Skip to Main Navigation

Engendering macroeconomic theory and policy (English)

Over the last 20 years, macroeconomists have increasingly given attention to the role of gender in the macroeconomy and the implications of macro-level policies for gender equality. This paper reviews the salient findings of that literature. Research shows that gender gaps in education, health, unpaid labor, employment, and wages affect the macroeconomy, influencing the rate of per capita GDP growth. The effects are transmitted via both the supply side of the economy, principally through labor productivity, and the demand side, through business spending, exports, saving, and the balance of payments. Theoretical perspectives influence which gender gaps are incorporated into models as well as how. For example, heterodox economists emphasize the demand and supply side in the short and long run, while neoclassical economists tend to focus on long-run supply-side effects. There is widespread agreement in the literature that greater gender equality in education and employment (proxied by labor force participation rates) stimulates long-run per capita growth. Improving women’s relative productivity through educational investments and facilitating their participation in paid labor serves several purposes. For example, assuming talent is equally distributed across men and women, a narrowing of gender gaps in education and employment contributes to higher average educational attainment and a more efficient allocation of labor. As educational attainment rises and women gain greater access to paid work, the opportunity cost of having additional children also rises, leading to a decline in fertility rates. Women’s bargaining power within the household rises at the same time. This increases their ability to allocate household spending in ways that benefit children, and as a result, economy-wide labor productivity growth. The weak link in this chain is that aggregate demand may be insufficient to absorb an increase in women’s relative labor supply. Demand-stimulating policies as well as other policy measures may be necessary to ensure women’s relative employment rate rises. Full employment policies can help to narrow the employment gap and well-targeted physical and social infrastructure investments have been found to promote women’s access to paid work. Finally, traditional monetary policy—that is, the use of interest rates to manage demand and by extension, inflation, has gender-related employment effects, and exchange rate policy also influences the gender wage gap. This area of policymaking has received much less attention than fiscal policy as a tool for promoting gender equality. The paper concludes with a discussion of areas for future research.

Details

  • Author

    Seguino,Stephanie

  • Document Date

    2017/11/01

  • Document Type

    Working Paper

  • Report Number

    121781

  • Volume No

    1

  • Total Volume(s)

    1

  • Country

    World,

  • Region

    The World Region,

  • Disclosure Date

    2017/11/30

  • Disclosure Status

    Disclosed

  • Doc Name

    Engendering macroeconomic theory and policy

  • Keywords

    Gender Equality;female labor force participation rates;gender equality in education;gender gap in education;gender division of labor;Gender Inequality;gender inequalities;effects of gender;gender wage gap;balance of payment;impact on gender equality;marginal propensity to save;gender equality in access;balance of payment crisis;research need;secondary school enrollment ratio;gender disparity in education;gender gap in access;marginal propensity to import;gender difference;bargaining power;aggregate demand;labor productivity;Macroeconomic Policy;structure of production;role of gender;exchange rate policy;Exchange rate policies;full employment policy;labor market deregulation;gender and growth;female labor supply;Educational Equality;human capital;negative effect;labor market distortion;quality of work;Labor market rigidities;labor market rigidity;working age population;education and health;trade and investment;labor productivity growth;household income inequality;allocation of labor;industrial sector;wage discrimination;maternal mortality rate;real exchange rate;access to infrastructure;foreign direct investment;human capital accumulation;public sector budget;development of skill;adolescent fertility rate;demand for import;unit labor costs;lower fertility rate;labor market discrimination;Early childhood education;cash crop production;labor market participation;safe working conditions;opportunity for woman;Type of Investment;cost of labor;short time span;constraints to growth;care of child;household resource allocation;enforcement of law;allocation of income;formal sector employment;study on gender;lack of sex;factor of production;forms of compensation;asian financial crisis;measure of inequality;general equilibrium model;demand management policy;access to job;share of income;structural adjustment policies;rate of growth;department of economics;promoting gender equality;decline in fertility;average educational attainment;privileges and immunity;secondary enrollment rate;output per worker;gdp growth rate;level of consumption;forms of gender;competitive labor market;impact on fertility;Access to Education;Labor Market Flexibility;differentials between women;neoclassical growth model;saving rate;employment gap;future research;Fiscal policies;fiscal policy;labor demand;gender relation;educational gap;opportunity cost;wage inequality;supply side;macro model;unpaid work;export demand;export sector;employment rate;social infrastructure;neoclassical model;theoretical model;food production;informal sector;job opportunities;macroeconomic model;selection bias;male worker;job opportunity;explanatory variable;macro policies;macro policy;gender discrimination;employment equality;employment data;neoclassical economist;wage data;gender dimension;monetary policy;gender impact;research show;formal employment;dependency ratio;transmission mechanism;differential impact;male wage;household structure;panel data;allocation problem;tradable good;job loss;composite measure;positive impact;subsistence agriculture;female education;neoclassical approach;gender education;employment growth;output growth;high fertility;Job Creation;physical infrastructure;capital stock;instrumental variable;household bargaining;empirical study;human capacity;net effect;child rearing;aggregate savings;agricultural economy;flow variable;export industry;occupational segregation;demand-side effects;household allocation;macroeconomic equilibrium;job security;fiscal consolidation;gender norm;educational effect;investment increase;cognitive development;high share;child rise;estimation method;theoretic model;female employment;social insurance;fertility decline;empirical work;longer life;cross-country study;manufactured goods;world market;living wage;agricultural resource;upward mobility;savings propensity;future labor;composite index;government spending;multiple dimension;cyclical factor;low-income woman;open economy;parliamentary seats;Talent Pools;innovation potential

Downloads

COMPLETE REPORT

Official version of document (may contain signatures, etc)

Citation

Seguino,Stephanie

Engendering macroeconomic theory and policy (English). Washington, D.C. : World Bank Group. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/275461512048851974/Engendering-macroeconomic-theory-and-policy