies.â€? Agricultural and Rural Statistics.â€? Report of the Friends of the Unpublished report prepared for PROFISH in collaborations with Chair on Agricultural Statistics. Statistical Commission, Forty- FAO and WorldFish Center. ï¬?rst Session, February 23–26. Westlund, L., Poulain, F., Bage, H., and van Anrooy, R. 2007. Disaster UN and FAO 2004. “Integrated Environmental and Economic Response and Risk Management in the Fisheries Sector. FAO Accounting for Fisheries.â€? Studies in Methods Handbook of Fisheries Technical Paper No. 479. Rome: FAO. National Accounting. http://unstats.un.org/unsd/envaccounting/ Wilson, J. D. K. 2004. Fiscal Arrangements in the Tanzanian Fisheries Fish_ï¬?nal_whitecover. Sector. FAO Fisheries Circular No. 1000. Rome: Food and UN Statistics Division. 1993. System of National Accounts 1993 Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. http://www.fao (SNA93). http://unstats.un.org/unsd/nationalaccount/sna.asp. .org/docrep/007/j2760e/j2760e00.htm#Contents. U.S. BEA (U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis). 2008. “Regional World Bank. 2011. World development indicators. World Bank, Input-Output Modeling System (RIMS II).â€? https://www.bea.gov/ Washington, DC. regional/rims/update.cfm. World Bank and FAO. 2009 The Sunken Billions? The Economic Van der Knaap, M. 2008. “Key Issues to Secure Small-Scale Fisheries Justiï¬?cation for Fisheries Reform. Washington, DC: World Bank/ and Enhance Their Contribution to Food Security, Poverty Rome: FAO. Alleviation and Sustainable Development: The Lake Victoria Case World Bank, FAO, and IFAD. 2007. “Gender in Fisheries and Study.â€? Unpublished BNP working document. Aquaculture.â€? Module 13, Gender in Agriculture Sourcebook. Van Marlen, B. (Ed.), 2008. Energy Saving in Fisheries (ESIF) Agriculture and Rural Development Department of the World FISH/2006/17 LOT3–Final Report. IMARES Report number Bank, UN Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO), and C002/08. International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD). http:// www.worldbank.org/genderinag. Velasco Canziani, G. 2008. “Global Big Numbers Project—Report for Brazil.â€? Unpublished BNP working document. Xie, Yingliang. 2008. “A Draft Report on BNP in China.â€? Unpublished BNP working document. Virtanen, J., Setala, J., Saarni, K., and Honkanen, A. 2003. “Multiplicative Effects of the Fishery Industries in Finland: An Yaron, G., and Moyini, Y., with Wasike D., Kabi, M., and Barungi, Input-Output Approach.â€? Finnish Game and Fisheries Research M. 2004. “The Role of Environment in Increasing Growth and Institute. In Proceedings of the XV EAFE Conference, Brest, May Reducing Poverty in Uganda. Technical Report: Final.â€? http:// 2003. www.dï¬?d.gov.uk/r4d/PDF/Outputs/Misc_Env/uganda_environ- ment_ï¬?nal.pdf. Vivekanandan, V. 2009. “Big Numbers Project Report—India (Inland).â€? Unpublished BNP working document. Zeller, D., Booth, S., and Pauly, D. “Fisheries Contributions to GDP: Underestimating Small-scale Fisheries in the Paciï¬?c.â€? Marine Walfoort, D. 2008. “Big Numbers Project—Myanmar.â€? Unpublished Resource Economics 21(4): 355–74. BNP working document. Wedekind, H., Hilge, V., and Steffens, W. 2001. “Present Status, and Social and Economic Signiï¬?cance of Inland Fisheries in Germany.â€? Fisheries Management and Ecology 8(4–5) 405–14. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK ANN E X — D ATA S OURCE S AND NOT E S F OR GDP CA LCULATIONS 55 Annex: DATA SOURCES AND NOTES FOR GDP CALCULATIONS A.1 NOTES ON DATA SOURCES provides ï¬?sheries GDP ï¬?gures for the member countries, but it does not provide the method of calculating GDP in Africa Caribbean Paciï¬?c and Other Developing Countries detail. For some countries, the data are quite old (early GDP data were collected from the 17 developing country 1990s). case study coordinators via email, and information was A.1.1 Asia and Paciï¬?c compiled from existing secondary sources, complemented Bangladesh, China, Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Lao PDR, where possible by primary data collection or review. In some Thailand, Vietnam. A report by Sugiyama et al. (2004) contains cases (such as Thailand and Vietnam), catch information was crude estimation of capture production values and aquaculture cross-checked and recalibrated by analysis of household con- values as percentage of GDP. GDP values in 2001 calculated sumption surveys. Fisheries GDP data were available for the from the ESCAP ofï¬?cial statistics except Taiwan POC. The data of some states are from 2000. The report noted that “the data following countries: to quantify the value of capture production is not readily avail- able for many States. As indicative ï¬?gures, unit value of 0.8 Maldives. Source: U.S. Department of State, Country US$ per kg was applied for this estimation of capture produc- Background Notes. The ï¬?sheries industry, including tion value.â€? ï¬?sh processing, traditionally contributes about 7 per- Cambodia. Assumptions were made for production/postharvest cent of GDP, but it was only about 5 percent in 2007 breakdown on the basis of government ofï¬?cial ï¬?gures of 10 because of a drastic drop in the ï¬?sh catch. The web- percent ï¬?sheries GDP (capture, 5.85 percent; postharvest, 3.74 site does not provide the data sources and method percent; and the rest is aquaculture). Value added for posthar- vest includes smoking, drying, and making ï¬?sh sauce and naim used. http://www.state.gov/r/pa/ei/bgn/5476.htm. pickled ï¬?sh (Thompson 1980). Namibia. Source: Bank of Namibia Quarterly Report, China. Data from the Chinese Fisheries Yearbook for 2004. September 2007, http://www.tradedirectory.com The capture fisheries value accounted for about 1 percent .na/documents/sbn5.pdf. The table provides GDP by of overall national GDP. The total value of capture fisheries economic activities in 1995, including “ï¬?shing and and aquaculture accounted for about 2.4 percent of overall ï¬?sh processing on boardâ€? and “ï¬?shing processing national GDP. The total value of capture fisheries, aquacul- ture, aquatic products processing, boatbuilding, and fishery on shoreâ€? but does not provide methodology or data industry accounted for about 3 percent of the overall national sources. GDP (Xie 2008). Seychelles. Source: Seychelles Strategy 2007 Japan. Data from the Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries, (K. Kelleher/X. Vincent, personal communication). http://www.maff.go.jp/j/tokei/sihyo/index.html. Tanzania. Source: Wilson 2004. The ï¬?sheries contribu- Vietnam. Data from World Bank 2005, http://siteresources.world- tion to GDP was obtained from the Bank of Tanzania, bank.org/INTVIETNAM/Resources/vn_fisheries-report-final Economic Operations Report 2001. No detail is .pdf. provided on how GDP was calculated. http://www.fao Canada. GDP contributions of Canadian ï¬?shing industry was divided .org/docrep/007/j2760e/j2760e00.htm#Contents. into two groups: (1) primary ï¬?sheries and mariculture and (2) pro- cessing. In addition, the contribution of the ocean transport indus- Uganda. Source: Banks (2003), cited in Bahiigwa, try (including marine shipping, ship- and boat-building and repair), Mugambe, and Keizire 2003. ocean tourism industry (recreational ï¬?shing, coastal and cruise ship tourism), marine construction industry, ocean manufacturing The Caribbean Regional Fisheries Mechanism’s website and service industry, and government services in marine were (http://www.caricom-ï¬?sheries.com/members/antigua.asp) calculated separately (Roger A. Stacey Consultants 1998). EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 56 A NNEX — D ATA SOUR C ES A ND NOTES FOR GD P CA LC ULATIONS Statistics New Zealand. The Fish Monetary Stock Account 1996–2009. Employment in ï¬?sh processing is from Eurostat, data 2006. (http://www.stats.govt.nz/browse_for_stats/environment/natural_ Employment is in full-time equivalents. resources/ï¬?sh-monetary-stock-account-1996-2009.aspx accessed GDP and euro-dollar exchange rate is from Eurostat, data 2006. February 2010). Contribution to GDP is related only to income created by the McDermott Fairgray Group Ltd. 2000. The New Zealand Seafood catching subsector. Industry Council Economic Impact Assessment for New Zealand Fuel prices are from van Marlen (2008). Regions. May 2000. See http://www.seafood.co.nz/f420, 21397/21397_Economic_Impact_Assessment_NZ_Regions.pdf France. Inland ï¬?sheries data are from European Fisheries Fund. ADD accessed March 2010. National Strategic Programme 2007–2013. Denmark. Data are from Statistics Denmark, http://www.statistikbank- A.1.2 Europe en.dk/statbank5a/default.asp?w=1280. Inland ï¬?sheries information Production and processing values were compiled mainly from via personal communication from Institute of Food and Resource Eurostat data in 2006. Eurostat has data for value added for Economics, and catch for nonhuman uses information from Danish “Processing and preserving of ï¬?sh and ï¬?sh productsâ€? for EU Ministry of Agriculture and Fisheries Yearbook 2006, p. 59. countries. Data do not include marketing and postharvest activi- Netherlands. Processing data are from Smit and Taal (2007). ties other than processing. Scotland. Data are from the Scottish Government, http://www EU fleet performance and employment (except Spain), data 2006, .scotland.gov.uk/Publications/2004/03/19079/34369. from STECF-SGECA (2008), Annual Economic Report 2008, Copenhagen, April 21–25, 2008. Employment is in full-time Iceland. Data are from Central Bank of Iceland 2008. The economy equivalents, including self-employed. of Iceland. Available at: http://www.sedlabanki.is/lisalib/getï¬?le. aspx?itemid=6372 and Agnarsson, S., and Ã?rnason, R. 2003. Spanish data on fleet performance, data 2006 (value and vol- The Role of the Fishing Industry in the Icelandic Economy: A ume of catch, value added and employment), from MAPYA Historical Examination. http://www.ioes.hi.is/publications/wp/ (Ministerio de Agricultura, Pesca y Alimentación), Indicadores w0307.pdf. The reports show ï¬?shing and ï¬?sh processing ac- económicos de pesca marítima, Principales resultados, count for 7 percent of GDP. Ejercicio 2006. Aquaculture employment data for 2005–06 is from Salz et al. (2008). Review of the EU Aquaculture Subsector, Draft Final Report (un- der preparation), Project Deï¬?nition of Data Collection Needs for Aquaculture (FISH/2006/15 lot 6). Employment is in employed persons, including self-employed (not in full-time equivalents). H ID D E N H A RV ES T ANN E X — D ATA S OURCE S AND NOT E S F OR GDP CA LCULATIONS 57 TABLE A.1: Postharvest Share of Fisheries GDP for 21 Sample Countries POSTHARVEST POSTHARVEST COUNTRY FISHING GDP % GDP % FISHERIES GDP % SHARE % YEAR SOURCE Benin 1.76 1.24 3.00 41.3 2002 Kébé and Tallec 2006 Burkina Faso 0.20 0.10 0.30 33.3 2002 Kébé and Tallec 2006 Cambodia 10.00 6.00 16.00 37.5 2003 Thomson 1980 Cameroon 0.90 0.80 1.70 47.1 2002 Kébé & Tallec 2006 Canada 0.16 0.12 0.28 42.9 2000 Roger A. Stacey Consultants 2003 Cape Verde 1.28 2.66 3.94 67.5 2002 Kébé and Tallec 2006 Congo, Republic of 1.39 1.36 2.75 49.5 2003 FAO 2008b Côte d’Ivoire 0.76 0.76 1.52 50.0 2002 Kébé and Tallec 2006 Denmark 0.13 0.22 0.35 62.3 2005 Statistics Denmark Finland 0.10 0.02 0.12 16.7 2000 Eurostat (Pavel Salz) France 0.07 0.04 0.11 36.4 2003? Westlund 2009b and personal communication January 2010. Gabon 0.76 0.75 1.51 49.5 2002 Kébé and Tallec 2006 Gambia 1.75 3.95 5.70 69.3 2002 Kébé and Tallec 2006 Ghana 8.00 1.70 9.70 17.5 2006 Eurostat 2006 Iceland 5.00 2.00 7.00 28.6 2007 Hall, Heidarsson, and Saevaldsson, no date Namibia 2.97 0.83 3.80 21.8 2006 Bank of Namibia Quarterly Report September 2007 Sao Tome and 5.20 0.60 5.80 10.3 2002? FAO 2008b Principe Senegal 1.81 2.29 4.10 55.9 2003 FAO 2008b Sweden 0.02 0.03 0.06 57.1 n.a. Westlund 2009b and personal communication January 2010. Uganda 3.00 9.00 12.00 75.0 2002 Banks 2003 United States 0.30 0.27 0.57 47.4 2006 unstat.org Notes: Kébé and Tallec (2006) includes marketing, processing, handling, sale and repair of canoes, etc. Roger A. Stacey Consultants 2003 includes aquaculture. Eurostat (2006) includes processing but excludes marketing and other post-harvest activities. Hall, Heidarsson, and Saevaldsson (no date) includes both ï¬?shing and ï¬?sh processing. Banks (2003) includes trade sector. Ofï¬?cial ï¬?gure of 2.4 percent is assumed undervalued. Westlund 2009b and personal communication January 2010. TABLE A.2: Calculation of Mean and Median Extended Fisheries Sector GDPs Based on 128 Countries EXTENDED FISHERIES GDP EXTENDED FISHERIES GDP FISHING GDP % NATIONAL (BASED ON MEDIAN FISHING GDP) (BASED ON MEAN FISHING GDP) MEDIAN MEAN MEDIAN MEAN 128 countries 1.29% 2.64% 2.20% 4.49% Developed 0.19% 0.46% — — Developing 1.79% 3.23% — — EXTENDED FISHERIES GDP (mUSD) EXTENDED FISHERIES GDP (mUSD) TOTAL GDP (mUSD) MEDIAN MEAN 128 countries 43,254,750 950,404 1,942,179 Developed 32,323,881 710,228 1,451,373 Developing 10,930,869 240,176 490,806 Source: Authors, based on data from Table A.3. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 58 A NNEX — D ATA SOUR C ES A ND NOTES FOR GD P CA LC ULATIONS TABLE A.3: Base Data and Data Sources Used to Estimate Extended Fisheries Sector GDP FISHING GDP POSTHARVEST FISHERIES AQUACULTURE COMMENT ON FISHERIES COUNTRY (MILLION USD) GDP GDP INCLUDED GDP CALCULATION YEAR SOURCE American Samoa 0.23 n.a. n.a. 0.47 Commercial and subsistence ï¬?sh- 2007 Gillett 2009 ing, aquaculture Angola 3.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2006 SIFP 2008 calculated Anguilla 2.60 n.a. n.a. n.a. ? Lovell, T. 2008 Antigua and 1.48 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2003 CRFM Barbuda calculated websitea Bahamas 1.40 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2004 CRFM calculated website Bangladesh 3.92 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2009 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Barbados 1.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2002 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Belgium 0.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. Share in the national GDP and 2003 FAO Country contribution to employment almost Proï¬?le negligible Belize 2.80 n.a. n.a. 2.20 Includes aquaculture; unclear 2003 FAO Country whether processing, etc., is Proï¬?le included Benin 1.76 1.24 3.00 n.a. Includes marketing, processing, 2002 Kébé and handling, sale and repair of canoes, Tallec 2006 etc. Botswana 0.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2002 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Brazil 0.40 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2000 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le British Virgin 0.70 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. Lovell, T. Islands 2008 Burkina Faso 0.20 0.10 0.30 n.a. Includes marketing, processing, 2002 Kébé and handling, sale and repair of canoes, Tallec 2006 etc. Burundi 1.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. GDP contribution of 1% based on 2003 FAO Country ï¬?sh production only Proï¬?le Cambodia 10.00 6.00 16.00 n.a. 2003 Thomson 1980 Cameroon 0.90 0.80 1.70 n.a. Includes marketing, processing, 2002 Kébé and handling, sale and repair of canoes, Tallec 2006 etc. Canada 0.16 0.12 0.28 0.05 Includes aquaculture 2000 Roger A. Stacey Consultants 2003 Cape Verde 1.28 2.66 3.94 n.a. Includes marketing, processing, 2002 Kébé and handling, sale and repair of canoes, Tallec 2006 etc. Chad 1.30 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2002 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le China 2.40 n.a. n.a. n.a. GDP share based on gross value of 2004 FAO Country ï¬?sheries output Proï¬?le Chile 1.50 n.a. n.a. n.a. 1998 FAO Country Proï¬?le H ID D E N H A RV ES T ANN E X — D ATA S OURCE S AND NOT E S F OR GDP CA LCULATIONS 59 TABLE A.3: Base Data and Data Sources Used to Estimate Extended Fisheries Sector GDP (continued) FISHING GDP POSTHARVEST FISHERIES AQUACULTURE COMMENT ON FISHERIES COUNTRY (MILLION USD) GDP GDP INCLUDED GDP CALCULATION YEAR SOURCE Comoros 15.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. Gross value of ï¬?sheries output as ? SWIOFC % of GDP 2006b Congo, Republic of 1.39 1.36 2.75 n.a. SFLP method (see note) 2003? FAO 2008b Cook Islands 4.16 n.a. n.a. 2.14 Commercial and subsistence ï¬?sh- 2007 Gillett 2009 ing, aquaculture Costa Rica 0.32 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2002 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Côte d’Ivoire 0.76 0.76 1.52 n.a. Includes marketing, processing, 2002 Kébé and handling, sale and repair of canoes, Tallec 2006 etc. Croatia 0.23 n.a. n.a. n.a. Catch value only 2004 FAO Country Proï¬?le Cyprus 0.24 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2004 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Czech Republic 0.03 n.a. n.a. n.a. The role of ï¬?sheries is rather 2004 FAO Country marginal. No detail on how GDP Proï¬?le was calculated Denmark 0.13 0.22 0.35 n.a. n.a. 2005 Statistics Denmarka Djibouti 0.10 n.a. n.a. n.a. Contribution of ï¬?sheries to GDP 2001? FAO Country less than 0.1% Proï¬?le Dominica 1.77 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 1994 CRFM calculated website Dominican 0.01 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2005 FAO Country Republic calculated Proï¬?le Eritrea 2.30 n.a. n.a. n.a. GDP contribution includes value of 2002 WB 2004; production only Fisheries ESWc Ethiopia 0.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. Contribution of ï¬?sheries to GDP is 2001 FAO Country marginal Proï¬?le Fiji Islands 1.38 n.a. n.a. 0.02 Commercial and subsistence ï¬?sh- 2007 Gillett 2009 ing, aquaculture Finland 0.10 0.02 n.a. n.a. n.a. 2000 Eurostat 2006 France 0.07 0.04 n.a. n.a. n.a. 2003? Westlund personal communica- tion February 2010. French Polynesia 1.10 n.a. n.a. n.a. SFLP method (see note) 2001 SFLP Gabon 0.76 0.75 1.51 n.a. Includes marketing, processing, 2002 Kébé and handling, sale and repair of canoes, Tallec 2006 etc. Gambia 1.75 3.95 5.70 n.a. Includes marketing, processing, 2002 Kébé and handling, sale and repair of canoes, Tallec 2006 etc. Georgia 1.10 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2003 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Germany 0.02 0.02 0.04 n.a. Value of ï¬?shery production only 2005 Eurostat 2006 Ghana 8.00 1.70 9.70 n.a. Processing included; marketing 2006 Eurostat 2006 and other postharvest activities excluded EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 60 A NNEX — D ATA SOUR C ES A ND NOTES FOR GD P CA LC ULATIONS TABLE A.3: Base Data and Data Sources Used to Estimate Extended Fisheries Sector GDP (continued) FISHING GDP POSTHARVEST FISHERIES AQUACULTURE COMMENT ON FISHERIES COUNTRY (MILLION USD) GDP GDP INCLUDED GDP CALCULATION YEAR SOURCE Greece 0.35 0.07 0.42 n.a. Value of primary production only; 2003 FAO Country 0.42% from Eurostat (2006) Proï¬?le Grenada 1.83 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 1994 CRFM calculated website Guinea 1.80 n.a. n.a. n.a. Includes marketing, processing, 2002 Kébé and handling, sale and repair of canoes, Tallec 2006 etc. Guinea Bissau 3.70 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 1999 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Guyana 2.80 n.a. n.a. n.a. Primary (harvest) subsector only 2004 FAO Country Proï¬?le Haiti 2.50 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was ? UNLOS 2008 calculated Iceland 5.00 2.00 7.00 n.a. Includes both ï¬?shing and ï¬?sh 2007 Hall, processing Heidarsson, and Saevaldsson, no date India 1.07 n.a. n.a. n.a. GDP based on price of ï¬?sh in 2003–04 FAO Country 2003–04 Proï¬?le Indonesia 2.40 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2004 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Iran, Islamic 0.23 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2002 FAO Country Republic of calculated Proï¬?le Israel 0.06 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2005 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Italy 0.10 n.a. n.a. n.a. Processing included; marketing Eurostat 2006 and other postharvest activities excluded Jamaica 0.50 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2003? FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Japan 0.13 n.a. n.a. 0.07 Value of ï¬?sheries production only. 2006 MAFF 2010 Includes aquaculture Jordan 0.01 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2001–02 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Kenya 0.50 n.a. n.a. n.a. Production only; value added from 2005 FAO Country various supply chains excluded Proï¬?le Kiribati 21.5 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 2000 FAO Country Proï¬?leb Korea, Republic of 1.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2000 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Kyrgyzstan 1.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2006 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Laos 6.80 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2005 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Latvia 1.15 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2003 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Lesotho 0.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. Currently no signiï¬?cant economic 2007 FAO Country role Proï¬?le Liberia 4.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2005 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le H ID D E N H A RV ES T ANN E X — D ATA S OURCE S AND NOT E S F OR GDP CA LCULATIONS 61 TABLE A.3: Base Data and Data Sources Used to Estimate Extended Fisheries Sector GDP (continued) FISHING GDP POSTHARVEST FISHERIES AQUACULTURE COMMENT ON FISHERIES COUNTRY (MILLION USD) GDP GDP INCLUDED GDP CALCULATION YEAR SOURCE Madagascar 5.46 n.a. n.a. 1.54 Includes aquaculture. Unclear 2006? FAO Country whether processing and marketing Proï¬?le is included Malawi 4.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2003 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Malaysia 1.73 n.a. n.a. n.a. GDP based on total value of ï¬?sh 2004 FAO Country landings in 2004 Proï¬?le Maldives 4.50 n.a. n.a. n.a. Includes ï¬?sh processing 2007 Global Edge 2010 Mali 4.50 n.a. n.a. n.a. SFLP method (see note) 2002? FAO 2008b Malta 0.16 n.a. n.a. n.a. Catch value only 2004 FAO Country Proï¬?le Marshall Islands 26.65 n.a. n.a. 0.05 Commercial and subsistence ï¬?sh- 2007 Gillett 2009 ing, aquaculture Mauritania 4.50 n.a. n.a. n.a. SFLP method (see note) 2006? FAO 2008b Mauritius 1.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2004 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Mexico 0.80 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2001 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Micronesia, 9.53 2.23 11.76 0.01 Commercial and subsistence ï¬?sh- 2006 Gillett 2009 Federal States of ing, aquaculture Morocco 2.50 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2005 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Mozambique 4.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2006 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Namibia 2.97 0.83 3.80 n.a. n.a. 2006 Bank of Namibia Qu. Rep. 2007c Netherlands 0.07 n.a. n.a. n.a. Processing included, but marketing 2006 Eurostat 2006 and other postharvest not included New Zealand 0.25 n.a. n.a. n.a. Includes manufacturing; excludes 2006 MAF 2006 downstream Nigeria 1.55 n.a. n.a. n.a. Capture and aquaculture production 2000–05 FAO Country value only (2000–05 average) Proï¬?le Norway 0.30 n.a. n.a. 0.10 Fishing and farming of all com- 2008 Statistics mercial ï¬?shing for ï¬?sh, sharks, Norway 2008 mollusks, and crustaceans Oman 0.60 n.a. n.a. n.a. GDP based on total value of ï¬?sh 2005 FAO Country landings in 2004 Proï¬?le Palau 6.08 n.a. n.a. 0.02 Commercial and subsistence ï¬?sh- 2006 Gillett 2009 ing, aquaculture Papua New 3.09 n.a. n.a. 0.01 Commercial and subsistence ï¬?sh- 2006 Gillett 2009 Guinea ing, aquaculture Peru 1.98 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2002 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Philippines 2.20 n.a. n.a. n.a. GDP based on total value of ï¬?sh 2002 FAO Country landings in 2003 Proï¬?le Poland 0.01 n.a. n.a. n.a. Harvesting only. Share in national 2005 FAO Country GDP is almost negligible Proï¬?le Portugal 0.22 n.a. n.a. n.a. Processing included; marketing 2006 Eurostat 2006 and other postharvest activities excluded EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 62 A NNEX — D ATA SOUR C ES A ND NOTES FOR GD P CA LC ULATIONS TABLE A.3: Base Data and Data Sources Used to Estimate Extended Fisheries Sector GDP (continued) FISHING GDP POSTHARVEST FISHERIES AQUACULTURE COMMENT ON FISHERIES COUNTRY (MILLION USD) GDP GDP INCLUDED GDP CALCULATION YEAR SOURCE Qatar 0.10 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2001–02 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Romania 0.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. Sector makes a marginal contribu- 2002 FAO Country tion to GDP Proï¬?le Russian 0.30 n.a. n.a. n.a. Value of ï¬?shery production only 2006 FAO Country Federation Proï¬?le Rwanda 0.33 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2004? FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Saint Kitts and 0.84 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2005 FAO Country Nevis calculated Proï¬?le Saint Lucia 1.50 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2001 CRFM calculated website Saint Vincent/ 2.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 1999 FAO Country Grenadines calculated Proï¬?le Samoa 6.20 n.a. n.a. 0.00 Commercial and subsistence ï¬?sh- 2007 Gillett 2009 ing, aquaculture Sao Tome and 5.20 0.60 5.80 n.a. SFLP method (see note) 2002? FAO 2008b Principe Senegal 1.81 2.29 4.10 n.a. SFLP method (see note) 2003 FAO 2008b Seychelles 30.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 2005 Seychelles Strategy 2007 Sierra Leone 9.40 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2006 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Solomon Islands 6.19 n.a. n.a. 0.01 Commercial and subsistence ï¬?sh- 2007 Gillett 2009 ing, aquaculture Somalia 2.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 1990 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le South Africa 1.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2002 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Spain 0.17 n.a. n.a. n.a. Processing included; marketing 2006 Eurostat 2006 and other postharvest activities excluded Sri Lanka 2.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2004 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Sudan 0.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. The contribution of ï¬?sheries to GDP 2006 FAO Country is marginal Proï¬?le Suriname 4.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was ? UNLOS 2008 calculated Swaziland 0.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. Fishing does not play a signiï¬?cant 2003 FAO Country economic role Proï¬?le Sweden 0.02 0.03 0.06 n.a. n.a. ? Lena Westlund (personal communica- tion, February 2010) Taiwan 0.54 n.a. n.a. n.a. Overseas Fisheries Development 2003 Council, Republic of China Tanzania 2.70 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2000 Wilson 2004 calculated H ID D E N H A RV ES T ANN E X — D ATA S OURCE S AND NOT E S F OR GDP CA LCULATIONS 63 TABLE A.3: Base Data and Data Sources Used to Estimate Extended Fisheries Sector GDP (continued) FISHING GDP POSTHARVEST FISHERIES AQUACULTURE COMMENT ON FISHERIES COUNTRY (MILLION USD) GDP GDP INCLUDED GDP CALCULATION YEAR SOURCE Thailand 1.90 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 1996 FAO Country calculated Proï¬?le Togo 4.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. Harvesting subsector only 2005 FAO Country Proï¬?le Tonga 5.10 n.a. n.a. 0.00 Commercial and subsistence ï¬?sh- 2005–06 Gillett 2009 ing, aquaculture Trinidad and 0.09 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2005 FAO Country Tobago calculated Proï¬?le Turkey 0.22 0.06 0.40 0.08 Includes production, processing, 2006 FAO Country aquaculture, and support industries Proï¬?le Tuvalu 8.20 2.10 10.30 n.a. Commercial and subsistence ï¬?sh- 2002 Gillett 2009 ing. No aquaculture Uganda 3.00 9.00 12.00 n.a. Includes trade sector. Ofï¬?cial ï¬?gure 2002 Banks 2003 of 2.4% assumed undervalued United Kingdom 0.04 n.a. n.a. n.a. Processing included; marketing 2006 Eurostat 2006 and other postharvest activities excluded United States 0.30 0.27 0.57 n.a. n.a. 2006 unstat.org Vanuatu 1.67 n.a. n.a. 0.03 Commercial and subsistence ï¬?sh- 2007 Gillett 2009 ing, aquaculture Venezuela, 0.50 n.a. n.a. n.a. No detail on how ï¬?shery GDP was 2002 FAO Country Bolivarian calculated Proï¬?le Republic of Vietnam 4.00 n.a. n.a. 5.78 Direct production value only 2005 Van Trong Zambia 0.42 n.a. n.a. n.a. GDP based on contribution from 2005 FAO Country capture ï¬?shery alone Proï¬?le Zimbabwe 0.00 n.a. n.a. n.a. Fish production is not a major 2004 FAO Country contributor to GDP Proï¬?le Note: Unadjusted values with respect to the economic contribution of aquaculture. a http://www.statistikbanken.dk/statbank5a/default.asp?w=1280. b Lena Westlund (personal communication). February 2010. c http://www.tradedirectory.com.na/documents/sbn5.pdf. Stop Illegal Fishing Programme 2008. Angola Country proï¬?le. Lovell, T. 2008. Promise and Problems of a Caricom Fisheries Agreement. The United Nations-Nippon Foundation Fellowship Programme 2007–2008 Division for Ocean Affairs and the Law of the Sea Ofï¬?ce of Legal Affairs, The United Nations New York, 2008. http://www.un.org/Depts/los/nippon/unnff_ programme_home/fellows_pages/fellows_papers/lovell_0708_antigua-barbuda.pdf. Caribbean Regional Fisheries Mechanism (website) http://www.caricom-ï¬?sheries.com/members/antigua.asp accessed February 2010. South West Indian ocean Fisheries Project 2006. Comoros Country Proï¬?le. http://www.swiofp.net/swiofc/contributions.pdf accessed February 2010. World Bank 2004. Fisheries Sector Management and Development Action Plan. State of Eritrea. Report prepared by the World Bank in collaboration with Eritrea’s Ministry of Fisheries and Donor Partners. March 2004. (unpubl.) Ministry of Agriculture Forestry and Fisheries 2010. http://www.maff.go.jp/j/tokei/sihyo/index.html accessed February 2010. Global Edge 2010. http://globaledge.msu.edu/countryinsights/economy.asp?countryID=195®ionID=6 accessed February 2010. MAF 2006, “http://www.maf.govt.nz/mafnet/new-zealand-fast-forward/oia/060831-b152-nzs-recent-growth-performance.pdfaccessed January 2010â€? accessed January 2010. Van Trong, N. no date. Vietnam – Working Toward the Production of Safe and High-Quality Aquaculture Foods. RIA No. 2. Ho Chi Minh City, Vietnam. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 64 A NNEX — D ATA SOUR C ES A ND NOTES FOR GD P CA LC ULATIONS TABLE A.4: Estimated Extended Fisheries Sector GDP (proportion and $ millions) (continued) EXTENDED FISHERIES COUNTRY GDP IN 2007 ($ MILLION) FISHING GDP (%) POST-HARVEST GDP (%) GDP ($ MILLION) American Samoa — 0.2% — — Angola 58,547 3.0% — 3,100 Anguilla 109 2.6% — 5 Antigua Barbuda 1,026 1.5% — 27 Bahamas 6,586 1.4% — 163 Bangladesh 67,694 2.3% — 2,798 Barbados 3,430 1.0% — 61 Belgium 448,560 0.0% — — Belize 1,274 2.8% — 63 Benin 5,428 1.8% 1.2% 163 Botswana 11,781 0.0% — — Brazil 1,314,170 0.3% — 7,113 British VI — 0.7% — — Burkina Faso 6,767 0.2% 0.1% 20 Burundi 974 1.0% — 17 Cambodia 8,628 9.2% 6.0% 1,314 Cameroon 20,644 0.9% 0.8% 351 Canada 1,326,376 0.2% 0.1% 3,714 Cape Verde 1,434 1.3% 2.7% 56 Chad 7,085 1.3% — 163 China 3,280,053 0.8% — 43,764 Chile 169,458 1.3% — 3,950 Comoros 449 15.0% — 119 Congo R 7,646 1.4% 1.4% 210 Cook Islands 183 4.2% — 13 Costa Rica 25,225 0.2% — 89 Cote d’Ivoire 19,570 0.8% 0.8% 297 Croatia 51,277 0.2% — 208 Cyprus 21,277 0.2% — 60 Czech Republic 168,142 0.0% — 16 Denmark 308,093 0.1% 0.2% 1,078 Djibouti 830 0.1% — 1 Dominica 328 1.8% — 10 Dominican Republic 36,686 0.0% — 6 Eritrea 1,201 2.0% — 42 Ethiopia 19,395 0.0% — — Fiji 3,433 1.4% — 84 Finland 246,020 0.1% — 434 France 2,562,288 0.1% — 2,279 French Polynesia 5,300 1.0% — 92 Gabon 10,654 0.8% 0.8% 161 H ID D E N H A RV ES T ANN E X — D ATA S OURCE S AND NOT E S F OR GDP CA LCULATIONS 65 TABLE A.4: Estimated Extended Fisheries Sector GDP (proportion and $ millions) (continued) EXTENDED FISHERIES COUNTRY GDP IN 2007 ($ MILLION) FISHING GDP (%) POST-HARVEST GDP (%) GDP ($ MILLION) Gambia 643 1.8% 4.0% 37 Georgia 10,176 1.1% — 198 Germany 3,297,233 0.0% — 1,164 Ghana 15,246 8.0% 1.7% 1,479 Greece 360,031 0.2% 0.1% 897 Grenada 554 1.8% — 18 Guinea 4,564 1.8% — 145 Guinea Bissau 357 3.7% — 23 Guyana 1,044 2.8% — 52 Haiti 6,137 2.5% — 271 Iceland 19,510 5.0% 2.0% 1,366 India 1,170,968 0.6% — 13,313 Indonesia 432,817 1.8% — 13,906 Iran 270,937 0.2% — 908 Israel 161,822 0.0% — 31 Italy 2,107,481 0.1% — 2,346 Jamaica 10,739 0.4% — 68 Japan 43,767 0.1% — 100 Jordan 15,832 0.0% — 3 Kenya 29,509 0.5% — 260 Kiribati 87 53.4% — 82 Korea R 969,795 0.7% — 11,423 Kyrgyzstan 3,505 0.4% — 22 Lao 4,008 2.4% — 170 Latvia 27,154 1.2% — 551 Lesotho 1,600 0.0% — — Liberia 725 4.0% — 51 Madagascar 7,326 5.5% — 706 Malawi 3,552 4.0% — 251 Malaysia 180,714 1.5% — 4,798 Maldives 1,049 4.5% — 83 Mali 6,863 4.5% — 545 Malta 6,375 0.1% — 8 Marshall Islands 163 26.7% — 77 Mauritania 2,644 4.5% — 210 Mauritius 6,363 1.0% — 112 Mexico 893,364 0.8% — 12,614 Micronesia 257 9.4% 2.2% 30 Morocco 73,275 2.5% — 3,233 Mozambique 7,752 4.0% — 547 Namibia 6,740 3.0% 0.8% 256 EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 66 A NNEX — D ATA SOUR C ES A ND NOTES FOR GD P CA LC ULATIONS TABLE A.4: Estimated Extended Fisheries Sector GDP (proportion and $ millions) (continued) EXTENDED FISHERIES COUNTRY GDP IN 2007 ($ MILLION) FISHING GDP (%) POST-HARVEST GDP (%) GDP ($ MILLION) Nauru 28 2.1% — 1 Netherlands 754,203 0.1% — 825 New Zealand 129,372 0.2% — 488 Nigeria 165,690 1.4% — 4,184 Niue — 4.2% — — Norway 381,951 0.3% — 2,022 Oman 35,729 0.6% — 378 Palau 164 6.1% — 18 Papua New Guinea 6,261 3.1% — 341 Peru 109,088 2.0% — 3,812 Philippines 144,129 1.3% — 3,305 Poland 420,321 0.0% — 31 Portugal — 0.2% — — Qatar 42,463 0.1% — 75 Romania 165,980 0.0% — — Russia 1,291,011 0.3% — 6,836 Rwanda 3,320 0.3% — 19 Saint Kitts 527 0.8% — 8 Saint Lucia 958 1.5% — 25 Saint Vincent 553 2.0% — 20 Samoa 482 6.2% — 53 SaoTome Principe 145 5.2% 0.6% 8 Senegal 11,151 2.3% 2.6% 544 Seychelles 728 30.0% — 385 SierraLeone 1,672 9.4% — 277 Solomon Islands 369 6.2% — 40 Somalia 2,532 2.0% — 89 South Africa 277,581 1.0% — 4,899 Spain 1,429,226 0.1% — 3,373 SriLanka 32,354 2.0% — 1,142 Sudan 47,632 0.0% — — Suriname 2,241 4.0% — 158 Swaziland 2,942 0.0% — — Sweden 444,443 0.0% 0.0% 222 Tanzania 16,181 2.7% — 771 Thailand 245,818 1.4% — 6,068 Togo 2,493 4.0% — 176 Tonga 231 5.1% — 21 Trinidad Tobago 19,982 0.1% — 32 Turkey 657,091 0.2% — 2,551 Tuvalu 27 8.2% — 4 H ID D E N H A RV ES T ANN E X — D ATA S OURCE S AND NOT E S F OR GDP CA LCULATIONS 67 TABLE A.4: Estimated Extended Fisheries Sector GDP (proportion and $ millions) (continued) EXTENDED FISHERIES COUNTRY GDP IN 2007 ($ MILLION) FISHING GDP (%) POST-HARVEST GDP (%) GDP ($ MILLION) Uganda 11,214 2.9% 9.0% 1,336 United Kingdom 2,727,806 0.0% — 1,666 United States 14,093,310 0.3% 0.3% 76,366 Vanuatu 452 0.5% — 4 Venezuela 228,071 0.5% — 2,013 Viet Nam 71,216 4.0% — 5,028 Zambia 11,363 0.4% — 84 Zimbabwe 3,418 0.0% — — 274,099 Source: Authors, based on data from Tables A.1–A.3. Note: This table shows unadjusted values with respect to the economic contribution of aquaculture. The values used to estimate the global extended capture ï¬?sheries GDP were adjusted by reducing the harvest-level GDP by the proportion of the harvest represented by recorded aquacultre production. TABLE A.5: Fisheries Sector Multipliers (continued) MARINE INDUSTRY OUTPUT EMPLOYMENT VALUE ADDED INCOME COUNTRY/ MULTIPLIER LOCATION SOURCES YEAR TYPE (I/II) I II I II I II I II Australia Allen Consulting 1996–97 Marine tourism 2.50 n.a. 2.37 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. Group 2004 Australia Allen Consulting 1996–97 Fisheries and seafood 2.27 n.a. 2.19 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. Group 2004 Queensland KPMG 1994–95 Commercial ï¬?shing 1.60 n.a. 1.74 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. Consulting Queensland KPMG 1994–95 Recreational ï¬?shing / 2.10 n.a. 1.74 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. Consulting boating Canada Fisheries and 2006 Traditional ï¬?shery n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.66 n.a. n.a. Oceans Canada Canada Fisheries and 2006 Fish processing n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.79 n.a. n.a. Oceans Canada Canada Fisheries and 2006 Ocean-related tourism n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.83 n.a. n.a. Oceans Canada Newfoundland/ Pinfold 2009 2006 Fishing n.a. n.a. 5.71 7.10 0.55 0.67 n.a. n.a. Labrador Newfoundland/ Pinfold 2009 2006 Fish processing n.a. n.a. 9.94 12.03 0.58 0.61 n.a. n.a. Labrador Newfoundland/ Pinfold 2009 2006 Marine tourism n.a. n.a. 17.00 20.57 0.70 0.85 n.a. n.a. Labrador Nova Scotia Pinfold 2009 2006 Fishing n.a. n.a. 9.23 11.54 0.64 0.81 n.a. n.a. Nova Scotia Pinfold 2009 2006 Fish processing n.a. n.a. 12.50 15.63 0.53 0.67 n.a. n.a. Nova Scotia Pinfold 2009 2006 Marine tourism n.a. n.a. 19.00 23.75 0.67 0.84 n.a. n.a. New Brunswick Pinfold 2009 2006 Fishing n.a. n.a. 11.74 14.79 0.78 0.96 n.a. n.a. New Brunswick Pinfold 2009 2006 Fish processing n.a. n.a. 6.36 8.01 0.33 0.40 n.a. n.a. New Brunswick Pinfold 2009 2006 Marine tourism n.a. n.a. 21.00 26.72 0.60 0.74 n.a. n.a. Prince Edward Pinfold 2009 2006 Fishing n.a. n.a. 7.64 9.70 0.69 0.83 n.a. n.a. Island EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK 68 A NNEX — D ATA S OUR C ES A ND NOTES FOR GD P CA LC ULATIONS TABLE A.5: Fisheries Sector Multipliers (continued) MARINE INDUSTRY OUTPUT EMPLOYMENT VALUE ADDED INCOME COUNTRY/ MULTIPLIER LOCATION SOURCES YEAR TYPE (I/II) I II I II I II I II Prince Edward Pinfold 2009 2006 Fish processing n.a. n.a. 14.46 18.36 0.45 0.54 n.a. n.a. Island Prince Edward Pinfold 2009 2006 Marine tourism n.a. n.a. 15.00 19.05 0.58 0.70 n.a. n.a. Island Québec Pinfold 2009 2006 Fishing n.a. n.a. 7.80 10.69 0.73 0.98 n.a. n.a. Québec Pinfold 2009 2006 Fish processing n.a. n.a. 5.27 7.22 0.43 0.58 n.a. n.a. Québec Pinfold 2009 2006 Marine tourism n.a. n.a. 20.00 27.40 0.86 1.15 n.a. n.a. British Columbia Pinfold 2009 2006 Fishing n.a. n.a. 3.49 4.57 0.61 0.82 n.a. n.a. British Columbia Pinfold 2009 2006 Fish processing n.a. n.a. 8.36 10.95 0.50 0.67 n.a. n.a. British Columbia Pinfold 2009 2006 Marine tourism n.a. n.a. 15.00 19.65 0.73 0.98 n.a. n.a. Canada GPOR and SGA 2006 Recreational ï¬?shing/ n.a. 2.76 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. boating United Kingdom Greig 1999 >1999 Catching 1.82 n.a. 1.44 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. United Kingdom Greig 1999 >1999 Processing 2.14 n.a. 2.72 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. England Seaï¬?sh 2007 2007 Demersal ï¬?shing 2.17 3.35 1.52 2.13 3.16 5.50 n.a. n.a. England Seaï¬?sh 2007 2007 Shellï¬?sh ï¬?shing 2.39 3.83 1.32 1.59 6.50 12.34 n.a. n.a. England Seaï¬?sh 2007 2007 Pelagic ï¬?shing 2.35 3.38 2.81 4.32 1.89 2.97 n.a. n.a. England Seaï¬?sh 2007 2007 Fish processing 2.08 3.65 3.33 6.89 2.39 4.78 n.a. n.a. Scotland Greig 1999 >1999 Catching 1.65 n.a. 1.50 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. Scotland Greig 1999 >1999 Processing 2.26 n.a. 2.64 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. Scotland Robert et al., 1999 Sea ï¬?shing 1.66 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 1999 Scotland Robert et al., 1999 Finï¬?sh farming 1.17 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 1999 Scotland Robert et al., 1999 Fish processing 1.72 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 1999 United States Murray and 2004 Steelhead ï¬?shery 1.56 n.a. 1.29 n.a. 1.60 n.a. n.a. n.a. (Pennsylvania) Shields 2004 United States Peterson 2005 1997 Swordï¬?sh longline 1.44 1.84 14.64 19.34 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. (Hawaii) United States Peterson 2005 1997 Small commercial boat 1.49 2.16 49.69 57.39 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. (Hawaii) United States O’Bara C. 1999 1997 Recreational walleye 2.08 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. (Tennessee) ï¬?shery Southeast Asia Thia-Eng and 1992 Fishing n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 1.50 n.a. n.a. n.a. Garces 1994 Bangladesh MacFadyen et al., >2001 Shrimp farming 2.15 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 2001 New Zealand McDermott 1998 Ocean/coastal ï¬?shing 1.97 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. Fairgray New Zealand n.a. 1998 Inland ï¬?shing and ï¬?sh 4.52 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. farming New Zealand n.a. 1998 Fish and shellï¬?sh 3.02 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. processing Taranaki (NZ) BERL 2007 2006 Commercial ï¬?shing 1.37 1.52 1.45 1.67 1.50 1.76 n.a. n.a. Taranaki (NZ) BERL 2007 2006 Seafood processing 1.35 1.45 1.68 1.89 1.46 1.64 n.a. n.a. Africa Dyck and 2003 Ocean ï¬?shing 2.12 3.88 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.3 0.57 Sumaila 2009 H ID D E N H A RV ES T ANN E X — D ATA S OURCE S AND NOT E S F OR GDP CA LCULATIONS 69 TABLE A.5: Fisheries Sector Multipliers (continued) MARINE INDUSTRY OUTPUT EMPLOYMENT VALUE ADDED INCOME COUNTRY/ MULTIPLIER LOCATION SOURCES YEAR TYPE (I/II) I II I II I II I II Asia Dyck and 2003 Ocean ï¬?shing 1.81 3.33 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.27 0.47 Sumaila 2009 Europe Dyck and 2003 Ocean ï¬?shing 2.72 5.65 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.37 0.81 Sumaila 2009 Latin America Dyck and 2003 Ocean ï¬?shing 1.84 3.21 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.25 0.45 and Caribbean Sumaila 2009 North America Dyck and 2003 Ocean ï¬?shing 3.38 7.98 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.49 1.27 Sumaila 2009 Oceania Dyck and 2003 Ocean ï¬?shing 2.68 4.99 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.34 0.67 Sumaila 2009 Source: KPMG Consulting 2000. “Economic and Financial Vales of the Great Barrier Reef Marine Park.â€? Great Barrier Reef Marine Park Authority Research Publication No. 63, Townsville. Fisheries and Oceans Canada no date. “Economic Impact of Marine Related Activities in Canadaâ€? SEAS Publication http://www.dfo-mpo.gc.ca/ea-ae/cat1/ no1-1/no1-1-eng.htm#acknowledgement accessed January 2010. Genesis Public Opinion Research Inc./Smith Gunther Associates 2007. “Economic Impact of the Canadian Recreational Boating Industry: 2006.â€? Final report. Greig, G. T. 1999. “Multiplier Values for the Fishing and Fish Processing Industries in the UK and in Scotland: An Input - Output Analysis.â€? The XIth Annual Conference of the European Association of Fisheries Economists. Dublin 1999. Roberts D., Thomson K.J and Snowdon P. (1999), “Modelling the Western Isles Economy: Regional Accounts 1997â€?, MLURI / University of Aberdeen. O’Bara, C. 1999. “Economic Beneï¬?ts and Value of a Localized and Seasonal Walleye Fishery. In Pitcher, T. (Ed) Evaluating the Beneï¬?ts of Recreational Fisheries.â€? Fisheries Centre Research Reports, Vol. 7 No. 2 Pages: 169pp. 1999. Thia-Eng, C. and Garces, L.R. 1994. “Marine Living Resources Management in the ASEAN Region: Lessons Learned and the Integrated Management Approach.â€? Hydrobiologia Volume 285, Numbers 1–3 (1994), 257–270. Macfadyen, G, Aeron-Thomas, M, Saleh 2001., “The Costs and Beneï¬?ts of Bagda Shrimp Farming in Bangladesh – An Economic, Financial and Livelihoods Assessmentâ€?, Fourth Fisheries Project, BCAS / MRAG / Poseidon Aquatic Resource Management Ltd, 2001. Business and Economic Research Limited 2007. “Economic Impact of the Commercial Fishing Industry in The Taranaki Region.â€? Final Report prepared for Venture Taranaki. October 2007. TABLE A.6: Examples of Supply-Driven Multipliers MARINE OUTPUT EMPLOYMENT COUNTRY YEAR INDUSTRY UPSTREAM DOWNSTREAM UPSTREAM DOWNSTREAM Finland 2003 Fishing 1.6 3.0 1.3 1.7 Finland 2003 Aquaculture 2.2 2.3 2.9 2.5 Finland 2003 Fish processing 2.8 2.1 5.3 2.7 Finland 2003 Fish wholesaling 2.4 2.5 6.2 7.3 United States 1997 Tuna longline 1.4 1.0 n.a. n.a. (Hawaii) United States 1997 Swordï¬?sh longline 1.4 1.3 n.a. n.a. (Hawaii) United States 1997 Small commercial 1.5 1.3 n.a. n.a. (Hawaii) United States 1997 Charter boats 1.5 1.0 n.a. n.a. (Hawaii) United States 1997 Recreation boats 2.2 1.0 n.a. n.a. (Hawaii) United States 1997 Expense boats 2.3 1.3 n.a. n.a. (Hawaii) Sources: Finland: Virtanen et al. 2003; United States: Cai et al. 2005. EC O N O M I C A N D S E CT OR WORK A G R I C U L T U R E A N D R U R A L D E V E L O P M E N T This is a joint publication with: Agriculture and Rural Development (ARD) 1818 H Street, NW Washington, D.C. 20433 USA Telephone: 202-477-1000 ARD AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT Internet: www.worldbank.org/ard