Skip to Main Navigation

Macroeconomic policy and trade liberalization : some guidelines (English)

Appropriate conduct of macroeconomic policy can play a crucial role in the success of trade liberalization. At a given nominal exchange rate, a trade liberalization that significantly reduces tariffs and quantitative restrictions on imports normally implies a reduction in the general level of domestic prices and wages, especially in the import competing sector. To diminish recessionary effects of domestic price and wage deflation, it is often appropriate to devaluate a country's currency in conjunction with a major trade liberalization. Monetary policy needs to be consistent with exchange rate policy, avoiding both restrictiveness that might induce recession and excessive ease that would fuel inflation and force future devaluations. Since trade liberalization can induce a short-run deterioration of the government's budget position, fiscal policy needs to remain restrained in order to limit the dangers posed by large government deficits. Wage policy should be directed toward facilitating adjustments in relative wage rates and credit policy should assume that adequate credit is available to finance expansion. Finally, government policy should avoid large balance of payments deficits.

Details

  • Author

    Mussa, Michael

  • Document Date

    1987/01/31

  • Document Type

    Journal Article

  • Report Number

    14119

  • Volume No

    1

  • Total Volume(s)

    1

  • Disclosure Date

    2001/04/27

  • Doc Name

    Macroeconomic policy and trade liberalization : some guidelines

  • Keywords

    nominal exchange rate;balance of payment;Exchange Rates;high levels of protection;high real interest rate;domestic price;history of exchange rate;Operational Core Curriculum;Monetary and Credit Policies;real exchange rate;real wage;expansion of export;exchange rate policy;Exchange rate policies;effect of trade;monetary policy;Foreign Exchange Reserve;allocation of resource;Macroeconomic Policy;exchange rate depreciation;cost of capital;general price inflation;private sector worker;nominal interest rate;allocation of credit;terms of trade;liberal trade policy;real wage rate;general price level;decline in revenue;department of economics;domestic banking system;fiscal policy;Fiscal policies;poor macroeconomic policy;consumer price index;price of imports;financing budget deficits;domestic price level;trade policy research;reallocation of resource;open economy macroeconomics;exchange rate regime;diversion of credit;effect of tariff;international trade theory;domestic financial institution;implicit export taxes;rates of protection;costs of inflation;exchange rate devaluation;future tax revenue;success and failure;fixed exchange rate;future tax liability;liberalization of control;demand for import;loss of revenue;benefits of trade;monetary approach;import substitute;relative price;nontraded good;commercial policy;domestic money;rapid inflation;wage policy;protected activity;government revenue;freer trade;financial system;domestic credit;nominal price;government deficit;international finance;financial reform;factor price;credit policy;fiscal position;foreign reserve;money demand;tradable good;nominal tariff;Trade Policies;protectionist policy;private enterprise;supply elasticity;liberalizing trade;international economics;liberalized trade;international borrowing;economic liberalization;export incentive;high unemployment;export industry;financial market;economic efficiency;nontradable goods;ad valorem;Wage Subsidies;political pressure;alternative use;wage subsidy;financial difficulties;real rate;credit problem;foreign borrowing;import quota;economic welfare;social opportunities;real capital;import tariff;price stability;increasing exports;international lender;perceived likelihood;minimum wage;deflationary effect;government regulation;government worker;significant loss;protected industry;tariff reduction;fiscal deficit;business failure;debt contract;standard model;total trade;tariff equivalent;wage adjustment;fiscal benefit;distressed workers;government budget;permanent loss;production structure;money balance;political power;import control;budget share;competitive behavior;domestic seller;import product;government enterprise;import price;domestic resident;structural adjustment;liberal policies;private entrepreneur;real cost;credit market;domestic product;domestic service;Fiscal Expansion;adjustment process;commercial credit;political equilibrium;liberalization process;social loss;aggregate output;money illusion;massive increase;domestic inflation;real income;equilibrium level;domestic output;full employment;reasonable assumption;social marginal;adjustment assistance;government supervision;domestic good;restrictive trade;import good;policy prescriptions;price rise;world economic;Macroeconomic Management;competitive imports;political force;wage increase;adequate supply;credible commitment;indirect access;private borrower;private investment;government's capacity;adverse consequence;export revenue;government borrowing;finance budget;working capital;world price;protection rate;nominal rate;world economy;market power;profit margin;financial problem;world trade;financial resource;world market;traded goods;domestic demand;macroeconomic reform;fixed investment;nominal wage;financial control;subsidized credit;resource cost;export activity;reducing protection;lending practice;effective tax;savings need;inflation rate;asset market;bankruptcy process;financial policies;efficiency gain;crawling peg;tariff cut;upward pressure;domestic spending

Downloads

COMPLETE REPORT

Official version of document (may contain signatures, etc)

  • TXT*
  • Total Downloads** :
  • Download Stats
  • *The text version is uncorrected OCR text and is included solely to benefit users with slow connectivity.

Citation

Mussa, Michael

Macroeconomic policy and trade liberalization : some guidelines (English). Washington, D.C. : World Bank Group. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/339271468740211717/Macroeconomic-policy-and-trade-liberalization-some-guidelines