50208 v3 Growth through Innovation An Industrial Strategy for Shanghai By Shahid Yusuf Kaoru Nabeshima April 22nd, 2009 The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this study are entirely those of the authors and should not be attributed in any manner to the World Bank, to its affiliated organizations, or to members of its Board of Executive Directors or the countries they represent. ii Table of Contents Chapter 1 Introduction and Overview ........................................................................................... 1 Chapter 2 The Economic Context ................................................................................................. 9 Chapter 3 Manufacturing Industry: The Locomotive for Innovation and Growth ..................... 21 I. Why a Broad Manufacturing Base Matters .......................................................................... 24 II. Industrial Productivity and Innovation ............................................................................... 30 Chapter 4 Pitfalls of Early De-Industrialization .......................................................................... 49 I. Services Expand ................................................................................................................... 50 II. Five Stylized Tendencies and their Implications ................................................................ 59 Chapter 5 Shanghai's Economic Composition, Resources and Potential for Innovation .......... 65 I. The Industrial Economy ....................................................................................................... 65 II. The Financial Sector ........................................................................................................... 75 III. Labor and Skills................................................................................................................. 79 IV. Tertiary Education and the Innovation System ................................................................. 81 V. University Industry Linkages ............................................................................................. 88 VI. Innovation Outcomes ........................................................................................................ 95 VII. Shanghai: Moving to a more Innovative Economy ....................................................... 107 Chapter 6 Making Shanghai's Industries Innovative ................................................................ 109 I. Urban Strategy and Policy Directions ................................................................................ 110 II. Policy Messages for Shanghai .......................................................................................... 140 List of Figures Figure 2.1: GDP Composition of China, 1979-2006 ........................................................ 10 Figure 2.2: Share of Exports in GDP and Growth of Exports in China, 1979-2007 ........ 10 Figure 2.3: Foreign Direct Investment Inflow to China, 1990-2006 ................................ 13 Figure 3.1: Relationship between the share of manufacturing and per capita income, 1960-2007 ................................................................................................................. 22 Figure 3.2: Relationship between the share of manufacturing and growth for OECD countries, 1961-2007................................................................................................. 23 iii Figure 3.3: Relationship between the share of manufacturing and growth for East Asian economies, 1961-2007 .............................................................................................. 23 Figure 3.4: Industry Contributions to Total Factor Productivity Growth in the US, 1960- 2005........................................................................................................................... 33 Figure 3.5: R&D as A Share of Sales ............................................................................... 36 Figure 3.6: R&D Intensity by Industry ............................................................................. 37 Figure 3.7: Top R&D Spending Sectors among Top 1000 R&D Spenders ..................... 38 Figure 3.8: Share of Patents by Industry, 1986 ................................................................. 39 Figure 3.9: Share of Patents by Industry, 2006 ................................................................. 40 Figure 5.1: GDP composition (%) .................................................................................... 68 Figure 5.2: Gross Value of Industrial Output by Ownership Categories in Shanghai ...... 73 Figure 5.3: Expenditure on R&D by Type of Activity in Shanghai ................................. 87 Figure 5.4: R&D Expenditure by Type of Institution in Shanghai ................................... 88 Figure 5.5: Number of Scientific Papers Published .......................................................... 99 Figure 5.6: Changes in Share of New Product Output in Shanghai................................ 101 Figure 5.7: Amount of foreign direct investment inflow to Shanghai (billion US$)...... 103 Figure 6.1: Product Space for China, 2000-2004 ........................................................... 114 Figure 6.2: Components of The Boston Life Sciences Cluster....................................... 145 List of Tables Table 2.1: Productivity Growth in China, 1978-2005 ...................................................... 13 Table 2.2: Gross Enrollment Rates in China, 1991, 2001, and 2006 ................................ 15 Table 2.3: Major National Programs in China .................................................................. 16 Table 2.4: China's exports as a share of world exports, 2006 ........................................... 20 Table 3.1: Revealed Comparative Advantage in Engineering and Electronics Goods, 2006 ................................................................................................................................... 27 Table 3.2: Selected Japanese Exports with High RCA, 2006 ........................................... 28 Table 3.3: Selected German Exports with High RCA, 2006 ............................................ 28 Table 3.4: Selected Korean Exports with High RCA, 2006 ............................................. 29 Table 3.5: Germany's Top 10 Exports, 2006.................................................................... 29 iv Table 3.6: Share of Engineering and Electronics Exports in Germany, Japan, and the US (%)............................................................................................................................. 29 Table 3.7: Patents Granted to Services-Oriented Firms.................................................... 34 Table 3.8: Major Innovations by Small US Firms in the Twentieth Century ................... 43 Table 3.9: Share of Intermediate Input Use in the United States, 2002............................ 47 Table 3.10: Share of Intermediate Input Use in China, 2002 ........................................... 48 Table 4.1: Share of National Income (%), 2005 ............................................................... 50 Table 4.2: Subsectoral Breakdown for Tokyo by Establishments and Employees, 2006 57 Table 4.3: Fixed-shares growth rate for total factor productivity for different periods .... 62 Table 4.4: Gini Coefficients in Selected Cities ................................................................. 64 Table 5.1: Share of National Population (%) .................................................................... 66 Table 5.2: Share of National GDP (%) ............................................................................. 66 Table 5.3 Subsectoral Composition of Manufacturing Activities in Shanghai, 1994 ...... 69 Table 5.4: Subsectoral Composition of Manufacturing Activities in Shanghai, 2007 ..... 70 Table 5.5: Share of Manufacturing Activities in Tokyo, 2001 and 2006 ......................... 71 Table 5.6: Share of Exports for Top European Exporters in 2003 ................................... 73 Table 5.7: Deposits and Loan Balances of Financial Institutions in Shanghai (billion yuan) ......................................................................................................................... 76 Table 5.8: Number of Financial Institutions in Shanghai, 2006-2007 .............................. 76 Table 5.9: Share of Loans and Savings in Beijing and China, 2000 and 2007................. 77 Table 5.10: Basic Statistics on Shanghai Stock Exchange ............................................... 78 Table 5.11: Educational level of population as a % of reference population ................... 79 Table 5.12: Educational level of population, Number in millions.................................... 80 Table 5.13: Personnel of Industrial Enterprises, 2005 (Scientists and Engineers) ........... 80 Table 5.14: Number of Universities.................................................................................. 81 Table 5.15: Number of Students ....................................................................................... 81 Table 5.16: STEM share of Undergraduate students ........................................................ 82 Table 5.17: Students enrolled in post graduate programs ................................................. 82 Table 5.18: Students enrolled in PhD programs ............................................................... 83 Table 5.19: Spending on Training in Shanghai, 2006-2007 ............................................. 84 Table 5.20: Number of People Receiving Training .......................................................... 84 v Table 5.21: Ranking of Universities in Beijing, Hong Kong, Shanghai, and Tokyo, 2008 ................................................................................................................................... 85 Table 5.22: Times Higher Education Global Ranking of Universities, 2007 ................... 85 Table 5.23: R&D Spending Share of Regional GDP (%)................................................. 87 Table 5.24: Expenditure on R&D and Its Composition in Beijing, 2005-2006 ............... 88 Table 5.25: Technological Transfer from Universities (Science, Engineering, Agriculture and Medicine) ........................................................................................ 90 Table 5.26: Technological acquisition and Transfer by Natural Science Research and Technology Development Institutions (2006) .......................................................... 91 Table 5.27: Technical Contracting in Shanghai, 2006 ...................................................... 91 Table 5.28: Technical Contracting in Shanghai, 2006 ...................................................... 92 Table 5.29: Areas of Technical Contracting in Shanghai, 2006 ....................................... 93 Table 5.30: Technical Contracting in Shanghai, 2006 ...................................................... 94 Table 5.31: Flow of Technical Contracting in China, 2006 ............................................. 95 Table 5.32: Share of Domestic Invention Patents from Beijing, Shanghai, and Hong Kong, 1990-2006 ...................................................................................................... 96 Table 5.33: Share of Patent Applications by Different Types of Organizations in Shanghai .................................................................................................................... 96 Table 5.34: Share of Invention Patents by Different Types of Organizations in Shanghai, 2006........................................................................................................................... 97 Table 5.35: Distribution of Patent Applications and Grants in Shanghai among Manufacturing Subsectors, 2006 .............................................................................. 98 Table 5.36: New Products Development of Industrial Enterprises in Shanghai, 2007... 100 Table 5.37: Value of Exports of High-tech Products in Shanghai (2001-2006), billion US$ ......................................................................................................................... 102 Table 5.38: Number of Venture Capital Firms and Capital Committed in Shanghai, 2004- 2007......................................................................................................................... 104 Table 5.39: Areas of Investment by VC in Shanghai, 2004-2007 (%) ........................... 104 Table 5.40: Area of Investment by Foreign VC in Shanghai, 2004-2007 (%) ............... 105 Table 5.41: Distributions of VC Investment in Shanghai, 2006 and 2007 (%) .............. 105 Table 5.42: Factors Considered Important by VC Prior to Investment (%) ................... 106 vi Table 5.43: Modes of Exit by Start-Up Firms (%) ......................................................... 106 Table 5.44: Number of Employees at VC in Shanghai, 2003-2007 ............................... 107 Table 6.1: Exports of China and the Share of Commodities in which China Has A Comparative Advantage.......................................................................................... 114 Table 6.2: Selected "upscale" commodities with highest density in China, 2000-2004. 115 Table 6.3: Export Similarity with OECD ....................................................................... 116 Table 6.4: Number of Highly Cited Researchers, 1980-1999 ........................................ 134 Table 6.5: Fiscal Incentives for Innovation Offered in China ........................................ 142 Table 6.6: Technology Licensing Offices in Tokyo ....................................................... 144 vii Chapter 1 Introduction and Overview In broad terms, the sources of economic growth are well understood but relatively few countries have succeeded in effectively harnessing this knowledge for policy purposes so as to sustain high rates of growth over an extended period of time (Commission on Growth and Development 2008; Yusuf 2009a). 1 Among the ones that have done so, China stands out. Its GDP growth rate averaging almost 10 percent between 1978 and 2007 is unmatched. Even more remarkable is the performance of China's two leading industrial regions: the Yangtze River (Changjiang) Delta area and the Pearl River Delta. 2 Both these regions have averaged growth rates well above 11 percent since 1985. Shanghai, the focus of this study, is the urban axis of the Yangtze River Delta's thriving economy. 3 Its future performance and that of a handful of other urban regions will determine China's economic fortunes in the coming decades. Can Shanghai sustain the momentum it has achieved with the help of investment in infrastructure, real estate and industry over the medium term? Are growth rates in the 8 -10 percent range feasible given the stage of urban development it is at and the likelihood that foreign trade might be a less reliable source of future growth? Would an accelerated expansion of the services sector be a desirable step and could the export of services to other countries and to the rest of China partially offset a decline in commodity trade? Could a systematic effort to deepen Shanghai's innovation capacity significantly improve its growth prospects? And if so, what measures and under what circumstances are likely to yield growth promoting outcomes? These are some of the questions which are uppermost in the minds of policymakers in the Shanghai Municipality and in the central 1 Easterly and others (1993) showed that for most countries, periods of fast or slow growth have tended to be temporary with countries reverting to a global mean rate after a brief period. The correlation in rates of growth between successive periods is close to zero. 2 The Pearl River Delta covers an area of over 40,000 sq km and has a population of 41 million (Yusuf 2007). Two-thirds of PRD's GDP comes from just four cities: Guangzhou, Shenzhen, Foshan, and Dongguan (World Bank 2009a). 3 See Yao and Ning (2008) and P. Hu (2007) for a recent analysis of the industrial dynamic in Yangtze River Delta. government as they come to terms with a maturing urban industrial economy and the knowledge that cost efficiency will be only one factor contributing to Shanghai's competiveness and dynamism. 4 Success at innovating appeals to all parties because it promises to introduce new products and services, the profitability of which increases with globalization, ways of enhancing productivity, and means of increasing consumer welfare by widening choices and providing better value. Moreover, national market integration and globalization have both increased the returns to innovation. If innovation could be systematized and effectively harnessed by manufacturers and services providers alike, then it would complement and appreciably extend the gains from investment and from progressive improvements in the quality of the urban workforce. An innovative urban economy is a highly attractive objective and international experience offers some clues as to how it might be achieved. But the current state of knowledge offers only a number of broad policy directions which collectively can contribute to making an economy innovative. There is no short cut: ideas conducive to innovation of all kinds are likely to flourish in skill intensive urban environments furnished with certain kinds of institutions and amenities and which support certain types of economic activities (E. L. Glaeser 2009). There are no tested recipes for creating such an environment, however, research is providing some guidance. The biggest challenge is to embed a culture of innovation which nourishes existing growth industries while providing the seeds for new activities which can emerge as the leading sectors of the future. To sustain adequate rates of growth over the next decade and more and to make a transition to an economy which derives impetus from innovation, Shanghai will need a strategy which builds on its strengths, and through these, develops tradable activities with the greatest potential for innovation capable of generating attractive returns. Identifying Shanghai's advantage in this regard, examining the innovation potential of candidate activities, and indicating how Shanghai can realize their potential, is the purpose of this study. Shanghai's strengths derive from its size and industrial diversity which are a source of scale and urbanization economies; the competitiveness of several 4 Some of the increase, of course, would derive from an appreciation of the exchange rate. 2 manufacturing subsectors; the emergence of business services; its expanding technological capabilities being nurtured by a deepening pool of human capital, by increasing R&D, by FDI in high-tech activities, and by the openness of the city to the rest of the world; and from a growing middle class which is likely to feed a nascent demand for innovation. Shanghai is currently pursuing a strategy which is attempting to raise the salience of finance and business services in GDP. 5 Shanghai is also seeking to increase the share of life sciences, advanced materials, and nano-tech based activities in manufacturing. The importance given to services and the effort to make Shanghai into a financial and logistics hub is similar to the approach adopted in the past by other global cities and has well established precedents. This study argues, however, that a high growth strategy which puts technology upgrading and innovation at the center might warrant a different approach from the one currently favored. It derives from the experience of global cities such as New York and London and the empirical research on industrial performance and on innovation. This has yielded four significant findings: First, monosectoral services based economies grow slowly because they benefit less from increases in productivity and from innovation. Second, manufacturing industries producing complex capital goods, electronic equipment, and sophisticated components are more R&D intensive, generate many more innovations, are more export oriented, have a solid track record of rising productivity, and having achieved competitiveness, are in a better position to sustain it because the entry barriers to these industries tend to be higher. By giving rise to dense backward and forward linkages these industries can serve as the nuclei of urban clusters and maximize employment generation. Third, industrial cities create many more jobs for a middle class and tend to have a more equal distribution of income than cities which are dominated by services. Fourth, and finally, cities with a world class tertiary education and research infrastructure linked to industry, are more resilient in the face of shocks, more innovative, and better able to reinvent themselves (E. L. Glaeser 2005a;2009). 5 The services sector was given priority by the Shanghai authorities starting with the Shanghai's 8th Five Year Plan (1985-1990). 3 These findings and others motivate the proposal for a strategy which has four elements: ˇ Shanghai should aim for a balanced economic structure with manufacturing activities continuing to account for a quarter or more of GDP. While the growth of business services is a welcome development, Shanghai's objective should be to maintain the presence of key manufacturing sectors in the periphery of the core metro area, and to promote their competitiveness. The focus should be on complex capital goods and associated components whose productivity, profitability, and competitiveness are more durable. The city should encourage the life sciences, new materials, and electronics while recognizing that these are subject to long gestation lags and might not generate significant profits or employment and contribute modestly to growth in the short-run. A balanced approach is more likely to lead to sustainable growth with equity and sustain a diverse urban population. It would call for a rationalizing and recalibrating of incentive policies for industry affecting land use, cost of inputs, and tax obligations so as to avoid a narrowing of the incentives for industry relative to services or other activities. ˇ An innovative economy will be a function of what kind of industry flourishes in the city and the strategy and dynamism of the leading firms (many of which are currently SOEs) ­ because innovation is industry specific and large firms conduct the bulk of the research. There is little correlation between innovations and spending on R&D by firms, hence incentives for R&D are subject to diminishing returns. An innovative economy will also depend on the quality of the leading universities and how they contribute to the intellectual culture of the city. Aside from aiming to attract the best talent, universities must view teaching and basic research as their primary missions. This is how they can most effectively serve the knowledge economy and enhance the demand for innovation. Downstream applied research which could have commercial applications 4 should be ­ as it is in the advanced countries ­ a secondary and for the majority of universities, a relatively minor objective. ˇ Education and medical services can be the basis of two important research-cum-industrial high-tech clusters. As the experience of Boston and San Francisco has shown, tertiary education and health services, if they are world class, can be immensely profitable sectors which generate demand for other business services, can become leading exporters, give rise to significant idea spillovers and induce the entry of new firms. ˇ Shanghai's innovativeness will depend in part on its openness to ideas, and people, and on its livability, which attracts and retains highly skilled and mobile knowledge workers. It will also be influenced by the city emerging as an intellectual leader among the global centers with its own distinctive vision and strategic initiatives. The current real estate driven development is leading to sprawl, automobility, the multiplication of residential towers with limited recreational amenities, and to gated communities, all of which threatens the cultural, aesthetic and environmental attributes of the city, not to mention its social capital. Other world cities have gone down this road are now having to reinvent themselves and to redefine livability and cultural capital, emphasize compactness and dynamic mixed use neighborhoods, put a premium on amenities, and to minimize their environmental footprints. The financial crisis and the global slowdown that started in 2008, have brought the world economy to a crucial juncture. There is need to interpret afresh for the purposes of policymaking, the past trends, stylized facts and lessons from the experience of the developed world, as well as the direction, pace and characteristics of urban development in China. This is a time for global economic consolidation and a rethinking of strategy for Shanghai (and China). Views - and past findings - regarding the roles of industry and services and policies to "rebalance" the economy could usefully be reconsidered. In the years ahead, the opportunities for China might be different and greater if it exercises strategic foresight in fully harnessing its economic potential and 5 advantages. The major economies of the world are in for an industrial shake-out. Many firms will close their doors and industrial capacity will be redistributed throughout the world. This outcome ­ which will be painful - represents a great opportunity for Shanghai to strengthen its economic base. No other major industrializing country has the nascent urban centers, the savings, the low indebtedness, the accumulated industrial capabilities, the elastic supply of human capital and the momentum which China (and Shanghai) does to discover growth opportunities in these challenging times. A new medium-term development strategy should include three additional short term objectives. First, because Shanghai's current and future comparative advantage lies in complex capital goods and high tech components among others, it needs to ensure that these sectors survive and emerge stronger and better positioned to compete and to expand their shares of the global market. 6 This requires that they have access to the resources to last out the downturn, sustain capability enhancing investments and add to their technological capacities. Certain capital goods sectors are likely to benefit from the investment in physical infrastructure which has strong policy support in China and the world. Second, this might be a time to very selectively acquire production, research, and intellectual property related assets from foreign companies which are going out of business, as well as critical tacit knowledge and brand names. Third, this is also the time to move faster with the transition out of those industrial subsectors in which Shanghai's comparative advantage is vanishing and to channel the resources from these sectors to others with better prospects, as well as to redouble the efforts to retrain and equip the human assets released by these subsectors so that they can be absorbed elsewhere in the economy, once recovery begins. Such a transfer of resources will provide a welcome boost to productivity and reduce the overhang of excess capacity in light industries. The study is divided into five parts. Chapter 2 encapsulates the sources of China's growth and the current and future role of urban regions in China. The case for the continuing importance of manufacturing industry for growth and innovation in Shanghai is made described in Chapter 3. Chapter 4 briefly examines the economic 6 The mid-term evaluation of the 11th Five Year Plan of China (covering the time period 2006-2010) reveals that while the growth of high-tech industry has been impressive, it falls short of expectations. The target was for high-tech industry to account for 10 percent of the value-added. However, by 2006 its share was 5 percent and a doubling in four years is unlikely (World Bank 2008b). 6 transformation of four global cities and distills stylized trends which can inform Shanghai's future development. Chapter 5 describes Shanghai's current industrial structure and identifies promising industrial areas and the analysis of resource base which would underpin growth fuelled by innovation. Finally, Chapter 6 suggests how strategy could be re-oriented based on the lessons delineated in Chapter 4 and the capabilities of the Shanghai economy presented in Chapter 5. 7 Chapter 2 The Economic Context China's growth experience has been exhaustively analyzed, 1 hence it suffices at the outset to briefly identify the principal determinants over the past three decades and to indicate which of these are most likely to influence the economic prospects of China's urban regions. 2 Although, agriculture played an important role in the first half of the 1980s, 3 much of the impetus since has derived from continuous double digit growth of industry supported by domestic and foreign demand. Rapid evolution and technological catching-up of manufacturing coupled with expanding exports of sophisticated industrial products, have been largely responsible for China's industrial performance to date (Holz 2008; Schott 2006). Manufacturing activities are likely to remain the engine of China's urban growth for the next decade and possibly longer (see Figure 2.1 and Figure 2.2). Other countries have also attempted to achieve high growth rates through industrialization, however, few have equaled China's performance and the question frequently asked is, why has China done so much better than most other developing nations. There are six possible reasons. 1 See for instance, Brandt and Rawski (2008), Naughton (2007), Yusuf, Nabeshima and Perkins (2005), Holz (2008) and Lin, Cai and Li (2003). 2 Allen Scott (2001 2001b, p.813) extends the concept of a global city, "As a cosmopolitan metropolis , a command post for the operations of MNCs, a center of advanced services and information processing activities, and a deeply segmented space marked by extremes of poverty and wealth, to incorporate the notion of a wider (urban) region as an emerging political economic unit with increasing autonomy of action on the national and world stages". 3 Rural reforms, which spearheaded China's reforms and were responsible for the growth spurt (7.7 per cent per annum) during 1979-84, are described by Perkins and Yusuf (1984), Carter, Zhong and Cai (1996), and J. Huang, Otsuka and Rozelle (2008). Figure 2.1: GDP Composition of China, 1979-2006 60 50 40 30 % 20 10 0 79 81 83 85 87 89 91 93 95 97 99 01 03 05 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 20 20 20 Agriculture Industry Manufacturing Services Source: World Development Indicators Figure 2.2: Share of Exports in GDP and Growth of Exports in China, 1979-2007 45 40 35 30 25 20 % 15 10 5 0 -5 79 81 83 85 87 89 91 93 95 97 99 01 03 05 07 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 20 20 20 20 Exports of goods and services (% of GDP) Exports of goods and services (annual % growth) Source: World Development Indicators 10 First, China's Big Push to industrialize, starting in the 1950s, 4 helped to lay the foundations of manufacturing capacity, created a broad base of expertise in both light and heavy manufacturing in several parts of the country, and brought into existence an urban industrial labor force of managers, technicians and assembly line workers. When China's reforms commenced in 1979, a large industrial sector, accounting for over half of China's GDP, already existed and was able to exploit the opportunities inherent in the wide technological and productivity gaps between China and the industrially advanced countries. Few, if any other developing countries had an industrial establishment as large as this in the 1980s or earlier. Second, this accumulated industrial capacity was vital in leveraging the gains from the opening to trade and to foreign direct investment (FDI) starting in 1979 and accelerating after 1994 (see Figure 2.3). 5 Trade and foreign direct investment are the source of three main benefits: they channeled capital into export oriented light industries in the initial post reform years and stimulated the growth of this important sector. 6 Since then, domestic capital and FDI has flowed into high tech manufacturing industries, services and real estate as well. Trade and FDI have served as vehicles for technology transfer embodied in plant and equipment and also knowledge transfer on plant operations, management, business organization, work place practices, logistics and other areas. 7 These have substantially augmented productivity in foreign invested firms and through knowledge spillovers, in domestic enterprises. 8 FDI has partially ameliorated the 4 For a brief history of the term Big Push coined by Paul Rosenstein-Rodan in 1943 and elaborated by Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny in 1989, see Yusuf (2009a) and Easterly (2006). 5 The extensive involvement of foreign firms in China's export oriented industrialization was neither planned nor anticipated when reforms were initiated. It evolved over time. 6 China's opening up is described by Kleinberg (1990) and the positive effects of trade of industrial production in cities is estimated by Wei (1993). Initially the opening aroused opposition within the country, however, following Deng Xiaoping's intervention in 1984 and the creation of 14 open cities, the process acquired new momentum (Lai 2006). See also D. Comin and Hobijn (2004) on the positive effect of increased trade and human capital on technology adoption. 7 Trade is one of the conduits for technology transfer, especially technologies embedded in capital goods (D. T. Coe and Helpman 1995; D. T. Coe, Helpman and Hoffmaister 1997; Eaton and Kortum 1999;2001). 8 FDI inflow is another important avenue of technology transfer. However, the empirical findings to date present a mixed picture (B. Aitken, Hanson and Harrison 1997; B. J. Aitken and Harrison 1999; Blomstrom and Sjoholm 1999; Haddad and Harrison 1993). For a survey of technology transfer via FOT, see Saggi (2006). The literature mainly focuses on the flow of spillovers from MNCs to local firms. However, it is also possible to have spillovers from local firms to MNCs. See Yingqi Wei, Liu and Wang (2008) on the case of China. A number of different avenues for technology spillovers have been identified: demonstration effects, vertical linkages, circulation of workers, and managerial capabilities (Smeets 2008). 11 distortions in China's financial markets and made more capital available to SMEs producing tradable goods (Y. Huang 2005). FDI has accelerated the integration of China's manufacturing sector with the global economy. This process, assisted by the overseas Chinese diaspora, is enabling Chinese producers to tighten their links with international production networks and consolidate their entry into foreign retail markets (Bair 2009; Rauch and Trindade 2002; Yusuf and others 2003). 9 Trade and FDI will continue to promote technological change in Shanghai during the medium term albeit to a lesser degree as local capacity grows. Third, the large volume of domestic investment in production capacity and in physical infrastructure has complemented FDI and conferred several significant benefits. It has rapidly increased capital labor ratios and introduced new technologies embodied in capital equipment which confer productivity and quality advantages and contribute to China's industrial competitiveness. Factor productivity which is the main source of Demonstration effects are often measured as the change in productivity of firms in the same sector (horizontal spillovers). Griffith, Redding and Simpson (2002), Griffith, Redding, and van Reenen (2004), Castellani and Zanfei (2003), and Peri and Urban (2006) note that increased FDI results in a positive effect on the productivity of the local firms (relative to the best performance within the same industrial category). However, using design patents as the measure, Cheung and Lin (2004) found evidence of increased FDI leading to a rise in the number of design patents that can be most easily copied. Vertical spillovers seem to be more prevalent mode. Javorcik (2004) finds evidence on positive impact through backward linkages only. Vertical (inter-industry) spillovers through increased demand for intermediate inputs were also found by Javorcik and Spatareanu (2008) under the condition of joint ownership, while the horizontal (intra- industry) impact was negative. Kugler (2006), Bwalya (2006) and Schoors and van der Tol (2002) also find evidence of positive backward linkages. However, Blalock and Gertler (2008) and Javorcik and Spatareanu (2005) point out that local firm productivity increases might be a consequence of intentional technology transfers rather than spillovers. Circulation of workers among foreign and domestic firms seem to be broadly productivity enhancing, although such positive spillovers occur only when workers are moving within a single industry or related industries (Gorg and Strobl 2001). Knowledge spillovers are confined in rather small areas. Proximity is important (Barrios, Bertinelli, and Strobl (Barrios, Bertinelli and Strobl 2006), Girma and Wakelin (2007), and Nicolini and Resmini (2007)). Moreover, even if there are many MNCs willing to assist local firms through backward linkages, and these firms are located close to each other, local firms need to have a certain level of absorptive capacity (as noted by Cohen and Levinthal 1990). Girma (2005) and Girma and Gorg (2007) show that the mediating effect of knowledge spillover is maximized at intermediate levels of absorptive capacity. Smeets (2008) concludes by pointing out that the effect of FDI depends on spillover channels, mediating factors, and FDI heterogeneity, which coexist and interact in determining the extent of knowledge spillovers. According to Wei and Liu (2006) and Liang (2008) theoretical and empirical research should therefore try to address these aspects simultaneously. 9 Access to the markets of developed countries frequently depends upon entry into the global value chains of core firms from industrialized economies (Nolan, Zhang and Liu 2008). See Li and Lin (2006) and Fung, Fung and Wind (2008) on the mutually reinforcing interaction between global value chains, the increasing logistical sophistication of producers and the effective assimilation of IT, the science and art of networked logistics, and flexible manufacturing in East Asia. 12 differences in per capita GDP among countries rose by 3-4 percent between 1993 and 2005 (see Table 2.1). 10 By enabling Chinese producers to quickly ramp up capacity, the outlay on production capacity has accelerated `learning' and made it easier to achieve the production scale required by foreign buyers, 11 Moreover, investment spending generates domestic demand and alongside exports and growth, this has been a consistent source of growth. Figure 2.3: Foreign Direct Investment Inflow to China, 1990-2006 7 90 80 6 70 5 60 Billion US$ 4 50 % 3 40 30 2 20 1 10 0 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Foreign direct investment, net inflows (% of GDP) Foreign direct investment, net inflows (BoP, current US$ billion) Source: World Development Indicators Table 2.1: Productivity Growth in China, 1978-2005 Bosworth and Collins (2007) He and Kuijs (2007) 1978-2004 1978-1993 1993-2004 1978-1993 1993-2005 Output growth 9.3 8.9 9.7 9.7 9.6 Employment 2.0 2.5 1.2 2.5 1.1 Output per worker 7.3 6.4 8.5 7.0 8.4 Physical capital 3.2 2.5 4.2 3.2 5.3 Land 0.0 -0.1 0.0 - - Education 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.5 0.2 Factor productivity 3.8 3.6 4.0 3.3 2.8 Of which: - - - 1.3 1.1 10 See R. E. Hall and Jones (1999); Diego Comin, Hobijn and Rovito (2004; 2008) on lags in technology adoption and their implications for TFP. 11 The ability to quickly and flexibly service large orders from foreign buyers is a big advantage for Chinese suppliers over competitors in India ­ although that gap may now be closing in certain industries as Indian firms build capacity (Luthra, Mangaleswaran and Padhi 2005). 13 reallocation of labor between sectors Source: Bosworth and Collins (2007); He and Kuijs (2007) Physical capital is only one part of China's growth story. Human capital increasingly abundant in the large urban centers such as Shanghai, is an equally important part and a fourth reason explaining China's unusually brisk economic performance. Achieving universal literacy and a high level of primary enrollment was China's objective from the 1950s. This equipped the Chinese workforce with the basic skills needed for the earlier stages of industrialization in the late 1970s and early 1980s. 12 A redoubling of effort at raising levels of education after 1980 has paid handsome dividends. China has vastly expanded secondary and tertiary education and vocational training domestically and sent hundreds of thousands of its nationals for training abroad as well (see Table 2.2). 13 Shanghai is among the most successful cities in attracting some of these knowledge workers back. These efforts are expanding the supplies of skilled, technical and professional workers, who are needed to assimilate advanced technologies from overseas in manufacturing and services, to manage China's increasingly more complex economy and to initiate home grown innovations in a variety of fields (Yusuf, Nabeshima and Perkins 2007). With technology absorption and innovation now viewed as the most potent sources of economic dynamism and of gains in productivity, the supply and quality of human capital might eventually overtake physical capital as the principal driver of growth via gains in TFP. 14 As shown by Diego Comin, Hobijn and Rovito (2008), closing inter-country disparities in TFP is in large part a function of lags in the adoption of new technologies and the intensity of usage. Human and knowledge capital can reduce both. 12 The emphasis on raising literacy and school enrollment dates back to the late 1950s, MacFarquhar and Fairbank (1987). 13 Approximately 800,000 Chinese have gone abroad to study and of these, about 30 percent have returned although the percentage is on the rise. 14 Chi (2008) shows that the impact of fixed capital on growth is insignificant. It is the provincial stock of human capital ­ especially tertiary level skills ­ which determine the accumulation of physical capital. Hence, human capital is the principal determinant of growth. 14 Table 2.2: Gross Enrollment Rates in China, 1991, 2001, and 2006 1991 2001 2006 Primary 125.9 117.4 111.2 Secondary 49.1 65.0 75.5 Tertiary 3.0 9.9 21.6 Source: World Development Indicators Fifth, the renewed priority given to education starting in the 1980s, 15 was followed later in the decade by increasing attention to R&D with the launching of a number of programs such as the Spark and Torch Programs (see Table 2.3 for a list of various national innovation programs and Sigurdson (2005)). This is building technological capacity and laying the groundwork for a culture of innovation, most notably in the leading industrial centers. The early emphasis given to R&D means that China is accumulating research capital faster, which expedites technology transfer and technology absorption. 16, Gao and Jefferson (2007) introduce the notion of a science and technology take-off which refers to the scientific productivity of a country. They suggest that such a take-off which is likely to precede a surge in innovation, is associated with the doubling of research expenditures over a period of a decade or less. They show that the United States, several European countries and a few East Asian economies were able to achieve this and some are now demonstrating their innovation capabilities. By this yardstick, China and even more notably Shanghai, have achieved takeoffs. How rapidly this translates into a steady flow of innovations which are reflected in new products, exports, and GDP growth, still remains to be seen. 15 The first loan by the World Bank to China in 1981 was for higher education. 16 In 2008, China joined the list of countries with the 10 fastest computers in the world. The fastest computer in China is produced by Dawning, a domestic server manufacturer established in 1995 as a result of "863" program (http://www.dawning.com.cn/en/aboutus.asp). It is housed in the Shanghai Super Computer Center. China now has 15 of the world's 500 fastest computers ("Frontiers Expand" 2008). 15 Table 2.3: Major National Programs in China Program Agency Year begun Key focus Spark Ministry of Science 1985 Improve agricultural technology and and Technology develop agro-industrial clusters Torch Ministry of Science 1998 Develop high-tech industries and and Technology development zones and provide laboratories and equipment 863 (national high- Ministry of Science March 1986 Enhance international competitiveness technology research and Technology and improve overall capability of R&D and development in high technology (with 19 priorities) program) National Key Ministry of Science 1982 Support applied R&D to meet critical Technologies R&D and Technology technological needs in key sectors Program 973 (national basic Ministry of Science June 1997 Strengthen basic research in line with research program) and Technology (combined national strategic targets (primarily in with agriculture, energy, information, "Climbing" resources and environment, population program, and health, and materials) initiated in 1992) R&D Infrastructure and Ministry of Science 1984 (National Support National Key Laboratories Facility Development and Technology Key Development Program, National Key Laboratories Science Projects Program, and National Program) Engineering Technology Research Centers Development Program National Natural National Natural 1986 Promote and finance basic research and Science Foundation Science Foundation some applied research 211 Ministry of Education 1995 Improve overall institutional capacity and develop key disciplinary areas in selected universities, and develop public service system of higher education (three networks) 985 Ministry of Education 1998 (first Turn China's top 150 universities into phase); world-class research institutions 2004 (second phase) The Outline of the 2006 To make China an innovation-driven Medium and Long- economy by 2020 through increase in term National Plan investment in S&T; shifting focus more for Science and to basic and frontier research; Technology preferential tax treatment to stimulate Development R&D; government procurement; (OMLP), 2006-2020 indigenizing foreign technologies; strengthening IP protection; and human capital development. R&D to GDP ratio should be at least 2.5% and China should rank among top 5 in patents granted and papers published by 2020. Source: Wu (2007); Sigurdson (2005); Rongping and Wan (2008). 16 From the early 1980s, China's industrial capacity grew most rapidly in a few densely populated urban regions centered on cities such as Shanghai, Guangzhou, and Shenzhen which are gaining agglomeration economies (Yusuf 2007). 17 This process accelerated between 1998 and 2005, although relative to more advanced countries, China is still low on the scale of industrial agglomeration (J. Lu and Tao 2009). 18 Size and the agglomeration of activities translate into advantages of scale, of industrial diversity, of deep labor markets and a strong services economy. Together, these have led to productivity gains for firms and created an environment more conducive to technological advance, which is universally an urban phenomenon (Yusuf and others 2003). 19 In other words, the five factors referred to above have been reinforced by agglomeration economies. Urbanization has thus interacted most fruitfully with other factors in promoting growth. These six elements highlight the role of industrialization: an early start at building industrial capacity; FDI that initiated the growth of exports; the high level of investment in plant, equipment and infrastructure; rapid accumulation of human capital on a broad front; the attention given to R&D; and the geographically concentrated spiral of urbanization. Together they are responsible for the stimulating and sustaining China's growth to date. Each contributing element depended upon a succession of policy initiatives that after experimentation and validation, defined and progressively elaborated China's unique development strategy. 20 In other words, policies that gave primacy to or accommodated these six elements were ultimately responsible for the huge economic strides taken by the country during the past three decades. Starting in the 1980s, China's industrial efforts were assisted by the global industrial product cycle, 21 and by the strategies of MNCs and of major retailers in the United States. Rising costs of production in their home countries and the emerging 17 Ge (2009) finds that export-orientation and FDI have contributed to the agglomeration of industries in China. 18 One of the constraints on further agglomeration is local protectionism (J. Lu and Tao 2009). 19 From the nineteenth century onwards the innovation has flourished in cities and diffused most readily in the urban environment (Bairoch 1991, Ch. 20). 20 Vividly depicted as, "crossing the river by feeling the stones." It combined varied countrywide experimentation with the rapid diffusion of successful models. 21 This refers to the transfer of production from advanced to industrializing countries as products mature, and the product itself becomes a commodity. See Vernon (1979). 17 capacity to manage dispersed operations with the help of IT, persuaded the MNCs to transfer the manufacture of mature standardized commodities whose production technologies had stabilized and become codified, to East Asia. The big retail chains in the United States found it expedient and cost effective to source from overseas (Bair 2009). 22 As transport costs fell, the cost advantage enjoyed by East Asia producers grew (Hummels, Ishii and Yi 2001). 23 Starting in the 1980s and at an accelerating rate in the second half of the 1990s, China was able to grasp the opportunities as they emerged by building production capacity and acquiring the manufacturing capability and scale demanded by foreign buyers. According to Hamilton and Gereffi (2008), it was the speed with which Chinese and other East Asian manufacturers adapted to the needs of contract manufacturing which explains why they were able to beat the competition. Furthermore, as China's technological know-how improved, it diversified into medium and high tech products at a faster rate than other countries and established a commanding lead in markets for a wide range of manufactures. Table 2.4 shows that China currently dominates the export market for various types of garments, toys, furniture, and leather goods. This is the past. What of the future. China is now the world's second largest exporter and the second largest manufacturer. Maintaining the recent trend rates of growth of the existing mix of products in the unfolding world environment will be difficult, perhaps impossible. 24 Market saturation for some manufactured exports, rising 22 Japanese trading companies and "lean retailers" in the United States gave rise to the demand for production networks spanning the Pacific. Their interest and involvement stimulated entrepreneurship in Taiwan (China) and Korea, giving rise to a highly efficient base of small suppliers in Taiwan (China) producing a variety of light consumer items, and to a comparable production base in Korea created by conglomerates called chaebol. The remarkable celerity with which the business communities in these two economies grasped the opportunities largely explains the subsequent elaboration of the production networks and their contribution to the growth of intra-regional and cross-Pacific trade (Feenstra and Hamilton 2006). For a recent survey on the global production networks, see N. M. Coe, Dicken and Hess (2008), Sturgeon, van Biesebroeck and Gereffi (2008) on the automotive industry, and Pietrobelli and Saliola (2008) on the role of lead MNCs in global production networks and in developing local suppliers. 23 E. Glaeser and Kohlhase (2003) estimate that transportation costs declined by 95% during the 20th century. 24 While China is in a better shape than other smaller export oriented economies to weather the global financial crisis, it is not immune from it. China has relied on exports for between 2 and 3 percent of its growth. With exports stagnating growth has slackened ("Beijing Hesitates" 2008). Before the crisis, the Chinese authorities tightened the credit so as to avoid inflation. As a result, domestic consumption and investment also slowed. The estimated growth for the third quarter of 2008 was 9 percent, the first single- 18 domestic costs of production, natural resource scarcities and trade frictions 25 are some of the factors arguing for a growth and export strategy which more fully harnesses technology assimilation from abroad, domestic innovation, productivity growth, industrial deepening, and the potential residing in business services still a relatively under-developed sector in China. The "low cost" model and industrial widening are still capable of delivering growth, but to a lesser degree. Thus, if gains in productivity, backward integration to increase value added, and innovation to generate new goods and services, better processes and better business models are the means of achieving sustainable growth, then strengthening technological and innovation capabilities promises the highest payoff. 26 By building and tuning and coordinating technological capabilities and creating a functioning innovation system, the economy will be more productive, less resource and energy intensive and better able to generate goods and services enjoying wider profit margins. 27 There are many empirical findings and lessons from more advanced countries which can help make China's industrial economy more innovative. But among these, one stands out. Innovation whether in manufacturing or in services needs to be nourished in a few major urban centers which combine significant agglomeration economies with an intellectual culture which encourages innovation and an urban environment high on the scale. China's technological capacity is already highly concentrated and very likely a relatively small number of cities will drive knowledge intensive growth. Shanghai can be the leader or tie with Beijing for first place. digit growth since 2001. The World Bank forecasts that China's growth in 2008 will be 9.0 percent and slowing further to 6.5 percent in 2009 (World Bank 2008c). 25 A lengthy period of slow growth could lead to a reappearance of trade barriers as happened in the earlier decades of the twentieth century, and this would dilute some of the major gains from globalization. Recognizing this danger, several economists have proposed ways of avoiding such an outcome. See Baldwin and Evenett (2008). So-called "murky protectionism" has begun spreading since 2008. 26 For assessments of the science and technology system in China, see A. G. Hu and Jefferson (2008) and Sigurdson (2005); for a general overview; and Zhang (2008) for analysis of innovation by SMEs and of other issues such as the role of VC. On East European experience with developing a competitive knowledge based economy, see the papers in Runiewicz-Wardyn (2008) and Goldberg and others (2008). 27 Although China exported 4,898 products out of 5,041 products traded globally in 2004, versus 4,932 by Germany, Japanese unit values for similar products were 2.9 times higher and those of the United States 2.4 times higher. (Fontagne, Gaulier and Zignago 2008). 19 Table 2.4: China's exports as a share of world exports, 2006 Commodities % Outerwear knitted or crocheted, not elastic nor rubberized 36.1 Baby carriages, toys, games and sporting goods 31.2 Articles of apparel, clothing accessories, non-textile, headgear 29.8 Under garments of textile fabrics, not knitted or crocheted 29.3 Men's and boys' outerwear, textile fabrics not knitted or crocheted 28.5 Clothing accessories, of textile fabrics, nes 26.8 Women's, girl's, infants outerwear, textile, not knitted or crocheted 26.7 Under-garments, knitted or crocheted 25.9 Furniture and parts thereof 17.0 Manufactures of leather or of composition leather, nes; etc 14.7 Leather 6.8 Source: Authors' calculations Although the past is one guide to future development, past patterns should not be seen as binding. In fact they could mislead. Hence, in this study, we will draw selectively and critically upon the relevant global and Chinese experience of mega cities, in proposing a high growth strategy for Shanghai. 20 Chapter 3 Manufacturing Industry: The Locomotive for Innovation and Growth Twenty years ago, Dertouzos, Lester and Solow (1989) recognized the importance of manufacturing industry for the US economy. In "Made in America", they stressed that "[t]he United States ... has no choice but to continue competing in the world market for manufactures. ..., the best way for Americans to share in rising world prosperity is to retain on American soil those industries that have high and rapidly rising productivity. Manufacturing, and high-technology manufacturing in particular, belongs in this category" (p.40). Their argument is based on the innovation intensity of manufacturing industry. To quote, "A related fact is that manufacturing firms account for virtually all of the research and development done by American industry. They thus generate most of the technological innovations adopted both inside and outside their own industry. High technology manufacturing industries account for amount three-quarters of all funding for research and development and the other manufacturing industries account for most of the rest. The roots of much of the technological progress responsible for long-term economic growth can ultimately be traced to the nation's manufacturing base" (Dertouzos, Lester and Solow 1989, pp.40-41). Looking at the experience of OECD countries, it seems that there is an inverted U-shape relationship between the share of manufacturing and the level of income (see Figure 3.1). At the initial stage, as countries increases its share of manufacturing, the income is rising. At certain point of the income, these economies shift to become more services oriented economy. Looking at the relationship between the share of manufacturing and the growth of income is quite revealing. There is a slight positive correlation between the share of manufacturing and growth for OECD countries and also for East Asian economies (Figure 3.2 and Figure 3.3). This may account in part for the slower growth of higher income countries and the continuing importance of manufacturing industry for growth. 1 Even though the manufacturing industry now employs just 10 percent of the workforce and produces less than a fifth of GDP in the United States (and in other developed countries), the financial crisis started in the late 2008 has focused attention on the role of manufacturing industry in restoring growth and enabling the United States and other countries in narrowing trade gaps. 2 Figure 3.1: Relationship between the share of manufacturing and per capita income, 1960-2007 35 30 Manufacturing Share (% of GDP) 15 2010 25 0 20000 40000 60000 per capita GDP (constant 2000 US$) Note: the data includes all the current OECD members (30 countries) between 1960 and 2007 for which data were available in World Development Indicators. Source: Authors' calculations 1 A simple fixed effect panel regression also suggests that the share of manufacturing is an important and sizable contributor to growth. 2 They were also of the opinion that sustaining trade deficit will be impossible and increase in services exports have not and will not be able to finance the imports of manufactured goods (Dertouzos, Lester and Solow 1989). 22 Figure 3.2: Relationship between the share of manufacturing and growth for OECD countries, 1961- 2007 20 10 per capita GDP growth -10 -200 10 15 20 25 30 35 Manufacturing Share (% of GDP) per capita GDP growth trend line Note: the data includes all the current OECD members (30 countries) between 1961 and 2007 for which data were available in World Development Indicators. Source: Authors' calculations Figure 3.3: Relationship between the share of manufacturing and growth for East Asian economies, 1961-2007 20 10 per capita GDP growth -10 -20 -30 0 0 10 20 30 40 Manufacturing Share (% of GDP) per capita GDP growth trend line Note: The economies included are China, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea, Japan, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan (China), Thailand between 1961 and 2007 for which data were available in World Development Indicators. Source: Authors' calculations 23 I. Why a Broad Manufacturing Base Matters By maintaining the share of manufacturing in the 25-30 percent range, 3 Shanghai could capitalize on gains in industrial productivity and enlarge the scope for innovation. 4 However, the global economic slowdown caused by the financial crisis which erupted in 2008 will jeopardize the survival of segments of industry which are heavily dependent on exports. World trade grew by just 4 percent in real terms during 2008 and is forecast to decline by 9 percent in 2009 (WTO 2009). The adjustments required of countries such as the United States to correct their external and/or internal resource imbalances could also presage a period of slow growth in global trade in manufactures and the persistence of excess capacity in a number of industries over the near term. During 2009-2010, exports are likely to contribute far less to Shanghai's growth than in the past, FDI will diminish and there will be less technology transfer through the medium of imports. Shanghai's remaining low tech and labor intensive industries are likely to suffer rapid erosion in competitiveness and to either close down or relocate elsewhere. Some shrinkage of the manufacturing sector seems unavoidable over the near term. But an expansion of the tradable services ­ even it is feasible in the face of weaker domestic and foreign demand is unlikely to restore growth and employment in the short run, and if it increasingly displaces manufacturing, will be detrimental to growth over the longer term. If Shanghai's objective is achieve rising incomes based increasingly on gains arising from a productively networked and innovative economy, there is no substitute for manufacturing. But the future of a diversified and growing industrial base will depend upon measures taken to bolster the competitiveness of mature industries with considerable potential in global markets. It will also be a function of the entry of manufacturing firms into new industrial sub fields which can remain profitable over the 3 This is fairly close to the share of the manufacturing sector in 2007. 4 This does not mean that factories would locate in the core downtown area. A city wanting to maintain a solid manufacturing base must develop edge industrial centers and be well integrated to these so as to form a polycentric urban region. To a certain extent, Shanghai has a plan in place to achieve this. The plan calls for "one core, three circular belts, six development corridors, and eight medium-sized cities." The core will be the central business and commercial areas. Three belts and six development corridors will concentrate on specific industries such as petrochemical, electronic machinery, automotives, and other activities. These are all linked with major highways, subways, bridge, and an additional airport (Han 2000). 24 longer term. 5 Furthermore, such entry depends upon spatial development policies in urban and suburban areas. Industrial hollowing is not inevitable but once it gathers momentum it is difficult to reverse. Manufacturing offers the densest backward and forward linkages among the various economic activities. From the input-output table for the United States, it can be seen that manufacturing industry is the largest consumer of other intermediate inputs, consuming about 30 percent of all the intermediate inputs (see Table 3.9). It is the largest consumer of the agriculture, mining, utilities, manufacturing, and transportation sectors and of warehousing, wholesale, retail, professional and business services, and of scrap material. Finance, insurance, and real estate (FIRE) consumes about 14 percent of the intermediate inputs, the second largest overall consumer after the manufacturing sector. However, FIRE consumes only 2.4 percent of manufacturing output for intermediate use. 6 The bulk of intermediate inputs consumed by FIRE are provided by construction, real estate being the largest consumer of the output of the construction industry, FIRE itself, arts and entertainment, and other services. As in the U.S, the manufacturing industry is China's largest consumer of other intermediate inputs; consuming 44 percent of all the intermediate inputs (see Table 3.10). Unlike the United States, China's banking and insurance sectors are major consumers of manufacturing output. The Case for Complex Capital Goods As cities ascend the income ladder, the attractiveness of certain types of manufacturing industries increases. One set of activities are those whose profitability rests upon the slow accumulation of learning, tacit knowledge and specialized skills. This is a type of industry that produces customized, complex capital goods or engages in small batch production of customized high value items. Industries producing complex capital goods ­ e.g., plant equipment, power generating equipment and transport 5 Entry barriers to firms are a function among other things of the efficacy of competition laws. China's antimonopoly law - promulgated on August 30, 2007 - finally came into force on August 1, 2008 ("China's Landmark" 2008). It is too early to judge whether this law would be effective (Mehra and Meng 2008). 6 The information sector (financial services, other producer services, and advanced consumer services) consumed very little of the manufacturing output in 1972 and also in 1996. The share of outputs sold by the information sector to goods production and distribution sector between 1972 and 1996 dropped significantly, from 44.0 percent to 18.7 percent. This suggest that the goods producing sector is becoming a less important customer for the information producing industry (Drennan 2002). 25 equipment ­ have significant backward linkages and involve a host of specialized suppliers, which frequently cluster near the main assemblers, collaborate in joint R&D programs to meet specific needs of end users, and in producing new generations of equipment. 7 With respect to innovation in the capital goods and components industries, Cooke and others (2007, p.57) note that "these are characterized by a systematic knowledge. In such settings, the application of existing knowledge or the new combination of available knowledge may lead to innovations. This often occurs in the need to solve actual problems on the shop floor or in the interaction with key customers or users or suppliers. Research and development are generally less important and university industry links are less frequent. Knowledge is created ... through an inductive process of testing, experimentation or through practical work." The revealed comparative advantage of Germany, 8 Japan and Korea still lies in these industries. Such industries also derive substantial revenues from after sales services, upgrading or refurbishing existing equipment (e.g. aircraft, earthmoving equipment, engines, and railways) and by supplying spare parts for long lived capital goods. Global suppliers of complex goods can sustain a flotilla of affiliated firms providing well paid jobs in an urban environment. In line with this reasoning, The 11th Five Year Plan gave priority to the complex capital goods sector, calling for the market share of domestic independent brand owners to exceed 50 percent of the automobile and machinery industries by 2010. Progress while adequate, has fallen short of plan targets with market shares of domestic firms being 26 percent and 31 percent respectively in 2007 (World Bank 2008b). As noted above and demonstrated by the recent experience of the U.S., Germany and Japan, complex capital goods, components and electrical equipment are among the industrial products most suited for capital abundant economies with a skilled and high 7 This collaborative activity between assemblers and their suppliers most notably in the transport sector is well known and is associated with the embracing of JIT delivery practices. Subcontractors have taken on the responsibility for major modules (See Smitka 1991). Collaboration and proximity might be taken a step further if Toyota for example realizes its ambition to further minimize the movement of parts (Stewart and Raman 2007). 8 Manufactures comprise 83 percent of Germany's exports with transport equipment and automotive being the leading exports. 26 wage workforce. 9 This is apparent from the estimates of the revealed comparative advantages of these countries (see Table 3.1 to Table 3.4), 10 the top 10 export goods from Germany (see Table 3.5), and also from the rising share of these exports (see Table 3.6). The fact that these industries have survived and prospered in the advanced countries singles them out as the right candidates for China's premier industrial city. However, there are other reasons for making these industries an integral part of a growth strategy. Table 3.1: Revealed Comparative Advantage in Engineering and Electronics Goods, 2006 RCA Germany 1.1 Japan 1.4 USA 1.1 9 The most dynamic Japanese firms in the country's shrinking manufacturing g sector are ones that are specialized in components in engineering and in materials technologies. These are companies contributing to the success of some of the latest Apple products and the newest generation of jet airliners (Schaede 2008). 10 Revealed comparative advantage (RCA) is often used to measure the export competitiveness of a commodity (or an industry) of a country. It is a ratio of two shares: the share of a commodity's export in the overall exports of a country; and the share of the same commodity in global exports (see the equation below). Export ij Export ij RCA = i Export j ij Export i j ij , where i denotes the commodity and j denotes countries (over the set of commodities, i = 1...I, and over the set of countries, j = 1...J). An RCA greater than one means that the country has a "revealed comparative advantage" in that commodity. This is assuming that the numerator and the denominator are increasing. If that is not the case, greater care is needed in interpreting the results. Rearranging the equation, one can obtain, Export ij Export ij RCA = j . Export i ij Export i j ij The numerator is now country j's market share of commodity i in the world export market and the denominator is country j's share of exports in overall world exports. Thus, even if country j is losing market share, if overall exports from country j relative to world exports are shrinking faster, the RCA will be greater than one (S. Lall, Weiss and Zhang 2006). 27 Source: UN Comtrade Table 3.2: Selected Japanese Exports with High RCA, 2006 Technology SITC4 Short description RCA Class 7851 Motorcycles, auto-cycles; side-cars of all kind, etc 6.5189 MT1 7126 Steam power units (mobile engines but not steam tractors, etc) 6.5187 HT2 8841 Lenses and other optical elements of any material 4.7949 MT3 7133 Internal combustion piston engines, marine propulsion 4.6160 MT3 Note: Technology classification is based on S. Lall (2000). PP: Primary Products, RB1: Agro-Based, RB2: Other Resource-Based, LT1: Textile, garment & footwear, LT2: Other, Low-Technology, MT1: Automotive, MT2: Process, MT3: Engineering, HT1: Electronic & Electrical, and HT2: Other, High- Technology. Source: UN Comtrade Table 3.3: Selected German Exports with High RCA, 2006 Technology SITC4 Short description RCA Class 7911 Rail locomotives, electric 5.0069 MT2 7264 Printing presses 4.3978 MT3 7913 Mechanically propelled railway, tramway, trolleys, etc 3.8624 MT2 7423 Rotary pumps (other than those of heading 74281) 3.8014 MT3 7163 Rotary converters 3.6922 HT1 Note: Technology classification is based on S. Lall (2000). PP: Primary Products, RB1: Agro-Based, RB2: Other Resource-Based, LT1: Textile, garment & footwear, LT2: Other, Low-Technology, MT1: Automotive, MT2: Process, MT3: Engineering, HT1: Electronic & Electrical, and HT2: Other, High- Technology. Source: UN Comtrade 28 Table 3.4: Selected Korean Exports with High RCA, 2006 Technology SITC4 Short description RCA Class 8710 Optical instruments and apparatus 9.7947 HT2 7932 Ships, boats and other vessels 8.8697 MT3 7938 Tugs, special purpose vessels and floating structures 7.5444 MT3 7761 Television picture tubes, cathode ray 5.6905 HT1 7247 Textile machinery, nes for cleaning, cutting, etc, and parts nes 4.8618 MT3 Note: Technology classification is based on S. Lall (2000). PP: Primary Products, RB1: Agro-Based, RB2: Other Resource-Based, LT1: Textile, garment & footwear, LT2: Other, Low-Technology, MT1: Automotive, MT2: Process, MT3: Engineering, HT1: Electronic & Electrical, and HT2: Other, High- Technology. Source: UN Comtrade Table 3.5: Germany's Top 10 Exports, 2006 Share of total Commodities exports Road vehicles 16.9 Electric machinery, apparatus and appliances, nes, and parts, nes 7.9 General industrial machinery and equipment, nes, and parts of, nes 7.1 Machinery specialized for particular industries 5.1 Medicinal and pharmaceutical products 4.2 Power generating machinery and equipment 4.0 Miscellaneous manufactured articles, nes 3.7 Artificial resins and plastic materials, and cellulose esters etc 3.3 Manufactures of metals, nes 3.3 Iron and steel 3.1 Source: UN Comtrade Table 3.6: Share of Engineering and Electronics Exports in Germany, Japan, and the US (%) 1978 2006 Germany 32.8 33.1 Japan 41.1 45.6 US 28.9 35.7 Source: UN Comtrade Other types of manufacturing industries are profitable because they innovate incrementally and every so often introduce a revolutionary (disruptive) new product that 29 redraws market boundaries and brings new firms to the forefront. 11 This category of manufacturing industries ranges from food processing and cosmetics to medical imaging and nanotechnology to new materials. But they all share one distinctive feature. They are all R&D intensive, often rely on research covering several fields and frequently draw upon the basic or applied research conducted in universities or specialized institutes (Boozer and others 2003; Jaruzelski and Dehoff 2007a; Jaruzelski, Dehoff and Bordia 2005;2006). Firms in industries associated with the life sciences and in advanced materials, are not infrequently started by university faculty, draw upon the research conducted in universities, and are heavy users of legal, 12 consulting, managerial and financial services with the result that they integrate closely with the services providers in the city. Both types of industries depend for their growth, profitability and longer term survival, on knowledge deepening and on product differentiation through customization, innovation of all kinds, including business models, and the packaging of products with services ("The World's Most" 2006). 13 II. Industrial Productivity and Innovation Retaining a manufacturing base that is knowledge intensive, relies beyond technological capabilities, upon innovation to keep its competitive edge and flexibly accommodates new industries as existing ones migrate, is critically dependent upon three types of services. First there is the quality of the education imparted by urban schools, how effectively it instills science and math skills, and whether it nurtures a spirit of enquiry and an aptitude at solving problems (Yusuf 2009b). A solid base of primary, 11 Many innovative firms also reorganize the way in which they conduct their R&D ("The World's Most" 2006). In the 2008 edition of the "World' Most Innovative Companies" by Business Week, no Chinese firms made it to top 50, while two firms (Tata and Reliance) from India did so (http://bwnt.businessweek.com/interactive_reports/innovative_companies/). See also Christensen and Raynor (2003). 12 IP protection is frequently a concern for high-tech firms in areas such as biotechnology and electronics. 13 The success of innovations in advanced materials has been closely associated with complementary innovations which can delay adoption or widespread use for many years. Realizing the full potential of glassfibre was paced by the evolution of laser technology which brought the fibre-optic infrastructure into existence; Kevlar came into widespread use following advances in the design of body armor. And currently proton exchange membrane (PEM) fuel cells for automobiles are in a holding pattern waiting for other innovations which will reduce production costs and lead to superior catalysts and fuel cell stacks that together will result in an economically viable substitute for the internal combustion engine (Maine and Garnsey 2005). 30 secondary and technical/vocational schooling is the foundation of an industrially diverse global city. A sound university system with several world class universities builds upon this and produces the advanced STEM (science, technology, engineering, and mathematics) skills required by dynamic urban industries whether manufacturing or services. 14 A third set of services is provided by the city's research establishment. This is usually centered on a few key universities but also includes private and public research institutions, 15 which collaborate with leading local or multinational companies and contribute to the tenor of activities in the city. Openness and networking among local researchers and their interaction with peers around the world is a knowledge multiplier whose value is increasingly recognized. Only Certain Industrial Sectors Are Innovative From the past experience of the United States, it turns out that equipment, components and materials producing industries were among the twenty which registered the greatest gains in total factor productivity between 1960 and 2005 with office equipment and electronic components being the first and the fourth on the list. Should such trends extend into the future then Shanghai's own industries will benefit doubly from combination of catching-up and continuing growth of productivity in these subsectors in the advanced economies. Figure 3.4 also shows that productivity rose in several service industries such as wholesale and retail trade, real estate, telecommunications and banks. However, it should be noted that much of this increase occurred after the mid 1990s and was the result mainly of major advances in IT and logistics starting in the 1980s, coupled with innovations in business models (Oliner and Sichel 2000). A significant part of the gains have accrued from the introduction of new equipment ­ computers, other office equipment, telecommunications equipment, etc., that 14 In the U.S. math related occupations are the most well-paid ("Doing the Math" 2009). 15 Starting in 1999, China restructured public research institutes to become enterprises while providing financial support, at least initially. Some of the reformed research institutes are now listed in Shanghai or Shenzhen Stock Exchange (World Bank 2009b). 31 is they are driven by improvements in hardware. 16 IT hardware has enabled providers of services to increase the efficiency of their supply chains and warehousing, to diversify their services, to consolidate their operations, and to outsource and massively reduce the labor intensity of their operations. 16 But not just hardware, software, organizational changes, changes in work practices and training all contributed. 32 Figure 3.4: Industry Contributions to Total Factor Productivity Growth in the US, 1960-2005 Source: Jorgenson and others (2007). 33 Arguably this surge of productivity in services is unlikely to persist (it has been much less evident in other advanced countries 17 and has declined in the United States since 2005), absent significant breakthroughs in hardware, in the delivery of services or in their quality. 18 Data from the USPTO shows that leading companies in the most productive services, activities took out few patents as can be seen from Table 3.7. The firm with the most patents is Target, a retailer, with 441 patents since 1976. By comparison, during the same period, IBM was granted more than 49,000 patents, GE more than 27,000, and Intel ­ a relatively young firm compared to the first two ­ more than 16,000. Table 3.7: Patents Granted to Services-Oriented Firms Cumulative Number of Patents since Firms 1976 Accenture 284 Goldman Sachs 50 JP Morgan 29 General Electric Capital 45 Citibank 112 American Express Travel 181 GE CAPITAL COMMERCIAL FINANCE 16 UNITED PARCEL SERVICE OF AMERICA 210 Fedex Corporation 3 BANK ONE, DELAWARE, NATIONAL ASSOCIATION 8 THE CHASE MANHATTAN BANK 31 CITICORP DEVELOPMENT CENTER 56 GE CORPORATE FINANCIAL SERVICES 6 VISA INTERNATIONAL SERVICE ASSOCIATION 59 REUTERS LIMITED 32 RESTAURANT SERVICES 6 Wal-Mart 15 Target 441 Note: Patent search was conducting using the above assignee names. Data current as of October 28, 2008 Source: USPTO (http://patft.uspto.gov/netahtml/PTO/search-bool.html). 17 This might be linked to the strength of labor unions and other laws protecting small services providers. 18 While process innovations associated with investment in IT hardware led to positive productivity growth for the financial sector, the financial crisis of 2008 calls into the question of the merit of a number of product innovations in financial sector (and the effectiveness of data mining techniques), especially that of derivatives ("Wind Down" 2009). 34 Empirical findings have pointed to the high returns that accrue from R&D and also the relationship between R&D and technological change which feeds GDP growth (Wieser 2005). Not all activities stimulate R&D because in many, the scope for conducting formal research is relatively small. Most services fall into this category as do a number of light industries. Figure 3.5 shows the R&D intensities (measured by R&D spending as a share of sales) among different subsectors based on top 1,000 R&D spenders globally, and Figure 3.6 which uses data from 10 leading OECD countries presents the variation in research intensity across a range of subsectors. Clearly, the manufacturing industries led by office and computing machinery are in the forefront followed by pharmaceuticals and machinery and transport equipment. In fact, the bulk of R&D spending is in just three areas, electronics, pharmaceuticals (including biotechnology) and machinery and equipment of all kinds, particularly automotive equipment (see Figure 3.7). The auto industry will remain one of the most research intensive and one where the scope for innovation is wide for a number of reasons. First, the development of commercially viable "clean" automobiles will absorb a large volume of R&D in hybrid, electric, and fuel cell technologies plus other alternatives. 19 SAIC and Volkswagen are already engaged in such research in collaboration with Tongji University. Second, the increasing use of electronics in improving the performance of auto engines, entertainment systems, dashboard displays and safety and handling features opens fruitful opportunities for innovation. Already premium cars require 100 million lines of code to operate their electronic control units, and electronics accounts for almost 40 percent of the value of the vehicle. Third, the auto industry is also greatly interested in advanced materials which can reduce weight and facilitate the repair and recycling of the vehicle (Charette 2009). 20 As environmental regulations and their implementation are 19 The Chinese government plans to increase the production capacity of hybrid and electric cars to 500,000 units by 2011. In 2007, the production of these alternative cars were only 2,100. To stimulate the demand for hybrid and electric cars, the government is offering $8,800 per vehicles purchased to taxi companies and local governments. The government is also requring the power companies to install charging stations for electric cars in Shanghai, Beijing, and Tianjing ("China Vies" 2009). 20 Automobiles have evolved into highly complex systems and the trend with hybrids, electric and fuel cell based automobiles is towards greater technical complexity entailing a vast amount of ground breaking research. A premium car now has 70 to 100 microprocessor based electronic control units (ECU), which can execute up to 100 million lines of code. This is comparable to the number of ECUs in the Airbus 380 (not including the aircraft's entertainment system). A car's electronics and software amount to between 15 35 tightened in Shanghai and across China, and with greater emphasis on energy efficiency, the pressure to innovate can only increase (Gallagher 2006; Gan 2003). The share of the services sector is the smallest, which is not to deny that services industries do not innovate, in fact they do, but formal R&D plays a small role and policies that can influence R&D will have little effect on innovation in services. For services, business model innovations may be more important. Figure 3.5: R&D as A Share of Sales 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 to er er m ls re et se gy cs ria Au th co um ca rn en er ni O te st le ns tro th En ef du Te In al D Co ec In d d He d an an el an nd e ls e ar ica ra ac ftw te em sp So pu ro Ch m Ae Co Source: Jaruzelski and Dehoff (2007b) and 40 percent of the total cost and as cars become smarter, this share could soon approach 50 percent (Charette 2009). 36 Figure 3.6: R&D Intensity by Industry 37 Figure 3.7: Top R&D Spending Sectors among Top 1000 R&D Spenders Computer and electronics Health care Auto Industrials Chemicals and Energy Software and Internet Aerospace and Defense Consumer Telecom Other Source: Jaruzelski and Dehoff (2007b) Patent data from the USPTO and from China underscores the relative importance of innovation in manufacturing. Invention patents are more numerous in manufacturing industries, notwithstanding a considerable jump in services (inventions) patents over the past decade. It should be noted that questions have been raised as to the quality of patents issued for software and other services. Within manufacturing industries, only a dozen or so industrial subsectors account for 60-70 percent of the invention patents. Comparing Figure 3.8 and Figure 3.9, it is apparent that the distribution of the patents seems to have become more skewed towards only a handful of the subsectors, namely electronic components, office machines, and professional and scientific instruments (see Figure 3.9). This concentration is even more pronounced in Shanghai as shown below (see Table 5.35). 38 Figure 3.8: Share of Patents by Industry, 1986 Professional and Scientific Instruments Electronic components and accessories and communications equipment Fabricated Metal Products Industrial organic chemistry Rubber and Miscellaneous Plastics Products General industrial machinery and equipment Special industry machinery, except metal w orking Office computing and accounting machines Drugs and medicines Electrical transmission and distribution equipment Metal w orking machinery and equipment Stone, Clay, Glass and Concrete products Motor vehicles and other motor vehicle equipment 0.0 5.0 10.0 15.0 20.0 25.0 Source: Authors' calculation based on USPTO data 39 Figure 3.9: Share of Patents by Industry, 2006 Electronic components and accessories and communications equipment Office computing and accounting machines Professional and Scientific Instruments Electrical transmission and distribution equipment Industrial organic chemistry Drugs and medicines Fabricated Metal Products Radio and television receiving equipment except communication type General industrial machinery and equipment Rubber and Miscellaneous Plastics Products Motor vehicles and other motor vehicle equipment 0.0 5.0 10.0 15.0 20.0 25.0 Source: Authors' calculation based on USPTO data Interactions with Universities Industrial competitiveness and industrial resilience in the face of shocks and shifting industrial fortunes is closely tied to the capabilities of the education and research 40 infrastructure that adds to the stock of the pool of scientific knowledge, and of skills. The depth and quality of the pool of skills is a determinant of productivity and also the speed with which local industry can respond to competitive threats as well as to new opportunities. 21 Research universities are ideally placed to conduct basic and interdisciplinary research which underpins innovation and which firms and specialized research institutions are unwilling (because of the low perceived commercial potential) or unequipped (narrow focus and/or applied R&D orientation) to do. However, close engagement between firms and local universities, is vital for three reasons. First it energizes research in both firms and universities ­ generally firms that link with universities do more research themselves (Adams and Clemmons 2008). Second being close to leading research universities is valuable to firms because the latest findings and state of the art knowledge diffuses slowly and usually by word of mouth 22 ­ hence physical proximity and formal or informal links matter. Third, interaction between firms and universities enables universities to raise funds and to create and to staff suitably tailored programs for local firms. The business community can, in addition, provide feedback to universities directly and through internships on how they can improve pedagogical practices, the curriculum, practical training and communication and teamwork skills, so as to enhance students' readiness for careers after they graduate. (Bramwell and Wolfe 2008; Lundvall 2007). Tertiary education can in turn become a leading sector in its own right, one that has high added value, substantial multiplier effects on the local economy and the potential for exporting its services and in the process attracting talent from overseas, as Boston and San Francisco have been able to do by leveraging their world class universities. 23 21 E. L. Glaeser (2005a) ascribes the revival of Boston in the 1980s to the abundant supply of human capital and ideas generated by the area's universities. 22 Seminars and conferences organized by universities are venues for airing and discussing ongoing research (Bramwell and Wolfe 2008). 23 Direct or `first round' contributions of major universities in the United States to the local and state economy, in terms of income and employment created, are substantial. In 2002, the eight universities, comprising Boston College, Boston University, Brandeis University, Harvard University, the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Northeastern University, Tufts University and the University of Massachusetts, in the Boston metropolitan area employed 50,750 people, exceeding the number employed 41 Technology intensive manufacturing stimulates and can help partially finance university research with the potential for substantial spillovers. The proximity of industry and industry-university partnerships can lend a focus to a university's applied research, facilitates a quicker dissemination of the findings and their commercialization. If there is one important lesson to be drawn from the experience of Silicon Valley it is that the presence of several companies operating at the frontiers of high technology industries, catalyzed the university based research and training infrastructure and generated immensely fruitful symbiotic relationships between Silicon Valley firms and universities such as Stanford, UC Berkeley and San Jose State. It was the presence of firms with a hunger for new technology which set the stage for the emergence of a local innovation system. However, an integrated and productive system might never have emerged were it not for the initiative of universities which glimpsed an opportunity and took steps to grasp it by setting up new departments, attracting talent from across the United States and by Greater Boston's financial services industry. Four amongst these and their five affiliated medical centers qualify as the top 25 employers in Massachusetts. In 2002, local employees earned approximately $2.2 billion from all eight universities. In addition, new construction projects generated around 3,300 full- time jobs in 2000. Students and visitors spent $850 and $250 million in 2000. The estimated impact of the universities' $3.9 billion spending (payroll, purchase and construction) as well as expenditures by affiliated institutions and students and visitors had a regional impact of $7 billion in 2000. The concurrent employment generated was 37,000 full-time jobs (Appleseed 2003). During FY 2006-07, UC San Diego made a net contribution of approximately $463.1 million to the economy of the San Diego area in Southern California based on its expenditure of $1.7 billion on salaries and wages, goods and services and construction and revenue of $1.2 billion from within the county. It is among the top 3 employers locally employing 16,760 people, second only to the State of California and the Federal Government. In FY 2006-07, UC San Diego spent over $625.3 million on purchases of goods and services and construction in the San Diego County, and $1.1 billion on wages and salaries. Using the IMPLAN input-output model, CBRE estimated that the "total" economic consequences, incorporating direct, indirect, and induced impact, of the University's spending on the above mentioned activities, at the state level, was approximately $4.0 billion in total spending, 34,230 full-time equivalent jobs, and $2.3 billion in income generated, in the 2006-07 fiscal year. Using the same model, "total" economic impacts associated with spending incurred by students, extension and international students, visitors, and retirees, was estimated to be $600 million in total spending, 4,770 full-time equivalent jobs, and $288 million income generated at the state level during FY 2006-07 (CBRE consulting 2008). Indirect or `second round' effects of university research on the regional economy, in terms of starting up ventures and consequent income and jobs generated have also been substantial in a few cases as in the Boston area and in San Diego. Analog Devices, Biogen, EMC, Lycos and Staples are examples of major companies founded by alumni from these universities, four among which are listed in the top 25 employers. The universities started up 41 new ventures in 2000. Licensing of university technologies to private enterprises generated $44.5 million income. The local economy has also been given a boost due to national and international companies' (e.g. Amgen, Cisco, Merck, Novartis, Pfizer and Sun Microsystems) decision to locate major research operations in the Boston area (Appleseed 2003). 42 overseas, and designing courses to meet the current and emerging needs of local firms. 24 In other words, by strengthening their capacity to meet the skilled manpower and upstream research needs of an industry. Replicating this model has proven to be difficult elsewhere in the United States and abroad. 25 The Role of Small and Young Firms Although those large corporations, which have successfully routinized the art of (generally incremental) innovation, comprise the vanguard of the innovation system in any country, in a number of dynamic scientific fields such as the life sciences, advanced materials, and IT, "young innovative companies" are significant contributors and the source of most of the radical innovations. Once reason why the United States is the innovation frontrunner is because it provides a hospitable environment for large number of young innovative firms who contribute to both R&D and to sales (see Veugelers 2009, Table 3.8). Table 3.8: Major Innovations by Small US Firms in the Twentieth Century Air conditioning High-resolution CAT scanner Optical scanner Biomagnetic imaging Hydraulic brake Pacemaker Polaroid camera Kidney stone laser Quick-frozen food Electronic spreadsheet Microprocessor Soft contact lenses Heat sensor Magnetic resonance scanner Two-armed mobile robot Source: Veugelers (2009) Two necessary conditions for the multiplication of promising new ventures are entrepreneurial talent and ideas. These depend upon the existence of large firms and research universities. Both are a source of experienced and talented people, of fruitful ideas springing from their own research and knowledge of technologies, and by other 24 Rosenberg (2003) observes that "Stanford's responsiveness in the case of IC [technology] lay in the speed with which it diffused knowledge of an invention that had already been developed in industry and not in the academic world, a speed that was of great competitive significance for both Stanford and Silicon Valley" (p.118). After the IC was introduced, Stanford's Electrical Engineering Department launched a course on design and fabrication. Each time IC technology improved, Stanford initiated new courses or modified its curriculum so that new generations of engineers were fully conversant with the latest technologies and could contribute to their further advancement (Rosenberg 2003, p.114). 25 On variant models, some of which have enjoyed success, see Yusuf and Nabeshima (2007) 43 similar entities (Avnimelech, Kenney and Teubal 2004). 26 Entrepreneurship with assistance from public providers can gradually enhance the supply of patient capital, lack of which generally impedes the birth of firms. Much has been made of venture capital but in the vast majority of cases, whether in the Untied States or in East Asia banks - public or private ­ have provided the supplementary financing for start-up firms whose primary source of funding is invariably own resources and the resources of the family and friends. Venture capitalists especially if they are highly experienced, well-established providers with deep pockets can make a difference to the prospects of start-up firms with innovative ideas but not to the pace of innovation itself (Hirukawa and Ueda 2008a;b). But VCs can make this difference only under certain conditions. First, they have to be highly selective and skilled in picking potential winners with the right VC friendly technologies. Second, they need to be in a position to put up a significant amount of financing over a number of years with reference to performance and actively assist firms manage, develop products, and market. Third, their own profitability rests upon investing in companies which can establish their worth in not much more than five years (Puri and Zarutskie 2008). 27 The refinement, testing, development and marketing of most bio- pharmaceuticals and advanced materials can easily take 10 to 15 years which is longer than what venture capitalists are willing to wait. Hence, they either will select firms promising an early pay-off or provide mezzanine financing to companies with a proven product. Public providers of patient capital ­ development banks or venture capitalists ­ can wait longer, but their success rate is also low. Perhaps the most successful model is one with several large firms which depend upon growth through innovation and are on the lookout for firms with good products; a 26 Successful spinout institutions are closely networked with university faculty members, with financial institutions and with providers of business services. Business angels can also provide valuable support especially with respect to the management of fledgling firms because most often, it is the quality of management rather than of the technology which determines success. Few scientists can substitute for managers with professional expertise. Promoting spinouts can on occasion be valuable for universities because their success and the technology they commercialize are indicators of the nature and utility of the research being conducted by the university (European Commission 2002). See Kenney and Florida (2000) on the role of VC in Silicon Valley, Kenney, Han and Tanaka (2004) on the development of VC in East Asia, and Zhang (2008) on China. 27 Interestingly, the likelihood of a new company succeeding with venture capital or other traditional sources of financing, are about even although at the end of five years, firms which had received financing from venture capitalists, are likely to be larger. 44 system for financing start-ups using public funds channeled through banks and other public agencies complemented by private VCs; and emerging clusters of networked firms which provide a base of specialized suppliers, and of mutually reinforcing R&D activities and are a source of valuable technological spillovers. Innovation Drivers Innovation as measured by R&D and patenting seems to be influenced by five sets of policies and institutions: - policies affecting the composition of industry, of acquired technological capability and the contribution of FDI (and the diaspora) to this capability - policies affecting urban scale and urbanization economies as well as knowledge spillovers in urban centers 28 - education and research policies which determine the foundation building strengths of primary and secondary schooling, the quality of tertiary education and the volume and productivity of research 29 - socio political institutions which assign status and recognition to learning, and encourage intellectual achievement; safeguard intellectual property; and which also promote openness to ideas and to the circulation of knowledge workers - Institutions which stimulate competition among producers of ideas, of goods, and of services which regulate performance and set standards. In other words, countries need first to build their knowledge base and to move closer to the frontiers of technology in selected fields. Once this is achieved there is scope for sustained innovation. But acquiring this technological capability is no simple matter ­ it remains uncodified. 30 And once countries have acquired substantial technological depth and are near the frontiers of knowledge, it is difficult to say what might push the system 28 The importance of such openness and the contribution diversity can make has been strongly championed by Florida (2002). 29 Patenting by Korean residents has been influenced by both the spread of higher education and the increasing expenditure on R&D (Lee and Kim 2009). 30 Nonetheless, the Japanese experience shows that foremost investment in human capital is critical and the government can assist firms assimilate foreign technologies and develop indigenous technologies (P. Fan and Watanabe 2006). 45 they have created to deliver high and persisting levels of innovation. Spending on R&D can help; the innovation strategies of major firms can make a contribution especially if they spin-off innovative firms; and the excellence of the research universities can feed the pool of skills, of ideas, and of entrepreneurship. Beyond this there is little concrete to say. Whether research can fulfill the demands of national policymakers and CEOs who would like to routinize innovation, remains an open question. 46 Table 3.9: Share of Intermediate Input Use in the United States, 2002 Finance, insuranc e, real For the distribution of commodities consumed by an industry, read estate, Profession the column for that industry. Transportati rental, al and For the distribution of industries consuming a commodity, read the Manufacturi Wholes Retail on and Informati and business row for that commodity. ng ale trade trade warehousing on leasing services Agriculture, forestry, fishing and hunting 63.0 0.1 0.8 0.0 0.0 0.6 0.3 Mining 60.5 0.0 0.0 0.5 0.1 0.6 0.2 Utilities 32.4 2.5 6.6 1.9 2.3 9.6 4.3 Construction 8.0 0.7 2.0 2.9 3.5 36.4 3.3 Manufacturing 55.5 1.7 2.6 2.7 2.3 2.4 2.9 Wholesale trade 50.3 7.4 3.9 2.2 1.8 3.4 2.3 Retail trade 11.2 1.0 3.0 2.9 0.2 10.8 1.2 Transportation and warehousing 23.5 7.5 7.7 18.3 3.2 3.6 6.3 Information 8.4 2.3 3.0 1.7 34.6 7.7 14.1 Finance, insurance, real estate, rental, and leasing 5.8 2.8 6.0 3.1 3.3 42.3 9.5 Professional and business services 20.5 5.5 4.9 3.1 6.1 11.2 15.3 Educational services, health care, and social assistance 0.2 0.9 4.5 0.1 0.9 0.2 1.1 Arts, entertainment, recreation, accommodation, and food services 9.0 2.4 3.0 2.8 10.3 12.9 22.2 Other services, except government 11.9 4.0 4.5 3.5 4.7 16.3 13.0 Government 3.2 9.9 9.4 17.7 5.1 8.9 8.5 Scrap, used and secondhand goods 75.1 0.0 3.8 6.6 0.5 -5.0 3.2 Other inputs1 16.8 7.3 0.5 15.9 11.1 21.1 8.4 Total intermediate inputs 30.2 3.4 4.1 3.6 5.0 13.6 8.1 Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis (http://www.bea.gov/industry/xls/2002summary_makeuse_sector.xls) Table 3.10: Share of Intermediate Input Use in China, 2002 Wholesale and Retail Trades, Real Transportation, Hotels Estate, Postal and and Leasing and Banking Telecommunic Catering Business and Other Manufacturing ation Services Services Services Insurance Services Intermediate Input Agriculture 48.0 0.8 7.8 0.1 0.0 0.7 Production and Supply of Electric 51.7 2.8 6.5 3.2 1.1 8.0 Coking, Gas and Petroleum Refining 30.4 28.7 4.6 0.8 0.4 4.5 Mining and Quarrying 37.4 0.7 0.5 0.4 0.0 1.9 Construction 3.8 10.7 12.5 20.1 6.1 41.0 Manufacturing 1.4 0.5 13.4 2.4 13.7 37.0 Transportation, Postal and Telecommunication Services 39.1 14.9 6.1 2.2 1.9 9.2 Wholesale and Retail Trades, Hotels and Catering Services 46.7 3.0 9.2 4.6 2.0 12.7 Real Estate, Leasing and Business Services 30.6 3.0 14.3 7.9 7.8 17.2 Banking and Insurance 24.6 11.5 17.8 12.0 7.9 8.2 Other Services 27.3 3.1 11.1 5.5 2.7 26.1 Total Input 43.8 4.7 7.8 5.5 2.3 9.8 Source: China Statistical Yearbook 2007 Chapter 4 Pitfalls of Early De-Industrialization The industrial revolution unleashed a wave of urbanization which has spread from the West to the rest of the world and shows no sign of receding. This it did by enormously accelerating the generation of wealth and employment through a production system rooted in cities. 1 Industry flourished in cities because it was easier to raise capital, to hire workers, to find buyers for products, to obtain needed services, to gather information, and to find housing and other amenities. 2 From at least the mid nineteenth century onwards, modern manufacturing industry became one of the principal if not the principal drivers of growth in all the major cities (and some smaller towns) of Europe and the United States and later of Japan as well. Industry maintained a dominant position through the middle of the twentieth century, however, from then onwards the situation began changing in at least the leading cities of the advanced countries. The share of industry began to shrink and that of services to expand. How quickly this occurred and, how radically it altered the urban landscape can be observed from the experience of four cities ­ New York, 3 London, Tokyo, and Chicago. These cities account for a substantial share of the national income of their respective countries (see Table 4.1). 4 1 Hohenberg and Lees (1995) observe that "the first phase of modern industrialization continued the emphasis on rural investment with the building of railroads and the progressive mechanization of manufactures. As the workers concentrated around mills and workshops, industrial capital simply became urban. In later phases, factories and their machinery were predominantly sited in urban places" (p.176). "Modern industry [in the nineteenth century] meant principally iron, cotton textiles, and steam driven machinery" (p. 194). 2 See Hohenberg and Lees (1995). 3 Shanghai is often compared to New York and sometimes referred to as "Chinese New York", among other nicknames such as the "Oriental Pearl" and the "Paris of East" (H. Lu 2004). Partly this refers back to large international concessions set up in Shanghai after the Opium War (H. Lu 2004). 4 Using PPP rates, PwC estimates that the largest 30 cities in the world were responsible for 16 percent of global GDP in 2005 and the top 100 cities for a quarter of the GDP. Four East Asian cities were among the top 30 ­ ranked by GDP: Tokyo (1), Osaka-Kobe (7), Hong Kong (14) and Seoul (20). (PricewaterhouseCoopers 2007). See also the papers on global city regions in Scott (2001a). Table 4.1: Share of National Income (%), 2005 New York 8.3 Chicago 3.6 Tokyo (2000) 18.4 London 20 Source: Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2008; Japan Statistical Yearbooks, 2002. I. Services Expand Why have services squeezed out manufacturing from these cities? One explanation is the cost of land and labor in cities. It is claimed that, manufacturing being land intensive, moves out of the inner parts of major cities as rents rise and environmental regulations begin constraining those activities that are significant polluters (air, water, and noise). Manufacturing can transfer to the periphery of the city where rental costs are lower or it can seek green field sites in smaller and medium sized cities. A second explanation is higher wage costs. It is argued that the cost of living in large cities drives up wages and forces manufacturing, which is labor intensive, to migrate to areas where labor is cheaper 5. A third reason put forward is that services edge out manufacturing from the major cities because it is the demand for services that grows most strongly in urban areas. Furthermore, urban densification favors services because of effect it has on information flows and the transport cost advantages reaped by services (E. L. Glaeser 2005b). But fourth and most importantly, city authorities allied with urban residents, anxious to safeguard the quality of life, and developers have in all these cases actively pursued the development of housing and services in the CBD and core areas through zoning laws 6, real estate taxes, and preferential treatment. Urban planners believe that a concentration of services is more likely to contribute to longer term prosperity (because services are less subject to fluctuations in demand, are arguably less footloose, and have better long term prospects) and to urban revenues. 7 Noisy, polluting, low value adding 5 E. L. Glaeser (2009) points out that in 1970 workers demanded a hefty wage premium in large cities in the United States. However, as urban amenities have improved and crime has diminished, the premium also has vanished. 6 Zoning specifies rules governing permissible activities, sizes of lots, numbers of buildings and relationships between buildings. 7 New York's zoning ordinance of 1916 favoring the 5th Avenue retailers pushed out the garment industry with its workforce of poor immigrant women and Thomas Adam's Regional Plan of 1929 brought 50 manufacturing activities are seen more as a handicap than as an asset and are encouraged to relocate with a mix of negative and positive incentives. Developers and providers of real estate services actively support such development. The need for land use regulation through zoning began to be felt in New York in the latter half of the nineteenth century with the appearance of tall buildings 8 which overshadowed smaller structures, blocked light and impeded air circulation. 9 As early as 1860, a statute was introduced to ban commercial activities along the Eastern Parkway in Brooklyn. However, it was the construction of the 42 story Equitable Building in 1915 which brought home the problems associated with such large structures with no setbacks (New York City Government ). By 1916, New York had put in place the State Zoning Enabling Act. 10 This regulation and its subsequent extensions and modifications (in 1961 for example) came to determine the physical as well as the industrial characteristics of the city and very quickly they were adopted by Chicago "as these two world cities were linked not only with one another but with European traditions and models" (Abu-Lughod 1999, p.93). Zoning helped to privilege housing to absorb the enormous influx of migrants to the city, it accommodated the creation of mass-transit routes and the widening use of the automobile and it ensured through setbacks, 11 public plazas, green spaces and amenities that the building technologies facilitating ever taller buildings did not choke the livability of the city. However, zoning also ushered most manufacturing activities out of the core areas of New York into smaller towns and cities on the far periphery. It started with regulations to protect the wealthy residential districts in Manhattan's Upper East Side from the pollution caused by the garments and textile skyscraper based commercial activities to downtown areas and assigned industry to the periphery. In the 1980s, Michael Heseltine spearheaded initiatives which transformed London's governance and land use especially in the Docklands (P. Hall 1998). 8 The height of buildings was affected by three developments: the invention of the elevator; the introduction of the travelling crane; and the construction of buildings using steel frames and curtain walls instead of stone whose weight made it impossible to construct tall structures. 9 Until the invention of fluorescent lighting (1940) and air conditioning (1930s), the occupants of building depended upon natural light and air circulation through windows. For this reason offices were usually less than thirty feet deep. A tall building by blocking sunlight and the circulation of air, could thus create a serious problem for its neighbors (O'Flaherty 2005, p.172). 10 Zoning was first introduced in Frankfurt am Main in Germany in 1891 (O'Flaherty 2005, p.171). 11 In order to allow enough light and air to buildings lit by dim incandescent bulbs and without space cooling, buildings had to be stepped back as they increased in height with reference to a fixed angle from the center of the street. This resulted in a wedding cake configuration which endowed New York with its distinctive skyline (Abu-Lughod 1999, p.94-95). 51 industries which had mushroomed in close proximity (Freeman 2008). Thereafter, and gradually rezoning which favored commercial offices and housing developments ratcheted up the incentives for factories to exit the city. By the early decades of the twentieth century, with the spread of "banking, accounting, management, law, journalism, and advertizing ­ a new form of specialized human activity was firmly established the white collar office worker" (Reader 2006, p.256). In recent years, the effect of zoning on land use, lot sizes and housing in New York have been reinforced by environmental impact reviews and by the activities of the Landmarks Preservation Commission which has effectively blocked the construction of tall buildings in the better neighborhoods (E. L. Glaeser 2009). E. L. Glaeser, Gyourko and Saks (2005) estimate that the cost of regulation to be close to 100 percent of the actual building cost. 12 They note further that inefficient regulation stems from the gradual transfer of property rights (or rents) from developers to homeowners, who have the incentives to restrict and exercise their political rights to prevent additional supply of housing units so as to raise the prices of existing housing stocks. As a result, the number of permits approved for new housing units has declined in New York City, housing prices have increased dramatically since 1980s, and this has constrained the growth of the urban economy. Each of the above reasons carries some weight, however, the exodus of manufacturing activities from the leading global cities and the rise of the financial sector is also the outcome of historical circumstances. Early in the twentieth century, industry and logistics were the pillars of New York's economy. Garments, printing, sugar refining, footwear, electronics and meat packing industries generated $1.5 billion worth of output in 1910 (E. L. Glaeser 2005b). New York was also a major transport hub serving its own producers and those in its hinterland. 13 The exodus of industry commenced in the late 1920s and by the 1980s, New York was largely denuded of manufacturing except for tiny pockets in the core city14 and 12 This is even after taking account for possible negative externality associated with additional housing units such as congestion. 13 It was in addition, a magnet for migrants from Europe. 14 There were 2 million industrial jobs in 1950 and these declined to 500,000 by 2000. Most of the firms are small businesses in subsectors such as manufacturing, construction, wholesaling, utilities and waste management. Manufacturing firms are in high end garments, printing and publishing, furniture and food processing. The last two are among the fastest growing. 52 a few concentrations in the suburbs. New York's importance as a logistics hub also diminished rapidly as a result of containerization, competition from other ports, and the role of trade with East Asia which privileges ports on the West Coast, with the result that the city's economy became progressively more reliant on business and other services. 15 In particular, financial services, 16 already a significant force in New York's economy because of its earlier status as the country's biggest port, acquired ever greater weight as a gradual dismantling of regulations from the early 1970s, a strategy favoring the services sector and the start of globalization ushered in the golden age of finance (Eichengreen and Leblang 2008). By 1990, financial services in conjunction with insurance, legal, accounting and other professional services, accounted for 32 percent of total GDP. Other services and creative industries such as media, fashion and web-based services also mattered, but New York's economy mainly revolved around the well-oiled, money making machine extending from Wall Street to mid-Manhattan and reaching out to the far corners of the globe (E. L. Glaeser 2005b). 17 London and to a lesser extent Chicago, have both experienced similar seismic shifts. By favoring services over industry, London has allowed manufacturing to shrink into insignificance. 18 Its fortunes are tied to finance, other services, and tourism. The financial center in the City of London was the beneficiary of the commercial and marine activities associated with London's port, including the insurance market which was primarily engaged in insuring ships and cargoes. Three factors ensured that London remained at the center stage of international financial centers, along with New York and later Tokyo, over 1890-2000 (Cassis and Brussiere 2005). First, progressive financial specialization deepened expertise and helped build comparative advantage. By 1913, the city had almost 226 merchant banks and discount houses, major joint-stock or large European banks, which effectively made London the payments center of the international economy. By the end of the First World War, London retained the first rank in commerce, shipping, and marine insurance, and only New York was a larger source of 15 However, air cargo traffic remains important. 16 The development of New York and Chicago is described and compared by Abu-Lughod (1999). 17 One consequence of this noted by Markusen and Gwiasda (1994) is that New York does not benefit from multiple layers of functions, political, industrial, financial and industrial which promote innovation and a variety of employment opportunities 18 Since 1970, close to 600,000 jobs in manufacturing have been lost. 53 financing. Second was the city's ability to adapt to changing global challenges and to opportunities. In spite of the decline in the strength of the British economy and of sterling as an international currency after the Second World War, London grasped the opportunity arising from the restrictions imposed by the US government on the stock exchange and legislation which forbade commercial banks from engaging in investment banking. Consequently, some US banks opened offices in London. By the 1970s, the development of the Eurodollar market made London the center of attraction for banks that conducted international operations in money, foreign exchange, securities, and capital markets (exchange control were lifted in 1979). From 82 foreign banks in 1961, the number doubled to 159 in 1970 and to 280 by 1978. The resurgence of London to an international center for financial transactions was facilitated by the personnel and expertise that was retained from the heavily regulated years, during the 1940s and 50s, relearning of lost skills and willingness to accept foreigners especially from the US and the former Empire. Third, the deregulation of the securities industry in 1988 along with the related financial market reforms known as the "Big Bang," further enhanced the City of London's attractions and led to significant changes in business organizations. It resulted in dismantling of the traditional, specialized and modestly sized British firms, during the 1980s and 1990s, which were replaced by massive, globally active banks undertaking the full range of financial activities. A second set of complementary large firms comprising of lawyers, accountants, and (private equity and hedge) fund managers also emerged. An enabling regulatory and legal environment (a host of regulations were replaced by a single Financial Services Authority in 2001), sound accounting standards, and relatively lenient immigration rules for knowledge workers further boosted London's financial sector. By the beginning of the 21st century, London was consolidating its status as the foremost beneficiary of the globalization era (Cassis and Brussiere 2005). 19 The city profited from the growth of international trade which stimulated financial activities associated with trade - foreign exchange, ship and aircraft brokerage and insurance. 19 It is the only city in Europe which equals American levels of productivity and competitiveness. Brussels is a distant second. 54 Through its leadership of the international banking industry and aided by the advances in technology, London became the principal center for offshore financial activities in particular through the Eurobond market. The biggest impetus behind the economies of scale (enjoyed by the city), derived from the conglomeration of a large number of international services firms. Economies of scope arose from the availability of a critical mass of supporting, specialist services such as commercial lawyers, IT experts, and public relations consultants. The distribution of local employment clearly demonstrates the importance of the local workforce in terms of expertise in the financial sector. In 2000, around 40,000 people worked in the 481 foreign banks, while the domestic, head- office type banks occupied around 25,000. In addition, foreign exchange, investment banking, derivatives, fund management, insurance, and professional and specialist services employed another 200,000 people. Compared with the total of 360,000 in New York in 2000, the aggregate number of financial services workforce in London (335,000) far exceeded the 167,000 in Hong Kong (1997) and almost 80,000 in Frankfurt. As of 2007, the two financial hubs of New York and London remained far ahead of the rest of the world, and mutually benefited from the network effects reinforced by the surge in cross-border mergers and acquisitions and alternative investments ("Friends and rivals" 2007). 20 In contrast to London, which tapped foreign interests to maintain its vitality, New York looked inwards and relied more on straight-forward, heavily traded products such as equities (the NYSE together with NASDAQ accounted for almost half of the global trading in stocks in 2006), while London looked to profit from the legal, tax and regulatory advantages it had compared with the rest of Europe. New York prides in employing 15% of the local workforce in the financial sector. London, on the other hand, leads the field in structured finance and new stock listings. The City accounted for 24% of the world's exports of financial services (compared with 39% the United States as a whole), and two-thirds and 42% of EU's foreign-exchange and derivatives, and share trading was conducted in London. Chicago's strategic location at the point where the Illinois and Michigan canal links the Mississippi River with the Great Lakes made it a key transport hub during an era 20 Both cities have experienced population growth mainly through in-migration. In fact, almost 31 percent of London's population is foreign born. 55 when water borne transport was the lowest cost means of conveyance. Its role as a logistics hub was reinforced by the development of railways which linked the city to the vast corn and wheat growing farms in Illinois and Ohio. Chicago became famous for its stockyards and the meatpacking industry which with the help of refrigerated railcars, provided the Eastern cities with ham, bacon, and dressed beef. When the inventor of the mechanical reaper, Cyrus McCormick moved to Chicago, it became the center of the farm machinery industry and later also a focus of garments production and other manufactures (E. L. Glaeser 2009). But all those industries are now a fading memory. Chicago's meat packing, iron and steel, railway wagon and farm machinery industries have also largely vanished along with their blue collar workers ­ manufacturing employment fell from 45 percent in 1963 to 18 percent in 1998 (Johnson 2001). Their place has been filled, by the Mercantile Exchange (CME) 21 and commodity exchanges and trading of derivatives as well as by firms specialized in IT, the life sciences, telecommunications and software. All these activities feed off the skilled workers and research findings generated by Chicago's universities and are attracted by the access to pools of capital. Chicago is the nation's fourth largest employer of high tech workers (Johnson 2001). And following the merger of the CME and the Chicago Board of Trade in 2007, Chicago became the leading center of the trade in derivatives. But Chicago is keenly aware of the need to restore a broader economic base by rebuilding industrial corridors with the help of incubators, by policy measures which will build industrial clusters, programs for upgrading workforce skills, and a reform of property taxes which will free up underutilized land for industrial purposes. This is being buttressed by efforts to enhance Chicago's logistics capabilities and employment by improving the links between intermodal hubs, freight facilities, air freight centers and interstate highways (Johnson 2001). Tokyo was services oriented but with substantial manufacturing subsectors until the early part of the 1980s. However, the appreciation of the yen following the Plaza and Louvre Accords in 1985-86 and the economic bubble which grew through the latter part 21 This was started in 1898 to trade contracts in butter and eggs produced in Chicago's agricultural hinterland. In the early 1960s, the Exchange expanded its scope to include pork bellies and live cattle futures. 56 of the 1980s, created cost pressures which drove manufacturing out of the city. Even though the bubble deflated in the 1990s, the industries that had left did not return. The difference is that the leading Japanese manufacturing firms whose headquarters are located in Tokyo (and Osaka) still retain much of the R&D operations close by, sustain their formal and informal links with researchers in the local universities, and do their prototyping and trial batch production at their research facilities. In other respects, Tokyo has begun resembling New York and London in its reliance on services except that the share of finance does not loom as large, and finance is not the leading sector or the largest source of public revenues. Hence manufacturing, mainly in the suburban prefectures, remains a considerable presence, even though its share of total metropolitan output has fallen to 10.7 percent. As a financial center, Tokyo is not of the same league as New York and London, although it hosts the world's second biggest market for equities. 22 It mainly serves domestic borrowers. Consequently in spite of the scale of the Japanese financial market, Tokyo's financial sector does not dominate the urban economy to the extent that Wall Street, for example dominates New York's economy. Only 4 percent of the workforce is directly employed by the finance and insurance industries (see Table 4.2) and finance is not a major source of public revenue. The share of employment in business services is 15-16 percent. 23 That this may be an advantage is a point elaborated below. Table 4.2: Subsectoral Breakdown for Tokyo by Establishments and Employees, 2006 Establishments Employees Wholesale, retail 25.5 21.3 manufacturing 9.1 10.3 Restaurants, Hotels 14.6 8.9 Telecommunication 3.1 8.7 Other business services 2.3 7.2 Medical and Social services 5.8 6.7 construction 6.2 5.1 Transportation 3.0 4.7 Education 2.9 4.7 22 The nature of the regulatory environment and differences in the accounting rules also discourages foreign participants. 23 This is calculated as the sum of "other business services", "finance and insurance", "advertising" and "specialized services" in Table 4.2. 57 Finance and Insurance 1.4 4.1 Specialized services 6.1 3.8 Government Services 0.3 2.7 cloth washing, beauty salon, bath 5.2 1.7 houses Entertainment 1.2 1.3 Services related to lifestyles 1.1 0.8 Advertising 0.6 0.8 Academic and R&D 0.1 0.5 Electricity, Gas, water 0.1 0.4 Other services 3.8 3.4 Note: Sorted by the share of employees. Source: Tokyo Metropolitan Government Early Industrialization and Industrial Turnover New York, London, Chicago and to a lesser extent Tokyo were among the early industrializers and they attracted textiles, clothing, food processing, publishing, 24 metallurgical and equipment manufacturing activities ­ all of which were the leading subsectors in the earlier stages of industrial development. These tended to be labor intensive and frequently employed numerous semi- and unskilled workers; the factory layouts were indeed sprawling; and several of these activities caused severe air, water and noise pollution. As land and labor costs increased and cities become more densely populated, these industries were pushed out (E. L. Glaeser 2005b). The rise and spread of service activities and a variety of regulatory measures (including anti-pollution measures) also helped to ensure that new kinds of manufacturing activities did not return to these cities. New York, London and Chicago de-industrialized and bypassed the opportunity to benefit from a new generation of industries which use no more land than activities producing services, which are less labor intensive than many services, which employ a high proportion of skilled or technical workers, which generate little pollution thanks to advances in pollution abatement techniques, and the value added per worker of which can match or exceed that of workers in services occupations. Unlike many if not most service activities, the new generation of manufacturing activities have three additional advantages; they register high rates of increase in productivity because of learning and continuing refinements in production techniques; these industries are among 24 E. L. Glaeser (2009) observes that New York's rise as the publishing capital of the country was because being the natural hub for cross- Atlantic trade it had a clear edge in pirating books published in England. 58 the most dynamic in the technological sense with backward linkages to research institutes and universities and forward linkages to some of the fastest growing services such as multimedia, design, digital entertainment and health; and they have higher employment multipliers than services providers. 25 New York, London, and Chicago are victims of premature deindustrialization once "old" manufacturing industries either migrated to provincial centers or as in the case of textiles, overseas. The first two were quick to extend and consolidate a comparative advantage in financial services. Chicago built up the services sector following the success of the Mercantile Exchange. The rapid expansion of financial and related services created its own virtuous spiral of development but it resulted in ever greater specialization in business services assisted by deregulation and the stripping away of exchange controls. The IT and digital revolutions have promoted financial innovation and the creative industries have triggered some diversification, but mostly into other services and have failed to attract a new generation of manufacturing industries. 26 Starting with Tokyo in the second half of the 1980s and extending to New York and London from the mid 1990s, real estate bubbles have denuded these cities of all but a few economic activities and have profoundly gentrified the more exclusive neighborhoods. Because, New York, Tokyo and London are the iconic global cities, it is now seen as axiomatic that the future of dynamic cities lies in services. II. Five Stylized Tendencies and their Implications The experience of these four cities and of other cities in industrialized countries yield five stylized tendencies of relevance for Shanghai as it maps a future strategy. Agglomeration Economies Bring Many Benefits Size and industrial heterogeneity can deliver scale and urbanization economies, permitting gains in productivity and innovation which contribute to the competitiveness of existing industries and also to the emergence of new activities. In principle, 25 The auto sector in the United States has an employment multiplier of 7. 26 Silicon Alley in New York failed to usher in new manufacturing activities mainly because soaring property values in Manhattan fueled by the real estate bubble not only prevented such diversification but also sharply constrained the expansion of `Silicon Alley' (Indergaard 2004). 59 heterogeneity enlarges the options for a city to diversify, and a sizable concentration of relatively affluent and discriminating consumers and businesses demanding innovation makes it easier to introduce new products and new lines of business. 27 The potential for co-creating valuable innovations with customers is also greater in cities (Prahalad and Krishnan 2008). The productivity gains arising from agglomeration and scale economies are a consequence of a greater circulation of inter-industry information, `thicker' labor markets, superior access to specialized services, as well as to better public infrastructure and to public facilities (Melo, Graham and Noland 2009). A review of research findings shows that the productivity advantages conferred by size and urbanization economies range from 3 percent to 14 percent of GDP (Rosenthal and Strange 2004). 28 Large cities that are absorbing young migrants and where many newcomers are educated and skilled, benefit from their energy, entrepreneurship and human capital (D. E. Bloom and Williamson 1998; Parker 2007). 29 A growing population, many with skills that deepen the urban labor pool, can add one to two percent to economic growth if it also crowds in more capital into local productive activities through new starts which can spawn new industrial clusters, 30 for example (E. L. Glaeser and Kerr 2008). 31 27 The strength of Tokyo as an innovation hotspot derives from the existence of a critical mass of sophisticated and adventurous consumers who are willing to try new products (K. Fujita and Hill 2005). 28 Reviewing the evidence on agglomeration economies, Rosenthal and Strange (2004) find that with each doubling of the size of city, the urban GDP can increase by between 3 and 14 percent. Venables and Rice (2005) estimate that a doubling of the population of a city can raise productivity by 3.5 percent. Henderson concludes from his assessment of the size and productivity of cities in China, that most are sub-optimal in size ­ i.e. below 5 million (Au and Henderson 2006b) ­ and that productivity gains from an expansion would be about 4.1 percent if the city were 20 percent below optimal but as much as 35 percent if the city is half the optimal size (Henderson 2004; Rosenthal and Strange 2004). While evidence on urbanization economies (arising from industrial diversity) is mixed (and greater for some industries than others), that for diversity of high tech industries is much clearer. Overman and Venables (2005) find that a one standard deviation increase in the diversity index raises productivity by 60 percent (p.18). See also S. V. Lall, Shalizi and Deichmann (2004); Deichmann and others (2005); World Bank (2009c); M. Fujita and Thisse (2002); and Quigley (2008). 29 The influx of such talented immigrants from across Europe partly explains the Irish Miracle and London's dominance in the UK economy. 30 Clusters of firms modeled on the Italian industrial district, small firm cluster have emerged in the Pearl River Delta urban region as the thousands of Chinese workers and entrepreneurs who have gained experience in Prato, have returned to set up shop in China. 31 Rosenthal and Strange (2008) point to the benefits accruing from a concentration of college educated workers but they also find that the agglomeration benefits diminish the farther one moves away from the center of the agglomeration. 60 A Services Economy Is A Mixed Blessing Leading cities emerged as centers of industry or as administrative and logistics hubs ­ often all three ­ in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. 32 Frequently manufacturing was the engine of growth with services playing a secondary role even when services generated a majority of the jobs. Mainly because of historical circumstances and location, a few of the very largest, strategically located cities diversified into financial and business services which initially served regional or colonial markets and later, global markets. Financial globalization expedited by the progressive dismantling of capital and exchange controls and the parallel partial deregulation of the financial sector has enabled the early starters, in particular London and New York, to rapidly expand the scale of their financial activities using a variety of instruments, and to widen their international reach (Eichengreen and Leblang 2008; Obstfeld and Taylor 2003). The growth of finance and associated business services provided a new growth engine for the global cities and to some lesser ones as well and hastened the exodus of manufacturing. Finance can become the foremost leading sector when a city begins serving a large regional or a global market. In other words, the push exerted by the expansion of increasingly highly paid services employment especially in finance, and the activities of urban developers catering to these services, can reinforce the pull exerted by other lower cost locations on manufacturing, resulting in a rapid shrinkage of manufacturing industry. The consequence is an increasingly mono-industrial economy dominated by a few business services and retail and personal services; and declining industrial heterogeneity and layering which was once the strength of the leading financial centers. The remaining and significantly attenuated urbanization economies arise from the diversity of services activities. Most industrial cities are unable to make a transition to global cities led by finance and other business services. 33 Once manufacturing fades away, these cities cannot sustain earlier levels of prosperity on the back of the services that remain or on 32 A meta-analysis of the research on agglomeration economies also finds that proximity appears to produce larger gains in productivity for services than it does for manufacturing activities (Melo, Graham and Noland 2009). 33 Part of the reason is that these services tend to have much lower linkages to other industrial sectors. For instance, the burgeoning business processing outsourcing sector in the Philippines has not stimulated the production in other industrial sectors (Magtibay-Ramos, Estrada and Felipe 2008). 61 new services attracted to these cities most of which have a local clientele (or at best a regional) and rarely tap into the global market. The result can be a vicious downward spiral. As the economic and revenue bases narrow, industrial diversity is reduced, the supply of skilled workers becomes smaller as the most talented migrate, and the chances of a revival diminish. Even a large injection of capital from central or sub-national governments is unable to jumpstart these municipal cities once industry has been denuded, labor and entrepreneurs have departed and the industrial fabric has developed large holes. Productivity Growth Favors Manufacturing Historical experience shows that productivity has grown fastest in manufacturing activities. Hence the diminishing share of manufacturing in GDP eats into the contribution of productivity to growth. With national and urban economies in industrialized countries drawing more of their growth impetus from productivity, the changing composition of economic activities ­ which has been labeled Baumol's Disease ­ means a trend reduction in growth as there is little evidence that most services can generate rates of productivity increase comparable to those of manufacturing industries. 34 Table 4.3 shows the effect of changing GDP composition on TFP growth in the United States. Had the GDP composition remained fixed at the proportion reached in 1948, the annual TFP growth in the United States would have been 1.49 percent. The GDP composition as of 2001 results in an annual rate of TFP growth of 0.85 percent. Thus, changes in the composition of GDP between 1948 and 2001 are responsible for a reduction of 0.64 percentage point of TFP growth per annum. The shift to services can, therefore, be doubly disadvantageous. Aside from constraining urbanization economies and the scope for diversification, mono-sectoral urban economies, even very large ones, risk sacrificing growth over the long run. Table 4.3: Fixed-shares growth rate for total factor productivity for different periods 1948 1959 1973 1989 2001 1948-59 1.61 1.75 1.71 1.51 1.34 34 See Baumol and Bowen (1966) and Baumol (1967) 62 1959-73 1.44 1.39 1.26 1.03 0.78 1973-89 1.27 0.92 0.83 0.56 0.38 1989-2001 1.73 1.47 1.42 1.19 1.11 1948-2001 1.49 1.34 1.26 1.02 0.85 Source: Nordhaus (2008) Innovativeness Is Greatest in Research Intensive Activities Total factor productivity and growth are intertwined with innovation. Large urban centers are on balance more innovative. 35 But the level of innovation and its commercial outcomes are also a function of industrial composition. Some kinds of activities are more research intensive and innovative. It is not only R&D that leads to innovation, however, there is a robust relationship running from R&D to patents, and publications which are widely viewed as proxies for innovation (Griliches 2000; B. Hall and Mairesse 2006; Jaffe 1986; Wieser 2005). Manufacturing industries, especially the high tech ones engage in more R&D and produce many more patents than services activities. If patents signal innovation, then manufacturing is more likely to spawn subfields and new starts, which can widen existing markets or give rise to new markets; and introduce process innovations which are widespread in manufacturing and have a higher probability of promoting productivity. Monosectoral Urban Economies Tend to Be Unequal Large cities that transition rapidly from an economy based on manufacturing to one whose center of gravity lies in services, face the challenge of finding alternative employment opportunities for workers and of sustaining an urban middle class. The experience of New York, London, Singapore and Hong Kong suggests that services industries do not on the average generate as many additional jobs or jobs that pay as well as the manufacturing activities they replace (Sassen 1991). Some services such as finance, legal and accounting do create well paid jobs but only for highly educated workers and not for ex-factory hands. Retraining middle aged factory workers has been a failure wherever it has been tried and many factory workers can end up being permanently unemployed as has happened across Europe. The result is rising inequality 35 The size and the density of employment and industrial activities is also positively correlated with the innovativeness of a place (Bettencourt, Lobo and Strumsky 2007; Carlino, Chatterjee and Hunt 2007). 63 and a shrinking middle class. 36 Too much of the city's income derives from a few activities and it can become concentrated in the hands of few, generally mobile workers. 37 Such a distribution of incomes affects real estate values, drives the lower and middle income workers away from the core areas of the city, and unravels communities and neighborhoods that saps the vitality of a city, and affects the urban quality of life by leading to a homogenization of neighborhoods as well as a diminishing diversity of people and of activities in the core city areas (see Table 4.4). 38 These stylized tendencies can inform development policies in Shanghai. However, as we noted earlier, times have changed as have industrial lifecycles. Shanghai is quite unlike New York in the earlier decades of the twentieth century and its opportunity set and constraints also differ a great deal. How it could evolve will depend on a variety of factors which are discussed in the remainder of this volume. Table 4.4: Gini Coefficients in Selected Cities Cities Gini Coefficient Year Beijing 0.22 2003 Hong Kong 0.53 2001 London New York 0.54 2007 Singapore 0.44 2006 Shanghai 0.32 2004/5 Tokyo 0.31 2004 Note: New York data from 2007 American Community Survey Source: UN-HABITAT 2008 36 Social tensions, rising rates of homicide and slowing growth are some of the consequences of inequality (E. L. Glaeser, Resseger and Tobio 2008; UN-HABITAT 2008) 37 E. L. Glaeser, Resseger and Tobio (2008) note the high income inequality in Manhattan (Gini of 0.6) and show that inequality in U.S. cities is related to the emerging skill mix in these cities and to the returns from skills. 38 In the past three decades, inequality in Hong Kong has been steadily rising from 0.45 in 1981, 0.476 in 1991, 0.525 in 2001 (UN-HABITAT 2008) and closer to 0.6 currently. Inequality has also risen in Singapore from 0.49 at the start of the decade to 0.51 in 2007. 64 Chapter 5 Shanghai's Economic Composition, Resources and Potential for Innovation In the light of the above, the first part of this chapter presents factual information on the evolution of Shanghai's economic and industrial structure since 1990. 1 The second part of the section examines the evolution of the capabilities that will, in conjunction with policy actions and market signals, affect future development and the pace of growth. When discussing `capabilities', explicit distinction is made between "technological capability" and "innovation capacity." 2 The former refers to the ability to assimilate, adapt, and exploit knowledge commercially. Innovation capacity refers to the potential inherent with in an urban environment variously furnished with universities, research entities and firms, to create new ideas, products, processes, and business models. I. The Industrial Economy With 1.4 percent of China's population Shanghai produces close to 5 percent of the national GDP (see Table 5.1). While the share is smaller than that of Hong Kong, it is larger than Beijing's (see Table 5.2), highlighting the importance of the Shanghai urban industrial region in China's economy. 1 Shanghai was designated as an "open city" (open for foreign direct investment) in 1984. During the 1980s, Shanghai did not experience the explosive growth which occurred in the four free trade zones and in the PRD. It entered a period of rapid development following a decision in the early 1990s to transform Shanghai as the "dragonhead of development" for the Yangtze River Delta region (H. Lu 2004). 2 This also applies to policies. Innovation policy encompasses more than the technology policy might. A technology policy tends to be narrowly focused on certain area or issues while innovation policy needs to consider various supporting institutions. Table 5.1: Share of National Population (%) City 1995 2000 2007 Beijing 1.03 1.09 1.24 Shanghai 1.17 1.32 1.41 Tokyo 9.39 9.51 10.01 Hong Kong 0.26 0.26 0.25 Source: Beijing, Shanghai and China Statistical Yearbooks, various years; Tokyo Statistics Bureau, Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications. Bureau of General Affairs, T.M.G.; Hong Kong Demographic Statistics Section, Census and Statistics Department, August 2008 Revision; Japan World Development Indicators (WDI) 2008. Table 5.2: Share of National GDP (%) City 1995 2000 2007 Beijing 2.29 2.50 3.61 Shanghai 4.05 4.59 4.81 Tokyo* 16.60 17.84 18.40 Hong Kong 19.80 14.12 6.32 Note: * denotes data is for the years 1996, 2000 and 2005 Source: Beijing, Shanghai and China Statistical Yearbooks, various years; Tokyo: Statistical Department, TMG (http://www.toukei.metro.tokyo.jp/keizaik/kk05pa0100.xls); Hong Kong: National Income Section (1)1, Census and Statistics Department, August 2008 Revision; Japan: World Development Indicators (WDI) 2008. In contrast to Beijing, and in conformity with China as a whole, manufacturing remains the engine of Shanghai's economy. The share of manufacturing in GDP, although it is eight percentage points lower than in 1995, was 44 percent, in 2006 (see Figure 5.1) and has remained more or less stable since 2000. The detailed picture that emerges from industrial censuses reveals three major and largely positive changes over the past decade: light industries, in particular those producing textiles, footwear, and garments have lost shares and in their place, transport, engineering, electronics and metallurgical industries have increased in prominence (see Table 5.3 and Table 5.4). Computers and electronic equipment generate about one quarter of the industrial output in Shanghai. And close to two-thirds of the industrial output comes from just six subsectors, which account for 38 percent of the establishments and 46 percent of the employment in manufacturing. In comparison, printing and publishing now dominate the substantially hollowed out manufacturing activities of Tokyo (and in New York), both in terms of establishments 66 and the number of employees. 3 Vestiges of Tokyo's past industrial strength can be seen in the continued presence of plants producing chemicals, food processing, electric machinery, telecommunication hardware, and metal products. But with the relocation of the bulk of manufacturing activity to other places, Tokyo has been transformed into a cultural and business center. If industry flees, this is what Shanghai could become. And if it does, the city will have to settle for rates of GDP growth in the 1 ­ 4 per cent per annum range. 3 It also was and remains the major manufacturing industry in New York. 67 Figure 5.1: GDP composition (%) GDP Composition (% ) Shanghai 1995 Shanghai 2000 Shanghai 2007 Beijing 1995 Share of Primary Beijing 2000 Sector Beijing 2007 Tokyo 1995 Share of Tokyo 2000 Manufacturing Tokyo 2007 Hong Kong 1995 Share of Hong Kong 2000 Secondary Sector Net of Hong Kong 2007 Manufacturing China 1995 Share of China 2000 Tertiary Sector China 2007 Japan 1995 Japan 2000 Japan 2007 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% Source: Beijing, Shanghai and China Statistical Yearbooks, various years; Tokyo: TMG (http://www.toukei.metro.tokyo.jp/keizaik/kk05pa1000.xls); Hong Kong: National Income Section (2)1, Census and Statistics Department, May 2008 Revision; Japan World Development Indicators (WDI) 2008. 68 Table 5.3 Subsectoral Composition of Manufacturing Activities in Shanghai, 1994 Share of Share Establishme Share of of nts employees GVIO Smelting and Pressing of Ferrous Metals 1.0 5.6 14.4 Transportation Equipment Manufacturing 4.8 7.7 9.6 Textile 7.9 13.9 8.5 Electric Machinery Equipments and Manufacturing 9.1 6.9 7.1 Raw Chemical Materials and Chemical Products Manufacturing 5.1 5.1 6.3 General Equipment Manufacturing 7.8 8.0 5.9 Communications Equipment, Computer and Other Electronic Equipment Manufacturing 3.4 4.1 5.5 Metal Products Manufacturing 9.0 5.7 4.8 Garments, Shoes and Accessories Manufacturing 7.0 5.3 4.1 Special Purpose Equipment Manufacturing 5.4 6.6 3.9 Chemical Fiber Manufacturing 0.4 2.0 3.1 Nonmetal Mineral Products 4.1 4.1 2.6 Smelting and Pressing of Nonferrous Metals 1.1 1.3 2.4 Artworks and Other Manufacturing 3.7 2.0 2.2 Farm and Sideline Products Processing 2.4 1.4 2.2 Oil Processing, Coking and Nuclear Fuel Processing 0.2 0.6 2.0 Medicine Manufacturing 1.2 1.5 1.7 Instruments, Meters, Culture and Office Equipments Manufacturing 3.5 3.6 1.6 Plastic Products Manufacturing 4.7 2.0 1.5 Rubber Products Manufacturing 1.3 1.9 1.5 Leather, Fur, and Wool Products Manufacturing 2.4 1.8 1.4 Food Manufacturing 3.1 1.9 1.4 Stationary, Education and Sports Goods Manufacturing 2.6 2.1 1.3 Tobacco Manufacturing 0.0 0.2 1.0 Paper-making and Paper Products Manufacturing 2.2 1.4 1.0 Printing and Record Duplicating 3.8 1.5 0.9 Beverage Manufacturing 0.7 0.6 0.9 Timber Processing and Timber, Bamboo, Rattan, Coir and Straw Products Manufacturing 1.0 0.6 0.7 Furniture Manufacturing 1.2 0.6 0.4 Note: Ranked by Gross Value Industrial Output (GVIO). Source: Shanghai Statistical Yearbook 1995. 69 Table 5.4: Subsectoral Composition of Manufacturing Activities in Shanghai, 2007 (%) Share of establish Share of Share of Subsectors ments Employees GVIO Communications Equipment, Computer and Other Electronic Equipment 4.7 13.5 23.2 Transportation Equipment 5.3 7.9 11.0 General Equipment 11.7 9.5 8.8 Raw Chemical Materials and Chemical Products 7.1 4.1 7.6 Smelting and Pressing of Ferrous Metals 1.1 1.6 7.5 Electric Machinery Equipments 8.3 9.0 7.3 Oil Processing, Coking and Nuclear Fuel Processing 0.3 0.8 4.5 Metal Products 9.0 6.1 3.9 Special Purpose Equipment 6.1 4.7 2.8 Plastic Products 6.5 4.5 2.2 Garments, Shoes and Accessories 6.9 7.9 2.0 Smelting and Pressing of Nonferrous Metals 1.7 1.5 2.0 Nonmetal Mineral Products 4.1 2.9 2.0 Textile 6.1 5.1 1.7 Instruments, Meters, Culture and Office Equipments 2.2 2.3 1.5 Food 1.7 2.0 1.3 Tobacco 0.0 0.1 1.3 Medicine 1.5 2.0 1.3 Farm and Sideline Products Processing 1.1 0.9 1.0 Furniture 1.7 2.0 0.9 Paper-making and Paper Products 2.2 1.3 0.9 Rubber Products 1.6 1.6 0.8 Printing and Record Duplicating 2.5 1.7 0.8 Stationary, Education and Sports Goods 1.9 2.3 0.8 Beverage 0.4 0.4 0.6 Leather, Fur, and Wool Products 1.5 2.0 0.6 Artworks and Other 1.1 0.9 0.5 Chemical Fiber 0.3 0.3 0.5 Timber Processing and Timber, Bamboo, Rattan, Coir and Straw Products 1.1 0.8 0.4 Waste Resources and Materials Recycling and Processing 0.3 0.1 0.2 Note: Ranked by Gross Value Industrial Output (GVIO). Source: Shanghai Statistical Yearbook 2008 70 Table 5.5: Share of Manufacturing Activities in Tokyo, 2001 and 2006 2001 2006 establis hments employees Establishments Employees printing, printing, publishing 21.3 14.5 publishing 18.0 14.0 machinery 11.9 10.0 machinery 11.4 10.4 chemical 2.2 7.9 chemical 2.1 9.0 metal products 12.9 7.2 food processing 4.0 8.3 electric electric machinery 4.9 7.2 machinery 4.4 7.0 food processing 3.8 6.6 metal products 13.6 6.8 telecommunication, IT telecommunicati hardware 1.6 6.1 on, IT hardware 1.3 6.0 transportation transportation equipment 2.4 5.2 equipment 2.2 5.1 precision electronic devices 3.1 4.9 instruments 3.9 4.6 electronic others 6.7 4.9 devices 2.7 4.6 precision instruments 4.0 4.4 others 7.4 4.5 plastics 4.7 3.6 plastics 4.7 3.1 garment 5.5 3.1 garment 6.8 2.9 pulp, paper 3.3 2.7 pulp, paper 3.2 2.2 Glass, cement, Glass, cement, ceramics 1.5 2.0 ceramics 1.6 1.8 leather products 2.7 1.7 leather products 4.5 1.6 non-ferocious metal 1.0 1.7 iron and steel 0.8 1.4 iron and steel 0.9 1.6 rubber products 1.5 1.3 drinks, tobacco, rubber products 1.4 1.2 feed 0.3 1.2 non-ferocious drinks, tobacco, feed 0.3 1.1 metal 0.9 1.2 furniture 2.3 1.1 furniture 2.8 1.2 petrochemical, textile 0.8 0.6 excl. plastics 0.1 0.7 petrochemical, excl. plastics 0.1 0.6 textile 1.0 0.6 wood product, excl. wood product, furniture 0.7 0.4 excl. furniture 1.0 0.5 Source: Tokyo Metropolitan Government 71 The changing shape of industry in Shanghai is mirrored in the shares of large firms as against small and medium sized ones, and in the increasing salience of private and multinational firms. 4 Large firms accounted for 41 percent of the output in 2007 as against 50 percent in 1994. Private and foreign invested firms produced 64 percent of the GVIO in 2007, and they have increased Shanghai's integration with the global economy (see Figure 5.2). 5 Key industries such as electronics and engineering, export 70 and 22 percent of their output respectively and in the aggregate, more than 60 percent of Shanghai's GDP was traded in 2007. As is the case throughout China, a disproportionate share of Shanghai's exports ­ almost 77 percent ­ come from foreign invested enterprises in 2007. 6 This mirrors the experience in other countries. The larger the share of foreign ownership, the more likely is the firm to export. In addition, the bulk of the exports are done by few high-performing firms. 7 While this broadly describes the current situation in Shanghai, the increasing share of smaller, private and foreign invested firms in the export sector and the concomitant decline in the share of SOEs, are welcome developments. SOEs tend to be on balance less productive, profitable and innovative. 8 But there are some important exceptions which have benefited from enterprise reform and corporatization. Firms such as SAIC, Baosteel, SMIC, and Zhenhua Port Cranes 9 are among the most dynamic firms in China today, and could become the driving force 4 After the reform of the state-owned enterprises (SOEs), the footprints of SOEs (and collectively-owned enterprises (COEs)) have diminished over the years in establishments, employment, and industrial output. For a detailed discussion on the SOE reform in China and elsewhere, see Yusuf, Nabeshima and Perkins (2005). 5 If firms from Hong Kong and Taiwan (China) are included, the share increases to 76 percent. 6 For China as a whole, the traded share of foreign invested firms is 57 percent. 7 In the case of European firms, the top 1 (5) percent of the firms accounts for 40 (70) percent of the total exports, respectively (see Table 5.6) (Mayer and Ottaviano 2008). Moreover, there is a wide variation in productivity among firms. The bottom performing ones are mainly focused on the domestic market, better performing ones tend to be exporters, and the top performing ones are multinationals (Mayer and Ottaviano 2008). 8 Industrial SOEs in China and elsewhere, are less efficient compared to private firms. The managerial, technical, and organization capabilities of even those SOEs which have been corporatized continue to lag far behind those of MNCs operating in China in large part because of the limited capacity of most SOEs to absorb and profit from new technologies hard and soft and to craft superior business models (Girma and Yundan 2008) See Yusuf, Nabeshima and Perkins (2005); Dollar and Wei (2007); and Y. Huang (2008). 9 See Zeng and Williamson (2007). 72 behind incremental innovation in Shanghai, the role that large firms perform elsewhere. 10 Once they are able to, a rising percentage of Shanghai's exports will be sourced from Chinese owned firms as should be the case. Figure 5.2: Gross Value of Industrial Output by Ownership Categories in Shanghai 100.0 90.0 80.0 70.0 60.0 50.0 40.0 30.0 20.0 10.0 0.0 1994 2001 2006 2007 State-owned Collective-owned Share-holding Cooperation Joint Owned Companies with Limited Liabilities Share-holding Companies with Limited Liabilities Private Others Hong Kong, Macao and Taiwan Funded Foreign Funded Source: Shanghai Statistical Yearbooks, various years Table 5.6: Share of Exports for Top European Exporters in 2003 Top 1% Top 5% Top 10% France 68 88 94 Italy 32 59 72 Hungary 77 91 96 Belgium 48 73 84 Norway 53 81 91 Source: Mayer and Ottaviano 2008 10 The durable innovation hotspots around the world, the ones which have given rise to resilient clusters of firms share one common trait, which is the vital, procreative and nurturing role of a few firms which struck root at an early stage, survived, innovated, built up competencies, grew in size, and most importantly were responsible for numerous spin-offs and for attracting many start-ups. This was true for the clusters in Silicon Valley, Bangalore, and Akron (Buenstorf and Klepper 2009; Smilor and others 2005). Drofiak and Garnsey (2009) observe that, "competence accumulates through successive spin-outs of knowledge-based firms, as well as within specific firms... Spinouts from previous spin-out firms create new clusters of activity over time... [as for instance] with the Cambridge ink-jet printing cluster and the ensuing display technology cluster, which originated from one university spinout firm, CCL" (p.20). 73 The Role of Large SOEs Research shows larger firms account for the bulk of private spending on technology development and on innovation. They are the ones with the resources to devote to R&D activities and to promote routinized innovation as a conscious strategy. In the context of China, and to a degree in Shanghai, the state-owned enterprises and state-holding firms are of the requisite size to actively pursue the innovation agenda. Nationally, the state-owned enterprises and state-holding firms account for one third of industrial output and value-added. They account for 45 percent of fixed assets, making them more capital-intensive and also larger than the average firm. In some industrial sectors such as chemicals, automotive, iron and steel, and non-ferrous metal, SOEs produce between 50 to 80 percent of the output. Only in electronics, the presence of the state sector is small. And it is responsible for close to half of the new products introduced in China. The state sector accounts for 54 percent of R&D (FTE) personnel and 48 percent of domestic R&D spending. However, only one quarter of these new products are exported, a much lower ratio compared to other types of firms. This suggests that many of the new products are aimed at the domestic market instead of the export market. In addition, invention patent applications by the state sector are only 24 percent of the total, suggesting that it is less efficient in utilizing R&D inputs. Nonetheless, several state sector firms such as China International Marine Containers (CIMC) 11 have emerged as highly successful innovators through domestic consolidation and by leveraging the domestic market and have firmly established themselves in the global market. The expanding domestic market has been an asset for Chinese companies both new and old, state-owned and private to acquire valuable experience, use their local knowledge to build their domestic operations, before venturing abroad to export as well as to conduct a focused search for new technologies and intellectual property (Zhou 2008). As Khanna and Palepu (2006, p.64) point out, "Many emerging market companies have become world class businesses by capitalizing on their knowledge of local product markets". They note in particular, Haier's success in customizing its products to suit local 11 See Zeng and Williamson (2007) and Meyer and Liu (2004) for detailed accounts of the evolution of CIMC as the leading producer of maritime containers. 74 needs first in China and now overseas, and in building an effective distribution and service network. Chinese SOEs wanting to build innovation capacity have more to learn from large bureaucratic top-down management style companies such as Canon, Toyota, Samsung, and Hyundai than from Western companies with very different managerial structures. Toyota has generated new knowledge and a steady stream of incremental innovations by carefully defining problems and systematically working to solve them; by diffusing the learning through the company; and by infusing this problem-solving through innovation mentality across all levels of management (Spear 2008). II. The Financial Sector China's banking centered financial system has effectively supported development fuelled by heavy investment in infrastructure, urban real estate, and capital intensive manufacturing activities. This system has tended to favor SOEs and entities affiliated with local governments which have an adequate amount of assets to offer as collateral for loans. As the economy diversifies, services multiply, and the role of smaller firms continues increasing, a deepening of financial markets and the provision of a wider menu of financial choices would bolster economic performance. Shanghai's financial sector is a leader in this regard and is contributing significantly not only to the municipal economy but more broadly to the emerging needs of the national economy. Industrial trends which enlarge the share of the technologically dynamic and potentially most competitive industries strengthen Shanghai's longer term growth prospects. They are being buttressed by a widening of the financial system. Shanghai's financial market has made solid progress in building the institutions mobilizing the resources and introducing the instruments to promote the expansion of the industrial activity in the Yangtze River region (see Table 5.7). Between 2000 and 2007 savings deposits and loan balances have approximately tripled and by 2007, the deposit to GDP ratio had risen to 2. 75 Table 5.7: Deposits and Loan Balances of Financial Institutions in Shanghai (billion yuan) 2000 2007 Saving Deposit Balance of Financial Institutions 935.0 3,031.6 Chinese Financial Institutions 908.9 2,816.9 RMB 777.2 2,704.5 Foreign Currencies (Converting into RMB) 131.7 112.4 Foreign-funded Financial Institutions 26.1 214.7 Foreign Currencies (Converting into RMB) 19.6 70.3 RMB 6.5 144.4 Loan Balance of Financial Institutions 725.4 2,171.0 Chinese Financial Institutions 642.8 1,801.9 RMB 596.0 1,660.8 Foreign Currencies (Converting into RMB) 46.8 141.2 Foreign-funded Financial Institutions 82.6 369.1 Foreign Currencies (Converting into RMB) 63.6 170.3 RMB 19.1 198.8 Source: Shanghai Statistical Yearbook 2008 Other measures of financial depth provide corroborating evidence such as the number of banks operating in Shanghai and the savings and investment ratio in Shanghai. In 2007, there were 109 domestic banks and 84 foreign banks operating in Shanghai (see Table 5.8). Among the 84 foreign banks, 45 could accept deposits and loans in yuan and were able to compete against local banks. Financial institutions in Shanghai, both foreign and local, have taken the lead in introducing new financial instruments and practices which are contributing to better resource allocation, improving the access to finance by smaller firms and consumers, and helping to enhance the growth potential of the entire urban region. Table 5.8: Number of Financial Institutions in Shanghai, 2006-2007 Indicators 2000 2007 Financial Institutions 504 604 # Banking Institutions 82 109 Insurance Institutions 222 261 Security Institutions 90 94 # Foreign Financial Institutions Operating in Shanghai 110 140 # Foreign Bank and Finance Company Operating in Shanghai 63 84 # Permission of Operating RMB Business Gained 43 45 Source: Shanghai Statistical Yearbook 2008 Investment accounts for a large share of the growth in China and this is also true for Shanghai. It is supported by the local savings which have remained high. In 2007, 76 the savings to GDP ratio in Shanghai was 249 percent and the ratio of loan to GDP was 178 percent. While the savings to GDP ratio in Shanghai is much higher than the national average, it is about one half of that in Beijing (see Table 5.9). Table 5.9: Share of Loans and Savings in Beijing and China, 2000 and 2007 2000 2007 Beijing Savings 465.0 429.4 Loans 258.5 230.4 China Savings 124.8 156.0 Loans 100.2 104.9 Note: Data for Beijing is from 2006 Source: China Statistical Yearbook 2008 Shanghai hosts the largest stock exchange in mainland China (the other stock exchange in located in Shenzhen). Based on the market capitalization, the SSE is the fifth largest in the world. The Shanghai Stock Exchange (SSE) began operating in December 1990. The number of listed companies increased from 188 in 1995 to 572 in 2000 and 834 in 2005 (Shanghai Stock Exchange 2007). The number of stocks listed rose from 220 in 1995 to 614 in 2000 and 904 in 2007. Correspondingly, the market value of stocks went from 253 billion yuan in 1995 to 2,693 billion yuan in 2000 and 26,884 billion yuan in 2007 (Shanghai Statistical Yearbook, 2008). In February 2008, 861 companies were listed on the SSE, and the total market capitalization of SSE was 23,340.9 billion yuan (or US$3,241.8 billion) (see Table 5.10). In 1995, the total volume of stocks issued was 55.8 billion yuan, which went up to 213 billion yuan in 2000 and 1,237 billion yuan in 2006 (Shanghai Statistical Yearbook, 2007). One unique characteristics of the SSE (and the one in Shenzhen) is the different classification of shares. "A" shares denominated in yuan, were originally restricted to trading among domestic investors only. "B" shares denominated in US dollars, were open to foreign investors, but were closed to domestic investors. Subsequent reforms have eased these restrictions but there are still limitations on trading these shares by domestic and foreign investors. Between 2006 and 2008, Shanghai's stock market rose steeply as large current account surpluses increased the money supply which then fed the demand for equities. 77 This demand was exacerbated by the continuing paucity of alternative sources of investment (DeWoskin 2008). Although the Shanghai market followed the international bourses down after the collapse of Lehman Brothers, the market began reviving in April 2009 and it market capitalization is currently 73 percent of GDP which is higher than that of the U.S. (68), the UK (67) and Japan (64). The market's recent performance notwithstanding it remains a highly managed and largely domestic entity with licensed foreigners accounting for little more than one percent of the market capitalization. Furthermore, the stock market primarily serves the SOEs, many of which have diverted their productive assets into listed subsidiaries while retaining four-fifths of their shares, the bulk of which remain untraded even though in theory, up to 50 percent of the share should come onto the market as IPO lock-ups expire (Y. Huang, Saich and Steinfeld 2005; "Shanghigh" 2009). Development of the financial futures market and other attempts at broadening may have to wait until the financial crisis has passed and the shape of the new international regulatory architecture and of domestic systemic regulation becomes clearer. However, China is preparing to launch its own version of NASDAQ, The Growth Enterprise Board, which is scheduled to open on May 1st, 2009 at the Shenzhen Stock Exchange ("China to Establish" 2008). This board will provide an avenue for smaller high-tech companies to raise capital more easily from sources other than banks and family. 12 Table 5.10: Basic Statistics on Shanghai Stock Exchange 1995 2000 2007 # of Listed Companies 188 572 860 # of Stocks Listed 220 614 904 Market Value of Stocks (billion yuan) 252.6 2,693.1 26,983.9 Volume of Stocks (billion yuan) 55.8 212.8 1,236.7 Source: Shanghai Statistical Yearbook, 2007 12 To be listed on GEB, firms must have a minimum of 10 million yuan of accumulated net profits in the two years prior to listing. The requirement for the main boards in Shanghai and Shenzhen is at least 30 million yuan of accumulated net profits in the previous three years ("Regulator Rolls out Norms for GEB" 2009). 78 III. Labor and Skills The industrial base and Shanghai's maturing financial and business services are important building blocks, but sustaining Shanghai's growth over the longer term will depend upon the quality and variety of human capital, and on innovation capabilities. Shanghai's labor market is already fairly deep and diverse. There are 9 million workers in the formal labor force supplemented by several million migrant workers who comprise Shanghai's floating population. Over a quarter of the formal workforce in 2000, were high school graduates, and 6 percent of the workforce had earned bachelor's degrees (see Table 5.11). The likely cause of the small decline in the percentage of workers with high school degrees was the near doubling of Shanghai's population between 1990 and 2000 (from 6.9 million to 12.3 million) partly as a result of the influx of less educated migrants (see Table 5.12). The vast majority of the migrant workforce is engaged in construction, light manufacturing and assembly type activities, household services and other occupations, mostly unskilled or semi-skilled jobs. But Shanghai has also attracted significant numbers of highly skilled knowledge workers from other parts of China and overseas who fill the growing demand from Shanghai's technology intensive activities. Close to 50,000 scientists and engineers are employed at large and medium manufacturing enterprises in Shanghai of which 47,000 are in the machinery and the materials processing industries (see Table 5.13). One quarter of these S&E workers are employed in the electronics industry (including communication equipment and computer hardware). This capacity to attract knowledge workers is a tremendous asset (as is for London and New York) and must be enhanced by further augmenting the vitality and distinctiveness of the city and the convenience of living there. Table 5.11: Educational level of population as a % of reference population This degree or above 1990 2000 1990 2000 1990 2000 United United Shanghai Shanghai China China States States High School 30.1 27.1 11.4 12.0 75.2 80.4 Some college 45.2 51.8 College-level associate degree 5.6 7.1 1.2 2.5 Bachelor's degree 5.8 6.2 0.8 1.2 20.3 24.4 Advanced degree n.a. 0.6 n.a. 0.1 7.2 8.9 Note: Reference population is aged 6 and over for Shanghai and China, and aged 25 or higher for United States. 79 Source: Shanghai and China Census data various years; United States data is from Table4 of Holz (2008) Table 5.12: Educational level of population, Number in millions This degree or above 1990 2000 1990 2000 1990 2000 United United Shanghai Shanghai China China States States High School 2.1 3.3 89.9 138.3 119.5 146.5 Some college 71.8 94.4 College-level associate degree 0.4 0.9 9.6 29.0 Bachelor's degree 0.4 0.8 6.1 14.2 32.3 44.5 Advanced degree n.a. 0.1 n.a. 0.9 11.4 16.2 Total population 6.9 12.3 789.2 1156.7 158.9 182.2 Note: Reference population is aged 6 and over for Shanghai and China, and aged 25 or higher for United States. Source: Shanghai and China Census data various years; United States data is from Table4 of Holz (2008) Table 5.13: Personnel of Industrial Enterprises, 2005 (Scientists and Engineers) persons Manufacture Industry 49,795 Communications Equipments, Computer and Other Electronic Equipment Manufacturing 12,393 Transportation Equipment Manufacturing 6,993 General Equipment Manufacturing 5,686 Electric Machinery Equipments and Manufacturing 3,836 Smelting and Pressing of Ferrous Metals 3,668 Special Purpose Equipment Manufacturing 3,002 Raw Chemical Materials and Chemical 2,962 Instruments, Meters, Culture and Office Equipments Manufacturing 2,197 Medicine Manufacturing 2,146 Oil Processing, Coking and Nuclear 1,472 Nonmetal Mineral Products 680 Metal Products Manufacturing 655 Printing and Record Duplicating 630 Textile 513 Plastic Products Manufacturing 482 Rubber Products Manufacturing 458 Food Manufacturing 429 Smelting and Pressing of Nonferrous Metals 395 Stationary, Education and Sports Goods Manufacturing 321 Tobacco Manufacturing 195 Artworks and Other Manufacturing 157 Furniture Manufacturing 143 Farm and Sideline Products Processing 106 Chemical Fiber Manufacturing 79 Beverage Manufacturing 63 Petroleum and Natural Gas Exploiting 54 Paper-making and Paper Products Manufacturing 38 Garments, Shoes and Accessories Manufacturing 37 Timber Processing and Timber, Bamboo, Rattan, Coir and Straw Products Manufacturing 5 80 Note: Data is based on firms with revenues greater than 5 million yuan. Source: Shanghai S&T Yearbook 2007. IV. Tertiary Education and the Innovation System A technologically dynamic industrial economy relies mainly on the local production of knowledge workers and the retention of graduates. In this respect, Shanghai has made considerable progress. The number of universities has risen from 45 to 60 during 1995 ­ 2006 (only Beijing has more universities in China) and enrollment from 147,926 to 466,333 (see Table 5.14 and Table 5.15). Approximately 40 percent of tertiary level students major in science and engineering so that at least in terms of the numbers of graduates with STEM skills, Shanghai is well supplied (Table 5.16). 13 Furthermore, the attractions of the city and opportunities for jobs are such that the vast majority of graduates choose to remain in Shanghai. Table 5.14: Number of Universities Region/Country 1995 1996 2000 2001 2002 2006 2007 Beijing 65 58 61 80 Shanghai 45 41 37 45 50 60 60 Tokyo** 187 186 187 190 Hong Kong* 30 35 35 China 1,041 1,867 Japan 1,161 1,174 1,221 1,228 1,227 1,214 1,212 * denotes data is for the years 2002/3, 2006/7 and 2007/8 ** includes junior colleges and universities Source: Beijing, Shanghai and China Statistical Yearbooks, various years; Hong Kong: Education Bureau, Tokyo Metropolitan Government Table 5.15: Number of Students Region/Country 1995 1996 1997 2000 2001 2002 2006 2007 Beijing 189,953 340,284 Shanghai 147,926 153,804 226,798 279,966 331,649 442,620 466,333 Tokyo 726,485 724,082 721,720 735,726 731,099 Hong Kong* 169,600 184,500 188,300 17,388,00 China 2,906,000 3,021,000 3,174,000 5,560,900 7,190,700 9,033,600 0 13 Although as a percent of the total the number has dropped steadily from 52 percent in 1997, and 42 percent in 2001. Rising enrollment rates after 1999 by increasing the supply of graduates and reducing the growth of salaries of STEM graduates, might be discouraging students from pursuing the hard sciences. Information gathered from interviews suggests that only the engineering and science graduates from the top schools are adequately prepared for entry into the job market and have good job prospects (Wadhwa and others 2007). 81 Japan 3,045,165 3,069,946 3,080,540 3,067,703 3,054,903 3,053,118 3,061,466 3,015,375 * denotes data is for the years 2002/3, 2006/7 and 2007/8 ** includes junior colleges and universities Source: Beijing, Shanghai and China Statistical Yearbooks, various years; Hong Kong: Education Bureau; Japan MEXT Table 5.16: STEM share of Undergraduate students Region/Country 1995 1996 1997 2000 2001 2006 2007 Beijing 52.5 45.6 Shanghai 52.5 42.0 39.9 Tokyo Hong Kong 44.7 46.5 46.6 China 50.8 48.3 49.5 Japan 28.4 28.3 28.4 28.5 * denotes data is for the years 2002/3, 2006/7 and 2007/8 ** includes junior colleges and universities. For Japan, STEM includes Science, Engineering and Medicine. For Hong Kong, the data is based on enrollment for undergraduate and graduate students at universities funded by the UGC. Source: Beijing, Shanghai and China Statistical Yearbooks, various years; Hong Kong: Education Bureau; Japan MEXT. Hong Kong: the University Grants Committee (http://www.ugc.edu.hk/eng/doc/ugc/stat/apcfte_series.pdf). Equally encouraging is the increase in the number of students enrolled in programs for advanced degrees. In 1995, there were about 15,000 students enrolled in such programs (see Table 5.17). This rose to 92,000 in 2007. However, the absolute number of students enrolled is still about half of those in Beijing, and one third of those in Japan. The number of students enrolled in PhD programs in Shanghai has also climbed tenfold in 12 years to 23,00 in 2007, still less than half the enrollment in Beijing but far above Hong Kong's level (see Table 5.18). Table 5.17: Students enrolled in post graduate programs City 1995 1996 2000 2001 2006 2007 Beijing 30,299 79,411 178,091 Shanghai 14,713 30,614 91,763 Tokyo Hong Kong 10,197 8,411 8,517 China 145,443 301,239 1,104,653 Japan 153,423 205,311 261,049 262,113 Source: Beijing, Shanghai and China Statistical Yearbooks, various years; Japan MEXT. Hong Kong: the University Grants Committee (http://www.ugc.edu.hk/eng/ugc/publication/report/figure2007/figures/03.pdf). 82 Table 5.18: Students enrolled in PhD programs City 1995 1996 2000 2001 2006 2007 Beijing 7,475 22,826 49,474 Shanghai 2,333 2,670 8,236 10,503 21,882 23,105 Tokyo Hong Kong 4,033 5,465 5,627 China 55,955 Japan 43,774 62,481 75,365 74,811 Based on average ratios of PhD graduates compared with Masters graduates: * about 16% were enrolled in PhD programs; ** about 25% were enrolled in PhD programs Source: Beijing, Shanghai and China Statistical Yearbooks, various years; Japan MEXT, Hong Kong: the University Grants Committee (http://www.ugc.edu.hk/eng/ugc/publication/report/figure2007/figures/03.pdf). The quality of graduates is a different matter and there is scope here for substantial improvement in order to raise Shanghai's technological capacity and prepare the ground for innovation. 14 Employers find that graduates from even the finest universities have a number of limitations. Although the better graduates have a sound grasp of theory, they lag behind in their knowledge of the latest developments in their fields, have weak communication and practical problem solving skills, and given the emphasis on rote learning, graduates tend to display limited initiative when on the job. According to Simon and Cao (2008, p.192) many students who are "fresh out of universities have trouble handling tasks that require knowledge and skills beyond formal education". Most firms need to invest in 3 to 6 months of training to upgrade the technical and practical skills of their new hires and to instill the corporate culture. More than quantity, Shanghai's tertiary education system now needs to focus on quality of skills hard and soft as innovativeness depends on both. This will require years of effort not just by the universities but also by the municipality and the central government to embed a creative culture (Yusuf 2009b). Only about 10 percent of Chinese professors have doctoral level qualifications ­ 20 percent in elite institutions (Simon and Cao 2008). 14 The increase in class sizes since 1999 could be compromising quality. In this regard Simon and Cao (2008) remark that it is not uncommon for a professor to be supervising as many as ten doctoral students at one time. See Liu (2007) on the ranking and Xin and Normile (2008) for the challenges facing Chinese universities as they attempt to improve the quality of instruction and research. China still faces some difficulties in effectively participating in and collaborating with international scientific organizations (Xu 2008). 83 This is being remedied through new hires but experience will remain in short supply for some time. In order to close the skill gap, the Shanghai government spent 27 billion yuan on social security and job related expenditure in 2007 (13 percent of the fiscal expenditure as against 10 percent in 2006, see Table 5.19) so as to provide more people with career- related training (see Table 5.20). In 2007, more than one million persons (this includes double-counting) received training through public training institutes, an increase of 25 percent over 2004. Raising the quality of education could lessen the need for such remedial training by public institutes and firms. Table 5.19: Spending on Training in Shanghai, 2006-2007 Shanghai 2006 2007 Social Security and Jobs (billion yuan) 17.48 27.42 Social Security and Jobs as % of local fiscal expenditure 9.6 12.5 Source: Shanghai Statistical Yearbook (2008) Table 5.20: Number of People Receiving Training Shanghai 000 001 002 003 004 005 006 007 Number of People Receiving Career Training (1 000 person times) 55.81 15.8 87.6 66.4 82.3 71.2 103.8 105.3 Source: Shanghai Statistical Yearbook (2008) Two universities - Shanghai Jiao Tong University and Fudan University ­ are among the top (globally) ranked universities in Shanghai (see Table 5.21 and Table 5.22). These universities also rank in the top 10 within China (excluding those in Hong Kong). While these rankings typically do not change much from year to year, Shanghai Jiao Tong University has moved up its global ranking from 404-502 in 2004 to 201-302 in 2008. 84 Table 5.21: Ranking of Universities in Beijing, Hong Kong, Shanghai, and Tokyo, 2008 World Regional National Institution* Country Location Rank Rank Rank 19 1 1 Tokyo Univ Japan Tokyo 101-151 9-16 5-7 Tokyo Inst Tech Japan Tokyo 201-302 23-41 1-3 Chinese Univ Hong Kong China-hk Hong Kong 201-302 23-41 1-3 Hong Kong Univ Sci & Tech China-hk Hong Kong 201-302 23-41 10-12 Keio Univ Japan Tokyo 201-302 23-41 1-6 Peking Univ China Beijing 201-302 23-41 1-6 Shanghai Jiao Tong Univ China Shanghai 201-302 23-41 1-6 Tsinghua Univ China Beijing 201-302 23-41 1-3 Univ Hong Kong China-hk Hong Kong 201-302 23-41 1-6 Univ Sci & Tech China China Beijing 303-401 42-68 4-5 City Univ Hong Kong China-hk Hong Kong 303-401 42-68 7 Fudan Univ China Shanghai 303-401 42-68 4-5 Hong Kong Polytechnic Univ China-hk Hong Kong 303-401 42-68 13-18 Tokyo Med & Dental Univ Japan Tokyo 303-401 42-68 13-18 Waseda Univ Japan Tokyo 402-503 69-100 8-18 China Agr Univ China Beijing 402-503 69-100 19-31 Nihon Univ Japan Tokyo 402-503 69-100 19-31 Tokyo Metropolitan Univ Japan Tokyo 402-503 69-100 19-31 Tokyo Univ Agr & Tech Japan Tokyo Note: Institutions within the same rank range are listed alphabetically. Source: Center for World-Class Universities, Shanghai Jiao Tong University (http://www.arwu.org/rank2008/en2008.htm). Table 5.22: Times Higher Education Global Ranking of Universities, 2007 2007 2006 RANK RANK NAME City 19 17 University of Tokyo Tokyo 26 18 University of Hong Kong Hong Kong 39 53= Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Hong Kong 42 38 Chinese University of Hong Kong Hong Kong 50= 36 Peking University Beijing 56 40 Tsinghua University Beijing 61 90= Tokyo Institute of Technology Tokyo 113 85= Fudan University Shanghai 141 155= University of Science and Technology of China Beijing 144= 163= Shanghai Jiao Tong University Shanghai 147= 149= City University of Hong Kong Hong Kong 180= 180= Waseda University Tokyo Note: = means that the rank is tied. Source: Times Higher Education (http://www.timeshighereducation.co.uk/hybrid.asp?typeCode=243&pubCode=1&navcode=137). 85 The volume of S&T skills and the quality of the workforce is an indicator of technological capacity of relevance to advanced manufacturing industries. The level of R&D and its productivity is a gauge of innovation capacity. Shanghai invested 2.6 percent of its GDP in R&D in 2007 up from 1.3 percent in 1995 and more than a percentage point higher than the average for China (see Table 5.23). 15 This is second only to Beijing which invests 6 percent. As is the case in the rest of China and in industrialized countries, two thirds of the R&D is done by firms. The distribution of R&D in Shanghai and in Beijing is shown in Figure 5.3 and Table 5.24. The trend is in the direction seen in the advanced industrial economies, away from government institutes towards firms and universities. However, the productivity of R&D in many of the SOEs is questionable. Most of these companies do not yet have in place the business models, incentives, and experienced managerial and supervisory staff to effectively organize research activities, to derive adequate benefits from R&D by integrating it closely with production and marketing, and to routinize incremental innovation throughout the firm. However, some of the SOEs are learning how to harness their R&D more effectively. The value of R&D by MNCs and the spillovers are also questionable. It is difficult to say whether enough core R&D is being done in Shanghai by MNCs and given worries over IP, probably relatively little. The fact that hardly any researchers leave major MNCs to start their own firms would point to few much needed spin-offs although employee turnover in the MNCs does transfer knowledge to local producers. The share of universities in research was about 10 percent in 2006, about the same as in 2001. As most of the basic and upstream applied research vital for innovation in high tech industries is likely to be conducted in universities, in future they have a major role in pushing outward the frontiers of potentially commercializable knowledge and in imparting the skills of relevance for dynamic fast growing industries (see Figure 5.4). 16 15 Europe is losing ground in research and innovation because spending on R&D has stagnated at around 2 percent for 10 years and because of the low academic attainment of most European universities which has affected the quality of graduates and postgraduate students and induced many of the brightest to emigrate to the United States (Patten 2006). 16 "From the point of view of the unthinking market mechanism, investment in basic research is largely a wasteful expenditure because the outlay offers no dependable promise of addition to the profits of the firm" (Baumol 2004, p.24). Basic research will depend largely on state funding because of its public good nature. That such research can initiate cycles of innovation, is supported by the experience of government funding for IC and biotechnology in the United States, of the Internet and of digital search technology. To 86 Thus growth in the shares of universities and of basic research in total research, are desirable developments. Table 5.23: R&D Spending Share of Regional GDP (%) Region/Country 1995 2000 2007 Beijing* 8.9 6.0 Shanghai 1.3 1.7 2.6 Hong Kong** 0.4 0.6 0.8 China* 0.6 1.0 1.4 Japan** 3.0 3.2 3.0 Note: * denotes end year is 2006 ** denotes data is from the years 1998, 2002 and 2006. Source: Beijing, Shanghai and China Statistical Yearbooks, various years; Tokyo: TMG (http://www.toukei.metro.tokyo.jp/keizaik/kk05pa1000.xls); Hong Kong: Science & Technology Statistics Section, Census and Statistics Department, May 2008 Revision; Japan: World Development Indicators (WDI) 2008. Figure 5.3: Expenditure on R&D by Type of Activity in Shanghai Expenditure on R&D By Type of Activity 30 25 Experimental 20 Development Applied Research 15 10 Basic Research 5 0 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 cite just one currently famous example, the firm Google, was the outcome of an NSF grant to Stanford to research digital libraries. 87 Figure 5.4: R&D Expenditure by Type of Institution in Shanghai R&D Expenditure By Sector of Performance 100% Others 80% Higher Education 60% Business Net of Large & Medium 40% Enterprise Large and Medium 20% Enterprises 0% Research Institutions 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 Table 5.24: Expenditure on R&D and Its Composition in Beijing, 2005-2006 Share (%) 2005 2006 2005 2006 Total (billion yuan) 75.10 87.48 Group by Execution Body Scientific Research Institutions 27.00 32.41 35.96 37.05 Institutions of Higher Education 7.86 9.02 10.47 10.32 Enterprise 38.52 43.21 51.30 49.40 Medium- and Large-sized Industrial Enterprises 8.37 11.48 11.15 13.12 Others 1.70 2.83 2.27 3.24 Source: Beijing Statistical Yearbook 2006, 2007 V. University Industry Linkages Both universities and firms are important components of a national innovation system. With globalization and intensifying competitive pressure, many countries are now seeing the collaboration between universities and industrial sector as a means of spurring innovation. 17 The experience from the United States shows that productivity in 17 The best research universities strive to create an environment which encourages interdepartmental and interdisciplinary collaborative work. They work hard to attract and nurture the very best talents, and they attempt to deepen the research in fields, with the greatest perceived potential. Stanford for example got it right when it decided to build its research capacity in solid state electronics by hiring new faculty, expanding graduate programs and setting up specialized laboratories (Lenoir and others 2004). 88 terms of innovation increases when there is a joint venture between universities and firms (Darby, Zucker and Wang 2003). 18 National and local governments have introduced a number of schemes to encourage key universities to increase research and to engage with firms so as to stimulate innovative activities in their locale. Shanghai is no exception. There are two broad vehicles for university-industry linkages in China. The first consists of the traditional mechanisms such as licensing, consulting, and collaborative R&D activities. This was formally encouraged by the establishment of six state technology transfer centers in key universities. Shanghai Jiao Tong University (SJTU) is one such center. The other vehicle is the establishment of university start-ups and spin- offs, in many industrial subfields few of which are high tech (K. Chen and Kenney 2007). 19 Often these university enterprises were established to supplement a university's budget and to absorb surplus university personnel although this practice is declining (Wu 2007). 20 Fudan University and Shanghai Jiao Tong Universities are the two premier universities in Shanghai. Their technology licensing revenue in 2003 was 73.3 million yuan for Fudan and 224.5 million yuan for SJTU (Wu 2007). The state technology transfer center at SJTU has branch offices in the Yangtze River and Pearl River Delta regions, to extend their reach. Fudan University established a Commercialization and University Enterprise Management Office to promote spin-off activities. By 2003, there were more than 100 spin-off firms managed by the office. Some have gone public such as Fudan Fuhua Pharmaceuticals and Shanghai Fudan Microelectronics Company Limited, an IC firm. SJTU also has a number of spin-off firms, Angli Ltd., being the most well-known. Both universities find that the absorptive capabilities of local domestic 18 This is based on the behavior of firms participating in the Advanced Technology Program (ATP) in the United States. Participating in the ATP itself increases the number of patents applied by firms. This is further enhanced through partnership with universities. The ATP program was introduced in the United States after the successful implementation of R&D consortia in Japan (Fukuda and Watanabe 2008). For the analysis of R&D consortia in Japan, see Sakakibara (1997), Sakakibara (2001), and Sakakibara and Cho (2002). 19 During 1997-2004, Chinese universities spun off 42,945 firms, although most of these are not high-tech operations and many were created to provide employment for university staff that were redundant. Nevertheless, this is a striking achievement and points to the role that the universities can play (M. C. Hu and Mathews 2008). 20 However, Fudan University restructured all existing university enterprises so that these enterprises are separated from the university (Wu 2007). 89 firms, especially that of SMEs to be weak. These universities engage with MNCs mainly through joint R&D efforts, often focusing on the localizing of foreign technologies for the Chinese market (Wu 2007). In 2007, the contract value of technologies transferred by universities in Shanghai was 171 million yuan (see Table 5.25). About quarter of this contract income is from the sale of patents. State-owned enterprises are the most frequent users of the technology developed in universities, followed by private enterprises. Foreign firms are not actively involved in university-industry linkages since they can draw on the parent firm's expertise, the expertise of buyers and suppliers, and in-house research centers with the relevant specialized skills. Table 5.25: Technological Transfer from Universities (Science, Engineering, Agriculture and Medicine) Real Income Contracts at Present Number of Value Year Contracts 1 000yuan) (1 000yuan) Total 329 170,630 123,342 of which: Patent Sale 62 40,763 27,933 Sale of Other Intellectual Property Right 131 37,380 34,280 By Type of Technological Transfer State-owned Enterprises 126 90,223 60,475 Foreign Funded Enterprises 31 17,692 18,215 Private Enterprises 131 52,530 35,784 Others 41 10,185 8,868 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 A shortage of promising new startups is one constraint which is compounded ­ albeit to a diminishing extent ­ by the limited availability of venture financing for the riskier firms. Many start-ups, and even the spin-offs rely on personal and family financial resources for the seed capital (Wu 2007). 21 Public research institutes in Shanghai are becoming more actively engaged in technology acquisition and transfer. In 2006, the total amount expended on acquiring technologies was 25 million yuan (see Table 5.26). This amount is almost equally 21 Own resources, family and friends are the principal sources of seed capital in advanced economics with mature capital markets. The complaints voiced by entrepreneurs in New York are little different from those of individuals starting up firms in Shanghai. 90 divided in between natural science and engineering. These institutes also received 570 million yuan from technology transfers. More than three quarters of the revenues come from technology transfer in engineering, followed by natural sciences and medical science (see Table 5.26). Clearly the comparative advantage in engineering is substantial. Table 5.26: Technological acquisition and Transfer by Natural Science Research and Technology Development Institutions (2006) Expenditures for Technology Revenue from Acquisition in Technology Transfer 2006(1 000yuan) at 2006(1 000yuan) Total 25,127 569,129 by Subject Natural Sciences 13,074 104,129 Agriculture Science 0 0 Medical Science 0 25,670 Engineering 12,053 439,330 Social Science and Humanities 0 0 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 A total of 28,191 technical contracts were issued in Shanghai, valued at 34 billion yuan (see Table 5.27). This represents a significant increase over the 23,816 technical contracts signed in 2001. The largest single type of contract in terms of value was in the area of technology transfer, followed by technological development, however, the majority of contracts were for services. Table 5.27: Technical Contracting in Shanghai, 2006 Number of Contracts(item) Contract Value (million yuan) Total 28191 34,442.8 By type of Contracts Technological Development 6165 14,279.2 Technological Transfer 2172 16,517.7 Technological Consulting 3592 760.2 Technological Service 16262 2,885.6 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 Closer inspection of the purpose of such technical contracts reveals that industrial promotion has the largest share (see Table 5.28). Within industry, electronics and 91 information technology dominate other areas. Advanced manufacturing technology was second ranked and medicine and medical equipment came third (see Table 5.29). Table 5.28: Technical Contracting in Shanghai, 2006 Number of Contract Value (million Contracts(item) yuan) Total 28,191 34,442.8 By Social and Economic Purposes Agriculture, Animal Husbandry and Fishery 66 42.7 Promoting Industry 5,472 11,270.7 Promoting Production, Allocation and Utilization of Energy 968 974.6 Promoting Infrastructure 1,258 3,211.9 Environmental Protection and Treatment of Pollution 2,840 294.0 Public Health(not including Pollution) 1,056 2,351.3 Social Development and Service 8,031 5,786.0 Exploration and Utilization of the Earth and Atmosphere 14 30.5 Knowledge Development 369 279.3 Civil Space 515 4,290.1 National Defense 158 80.5 Others 7,444 5,831.4 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 92 Table 5.29: Areas of Technical Contracting in Shanghai, 2006 Number of Contract Value (million Contracts(item) yuan) Total 28,191 34,442.8 By Areas of Technology Electronic Information Technology 6,921 15,739.1 Aviation and Aircraft Technology 181 78.7 Advanced Manufacture Technology 2,657 5,416.3 Biology, Medicine and Medical Equipment 2,886 3,469.4 New Material and its Application 789 3,269.5 New Energy and High Efficiency Energy Saving 1,384 1,687.1 Environmental Protection and Comprehensive Resource Utilization Technology 3,331 439.2 Nuclear Application Technology 62 19.0 Agricultural Technology 158 66.7 Modern Traffic 1,430 2,321.0 Urban Construction and Social Development 8,392 1,937.0 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 Shanghai is still at the intermediate stage of industrialization and firms are attempting to upgrade technology. When these firms seek technological support they look to ­ public research institutes and universities to identify and adopt new technologies to meet their requirements. Therefore, the resulting intellectual properties tend to be trade secrets (since these technologies would be rather firm specific) and computer software (which are most likely embedded software either for machinery or the final products, see Table 5.30). Only a few result in patents since not many firms are engaging in development of new technologies. This is also consistent with the fact that majority of the entities seeking technology are SOEs and local private firms that have limited in- house R&D. Foreign funded firms, tended to rely on parent firms for localization and adaptation of technologies, although more of them are entering into contract relationships with local public research institutes and local universities. 93 Table 5.30: Technical Contracting in Shanghai, 2006 Number of Contracts(item) Contract Value (million yuan) Total 28,191 34,442.8 By Intellectual Property Technical Secret 22,189 17,320.7 Patent 586 4,003.8 Computer Software 3,812 8,448.2 New Product of Animal and Plant 2 0.4 Designing Integrated Circuit Layout 94 3,057.3 New Product of Biology and Medicine 329 1,055.1 Intellectual Property Not Involved 1,179 557.3 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 The majority of the technical contracts entered into originated in Shanghai, followed by the neighboring provinces of Jiangsu and Zhejiang (see Table 5.31). In addition, there are a large number of contracts (and in terms of the value, the second largest), coming from abroad. This may reflect the business accruing to the increasing number of R&D centers run by foreign firms. 22, 23 Since R&D activities are typically associated with activities of the parent firms instead of affiliates, these contracts may be classified as "foreign" in origin. It appears that Shanghai is on the threshold to becoming a regional innovation hub for industrial research, a promising development which if it does materialize, should benefit local industries. 22 In 1980, close to half (45%) of the MNCs conducted R&D only in their home countries. By 2000 this share was down to 27%. In 2000, the median number of countries where MNCs operate R&D centers was four while a handful of MNCs conduct R&D in more than 10 countries (Quintas and others 2008). 23 China now hosts more than 1,000 such R&D facilities, although some of these R&D facilities are established purely to meet the conditions imposed by the government. However, an increasing number are starting to do real R&D work that is reflected in the patenting statistics. See Sun, Du and Huang (2006) for a detailed look into MNCs' R&D operations in Shanghai and Y.-C. Chen (2008) on factors attracting MNCs to conduct R&D in Beijing. In 2008 China ranked higher than the United States as the preferred location for the R&D facilities of MNCs ­ 61 percent preferred China and only 41 percent polled for the U.S. Between 1998 and 2003, U.S. companies investment in their R&D operations overseas was twice (52 percent) the rate of their investments in the U.S. (26 percent). See Auerswald and Branscomb (2008). 94 Table 5.31: Flow of Technical Contracting in China, 2006 Number of Contracts(item) Contract Value (million yuan) Total 28,191 34,442.8 By Flow Direction Beijing 847 2,344.2 Tianjin 129 108.3 Shanghai 20,742 18,781.5 Jiangsu 1,403 620.0 Zhejiang 1,134 390.2 Guangdong 498 540.6 Hong Kong, Macao, Taiwan 149 648.7 Abroad 1,410 8,894.2 Other provinces 1,879 2,115 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 Private initiative was one part of the story, government support for R&D and demand for high tech products was the crucial second part. Abundant government funding and encouragement was critical to the coalescence of the Silicon Valley industrial cluster. It was government support spread over decades (much of it motivated by defense related spending), that provided the essential underpinnings for the mixed public and private tertiary education and research ecosystem which has sustained Silicon Valley's legendary technological dynamism and ability to transition from one type of technologies to the next. This ecosystem is now a vast and vibrant service industry in itself employing large numbers of people and is tightly linked not only to firms in the Valley and California but also to services, venture capital providers, and industries throughout the United States and in India, Taiwan (China) and Israel to name some of the most prominent (Bresnahan and Gambardella 2004). VI. Innovation Outcomes The expenditure on R&D is a highly imperfect indicator of innovation capability because a lot of what is classified as R&D by firms is little more than minor product development and testing. Calling it R&D brings tax credits or other financial benefits but is not conducive to innovation. The indirect measures of innovation capacity are invention patents, papers published in refereed scientific journal, and new products. The newness of the latter is also often suspect and newness cannot be equated with innovation, nevertheless, it is a pointer. Patents and papers infrequently lead to 95 commercial innovation however, these two contribute to the pool of scientific knowledge and useable ideas out of which come innovative products, processes or services which can be profitable over the longer term. Strong encouragement by central and municipal governments, starting in 1999, produced a sharp increase in these three indicators of innovation capacity, after 2001. Table 5.32 indicates how Shanghai has performed relative to China as a whole and to Beijing its closest competitor in patenting. 24 Although the shares of applications from Shanghai are close to those from Beijing, patent applications emanating from Beijing seem to be approved more frequently, suggesting that the quality of patents from Beijing is higher. Table 5.32: Share of Domestic Invention Patents from Beijing, Shanghai, and Hong Kong, 1990-2006 (%) Applications Granted Hong Beijing Shanghai Hong Kong Beijing Shanghai Kong 1990 14.2 5.1 - 18.8 8.6 - 1995 12.5 3.6 - 21.4 4.7 - 2000 13.4 18.6 0.6 17.4 4.9 0.5 2006 11.6 9.9 0.5 15.4 10.5 0.6 Note: only invention patents are included in the figure. Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007, China Statistical Yearbook on Science and Technology various years. While the share of patent applications (including invention, utility, and design) from universities and colleges are increasing in recent years, more than two-thirds of patent applications come from firms (see Table 5.33). 25 Universities submit 25 percent of the invention patents, but the majority of patents are still granted to firms. 26 Table 5.33: Share of Patent Applications by Different Types of Organizations in Shanghai 24 Patenting in China has increased dramatically, especially since 2000. It stems from the reform of the patent law, clearer assignment of property rights, and inflow of foreign direct investment ­ both in production and research activities (A. G. Hu and Jefferson 2006). 25 In the United States, universities and colleges account for at most four percent of patents granted in any given year. 26 Even so, the contribution of universities to innovative outcome in China is much larger than compared to other economies in East Asia (Tuan and Ng 2007). 96 (%) Industrial and Government Research Universities and Colleges Mining Agencies and Institutions Enterprises Organizations 1996 2.1 4.7 32.7 11.2 2000 4.5 5.3 51.9 0.9 2003 2.8 3.1 81.9 0.5 2006 9.6 5.2 69.3 1.7 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 Table 5.34: Share of Invention Patents by Different Types of Organizations in Shanghai, 2006 (%) Natural Science R&D Universities Private R&D Applications 11.2 25.0 41.2 Grants 15.5 4.9 34.8 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 Firms in communication equipment, computers and other electronic equipment are in the forefront of applicants for invention patents and in being granted patents. 27 In 2006, firms in this subsector applied for 1,289 patents (more than half of all applications for invention patents) and were granted 430 patents (about one-third of all invention patent grants) (see Table 5.35). Firms in smelting and pressing of ferrous metals, general machinery, chemicals, medicine, and transport equipment follow the electronic industry in terms of patents. Firms in other manufacturing subsectors rarely apply for patents. 27 From his analysis of data on patents from China's State Intellectual Property Office, A. G. Hu (2008, p.261) finds that most patents go to the machinery industry, followed by other chemicals, radio and TV and basic chemicals. 97 Table 5.35: Distribution of Patent Applications and Grants in Shanghai among Manufacturing Subsectors, 2006 Applicati Grants ons Total 2301 1474 By Industrial Sectors Processing of Food from Agricultural Products 0 2 Manufacture of Foods 4 7 Manufacture of Beverages 1 1 Manufacture of Tobacco 2 12 Manufacture of Textile 17 10 Manufacture of Textile Wearing Apparel, Footwear and Caps 0 0 Manufacture of Leather, Fur, Feather and Related Products 0 0 Processing of Timber, Manufacture of Wood, Bamboo, Rattan, Palm and Straw Products 4 1 Manufacture of Furniture 0 0 Manufacture of Paper and Paper Products 2 3 Printing ,Reproduction of Recording Media 9 4 Manufacture of Articles For Culture, Education and Sport Activities 10 1 Processing of Petroleum, Coking, Processing of Nuclear Fuel 42 118 Manufacture of Raw Chemical Materials and Chemical Products 128 130 Manufacture of Medicines 70 117 Manufacture of Chemical Fibers 0 0 Manufacture of Rubber 6 10 Manufacture of Plastics 6 1 Manufacture of Non-metallic Mineral Products 17 24 Smelting and Pressing of Ferrous Metals 323 266 Smelting and Pressing of Non-ferrous Metals 3 4 Manufacture of Metal Products 15 16 Manufacture of General Purpose Machinery 151 144 Manufacture of Special Purpose Machinery 81 35 Manufacture of Transport Equipment 74 51 Manufacture of Electrical Machinery and Equipment 22 62 Manufacture of Communication Equipment, Computers and Other Electronic Equipment 1,289 430 Manufacture of Measuring Instruments and Machinery for Cultural Activity and Office Work 9 5 Manufacture of Artwork and Other Manufacturing 0 0 Recycling and Disposal of Waste 0 0 Production and Supply of Electric Power and Heat Power 11 19 Production and Supply of Gas 0 0 Production and Supply of Water 5 1 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 The number of papers published also increased dramatically (see Figure 5.5). Clearly, innovation capacity as measured by these imperfect criteria, is on an upswing. 98 Figure 5.5: Number of Scientific Papers Published Number of Scientific Papers Published 18,000 16,000 14,000 12,000 10,000 Total(piece) 8,000 SCI 6,000 4,000 2,000 0 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 19 19 19 19 20 20 20 20 20 20 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 Introduction of new products to the market is also viewed as an indicator of innovativeness. In 2007, revenues from such new products accounted for 21 percent of gross value of industrial output in Shanghai as against 13 percent in 2001 (see Table 5.36). There are a number of subsectors where the share of revenues from new products exceeded the average for Shanghai. It is noteworthy that equipment producers of various kinds lead the field. Three subsectors stand out. These are: general equipment; transportation equipment; and communications equipment, computers and other electronic equipment. These three subsectors account for more than 70 percent of the new product output, suggesting that their outputs are much larger than those coming from other subsectors, even innovative ones. Judging from Table 5.36, it appears that these three subsectors also have the highest share of new products in exports, although export intensity and the revenues from new products are not correlated. There are some subsectors that have high export intensity (e.g. metal products, chemical fibers, and rubber products), although they do not introduce many new products. Since 1994, manufacturers of general equipment, transportation equipment, and communications equipment, computer and other electronic equipment, have introduced the largest number of new products (see Figure 5.6). 99 Table 5.36: New Products Development of Industrial Enterprises in Shanghai, 2007 Share of New Share of New Share of New Products in Products Products GVIO by Output in Exports in Export Subsector (%) Shanghai (%) Shanghai (%) Intensity (%) Overall Manufacturing 21.5 17.1 # Farm and Sideline Products Processing 0.4 0.0 0.0 6.4 Food 3.2 0.2 0.1 5.1 Beverage 0.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 Tobacco 11.9 0.7 0.1 3.2 Textile 4.6 0.4 0.1 5.4 Garments, Shoes and Accessories 0.4 0.0 0.0 20.2 Furniture 27.8 1.2 1.3 18.4 Paper-making and Paper Products 0.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 Printing and Record Duplicating 12.6 0.5 0.0 1.1 Stationary, Education and Sports Goods 2.4 0.1 0.1 10.4 Oil Processing, Coking and Nuclear 9.7 2.1 0.0 0.0 Raw Chemical Materials and Chemical 11.5 4.0 1.6 6.9 Medicine 26.4 1.6 0.3 3.5 Chemical Fiber 0.5 0.0 0.0 36.7 Rubber Products 17.5 0.6 1.2 33.6 Plastic Products 2.0 0.2 0.3 22.9 Nonmetal Mineral Products 4.9 0.4 0.4 14.5 Smelting and Pressing of Ferrous Metals 22.2 7.7 2.0 4.4 Smelting and Pressing of Nonferrous Metals 3.9 0.4 0.1 2.5 Metal Products 4.1 0.7 2.7 62.0 General Equipment 27.9 11.4 18.4 27.4 Special Purpose Equipment 14.7 1.9 1.7 15.4 Transportation Equipment 57.5 29.4 21.5 12.5 Electric Machinery Equipments 15.7 5.4 9.3 29.8 Communications Equipments, Computer and Other Electronic Equipment 27.3 29.4 33.6 19.5 Instruments, Meters, Culture and Office Equipments 21.5 1.5 5.0 57.0 Artworks and Other 0.9 0.0 0.0 31.7 Note: Export intensity is calculated as the share of new products exports over the revenue from the new products. Data is based on firms with revenues greater than 5 million yuan. Source: Shanghai Statistical Yearbook 2008 100 Figure 5.6: Changes in Share of New Product Output in Shanghai 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1994 2001 2006 Timber Processing, Bamboo, Cane, Plam Fiber, Straw Products Leather, Furs, Dow n and Related Products Other Manufacturing Instruments,Meters,Culture and Office Equipments Manufacturing Communications Equipments,Computer and Othe Electronic Equipment Manufacturing Electric Machinery Equipments and Manufacturing Transportation Equipment Manufacturing Special Purpose Equipment Manufacturing General Equipment Manufacturing Metal Products Manufacturing S lti dP i fN f M t l Source: Shanghai Statistical Yearbook 2008 Another indicator of technological, if not innovation capacity is the changing share of high tech components and capital goods in Shanghai's exports. Close to 40 percent of exports from Shanghai are high-tech products up from 20 percent in 2001 (see Table 5.37). The bulk of the high-tech exports are computer and telecommunication related goods. This also is a promising trend although thus far, most of these exports are produced by foreign invested firms using imported inputs. 101 Table 5.37: Value of Exports of High-tech Products in Shanghai (2001-2006), billion US$ 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Value of Exports of High-tech 5.4 7.5 16.4 28.9 36.3 44.3 Products Exports 27.6 32.1 48.5 73.5 90.7 113.6 Value of Exports of High-tech Products/Exports 19.6 23.4 33.8 39.3 40.0 39.0 By Technology Field of Which: Computers and 3.2 4.2 11.3 19.1 24.4 30.2 telecommunications Electronics 1.7 2.8 4.1 7.1 7.8 10.6 Life science 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.7 0.9 By Trade Mode of which: Processing with 3.3 4.7 12.0 20.4 27.2 34.8 imported materials General Trade 0.5 0.7 1.4 2.6 3.2 4.4 By Ownership of which: State-owned and 0.5 0.7 0.8 0.8 1.1 1.6 Collective-owned Cooperative 2.4 2.0 2.6 3.9 3.9 3.7 Foreign Funded 2.4 4.7 12.7 23.8 30.4 37.9 By Destinations of which: US 1.3 1.5 4.6 7.9 10.2 12.6 EU 1.3 1.5 4.1 7.9 10.6 12.3 Hong Kong 0.8 1.2 2.0 3.5 4.6 6.0 Japan 0.6 0.9 1.6 2.6 2.8 3.2 Source: Shanghai Science and Technology Yearbook 2007 The level and distribution of FDI offers an additional indirect perspective on how Shanghai's comparative advantage is perceived by foreign investors. 28 It is useful because such investors are able to compare Shanghai's medium term potential with that of other cities in China and abroad and to make decisions which weigh a variety of options. By selecting specific industries, MNCs are factoring in incentives as well as technological capacity, the quality and productivity of the workforce, the adequacy of the physical infrastructure, and the livability of the city. From the information contained in Figure 5.7 one can see how rapidly FDI in Shanghai has risen since 1990. In 1990, the total FDI inflow was US$0.2 billion and 28 On the links between FDI and development in China's two major urban regions enjoying substantial agglomeration economies (the Yangtze and Pearl River deltas), see Tuan and Ng (2007). 102 there were hardly any wholly-owned foreign firms. By 2007, the actual FDI flow had increased to US$7.9 billion, three-quarters into wholly-owned foreign subsidiaries. Figure 5.7: Amount of foreign direct investment inflow to Shanghai (billion US$) 8.0 7.0 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 1990 2000 2006 2007 # Joint Ventures Cooperative Ventures Sole-foreign Funded Enterprises Source: Shanghai Statistical Yearbook 2008 These are encouraging trends because they suggest that foreign businesses are beginning to view Shanghai as a center for advanced manufacturing activities which is making progress in perfecting a local innovation system. Venture Capital Much of the patient capital raised by firms in Shanghai comes from the banking sector which reflects an East Asia wide pattern. Banks being the dominant financial institutions do engage in venture financing, partly as a way of building their lending business. 29 However, bank lending is only a partial substitute for the kind of risk capital innovative firms need, hence attention in China and elsewhere has focused on the venture capital industry. In 2007, there were 236 venture capital firms (including foreign venture 29 See Hellman, Lindsey and Puri (2004) on venture lending by U.S. banks. 103 capital) in Shanghai with investment of 30 billion yuan (see Table 5.38). VC industry in Shanghai accounts for 40 percent of all VC activities in China (Shanghai Venture Capital Association 2008). Table 5.38: Number of Venture Capital Firms and Capital Committed in Shanghai, 2004-2007 2004 2005 2006 2007 # of firms 106 204 215 236 capital under management (billion yuan) 16.8 25.0 28.0 30.46 Source: Shanghai Venture Capital Association (2008) As one would expect, the type of subsector that VCs invest in is heavily geared towards high-tech areas such as software and networks; biotechnology; microelectronics; new materials; and also financial services (see Table 5.39), although in recent years, the spread among different subsectors is lessening. The VC industry's areas of focus overall are stable, but those by foreign VCs shift from one year to the next. In 2004, investments in software and biotech accounted for almost half of foreign VC investment. However, by 2006, the focus had shifted to telecommunication and traditional manufacturing. Broadly, the area of concentration is similar between the domestic and foreign firms in 2007, although foreign firms are more active in telecommunication and less so in biotech (Table 5.40). Table 5.39: Areas of Investment by VC in Shanghai, 2004-2007 (%) 2004 2005 2006 2007 Software and Networks 25.0 20.9 16.2 14.3 Biotechnology and Medical Care 21.3 20.9 16.2 13.7 Financial Services 5.0 7.0 5.4 8.6 Microelectronics 7.5 8.1 9.9 7.4 New Material 7.5 8.1 12.6 7.4 Telecommunication 5.0 9.3 8.1 6.9 Energy Technology 1.3 2.3 9.9 6.3 Traditional Manufacturing 2.5 0.0 3.6 6.3 Computer Hardware 2.5 1.2 3.6 2.9 Environment 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.9 Agriculture 0.0 0.0 1.8 2.3 Others 22.5 22.1 12.6 21.1 Source: Shanghai Venture Capital Association (2008) 104 Table 5.40: Area of Investment by Foreign VC in Shanghai, 2004-2007 (%) 2004 2005 2006 2007 Software and Networks 31.3 18.8 0.0 10.7 Microelectronics 12.5 18.8 15.4 10.7 Financial Services 12.5 6.3 0.0 10.7 Telecommunication 12.5 18.8 23.1 8.9 Computer Hardware 6.3 6.3 0.0 7.1 Biotechnology and Medical Care 18.8 6.3 7.7 7.1 New Material 0.0 6.3 0.0 7.1 Traditional Manufacturing 0.0 0.0 15.4 7.1 Energy Technology 0.0 0.0 15.4 5.4 Agriculture 0.0 0.0 7.7 3.6 Environment 0.0 0.0 0.0 3.6 Others 6.3 18.8 15.4 17.9 Note: Foreign VC includes those from Hong Kong, Taiwan (China), and Macao (China). This table is based on 16 foreign firms among the 85 VC firms sampled and returned the survey. Source: Shanghai Venture Capital Association (2008) VC investment in Shanghai is concentrated in the growth and expansion stage of the firm and not in the very early stages. Compared to the distribution in 2006 and that in 2007, the latest year for which information is available, has not changed radically, although there is more emphasis on the seed stage (see Table 5.41). Foreign VCs also tend to prefer growth and expansion stages. This is also the pattern of venture capital investment in the United States and elsewhere. Typically, seed capital comes from angel investors rather than from venture capital (Auerswald and Branscomb 2003). Table 5.41: Distributions of VC Investment in Shanghai, 2006 and 2007 (%) 2006 2007 Seed 21.6 23.1 Growth 36.4 34.6 Expansion 29.6 30.8 Mature 12.3 11.5 Source: Shanghai Venture Capital Association (2008) Among the sampled VC firms, market prospects were singled out as the most important consideration before making an investment, followed by the quality of the management team, the financial condition of the firm, and the technological capability of 105 the firm (see Table 5.42). 30 Foreign firms assign similar weights on these factors, except for technological capabilities. Instead, foreign VCs put more emphasis on the integrity of corporate governance. Table 5.42: Factors Considered Important by VC Prior to Investment (%) 2006 2007 Market Prospects 32.6 32.4 Management team 24.5 23.1 Financial condition 16.3 14.7 Technology 11.4 12.2 Corporate Governance 6.5 6.3 Stock price 4.3 6.3 Investment location 2.2 3.4 others 2.2 1.7 Note: based on the responses by 83 firms sampled in 2007 Source: Shanghai Venture Capital Association (2008) The most often used vehicle for exit is acquisition by domestic non-listed firms (or natural persons) (see Table 5.43). Listing on the stock exchange abroad, ranks as the second most favored method. Combining this with domestic listings accounts for close to 40 percent of the exits. The balance is through acquisition by various types of firms. What is notable is that the acquisition by listed foreign firms is quite small, representing only 1.6 percent of the total. Table 5.43: Modes of Exit by Start-Up Firms (%) 2004 2005 2006 2007 Acquisition by domestic non-listed firms or natural persons 32.0 43.9 25.0 29.3 Listing abroad 20.0 20.5 18.8 26.0 Acquisition by estate management 17.3 9.1 29.5 15.4 Acquisition by foreign non-listed firms 17.3 18.9 7.1 13.8 Listing domestically 9.3 5.3 10.7 13.8 Acquisition by listed foreign firms 4.0 2.3 8.9 1.6 Source: Shanghai Venture Capital Association (2008) 30 Firms in the famous Silicon Fen cluster in Cambridge, UK have relied mainly on local banks for their borrowings and the volume of lending was constrained by the fewness of bank managers acquainted with the technologies being involved in the cluster. VCs, although active in Cambridge, have financed no more than 10 percent of the firms (Drofiak and Garnsey 2009). 106 The number of people working for VCs more than doubled from 2003 to 2007. The number of professional managers also increased during these period. However, it seemed that the increase in the supply of professional managers was not able to keep up with the expansion of VC industry and the share of professional managers was decreasing until 2005. 31 Since then, the supply of managers has begun outpacing the expansion of the industry. Foreign VCs are more often staffed with professional managers relative to the overall sample. The trend should enhance the effectiveness of the VC industry and facilitate the growth of more technology intensive firms. Nevertheless, more capable VCs can only make a contribution if innovative ideas are forthcoming. Venture capital cannot push innovation. It is pulled by innovation generally of the kind where the payback period is in the region of five years. 32 Table 5.44: Number of Employees at VC in Shanghai, 2003-2007 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 All sampled firms Total 405 711 765 868 962 Professional Managers 166 270 242 319 365 Share of Professional Managers (%) 41.0 38.0 31.6 36.8 37.9 Sample firms 51 70 81 65 83 Of which: Foreign Total 113 99 140 Professional Managers 38 54 67 Share of Professional Managers (%) 33.6 54.5 47.9 Sampled foreign firms 15 7 16 Note: based on sampled firms Source: Shanghai Venture Capital Association (2008) VII. Shanghai: Moving to a more Innovative Economy Recent changes in the composition and capabilities of Shanghai's economy have been mainly in the right direction. The share of manufacturing industries producing 31 The lack of mature and experienced venture capital is also identified as one of the key problems facing firms in Zhongguancun Science Park in Beijing (Cao 2004). 32 Hirukawa and Ueda find that while the growth of VC is positively associated with patent propensity of an industry, VC investments do not necessary lead to an increase in factor productivity. In fact, it is the growth in total factor productivity that attracts venture capital (Hirukawa and Ueda 2008a;b). 107 complex capital and high-tech goods is increasing; there has been a substantial deepening of financial and business services; creative industries are beginning to mature; Shanghai's tertiary education and research sectors are expanding rapidly and beginning to forge links with industry; incentives to conduct R&D and to patent are bearing fruit; venture capital is more abundant and the investors themselves gaining in experience; and the quality of urban infrastructure itself has vastly improved over what it was 15 years ago. Shanghai's industry has accumulated manufacturing and technological capabilities comparable to those of an advanced middle income economy. However, to derive more of its future growth from innovation, Shanghai will need to sustain and further refine its current industrial strengths, and develop innovative capacity across a range of activities through a mix of initiatives affecting firms, knowledge producers, and the quality of life in the city itself. These measures, foreshadowed in earlier sections, are presented in Chapter 6. 108 Chapter 6 Making Shanghai's Industries Innovative With a population approaching 19 million, Shanghai has ample scope for exploiting the productivity enhancing benefits of scale and agglomeration economies. 1 Although some research suggests that the optimal economic size of a Chinese city is reached when population is in the region of 5 million (Au and Henderson 2006a), other findings indicate that well managed cities can continue growing in size without encountering decreasing returns. In fact, Overman and Venables (2005) observe that for a city, being too small is more of a disadvantage than being too large. Shanghai is also a remarkably industrialized city. The share of manufacturing in GDP is twice that of Beijing and it is four times greater than Tokyo and six times that of New York. Even forty years ago, manufacturing industries generated no more than a quarter of Tokyo's GDP and a fifth of the GDP of New York. Shanghai's manufacturing sector moreover, is highly diversified. Of the top six manufacturing subsectors, four comprise equipment of various kinds: general, communications, electronics and transportation. If to these are added special purpose equipment and instruments and office equipment, the six subsectors account for 55 percent of industrial GDP. Metallurgical and chemical industries together contribute 25 percent of the output with industries producing textiles, food, furniture, paper, plastic and wood products making up the rest. The strong export orientation of the leading industries is a good indicator of their competitiveness. With this product mix and industrial diversity, Shanghai can reap the benefits of urbanization economies and also the advantages accruing from a strong focus on industries producing complex capital goods, high technology components and key industrial materials. These industries have multiple linkages with other sectors, and have a history of high productivity growth and of R&D intensity. A comparison of the scale and composition of Shanghai's industrial activities with those of Tokyo suggests that it is better positioned 1 This is especially so because the population density is also high, and agglomeration economies, especially the induced accumulation of human capital, are particularly beneficial at earlier stages of development (Brülhart and Sbergami 2009). In addition, Shanghai is advantaged by its location at close to the mid point of China's coastline (H. Lu 2004). to maintain a strong industrial lead well into the future by complementing its technological capabilities with the capacity to innovate, even as wages and land costs rise and certain kinds of labor intensive industries migrate to other parts of China and to other countries. Moreover, the crisis of 2008-9 and the industrial restructuring it has triggered in China and throughout the world economy, increases the opportunities for radical innovations by dynamic firms (Bers and others 2009), 2 and for an acceleration in labor productivity. Between 1995 and 2003, industrial reform which catalyzed the restructuring of industrial enterprises and a reallocation of resources, contributed over 40 percent of the annual 20 percent increase in labor productivity. There remains scope for further reallocation and "creative destruction" 3 in Shanghai and a closing of the `efficiency gap' between Chinese firms and their overseas competitors (in services and manufacturing industries) which could deliver a continuing productivity bonus over the course of a decade. 4 I. Urban Strategy and Policy Directions China's central and municipal authorities are actively promoting the development of technological and innovation capabilities which will help urban centers to upgrade existing industries and to extend their comparative advantage to new industries with higher profitability and better growth prospects. 5 Shanghai is at the epicenter of these efforts. Starting in the mid 1990s, Shanghai launched a program to develop six pillar industries. These being: information, finance, trade, automobiles, complete sets of equipment, and real estate. More recently it has turned its attention to building business services with an emphasis on finance so as to eventually make Shanghai a world city akin 2 Two examples of firms which have made remarkable strides in cost innovation are the battery maker BYD which has drastically reduced the prices of lithium ion cells; and Zhongxing Medical which has scaled down the costs of direct digital radiography (Williamson and Zeng 2009). BYD is now eyeing the electric car market based on its strength in battery technology. The firm employs 5,000 battery engineers and 5,000 automotive engineers ("China Vies" 2009). 3 This creative destruction will lead to the disappearance of weaker companies and of the considerable excess capacity in several industries (See Foster and Kaplan 2001). 4 J. Zheng, Bigsten and Hu (2009). See for instance the comparison by Crafts and Toniolo (2008) of the persisting productivity differences between the U.S. and European countries. 5 Technology policy will require the coordinated action of national, provincial and local governments. The near term objectives need not be system wide innovation but innovation in specific industries and fields and in specific geographic locations. 110 to New York and London. 6 In pursuance of these strategic initiatives, Shanghai is also actively addressing the factors that affect technological adoption, deepening, and innovation. By strengthening the individual components of a `municipal innovation system' and its linkages, Shanghai seeks to accelerate industrial change in directions that will be advantageous for growth and employment. Space and data limitations make it impossible to evaluate the effectiveness of existing fiscal and financial incentives given to pillar industries and to enhance Shanghai's innovation capacity. However, a listing of the major incentives in Table 6.5 suggests that they are comprehensive, and comparable to incentives provided for high tech industrial development in the OECD countries. Given the uncertainties regarding the effectiveness of these instruments, adding to the list of incentives or making current incentives more generous, may not be desirable. Moreover, the feedback from interviews conducted for this study indicates that neither industry nor research entities are pressing for additional fiscal or financial incentives. What we propose here is a partial reorientation of Shanghai's development strategy based on the findings and views presented in earlier chapters and factoring in Shanghai's industrial assets and capabilities. The intention is, paraphrasing Paul Romer (1993), to introduce better recipes and not just to engage in more cooking. This strategy would: - Emphasize a balanced development of manufacturing and services to maintain the share of manufacturing in municipal output in the 25-30 percent range over the longer term. - Prioritize activities with reference to longer term profitability, local linkages and value added, and scope for incremental innovation and export prospects. - Encourage process innovation (over the medium term) by leading firms in the principal industries over radical product innovation in new high tech areas. On this, the large firms must take the lead, 6 New York and London are the most competitive cities in the world. Shanghai ranks 41st and Beijing 66th ("Urban Competitiveness" 2008). 111 - Promote tertiary education and healthcare, and cultivate strong linkages between these services industry and other industries, - Focus on the quality of workers and entrepreneurs so as to prepare them to contribute more actively to innovation. - Create a culturally rich, aesthetically pleasing, and efficient urban environment so as to attract and retains high value adding economic activities and an increasingly affluent and educated workforce. Balanced development For the purposes of growth that is fuelled by productivity and innovation, Shanghai needs to pursue a two pronged approach. One prong would rely on fiscal, land use, skill deepening, and innovation policies to sustain those industries which by virtue of accumulated tacit knowledge, product customization and differentiation, multiple linkages, research intensity, potential for innovation and high entry barriers, have sound long term profitability, although as in 2009, they may go through cyclical downturns. Several of these industries are likely to be ones producing complex capital goods, components and processed materials. Others at the research intensive end of the spectrum, might trace their technological lineage to the life and the nano sciences or to IT sector or be engaged in developing advanced materials and their competitive strength will depend upon their ties with research centers. What matters more is not only an industry's research intensity but its profitability and the capacity to sustain profitability through a variety of measures, among which innovation in a variety of areas could play a prominent role (Porter 2008). Industries can be research intensive but may struggle to generate a pipeline of products and to achieve profitability as for instance biotechnology, in which case it is far from obvious that they deserve priority over less technologically glamorous industries that are reliably profitable. The drugs introduced by the biopharmaceutical firms (or firms producing advanced materials) take 10 to 15 year to reach the market, cost, development costs as much as drugs introduced by pharmaceutical companies ­ that is, $800 million to $1 billion ­ and biotechnology has made it no easier to discover new and effective drugs. What discoveries (which have spawned new sub-disciplines), and new techniques have uncovered are new layers of complexity requiring inter-disciplinary 112 effort but without any short-cuts. Small doses of venture capital while sufficient for chip design, web based technologies and software, are no more than drops in the bucket for biopharma firms. The U.S. experience cautions against putting too much store by high tech industries. Since 2000, employment in the computer and electronics subsectors has stagnated and the web based and media industries have generated little new employment. Other high tech stars such as biotechnology have yielded new products but breakthrough discoveries have been rare. Nanotechnology has considerable promise but again the commercial successes of nanotech research have been modest and slow to materialize even though U.S. researchers and companies are in the forefront ("Can America Invent" 2008; Pilkington and others 2009). A balanced portfolio of manufacturing industries for Shanghai would assign the highest weights to the machinery, electronic components and processing industries (assuming that the pollution these cause can be contained through regulation coupled with technological advances). It would assign lower weights initially to the research intensive life and nano sciences which have abundant potential but are slow to generate highly profitable products commanding global markets. Supporting these industries makes good strategic sense and safeguards future options. Nevertheless, a realistic appraisal of their contribution to the local economy is needed to ensure that they do not divert an excessive amount of capital and research talent from the backbone sectors. China and Shanghai, have demonstrated a strong and growing comparative advantage in manufactures (see Table 6.1). China has comparative advantage in more than one third of commodities that it exports. 7 By building upon this comparative advantage, following the past example of Germany, Japan, and Korea, China can deepen and extend this advantage into higher value added and knowledge intensive products, thereby increasing its export shares in the more profitable segments of the international market for manufactures. Figure 6.1 shows the product space for China. "Product spaces", pioneered by Hausmann and Klinger (2006), assumes that each commodity produced gives rise to different opportunities for future diversification. That is, some products offer easier and multiple diversification paths to other related products while others do not. In general, primary and resource-based products do not lead to many 7 In comparison, Malaysia has comparative advantage in 16 percent of the products that it exports. 113 opportunities for diversification. By contrast, manufacturing goods such as electronics generate skills and assets that are similar to those required for the production of other manufacturing commodities, and hence are classified as high value products. The x-axis is the inverse of the density (i.e. closer to the origin indicates higher density) and the y- axis measures the difference between PRODY and EXPY (i.e. a positive number means "upgrading" in a sense of exporting more sophisticated commodities relative to the overall export basket). The commodities that are in the area of high density are mostly higher valued commodities such as engineering and high technology goods among others (see Table 6.2). 8 Table 6.1: Exports of China and the Share of Commodities in which China Has A Comparative Advantage 1995 2000 2006/7 Number of commodities exported by China 766 763 763 Number of commodities that China has comparative advantage 274 279 278 (35.8%) (36.6%) (36.4%) Note: There were about 780 products exported by at least one country each year. Source: Authors' calculations Figure 6.1: Product Space for China, 2000-2004 CHN 10000 20000 0 -10000 0 5 10 invdensity Electronics and Electricals Other, High-Technology Automotive Process Engineering Textile, garment & footwear Other, Low-Technology Agro-Based Other, Resource-Based Primary Products Graphs by co untry 8 The discussion in this section focuses on the "upscale" goods i.e. PRODY-EXPY are both positive. 114 Source: Authors' calculations Table 6.2: Selected "upscale" commodities with highest density in China, 2000-2004. PRODY - Product Name Product Density Tech EXPY Other sound recorders and reproduce 7638 0.537294 mt3 4765.33 Television receivers, monochrome 7612 0.524965 ht1 5388.19 Optical instruments and apparatus 8710 0.483351 ht2 10039.76 Peripheral units, incl.control & ada 7525 0.478158 ht1 5142.37 Microphones, loudspeakers, amplifiers 7642 0.472566 ht1 1301.51 Printed circuits and parts thereof 7722 0.468498 mt3 2855.42 Source: Authors' calculations With the global downturn in economic activity which began in 2008, firms in the industrialized countries are abandoning certain types of manufacturing activity ­ as is the case with many mittelstand in Germany. 9 This is opening up lucrative niches in the global market place. 10 Chinese firms can occupy these niches. Furthermore, many firms are in dire straits, which represents an opportunity for Chinese firms to acquire needed technology (codified and tacit), intellectual property, brand names, and market access. 11 The government can facilitate this process by improving access to financing however, the ultimate outcomes will depend upon the initiatives of the firms themselves, the receptivity to such takeovers in the OECD countries and the capacity of Chinese firms to absorb technology ­ and in some cases foreign firms. Chinese firms which will spearhead this process are more likely to succeed with manufactures and services associated with manufactures, than with services, because they already have a head start and have an export product mix comparable to advanced countries (see Table 6.3). 12 And among Chinese cities, Shanghai with its well developed industrial capabilities can emerge as a leading global producer and exporter of the technology intensive, high end manufactures. This is not to deny the contributions that services and the export of services can make to 9 In 2003, Chinese firms acquired 278 small and medium sized German firms (Zeng and Williamson 2007). 10 The US is the leader in only five product categories: computer hardware, software, biotech, aerospace, and entertainment. ("America's Decline" 2008). 11 Samsung was unable to develop or acquire the necessary semiconductor technology until Micron Technology was in a financial distress and willing to make this available (Nabeshima 2004). 12 Even though China exports a similar bundle of goods, there may be substantial quality differences within each commodity. For instance, average unit values of Japanese exports are 2.9 times of China's, suggesting that Japanese exports are of higher quality (Fontagne, Gaulier and Zignago 2008). 115 Shanghai's economy. They can be vital complements. 13 However, even impersonal services are inherently less export intensive, 14 and East Asian and international experience suggests that acquiring an international brand name in services and a sizable global market share, is harder because of entry barriers and takes longer. Table 6.3: Export Similarity with OECD 1972 1981 1991 2001 Asia 0.16 0.20 0.26 0.27 China 0.09 0.28 0.55 0.75 Latin America 0.22 0.22 0.31 0.34 Note: Asia excludes China. The export similarity is calculated as the overlap of export commodities to the United States from OECD and China (and other regions), with 0 being no overlap and 1 being complete overlap. Source: Schott (2006) Manufacturing employs 32.5 percent of Shanghai's workforce. This is a high percentage and many of these jobs are for skilled, middle aged workers who are relatively well paid. The availability of employment on such a scale, buttresses Shanghai's prosperity but there is more to it than that. Capital and skill intensive manufacturing activities also affect the income distribution in the urban area helping to provide the crucial middle layer of income earners which are the vanguard of China's consuming class and whose growth is also a way of checking income inequality. Manufacturing is an urban balance wheel, maintaining growth with equity and the urban economic diversity which is at the root of urbanization economies. I-O data for China shows that capital and knowledge intensive manufacturing activities give rise to a multiplicity of backward and forward linkages supporting a vast number of suppliers of products and services. From the I-O tables we can see that transport equipment manufacturing to take one example, is linked to and sustains a wide spectrum of activities, several of which contribute to innovation and technological progress. The cumulative contribution of the activities associated with transport 13 As a matter of fact, as incomes rise, so does the share of the services industry. Because of its larger share, the growth, especially that of productivity, in services would be desirable. However, it is unlikely that reliance on services sector alone would enable a city (or a country) to achieve growth rates in 6 to 8 percent range. 14 Export of services to other parts of China is likely to become a growing business for firms in Shanghai. 116 equipment subsector to growth for example, is highly significant. Manufacturing is also strongly linked to the logistics/transport sector that is a key industry in Shanghai (see Table 3.10). 15 Manufacturing and logistics are mutually reinforcing and together comprise the principal growth pole of Shanghai's economy. In 2006, out of 100 million TEUs of containers handled in China, 21 million were by Shanghai's ports ("A Failure to Keep" 2007). With one of the busiest ports in China, and a new deep seaport, the opportunities are there for the domestic logistic firms to develop intermodal capabilities and become world class players. 16, 17 The supplier networks which are at the heart of the transport, engineering, and electronics industries are a significant source of value-added and of technological advances. Very likely the survival of suppliers many of which are small and medium sized firms that co-create components and modules with the final assemblers and provide just-in-time services, will determine the future of these industries in Shanghai. Safeguarding the health of the supply chain has always been a consideration, but in a downturn, it takes on added significance because smaller firms servicing narrow markets, are less resilient in the face of demand shocks. With market demand shrinking and credit becoming harder to obtain, specialized component suppliers struggle to survive, and the weaker ones will close their doors. 18 Assisting the majority to weather the recession and also strengthening the foundations of the parts manufacturing industry calls for three types of measures: credit programs catering to firms which are critical nodes in the supply chain and ones with substantial technological capabilities; encouraging 15 Shipbuilding is now a booming industry in the Yangtze River Delta with sound long-term prospects. 16 Unlike some other industries, the logistic industry is still rather fragmented. The top 10 logistics firms accounted for less than 40 percent of the global share in 2006 ("Where Winners" 2007). This provides some opportunities for a new firm to enter the global market since MNCs are now looking for logistics firms that can operate globally. One such firm, Shanghai International Port Group has acquired terminals in Belgium as a first step to becoming a global container operator ("A Very Solid Foundation" 2007). A strong logistics sector can in addition, stimulate financial and insurance transactions as was the case in London and New York. 17 The logistics sector is an important source of earnings and employment in cities such as Miami and Los Angeles. For instance, the Miami International Airport directly and indirectly has created nearly a quarter of a million jobs for the Miami-Dade county area and its annual economic impact via tourism, international banking, and trade in 2006 was estimated at $19 billion. The ports of Long Beach and Los Angeles directly employ 280,000 workers and indirectly support the employment of another 900,000 in the Southern California region ("California's Wipeout Economy" 2009). 18 In 2008, about 300,000 factories ceased their operations, often abandoned by the owners, leaving creditors and workers unpaid ("As Factories Fail" 2009). 117 consolidation of small firms with overlapping product lines into more viable units; 19 and the provision of industrial extension, financial and labor training services to small firms so as to bolster their productivity and widen revenue margins. Rethinking the Role of Finance and Business Services Although the share of services is bound to increase because of trends in demand and in relative prices, it is desirable that over the foreseeable future services should complement and not massively displace industry. The experience of Japan and Germany suggests that even though the services have greatly enlarged their share of GDP, the prosperity of these countries and their positions in the world of trade continues to rest on their advanced manufacturing industries. 20 It is the high productivity of these industries which supports myriad services activities (whose value added is far lower and which have failed over almost two decades to catch-up with equivalent activities in the U.S.), and it also enables Germany and Japan to maintain favorable trade balances. By comparison, it is the relative decline of manufacturing which is partly to blame for the trade deficit the United States confronts and which it will need to narrow. Furthermore, balancing the portfolio of producer services with manufacturing industries minimizes the damage inflicted by shocks affecting particular activities, and can with appropriate coordination, give rise to many more growth promoting linkages. The international experience with the development of major clusters of financial and business services is mixed at best. From a national perspective, financial development is definitely a plus. Financial development which increases the institutional 19 In December 2008, the Chinese government has relaxed the financing rule to allow firms to borrow from banks for the merger and acquisition of firms in the same line of business (in the past, the funding must come from retained earnings, issuing of more stocks or bonds). This has led to some of the cash-rich state- owned enterprises to acquire weaker rivals whether they are state-owned, privately held, or located abroad, especially in strategic industries such as steel and automotives. For instance, Baosteel acquired Ningbo Steel and Baotou Steel through a loan ("China: Pace of Mergers" 2009). The Chinese government is also planning reduce the number of automotive makers from 14 to 10 by 2011 through mergers ("Beijing Drives" 2009). Even though at the same time, the Chinese government is restricting M&A activities, especially those by foreign firms through the anti-monopoly law which became effective on August 1, 2008 ("Deals on Hold?" 2008). Although the Ministry of Commerce approved the InBev's acquisition of Anheuser-Busch, it imposed restrictions on InBev from further increasing their shares in Tsingtao Brewery and Zhujiang Brewery and prohibited from buying shares of two other Chinese breweries ("InBev Ruling" 2008). The Ministry of Commerce prevented Coca-Cola to acquire Huiyuan Juice, a leading juice maker in China ("Beijing Scuppers" 2009). 20 This reliance is also the cause of much economic grief because of the global recession in 2009. 118 stake and leverage of insurance companies, pension funds, and others in publicly listed corporate entities could in a competitive global environment, encourage innovation and improve corporate governance (Aghion, Van Reenen and Zingales 2009). 21 It is also associated with stronger economic performance. Whether finance and business services can be an effective growth engine for mega cities is less obvious. Only New York and London can be classified as major world class finance-cum-services centers. They are trailed by Tokyo and on a lesser scale by Hong Kong and Singapore. Cities such as Paris, Frankfurt, Zurich and Sao Paolo do not make the cut. The scale, diversity and export of services from these secondary regional centers are much more limited. Finance and business services are the drivers of growth in New York, London and to some degree, in Tokyo but in each case, these have generated only quite modest rates of growth for the city as a whole and much of the income gains have been reaped by a small segment of the workforce. Higher growth in other cities with a services orientation depends upon the push provided by alternative sources of growth such as manufacturing and logistics. Research on the effects of financial deepening suggests that short term financial objectives can crowd out longer term real investment through two different channels. The first channel is the crowding out of real investment by an increase in the investment in financial assets (Crotty 2005). Many non-financial firms have invested in financial assets and financial subsidiaries in recent years, to the point that they hold as many financial assets as physical assets and significant amount of profits are derived from these financial assets (Orhangazi 2008). 22 Short-term focus is the second channel. Increasing numbers of managers have adopted the "portfolio view of the firm" with emphasis on the deployment of firm's assets for the sake of short-run returns. 23 This change in the view stems from several institutional development relating to corporate governance such as the increasing use of stock options as a part of the compensation package; more emphasis on 21 However, examining the growth experience of Japan, Korea, and Taiwan (China), W.-C. Liu and Hsu (2006) find financial development under globalization did not have positive effect in all aspects. Especially, capital outflow from these economies had a negative impact on their growth. 22 As early as in 1965, Tobin (1965) recognized that financial and real investments by firms can be substitutes. This is especially so when the returns from financial investments are higher than that from real investments. 23 This changed the corporate strategy from "retain and reinvest" to "downsize and distribute" (Lazonick and O'Sullivan 2000). 119 the shareholder value 24 rather than the long-term viability of firms; and the impatience of investors. These two channels together have made firms focus on meeting "the short term objectives of financial markets rather than in the long term growth of the firm" (Orhangazi 2008, p.870). Management emphasizes the distribution of revenues so as to raise the company's stock prices and thereby enlarge the value of stock options (p.869). 25 When "financial markets undervalue long term investments, then managers will undervalue them too as their activities are judged and rewarded by the performance of the company's assets" (Orhangazi 2008, p.871). 26 The financial crisis which started in 2008, has suspended a question over the value added by financial innovations ­ and the longer term contribution of finance to urban development. It has underlined once again, the difficulties in regulating increasingly sophisticated activities and the powerful vested interests they create, so as to avoid serious financial shocks which have painful consequences for the real sector. It is also raising questions as to the longer term stability of an economy overly dependent on consumption as the main driver of growth, especially when such consumption is substantially facilitated by financial innovation and financial depth which makes consumer credit more widely available at attractive rates and has the unfortunate side effects of burdening consumers with debt and giving rise to real estate and other asset bubbles. Cities such as New York and London, but also some of the regional financial centers, are discovering the risks of excessive reliance on financial and affiliated business services. Moreover, the longer term shape and pace of financial development is less clear given the seriousness of the 2008-9 crisis and the doubts it has cast on the economic gains to be derived from current financial instruments, practices and forms of organization as well as the concerns it has aroused regarding the political power accumulated by the financial sector. 24 See, for instance, Grossman and Hart (1999) on the origin of the shareholder value. 25 Buying back stocks is one of the often used strategies to increase share prices. This again diminishes the resources available for real investment (Grullon and Michaely 2002; Lazonick and O'Sullivan 2000). 26 Jack Welch, the former CEO of GE made headlines in March 2009 when he claimed that "shareholder value is the dumbest idea in the world! It is not a strategy; it needs to be an outcome." 120 Undoubtedly finance and business services will retain a major role in urban economies, but for a city at Shanghai's level of development and with Shanghai's growth aspirations, it may be desirable to reconsider the importance attached to the financial sector and associated business services in future growth strategy. From the perspective of rapid and sustainable growth, it might be desirable to groom a suite of tradable producer services, selecting those that directly or indirectly support a range of manufacturing-related activities. Aside from finance, tertiary education, healthcare and engineering services, may be well suited for Shanghai's strategic objectives. Inducing Innovation: Demand Pull and Supply Push Innovation capability arises from a matrix of elements with no clear rules for their combining. Increased spending on research is only one ingredient, an important one doubtless but far from being enough. The quality and experience of researchers and the availability of state of the art facilities noted earlier, is a second element. The deliberate creation of spaces ­ science parks and incubators ­ so as to nurture activities which could quicken the technological change is a third. Institutions protecting intellectual property rights and incentive mechanisms for firms and researchers to innovate through monetary and other rewards are a fourth. 27 Regulations and standards which induce firms to develop and introduce new technologies is a fifth factor. For example, environmental regulations supported by publicly financed R&D have promoted innovation in a number of fields and the diffusion of technology. 28 A culture of enquiry, one which assigns a special significance to individuals who innovate, is a fourth factor. And sixth is an urban environment which is conducive to the pursuit, exchange and refining of new ideas and where commercialization of innovations is actively promoted. Shanghai's policymakers are working on all these registers, however tangible evidence of innovativeness is 27 In this regard, China may want to consider centralizing the appeal process to a single specialized IP court to facilitate the further development of IP market. The experience in the United States have shown that the establishment of such an IP court has led to reduction in the duration for settlements and judgments at the lower courts. The establishment of a single appeals court has clarified the scope and the extent of IP protection, proving much more certainty to the outcome of the trials relative to the case where judgments can range widely depending on the jurisdiction of the court (Galasso and Schankerman 2008). 28 See Popp, Newell and Jaffe (2009) for a comprehensive survey of the findings on environmental regulation and its technological spillovers. 121 materializing slowly as experienced researchers, intermediaries and VCs aggregate into critical masses and an innovation culture jells within an enabling urban environment. Typically there is a strong desire to hurry the process along. Governments' Efforts to Encourage Innovation One avenue to an innovative manufacturing sector actively pursued in Shanghai, leads to science parks. Shanghai has a number of parks which offer tax and financial benefits, incubators providing space services and seed money, extension services, multiple special funds for different categories of firms, bonuses and prizes for inventors, subsidies for patenting and scholarships and grants for researchers, not to mention tax holidays and depreciation allowances for R&D spending and high tech firms. The question not being asked insistently enough is whether these are producing the desired results, which of the incentives are most effective and deserve to be expanded; and which wound down. 29 Absent such a disentangling and assessment of the incentive regime in Shanghai, it is difficult to determine whether existing measures are yielding good returns and to indicate how these might be augmented, especially given the prevailing economic circumstances. Casual empiricism would suggest that the incentives to induce innovation are expensive and thus far the returns have been meager. For example: - In principle, science parks can lead to productivity gains from idea spillovers through agglomeration and reduce the wasteful duplication of research and induce older firms to sustain their patenting efforts. Successful parks also promote networking and co-creation of innovations by linked firms. 30 A study of new technology based firms in Hsinchu Science Industrial Park showed 29 Tax exemption credits and rebates as a means of stimulating R&D spending have been most extensively analyzed in the U.S. The results tend to be mixed, although on balance, tax credits show some results. A study of nine OECD countries found that a dollar's tax expenditure increased private spending on research by one dollar over the longer term, suggesting that tax incentives as distinct from direct public spending on R&D are superior, if the private sector is more efficient at allocating resources for research and/or private research produces more spillovers (B. Hall 2001; Yusuf, Wang and Nabeshima 2009). In sum, the limited empirical evidence on the role of tax policy does not make a strong case for such incentives (N. Bloom, Griffith and Van Reenen 2002; Klemm 2009; Yusuf, Wang and Nabeshima 2009). 30 See Gerlach, Rřnde and Stahl (2009); Squicciarini (2008); and Martin, Mayer and Mayneris (2008) who note that in France, productivity gains follow a U shape and decline as concentration raises congestion costs. 122 that the elasticity of R&D with respect to outputs was greater for firms in the park than in firms located outside. 31 The study also found that park based firms invested more efficiently in R&D (Yang, Motohashi and Chen 2009). How successful the parks in Shanghai are with respect to specific metrics of networking, productivity and innovative performance, requires detailed research supported by abundant data. What emerges from the interviews conducted is that science parks periodically change their objectives and are focused more on attracting firms and maximizing exports than on technological advancement. Furthermore, the links between firms in Zhangjiang Park and universities are relatively weak in part because most universities are some distance away in Puxi and only the Shanghai Chinese Medicine University is adjacent to the park. Inter-firm collaboration is also quite limited with Chinese owned firms being more skeptical than foreign invested ones and firms run by individuals with overseas training or experience. Chinese owned firms preferred to do most of their R&D in-house for fear of loss of intellectual property. Competitive pressures appear to be overriding the advantages of collaboration. - The quality of innovation being supported by incubators is difficult to judge and without a thorough evaluation of the graduates from incubators, it is impossible to say which of these programs is working and why. - Developing networked clusters of firms in industrial parks is one way of building innovation capabilities and creating a base of suppliers which draw large MNCs, and partner with foreign firms in building competitive strength 32. Such networked clusters have yet to emerge in the leading parks and neither our interviews nor the published research suggest that they have begun to 31 Yang, Motohashi and Chen (2009, p.81) maintain that output elasticity is a more appropriate measure than patent elasticity, because the ultimate objective of firms is to increase profits and they will do this by suitably allocating their R&D spending to promote process and product innovations. 32 Such clusters of specialized engineering firms were responsible for the emergence of Detroit as the center of auto manufacturing in the United States in the early twentieth century, other clusters account for the reputation of the textile, ceramic and furniture based industrial districts in Italy, and of the electronic clusters in Silicon Valley and Hsinchu Park. Clusters are advantageous also because they provide the fertile soil for the emergence of new firms (Quigley 2008). 123 germinate. A related concern is that few experienced engineers and technicians are leaving MNCs to start their own firms. The increased funding for R&D and the inducements of patent and write papers in scientific journals has produced a surge in output. But the worth of this output, in particular the longer term commercial value of the findings, is uncertain: Too many researchers might be engaged in inconsequential research. Quantity may be trumping quality. Given how short a time has elapsed since the surge in research commenced in the late 1990s, it may be another decade before the research capital which is accumulating begins to yield a harvest of innovations. In the meantime, Chinese firms might most usefully upgrade their technological game increasing their familiarity with best practice and how to push it a notch higher. For this purpose, the creation of a "Vision Group" by the municipality to screen and synthesize the new knowledge on how the leading Chinese and foreign MNCs operating in China are pursuing innovation, could be desirable step at this juncture and arguably more effective than additional monetary incentives for R&D because it could help bridge knowledge gaps. The Group could help identify and systematize the constellation of factors which are contributing to firm level productivity and innovation in the Yangtze Basin area and make these findings widely known so that other firms can benchmark themselves. An important contribution of such a vision group would be to tailor the lessons for specific categories of firms in the Shanghai area taking into account their characteristics and the conditions they face. A "Manufacturing Vision Group" was formed in the U.S. in 1988 and its investigation of new projects in several innovative companies brought to light a wealth of relevant clues on how some companies create the conditions for serial innovation (Bowen and others 1994). Successful Innovative Firms We think that the municipal authorities and the national government are providing leadership, incentives and resources, however, accelerating the development of the innovation system will depend increasingly upon the business sector. Innovation must be pulled by demand and the search for profitable opportunities even as it is pushed by increased spending on inputs if it is to be successful in the marketplace. Demand from the 124 business sector and from consumers is essential to realizing innovations that must meet the market test. It is difficult for governments using public sector entities and `push' mechanisms alone to bring into existence an innovation system that delivers results. In most respects, the business sector is the part of the urban economy that is already primed to innovate. It has the organization, the exposure to new technologies, and the experience with absorbing, assimilating and adapting technologies. It has the strongest incentives to innovate, to carefully select from among options, and it benefits immediately from successful innovation. Moreover, many firms are already engaged in R&D and have the infrastructure and teams in place. Firms conducting some R&D are more likely to establish research linkages with universities. Their support for government initiatives to improve the quality of tertiary education, to strengthen the research capabilities of universities and to develop a local research culture can be invaluable. Process innovation by firms provides the preconditions for the building of an innovation system, because these can be more readily integrated into the operations of a firm and the returns accrue quickly. Once process innovation which is generally incremental, gathers momentum and its utility is widely perceived, R&D gains stronger adherence both within and beyond the firm and becomes better integrated into its operations. Hence, encouraging firms to pursue process and product innovations so as to make it a mainstream activity and generate the demand for R&D, is a key task for government policy. International experience underscores this. Policies that seek to augment the supply of research in universities and public research institutions with the help of public financing may raise the supply of scientific findings but they will produce few tangible economic results. Businesses must be convinced of the utility of innovating and convinced of the value of routinizing innovation. One striking finding from the research on firms in that there seems to be only a weak relationship between the level of R&D spending and the metrics used to measure the success of firms. Increasing R&D can raise the number of patents but patents do not readily translate into desired business outcomes such as profitability and market share, for example. In fact, excessive spending can be dysfunctional if it throws up barriers to innovation by making scientists into constituents who become wedded to the status quo (Jaruzelski, Dehoff and Bordia 2005). The most successful innovative companies are 125 ones who can extract the maximum innovation from a moderate R&D budget. These companies share a number of characteristics: - An innovation culture deliberately cultivated and constantly reinforced by top management and an innovation strategy fully aligned with corporate strategy. - The innovation strategy is a comprehensive one keyed to long run competitiveness and the avoidance of frequent restructuring and changes of direction 33 . It embraces not only products but also process innovation, innovations in marketing, associated services and the business model of the firm itself. A study of innovative firms by Hargadon and Sutton (2000, p.158) found that serial innovators had perfected a "knowledge brokering cycle made up of four intertwined work practices: capturing good ideas, keeping ideas alive, imagining new uses for old ideas and putting promising concepts to the test." Some research suggests that the highest stock market returns and growth of revenues were achieved by firms with the most innovative business models and not the ones with the innovative products (Hagel, Brown and Davison 2008; "The Biggest Bang" 2008). - Successful innovators adopted an open and collaborative approach to innovation, recognizing that they could not excel in more than a few areas of research and need to canvas ideas from a variety of sources. 34 - The focus of the research efforts and the quality of leadership is critical to success, as is the closeness of interaction between the research wing of the firm and the production and marketing departments. - Successful innovators tended to have a flatter and nimbler managerial structure and effective procedures for vetting research proposals, tracking 33 The Hay Group finds that companies with consistent and stable strategies which can avoid paroxysm of restructurings, have a better chance of forging and sustaining a reputation for performance ("The World's Most Admired Companies" 2009). 34 Open innovation systems which emphasize tools such as alliances, licensing, consortia, and innovation exchanges, and joint ventures assume that innovation is a cumulative process which requires melding a number of different and intersecting technologies. Tetra Pak found that it had to draw upon the expertise of a number of other companies before it could develop a paperboard container which could be sterilized, was lightweight, rectangular and easy to hold and pour. Similarly, Cargill only managed to perfect a new family of corn based plastics when it teamed up with Dow Chemical (Rigby and Zook 2002). During the Second World War, the large scale production of penicillin became a reality after America's agricultural scientists and technicians, who knew a lot about culturing moulds, became involved. 126 progress and screening out failures (Lynch 2007). These companies also have well articulated procedures for developing and commercializing products. - In industrializing countries, the successful innovators leverage their knowledge of the local market to innovate by customizing products and innovate also in the distribution of products. One of the issues to be confronted by Shanghai ­ and China ­ is that most applied research and innovation is done by large companies. They are responsible for most of the incremental process and product innovation and it is through their own efforts and the marketing of innovations by others that radical advances achieve commercial success. 35 Large firms often do not give rise to breakthrough innovations ­ for reasons delineated by Christensen and Raynor (2003) ­ however, their development and marketing inputs frequently determine the success of disruptive innovations. 36 Some research by Zucker and Darby (2007) also shows that notwithstanding the drawbacks of industrial concentration and oligopolistic producers, consumers derive larger welfare gains from the innovativeness of large oligopolistic firms. Most of the bigger firms in Shanghai are wholly or partially state owned and they dominate both traditional and high tech subsectors. Hence in the medium term and perhaps over the longer run as well, SOEs need to take the lead in innovating which has not been their strength thus far (Muller and Sternberg 2008, pp. 236-7). In fact, for the urban innovation system to find its stride there is no substitute for the initiative and leadership that large firms with transnational strategies can provide. Government incentives and purchasing policies can encourage innovation, 37 universities and research institutes can assist, and incubators and science 35 Baumol (2004) notes that technical progress requires both breakthrough ideas and a protracted follow-up process of cumulative incremental improvement of those breakthroughs with the combined incremental contribution of this second phase often exceeding that of the first (p.4) ........ In today's economy, many rival firms use innovation as their main battle weapon with which they protect themselves from competitors .... The result is precisely analogous to an arms race (p.10)". 36 The spread of electricity and the internal combustion engine was expedited by takeovers which consolidated production in a few large firms which could reap scale advantages and sustain technological advance. 37 For instance, Shanghai has the first maglev trains operated commercially in the world. Future railroad development could be based on this technology (especially for a newer high speed train system) and being the leader, firms in Shanghai can accumulate tacit knowledge concerning this technology and evolve to become global players. 127 parks can nurture new ideas, but SOEs which seek to compete and earn profits on the basis of innovation, must provide a good part of the impetus ­ the demand for innovation and some of them need to become the innovation hothouses of China. Many more SOEs must be induced to become as dynamic and competitive as China's corporate icons such as Huawei, ZTE, SAIC, CIMC, Wangxiang and others. 38 A further round of ownership and governance reforms will need to be complemented by changes in management and organization, a trimming of the dead weight of diffuse (and sometimes geographically dispersed) unprofitable activities that distract management, and an aligning of incentives in support of profitable innovation. It scarcely bears repeating that the productivity and innovativeness of SOEs will be directly influenced by the quality of management and how this is monitored by boards of directors. 39 Time and again, research findings show that the productivity of firms, their capacity to innovate and the returns on innovation, and their harnessing of IT to enhance competitiveness is correlated with management (N. Bloom, Sadun and Van Reenen 2007). Augmenting the talent in the managerial ranks of the SOEs is inseparable from other measures to raise long-term performance. 40 Large Chinese firms will have to lead Shanghai and China to the innovative economy which is profitable and sustainable. If the global recession and a slowing of growth in China leads to an industrial shake-out and a reduction in capacity, then research suggests that well established older firms which pursue competition strategies based on innovation, are more likely to survive and prosper (Klepper and Simons 2005). Much like international production networking, the networking of the innovation process is becoming an important source of competitiveness advantage. This process is exemplified by the example of the iPod which brought together in one imaginative and extraordinary successful package, innovations in a number of discrete technologies. The revolutionary feature of this product was the skillful yoking together of innovative energies of many firms and the use of electronics production networks to locate the manufacture of components first in Taiwan (China) and later in China (Sener and Zhao 38 There is some evidence suggesting that older SOEs are taking a more active interest in upgrading their production capabilities and in innovation (Girma, Gong and Görg 2009). 39 For instance, Yusuf, Nabeshima and Perkins (2005) find that managers circulate among SOEs and reformed SOEs. Reformed SOEs with managers from former SOEs did not see their performance improve. 40 Better management practices can also lead to more efficient use of resources (N. Bloom and others 2008). 128 2009). 41 This is a lesson for Chinese MNCs, also. It is becoming vital to acquire the skills to seek and integrate innovation from diverse sources. In-house innovation and in- house production capacity should be seen as only some of the assets a company can draw upon. No less significant are the assets to be harnessed from other sources. Winning innovation contests will demand that globally oriented firms look beyond their own walls, to think of the innovation possibility set in a far more expansive way and to begin planning their international networking and acquisitions accordingly. Sustaining R&D operations by Firms Firms can react to a recession by slashing their R&D expenditures in an effort to improve short-term results. In recessions, firms worry about two kinds of failure, "missing the boat" (missing a great opportunity) or "sinking the boat" (bankruptcy) (Dickson and Giglierano 1986). They worry more about the failure of a firm rather than the missed opportunity. However, this can prove to be shortsighted as companies which sustain their efforts to innovate improve their chances of bouncing back and increasing their market share. This was the experience of U.S. companies following the 1990-91 recession. Some important innovations have been introduced during recessions to the advantage of the producing firms, such as the transistor launched by Texas Instruments in 1954 and the iPod in 2001, following an increase in Apple's R&D spending by 42% between 1999 and 2002. This learning has induced many MNCs to protect their R&D efforts from the recession which commenced in 2008. Companies such as Intel, Microsoft, Cisco, and TI raised their R&D between 2007 and 2008. P&G is increasing its spending on new engineering and manufacturing technologies and other companies are also resisting pressures to pare back ("How P&G Plans" 2009; "Intel Tries to Invest" 2009; "R&D Spending Holds Steady" 2009). However, if slower growth persists through 2010, R&D might succumb to a sense of uncertainty and more companies will be induced 41 From the cost breakdown of video iPod, it is estimated that Apple makes a gross profit of about $80 per unit (of the retail price of $299). China was responsible for assembly of all these parts into a complete iPod. However, the value added in China was only about $4 (Dedrick, Kraemer and Linden 2008). In 2006, there were more than 41,000 workers associated with the production of iPod. Of this total, China's share was 30 percent. However, its share of total wages was 2.4 percent, because most of the workers were engaged in assembly. In contrast, the majority of workers in the US, Japan, and Korea are classified as professionals (Linden, Dedrick and Kraemer 2009). 129 to scale back (N. Bloom 2007). Minimizing such cutbacks among firms in Shanghai may require going beyond the fiscal measures currently extended to firms and offering targeted subsidies for one to two years to firms in the technology intensive subsectors. This would offset the uncertainty firms' face and enable them to husband valuable research capital which takes years to accumulate. In addition, a significant expansion of the municipal government's extension and product development services to SMEs may be desirable. These can serve as means of transferring valuable technical and problem solving skills to industry; they can also be vehicles for absorbing a large number of temporarily unemployed skilled and technical workers and channeling their expertise into value adding activities. Such a program which could be modeled on the Fraunhofer Institutes in Germany or the Advanced Technology Program introduced by the National Institute for Standards and Technology, 42 would confer three additional benefits: it would increase the skill intensity of the SME sector and encourage R&D activity in firms that rarely engage in research; it would give university graduates an opportunity to acquire practical experience and provide job opportunities (Bramwell and Wolfe 2008; Lundvall 2007); and it would partially neutralize the disincentive effects of the economic downturn for students contemplating a future in science and engineering or in R&D. Healthcare as an Urban Growth Pole A healthcare industry that has linkages to manufacturing industries such as pharmaceutical industry, diagnostic equipment manufacturers, and manufacturers of implants and high-tech electronic instruments and other IT services providers 43 can be a 42 Darby, Zucker and Wang (2003, pp.5-6), explain the advantages of the ATP as follows: "It has a goal of encouraging collaboration among firms and between firms and universities and other organizations in the U.S. innovation system. ATP encourages the formation of JVs, providing potentially higher award levels and more years of funding, and encourages JV members to establish governance structures for internal management of JVs....ATP in effect opens up boundaries where the ATP project impinges, encouraging joint governance and reasonable access by all JV members of intellectual property created within the JV...The firms not only have more financial resources through ATP funding but also have changed social relationships. These relationships provide intellectual capital and social contacts that add value through learning processes". 43 The technological revolution that is sweeping the medical sector as a result of the confluence of biology, information, engineering and material technologies, is described in "Medicine Goes Digital" ("Medicine Goes Digital" 2009). 130 source of local employment, substantial value addition, innovation at many levels and exports of services and complex manufactures in addition to the direct social benefits it can provide to the population of the municipality. Creating a competitive healthcare industry in conjunction with tertiary education and high tech manufacturing subsectors, could create an economic powerhouse with long-run growth potential (see Figure 6.2) 44. With an ageing population, Shanghai can anticipate strong demand for eldercare and chronic diseases in particular. This kind of demand can be used to reshape the healthcare system in Shanghai so that care providers are linked to and benefit from university based research on new drugs, traditional medicine, bioengineering, bioinformatics, robotics and imaging technologies to name just a few of the research fields that are helping to enhance the quality of medical care. Healthcare, much like telecommunications, is also increasingly a capital intensive service which relies upon an array of diagnostic and imaging devices, 45 implants, instrumentation and IT equipment. Many of these are high value, knowledge intensive manufactures that are growth areas for Shanghai's electronics, new materials, precision engineering, pharmaceutical and biotechnology industries. 46 Because each of these fields attracts new starts, they look to venture capitalists for early stage and mezzanine financing. With the help of suitable incentives, healthcare can become the core of a flourishing cluster comprised of university hospitals, high-tech manufacturing firms, research centers and providers of risk capital as well as other services. Experience from the United States suggests that this may not happen spontaneously but may require incentives from the government coupled with coordination among a variety producers, standard setting and certification, and regulation. The point to be emphasized here is that the gains for the city in terms of growth and employment can be greatly magnified if the linkages from healthcare to manufacturing and university based research can be realized within the geographical confines of the city. Medical ­ manufacturing ­ research clusters 44 Porter and Teisberg (2006) discuss the competition strategies for healthcare providers and program which could enlarge the benefits for users. 45 There are a number of areas in which improvements can be made. One promising area is a miniaturization of the MRI. Researchers so far has been able to miniaturize nuclear magnetic resonance (NMR) device, which is quite similar to MRI (Blumich 2008). 46 Although biotechnology faces an uncertain future (Pisano 2006). 131 have great promise and can become prolific exporters of state of the art medical services as well as complex high tech and profitable products. Quality of Education and Tertiary Education as a Leading Sector Premier Wen Jiabao has observed that China must "cultivate large numbers of innovative talents [through] a free environment to enable [students] to develop creative thinking and critical thinking ...... To raise a question or to discover a problem is more important than solving a problem" (cited in interview by Xin and Stone 2008). The competitiveness of Shanghai's industry and services, the capacity to innovate, and the pace of diversification into new activities will be a function most directly of the quality of education. Those individuals with more education or better quality have a higher probability of starting a technology intensive business, hire skilled workers, and to engage in innovation. 47 Workers with a solid grounding in the sciences and in engineering, with good analytic problem solving and team working capabilities, require less remedial training once they join a firm and can more fruitfully contribute to incremental process innovations which are frequently the life blood of competitiveness. Interviews with firms in Shanghai suggest that one of the major hurdles they face relates to the workforce. 48 University graduates enter the job market with a grounding in theory but with little practical knowledge and analytical skills. Employers ascribe this to the continuing reliance on rote learning and on training to take tests; on the knowledge and pedagogical techniques of many of the teaching staff which could be seriously outdated; on the low quality of textbooks; the limited attention given to practical training; and the obsolescence of lab and testing equipment that is available to the students. All these factors combine to constrain the productivity, the innovativeness and the entrepreneurial capacity of the workforce which is Shanghai's single most important asset. Among the suggestions for improving the performance of universities coming from Europe are performance criteria that include both the quality of graduates and 47 Entrepreneurial performance is associated with the quality of formal schooling (Berry and Glaeser 2005; E. L. Glaeser 2007; van der Sluis, van Praag and Vijverberg 2008). 48 Lack of industry experience, a "big picture mindset" creativity and to "think outside the box" were some of the weaknesses noted. Firms also did not cite the education and training as the distinguishing feature of graduates from the best schools. Nor did they comment on the readiness to work long hours (Wadhwa and others 2007; and interviews). 132 graduation rates, diversified and shorter diploma courses which give students more choice and the option of deciding when to stop, and greater autonomy for universities (Boarini and Martins 2008). The emphasis of tertiary education policies supporting innovation ought not to be limited to enhancing STEM skills but should seek to produce graduates who are versatile "with unique skills and a penchant for sustaining their excellence through career long self-education" (Flanagan 2006, p.5). 49 In a world where technology is continually evolving, such an attribute would be enduring value. The importance of creating and fully utilizing the research potential of Chinese universities cannot be minimized. This calls for attention to the design of institutions and a focus on the quality of teaching and research so as to build a tradition of scientific excellence. This can entail autonomy in hiring staff, in determining salaries, and incentive mechanisms, and in budget management. It can depend upon the capacity to compete for first rate talent from across the nation and all over the world. And it is strongly influenced by visionary leadership by key university administrators. A comparison between American and European universities reveals starkly how these factors influence the quality of university faculty and the value of the research conducted. By identifying the top 250 most highly cited researchers in each of 21 scientific disciplines, Bauwens, Mion and Thisse (2008) were able to show that American universities accounted for two thirds of the total during 1981-1999 and European universities for only 22 percent (see Table 6.4). Two other findings are also notable. First, the United States has a significant edge over European universities in every field except pharmacology. Second, the top 25 institutions with the most highly cited researchers (HCR) accounted for 30 percent of the total HCR and all but three were in the United States. Clearly American universities are contributing to inventiveness and they are able to do so because they have built up durable tradition based on the excellence of both teaching and of research and other institutional differences. 50 For instance, Aghion (2009) observes "that both Anglo American and Scandinavian countries (plus Switzerland) perform relatively well, whereas continental countries (particularly France, 49 See also World Bank (2008a) on the thinking with regard to tertiary education policies and Salmi (2009) on the ingredients of world class universities. 50 This does not mean that these researchers are all Americans. The data is based on the addresses of the institutions with where researchers are affiliated. 133 Italy, and Spain) perform relatively poorly. Interestingly, unlike their AngloAmerican counterparts, Swiss or Swedish universities are mostly public, charge low tuitions, and are not very selective when accepting applicants at the undergraduate level. However, good performance always relies on high budgets per student combined with budget and hiring autonomy ... The main findings are that (i) higher autonomy is more growth enhancing or patentenhancing in states that are closer to the technological frontier, and (ii) autonomy and spending are complementary in generating higher growth or higher patenting in the state"(Aghion 2009, p.23). Table 6.4: Number of Highly Cited Researchers, 1980-1999 EU17 Discipline US EU17 without UK Agricultural Sciences 113 84 64 Biology and Biochemistry 138 40 29 Chemistry 143 72 51 Clinical Medicine 161 36 17 Computer Science 226 45 35 Ecology-Environment 192 73 48 Economics-Business 263 24 11 Engineering 138 32 24 Geosciences 219 70 43 Immunology 201 81 66 Materials Sciences 159 50 33 Mathematics 221 75 53 Microbiology 159 71 49 Molecular Biology and Genetics 197 63 47 Neuroscience 182 73 39 Pharmacology 93 121 73 Physics 148 74 59 Plant and Animal Science 147 100 59 Psychology-Psychiatry 228 23 5 Social Sciences, General 295 11 3 Space Sciences 206 74 45 Total 3,829 1,292 853 Source: Bauwens, Mion and Thisse 2008 Incentives and encouragement to university faculty to conduct applied research with the potential of yielding commercial outcomes needs to be carefully calibrated so as not to divert attention and resources from the core mission of the leading research universities. First and foremost, Chinese universities many of which have expanded 134 enrollment, need to ensure the quality of their teaching and research by building up the caliber and experience of their faculties. 51 Equipping students with up-to-date theoretical knowledge, and soft skills which employers' value, must be the principal objective of the university. Strengthening the capacity to conduct basic research so as to generate new knowledge ­ which the private sector does little of ­ is a second major objective requiring investment in graduate and post doctoral programs; faculty with the requisite skills to lead and manage significant research projects; a well-equipped laboratory infrastructure; and leadership at the apex of the university as well as at the level of departments. The evolution of the field of biotechnology vividly illustrates the contributions of fundamental research in several seemingly unrelated fields conducted over a period of many years. Biotechnology owes its current eminence to breakthroughs in theoretical biology, in imaging techniques arising from advances in high energy physics and in computing technologies. Many of these advances were the results of university based research financed by the U.S. government through the National Science Foundation (NSF) and the National Institute of Health (NIH). According to Lawlor (2003, p.30), "It is the long term nurturing of the broad basic science base that has produced the U.S. competitive edge in biotechnology [with the help] of a non-centralized government funded but largely university performed basic research." Applied research and its commercialization through licensing, consulting, and start-ups can be a third objective however, it should not detract from the first two. In fact, the success of university entrepreneurship depends upon the university's reputation in providing quality education in important research fields. Very few universities in the United States ­ perhaps no more than five ­ derive a significant income from licensing of research findings and royalties. Most do not even manage to cover the operating expenses of their technology licensing offices from the commercialization of research. The equity stakes universities acquire in start ups are modest and have frequently proven to be worthless (Lerner 2005). 52 Start-ups in fields directly linked to basic and upstream applied research in universities such as biopharmaceuticals and nanotechnology, can be a 51 Salmi (2009) describes the attributes of world class universities. See also Altbach (2003) and Levin, Jeong and Ou (2006). 52 University venture funds in the U.S. have a poor track record and few have reached maturity (Lerner 2005). 135 benefit but the risks are high and the payoff uncertain (Feldman 2003), 53 Moreover, as indicated by Miner and others (2001), "Efforts [by the university] to stimulate new ventures may generate short-term prosperity but may ultimately harm the university incentives that lead productive faculty who previously generated steams of inventions, to leave the university to create new firms. Overtime, this process could ultimately destroy the university's underlying capacity to generate new knowledge and could leave the university with faculty members least likely to produce sustained inventions" (p140-41). Even Shanghai's premier research universities must first augment their core functions of providing world class training and of conducting world class research before embarking upon technological entrepreneurship. The first two are vital for the longer term success and technological evolution of Shanghai's economy and to the crafting an intellectual climate conducive to innovation. Technological entrepreneurship can become a minor source of revenue for a few research universities and a conduit for knowledge transfer from the leading institutions, but only after they have built up strong research programs. Although universities in Shanghai are engaging in research in photonics, nanotechnology, new materials and biotechnology, it may be some years before they can contribute significantly to advances in knowledge. A global recession which is forcing leading universities around the world to retrench some of their research endeavors and look for partners, presents an opportunity to launch two or three broad ranging blue sky research projects comprised of cross-national teams with researchers in Shanghai co-directing the activities and playing a significant role. The research should be of long-term consequence with spillovers for other areas and the subject matter could be drawn from the physical or social sciences. The advantages of such research at this point, is first to engage a sizable number of researchers in a challenging, high-level collaborative endeavor with potentially a large payoff. Second through collaboration, it will build much needed experience and analytical skills among young researchers in Shanghai which will help to raise the quality of teaching and research in universities. By staying focused and building up their research capital and teaching capabilities, some universities will raise 53 Chinese universities are also discovering the downside of start-ups and distancing themselves from direct ownership and responsibilities (Zhou 2008). 136 the skill level of the Shanghai urban region and be better able to service the needs of industry and begin building fruitful linkages with industry. By strengthening tertiary education, and promoting university research, Shanghai would greatly enlarge the benefits to local industry. It could moreover, make this sector attractive as a services provider for foreign students some of whom would supplement the local talent pool, and for foreign companies wanting to enter into research partnerships or to outsource their research. Through a variety of channels, the education sector can boost Shanghai's growth and build resilience against shocks affecting individual industries. An Innovative City Most innovation takes place in a few large cities and a lot hangs on what kind of people live in the city and visit the city, how they interact, float and exchange ideas, and perceive opportunities for fulfilling their ambitions. Large cities have the edge over smaller ones in terms of employment opportunities and avenues for pursuing entrepreneurial options. Those open cities which attract many visitors and migrants from within the country and abroad, are doubly advantaged by the influx and circulation of diverse ideas and talent. As E. L. Glaeser (2009, p.50) notes, "attracting and retaining skilled people is a critical task for local governments." And the experience of the United States suggests that consumer amenities are the most effective way of building the skilled workforce which is invaluable under any set of circumstances but most especially when industrial change is in the offing. Phillips (2008, p.731) presciently observes that "Most cities are the longest running examples of large open source projects. Cities were open source long before Linux." And cities that are designed with an eye to the quality of the socio-cultural environment, amenities, and physical aesthetics are triply advantaged because talented and discriminating knowledge workers gravitate to the city and some may choose to live there. Cities can also instill the culture of inquiry and interest in sciences by actively promoting science-oriented conferences, fairs, and exhibitions. Shanghai has the advantages of size and in China it is a city that attracts many visitors. It is also a city in the throes of change and this is where great care is needed in order to create a socio-cultural environment and an urban aesthetic that will buttress the 137 productive innovation system the city wants. 54 Perhaps this is the most difficult attribute of a city to capture. 55 Insufficient attention to forward looking urban planning is leading in one major city after another to single function zones, emphasis on auto-mobility, urban sprawl (and dormitory suburbs), elevated expressways, hundreds of residential tower blocks devoid of recreational amenities, shopping malls, gated communities and segregation by income groups, with the poor concentrated in squalid decaying ghettos often (but not always) on the periphery of the city. This is the very antithesis of the dynamic global city of tomorrow which is compact so as to facilitate the use of public transport and encourage a healthier, walking lifestyle, industrially balanced, well-connected nationally and with international urban nodes, energy frugal, with numerous mixed use neighborhoods (which maximize use of land and infrastructure and can induce an environment that minimizes criminal activity) and with the cultural and recreational amenities which enhance the quality of life 56 even as incomes rise and make urban life in Sennett's words "a source of mutual strength rather than a source of mutual estrangement and `civic bitterness'". Leading global cities have only some of these attributes. They are struggling to undo the damage done by past decisions because these attributes will determine whether a skilled labor force can be retained and a cycle generating a succession of knowledge intensive industries made integral to the urban dynamic. In its haste to modernize, Shanghai might lose sight of these objectives, but it needs remembering that `urban deserts' do not breed innovation. 57 And cities that are resistant to in-migration quickly lose dynamism and entrepreneurial vigor which can result in an irreversible decline of growth. 54 A continuing adjustment of the hukou system might be needed to ensure the flow of high quality human capital from elsewhere in China, and from abroad. See C. C. Fan (2008) for current issues surrounding hukou system. Shanghai's fourth reform of the hukou system announced in February 2009, took another step towards easing the constraints on obtaining a resident status. 55 See for instance Florida (2005; 2008). 56 Surveys of life satisfactions in China identify unemployment and pollution as two main sources of unhappiness among its urban residents (Appleton and Song 2008). The housing prices across cities in China are influenced by pollution. Housing prices in cities with less air pollution are higher than those with more severe air pollution (S. Zheng, Kahn and Liu 2009). 57 Since 1993, Shanghai has experienced a massive construction wave so much so that the municipal government has needed to print a new map of the city every three months (H. Lu 2004). 138 Many cities are aspiring to be "creative," few will succeed. If Shanghai is to be among the leaders then Shanghainese must emerge as trendsetters in China and in the world demanding innovation from companies and providing a crucible for the testing and selection of concepts and products. Shanghai will need to become the preferred habitat for a cosmopolitan creative class because the city can offer choices and it is rich in opportunities. The transition to a creative central place in the global economy demands action at three levels: the visual; the intellectual; and the strategic. Physically Shanghai needs to strike a happy balance between local distinctiveness and enduring and vital global chic. This can be achieved through inspired efforts to build dynamic neighborhoods fused together by a well planned transport infrastructure. Intellectual leadership will derive from the excellence of universities and think tanks and how their physical presence in the heart of the city feeds and enhances the sophistication of urban culture. In cities such as New York, Philadelphia, and London, the location and the quality of the universities has added immeasurably to the richness of the discourse. This does require an avoidance of a narrow focus on technology development on the part of the key universities and a broader expansive engagement with the sciences as well as the arts. The convening of seminars, workshops, and science festivals catering to a general audience would further the process of engagement between the creative class and the general urban population, thereby enabling the culture of creativity to strike deeper roots 58. Writing on the celebration of science in New York, Lawrence Krauss (2008) observes that "what are these science festivals have done is to let people indulge the natural inner fascination with the world around us in a context that is neither intimidating nor culturally remote as university lecture hall too often seems" (p. 643). The visual characteristics of the city and its intellectual vigor need to be topped by audacious strategic initiatives which put Shanghai on the map and able to begin 58 Shenzhen began hosting an International High-Tech Achievements Fair starting in the autumn of 1999, while Beijing convenes an International High-Tech Industries week in May each year (P. Fan and Watanabe 2006, p.314). 139 influencing global networks at the level of technology and ideas and not only through the scale of its construction activities. The global cities of today are all reinventing themselves or rethinking their development strategies so as to sustain or enhance their economic prospects and to attract the skilled workforce needed for new industries. Many global cities have become monosectoral service-based economies without any emerging leading subsectors. To survive, these cities will need to reverse decades of shortsighted decision-making, zoning, land development, and transport policies and to prepare for a harsher economic environment made more challenging by an ageing workforce, rising energy and resource costs and by climate change. 59 These cities are not the models for future global cities but they do offer lessons on desirable industrial structures and capabilities which are described above. II. Policy Messages for Shanghai Our findings in this study lead us to five policy messages, relevant to formulate medium- to long-term growth strategy for Shanghai. These are: ˇ Maintain and upgrade the manufacturing base in key areas; ˇ Augment the research capital of the city by focusing universities on teaching and basic research which is knowledge deepening; ˇ Develop services industries such as education and health which have spillovers for manufacturing; ˇ Attend to the livability of the city so that it attracts and holds knowledge workers; ˇ and Carefully evaluate current incentive policies so as to maximize the benefits. In addition to longer-term objectives, Shanghai'[s development strategy needs to address near term objectives. First, industries which will be the drivers of future growth 59 Coastal cities will need to prepare for rising sea levels by minimizing land subsidence associated with the pumping of groundwater, by building dikes and pumping facilities, and using natural passive defenses such as wetlands and mangrove forests (Day and others 2007; UN-HABITAT 2008). 140 should have support needed to weather the recession which commenced in 2008 and the incentives to consolidate and improve competitiveness by accumulating knowledge capital. In this context, Chinese firms might step up their efforts to acquire equipment, tacit knowledge, and IP from technologically advanced foreign firms which are going out of business. Second, the economic downturn is a time to accelerate the exit from declining labor intensive industries and to reallocate the land and human resources to other uses with a higher pay-off. In particular, this will require retraining workers made redundant by sunset industries. The freeing and transfer of resources will stimulate productivity aside from reducing the excess capacity in a number of light manufacturing industries. How Shanghai can apply the elements of strategies suggested above depends on the assessments of current policies in place in Shanghai and elsewhere. Unfortunately our knowledge on these matters is limited to an assortment of anecdotes and is lacking in a reliable expectation of their effectiveness if applied in other places in a different time. To move forward, we need to deepen our understanding of the effectiveness of policy instruments that are in place in Shanghai so as to improve upon them. 141 Table 6.5: Fiscal Incentives for Innovation Offered in China Fiscal Incentives for R&D Provision of import tariff exemptions: and Related Activities o To facilitate firms' technological renovation and product upgrading in existing state-owned enterprises. In addition, targeted industries such as those in the electronics sector were exempted from tariffs and import- related VAT on equipment during the 9th and 10th five-year periods. o To promote technical transfer and commercialization. Foreign individuals, firms, R&D centers engaged in activities of consulting, and technical services related to technology transfer and technological development are exempted from corporate tax on their incomes. Fiscal Incentives Given to Establishing economic zones, new and high-tech industrial zones (HTIZs), and economic and technological Various Technology development zones is one of the key measures the Chinese government has adopted in facilitating acquisition of new Development Zones and advanced technologies, promoting technological innovation, promoting the commercialization of S&T results, and enhancing China's industrial competitiveness. From the early 1980s, China began establishing special economic zones and, since the 1990s, high-tech industrial development zones. In 1991 China approved 21 national HTIZs, and by 2005 the total number countrywide had risen to 150, of which 53 are at the national level. These HTIZs have nursed 39,000 high-tech firms employing 4.5 million people. The total turnover of firms reached 2.7 trillion yuan in 2004, an increase of 31 percent over the previous year. The per capita profit was 33,000 yuan; per capita tax yield was 29,000 yuan, and the per capita foreign earnings were 157,320 yuan (US$19,000) In the national HTIZs a series of investor-friendly policies and measures have been introduced. These measures include tax reduction and exemption policies. Fiscal Incentives Related to The Chinese government offers various tax holiday schemes to different types of firms. Income Tax Foreign-invested enterprises can enjoy the preferential treatment of income tax exemption in the first two years after making profits and an income tax reduction (by half) in the following three years. Foreign-invested high-tech enterprises can enjoy income tax exemption in the first two years after making profits and an income tax reduction (by half) in the following six years. Sino-foreign joint ventures can enjoy income tax exemption in the first two years after making profits. Other firms are eligible for income tax exemption in the first two years when starting productive operation. Domestic firms in HTIZs are eligible for preferential treatment but with limits in terms of types of business activities (income earned from technology transfer or activities related to technology transfer, such as technical consulting service and training). A ceiling is imposed on how much they can benefit from income tax exemption (less than 300, 000 yuan). Income tax rate is set at 15 percent in these zones, which is much lower compared with the normal rate for those located outside the zones. Firms whose export share is above 70 percent of their annual production can enjoy further income tax reduction (10 percent). Turnover tax Foreign enterprises and foreign-invested enterprises are also exempted from the business tax on technology transfer. Tariff and import duties Tariff and import-stage VAT exemptions have been granted to foreign funded enterprises for their importation of equipment and technologies that are listed in the Catalogue of Encouragement Accelerated depreciation New and high-tech firms are granted accelerated depreciation for equipment and instruments (since 1991; see China's State Council Document [1991] No. 12). Scholarships for Students The Chinese government has created an Overseas Study Fund to sponsor Chinese students and scholars to pursue their Studying in Science and studies or training overseas. In 2004, the fund sponsored 3,630 people for advanced studies or research programs Engineering Fields in China overseas. In line with China's development priorities, the fund identified seven disciplines or academic fields as its and Abroad sponsorship priorities for 2004: Telecommunications and information technology High- and new technology in agricultural science Life science and population health Material science and new materials Energy and environment Engineering science Applied social science and subjects related to WTO issue Incentives Given to Attract The Chunhui program has sponsored 8,000 Chinese scholars with PhDs obtained overseas to come back to carry out Overseas Chinese Back short-term work. The Yangtze River Fellowship program awarded 537 overseas Chinese scholars professional appointments in Chinese universities for curriculum building and teaching and for joint academic research. Fiscal Incentives Given to The fiscal incentives offered include the following: Attract the Establishment of Exemption from import duties and import-related VAT for imports of equipment, devices, and spare parts for R&D R&D Centers by MNCs purposes (1997). Tariff and import-related VAT exemption for acquiring imported new and advanced technologies. Foreign-funded R&D centers receive the same fiscal benefits as foreign-funded high-tech firms and enjoy the same fiscal preferential treatments (November 2004). Exemption from corporate tax for revenue earned through the delivery of consulting or other technical services related to technology transfer, and technical development activities (1999; no. 273). Reduction in income tax payment for those R&D centers whose expenditures on R&D increased more than 10 percent annually. Source: Yusuf, Wang and Nabeshima 2009 143 Table 6.6: Technology Licensing Offices in Tokyo Approved by Spin- Name Universities METI, MEXT # of license offs Todai TLO University of Tokyo 1998 948 - Nihon University Business, Research and Intellectual Property Center Nihon University 1998 249 - Waseda University Research Collaboration and Promotion Center Waseda University 1999 245 101 as of March, 2007 Keio University Intellectual Property Center Keio University 1999 260 - Tokyo Denki University TLO Tokyo Denki University 2000 17 - Technology Advanced Metropolitan Area - TLO 16 universities (mainly in Tokyo area) 2000 128 - Meiji University The Intellectual Property Headquarters for the Promotion of Social Collaboration Meiji University 2001 21 - The Foundation for the Promotion of Industrial Science University of Tokyo 2001 108 Tokyo University of Agriculture and Technology TLO Tokyo University of Agriculture and Technology 2001 61 Campus Create University of Electro-Communications 2003 23 Nippon Medical School, Nippon veterinary and Life Nippon Medical School TLO Science University 2003 17 - Tokyo University of Science, Tokyo University of Science at Yamaguchi, Tokyo University of Science Ridai Scitec at Suwa 2003 27 9 (includes all spin-offs in Office of Industry Liaison, Tokyo Institute of Technology Tokyo Institute of Technology 2007 206 47 the past) Tokyo Medical and Dental University TLO Tokyo Medical and Dental University 2008 0 - Located in Tsukuba but Japan Industrial Technology Association Advanced Industrial Science and Technology 2001 - - has Tokyo office various research institutes under the Ministry of Japan Health Sciences Foundation Health. Labor and Welfare 2003 - - Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries Technical Information various research institutes under the Ministry of Society Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries 2003 - - Support Center for Advanced Telecommunications Technology National Institute of Information and Research Communications Technology 2004 - - Note: The list includes those approved and certified TLOs located in Tokyo. There are 48 approved TLOs and 4 certified TLOs nationally as of April, 2008. Source: Japan Patent and Trademark Office 144 Figure 6.2: Components of The Boston Life Sciences Cluster The Boston Life Sciences Health and Beauty Cluster Organizations Products MassMedic, MassBio, others Teaching and Specialized Hospitals Surgical Instruments and Suppliers Medical Equipment Specialized Business Services Biological Biopharma Banking, Accounting, Legal Dental Instruments Products ceutical and Suppliers Products Specialized Risk Capital Ophthalmic Goods VC Firms, Angel Networks Diagnostic Substances Specialized Research Research Organizations Service Providers Containers Laboratory, Clinical Testing Educational Institutions Harvard University, MIT, Tufts University, Boston University, UMass Analytical Instruments 145 References "A Failure to Keep up with the Times." 2007. Financial Times, 03/27. "A Very Solid Foundation from Which to Growth." 2007. Financial Times, 03/27. Abu-Lughod, Janet L. 1999. New York, Chicago, Los Angeles: America's Global Cities. Minneapolis; London: University of Minnesota Press. Adams, James D. and Roger J. Clemmons. 2008. "The Origins of Industrial Scientific Discoveries." NBER Working Paper 13823. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Aghion, Philippe. 2009. "Growth and Education." Commission on Growth and Development 56. World Bank: Washington, DC. Aghion, Philippe, John Van Reenen and Luigi Zingales. 2009. "Innovation and Institutional Ownership." CEPR Discussion Paper 7195. Centre for Economic Policy Research: London. Aitken, Brian, Gordon H. Hanson and Ann E. Harrison. 1997. "Spillovers, Foreign Investment, and Export Behavior." Journal of International Economics, 43(1-2): 103-32. Aitken, Brian J. and Ann E. Harrison. 1999. "Do Domestic Firms Benefit from Direct Foreign Investment? Evidence from Venezuela." American Economic Review, 89(3): 605-18. Altbach, Philip G. 2003. "The Costs and Benefits of World-Class Universities." International Higher Education, 33(Fall 2003). "America's Decline Will Not Be Easily Reversed." 2008. Financial Times, 08/11. Appleseed. 2003. Engines of Economic Growth: The Economic Impact of Boston's Eight Research Universities on the Metropolitan Boston Area. Boston, MA: Appleseed. Appleton, Simon and Lina Song. 2008. "Life Satisfaction in Urban China: Components and Determinants." World Development, 36(11): 2325-40. "As Factories Fail, So Does Business Law."2009. BusinessWeek. Au, Chung-Chung and J.Vernon Henderson. 2006a. "Are Chinese Cities Too Small?" Review of Economic Studies, 73(2): 549-76. ____. 2006b. "How Immigration Restrictions Limit Agglomeration and Productivity in China." Journal of Development Economics, 80(2): 350-88. Auerswald, Philip and Lewis Branscomb. 2003. "Spin-Offs and Start-Ups: The Role of the Entrepreneur in Technology-Based Innovation," In D. Hart (ed.) The Emergence of Entrepreneurship Policy: Governance, Start-Ups, and Growth in the Knowledge Economy. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Auerswald, Philip and Lewis M. Branscomb. 2008. "Research and Innovation in a Networked World." Technology in Society, 30(3-4): 339-47. Avnimelech, Gil, Martin Kenney and Morris Teubal. 2004. "Building Venture Capital Industries: Understanding the U.S. And Israeli Experience." University of California, Berkeley. http://repositories.cdlib.org/brie/BRIEWP160. Bair, Jennifer. 2009. Frontiers of Community Chain Research. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press. Bairoch, Paul. 1991. Cities and Economic Development: From the Dawn of History to the Present. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Baldwin, Richard and Simon Evenett. 2008. "Restoring the G20's Credibility on Trade: Plan B and the WTO Trade Talks." http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/2692. Barrios, Salvador, Luisito Bertinelli and Eric Strobl. 2006. "Coagglomeration and Spillovers." 36(4): 467-81. Baumol, William J. 1967. "Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The Anatomy of Urban Crisis." The American Economic Review, 57(3): 419-20. ____. 2004. "Education for Innovation: Entrepreneurial Breakthroughs Vs. Corporate Incremental Improvements." NBER Working Paper 10578. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Baumol, William J. and William G. Bowen. 1966. Performing Arts- the Economic Dilemma. New York: The Twentieth Century Fund. Bauwens, Luc, Giordana Mion and Jacques-Francois Thisse. 2008. "The Resistible Decline of European Science." CEPR Discussion Paper Series 6625. Centre for Economic Policy Research: London. "Beijing Drives Car and Steel Mergers Message." 2009. Financial Times, 03/23/2009. "Beijing Hesitates at the Global Threshold." 2008. Financial Times, 11/24. "Beijing Scuppers $2.4bn Coke Move." 2009. Financial Times, 2009/03/19. Berry, Christopher and Edward L. Glaeser. 2005. "The Divergence of Human Capital Levels across Cities." NBER Working Paper 11617. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Bers, John A., John P. Dismukes, Lawrence K. Miller and Aleksey Dubrovensky. 2009. "Accelerated Radical Innovation: Theory and Application." Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 76(1): 165-77. Bettencourt, Luis M.A., Jose Lobo and Deborah Strumsky. 2007. "Invention in the City: Increasing Returns to Patenting as a Scaling Function of Metropolitan Size." Research Policy, 36(1): 107-20. Blalock, Garrick and Paul J. Gertler. 2008. "Welfare Gains from Foreign Direct Investment through Technology Transfer to Local Suppliers." Journal of International Economics, 74(2): 402-21. Blomstrom, Magnus and Fredrik Sjoholm. 1999. "Technology Transfer and Spillovers: Does Local Participation with Multinationals Matter?" European Economic Review, 43(4-6): 915-23. Bloom, David E. and Jeffrey G. Williamson. 1998. "Demographic Transition and Economic Miracles in Emerging Asia." World Bank Economic Review, 12(3): 419-55. Bloom, Nicholas. 2007. "Uncertainty and the Dynamics of R&D." NBER Working Paper 12841. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Bloom, Nicholas, Christos Genakos, Ralf Martin and Raffaella Sadun. 2008. "Modern Management: Good for the Environment or Just Hot Air?" NBER Working Paper 14394. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. 148 Bloom, Nicholas, Rachel Griffith and John Van Reenen. 2002. "Do R&D Tax Credits Work? Evidence from a Panel of Countries 1979-1997." Journal of Public Economics, 85(1): 1-31. Bloom, Nicholas, Raffaella Sadun and John Van Reenen. 2007. "Americans Do I.T. Better: Us Multinationals and the Productivity Miracle." CEPR Discussion Paper 6291. Centre for Economic Policy Research: London. Blumich, Bernhard. 2008. "The Incredible Shrinking Scanner." Scientific American, November: 92-98. Boarini, Romina and Joaquim Oliveira Martins. 2008. "How Do Policies Influence the Investment in Higher Education?" VOX. Boozer, Michael, Gustav Ranis, Frances Stewart and Tavneet Suri. 2003. "Paths to Success: The Relationship between Human Development and Economic Growth." Economic Growth Center Discussion Paper 874. Bosworth, Barry P. and Susan M. Collins. 2007. "Accounting for Growth: Comparing China and India." NBER Working Paper 12943. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Bowen, H. Kent, Kim B. Clark, Charles A. Holloway and Steven C. Wheelwright. 1994. "Regaining the Lead in Manufacturing." Harvard Business Review, 72(5): 121-30. Bramwell, Allison and David A. Wolfe. 2008. "Universities and Regional Economic Development: The Entrepreneurial University of Waterloo." Research Policy, 37(8): 1175-87. Brandt, Loren and Thomas Rawski. 2008. China's Great Economic Transformation. New York: Cambridge University Press. Bresnahan, Timothy and Alfonso Gambardella. 2004. Building High-Tech Clusters. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Brülhart, Marius and Federica Sbergami. 2009. "Agglomeration and Growth: Cross- Country Evidence." Journal of Urban Economics, 65(1): 48-63. Buenstorf, Guido and Steven Klepper. 2009. "Heritage and Agglomeration: The Akron Tyre Cluster Revisited." The Economic Journal, 119(537): 705-33. Bwalya, Samuel Mulenga. 2006. "Foreign Direct Investment and Technology Spillovers: Evidence from Panel Data Analysis of Manufacturing Firms in Zambia." Journal of Development Economics, 81(2): 514-26. "California's Wipeout Economy." 2009. Washington Post, 03/25/2009. "Can America Invent Its Way Back?" 2008. BusinessWeek, 09/22. Cao, Cong. 2004. "Zhongguancun and China's High-Tech Parks in Transition: Growing Pains or Premature Senility?" Asian Survey, 44(5): 647-68. Carlino, Gerald A., Satyajit Chatterjee and Robert M. Hunt. 2007. "Urban Density and the Rate of Invention." Journal of Urban Economics, 61(3): 389-419. Carter, Colin A., Funing Zhong and Fang Cai. 1996. China's Ongoing Agricultural Reform. San Francisco, CA: 1990 Institute. Cassis, Youssef and Eric Brussiere. 2005. London and Paris as International Financial Centres in the Twentieth Century. Oxford; New York: Oxford University Press. Castellani, Davide and Antonello Zanfei. 2003. "Technology Gaps, Absorptive Capacity and the Impact of Inward Investments on Productivity of European Firms." Economics of Innovation & New Technology, 12(6): 1. 149 Cbre Consulting. 2008. "A Study of the Economic Impact and Benefits of Uc San Diego." CBRE Consulting: San Francisco, CA. Charette, Robert N. 2009. "This Car Runs on Code." IEEE Spectrum. http://www.spectrum.ieee.org/feb09/7649. Chen, Kun and Martin Kenney. 2007. "Universities/Research Institutes and Regional Innovation Systems: The Cases of Beijing and Shenzhen." World Development, 35(6): 1056-74. Chen, Yun-Chung. 2008. "Why Do Multinational Corporations Locate Their Advanced R&D Centres in Beijing?" Journal of Development Studies, 44(5): 622-44. Cheung, Kui Yin and Ping Lin. 2004. "Spillover Effects of FDI on Innovation in China: Evidence from the Provincial Data." 15(1): 25. Chi, Wei. 2008. "The Role of Human Capital in China's Economic Development: Review and New Evidence." China Economic Review, 19(3): 421-36. "China to Establish Stock Market for Growth Enterprises." 2008. Xinhua News Agency, 03/05. "China Vies to Be World's Leader in Electric Cars." 2009. New York Times, 04/01/2009. "China: Pace of Mergers and Acquisitions Will Increase." 2009. Oxford Analytica, 03/16/2009. "China's Landmark Antimonopoly Law Finally Taking Effect." 2008. International Herald Tribune, 07/31. Christensen, Clayton M. and Michael E. Raynor. 2003. The Innovators' Solution. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. Coe, David T. and Elhanan Helpman. 1995. "International R&D Spillovers." European Economic Review, 39(5): 859-87. Coe, David T., Elhanan Helpman and Alexander W. Hoffmaister. 1997. "North-South R&D Spillovers." 107(440): 134-49. Coe, Neil M., Peter Dicken and Martin Hess. 2008. "Global Production Networks: Realizing the Potential." Journal of Economic Geography, 8(3): 271-95. Cohen, Wesley M. and Daniel A. Levinthal. 1990. "Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on Learning and Innovation." Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(March): 128-52. Comin, D. and B. Hobijn. 2004. "Cross-Country Technology Adoption: Making the Theories Face the Facts." Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(1): 39-83. Comin, Diego, Bart Hobijn and Emilie Rovito. 2008. "Technology Usage Lags." Journal of Economic Growth, 13(4): 237-56. Commission on Growth and Development. 2008. The Growth Report: Strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive Development. Washington, DC: World Bank. Cooke, Philip, Carla Laurentis, Franz Tödtling and Michaela Trippl. 2007. Regional Knowledge Economies: Markets, Clusters and Innovation. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. Crafts, Nicholas and Gianni Toniolo. 2008. "European Economic Growth, 1950-2005: An Overview." CEPR Discussion Paper 6863. Centre for Economic Policy Research: London. Crotty, James. 2005. "The Neoliberal Paradox: The Impact of Destructive Product Market Competition and 'Modern' Financial Markets on Nonfinancial Corporation 150 Performance in the Neoliberal Era," In G. A. Epstein (ed.) Financialization and the World Economy. Northampton, MA: Elgar, 77-110. Darby, Michael, Lynne Zucker and Andrew Wang. 2003. "Universities, Joint Ventures, and Success in the Advanced Technology Program." NBER Working Paper 9463. National bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Day, John W., Jr., Donald F. Boesch, Ellis J. Clairain, G.Paul Kemp, Shirley B. Laska, William J. Mitsch, Kenneth Orth, Hassan Mashriqui, Denise J. Reed, Leonard Shabman, Charles A. Simenstad, Bill J. Streever, Robert R. Twilley, Chester C. Watson, John T. Wells and Dennis F. Whigham. 2007. "Restoration of the Mississippi Delta: Lessons from Hurricanes Katrina and Rita." Science, 315(5819): 1679-84. "Deals on Hold? Business Awaits the Impact of Asia's New Competition Regimes." 2008. Financial Times, 2008/07/29. Dedrick, Jason, Kenneth L. Kraemer and Greg Linden. 2008. "Who Profits from Innovation in Global Value Chains? A Study of the iPod and Notebook Pcs." processed. University of California, Irvine: Irvine, CA. Deichmann, U., Kai Kaiser, Somik Lall and Zmarak Shalizi. 2005. "Agglomeration, Transport, and Regional Development in Indonesia." World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3477. World Bank: Washington, DC. Dertouzos, Michael L., Richard K. Lester and Robert M. Solow. 1989. Made in America: Regaining the Productive Edge. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. "Can China Attract the World's Capital?" 2008. Far Eastern Economic Review, 10/03/2008. Dickson, Peter R. and Joseph J. Giglierano. 1986. "Missing the Boat and Sinking the Boat: A Conceptual Model of Entrepreneurial Risk." Journal of Marketing, 50(1): 58-70. "Doing the Math to Find the Good Jobs." 2009. The Wall Street Journal, 01/06. Dollar, David and Shang Jin Wei. 2007. "Das (Wasted) Kapital: Firm Ownership and Investment Efficiency in China." IMF Working Paper WP/07/9. International Monetary Fund: Washington, DC. Drennan, Matthew P. 2002. The Information Economy and American Cities. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Drofiak, Alex and Elizabeth Garnsey. 2009. "The Cambridge High Tech Cluster: Resilience and Response to Cyclical Trends." Centre for Technology Management Working Paper 2009/01. University of Cambridge: Cambridge, UK. Easterly, William. 2006. "Reliving the 1950s: The Big Push, Poverty Traps, and Takeoffs in Economic Development." Journal of Economic Growth, 11(4): 289-318. Easterly, William, Michael Kremer, Lant Pritchett and Lawrence H. Summers. 1993. "Good Policy or Good Luck? Country Growth Performance and Temporary Shocks." Journal of Monetary Economics, 32(3): 459-83. Eaton, Jonathan and Samuel Kortum. 1999. "International Technology Diffusion: Theory and Measurement." International Economic Review, 40(3): 537-70. ____. 2001. "Trade in Capital Goods." European Economic Review, 45(7): 1195-235. Eichengreen, Barry and David Leblang. 2008. "Democracy and Globalization." 20(3): 289-334. 151 European Commission. 2002. "University Spin-Outs in Europe - Overview and Good Practice." Innovation papers No.21 Office for Official Publications of the European Communities: Luxembourg. Fan, C.Cindy. 2008. "Migration,Hukou, and the City," In S. Yusuf and T. Saich (eds.), China Urbanizes: Consequences, Strategies, and Policies. Washington D.C.: World Bank. Fan, Peilei and Chihiro Watanabe. 2006. "Promoting Industrial Development through Technology Policy: Lessons from Japan and China." Technology in Society, 28(3): 303-20. Feenstra, Robert C. and Gary C. Hamilton. 2006. Emergent Economies, Divergent Paths: Economic Organization and International Trade in South Korea and Taiwan. New York: Cambridge University Press. Feldman, Maryann P. 2003. "Entrepreneurship and American Research Universities: Evolution in Technology Transfer," In D. Hart (ed.) The Emergence of Entrepreneurship Policy: Governance, Start-Ups, and Growth in the U.S. Knowledge Economy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Flanagan, James L. 2006. "U.S. Competitiveness and the Profession of Engineering." IEEE-USA Today's Engineer Online. Florida, Richard. 2002. The Rise of the Creative Class and How It's Transforming Work, Leisure and Everyday Life. New York, NY: Basic Books. ____. 2005. Cities and the Creative Class. London, U.K.: Routledge. ____. 2008. Who's Your City? How the Creative Economy Is Making Where to Live the Most Important Decision of Your Life. New York: Basic Books. Fontagne, Lionel, Guillaume Gaulier and Soledad Zignago. 2008. "Specialization across Varieties and North-South Competition." Economic Policy, 23(53): 51-91. Foster, Richard N. and Sarah Kaplan. 2001. Creative Destruction: Why Companies That Are Built to Last Underperform the Market - and How to Successfully Transform Them. New York: Broadway Business. Freeman, Lance. 2008. "Should We Use Zoning to Preserve Manufacturing?" Planetizen. http://www.planetizen.com/node/34999. "Friends and Rivals." 2007. Economist, 09/15. "Frontiers Expand for Super-Fast Computers." 2008. International Herald Tribune, 04/19. Fujita, Kuniko and Richard Child Hill. 2005. "Innovative Tokyo." World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3507. World Bank: Washington, DC. Fujita, Masahisa and Jacques-Francois Thisse. 2002. Economics of Agglomeration: Cities, Industrial Location, and Regional Growth. New York: Cambridge University Press. Fukuda, Kayano and Chihiro Watanabe. 2008. "Japanese and Us Perspectives on the National Innovation Ecosystem." Technology in Society, 30(1): 49-63. Fung, Victor K., William K. Fung and Yoram Wind. 2008. Competing in a Flat World: Building Enterprises for a Borderless World. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education Inc. Galasso, Alberto and Mark Schankerman. 2008. "Patent Thickets and the Market for Innovation: Evidence from Settlement of Patent Disputes." CEPR Discussion Paper 6946. Centre for Economic Policy Research: London. 152 Gallagher, Sims Kelly. 2006. "Limits to Leapfrogging in Energy Technologies? Evidence from the Chinese Automobile Industry." Energy Policy, 34(4): 383-94. Gan, Lin. 2003. "Globalization of the Automobile Industry in China: Dynamics and Barriers in Greening of the Road Transportation." Energy Policy, 31(6): 537-51. Gao, Jian and Gary H. Jefferson. 2007. "Science and Technology Take-Off in China?: Sources of Rising R&Amp;D Intensity." Asia Pacific Business Review, 13(3): 357 - 71. Ge, Ying. 2009. "Globalization and Industry Agglomeration in China." World Development, 37(3): 550-59. Gerlach, Heiko, Thomas Rřnde and Konrad Stahl. 2009. "Labor Pooling in R&D Intensive Industries." Journal of Urban Economics, 65(1): 99-111. Girma, Sourafel. 2005. "Absorptive Capacity and Productivity Spillovers from FDI: A Threshold Regression Analysis." 67(3): 281-306. Girma, Sourafel, Yundan Gong and Holger Görg. 2009. "What Determines Innovation Activity in Chinese State-Owned Enterprises? The Role of Foreign Direct Investment." World Development, 37(4): 866-73. Girma, Sourafel and Holger Gorg. 2007. "The Role of the Efficiency Gap for Spillovers from FDI: Evidence from the Uk Electronics and Engineering Sectors." 18(2): 215-32. Girma, Sourafel and Katharine Wakelin. 2007. "Local Productivity Spillovers from Foreign Direct Investment in the U.K. Electronics Industry." 37(3): 399-412. Girma, Sourafel and Gong Yundan. 2008. "FDI, Linkages and the Efficiency of State- Owned Enterprises in China." Journal of Development Studies, 44(5): 728-49. Glaeser, Edward and Janet E. Kohlhase. 2003. "Cities, Regions and Decline of Transport Costs." Harvard Institute of Economic Research Discussion Paper 2014. Harvard University: Cambridge, MA. Glaeser, Edward L. 2005a. "Reinventing Boston: 1640-2003." Journal of Economic Geography, 5(2): 119-53. ____. 2005b. "Urban Colossus: Why Is New York America's Largest City?" NBER Working Paper 11398. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. ____. 2007. "Entrepreneurship and the City." NBER Working Paper 13551. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. ____. 2009. "Growth: The Death and Life of Cities," In R. P. Inman (ed.) Making Cities Work: Prospects and Policies for Urban America. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 22-62. Glaeser, Edward L., Joseph Gyourko and Raven Saks. 2005. "Why Is Manhattan So Expensive? Regulation and the Rise in Housing Prices." Journal of Law and Economics, 48(2): 331-69. Glaeser, Edward L. and William R. Kerr. 2008. "Local Industrial Conditions and Entrepreneurship: How Much of the Spatial Distribution Can We Explain?" NBER Working Paper 14407. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Glaeser, Edward L., Matthew Resseger and Kristina Tobio. 2008. "Urban Inequality." NBER Working Paper 14419. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. 153 Goldberg, Itzhak, Lee Branstetter, John Gabriel Goddard and Smita Kuriakose. 2008. "Globalization and Technology Absorption in Europe and Central Asia." World Bank Working Paper 150. World Bank: Washington, DC. Gorg, Holger and Eric Strobl. 2001. "Multinational Companies and Productivity Spillovers: A Meta-Analysis." 111(475): 723-39. Griffith, Rachel, Stephen J. Redding and Helen Simpson. 2002. "Productivity Convergence and Foreign Ownership at the Establishment Level." Institute for Fiscal Studies Working Paper 22. Institute for Fiscal Studies: London. Griffith, Rachel, Stephen Redding and John Van Reenen. 2004. "Mapping the Two Faces of R&D: Productivity Growth in a Panel of Oecd Industries." 86(4): 883-95. Griliches, Zvi. 2000. R&D, Education and Productivity. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Grossman, Sanford J. and Oliver D. Hart. 1999. "Corporate Financial Structure and Managerial Incentives," In K. Keasey, S. Thompson and M. Wright (eds.), Corporate Governance. Volume 2. Governance Mechanisms, Part 1. Elgar Reference Collection. International Library of Critical Writings in Economics, vol. 106. Cheltenham, U.K. and Northampton, Mass.: Elgar; distributed by American International Distribution Corporation, Williston, Vt., 211-41. Grullon, Gustavo and Roni Michaely. 2002. "Dividends, Share Repurchases, and the Substitution Hypothesis." Journal of Finance, 57(4): 1649-84. Haddad, Mona and Ann Harrison. 1993. "Are There Positive Spillovers from Direct Foreign Investment? Evidence from Panel Data for Morocco." Journal of Development Economics, 42(1): 51-74. Hagel, John Iii, John Seely Brown and Lang Davison. 2008. "Shaping Strategy in a World of Constant Disruption." Harvard Business Review, October: 81-89. Hall, Bronwyn. 2001. "The Economics of Tax Credits." Presented at the Tax Policy Institute Conference on the R&D Tax Credit in Washington, DC on 02/15/2001. Hall, Bronwyn and Jacques Mairesse. 2006. "Empirical Studies of Innovation in the Knowledge Driven Economy." NBER Working Paper 12320. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Hall, Peter. 1998. Cities in Civilization:. New York: Pantheon. Hall, Robert E. and Charles I. Jones. 1999. "Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Per Worker Than Others?" Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(1): 83- 116. Hamilton, G. and Gary Gereffi. 2008. "Global Commodity Chains, Market Makers, and the Rise of Demand-Responsive Economies," In J. Bair (ed.) Frontiers of Commodity Chain Research. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Han, Sun Sheng. 2000. "Shanghai between State and Market in Urban Transformation." Urban Studies, 37(11): 2091-112. Hargadon, Andrew and Robert I. Sutton. 2000. "Building an Innovation Factory." Harvard Business Review, 78(3): 157-66. Hausmann, Ricardo and Bailey Klinger. 2006. "Structural Transformation and Patterns of Comparative Advantage in the Product Space." processed. Center for International Development, Harvard University: Cambridge, MA. 154 He, Jianwu and Louis Kuijs. 2007. "Rebalancing China's Economy: Modeling a Policy Package." World Bank China Research Paper 7. World Bank: Beijing, China. Hellman, Thomas, Laura Lindsey and Manju Puri. 2004. "Building Relationships Early: Banks in Venture Capital." NBER Working Paper 10535. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Henderson, J.Vernon. 2004. "Issues Concerning Urbanization in China." Prepared for the 11th Five Year Plan of China. World Bank: Washington, DC. Hirukawa, Masayuki and Masako Ueda. 2008a. "Venture Capital and Industrial "Innovation"." CEPR Discussion Paper 7089. Centre for Economic Policy Research: London. ____. 2008b. "Venture Capital and Innovation: Which Is First?" CEPR Discussion Paper 7090. Centre for Economic Policy Research: London. Hohenberg, Paul and Lynn Lees. 1995. The Making of Urban Europe, 1000-1994. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Holz, Carsten A. 2008. "China's Economic Growth 1978-2025: What We Know Today About China's Economic Growth Tomorrow." World Development, 36(10): 1665- 91. "How P&G Plans to Clean Up."2009. BusinessWeek. Hu, Albert Guangzhou. 2008. "What Do They Patent in China, and Why?," In H. S. Rowen, M. G. Hancock and W. F. Miller (eds.), Greater China's Quest for Innovation. Stanford, CA: Walter H. Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center. Hu, Albert Guangzhou and Gary H. Jefferson. 2006. "A Great Wall of Patents: What Is Behind China's Recent Patent Explosion?" National University of Singapore: Singapore. ____. 2008. "Science and Technology in China," In L. Brandt and T. G. Rawski (eds.), China's Great Economic Transformation. Cambridge University Press. Hu, Mei Chih and John A. Mathews. 2008. "China's National Innovative Capacity." Research Policy, 37(9): 1465-79. Hu, Ping. 2007. "Research on Regional Inequalities of Industrial Structure and Its Contribution to Economic Growth in Yangzi River Delta." E-Journal of China Urban Studies, 2(3): 132-38. Huang, Jikun, Keijiro Otsuka and Scott Rozelle. 2008. "Agriculture in China's Development: Past Disappointments, Recent Successes and Future Challenges," In L. Brandt and T. Rawski (eds.), China's Great Economic Transformation. New York: Cambridge University Press. Huang, Yasheng. 2005. Selling China: Foreign Direct Investment During the Reform Era. New York: Cambridge University Press. ____. 2008. Capitalism with Chinese Characteristics: Entrepreneurship and the State. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press. Huang, Yasheng, Tony Saich and Edward S. Steinfeld (eds). 2005. Financial Sector Reform in China. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Hummels, David, Jun Ishii and Kei-Mu Yi. 2001. "The Nature and Growth of Vertical Specialization in World Trade." Journal of International Economics, 54(1): 75- 96. "InBev Ruling Sparks Fears for M&A in China." 2008. Financial Times, 2008/12/01. 155 Indergaard, Mich. 2004. Silicon Alley: The Rise and Fall of a New Media District. Routledge. "Intel Tries to Invest Its Way out of a Rut."2009. BusinessWeek. Jaffe, Adam B. 1986. "Technological Opportunity and Spillovers of R&D: Evidence from Firms' Patents, Profits, and Market Value." American Economic Review, 76(5): 984-1001. Jaruzelski, Barry and Kevin Dehoff. 2007a. "The Booz Allen Hamilton Global Innovation 1000: The Customer Connection." Strategy+Business, 49: 1-16. ____. 2007b. "The Consumer Connection: The Global Innovation 1000." Jaruzelski, Barry, Kevin Dehoff and Rakesh Bordia. 2005. "The Booz Allen Hamilton Global Innovation 1000: Money Isn't Everything." Strategy+Business, (41): 1-14. ____. 2006. "The Booz Allen Hamilton Global Innovation 1000: Smart Spenders." Strategy+Business, 45: 46-61. Javorcik, Beata S. and Mariana Spatareanu. 2005. "Disentangling FDI Spillover Effects: What Do Firm Perceptions Tell Us?," In Does Foreign Direct Investment Promote Development? Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics and Center for Global Devlopment. Javorcik, Beata Smarzynska. 2004. "Does Foreign Direct Investment Increase the Productivity of Domestic Firms? Is Search of Spillovers through Backward Linkages." American Economic Review, 94(3): 605-27. Javorcik, Beata Smarzynska and Mariana Spatareanu. 2008. "To Share or Not to Share: Does Local Participation Matter for Spillovers from Foreign Direct Investment?" Journal of Development Economics, 85(1-2): 194-217. Johnson, Elmer W. 2001. Chicago Metropolis 2020: The Chicago Plan for the Twenty- First Century. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Jorgenson, Dale W., S.Ho Mun, Jon D. Samuels and Kevin J. Stiroh. 2007. "Industry Origins of the American Productivity Resurgence." processed. Harvard University: Cambridge, MA. Kenney, Martin and Richard Florida. 2000. "Venture Capital in Silicon Valley: Fueling New Firm Formation," In Understanding Silicon Valley. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Kenney, Martin, Kyonghee Han and Shoko Tanaka. 2004. "Venture Capital Industries," In S. Yusuf, M. A. Altaf and K. Nabeshima (eds.), Global Change and East Asian Policy Initiatives. New York: Oxford University Press. Kleinberg, Robert. 1990. China's Opening to the Outside World. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Klemm, Alexander. 2009. "Causes, Benefits, and Risks of Business Tax Incentives." IMF Working Paper WP/09/21. International Monetary Fund: Washington, DC. Klepper, Steven and Kenneth L. Simons. 2005. "Industry Shakeouts and Technological Change." International Journal of Industrial Organization, 23(1-2): 23-43. Krauss, Lawrence M. 2008. "Celebrating Science as Culture." Science, 321(5889): 643. Kugler, Maurice. 2006. "Spillovers from Foreign Direct Investment: Within or between Industries?" Journal of Development Economics, 80(2): 444-77. Lai, Hongyi. 2006. Reform and the Non-State Economy in China: The Political Economy of Liberalization Strategies. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. 156 Lall, Sanjaya. 2000. "The Technological Structure and Performance of Developing Country Manufactured Exports, 1985-98." Oxford Development Studies, 28(3): 337-69. Lall, Sanjaya, John Weiss and Jinkang Zhang. 2006. "The "Sophistication" of Exports: A New Trade Measure." World Development, 34(2): 222-37. Lall, Somik V., Zmarak Shalizi and Uwe Deichmann. 2004. "Agglomeration Economies and Productivity in Indian Industry." American Economic Review, 73(3): 643-73. Lawlor, Michael. 2003. "Biotechnology and Government Funding." Challenge, 46(1): 15-37. Lazonick, William and Mary O'sullivan. 2000. "Maximizing Shareholder Value: A New Ideology for Corporate Governance." Economy and Society, 29(1): 13-35. Lee, Keun and Byung-Yeon Kim. 2009. "Both Institutions and Policies Matter but Differently for Different Income Groups of Countries: Determinants of Long-Run Economic Growth Revisited." World Development, 37(3): 533-49. Lenoir, Timothy, Nathan Rosenberg, Henry Rowen, Christophe Lecuyer, Jeannette Colyvas and Brent Goldfarb. 2004. "Inventing the Entrepreneurial University: Stanford and the Co-Evolution of Silicon Valley." Unpublished manuscript. Lerner, Josh. 2005. "The University and the Start-Up: Lessons from the Past Two Decades." Journal of Technology Transfer, 30(1/2): 49-56. Levin, Henry M., Dong Wook Jeong and Dongshu Ou. 2006. "What Is a World Class University?" Presented at the 2006 Conference of the Comparative & International Education Society in Honolulu, HI on 03/16/2006. Li, Po Chien and Bou Wen Lin. 2006. "Building Global Logistics Competence with Chinese Oem Suppliers." Technology in Society, 28(3): 333-48. Liang, Feng. 2008. "Does Foreign Direct Investment Improve the Productivity of Domestic Firms? Technology Spillovers, Industry Linkages, and Firm Capabilities." Haas School of Business. University of California,: Berkeley, CA. Lin, Justin Yifu, Fang Cai and Zhou Li. 2003. The Chinese Miracle: Development Strategy and Economic Reform (Revised Edition). Hong Kong: Chinese University Press. Linden, Greg, Jason Dedrick and Kenneth L. Kraemer. 2009. "Innovation and Job Creation in a Global Economy: The Case of Apple's iPod." processed. University of California, Irvine: Irvine, CA. Liu, Nian Cai. 2007. "Research Universities in China: Differentiation,, Classification, and Future World-Class Status," In P. G. Altbach and J. Bal n (eds.), World Class Worldwide: Transforming Research Universities in Asia and Latin America. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 54-69. Liu, Wan-Chun and Chen-Min Hsu. 2006. "The Role of Financial Development in Economic Growth: The Experiences of Taiwan, Korea, and Japan." Journal of Asian Economics, 17(4): 667-90. Lu, Hanchao. 2004. "Shanghai Rising: Resurgence of China's New York City?," In A. Chen, G. G. Liu and K. H. Zhang (eds.), Urban Transformation in China. Burlington, VT: Ashgate, 250-65. Lu, Jiangyong and Zhigang Tao. 2009. "Trends and Determinants of China's Industrial Agglomeration." Journal of Urban Economics, 65(2): 167-80. 157 Lundvall, Bengt-Ake. 2007. "Higher Education, Innovation and Economic Development." Presented at the World Bank's Regional Bank Conference on Development Economies in Beijing, China on 2007///. Luthra, Shashank, Ramesh Mangaleswaran and Asutosh Padhi. 2005. "What to Make India a Manufacturing Base." McKinsey Quarterly, 2005(Special Edition): 62-73. Lynch, Lisa M. 2007. "Organizational Innovation and Us Productivity." VOX. Macfarquhar, Roderick and John K. Fairbank. 1987. The Cambridge History of China, Vol. 14: The People's Republic, Part 1: The Emergence of Revolutionary China, 1949-1965. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Magtibay-Ramos, Nedelyn, Gemma Estrada and Jesus Felipe. 2008. "An Input-out Analysis of the Philippine Bpo Industry." Asian-Pacific Economic Literature, 22(1): 41-56. Maine, Elicia and Elizabeth Garnsey. 2005. "Commercializing Generic Technology: The Case of Advanced Materials Ventures." Centre for Technology Management 2004/04. University of Cambridge: Cambridge, UK. Markusen, Ann and Vickie Gwiasda. 1994. "Multi-Polarity and the Layering of Functions in World Cities: New York City's Struggle to Stay on Top." The Inaternational Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 18(2): 167-93. Martin, Philippe, Thierry Mayer and Florian Mayneris. 2008. "Spatial Concentration and Firm-Level Productivity in France." CEPR Discussion Paper 6858. Centre for Economic Policy Research: London. Mayer, Thierry and Gianmarco Ottaviano. 2008. "The Happy Few: The Internationalisation of European Firms." Intereconomics, 43(3): 135-48. "Medicine Goes Digital." 2009. The Economist, 04/16/2009. Mehra, Salil K. and Yanbei Meng. 2008. "Against Antitrust Functionalism: Reconsidering China's Antimonopoly Law." Virginia Journal of International Law, 49(2). Melo, Patricia C., Daniel J. Graham and Robert B. Noland. 2009. "A Meta-Analysis of Estimates of Urban Agglomeration Economies." Regional Science and Urban Economics, 39(3): 332-42. Meyer, Marshall W. and Xiaohui Liu. 2004. "Managing Indefinite Boundaries: The Strategy and Structure of a Chinese Business Firm." Management and Organization Review, 1(1): 57-86. Miner, Anne S., Dale T. Eesley, Michael Devaughn and Thekla Rura-Polley. 2001. "The Magic Beanstalk Vision: Commercializing University Inventions and Research," In C. B. Schoonhoven and E. Romanelli (eds.), The Entrepreneurship Dynamic: Origins of Entrepreneurship and the Evolution of Industries. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press, 109-46. Muller, Claudia and Rolf Sternberg. 2008. "China's Return Migrants and Its Innovative Capacity," In H. S. Rowen, M. G. Hancock and W. F. Miller (eds.), Greater China's Quest for Innovation. Stanford, CA: Walter H. Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center. Murphy, Kevin M., Andrei Schleifer and Robert W. Vishny. 1989. "Increasing Returns, Durables and Economic Fluctuations." NBER Working Papers 3014. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. 158 Nabeshima, Kaoru. 2004. "Technology Transfer in East Asia: A Survey," In S. Yusuf, M. A. Altaf and K. Nabeshima (eds.), Global Production Networking and Technological Change in East Asia. New York: Oxford University Press, 395- 434. Naughton, Barry. 2007. The Chinese Economy: Transitions and Growth. Cambridge, Mass.; London, England: MIT Press. New York City Government. 2009. "About NYC Zoning." New York City Government. http://www.nyc.gov/html/dcp/html/zone/zonehis.shtml. Nicolini, Marcella and Laura Resmini. 2007. "Productivity Spillovers and Multinational Enterprises: In Search of a Spatial Dimension." DYNREG Working Paper 10. Economic and Social Research Institute: Dublin. Nolan, Peter, Jin Zhang and Chunhang Liu. 2008. "The Global Business Revolution, the Cascade Effect, and the Challenge for Firms from Developing Countries." Cambridge Journal of Economics, 32(1): 29-47. Nordhaus, William D. 2008. "Baumol's Diseases: A Macroeconomic Perspective." 8(1 (Contributions)): 1-37. Obstfeld, Maurice and Alan M. Taylor. 2003. "Globalization and Capital Markets," In M. D. Bordo, A. M. Taylor and J. G. Williamson (eds.), Globalization in Historical Perspective. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 121-83. O'flaherty, Brendan. 2005. City Economics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Oliner, Stephen D. and Daniel E. Sichel. 2000. "The Resurgence of Growth in the Late 1990s: Is Information Technology the Story?" Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4): 3-22. Orhangazi, Ozgur. 2008. "Financialisation and Capital Accumulation in the Non- Financial Corporate Sector:: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation on the Us Economy: 1973-2003." Cambridge Journal of Economics, 32(6): 863-86. Overman, Henry G. and Anthony J. Venables. 2005. "Cities in the Developing World." CEPR Discussion Paper 0695. Centre for Economic Policy Research: London. Parker, Simon. 2007. "Interview: Ken Livingstone." Prospect Magazine, (133). Patten, Lord. 2006. "Europe Pays the Price for Spending Less." Nature, 441(7094): 691- 93. Peri, Giovanni and Dieter Urban. 2006. "Catching-up to Foreign Technology? Evidence on the "Veblen-Gerschenkron" Effect of Foreign Investments." 36(1): 72-98. Perkins, Dwight H. and Shahid Yusuf. 1984. Rural Development in China. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Press. Phillips, Fred. 2008. "Change in Socio-Technical Systems: Researching the Multis, the Biggers, and the More Connecteds." Technological Forecasting & Social Change, 75(5): 721-34. Pietrobelli, Carlo and Federica Saliola. 2008. "Power Relationships Along the Value Chain: Multinational Firms, Global Buyers and Performance of Local Suppliers." Cambridge Journal of Economics, 32(6): 947-62. Pilkington, Alan, Linda L. Lee, Casey K. Chan and Seeram Ramakrishna. 2009. "Defining Key Inventors: A Comparison of Fuel Cell and Nanotechnology Industries." Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 76(1): 118-27. Pisano, Gary P. 2006. "Can Science Be a Business? Lessons from Biotech." Harvard Business Review, (October): 114-25. 159 Popp, David, Richard G. Newell and Adam B. Jaffe. 2009. "Energy, the Environment, and Technological Change." NBER Working Paper 14832. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Porter, Michael E. 2008. "The Five Competitive Forces That Shape Strategy." Harvard Business Review 1. Porter, Michael E. and Elizabeth Olmsted Teisberg. 2006. Redefining Health Care: Creating Value-Based Competition on Results. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Prahalad, C.K. and M.S. Krishnan. 2008. The New Age of Innovation: Driving Cocreated Value through Global Networks. McGraw-Hill. Pricewaterhousecoopers. 2007. "Largest City Economies in the World in 2005 and 2020." Puri, Manju and Rebecca Zarutskie. 2008. "On the Lifecycle Dynamics of Venture- Capital- and Non-Venture-Capital-Financed Firms." NBER Working Paper 14250. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Quigley, John M. 2008. "Urbanization, Agglomeration, and Economic Development." Commission on Growth and Development Working Paper Series 19. World Bank: Washington, DC. Quintas, Maria A., Xose, H. Vazquez, Jose, M. Garcia and Gloria Caballero. 2008. "Geographical Amplitude in the International Generation of Technology: Present Situation and Business Determinants." Research Policy, 37(8): 1371-81. "R&D Spending Holds Steady in Slump." 2009. The Wall Street Journal, 04/06/2009. Rauch, James E. and Vitor Trindade. 2002. "Ethnic Chinese Networks in International Trade." Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(1): 116-30. Reader, John. 2006. Cities. New York: Grove Press. "Regulator Rolls out Norms for GEB." 2009. China Daily, 04/01/2009. Rigby, Darrell and Chris Zook. 2002. "Open-Market Innovation." Harvard Business Review, 80(10): 80-89. Romer, Paul. 1993. "Ideas Gaps and Object Gaps in Economic Development." Journal of Monetary Economics, 32(3): 543-73. Rongping, Mu and Qu Wan. 2008. "The Development of Science and Technology in China: A Comparison with India and the United States." Technology in Society, 30(3-4): 319-29. Rosenberg, Nathan. 2003. "America's Entrepreneurial Universities," In D. Hart (ed.) The Emergence of Entrepreneurship Policy: Governance, Start-Ups, and Growth in the U.S. Knowledge Economy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Rosenstein-Rodan, P.N. 1943. "Problems of Industrialization of Eastern and South- Eastern Europe." The Economic Journal, 53(210/211): 202-11. Rosenthal, Stuart S. and William C. Strange. 2004. "Evidence on the Nature and Sources of Agglomeration Economics," In J. V. Henderson and J.-F. Thisse (eds.), Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics. North Holland, 2119-71. ____. 2008. "Small Establishments/Big Effects: Agglomeration, Industrial Organization and Entrepreneurship," In E. Glaeser (ed.) The Economics of Agglomeration. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Runiewicz-Wardyn, Malgorzata. 2008. Knowledge-Based Economy: As Factor of Competitiveness and Economic Growth. Warsaw: Academic and Professional Press. 160 Saggi, Kamal. 2006. "Foreign Direct Investment, Linkages, and Technology Spillovers," In B. Hoekman and B. S. Javorcik (eds.), Global Integration & Technology Transfer. Washington, DC: World Bank, 51-65. Sakakibara, Mariko. 1997. "Evaluating Government-Sponsored R&D Consortia in Japan: Who Benefits and How?" Research Policy, 26(4-5): 447-73. ____. 2001. "Cooperative Research and Development: Who Participates and in Which Industries Do Projects Take Place?" Research Policy, 30(7): 993-1018. Sakakibara, Mariko and Dong-Sung Cho. 2002. "Cooperative R&D in Japan and Korea: A Comparison of Industrial Policy." Research Policy, 31(5): 673-92. Salmi, Jamil. 2009. The Challenges of Establishing World-Class Universities. Washington, DC: World Bank. Sassen, Saskia. 1991. The Global City: New York, London, Tokyo. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Schaede, Ulrike. 2008. Choose and Focus: Japanese Business Strategies for the 21st Century. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Schoors, Koen and Bartoldus Van Der Tol. 2002. "Foreign Direct Investment Spillovers within and between Sectors: Evidence from Hungarian Data." Department of Economics Working Paper, 157. Ghent University, Belgium. Schott, Peter K. 2006. "The Relative Sophistication of Chinese Exports." NBER Working Paper 12173. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Scott, Allen J. 2001a. Global City Regions. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. ____. 2001b. "Globalization and the Rise of City-Regions." European Planning Studies, 9(7): 813-26. Sener, Fuat and Laixun Zhao. 2009. "Globalization, R&D and the iPod Cycle." Journal of International Economics, 77(1): 101-08. Shanghai Stock Exchange. 2007. "Shanghai Stock Exchange." Shanghai Venture Capital Association. 2008. Shanghai Venture Capital Industry Investigation Report, 2007. Shanghai: Shanghai Venture Capital Association. "Shanghigh." 2009. Financial Times, 04/03/2009. Sigurdson, Jon. 2005. Technological Superpower China. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing. Simon, Denis Fred and Cong Cao. 2008. "China's Emerging Science and Technology Talent Pool: A Quantitative and Qualitative Assessment," In H. S. Rowen, M. G. Hancock and W. F. Miller (eds.), Greater China's Quest for Innovation. Stanford, CA: Walter H. Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center. Smeets, Roger. 2008. "Collecting the Pieces of the FDI Knowledge Spillovers Puzzle." The World Bank Research Observer, 23(2): 107-38. Smilor, Raymond, Niall O'donnell, Gregory Stein and Robert Welborn. 2005. "The Research University and the Development of High Technology Centers in the U.S." Presented at the Conference on University Industry Linkages in Metropolitan Areas in Asia in Washington, DC on 11/17. Smitka, Michael J. 1991. Subcontracting in the Japanese Automobile Industry. New York: Columbia University Press. Spear, Steven. 2008. Chasing the Rabbit: How Market Leaders Outdistance the Competition and How Great Companies Can Catch up and Win. New York: McGraw-Hill. 161 Squicciarini, Mariagrazia. 2008. "Science Parks' Tenants Versus out-of-Park Firms: Who Innovates More? A Duration Model." The Journal of Technology Transfer, 33(1): 45-71. Stewart, Thomas A. and Anand P. Raman. 2007. "Lessons from Toyota's Long Drive." Harvard Business Review, 85(7/8): 74-83. Sturgeon, Timothy J., Johannes Van Biesebroeck and Gary Gereffi. 2008. "Value Chains, Network and Clusters: Reframing the Global Automotive Industry." Journal of Economic Geography, 8(3): 297-321. Sun, Yifei, Debin Du and Li Huang. 2006. "Foreign R&D in Developing Countries: Empirical Evidence from Shanghai, China." The China Review, 6(1): 67-91. Tarun, Khanna and G.Palepu Krishna. 2006. "Emerging Giants. (Cover Story)." Harvard Business Review, 84(10): 60-69. "The Biggest Bang for the Buck." 2008. BusinessWeek, 09/22. "The World's Most Innovative Companies." 2006. BusinessWeek, 04/24. Tobin, James. 1965. "Money and Economic Growth." Econometrica, 33(4): 671-84. Tuan, Chyau and Linda Fung-Yee Ng. 2007. "The Place of FDI in China's Regional Economic Development: Emergence of the Globalized Delta Economies." Journal of Asian Economics, 18(2): 348-64. Un-Habitat. 2008. State of the World Cities 2008/2009: Harmonious Cities. London: UN- HABITAT. "Urban Competitiveness." 2008. The Economist, 08/16. Van Der Sluis, Justin, Mirjam Van Praag and Wim Vijverberg. 2008. "Education and Entrepreneurship Selection and Performance: A Review of the Empirical Literature." 22(5): 795-841. Venables, A.J. and Patricia Rice. 2005. "Spatial Determinants of Productivity: Analysis for the Regions of Great Britain." CEPR Discussion Paper Centre for Economic Policy Research: London. Vernon, Raymond. 1979. "The Product Cycle Hypothesis in a New International Environment." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 41(4): 255-67. Veugelers, Reinhilde. 2009. "A Lifeline for Europe's Young Radical Innovators." Bruegel Policy Brief. http://www.bruegel.org/Public/fileDownload.php?target=/Files/media/PDF/ Publications/Policy%20Briefs/pb-2009-01-YICs.pdf. Wadhwa, Vivek, Gary Gereffi, Ben Rising and Ryan Ong. 2007. "Where the Engineers Are." Issues in Science and Technology, Spring. Wei, Shang-Jin. 1993. "Open Door Policy and China's Rapid Growth: Evidence from City-Level Data." NBER Working Paper 4602. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Wei, Y. and X. Liu. 2006. "Productivity Spillovers from R&D, Exports and FDI in China's Manufacturing Sector." Journal of International Business Studies, 37(4): 544-57. Wei, Yingqi, Xiaming Liu and Chengang Wang. 2008. "Mutual Productivity Spillovers between Foreign and Local Firms in China." Cambridge Journal of Economics, 32(4): 609-31. "Where Winners Are Fast Rather Than Large." 2007. Financial Times, 03/27. 162 Wieser, Robert. 2005. "Research and Development Productivity and Spillovers: Empirical Evidence at the Firm Level." 19: 593-96. Williamson, Peter and Ming Zeng. 2009. "Value-for-Money Strategies for Recessionary Times." Harvard Business Review, (March): 66-74. "Wind Down the Market in Five-Legged Dogs." 2009. Financial Times, 01/21. World Bank. 2008a. Accelerating Catch-Up: Tertiary Education for Growth in SSA. Washington, DC: World Bank. ____. 2008b. "Mid-Term Evaluation of China's 11th Five Year Plan." World Bank: Washington, DC. ____. 2008c. "Quarterly Update: December 2008." World Bank: World Bank Beijing Office. ____. 2009a. "China: Reducing Inequality and Promoting Lagging Region Development in Guangdong." processed. World Bank: Washington, DC. ____. 2009b. "Restructuring of Research and Development Institutes in Europe and Central Asia." processed. World Bank: Washington, DC. ____. 2009c. World Development Report 2009: Reshaping Economic Geography. Washington, DC: World Bank. "The World's Most Admired Companies." 2009. Fortune, 3/16/2009. WTO. 2009. "WTO Sees 9% Global Trade Decline in 2009 as Recession Strikes." Press Release 554. Geneva. Wu, Weiping. 2007. "Cultivating Research Universities and Industrial Linkages: The Case of Shanghai." World Development, 35(6): 1075-93. Xin, Hao and Dennis Normile. 2008. "Gunning for the Ivy League." Science, 319(5860): 148-51. Xin, Hao and Richard Stone. 2008. "Q&A: China's Scientist Premier." Science, 322(5900): 362-64. Xu, Ang. 2008. "China Looks Abroad: Changing Directions in International Science." Minerva, 46(1): 37-51. Yang, Chih-Hai, Kazuyuki Motohashi and Jong-Rong Chen. 2009. "Are New Technology-Based Firms Located on Science Parks Really More Innovative?: Evidence from Taiwan." Research Policy, 38(1): 77-85. Yao, Yao and Yuemin Ning. 2008. "An Analysis of the Developing Level and Spatial Differences of Manufacturing in the Yangtze River Delta." E-Journal of China Urban Studies, 3(2): 57-64. Yusuf, Shahid. 2007. "Promise and Peril: Regional Development in China's Pearl River Delta and the Northeast," In A. J. Scott and G. Garofoli (eds.), Development on the Ground: Clusters, Networks and Regions in Emerging Economies. New York, NY: Routledge. ____. 2009a. Development Economics through the Decades: A Critical Look at 30 Years of the World Development Report. Washington, DC: World Bank. ____. 2009b. "From Creativity to Innovation." Technology in Society, 31(1): 1-8. Yusuf, Shahid, M.Anjum Altaf, Barry Eichengreen, Sudarshan Gooptu, Kaoru Nabeshima, Charles Kenny, Dwight H. Perkins and Marc Shotten. 2003. Innovative East Asia: The Future of Growth. New York: Oxford University Press. Yusuf, Shahid and Kaoru Nabeshima. 2007. How Universities Promote Economic Growth. Washington D.C.: World Bank. 163 Yusuf, Shahid, Kaoru Nabeshima and Dwight H. Perkins. 2005. Under New Ownership: Privatizing China's State-Owned Enterprises. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. ____. 2007. "China and India Reshape Global Industrial Geography," In L. A. Winters and S. Yusuf (eds.), Dancing with Giants: China, India, and the Global Economy. Washington, DC: World Bank. Yusuf, Shahid, Shuilin Wang and Kaoru Nabeshima. 2009. "Fiscal Policies for Innovation," In Q. Fan, K. Li, D. Z. Zeng, Y. Dong and R. Peng (eds.), Innovation for Development and the Role of Government: A Perspective from the East Asia and Pacific Region. Washington, DC: World Bank, 149-80. Zeng, Ming and Peter Williamson. 2007. Dragons at Your Door. Harvard Business School Press. Zhang, Chunlin. 2008. "China: Promoting Enterprise-Led Innovation." processed. World Bank: Beijing. Zheng, Jinghai, Arne Bigsten and Angang Hu. 2009. "Can China's Growth Be Sustained? A Productivity Perspective." World Development, 37(4): 874-88. Zheng, Siqi, Matthew E. Kahn and Hongyu Liu. 2009. "Towards a System of Open Cities in China: Home Prices, FDI Flows and Air Quality in 35 Major Cities." NBER Working Paper 14751. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Zhou, Yu. 2008. The inside Story of China's High-Tech Industry: Making Silicon Valley in Beijing. New York: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers. Zucker, Lynne G. and Michael R. Darby. 2007. "Star Scientists, Innovation and Regional and National Immigration." NBER Working Paper 13547. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. wb231476 C:\Users\wb231476\Desktop\Shanghai report\Shanghai final full report June 15 2009.doc 8/31/2009 3:05:00 PM 164